You are on page 1of 9

Local Government Expenditures: A Social Welfare Analysis

Author(s): James M. Henderson


Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics , May, 1968, Vol. 50, No. 2 (May, 1968),
pp. 156-163
Published by: The MIT Press

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1926191

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
Review of Economics and Statistics

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
LOCAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES:
A SOCIAL WELFARE ANALYSIS

James M. Henderson*

I Introduction using the concepts of the preceding section.


ANUMBER of economists have endeavored The behavior implications of estimates for
to "explain" one or more types of local metropolitan and nonmetropolitan counties are
government expenditures. Hawley [6], Brazer examined in the following two sections. A
[3], Hirsch [7], and Hansen [5] have been final section contains some concluding remarks.
prominent among these. Each has employed a
one-equation multiple-regression model to ex- II Community Welfare Maximization
press per capita local expenditures as a function Community Welfare Functions
of selected independent variables using cross-
The elected representatives of local govern-
section data. This paper also contains a mul-
mental units make many decisions on behalf
tiple-regression analysis of per capita cross- of the residents of their communities. Atten-
section data. However, two equations derived
tion is here centered upon their selection of
from explicit optimizing behavior are used.
local public expenditure and tax levels. The
The theory of collective choice through the
major exogenous variables which influence their
medium of a social-welfare function was in- decisions, but are not influenced by them in-
troduced by Bergson [2], and extended by clude personal income levels and revenues from
Samuelson [8], Arrow [1], and Graaff [4]. other governments, and population size.
Theil [9], has developed an elaborate empiri-
The analysis of expenditure and tax decisions
cally oriented analysis in which quadratic is focused upon two goods -or more accu-
social-welfare functions play a major role. rately, two types of expenditures - from which
Beyond this, social-welfare functions have sel- the members of a community derive satisfac-
dom served as a basis for empirical work.
tion: (1) public expenditures and (2) private
This paper attempts another move in the em- expenditures. In this context public expendi-
pirical direction. Some of the concepts of tures are limited to expenditures made by the
social-welfare analysis are applied to the ex- local government or governments being investi-
penditure and tax decisions of local govern- gated. Private expenditures are defined as per-
ments. The collective consumer is the popu- sonal income less local taxes and thus include
lace of a local area. Collective decisions are taxes paid to state and federal governments
made by elected representatives following the as well as consumption and savings.
rules of a democratic society. It is postulated A community's ordinal collective welfare, de-
here that the resultant public expenditure and noted by W, is expressed as a function of its
tax decisions can be explained as if they were per capita public and private expenditure levels,
the result of maximizing a social welfare func- denoted by G and X respectively:
tion subject to a social budget constraint, both
Wz= (ao+alY+a2R + a3P) logeG + X (1)
defined in expenditure space.
where Y is the community's per capita personal
Particular forms for social, or in the current
income, R is its per capita revenue from federal
context community, welfare functions and
and state governments, P is its population, and
budget constraints are assumed and the conse-
e = 2.71828 . . . is the base of the system of
quences of community welfare maximization
natural logarithms. The functional form (1)
examined in the next section of this paper. The
is termed "logex" since the variable G is raised
third section contains descriptions of data, pro-
to the power given by the expression in paren-
cedures and results for empirical analyses of
thesis and X enters as an exponent of e.1 The
United States counties on a cross-section basis
'The ordinal function (1) also can be written as
*The author is grateful to John C. Hause and Anne U = G(ao + ai Y + a2R + a3P)ex
0. Krueger for their helpful suggestions. after the transformation U = eW.

[ 156 ]

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
LOCAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES 157

general form of the welfare function covers all munity's welfare (1) subject to its budget con-
communities. The values of Y, R, and P may straint (3). Form the Lagrange function.
vary from community to community. Since L = (ao + alY + a2R + a3P) logeG
they are exogenous for the decision makers in
each community, the term in parenthesis in
+X-x(X+,BG-Y-/3R) (4)
(1) is a parameter. and set its partial derivates equal to zero,
DL (ao+al+a2R+a3P) _ =
Community Budget Constraints DG G
A consumer's expenditures are limited by DL
DX - 1-k = 0
the finance provided by his income, assets and
ability to borrow. Community expenditures are
similarly limited. They are financed by local aL - X +#G - Y -,BR = 0.
taxes, intergovernmental revenues and new Eliminating X = 1 the first-order conditions for
debt. The canons of local finance are sum-
community welfare maximization are
marized by the equation:
T= /(G-R) (2) G =A+ y + a2R + :3P
in which per capita local taxes, T, are assumed
X=Y-/3(G-R) (5)
to be a fixed proportion of the difference be-
tween local expenditures and intergovernmental together with the definitions
revenues. New per capita debt, denoted by D, T= Y-X
is the difference between local expenditures and D=G-T-R. (6)
local taxes plus intergovernmental revenues:
The second-order condition for constrained-
D =G - T - R = (1 - ,) (G - R). welfare maximization requires that the com-
If j8 = 1, local taxes would just cover expendi- munity indifference curve be convex. Differen-
tures not financed by intergovernmental rev- tiating (1) totally and substituting from (5),
enues and the community would incur no new the first and second-order conditions imply
debt. This is not the usual observed case, how- that
ever. Most local governments have increased d2X (ao + al Y+ a2R + a3P) ,B
debt rapidly in recent years to partially finance dG2 G2 G
capital expenditures. Hence, values for ,8 of Since both j8 and optimal values of G must be
less than unity appear normal.
positive for the system to be meaningful, the
Substituting T = Y - X in (2) and re- fulfillment of the first-order conditions will en-
arranging terms, the community budget con- sure fulfillment of the second-order condition.
straint can be expressed in terms of the same
variables as the community-welfare function:
III Empirical Estimates
X +P8G = Y +PAR. (3)
The Data
The left-hand side of (3) relates expenditures Estimates for the parameters of the first-
to income sacrifice. Each dollar of private ex- order conditions, (5) and (6), have been de-
penditure utilizes one dollar of income. Each rived from cross-section data for United States
dollar of local expenditures, however, requires counties. Per capita values for G, T, and R
a sacrifice of only ,B dollars for local taxes with are from the 1957 Census of Governments.2
the remaining (1 - ,) dollars financed by new These figures cover all of the local govern-
debt. Intergovernmental revenues are con- ments, i.e., cities, school boards, special dis-
verted to an income equivalent in a similar tricts and commissions, etc., within each
fashion on the right-hand side of (3).
2 See Local Government Finances and Employment in
Relation of Population: 1957, State and Local Government
Maximum Welfare Special Studies: Number 45 (Washington, 1961). The spe-
cific categories used are "total general expenditure" for G,
Local representatives are assumed to select
"total taxes" plus "charges and miscellaneous general rev-
values for G and X that maximize their com- enue" for T, and "total intergovernmental revenue" for R.

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
158 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

county. Corresponding county per capita per- and


sonal income data cover 1959 and are drawn T = .9046(G - R) R2 = .389
from the 1960 Census of Population.3 Personal (.1183)
income generally increased between 1957 and were P is measured in thousands of persons and
1959. However, the Census income data ap- the remaining variables in 1957 dollars per
pear to be underestimates on the basis of in- capita. The corresponding nonmetropolitan
dependent data for the United States as a equations are
whole. Therefore, the Census per capita income G- -20.8280 + .0819Y + 1.0371R - .2734P
data for 1959 were taken as true data for (2.7829) (.0020) (.0259) (.0203)
1957. County population levels for 1957 were R2 = .552,
derived from Census of Population data for and
1950 and 1960 by assuming constant annual T=.9651 (G-R) R2 - .377.
rates of change over the ten-year period. (.0229)

Each coefficient, except the constant in the


The Regression Equations metropolitan expenditure equation, is signifi-
Rewriting the local expenditure and tax cantly different from zero at a one per cent
equations of (5) and (6) in stochastic form, confidence level with a t-test.

ao +ali a a3
Gi = + p Y, + Rj + -3Pi + U*
IV Local Behavior

T, = (G, - Rj) + v, (7) The coefficient estimates presented in the last


section are used to draw inferences about the
where the subscript i denotes observations, and
behavior of local governmental bodies in metro-
ui and vi are disturbances. Simple least squares
politan and nonmetropolitan counties and be-
is appropriate for the expenditure equation.
havioral differences between the two groups
The tax equation has the dependent variable G
of counties. These inferences are prefaced by
on its right-hand side and simple least-squares
a brief comparison of the two groups of coun-
usually would provide inconsistent estimators
ties.
of /.4 Therefore, two-stage least squares are
used for the tax equation.5 The tax equation
County Characteristics
is also unusual in that its constant term is
forced to zero. The mean metropolitan and nonmetropoli-
The regression equations were fitted sep- tan counties are quite different. Foremost, the
arately for metropolitan and nonmetropolitan mean metropolitan county has a much larger
population and a much higher personal in-
counties. The 100 counties with the largest
1957 populations are defined as metropolitan. come than its nonmetropolitan counterpart-
692,580 people contrasted with 21,241 and 2172
The remaining 2,980 counties for which the
requisite data are available comprise the non- dollars per capita contrasted with 1334. The
metropolitan group. mean metropolitan county pays higher local
The metropolitan equations are taxes ($117.91 to $78.79), has larger local ex-
penditures ($170.11 to $130.85), and has
G = 9.9982 + .0439Y + 1.4231R + .0102P
(16.9620) (.0077) (.1376) (.0037) smaller intergovernmental revenues ($40.52 to
-2 = .651, $49.11). The mean nonmetropolitan county
carries a heavier local tax burden - 5.95 per
3 See Bureau of the Census, County and City Data
cent of personal income contrasted with 5.39
Book: 1962 (Washington, 19.62). Table 2 provides 1959
aggregate income and 1960 population on a county basis. per cent.
The 1960 population data were adjusted to 1959 by assum-
ing constant annual rates of change between 1950 and Expenditures, Taxes and Debt
1960.
'Simple least squares would yield a consistent esti- The coefficient ,8 gives the proportion of local
mator if us and v4 were independent. See Wold [10]. Un- expenditures not financed by intergovernmental
fortunately, this assumption does not hold in the present
revenue that are financed by local taxes. The
case.
' See Theil [9], 225-231. remaining proportion (1 - 8) is financed by

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
LOCAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES 159

new local debt. The estimated j3 coefficients TABLE 1. -RESPONSE OF ENDOGENOUS VARIABLES TO
PERSONAL INCOME INCREMENTS
are less than unity for both groups of counties
(dollars per dollar)
indicating that both use debt as a means of
finance. The coefficients, 0.9046 for the metro- Metropolitan Nonmetropolitan
Counties Counties
politan counties and 0.9651 for the nonmetro-
Local expenditures .0439 .0819
politan, suggest a greater reliance upon debt Private expenditures .9603 .9210
for the metropolitan. This differential is in Local taxes .0397 .0790
Local debt .0042 .0029
accord with expectations in that the metro-
politan counties are growing faster, have a
higher proportion of total expenditures for capi- ties. The income response differential of the
tal purposes which are traditionally financed two groups of counties is discussed further in
in part by debt, have better credit ratings than section V where income elasticities of demand
smaller units and can borrow at lower cost. for local and private expenditures are derived.
However, the metropolitan coefficient has a
relatively high standard error and a t-test at a Intergovernment Revenue Response
confidence level of 5 per cent does not reject It is clear from the local budget constraint
the null hypothesis that the sample data were that intergovernmental revenues are an income
drawn from distributions with the same mean equivalent.
,B. If they were a perfect income
equivalent, one would expect the same distribu-
Income Response tion of such revenues between local and private
The responsiveness of the endogenous va-i- expenditures as would be achieved from a per-
ables to changes in the exogenous are deter- sonal income increment of the same amount.
mined given the assumption that the first-order Most intergovernmental grants require that
conditions are always satisfied. Differentiat- their proceeds be used directly to finance local
ing (5) and (6) totally and solving for the expenditures. Federal grants, in particular, are
endogenous variables in terms of the exoge- often made on a basis whereby the recipient
nous: must provide matching funds for a particular
purpose, e.g., highways or urban renewal. Such
dG = -dY + a2dR + 3 dP rules limit the use of intergovernmental rev-
dX = (1-aL)dY- (a2-,8)dR-- a3dP enues for the expansion -of private expendi-
dT = al dY + (a2-/3)dR + a3dP tures. Nonetheless, it may be possible to in-
directly allocate intergovernmental revenues to
dD= LdY + 'Y-dR+!adP private expenditures by simply providing less
(8) for tax-financed expenditures. This process
where yl = a(l -8), 72 = (a2-,/) (1-/3) cannot be observed directly. However, the re-
and Y3 = a3(1 - 8). gression coefficients provide some indirect evi-
The coefficients a, and (1 -a,) give the dence.
distribution of a marginal dollar of personal Response coefficients based upon the regres-
income for local taxes and private expenditures sion equation estimates are presented in table
respectively assuming that dR -dP= 0. Es- 2. A marginal dollar of intergovernmental rev-
timates of these coefficients derived from the enue leads to more than one dollar of new local
regression equations are listed in table 1. They expenditures for both groups of counties.
indicate that a marginal income dollar gen- Hence, these revenues are less than perfect in-
erates a tax increase for the nonmetropolitan come substitutes for both. An intergovernmen-
counties twice as large as a similar increase tal revenue increase also leads to increases of
for the metropolitan - $0.0790 contrasted with local taxes and debt, and a reduction of pri-
$0.0397. Private expenditures are increased vate expenditures for both groups of counties.
less in nonmetropolitan counties. The expendi- The relative response rates for the two groups
tures differential is somewhat smaller than the of counties contrast with their personal income
tax differential because of the greater expan- response rates. The metropolitan counties show
sion of local debt by the metropolitan coun- a much larger response than the nonmetropoli-

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
160 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

tan - $1.4231 of new local expenditures per support to a value substantially in excess of
marginal grant dollar contrasted with $1.03 71 unity. Brazer's sample covered 462 cities with
for the nonmetropolitan. The metropolitan populations over 25,000 for 1950-1951. His
counties also increase local taxes and debt more other independent variables were population
and decrease private expenditures more. density and past population growth.

TABLE 2. -RESPONSE OF ENDOGENOUS VARIABLES TO Population Response


INTERGOVERNMENT REVENUE INCREMENTS Population increments, with per capita per-
(dollars per dollar)
sonal income and grants fixed, have opposite
Metropolitan Nonmetropolitan
effects upon the two sets of counties. The
Counties Counties
metropolitan counties increase per capita local
Local expenditures 1.4231 1.0371 expenditures, taxes and debt, and reduce pri-
Private expenditures -.3827 -.0358
Local taxes .3827 .0358
vate expenditures as population increases. The
Local debt .0404 .0013 nonmetropolitan reduce local expenditures,
taxes and debt, and increase private expendi-
tures.
Unity provides a departure point for evalu-
The reduction of per capita local expendi-
ating local expenditure response to intergov-
tures with population increase is very marked
ernmental revenues. A value less than unity
for the nonmetropolitan counties, $0.2734 per
would be prima-facie evidence of the ability
thousand of population. This may be the re-
of communities to divert intergovernmental
sult of decreasing costs in the provision of pub-
revenues indirectly to private expenditures. If
lic services. A small community must provide
a grant requires y dollars of locally financed
many public services at relatively high per
local expenditures per dollar of grant, a coeffi-
capita costs which decline as its population in-
cient greater than unity but less than (1 + y)
creases. Education, hospitals, police and sew-
would also indicate a form of diversion. It is
age removal normally are examples. In each
not possible to estimate y directly. However,
case marginal cost is below average cost as
matching requirements are widespread and it
total service level increases.
appears reasonable to presume a value greater
than zero. TABLE 3. - RESPONSE OF ENDOGENOUS VARIABLES TO
The values of the local-expenditure response POPULATION INCREMENTS
coefficients given in table 2 are suggestive with (dollars per capita per thousand people)
respect to the problem of intergovernmental
Metropolitan Nonmetropolitan
revenue diversion. The coefficient for the non- Counties Counties

metropolitan counties, $1.03 71, is close to unity Local expenditures .0102 -.2734

and may well be less than (1 + y). If so, there Private expenditures -.0093 .2638
Local taxes .0093 -.2638
is diversion for the nonmetropolitan. Local debt .0009 -.0096
The metropolitan response coefficient,
$1.4231, appears to be much larger than any
The average per capita cost for many pub-
reasonable value for (1 + y). Rather than
lic services may eventually increase. The
diversion, the metropolitan response suggests
metropolitan local expenditure response coeffi-
an element of "bandwagonism" in that the re-
cient is positive but much smaller in absolute
ceipt of grants may induce metropolitan coun-
value than the nonmetropolitan - $0.0102 in-
ties to commit local funds beyond matching re-
crease of per capita local expenditures per
quirements to projects that would not otherwise
thousand population increase. The largest
have been undertaken.
metropolitan county had a 1957 population in
Harvey Brazer obtained an intergovernmen-
excess of five million. The population coeffi-
tal revenue coefficient of 1.740 dollars with
cient suggests that its per capita local expendi-
total operating expenditures per capita as the
tures would exceed that of the smallest by
dependent variable.6 His results thus add some
more than fifty dollars given identical per-
'See [31,25. sonal income and grant levels. The costs of

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
LOCAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES 161

very large size and congestion may be substan- (a1-al) Y


tial. -(ao+a3P) + (1-al) Y- (a2-,(&)R
There is a reinforcing, or perhaps alternative, Elasticities for the expenditures with respect to
explanation of increasing per capital local ex- intergovernment revenue are derived from (8)
penditures with size for the metropolitan coun- with dY= dP 0:
ties. The larger communities provide a broader
DG R a2R
range of services than the smaller ones. There
DR G (ao+a3P) +alY+a2R
are many services that a small community (10)
cannot or need not provide. Therefore, the resi-
aX R
dents of the larger communities may receive
EX? R X
more per capita services for their larger per
(a,2-/3) R
capita expenditures as well as paying more for
-(ao+a3P)+(1-al)Y- (a2-/3)R
the same services provided in smaller metro-
politan areas. Unity is not an appropriate standard for thes
Brazer [3] concluded that city population elasticities. In general, an expenditure elas-
size was not a significant variable in the de- ticity is a ratio of marginal and average ex-
termination of per capita expenditures. He penditure rates. Thus, it is above unity if the
found a simple relationship between expendi- marginal rate exceeds the average and below
tures and population, but his population vari- unity if the average exceeds the marginal. The
able lost significance once other variables such marginal rates for the above elasticities are
as population density and past population each defined in terms of only one of two income
growth rate were included in his regression components -Y for (9) and R for (10). In
equations. Hirsch [7] found that population both cases the average rate reflects expendi-
was not a significant variable for communities tures from both income components. Hence,
within the St. Louis metropolitan area. Ex- (9) and (10) give partial elasticities.
periments with density and growth variables
Total Income Elasticities
such as those used by Brazier instead of popu-
lation were unsuccessful. Total income, denoted by Y*, is defined as
The conclusions of this study stand in con- the sum of the two income components:
trast to those of Brazer and Hirsch. Popula- Y* = Y + ,3R. Total income elasticities are
tion size is a significant variable. The impor- derived by assuming that Y and R change in
tance of the population variable appears to be proportion to their average ratio, i.e., R = uY,
a result of the stratification of counties into dR = udY and dY* = dY + /dR where u is
a constant:
metropolitan and nonmetropolitan groups. A
regression equation was fitted for the 462 coun- =EGY alY+a2R EGy + EGt
ties with the largest 1957 populations to allow (ao+a3P) +alY+ca2R
comparison with Brazer's results. The popu- (11)
lation variable was not significant at a 5 per (1 -al) Y-(a2-13)R
cent confidence level. EX =^ - (ao+a3P) + (1-al) Y- (a2-/3)R
- EXY + EXR
The total elasticities thus are sums of the par-
V Income Elasticities for Local Services
tial elasticities.
Partial Elasticities The average of the G and X total elasticities,
Elasticities for local and private expendi- using the respective expenditure weights ,G/Y*
tures with respect to personal income are de- and X/Y*, is unity. Hence, unity is a mean-
rived from (8) with dR -dP = 0: ingful standard for evaluation of the total elas-
aG Y a1Y ticities. If the term (ao + a3P) is positive,
aY G (ao+a3P)+alY+a2R zero or negative, EGY* will be less than, equal
(9) to or greater than unity respectively, and cor-
ax V respondingly Exy* will be greater than, equal
'Exy ay DX to or less than unity. The observed expenditure

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
162 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

weights for private expenditures are about ten ficient together with the nonmetropolitan means
times as great as those for local expenditure. yields a partial elasticity of 0.534; the non-
Hence, deviations of EGy* from unity will be metropolitan coefficient together with the met-
about ten times as large as deviations of EXy* ropolitan means yields 0.247.
from unity. The total elasticities reflect relative prefer-
ences, i.e., are greater than unity, for private
Empirical Elasticities expenditures for the mean metropolitan county
Partial and total income elasticities were and for local expenditures in the mean non-
computed by inserting regression coefficients metropolitan county. This may suggest that
and mean values of the variables in the elas- the poorer metropolitan counties have greater
ticity equations. These are presented in table unfilled needs for local services as witnessed
4*7 The wide differential between the personal by their willingness to sacrifice marginally more
private expenditures than the metropolitan.
TABLE 4. -PARTIAL AND TOTAL INCOME ELASTICITIES
FOR MEAN METROPOLITAN AND NONMETROPOLITAN
COUNTIES VI Concluding Remarks

Metropolitan Nonmetropolitan
This paper began with the assumption that
COy .561 .835
local expenditure and tax decisions could be ex-
eol .339 .389
plained as if local representatives maximized
eGy* .900 1.224 logex local welfare functions subject to local
budget constraints. The consequences of such
eXY 1.015 .979
constrained maximization have been derived
exR -.008 -.001

exy* 1.007 .978


and coefficients for first-order conditions esti-
mated by the application of two-stage least
squares to county data for metropolitan and
income partial elasticities is a result of the wide nonmetropolitan areas. None of the coefficients
difference in the regression coefficients (ac/f8) violated expectations as to sign and order of
noted in the last section. The differential ratios
magnitude, and all but one constant are signifi-
of personal income to local expenditures works
cantly different from zero at a one per cent
in the opposite direction. A partial elasticity
confidence level. The logex is only one of many
computed from the metropolitan coefficient and possible forms for a local welfare function.
the nonmetropolitan personal income-local ex-
Some other function may provide a better and
penditure ratio is 0.448 which is even lower
perhaps substantially different analysis.
than that obtained from the metropolitan ratio.
Comparisons based upon the regression equa-
The situation is somewhat different for the
tion coefficients show four major differences
intergovernmental revenue partial elasticities.
between the metropolitan and nonmetropolitan
The regression coefficient (a2/,8) is much counties: (1) the nonmetropolitan are more
higher for the metropolitan counties, but the
responsive to per capita personal income incre-
corresponding partial elasticity is much higher
ments with intergovernmental revenues and
for the nonmetropolitan. This follows from a
population constant, (2) the nonmetropolitan
large difference in the intergovernmental rev-
have a relative marginal income preference for
enue - local expenditure ratio - 4.198 for the
local over private expenditures and the metro-
metropolitan counties contrasted with 2.664 for
politan have a relative income preference for
the nonmetropolitan. The metropolitan coef-
private, (3) the metropolitan are more respon-
Since the tax equations have zero constant terms, they sive to per capita intergovernmental revenue
are not necessarily satisfied by the means of their variables. increments with personal income and popula-
Therefore, in lieu of means, values of X were calculated by
inserting the mean values of Y and G in the tax equations
tion constant, and (4) nonmetropolitan per
and subtracting these calculated T values from the mean capita local expenditures decrease with popula-
personal income levels. The differences between these calcu- tion increments with personal income and
lated values and the means for T and X are small - $0.13
for the metropolitan counties and $0.10 for the nonmetro-
grants constant and metropolitan per capita
politan. expenditures increase with population. In con-

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
LOCAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES 163

trast with other recent studies population is a [4] Graaff, J. de V., Theoretical Welfare Economics,
significant variable. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1957).
[5] Hansen, N. M., "The Structure and Determinants
A final word of caution is in order. All of of Local Public Investment Expenditures," this
the conclusions of this paper are based upon REVIEW (May 1965), 150-162.
cross-sectional county data for a single year. [6] Hawley, A. H., "Metropolitan Population and
Municipal Government Expenditures in Central
A time-series analysis might yield different
Cities," in P. K. Hatt and A. J. Reiss, Jr. (eds.),
conclusions. Cities and Society, revised, (Glencoe, Ill.: Free
Press, 1957), 773-782.
[7] Hirsch, W. Z., "Expenditure Implications of
REFERENCES Metropolitan Growth and Consolidation," this
REVIEW (Aug. 1959), 232-241.
[1] Arrow, K. J., Social Choice and Individual Values, [8] Samuelson, P. A., Foundations of Economics Anal-
(New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1951). ysis, Cambridge, Mass., 1947.
[2] Bergson, A. (A. Burk), "A Reformulation of Cer- [9] Theil, H., Economic Forecasts and Policy, 2nd
tain Aspects of Welfare Economics," Quarterly ed. (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co.,
Journal of Economics (Feb. 1938), 310-334. 1961).
[3] Brazer, H. E., City Expenditures in the United [10] Wold, H. 0. A., "A Generalization of Casual
States, National Bureau of Economic Research, Chain Models," Econometrica (Apr. 1960), 443-
Occasional Paper 66, New York, 1959. 463.

This content downloaded from


179.56.48.212 on Tue, 25 May 2021 21:43:41 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like