You are on page 1of 40

Effects of Female Literacy in Villages in Rural Rajasthan

Shirley Johnson-Lans and Shweta Kamdar*

*Vassar College.
____________________________________________________________________________________

The authors thank the Global Foundation for Humanity for permission to use its Vassar Study data.

Vassar College Economics Working Paper # 76


Effects of Female Literacy in Villages in Rural Rajasthan

I. Introduction.

The importance of education to economic development has long been recognized 1 The education

of women is viewed as a particularly important instrument to promote both development of macro-

economies and welfare of individuals and families2. Moreover, there is evidence that literacy is a

public good within families, with an illiterate adult family member earning more when living within

a family with literate members.3 The process by which female literacy affects the well being of

individual women and their families is, however, still not fully understood. Does literacy change

women’s tastes with respect to how resources are allocated within families? Does it give them more

power in the decision making within families and shift the family utility function from one which

merely reflects the tastes of the male head of household (a unitary function) to one that reflects
4
cooperation or bargaining? Since there may also be assortive mating in that men who marry

literate women in traditional societies have more progressive views about gender roles than does the

average male, female literacy may be associated with a different family utility function even when

the male head is the dominant or sole decision maker.5

1
See for instance, Behrman and W olfe (1984), Behrman and Birdsall (1987), and) Dreze and Sen (1989).

2
Rosenzweig and W olpin 1994) and Rosenzweig (2000).

3
Basu, K., et al., (2001).

4
The unitary model is usually attributed to Becker (1981). Representative work on cooperative or
bargaining models is that of Manser and Brown (1980) and Horney and McElroy (1981).

5
This was tested by A. M. Basu by looking at the education of daughters in families into which literate
women marry. (Basu, 2002) .

1
There is, however, a broad consensus that literacy rates of children, particularly female

children, are positively affected by the education level of the mother.6 Child health has also been

widely found to be positively associated with mother’s education level,7 and infant and child

mortality negatively associated with it.8 The relationship between female literacy and fertility is

more complex, even though usually found to be negatively correlated. 9 The econometric analysis

of fertility is complicated by the fact that family size and infant and child mortality are

interdependent.10 For developed nations, fertility is usually modeled as in part a trade-off between

quantity and quality of children.11 The same phenomenon is thought to apply in developing nations,

once educational opportunities and availability of consumer goods begin to increase.12

This study examines the effects of literacy on women’s own health, knowledge about health,

fertility, infant mortality, and the health, literacy and marital status of adolescent daughters. A new

data source is used to study female literacy in a group of traditional rural Indian villages. In 2004,

personal interviews and medical examinations were conducted on approximately 1000 adult women

(over 18 years of age) and 1000 adolescent girls (10 to 18 years of age) in nine villages near Jodhpur,

6
Behrman and Rosensweig (2002), W olfe and Behrman (1987).

7
Sandiford, et al. (1995); Glewwe (1999 ).

8
Bourne and W alker (1991), Cochrane (1979), Cleland and van Ginneken (1988), Aly and Grabowski
(1990), Singh (1994) .

9
A.M. Basu (2002); Bhat, (2002 ). However, the relationship between desired family size and the actual
number of surviving children may change in the course of economic development as infant and child mortality
decline and as methods of fertility control become more available. There may be periods in which education of
women and fertility are seen to be positively correlated, if mortality rates for children of literate women decline
faster than desired family size.

10
Mellington and Cameron (1999); Borooah (2003).

11
Becker (1960).

12
See, for instance, Basu (2002) op. cit.;W olfe and Behrman (1986).

2
in the western part of the state of Rajasthan. 13 A natural experiment is provided by the intervention

of an NGO, the Veerni Project, which provides rudimentary medical care, health education, and

schooling for girls (classes in literacy and numeracy) in a subset of the villages in this region. The

nine sample villages consist of three that experienced long-term (10 year) intervention from the

Veerni Project, three that received help from the Veerni Project for 2 years, and three that had not

been included in the Veerni Project at the time of the survey. The samples of women and girls were

constructed with the number of respondents from each village randomly chosen so as to sample the

same proportion of the populations in each of the villages.14

Since only a tiny fraction of the women and girls in this study group of rural villages have

had more than primary education, and many have become literate at least partly through attending

the classes provided by the NGO, we decided to use literate/illiterate as the measure of women’s and

adolescent girls’ education levels throughout this paper.

A Profile of Adult Female Literacy in the Study Villages,

Only about 15 percent of the sample of 951 adult women are literate, and even fewer have

completed primary level schooling. Literacy rates are particularly low for lower caste women. For

instance, in 1991 the literacy rate for scheduled caste women in rural Rajasthan was only 4.73

percent, the lowest rate in any Indian state.15 In our sample, the proportion of literate scheduled caste

women was only about 0.7 percent; the proportion of scheduled tribal women was only 0.8 percent.

The proportion of literate women in combined Castes 1 through 3 was only 6.5 percent.Since literacy

rates are expected to vary among villages as well as by caste and religion, dummy variables for

13
The survey was designed by Shirley Johnson-Lans, Vassar College, and overseen by Dr. Kanti Chandra
Joshi, Veerni Project Coordinator, and Mr. Chandra Shekhar Joshi, Jodhpur University.

14
This is a stratified sample of villages within the region.

15
Table 2, page 40, Narayanamoorthy and Kamble (2003).

3
village effects are introduced, and a variable for each lower caste is included: caste 1 = “scheduled

castes”, caste 2 = “scheduled tribes”, and caste 3 = “other backward castes” (OBC).16 A dummy

variable for “Muslim religion” distinguishes Muslim women who are in this part of the world a

minority and generally disadvantaged.17

A probit was run to investigate the effects of personal characteristics (age, caste, and

religion) and environmental (village) effects on the likelihood of a woman being literate. The

equation is of form

p(i) = $(1) + $(2)x(i2) + … + $(k)x(ik) + u(I) .

Results of this probit are shown in Table 1a. Lower caste and Muslim women were less likely to

be literate when compared with higher caste Hindu women. Living in three of the villages was also

associated with significantly lower literacy rates. Not surprisingly, the probability of being literate

was also found to decline with age, with the marginal effect of an additional year = -0.73 percent.

Variables for caste and religion are included in all estimating equations throughout this study.

Arranged marriages for young girls are common, although illegal, in India. Many girls are

“effectively married” by early adolescence. Effective marriage means that a woman has been through

a marriage ceremony and lives with her husband. In our sample of adolescent girls, 32.8 percent are

effectively married. It is widely believed that age of marriage has an effect on female literacy and

that literacy may also affect age of marriage.18 Even though there were concerns about endogeneity

between marital status, age of marriage and literacy, we estimated probit equations for probability

of adult female literacy in which marital status and age of marriage were also included as

16
The category, scheduled castes, or dalit, is roughly equivalent to the term, no longer used, “untouchable”.

17
Only one woman in the sample did not list herself as either Hindu or Muslim. The category “other” was
therefore omitted from this study.

18
Khan (1985); Field (2005).

4
explanatory variables. Being married was found to reduce the probability of a woman being literate

by 21-24 percent. Later marriage increased it by 0.7 percent per year of delayed marriage. [See

Tables 1b and 1c.]

II. Effects of Adult Female Literacy on Health.

The Health Conditions in the Study Villages.

Life in Rajasthani farming villages in the Thar desert is spartan, with income and nutrition dependant

on rainfall, since no pipelines exist to bring water from less arid areas. There is little government

investment in infra-structure that will reduce poverty or improve health. Only rudimentary NGO-

sponsored health care facilities are available within any of the villages.19 Malnutrition, particularly

iron deficiency, is very common in women and adolescent girls.

The following table, summarizes the prevalence of anemia among the women and girls in our

sample, using the Indian hemoglobin standard for anemia: <12 - 10 = mildly anemic, <10 - 7 =

moderately anemic, and <7 = severely anemic.

Level of Anemia in Study Villages

Percentages of Adolescent Girls Adult Women


Total Anemic 76.3% 81.9%
Mildly Anemic 68.4% 59.2%
Moderately Anemic 6.7% 20.1%
Severely Anemic 1.3% 2.6%

In this environment, a higher rate of adult female literacy may by itself have little immediate effect

on health. It may, however, affect future generations. Our null hypotheses are that female literacy

does not significantly affect own-health status, infant and child mortality, or health status of

19
The Veerni Project represents intervention on a very small-scale level. It provides health education
classes for women and girls, training for local health workers, and a weekly visit from a mobile medical unit
equipped with simple supplies such as iron pills, antiseptics, bandages, and one physician.

5
adolescent daughters.

A. Effects of Female Literacy on Own-Health.

Our estimating equations use several measures of health as dependent variables. A probit was

estimated for the probability of a woman showing symptoms of anemia. OLS regressions were

estimated for determinants of two measures of health: haematocrit level and body mass index (BMI).

Our regression equations are of general form

Y(i) = a + $1X1(i)+ .................$kXk(i) + :(i)

The estimating equations encompass both supply and demand-side factors, and hence are reduced

form equations. Demand-side explanatory variables include a vector of socio-economic variables

(caste, religion, family monthly income in rupees20, and whether the home has electricity21) and a

vector of personal characteristics (woman’s age, marital status, number of children she has borne,

and whether she is literate). The vector of environmental variables (village dummy variables and

NGO effects) are the supply-side factors. Equations are estimated using alternatively village and

NGO dummy variables.,

The null hypothesis that her literacy had no effect on the health status of a woman could not

be rejected when health was measured by BMI or haematocrit level. However, when a probit was

run with dependent variable “exhibits anemia symptoms,” and village fixed effects were included,

being literate was associated with a reduction in the probability that the woman would exhibit

anemia symptoms of approximately 12.4 percent. [Table 2a] Economic status did not appear to

20
Throughout this study, family income is measured by income of head of household. This was a
reasonably good approximation for total family monetary income, in the past since women were generally not
employed outside the family home and fields.t. As a result of the Veerni Project, this may soon no longer be true.
W omen in the villages are being given sewing machines and lessons in fashion and are now producing articles to
sell in the cities. These textile products are becoming a major “cash crop” of the villages.
It should also be noted that since income does not include imputed values for home-produced, home-consumed
food and other products, here as in other rural village economies throughout the world, monetary income is a very
imperfect measure of the family’s standard of living.

21
Having electricity in the home is used as a proxy variable for family wealth.

6
affect this aspect of an adult woman’s health nor did her age or the number of children she had

borne. However, several villages had significantly lower rates of adult female anemia symptoms,

and belonging to a scheduled tribe (Caste 2 ) was associated with an increase of 20 percent in risk

of anemia.

When NGO effects were substituted for village fixed effects, literacy status became less significant

(0.072) and the magnitude of its effect as reduced.. [See Table 2b.] This suggests that the effect of the Veerni

Project’s medical intervention overcame some of the negative effects of illiteracy on the health of village

women.

It is well known that in rural India women and girls often receive less food and other goods

than do men and boys.22 Since we control for income and wealth, our findings are at least consistent

with the notion that a woman’s literacy may be associated with a different intra-family allocation of

goods, and that literacy may help to overcome women’s inferior status in the family.

An alternative hypothesis, well substantiated in studies of high-income industrialized

nations, is that education makes people more efficient in the production of health.23 The observed

relationship between literacy and fewer anemia symptoms may also be a reflection of this, since we

do not know that other family members are not also healthier when adult women are literate.

Another indication that this may be true is provided by an examination of the relationship

between literacy and knowledge about health. Both adult women and adolescent girls were asked

a number of questions about their knowledge of diseases. A variable “knowledge of how HIV is

transmitted” is used in this study as a measure of knowledge about health. A probit was run for

“probability of a woman knowing how HIV is transmitted.”. We included the same set of personal,

environmental and family characteristics as explanatory variables plus a dummy variable for “has

a radio or TV”, since the media may be an important source of information about HIV. Being

22
Pitt et al. (1990).

23
Grossman (1972) and Kenkel (1991) .

7
literate was found to be associated with a 28 percent increase in the probability of an adult woman

knowing how HIV is transmitted. And having a radio or TV raised it by about 19 percent. [Table 3]

This finding is consistent with the hypothesis that literacy promotes efficiency in the production of

health, in that it increases ability to absorb information about the transmission and prevention of

disease.

B. Effect of Women’s Literacy on Fertility.

Observed fertility can be decomposed into intentional fertility and unintentional fertility. Educating

women may result in reduced intentional fertility and/or better control over fertility level. The latter

will reduce unintentional fertility. If education reduces child and infant mortality, it may well reduce

intentional fertility even if it does not affect the demand for children. However, given the lack of

observed effects of mother’s literacy on infant and child mortality rates in these villages [See C (1)

below] we would only expect to see female literacy associated with lower fertility if it reduces the

demand for children or leads to better control over fertility. Educating women is likely to reduce

the demand for number of children, since literate mothers are likely to want more education (quality)

for each child and thus make the well-known quantity/quality trade off. Being literate is also likely

to be associated with having more knowledge about controlling fertility. It was therefore not

surprising to find a negative correlation coefficient between female literacy and number of children

born.

In order to refine our understanding of the relationship between literacy and family size,

regressions were run with “number of children born” and “number of living children” as the

dependent variables. In addition to the usual set of environmental and socio-economic variables, both

age of mother and her age at marriage were included as explanatory variables. Female literacy was

found to be highly significant in this set of regressions. It was associated with a reduction of 0.85

children ever born and a reduction of 0.78 living children per woman, when village fixed effects

8
were included. [Tables 4a and 5a] Being literate was associated with reductions of 0.68 children

born and 0.64 living children per woman when NGO effects were substituted for village effects.

[Tables 4b and 5b] Economic status did not appear to be significant, unlike the usual findings for

high-income western nations.24 Our findings lend support to the hypotheses that intentional fertility

decreases with education of women and that education improves control over fertility. The expected

reduction in fertility (family size) associated with increases in female literacy rates should have at

least a modest effect on infant and child mortality, given the findings reported in Section C (1)

below.

C. Effect of Female Literacy on Health of Children.

(1) Infant Mortality


Frequently used measures of child health are infant and child mortality rates. Research studies

conducted in many countries have shown that female literacy reduces infant mortality, and this has

been especially true for studies of India.25 Since Indian culture has a strong son preference, we

examine separately the statistics on female and male infant mortality within a family. . Using the

adult women sample, regressions were run for male and female infant mortality rates and levels.26

Employing the usual set of environmental (village or NGO) and socio-economic (caste, religion,

income, and wealth) variables, plus mother’s age, marital status, literacy, and number of children

24
The variable which was found to have the largest effect on number of children born and number of
surviving children was the presence of the Veerni Project, which provides information about and access to clinics
that offer voluntary sterilization. The net effect of long-term intervention from the NGO was a reduction in average
fertility per woman of 2.7 children. Where the Veerni project has operated health clinics for only two years, its
presence was still associated with a reduction in average number of children born per woman of 1.66. The long- and
short-term NGO effects on average number of living children per woman were reductions of 2.15 and 1.08
respectively.

25
See Gleason (2003) and Caldwell (1986).

26
The rate is obtained by dividing the number of male or female infants reported died in infancy by the
number of children ever born to a woman. Regressions were also run, using the number of male and number of
female children who died in infancy that were reported by individual women. In the latter case, number of children
born to a woman is used as a control variable.

9
in the family, we could not reject the null hypothesis that female literacy has no effect on either the

male or female infant mortality.27

It should be noted, however, that the model was poor in its overall ability to predict infant

mortality. (Adjusted R2 s in the range of + .02 to +.03 were obtained.) The only variable which was

significant was “number of children”, and the value of its regression coefficient is questionable given

the degree of likely interdependency between mortality rates and family size.28 With this disclaimer

in mind, we report that an extra child in a family was associated with a .07 increase in average male

infant mortality and with a .077 increase in the female infant mortality per family.[See Tables 6a -

6b ]. The male infant mortality rate in our sample of adult women respondents was approximately

3 percent. The female infant mortality rate was closer to 3.7 percent.

(2) Effects of Mother’s Literacy on Adolescent Girls’ Health and Nutrition.

We next looked at effects of mother’s literacy on adolescent daughters’ health. As is common in

health economics studies, we use the outcome, daughter’s health status, as a measure of the demand

for health. The demand model we use is similar to the one employed by Henriques et al.29 Demand

for child health is modeled as a function of a set of child characteristics, household or parental

characteristics, and community characteristics. Demand for adolescent girl health is based on the

girl i’s characteristics [age (A); marital status (EM)30; education, e.g. whether literate (E); caste (C);

and religion (R)], household or parental characteristics [mother’s education (M), number of brothers

(B), number of sisters (S), father’s income (Y), and family wealth (W)] and community

27
As Borooah (2003) points out, many other factors besides literacy of women, including safe drinking
water and access to medical facilities are necessary to improve infant and child health and survival.

28
Using this data set, there does not appear to be a way to instrument for this.

29
Henriques, Strauss and Thomas (1991).

30
The state “effectively married” ( EM) is singled out, since in this case the girl is no longer living with her
parental family but with her husband.

10
characteristics (SS).31 The community characteristic, in this case the availability of health care and

health education, is proxied by the dummy variables for the long- or short-term presence of the NGO

(Veerni Project). We thus attain a demand function where

H(i) = f[A(i), EM(i), E(i), C(i), R(i), M(i), B(i), S(i), Y(i), W(i), SS(i)]
On the assumption that mother’s literacy does not affect the price of providing food and health care

to daughters, it is reasonable that a change in the amount of “daughter’s health” demanded by the

family is a reflection of a different family utility function.32 Here we remain agnostic about the way

in which the family utility function is determined. All tests are simply concerned with determining

whether the utility function of a family in which the mother is literate is different from one in which

she is illiterate. If a literate mother is associated with the family maximizing utility by directing

more of its resources to daughters, this should be reflected in such indicators as daughter’s body

mass index (BMI) and the probability of her showing anemia symptoms.

Throughout the analysis of the determinants of adolescent girls’ health, the null hypothesis

is that mother’s literacy has no effect. Using the adolescent girl data set, OLS regressions were run

for determinants of adolescent girls’ body mass index (BMI) and haematocrit level. In the case of

haematocrit level, the null hypothesis could not be rejected. However, BMI of daughters was found

to be positively associated with having a literate mother, at a significance level of .06 [Table 7a]

Female Literacy and Son Preference

An additional brother in the family was found to have a small but significant negative effect on a

girl’s BMI. The marginal effect of having a literate mother outweighed the negative effect of having

additional brothers as long as there were no more than three additional brothers.33 The negative
31
Village variables were not included in any probits or regressions employing the adolescent girl survey
due to high levels of multi-collinearity.

32
Behrman and W olfe (1984); Behrman and Deolaliker (1990).

33
This assumes that the marginal effect of an additional brother is a constant.

11
marginal effect of an additional sister was slightly less than half the magnitude of the effect of an

additional brother, and the regression coefficient was only significant at a 20 percent level. These

findings are consistent with the widespread view that there is discrimination in favor of sons in this

part of the world.34

There is, however, disagreement among scholars about the effect of female literacy on the

degree of gender bias in India. For instance, Murthi, Guio, and Dreze find that increasing female

literacy reduces the degree of discrimination in favor of sons. They find this result to be robust

across all regions in India.35 On the other hand, Sarmistha Pal has found mother’s literacy to be

associated with an increase in the degree of gender bias.36 In our study, an additional regression that

included an interaction term between mother’s literacy and number of brothers was estimated for

determinants of a girl’s BMI . The interaction variable, “bias”, proved to be significant and to have

a larger negative effect than number of brothers by itself, which, in the new estimation, was no

longer statistically significant. [Table 7b] When an F test was run on “mother” + “brothers” +

“bias”, the effect of the combination was found to be significant. This provides indirect support for

the notion that literacy in women reinforces the preference for male children or that it makes women

more efficient in implementing this preference. However, since BMI of daughters was still

significantly and positively related to mother’s literacy, it appears that literate mothers do allocate

more of the family’s resources to children.

A probit was run for “probability of a girl exhibiting anemia symptoms”. In our probit

34
Behrman (1988).

35
Murthi et al (1995).

36
Pal (1999).

12
estimation, we determine the likelihood of an adolescent girl showing anemia symptoms according

to the index function

y*(i) = $(1) + $(2)x(i2) + … + $(k)x(ik) + u(i)

where y*(i) is interpreted as the additional utility that family i would get by choosing y(i) = 0
rather than y(i) = 1.

In this test, a mother being literate was associated with a reduction of approximately 9

percent in the probability of a daughter having anemia symptoms. [Table 8] If the daughter herself

was literate, this lowered the probability by an additional 8 percent. The likelihood of a girl showing

anemia symptoms appeared unrelated to her number of brothers but increased with the number of

sisters, an additional sister being associated with about a 2.2 percent increase. The absence of any

significant effect of brothers was initially surprising. 37

It is likely that there are omitted variables in operation here. For example, the family’s

expected or permanent income (wealth) may be reduced by the birth of an additional daughter which

requires the drain on family resources associated with having to supply her with a dowry, whereas

permanent income may be increased by the birth of a son to the extent that he is an expected source

of future income for the family and, in particular, support for parents in their old age.

In addition, when we use the adolescent girl data file to regress number of sisters on

mother’s literacy, we obtain a highly significant negative coefficient, but when we substitute

number of brothers, the coefficient is not significant.38 This lends further support to the discouraging

hypothesis that sex selection is still important in these villages and that literate women are more

37
It should be noted that there is a significant positive correlation between number of sisters and number of
siblings reported by the girls, but no such relationship between number of brothers and number of siblings .
38
Having a literate mother reduces the predicted number of sisters by 0.47when we control for caste,
religion, and family income.

13
likely to successfully engage in it. In summary, it seems that illiterate mothers are likely to have

more daughters, but both mothers and daughters are more likely to exhibit symptoms of anemia.

III. Effect of Mother’s Literacy on Daughters’ Education.

Parents have to decide that it is worthwhile to allocate resources to daughters’ education or girls will

not be allowed to attend government schools or even the local NGO sponsored classes in reading and

arithmetic. An important component of the cost of educating a daughter in this environment is the

opportunity cost, e.g. the cost of not having her available to help in the household or fields.39 Her

number of siblings may be important in two ways. The opportunity cost of allowing a daughter to

attend classes will vary with the number of substitutes available for her contribution to home or

agricultural production., and the per capita budget constraint will be tighter if the family income

must be spread over more family members.

We employ a demand model similar to that described in II C (2) above. A probit is run to test for

the effect of mother’s literacy on the probability of an adolescent girl being literate. The same set

of personal and family explanatory variables are employed, plus a dummy variable for “family has

a TV or radio.” Again, we consider separately the effects of the number of sisters and the number

of brothers. We take into account whether a girl is effectively married, since her family’s willingness

to invest in her education is likely to be conditional on her marital status.40 Age is included since

39
This is the only cost in the case of the NGO sponsored village classes, since attendance at these classes,
unlike the free government schools, does not require travel, a uniform, or the purchase of books and other supplies .
40
An alternative probit estimation used “married” instead of “effectively married.” The results were
virtually the same.

14
being literate cannot be assumed to have been attained by age 10, especially where literacy is

acquired in the local village classes run by the NGO rather than in government schools.

The relevant supply-side effect is the availability of schooling. This is measured by dummy

variables for long- and short-run Veerni Project presence and by distance to school. The latter is

a dummy variable (“proble~e”) based on the girl’s response to the question, “Did you encounter

difficulty pursuing studies due to distance to school?” The response to this question is used as a

proxy variable for distance to school, since no reliable information was obtained on actual

availability and location of government schools.41

Having a literate mother was associated with a 14 percent increase in the probability that an

adolescent girl would be literate.[Table 9] The marginal effect of having an additional brother was

a reduction of approximately 2 percent in the probability that a girl would be literate, and the

coefficient was significant at a 10.9 percent level. Having an additional sister reduced the probability

of a girl being literate by 1.6 percent ( significant at a 9.3 percent level).

Since 85 percent of the adolescent girls in the sample were literate compared with only 15

percent of the adult women, factors other than mother’s literacy, such as availability of tuition-free

schools, are necessary to explain the increase in literacy rates of the younger generation. It should

also be noted that the effect of caste is much less important in predicting literacy of adolescent girls

than of adult women. Only scheduled tribal status (caste 2) had a significant (negative) effect on the

probability of an adolescent girl attaining literacy. This suggests that the combination of the targeted

programs in government schools and the availability of Veerni Project classes has helped to

overcome the caste differences in educational attainment of previous generations of village women.

However, Muslim girls continue to have much lower literacy rates than Hindu girls of all castes.

Although literacy rates are higher for girls than for women, and higher for younger than for older

41
Government statistics on schools could not be used since many schools exist “on the books” but are not
actually providing education.

15
adult women (See Table 1), it is still the case that less than three percent of the girls in our sample

have acquired a secondary level education.

IV. Effect of Mother’s Literacy on the Marital Status of Adolescent Girls.

An adolescent girl may be unmarried; she may be married in the sense that her parents have entered

into a marriage contract on her behalf, but not yet living with her husband and his family; or she may

be effectively married, in which case she has left her parental family and probably her village and

gone to live in the home of her husband. 42

Probits were run for the probability that an adolescent girl would be effectively married and

for the probability that she would be unmarried. The usual set of personal and family characteristics

were employed as explanatory variables with the exception that the girl’s literacy was omitted from

these estimating equations, since it is almost certainly conditional on her marital status. Families

are less likely to invest in a daughter’s education if she is already married, since any return on their

human capital investment will accrue to the husband’s not the parental family. Families that favor

child marriages are also less likely to be “progressive” in attitude toward the value of educating

daughters.

Whether her mother is literate was found to be a significant predictor of an adolescent girl’s

marital status. The probability that an adolescent girl would be effectively married was reduced by

approximately 16 percent if her mother was literate. [Table 10a] The probability of her being

unmarried was increased by 14 percent if her mother was literate. [Table 10b] Number of sisters did

42
As noted above, approximately 33 percent of these adolescent girls are effectively married.

16
not have any observed effects. The marginal effect of an additional brother was to increase the

probability of a girl being effectively married, but only by 2 ½ percent.

V. Discussion.

Does this study shed any light on the mechanisms by which women’s literacy promotes the

well-being of themselves and their daughters? Are women empowered by their education so that

they have more say in family decisions about such matters as family size, allocation of food, and

education of children, particularly daughters? Since we do not have data on the education of

husbands and fathers and can not estimate its effect on intra-family allocation of resources, the

process of decision making within the family still remains opaque, and takes place within a grey if

not a black box. 43 However, the empirical results require at least one of the following assumptions

to be true:

(1) Women’s tastes are changed by becoming literate so that they prefer to have fewer

children and to allocate more goods (food and education) to daughters.

(2) Literacy gives women more power in decision making within the family.

(3) Men who are married to literate women have different and more progressive tastes: They

favor more control over fertility or smaller family size, and are willing to allocate more goods (food,

education) to daughters.

If it were the case that assortive mating results in fathers who are married to literate women

still controlling the allocation of goods within the family but themselves preferring to allocate more

education and other goods to daughters, as in the third scenario, then women’s literacy would be

merely a ‘signal’ of the way in which the family allocates resources. In that case policy implications

43
The study is currently being enlarged to include information on literacy of fathers, husbands, and siblings.

17
might be different. Simply increasing educational opportunities for girls without changing the way

males are educated might not bring about the desired effects on future generations, since it would

merely increase the supply of literate brides. However, given the finding of Kaushik Basu et al. that

men who marry literate women are more likely to have literate sisters, we might tentatively conclude

that the education of girls may lead to a greater demand for sons’ wives who are literate.44 This may

be a positive spill-over effect of educating girls.

On the reasonable alternative assumptions that the men in these villages are quite

homogeneous and traditional in their attitudes about control over family decisions and that it is

women who generally want to allocate more resources to children, and in particular to daughters, it

is likely that being literate empowers women in intra-family decision making. It makes it easier for

them to limit family size, to provide food and education for daughters, and to allow daughters to

grow up before being married off. This interpretation is buttressed by the demonstration of Murthi,

Guio, and Dreze that female literacy increases the bargaining power of Indian women in the family

enough to reduce fertility levels.45 The fact that daughters have greater body mass and fewer anemia

symptoms when their mothers are literate provides some modest support for the notion that literate

women in this part of the world allocate more resources to their adolescent daughters.

On a less optimistic note, although we have provided evidence that adult women’s literacy

is associated with allocating more resources to surviving adolescent daughters, the evidence is

compelling that literate women in these villages also engage in more sex selection of children than

do illiterate women. This assertion is supported by the fact that adolescent daughters of literate

44
Basu et al.(2002).

45
Murthi, et al (1995).

18
women in these villages have fewer sisters, but not fewer brothers, than do their peers whose mothers

are illiterate.

VI. Conclusions.

The main findings of this study are that literate adult women in rural Rajasthan are healthier,

at least on one measure ( probability of exhibiting anemia symptoms), that they have a better

understanding of how diseases (HIV/AIDS) are contracted/transmitted, that they have, on average,

fewer children, or at least fewer daughters, and that adolescent daughters of literate women are more

likely to be better nourished and literate themselves, when control variables include daughter’s age,

number of sisters and brothers, environmental effects, and family’s socio-economic status and

religion. Mother’s literacy also significantly reduces the probability that an adolescent girl will be

already contracted into marriage or effectively married before the age of eighteen. However, adult

female literacy has not succeeded in removing the bias in favor of sons in rural Rajasthan.

Except for the apparent lack of effect of women’s literacy on infant mortality, the results of

the empirical analysis reinforce a large number of other studies which find that female literacy has,

on balance, positive effects on the health and education levels of both present and future generations

of women. The lack of evidence of literacy improving infant/child survival directly is not surprising,

given the poor standard of living and extremely high rates of malnutrition that still exist in these

villages. Improvements require significant investment in infrastructure, including clean drinking

water and desalinated water for irrigation.

Although literacy does not by itself appear to give women the ability to significantly reduce

infant mortality, it may be a public good within families, with an illiterate adult family member

having greater success in the labor market when living with literate family members. Increasing

19
women’s literacy rates may thus improve families’ welfare in this indirect way. This effect will not,

however, be apparent when family income is included as a control variable in estimating equations.

Improving female literacy rates is also likely to increase women’s own earning power and labor force

participation over time. Moreover, it may help women to acquire more political power. This is

already beginning to happen in rural Rajasthan as more women, and more lower caste women, are

becoming politically active in local government in these villages.46 Perhaps over time the further

education and empowerment of women will also reduce the degree of son preference in the villages.

References.

1. Aly, H.Y. and R. Grabowski, “Education and Child Mortality in Egypt,” World Development, 18:5 (May
1990): 733-43.

2. Basu, Alaka Malwade, “Why Does Education Lead to Lower Fertility? A Critical Review of Some of the
Possibilities,” World Development, 30:10 (October 2002): 1779-90.

3. Basu, Kaushik, et al., “Is Literacy Shared Within Households? Theory and Evidence for Bangladesh,”
Labour Economics, 8:6 (December 2001): 649-665.

4. Becker, Gary S., “An Economic Analysis of Fertility,” in Demographic and Economic Change in
Developed Countries (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960) and A Treatise on the Family (Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press, 1981).

5. Behrman , J.R., “Intrahousehold Allocation of Nutrients in Rural India: Are Boys Favored? Do Parents
Exhibit Inequality Aversion?” Oxford Economic Papers, 40:1 (Marhc 1988): 32-54.

6. Behrman, J.R. et al., “Marriage Markets, Labor Markets, and Unobserved Human Capigtal: An Empirical
Exploration for South-Central India,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 43:3 (April 1995): 585-
601.

7.Behrman, J.R. and A.B. Deolalikiar, “The Intrahousehold Demand for Nutrients in Rural South India:
Individual Estimates, Fixed Effects, and Permanent Income,” Journal of Human Resources, 24:4 (Fall 1989):
665-96.

46
The Veerni project has facilitated the empowerment of these village women by employing them as
project coordinators, and training them to be local health workers and teachers in the village classes.

20
8. Behrman, J.R. and M.R. Rosenzweig, “Does Increasing Women’s Schooling Raise the Schooling of the
Next Generation?” American Economic Review, 92: 1 (March 2002): 323-34.

9.Behrman, J.R. And B.L. Wolfe, “More Evidence on Nutrition Demand: Income Seems Overrated and
Women’s Schooling Underemphasized,” Journal of Development Economics, 14:1-2 (January-February
1984): 105-28.

10.Behrman, J.R. And B.L. Wolfe, “Does More Schooling Make Women Better Nourished and Healthier?
Adult Sibling Raqnhdom and Fixed Effects Estimates for Nicaragua,” Journal of Human Resources, 24:4 (Fall
1989) 644-63.

11. Bhat, P.N. Mari, “Returning a Favor: Reciprocity Between Female Education and Fertility in India,”
World Development, 30:10 (October 2002): 1791-1803.

12. Borooah, V.K., “Births, Infants, and Children: An Econometric Portrait of Women and Children in India,”
Development and Change, 34:1 (January 2003): 67-103.

13. Bourne, Katherine L, and Walker, George M., “The Differential Effect of Mothers’ Education on
Mortality of Boys and Girls in India,” Population Studies, 45:2 (July 1991): 203-219.

14. Caldwell, John, “Routes to Low Mortality in Poor Countries,” Population and Development Review, 12:2
(June 1986): 171-220.

15. Das Gupta, Monica and P.N. Mari Bhat, “Intensified Gender Bias in India: A Consequence of Fertility
Decline,” Gender, Population, and Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998): 73-93.

16. Dreze, Jean and Geeta Gandhi Kingdon, “School Participation in Rural India”, Review of Development
Economics, 5:1 (February 2001): 1-24.

17. Dreze, Jean, and Amartya Sen, Hunger and Public Action (Oxford: Oxford University Press,1989).

18. Field, Erica, “Early Marriage and Female Schooling in Bangladesh,” Working Paper, Harvard Economics
Department, April, 2005.

19. Gleason, Suzanne, M, “Publicly Provided Goods and Intrafamily Resource Allocation: Female Child
Survival in India.” Review of Development Economics, 7:1 (February 2003): 71-85.

20.. Grossman, Michael, “On the Concept of Health Capital and the Demand for Health,” Journal of Political
Economy, 80:2 (March-April 1972): 223-255

21. Henriques, Maria-Helena, John Strauss, and Duncan Thomas, “How Does Mother’s Education Affect
Child Height?” The Journal of Human Resources, 26:2 (Spring 1991): 183-211.

22. Horney, Mary and Marjorie McElroy, “Nash-Bargained Household Decisions: Toward a Generalization
of the Theory of Demand,” International Economic Review, 22:2 (June 1981):333-349.

23. Kenkel, D. S., “Health Behavior, Health Knowledge, and Schooling,”Journal of Political Economy, 99:2
(April 1991):287-305.

21
24. Khan, A.H., “Comments on ‘Literacy Transition and Female Nuptiality: Implications for Fertility in
Pakistan,’” Pakistani Development Review, 24: 3/4 (Autumn-Winter 1985): 601-03.

25. Mancer, M. and M. Brown., “Marriage and Household Decision-Making: A Bargaining Analysis,”
International Economic Review, 21:1 (February 1980): 31-44.

26. Mellington, Nicole, and Lisa Cameron, “Female Education and Child Mortality in Indonesia,”
Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 35:3 (December 1999): 115-44.

27. Murthi, Mamta, et al., “Mortality, Fertility, and Gender Bias in India: A District Level Analysis,”
Population and Development Review, 21:4 (December 1995): 745-82.

28. Narayanamoorthy, A. and B.N.Kamble, “Trends and Determinants of Rural Literacy Among Scheduled
Caste Population: a State Level Analysis,” Journal of Educational Planning and Administration, XVII:1
(January, 2003): 35-52.

29. Pal, Sarmistha, “An Analysis of Childhood Malnutrition in Rural India: Role of Gender, Income, and
Other Household Characteristics,” World Development, 27:7 (July 1999): 1151-1171.

30.. Pitt, M. M.and M.R. Rosenzweig, “Productivity, Health and Inequality in the Intrahousehold Distribution
of Food in Low-Income Countries”, American Economic Review, 31:4, (December 1990) : 1139-56.

31 Rosenzweig, M.R. and R. Evenson, “Fertility, Schooling, and the Economic Contribution of Children in
Rural India: An Econometric Analysis,” Economic Demography, vol. 2 (1998) 113-27.

32. Sandiford, P. et al., “The Impact of Women’s Literacy on Child Health and Its Interaction with Access
to Health Services,” Population Studies, 49:1 (March 1995): 5-17.

33. Thind, Satinderjit and Sushma Jaswal, “Gender Bias in Education Among the Rural Sikhs of Punjab,”
Journal of Educational Planning and Administration, XVIII:1 (January 2004): 49-56.

34. Thomas, Duncan, “Intra-household Resource Allocation: An Inferential Approach,” The Journal of Human
Resources, 25:4 (Autumn 2000): 68-95.

35. Toor, Imran Ashraf and Rizwana Parveen, “Factors Influencing Girls’ Primary Enrolment in Pakistan,”The
Lahore Journal of Economics, 9:2 (2004): 141-157.

36. Wolfe, B.L., and J.R. Behrman, “Women’s Schooling and Children’s Health: Are the Effects Robust with
Adult Sibling Control for the Women’s Childhood Background?” Journal of Health Economics, 6:3
(September 1987): 239-54.

37. United Nations, The World’s Women, 1970-1990:Trends and Statistics (New York: United Nations, 1991).

22
Alphabetical List of Variables
1. age: Tables 1-4b = age of adult woman; Tables 5a-8b = age of adolescent girl

2. age_at_mar~e: adult woman’s age at marriage

3. bias: interaction (brothers*mother)

4. brothers: number of brothers of adolescent girl

5. caste: Tables 1-4b = dummy variable for caste 1,2,or 3,of adult woman
Tables 5a-8b = dummy variable for caste 1,2, or 3 of adolescent girl

6. effective~e:1 if adolescent girl is effectively married, otherwise 0

7. electr~y: Tables 1-4b = family home of adult woman has/ has no electricity
Tables 5a-8b = family home of adolescent girl has/ has no electricity

8. family~: monthly income of head of family in rupees

9. female ~ y: number of female children in family who died in infancy


male ~ y: number of male children in family who died in infancy

10.literate: 1 if adult woman is literate, Tables 1-4b, otherwise 0


1 if adolescent girl is literate, Tables 5a-8b, otherwise 0

11. married: 1 if adult woman is married, Tables 1-4b.

12. mother: 1 if mother of adolescent girl is literate, Tables 5a-8b.

13. muslim: 1 if adult woman is muslim religion, Tables 1-4b, otherwise 0


1 if adolescent girl is muslim religion, Tables 5a-8b, otherwise 0
14 .number~n: number of children ever born to a woman

15. number~1: number of living children which a woman has

16. proble~e: 1 if adolescent girl has a problem with education because of distance to school

17. radio_TV: Tables 1-4b: 1 if home of adult women has electricity, otherwise 0
Tables 5a-8b: 1 if home of adolescent girl has electricity, otherwise 0

18. sisters: number of sisters of adolescent girl

19. .veerni~m: 1 if Veerni Project has been in one’s village for 10 years, otherwise 0
20. veerni~s: 1 if Veerni Project has been in one’s village for 2 years, otherwise 0
21. veerni~t: 1 if the village has had no help from the Veerni project, otherwise 0

22. villag~1 - villag~8: 1 if adult woman lives in village 1,....................8, otherwise 0.

23
Table 1a
Determinants of Adult Female Literacy
Number of obs = 951
Log likelihood = -343.28833
Pseudo R2 = 0.1510

Marginal effects after probit y = Pr(literate) (predict) = .11707913


------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
villag~1*| -.0121355 .05874 -0.21 0.836 -.127258 .102987 .060988
villag~2*| -.1235411 .01948 -6.34 0.000 -.16172 -.085363 .095689
villag~3*| -.0688548 .0395 -1.74 0.081 -.146267 .008557 .191377
villag~4*| -.0591821 .04128 -1.43 0.152 -.140091 .021727 .111462
villag~5*| -.0302487 .04877 -0.62 0.535 -.125841 .065344 .139853
villag~6*| -.0899369 .03271 -2.75 0.006 -.154046 -.025828 .053628
villag~7*| -.0600634 .04187 -1.43 0.151 -.142131 .022004 .176656
villag~8*| -.0790649 .03528 -2.24 0.025 -.148207 -.009922 .128286
age | -.0073397 .00141 -5.19 0.000 -.010112 -.004567 31.0273
caste1*| -.1666766 .01631 -10.22 0.000 -.198649 -.134704 .185068
caste2*| -.1044347 .01743 -5.99 0.000 -.13859 -.070279 .073607
caste3*| -.1577064 .02374 -6.64 0.000 -.204243 -.11117 .416404
muslim*| -.1220614 .0142 -8.59 0.000 -.149901 -.094222 .036803
------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Table 1b
Determinants of Adult Female Literacy with Marital Status
Number of obs = 951
Log likelihood = -339.72577
Pseudo R2 = 0.1598

Marginal effects after probit y = Pr(literate) (predict) = .11508823


------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
villag~1*| .0054368 .06561 0.08 0.934 -.123165 .134039 .060988
villag~2*| -.1159707 .02144 -5.41 0.000 -.157995 -.073947 .095689
villag~3*| -.0575765 .04263 -1.35 0.177 -.141131 .025978 .191377
villag~4*| -.0516136 .04407 -1.17 0.242 -.137998 .03477 .111462
villag~5*| -.016847 .05318 -0.32 0.751 -.121083 .087389 .139853
villag~6*| -.0872662 .03347 -2.61 0.009 -.152866 -.021666 .053628
villag~7*| -.0473246 .04556 -1.04 0.299 -.136626 .041976 .176656
villag~8*| -.0761347 .03632 -2.10 0.036 -.147315 -.004954 .128286
age | -.0076182 .00141 -5.42 0.000 -.010373 -.004863 31.0273
caste1*| -.1630296 .01633 -9.99 0.000 -.195028 -.131031 .185068
caste2*| -.1038783 .01701 -6.11 0.000 -.137225 -.070531 .073607
caste3*| -.1542406 .02357 -6.54 0.000 -.200438 -.108044 .416404
muslim*| -.1202245 .01406 -8.55 0.000 -.147777 -.092672 .036803
married*| -.2116292 .09825 -2.15 0.031 -.4042 -.019059 .970557
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

24
.
.

Table 1c
Determinants of Adult Female Literacy
With Marital Status and Age of Marriage

Probit regression Number of obs = 951


Log likelihood = -337.7382
Pseudo R2 = 0.1647

Marginal effects after probit y = Pr(literate) (predict) = .11429146


------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
villag~1*| .009482 .06692 0.14 0.887 -.121672 .140636 .060988
villag~2*| -.1001026 .02794 -3.58 0.000 -.154858 -.045348 .095689
villag~3*| -.0393926 .04754 -0.83 0.407 -.132568 .053782 .191377
villag~4*| -.0489123 .04476 -1.09 0.274 -.136634 .03881 .111462
villag~5*| -.0152632 .05354 -0.29 0.776 -.120203 .089677 .139853
villag~6*| -.082551 .03568 -2.31 0.021 -.152476 -.012626 .053628
villag~7*| -.0440837 .04624 -0.95 0.340 -.134709 .046541 .176656
villag~8*| -.0742303 .0367 -2.02 0.043 -.146152 -.002308 .128286
age | -.0074272 .0014 -5.29 0.000 -.01018 -.004674 31.0273
caste1*| -.1586637 .01653 -9.60 0.000 -.191071 -.126256 .185068
caste2*| -.0985921 .01816 -5.43 0.000 -.134185 -.062999 .073607
caste3*| -.1469407 .02383 -6.17 0.000 -.193645 -.100236 .416404
muslim*| -.1186205 .01438 -8.25 0.000 -.146811 -.09043 .036803
married*| -.2358181 .10171 -2.32 0.020 -.435158 -.036478 .970557
age_at~e | .0071141 .0036 1.98 0.048 .000057 .014171 16.3617
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

25
Table 2a
Probability of Women Exhibiting Anemia Symptoms
With Village Fixed Effects

Number of obs = 947


LR chi2(18) = 68.44
Prob > chi2 = 0.0000
Log likelihood = -609.77654 Pseudo R2 = 0.0531

Marginal effects after probit


y = Pr(anemia_symptoms) (predict) = .58735272
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
villag~1*| .1561908 .09899 1.58 0.115 -.037835 .350216 .061246
villag~2*| -.2809352 .10043 -2.80 0.005 -.477782 -.084089 .096093
villag~3*| -.1738407 .09461 -1.84 0.066 -.359269 .011588 .190074
villag~4*| -.0981108 .10134 -0.97 0.333 -.29674 .100518 .111932
villag~5*| -.1714542 .0978 -1.75 0.080 -.363129 .02022 .139388
villag~6*| -.0829328 .12444 -0.67 0.505 -.326826 .160961 .053854
villag~7*| -.1189242 .09698 -1.23 0.220 -.309001 .071153 .177402
villag~8*| -.1611797 .09979 -1.62 0.106 -.356759 .034399 .127772
age | -.0012587 .00275 -0.46 0.647 -.006651 .004134 31.0275
caste1*| .0501288 .05765 0.87 0.385 -.062862 .16312 .184794
caste2*| .205122 .0603 3.40 0.001 .086931 .323313 .073918
caste3*| -.0005473 .04727 -0.01 0.991 -.093195 .092101 .417107
muslim*| .1240263 .09888 1.25 0.210 -.069779 .317831 .036959
married*| -.0775445 .09686 -0.80 0.423 -.267382 .112293 .971489
literate*| -.1244518 .05218 -2.38 0.017 -.226729 -.022175 .151003
family~_ | -6.09e-06 .00001 -0.65 0.516 -.000024 .000012 2826.5
electr~y*| -.0379448 .03723 -1.02 0.308 -.110907 .035017 .485744
number~n | .0049495 .00863 0.57 0.566 -.011968 .021867 3.54699
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

26
Table 2b
Probability of Women Exhibiting Anemia Symptoms
With NGO Effects

Number of obs = 945


LR chi2(12) = 40.17
Prob > chi2 = 0.0001
Log likelihood = -622.49711 Pseudo R2 = 0.0313

Marginal effects after probit


y = Pr(anemia_symptoms) (predict)
= .58435543

------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
veerni~m*| -.014278 .04175 -0.34 0.732 -.096111 .067555 .348148
veerni~s*| -.0138687 .04136 -0.34 0.737 -.094932 .067195 .30582
age | -.001522 .00271 -0.56 0.574 -.006828 .003784 31.0265
caste1*| .1170477 .05039 2.32 0.020 .018293 .215802 .185185
caste2*| .2486306 .05211 4.77 0.000 .146489 .350772 .073016
caste3*| .0534829 .0414 1.29 0.196 -.02765 .134616 .416931
muslim*| .1983501 .07673 2.58 0.010 .047953 .348747 .037037
married*| -.0984542 .09691 -1.02 0.310 -.288392 .091483 .973545
literate*| -.0912117 .05068 -1.80 0.072 -.190552 .008129 .151323
family~_ | -6.69e-06 .00001 -0.73 0.465 -.000025 .000011 2821.9
electr~y*| -.0315089 .0365 -0.86 0.388 -.103038 .040021 .484656
number~n | .00678 .00839 0.81 0.419 -.009672 .023232 3.54392
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

27
Table 3
Probability of Women Knowing How HIV/AIDS is Spread

Number of obs = 948


Log likelihood = -359.97909
Pseudo R2 = 0.3393

Marginal effects after probit


y = Pr(hiv_aids_spread_knowledge) (predict)= .18122807
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
villag~1*| .0011248 .05578 0.02 0.984 -.108202 .110452 .061181
villag~2*| -.0829196 * .03841 -2.16 0.031 -.158194 -.007646 .095992
villag~4*| -.1808433 ** .02398 -7.54 0.000 -.227849 -.133838 .111814
villag~5*| -.1945018 ** .02279 -8.53 0.000 -.239171 -.149833 .139241
villag~6*| -.1592025 ** .02747 -5.80 0.000 -.213037 -.105368 .053797
villag~7*| -.0149678 .10353 -0.14 0.885 -.21788 .187944 .177215
villag~8*| .0848749 .12387 0.69 0.493 -.157909 .327659 .126582
veerni~t*| -.340122** .06374 -5.34 0.000 -.465059 -.215185 .345992
age | -.0031666 .00189 -1.68 0.094 -.006867 .000534 31.0137
caste1*| -.1460707** .03285 -4.45 0.000 -.210451 -.081691 .184599
caste2*| -.1051772** .03686 -2.85 0.004 -.177431 -.032924 .07384
caste3*| -.1039818** .03495 -2.98 0.003 -.172478 -.035486 .417722
muslim*| -.0430576 .06995 -0.62 0.538 -.18015 .094035 .03692
married*| -.2410941* .1223 -1.97 0.049 -.480806 -.001382 .972574
literate*| .2847581** .0557 5.11 0.000 .17558 .393937 .151899
family~_ | .0000102 .00001 1.31 0.189 -5.0e-06 .000025 2820.89
electr~y*| .0699122 .03637 1.92 0.055 -.001376 .1412 .485232
radio_tv*| .1869186 .04818 3.88 0.000 .092492 .281345 .235232
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

In this case one variable for NGO is used: No Veerni Project = veerni~t.

28
Table 4a
Number of Children Ever Born as Function of Literacy, Age, and Age of Marriage of Mother With
Village Fixed Effects

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 948


-------------+------------------------------ F( 17, 930) = 47.50
Model | 2864.73594 17 168.513879 Prob > F = 0.0000
Residual | 3299.62693 930 3.54798594 R-squared = 0.4647
-------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.4549
Total | 6164.36287 947 6.50935889 Root MSE = 1.8836

------------------------------------------------------------------------------
number_of_~n | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
village_1 | -1.515076 .394333 -3.84 0.000 -2.288961 -.74119
village_2 | -2.632678 .4004665 -6.57 0.000 -3.418601 -1.846756
village_3 | -1.49823 .3445541 -4.35 0.000 -2.174424 -.8220366
village_4 | -1.666196 .3556117 -4.69 0.000 -2.36409 -.9683017
village_5 | -1.484171 .3478563 -4.27 0.000 -2.166845 -.8014965
village_6 | -1.825864 .4402826 -4.15 0.000 -2.689927 -.9618019
village_7 | -1.955145 .3393315 -5.76 0.000 -2.621089 -1.289201
village_8 | -1.807052 .3537816 -5.11 0.000 -2.501355 -1.11275
age | .1939376 .0081925 23.67 0.000 .1778597 .2100155
caste1 | .150643 .2222045 0.68 0.498 -.2854374 .5867233
caste2 | .0953751 .2685638 0.36 0.723 -.4316862 .6224364
caste3 | -.2152241 .1791555 -1.20 0.230 -.56682 .1363718
muslim | .8917688 .4075005 2.19 0.029 .0920416 1.691496
literate | -.8484652 .1893811 -4.48 0.000 -1.220129 -.4768014
age_at_mar~e | -.1448564 .0212262 -6.82 0.000 -.1865133 -.1031995
family_mon~_ | -9.15e-06 .0000353 -0.26 0.796 -.0000785 .0000602
electricity | -.0657754 .1392496 -0.47 0.637 -.3390552 .2075044
_cons | 1.813234 .5940664 3.05 0.002 .647368 2.9791
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

29
Table 4b
Number of Children Ever Born as Function of Literacy, Age, and Age of Marriage of MotherWith
NGO Effects

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 946


-------------+------------------------------ F( 11, 934) = 65.17
Model | 2674.14928 11 243.10448 Prob > F = 0.0000
Residual | 3484.01563 934 3.73020945 R-squared = 0.4342
-------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.4276
Total | 6158.1649 945 6.51657662 Root MSE = 1.9314

------------------------------------------------------------------------------
number_of_~n | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
veerni_has~m | -.0132778 .1713423 -0.08 0.938 -.3495382 .3229827
veerni_has~s | .0562103 .1590898 0.35 0.724 -.2560046 .3684252
age | .1956057 .0083839 23.33 0.000 .1791522 .2120591
caste1 | .5188806 .207636 2.50 0.013 .1113934 .9263677
caste2 | .3038294 .2633376 1.15 0.249 -.2129725 .8206313
caste3 | .0146828 .1633789 0.09 0.928 -.3059495 .335315
muslim | 1.101472 .3613889 3.05 0.002 .3922441 1.810701
literate | -.6783982 .192173 -3.53 0.000 -1.055539 -.3012572
age_at_mar~e | -.1277574 .0211963 -6.03 0.000 -.1693552 -.0861595
family_mon~_ | -.0000313 .0000359 -0.87 0.384 -.0001017 .0000391
electricity | .0032106 .1412239 0.02 0.982 -.2739423 .2803635
_cons | -.4156601 .5067581 -0.82 0.412 -1.410177 .5788563
------------------------------------------------------------------------------

30
Table 5a.
Number of Living Children as Function of Literacy, Age, and Age of Marriage of Mother:
With Village Fixed Effects

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 948


-------------+------------------------------ F( 17, 930) = 44.57
Model | 2037.4927 17 119.852512 Prob > F = 0.0000
Residual | 2500.92397 930 2.68916556 R-squared = 0.4489
-------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.4389
Total | 4538.41667 947 4.79241464 Root MSE = 1.6399

------------------------------------------------------------------------------
number_of_~1 | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
village_1 | -.9915021 .3433057 -2.89 0.004 -1.665246 -.3177585
village_2 | -2.109348 .3486454 -6.05 0.000 -2.793571 -1.425125
village_3 | -1.117411 .2999682 -3.73 0.000 -1.706104 -.5287179
village_4 | -1.088841 .3095949 -3.52 0.000 -1.696426 -.481255
village_5 | -1.060465 .3028431 -3.50 0.000 -1.6548 -.4661299
village_6 | -1.279544 .3833093 -3.34 0.001 -2.031795 -.5272922
village_7 | -1.128683 .2954214 -3.82 0.000 -1.708453 -.5489132
village_8 | -1.136616 .3080017 -3.69 0.000 -1.741075 -.5321572
age | .1656072 .0071324 23.22 0.000 .1516098 .1796045
caste1 | -.0773119 .1934509 -0.40 0.690 -.4569627 .3023389
caste2 | .0134808 .2338112 0.06 0.954 -.4453778 .4723395
caste3 | -.2216009 .1559725 -1.42 0.156 -.5276997 .0844979
muslim | .9869699 .3547693 2.78 0.006 .2907288 1.683211
literate | -.7816883 .1648748 -4.74 0.000 -1.105258 -.4581185
age_at_mar~e | -.1147397 .0184795 -6.21 0.000 -.1510061 -.0784733
family_mon~_ | .0000123 .0000308 0.40 0.690 -.0000481 .0000727
electricity | -.1547798 .1212305 -1.28 0.202 -.3926968 .0831372
_cons | 1.209998 .5171932 2.34 0.020 .1949969 2.224999
------------------------------------------------------------------------------

31
Table 5b.
Number of Living Children as Function of Literacy, Age, and Age of Marriage of Mother:
With NGO Effects

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 946


-------------+------------------------------ F( 11, 934) = 63.50
Model | 1937.78549 11 176.162317 Prob > F = 0.0000
Residual | 2591.26843 934 2.77437733 R-squared = 0.4279
-------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.4211
Total | 4529.05391 945 4.79264964 Root MSE = 1.6656

------------------------------------------------------------------------------
number_of_~1 | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
veerni_has~m | -.2305268 .1477681 -1.56 0.119 -.5205227 .0594691
veerni_has~s | -.1079476 .1372014 -0.79 0.432 -.3772064 .1613111
age | .1664717 .0072304 23.02 0.000 .1522819 .1806614
caste1 | .2674927 .1790684 1.49 0.136 -.0839302 .6189156
caste2 | .2217096 .2271062 0.98 0.329 -.223988 .6674072
caste3 | .0156468 .1409004 0.11 0.912 -.2608711 .2921648
muslim | 1.19032 .3116671 3.82 0.000 .5786714 1.801969
literate | -.6477311 .1657329 -3.91 0.000 -.972983 -.3224791
age_at_mar~e | -.0962904 .01828 -5.27 0.000 -.132165 -.0604158
family_mon~_ | 1.16e-06 .0000309 0.04 0.970 -.0000596 .0000619
electricity | -.1055158 .1217936 -0.87 0.387 -.3445365 .1335049
_cons | -.3661565 .4370357 -0.84 0.402 -1.223842 .491529
------------------------------------------------------------------------------

32
Table 6a
Number of Male Infant Deaths
As a Function of Number of Children Born, Age, and Literacy Status of Mother

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 947


-------------+------------------------------ F( 19, 927) = 7.61
Model | 29.350643 19 1.54477069 Prob > F = 0.0000
Residual | 188.250202 927 .203074651 R-squared = 0.1349
-------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1172
Total | 217.600845 946 .230022035 Root MSE = .45064

------------------------------------------------------------------------------
___male_di~y | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
number_of_~n | .0716514 .0078547 9.12 0.000 .0562363 .0870664
village_1 | .1562849 .0953997 1.64 0.102 -.0309396 .3435093
village_2 | .1658597 .0985618 1.68 0.093 -.0275705 .3592899
village_3 | .2350992 .083562 2.81 0.005 .0711065 .3990919
village_4 | .1160435 .0861573 1.35 0.178 -.0530425 .2851294
village_5 | .0931774 .0843186 1.11 0.269 -.0723 .2586549
village_6 | .129251 .1063056 1.22 0.224 -.0793766 .3378785
village_7 | .0206308 .0828073 0.25 0.803 -.1418808 .1831424
village_8 | .0855083 .0858335 1.00 0.319 -.0829422 .2539588
age | -.0052779 .0024916 -2.12 0.034 -.0101677 -.0003881
caste1 | .0751125 .0533103 1.41 0.159 -.0295104 .1797355
caste2 | .0463562 .0643218 0.72 0.471 -.079877 .1725894
caste3 | .0279952 .0428981 0.65 0.514 -.0561935 .1121839
muslim | -.0082675 .0977426 -0.08 0.933 -.2000899 .1835549
married | .0051193 .0905967 0.06 0.955 -.1726791 .1829177
age_at_mar~e | .0040079 .0052342 0.77 0.444 -.0062644 .0142801
literate | .0086937 .0460742 0.19 0.850 -.081728 .0991155
family_mon~_ | -4.53e-06 8.46e-06 -0.54 0.593 -.0000211 .0000121
electricity | -.0005153 .0333763 -0.02 0.988 -.0660172 .0649866
_cons | -.1568177 .1632307 -0.96 0.337 -.4771623 .1635268
------------------------------------------------------------------------------

33
Table 6b
Number of Female Infant Deaths
As a Function of Number of Children Born, Age, and Literacy Status of Mother

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 948


-------------+------------------------------ F( 19, 928) = 6.95
Model | 31.0830621 19 1.63595064 Prob > F = 0.0000
Residual | 218.431706 928 .235378993 R-squared = 0.1246
-------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.1067
Total | 249.514768 947 .263479164 Root MSE = .48516

------------------------------------------------------------------------------
___female_~y | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
number_of_~n | .0778635 .0084538 9.21 0.000 .0612727 .0944543
village_1 | .2239298 .1027075 2.18 0.029 .0223639 .4254956
village_2 | .2303645 .1061069 2.17 0.030 .0221272 .4386018
village_3 | .2078074 .089962 2.31 0.021 .0312549 .38436
village_4 | .1472515 .0927538 1.59 0.113 -.03478 .3292831
village_5 | .1227072 .0906964 1.35 0.176 -.0552866 .300701
village_6 | .1026282 .1144488 0.90 0.370 -.1219802 .3272366
village_7 | .0459627 .0891505 0.52 0.606 -.1289973 .2209227
village_8 | .156432 .0924083 1.69 0.091 -.0249215 .3377854
age | -.0062471 .0026815 -2.33 0.020 -.0115095 -.0009847
caste1 | .0639185 .0573146 1.12 0.265 -.0485627 .1763997
caste2 | -.0329361 .0692488 -0.48 0.634 -.1688386 .1029664
caste3 | .0226898 .0461831 0.49 0.623 -.0679456 .1133251
muslim | -.1096015 .1052293 -1.04 0.298 -.3161164 .0969134
married | -.0307472 .0975341 -0.32 0.753 -.2221602 .1606658
age_at_mar~e | .0035448 .0056328 0.63 0.529 -.0075096 .0145992
literate | .0133946 .0495912 0.27 0.787 -.0839294 .1107185
family_mon~_ | -2.98e-06 9.11e-06 -0.33 0.743 -.0000209 .0000149
electricity | .0030372 .0359203 0.08 0.933 -.0674572 .0735316
_cons | -.109406 .1757344 -0.62 0.534 -.4542889 .2354768
------------------------------------------------------------------------------

34
Table 7a
Adolescent Girl’s BMI as a Function of Mother’s Literacy

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 902


-------------+------------------------------ F( 14, 887) = 4.87
Model | 407629.862 14 29116.4187 Prob > F = 0.0000
Residual | 5302736.22 887 5978.2821 R-squared = 0.0714
-------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.0567
Total | 5710366.08 901 6337.80919 Root MSE = 77.319
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
bmi_weight~2 | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
mother | 19.85599 10.53208 1.89 0.060 -.8147137 40.5267
literate | -3.373795 6.586292 -0.51 0.609 -16.30033 9.552738
veerni_has~m | -6.898515 6.435138 -1.07 0.284 -19.52839 5.731356
veerni_has~s | 12.56758 6.836346 1.84 0.066 -.8497194 25.98488
caste1 | -3.912365 8.440889 -0.46 0.643 -20.47881 12.65408
caste2 | 22.51594 10.1726 2.21 0.027 2.550759 42.48111
caste3 | -9.694841 6.861189 -1.41 0.158 -23.1609 3.771217
muslim | -2.245836 16.26448 -0.14 0.890 -34.16719 29.67552
age | .0204572 1.150919 0.02 0.986 -2.238384 2.279299
family_mon~_ | .009624 .0014455 6.66 0.000 .0067871 .012461
brothers | -4.975956 2.365593 -2.10 0.036 -9.618767 -.3331439
sisters | -2.181253 1.734967 -1.26 0.209 -5.586373 1.223866
effective_~e | 1.295391 5.994371 0.22 0.829 -10.46941 13.06019
electricity | -9.112647 5.77603 -1.58 0.115 -20.44893 2.223632
_cons | 15.68312 19.60276 0.80 0.424 -22.79007 54.15632
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------

35
Table 7b
Adolescent Girl’s BMI as a Function of Mother’s Literacy with Interaction Term

Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 902


-------------+------------------------------ F( 15, 886) = 4.99
Model | 444620.78 15 29641.3853 Prob > F = 0.0000
Residual | 5265745.3 886 5943.27912 R-squared = 0.0779
-------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.0623
Total | 5710366.08 901 6337.80919 Root MSE = 77.093
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
bmi_weight~2 | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
-------------+----------------------------------------------------------------
mother | 64.8147 20.85743 3.11 0.002 23.87897 105.7504
literate | -2.281766 6.581554 -0.35 0.729 -15.19902 10.63549
veerni_has~m | -7.358092 6.418915 -1.15 0.252 -19.95614 5.23996
veerni_has~s | 12.21304 6.817785 1.79 0.074 -1.167856 25.59393
caste1 | -3.46021 8.418093 -0.41 0.681 -19.98194 13.06152
caste2 | 21.65013 10.14871 2.13 0.033 1.731809 41.56845
caste3 | -9.744799 6.841102 -1.42 0.155 -23.17146 3.681856
muslim | -3.683823 16.22704 -0.23 0.820 -35.53174 28.16409
age | -.0304872 1.147726 -0.03 0.979 -2.283066 2.222092
family_mon~_ | .0097509 .0014421 6.76 0.000 .0069205 .0125813
brothers | -3.288863 2.453685 -1.34 0.180 -8.104577 1.52685
sisters | -2.121604 1.730046 -1.23 0.220 -5.51707 1.273862
effective_~e | .8992222 5.978905 0.15 0.880 -10.83525 12.63369
electricity | -9.908995 5.767935 -1.72 0.086 -21.2294 1.411414
bias | -21.86652 8.764865 -2.49 0.013 -39.06884 -4.664204
_cons | 12.19114 19.59534 0.62 0.534 -26.26756 50.64984
------------------------------------------------------------------------------

36
Table 8.
Probability of Anemia Symptoms in Adolescent Girls

N = 902
Marginal effects after probit
y = Pr(anemia_symptoms) (predict) = .17479484
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
mother*| -.0888108 .03933 -2.26 0.024 -.165892 -.01173 .070953
literate*| -.08094 .03463 -2.34 0.019 -.148808 -.013072 .749446
veerni~m*| .0242111 .03183 0.76 0.447 -.038171 .086593 .363636
veerni~s*| -.0691022 .03144 -2.20 0.028 -.130728 -.007477 .283814
caste1*| -.0014888 .03976 -0.04 0.970 -.079408 .07643 .185144
caste2*| .0719229 .05456 1.32 0.187 -.035008 .178854 .083149
caste3*| -.0778049 .03409 -2.28 0.022 -.14462 -.010989 .484479
age | .016951 .00533 3.18 0.001 .006501 .027401 13.2051
effect~e*| -.0211059 .02875 -0.73 0.463 -.077447 .035235 .327051
muslim*| -.1039068 .0514 -2.02 0.043 -.204649 -.003164 .032151
family~_ | -8.75e-06 .00001 -1.15 0.249 -.000024 6.1e-06 3028.16
brothers | .00193 .01196 0.16 0.872 -.021506 .025366 2.1918
sisters | .0222919 .00859 2.60 0.009 .005456 .039128 2.57761
electr~y*| -.0069962 .02911 -0.24 0.810 -.064055 .050063 .562084
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

Table 9.
Probability of An Adolescent Girl Being Literate

N = 907

Marginal effects after probit


y = Pr(literate) (predict)= .79184427 N = 907
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
age | -.0488199 .00569 -8.59 0.000 -.059963 -.037676 13.2051
caste1*| -.013131 .04747 -0.28 0.782 -.106168 .079906 .185144
caste2*| -.1278035 .06371 -2.01 0.045 -.252663 -.002944 .083149
caste3*| -.001167 .03928 -0.03 0.976 -.078148 .075814 .484479
muslim*| -.2880137 .11234 -2.56 0.010 -.508191 -.067836 .032151
veerni~m*| .1140606 .03205 3.56 0.000 .051249 .176873 .363636
veerni~s*| .1135478 .03204 3.54 0.000 .050747 .176349 .283814
effect~e*| -.062661 .03408 -1.84 0.066 -.129463 .004141 .327051
family~_ | .0000276 .00001 2.95 0.003 9.3e-06 .000046 3028.16
brothers | -.0205877 .01284 -1.60 0.109 -.045756 .004581 2.1918
sisters | -.0161546 .00962 -1.68 0.093 -.035016 .002707 2.57761
mother*| .1416215 .04128 3.43 0.001 .060717 .222526 .070953
electr~y*| .1142339 .03648 3.13 0.002 .042742 .185726 .562084
radio_tv*| .0513067 .03983 1.29 0.198 -.026766 .12938 .288248
proble~e*| .0058396 .04093 0.14 0.887 -.074378 .086057 .146341
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

37
Table 10a.
Probability of an Adolescent Girl being Effectively Married

N = 904

Marginal effects after probit


y = Pr(effective_marriage) (predict) = .29935245
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
mother*| -.1574522 .05403 -2.91 0.004 -.263349 -.051556 .070953
age | .0484347 .00631 7.67 0.000 .036062 .060807 13.2051
veerni~m*| -.0170199 .0392 -0.43 0.664 -.09385 .059811 .363636
veerni~s*| -.0399403 .04071 -0.98 0.327 -.119739 .039858 .283814
caste1*| .2172221 .05922 3.67 0.000 .101153 .333292 .185144
caste2*| .03037 .06853 0.44 0.658 -.103944 .164684 .083149
caste3*| .3070998 .04123 7.45 0.000 .226286 .387914 .484479
muslim*| -.1389466 .09121 -1.52 0.128 -.317721 .039828 .032151
family~_ | -5.73e-06 .00001 -0.59 0.558 -.000025 .000013 3028.16
electr~y*| -.1312543 .03998 -3.28 0.001 -.209622 -.052887 .562084
radio_tv*| .0245714 .04677 0.53 0.599 -.0671 .116242 .288248
brothers | .0258737 .01481 1.75 0.081 -.003151 .054898 2.1918
sisters | .0053172 .01085 0.49 0.624 -.015958 .026592 2.57761
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

Table 10b.
Probability of an Adolescent Girl Being Unmarried

N = 904

Marginal effects after probit


y = Pr(unmarried) (predict) = .63669901
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
variable | dy/dx Std. Err. z P>|z| [ 95% C.I. ] X
---------+--------------------------------------------------------------------
mother*| .141208 .06407 2.20 0.028 .015625 .266791 .070796
age | -.045728 .00672 -6.81 0.000 -.058898 -.032558 13.2046
veerni~m*| .0317306 .04145 0.77 0.444 -.049506 .112967 .363938
veerni~s*| .0260971 .04333 0.60 0.547 -.058833 .111027 .283186
caste1*| -.2997663 .05623 -5.33 0.000 -.40997 -.189562 .184735
caste2*| -.222457 .07103 -3.13 0.002 -.361669 -.083245 .082965
caste3*| -.3640231 .04134 -8.81 0.000 -.44504 -.283006 .484513
muslim*| .1580417 .10373 1.52 0.128 -.045265 .361348 .03208
family~_ | -2.72e-06 .00001 -0.27 0.785 -.000022 .000017 3033.41
electr~y*| .1395968 .04074 3.43 0.001 .059756 .219438 .561947
radio_tv*| -.001405 .04852 -0.03 0.977 -.0965 .09369 .288717
brothers | -.0132388 .01555 -0.85 0.395 -.043721 .017243 2.19027
sisters | -.0109418 .01142 -0.96 0.338 -.033325 .011442 2.57743
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) dy/dx is for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

38
39

You might also like