You are on page 1of 16

Setting Physicians’ Prices in FFS Medicare:

An Economic Perspective
Bryan Dowd, Ph.D., Roger Feldman, Ph.D., John Nyman, Ph.D., and Bob Town, Ph.D.

Recent policy discussions by the Medicare policy that have appeared in MedPAC
Payment Advisory Commission (MedPAC) reports. MedPAC was established by the
regarding physician prices in the traditional 1997 Balanced Budget Act to advise Con­
fee-for-service (FFS) Medicare Program re­­flect gress on the Medicare Program and is the
movement toward a market pricing model. successor to both the Physician Payment
Earlier objectives such as sustainable levels Review Commission (PPRC) and the Pro­­s­
of spending have given way to concerns over pective Payment Assessment Com­mis­sion.
the relationship between fees and actual costs, MedPAC’s reports not only present exten-
access to care, and the importance of demand sive analyses of policy issues, but also carry
and supply in local markets. An important substantial political influence, and thus
objective in other policy settings is economi- provide a reasonable focus for this analysis.
cally efficient distribution of services. We Reviewing MedPAC’s Reports to Con­
ex­plain the meaning of economic efficiency gress (2000-2005), we find a gradual move-
for Medicare physician prices and explore ment toward the goal of setting efficient
difficulties one might encounter in pursuing prices in the Medicare Program. We dis-
economic efficiency, as well as the cost of not cuss how economic efficiency might be
pursuing it. interpreted for Medicare physician prices
and some of the difficulties one might
INTRODUCTION encounter in pursuing it, as well as the cost
of not pursuing it.
Setting prices for physicians’ services in We assume that Medicare will continue
the traditional FFS Medicare Program is a to pay physicians on the basis of a fee sched-
topic of great importance to physicians, ule, but otherwise our analysis is general.
taxpayers, Medicare beneficiaries, and pol- We do not assume that the types of services
icymakers. Doctors are concerned about covered by Medicare will remain the same,
their practice revenue, taxpayers about or even that FFS Medicare will be adminis-
taxes, beneficiaries about the cost of care tered by the government. The government
and access to physician services, and poli- might contract administration of FFS Medi­
cymakers about the cost and performance care to private organizations, which already
of the Medicare Program. process claims and conduct quality assur-
Despite the importance of setting FFS ance activities. Although we couch the dis-
Medicare prices, the objectives of the price- cussion in terms of physician fees, much of
setting process have not always been clear the analysis could apply to setting prices for
(Pauly, 1991). In this article, we review other types of services, including hospital
recent discussions of Medicare payment services and prescription drugs.
The authors are with the University of Minnesota. The  Some of the issues discussed in this analysis would be obviated
statements expressed in this article are those of the authors if local private organizations had the authority to set fees.
and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Uni-
versity of Minnesota or the Centers for Medicare & Medicaid
Services (CMS).

Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2 97


Medicare’s Physician Pricing MedPAC (2001) modified the goal of FFS
Objectives pricing to be maintenance of sustainable
expenditure growth while “…accounting
Two primary features of any FFS pay- for factors that affect the cost of providing
ment system are the ways in which the care.” In their report they suggested that
quantity of services is defined and unit Congress consider a new approach to
prices are set. Different Medicare policy updating the FFS Medicare fee schedule
initiatives have focused on each feature. In that would reflect more accurately changes
the 1980s, resource-based relative value in the unit costs of providing physician ser-
units (RBRVUs) represented a new way to vices. This interest in providers’ costs could
define the quantity of physician services be interpreted as greater emphasis on
(Hsiao et al., 1988). Equally important, supply, as opposed to consumer demand.
however, is the unit price of services, or the The objective of payment adequacy was
multiplier that converts RBRVUs into pay- introduced by Med PAC (2002) and defined
ment amounts, because it influences the operationally as access to physician ser-
supply of services by physicians. This anal- vices. The emphasis on payment adequacy
ysis focuses on the objectives that Medi­ could be interpreted as recognition that
care might pursue when it sets the multiplier both supply and demand determine the
to determine unit prices. quantity of Medicare services supplied by
One of the earliest objectives of setting physicians. However, there was no discus-
FFS Medicare prices was controlling total sion of possible disparities between supply
expenditures. Concern over total spending and demand or of the notion that Medicare
began shortly after the program was estab- might wish to adjust prices on the basis of
lished in 1965 (Dowd, Feldman, and such disparities.
Christianson, 1996). Physician pricing pro- The emphasis on access intensified after
visions in the 1989 Omnibus Budget 2002. Anecdotal reports of access problems
Reconciliation Act (OBRA) were a response were beginning to surface in selected mar-
to the widely held perception that the usual, kets (e.g., Seattle, Denver, and Austin).
customary, and reasonable method of pay- However, it was not clear that these prob-
ing physicians was inherently inflationary. lems were specific to Medicare, if they
In addition to establishing the RBRVU fee existed at all. Data from the 2000-2003
schedule, OBRA established volume per- Consumer Assessment of Health Plans
formance standards, designed to control Surveys showed that about 90 percent of
ex­penditures on physician services. These beneficiaries seeking a new physician
standards linked the growth in physician reported minor or no problems doing so,
fees to growth in the volume of services while special Targeted Beneficiary Surveys
provided by all physicians. This method of commissioned by CMS found that physi-
regulating fees also proved to be inherently cian access generally was better for Medi­
inflationary. In response, Congress estab- care beneficiaries than for the privately
lished a sustainable growth rate as part of insured population. MedPAC (2004) also
the 1997 Balanced Budget Act. This linked began reporting comparisons of Medicare
growth in physician fees to growth in the physician fees to those of private insurers.
gross domestic product, adjusted for physi- Although Medicare’s prices were 66 percent
cian practice cost inflation, changes in FFS of private fees in 1994, they were 83 percent
Medicare enrollment, and the effects of of private fees in 2001, primarily due to a
laws and regulations (Hackbarth, 2005). decline in private fees.

98 Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2


MedPAC’s reports reflect a gradual, but must choose among them using some type
important, trend in their thinking about of decision rule. However, any efficient dis-
setting FFS Medicare prices. In one sense, tribution of resources can be achieved by
their objectives have evolved from global adjusting the initial distribution of income,
objectives (sustainable growth in total pro- either through cash or in-kind transfers,
gram expenditures) toward recognition of and then allowing a competitive market to
the importance of local variations in supply reach equilibrium. This is the second fun-
and demand. Nonetheless, MedPAC con- damental theorem of welfare economics
tinues to recommend basing physician (Rosen, 2002; Varian, 1992).
price increases on nationwide estimates of Income could be redistributed to the
inflation in the prices of inputs to physician poor and disabled elderly through Social
services and increased productivity. Security, leaving Medicare free to pursue
The evolution of MedPAC’s thinking also efficient prices. Our discussion of Medicare
can be viewed as a process of refinement— pricing focuses primarily on economic
from the early focus on total expenditures efficiency, but we point out that Medicare
(sustainable growth), to interest in supply fees could have an important impact on
curves (accurate accounting for cost fac- fairness of access to services by privately
tors and providers’ willingness to see insured consumers.
patients), and most recently, a combination
of supply and demand factors (access to DIAGRAMMATIC EXPOSITION OF
care). Finally, MedPAC’s comparisons of MEDICARE PRICING OBJECTIVES
Medicare fees to those of private insurers
reflect the recognition that FFS Medicare Competitive Market for Physicians’
is not the only payer in the market. Ser vices
MedPAC’s growing concern over the
supply and demand for physicians’ services Figure 1 shows the simplest competitive
in the Medicare Program suggests move- market for physician services. In this sim-
ment toward a market model of pricing. plest model, there is no insurance so con-
But what would a market pricing model for sumers pay out-of-pocket expenses for
physician services look like? physician services. At the competitive equi-
A perfectly competitive market produces librium price (PC) the amount of services
a competitive equilibrium in which supply demanded by consumers equals the amount
and demand are equal. There is no unsatis- of services that providers are willing to sup-
fied demand for services, given beneficia- ply (QE). Total expenditures for services
ries’ income and preferences, and no are the product of PC times QE.
unsatisfied supply of services, given physi- In Figure 1, any price other than PC is
cians’ cost functions. The competitive equi- inefficient. At PH, for example, providers
librium is ideal in the narrow, but important would be willing to supply QHS services,
sense of economic efficiency. Efficiency but beneficiaries would demand only QHD.
means that no provider or consumer can be Similarly, at PL, beneficiaries would demand
made better off without making another QLD services, but providers would supply
provider or consumer worse off. An effi- only QLS. Once price departs from PC, the
cient distribution of resources is termed quantity of services observed in the mar-
“Pareto optimal.” There are many Pareto ket is determined by the lesser of demand
optimal distributions of resources. Society or supply, and there will be either excess

Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2 99


Figure 1
Model of the Market for Physicians’ Services Without Insurance

Supply

PH

PC
Price

PL

Demand

0 QLS QHD QE QLD QHS

Quantity of Services

NOTES: PC is the competitive equilibrium price. PH is a price higher than the competitive
equilibrium price. PL is a price lower than the competitive equilibrium price. QE is the
quantity of services demanded and supplied at price PC. QLS is the quantity of services
supplied at price PL. QLD is the quantity of services supplied at price PL. QHS is the quantity
of services supplied at price PH. QHD is the quantity of services demanded at price PH. 0 is
the number zero. The competitive equilibrium price (PC) and quantity (QE) correspond to the
intersection of the market demand and supply curves (QE).
SOURCE: Dowd, B., Feldman, R., Nyman, J., and Town, B., University of Minnesota, 2006.

supply (beyond the quantity demanded by form, health insurance pays off in the event
consumers) or excess demand (beyond the of illness by reducing the consumer’s out-
quantity supplied by providers). of-pocket price of services. For example,
insurance might cover 80 percent of
Advantages and Disadvantages of medical expenditures, while the consumer
Insurance Coverage pays the remaining 20 percent. This type
of price-reduction insurance distorts the
The perfectly competitive market with- consumer’s price of health care services,
out insurance ignores an important prob- resulting in increased consumer demand
lem: demand for health care is uncertain for services. Economists refer to the
and treatments for many illnesses are extra consumption induced by insurance as
extremely expensive. Risk-averse consum- moral hazard.
ers seek financial protection from these Figure 2 illustrates the effect of in­surance
events by purchasing health insurance. on the demand for medical care. There
The primary advantage of health insur- are two demand cur ves: one represent­
ance is that it protects consumers from ing demand with insurance, (DI), and one
the costs associated with adverse health representing demand without insurance
events by spreading the risk over a pool of (DNI). DI is the demand curve seen by the
individuals. However, in its most common providers of services to insured consumers.
100 Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2
Figure 2
Competitive Market for Medical Care with Insurance

DI
Supply
DNI

PI

PNI
Price

QNI QI

Quantity of Services

NOTES: PI is the consumer’s out-of-pocket price of services with insurance. PNI is the
consumer’s out-of-pocket price of services without insurance. QI is the quantity of
services demanded by the consumer at PI. QNI is the quantity of services demanded by the
consumer at PNI. DI is demand with insurance. DNI is demand without insurance.
SOURCE: Dowd, B., Feldman, R., Nyman, J., and Town, B., University of Minnesota, 2006.

The DI is nearly vertical reflecting our inefficient distribution of health care ser-
assump­tion that most Medicare beneficia- vices relative to other goods and services
ries in FFS Medicare have supplementary in the market.
Medi­gap insurance that substantially re­­ However, Nyman (2003) has suggested
duces the consumer’s out-of-pocket price so that moral hazard has both an efficient and
that changing the supply price of services an inefficient component. He uses the fol-
has little effect on demand. lowing thought experiment to distinguish
The conventional view of moral hazard is between efficient and inefficient moral haz-
that although consumers derive some ben- ard. Conventional health insurance pays off
efit from the additional services triggered by reducing the price of health care ser-
by price-reduction insurance, the additional vices. Suppose, however, that health insur-
services are valued by consumers at less ance paid off by giving policyholders a cash
than their cost. (If the services were valued payment equal to the amount that insured
at least as much as their cost, consumers consumers spend under the traditional
would have purchased them in the absence price-reduction form of insurance. Con­
of insurance.) The distortion of prices sumers would be free to spend the cash
induced by price-reduction insurance thus payment on health care or anything else.
is a form of market failure, resulting in an

Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2 101


Figure 3
Efficient and Inefficient Moral Hazard

$100

90

80
Expenditures in Thousands

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0
Uninsured Cash Payoff Traditional
Insurance Insurance
Insurance Status

NOTES: The three bars represent the level of spending by the same individual if the individual (1) was uninsured, (2) had insurance
that provide a cash payment if the individual had a particular medical condition, or (3) had traditional health insurance that reduces the
consumer’s out-of-pocket price of services.
SOURCE: Dowd, B., Feldman, R., Nyman, J., and Town, B., University of Minnesota, 2006.

Now suppose that individuals were $100,000, so total moral hazard is $80,000
assigned randomly to (1) no insurance, (2) ($100,000 - $20,000). Individuals with cash
cash payoff policies, or (3) traditional payoff policies spend $80,000 on health care,
price-reduction insurance. Comparing the and thus the amount of inefficient moral
expenditure on health care by uninsured hazard is $20,000 ($100,000 - $80,000). By
in­divi­duals and individuals with traditional subtraction, the remaining moral hazard of
price-reduction insurance would yield an $60,000 is efficient ($80,000 - $20,000). Thus,
estimate of total moral hazard. Comparing the inefficient portion of moral hazard is
the expenditure on health care by individu- the additional health care demand attribut-
als with traditional insurance versus able to the use of price-reduction insurance
cash payoff policies would estimate the versus cash payoff insurance.
amount of inefficient moral hazard. The If Medicare beneficiaries paid their entire
comparison is illustrated in Figure 3. In this health insurance premiums out-of-pocket,
example, expenditures in response to a then we might assume that the policies
particular illness by uninsured consumers they demanded reflected the best balance
are $20,000, while individuals with tradi- of moral hazard and protection against
tional price reducing insurance spend risk. However, Medicare premiums are

102 Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2


heavily subsidized by the government, Alternatively, Medicare could reduce
even when prepayment of premiums during con­­sumption by reducing the supply price
the beneficiary’s income-earning years is of services—for example, to PL in Figure
considered. Medicare beneficiaries retiring 1. For the remainder of the analysis, we
in 1994 received, on average, $5.19 in Part assume that Medicare influences consump-
A benefits for every dollar they paid into the tion primarily by setting the supply price of
system (King, 1994). Part B premiums are services, rather than the demand price faced
designed to cover only 25 percent of costs. by beneficiaries. Thus, when we refer to the
Thus, beneficiaries lobby the government price of physician services we are referring
for more Medicare coverage, with greater to the price paid to providers, rather than
levels of moral hazard, than one would the price faced by beneficiaries.
observe in the absence of those subsidies. We denote the quantity of services deemed
The subsidy of Medicare premiums obli- efficient by Medicare as QM and we assume
gates Medicare to distinguish between that the government’s objective is to pur-
efficient and inefficient moral hazard. chase QM for FFS Medicare beneficiaries.
Further­more, because Medicare pays for QM is not necessarily equal to QNI (or to QI),
health services with taxes (primarily in­­ but may reflect efficient moral hazard and
come and wage taxes), the calculation of other considerations as described in the
efficient moral hazard should include a remainder of the article.
comparison of the benefits associated with
another dollar of Medicare spending to the Multiple Payers
administrative cost of collecting the addi-
tional dollar of tax revenue and the effect of Despite MedPAC’s recent comparison of
those taxes on productivity (known as the Medicare physician fees to those of private
deadweight loss of tax revenue). insurers, Medicare’s current price-setting
In theory, Medicare could reduce policy does not recognize explicitly any
demand by increasing beneficiaries’ coin- interaction of its prices with activity in the
surance and deductibles. However, most private health insurance market. But the
FFS Medicare beneficiaries purchase sup- FFS Medicare Program does not exist in
plementary insurance that covers much of isolation from private health insurance.
their point-of-purchase cost sharing, and Virtually all types of medical care (with the
the government subsidizes the purchase of possible exception of treatment for end
that supplementary coverage. We assume stage renal disease) consumed by Medicare
that such supplementary coverage will beneficiaries also are consumed by individ-
remain legal, unrestricted, and subsidized, uals with private insurance.
so most beneficiaries will continue to Figure 4 shows the private demand and
purchase it. Thus, manipulating point- adjusted total demand curves for physician
of-purchase cost sharing (i.e., coinsurance services, along with the market supply
and deductible) is likely to be a way to curve. Total demand is the sum of private
regulate consumption. demand and QM. The efficient total quan-
tity of services is found where total demand
 Employment-based health insurance premiums and out-of-
pocket spending on health care services also receive implicit
is equal to supply.
subsidy through exemption from State and Federal personal Figure 4 also illustrates an important
income and FICA taxes.
 Medigap premiums are subsidized because Medicare pays fact about the Medicare Program: because
approximately 80 percent of the cost of additional utiliza- Medi­care is a large health plan and com-
tion induced by filling the gaps in the entitlement coverage
(Christensen, 1987). petes with private insurers for the services

Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2 103


Figure 4
Efficient Medicare Price in a Competitive Market with Multiple Payers

Private
Demand
Plus Qm
Private Supply
Demand

P Medicare Fee Level


Price

QM

0 QP Private Quantity + QM

Quantity

NOTES: QM is the quantity of services deemed efficient by Medicare. QP is the level of services demanded by
privately insured consumers at price P. P is the price of services that equalizes total demand and supply.
SOURCE: Dowd, B., Feldman, R., Nyman, J., and Town, B., University of Minnesota, 2006.

of the same set of physicians, the prices Medicare fees high enough to eliminate all
that Medicare pays for services influ- excess demand by Medicare beneficiaries?
ence the level of consumption by privately Recall that many FFS Medicare beneficia-
insured consumers. If the Medicare price ries face out-of-pocket prices that are close
is higher than P, then consumption by Medi­ to zero.
care beneficiaries will increase (assum­ing Second, the efficiency of price P could be
QM is less than the amount of services threatened by the way in which physicians
that beneficiaries would demand at zero respond to a reduction in the Medicare
out-of-pocket price) and consumption by price. Individual physicians could respond
privately insured consumers will decrease. to Medicare fee changes by altering either
The opposite outcome will happen if the the quantity or quality of services provided
Medicare price is lower than P. to Medicare beneficiaries. If physicians
Price P is economically efficient, given an responded to a price decrease by rationing
initial distribution of resources and deter- medical care according to any method
mination of QM. However, two problems other than willingness to pay, the resulting
could arise. First, the resulting level of pri- distribution of Medicare services would be
vate consumption (QP) could be considered inefficient (in the absence of other sources
unfair if the initial distribution of resources of market failure), even though the total
was unfair. With over 40 million uninsured quantity of services consumed by Medicare
Americans under age 65, the government beneficiaries remained at QM. For example,
needs to consider carefully its policies rationing on the basis of the beneficiary’s
re­garding unmet demand by Medicare willingness to wait in the office would
beneficiaries. Should the government set be inefficient.
104 Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2
Allowing physicians to charge some cians dropping higher-cost patients. The
Medicare beneficiaries a fee in addition to presumption was that these patients likely
the government payment rate would allevi- would be Medicare beneficiaries. MedPAC’s
ate that inefficiency. This practice is known concern implies that Medicare has not
as balance billing. Physicians have a limited adjusted physician prices adequately for
ability to balance bill Medicare patients, the extra complexity of Medicare patients.
but only if they do not accept assign­ment. If that is the case, then patients with uncom-
Accepting assignment means that physi­ pensated levels of complexity will be dis-
cians agree to accept Medicare’s price as criminated against in the current payment
payment in full. In return, the physician can system. The preferred solution would be to
bill Medicare directly, collecting only the correct the relative fees and then pursue
coinsurance and deductible from the patient. efficient pricing.
Physicians who agree to accept assign- Manipulating the general supply price of
ment on all allowed claims are referred to physician services would not address other
as participating physicians and receive a important problems. Analyses by Baicker
5-percent increase in fees. How­ever, par- et al. (2004), Fisher et al. (2004; 2003a,b),
ticipation does not carry an obligation to and Wennberg, Fisher, and Skinner (2002),
see Medicare patients. Limits on balance suggest that a significant percentage of
billing effectively limit the physician’s addi- medical spending may not be associated
tional revenue to 9.25 percent (MedPAC, with improvements in patient health.
2004) and some States have passed legisla- Addressing that issue could require adjust-
tion prohibiting balance billing of Medicare ments in the prices of specific services to
patients (McKnight, 2004). specific patients, rather than overall adjust-
It appears doubtful that balance billing is ment to the fee schedule. Another approach
needed on a large scale. Ninety-nine per- might be better consumer information.
cent of allowed Medicare charges were Primary care physicians and their patients
assigned in 2003. Moreover, physician par- will respond to improved information on
ticipation and assignment rates in Medicare the risks and benefits of some surgical
have been rising in recent years (MedPAC, interventions (Kolata, 2006).
2004). These data, taken in conjunction
with the rising rate at which physicians are Imperfect Competition Among Health
accepting new Medicare patients and Care Providers
MedPAC’s surveys that show a narrowing
gap between Medicare and private physi- In addition to insurance itself, price dis-
cian prices, suggest that the marginal net tortions can arise if providers have market
revenue of Medicare versus privately- power. Market power can result from natu-
insured patients is not substantially differ- ral monopoly (decreasing marginal cost)
ent. McKnight (2004) finds little effect of or restricted entry that keeps new compe­
balance billing on the quality or quantity of titors out of the market when profits exceed
Medicare physician services. the competitive rate of return. When a
In response to an early draft of this arti- single provider controls the entire supply
cle, MedPAC staff expressed concern that of a service, the provider’s marginal cost
if payments were not adjusted adequately curve is the same as the market supply
for differences in patient costs, then low- curve. A monopolistic provider sets price at
ering Medicare fees might result in physi- the intersection of marginal revenue and

Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2 105


Figure 5
Monopolistic Local Market for Health Care Services with Government-Set Prices
Marginal
Cost

PE
Price

Marginal
Revenue
D

Q QE

Quantity of Services

NOTES: D is Demand. PE is the competitive equilibrium price. QE is the competitive


equilibrium quantity. P is the monopolist’s price. Q is the monopolist’s quantity.
SOURCE: Dowd, B., Feldman, R., Nyman, J., and Town, B., University of Minnesota, 2006.

marginal cost, resulting in restricted output Combination of Multiple Payers


and a higher price of services compared and a Monopolistic Provider
with the competitive equilibrium.
Figure 5 shows a monopolistic market Figure 6 shows the combination of multi-
where demand and marginal revenue are D ple payers and a monopolistic provider.
and MR, respectively. The efficient price is Because health care services cannot be
PE with demand QE. However, the profit- resold, a monopolistic provider can price
maximizing price for the monopolist is P discriminate between privately insured
with demand Q. consumers and FFS Medicare beneficia-
How should the government respond to ries. The monopolist will supply services to
this situation? In a market with only one each payer so that the marginal revenue
type of consumer (e.g., Medicare beneficia- from privately insured consumers equals
ries), a public utility response would give the government price and the marginal
the government the power to set prices. cost of services (assuming that costs are
The perfectly informed regulator would set the same in the two markets).
price at PE. The monopolist would respond The monopolistic provider’s profit is: π =
by supplying quantity QE, which corre- RP (QP) + (PG × QM) – C(QP + QM) where π
sponds to consumer demand at PE, thus = profit; RP = revenue from privately-insured
achieving the same result as the competi- patients; QP and QM are quantities of ser-
tive market. But the real world is more com- vices supplied to privately-insured and FFS
plicated because there are multiple payers. Medicare patients, respectively; PG = the
FFS Medicare fee; and C = cost. Profit max-
imization with respect to QP and QM yields
106 Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2
Figure 6
Market with Multiple Payers, Government Prices, and a Monopolistic Provider

PD Private Marginal Revenue


PP Plus QG

PP ⁄
Provider’s
Marginal Cost

PG

QG
Price

PG ⁄

QG ⁄

0 QP QP ⁄ QT

Quantity of Services
NOTES: PG is the initial price of Medicare services set by the government. PP is the
monopolist’s price when then government’s price is PG. PG/ is the new, lower price
of Medicare services set by the government. PP/ is the monopolist’s price when then
government’s price is PG/. QP is the quantity of services demanded by privately insured
consumers at price PP. QP/ is the quantity of services demanded by privately insured
consumers at price PP/. QT is the total quantity of services demanded by all consumers
when the government’s price is PG/. 0 is the number zero.
SOURCE: Dowd, B., Feldman, R., Nyman, J., and Town, B., University of Minnesota, 2006.

∂RP/∂QP = PG = ∂C/∂(QP + QM), which amount of services supplied to FFS


means the marginal revenue from private Medicare beneficiaries is determined by
patients must equal the government fee the intersection of the government price
and the marginal cost of services in both with overall marginal cost.
markets combined. We assume that ∂C/∂QP Suppose the government wanted to pur-
= ∂C/∂QM and that the potential number of chase QG physicians’ services for Medicare
Medicare patients is unlimited. beneficiaries based on supply and demand
If FFS Medicare did not set prices and for Medicare services in a single market,
FFS Medicare beneficiaries were less price- adjusted for inefficient moral hazard. By
sensitive than privately insured consumers, setting price at PG, the government could
then beneficiaries would pay higher prices, get providers to supply QG. But would that
and vice versa. However, FFS Medicare can quantity of services be the efficient quan-
set prices for its own beneficiaries. In that tity that we refer to as QM? The outcome
case, the monopolistic provider maximizes shown in Figure 6 is inefficient due to the
profit by supplying services to privately presence of monopoly power in the private
insured consumers up to the point (QP) insurance market. Privately insured con-
where marginal revenue in the private mar- sumers value an additional unit of service
ket equals the government-determined at PP dollars, but Medicare values the same
price for FFS Medicare services. The marginal service at only PG dollars. Thus,
Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2 107
privately insured consumers would be will- demographic factors (e.g., Hispanic ethnic-
ing to pay the government to reduce PG to ity and sex) explained 70 percent of the
something like PG/. variance; and health maintenance organiza-
The government could increase effi- tion and medical supply variables, includ-
ciency by reducing its price below PG, to ing the percent of doctors who are specialists
the point that access problems start to and the supply of hospital beds, added 10
appear in FFS Medicare. This would induce percent to explained variance. In an earlier
providers to reduce the private price to PP/ study with a different specification, Rizzo
and increase the quantity of services sup- (1992) found that per capita income was
plied to privately insured consumers to negatively related to the probability of uti-
QP/. Medicare beneficiaries then would be lizing some Part A services, but positively
supplied only QG/ services. The govern- related to the probability of utilizing some
ment must determine whether the target Part B services. These studies show that
level of consumption for Medicare benefi- there is substantial variation in Medicare
ciaries (QM) is QG, QG/, or some other level spending across markets due to variation
of consumption. The fairness of this in demand and supply factors.
outcome depends on the fairness of the Adjusting prices for demand-shift vari-
processes that determine private demand ables requires careful thought in efficient
and QM, including the initial distribution pricing systems. In a competitive market,
of income. changes in demand alter the efficient price
If private demand became less elastic only if the long-run supply curve is upward-
(for example, because the prevalence of ill- sloping (Figure 1). The supply curve
ness increased), the monopolist would slopes upward if the prices of inputs rise
raise its price to private consumers. If FFS with the quantity of output. Thus, in com-
Medicare chose to offset this effect, it petitive markets, Medicare could incorpo-
would do so by lowering its price. The same rate the effect of demand-shift variables
approach would apply to a market in which into its price-setting decisions by adjusting
providers had greater monopoly power— the supply price of services for input prices.
FFS Medicare should pay less in that mar- That is the purpose of the geographic prac-
ket to induce the monopolist to reduce its tice cost index (GPCI), as explained by
price (and increase the supply) of services Zuckerman and Maxwell (2004) which
to privately insured consumers. adjusts prices for local variation in physi-
cian work, practice expense, and profes-
Local Market Variation in Demand sional liability insurance (MedPAC, 2003).
and Supply In its current form, however, the local mar-
kets that the GPCI uses to adjust prices are
Each topic discussed thus far could apply quite large. There are only 89 GPCI market
either to FFS Medicare as a whole or to areas for the entire U.S. If FFS Medicare
individual local markets. If there are signifi- adopted an efficient pricing model, it would
cant variations in demand and supply in be necessary to explore new market defini-
local markets, then efficient pricing tions that correspond more closely to geo-
requires that Medicare recognize those dif- graphic markets for physician services.
ferences. Cutler and Sheiner (1999) found
 The profit-maximizing monopoly price depends on the slope
that illness variables explained 66 percent of the demand (and thus the marginal revenue) curve, but the
of the variance in adjusted Medicare spend- efficient price always corresponds to the intersection of market
supply and demand.
ing among hospital referral regions. Adding

108 Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2


Factors related to the supply of services, to cash payoff policies and traditional price-
including institutional differences in health reduction insurance. The difference in
care organizations, also can shift the local health care utilization between these two
market supply curve. Currently, Medicare groups would be a measure of inefficient
does not adjust prices for supply-shift moral hazard.
variables other than input prices. For Third, Medicare would need to decide if
example, suppose that a State prohibits its prices should be adjusted to recognize
for-profit hospitals, which are more (or the effect of Medicare prices on consump-
less) efficient than not-for-profit hospitals. tion by privately insured consumers. This
Should Medi­care raise (or lower) its fees approach would require monitoring of excess
in that State? (i.e., unmet) demand in dif­ferent markets.
Such monitoring activity should take place
Policy Implications regardless of Medicare’s pricing approach.
Additional research would be needed on
To implement efficient pricing, Medicare the extent to which the GPCI could be used
would need to determine the desired level to achieve efficient pricing in local mar­
of physician services for beneficiaries to kets. The current 89 GPCI regions might
consume (QM) in each market area, and be too large to make effective adjustments
then set prices to achieve that level of sup- for local variation in supply conditions.
ply. The first step would be to identify the The data required to set Medicare prices
level of consumption that would be observed that are both efficient and fair are signifi-
in a competitive market with a single insurer cant, but by no means prohibitive. Many of
and current insurance coverage. The level the variables currently are collected in an
of competition varies among markets, but a uncoordinated way, and others such as
regression model could be estimated that provider concentration should be collected
accounted for competition, as well as other whether or not FFS Medicare changes
factors. The estimated equation could be its pricing approach. Any data source used
used to predict QM in each market with to adjust local prices would have to be
high levels of competition. Medicare also transparent and probably publicly avail-
could identify markets that scored well on able, as would the methodology used to
measures of health outcomes and con- adjust prices.
sumer satisfaction with access to and qual- It is important to understand that
ity of physician services. Medicare already makes implicit policy
Second, Medicare would need to adjust decisions regarding all the issues raised
the desired level of utilization for inefficient in this analysis. Medicare provides sub-
moral hazard. The way to determine the stantial subsidies for basic benefits and pri-
amount of inefficient moral hazard is to vate supplementary insurance, regardless
turn Nyman’s thought experiment into a of the beneficiary’s income, suggesting
real experiment. During the 1970s, the that moral hazard is not thought to be an
Federal Government spent 136 million important problem, or that all moral hazard
(1984) dollars to determine the effect of is thought to be efficient. Medicare cur-
coinsurance and deductibles on health care rently sets physician fees without regard to
spending (Manning et al., 1987). To deter- the effect on the quantity of services
mine the amount of inefficient moral supplied to privately insured consum-
hazard, the government could conduct ers. From an operational viewpoint, local
another experiment, randomizing subjects variations in supply conditions other than

Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2 109


input prices have been deemed irrelevant, Hsiao, W.C., Braun, P., Dunn, D., et al.: Resource-
as well. Based Relative Values: An Overview. Journal of the
American Medical Association 260(16):2347–2353,
Clarifying the efficiency and fairness October 28, 1988.
goals of setting FFS Medicare fees would King, G.: Health Care Reform and the Medicare
bring many important topics into the Program. Health Affairs 13(5):39-43, Winter 1994.
open for careful analysis and debate, Kolata, G.: Medicare Says It Will Pay, but Patients
including local monopoly power, the Say “No Thanks.” New York Times March 3, 2006.
role of supplementary coverage, the Manning, W.G., Newhouse, J.P., Duan, N., et al.:
effect of Medicare prices on privately- Health Insurance and the Demand for Medical Care:
Evidence from a Randomized Experiment. American
insured consumers, and the efficiency of Economic Review 77(3):251-277, June 1987.
moral hazard.
McCombs, J.S.: A Competitive Bidding Approach
to Physician Payment. Health Affairs 8(1):50-64,
REFERENCES Spring 1989.
McKnight, R.: Medicare Balance Billing Restrictions:
Baicker, K., Chandra, A., Skinner, J.S., et al.: Who Impacts on Physicians and Beneficiaries. Department
You Are And Where You Live: How Race And of Economics, University of Oregon. September
Geography Affect The Treatment Of Medicare 2004. Internet address: http://economics.uoregon.
Beneficiaries. Web Exclusive. Health Affairs VAR33- edu/papers/UO-2004-13_McKnight_Medicare.pdf
VAR44. October 7, 2004. Internet address: http:// (Accessed 2006.)
www.healthaffairs.org (Accessed 2006.)
Medicare Payment Advisory Com­mission: Geo­
Christensen, S.: Acute Health Care Costs for the graphic Practice Cost Indexes. August 12, 2003.
Aged Medicare Population: Overview and Policy Internet address: http://www.medpac.gov/publica-
Options. Milbank Quarterly 65(3):397-425, 1987. tions/other_repor ts/Aug03_GPCI_2pgrKH.pdf
Cutler, D.M. and Sheiner, L.: The Geography of (Accessed 2006.)
Medicare. American Economic Review 89(2):228- Medicare Payment Advisory Com­mission. Report to
233, May 1999. Congress: Medicare in Rural America. June 2001.
Dowd, B.E., Feldman, R., and Christianson, J.: Medicare Payment Advisory Com­mission: Report to
Competitive Pricing for Medicare. American Congress: Medicare Payment Policy. Washington,
Enterprise Institute Press. Washington, DC. 1996. DC. March 2002.
Fisher, E.S., Wennberg, D.E., Stukel, T.A., et al.: Medicare Payment Advisory Commission: Report to
Variations in the Longitundinal Efficiency of Congress: Medicare Payment Policy. Washington,
Academic Medical Centers. Web Exclusive. DC. March 2004.
Health Affairs VAR19- VAR32. October 7, 2004.
Internet address: http://www.healthaffairs.org Nyman, J.A.: The Theory of Demand for Health
(Accessed 2006.) Insurance. Stanford University Press. Stanford,
CA. 2003.
Fisher, E.S., Wennberg, D.E., Stukel, T.A., et al.: The
Implications of Regional Variations in Medicare Pauly, M.V.: Fee Schedules and Utilization. In
Spending. Part 1: The Content, Quality and Regulating Doctors’ Fees: Competition, Benefits, and
Accessibility of Care. Annals of Internal Medicine Controls under Medicare. American Enterprise
138(4): 273-288, February 18, 2003a. Institute Press. Washington, DC. 1991.
Fisher, E.S., Wennberg, D.E., Stukel, T.A., et al.: The Rizzo, J.: Supply and Demand Factors in
Implications of Regional Variations in Medicare Medicare. Health Services Research 26(6):705-724,
Spending. Part 2: Health Outcomes and Satisfaction February 1992.
with Care. Annals of Internal Medicine 138(4): 288- Rosen, H.S.: Public Finance (Sixth Edition).
299, February 18, 2003b. McGraw-Hill/Irwin. New York, NY. 2002.
Hackbarth, G.M.: Medicare Payments to Physicians. Varian, H.: Microeconomic Analysis. W.W. Norton
Statement before the Subcommittee on Health and Company. New York, NY. 1992.
Committee on Ways and Means. U.S. House of Rep­ Wennberg, J.E., Fisher, E.S., and Skinner, J.S.:
re­sentatives. November 17, 2005. Internet address: Geography and the Debate Over Medicare Reform.
http://www.medpac.gov/publications/con­ Web Exclusive. Health Affairs W96-W114, February
gressional_testimony/Testimony_111705_Phys_ 13, 2002.
Pay.pdf?CFID=1767404&CFTOKEN=79633076
(Accessed 2006.)
110 Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2
Zuckerman, S. and Maxwell, S.: Reconsidering
Geographic Adjustments to Medicare Physician
Fees. The Urban Institute. September, 2004.
Internet address: http://www.urban.org/Uploaded
PDF/411076_geo_adjustments.pdf (Accessed 2006).

Reprint Requests: Bryan E. Dowd, Ph.D., Division of Health,


School of Public Health, University of Minnesota, Box 729,
MMC, Minneapolis, MN 55455. E-mail: dowdx001@umn.edu

Health Care Financing Review/Winter 2006-2007/Volume 28, Number 2 111

You might also like