You are on page 1of 11

Political Research Quarterly

The Relationship between Defense 63(4) 760­–770


© 2010 University of Utah
Reprints and permission:
Spending and Economic Growth sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/1065912909334427

in the United States http://prq.sagepub.com

Uk Heo1

Abstract
Recent increases in U.S. defense spending have renewed interest in the defense–growth nexus. The Feder-Ram–based
models have traditionally been used in examining this relationship, but Dunn, Smith, and Willenbockel recommend
the augmented Solow model because of several weaknesses inherent in the Feder-Ram model (including its static
nature, simultaneity bias, and multicollinearity issues). The augmented Solow model addresses these issues, but it
has weaknesses too. Thus, by employing both the Feder-Ram and augmented Solow models, the author tests the
defense–growth nexus in the United States for 1954 through 2005. The results indicate that defense spending does
not significantly affect the U.S. economy.

Keywords
Defense Spending, Economic Growth, Feder-Ram Based Model,   Augmented Solow Model, United States

The Defense–Growth Nexus http://www.bea.gov/National/nipaweb/Index.asp) and the


in the United States national debt went from $5.8 trillion to $8.6 trillion (Treasury
Department n.d.). Coincidentally, the International Mone-
The annual budget for the U.S. Department of Defense tary Fund (IMF) warned that continuing twin deficits (the
(DOD) in fiscal year (FY) 2006 was approximately $419.3 budget and trade deficits) along with record-breaking debt
billion. This was a 4.8 percent boost from the previous increases in the United States threaten the financial stability
year. However, this increase in defense spending in FY of both the U.S. and global economies (Elizabeth Becker
2006 was not an isolated case in the recent past. Accord- and Edmund Andrews, New York Times, January 8, 2007).
ing to the Office of Management and Budget (OMB), Moreover, slow economic growth is expected in coming
defense spending from 2001 to 2006 increased by 41 per- months for various reasons (Joanne Morrison, Reuters,
cent (OMB 2006; see also Ann Scott Tyson, Washington November 28, 2007).
Post, February 6, 2007). The DOD’s base budget for FY Are recent increases in defense spending for the war
2007 was $439.3 billion. An additional $50 billion was on terrorism one of the reasons for slower economic
also provided to support the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq growth? Despite the volume of studies on the defense–
(OMB 2007). These increases in defense spending are the growth relationship, there is no consensus about the rela-
largest since the Reagan administration. tionship between defense spending and economic growth
According to former Secretary of Defense Donald in the United States. Some scholars argue that defense
Rumsfeld, these increases are necessary because “when spending in the United States helps growth (e.g., Atesoglu
the Cold War ended, a defense drawdown took place that 2002; Atesoglu and Mueller 1990; Mehay and Solnick
went too far . . . [and] overshot the mark. Now, through 1990; Mueller and Atesoglu 1993), while others contend
the prism of September 11, we can see that challenge is that the indirect, delayed, negative effects of defense
not simply to fix the underfunding of the past” (New York spending on the U.S. economy are greater than the positive
Times, February 5, 2002). He went further by saying that ones (e.g., Goldstein 1988; Heo and Eger 2005; Mintz
a “decade of overuse and underfunding” requires catch
up to meet all the demands the military is currently facing 1
University of Wisconsin–Milwaukee
since “we are a nation at war” (DOD 2005).
Corresponding Author:
During the same period (2001-2006), the average annual Uk Heo, Professor, Department of Political Science, University of
economic growth rate was a mere 2.4 percent (Bureau of Wisconsin–Milwaukee
Economic Analysis’s National Economic Accounts; see Email: heouk@uwm.edu.

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


Heo 761

and Huang 1990, 1991; Ward and Davis 1992; Ward, larger government budget deficit; inflation; a decline of
Davis, and Lofdahl 1995). social welfare spending, such as expenditures on public
What are the causes of different empirical findings on health or education; or a combination of them (Adams and
the U.S. defense–growth nexus? According to Dunne, Gold 1987; Chan 1987: Mintz 1989; Russett 1982; Ward
Smith, and Willenbockel (2005), the reason previous studies and Davis 1992; Ward, Davis, and Lofdahl 1995). All of
found positive or negative relationships between defense these have long-term economic implications.1
spending and economic growth is because they used various The bottleneck effect of defense spending on capital
versions of the Feder-Ram–based defense–growth model. stocks occurs because defense spending has a dampening
Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel point out that the Feder- effect on investment through competition for the noncon-
Ram defense–growth model is not commonly used in the sumption portion of total economic output (DeGrasse 1983;
mainstream growth literature in economics. This body of Heo and Eger 2005; Mintz and Huang 1990, 1991).2
literature has found an insignificant relationship between According to Mintz and Huang (1990, 1284), more than
defense spending and economic growth (e.g., Sala-i-Martin, half of total economic output in the United States comes
Doppelhofer, and Miller 2004). They further argue that the from private consumption and nonmilitary public expen-
Feder-Ram–based defense–growth model should not be ditures. Since it is politically unappealing, politicians tend
used in defense economics research because of simultaneity to hesitate to cut off nonmilitary public spending, while
bias, multicollinearity between independent variables, and individuals tend to resist cutting back on personal con-
its static nature stemming from the lack of lagged regressors. sumption. As a result, defense spending and private invest-
To address these issues, they recommend the augmented ment vie for the nonconsumption portion of the total
Solow model. capital available in the economy, which means that more
Thus, in this article, I theoretically compare these spending on defense programs is likely to result in the
two models and empirically test the relationship between decline of private investment.
defense spending and economic growth in the United Mintz and Huang (1990, 1991) report that defense
States for 1954 through 2005, employing both models to increases in the United States stifle private investment,
investigate how increases in defense spending affect although it takes five years for the effect to appear. Heo
the U.S. economy. Considering the recent and scheduled and Eger (2005) also find that defense spending has a
increases in defense spending, the findings of this study dampening effect on private investment but with only a
will further our understanding of the relationship between one-year delay (although both studies report insignificant,
defense spending and economic growth and will have direct effects of defense spending on economic growth).
important policy implications for the U.S. government. Lindgren (1984, 376), in his review of more than a dozen
studies of the relationship between defense spending and
investment, also reports that increases in defense expendi-
Literature Review on the tures result in the decline of private investment.
Relationship between Defense In addition, defense spending dampens human capital,
Spending and Economic Growth which in turn has a restraining effect on productivity growth.3
in the United States According to Melman (1983), defense industries attract
highly trained workers and engineers and thus have a drain-
Negative Effects
ing effect on human resources for private industries. Hong
From a purely economic point of view, defense expen- (1979) shows empirical evidence of a U.S. productivity
ditures can be unproductive, although they provide decline due to a resource shift from civilian to military use
insurance against war (Cuaresma and Reitschuler 2004). (see also Gold 1990).4 Ward and Davis (1992) also find that
Goldstein (1988) argues that a 1 percent increase in the the factor productivity of the civilian sector in the United
defense share of GNP in the United States reduces eco- States is higher than that of both the military and the non-
nomic growth by about one-half percent because of the military public sectors. These and other studies show that
opportunity cost: a trade-off in the budget and the bottle- defense spending hampers economic growth in the United
neck effect of defense spending on capital stock (see also States (Ward, Davis, and Lofdahl 1995).
Heo and Eger 2005; Mintz 1989; Mintz and Huang 1990,
1991). The budgetary trade-off occurs because govern-
ment expenditures are generally financed through taxes, Positive Effects
budget deficits, the guns-versus-butter trade-off, or print- Mueller and Atesoglu (1993), in their empirical analysis,
ing new money (Cappelen, Gleditsch, and Bjerkholt 1984; find that defense spending stimulates the U.S. economy
Chan 1987; DeGrasse 1983). In other words, each incre- (see also Atesoglu 2002; Atesoglu and Mueller 1990).
ment of defense spending brings a heavier tax burden; a Cuaresma and Reitschuler (2004) report that the externality

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


762 Political Research Quarterly 63(4)

effects of U.S. defense spending on economic growth are relationship. The results in both studies indicate no causal
also positive. One of the reasons commonly cited for the relationship between the two variables.
positive association between the two variables is job cre- Gerace (2002) shows that defense spending in the
ation. Since the average salary of the military sector is United States does not have a significant impact on eco-
generally lower than that of the private sector, defense nomic growth in his spectral analysis. He argues that
spending is economically more efficient in terms of job defense spending per capita in the United States is simply
creation than other expenditures. not large enough to have a statistically meaningful effect
Nincic and Cusack (1979) as well as Blank and on economic growth (see Becker 1991 for a similar argu-
Rothschild (1985) report that defense programs generate ment). Biswas and Ram (1986) also assert that defense
employment in the United States because of the large size of expenditures in general may affect economic growth pos-
the U.S. armed forces.5 Former Secretary of Defense Casper itively or negatively, but the effect is unlikely to be con-
Weinberger (1983, 68) argued in the FY 1984 Report of the sistently significant on the grounds that the nature and the
Secretary of Defense that defense cutbacks of $1 billion amount of the spending vary over time.
would result in the loss of approximately 35,000 jobs in the Heo (2000) conducted an empirical analysis to test the
United States. DOD economist David Blond also contends direct effects of defense spending on economic growth
that an average defense spending increase of 10 percent in in the United States for 1948 through 1996 employing
the United States may lead to a decline in unemployment various versions of the Feder-Ram–based defense–growth
of 0.6 to 2.4 percent.6 He points out that the DOD makes models proposed in the literature. Regardless of the model
direct hires for military and support programs. Addition- specifications, he finds a consistently insignificant rela-
ally, defense contracts generate jobs for defense industries tionship between defense spending and economic growth.
and their subcontractors, thus leading to multiplier effects Thus, he concludes that data from various sources, rather
on employment. than model specifications, are the main cause of inconsis-
The positive employment effects of defense spending tent findings of the relationship between defense spending
also boost aggregate demand in the economy. Those who and economic growth in the United States.
earn income through defense programs or DOD contract
awards consume their earnings, which enhances aggregate
demand (Chan 1995). In addition, Adams and Gold (1987) The Evolution of the Feder-Ram
contend that the defense industry has been a source of sig- Defense–Growth Model
nificant technological innovation in the United States and As stated earlier, there is a strong tradition of using the
has promoted growth through a spin-off effect on the pri- neoclassical production function approach in studying
vate sector (see also Gold 1990; Sandler and Hartley 1995). the defense–growth relationship. This approach employs a
In addition, a portion of defense spending is used to supply-side description of changes in aggregate output,
support education, which enhances human capital. As Barro which assumes that economic growth is a function of
(1990) notes, the quality of human capital is an import labor and capital. Based on this logic, Ram (1986) devel-
element in economic growth. Human capital enhance- oped a two-sector growth model to examine the relation-
ment through supporting/subsidizing education can indi- ship between government spending and economic growth.
rectly and positively affect the civilian sector later. Her logic for dividing the total economic output into two
Finally, defense spending contributes to maintaining (government and private) sectors is that there is a differ-
both internal and external security, which is critical for ence between the public and the private sectors with
economic activities. A secure environment may also attract respect to productivity.
greater foreign direct investment and international eco- According to Mintz and Huang (1990, 1991), however,
nomic exchanges, which both contribute to economic the effects of defense expenditures on growth may not be
growth (see Sandler and Hartley 1995). the same as those of nonmilitary government spending.
The reason is that the military is unique; therefore, defense
programs exist for a number of different reasons and pur-
Insignificant Effects poses (see Dumas 1986; Heo 1998). Moreover, Alexander
In contrast to the discussion thus far, a group of scholars (1990) notes that the nonmilitary government sector can
finds no statistically significant direct relationship between stimulate positive externality effects on other sectors of the
defense spending and economic growth in the United economy because nonmilitary public expenditures provide
States (Gerace 2002; Heo 2000; Kinsella 1990; Payne and public inputs to improve economic infrastructure while the
Ross 1992). Kinsella (1990) as well as Payne and Ross military sector may not. Thus, it is theoretically reasonable
(1992) conducted vector autoregression analysis to test if to separate the military and nonmilitary government sec-
U.S. defense spending and economic growth have a causal tors in order to study how various components of public

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


Heo 763

spending affect economic performance differently. Mintz production function approach, the Feder-Ram–based
and Huang do this and were able to set apart the effects defense–growth model assumes that labor and capital
of military and nonmilitary government spending on along with government expenditures play a key role in
economic growth.7 national economic production. By separating defense spend-
Mueller and Atesoglu (1993), however, argue that pre- ing from government expenditures, the model enables us
vious defense–growth models overlooked the importance to empirically test the defense–growth relationship in the
of technological progress, although Solow (1970) con- context of the macroeconomic theory of growth. Further-
tends that technology is what tells us how much eco- more, the model can separately test the economic effects of
nomic output can be produced from the amount of labor defense spending and nonmilitary government spending
and capital used in production.8 To this end, Mueller and on growth.
Atesoglu include technological progress in their two- Second, according to Ward and Davis (1992, 749; see
sector (defense and nondefense economic sectors) non- also Cornes and Sandler 1986), as public expenditures con-
linear defense–growth model to test the defense–growth tribute to national productivity, defense spending also has
relationship in the United States. They assume techno- spillover effects on overall growth, the so-called externality
logical progress changes at a constant exponential rate effects. Most of the Feder-Ram defense–growth models
over time, although the progress rates may fluctuate include both the economic effects of defense spending
annually (see also Cuaresma and Reitschuler 2004). and nonmilitary government spending on growth and their
Heo and DeRouen (1998) agree with the Mueller externality effects.11 Thus, the Feder-Ram-based defense-
and Atesoglu (1993) approach of including technologi- growth model enables students of defense economics to test
cal progress in the defense–growth model. However, Heo the differential effects of defense and nondefense govern-
and DeRouen follow Mintz and Huang’s (1990) logic ment spending and their externality effects on economic
that the nonmilitary public sector should be separated growth (e.g., DeRouen and Heo 2001; Heo 1998, 2000;
from the private sector of the economy because it is a Heo and DeRouen 1998; Heo and Eger 2005; Huang and
public component of the economy (see also Ram 1986 Mintz 1991; Mintz and Huang 1990, 1991; Ward and Davis
for an argument in favor of separating the public sector 1992; Ward, Davis, and Lofdahl 1995).
from the private sector). Thus, they augment Mueller and However, Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005) criti-
Atesoglu’s nonlinear defense–growth model by dividing cize the Feder-Ram–based defense–growth model because
the nonmilitary sector into the nonmilitary government of a number of issues embedded in it regardless of the num-
and private sectors while still accounting for technologi- ber of economic sectors. To replace the Feder-Ram–based
cal progress. model, they recommend the augmented Solow model by
Heo and Eger (2005) further expand Heo and DeRouen’s addressing the issues embedded in the Feder-Ram–based
(1998) model by separating the nonmilitary sector into defense–growth model. Thus, I discuss the theoretical
three components—nonmilitary government, export, and strengths and weaknesses of both models and employ them
the remainder of the economy—in addition to the military to empirically test the economic effects of defense spending
sector based on Alexander’s (1990) and Feder’s (1983) on growth in the United States from 1954 to 2005.
arguments. Alexander (1990, 43) contends that the total
economic output needs to be separated into at least four
sectors to accurately measure the defense–growth rela- Research Design
tionship.9 Feder (1983, 59) asserts that export-oriented The Feder-Ram-based
industries have a higher factor productivity than non- Defense–Growth Model
export-oriented industries; thus, they should enter the
growth model separately.10 Following this logic, Heo and Regardless of the number of economic output sectors,
Eger develop a defense–growth model with four economic all the supply-side defense–growth models based on the
sectors while including technological progress as an ele- Feder-Ram approach have been derived from the aggre-
ment of economic input. gate production function including a marginal factor pro-
As discussed thus far, the empirical models employed ductivity differential across sectors (Sandler and Hartley
in studying the supply-side defense–growth nexus have 1995). For instance, the following is the description of the
been based on the Feder-Ram defense–growth model. The aggregate production function of a typical three-sector
Feder-Ram–based defense–growth model has much to defense–growth model.12
offer thanks to its theoretical nature (Sandler and Hartley
1995, 208). First, the model is developed from macroeco- M = M(Lm, Km),
nomic theory of growth instead of ad hoc justifications N = N(Ln, Kn), and
for their model specification. Based on the neoclassical C = C(Lc, Kc, M, N),

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


764 Political Research Quarterly 63(4)

where M, N, and C (both capital and lowercase subscript) expenditures (and nonmilitary government spending) if
represent the military, nonmilitary public, and civilian the defense (nondefense public) spending share of eco-
sectors, respectively, and L and K (both capital and subscript nomic output is constant. In addition, according to Sandler
in later equations) indicate labor and capital. The reason and Hartley (1995, 209), there may be a potential interac-
that M and N entered the aggregate production function of tion between investment and nonmilitary public expendi-
the civilian sector is because of their externality effects. tures because the latter may improve the environment for
Total economic output and a marginal factor productiv- private investment. Thus, they recommend the use of a
ity differential between the military, nonmilitary public, causality test to identify the relationship between the two
and civilian sectors can be described as follows: variables.
Multicollinearity may also arise between the last four
terms (defense share of GDP, nondefense share of GDP,
Y = M + N + C = f(L, K) = ML+ MK + NL+ NK + CL + CK, defense spending increase, and nondefense public spend-
ing increase) of the equation because of the similarity of
ML MK the variables (Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel 2005) and
¼ ¼ 1 þ dm the way nonmilitary government spending is calculated.
CL CK
Nonmilitary government spending is often constructed by
subtracting defense spending from total government
NL NK
¼ ¼ 1 þ dn expenditures. Therefore, there could be a multicollinear-
CL CK ity issue on the grounds that the rise of defense spending
is likely to lead to the decline of nonmilitary government
where Y is national income (gross domestic product), and spending unless total government expenditures increase.14
δi denotes the productivity differential between the public This is why Huang and Mintz (1991) employed ordinary
(military and nonmilitary) and civilian sectors. According ridge regression (ORR) in their study (see also Mintz and
to Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005, 454-55), the Huang 1990, 1991).
interpretation of a productivity differential δi in previous
studies is problematic because scholars interpreted nonzero
δi as one sector becoming more or less efficient than the The Augmented Solow
other, although nonzero δi occurs when the implicit price Defense–Growth Model
ratio between the military (or nonmilitary public) and Because of the issues described above, Dunne, Smith,
civilian sectors used in the evaluation of GDP deviates and Willenbockel (2005, 458) recommend the aug-
from the marginal rate of the guns-versus-butter trade- mented Solow model. The augmented Solow model
off. They argue that this misinterpretation often leads to derived by Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel is dynamic,
incorrect conclusions. unlike the static Feder-Ram–based models, because
Turning to the empirical model, taking the total it includes a lagged defense spending variable on the
differential of economic output with respect to time right-hand side of the equation. Furthermore, the aug-
in the three-sector Feder-Ram–based defense–growth mented Solow model excludes nonmilitary govern-
model leads to the following equation:13 ment spending as well as the externality effects of defense
expenditures on growth. By doing so, the model can
 d reduce the possibility of multicollinearity. The aug-
^ ¼ CL L L^ þ CK I þ
M
Y
m
þ ym M^ þ ym M
^ mented Solow model by Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel
Y Y 1 þ dm Y is as follows:
 d N
n ^ þ yn N
^ þe
þ þ yn N
1 þ dn Y ∆ln y(t) = β0 + β1ln y(t – 1) + β2ln s + β3ln (g + n + d)
+ β4ln m(t) + β5ln m(t – 1) + ε,
where I is investment, N represents nonmilitary public
expenditures, θ indicates the externality effects of the where ∆ represents difference, y is national income,
military and nonmilitary public sectors, and ^ denotes s specifies private-sector savings as a share of GDP, g is
growth rates. the technological progress, n indicates the labor force
According to Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005), growth rate, d shows capital depreciation, and m denotes
having the growth rate of defense expenditures on the the share of defense spending in GDP.
right-hand side to test the externality effects of defense According to Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005),
spending may cause a serious simultaneity problem the theoretical advantage of the augmented Solow model
because economic growth will affect the level of defense to the Feder-Ram–based model is threefold. First, the

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


Heo 765

augmented Solow model is dynamic rather than static Method


because it includes a lag of defense expenditures.
Thus, the current and delayed (although limited to one To test the augmented Solow model and a typical three-
time unit, which is a year in this case) effects of defense sector Feder-Ram–based defense–growth model, I employ
spending on economic growth can be tested with this ordinary least squares. Considering the data set is a time
model. In contrast, the Feder-Ram model cannot test series, there are two methodological concerns: stationar-
the lagged relationship between defense spending and ity of the variables and autocorrelation. As Dunne, Smith,
economic growth because of its static nature. Second, and Willenbockel (2005) and Sandler and Hartley (1995)
there is a lower likelihood of multicollinearity in note, there is also a potential simultaneity problem between
the augmented Solow model due to the exclusion of economic growth and the growth rates of defense spend-
nonmilitary government (state) spending and exter- ing and between investment and nonmilitary government
nality effects from the equation. Third and finally, spending in the Feder-Ram model. I address each of these
labor input is theoretically better specified by includ- in this section.
ing capital depreciation and technological progress According to Granger and Newbold (1974), if any
(total factor productivity) instead of a simple growth variable in a regression equation is not stationary, the
rate of employed labor. results of the time-series analysis may be spurious. Since
However, the advantages of the augmented Solow model the log changes are used for the analysis of the augmented
are achieved by losing some benefits of the Feder-Ram– Solow model, the variables are stationary. Thus, I tested
based model. First, exclusion of nonmilitary public expen- each variable of the Feder-Ram model only for the pres-
ditures and the externality effect terms of military and ence of a unit root, employing the augmented Dickey-
nonmilitary public expenditures to reduce the possibility of Fuller test. The results of the augmented Dickey-Fuller
multicollinearity makes it impossible to test the externality test revealed the presence of a unit root only for invest-
effects of public expenditures and the impact of nonmili- ment –YI . Therefore, I use the first difference of investment
tary government spending on economic growth. Second, share of GDP to address the issue.
while the inclusion of both current and lagged defense Turning to the potential autocorrelation problem in
spending in the model may make the model dynamic and both models, I tested for autocorrelation using the Durbin-
allow it to test for delayed effects, it increases the possibil- Watson (D-W) statistic. The D-W statistic indicates that
ity of multicollinearity between the two terms, as defense there is an autocorrelation problem for the augmented
spending tends to have a trend over time. Thus, the aug- Solow model but not for the Feder-Ram–based defense–
mented Solow model may ease some concerns embedded growth model (D-W  = 1.16 and 1.66, respectively). To
in the Feder-Ram–based defense–growth model, but it address this issue, I employed the Prais-Winsten method
also has some weaknesses. I deal with these issues empir- for the augmented Solow model.
ically by employing both models in testing the defense– For the potential simultaneity problem between eco-
growth nexus in the United States. nomic growth and defense spending growth and between
investment and nonmilitary government spending in the
Feder-Ram model, I employed a Granger causal analysis to
Data and Method test for exogeneity. The Granger causal analysis reveals that
Data there is no simultaneity bias. There is no statistically signifi-
cant causal effect in either direction in both relationships.16
Data for GDP, private-sector savings, employed labor, For the statistical analysis, Intercooled STATA 9.2 is
capital depreciation, and defense spending are from the used. Empirical measures employed for the augmented
National Income and Product Account Tables in the Bureau Solow model are as follows:
of Economic Analysis’s National Economic Accounts,
available online.15 I converted all the current currency val- ∆ln y(t): growth in gross domestic product—the
ues (billions of dollars) to constant values (2,000 = 100) log of gross domestic product less the log of
using the implicit price deflator for GDP provided in the gross domestic product in the previous year;
same source. Data for employed labor are total full-time ln y(t – 1): the log of gross domestic product in the
and part-time employees (thousands), and capital deprecia- previous year;
tion is the percentage change in consumption of fixed capi- ln s: private-sector savings ratio—the log of the
tal from the preceding year, provided in the same source. proportion of gross domestic investment to
I used the private business sector’s multifactor ­productivity gross domestic product;
index (2,000 = 100) provided by the Bureau of Labor Sta- ln (g + n + d): the log of the sum of the employed
tistics as a proxy for technological progress. labor growth rate, capital depreciation rate, and

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


766 Political Research Quarterly 63(4)

the changes in private business sector’s multifac- Table 1. The Economic Effects of Defense Spending
tor productivity index;17 on Growth in the United States (1954-2005), Augmented
ln m(t): the log of the share of defense spending in Solow Model
GDP; and Dependent Variable: Coefficient
ln m(t – 1): the log of the share of defense spend- Economic Growth Rate, ∆ln y(t) (Standard Error)
ing in GDP in the previous year.
GDPt – 1, ln y(t – 1) -0.2026*** (0.0484)
Capital investment, ln s   0.1932*** (0.0385)
Empirical measures employed for the Feder-Ram Labor, ln (g + n + d)   0.1899*** (0.0383)
defense–growth model are as follows: Military Spendingt, ln m(t) -0.1271*** (0.0423)
Military Spending t – 1, ln m(t – 1)   0.1463*** (0.0428)
Ŷ: growth rate of gross domestic product; Constant    1.3990** (0.2462)
^ : growth rate of employed labor;
L Adjusted R2 0.68
–YI : investment share of GDP; Durbin-Watson 1.87
–M ^
Y M : changes in defense spending share of GDP; *p < .10. **p < .05. ***p < .01 (one-tailed test).
M ^ : growth rate of defense spending;
–YN N^ : changes in nonmilitary government spend-
ing share of GDP; and found the immediate positive effects and the magnitude
N^ :growth rate of non-military government of the effects was much greater.18 In sum, a 1 percent
spending. increase in the defense spending share of GDP in the
United States is expected to lead to a 0.019 percent increase
in economic growth over two years. This result indicates
Findings
that the economic effects of defense spending on growth
The results of the empirical analyses are reported in in the United States are meaningless because the size of
Tables 1 and 2. Both models perform well with the the effects is virtually zero. See Table 1.
adjusted R2 of .68 for the augmented Solow model and Contrary to Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel’s (2005)
.67 for the Feder-Ram–based model, although indepen- argument that the statistically significant relationship
dent variables perform better individually for the former between defense spending and economic growth comes
than for the latter. In terms of the results of the augmented from the use of the variant types of the Feder-Ram
Solow model, as expected, capital investment and employed defense–growth model, the augmented Solow model rec-
labor (which accounts for capital depreciation and tech- ommended by them shows the statistically significant
nological progress with changes in multifactor productiv- relationship between the two variables. However, as stated,
ity of the private business sector) show a highly significant the significant effects of defense spending on growth
and positive effect on economic growth. become meaningless over two years because of the offset
Turning to the effects of defense spending on eco- by the delayed effects. This confirms the insignificant
nomic growth, the inclusion of both current and lagged relationship proposed by Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel
defense spending in the model leads to a high level of and previously shown by Heo (2000).
bivariate correlation between the two variables (r = .98). Turning to the Feder-Ram–based defense–growth
However, the effects of both current and lagged defense model, the economic effects of capital investment and
spending on economic growth are strong enough to show the simple growth rates of employed labor both show
a statistically significant impact. The result is that defense positive and significant effects on growth, as macroeco-
spending shows a contemporary, harmful effect on eco- nomic theory predicts. However, changes in the defense
nomic growth, but the lagged effect becomes positive and spending share of GDP and its externality effects show
significant, thus offsetting the negative effects. A 1 per- an insignificant effect on growth, as found in previous
cent increase in defense spending as a share of GDP leads studies, including Mintz and Huang (1990, 1991), Heo
to a 0.127 percent contemporary decline of the economic (2000), and Heo and Eger (2005). As Ward and Davis
growth rate in the United States while boosting economic (1992) as well as Heo and Eger found, nonmilitary gov-
growth by 0.146 percent in the following year. According ernment spending shows a positive and significant effect
to this result, as Ward and Davis (1992) found, the imme- on economic growth, yet its externality effects are statis-
diate effects of defense spending on economic growth in tically insignificant.
the United States are negative, although the delayed Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005) raised a con-
effects are positive. This positive effect is similar to the cern about the possibility of multicollinearity between
findings of Atesoglu (2002), Atesoglu and Mueller public expenditures (both defense and nonmilitary gov-
(1990), and Mueller and Atesoglu (1993), although they ernment spending) and their externality effect terms

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


Heo 767

Table 2. The Economic Effects of Defense Spending current and lagged defense expenditures. Thus, I employed
on Growth in the United States (1954-2005), Feder- both the Feder-Ram and augmented Solow models to test
Ram-based Model the economic effects of defense spending on growth in
Dependent Variable: Economic Coefficient the United States from 1954 to 2005.
Growth Rate (Ŷ) (Standard Error) The empirical results of both models show that defense
spending does not significantly affect economic growth
Capital investment ( –YI ) 0.0438* (0.0322)
in the United States. For the augmented Solow model,
Employed labor growth (L^) 1.0029*** (0.1062)
Military Spendingt ( –M ^ -1.6825 (1.6808) defense spending appears to contemporaneously harm
Y M )
^ )
Military spending externality (M 0.1054 (0.1282) economic growth, but the damage is negated by the posi-
Nonmilitary public 2.2877*** (0.7336) tive effects that follow later. For the Feder-Ram defense–
  spending ( –YN N^ ) growth model, defense spending showed a statistically
Nonmilitary public spending -0.0044** (0.0021) insignificant effect on economic growth, while nonmili-
  externality (N^ ) tary public expenditures hampered economic growth.
Constant -0.0020 (0.0066)
The potential simultaneity bias noted by Dunne, Smith,
Adjusted R2 0.67
Durbin-Watson 1.73 and Willenbockel (2005) between economic growth and
defense spending or between investment and nonmilitary
*p < .10. **p < .05. ***p < .01 (one-tailed test). public expenditures did not exist in the U.S. case. Multi-
collinearity appeared in both models, although it did not
significantly affect the results of the statistical analyses.
because of their similarity. I tested the bivariate correlation In sum, the augmented Solow model recommended by
among them.19 There is a high level of bivariate correlation Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005) theoretically may
between defense spending and its externality effect (r = .95) avoid some potential issues embedded in the Feder-Ram–
but not for the rest. Thus, I ran two more regressions: one based defense–growth model, such as simultaneity bias and
without externality terms and the other excluding both the its static nature, but it has a multicollinearity issue and results
externality terms and nonmilitary government spending. In in the same conclusions as those found with the Feder-Ram–
both cases, defense spending showed a statistically insig- based defense–growth model (at least for the U.S. case).
nificant relationship with economic growth, confirming In conclusion, as earlier work by Heo (2000) found,
the original results.20 See Table 2. the relationship between defense spending and economic
growth in the United States is statistically insignificant
regardless of which models are used to examine the rela-
Conclusion tionship. Considering that defense spending is projected
Sharp increases in U.S. defense spending in the past few to continue to rise, this finding has important policy
years are likely to continue as the war on terrorism contin- implications for the U.S. government on the grounds that
ues. This trend, coupled with increasing annual budget increased defense spending is unlikely to have a signifi-
deficits, has generated renewed interest in studying the cant, direct effect on the U.S. economy.
relationship between defense spending and economic The real effects of defense spending on the U.S. econ-
growth. Previously, the Feder-Ram–based supply-side omy, however, may not be direct. As Mintz and Hunag
models have dominated theoretical frameworks in testing (1990, 1991) as well as Heo and Eger (2005) note, the
the economic effects of defense spending on growth. How- real effects of a defense spending increase on the U.S.
ever, Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005) argue that economy may be delayed and through indirect channels,
the Feder-Ram–based defense–growth model is not com- such as investment, consumption, employment, interna-
monly used in mainstream growth studies in economics tional competitiveness, national debt, and budgetary trade-
(e.g., Sala-i-Martin, Doppelhofer, and Miller 2004) and offs through cutbacks on public expenditures on health
should not be used in studying the defense–growth nexus and education. Moreover, defense budget allocations are
due to statistical problems inherent in the model. Thus, directed toward a small number of states. Thus, further
they recommended the augmented Solow model. studies at the state level are also required to get a better
The benefits of the augmented Solow model are picture of the relationship between defense spending and
achieved through the loss of the Feder-Ram model’s ben- economic growth in the United States.
efits as far as testing the economic effects of nonmilitary
expenditures compared with those of defense spending Author’s Note
and the externality effects of both public expenditures. I would like to thank John Bohte and Terence Roehrig for their
Moreover, the augmented Solow model may also have helpful comments and suggestions. Of course, I take the full
multicollinearity issues because of the inclusion of both responsibility for all the remaining errors.

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


768 Political Research Quarterly 63(4)

Notes Hartley (1995, 209) contend that “the pattern of externali-


ties among sectors is difficult to fix at the outset.”
  1. According to Kennedy (1987), high levels of U.S. defense 13. Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005) did not include
spending during the Cold War led the country to become nonmilitary government expenditures and the externality
the world’s largest debtor because it was financed through effects of defense and nondefense public spending in their
high levels of government debt. The Reagan military build- description of the Feder-Ram defense–growth model,
up in the 1980s at the cost of a large government budget although they are typically included (e.g., Heo 1998; Heo
deficit is another example of this problem (see Adams and and DeRouen 1998; Heo and Eger 2005; Huang and Mintz,
Gold 1987; Gold 1990; Mintz 1989). 1991; Mintz and Huang 1990, 1991; Ward and Davis 1992).
  2. In contrast, Boulding (1973) argues that defense spending Thus, I describe the Feder-Ram defense–growth model dif-
has little impact on investment. He compared U.S. invest- ferently than Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel by including
ment in 1929 and 1969 and found that increased defense them in the model.
spending had very little impact on investment. 14. This problem may not be severe in some cases because
  3. The military sector in the United States also owns a large changes in defense and nondefense spending share of GDP
portion of the capital equipment, structures, and inventories, are used instead of simple percentage of defense and non-
which could be used for other purposes (see also Lumsden defense government spending to GDP.
1980). In the 1971 Economic Report of the President (p. 115), 15. See http://www.bea.gov/National/nipaweb/Index.asp.
Arthur Burns, chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors 16. The results of the Granger causal analysis are:
under President Eisenhower, asserted that “the real cost of
the defense sector consists, therefore, not only of the civilian Defense spending growth → Economic growth,
goods and services that are currently foregone on its account; c2 = 0.3352 (probability > c2 = 0.846)
it includes also an element of growth that could have been Economic growth → Defense spending growth,
achieved through larger investments in human or business c2 = 2.0375 (probability > c2 = 0.361)
capital” (cited in Ward, Davis, and Lofdahl 1995, 28). Investment → Nonmilitary public expenditures,
  4. According to Denison (1985), however, slowdowns in U.S. c2 = 3.22 (probability > c2 = 0.199)
productivity are not because of increased defense spending Nonmilitary public expenditures → Investment,
but because of cyclical phenomena. c2 = 3.84 (probability > c2 = 0.146)
  5. According to Sandler and Hartley (1995, 201), defense
spending can boost employment during a period of unem- 17. Dunne, Smith, and Willenbockel (2005) described the labor
ployment, but this effect does not last once the economy variable as ln (g + n + d), and I imported their description of
recovers to near full employment. the augmented Solow model for this study. However, since
  6. Office of the Secretary of Defense, Symposium on the the data for capital depreciation has absolute value of capi-
Impact of Higher Levels of Defense Expenditures on the tal depreciation percentage, I subtract (instead of add) that
United States Economy in the 1980s, October 26-29, 1980, in my calculation of the ln (g + n + d) variable despite that
Arlington, VA. Also cited in Adams and Gold (1987, 33). it is described as ln (g + n + d).
See also Dunne and Smith (1990). 18. Mueller and Atesoglu (1993) reported that a 1 percent
  7. Ward and Davis (1992) also developed a two-sector defense– increase of defense spending leads to 0.046 percent of eco-
growth model based on the Feder-Ram model, but they sep- nomic growth in the United States. Cuaresma and Reitschul-
arate the state sector into two components: military spend- er (2004) also found a contemporaneous negative effect of
ing and nonmilitary state spending. defense spending on growth in the United States, but the
  8. Solow (1970, 35) writes that “labor augmenting form of externality effects of defense spending showed positive ef-
technological progress is necessary for steady-state growth fects on growth.
to be possible.” 19. The bivariate correlation matrix is as follows:
  9. Alexander (1990) developed a four-sector defense–growth
model without technology spillover. Military M externality Nonmilitary Nonexternality
10. Relatedly, Levine and Renelt (1992) find a consistently
positive relationship between trade and economic growth Military —
M externality   .95 —
in their sensitivity analysis with cross-national data. Nonmilitary –.03 –.07 —
11. Ward and Davis (1992) specify the externality effects Non- –.06 –.10 .39 —
externality
as the defense spending share of the total government
expenditures. M externality, military spending externality.
12. Despite the common usage of entering multiple economic
sectors and externality effects into the model, Sandler and 20. The results are available from the author upon request.

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


Heo 769

References DeRouen, Karl, Jr., and Uk Heo. 2001. Modernisation and the
military in Latin America. British Journal of Political Sci-
Adams, Gordon, and David Gold. 1987. Defense spending and ence 31:475-96.
the economy: Does the defense dollar make a difference? Dumas, Lloyd J. 1986. The overburdened economy. Berkeley:
Washington, DC: Defense Budget Project. University of California Press.
Alexander, W. Robert J. 1990. The impact of defence spending Dunne, Paul, and Ron Smith. 1990. Military expenditure and
on economic growth: A multisectoral approach to defence unemployment in the OECD. Defence Economics 1:57-73.
spending and economic growth with evidence from devel- Dunne, Paul, Ron Smith, and Dirk Willenbockel. 2005. Models of
oped economies. Defence Economics 1:39-55. military expenditure and growth: A critical review. Defence
Atesoglu, H. Sonmez. 2002. Defense spending promotes aggre- and Peace Economics 16:449-61.
gate output in the United States: Evidence from cointegra- Feder, Gershon. 1983. On exports and economic growth. Jour-
tion analysis. Defence and Peace Economics 13:55-60. nal of Development Economics 12:59-73.
Atesoglu, H. Sonmez, and J. Michael Mueller. 1990. Defence Gerace, M. P. 2002. US military expenditure and economic
spending and economic growth. Defence Economics 1: growth: Some evidence from spectral methods. Defence and
19-27. Peace Economics 13:1-11.
Barro, Robert. 1990. Government Spending in a Simple Model Gold, David. 1990. The impact of defense spending on invest-
of Endogenous Growth. Journal of Political Economy 98(5): ment, productivity and economic growth. Washington, DC:
S103-S126. Defense Budget Project.
Becker, Gary. 1991. Defense spending isn’t stunting the U.S. Goldstein, Joshua. 1988. Long cycles: Prosperity and war in the
economy. Business Week, February 25, 1991. modern age. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Biswas, Basudeb, and Rati Ram. 1986. Military expenditures Granger, C. W. J., and Paul Newbold. 1974. Spurious regres-
and economic growth in less developed countries: An aug- sions in econometrics. Journal of Econometrics 2:111-20.
mented model and further evidence. Economic Development Heo, Uk. 1998. Modeling the defense–growth relationship
and Cultural Change 34:361-72. around the globe. Journal of Conflict Resolution 42:637-57.
Blank, Richard, and Erin Rothschild. 1985. The effect of United Heo, Uk. 2000. The defense–growth nexus in the United States
States defense spending on employment and output. Inter- revisited. American Politics Quarterly 28:110-27.
national Labour Review 124:677-97. Heo, Uk, and Karl DeRouen Jr. 1998. Military expenditures,
Boulding, Kenneth. 1973. The Impact of the Defense Industry technological change, and economic growth in the East Asian
on the Structure of the American Economy. In The Eco- NICs. Journal of Politics 60:830-46.
nomic Consequences of Reducing Military Spending, ed. Heo, Uk, and Robert Eger. 2005. Paying for security: The security–
Bernard Udis. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books. prosperity dilemma in the United States. Journal of Conflict
Cappelen, Adne, Nils Petter Gleditsch, and Olav Bjerkholt. Resolution 49 (5): 792-817.
1984. Military spending and economic growth in the OECD Hong, Byung Yoo. 1979. Inflation under cost pass-along man-
countries. Journal of Peace Research 21:361-73. agement. New York: Praeger.
Chan, Steve. 1987. Military expenditures and economic perfor- Huang, Chi, and Alex Mintz. 1991. Defense expenditures and
mance. In World military expenditures and arms transfers, economic growth: The externality effects. Defence Econom-
1986, ed. United States Arms Control and Disarmament ics 2:35-40.
Agency, 29-38. Washington, DC: United States Arms Con- Kennedy, Paul. 1987. The rise and fall of great powers. New York:
trol and Disarmament Agency. St. Martin’s.
Chan, Steve. 1995. Grasping the peace dividend: Some proposi- Kinsella, David. 1990. Defense spending and economic
tions on the conversion of swords into plowshares. Mershon performance in the United States. Defence Economics 1:
International Studies Review 39:53-95. 295-309.
Cornes, Richard, and Todd Sandler. 1986. The theory of exter- Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. 1992. A sensitivity analysis
nalities, public goods, and club goods. Cambridge, UK: Cam- of cross-country growth regressions. American Economic
bridge University Press. Review 82:942-963.
Cuaresma, Crespo J., and G. Reitschuler. 2004. A non-linear Lindgren, Goran. 1984. Armaments and economic performance
defence–growth nexus? Evidence from the US economy. in industrialized market economies. Journal of Peace Research
Defence and Peace Economics 15:71-82. 21:375-87.
DeGrasse, Robert W., Jr. 1983. Military expansion economic Lumsden, Malvern. 1980. The military use of a scarce resource:
decline: The impact of military spending on US economic The case of land. Stockholm: SIPRI.
performance. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe. Mehay, Stephen, and Loren Solnick. 1990. Defense spending and
Denison, Edward F. 1985. Trends in American economic growth, state economic growth. Review essay. Journal of Regional
1929-1982. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Science 30:477-87.

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016


770 Political Research Quarterly 63(4)

Melman, Seymour. 1983. Profits without production. New York: Russett, Bruce. 1982. Defense expenditures and national well-
Knopf. being. American Political Science Review 76:767-77.
Mintz, Alex. 1989. Guns vs. butter: A disaggregated analysis. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, Gernot Doppelhofer, and Ronald I. Miller.
American Political Science Review 83:1285-93. 2004. Determinants of long-term growth: A Bayesian averaging
Mintz, Alex, and Chi Huang. 1990. Defense expenditures, eco- of classical estimates (BACE) approach. American Economic
nomic growth and the “peace dividend.” American Political Review 94:813-35.
Science Review 84:1283-93. Sandler, Todd, and Keith Hartley. 1995. The economics of
Mintz, Alex, and Chi Huang. 1991. Guns versus butter: The indi- defense. New York: Cambridge University Press.
rect link. American Journal of Political Science 35:738-57. Solow, Robert. 1970. Growth theory: An exposition. New York:
Mueller, Michael, and Atesoglu, H. Sonmez. 1993. Defense Oxford University Press.
spending, technological change, and economic growth in the Treasury Department. n.d. Public debt. http://www.treasurydirect
United States. Defence Economics 4:259-69. .gov/NP/BPDLogin?application=np
Nincic, Miroslav, and Thomas Cusack. 1979. The political economy U.S. Department of Defense. 2005. News release, February 7,
of US military spending. Journal of Peace Research 16:101-14. 2005.
Office of Management and Budget. 2006. Overview of the Ward, Michael, and David Davis. 1992. Sizing up the peace
president’s 2006 budget. http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/ dividend: Economic growth and military spending in the
budget/fy2006/overview.html. United States, 1948-1996. American Political Science Review
Office of Management and Budget. 2007. Department of Defense. 86:748-55.
http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/fy2007/defense.html Ward, Michael, David Davis, and Corey Lofdahl. 1995. A century
Payne, James E. and Kevin L. Ross. 1992. Defense Spending of tradeoffs: Defense and growth in Japan and the United
and the Macroeconomy. Defence Economics 3:161-8. States. International Studies Quarterly 39:27-50.
Ram, Rati. 1986. Government size and economic growth: A new Weinberger, Casper. 1983. Hearings on Department of Defense
framework and some evidence from cross-section and time- appropriations for FY 1984, Part 1. Washington, DC: Depart-
series data. American Economic Review 76:191-203. ment of Defense.

Downloaded from prq.sagepub.com at PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIV on March 5, 2016

You might also like