You are on page 1of 26

BANK COMPETITION AND FINANCIAL STABILITY: LIQUIDITY RISK

PERSPECTIVE

JEONGSIM KIM∗

We study whether competition affects banks’ liquidity risk-taking, which was at the
heart of the 2008 financial crisis. We find that banks with greater market power take
more liquidity risk, implying that decreased competition leads to financial fragility.
During a financial crisis, however, the effect of market power on liquidity risk varies
across bank size. Small banks with greater market power reduce liquidity risk while large
banks with greater market power do not change their liquidity risk-taking behavior. This
suggests that enhanced charter values due to reduced competition lowers small banks’
risk-shifting incentives when their default risk significantly increases during a crisis.
(JEL G21, G28)

I. INTRODUCTION questions. First, does competition affect banks’


liquidity risk-taking behavior? There are two
Although the effect of bank competition on conflicting hypotheses. On the one hand, compe-
financial stability has long been a subject of tition contributes to lower liquidity risk because
interest to both researchers and policy makers, banks with greater market power take on more
the 2008 global financial crisis reminds us that liquidity risk by granting more loans and reduc-
more research is needed on this issue. Exten- ing liquid reserves (Carletti and Leonello 2014;
sive previous studies have focused on the impact Petersen and Rajan 1995). Strengthened market
of competition on bank risk-taking in the form power increases opportunity costs of holding
of credit or default risk. Not much attention has liquid assets as loans become more profitable.
been paid to the role of competition in liquidity
On the other hand, competition leads to higher
risk-taking,1 despite its central part in the devel-
liquidity risk because competition destroys a
opment of the unprecedented crisis. A number
bank’s charter value and thus compels it to take
of banks failed during the crisis because they
on more liquidity risk. Keeley (1990) shows that
were engaged in excessive liquidity risk-taking
competition encourages banks to take excessive
(Acharya and Naqvi 2012; Brunnermeier and
risk by reducing their capital buffers and creating
Oehmke 2013; Farhi and Tirole 2012).
risk-shifting incentives.
This paper attempts to fill this gap in the
literature by exploring the following three
ABBREVIATIONS
∗ Thiswork was supported by the National Research 2SLS: Two-Stage Least Squares
Foundation of Korea Grant funded by the Korean Government FE: Fixed Effects Model
(NRF-2014S1A5B8060964). GDP: Gross Domestic Product
Kim: Research Professor, College of Economics, GMM: Generalized Method of Moments
Sungkyunkwan University, 25-2, Sungkyunkwan-ro,
Jongno-gu, Seoul 03063, Korea. Phone +82-2-760-0825, HHI: Herfindahl–Hirschman Index
Fax +82-2-760-0950, E-mail js.kim@skku.edu IFS: International Financial Statistics
IMF: International Monetary Fund
IV: Instrumental Variables
1. In this paper, we focus on funding liquidity risk, which M&A: Mergers and Acquisitions
is the risk where a bank has difficulty in meeting creditors’ (or
OECD: Organization for Economic Co-operation and
borrowers’) demands for their money (Allen and Gale 2004;
Bryant 1980; Diamond and Dybvig 1983; Diamond and Rajan Development
2001). Funding liquidity risk arises from a bank’s inability to TBTF: Too-Big-to-Fail
liquidate assets promptly or obtain sufficient funds to settle TOC: Total Operating Costs
its obligations, whereas market liquidity risk is the risk in WDI: World Development Indicators
which banks are forced to sell assets at fire-sale prices due WGI: Worldwide Governance Indicators
to serious deterioration of market conditions (Brunnermeier
and Pedersen 2009). WLS: Weighted Least Squares

doi:10.1111/coep.12243
Contemporary Economic Policy (ISSN 1465-7287) © 2017 Western Economic Association International
2 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

Our next question is concerned with how From a panel dataset that was constructed for
competition affects bank liquidity risk during a 10,979 banks in 25 Organization for Economic
crisis. An understanding of the effect of competi- Co-operation and Development (OECD) coun-
tion policy during a crisis is essential to restore tries from 2000 to 2014, we find that market
financial stability as well as to prevent another power is positively associated with liquidity risk,
crisis. Particularly, stability issues and market suggesting that competition is beneficial to finan-
power concerns are acutely conflicting during cial stability. This result is robust even after con-
times of market stress. Essentially, banks suf- trolling for endogeneity concerns. During a crisis,
fer from reduced charter values during a cri- however, the effects of market power on liquid-
sis. In this situation, more intense competition ity risk are different for large and small banks:
aggravates the problem. This may lead banks the positive effect of market power on liquidity
to take higher liquidity risk due to risk shift- risk remains unchanged for large banks, whereas
ing in a more competitive market during a crisis the positive effect weakens for small banks, espe-
(Hakenes and Schnabel 2010; Jensen and Meck- cially for very small banks, in which their default
ling 1976; Stiglitz and Weiss 1981). Implicit or rate increases significantly. In other words, com-
explicit guarantees enable banks to behave pru- petition is desirable for financial stability of large
dently by reducing the risk-shifting incentives.2 banks but, in contrast, it is harmful for financial
However, public guarantees pose another prob- stability of small banks during times of financial
lem, namely that of moral hazard. They distort turbulence. These results imply that enhanced
competition and disturb the level playing field in market power during a crisis helps small banks
the banking system, as protected banks are able behave prudently to protect their increased char-
to have lower funding costs (Akins et al. 2016; ter values, whereas it makes large banks subject
Beck et al. 2010; Gropp, Hakenes, and Schnabel to moral hazard.
2011). Therefore, guaranteed banks are expected We address potential endogeneity problems
to take higher liquidity risk through increasing because market power and liquidity risk may
both lending and funding. be jointly determined. For example, a bank tak-
Our last question is concerned with how the ing higher liquidity risk—through granting more
effect of competition on banks’ liquidity risk- loans and credit lines—can gain more market
taking varies across bank size during a crisis. The power. To address the potential endogeneity, we
large and small banks have different character- perform instrumental variables (IV) regressions
istics in terms of business strategies or funding using a generalized method of moments (GMM)
structures. A more pronounced feature of large estimator. We employ entry barriers and control
banks is that they are more likely to be publicly of corruption as IV of market power.
guaranteed than small banks during a crisis (Boyd Additionally, we conduct a variety of robust-
and Gertler 1994; Hughes and Mester 2013; ness checks to ensure the validity of our results.
O’Hara and Shaw 1990; Vives 2011). Therefore, We employ the dynamic panel GMM esti-
large banks may have less incentive to behave mator to control for the dynamic relationship
prudently when their market power increases dur- between competition and bank liquidity risk as
ing the period of economic turbulence. That is, well as the panel Tobit analysis to account for
large banks with greater market power have an left-censored observations of some dependent
incentive to take more liquidity risk due to moral variables. Furthermore, we control for several
hazard. In contrast, small banks with greater mar- bank characteristics, country characteristics, and
ket power reduce liquidity risk exposure in order macroeconomic conditions, including market
to protect their enhanced charter value. To put liquidity risk, because a bank’s liquidity risk is
it differently, intense competition during a cri- affected by fluctuations in market-wide liquidity.
sis aggravates the risk-shifting problem of small Our finding that competition is beneficial for
banks, which already suffer from reduced char- financial stability in terms of bank liquidity risk
ter value due to the sluggish economy, and thus is highly robust across multiple econometric
forces them to take more liquidity risk. specifications, liquidity risk and competition
measures, and control variables.
2. In fact, numerous countries provided extensive bailout This study contributes to the previous liter-
programs during the recent crisis to stabilize the economy. ature in three ways. First, to the best of our
Northern Rock was nationalized by the British government knowledge, this is the first study to empiri-
in 2008. UBS (Switzerland), Citibank (US), and Fortis (Bel-
gium, Luxembourg, Netherlands) were also bailed out during cally investigate the relationship between com-
the crisis. petition and stability from the perspective of
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK 3

liquidity risk. Second, our study contributes to banks experienced runs by borrowers who drew
the competition-stability strand in the literature down their existing lines of credit (Cornett et al.
by further extending the scope of stability to 2011; Ivashina and Scharfstein 2010). Therefore,
include liquidity risk because previous litera- we focus on liquidity risks in the form of com-
ture has mainly focused on credit or default mitted credit lines, liquidity creation, and liquid
risk. Finally, we add to the liquidity risk lit- asset holdings.
erature by considering competition as a main Competition particularly matters in the bank-
driving force that affects a bank’s liquidity risk- ing sector because banks are inherently exposed
taking behavior. to the risk of instability and systemic financial
The remainder of the paper proceeds as crises (Claessens and Laeven 2004; Vives 2011).
follows. Section II reviews the literature and Like other industries, competition enhances effi-
develops our hypotheses. Section III describes ciency, innovation, and the quality of products.
methods of constructing measures for liquidity However, more importantly for the banking sec-
risks and market power. Section IV explains tor, the degree of competition is closely related
the data and empirical strategies. Section V to banks’ risk-taking behavior, which affects the
presents the empirical results. Section VI pro- stability of the economy. Because of the impor-
vides robustness checks. Section VII concludes tance of competition policy, there has been rich
the paper. research studying the relationship between com-
petition and financial stability (Carletti 2008;
Zigraiova and Havranek 2016). However, previ-
II. LITERATURE REVIEW ous studies provided mixed findings about the
What is liquidity risk in banking? Liquid- relationship. Some studies argue that higher com-
ity risk for a bank is the risk where a bank is petition leads to financial fragility (e.g., Keeley
unable to settle its obligations in a timely man- 1990); whereas others suggest that more com-
ner when depositors attempt to withdraw funds. petition contributes to stability (e.g., Boyd and
This liquidity risk stems from banks’ liquidity Nicoló 2005).
creation function wherein banks create liquidity The “competition-fragility” view is based on
by transforming illiquid assets into liquid demand the idea that more intense competition erodes
deposits (e.g., Diamond and Dybvig 1983). How- bank charter values, and thus decreases their
ever, this fundamental role makes banks vul- incentives to behave prudently (Hellmann, Mur-
nerable to liquidity risk because the customers’ dock, and Stiglitz 2000; Keeley 1990; Marcus
demand for funds may arise at an inconvenient 1984; Matutes and Vives 1996). According to
time, thereby making it difficult for banks to meet the charter value hypothesis, banks restrain their
its obligations by liquidating illiquid assets with risk-taking to protect monopoly rents from bank
immediacy (Allen and Gale 2004; Diamond and charters. The decrease in charter value leads
Rajan 2001). Therefore, banks hold liquid assets banks to take excessive risk because it reduces
in order to manage their liquidity risk. the penalty from bank failure. Keeley (1990)
Traditionally, bank liquidity risk was consid- finds that increased competition attributable to
ered to originate from a bank’s role as a liq- deregulation in the 1980s reduces bank capi-
uidity creator in relation to demand deposits. In tal buffers and thus increases the probability
recent years, however, liquidity risk from demand of default. Repullo (2004) shows that greater
deposits has not been severe because deposits market power reduces banks’ gambling incen-
are protected by insurance in most countries.3 tives. Using data on 69 countries from 1980
Recent studies pay attention to liquidity risk to 1997, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine
that stems from committed credit lines (Holm- (2006) find that banking crises are less likely
ström and Tirole 1998; Kashyap, Rajan, and to occur in economies with more concentrated
Stein 2002). A line of credit gives a borrower banking systems.
an option to draw down funds at any time dur- The “competition-stability” view, however,
ing the period of the contract. That is, credit challenges the conventional view. Boyd and
lines also leave banks fragile to liquidity risk. Nicoló (2005) show that more market power
After the failure of Lehman Brothers in 2008, results in higher loan rates, which lead borrowers
to choose more risky investments. Consequently,
3. In fact, deposits rather flow into banks to search for this results in higher risk of bank failures.
safe havens during a crisis (Acharya and Mora 2015; Gatev, Boyd, Nicoló, and Jalal (2007) and Nicoló
Schuermann and Strahan 2009; Gatev and Strahan 2006). and Loukoianova (2007) provide an empirical
4 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

evidence that banks are more likely to take III. MEASUREMENTS OF LIQUIDITY RISKS AND
greater risk in a less competitive banking system. COMPETITION
Carletti and Leonello (2014) argue that competi- A. Liquidity Risk Measures
tion enhances stability in terms of bank liquidity
risk. Greater market power increases opportunity A growing literature has tried to develop con-
costs of holding liquid assets as loans become crete liquidity risk measures, in response to the
more profitable, which lead banks to take more growing interest in liquidity risk in the aftermath
liquidity risk. of the recent financial crisis. However, there is
Is competition desirable or detrimental to still a lack of consensus on the empirical mea-
stability during crises? In times of financial sure for liquidity risk (Drehmann and Nikolaou
turmoil, the trade-off between market power 2013; Soula 2015). In the past, liquidity risk
concerns and stability considerations become measures mostly focused on the use of liquid-
particularly acute. Some studies argue that ity ratios—such as the share of liquid (illiquid)
competition should not be suppressed due to assets in total assets—based on the bank bal-
the positive impact of a crisis on the economy ance sheet data (e.g., Molyneux and Thornton
through its disciplinary role, while others argue 1992). For instance, more cash and other liq-
that protecting the system by avoiding conta- uid assets as a buffer make banks less vulner-
gion of bank failure dominates market power able to liquidity risk. Similarly, more illiquid
concerns during times of market stress (Vives assets, which are difficult to liquidate promptly
2011). During a crisis, competition may place a during a crisis, expose banks to greater liquid-
higher burden on banks through its destruction ity risk. Although the liquidity of assets is not
of monopoly rents. a direct measure of liquidity risk, these liquid-
Governments provide various guarantee pro- ity ratios are widely used as proxies for liquidity
grams in order to prevent negative economy-wide risk because they represent the exposure to liq-
externalities and to stabilize the economy dur- uidity risk from the asset side (Shen et al. 2009).
ing crises. However, stability through govern- Recent empirical studies have focused on liq-
ment guarantees comes at a cost. Those programs uidity risk from undrawn credit lines, which are
impede fair competition and disturb level playing held off the balance sheet (Cornett et al. 2011;
fields in the banking system, as publicly guaran- Gatev, Schuermann, and Strahan 2009). In addi-
teed banks are able to have lower cost of capi- tion, Berger and Bouwman (2009) developed liq-
tal (Akins et al. 2016; Beck et al. 2010). Large uidity creation measures considering the on- and
banks are more likely to be protected because off-balance sheet positions. Although Berger and
they are more systemically important than small Bouwman’s (2009) measures comprehensively
banks (Boyd and Gertler 1994; O’Hara and Shaw reflect the magnitude of liquidity creation, the
1990). Using a panel dataset for U.S. commercial weights assigned by them to construct liquidity
banks from 2006 to 2012, Kim and Joh (2015) creation measures are not time varying depend-
find that most failed banks were small while ing on market conditions (Krishnamurthy, Bai,
no too-big-to-fail (TBTF) banks failed during and Weymuller 2016). Therefore, the develop-
the recent financial crisis. Therefore, the effect ment of concrete liquidity risk measures is still
of competition on financial stability may vary open to debate.
across bank size. Protected banks attempt to take To check the robustness of our empirical
advantage of their monopoly rents from govern- results, we consider the three types of liquidity
ment guarantees (Gropp, Hakenes, and Schnabel risks simultaneously: committed credit lines,
2011). In the presence of this kind of moral haz- liquid asset holdings, and liquidity creation.
ard, competition is expected to be beneficial to We calculate our liquidity measures as follows.
stability of large banks by mitigating the moral First, liquidity risk from committed credit lines
hazard problem. In contrast, small banks, which is calculated by expressing committed credit
are less likely to be publicly guaranteed, are sub- lines as a fraction of total assets plus committed
ject to the risk-shifting problem due to lower credit lines, following Cornett et al. (2011).
charter values during times of turbulence. In this Second, liquidity risk from the magnitude of
situation, higher competitive pressure deterio- liquid reserves is calculated as the ratio of liquid
rates small banks’ charter values more signifi- asset holdings to total assets. The estimated
cantly. Therefore, competition is expected to be coefficients of liquid asset holdings are expected
harmful for the stability of small banks during to have opposite signs of other liquidity risk
the crisis. measures because the more liquid assets a bank
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK 5

holds, the lower liquidity risk the bank has. Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2006) find no evi-
Finally, liquidity risk from liquidity creation is dence that competition is negatively associated
calculated as the Berger and Bouwman’s (2009) with market concentration. Second, the Lerner
liquidity creation measure divided by total assets. index allows us to calculate the degree of market
We construct their preferred “cat fat” liquidity power as in the bank-year observation, although
creation measure using the following three-step other competition measures are calculated as in
procedures. First, we classify all on- and off- the country-year level. The country-year level
balance sheet activities4 as illiquid, semi-liquid, variables do not consider the fact that banks
and liquid depending on the ease, cost, and time often compete across national borders. Finally,
for customers to obtain liquid funds from the the Lerner index does not impose certain restric-
bank (liability side) and the ease, cost, and time tive assumptions, unlike, for example, the H-
for banks to dispose of their obligations (asset statistic, which requires that the banking market
side). Second, we assign weights to all the activ- be in long-run equilibrium (Bikker, Shaffer, and
ities classified in the first step. The weights are Spierdijk 2012).
based on the liquidity creation theory according Following Berger, Klapper, and Turk-Ariss
to which liquidity is created when illiquid assets (2009), we construct the Lerner index as follows
are transformed into liquid liabilities, whereas
pit − MCit
liquidity is destroyed when liquid assets are (1) Lernerit =
transformed into illiquid liabilities or equity. In pit
the final step, we calculate the level of liquidity where Lernerit denotes the Lerner index for
creation by combining all activities, which are bank i in year t. pit indicates the output price,
classified in step 1 and then weighted in step 2. which is calculated as total revenues divided by
total assets. Total revenues include both interest
B. Competition Measure: Lerner Index income and noninterest income, since a bank’s
There is no perfect measure for competition revenues come from both activities. MCit is the
between banks, although previous literature has marginal cost at the current output level, derived
used a variety of competition measures. The most from the following translog cost function. We
widely used measures are the market structure modify the translog cost function by Berger,
measures (such as the Herfindahl–Hirschman Klapper, and Turk-Ariss (2009) to control for the
Index [HHI], number of banks, and concentration effect of risk, by adding nonperforming loans
ratios), Lerner index, Boone (2008) indicator, and ratios and bank capital as proxies of risk pre-
Panzar and Rosse (1987) H-statistic (Zigraiova mium in the control variables set.5 A bank’s cost
and Havranek 2016). Among these measures, we depends on its risk exposure, reflecting a bank’s
employ the Lerner index as the main competition business strategy or economic environments
measure. In addition, we re-estimate our baseline such as a financial crisis (Hughes and Mester
models of Equation (4) by employing the Boone 2013; Hughes, Mester, and Moon 2001; Jiménez,
indicator to check for the robustness of our results Lopez, and Saurina 2013; Oliver, Fumas, and
(Table 10). Saurina 2006).
The Lerner index, which is a measure of mar- α
(2) ln TOCit = α0 + α1 lnTAit + 2 lnTA2it
ket power, captures a bank’s pricing power of 2
charging price above its marginal cost. It has the
following advantages as a proxy of competition ∑
3

2
+ δk lnωkit + λh lnRhit
compared to other competition measures. First, k=1 h=1
the Lerner index is a more direct proxy to mea-
sure bank market power, which conforms to the ∑3

2

notion of the charter value hypothesis. In contrast, + ξk lnTAit lnωkit + ψh lnTAit lnRhit
the market structure measures do not directly k=1 h=1
link to price levels due to a bank’s competitive
behavior. Claessens and Laeven (2004) and Beck, 5. To check the robustness of our findings, we re-estimate
all empirical models by using only nonperforming loans ratios
(excluding bank capital) or by replacing nonperforming loans
4. Berger and Bouwman (2009) suggest that both on- and ratios with loan-loss provision ratios as a proxy for risk
off-balance sheet activities should be considered to precisely premium in Equation (2). We also re-estimate our empirical
measure the degree of liquidity creation. Among their four models without any risk proxies (Rhit ), as in Berger, Klapper,
measures of liquidity creation, the “cat fat” measure considers and Turk-Ariss (2009). Our findings continue to hold in all
both the on- and off-balance sheet activities simultaneously. cases.
6 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

and 2012), and the Worldwide Governance Indi-


∑ ∑
3 3 cators (WGI) developed by Kaufmann, Kraay,
+ ρkj lnωkit lnωjit and Mastruzzi (2011), respectively.
k=1 j=1 We apply multiple selection criteria. First,
banks with missing data on dependent, explana-
∑ ∑
3 2
tory, and IV are deleted from the sample. Second,
+ ζkh lnωkit lnRhit
k=1 h=1
banks with zero total assets, loans, deposits, and
equity are removed. Third, countries with fewer
∑ ∑
2 2
than five banks are excluded from the sample.6
+ ϕhm lnRhit lnRmit + μt + ηit . Finally, the bank-level financial statement vari-
h=1 m=1 ables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles
The marginal cost is defined as: to account for the impact of outliers. The final
sample consists of 118,894 bank-year observa-
[
∂TOCit TOCit tions for 10,979 banks from 25 OECD countries,
(3) MCit = = ̂α1 + ̂
α2 lnTAit spanning from 2000 to 2014.
∂TAit TAit
]
∑3
∑2
B. Empirical Methods
+ ̂ ξk lnωkit + ̂ h lnRhit
ψ
k=1 h=1 In this study, we employ various economet-
ric methodologies: the fixed effects model as our
where TOCit indicates total operating costs. TAit main empirical strategy,7 the IV analysis to mit-
measures total assets, which is a proxy for a igate endogeneity concerns, the dynamic panel
bank’s output. ωkit represents input prices, which GMM estimations to account for the dynamic
includes the price of labor (the ratio of personnel aspect of the relationship between competition
expenses to total assets), price of borrowed funds and bank liquidity risk-taking, and the panel Tobit
(the ratio of interest expenses to total deposits regressions to control for left-censored observa-
and money market funding), and price of fixed tions of some dependent variables.
assets (the ratio of other operating and admin- Our main empirical methodology is the fol-
istrative expenses to total assets), respectively. lowing fixed effects model:
Rhit indicates risk premium, which includes non-
performing loans ratios and bank capital. Time (4) Liquidity Riskijt = β0 + β1 Competitionijt
dummies are included to control for changes in
+ β2 Bankijt + β3 Countryjt + θi + τt + εijt
technological and macroeconomic environments.
All standard errors are robust to heteroskedastic- where Liquidity Riskijt denotes liquidity risk for
ity and are clustered by country to control for bank i from country j in year t; Competitionijt
serial correlation. denotes the degree of market power8 ; Bankijt
denotes bank-specific characteristics; Countryjt
country-specific characteristics; and εijt the error-
IV. DATA AND METHODOLOGY term.9 All regressions include bank fixed effects
(θi ) to capture time-independent differences
A. Data
across banks, as well as time fixed effects (τt ) to
We construct a panel dataset for commercial control for changes in the macroeconomic and
banks in OECD countries from 2000 to 2014.
The bank-level financial information is obtained 6. Eight countries—Austria, Chile, Estonia, Finland,
from the Bankscope database. The information Greece, Iceland, Ireland, and New Zealand—are removed
on merger and acquisition activities is collected from the initial sample.
from Thomson’s SDC platinum database. The 7. We employ the fixed effects model instead of the ran-
dom effects model because the Hausman test for endogeneity
data on gross domestic product (GDP) per capita rejects the null hypothesis that unobserved individual effects
and GDP growth rates are from the World Devel- are uncorrelated with other regressors in the model.
opment Indicators (WDI). M2 is retrieved from 8. We re-estimate our models, replacing the Lerner index
the International Monetary Fund’s International with the Boone indicator in Table 10. We find that our results
remain unchanged with the alternative competition measure.
Financial Statistics (IMF IFS). For our IV, infor- 9. We continue to find the same qualitative results even
mation on entry barriers and control of corruption after employing 1-year lagged values for competition (Com-
is collected from the databases provided by Barth, petitionijt − 1 ) to mitigate the impact of the potential endogene-
Caprio, and Levine (2001, updated in 2003, 2008, ity of market power.
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK 7

business environment common to all banks in dependent variables are left-censored at zero. We
our sample. Robust standard errors are clustered run panel Tobit regressions with random effects
at the country level. and report the estimated marginal effects. For
dummy variables, the marginal effects are calcu-
(5) Liquidity Riskijt = γ0 + γ1 Competitionijt lated as the discrete change in the expected value
+ γ2 Crisist + γ3 Competitionijt ∗ Crisist of the dependent variable as the dummy variable
changes from 0 to 1. The ρ-statistic evaluates
+ γ4 Bankijt + γ5 Countryjt + φi + υt + εijt whether the panel Tobit estimation is required.
where Crisist is a dummy variable that equals When ρ is close to zero, the panel Tobit analy-
to one, if the year is 2008 or 2009. Compe- sis is not significantly different from the standard
titionijt * Crisist is an interaction term between Tobit analysis.
Competitionijt and Crisist . Bank fixed effects (φi )
and time fixed effects (υt ) are included in regres- C. Variables
sions. εijt is the error-term. Robust standard errors
are clustered by country. Table 1 shows definitions and data sources
To address the endogeneity problem, we per- of dependent, explanatory, and instrumental
form GMM estimations because this method variables. Specifically, Liquidity Riskijt includes
is more efficient than two-stage least squares liquidity risks from committed credit lines
(2SLS) where there is heterogeneity of unknown (Credit Lines), liquid asset holdings (Liquid
form. For the IV approach using a GMM estima- Assets), and liquidity creation (Liquidity Cre-
tor, we employ entry restrictions (Entry Barriers) ation). The Lerner index is employed as a proxy
and the control of corruption index (Control of for market power (Competitionijt ).
Corruption) as IV. The restriction on entry into The bank-specific factors include bank size
banking is a composite index that takes values (Assets), bank credit risk (Nonperforming Loans
between 1 and 8. Higher values indicate greater Ratios), equity ratio (Equity Ratios), and merg-
entry restrictions arising from legal requirements ers and acquisitions activities (M&A Activity).
for obtaining a banking license. Information on Bank size, which is calculated as the natural log-
entry barrier is obtained from Barth, Caprio, and arithm of total assets, is included to capture dif-
Levine (2001, and updated in 2003, 2008, and ferences in risk management capabilities (Dem-
2012). We use the values of 2012 as entry barri- setz and Strahan 1997; Elsas, Hackethal, and
ers for the observations since 2012.10 The control Holzhäuser 2010) and in the possibility of pub-
of corruption index captures the perceived levels lic bailouts (i.e., TBTF policy) between large
of corruption in a country, which has values from and small banks. The squared bank size term
−2.5 (weak) to 2.5 (strong). Higher values indi- (Assets2 ) is also included to capture nonlinearity
cate less corruption. In order to include bank fixed in the effect of bank size on liquidity risk-taking.
effects in the GMM regressions, we choose IV Bank credit risk is measured by nonperforming
that have sufficient variations. loans as a fraction of total loans. Nonperforming
Another possible source of endogeneity is that loans may be negatively associated with liquidity
the current market power is a function of their risk, because a bank with a high nonperforming
liquidity risk-taking in the past. To account for loans ratio is subject to suffering from the lack
the dynamic nature of the relationship between of lending capacity or from holding more liquid
competition and bank liquidity risk, we use the assets in order to improve its risk management.
dynamic panel GMM estimator developed by The equity ratio is defined as the ratio of total
Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and equity to total assets. The relationship between
Bond (1998). The AR (1) and AR (2) show the bank equity capital and liquidity risk is ambigu-
Arellano-Bond tests for first- and second-order ous. On the one hand, more capital leads to higher
autocorrelation in the first-differenced residuals. liquidity risk as it improves a bank’s risk-bearing
The Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions capacity (Bhattacharya and Thakor 1993). On the
examines the validity of IV. other hand, more bank capital results in lower liq-
In addition, we conduct the Tobit estimations uidity risk because the less fragile capital struc-
for Credit Lines and Liquid Assets because those ture discourages the bank to create more liquidity,
which in turn encourages the bank to expropri-
10. We re-estimate our model, excluding the entry bar- ate rents from its customers (Diamond and Rajan
riers. Our results when controlling only for the control of 2001). M&A activity is a dummy variable that
corruption, which varies every year, as an IV continue to hold. equals one if a bank engages in one or more M&A
8 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

TABLE 1
Variable Definition and Data Sources
Variables Definitions Sources
Panel A: Competition and Bank Liquidity Risk
Dependent variables
Credit Lines Liquidity risk from committed credit lines, calculated as the Bankscope
ratio of committed credit lines to total assets plus
committed credit lines. Higher values indicate more
liquidity risk.
Liquid Assets Liquidity risk derived from the extent to which a bank holds Bankscope
liquid assets, calculated as the ratio of liquid reserves to
total assets. Higher values indicate less liquidity risk.
Liquidity Creation Liquidity risk from liquidity creation, measured as the ratio Bankscope Authors’
of Berger and Bouwman’s (2009) “cat fat” liquidity calculations
creation measure, which is constructed by categorizing
all on- and off-balance sheet activities and then by
imposing weights on them, divided by total assets.
Higher values indicate more liquidity risk.
Explanatory variables
Lerner Lerner index, calculated as the difference between price and Bankscope Authors’
marginal cost divided by price. Higher values indicate calculations
more market power.
Assets Natural logarithm of total assets Bankscope
Nonperforming Loans Ratios Nonperforming loans as a fraction of total loans Bankscope
Equity Ratios Equity to total assets Bankscope
M&A Activity A dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if a bank was SDC Platinum
involved in one or more mergers and acquisitions over
the past 3 years
GDP per Capita Natural logarithm of GDP per capita WDI
GDP Growth Rates Annual percentage growth rate of GDP WDI
M2 to GDP M2 divided by GDP. M2 consists of M1, savings deposits, IMF IFS
money market deposit accounts, and time deposits.
Instrumental variables
Entry Barriers An index that takes values between 1 and 8, with higher Barth, Caprio, and Levine
values indicating greater entry restrictions (2001, updated in 2003,
2008, and 2012)
Control of Corruption An annual index that represents the level of control of WGI
corruption, ranging from −2.5 (weak) to 2.5 (strong).
Higher values indicate less corruption.
Panel B: Translog Cost Function
Log of Total Operating Costs Natural logarithm of total operating costs Bankscope
Price of Labor Personnel expenses to total assets Bankscope
Price of Funding Interest expenses to total deposits and money market Bankscope
funding
Price of Fixed Assets Other operating and administrative expenses to total assets Bankscope
Average Price of Bank Output Output price, calculated as total revenues divided by total Bankscope
assets
Marginal Costs Marginal costs, obtained from an estimated translog cost Bankscope
function with respect to bank output

Notes: This table provides the definitions and data sources for the variables used in the estimations. Panel A provides
information on the variables that are employed as dependent, explanatory, and IV in the competition-stability (bank liquidity
risk) regressions. Panel B shows information on the variables that are used to construct the Lerner index.

activities during the previous 3 years. It is added is included to capture the impact of the degree of
to account for the impact of M&A events on cor- aggregate liquidity in a country.
porate strategies for liquidity risk management Table 2 shows summary statistics for the
(Carletti, Hartmann, and Spagnolo 2007). main variables we use in the empirical anal-
The country-specific factors include the GDP yses. Among our three dependent variables,
per capita (GDP per Capita), the GDP growth Credit Lines has 7,562 zero-value observations
rate (GDP Growth Rates), and the money sup- in the sample. In unreported tests, we attempt
ply (M2 to GDP). The GDP per capita and the to mitigate the estimation problem arising from
GDP growth rate are introduced to control for these zero-value observations by re-estimating
the impact of economic development and of the regressions after dropping zero observations
business cycle, respectively. The money supply of Credit Lines. In addition, we conduct Tobit
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK 9

TABLE 2
Summary Statistics
Variables Obs. Mean SD Min Max
Panel A: Competition and Bank Liquidity Risk
Dependent variables
Credit Lines 118,894 0.0824 0.0629 0 0.3276
Liquid Assets 118,894 0.1184 0.1276 0.0051 0.8242
Liquidity Creation 118,894 0.2950 0.2429 −0.3874 1.3312
Explanatory variables
Lerner 118,894 0.2183 0.1498 −0.4198 0.5464
Assets 118,894 12.186 1.6104 9.049 18.348
Nonperforming Loans Ratios 118,894 0.0160 0.0268 0.0002 0.1560
Equity Ratios 118,894 0.1114 0.0643 0.0223 0.7839
M&A Activity 118,894 0.0115 0.1066 0 1
GDP per Capita 118,894 10.6639 0.2289 8.4016 11.6855
GDP Growth Rates 118,894 0.0190 0.0167 −0.0780 0.1058
M2 to GDP 118,894 0.8768 0.4833 0.2319 6.8317
Instrumental variables
Entry Barriers 118,894 7.8068 0.4966 3 8
Control of Corruption 118,894 1.5162 0.3577 −0.7332 2.5506
Panel B: Translog Cost Function
Log of Total Operating Costs 118,894 9.0703 1.5708 5.8749 14.760
Price of Labor 118,894 0.0164 0.0133 0.0001 0.6137
Price of Funding 118,894 0.0180 0.0131 0.0008 1.1502
Price of Fixed Assets 118,894 0.0153 0.0305 0.0005 3.3135
Average Price of Bank Output 118,894 0.0620 0.0213 0.0152 0.1713
Marginal Costs 118,894 0.0484 0.0186 0.0100 0.1364

Notes: This table shows descriptive statistics for variables used in the regressions. The sample contains 10,979 commercial
banks in 25 OECD countries from 2000 to 2014. Panel A presents information on summary statistics of the variables used as
dependent, explanatory, and IV in the competition-stability (in terms of bank liquidity risk) regressions. Bank liquidity risk is
proxied for the exposure to credit-line drawdowns (committed credit lines), liquid asset holdings, and the degree of liquidity
creation. Panel B reports summary statistics of the variables employed to construct the Lerner index. Detailed information on the
variables is provided in Table 1.

regressions for Credit Lines and Liquid Assets to reduce the exposure to liquidity risk, consis-
because those dependent variables are left- tent with Boyd and Nicoló (2005) and Carletti
censored at zero. According to Berger and and Leonello (2014). We allow for a nonlinear
Bouwman (2009), banks with negative liquidity relationship between bank size and liquidity risk
creation (Liquidity Creation) may exist to per- by using a squared term of bank size (Assets2 ).
form the other crucial roles of banks, such as The coefficient of the linear term (Assets) is
risk transformation. significantly positive, while that of the squared
term is significantly negative. Therefore, the bank
size exhibits a nonlinear relationship with liquid-
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS ity risk from committed credit lines. The coeffi-
A. The Effect of Market Power on Liquidity Risk cient of Nonperforming Loans Ratios is negative
(−0.2758) and statistically significant at the 1%
Table 3 reports the results of the fixed effects level, implying that banks with high credit risks
regressions on the relationship between market take less liquidity risk. Equity Ratios is positively
power and liquidity risk (Equation (4)). Depen- related to Credit Lines, implying that better capi-
dent variables are liquidity risks, which stem talized banks take greater liquidity risk.
from committed credit lines, liquid asset hold- The remaining models confirm the results of
ings, and liquidity creation. Model (1), using other liquidity risk measures
In Model (1), we find that market power (Liquid Assets and Liquidity Creation) as depen-
(Lerner) is positively associated with liquidity dent variables. The results show that our find-
risk from credit lines (Credit Lines).11 This result ings are pretty robust across various liquidity risk
suggests that enhanced competition helps a bank

11. We re-estimate regressions after dropping zero-value positive relationship between market power and liquidity risk
observations of Credit Lines in the sample. We again find the from undrawn credit lines.
10 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

TABLE 3 B. The Impact of the 2008 Global Financial


The Effect of Market Power on Bank Liquidity Crisis
Risk In Table 4, we test whether the positive effect
Credit Liquid Liquidity of market power on liquidity risk changes dur-
Lines Assets Creation ing the financial crisis of 2008. To accomplish
(1) (2) (3) this, we add an interaction term (Lerner*Crisis)
Lerner 0.0262*** −0.0559*** 0.0687*** between Lerner and Crisis. Crisis is a dummy
(14.92) (−13.52) (5.59) variable that equals one if the year is 2008 or
Assets 0.0101* −0.0616*** −0.0013 2009. The coefficients of the crisis dummies
(2.06) (−5.92) (−0.04)
Assets2 −0.0005** 0.0016*** 0.0002 of Credit Lines and Liquid Assets are negative
(−2.38) (4.32) (0.13) (−0.0122) and positive (0.0962), respectively.
Nonperforming −0.2758*** 0.0448* −0.2996*** These results suggest that banks reduce their
Loans Ratios exposure to liquidity risks during a crisis.
(−6.13) (1.89) (−9.01)
Equity Ratios 0.0561*** −0.0276*** −0.1336**
Lerner*Crisis provides mixed findings. That
(7.17) (−3.08) (−2.46) is, the effect of market power on liquidity risk
M&A Activity 0.0001 0.0028 −0.0165** during the crisis is different depending on liquid-
(0.03) (1.16) (−2.78) ity risk measures. Specifically, the positive rela-
GDP per Capita 0.0180 −0.0495 −0.0305
(1.70) (−1.08) (−0.36)
tionship between market power and liquidity risk
GDP Growth −0.2002*** 0.8702*** −0.6370*** from committed credit lines is intensified during
Rates the crisis; the coefficient of Lerner*Crisis is pos-
(−3.31) (5.14) (−3.39) itive (0.0021) and statistically significant at the
M2 to GDP −0.0021 −0.0126 −0.0023
(−0.53) (−0.92) (−0.05) 5% level. In contrast to Model (1), Models (2)
Constant −0.1613 1.1155** 0.5840 and (3) for Liquid Assets and Liquidity Creation
(−1.33) (2.32) (0.63) provide evidence that the positive relationship
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes between market power and liquidity risk weak-
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.1216 0.0698 0.1151
ens during the crisis; Lerner*Crisis is positively
Observations 118,894 118,894 118,894 (0.0160) related to Liquid Assets and negatively
(−0.0437) associated with Liquidity Creation.
Notes: This table shows fixed effects regression esti- These results suggest that banks with greater mar-
mates of market power on liquidity risk. The dependent vari- ket power decrease liquidity risk-taking by hold-
ables are liquidity risk from committed credit lines (Credit
Lines), liquid asset holdings (Liquid Assets), and liquidity cre-
ing more liquid assets and by reducing liquidity
ation (Liquidity Creation). Assets2 is the squared bank size creation during a crisis.
term. Detailed information on the variables is provided in What is the reason for these conflicting find-
Table 1. Robust standard errors are clustered by country. The ings? How do we reconcile them? To address
t-statistics are in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, this issue, we focus on bank size. Particularly, we
5%, and 10% levels, respectively. focus on the difference in the possibility of being
publicly guaranteed depending on bank size. It is
well known that large banks are more likely to be
bailed out. Therefore, they may have less incen-
measures. Model (2) employs liquid asset hold- tive to behave prudently than small banks during
ings as a dependent variable. The estimated coef- the period of turbulence.
ficients of Liquid Assets are expected to have Table 5 reports the regression estimates of
opposite signs of other liquidity risk measures market power on liquidity risk, by dividing
because more liquid asset holdings mean lower banks into four groups, depending on their total
liquidity risk. Our results still strongly hold to assets, following Cornett et al. (2011).12 Panels
liquidity risk from the degree of liquid reserves. A and B show results for large banks (total assets
The coefficient of Lerner is negative (−0.0559) greater than US$1 billion) and medium banks
and statistically significant at the 1% level, sug- (total assets between US$500 million and US$1
gesting that banks hold fewer liquid assets as they
have greater market power. Model (3) for Liquid- 12. We re-estimate our models by dividing banks into
ity Creation provides the same results with pre- tercile, quartile, quintile, or decile groups depending on their
vious tests. Lerner is positively and significantly total assets per year in the corresponding country. We also re-
estimate our models by changing the definition of large banks
associated with Liquidity Creation, implying that to those with total assets greater than US$3 billion, US$10
banks with higher market power create more liq- billion, or US$50 billion. Our findings remain qualitatively
uidity, leaving them vulnerable to liquidity risk. unchanged.
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK 11

TABLE 4 risk regardless of unfavorable macroeconomic


The Effect of Market Power on Bank Liquidity conditions. This may be attributed to moral
Risk Considering the Impact of the 2008 hazard of large banks, taking advantage of public
Financial Crisis guarantees during times of crisis. Small banks
in Panel C, however, exhibit different liquid-
Credit Liquid Liquidity ity risk-taking behavior when they have more
Lines Assets Creation
(1) (2) (3) market power during a crisis. Small banks that
already suffer from reduced charter value due
Lerner 0.0258*** −0.0590*** 0.0773***
(15.47) (−13.58) (5.88)
to a sluggish economy seem to pursue safer
Crisis −0.0122* 0.0962*** 0.0066 strategies to preserve their charter values with
(−2.05) (4.51) (0.19) greater market power during a crisis.
Lerner*Crisis 0.0021** 0.0160*** −0.0437*** This tendency is more pronounced in very
(2.28) (3.99) (−7.28) small banks in which their default rate signifi-
Assets 0.0103** −0.0602*** −0.0051
(2.08) (−5.74) (−0.14) cantly increases during a crisis. For Model (1)
Assets2 −0.0005** 0.0015*** 0.0003 in Panel C2 for smallest banks, the coefficient
(−2.39) (4.17) (0.21) of Lerner*Crisis is significantly negative, while
Nonperforming −0.2756*** 0.0465* −0.3042*** that of Lerner is significantly positive; it sug-
Loans Ratios
(−6.13) (1.97) (−9.20) gests that the positive effect of market power
Equity Ratios 0.0563*** −0.0258*** −0.1385** on the exposure to undrawn credit lines reduces
(7.13) (−2.87) (−2.58) during a crisis. For Model (2) in Panel C2,
M&A Activity 0.0001 0.0028 −0.0164** Lerner*Crisis is positively (0.0184) and signifi-
(0.03) (1.14) (−2.75)
GDP per Capita 0.0180 −0.0497 −0.0299
cantly related to Liquid Assets, while Lerner is
(1.70) (−1.08) (−0.35) negatively (−0.0544) and significantly related to
GDP Growth −0.2000*** 0.8717*** −0.6413*** Liquid Assets. These results imply that, for very
Rates small banks, the negative effect of market power
(−3.31) (5.15) (−3.42)
M2 to GDP −0.0021 −0.0126 −0.0021 on holding liquid assets weakens during a crisis.
(−0.53) (−0.92) (−0.04) Consistent with the results of Models (1) and (2),
Constant −0.1624 1.1078** 0.6049 Model (3) shows that the positive effect of market
(−1.33) (2.31) (0.65) power on the degree of liquidity creation reduces
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes during a crisis. The coefficient of Lerner*Crisis
R2 0.1216 0.0699 0.1155 is negative (−0.0381) and statistically significant
Observations 118,894 118,894 118,894 at the 1% level.
Notes: This table reports fixed effects regression estimates
of market power on liquidity risk considering the impact of VI. ROBUSTNESS CHECKS
the 2008 global financial crisis. The dependent variables are
liquidity risks from committed credit lines (Credit Lines), To ensure the validity of our results, we con-
liquid asset holdings (Liquid Assets), and liquidity creation
(Liquidity Creation). Crisis is a dummy variable that equals duct a number of robustness tests by addressing
one if the year is 2008 or 2009. Lerner*Crisis is an interaction potential econometric concerns and employing
term between Lerner and Crisis. Assets2 is the squared bank additional control variables.
size term. Detailed information on the variables is provided in
Table 1. Robust standard errors are clustered by country. The
t-statistics are in parentheses. A. Endogeneity Issues
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%,
5%, and 10% levels, respectively. We confirm our findings using IV regressions
in Table 6. Panels A, B, and C provide the second-
stage regression results for all banks, large banks
billion), respectively. Panel C consists of Panel (total assets greater than US$1 billion), and small
C1 (small banks) and Panel C2 (smallest banks); banks (total assets less than or equal to US$100
small banks are those with total assets between million), respectively. The lower panel of the
US$100 million and US$500 million, while table shows the first-stage regression results for
smallest banks are those with total assets less our IV. The dependent variable of the first-stage
than or equal to US$100 million. regressions is Lerner. For the sake of brevity,
In Panel A for large banks, the coeffi- we do not separately report the first-stage regres-
cients of Lerner*Crisis in Models (1)–(3) sion tables except for the IV. We employ the
are insignificant. On balance, large banks with level of entry restrictions (Entry Barriers) and the
greater market power still take more liquidity control of corruption (Control of Corruption) in
12
TABLE 5
The Effect of Market Power on Bank Liquidity Risk across Bank Size
Panel B: Medium Banks
Panel A: Large Banks (total assets US$500 million Panel C: Small Banks
(total assets > US$1 billion) to US$1 billion) (total assets ≤ US$500 million)
Panel C1: Small Banks
(total assets US$100 Panel C2: Smallest Banks
million to US$500 million) (total assets ≤ US$100 million)
Credit Liquid Liquidity Credit Liquid Liquidity Credit Liquid Liquidity Credit Liquid Liquidity
Lines Assets Creation Lines Assets Creation Lines Assets Creation Lines Assets Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Lerner 0.0344*** −0.0744*** 0.0693* 0.0414*** −0.0615*** 0.0478** 0.0376*** −0.0449*** 0.1043*** 0.0210*** −0.0544*** 0.0735***
(3.16) (−4.32) (2.04) (7.70) (−2.87) (2.09) (9.50) (−4.28) (10.14) (22.41) (−25.86) (17.30)
Crisis 0.0142 0.0656*** −0.0805 0.0098 0.0615* 0.1528** 0.0193 0.0044 0.0648 −0.0127** 0.0131 −0.1295*
(1.02) (3.23) (1.43) (1.04) (1.94) (2.64) (0.56) (0.29) (1.46) (−2.38) (0.53) (−1.89)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0099 0.0246 −0.0355 0.0020*** 0.0121 0.0116 0.0049 −0.0067 −0.0384*** −0.0006* 0.0184*** −0.0381***
(−1.47) (1.55) (−0.61) (2.81) (0.90) (0.39) (1.59) (−0.99) (−3.68) (−1.95) (4.58) (−11.21)
Assets 0.0285 −0.0324 0.0449 −0.0023 −0.0023 −0.3248 −0.0624*** −0.0613 0.2455 0.0412*** −0.0639*** −0.0329
(1.67) (−1.43) (0.84) (−0.08) (−0.03) (−1.22) (−4.48) (−1.20) (−0.77) (14.31) (−8.55) (−0.80)
Assets2 −0.0010 0.0009 −0.0014 −0.0002 −0.0005 0.0120 0.0022*** 0.0019 0.0097 −0.0019*** 0.0013*** 0.0022
(−1.67) (1.27) (−0.74) (−0.13) (−0.17) (1.20) (3.72) (0.87) (0.73) (−13.82) (3.88) (0.72)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.1102 0.1072 −0.0586 −0.2916*** 0.1140* −0.6153*** −0.2971*** 0.0878** −0.3197*** −0.2220*** 0.0510*** −0.1808***
(−1.62) (1.65) (−0.44) (−7.88) (1.83) (−6.17) (−13.05) (2.13) (−9.86) (−155.32) (9.27) (−6.18)
Equity Ratios 0.0588* −0.0942** 0.0770 −0.0270 −0.0162 −0.3724* 0.0027 −0.0356* −0.2388*** 0.0710*** −0.0077 −0.1581***
(1.91) (−2.35) (0.47) (−1.02) (−0.24) (−1.93) (0.18) (−2.04) (−3.75) (17.09) (−0.90) (−3.93)
M&A Activity 0.0031 −0.0037 0.0015 0.0007 0.0002 −0.0099*** −0.0011 −0.0025 −0.0235** 0.0020*** −0.0070** −0.0174***
(0.88) (−0.72) (0.16) (0.51) (0.05) (−3.61) (−0.36) (−0.70) (−2.68) (24.09) (−2.30) (−12.78)
GDP per Capita 0.0278* −0.0944** −0.0770 0.0077 −0.1484* −0.2782* −0.0033 0.0671 0.0580 −0.0101 −0.0112 −0.1581
(1.85) (−2.21) (−1.12) (0.33) (−1.80) (−2.04) (−0.26) (1.70) (0.61) (−0.66) (−0.11) (−0.79)
GDP Growth Rates −0.2527** 0.6932*** −0.4280* −0.1623* 0.7360** −0.8574* 0.0618 0.7311*** −0.4730 0.0142 0.4561* 0.1858
(−2.55) (3.81) (−1.90) (−1.94) (2.22) (−1.80) (0.86) (3.33) (−1.09) (0.10) (1.98) (0.41)
M2 to GDP −0.0036 −0.0271** −0.0165 0.0048* −0.0238 −0.0018 −0.0020 −0.0169 0.0364 0.0165 0.1273 0.2519
CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

(−0.85) (−2.30) (−0.57) (1.72) (−1.54) (−0.05) (−0.36) (−0.52) (0.83) (0.80) (0.88) (1.13)
Constant −0.3838* 1.4322*** 0.8771 0.0667 1.7773* 5.4739** 0.5384*** −0.1509 1.1832 −0.0854 0.6564 1.7716
(−1.76) (3.66) (1.24) (0.21) (1.79) (2.48) (4.12) (−0.29) (1.17) (−0.56) (0.66) (0.86)
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.0592 0.0334 0.0458 0.1999 0.0687 0.1200 0.2001 0.0784 0.1453 0.0910 0.1087 0.1794
Observations 14,806 14,806 14,806 9,237 9,237 9,237 49,915 49,915 49,915 44,936 44,936 44,936

Notes: This table reports the fixed effects regression estimates of market power on liquidity risk by dividing banks into four groups, depending on total assets, following Cornett et al. (2011). Panels A and B show
the results for large banks (total assets greater than US$1 billion) and medium banks (total assets between US$500 million and US$1 billion), respectively. Panel C consists of Panel C1 (small banks) and Panel C2
(smallest banks); small banks are those with total assets between US$100 million and US$500 million, while smallest banks are those with total assets less than or equal to US$100 million. The dependent variables are
liquidity risks from committed credit lines (Credit Lines), liquid asset holdings (Liquid Assets), and liquidity creation (Liquidity Creation). Assets2 is the squared bank size term. Detailed information on the variables
is provided in Table 1. Robust standard errors are clustered by country. The t-statistics are in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
TABLE 6
Instrumental Variables Approach
Panel A: All Banks Panel B: Large Banks Panel C: Small Banks
Credit Liquid Liquidity Credit Liquid Liquidity Credit Liquid Liquidity
Lines Assets Creation Lines Assets Creation Lines Assets Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Lerner 0.1218*** 0.0047 0.4483* 0.0162*** −0.2565*** 0.2682** 0.1049*** −0.0868 0.5168***
(4.45) (0.04) (1.89) (3.20) (−3.28) (2.46) (19.62) (−1.45) (4.96)
Crisis −0.0067 0.0356** −0.0503 −0.0135*** 0.0437*** −0.1166***
(0.67) (2.02) (−0.45) (−28.12) (13.65) (−11.19)
Lerner*Crisis 0.0043 0.1315 0.1708 −0.0375*** 0.0446*** −0.2416***
(0.08) (1.17) (0.49) (−14.50) (2.83) (−5.04)
Assets −0.0059 −0.0536** −0.0183 0.0084 −0.0173 0.0177 0.0428*** −0.0523*** 0.0330
(−0.78) (−1.96) (−0.28) (0.52) (−0.71) (0.32) (18.29) (−5.90) (−1.18)
Assets2 −0.0001 0.0012* −0.0002 −0.0004 0.0008 −0.0001 −0.0024*** 0.0001 −0.0003
(−0.43) (1.75) (−0.10) (−0.63) (1.19) (−0.06) (−21.66) (0.10) (−0.44)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.1140*** 0.1021 0.1133 −0.2519** 0.0768 −0.4477* −0.1335*** 0.2236*** −0.2355**
(−2.92) (0.61) (0.37) (−2.47) (0.72) (−1.74) (−21.60) (5.78) (−2.07)
Equity Ratios 0.0575*** −0.0189 −0.1324* 0.0391 0.0048 0.2162 0.0796*** 0.0141 −0.1396***
(7.24) (−0.80) (−1.66) (1.38) (0.06) (1.53) (26.71) (1.39) (−6.88)
M&A Activity −0.0018 0.0039 −0.0122** 0.0041 −0.0076* 0.0111 0.0030*** −0.0107*** −0.0044
(−0.86) (1.40) (−2.15) (1.28) (−1.95) (1.14) (7.22) (−3.39) (−0.91)
GDP per Capita 0.0295*** −0.0518 0.0928 0.0219*** −0.0020 −0.0047 0.0488*** −0.0072 0.1243
(2.77) (−1.52) (1.14) (2.60) (−0.08) (−0.14) (9.71) (−0.33) (1.28)
GDP Growth Rates −0.0919*** 0.2096 −0.9777*** 0.0103 0.1345 0.2635 −0.0152 0.4310*** −0.9618***
(−3.57) (1.46) (−5.14) (0.23) (1.23) (0.90) (−0.91) (6.24) (−2.77)
M2 to GDP −0.0001 −0.0100 0.0100 −0.0063 −0.0291** −0.0210 −0.0633*** 0.2881*** −0.6028***
(−0.02) (−0.68) (0.25) (−1.50) (−2.57) (−0.78) (−5.80) (6.07) (−2.79)
First-stage
Instrumental variable
Entry Barriers 0.0312*** 0.0312*** 0.0312*** 0.0076 0.0076 0.0076 0.0418*** 0.0418*** 0.0418***
(3.18) (3.18) (3.18) (0.82) (0.82) (0.82) (28.11) (28.11) (28.11)
Control of Corruption −0.0136** −0.0136** −0.0136** −0.0401** −0.0401** −0.0401** −0.0225*** −0.0225*** −0.0225***
(−2.14) (−2.14) (−2.14) (−2.37) (−2.37) (−2.37) (−7.05) (−7.05) (−7.05)
First stage F-test of instruments 16.19 16.19 16.19 13.24 13.24 13.24 104.23 104.23 104.23
p value 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0056 0.0056 0.0056 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Hansen J-test of overidentifying restrictions 1.979 2.047 2.315 1.216 2.510 1.103 0.668 0.944 1.709
p value 0.1595 0.1525 0.1281 0.2701 0.1131 0.5761 0.4137 0.3312 0.1911
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK

Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.0308 0.0504 0.0188 0.0351 0.0273 0.0141 0.0148 0.0678 0.0264
Observations 118,894 118,894 118,894 14,806 14,806 14,806 44,936 44,936 44,936

Notes: This table reports the results of IV regressions on the relation between market power and liquidity risk. Panels A, B, and C show the second-stage regression results for all banks, large banks (total assets
greater than US$1 billion), and small banks (total assets less than or equal to US$100 million), respectively. The dependent variables of the second-stage regressions are liquidity risks from committed credit lines
(Credit Lines), liquid asset holdings (Liquid Assets), and liquidity creation (Liquidity Creation). Assets2 is the squared bank size term. The lower panel of the table shows the first-stage regression results—the dependent
variable is the Lerner index (Lerner)—for our IV. The first stage F-test and the Hansen’s J-test check for the relevance and the validity of the instruments, respectively. Robust standard errors are clustered by country.
Detailed information on the variables is provided in Table 1. The z-statistics are in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
13
14 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

a country as IV. Tighter entry restrictions help with Panel A. In addition, the F-statistic and
banks increase market power (Cetorelli and Stra- J-statistic of small banks also confirm that our
han 2006; Claessens and Laeven 2004). Control IV are valid.
of Corruption measures the degree to which pub-
lic power is exercised for private gain. Corruption B. Tobit Analysis
hinders transparency and effective competition.
Panel A shows that coefficients of Lerner for Table 7 reports the results of panel Tobit
Credit Lines and Liquidity Creation are positive regressions of market power on liquidity risk
and statistically significant. These results indi- from committed credit lines and liquid reserves.
cate that banks with greater market power take The Tobit estimations also show consistent
on more liquidity risk. With respect to IV, Entry results with our previous findings. Specifically,
Barriers is positively (0.0312) and significantly Panels A, B, and C provide results for all banks,
related to Lerner, and therefore, consistent with large banks (total assets greater than US$1 bil-
the above notion. Control of Corruption is nega- lion), and small banks (total assets less than or
tively (−0.0136) and significantly associated with equal to US$100 million), respectively. Panel A
Lerner, implying that a country with better con- shows a positive relationship between market
trol of corruption has a more competitive bank- power and liquidity risk. For liquidity risk from
ing system. To be valid, the IV should satisfy committed credit lines, the coefficient of Lerner
two conditions. First, they have to be exogenous is positive and statistically significant at the 1%
to liquidity risk-taking during the sample period. level, suggesting that banks with greater market
Second, they have to be correlated with mar- power take more liquidity risk by increasing the
ket power. We present the results of specification exposure to committed credit lines. For liquidity
tests regarding the relevance and the validity of risk from liquid asset holdings, the coefficient of
the IV. The F-statistic and J-statistic show that Lerner is negative and statistically significant,
our instruments are appropriate. implying that banks with greater market power
In Panel B, the coefficients of Lerner in Mod- take more liquidity risk by reducing liquid asset
els (1)–(3) confirm that large banks take more reserves. Panel B presents that, during a crisis,
liquidity risk as they obtain more market power. large banks with greater market power do not
change their liquidity-risk taking behavior in
The coefficients of Lerner*Crisis in all models
terms of liquidity risk from committed credit
for large banks are insignificant, suggesting that
lines and from liquid asset holdings. Small
large banks with greater market power still take
banks in Panel C, however, reduce liquidity risk
on more liquidity risk during a crisis. For the IV,
as they have more market power during times
the coefficients of Entry Barriers and Control of
of crisis.
Corruption have the expected signs. The coef-
ficient of Control of Corruption is significantly
negative while that of Entry Barriers is insignifi- C. Dynamic Panel GMM Estimation
cantly positive. Table 8 reports the system GMM estimates
During normal times, small banks in Panel of the dynamic model. Panels A, B, and C pro-
C also show the same results as large banks; vide results for all banks, large banks (total
competition is beneficial for financial stabil- assets greater than US$1 billion), and small banks
ity of small banks. The coefficients of Lerner (total assets less than or equal to US$100 mil-
for Credit Lines and Liquidity Creation are lion), respectively. In Panel A, the lagged depen-
positive and statistically significant at the 1% dent variables (L. Credit Lines, L. Liquid Assets,
level while the coefficient of Liquid Assets is and L. Liquidity Creation) are positively and
insignificantly negative. During a crisis, how- significantly related to the dependent variables
ever, small banks decrease their liquidity risk (Credit Lines, Liquid Assets, and Liquidity Cre-
exposure when they have greater market power. ation), suggesting that a bank’s liquidity risk-
Lerner*Crisis is significantly negatively related taking behavior is highly persistent over time.
to Credit Lines and Liquidity Creation while it Consistent with our earlier results, market power
is significantly positively associated with Liquid has a positive and significant effect on a bank’s
Assets. These results suggest that competition liquidity risk-taking, even after controlling for
is detrimental for the stability of small banks the dynamic nature of the relationship between
in turbulent times. The coefficients of Entry competition and liquidity risk. The lower panel
Barriers and Control of Corruption of small in Table 8 shows test statistics and p values
banks also provide results that are consistent for the AR (1) and AR (2) tests as well as the
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK 15

TABLE 7
Tobit Analysis
Panel A: All Banks Panel B: Large Banks Panel C: Small Banks
Credit Lines Liquid Assets Credit Lines Liquid Assets Credit Lines Liquid Assets
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
Lerner 0.0241*** −0.0608*** 0.0439*** −0.0856*** 0.0129*** −0.0492***
(24.04) (−30.43) (9.27) (−11.07) (8.46) (−14.53)
Crisis −0.0315 0.0578 −0.0052*** 0.0446
(−1.48) (0.20) (−3.61) (1.08)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0134 0.0322 −0.0033** 0.0201***
(−0.85) (1.06) (−2.03) (3.50)
Assets 0.0153*** −0.0694*** 0.0345*** −0.0324** 0.0515*** −0.0672***
(8.90) (−20.76) (4.27) (−2.37) (10.82) (−6.40)
Assets2 −0.0005*** 0.0023*** −0.0011*** 0.0010** −0.0021*** 0.0017***
(−8.09) (17.77) (−4.34) (2.18) (−9.30) (3.43)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.2794*** 0.0116 −0.0560*** 0.0214 −0.2330*** 0.0551***
(−57.17) (1.18) (−2.93) (0.67) (−28.98) (2.97)
Equity Ratios 0.0664*** 0.0152*** 0.0945*** −0.0835*** 0.0898*** 0.0417
(26.87) (3.10) (6.80) (−3.74) (27.00) (0.86)
M&A Activity 0.0004 0.0025 0.0025 −0.0027 0.0027 −0.0091
(0.36) (1.16) (1.09) (−0.71) (0.71) (−1.00)
GDP per Capita 0.0397*** −0.0836*** 0.0454*** −0.0640*** 0.0916*** −0.1220***
(21.35) (−25.82) (11.21) (−9.77) (12.75) (−11.73)
GDP Growth Rates −0.1867*** 0.8465*** −0.2583*** 0.6455*** 0.0141 0.3010
(−8.29) (20.73) (−5.76) (9.11) (0.12) (1.48)
M2 to GDP −0.0245*** 0.0692*** −0.0303*** 0.0347*** −0.1039*** 0.1753***
(−25.24) (40.83) (−16.46) (11.58) (−16.85) (26.08)
Constant −0.4309*** 1.4098*** −0.6293*** 1.0525*** −1.1397*** 1.7734***
(−18.78) (34.17) (−8.34) (8.38) (−14.34) (14.48)
Time dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Wald χ2 14,985.00 9,580.79 1,023.82 532.71 4,364.15 6,095.95
p value 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
ρ 0.8177 0.7691 0.8309 0.8266 0.8085 0.6542
Observations 118,894 118,894 14,806 14,806 44,936 44,936

Notes: This table shows the results of the random-effect Tobit regressions regarding liquidity risk from committed credit lines
and liquid asset holdings because those two dependent variables are left-censored at zero. Panels A, B, and C show the results
for all banks, large banks (total assets greater than US$1 billion), and small banks (total assets less than or equal to US$100
million), respectively. Assets2 is the squared bank size term. Detailed information on the variables is provided in Table 1. This
table provides the estimated marginal effects. For dummy variables, the marginal effects are calculated as the discrete change in
the expected value of the dependent variables. Robust standard errors are clustered by country. The z-statistics are in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Sargan test. The AR (1) and AR (2) tests show D. Weighted Least Squares Regressions and
high first-order autocorrelation and no significant Subsample Regressions Excluding Banks in the
second-order autocorrelation. The Sargan test of United States
over-identifying restrictions does not reject the We note that most of our observations come
null hypothesis that the instruments are valid. from the United States. To assess whether our
Therefore, the statistics suggest that our specifi- results for the relationship between market power
cations are all appropriate. Panels B and C also and bank liquidity risk are driven by the United
confirm our previous findings; large banks do not States, we re-estimate our models as follows.
have significant coefficients for Lerner*Crisis, First, we conduct weighted least squares (WLS)
whereas small banks show a negative relationship regressions to limit the overrepresentation of U.S.
between market power and bank liquidity risk banks. The WLS regression results are presented
during a crisis, after controlling for the dynamic in Panel A. We weigh each observation by the
aspect of the relationship between competition inverse number of bank-year observations per
and liquidity risk. country. Consistent with our earlier regression
16
TABLE 8
Dynamic Panel Data Models
Panel A: All Banks Panel B: Large Banks Panel C: Small Banks
Credit Liquid Liquidity Credit Liquid Liquidity Credit Liquid Liquidity
Lines Assets Creation Lines Assets Creation Lines Assets Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
L. Credit Lines 0.6454*** 0.7539*** 0.5573***
(56.66) (24.75) (28.19)
L. Liquid Assets 0.4554*** 0.5422*** 0.4389***
(22.22) (10.06) (17.75)
L. Liquidity Creation 0.7756*** 0.8252*** 0.7371***
(64.45) (26.18) (45.18)
Lerner 0.0057*** −0.0352*** 0.0151* 0.0131** −0.0281* 0.0081* 0.0039** −0.0370*** −0.0002
(2.73) (−6.55) (1.90) (2.54) (−1.91) (1.85) (2.29) (−3.69) (−1.02)
Crisis −0.0212*** 0.0106* −0.0397*** −0.0074* 0.0103 −0.0297
(−7.75) (1.78) (−3.55) (−1.96) (0.82) (−0.92)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0108 −0.0042 −0.0144 −0.0027*** 0.0223* −0.0316***
(−0.87) (−0.28) (−0.48) (−2.63) (1.77) (−3.49)
Assets −0.0071 −0.0487** −0.0450 −0.0030 0.0092 −0.0292 −0.0359 −0.1233 0.2061**
(−0.95) (−1.96) (−1.22) (−0.22) (0.40) (−0.47) (−0.82) (−1.30) (2.68)
Assets2 0.0002 0.0011 0.0022 0.0002 −0.0001 0.0012 −0.0018** 0.0044 −0.0098***
(0.80) (1.08) (1.51) (0.45) (−0.09) (0.56) (−2.01) (0.99) (−3.53)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.0755*** 0.1418*** −0.1788*** −0.0760*** 0.2321*** −0.0906 −0.0633*** 0.1230*** −0.1800***
(−7.96) (6.91) (−5.03) (−2.59) (4.13) (−0.83) (−4.32) (2.91) (−2.98)
Equity Ratios 0.0140 −0.3837*** 0.2802*** 0.0701*** −0.0024 0.4145*** 0.0238 −0.3824*** −0.0458
(0.91) (−8.06) (3.93) (2.70) (−0.02) (3.09) (1.40) (−4.80) (−0.48)
M&A Activity 0.0007 −0.0050 −0.0099 0.0002 −0.0050 −0.0013 0.0133*** 0.0090 0.0086
(0.41) (−1.64) (−1.64) (0.08) (−1.10) (−0.14) (2.62) (0.99) (0.58)
GDP per Capita 0.0071** 0.0099 0.0387*** 0.0214*** −0.0068 0.0261 0.0230*** 0.0792*** 0.1287***
(2.38) (1.41) (4.34) (3.40) (−0.41) (1.05) (3.09) (3.74) (4.64)
GDP Growth Rates 0.1683*** −0.1547*** 0.4121*** −0.0870** 0.0115 −0.1176 0.0873 −1.4873*** 0.0599
(6.60) (−2.65) (4.67) (−2.01) (0.12) (−0.73) (1.47) (−7.16) (0.24)
M2 to GDP −0.0027 0.0145 −0.0070 −0.0092*** 0.0178 0.0169 −0.0585* 0.4691 −0.2704*
(−0.81) (0.92) (−0.59) (−2.71) (1.31) (1.18) (−1.70) (−0.77) (−1.84)
CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

Constant −0.0024 0.4044** −0.1576 −0.1871 −0.0104 −0.0625 −0.0132 0.4497 −2.1728***
(−0.04) (2.32) (−0.65) (−1.52) (−0.04) (−0.12) (−0.11) (0.82) (−2.96)
Time dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 105,908 105,908 105,908 12,948 12,948 12,948 38,907 38,907 38,907
Number of banks 10,694 10,694 10,694 2,102 2,102 2,102 5,071 5,071 5,071
Number of instruments 127 127 127 127 127 127 127 127 127
AR(1) (p value) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
AR(2) (p value) 0.9981 0.2770 0.7540 0.3478 0.0043 0.1019 0.8015 0.1193 0.4040
Sargan test (p value) 0.7545 0.8688 0.7178 0.8244 0.8097 0.5751 0.5958 0.2916 0.4956

Notes: This table shows the results of dynamic panel system GMM regressions. Panels A, B, and C show the results for all banks, large banks (total assets greater than US$1 billion), and small banks (total assets less
than or equal to US$100 million), respectively. The dependent variables are liquidity risks from committed credit lines (Credit Lines), liquid asset holdings (Liquid Assets), and liquidity creation (Liquidity Creation).
Detailed information on the variables is provided in Table 1. Assets2 is the squared bank size term. The number of instruments is fewer than the number of groups. The AR (1) and AR (2) show the Arellano-Bond tests
for first- and second-order autocorrelation in the first-differenced residuals. The Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions examines the validity of IV. Detailed information on the variables is provided in Table 1. The
z-statistics are in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK 17

results, we find a positive relationship between of money supply (M2) to control for market liq-
market power and bank liquidity risk. During a uidity in our previous regressions (Equations (4)
crisis, large banks with greater market power still and (5)).
take higher liquidity risk while small banks with Table 11 repeats the previous tests adding the
more market power decrease their liquidity risk- risk premium on lending (Panel A) and the real
taking. Second, we remove U.S. bank observa- interest rates (Panel B) to account for the effect
tions from the sample in Panel B. Our findings of market liquidity risk. The information on the
are robust to the exclusion of U.S. banks’ obser- risk premium on lending and the real interest
vations (Table 9). rates is obtained from the WDI. Risk Premium
on Lending is defined as the interest rate charged
E. Alternative Measure of Competition: Boone by banks on loans to private sector customers
Indicator minus the “risk free” treasury bill interest rate.
It has 112,750 observations because there are
The Boone indicator, defined as the elasticity missing values for some countries. It ranges from
of profits to marginal costs, was recently added −0.0005 to 0.0892, with a mean of 0.0318 and a
to the literature. The indicator captures competi- standard deviation of 0.0049. Real Interest Rates
tion via the reallocation of profits from inefficient is defined as the lending interest rate adjusted
banks to the efficient ones. Specifically, competi- for inflation, as measured by the GDP deflator. It
tion enhances performance of efficient banks with ranges from −0.0563 to 0.1473, with a mean of
lower marginal costs. The Boone indicator should 0.0302 and a standard deviation of 0.0170. Our
be negative, given that profits and marginal cost findings remain unchanged even after controlling
have a negative relationship. Hence, higher val- for the effect of market liquidity risk.
ues of the Boone indicator represent a less com- Moreover, we conduct several robustness tests
petitive industry. as follows. First, we replace bank fixed effects
We construct the Boone indicator following with country fixed effects. In this case, standard
Schaeck and Cihák (2014) by using marginal errors are clustered at the bank level to control
costs calculated from Equation (3), instead of for heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. The
using average costs. It ranges from −0.1280 to results are reported in Table 12.
0.0384, with a mean of −0.0552 and a standard Second, a higher level of credit line commit-
deviation of 0.0222. Table 10 shows the results ment and liquidity creation may not necessar-
for the Boone indicator. Panel A provides the ily imply higher liquidity risk if sufficient fund-
results for all banks. The coefficients of Credit ing sources support liquidity production. There-
Lines and Liquidity Creation are significantly fore, as shown in Table 13, we introduce the
positive, while the coefficient of Liquid Assets is short-term money market funding ratio (Short-
significantly negative. These results suggest that term Funding) as a funding side variable in the
an increase in a bank’s market power—through control variable set. Third, we re-estimate our
the reallocation of profits from inefficient banks models for bank size (shown in Table 5) by using
to efficient ones—leads the bank to take on more only the linear term (Assets), instead of using
liquidity risk. Panels B and C report the results both the linear term (Assets) and the squared
for large and small banks, respectively. During term (Assets2 ) in Equation (5). Finally, to check
a crisis, large banks with more market power whether our results are driven by outliers, we
do not change their liquidity risk-taking behav- repeat our tests by excluding largest banks (total
ior. However, small banks with greater market assets > US$100 billion or total assets > US$50
power, which may be attributed to efficient busi- billion) from the sample. Our results continue to
ness strategies, pursue more sound liquidity risk hold in all cases.
policies in turbulent times.

F. Market Liquidity Risk VII. CONCLUSION

Funding liquidity is closely related to mar- There is a rich body of research on the rela-
ket liquidity (Brunnermeier and Pedersen 2009). tionship between bank competition and financial
When market liquidity dries up, banks often stability from the perspective of credit risk or
face difficulties to sell assets without significant default risk. However, in spite of the importance
losses. Therefore, funding liquidity risk and mar- of liquidity risk, a few studies have done from this
ket liquidity risk should be considered simultane- perspective. Does the magnitude of competition
ously (Soula 2015). We included the magnitude affect banks’ liquidity risk-taking behavior? Does
18

TABLE 9
Weighted Least Squares Regressions and Subsample Regressions Excluding U.S. Banks
Panel A: WLS Regressions
Panel A1: All Banks Panel A2: Large Banks Panel A3: Small Banks
Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Lerner 0.0148*** −0.0364** 0.0971*** 0.0171** −0.0217* 0.0939** 0.0010** −0.1048*** 0.1037*
(3.89) (−2.15) (3.20) (2.40) (−1.77) (2.31) (2.15) (−2.82) (1.93)
Crisis 0.0207 0.1224*** −0.0363* −0.0275** 0.0693 −0.0094
(1.45) (3.69) (−1.98) (−2.35) (0.96) (−0.09)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0107 −0.0092 −0.1315 −0.0156** 0.0024* −0.0781**
(−0.46) (−0.19) (−1.58) (−2.14) (1.92) (−2.52)
Assets 0.0214*** −0.0406** 0.1820*** 0.0236** −0.1217*** −0.0281 0.0199 −0.0131 0.4394**
(3.85) (−2.56) (6.42) (2.16) (−3.34) (−0.42) (0.87) (−0.12) (2.04)
Assets2 −0.0004** 0.0009* −0.0072*** −0.0005 0.0036*** −0.0005 −0.0003 0.0027 −0.0172*
(−2.27) (1.82) (−7.44) (−0.80) (3.14) (−0.25) (−0.22) (0.54) (−1.90)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios 0.0270 −0.4122*** −0.0849 0.0310 −0.3553*** −0.2181* −0.0097 0.1146 0.8751**
(1.20) (−6.17) (−0.76) (1.02) (−4.52) (−1.78) (−0.10) (0.41) (2.10)
Equity Ratios 0.0481*** 0.0488 −0.5170*** 0.0609*** −0.1716*** −0.4939*** −0.0085 0.2491*** −0.6508***
(5.19) (1.59) (−9.71) (2.87) (−3.00) (−5.52) (−1.00) (4.04) (−7.59)
M&A Activity 0.0070 −0.0133* −0.0483*** 0.0052 −0.0168** −0.0522*** −0.0324*** −0.1224** −0.4204***
(1.49) (−1.85) (−3.15) (1.04) (−2.30) (−3.14) (−2.83) (−2.55) (−3.99)
GDP per Capita 0.0135 −0.2161*** −0.1421*** 0.0114 −0.1751*** −0.0624 0.0286** 0.2374*** −0.0984
(1.61) (−10.11) (−3.93) (1.00) (−6.29) (−1.43) (2.39) (2.86) (−0.84)
GDP Growth Rates 0.1733** 0.7398*** −0.4929 0.1607 0.7014*** −0.7758** −0.0354 0.5034 0.3426
CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

(2.28) (4.05) (−1.51) (1.62) (3.34) (−2.17) (−0.25) (0.62) (0.31)


M2 to GDP −0.0094*** 0.0090 0.0260* −0.0128*** 0.0107 0.0321* 0.0100 −0.2245*** −0.1580*
(−2.79) (0.84) (1.70) (−2.88) (0.91) (1.72) (1.04) (−3.21) (−1.65)
Constant −0.3442*** 2.8275*** 1.0379** −0.3480* 3.0806*** 1.8771*** −0.4730*** −2.0956** −0.7545
(−3.61) (11.74) (2.49) (−1.68) (7.76) (2.71) (−3.75) (−2.30) (−0.47)
Country fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.2445 0.2553 0.2822 0.2492 0.2608 0.2556 0.2712 0.3868 0.3920
Observations 118,894 118,894 118,894 14,806 14,806 14,806 44,936 44,936 44,936
TABLE 9
Continued
Panel B: FE Regressions excluding U.S. Banks
Panel B1: All Banks Panel B2: Large Banks Panel B3: Small Banks
Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Lerner 0.0076* −0.0502** 0.0451** 0.0092*** −0.0618** 0.0374*** 0.0701* −0.0231** 0.0832***
(1.98) (−2.23) (2.61) (3.10) (−2.11) (3.89) (1.90) (2.64) (3.06)
Crisis −0.0153 0.0693** −0.1174** 0.0100 0.5372 −0.6431*
(−0.83) (2.54) (−2.13) (0.54) (0.43) (−1.85)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0093 0.0278 0.0515 −0.0139* 0.1053*** −0.0553**
(−0.92) (1.00) (1.13) (−2.04) (2.97) (−2.35)
Assets 0.0280* −0.0326** 0.2110 0.0377* −0.0134 0.0610 0.0122 −0.0821 0.1403**
(1.74) (−2.36) (0.70) (1.83) (−0.33) (0.69) (0.48) (−0.50) (2.41)
Assets2 −0.0010* 0.0013* −0.0078 −0.0013* 0.0004 −0.0028 −0.0002** 0.0047 −0.0046
(−1.75) (1.92) (−0.58) (−1.75) (0.29) (−0.91) (−2.14) (0.57) (−0.30)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios 0.0027 0.1299 −0.1212 0.0068 0.0901 0.1667 −0.0656* 0.2219 −1.5615*
(0.09) (1.17) (−0.72) (0.16) (0.88) (0.94) (−1.88) (1.48) (−2.02)
Equity Ratios 0.0243** 0.0221 −0.4329*** 0.0982*** −0.0757 −0.2407 0.0267** 0.0156 −0.6778**
(2.54) (0.49) (−4.32) (2.86) (−1.00) (−1.70) (2.10) (0.13) (−2.40)
M&A Activity 0.0041 −0.0027 0.0052 0.0073 −0.0100 −0.0083 0.0023 −0.2108** −0.0603
(0.76) (−0.27) (0.26) (1.39) (−1.37) (−0.58) (0.13) (−2.72) (−0.71)
GDP per Capita 0.0245 −0.0582 0.0681 0.0263 −0.0966 0.0593 0.0013 −0.6490*** −0.8817
(1.22) (−0.65) (0.65) (1.09) (−1.59) (0.90) (0.05) (−3.04) (−1.63)
GDP Growth Rates −0.0585 0.6062*** −0.3896 −0.0896 0.4867*** −0.4841* 0.3099* 0.4764 −0.2719
(−0.84) (3.32) (−1.19) (−1.13) (3.05) (−1.80) (2.08) (0.99) (−0.24)
M2 to GDP −0.0039 −0.0199 0.0003 −0.0027 −0.0296** −0.0226 0.0198 −0.0061 0.0063
(−1.49) (−1.12) (0.01) (−1.10) (−2.44) (−0.70) (1.12) (−0.04) (0.03)
Constant −0.3917 0.6799 −1.4034 −0.4810 1.3974** −0.1824 −0.1517 7.1445*** 8.5298
(−1.44) (0.69) (−1.27) (−1.59) (2.36) (−0.23) (−0.54) (2.94) (1.32)
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK

R2 0.0175 0.0189 0.0436 0.0288 0.0327 0.0470 0.0404 0.1098 0.2064


Observations 12,797 12,797 12,797 7,553 7,553 7,553 720 720 720

Notes: This table shows the results to mitigate the concern for overrepresentation of U.S. banks. Panel A reports the results of the WLS regressions. Panels A1, A2, and A3 show the
results for all banks, large banks (total assets greater than US$1 billion), and small banks (total assets less than or equal to US$100 million), respectively. Each observation is weighted by
the inverse number of bank-year observations in the corresponding country. Panel B presents the FE regression results for banks in all sample countries, excluding the US. Panels B1, B2,
and B3 show the results for all banks, large banks, and small banks, respectively. The dependent variables are liquidity risks from committed credit lines (Credit Lines), liquid asset holdings
(Liquid Assets), and liquidity creation (Liquidity Creation). Detailed information on the variables is provided in Table 1. Robust standard errors are clustered by country. The t-statistics are
in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
19
20

TABLE 10
Alternative Measure of Competition: Boone Indicator
Panel A: All Banks Panel B: Large Banks Panel C: Small Banks
Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Boone 0.0232** −0.0662* 0.1943*** 0.0853*** −0.0385 0.1777* 0.1235** −0.4161** 0.1249***
(2.08) (−1.93) (4.99) (2.83) (−1.50) (2.03) (2.32) (−2.15) (3.24)
Crisis −0.0136* 0.0877*** 0.0767 −0.0278** 0.0671 0.0724
(−1.72) (3.88) (1.53) (−2.33) (1.08) (0.70)
Boone*Crisis 0.0508 0.2586 0.1226 −0.0391** 0.3236* −0.0871**
(1.63) (1.39) (0.83) (−2.52) (1.99) (−2.23)
Assets 0.0155*** −0.0727*** 0.0119 0.0283* −0.0288 0.0457 0.0389*** −0.0600*** −0.0383
(2.99) (−6.63) (0.36) (1.91) (−1.28) (0.87) (17.09) (−7.47) (−1.23)
Assets2 −0.0006*** 0.0019*** −0.0001 −0.0010 0.0007 −0.0014 −0.0016*** 0.0008** 0.0028*
(−2.92) (4.86) (−0.09) (−1.53) (1.01) (−0.72) (−15.30) (2.19) (1.88)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.3101*** 0.1161*** −0.3842*** −0.1308 0.1529** −0.0763 −0.2483*** 0.1140*** −0.2617***
(−6.01) (6.76) (−11.26) (−1.58) (2.28) (−0.54) (−80.28) (28.91) (−9.07)
Equity Ratios 0.0529*** −0.0209** −0.1424*** 0.0663** −0.1104*** 0.0958 0.0672*** 0.0015 −0.1712***
(8.55) (−2.71) (−2.92) (2.16) (−2.83) (0.56) (22.88) (0.17) (−4.32)
M&A Activity 0.0004 0.0025 −0.0167** 0.0038 −0.0051 0.0019 0.0018*** −0.0067* −0.0176***
(0.19) (0.99) (−2.72) (1.06) (−0.96) (0.20) (19.14) (−2.07) (−17.16)
GDP per Capita 0.0170 −0.0476 −0.0315 0.0309* −0.1067** −0.0667 −0.0176 −0.0135 −0.1673
(1.62) (−0.99) (−0.38) (2.05) (−2.58) (−0.97) (−1.03) (−0.13) (−0.85)
GDP Growth Rates −0.1943*** 0.8477*** −0.5933*** −0.2418** 0.6766*** −0.4048 0.0745 0.5753* 0.2422
(−2.93) (4.78) (−3.25) (−2.55) (3.69) (−1.71) (0.56) (1.75) (0.43)
M2 to GDP −0.0026 −0.0118 −0.0023 −0.0035 −0.0267** −0.0160 0.0160 0.1316 0.2604
(−0.64) (−0.79) (−0.05) (−0.85) (−2.31) (−0.55) (0.69) (0.87) (1.21)
CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

Constant −0.1921 1.1818** 0.4813 −0.4220* 1.5389*** 0.7459 −0.0165 0.6432 1.8662
(−1.58) (2.34) (0.53) (−1.94) (4.02) (1.06) (−0.10) (0.62) (0.93)
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.1158 0.0634 0.1125 0.0545 0.0288 0.0445 0.0862 0.1039 0.1763
Observations 118,894 118,894 118,894 14,806 14,806 14,806 44,936 44,936 44,936

Notes: This table shows fixed effects regression estimates, employing the Boone indicator as an alternative measure of competition. Panels A, B, and C show the results for all banks, large
banks (total assets greater than US$1 billion), and small banks (total assets less than or equal to US$100 million), respectively. The dependent variables are liquidity risks from committed
credit lines (Credit Lines), liquid asset holdings (Liquid Assets), and liquidity creation (Liquidity Creation). Detailed information on the variables is provided in Table 1. Robust standard
errors are clustered by country. The t-statistics are in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
TABLE 11
Market Liquidity Risk
Panel A: Risk Premium on Lending
Panel A1: All Banks Panel A2: Large Banks Panel A3: Small Banks
Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Lerner 0.0273*** −0.0603*** 0.0753*** 0.0435*** −0.1023*** 0.1017*** 0.0213*** −0.0556*** 0.0726***
(33.65) (−17.85) (9.56) (5.26) (−6.75) (3.39) (30.13) (−71.01) (18.41)
Crisis 0.0010 0.0489* 0.0601 −0.0109** 0.0447 0.1350
(0.03) (1.96) (1.07) (−2.17) (1.62) (1.39)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0161 0.0513 −0.0867 −0.0010* 0.0192*** −0.0413***
(−0.96) (1.58) (−1.62) (−1.81) (6.83) (−12.02)
Assets 0.0123** −0.0656*** −0.0239 0.0123 −0.0289 0.0147 0.0427*** −0.0688*** −0.0400
(2.41) (−10.69) (−0.97) (0.52) (−1.00) (0.18) (34.86) (−8.56) (−1.13)
Assets2 −0.0006** 0.0017*** 0.0011 −0.0004 0.0008 0.0000 −0.0019*** 0.0015*** 0.0025
(−2.76) (7.11) (1.14) (−0.52) (0.94) (0.02) (−29.77) (4.38) (1.15)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.3012*** 0.0343** −0.2882*** −0.1636** 0.0912* 0.0510 −0.2223*** 0.0470*** −0.2029***
(−11.75) (2.64) (−11.73) (−2.84) (2.04) (0.39) (−509.73) (16.03) (−18.19)
Equity Ratios 0.0607*** −0.0360*** −0.1063*** 0.0446 −0.1017* 0.3330*** 0.0739*** −0.0139 −0.1495***
(15.32) (−4.59) (−3.85) (1.26) (−1.90) (8.71) (66.35) (−1.41) (−4.80)
M&A Activity 0.0030 0.0031 −0.0126 0.0050 0.0002 0.0062 0.0020*** −0.0047*** −0.0167***
(1.52) (1.46) (−1.65) (1.34) (0.04) (0.68) (81.45) (−51.52) (−93.09)
GDP per Capita −0.0061 −0.0342 0.0126 −0.0012 −0.0993* −0.0727 0.0050 −0.1032 −0.1499
(−0.57) (−0.57) (0.15) (−0.07) (−2.02) (−0.93) (0.38) (−0.83) (−0.43)
GDP Growth Rates −0.0519 0.5960** −0.1256 −0.0971 0.3405 −0.4585 0.0389 1.2266** 1.1965
(−0.50) (2.14) (−0.26) (−0.71) (1.26) (−0.77) (0.40) (2.51) (0.89)
M2 to GDP 0.0215** −0.0185 0.1900* 0.0262** −0.0752 0.0884 −0.0008 0.2837 0.4639
(2.37) (−0.24) (2.07) (2.25) (−0.95) (1.30) (−0.04) (1.10) (1.37)
Risk Premium on Lending 0.0915 −0.1087 0.2819 0.1073 −0.3060 0.4174 0.4453** 1.1177 0.6510
(0.60) (−0.19) (0.31) (0.41) (−0.61) (0.49) (2.49) (0.98) (0.40)
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK

Constant 0.0530 0.9982 0.0767 0.0064 1.4897*** 0.7558 −0.2566* 1.4773 1.5132
(0.48) (1.60) (0.09) (0.02) (3.44) (0.87) (−2.07) (1.25) (0.45)
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.1411 0.0871 0.1303 0.1011 0.0548 0.0672 0.0923 0.1123 0.1822
Observations 112,750 112,750 112,750 11,042 11,042 11,042 44,625 44,625 44,625
21
22
TABLE 11
Continued
Panel B: Real Interest Rates
Panel B1: All Banks Panel B2: Large Banks Panel B3: Small Banks
Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Lerner 0.0273*** −0.0599*** 0.0751*** 0.0410*** −0.0991*** 0.0976*** 0.0213*** −0.0559*** 0.0722***
(32.54) (−16.96) (9.54) (4.33) (−6.28) (3.11) (29.29) (−82.42) (16.66)
Crisis −0.0030 0.0305** −0.1156 −0.0158** −0.0036 0.0552
(−0.33) (2.20) (−0.95) (−2.54) (−0.09) (0.55)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0129 0.0543 −0.0800 −0.0009* 0.0196*** −0.0410***
(−1.34) (1.56) (−0.45) (−1.88) (8.25) (−13.99)
Assets 0.0132** −0.0607*** −0.0199 0.0226 −0.0162 0.0240 0.0427*** −0.0686*** −0.0395
(2.64) (−6.46) (−0.74) (0.87) (−0.50) (0.31) (33.96) (−8.86) (−1.18)
Assets2 −0.0006*** 0.0015*** 0.0010 −0.0008 0.0003 −0.0004 −0.0019*** 0.0015*** 0.0025
(−3.01) (4.00) (0.88) (−0.88) (0.31) (−0.14) (−29.25) (4.47) (1.22)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.2984*** 0.0377** −0.2949*** −0.1638** 0.1264* −0.0497 −0.2223*** 0.0471*** −0.2027***
(−10.78) (2.64) (−11.77) (−2.83) (2.08) (−0.37) (−442.98) (17.47) (−18.58)
Equity Ratios 0.0610*** −0.0332*** −0.1060*** 0.0453 −0.1012* 0.3143*** 0.0738*** −0.0136 −0.1489***
(15.24) (−4.53) (−3.70) (1.32) (−1.92) (7.20) (63.49) (−1.45) (−4.92)
M&A Activity 0.0024 0.0018 −0.0136* 0.0048 −0.0016 0.0067 0.0020*** −0.0047*** −0.0167***
(1.17) (0.73) (−1.96) (1.19) (−0.36) (0.73) (83.52) (−50.75) (−90.98)
GDP per Capita 0.0084 −0.0482 −0.0278 0.0154 −0.0981* −0.1158 0.0054 −0.0675 −0.0957
(0.66) (−0.76) (−0.34) (0.88) (−2.04) (−1.69) (0.42) (−0.52) (−0.30)
GDP Growth Rates −0.0227 0.4591* −0.1599 −0.0668 0.2078 −0.3921 −0.0179 0.6404 0.5204
(−0.19) (1.75) (−0.39) (−0.50) (1.15) (−0.91) (−0.19) (1.71) (0.47)
M2 to GDP 0.0193 −0.0179 0.1565* 0.0288** −0.0610 0.0652 −0.0001 0.2840 0.4631
(1.61) (−0.25) (2.05) (2.17) (−0.88) (1.03) (−0.01) (1.23) (1.48)
Real Interest Rates 0.0093 −0.0934 0.6741 0.0344 −0.3094 0.9697** 0.1711* −0.4259 −0.9959
CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

(0.15) (−0.46) (1.33) (0.46) (−1.31) (2.81) (1.99) (−0.67) (−0.94)


Constant −0.1010 1.1252 0.4661 −0.2414 1.4028*** 1.1301 −0.2549* 1.1927 1.0605
(−0.73) (1.70) (0.55) (−0.82) (3.24) (1.42) (−2.07) (0.96) (0.33)
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.1391 0.0864 0.1282 0.0940 0.0561 0.0659 0.0924 0.1122 0.1822
Observations 113,489 113,489 113,489 11,520 11,520 11,520 44,650 44,650 44,650

Notes: This table shows fixed effects regression estimates, adding the risk premium on lending (Panel A) and the real interest rates (Panel B) as proxies for market liquidity risk in the
regressions. Panels A1 (B1), A2 (B2), and A3 (B3) provide the results for all banks, large banks (total assets greater than US$1 billion), and small banks (total assets less than or equal to
US$100 million), respectively. The dependent variables are liquidity risk from committed credit lines (Credit Lines), liquid asset holdings (Liquid Assets), and liquidity creation (Liquidity
Creation). Assets2 is the squared bank size term. Detailed information on the variables is provided in Table 1. Risk Premium on Lending is defined as lending rates minus the treasury bill
rates. Real Interest Rates is defined as the lending interest rate adjusted for inflation, as measured by the GDP deflator. Robust standard errors are clustered by country. The t-statistics are in
parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
TABLE 12
Country Fixed Effects
Panel A: All Banks Panel B: Large Banks Panel C: Small Banks
Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation Credit Lines Liquid Assets Liquidity Creation
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Lerner 0.0206*** −0.0554*** 0.0563*** 0.0343*** −0.0748*** 0.0799*** 0.0117*** −0.0508*** 0.0407***
(12.17) (−12.31) (7.43) (6.04) (−5.26) (3.18) (4.69) (−7.18) (3.62)
Crisis −0.0338*** 0.0857*** 0.0088 0.0071 0.0418 0.0664
(−4.76) (5.86) (0.32) (0.74) (1.13) (1.05)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0074 0.0260 −0.0452 −0.0040** 0.0176** −0.0350***
(−1.12) (1.49) (−1.21) (−2.26) (2.17) (−2.87)
Assets 0.0107*** −0.0709*** 0.0308* 0.0240* −0.0326 0.0566 0.0475*** −0.0760** −0.0211
(2.66) (−7.46) (1.79) (1.72) (−1.53) (1.29) (4.44) (−2.01) (−0.45)
Assets2 −0.0002 0.0021*** −0.0009 −0.0006 0.0010 −0.0021 −0.0019*** 0.0020 0.0017
(−1.26) (5.68) (−1.40) (−1.32) (1.41) (−1.46) (−3.78) (1.15) (0.79)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.2791*** 0.0323* −0.2902*** −0.1056*** 0.0668 −0.0841 −0.2284*** 0.0501 −0.1692***
(−29.73) (1.66) (−8.34) (−3.36) (1.19) (−0.81) (−17.90) (1.60) (−3.11)
Equity Ratios 0.0761*** −0.0091 −0.1174*** 0.0897*** −0.0825* 0.0444 0.0908*** 0.0170 −0.1220***
(13.93) (−0.71) (−4.60) (3.42) (−1.86) (0.36) (14.06) (0.93) (−4.44)
M&A Activity 0.0003 0.0022 −0.0180*** 0.0022 −0.0046 −0.0020 0.0019 −0.0085 −0.0148
(0.19) (0.79) (−3.00) (0.76) (−1.02) (−0.21) (0.39) (−1.22) (−0.91)
GDP per Capita 0.0102* −0.0569*** −0.0345 0.0265** −0.0950*** 0.0744 −0.0222 0.1026 −0.1873
(1.70) (−3.48) (−1.30) (2.57) (−4.33) (1.01) (−1.54) (1.10) (−1.15)
GDP Growth Rates −0.1928*** 0.8909*** −0.6278*** −0.2534*** 0.6853*** −0.4459** 0.0084 0.6069 0.2725
(−5.65) (9.52) (−4.19) (−5.49) (6.19) (−2.29) (0.07) (1.61) (0.46)
M2 to GDP −0.0036 −0.0101 0.0012 −0.0048 −0.0239* −0.0099 0.0198 0.0169 0.1781
(−1.12) (−0.94) (0.07) (−1.11) (−1.84) (−0.50) (1.16) (0.18) (1.06)
Constant −0.2105*** 1.4293*** 0.7468** −0.4777*** 1.5648*** 1.0284** −0.1182 −0.2945 2.1456
(−3.00) (7.90) (2.48) (−3.06) (5.93) (2.06) (−0.83) (−0.33) (1.32)
Country fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.1158 0.0693 0.1148 0.0552 0.0332 0.0452 0.0890 0.1078 0.1783
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK

Observations 118,894 118,894 118,894 14,806 14,806 14,806 44,936 44,936 44,936

Notes: This table shows fixed effects regression estimates of market power on liquidity risk, using country fixed effects. Panels A, B, and C provides the results for all banks, large banks
(total assets greater than US$1 billion), and small banks (total assets less than or equal to US$100 million), respectively. The dependent variables are liquidity risk from committed credit
lines (Credit Lines), liquid asset holdings (Liquid Assets), and liquidity creation (Liquidity Creation). Assets2 is the squared bank size term. Detailed information on the variables is provided
in Table 1. Robust standard errors are clustered at the bank level. The t-statistics are in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
23
24 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

TABLE 13
Funding Structure
Panel A: All Banks Panel B: Large Banks Panel C: Small Banks
Credit Liquidity Credit Liquidity Credit Liquidity
Lines Creation Lines Creation Lines Creation
(1) (2) (1) (2) (1) (2)
Lerner 0.0262*** 0.0680*** 0.0345*** 0.0663* 0.0210*** 0.0735***
(15.09) (5.28) (3.22) (1.80) (23.71) (16.83)
Crisis 0.0143 0.0838 −0.0112** −0.1289*
(1.04) (1.46) (−2.21) (−2.00)
Lerner*Crisis −0.0100 −0.0327 −0.0006* −0.0381***
(−1.51) (−0.54) (−1.78) (−11.18)
Short-term Funding 0.0084 0.1254 −0.0040 0.1680*** 0.0212*** 0.0084
(0.93) (1.56) (−0.46) (3.09) (6.78) (0.18)
Assets 0.0102** 0.0008 0.0284 0.0471 0.0410*** −0.0330
(2.09) (0.02) (1.68) (0.86) (13.99) (−0.76)
Assets2 −0.0005** 0.0001 −0.0010 −0.0016 −0.0018*** 0.0022
(−2.42) (0.04) (−1.68) (−0.80) (−13.54) (0.69)
Nonperforming Loans Ratios −0.2751*** −0.2892*** −0.1105 −0.0460 −0.2209*** −0.1803***
(−6.19) (−9.19) (−1.63) (−0.34) (−146.48) (−6.06)
Equity Ratios 0.0565*** −0.1277** 0.0583* 0.1016 0.0711*** −0.1581***
(7.07) (−2.63) (1.93) (0.64) (17.46) (−3.94)
M&A Activity 0.0001 −0.0163** 0.0030 0.0025 0.0018*** −0.0175***
(0.04) (−2.67) (0.88) (0.28) (23.48) (−9.79)
GDP per Capita 0.0189* −0.0174 0.0276* −0.0688 −0.0051 −0.1561
(1.77) (−0.20) (1.82) (−0.96) (−0.34) (−0.80)
GDP Growth Rates −0.1997*** −0.6285*** −0.2539** −0.3810* 0.0109 0.1845
(−3.31) (−3.27) (−2.60) (−1.81) (0.08) (0.40)
M2 to GDP −0.0022 −0.0037 −0.0035 −0.0189 0.0157 0.2515
(−0.56) (−0.08) (−0.82) (−0.67) (0.74) (1.13)
Constant −0.1713 0.4344 −0.3812* 0.7653 −0.1355 1.7517
(−1.39) (0.44) (−1.76) (1.03) (−0.91) (0.86)
Bank fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.1218 0.1172 0.0592 0.0522 0.0914 0.1794
Observations 118,894 118,894 14,806 14,806 44,936 44,936

Notes: This table shows fixed effects regression estimates of market power on liquidity risk, controlling for the funding
structure. Panels A, B, and C provide the results for all banks, large banks (total assets greater than US$1 billion), and small
banks (total assets less than or equal to US$100 million), respectively. The dependent variables are liquidity risk from committed
credit lines (Credit Lines) and liquidity creation (Liquidity Creation). Short-term Funding is the ratio of short-term wholesale
funding to total assets. Assets2 is the squared bank size term. Detailed information on the variables is provided in Table 1. Robust
standard errors are clustered by country. The t-statistics are in parentheses.
***, **, and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

the impact of competition on liquidity risk change different econometric specifications. During the
during the crisis? Is there a difference between crisis, however, the effects of bank market power
large and small banks in changing their liquidity on liquidity risk vary across bank size. When
risk-taking incentives depending on the degree of the economy tightens, large banks do not change
competition during the crisis? We seek answers their liquidity risk-taking behavior as they obtain
to these three questions and contribute to the lit- more market power. Instead, large banks with
erature on competition, liquidity risk, and finan- greater market power increase the exposure to
cial stability. committed credit lines during the financial cri-
Using commercial bank data from 25 OECD sis of 2008. This implies that large banks with
countries during the period 2000–2010, we find greater market power take more liquidity risk,
evidence that banks take on more liquidity risk due to the fact that they are more likely to be
as they achieve greater market power. This result bailed out during times of financial turbulence. In
implies that competition is beneficial to finan- contrast, small banks with greater market power
cial stability. This result is robust after controlling reduce liquidity risk-taking during the crisis by
for endogeneity concerns, and is robust across holding more liquid assets and by creating less
KIM: THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON BANK LIQUIDITY RISK 25

liquidity. These results suggest that increased Bikker, J. A., S. Shaffer, and L. Spierdijk. “Assessing Com-
charter value from enhanced market power con- petition with the Panzar-Rosse Model: The Role of
Scale, Costs, and Equilibrium.” Review of Economics
tributes to small banks’ financial stability dur- and Statistics, 94(4), 2012, 1025–44.
ing the crisis. To put it differently, if competi- Blundell, R., and S. Bond. “Initial Conditions and Moment
tion becomes more severe, small banks, which are Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models.” Journal
of Econometrics, 87(1), 1998, 115–43.
less likely to be bailed out, are subject to higher Boone, J. “A New Way to Measure Competition.” Economic
risk-shifting incentives to survive when the econ- Journal, 118(531), 2008, 1245–61.
omy tightens. Boyd, J. H., and M. Gertler. “The Role of Large Banks in the
Recent US Banking Crisis.” Federal Reserve Bank of
While this paper is the first to empirically Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 18(1), 1994, 2–21.
investigate the relationship between competition Boyd, J. H., and G. D. Nicoló. “The Theory of Bank Risk
and stability in terms of bank liquidity risk, it Taking and Competition Revisited.” Journal of Finance,
has some limitations which are worth including 60(3), 2005, 1329–43.
Boyd, J. H., G. D. Nicoló, and A. M. Jalal. “Bank Risk-
in future work. First, as mentioned above, our liq- Taking and Competition Revisited: New Theory and
uidity risk measures are incomplete because there New Evidence.” International Monetary Fund Working
are no concrete liquidity risk measures at present. Paper No. 06/297, 2007.
Brunnermeier, M. K., and M. Oehmke. “The Maturity Rat
Therefore, it would be interesting to investigate Race.” Journal of Finance, 68(2), 2013, 483–521.
the effect of competition on liquidity risk by Brunnermeier, M. K., and L. H. Pedersen. “Market Liquidity
using more rigorous liquidity risk measures in and Funding Liquidity.” Review of Financial Studies,
the future. Second, this study does not consider 22(6), 2009, 2201–38.
Bryant, J. “A Model of Reserves, Bank Runs, and Deposit
the potential interactions between liquidity risk Insurance.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 4(4),
and other bank risks, such as credit risk or over- 1980, 335–44.
all bank risks. Exploring such interactions would Carletti, E. “Competition and Regulation in Banking.” Hand-
book of Financial Intermediation and Banking, 126(5),
be an important extension for future work. 2008, 449–82.
Carletti, E., and A. Leonello. “Credit Market Competition and
Liquidity Crises.” Center for Economic Studies and Ifo
REFERENCES Institute Working Paper Series No. 4647, 2014.
Carletti, E., P. Hartmann, and G. Spagnolo. “Bank Mergers,
Acharya, V., and N. Mora. “A Crisis of Banks as Liquidity Competition, and Liquidity.” Journal of Money, Credit,
Providers.” Journal of Finance, 70(1), 2015, 1–43. and Banking, 39(5), 2007, 1067–105.
Acharya, V., and H. Naqvi. “The Seeds of a Crisis: A Theory Cetorelli, N., and P. E. Strahan. “Finance as a Barrier to Entry:
of Bank Liquidity and Risk Taking over the Business Bank Competition and Industry Structure in Local US
Cycle.” Journal of Financial Economics, 106(2), 2012, Markets.” Journal of Finance, 61(1), 2006, 437–61.
349–66. Claessens, S., and L. Laeven. “What Drives Bank Competi-
Akins, B., L. Li, J. Ng, and T. O. Rusticus. “Bank Competition tion? Some International Evidence.” Journal of Money,
and Financial Stability: Evidence from the Financial Credit, and Banking, 36(3), 2004, 563–83.
Crisis.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Cornett, M. M., J. J. McNutt, P. E. Strahan, and H. Tehra-
51(01), 2016, 1–28. nian. “Liquidity Risk Management and Credit Supply in
Allen, F., and D. Gale. “Financial Fragility, Liquidity, and the Financial Crisis.” Journal of Financial Economics,
Asset Prices.” Journal of the European Economic Asso- 101(2), 2011, 297–312.
ciation, 2(6), 2004, 1015–48. Demsetz, R. S., and P. E. Strahan. “Diversification, Size, and
Arellano, M., and O. Bover. “Another Look at the Instrumen- Risk at Bank Holding Companies.” Journal of Money,
tal Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models.” Credit, and Banking, 29(3), 1997, 300–13.
Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 1995, 29–51. Diamond, D. W., and P. H. Dybvig. “Bank Runs, Deposit
Barth, J. R., G. Caprio, and R. Levine. “The Regulation Insurance, and Liquidity.” Journal of Political Econ-
and Supervision of Banks around the World: A New omy, 91(3), 1983, 401–19.
Database.” World Bank Policy Research Working Diamond, D. W., and R. G. Rajan. “Liquidity Risk, Liq-
Paper No. 2588, 2001 (Updated in 2003, 2008, uidity Creation, and Financial Fragility: A Theory of
and 2012). Banking.” Journal of Political Economy, 109(2), 2001,
Beck, T., A. Demirgüç-Kunt, and R. Levine. “Bank Concen- 287–327.
tration, Competition, and Crises: First Results.” Journal Drehmann, M., and K. Nikolaou. “Funding Liquidity Risk:
of Banking and Finance, 30(5), 2006, 1581–603. Definition and Measurement.” Journal of Banking and
Beck, T., D. Coyle, M. Dewatripont, X. Freixas, and Finance, 37(7), 2013, 2173–82.
P. Seabright. “Bailing Out the Banks: Reconciling Elsas, R., A. Hackethal, and M. Holzhäuser. “The Anatomy of
Stability and Competition.” Centre for Economic Bank Diversification.” Journal of Banking and Finance,
Policy Research, Working Paper 2010. 34(6), 2010, 1274–87.
Berger, A. N., and C. H. S. Bouwman. “Bank Liquidity Farhi, E., and J. Tirole. “Collective Moral Hazard, Matu-
Creation.” Review of Financial Studies, 22(9), 2009, rity Mismatch, and Systemic Bailouts.” American Eco-
3779–837. nomic Review, 102(1), 2012, 60–93.
Berger, A. N., L. Klapper, and R. Turk-Ariss. “Bank Com- Gatev, E., and P. E. Strahan. “Banks Advantage in Hedging
petition and Financial Stability.” Journal of Financial Liquidity Risk: Theory and Evidence from the Com-
Services Research, 35(2), 2009, 99–118. mercial Paper Market.” Journal of Finance, 61(2), 2006,
Bhattacharya, S., and A. V. Thakor. “Contemporary Bank- 867–92.
ing Theory.” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 3(1), Gatev, E., T. Schuermann, and P. E. Strahan. “Managing Bank
1993, 2–50. Liquidity Risk: How Deposit-Loan Synergies Vary with
26 CONTEMPORARY ECONOMIC POLICY

Market Conditions.” Review of Financial Studies, 22(3), Krishnamurthy, A., J. Bai, and C. H. Weymuller. “Mea-
2009, 995–1020. suring Liquidity Mismatch in the Banking Sector.”
Gropp, R., H. Hakenes, and I. Schnabel. “Competition, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
Risk-Shifting, and Public Bail-Out Policies.” Review of No. 22729, 2016.
Financial Studies, 24(6), 2011, 2084–120. Marcus, A. J. “Deregulation and Bank Financial Policy.”
Hakenes, H., and I. Schnabel. “Banks without Parachutes: Journal of Banking and Finance, 8(4), 1984, 557–65.
Competitive Effects of Government Bail-Out Poli- Matutes, C., and X. Vives. “Competition for Deposits,
cies.” Journal of Financial Stability, 6(3), 2010, Fragility, and Insurance.” Journal of Financial
156–68. intermediation, 5(2), 1996, 184–216.
Hellmann, T. F., K. C. Murdock, and J. E. Stiglitz. “Liberal- Molyneux, P., and J. Thornton. “Determinants of European
ization, Moral Hazard in Banking, and Prudential Reg- Bank Profitability: A Note.” Journal of Banking and
ulation: Are Capital Requirements Enough?” American Finance, 16(6), 1992, 1173–78.
Economic Review, 90(1), 2000, 147–65. Nicoló, D. G., and E. Loukoianova. “Bank Ownership, Mar-
Holmström, B., and J. Tirole. “Private and Public Supply of ket Structure and Risk.” International Monetary Fund
Liquidity.” Journal of Political Economy, 106(1), 1998, Working Paper No. 07/215, 2007.
663–91. O’Hara, M., and W. Shaw. “Deposit Insurance and Wealth
Hughes, J. P., and L. J. Mester. “Who Said Large Banks Don’t Effects: The Value of Being ‘Too Big to Fail’.” Journal
Experience Scale Economies? Evidence from a Risk- of Finance, 45(5), 1990, 1587–600.
Return-Driven Cost Function.” Journal of Financial Oliver, A. M., V. S. Fumas, and J. Saurina. “Risk Premium and
Intermediation, 22(4), 2013, 559–85. Market Power in Credit Markets.” Economics Letters,
Hughes, J. P., L. J. Mester, and C. G. Moon. “Are Scale 93(3), 2006, 450–56.
Economies in Banking Elusive or Illusive?: Evi- Panzar, J. C., and J. N. Rosse. “Testing for ‘Monopoly’
dence Obtained by Incorporating Capital Structure Equilibrium.” Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4),
and Risk-Taking into Models of Bank Production.” 1987, 443–56.
Journal of Banking and Finance, 25(12), 2001, Petersen, M. A., and R. G. Rajan. “The Effect of Credit Mar-
2169–208. ket Competition on Lending Relationships.” Quarterly
Ivashina, V., and D. Scharfstein. “Bank Lending during the Journal of Economics, 110(2), 1995, 407–43.
Financial Crisis of 2008.” Journal of Financial Eco- Repullo, R. “Capital Requirements, Market Power, and Risk-
nomics, 97(3), 2010, 319–81. Taking in Banking.” Journal of Financial Intermedia-
Jensen, M. C., and W. H. Meckling. “Theory of the Firm: tion, 13(2), 2004, 156–82.
Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Schaeck, K., and M. Cihák. “Competition, Efficiency, and
Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 1976, Stability in Banking.” Financial Management, 43(1),
305–60. 2014, 215–41.
Jiménez, G., J. A. Lopez, and J. Saurina. “How Does Compe- Shen, C. H., Y. K. Chen, L. F. Kao, and C. Y. Yeh. “Bank
tition Affect Bank Risk-Taking?” Journal of Financial Liquidity Risk and Performance.” 17th Conference on
Stability, 9(2), 2013, 185–95. the Theories and Practices of Securities and Financial
Kashyap, A. K., R. Rajan, and J. C. Stein. “Banks as Liq- Markets, Hsi-Tze Bay, Kaohsiung, Taiwan, 2009.
uidity Providers: An Explanation for the Coexistence Soula, J. L. “Measuring Heterogeneity in Bank Liquidity
of Lending and Deposit-taking.” Journal of Finance, Risk: Who Are the Winners and the Losers?” Labora-
57(1), 2002, 33–73. toire de Recherche en Gestion et Economie (LaRGE),
Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. “The Worldwide Université de Strasbourg, 2015.
Governance Indicators: Methodology and Analytical Stiglitz, J. E., and A. Weiss. “Credit Rationing in Markets with
Issues.” Hague Journal on the Rule of Law, 3(2), 2011, Imperfect Information.” American Economic Review,
220–46. 71(3), 1981, 393–410.
Keeley, M. C. “Deposit Insurance, Risk, and Market Power Vives, X. “Competition and Stability in Banking.” Central
in Banking.” American Economic Review, 80(5), 1990, Banking, Analysis, and Economic Policies Book Series,
1183–200. 16, 2011, 455–502.
Kim, J., and S. Joh. “Effects of the Dodd-Frank Act on Bank Zigraiova, D., and T. Havranek. “Bank Competition and
Financing: Evidence from US Commercial Banks.” Financial Stability: Much Ado about Nothing?” Journal
Financial Stability Studies, 16(2), 2015, 1–34. of Economic Surveys, 30(5), 2016, 944–81.

You might also like