You are on page 1of 13

Collective Bargaining and the Trade Practices Act: The Trade Practices

Legislation Amendment Act (No 1) 2006 (Cth) — (2007) 20 AJLL 207

Copy Citation
Australian Journal of Labour Law
Shae McCrystal
Legislative Developments
Collective Bargaining and the Trade Practices Act: The Trade Practices
Legislation Amendment Act (No 1) 2006 (Cth)

Shae McCrystal*

The use of collective bargaining as a tool to improve the economic and working
conditions of individuals has generally been utilised by employed workers organised
within trade unions. The traditional hostility of the common law to combination was
countered through the passage of industrial relations legislation which allowed for
lawful combination and established structures for the pursuit of common working
conditions. In Australia this has taken the form of legislation providing for the
conciliation and arbitration of industrial disputes and, more recently, structures for
collective bargaining.
In contrast, collective bargaining in the commercial context, for example by
corporations, self employed persons or independent contractors, has remained
unlawful because of the anti-competitive effect of combination by such individuals or
corporations. The use of collectives to bargain over the price of services, products or
conditions of business is generally unlawful under the anti-competitive conduct
provisions in Pt IV of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (Cth) (TPA) (and the identical
provisions applying to individuals under the National Competition Code). While it has
been possible under the TPA to obtain authorisations to collectively bargain in
contravention of Pt IV, this process is lengthy, often difficult and time consuming,
rendering access to collective bargaining difficult for most small commercial
operators. The combination of these factors has meant that collective bargaining has
not been available to non-employed workers economically dependent on the sale of
their labour (for example, independent contractors and self employed persons) as a
tool to improve their economic and working conditions.
The ability of non-employed workers to engage in collective bargaining has
significantly increased with the passage of legislation which I discussed (in proposed
form) in an article in this Journal,1 the Trade Practices Legislation Amendment Act
(No 1) 2006 (Cth) (Amendment Act). The Amendment Act has altered the TPA,
supplementing the existing authorisation process with a new notification process
which permits relevant individuals2 or corporations to lodge a ‘collective bargaining
notice’ with the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) of their
intention to engage in collective bargaining with a named target. Once in force, such a
notice protects the parties engaged in collective bargaining from Pt IV liability with
respect to collective boycotts, price fixing or contracts, arrangements or
understandings which may substantially lessen competition.
The passage of these amendments to the TPA was not specifically targeted at
non-employed workers who are economically dependent on the sale of their labour,
but at ‘small business’ more generally. However, the provisions, when taken in
combination with the Independent Contractors Act 2006 (Cth) (ICA), have changed
the regulatory environment in which these workers operate.3 They remain
substantially excluded from the industrial relations system and indeed, the ICA
prevents their further regulation under state industrial legislation. However, the ICA
provides a jurisdiction to challenge unfair services contracts,4 and the TPA changes
enhance the capacity of these workers to engage in collective bargaining. While this
change is embryonic, it has the potential to challenge the assumption that all
non-employed workers operate in an arms length commercial environment, presenting
the opportunity for a significant change in the regulation of their working conditions.
Consequently, it is worthy of attention in the labour law context. The irony of this
development, coming at a time when individual bargaining in employment is
championed and assumptions of inherent power imbalance are challenged, has been
noted elsewhere.5
This legislative note will briefly examine the legislative history of the Amendment
Act before analysing the substance of the changes.
Legislative History
The collective bargaining notification provisions were recommended by Dawson et
al’s Review of the Competition Provisions of the Trade Practices Act in 2003
(Dawson Report).6 The report concluded that the anti-competitive conduct provisions
in Pt IV of the TPA largely prevent ‘collective’ conduct by small businesses in their
dealings with larger businesses and acknowledged that collective activity could be
pro-competitive if it corrected an imbalance of bargaining power in certain
situations.The Dawson Report recommended the introduction of a notification process
for collective bargaining by small businesses dealing with large businesses in
circumstances where such bargaining could generate public benefit.7
The recommendations of the Dawson Report with respect to collective bargaining and
other aspects of the anti-competitive conduct provisions of the TPA were largely
adopted by the Federal Government and introduced into Federal Parliament in the
Trade Practices Legislation Amendment Bill (No 1) 2005 (Cth). The Bill passed the
House of Representatives but was the subject of difficulty in the Senate, due to
concern expressed by some government Senators over provisions regulating mergers
contained in one of the Schedules.8 The content of the Bill relating to mergers was
renegotiated and finally passed through Federal Parliament in late 2006. The
amendments to the TPA took effect from 1 January 2007.9
Collective Bargaining Notifications
Collective bargaining by non-employed workers undertaken to regulate their
relationships with the purchasers of their labour could potentially contravene TPA
s 45(2) in three ways.10 First, an agreement between the collective could constitute a
collective boycott of the target if they collectively refuse to deal with the
target.11 Further, it could constitute price fixing if they seek to set the price at which
each of the members of the collective will sell services to the target.12 Finally, the
conduct could constitute a contract, arrangement or understanding that substantially
lessens competition either in the market in which the members of the collective
operate, or in the market in which the target operates.13 The new notification scheme
for collective bargaining enables parties to lodge a notice of such conduct with the
ACCC. The conduct can then proceed without attracting TPA liability for these
offences.
Collective bargaining notices
Under the TPA as amended, s 45(2) does not apply to a corporation (or individual via
the NCC) engaging in conduct that contravenes the section if a collective bargaining
notice is in force.14 A collective bargaining notice is a notice given to the ACCC by
an applicant that they have made, or propose to make, a contract with one or more
persons about the supply or acquisition of goods or services to or from a ‘target’; and
that they reasonably expect that they will make one or more contracts with the target
about the supply or acquisition of goods or services.15 Here, the person giving the
notice to the ACCC has formed, or intends to form, a collective of two or more
persons or entities to collectively negotiate with a third person, the target, over the
conditions of the transactions that each of the members of the collective has with the
target.
Who may lodge a collective bargaining notice?
A collective bargaining notice may be lodged by a corporation or person on behalf of
an identified collective that satisfies the requirements above (is proposing to engage in
collective bargaining) where the corporation or person reasonably expects that the
contract to be made with the target, or the combined sum of the contracts to be made
with the target, for the supply or acquisition of goods or services, will not exceed
$3 million, or such other amount as prescribed by the regulations, in any 12 month
period.16 This provision limits access to collective bargaining notices to ‘small
business’ bargaining transactions involving relatively small contract prices.
The Guide to Collective Bargaining Notifications produced by the ACCC (ACCC
Guide) notes that in calculating the likely transaction cost of the proposed contract or
contracts with the target, businesses can utilise information such as their own past
dealings with the target or information relating to other businesses transactions with
the target.17
In order for a collective bargaining notice to be valid, the lodging party must have a
reasonable expectation at the time of making the agreement with the other members
of the collective, and at the point of lodgment, that an agreement will be reached with
the target, and that the sum of the prices under the agreement with the target will not
exceed $3 million.18 This requirement means that parties wishing to utilise this
process cannot lodge a purely speculative collective bargaining notice. They must
reasonably expect the creation of an agreement with the target. In this respect the
system established under the TPA differs from collective bargaining by employees
under the Workplace Relations Act 1996 (Cth) (WR Act) which imposes no such
substantive requirement upon employee collective bargaining.
The further requirements for the lodgment of a collective bargaining notice are that
the notice complies with the form prescribed by the regulations, contains the relevant
information and is accompanied by the prescribed fee. The prescribed fee has been set
at $1000.19
A notice will be invalid if it is given on behalf of the bargaining parties by a trade
union, an officer of a trade union or a person acting at the direction of a trade
union.20 The inclusion of this provision was not a recommendation of the Dawson
Report and appears to have been included in consequence of the strong anti-trade
union inclination of the federal coalition government.The ACCC guide points out that
applications may be lodged by an organisation acting on behalf of the collective
bargaining group, like an industry organisation, but may not be lodged by a trade
union.21 The exact effect of the provision remains unclear.It clearly operates to
invalidate a notice lodged by, or by a person acting on behalf of, a trade union, but it
does not appear to extend to invalidating a notice prepared by, or in conjunction with,
a trade union if the notice is not lodged by, or on behalf of, that trade union. Therefore
it does not appear to exclude trade union involvement, just trade union lodgment. The
provision is unfortunate as the aim of the section appears to be to exclude
involvement of trade unions in the process of collective bargaining, one in which they
are uniquely positioned to provide assistance to independent contractors or small
businesses seeking to navigate collective bargaining procedures.22 Whether it
actually has this effect in practice, given the difference between assisting a collective
to prepare an application, and actually lodging an application, is questionable.
It is unlikely that this provision will be retained in the TPA if the Australian Labor
Party (ALP) gains office at the next federal election. ALP members of Federal
Parliament expressed vociferous opposition to the section during parliamentary
debates.23 Further, the ALP policy statement on small business and contractors
passed at the 2007 ALP National Conference refers to the need for small business and
contractors to have ‘choice as to who represents them in collective bargaining’.24
The notification form that must be used for lodging a collective bargaining notice is
set out in Sch 1 of the Trade Practices Regulations 1974 (Cth). Form GA must be
completed by applicants proposing to engage in collective bargaining arrangements.
The form requires the applicants to set out the details of the proposed or existing
collective arrangement, the process of bargaining and details of the expected
outcomes from bargaining. The form also requires the applicants to detail the possible
anti and pro competitive effects of the proposed conduct by outlining the public
detriments and benefits of the conduct. Here, collective bargaining in the commercial
context differs from the employment context where collective bargaining begins from
the premise that the bargaining parties are inherently unequal.This presumption has
not been imported for commercial actors. The necessity of collective bargaining and
the public, as opposed to private, benefit from the conduct must be clearly articulated.
This requirement has previously been a stumbling block to authorisation applications
for collective bargaining. The ACCC Guide provides examples of public benefit and
detriment and indicates that the ACCC will assist parties to identify these factors.
Once a collective bargaining notice is lodged, the ACCC will undertake a public
consultation process in order to assess the pro and anti-competitive effects of the
proposed arrangement.25 A collective bargaining notice will come into effect 14 days
from the day that the notice is lodged unless the ACCC objects to the
notification.26 Once in force a notice will apply for three years unless it is withdrawn
earlier or the ACCC issues an objection notice.27
ACCC conference and objection notice
After the lodgment of a collective bargaining notice, the ACCC may ‘object’ to the
notice on the grounds that the public detriment from the proposed conduct would
outweigh any public benefit.Where the ACCC objects to a notice, it must convene a
conference to discuss the objection, and that conference must involve the applicants
and any interested persons.28 The conference provides an opportunity for the
applicants and other interested persons to discuss the pro and anti- competitive effects
of the proposed conduct with the ACCC. After the conference has been convened, the
ACCC may issue an objection notice if it is satisfied that any public benefit from a
proposed collective boycott or price fixing arrangement is outweighed by the likely
public detriment.29 Where the conduct disclosed by the notice is a contract,
arrangement or understanding that may substantially lessen competition, the ACCC
may only issue an objection notice if it is satisfied that the contract, arrangement or
understanding would actually have the effect of substantially lessening competition
and any public benefit of the conduct is likely to be outweighed by the public
detriment of the conduct.30 Where an objection notice is issued, the collective
bargaining notification will not come into force.31 An applicant may appeal an
objection notice to the Australian Competition Tribunal which must set the notice
aside if it is satisfied that the public benefit outweighs the public detriment of the
conduct.32 In the case of contracts, arrangements or understandings that substantially
lessen competition, the tribunal must set aside the notice if it is satisfied that the
contract, arrangement or understanding does not or would not have the effect of
substantially lessening competition, or, if it is satisfied that in all the circumstances
the provision would result in a public benefit which would outweigh any public
detriment.33
Where an application is successful and a collective bargaining notification comes into
effect, the ACCC retains the power to review the notice during the period of its
operation and issue an objection notice.34 If this occurs, immunity from liability
under s 45(2) of the TPA ceases on the 31st day after the issuing of the notice, or on
such other day as the ACCC specifies.35
Impact of the Amendment Act
In an earlier analysis in this Journal I argued that the introduction of collective
bargaining notifications had the potential to significantly increase access to collective
bargaining for workers who are not employed, but who are economically dependent
on the sale of their own labour.36However, I also noted that the proposed
amendments did not go far enough in providing immunity for bargaining parties from
common law actions including the economic torts, the doctrine of restraint of trade,
potential liability under the secondary boycott provisions of the TPA, or in setting out
a process whereby collective agreements could be registered and
enforced.37 Collective bargaining by commercial actors has the potential to face legal
difficulties in all these areas, and this has not been addressed in the Amendment Act.
In addition to these problems, there are manifest difficulties with the process for
collective bargaining notices which may restrict the potential usefulness of this
process, particularly for the workers under discussion.
The first problem lies in the assessment of each notification by the ACCC on the
grounds of public detriment and public benefit. In making this assessment, the private
benefit to be gained by the parties to bargaining is not relevant. Accordingly, workers
economically dependent on the sale of their labour cannot point to a betterment of
their own personal circumstances as a manifest benefit of the conduct. Instead, the
application must demonstrate that the proposal would produce a public benefit in the
form of reduced transaction costs, increased efficiency or output, improved
informational asymmetry and improved competition through the development of new
markets. Benefits to the working conditions of the members of the collective
constitute a private benefit and are not a relevant consideration. Further, the ACCC
Guide specifically notes that ‘increased fairness’ or ‘improved industrial harmony’ are
generally not sufficient to demonstrate public benefit.38 The emphasis must be on the
ultimate consumers in a production or service chain and the effect on the market. For
non-employed workers who are economically dependent on the sale of their labour,
demonstrations of public benefit may be extremely difficult to make out where the
aim is to increase the price they receive for their labour. Increased efficiencies may
not be relevant or may be offset by increased costs, making it difficult to show any net
public benefit. Further, it would not be sufficient to argue that the conduct operates to
counteract power imbalance without further evidence of public benefit, as according
to the ACCC, ‘a mere change in the amount of bargaining power is not in itself a
public benefit’.39
An additional stumbling block is the requirement of ‘reasonable expectation’ within
the lodgment process. To lodge a collective bargaining notification, the applicants
must have a reasonable expectation of creating a contract with the target of the
bargaining. As noted above, this provision appears to have been included to prevent
purely speculative conduct on the part of collectives. However, it could also operate
as a barrier to bargaining for collectives. It is a requirement under the TPA for a target
of bargaining to be given a copy of the notification as soon as practical. Would an
unconditional statement on the part of a target to the effect that they will refuse to
enter into any agreement with the collective automatically derail a collective
bargaining notification? Issuing a statement to this effect suggests that the applicants
could not have a reasonable expectation of creating an agreement and therefore could
not proceed with the notification.
If this interpretation of the provisions is correct, the potential for the notification
system to assist in evening bargaining power between parties could be undermined
before any notification even came into effect. In the employment context, it is
recognised that collective pressure may legitimately be brought to bear in order to
convince a ‘target’ to engage in negotiations. The TPA bargaining model does not
appear to allow for such a situation where a target is unwilling to negotiate, and an
applicant cannot establish a ‘reasonable expectation’. This aspect of the legislation
has the potential to undermine the utility of the provisions in achieving any balance in
bargaining power between the collective and the target of the bargaining.
In addition to difficulties in establishing public benefit and the requirement of
reasonable expectation, collectives who propose to engage in a collective boycott face
more onerous scrutiny from the ACCC. For non-employed workers who are
economically dependent on the sale of their own labour, a collective boycott is the
equivalent of the right to strike for employees: it may be the only leverage that they
are able to bring to bear in a bargaining situation. However, the ACCC Guide
specifically notes that collective boycotts can significantly increase the
anti-competitive effects of collective bargaining and as such ‘it is unlikely to allow
protection from legal action to such conduct in most cases’.40 The success of any
notification involving a collective boycott would ‘be contingent on it being clear that
a failure to collectively negotiate would result in inefficiencies’.41 This view of the
manifest public detriment resulting from collective boycott activities is also reflected
in decisions of the Australian Competition Tribunal.42 This limitation on when
collectives can take positive action (a boycott) rather than passive negotiations will
have the effect of limiting the utility of collective bargaining notices for collectives
who are otherwise unable to bring any pressure to bear on the target of their action.
The problems with the notification process that have been discussed so far are clearly
contingent on the approach that will ultimately be adopted by the ACCC to collective
bargaining notifications. The Amendment Act affected a shift from an authorisation
process where applications had to be approved by the ACCC, to one whereby
notifications will come into effect unless the ACCC objects. In practice this means
that the extent to which the problems surrounding reasonable expectation, public
benefit and collective boycotts will impact upon the capacity of workers using the
provisions to engage in collective bargaining will depend on how vigilant the ACCC
is in vetting notifications, and how inflexibly it (and the Australian Competition
Tribunal on appeal) applies these requirements. While the stringency of the approach
of the ACCC cannot yet be ascertained, the ACCC Guide suggests that the ACCC
intends to assess all notifications for validity, and asserts that notifications that
include collective boycotts will be ‘unlikely’ to succeed in most cases.43
A more general difficulty with the notification process that has become evident since
the passage of the Amendment Act is the lack of public dissemination of information
on the new procedures. At the time of writing (July 2007) the ACCC notification
register records that there have been no notifications lodged for consideration. Further,
there has only been a limited newspaper public education campaign to raise awareness
of the notification scheme. The availability of collective bargaining for businesses
outside the employment context is not generally known. In order to ensure that the
provisions are utilised to the fullest, there must be a more extensive public awareness
campaign in order to shift the mindset that collective bargaining is just for employees.
Conclusion
The collective bargaining notification scheme introduced by the Trade Practices
Legislation Amendment Act (No 1) 2006 (Cth) has the potential to expand access to
collective bargaining as an option for many workers who are not employed but are
economically dependent on the sale of their own labour. However, the requirement
that parties establish and detail the ‘public benefit’ to be gained from the conduct may
operate as a stumbling block to successful notifications by these workers. Further, the
predominant view of the ACCC and Australian Competition Tribunal that there is no
public benefit in increasing bargaining power, and that collective boycotts are
significantly anti-competitive may operate to reduce the utility of collective
bargaining notifications.
The federal coalition government has asserted that collective bargaining notifications
are necessary to make it easier for small business to collectively bargain with big
business.44 The ALP opposition has asserted the need for collective bargaining
notifications to operate to assist in redressing power imbalances between small and
large businesses.45 However, the limitations that I have outlined in this note,
particularly with respect to the exclusion of private welfare as a component of public
benefit, the requirement that an applicant have a reasonable expectation of creating an
agreement before commencing bargaining, and the failure to recognise a correction of
bargaining power as a public benefit means that the notification scheme will be of
least benefit to those with the weakest bargaining power. These applicants will be
least able to demonstrate public benefit as they will be unable to include their private
welfare or weak bargaining position as a benefit. Further, they will be least able to
demonstrate a reasonable expectation of completing an agreement in the face of a
refusal to bargain by a target and will be unable to utilise a collective boycott for the
purposes of attempting to convince a target to enter into an agreement.
As both the federal coalition government and the ALP have publicly professed a
commitment to permitting collective bargaining by small business to assist in
counteracting power imbalance, amendment to the concept of public benefit for the
purposes of collective bargaining notifications is necessary. Further, the concept of
‘reasonable expectation’ should be repealed or, at least, modified to ensure that where
there is a power imbalance, the notification provisions can be utilised to bring
pressure on a target in order to encourage that target to agree to engage in bargaining.
These changes would ensure that the new provisions are not only utilised by
organisations that can demonstrate efficiency gains and the potential to open up new
markets, but are also utilised by workers who are economically dependent on the sale
of their labour.
• *
ANU College of Law, ANU.

Globalization and Health
Debate
Assessing the impact of the Australia-United States Free Trade
Agreement on Australian and global medicines policy
Thomas Faunce*1,2, Evan Doran1,3, David Henry1,4, Peter Drahos1,
Andrew Searles1,3, Brita Pekarsky1,5 and Warwick Neville1

Abstract
On 1 January 2005, a controversial trade agreement entered into force between Australia and the
United States. Though heralded by the parties as facilitating the removal of barriers to free trade
(in ways not achievable in multilateral fora), it also contained many trade-restricting intellectual
property provisions and others uniquely related to altering pharmaceutical regulation and public
health policy in Australia. The latter appear to have particularly focused on the world-respected
process of federal government reimbursement after expert cost-effectiveness evaluation, popularly
known as the Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme ('PBS'). It remains uncertain what sort of impacts –
if any – the Australia-United States Free Trade Agreement ('AUSFTA') will have on PBS processes
such as reference pricing and their important role in facilitating equitable and affordable access to
essential medicines.
This is now the field of inquiry for a major three year Australian Research Council ('ARC')-funded
study bringing together a team of senior researchers in regulatory theory from the Australian
National University and pharmacoeconomics from the University of Newcastle. The project
proposes to monitor, assess and analyse the real and potential impacts of the AUSFTA in this area,
providing Australian policy-makers with continuing expertise and options.
To the extent that the AUSFTA medicines provisions may represent an important precedent in a
global strategy by industry on cost-effectiveness evaluation of pharmaceuticals, the study will also
be of great interest to policy makers in other jurisdictions.

Introduction May 2004, by the Australian Trade Minister and the


The final text of the Australia-United States Free Trade United States Trade Representative. On 17 November
Agreement ('AUSFTA') was signed in Washington on 18 2004, the parties exchanged notes accepting their respec-
Globalization and Health 2005, 1:15 http://www.globalizationandhealth.com/content/1/1/15

tive implementing processes and the agreement entered claims that the US wanted the PBS dismantled[4]. They
into force on 1 January 2005. The AUSFTA contained argued that the regulatory changes required by these areas
numerous provisions either directly or indirectly related of the AUSFTA would (a) help redress an alleged current
to medicines regulation in Australia, particularly Annex undervaluing of pharmaceutical 'innovation' in Austral-
2C of Chapter Two, Chapter Seventeen on intellectual ian pricing arrangements and (b) stimulate locally-based
property and Chapter Twenty One on dispute resolution. research and development, as well as the local, mostly
generic, pharmaceutical industry[5]. They asserted the
It remains uncertain whether the AUSFTA will have either negotiated modifications would make Australia's regula-
a detrimental or beneficial impact on access to medicines tory system more oriented to the global market pressures
and the promotion and maintenance of good health in on industry, more responsible in its approach to intellec-
Australia. There does, however, appear to have been a sub- tual property rights and so more attractive to private
stantial difference in opinion between the Parties over investment, resulting in a net welfare benefit[6].
procedural changes that would result in Australian medi-
cines regulation. Others, however, have pointed to US legislation requiring
that nation's negotiators to seek in the AUSFTA provisions
Throughout the negotiations, the Australian Govern- facilitating the "elimination of government measures such
ment's position was either that the government cost-effec- as price controls and reference pricing which deny full
tiveness reimbursement system, the Pharmaceutical market access for United States [pharmaceutical] prod-
Benefits Scheme ('PBS'), would not be included in the ucts"[7]. The Australian Senate Select Committee on the
AUSFTA, or that if it was, it was an item of public health AUSFTA concluded:
policy whose core components would be protected[1].
After signature, the Australian government maintained While no single one of the specific commitments will create
that the fundamental architecture of the PBS remained immediate and measurable price rises for the PBS, the new
unchanged. It acknowledged commitments to make measures may well over time alter the bargaining power
improvements to the transparency and timeliness of PBS between the PBS and pharmaceutical companies. This may
processes. It also affirmed its reasonable expectations that, have long term ramifications that are not in the interest of Aus-
as a result of the AUSFTA, Australian citizens would bene- tralian consumers[8].
fit from faster access to new prescription medicines, that
the price of medicines on the PBS would not increase and Concern has been expressed about AUSFTA provisions
that the text of the AUSFTA made no changes to the cost- with the potential to encourage higher medicines prices in
effectiveness methods used to set PBS reimbursement lev- Australia. These include provisions in chapter 17 (Intellec-
els[2]. tual Property) that expand the obligations of the Trade
Related Intellectual Property Rights ('TRIPS') agreement
On the other hand, the Deputy US Trade Representative by prohibiting parallel importation, restricting compul-
stated to the US Congress: sory licensing to "national emergencies of extreme
urgency," prohibiting generic manufacturers exporting to
The U.S.-Australia FTA is the first to include non-tariff market a patent-expired market when a domestic patent exists
access provisions to address issues in the pharmaceutical sector. and increasing data exclusivity protections[9].
Recognizing the sensitivity of this issue, we drew on studies pre-
pared by the Australian government to propose changes that A significant additional worry for these commentators
would improve transparency and the regulatory procedures for was article 17.10.4. For the first time in Australia, this
listing new drugs in Australia. Under the FTA, the United linked generic regulatory market approval on quality and
States and Australia agreed to common principles on facilitat- safety grounds with the patent status of the relevant brand
ing high quality health care and continued improvements in name product[10]. This Hatch-Waxman-type provision
public health, including through government support for was felt to risk brand name manufacturers "evergreening"
research and development in the pharmaceutical industry. We soon-to-expire pharmaceutical patents, as had occurred
also agreed to establish a Medicines Working Group to discuss after comparable regulations were introduced in jurisdic-
emerging health policy issues. Australia committed to specific tions such as the US and Canada[11]. The academic, com-
steps to improve the transparency, accountability and prompt- munity and parliamentary concern in Australia was so
ness of the listing process, including establishment of an inde- great on this issue, that it resulted in the Australian gov-
pendent review of listing decisions[3]. ernment passing "anti-evergreening" amendments to its
AUSFTA implementing legislation. These imposed a $A10
Representatives of the multinational brand-name phar- million penalty for a bad faith challenge by a brand name
maceutical industry, including its regional organisation manufacturer of a generic notification certificate under
Medicines Australia, claimed that there was no basis to the new s26B of the Therapeutic Goods Act 1989 (Cth).
Globalization and Health 2005, 1:15 http://www.globalizationandhealth.com/content/1/1/15

They also allowed cost recovery in such circumstances by review such proposed changes for coherence with basic
the Australian government[12]. norms of bioethics, domestic law and international
human rights. We shall then attempt to determine their
Provisions in Annex 2C(1) emphasising the need for actual or potential impact on a range of indicators includ-
increased government recognition of pharmaceutical ing drug prices expenditure and affordability, drug availa-
"innovation" and "research and development" were like- bility and equity of access.
wise viewed by such critics as having the potential to
encourage brand name industry lobbying. This could We hope that publishing an outline of our proposed study
potentially weaken, in the long term, the capacity of Aus- will further encourage policy discussion, facilitate collab-
tralia's Pharmaceutical Benefits Advisory Committee orations and provide a template for governments of other
('PBAC') to reject, on clinical and cost effectiveness countries planning to enter such agreements. Although
grounds, new medicines from inclusion in the govern- much of the detail of the AUSFTA is specific to Australia,
ment's PBS positive reimbursement list, or to reference there are important elements likely to be relevant to future
their reimbursement price against older products with trade agreements involving the US or other countries that
equivalent efficacy but much reduced price[13]. have a major vested interest in the production, export and
rent generation associated with patented medicines. These
In this paper, we present a rationale and outline a draft include whether the strengthening of pharmaceutical
plan for a three-year study, funded by the Australian intellectual property protection and weakening of medi-
Research Council ('ARC'), which will examine the impact cines clinical and cost-effectiveness evaluation and/or ref-
of the AUSFTA on a range of regulatory, public health and erence pricing, necessarily involves a weakening of a
industrial interests involved with access to medicines in nation's social and economic fabric, or the capacity of its
Australia. An important initial point to make is that we population to age well and age productively.
consider the AUSFTA is best researched as a component of
an ongoing process of interaction with Australia's medi- Background: Australia's PBS in the Context of
cines policy by the global pharmaceutical industry. This the AUSFTA
trade agreement should be viewed, in other words, either Australia's pharmaceutical sector is dominated by the
as a catalyst that may enhance the speed of regulatory operation of the federally funded PBS, which, after a proc-
change, or a tangible manifestation of industry lobbying ess of clinical and cost-effectiveness evaluation contribut-
principles that, till now, may have been more implicit. It ing recommendations to price negotiation, provides
would be misleading, in any event, to investigate the AUS- reimbursement (currently approximately 75%) for
FTA's potential impacts on Australian medicines policy in around 80% of the prescription medicines used in Aus-
isolation of demonstrable long-term corporate strategies. tralia[15]. The PBS does not restrict market access, but
facilitates maximisation of sales volume for listed prod-
Some central issues our study will examine include to ucts. In developing relevant price indices, our study will
what extent the AUSFTA requires, facilitates, or is likely to also take into account AUSFTA impacts on prices for hos-
result in, changes to Australia's generic pharmaceutical pital-used medicines (which can be calculated from the
industry, as well as its PBS cost-effectiveness system of PBS reimbursement price less the minimum safety net
pharmaceutical regulation. We also aim to consider rele- value) and predict expenditure on medicines costed under
vant net welfare gain or loss; whether the Australian com- the co-payment level.
munity will get the same value-for-dollar spent on
medicines, either through Commonwealth government Central to our analysis of the impact of the AUSFTA on
reimbursement, hospital or patient purchase. medicines in Australia, however, will be an evaluation of
its effect on the PBS. Australia's PBS was established as a
We propose to investigate these questions empirically free formulary of essential drugs after the Second World
(and provide a sound structure for the gradual acquisition War by the Curtin-Chifley federal administrations[16]. It
of suitable data). This will be done first by identifying, was a social justice measure designed to ensure that all
with the assistance of qualitative interviews, actual or Australian citizens gained access to affordable, essential
likely AUSFTA-associated changes to the structure and medicines. Legislation to create the PBS had to survive two
process of Australia's PBAC, as well as the marketing proc- High Court challenges and required a successful Constitu-
esses, development and sector competitiveness of generic tional referendum[17]. Successive Commonwealth gov-
pharmaceutical manufacturers in Australia. This aspect of ernments used and built upon the 1940s enactments,
the study will also review the legitimacy of such actual or before a conservative party enacted the National Health Act
proposed alterations by examining the history of Aus- 1953 (Cth) ('National Health Act')[18]. This is an
tralia's PBS as a social justice measure designed to ensure extremely important point, that will be focused on by
universal access to essential medicines. We will also ARC research scholar Warwick Neville. The PBS is one of
Globalization and Health 2005, 1:15 http://www.globalizationandhealth.com/content/1/1/15

17. AG Vic (ex rel Dale and ors) v Cth (the Pharmaceutical Benefits Case) 1945, 41. Chaudhuri S, Goldberg PK, Jia P: The Effects of Extending Intellectual
71:CLR 237. Federal Council of the British Medical Association in Property Rights Protection to Developing Countries: A Case Study of the
Australia v Cth (1949) 79 CLR 201. Section 51xxiiiA inserted by Con- Indian Pharmaceutical Market Working Paper 10159 National Bureau
stitutional Referendum in 1946 of Economic Research; 2003.
18. Hunter T: 'Pharmaceutical Benefits Legislation'. The Economic 42. Branstetter LG: 'Do Stronger Patents Induce More Local inno-
Record 1965, 41:412-425. vation?'. In International Public Goods and Transfer of Technology Under
19. Hill S, Henry D, Pekarsky B, Mitchell A: 'Economic evaluation of a Globalized Intellectual Property Regime Edited by: Maskus KE, Reich-
pharmaceuticals: what are reasonable standards for clinical man JH. Cambridge University Press. Cambridge; 2005:309-320.
evidence – the Australian experience.'. British Journal of Clinical 43. Abbott FM: 'Managing the Hydra: The Herculean Task of
Pharmacology 1997, 44:421-5. Ensuring Acess to Essential Medicines'. In International Public
20. Henry DA, Hill SR: 'Assessing new health technologies: lessons Goods and Transfer of Technology Under a Globalized Intellectual Property
to be learnt from drugs.'. Medical Journal of Australia 1999, Regime Edited by: Maskus KE, Reichman JH. Cambridge University
171:554-6. Press. Cambridge; 2005:393-424.
21. Birkett DJ, Mitchell AS, McManus P: 'A Cost-Effectiveness 44. Sakakihara M, Bransteeter L: 'Do Stronger Patents Induce More
Approach to Drug Subsidy and Pricing in Australia'. Health Innovation. Evidence From 1988 Japanese Patent law
Affairs 2001, 20(3):104-114. Reforms'. NZEB Working paper 1999.
22. Mitchell A, Henry D: 'Is the drug 'cost-effective'?'. Australian Pre- 45. Pazderka B: 'Patent Protection and Pharmaceutical Research
scriber 1992, 15:74-5. and Development Spending in Canada'. Canadian Public Policy
23. Johannesson M, Henry DA, et al.: 'The Australian Guidelines for 1999, 23(1):29-64.
subsidisation of pharmaceuticals: the road to cost-effective 46. Faunce TA: Submission P5 to Parliament of Australia, Senate
prescribing?'. PharmacoEconomics 1992, 2:355-62. 422-6 Inquiry into Australia's Relationship with China 25 March
24. Harvey K, Murray M: 'Medicinal Drug Policy'. 2nd edition. Edited 2005. [http://www.aph.gov.au/Senate/committee/fadt_ctte/china/
by: Gardner H. The Politics of Health: The Australian Experience; submissions/sublist.htm]. last accessed 20 Sept 2005
1995:238. 47. Faunce TA: "Cashing in on our pharmaceutical expertise: A
25. Henry DA: 'Should Indirect Costs and Benefits be included?'. cost-effectiveness committee in the China-Australia FTA'
PharmacoEconomics 1992, 1:462-467. Canberra Times 11 April 2005. [http://www.bilaterals.org/arti
26. Hill SR, Mitchell AS, Henry DA: 'Problems with the Interpreta- cle.php3?id_article=1639]. last accessed 1 Oct 2005
tion of Pharmacoeconomic Analyses: A Review of Submis- 48. Faunce TA, et al.: 'Pharmaceutical Development, Reference
sions to the Australian Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme.'. Pricing Systems and Intellectual Property'. Medicine and Society
Journal of the American Medical Association 2000, 283:2116-21. 2005, 18(6):5-8. Chinese language publication
27. Australian Government. Productivity Commission 2003,
International Pharmaceutical Price Differences Research
Report [http://www.pc.gov.au/study/pbsprices/finalreport/]. last
accessed 11 September 2005
28. Drummond MF, Bloom BS, Freund DA, Evans D, Henry DA, Dittus R:
'Peer Review: Prescription Policy in Australia.'. Health Affairs
1992, 11(Winter):191-206.
29. US Department of Commerce, International Trade Admin-
istration. In Pharmaceutical Price Controls in OECD Countries. Implica-
tions for US Consumers, Pricing, Research and Development and Innovation
Washington DC; 2004.
30. Australian Government, Department of Foreign affairs and
Trade Australia-United States Free Trade Agreement. Full text, reports,
fact sheets, etc 2004 [http://www.dfat.gov.au/trade/negotiations/
us.html].
31. Faunce TA: 'FTA and the PBS:The Senate's Crucial Role' Aus-
tralian Policy Online 26 May 2005. [http://www.apo.org.au/link
board/results.chtml?filename_num=14643]. last accessed 1 Oct 2005
32. Faunce TA, Lokuge B: 'Sting in the Tail of the FTA.'. [http://
www.apo.org.au/webboard/results.chtml?filename_num=12465]. last
accessed 3 Oct 2005
33. Trachtman JP: 'The Domain of WTO Dispute Resolution'. Har-
vard Int L J 1999, 40:333-346.
34. Faunce TA: 'Global Intellectual Property Protection of Inno-
vative Pharmaceuticals: Challenges for Bioethics and Health
Law'. In Springer Dordrecht Edited by: Bennett B, Tomossy GF. Glo-
balisation and helath: Challenges for Bioethics and Health Law;
2005:87-107.
35. Faunce TA: 'Time to Gear Up for the Generic v Brand Name
Drugs Showdown'. Sydney Morning Herald 7 February 2005 [http:/
/www.healthyskepticism.org/library/2005.php]. last accessed 1 Oct
2005
36. O'Donoghue T, Scotchmer S, Thisse J-F: 'Patent Breadth, Patent
Life and the Pace of Technological Progress'. J of Economics and
Management 1998, 7(1):1-32.
37. Lerner J: 150 Years of Patent Protection, Harvard MA, Harvard Business
School Working Paper 2001.
38. Deardorff A: 'Welfare Effects of Global Patent Protection'.
Economica 1992, 59:35-51.
39. Nogues J: 'Patents and Pharmaceutical Drugs; Understanding
the Pressures on Developing Countries. World Bank Country
Economics Department 1990.
40. La Croix S, Kawaura A: 'Product Patent Reform and its Impact
on Korea's Pharmaceutical Industry'. Int Economics J 1996,
10(1):109.

You might also like