You are on page 1of 13

World Development Vol. 40, No. 4, pp.

808–820, 2012
Ó 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.09.021

Consumers’ Welfare and Trade Liberalization: Evidence


from the Car Industry in Colombia
JORGE TOVAR *
Universidad de los Andes, Bogotá, Colombia
Summary. — This paper examines the effects of tariff removal on consumers’ welfare focusing on the Colombian trade liberalization
process and its automobile industry. Using product level data this paper calculates the post-reform gains in consumers’ welfare to be
just below three thousand dollars per purchaser. Counterfactual simulations suggest that the gains achieved are due, for the most part,
to increased variety rather than to price competition.
Ó 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — trade liberalization, trade reforms, consumer surplus, automobiles, Latin America, Colombia

1. INTRODUCTION Arab boycott on the Israeli car industry led to a “per-pur-


chaser gain of approximately US$2,243”. Brambilla (2007)
Trade theory predicts that intensified international competi- measures the effect of adopting a customs union in the auto-
tion leads to efficiency gains on consumers’ welfare. 1 How- mobile market in Argentina and Brazil. She finds that under
ever, an overview of the existing empirical literature suggests a customs union, prices in Argentina will be lower, while
that although such gains may actually exist, it has rarely been consumers would be better off. The opposite is true for Brazil.
explicitly quantified. In fact, in a survey on the topic, Tybout Clerides (2008) reports average consumers’ gains of US$2.000
(2003) concludes that the expected benefits of free trade on per purchaser when used cars were authorized to massively
consumers have been for the most part inferred from the re- enter the Cyprian market. 4
sults, not directly measured. 2 This paper contributes in filling In the Colombian case, I focus on the automobile market
such a gap by quantifying consumers’ gains from a trade lib- and, using data prior and after the 1990s trade reforms, quan-
eralization process in the context of an oligopolistic market tify the effects of such reforms on consumerś surplus taking
with differentiated products. into account the effects of foreign competition. Specifically,
The Colombian case offers an excellent opportunity to study using prices, characteristics, and car sales in Colombia be-
such effects given the way the reforms were implemented. The tween 1986 and 1998, a discrete choice random utility model
trade reform was initially planned in the last quarter of 1990 is adopted to econometrically estimate demand. 5 A GMM
and scheduled to be gradually implemented over a four-year framework deals with the potential correlation between prices
period. However, by the second half of 1991, policy makers and unobserved car characteristics enabling consistent de-
did not observe the projected effects and decided to immedi- mand estimates. These estimates are then used to compute
ately (and unexpectedly) reduce tariffs to the levels expected the consumer surplus over the thirteen year period. Theory
in 1994. This unique feature, the fact that prior to 1992 no for- predicts that lower tariffs and stronger competition should
eign cars were available and that the number of domestic firms positively impact on consumers’ surplus. The source of such
remained constant over the entire sample period, allows for gains is originated in the associated increase in the number
the analysis of the effects of the liberalization process free of of product varieties generated by the trade reform. Indeed evi-
possible restrictive trade endogeneity issues. dence of this is found. The increased variety and lower car
The expected correlation between trade reforms and con- prices improved consumers’ welfare by almost three thousand
sumers’ welfare is tested using a discrete choice model, an ap-
proach widely used in the industrial organization literature to
estimate welfare effects in given markets but relatively uncom- * This paper is part of my Ph.D. dissertation in economics at the
mon when exploring international trade issues. 3 These models University of California, Berkeley. I wish to thank my advisor Aviv Nevo
are powerful in that they allow the researcher to quantify the and my dissertation committee members Aaron Edlin and Ann Harrison
consumers’ surplus given an exogenous shock. For instance, in for their suggestions, support, and helpful discussion. I also wish to thank
an early application to international trade, Berry, Grilli, and Richard Gilbert, Rebecca Hellerstein, Maurice Obstfeld, Sofia Berto
López de Silanes (1992) forecast the expected growth of the Villas-Boas, the editor, two anonymous referees, and participants in the
Mexican car industry in an attempt to anticipate the effects Industrial Organization and International Trade Seminars at UC Berkeley
of NAFTA. They conclude that economic growth joint with for helpful comments. Financial support from Colombia’s Central Bank,
a decline in prices toward international levels would expand Banco de la República fellowship for Graduate Studies in Economics
the Mexican auto market. Abroad, the UC Berkeley Summer Fellowship and Dean’s Fellowship is
The closest methodological applications to mine are those gratefully acknowledged. I am also grateful with Ann Harrison’s private
found in Fershtman and Gandal (1998), Brambilla (2007) research account in the Agricultural and Resource Economics Department
and Clerides (2008). As I do, they study and quantify the effect for funding my visit to Colombian Auto Firms. Finally, I am indebted to
of trade related shocks on consumers’ welfare. They differ in the Center of Latin American Studies at Stanford University for its
the specific empirical model used and the trade shock studied. hospitality while working on the revised version of the paper. All errors
Fershtman and Gandal (1998) estimate that the end of the are my own. Final revision accepted: August 12, 2011.
808
CONSUMERS’ WELFARE AND TRADE LIBERALIZATION 809

dollars per purchaser compared to the pre-reform period. requirements, and a series of taxes required when “nationaliz-
Counterfactual simulations suggest that such gains are mostly ing” the car made it impossible in practice.
explained by the increased number of car models available in Given that domestic firms assemble but do not produce cars
the market once the reform was implemented. in Colombia, most of its inputs are imported. The imported
Although extremely useful in its ability to quantify the effect materials known as CKD, which stands for Completely
of a major trade reform on consumers’ welfare, the use of Knocked Down, represent around 70% of a fully assembled
product level data comes at a cost. 6 The literature on the ef- car. Throughout the period of analysis (1986–98) the main reg-
fects of trade on growth, productivity, and welfare can be di- ulation changes were related to the 1991 structural reforms.
vided into three general categories: Cross country regressions, Prior to the reforms, the government intervention in the car
cross industry regressions, and product level analysis. 7 The market began to be relaxed, particularly in the second half
latter has no saying in productivity, growth, or labor realloca- of the 1980’s. Among other things, for example, a new con-
tions, especially given the characteristics of the car industry in tract unifying the operational conditions of all three firms in
Colombia (discussed later in Section 2). the market was signed in 1988.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section In 1991, as part of the reforms, the government authorized
2 describes the Colombian trade liberalization process and the entry of new firms willing to assemble cars, it eliminated
presents the specifics of its auto industry. Section 3 lays out the import license requirements for CKD units and reduced
the demand and supply model. Section 4 describes the data the tariffs for both CKD and imported or completely built up
while Section 5 discusses the estimation strategy. Section 6 re- (CBU) cars. Firms were allowed to freely assemble as many
ports and discusses the results. Finally Section 7 concludes. models and versions as they wanted, as long as they guaran-
teed the supply of auto parts and service for each model for
a period of at least 10 years. However, even today, there are
2. TRADE REFORM AND THE CAR INDUSTRY only three firms assembling cars, the rest are simply importers
IN COLOMBIA of ready to sell vehicles. Moreover, as in the 1980s, once the
reform was implemented, each of the Colombia firms retained
Following international trends, many Latin American coun- its only assembly plant. Thus, the trade reform had no effect
tries undertook international policy changes in the early 1980s. on plant closings or, for that matter, on layoffs at a significant
In Colombia, however, although some very timid liberaliza- scale.
tion measures were taken at the time, it was not until 1991
when deep structural fiscal, labor, monetary, and trade re-
forms were actually implemented. 8 Previously, high tariffs 3. THE MODEL
and various types of nontariff barriers prevailed in all sectors
of the economy making imported products scarce and expen- The use of disaggregated data offers several advantages.
sive to buy. By 1989, the outgoing government took initial First, physical output is observed as opposed to revenue, typ-
steps to open the economy, but different internal and external ically used when using industry (or plant) level data. Second,
events prevented any serious reforms from being implemented. competition is not inferred, but directly observed as imported
Therefore, it was not until 1990, when the recently elected cars entered the market. Third, the approach is powerful en-
Gaviria Administration designed a four-year program to grad- ough to fulfill the main objective of the paper: estimate the ex-
ually lower tariffs. In October 1991 the gradual program was pected gains in consumers’ welfare due to the trade
terminated and Colombian policy makers decided to abruptly liberalization process. 11
lower tariffs, breaking the program designed months earlier. 9
Tariffs were set, in the last quarter of 1991–94 expected levels. (a) Demand model
Among other reasons, the stagnation of both imports and ex-
ports induced government analysts to believe that economic The demand model described here is derived from McFad-
agents were postponing any investment decision until the mo- den’s (1978) generalized extreme value model (GEV) as devel-
ment when tariffs were at their lowest levels. Once tariffs were oped by Bresnahan et al. (1997). The product differentiation
taken down they did not vary substantially. general extreme value (PD GEV) model allocates each alterna-
During the sample period (1986–98) three companies were tive to one nest along each of pre-selected dimensions. It is
the sole assemblers (not producers) of cars in Colombia. The based on the notion that markets for differentiated products
three companies are Compañı́a Colombiana Automotriz exhibit increased cross-elasticity due to nesting relative to
(CCA), assembler of Mazda; Sociedad de Fabricación de Auto- dimensions. This paper differentiates characteristics along
motores S.A. (Sofasa), assembler of Renault and General Mo- two dimensions: origin (domestic vs. foreign) and size as per-
tors Colmotores S.A. (GM Colmotores), assembler of General ceived by engine displacement (small, medium, large).
Motor vehicles. The most commonly used version of GEV models is the
The oldest and historically largest firm, Colmotores, was nested logit. Motivated by different questions, Goldberg
founded in 1956. As part of GM, the company assembles (1995) and Goldberg and Verboven (2001) use a multi-level
and sells in Colombia Chevrolet’s, Opel’s, and Suzuki’s mod- and a two-level nested logit, respectively, to estimate demand
els under the Chevrolet make. CCA, the second oldest firm, for cars. 12 Similarly, also for cars, Berry, Levinsohn, and
was founded in 1960. Fiat models were produced until 1983 Pakes (1995), Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1999), Petrin
when the company was authorized to switch to Mazda’s. By (2002) and Brambilla (2007) use a random coefficient logit ap-
1993, the entire company was owned by Mazda. Sofasa was proach to determine demand estimates.
established in the late 1960’s with the creation of a joint society The main advantage of the PD GEV model over the nested
between the Colombia Government and Renault. By the end logit model is that while in the latter the order of the nests
of the sample period the company was owned by Renault, matters, in the former it does not. The nested logit model im-
Toyota, and Mitsui. 10 Therefore, prior to 1991 no imported plies that all alternatives are grouped into pre-determined
cars were sold massively in Colombia. Although it was legal mutually exclusive nests. This means that given two categories,
to import cars, barriers such as high tariffs, import license origin and size, a change in price on say, a small Colombian
810 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

car, will have the same effect on shares on a medium Colom- the conditions stated in Appendix 1, the model is consistent
bian car and over a large Colombian car. The PD GEV over- with random utility maximization for all possible values of
comes this limitation. the explanatory variables as long as qO and qS lie in the unit
In principle, the random coefficient logit model allows for interval. 14
flexible substitution patterns without a priori segmenting the Letting O(j) and S(j) denote the groups to which product j
market. As argued by Nevo (2000), this advantage comes at belongs, and using G(.) from Eqn. (2), the following share
a cost. First, the expression for the share function is solved equation is derived:
via simulation as opposed to the close form of the PD P P
GEV model. Second, detailed information about consumer aO eV ij =qo ð k2OðjÞ eV ik =qo Þqo 1 þ aS eV ij =qs ð k2SðjÞ eV ik =qs Þqs 1
sij ¼
heterogeneity is required to compute the market shares. GðeV i Þ
Third, Petrin (2002) notes that a very rich dataset set is re-
ð3Þ
quired in order to obtain precise estimates. Given the limita-
tions of the dataset, only 926 observations and no consumer Eqn. (3) is the probability that consumer i buys car j and is
heterogeneity available beyond income, I choose to use the composed of two terms, one for origin and one for size. It im-
PD GEV model. plies that for any car j, a change in the price or characteristics
The model used is relatively standard in the literature. 13 As- of any other product located in the same cluster will have a
sume that the conditional indirect utility function for con- stronger impact on product j than on any other product lo-
sumer i for product j in market (period) t depends on cated in a different cluster. The parameter q is a measure of
observed product characteristics (xjt), unobserved (to the re- the degree of independence in unobserved utility among the
searcher) product characteristics (njt), income (yit), price (pjt), products in nest n. That is, as q tends to zero, the dependence
and unknown parameters hjt. Building on a Cobb Douglas across products that share a particular nest become stronger.
utility function, Berry et al. (1995) showed that the following Conversely, if qs = 1, the model reduces to a nested logit by
functional form may be used to study the consumers’ decision origin status only. Similarly if qo = 1, the model reduces to
problem: a nested logit by size status only. Eqn. (3) is the close form
solution to the integral presented in Eqn. (A.1).
U ijt  a lnðy it  pjt Þ þ xjt b þ njt þ eijt Finally, the expression for Sij has to be aggregated up to
djt ¼ xjt b þ njt ð1Þ the product market share function. While aggregating in-
i ¼ 1 . . . I; j ¼ 1 . . . J ; t ¼ 1 . . . T come and population data available for Colombia are used.
Ten equally sized deciles are defined and the per capita in-
where eijt is defined below. Note that yit, as in Berry et al. come of consumers within each income class is computed,
(1995) and Goldberg and Verboven (2001) among others, is that is income is ‘common’ within each decile, but varies
individual specific. The way how this is dealt with is discussed across deciles and, of course, over time. This approach
below. resembles that of Goldberg and Verboven (2001). That is,
The djt term is common to all consumers and is, therefore, Eqn. (3) is calculated for the average consumer in each in-
referred to as the mean utility, a is the marginal utility from come class and the summation generates the aggregate mar-
income and b represents specific taste characteristics. Correla- ket share.
tion between the price and the unobserved product character-
istics is expected because when the price is set, the producer (a) The supply side
takes into account these (observed by the firm) characteristics.
When estimating the model, this endogeneity issue will be ta- The effect of the trade reform on consumers’ welfare can be
ken into consideration. As discussed in detail in Appendix 1, directly estimated by comparing the post-reform welfare with
the pre-reform welfare. Given the way that trade liberalization
eV ij Gj ðeV io ; . . . ; eV iJ Þ was implemented in Colombia, this seems like a valid way to
S ij ¼
GðeV io ; . . . ; eV iJ Þ calculate the (expected) positive effects. However, a simple
comparison between periods simultaneously captures both
is the market share equation of product j, where Vij = aln(yi the price and variety effects. In order to disentangle these ef-
 pj) + dj and Gj is the partial derivative of G with respect fects the following question should be answered: how much
to eVij. G(.) is defined as the weighted sum of two one-level would have consumers’ welfare changed if no imported cars
nested multinomial logit G(.) functions: had entered the market?
" !qO !qO # The counterfactual exercise is described in detail later on.
X X For now, note that in order to be able to perform such an exer-
Vi V ij =qO V ij =qO
Gðe Þ ¼ aO e þ e cise it is necessary to derive an equilibrium condition.
j2d j2f
Assume that in any given year t, there are F firms, each of
" !qS !qS which produces some subset Jf, of the j = 1. . .J different makes
X X
þ aS e V ij =qS
þ e V ij =qS of cars. The firms profit function is given by
j2s j2m
X
pf ¼ ðpj  mcj ÞMsj ðpÞ  C f
!qS # Jf
X
V ij =qS
þ e þ eV i;outside ð2Þ
j2l
where mcj is the marginal cost, Cj is the fixed cost of produc-
tion and M is the total market size. 15 The standard derivation,
presented in Appendix 2, yields in matrix notation:
ð1  qO Þ ð1  qS Þ
aO ¼ ; aS ¼
ð2  qO  qS Þ ð2  qO  qS Þ ðp  mcÞ ¼ X1 sðpÞ ð4Þ

where O denotes origin (domestic (d) or foreign (f)) and S where as is common in the literature, X is defined as the own-
stands for size (small (s), medium (m) or large (l)). Under ership matrix 16.
CONSUMERS’ WELFARE AND TRADE LIBERALIZATION 811

Table 1. Summary statistics means (sales weighted) (standard deviation in parenthesis)


No. of Models Pricea HP/Wb Engine Dimensiond ACe Power windowse Power door lockse Radioe Alloy wheelse
displacementc
1986 18 22,988 0.078 1.516 6.836 0.091 0.152 0.093 0.107 0.034
(6,571) (0.013) (0.337) (0.874) (0.296) (0.369) (0.299) (0.318) (0.185)
1987 23 25,082 0.079 1.508 6.831 0.177 0.243 0.267 0.268 0.132
(7’,967) (0.011) (0.377) (0.910) (0.389) (0.438) (0.452) (0.452) (0.345)
1988 19 23,522 0.078 1.459 6.652 0.275 0.416 0.242 0.224 0.137
(8,073) (0.013) (0.382) (0.989) (0.458) (0.506) (0.440) (0.428) (0.353)
1989 21 21,111 0.078 1.462 6.675 0.281 0.406 0.205 0.326 0.122
(6,801) (0.013) (0.365) (0.976) (0.460) (0.503) (0.413) (0.480) (0.334)
1990 27 20,815 0.079 1.473 6.718 0.212 0.390 0.319 0.354 0.150
(6,756) (0.012) (0.358) (0.911) (0.416) (0.496) (0.474) (0.487) (0.363)
1991 26 18,434 0.080 1.464 6.663 0.195 0.298 0.272 0.329 0.134
(6,349) (0.009) (0.333) (0.880) (0.404) (0.466) (0.453) (0.479) (0.347)
1992 71 19,415 0.082 1.508 6.889 0.289 0.325 0.238 0.360 0.363
(10,185) (0.013) (0.345) (0.722) (0.456) (0.471) (0.429) (0.483) (0.484)
1993 82 19,922 0.083 1.509 6.941 0.294 0.406 0.282 0.433 0.333
(9,778) (0.014) (0.353) (0.723) (0.458) (0.494) (0.453) (0.498) (0.474)
1994 122 18,679 0.082 1.447 6.823 0.308 0.367 0.282 0.447 0.401
(7,876) (0.0129) (0.317) (0.719) (0.463) (0.483) (0.452) (0.499) (0.492)
1995 127 17,986 0.081 1.425 6.736 0.276 0.348 0.287 0.401 0.492
(7,730) (0.013) (0.295) (0.671) (0.449) (0.478) (0.454) (0.492) (0.501)
1996 133 16,533 0.081 1.386 6.601 0.299 0.265 0.230 0.403 0.466
(7,083) (0.0123) (0.262) (0.664) (0.460) (0.442) (0.422) (0.492) (0.500)
1997 142 15,897 0.083 1.386 6.591 0.188 0.240 0.237 0.472 0.427
(6,379) (0.012) (0.239) (0.674) (0.392) (0.428) (0.426) (0.501) (0.496)
1998 115 14,444 0.086 1.418 6.653 0.328 0.274 0.227 0.547 0.463
(6,341) (0.012) (0.246) (0.709) (0.471) (0.448) (0.421) (0.500) (0.501)
1986–98 926 18,862 0.082 1.448 6.735 0.259 0.318 0.249 0.390 0.335
(8131) (0.013) (0.314) (0.771) (0.438) (0.465) (0.433) (0.488) (0.472)
1986–91 22 22,300 0.079 1.480 6.729 0.205 0.317 0.233 0.268 0.118
1992–98 113 17,437 0.083 1.440 6.748 0.283 0.318 0.255 0.437 0.421
a
Price in 1996 dollars.
b
HP/W: measured in Horse Power (HP) per Weight (in kilograms).
c
Engine displacement measured in cubic liters.
d
Dimension is width*length. Square meters.
e
Indicator variables, 1 if it has the characteristic as standard equipment, 0 otherwise.

4. DATA DESCRIPTION AND PRELIMINARY As a principle of differentiation, rather than using the cars
RESULTS dimensions (as used for example by Goldberg, 1995), I choose
engine displacement as measured by cubic centimeters (CC).
The dataset contains information on prices and characteris- My choice is based on the fact that automobiles are legally
tics per model sold in Colombia during 1986–98. Indicator classified in Colombia according to CC, among other things,
variables for whether the car has air conditioning (AC), power for insurance purposes. Additionally, consumers perceive
windows, power mirrors, power seats, alloy wheels, power many models differently, despite sharing the same chassis
door locks, assisted steering wheel, and radio as standard and body, because they are equipped with different engines.
equipment were obtained from Motor magazine. 17 Other Such vehicles have the same dimension, they look alike, but
product characteristics, obtained from each models brochure they actually belong to a different segment.
going back to 1986, include the car dimensions (length, width, During the sample period six hundred thousand cars were
and height), weight, engine displacement, horsepower, and the sold. It was possible to match price, quantity and characteris-
number of doors. tics to most of the cars in the dataset. However, it was not pos-
The price variable is the list price as shown in several issues sible to identify 24,406 cars because they show up as others in
of the Colombian Motor auto magazine. All prices are deflated the quantity dataset. Following Berry et al. (1995) a model/
by the consumer price index and are in 1996 Colombian pesos, year is treated as an observation. This results in a total sample
though the results, for ease of comparison, are presented in size of 936 observations. Additionally, no price information
1996 US dollars. The sales variable corresponds to sales in was available for ten observations, and so the final sample size
Colombia. is composed of 926 observations.
The estimations presented below use only the available data In addition, there are data available on tariffs, the value
on automobiles, by far, the most common type of vehicle sold added tax of each model and a real exchange rate index. 19
in Colombia. Prior to 1992, SUV’s and pickups sales repre- Tariffs vary by country of origin and engine displacement.
sented on average less than 20% of the market. Once the re- For a completely built up (CBU) car the corresponding tariff
forms were implemented, the sales share of automobiles was is that of a fully assembled, ready-to-sell vehicle. These are
never below 70%. 18 imported cars. For a domestically assembled car the tariff
812
Table 2. Summary statistics (sales weighted)
(i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix)
Pricea CKD (input) CBU (imported car) Tariffs Sales Real exchange Number of Market Shared Number of
tariffsb tariffsc tax rate index Models Offered Cars Sold
Domestic Foreign Small Medium Large Domestic Small Medium Large Total Domestic Foreign
1986 22,988 19.94 200.00 19.94 26.55 113.96 18 – 5 8 5 100.00 31.28 46.47 22.25 29,150 29,150 –
1987 25,082 20.66 200.00 20.66 26.86 114.77 23 – 6 10 7 100.00 43.62 30.11 26.27 34,277 34,277 –
1988 23,522 19.52 200.00 19.52 25.95 113.78 19 – 6 6 7 100.00 47.54 27.04 25.42 36,775 36,775 –

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
1989 21,111 20.24 218.00 20.24 26.88 120.60 21 – 6 8 7 100.00 47.68 30.07 22.25 30,471 30,471 –
1990 20,815 20.53 116.00 20.53 27.35 130.99 27 – 7 11 9 100.00 48.47 28.79 22.74 25,786 25,786 –
1991 18,434 19.45 75.00 19.45 26.45 114.75 26 – 7 11 8 100.00 45.14 34.04 20.82 22,206 22,206 –
1992 19,415 3.00 38.83 13.20 28.50 108.71 27 44 13 28 30 71.53 44.36 36.09 19.55 34,230 24,485 9,745
1993 19,922 3.00 38.12 18.38 28.80 110.29 23 59 14 36 32 56.22 42.60 39.89 17.51 62,324 35,037 27,287
1994 18,679 3.00 35.00 15.92 27.16 102.87 25 97 21 63 38 59.62 52.66 35.10 12.24 72,452 43,199 29,253
1995 17,986 3.00 35.00 14.96 26.48 104.46 28 99 26 67 34 62.64 56.67 35.00 8.33 66,191 41,462 24,729
1996 16,533 3.00 35.00 14.21 26.28 100.00 36 97 30 71 32 64.97 64.98 30.82 4.21 61,442 39,921 21,521
1997 15,897 3.00 34.64 18.12 27.12 92.77 32 110 37 81 24 52.01 53.62 44.04 2.34 74,687 38,999 35,688
1998 14,444 3.00 34.83 19.53 27.81 100.99 25 90 29 74 12 48.07 39.01 57.27 3.73 59,643 28,670 30,973
1986–91 22,300 20.06 168.17 20.06 26.67 118.14 22 – 6 9 7 100.00 43.96 32.75 23.29 29,778 29,778 –
1992–98 17,437 3.00 35.92 16.33 27.45 102.87 28 85 24 60 29 59.29 50.56 39.74 9.70 61,567 35,968 25,599
1986–98 24.74 10.87 96.96 18.05 27.09 109.92 25 85 16 36 19 78.08 47.51 36.52 15.97 46,895 33,111 25,599
a
Price in 1996 US dollar.
b
Tariffs for the CKD units used by domestic producers (%).
c
Tariff for imported cars (%).
d
As defined by total sales.
CONSUMERS’ WELFARE AND TRADE LIBERALIZATION 813

Table 3. Summary statistics tic firms despite an increase in overall variety. If such is the
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. case, an increase in consumers’ surplus should be expected.
One could even try to push the argument a little further: fol-
Sales tax 32.41 7.33 20 45 lowing the predictions of recent trade models domestic firms
Real exchange rate index 109.21 23.78 8.75 187.89
are dropping their least successful models (Bernard, Redding,
Tariffsa 26.82 13.48 3 40
& Schott, 2011). However, it would be necessary to further
CKD tariffsb 11.05 10.86 3 30
explore the models predictions in detail such as within firm
Assembled car tariffsc 58.69 54.27 31.5 218
composition changes and, even then, nothing can be said in
a
If domestic car, CKD tariffs. If imported car CBU tariffs. terms of exports given that during the sample period domestic
b
Tariffs for main components of domestically assembled cars (the CKD firms did not enter foreign markets. 20
unit). The data also show that prices in Colombia, in the 1980’s,
c
Tariffs for imported cars (CBU).
were abnormally high for international standards. In 1986
the mean price of a car was, in 1996 US dollars, almost
corresponds to that of its main input, the completely knock $23,000 while the average price for a car in the United States
down or CKD units. at the time was around $18,000. 21 By 1992, average prices in
Tables 1–3 provide summary statistics for the key variables. Colombia were over nineteen thousand dollars, approximately
Table 1 presents information on the main characteristics. a thousand dollars higher than in the US. At the end of the
These include horsepower per kilogram (HP/W), dimension, sample period, on average a car could be bought in the US
AC, power windows, power door locks, radio, engine displace- paying just over nineteen thousand dollars. In Colombia, that
ment, and alloy wheels. HP/W proxies for fuel efficiency as year, the average price of a car was less than fifteen thousand
well as for power; it is expected to affect positively the utility dollars (See Figure 1). 22
of a consumer. Dimension is defined as length times width. As shown in Fig. 2, even when adjusting for quality, prices
The effect is not clear, though one tends to believe that on fell significantly by 1992. In fact, when comparing the pre-
average individuals prefer bigger cars. Finally, engine reform (1986–91) and the post-reform (1992–98) periods, qual-
displacement is measured in liters and the indicator variables ity-unadjusted prices fell on average by 22% (column (i), Table
(1 if standard equipment, 0 if not) show how, on average, 2), while quality-adjusted prices dropped on average by 42%.
characteristics have changed over time. The quality adjusted trend is similar when considering the
This first overview of the data clearly illustrates the struc- two principles of differentiation. 23
tural changes observed in the market once the reforms took Immediately after the trade reforms were implemented, the
place. Both Table 1 and Figure 1 show significant changes be- number of cars sold increased. The 50% annual average
tween the pre-reform (1986–91) and the post-reform period growth rate observed during 1992–94 contrasts with the en-
(1992–98). On average, 22 models were offered during 1986– tire’s sample period 10% average growth rate. As imports in-
91. By 1992, 71 different car models were offered, peaking creased, the market share of domestic firms dropped. On
142 in 1997. average, importers gained in seven years over 40% of the car
Table 2 (column vi) shows that the number of domestic mod- market in Colombia.
els increased moderately despite foreign competition. In fact, A closer look at the data reveals that the number of domes-
during the early years of the reforms, the number of models of- tic cars sold expanded with the reforms for a short period of
fered by domestic firms fell to levels similar to those observed in time (Figure 1). Sales of domestically produced cars increased
the period 1986–89. This contrasts with the overall increase in from an average of less than thirty thousand cars per year
variety. That is, the addition of new models exceeds the number prior to the reforms to a peak of forty three thousand in
of drop outs. This could potentially be explained by stronger 1994. Since then, sales of domestically assembled cars steadily
product-market competition and the expansion of the potential dropped. By 1998, only 28,670 domestically assembled cars
market due to lower prices. It could be argued that this behav- were sold, less than in 1986.
ior follows the predictions suggested, at least, since Krugman Table 2 also shows the evolution of tariffs during the sample
(1980): a reduction in the number of models offered by domes- period. As noted earlier, both the CBU and CKD units’ tariffs

Evolution of Prices and Units Sold


1986-1998
26.000 80000

24.000 70000

22.000
60000
Prices (1996 dollars)

20.000
50000
Units Sold

18.000
40000
16.000
30000
14.000

12.000 20000

10.000 10000
1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998

Price (Left Axis) Total Units Sold (Right Axis) Total Colombian cars sold (Right Axis)

Figure 1. Evolution of prices and units sold 1986–98.


814 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Quality adjusted price


1986=1

1.4
1.2
Ïndex
1
.8
.6

87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98
Source: Author's calculations Year
Dotted lines are 95% confidence interval.

Figure 2. Quality adjusted price 1986=1.

fell substantially. The former dropped from an average of A second set of instruments is based on Bresnahan (1981,
200% in 1986 to 34% in 1998. The latter dropped to 3% from 1987) assumption that the observed characteristics xjt
an average of almost 20%. As noted earlier, such high tariffs are exogenous (or predetermined) and thus uncorrelated
were key in explaining why no foreign cars were imported with the unobserved characteristics, therefore, satisfying
prior to 1992. Eqn. (A.4). 26 Bresnahan et al. (1997) follow a similar
approach, but exploit their assumption about the group struc-
ture of product differentiation.
5. ESTIMATION OF THE MODEL Therefore, this second set of instruments is based on the idea
of the exogeneity of observed product characteristics and of
The predicted market share derived in Eqn. (3), analytically the number of models available in the market per period.
obtained by solving the integral in Eqn. (A.1), is a function of These are the average value of the characteristics by cluster
observed and unobserved product characteristics, as well as (origin and size) and by shared cluster. The total number of
prices (details are provided in Appendix 3). cars sold per cluster is also used. The latter are competition
The estimation of Eqn. (A.5) requires instrumental variables based instruments in that they assume that the number of cars
that satisfy Eqn. (A.4). The ideal instruments would be (mod- available in the market each year is correlated with prices but
el-level) cost data. However, beyond the average cost of not with unobserved characteristics. These guarantee instru-
assembling a car for each of the three domestic firms there ment variation at the product level.
was no access to direct cost data. This would be a valid, It should be noted that instruments based on nonprice char-
though insufficient instrument if the objective were to estimate acteristics of competing products are, potentially, problematic.
demand exclusively prior to 1992 when only domestic produc- However, as noted by Einav and Levin (2010) so is the main
ers served the market. 24 alternative used in the literature, the use of prices in other mar-
Fortunately, some cost related data are available. Given kets. 27 The intuition behind the use of the price of a car in
that (after 1991) imported cars represent a significant share alternatives markets as a valid instrument is that such price
of total sales and that the main inputs of domestically pro-
duced cars are also imported both a real exchange rate index
and import tariffs are used as instruments. Table 4. Demand estimates
The advantage of using exchange rates and tariffs as instru-
ments is that they are clearly exogenous to the car industry PD GEV estimate (S.E)
and that they both exhibit variation over time and across a 4.381 (1.504)**
car segments. These instruments are not model specific, but qo 0.619 (0.203)***
they differ across segments generating the necessary within qs 0.483 (0.279)*
year variation. Tariffs vary by (i) country of origin (CKD Domestic 0.708 (0.193)***
for domestic cars, CBU for imported cars) and by the (ii) en- Small 0.886 (0.153)***
gine displacement of the car, that is larger cars pay larger tar- Medium 0.363 (0.092)***
iffs. Dimension 1.257 (0.568)**
Similarly, the exchange rate varies per country of origin and HP/W 3.789 (2.314)*
over time. 25 The sales tax, also used as an instrument, varies AC 0.015 (0.071)
too by engine displacement and over time. It has the same Pwr Windows 0.159 (0.082)*
advantages and disadvantages of the aforementioned. Thus, Constant 19.491 (5.200)***
given the way the instruments are constructed, it is possible GMM 31.550
to include year time effects in the estimation in order to cap- Robust standard errors in parenthesis.
ture any industry-level shocks that might have occurred during *
Significant at 10% level.
**
the sample period. These instruments, however, are not suffi- Significant at 5% level.
***
cient for identification. Significant at 1% level.
CONSUMERS’ WELFARE AND TRADE LIBERALIZATION 815

is driven by the underlying costs. Thus, they are a valid proxy sumers to prefer domestically produced cars, given similar
for unobservable model/year specific costs. 28 characteristics.
This approach is not feasible in the current context and, fur- The results also show stronger preferences for small cars (in
ther, it does not guarantee a better cost proxy. There are seri- terms of engine displacement) relative to medium and large
ous operational shortcomings when trying to match the price cars. This might seem as a rather unexpected result as one
of each model/year price in the dataset with a corresponding would expect that, everything else constant, consumers would
match in other markets. First, prices would have to be gath- prefer larger cars. However, large cars (high CC) tend to con-
ered from various alternative countries because not all cars sume more gasoline and pay higher insurance rates. Since there
were sold simultaneously in all markets during the sample per- is no explicit data on either of these variables, it is likely that
iod. This is problematic because to make prices comparable this dummy variable captures such effect thus implying that
across markets (countries), exchange rates for every country consumers will tend to prefer a small rather than a large car.
would need to be used. But exchange rates are, at least par- Table 4 estimates are, therefore, those used to calculate the
tially, driven by macroeconomic events specific to each coun- consumers’ welfare. Nevertheless, it is well known in the dis-
try which empirically are not possible to control for. But, even crete choice literature that the decision of which characteristics
if it were possible to control for, the mere existence of unob- to include is ad hoc. In results not reported, I find that the
served shocks in other markets would violate the original model is robust to the choice of characteristics. 30
assumption: prices in other markets would not be a valid An alternative model would include brand dummies as in
proxy for costs. Nevo (2001). 31 The idea is that some components of the unob-
A second operational shortcoming is related to the quality served characteristics can be captured by these firm fixed
of the price data available in different countries. Typically, effects. 32 They are expected to capture time invariant character-
only list prices are available. But these may (as in many istics that vary by car maker. The results are reported in Table 5.
Europeans countries for instance) or may not (as in the As before, the marginal utility of income has the correct sign
USA) include the sales tax (or any other tax for that matter). and it is statistically different from zero and both qo and qs lie
Identifying this in a large number of countries during a period in the unit interval. The domestic dummy remains statistically
of 13 years can be extremely burdensome. Lastly, there is an significant, though the effect is smaller. In a relatively immature
availability issue. The data used in this paper go back to market, with only three traditional domestic firms, consumers
1986; matching this historical data was not possible for such do not differentiate substantively between firms. 33 Thus, firm
a long period of time. fixed effects are capturing effects already captured by the in-
Another potential alternative could be the use of price cost cluded domestic dummy. In terms of engine displacement, med-
margins in other markets. This was not feasible because of the ium cars are not statistically preferred to large cars. Foreign
lack of correspondence between Colombian models/years and firms entered the markets with a relatively small number of
those estimated by the literature (Brambilla, 2007, Berry, models, generally allocated with a given car segment. Given that
Levinsohn, and Pakes, 1999 or Goldberg & Verboven, 2001 on average they serve the Colombian market for just 5 years, it
among others). 29 Moreover, most of the literature estimated seems reasonable to believe that the firm effects are capturing ef-
these PCM using as instruments either of the above methods. fects already captured by the size dummies. Thus, given the spe-
In such a case we would be back to square one. cific structure of the car market in Colombia during the sample
period, the preferred estimates are those reported in Table 4.

6. RESULTS (a) Consumers’ welfare and trade liberalization

The results of the PD GEV model are presented in Table 4. A natural way to capture the effect of the trade liberalization
The coefficients are precisely estimated and appear to be rea- process on consumers’ welfare is to compare the post-reform
sonable from an economic point of view. The results suggest welfare versus the pre-reform welfare. 34 Taking advantage
that individuals prefer bigger cars as well as high horse power of the introduction of new (previously unavailable) foreign
relative to weight. The coefficient on power windows is negative models into the market, it can be argued that the difference
in every specification ran, remaining as the only counterintui-
tive result. Finally, the marginal utility of income has the cor-
rect sign and it is statistically different from zero and both qo
and qs lie in the unit interval as required to be consistent with Table 5. Demand estimates (firm fixed effects)
utility maximization. The estimated coefficients of these PD GEV estimate (SE)
parameters suggest that there is indeed a significant degree of
market segmentation along both origin and size dimensions. a 4.854 (2.860)*
The positive and statistically significant coefficient for the qo 0.498 (0.272)*
domestic dummy variable implies an outward shift of the de- qs 0.493 (0.213)**
mand curve if a car is Colombian made. The observed home Domestic 0.659 (0.180)***
bias means, given qo less than one, that a car will enjoy certain Small 0.363 (0.142)***
degree of protection against foreign competition if it is domes- Medium 0.187 (0.121)
tically produced. A likely explanation for this result is related Dimension 0.759 (0.641)
to the distribution network. The lack of foreign imports in HP/W 2.466 (2.592)
Colombia during the 1980s implied that when foreign firms en- AC 0.056 (0.073)
Pwr Windows 0.059 (0.077)*
tered the market in the 1990s they had to start from scratch.
Constant 19.568 (9.573)***
Not only did they have to set up a distribution network across
GMM 41.4
the country, they also had to import accessories and spare
parts which made them more expensive and (particularly in Robust standard errors in parenthesis.
*
the early nineties) were not as readily available as the Colom- Significant at 10% level.
**
bian counterparts. A combination of these factors made con- Significant at 5% level.
***
Significant at 1% level.
816 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 6. Welfare (1996 dollars) Table 7. Welfare improvements due to the existence of foreign cars in the
market (Observed Welfare minus Counterfactual Welfare) (1996 US$)
1986 4,772
1987 4,069 Counterfactual Counterfactual with
1988 4,512 with fixed price new equilibrium price
1989 2,817 1992 1,153 1,441
1990 2,008 1994 2,222 2,765
1991 1,746 1996 2,485 2,975
1992 3,067 1998 3,082 3,142
1993 7,913 1992–98 2,791 2,929
1994 6,841
1995 6,331 Source: Authors calculations.
1996 7,091
1997 7,551
1998 5,299 W Ctfl ðN D Þt1 is the per purchaser consumer surplus calculated
1986–91 3,321 when only domestic cars are available in the choice set (ND)
1992–98 6,299
and prices remain fixed to actual market prices. Under this
1986–98 4,924
scenario, the first column of Table 7 presents the difference
Source: Authors calculations. between the observed consumer welfare and the (new) esti-
mated welfare under the counterfactual assumptions. In the
first year of the reforms, the gains in consumer welfare are
represents the effects of the trade reforms. Given that prices small as few foreign models were available and because
fell (Figures 1 and 2) and that the number of models offered expensive luxurious cars accounted for a large part of the
increased (Table 2), theory suggests that consumers’ welfare imported vehicles. The gains per purchaser quickly rose by
should rise after 1992. As discussed in Clerides (2008), the 1994 when they reached US$2,222. Overall my estimates
Ackerberg and Rysman (2005) critic that discrete choice mod- suggest that the gains per consumer due to the availability
els tend to overestimate welfare gains from the introduction of of imported cars in the Colombian market (increased variety)
new goods does not apply here because such problem is only were around $2,800. 35
severe in “situations where the new goods are priced outside The next step is to relax the assumption that prices of
the range of previously unobserved prices”. For the most part, domestic cars remained unchanged in the absence of imported
this is not the case here. vehicles. 36 To do so, I need to re-compute the new equilibrium
The results in Table 6 suggest that, as expected, consumers’ price using Eqn. (4) assuming that only domestic cars were
surplus increased after the reforms took place. The average available in the Colombian market. The estimated (average)
consumer surplus difference between the post-reform and increase in the price of domestic vehicles is estimated to be just
pre-reform period was just below three thousand 1996 dollars. below 4%. I recalculate Eqn. (5) where W Ctfl ðN D Þt1 is defined as
These gains are per purchaser per year. The aggregate implica- before but the expected higher prices due to the (simulated)
tions are discussed below. Thus, as theory predicts, trade lib- lack of foreign completion is now taken into account.
eralization has a positive effect on consumers’ welfare. The second column of Table 8 reports welfare gains per pur-
Given the way that the trade liberalization process was chaser using this new set of prices. As prices are higher, the
implemented in Colombia the above strategy is valid and estimated consumer’s surplus per purchaser decreases, and,
one could argue it is enough to prove the hypothesis. It com- therefore, the welfare gains of introducing imported vehicles
pares the before and after were the main difference is the exis- in the market are slightly greater than those estimated with
tence of imported cars in the post-reform period. Thus, the fixed price. The average (estimated) increase in consumer wel-
difference in consumers’ surplus is explained by the introduc- fare per purchaser is $2,929.
tion of such foreign cars. When comparing the figure estimated under the fixed price
But theory suggests that there are two channels through assumption, one concludes that most of the welfare gains for
which trade liberalization can benefit consumers: price reduc- consumers came from variety, not from price changes. In fact,
tions and variety increase. The results reported in Table 6 say these results suggest that 95.3% of the welfare gains come in
nothing about this, they just quantify the increment in ob- the form of increased variety. This figure is larger than that re-
served consumers’ surplus. Thus, to grasp a complete view ported by Fershtman and Gandal (1998) who find that variety
of the effects of the reforms I ask what the consumers’ welfare explains 84.6% of consumers’ welfare gains. Contrary to the
would have been in the absence of imported vehicles. In order Colombian case (where no foreign vehicles were offered prior
to implement this counterfactual scenario all foreign models to 1992), in Israel, during the Arab Boycott, there were some
are removed from the available choice set, the market shares American and European imports, plus gradually some Japa-
of domestic cars alone are re-computed and consumer surplus nese and Korean cars entered the market. Arguably, the thirst
is re-estimated. for variety was stronger among Colombian consumers than
Given the unavailability of foreign vehicles before the re- among Israeli’s.
forms, the counterfactual exercise is only relevant from 1992 Furthermore, note that welfare gains represent around
onward. In such a case, the demand model discussed earlier re- 17% of the average post-reform price of a car. As before,
duces to a one level nested logit where the principle of differ- Fershtman and Gandal (1998) report a lower figure, 9.5%.
entiation is only size. Initially, assuming that prices and The same explanation applies. Gains are relatively more valu-
characteristics remain unchanged when the choice set is re- able for Colombia consumers.
duced to domestic cars only, Eqn. (5) is calculated. The aggregate figures are also significant. The gains to con-
W Obs ðN Þt1  W Ctfl ðN D Þt1 ; t1 ¼ 92; 93; . . . ; 98 ð5Þ sumers represent in 1997 (when sales peaked) 0.28% of GDP.
Considering that this represents the gains obtained by just one
Obs
where W ðN Þt1 refers to the per purchaser consumer surplus sector, the automobile industry, the effect is considerable. This
calculated earlier for N, the entire choice set in period t1. figure is similar to that found by Clerides (2008) for Cyprus
CONSUMERS’ WELFARE AND TRADE LIBERALIZATION 817

were the gains of admitting used cars into the market was cal- quantify total domestic welfare on the car industry, this paper
culated to be 0.24% of Cyprus GDP. Fershtman and Gandal would have to be extended in order to quantify the effects of
(1998), who focus on the end of the Arab Boycott on Israel the reforms on firms’ profits. No doubt this is an interesting
finds, a slightly larger number: 0.30% of Israeli GDP. question and the model derived in this paper would be useful
in such a task. However, fixed cost data, relatively hard to ac-
quire given the historical data used, are necessary to properly
7. CONCLUSION estimate profits. This is an ongoing project to complete the
picture not done in other similar events already described
This paper analyzes the effects of the early 1990s trade liber- above.
alization reforms that were implemented in Colombia. The re- Second, the paper is focused on one, albeit important, sector
sults of this natural experiment suggest that the reforms had a of the economy. A study of the overall impact of the trade re-
significant impact on the car industry. As tariffs were reduced, forms are out of the scope of this paper. Since the dawn of eco-
previously unavailable foreign cars were introduced into the nomic theory, it has been clear that international trade has
market and car prices dropped. As a consequence, relative winners and losers. The findings in this paper show that, given
to pre-reform levels, consumers’ welfare increased on average a durable, relatively expensive good, the increased variety had
by almost three thousand dollars per purchaser. Such gains a clear impact on consumers’ well being. In this case, it is clear
are, for the most part, explained by an increase in product that no plants were closed and no significant labor realloca-
variety as opposed to the decline in prices. tions occurred. But nothing can be said in terms of the impact
Despite the positive effects of the reforms, it is worth noting of the liberalization process on productivity or on the overall
that these effects are partial in at least two ways. First, to effect on the economy. The latter, remains an open question.

NOTES

1. See for instance Krugman (1980) and Melitz (2003) discussion on 11. An obvious drawback, as pointed out earlier, is that only one
consumers’ welfare improvement due to increased variety. particular market is analyzed. It is common, however, for trade
agreements to give a different treatment to certain sectors, particularly
2. Tybout’s review is mostly interested in how trade reforms affect firms’ the auto sector.
performance. (Grether, 1996; Haddad, De Melo, & Horton, 1996;
Harrison, 1994; Muendler, 2002; Pavcnik, 2002; Roberts, 1996; Tybout, 12. Goldberg and Verboven (2001) also attempt to estimate their model
1996). He reports mix results, stronger when using plant level data, weaker using a PD GEV, but they report that this model did not find support in
when using industry level data. their data.

3. Classic nontrade applications are available in Berry, Levinsohn, and 13. Although standard, it is worth reviewing the basics because the PD
Pakes (1995), Nevo (2001) and Petrin (2002). GEV share function has its own specifics.

4. Other trade—related uses of these discrete choice models include the


14. Train (2003) shows that for q > 1 the model is still consistent with
analysis of the effects of Japan’s voluntary imposition of export restraints
utility maximizing behavior for some range of the explanatory variables
to the US Goldberg (1995) finds that the VER were binding in the first
but not for all values.
years after they were imposed, while Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1999)
finds the opposite.
15. The market size is assumed to be the number of households that,
5. Random utility in the sense discussed in detail by Train (2003) and given their income, could at least buy the cheapest car each year. This is
applied by, for instance, Bresnahan, Stern, and Trajtenberg (1997). For approximately 80% of Colombian total households.
reasons explained in detail later on, this paper does not estimate a random
coefficient model. 16. The model, of course, has certain limitations. As in all other papers
referenced earlier that focus on the auto industry, the new car market is
6. The working paper version also deals with market performance as modeled as if used cars do not matter and if consumers were not forward
measured byprice—cost margins. At the suggestion of one of the referees I looking when buying durable goods. These restrictions are in good part
have narrowed the objective of the paper to one specific effect: gains in due to data unavailability of used cars, thus it is not possible to follow
consumers’ welfare. up the stock of such type of vehicles. In the Colombian case, however,
this is probably of less concern than when studying mature markets
7. An overview of cross-country regressions can be found in Harrison because of the relatively small size of the market during the sample
(1996), Frankel and Romer, (1999), and Rodrı́guez and Rodrik (2000). period.

8. See Garay et al., 1998. 17. Specifically I used the website www.motor.com.co, Internet version
of the specialized Colombian auto magazine Motor. Earlier years required
9. The program aimed to lower tariffs from an aggregate average level of the printed version.
around 25% in 1990, to a level of 11% in 1994.
18. Though sales information for both SUV’s and pickups was available,
10. Renault owned 60% of the company, Toyota 28% and Mitsui 12%. unfortunately characteristics data was not.
818 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

19. Tariffs data are provided by the National Planning Department and 29. In most cases, the sample period does not even match with that in my
the value added tax by the Ministry of Finance. The real exchange index paper.
was constructed on a per country of origin basis (CKD, when the car is
domestic) using each country’s CPI and the nominal exchange rate. This 30. The results are reported in the working version of the paper. Two
strategy guarantees that all three variables vary within and across years. robustness tests were performed. First, given its nonsignificance, the air
conditioning dummy was dropped from the main specification. Second,
20. A detailed explanation on the behavior of the number of models dimension is excluded because one might be concerned that both size
offered is out of the scope of this paper. I should emphasize that my (measured as engine displacement) and dimension (measured as length
objective is to study the effects of such increase in variety on consumers’ times width) are included. In both cases, the results from the preferred
welfare, not on explicitly explaining the changes in such variety. However, specification are valid as the estimated coefficients do not change
both referees did note that the post reform slight increase in the number of significantly.
models offered by Domestic firms is a characteristic worth pointing out. A
referee suggested that this could be related to a productivity increment as 31. Unlike in my case, Nevo (2001) has to deal with the fact that
discussed by Eckel and Neary (2010). However, these authors also predict observed characteristics vary very little across markets.
a reduction in product variety. And although such reduction is observed in
1993, the trend seems relatively stable afterward. A complementary 32. At the suggestion of a referee a specification using model fixed effects
argument is the one suggested by Bernard et al. (2011) and discussed in the was ran but it was not supported by the data, that is no convergence was
text. achieved.

21. The average US price is from the US Department of Commerce, 33. For instance, for the US, Train and Winston (2007) find that
Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts. consumers care more about the characteristics of the cars than on brand
loyalty.
22. Prices for US cars are not adjusted for quality due to the lack of US
detailed information. 34. Consumer surplus is estimated following the principles described in
Trajtenberg (1989).
23. I thank a referee for suggesting this exercise.
35. To avoid confusion recall that earlier I found the increase in
24. It is insufficient because there is no production or assembly cost data consumer welfare to be $2,978 per purchaser, when comparing the pre and
for imported vehicles. post reform period. The $2,791 figure should be taken as the increase in
consumers’ welfare due to a variety increase (from foreign vehicles) in the
25. I exploit the fact that the CKD is the 70% of a cost of a domestically Colombia market.
assembled car. Thus origin of the CKD determines the origin of the
domestically assembled car. 36. I will however keep the assumption that characteristics of domestic
cars are the same independent of the availability of foreign cars. Given the
26. This is particularly true in the Colombian case because both domestic trend of characteristics observed in Table 1, it seems a plausible
firms and importers are very small players relative to the world auto assumption.
industry. As a consequence, they have no power to influence over the
design of cars and their corresponding characteristics. 37. Specifically G(.) has to be nonnegative, homogenous of degree r,
(where r P 0), lim. G(.) ! 1 as eVj ! 1, for j = 0. . .J, and mixed
27. Used for instance in Hausman, Leonard, and Zona (1994) and Nevo partials of G(.) must alternate in sign with first partial nonnegative.
(2001).
38. Particularly when dealing with models where nonlinearities arise.
28. Although market is defined in this paper as year (Eqn. (1)), in this
particular context I refer to other countries as other “markets”. 39. The J products plus a normalized outside good.

REFERENCES

Ackerberg, D., & Rysman, M. (2005). Unobserved product differentiation Bresnahan, T. (1981). Departures from marginal-cost pricing in the
in discrete choice models: Estimating price elasticities and welfare American automobile industry: Estimates for 1977–1978. Journal of
effects. RAND Journal of Economics, 36, 771–788. Econometrics, 17, 201–227.
Bernard, R., Redding, S., & Schott, P. (2011). Multi-product firms and Bresnahan, T. (1987). Competition and collusion in the American
trade liberalization. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(3), automobile industry: The 1955 price war. Journal of Industrial
1271–1318. Economics, 35, 457–482.
Berry, S. (1994). Estimating discrete choice models of product differen- Bresnahan, T., Stern, S., & Trajtenberg, M. (1997). Market segmentation
tiation. Rand Journal of Economics, 25, 242–262. and the sources from rent innovation: Personal computers in the late
Berry, S., Grilli, V., & López de Silanes, F. (1992). The Automobile 1980’s. Rand Journal of Economics, 28, S17–S44.
Industry and the Mexico–US Free Trade Agreement. NBER Working Clerides, S. (2008). Gains from trade in used goods: Evidence from
Paper No. 4152. automobiles. Journal of International Economics, 76(2), 322–336.
Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., & Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market Eckel, C., & Neary, J. (2010). Multi-product firms and flexible manufac-
equilibrium. Econometrica, 63, 841–990. turing in the global economy. Review of Economic Studies, 77, 188–217.
Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., & Pakes, A. (1999). Voluntary export restraints Einav, L., & Levin, J. (2010). Empirical industrial organization. A
on automobiles: Evaluating a trade policy. American Economic Review, progress report. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(2), 145–162.
89(3), 400–430. Fershtman, C., & Gandal, N. (1998). The effect of the Arab boycott on
Brambilla, I. 2007. A Customs Union with Multinational Firms: The Israel: The automobile market. The Rand Journal of Economics, 29(1),
Automobile Market in Argentina and Brazil. Mimeo. Older 193–214.
version available as NBER working paper No. 11804, November Frankel, J., & Romer, D. (1999). Does trade cause growth? American
2005. Economic Review, 89(3), 379–399.
CONSUMERS’ WELFARE AND TRADE LIBERALIZATION 819

Garay, L., Quintero, L., Villamil, J., & Tovar, J. (1998). Colombia: U ðxjt ; njt ; pjt ; eijt ; hÞ P U ðxrt ; nrt ; prt ; eirt ; hÞ; for r ¼ 1 . . . J
Estructura Industrial e Internacionalización. 1967–1996, DNP-
MINCOMEX.
Goldberg, P. (1995). Product differentiation and oligopoly in international The model must take into account the possibility that consum-
markets: The case of US automobile industry. Econometrica, 63(4), ers may not want to buy a new car. Ignoring this possibility
891–951.
Goldberg, P., & Verboven, F. (2001). The evolution of price dispersion in
would imply that an even change in the price of all cars will
the European car market. Review of Economic Studies, 68(4), 811–848. have no effect over demand and so, the substitution patterns
Grether, J. (1996). Mexico, 1985–90: Trade liberalization, market struc- would be biased. Let Ajt be the set of values for e such that
ture, and manufacturing performance. In M. Roberts, & J. Tybout the consumer decides to buy good j.
(Eds.), Industrial evolution in developing countries (pp. 260–284). The
World Bank, Oxford University Press. Ajt ¼ fe : U ðxjt ; njt ; pjt ; eit ; hÞ P U ðxrt ; nrt ; prt ; eit ; hÞ;
Haddad, M., De Melo, J., & Horton, B. (1996). Morocco, 1984-1989:
Trade liberalization, exports and industrial performance. In M. for r ¼ 0; 1; . . . J g
Roberts, & J. Tybout (Eds.), Industrial evolution in developing countries
(pp. 285–313). The World Bank, Oxford University Press. Assuming ties occur with zero probability, and given P0(e), the
Harrison, A. (1994). Productivity, imperfect competition and trade density of e in the population, the market share of the jth good
reform. Journal of International Economics, 36, 53–74. as a function of the J + 1 goods competing in the market is:
Harrison, A. (1996). Openness and growth. Journal of Development Z
Economics, 48, 419–447. sjt ðx:t ; p:t ; n:t ; hÞ ¼ P o ðeÞ ðA:1Þ
Hausman, J., Leonard, G., & Zona, J. (1994). Competitive analysis with e2Ajt
differentiated products. Annales D’Économie et de Statisque, 34,
160–180. where xt = (x1t,. . .,xJt). Similarly for p and n. Dropping the t
Krugman, P. (1980). Scale economies, product differentiation, and the subscript, and defining M to be the size of the market, the J-
pattern of trade. American Economic Review, 70(5), 950–959. vector of demands is Msj(p,x,n;h).
McFadden, D. (1978). Modeling the choice of residential location. In A. The integral in Eqn. (A.1) can be computed either analyti-
Karlgvist et al. (Eds.), Spatial interaction theory and planning models.
Amsterdam: North Holland.
cally or numerically depending on the distribution assumption
Melitz, M. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations made for eij. If eij is assumed to be independently and identi-
and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), cally distributed across choices, if it is believed multivariate ex-
1695–1725. treme value and if no additional heterogeneity (beyond the eij
Muendler, M. (2002). Trade, Technology, and Productivity: A Study of term) is assumed, then the integral can be solved analytically.
Brazilian Manufacturers, 1986–1998. U.C. Berkeley, Ph.D. Thesis. Specifically, letting Vij = aln(yi  pj) + dj and making use of
Nevo, A. (2000). A practitioners guide to estimation of random McFadden (1978) the share function can be derived. That pa-
coefficients logit models of demand. Journal of Economics and
Management Strategy, 9(4), 513–548.
per shows that if F(eio,. . .,eiJ) denotes the J + 1 dimensional
Nevo, A. (2001). Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal CDF of e, and G(y0,. . .,yJ) is a nonnegative, homogeneous
industry. Econometrica, 69(2), 307–342. of degree one function satisfying certain restrictions, 37 then
Pavcnik, N. (2002). Trade liberalization, exit, and productivity improve- F ðeio ; . . . ; eiJ Þ ¼ expðGðeeio ; . . . ; eeiJ ÞÞ is the multivariate ex-
ments: evidence from chilean plants. Review of Economic Studies, 69, treme value distribution, and
245–276.
Petrin, A. (2002). Quantifying the benefits of new products: The case of the eV ij Gj ðeV io ; . . . ; eV iJ Þ
Minivan. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 705–729. S ij ¼
Roberts, M. (1996). Colombia, 1977-85: Producer turnover, margins and GðeV io ; . . . ; eV iJ Þ
trade exposure. In M. Roberts, & J. Tybout (Eds.), Industrial evolution
in developing countries (pp. 227–259). The World Bank, Oxford is the market share equation of product j, where Gj is the par-
University Press. tial derivative of G with respect to eVij
Rodrı́guez, F., Rodrik, D. 2000. Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A
Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-National Evidence. In B. Bernanke, K.
Rogoff (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 261–325. APPENDIX 2
Train, K. (2003). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge
University Press.
Train, J., & Winston, C. (2007). Vehicle choice behavior and the declining Under a pure Bertrand-Nash equilibrium, the resulting
market share of US automakers. International Economic Review, 48(4), prices must satisfy the following first order condition,
1469–1496. X @sr ðpÞ
Trajtenberg, M. (1989). The welfare analysis of product innovations, with sj ðpÞ þ ðpr  mcr Þ ¼0
and application to computed tomography scanners. The Journal of r2J
@pj
f
Political Economy, 97, 444–479.
Tybout, J. (1996). Chile: Trade liberalization and its aftermath. In M. where dsr(p)/dpj comes from the demand model.
Roberts, & J. Tybout (Eds.), Industrial evolution in developing countries The markups can be solved by defining a J  J matrix X
(pp. 200–226). The World Bank, Oxford University Press. whose (j,r) elements are given by:
Tybout, J. (2003). Plant- and firm-level evidence on ‘new’ trade theories. ( @s
In E. Kwan, & J. Harrigan (Eds.), Handbook of International  @pr ; if r and j are produced by the same firm;
Economics. Oxford: Basil-Blackwell, 2003. X¼ j

0; otherwise
In vector notation the above first order conditions become
sðpÞ  Xðp  mcÞ ¼ 0
APPENDIX 1 Noting that s(.), p and mc are J  1 vectors, the markup can
be estimated by solving for p  mc
Suppose that consumer i will buy car j if he/she reports a
higher utility, that is: ðp  mcÞ ¼ X1 sðpÞ
820 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

APPENDIX 3 where x, a function of the true parameters h*, is an error term


defined as,
A straightforward strategy to estimate the model is to
choose parameters that minimize the distance between the pre- x ¼ dð:Þ  X b  n
dicted and the observed market shares:
Min ksðx:; p:; n; hÞ  S k ðA:2Þ The moment condition given in Eqn. (A.4) can be used to de-
h fine the following generalized method of moment estimator
where s(.) are the predicted market shares and S the observed (GMM):
market shares. However, the expected correlation between
0
prices and the unobserved characteristics as well as other com- min L ¼ xðhÞ ZA1 Z 0 xðhÞ ðA:5Þ
a;b;q
putational issues led Berry (1994) to develop a technique that
deals with these complications. 38 where A is a consistent estimate of E[Z0 xx0 Z].
Berry (1994) defines n as a structural error term, rather than As is, the GMM estimator involves a potentially large set of
as the difference between the observed and predicted market parameters to estimate. However, noting that the b parameters
shares as is done in Eqn. (A.3). As shown in Eqn. (1), the mean enter linearly, the minimization in (A.5) can be performed only
utility dj(.), is linear in nj. Consequently, given the predicted with respect to the nonlinear parameters a and the q’s. The b’s
and observed market shares solve for d the following system are estimated as follows:
of J + 1 equations: 39
sðd; hÞ ¼ S: ðA:3Þ b ¼ ðX 0 ZA1 Z 0 X Þ1 X 0 ZA1 Z 0 dðs; a; qÞ; ðA:6Þ
Eqn. (A.3) cannot be solved analytically due to the presence of This expression is then plugged into the objective function
three nonlinear parameters, a, qo, and qs. Therefore, using a (A.5).
nonlinear numerical procedure d is derived as a function of A higher unobserved product quality, n should lead firms to
the observed market share and the nonlinear parameters. set higher prices. Additionally, due to the firms’ first order
Define Z = [z1,. . .,zM] to be a set of instruments such that conditions, n will also be correlated with the prices and the
E½Z m  xðh Þ ¼ 0; m ¼ 1 . . . M; ðA:4Þ market shares of the other products.

You might also like