You are on page 1of 9

Applied Economics Letters, 2005, 12, 871–879

The adjustments of stock prices


to information about inflation:
evidence from MENA countries
Samer A. M. Al-Rjoub
Department of Banking and Finance, Hashemite University,
PO Box 330195, Zarqa, Jordan
E-mail: salrjoub@hu.edu.jo

This study extends the empirical evidence by analysing the reaction


of monthly stock returns to the unexpected portion of CPI inflation rate
and by capturing the asymmetric shocks to volatility of unexpected
inflation in five MENA countries. Both Threshold GARCH and
Exponential GARCH are used to catch the news affect that unexpected
inflation may have on stock returns. Results document a negative and
strongly significant relationship between unexpected inflation and stock
returns in MENA countries. Results also indicate that the stock markets
of the listed MENA countries do not feel the high up and down movements
in the markets and as such the volatilities. The asymmetric news effect
is absent.

I. Introduction The present study extends the empirical evidence


by analysing the reaction of monthly stock returns to
An important question that has been extensively the unexpected portion of CPI inflation rate and by
asked in the financial economics literature is whether capturing the asymmetric shocks to volatility or the
nominal returns contain market assessments of news effect of unexpected inflation. This relationship
expected and unexpected inflation rates and whether is examined first by using Neslon and Schwert’s
common stocks are an effective hedge against infla- (1977) first order moving average process to calculate
tion. However, theoretical attempts to examine the unexpected inflation, and second by using both
relation between stock returns and inflation diverge. Threshold GARCH and Exponential GARCH to
While some studies found a significant negative catch the news affect that unexpected inflation may
relationship between unexpected inflation and stock have on stock returns.
returns (Bodie, 1976; Jaffe and Mandelker, 1976; Utilizing a long sample period and a time series
Nelson, 1976; Fama and Schwert, 1977; Schwert, measures of expectations and using threshold
1981; Fama, 1981; Chatrath, 1997) others found ARCH introduced independently by Zakoian
no significant relationship (Pearce and Roley, 1985; (1990) and Glosten et al. (1993) and Exponential
Hardouvelis, 1987; McQueen and Roley, 1993; GARCH model proposed by Nelson (1991), the
Caporale and Jung, 1997). In theses studies, interaction between the unexpected CPI inflation
unexpected inflation was created from time series rate and stock returns is examined in this article.
estimation of expected inflation, from the difference Section II describes the effects of unexpected
between nominal interest rats and inflation, or from inflation on stock returns. Section III presents the
experts’ predictions. methodology and describes the data. Section IV

Applied Economics Letters ISSN 1350-4851 print/ISSN 1466-4291 online ß 2005 Taylor & Francis 871
http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals
DOI: 10.1080/13504850500365806
872 S. A. M. Al-Rjoub
contains the EGARCH and TARCH results. Section higher rates to discount future earnings, ignoring
V concludes. the positive effect of inflation on nominal earnings,
the results is an incorrect under-valuation of stocks.
Feldstein (1980) argues that inflation lowers
II. The Effects of Unexpected Inflation stock prices because non-neutralities in the tax
treatment of the inventory and depreciation charges
An important question that has been extensively cause inflation to lower real after tax profits.
asked in the financial economics literature is whether Fama (1981) argues that the negative inflation-stock
nominal returns contain market assessments of return relationship is generated by a positive casual
expected inflation rates and whether common stocks link between real output and stock returns coupled
are effective hedge against inflation. Fisher (1930) with an inverse correlation between real output
first elaborated the hypothesis that interest rates and inflation. Fama (1981) implicitly argues that
contain market forecasts of future inflation rates. unexpected decline in real activity leads to an
Economists thought that this relation could be easily accommodating rise in inflation created by aggregate
extended to common stocks and assumed that supply shocks. The argument in Fama (1981) was
expected nominal stock returns should adjust uni- extended and further tested in a series of papers:
formly in a one to one correspondence with expected Kaul (1987), Ely and Robinson (1992), Geske and
inflation. Roll (1992), Balduzzi (1995) and Graham (1996).
However there is little empirical support for Kaul (1987) also suggest that, in one way or another,
the positive inflation-return relationship and to the changes in real activity and the money supply is
commonly held view that nominal interest rates are behind the negative relationship between inflation
reliable predictors of inflation (Boudloukh and and stock returns. Following the same line Marshall
Richardson, 1993, document positive long-horizon
(1992) argues that the negative inflation-returns
returns to an actual or expected changes in inflation).
correlation may be generated by real economic
Theoretical attempts to examine the relation between
fluctuations, by monetary fluctuations, or possibly
stock returns and inflation show that stock returns
both. Marshall also suggests that this negative
are actually negatively correlated with expected and
correlation is more strongly negative when inflation
unexpected inflation.
is caused by fluctuations in real economic activity
Indeed, typically, the coefficient of the inflation
than when it is caused by monetary fluctuations
term in a stock return equation is not only statistically
(supporting Fama prediction). Chatrath et al. (1997)
different from 1 but its sign is negative (e.g., Lintner,
test the relationship between stock market returns
1975; Bodie, 1976; Jaffe and Mandelker, 1976; Nelson,
1976; Fama and Schwert, 1977; Geske and Roll, 1983; and inflationary trends in India; in particular they
Pearce and Roley, 1983; Pearce, 1985). This puzzle test whether the negative stock return-inflation
has been the subject of a greet deal of work in the relationship is explained by a negative relationship
finance literature and several attempts were made between inflation and real economic activity, and
at explaining this puzzle (e.g., Modigliani and Cohn, a positive relationship between real activity and stock
1979; Feldstein, 1980; Fama, 1981; Geske and Roll, returns. Chatrath et al. provide partial support for
1983; Titman and Warge, 1989). the Fama’s hypothesis, found negative unexpected
One of the most widely quoted explanations inflation coefficient and absence of stock market
are the ‘money demand proxy hypothesis’ proposed returns and inflation in India.
by Fama (1981), the collective money illusion Geske and Roll (1983) suggest the reverse
proposed by Modigliani and Cohn (1979) and causality hypothesis between inflation and stock
the non-neutralities in the tax treatment of the returns; the evidence is still not conclusive. They
inventory and depreciation charges proposed by also suggested that if negative real macroeconomic
Feldstein (1980). There are also some variance in the shocks are accommodated by monetary expansion,
hypothesis explaining the relationship between unex- one observes a simultaneous decline in stock prices
pected inflation and stock prices. They are based on and an increase in inflation.
nominal contracting and tax effects, investors’ Titman and Warge (1989) offered another
misperception, and real-activity consequences of explanation where the stock returns are the predictor
unexpected inflation. of inflation using lagged stock returns. This relation
Modigliani and Cohn (1979) attribute the is found to be positive. In a recent contribution,
negative effect of unexpected inflation to the existence Hess and Lee (1999) account for the stock returns-
of collective money illusion. Unexpected inflation inflation relation with a supply and demand shock.
raises nominal interest rates and if investors use the Supply shocks are characterized as shocks to real
The adjustments of stock prices to information about inflation 873
activity, while the demand shocks originate largely Modelling the asymmetric effect
through shocks to the money supply. using EGARCH-M and TARCH
Despite the apparent successes of ARCH and
GARCH parameterizations, these models cannot
III. Data and Methodology capture the asymmetric news effect discovered by
Black (1976) and confirmed by Zakoian (1990),
Data Nelson (1991), Engle and Ng (1993), Glosten et al.
(1993) among others. This asymmetric effect (some-
Emerging Markets Data Base (EMDP) served as the
times called the leverage effect) reflects the observed
source for information on stock markets in five
fact that downward movements in the market are
emerging MENA countries: Bahrain, Egypt, Jordan,
followed by higher volatilities than upward move-
Oman and Saudi Arabia. A stock market index is
ments of the same magnitude. Statistically, the
used to represent the stock markets in each country.
leverage effect occurs when an unexpected drop in
For the Consumer Price Index (CPI) data,
price (bad news) increases predictable volatility more
International Financial Statistical (IFS) database is
than an unexpected increase in price (good news) of
used. The inflation rates are calculated as the
similar magnitude. If unexpected inflation is consid-
percentage change in the CPI. All data are monthly.
ered a bad news for the stock market, then
The sample period is different across these countries
unexpected inflation should be associated with a
and can be summarized as shown in Table 1.
decrease in stock prices at the current time (assuming
Before moving to methodology it’s important to
a one month lag).
stress the important relationship between market
The unexpected inflation-stock return effect is
capitalization and Gross Domestic Product (GDP).
tested using the univariate EGARCH (p, q)-M model
One expects a development of equity markets to lead
as shown below:
to a richer country. Table 2 includes some market
 
development indicators such as the GDP and GDP Rit ¼ i þ im UNEX þ #t2 þ "it , "it  N 0, IT
2
,
growth; GDP per capita adjusted for purchasing  2  2  "t1
power parity and Market capitalization as percent- log it ¼ ! þ   log it1 þ @  pffiffiffiffiffi
it2
age of GDP. Data are available from the World 2 3
Development Indicators CD. In order to stand on the pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi7
6 "t1
relationship between market development (as proxied þ  4qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi  2=5
2
it1
by market capitalization) and GDP growth one
regresses per capita GDP on market capitalization
i ¼ Bahrain, Egypt, Jordan, Oman,
as a percentage of GDP. In three out of five countries
beta coefficients were positive and significant. The and Saudia Arabia ð1Þ
beta coefficient for Bahrain cannot be considered as where
valid due to small sample problems. Finally, the beta
for Jordan shows no positive relationship between Rit is the monthly rate of return on the market
per capita GDP and market capitalization, beta portfolio of assets for country i in period t.
coefficient is insignificant. UNEX represents the unexpected inflation esti-
mates as the residuals form the first order
moving average process of the inflation rate.
Methodology it2 is the conditional variance at period t.
!, , @,
This study investigates the effect of unexpected and  are constant parameters.
inflation on stock returns in five MENA countries:
Bahrain, Egypt, Jordan, Oman and Saudi Arabia In this model if  < 0, then the leverage effect
using a family of GARCH models. The family nests exists and if  6¼ 0 the impact is asymmetric.
two basic models: EGARCH in mean and Threshold The EGARCH model is asymmetric because
GARCH. the level of the standardized errors is included with

Table 1. Sample periods

Bahrain Egypt Jordan Oman Saudia Arabia


1999:01–2002:07 1996:01–2002:07 1978:12–2002:07 1999:01–2002:07 1997:12–2002:07
874 S. A. M. Al-Rjoub
Table 2. Market capitalization of stock exchanges and GDP
Data are from World Development Indicators CD. B is the beta coefficient of regressing per capita GDP on market
capitalization as a percentage of GDP. The standard errors are computed using the Newey-West heteroskedasticity and
autocorrelation-consistent estimator of the covariance matrix P-values are in parentheses.

GDP per GDP Market cap


Country GDP GDP growth capita growth per capita, listed companies
code Year (current US ($)) (annual %) (annual %) PPP ($) B (% of GDP)
BHR 26.9 (0.05)
1998 6.18394 4.79 1.0416 13720 109.47711
1999 6.62065 3.9599 3.5323 14750 108.07088
2000 7.97069 5.3699 4.9366 15820 83.104467
2001 7.93505 0 0.411 16060 83.187865
EGY 8.3 (0.00)
1988 35.0446 5.3007 2.8032 2220 5.0221669
1989 39.6484 4.9723 2.5416 2260 4.3154284
1990 43.1304 5.7017 3.3136 2390 4.0922394
1991 36.9705 1.0788 1.136 2380 7.1705715
1992 41.856 4.4334 2.216 2520 7.7862038
1993 47.1968 2.8813 0.7668 2590 8.0810431
1994 51.8979 3.948 1.8824 2660 8.2141921
1995 60.1592 4.6652 2.6567 2810 13.444318
1996 67.6512 5.0096 3.0749 2910 20.950096
1997 75.8702 5.4923 3.4944 2990 27.454781
1998 82.0838 4.5489 2.5731 3030 29.702563
1999 89.0887 6.2848 4.2699 3250 36.859868
2000 99.4275 5.1084 3.127 3470 28.90647
2001 98.4757 2.8999 1.0039 3520 24.542076
JOR 2.6 (0.42)
1988 6.04982 1.852 5.247 3880 36.910175
1989 4.12843 13.45 16.51 3180 52.368502
1990 4.02026 0.9737 2.657 3140 49.772802
1991 4.19333 1.8238 8.947 3040 59.90457
1992 5.36646 18.829 12.844 3470 62.704191
1993 5.6658 4.63 0.002 3500 86.324934
1994 6.29738 4.978 0.9734 3580 72.950929
1995 6.81158 6.3815 2.9793 3770 68.559635
1996 7.02731 2.0997 0.97 3770 64.761576
1997 7.32358 3.0692 0.029 3710 74.362468
1998 7.95901 2.9433 0.151 3630 73.350763
1999 8.13399 3.0949 0.004 3720 71.637643
2000 8.45134 3.9999 0.8728 3820 58.487767
2001 8.8291 4.2 1.2176 3870 71.513484
OMN 7.6 (0.01)
1992 11.3076 6.7683 0.567 10330 9.3830098
1993 11.1674 7.0014 0.3205 10690 9.742565
1994 11.3102 3.511 0.6191 11330 15.07479
1995 12.1019 3.2 0.3481 9840 16.344473
1996 15.2769 2.8999 1.1005 11250 17.424907
1997 15.8387 6.2 2.2928 11490 44.877273
1998 14.0858 2.6499 0.5987 11720 31.180281
1999 15.7113 0.269 2.223 11680 27.381544
2000 19.8257 5.1799 2.4741 12040 17.467185
SAU 31.4 (0.05)
1991 118.034 10.477 7.1021 12250 40.846459
1992 123.204 2.7868 0.449 12810 44.608843
1993 118.515 0.637 3.203 12750 44.528407
1994 120.168 0.4815 2.112 12970 32.193202
1995 127.823 0.4424 2.15 12970 32.002658
1996 157.743 1.3931 1.224 13030 29.073118
1997 164.993 2.003 0.63 12890 35.992971
1998 145.967 1.7376 0.859 12660 29.159138
1999 161.172 0.785 3.305 12520 37.500256
2000 188.72 4.8499 2.1929 13460 35.592761
2001 186.488 1.2 2.039 13330 39.25547
The adjustments of stock prices to information about inflation 875
a coefficient . This coefficient is typically negative Table 3. Selection of a model using Ljung–Box Q-statistics
without violating the non-negative variance
The Ljung–Box
condition. This allows for positive return shocks Q-statistics The Ljung–Box
to generate less volatility than negative return for AR (1) Q-statistics for
innovations, all else being equal.1 ARMA (1,0) ARMA(1, 1)
While the unexpected inflation-stock return effect Bahrain Q(8) LOS* ¼ 0.006 Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.173
is tested using the univariate TARCH ( p, q)-M model Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.036 Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.066
as shown below: Egypt Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.819 Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.816
Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.513 Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.517
R~ it ¼ i þ im UNEX þ #t2 þ "it ,"it  Nð0, IT
2
Þ Jordan Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.14 Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.18
Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.02 Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.034
t2 ¼ ! þ "2t1 : þ "2t1 dt1 þ t1
2
ð2Þ Oman Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.725 Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.991
Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.114 Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.597
where dt ¼ 1 if "t < 0, and zero otherwise. Saudi Arabia Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.876 Q(8) LOS ¼ 0.892
Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.887 Q(12) LOS ¼ 0.910
In this model, good news ("t < 0) and bad news
("t > 0), have differential effects on the conditional Note: *Level of signifiance.
variance-good news has an impact of , while bad
news has an impact of  þ . If  > 0 one says that
the leverage effect exists. If  6¼ 0, the news impact is IV. EGARCH and TARCH Results
asymmetric.
The unexpected effects of inflation are investigated
simultaneously by incorporating them into two
Selecting the Wright model to describe alternative models of monthly returns. Table 4
the inflation process in MENA countries presents the results from the EGARCH-M (p, q),
An important question arises when one tries to TARCH-M (p, q) models to test for asymmetric
describe the inflation process in these five MENA effects during the periods of the study. The process
countries; what is the proper model? That is, what is is estimated in this step with the method of maximum
the best-fitting ARMA model? likelihood using Gauss–Newton BHHH and/or
In order to answer this question the Ljung- Marquardt methods.2 The standard errors are
Box Q-statistics is used. If the sample value of Q computed using the White heteroscedasticity consis-
exceeds the critical value of 2 with n degrees of tent estimator of the covariance matrix (White, 1980).
freedom, then at least the value of the tested series is In order to hit the point addressed in this study
statistically different from zero at the specified the constant and the slope in the mean equations of
significance level. In order to test whether the EGARCH and TARCH are reported and the
ARMA(p, q) model fits the inflation data the coefficients of the squared residuals and the leverage
Ljung–Box Q-statistics are reported for the residuals effect in the variance equations. Both the news impact
for lags 8 and 12 in Table 2. and the leverage effect are tested.
Table 3 shows the results of the best-fitting EGARCH results in Table 4 indicate that the
ARMA models for inflation in Bahrain, Egypt, unexpected inflation has a negative impact on stock
Jordan, Oman and Saudi Arabia. Best-fitting market returns in all the MENA countries. The
ARIMA models are determined after constructing impact is high and significant in Bahrain, Egypt,
the ACF and PACF for the residuals of the estimated Jordan and Saudi Arabia, and significant in Oman.
model. The Ljung–Box Q-statistics and the serial The leverage effect () for Bahrain is negative and
correlation Lagrange multiplier (LM) tests accept the statistically different from zero, indicating the
null hypothesis that there is no serial correlation in existence of the leverage effect in stock market
the equations. Inflation rate is modeled using an return during the 1999 : 01 through 2002 : 07 sample
ARMA (1, 1) model and. The residuals from inflation periods. The impact is asymmetric On the other hand
regressions represent unexpected inflation. the leverage effect () for Egypt is positive and

1
For more detailed specification of EGARCH see Nelson (1990), and Engle and Ng (1993).
2
BHHH algorithm follows Newton–Raphson. It replaces the negative of the Hessian by an approximation formed from the
sum of the outer product of the gradient vectors for each observation’s contribution to the objective function. The Marquardt
algorithm modifies the Gauss–Newton algorithm in exactly the same manner as BHHH modifies the Newton–Rapson
method. By adding a ridge factor to the Hessian approximation, this correction handles numerical problems when the outer
product is near singular and may improve the convergence rate.
876
Table 4. News effect of inflation
This table reports the results of the EGARCH (p, q)-M, and TGARCH (p, q) models. P-values are in parentheses.  and  are the coefficients for the mean equation
in the EARCH-M and the TGARCH while  and  are those for the variance equations to represent the leverage affect.

EGARCH ( p, q)-M TGARCH

Saudia Saudia
Coefficients Bahrain Egypt Jordan Oman Arabia Bahrain Egypt Jordan Oman Arabia

1999:01– 1996:01– 1978:12– 1999:01– 1997:12– 1999:01– 1996:01– 1978:12– 1999:01– 1997:12–
Mean equation 2002:07 2002:07 2002:07 2002:07 2002:07 2002:07 2002:07 2002:07 2002:07 2002:07
 29.22 2.12 132.7 93.64 0.014 7.38 5.31 132.25 96.01 1.58
(0.02) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.03)
 60.43 164.85 108.47 278.11 1.62 164.74 1.42 92.28 268.32 292.2
(0.00) (0.00) (0.02) (0.09) (0.00) (0.00) (0.37) (0.05) (0.37) (0.00)
Variance equation
 1.65 0.9 0.605 0.955 3.716
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
 1.15 3.11 0.069 0.195 0.246 3.90 59.15 0.059 0.0053 5.312
(0.00) (0.00) (0.09) (0.36) (0.54) (0.00) (0.00) (0.29) (0.98) (0.00)
þ 2.25 58.25 0.546 0.9497 1.596

S. A. M. Al-Rjoub
The adjustments of stock prices to information about inflation 877
statistically different from zero, indicating the free of serial correlation at the standard 1% level
non-existence of the leverage effect in stock market of significance. A Jarque–Bera LM test also always
return during the 1999 : 01 through 2002 : 07 sample overwhelmingly rejects the null of normality.
period. Results are similar for Jordan. For Oman and Further, a Lagrange Multiplier test is carried out to
Saudi Arabia there is no news effect of inflation on examine whether the standardized residuals exhibit
stock market data. additional ARCH. It is found that in all cases, the
TARCH results are reported in panel B of variance equations are correctly specified and that
Table 4. Results shows that unexpected inflation there should be no ARCH left in the standardized
has a negative effect on Bahraini (164.74 with a residuals. The F-test statistics and their p-values
P-value of (0.00)), Jordanian (92.28 with P-value indicate this result. All the F-statistics are insignif-
(0.05)), and Saudi stock market return (292.2 with icant across the two time periods. The coefficients
a P-value of (0.00)). The coefficients of unexpected of skewness and kurtosis show severe evidence
inflation are negative and highly significant. Only against the conditional normality assumption in the
Oman and Egypt shows insignificant results where residuals. The statistics show that returns are
unexpected inflation shows no effect on stock market negatively skewed although the skewness statistics
return data in the sample period. When testing for are not large. However, all the kurtosis values are
the leverage effect results shows the following: (1)  much larger than 3, significantly different from that
for Bahrain, Egypt and Saudi Arabia are negative of normal distribution. This indicates that much of
and significant indicating that leverage effect do not the non-normality is due to leptokurtosis. Despite
exists for these countries, (2)  is not significantly these facts, the estimates are still consistent
positive for Jordan and Oman so there appears to be under quasi-maximum likelihood assumptions. The
no asymmetric effect. The results are similar for those GARCH models encompass an autocorrelation
of EGARCHs. correction and are robust under non-normality.
All these results indicate that the stock markets Overall, results in Table 5 and 6 support the model
of the listed MENA countries do not feel the high up specification.
and down movements in the markets and as such the
volatilities. The asymmetric news effect is absent.
To assess the general descriptive validity of the V. Conclusion
model, a battery of standard specification tests is
employed. The test results are presented in Tables 5 This study extends the empirical evidence by analys-
and 6. Specification adequacy of the first two ing the reaction of monthly stock returns to the
conditional moments is verified through serial unexpected portion of CPI inflation rate and by
correlation tests of white noise. The Ljung–Box capturing the asymmetric shocks to volatility of
Q-Test is employed for serial correlation in the unexpected inflation in five MENA countries.
squared-standardized residuals ("2t /ht). All series are Both Threshold GARCH and Exponential GARCH

Table 5. Diagnostic statistics of the residuals from EGARCH estimation


This table includes a battery of standard specification tests. The squared standardized residuals ("2t =h) are reported.
J–B probability is the P-value for testing for normality in the EGARCH ( p, q)-M residuals. Standard errors are computed
using the robust inference procedures developed by Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1988).

EGARCH ( p,q)

ARCH LM test for the GARCH


"2t =ht squared standardized residuals model specification

Skewness Kurtosis J–B probability Ljung–Box (24) F-stat P-value


A
Bahrain 15.36 246.13 0.000 1.093 0.00037 0.98
EGARCH (1.1)
Egypt 13.79 212.86 0.000 18.525A 0.008578 0.77
EGARCH (1,3)
Jordan 2.56 15.03 0.00 14.694A 0.08325 0.77
EGARCH (1,2)
Oman 15.36 246.13 0.000 1.093A 0.0124 0.911
EGARCH (1,1)
Saudia Arabia 7.624 66.00 0.00 23.683A 2.22536 0.1369
EGARCH (1,3)
878 S. A. M. Al-Rjoub
Table 6. Diagnostic statistics of the residuals from TARCH estimation
This table includes a battery of standard specification tests. The squared standardized residuals ("2t =h) are reported.
J–B probability is the P-value for testing for normality in the TARCH ( p,q)-M residuals. Standard errors are computed using
the robust inference procedures developed by Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1988).

EGARCH ( p,q)

ARCH LM test for the


"2t =ht squared standardized residuals GARCH model specification

Skewness Kurtosis J–B probability Ljung–Box (24) F-stat P-value


A
Bahrain 14.06 216.79 0.00 14.251 0.506 0.477
EGARCH (1.1)
Egypt 16.65 278.7 0.000 0.036 0.0002 0.988
EGARCH(1,2)
Jordan 3.145 19.32 0.00 16.44A 3.0858 0.80
EGARCH(1,2)
Oman 2.17 9.94 0.00 20.284A 0.539 0.465
EGARCH(1,1)
Saudi Arabia 12.015 171.62 0.00 87.39 2.143 0.144
EGARCH (1,3)

are used to catch the news affect that unexpected Ely, D. P. and Robinson, K. J. (1992) Stock returns
inflation may have on stock returns. and inflation: future tests of the role of the
Central Bank, Journal of Macroeconomics, 14,
After selecting the right model to describe the 525–43.
inflation process in MENA countries, unexpected Engle, R. and Ng, V. (1993) Measuring and testing
inflation is regressed over the stock market return for the impact of news on volatility, Journal of Finance,
the five MENA countries: Bahrain, Egypt, Jordan, 48, 1749–78.
Oman and Saudi Arabia. Results show a negative and Fama, E. F. (1981) Stock returns, real activity,
inflation and money, American Economic Review, 4,
strongly significant relationship between unexpected 545–65.
inflation and stock returns in these countries. Results Fama, E. and Schwert, W. (1977) Asset return and
also indicate that the stock markets of the listed inflation, Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 115–46.
MENA countries do not feel the high up and down Fisher, I. (1930) The Theory of Interest, Macmillan,
movements in the markets and as such the volatilities. New York.
Feldstein, M. (1980) Inflation and the stock market,
The asymmetric news effect is absent. American Economic Review, 70, 839–47.
Geske, R. and Roll, R. (1983) The monetary and fiscal
linkage between stock returns and inflation,
Journal of Finance, 38, 1–33.
References Glosten, L. R., Jagannathan, R. and Runkle, D. (1993)
On the relation between the expected value and the
Balduzzi, P. (1995) Stock returns and the ‘proxy volatility of the normal excess return on stocks,
hypothesis’: a new look at the data, Economics Journal of Finance, 48, 1779–801.
Letters, 48, 47–53. Graham, F. C. (1996) Inflation, real stock returns
Black, F. (1976) Studies of stock price volatility changes, and monetary policy, Applied Financial Economics,
in proceedings of the 1976 meetings of the Business and 6, 29–35.
Economic Statistis Section, American Statistical Hardouvelis, G. (1987) Macroeconomic information
Association, pp. 177–81. and stock prices, Journal of Economics and
Bodie, Z. (1976) Common stocks as a hedge against Business, 39, 131–40.
inflation, Journal of Finance, 31, 459–70. Hess, P. J. and Lee, B.-S. (1999) Stock returns and
Box, G. and Jenkins, G. (1976) Time Series Analysis: inflation with supply and demand disturbances,
Forecasting and Control, Holden-Day, New York. Review of Financial Studies, 12, 1203–18.
Boudoukh, J. and Richardson, M. (1993) Stock returns Jaffe, J. and Mandelker, G. (1976) The ‘Fisher Effect’
and inflation: a long-horizon perspective, American for risky assets: an empirical investigation, Journal of
Economic Review, 83, 1346–55. Finance, 31, 447–58.
Caporale, T. and Jung, C. (1997) Inflation and real stock Kaul, G. (1987) Stock returns and inflation: the role of
prices, Applied Financial Economics, 7, 265–6. the monetary sector, Journal of Financial Economics,
Chatrath, A., Ramchander, S. and Song, F. (1997) Stock 18, 253–76.
prices, inflation and output: evidence from India, Lintner, J. (1975) Inflation and security return, Journal of
Applied Financial Economics, 7, 439–45. Finance, 30, 259–80.
The adjustments of stock prices to information about inflation 879
McQueen, G. and Roley, V. V. (1993) Stock prices, news, Pearce, D. K. (1985) Stock prices and economic news,
and business conditions, Review of Financial Studies, Journal of Business, 58, 49–67.
6, 683–707. Pearce, D. K. and Roley, V. V. (1983) The reaction of
Modigliani, F. and Richard, A. C. (1979) Inflation, rational stock prices to unanticipated changes in money: a
valuation and the market, Financial Analysts Journal, note, Journal of Finance, 38, 1323–33.
35, 24–44. Schwert, G. W. (1981) The adjustment of stock prices to
Nelson, C. R. (1976) Inflation and rates of return inflation, Journal of Finance, 36, 15–29.
on common stock, Journal of Finance, 31, 471–83. Titman, S. and Warga, A. (1989) Asset pricing and
Nelson, D. B. (1991) Conditional heteroskedasticity in expected inflation, Journal of Finance, 41, 209–23.
asset returns: a new approach, Econometrica, 59, Zakoian, J. M. (1990) Threshold Heteroskedastic Models,
347–70. Manuscript, CREST, INSEE, Paris.

You might also like