You are on page 1of 7

Commodity (Marxism)

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia


Jump to navigationJump to search

Part of a series on

Marxism

show

Theoretical works

show

Philosophy

show

Economics

show

Sociology

show

History

show
Aspects

show

Variants

show

People

show

Related topics

show

Related categories

 Outline

  Communism portal

  Philosophy portal

  Socialism portal

 v
 t
 e

In classical political economy and especially Karl Marx's critique of political economy,


a commodity is any good or service ("products" or "activities") [1] produced by human
labour[2] and offered as a product for general sale on the market. [3] Some other priced
goods are also treated as commodities, e.g. human labor-power, works of art and
natural resources, even though they may not be produced specifically for the market, or
be non-reproducible goods.
Marx's analysis of the commodity is intended to help solve the problem of what
establishes the economic value of goods, using the labor theory of value. This problem
was extensively debated by Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and Karl Rodbertus-Jagetzow,
among others. Value and price are not equivalent terms in economics, and theorising
the specific relationship of value to market price has been a challenge for both liberal
and Marxist economists.[4]
Contents

 1Characteristics of commodity
 2Historical origins of commodity trade
 3Forms of commodity trade
 4Cost structure of commodities
 5Pseudo-commodities
 6See also
 7Notes
 8References
 9Further reading

Characteristics of commodity[edit]
"We are doing everything possible to give work this new status as a social duty and to
link it on the one hand with the development of technology, which will create the
conditions for greater freedom, and on the other hand with voluntary work based on the
Marxist appreciation that one truly reaches a full human condition when no longer
compelled to produce by the physical necessity to sell oneself as a commodity."

— Che Guevara  [5]


In Marx's theory, a commodity is something that is bought and sold, or exchanged in a
market.[6]

 It has value, which represents a quantity of human labor.[7] Because it has value,


implies that people try to economise its use. A commodity also has a use value[8] and
an exchange value.[9]
 It has a use value because, by its intrinsic characteristics, it can satisfy some
human need or want, physical or ideal.[10] By nature this is a social use value, i.e. the
object is useful not just to the producer but has a use for others generally. [11]
 It has an exchange value, meaning that a commodity can be traded for other
commodities, and thus give its owner the benefit of others' labor (the labor done to
produce the purchased commodity).[12]
Price is then the monetary expression of exchange-value, but exchange value could
also be expressed as a direct trading ratio between two commodities without using
money, and goods could be priced using different valuations or criteria. [13]
According to the labor theory of value, product-values in an open market are regulated
by the average socially necessary labour time required to produce them, and price
relativities of products are ultimately governed by the law of value.[14]

Historical origins of commodity trade[edit]


Commodity-trade, Marx argues, historically begins at the boundaries of separate
economic communities based otherwise on a non-commercial form of production.
[15]
 Thus, producers trade in those goods of which those producers, have episodic or
permanent surpluses to their own requirements, and they aim to obtain different goods
with an equal value in return.
Marx refers to this as "simple exchange" which implies what Frederick Engels calls
"simple commodity production". At first, goods may not even be intentionally produced
for the explicit purpose of exchanging them, but as a regular market for goods develops
and a cash economy grows, this becomes more and more the case, and production
increasingly becomes integrated in commodity trade. "The product becomes a
commodity" and "exchange value of the commodity acquires a separate existence
alongside the commodity"[16]
Even so, in simple commodity production, not all inputs and outputs of the production
process are necessarily commodities or priced goods, and it is compatible with a variety
of different relations of production ranging from self-employment and family labour to
serfdom and slavery. Typically, however, it is the producer himself who trades his
surpluses.
However, as the division of labour becomes more complex, a class of merchants
emerges which specialises in trading commodities, buying here and selling there,
without producing products themselves, and parallel to this, property owners emerge
who extend credit and charge rents. This process goes together with the increased use
of money, and the aim of merchants, bankers and renters becomes to gain income from
the trade, by acting as intermediaries between producers and consumers.
The transformation of a labor-product into a commodity (its "marketing") is in reality not
a simple process, but has many technical and social preconditions. These often include
the following ten (10) main ones:

1. The existence of a reliable supply of a product, or at least a surplus or surplus


product.
2. The existence of a social need for it (a market demand) that must be met through
trade, or at any event cannot be met otherwise.
3. The legally sanctioned assertion of private ownership rights to the commodity.
4. The enforcement of these rights, so that ownership is secure.
5. The transferability of these private rights from one owner to another.
6. The right to buy and sell the commodity, and/or obtain (privately) and keep
income from such trade
7. The (physical) transferability of the commodity itself, i.e. the ability to store,
package, preserve and transport it from one owner to another.
8. The imposition of exclusivity of access to the commodity.
9. The possibility of the owner to use or consume the commodity privately.
10. Guarantees about the quality and safety of the commodity, and possibly a
guarantee of replacement or service, should it fail to function as intended.
Thus, the "commodification" of a good or service often involves a considerable practical
accomplishment in trade. It is a process that may be influenced not just by economic or
technical factors, but also political and cultural factors, insofar as it involves property
rights, claims to access to resources, and guarantees about quality or safety of use.
In absolute terms, exchange values can also be measured as quantities of average
labour-hours. Commodities which contain the same amount of socially necessary labor
have the same exchange value. By contrast, prices are normally measured in money-
units. For practical purposes, prices are, however, usually preferable to labour-hours, as
units of account, although in capitalist work processes the two are related to each other
(see labor power).

Forms of commodity trade[edit]


The seven basic forms of commodity trade can be summarised as follows:

 M-C (an act of purchase: a sum of money purchases a commodity, or "money is


changed into a commodity")[17]
 C-M (an act of sale: a commodity is sold for money)[18]
 M-M' (a sum of money is lent out at interest to obtain more money, or, one
currency or financial claim is traded for another; "money begets money") [19]
 C-C' (countertrade, in which a commodity trades directly for a different
commodity, with money possibly being used as an accounting referent, for example,
food for oil, or weapons for diamonds)
 C-M-C' (a commodity is sold for money, which buys another, different commodity
with an equal or higher value)
 M-C-M' (money is used to buy a commodity which is resold to obtain a larger
sum of money)[20]
 M-C...P...-C'-M' (money buys means of production and labour power used in
production to create a new commodity, which is sold for more money than the
original outlay; "the circular course of capital") [21]
The hyphens ("-") here refer to a transaction applying to an exchange involving goods or
money; the dots in the last-mentioned circuit ("...") indicate that a value-forming process
("P") occurs in between purchase of commodities and the sales of different
commodities. Thus, while at first merchants are intermediaries between producers and
consumers, later capitalist production becomes an intermediary between buyers and
sellers of commodities. In that case, the valuation of labour is determined by the value
of its products.
The reifying effects of universalised trade in commodities, involving a process Marx
calls "commodity fetishism",[22] mean that social relations become expressed as relations
between things;[23] for example, price relations. Markets mediate a complex network of
interdependencies and supply chains emerging among people who may not even know
who produced the goods they buy, or where they were produced.
Since no one agency can control or regulate the myriad of transactions that occur (apart
from blocking some trade here, and permitting it there), the whole of production falls
under the sway of the law of value, and economics becomes a science aiming to
understand market behaviour, i.e. the aggregate effects of a multitude of people
interacting in markets. How quantities of use-values are allocated in a market economy
depends mainly on their exchange value, and this allocation is mediated by the "cash
nexus".
In Marx's analysis of the capitalist mode of production, commodity sales increase the
amount of exchange-value in the possession of the owners of capital, i.e., they
yield profit and thus augment their capital (capital accumulation).

Cost structure of commodities[edit]


In considering the unit cost of a capitalistically produced commodity (in contrast
to simple commodity production), Marx claims that the value of any such commodity is
reducible to four components equal to:

 Variable capital used up to produce it.


 Fixed and circulating constant capital used up per unit.
 Incidental expenses which cost labour-time (faux frais of production).
 Surplus value per unit.
These components reflect respectively labour costs, the cost of materials and operating
expenses including depreciation, and generic profit.
In capitalism, Marx argues, commodity values are commercially expressed as the prices
of production of commodities (cost-price + average profit). Prices of production are
established jointly by average input costs and by the ruling profit margins applying to
outputs sold. They reflect the fact that production has become totally integrated into the
circuits of commodity trade, in which capital accumulation becomes the dominant
motive. But what prices of production simultaneously hide is the social nature of
the valorisation process, i.e. how an increase in capital-value occurs through
production.
Likewise, in considering the gross output of capitalist production in an economy as a
whole, Marx divides its value into these four components. He argues that the total new
value added in production, which he calls the value product, consists of the equivalent
of variable capital, plus surplus value. Thus, the workers produce by their labor both a
new value equal to their own wages, plus an additional new value which is claimed by
capitalists by virtue of their ownership and supply of productive capital.
By producing new capital in the form of new commodities, Marx argues the working
class continuously reproduces the capitalist relations of production; by their work,
workers create a new value distributed as both labour-income and property-income. If,
as free workers, they choose to stop working, the system begins to break down; hence,
capitalist civilisation strongly emphasizes the work ethic, regardless of religious belief.
People must work, because work is the source of new value, profits and capital.

Pseudo-commodities[edit]
Marx acknowledged explicitly that not all commodities are products of human labour; all
kinds of things can be traded "as if" they are commodities, so long as property rights
can be attached to them. These are "fictitious commodities" or "pseudo-commodities" or
"fiduciary commodities", i.e. their existence as commodities is only nominal or
conventional. They may not even be tangible objects, but exist only ideally. A property
right or financial claim, for instance, may be traded as a commodity.

You might also like