You are on page 1of 9

Useful Arbitrary Allocations (With a Comment on the Neutrality of Financial Accounting

Reports)
Author(s): Arthur L. Thomas
Source: The Accounting Review, Vol. 46, No. 3 (Jul., 1971), pp. 472-479
Published by: American Accounting Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/244516
Accessed: 12-07-2018 04:13 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

American Accounting Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and


extend access to The Accounting Review

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Useful Arbitrary Allocations (With a
Comment on the Neutrality of
Financial Accounting Reports)

Arthur L. Thomas

JN A recent monograph I concluded that tributed to individual recipients will vary.


most of financial accounting's alloca- The range of ambiguity of an allocation
tions are arbitrary, and that this with respect to an individual input is the
renders them useless for the general pur- extent to which the amounts attributed to
poses which financial accounting attempts that recipient may vary by virtue of choice
to serve.' Several friends have been kind of allocation methods.
enough to point out that an allocation may To get down to specifics, SAR #3 dis-
be unsuitable for general purposes yet cusses allocations (such as depreciation) in
highly useful for some specific purpose.2 which the costs of nonmonetary inputs
Although this does not alter the financial are written off. It points out that financial
accounting conclusions of SAR #3, it accounting theory requires that two kinds
should be evident by the end of this paper of allocations be performed in the amorti-
that the existence of useful arbitrary allo- zation of nonmonetary inputs. First, a
cations has implications for managerial series of contribution allocations must be
accounting which deserve further study. made in which the total net revenues of the
These implications are not pursued here;
instead, what follows is merely an initial I The Allocalion Problem in Financial Accounting
Theory, Studies in Accounting Research #3 (American
examination of when arbitrary allocations Accounting Association, 1969), hereafter designated
will be useful.' "SAR #3." A reply to certain criticisms of this mono-
graph and a study of its implications for revenue-
recognition controversies are now (March 1971) in
RANGE OF AMBIGUITY process.
I Of these friends, Alfred Rappaport and Yuji Ijiri
The concept of the "range of ambiguity" were the most persistent. In addition, this paper bene-
of an allocation was applied briefly in fited greatly from criticism by my colleague, L. G.
Eckel, and from technical assistance by Kathleen S.
SAR #3 to situations in which various Martin. Background research was in part supported
allocation methods are available and no by a 1970 McMaster University Summer Research
Stipend.
conclusive reasons for choosing any indi- As a preliminary analysis, I have tried to keep this
vidual possibility can be demonstrated. presentation brief. For example, only a single line of
argument is used to support the conclusions reached in
An accounting allocation divides a mone- the next section and the Appendix, despite the broad
tary magnitude among recipients (inputs implications of these conclusions.

to the firm, accounting periods, and so


forth). If different allocation methods are Arthur L. Thomas is Professor of Ac-
possible, the amounts which could be at- counting at McM aster University.

472

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Thomas: Arbitrary Allocations 473

firm during successive periods are allocated revenue," or, for brevity, the combined
to the various inputs which are deemed to interaction effect.
generate them; this yields a pattern of As is also illustrated below, there is no
periodic net revenue contributions which way to determine decisively whether any
have been attributed to the individual non- one allocation of this combined interaction
monetary input. This pattern is used to effect is preferable to any other. Therefore,
determine the amortization allocation of allocation of the entire combined inter-
that input's cost to different accounting action effect to any one input is just as
periods. defensible as allocation of none of the com-
bined interaction effect to that input.
AMBIGUITIES OF THE Two ALLOCATIONS
From this it follows that the range of
With respect to the contribution alloca- ambiguity in the contribution allocation of
tions, SAR #3 distinguishes between the any one period must be at least as large
separate effects of the individual inputs as the combined interaction effect.
and their interaction effects. A major part
of the allocation problem in financial ac- AIMBIGUITY IN THE INDIVIDUAL
counting is that at present there is no con- AMORTIZATION CHARGE

clusively defensible way to allocate these For financial accounting purposes, the
interaction effects to the individual inputs. most important range of ambiguity is that
(An illustration of this difficulty is given of the amortization charges for individual
later in this paper.) There is a similar inputs during individual accounting per-
problem of interaction among the total iods (such as the depreciation charge for a
inputs of different accounting periods which particular asset during a particular year).
afflicts the amortization allocation (inde- For brevity, this will be designated as the
pendently of the difficulties experienced range of ambiguity in the individual amorti-
with the contribution allocations). zation charge. This range of ambiguity is a
SAR #3 demonstrated (page 72) that the function of the ranges of ambiguity in the
range of ambiguity in the amortization input's amortization and contribution
allocation is at least as large as the differ- allocations. SAR :3 argued that this range
ence between the cost of the input and the of ambiguity was apt to be enormous-
total of the net-revenue contributions large enough to swamp the amortization
which are attributed to that input during charge calculation. The Appendix to this
all accounting periods. This difference may paper attempts to show that, paradoxical
be perceived as the combined interaction as this may seem, this range of ambiguity
effect of the contributions made by the in the individual amortization charge
input during the several periods. Similarly, usually will be at least as large as the total
the range of ambiguity in the contribution historical cost of the input.
allocation of any period with respect to any It is easily proved that any amortiza-
individual input will be at least as large tion in an individual period which exceeded
as the difference between the total net the input's historical cost would require
revenues generated by the particular input negative amortization (appreciation) of
alone or in combination with other inputs the input in at least one other period. Such
and the total separate effects of these recognition of appreciation raises issues
inputs; this may be designated the "com- which are best reserved for a study of the
bined interaction effect during theperiod impact of the allocation problem on reve-
of the individual input and all other inputs nue recognition; therefore, the simplifying
with which it interacts to generate net assumption that negative amortization is

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
474 The Accounting Review, July 1971

inappropriate will be made


Accounting instead.
Association's All o
Committee on
this leads to the following minimum con- Foundations of Accounting Mleasurement,5
clusion (which, though probably much and are not examined in detail here
more conservative than the truth, will (though they will be referred to in the
suffice for the purposes of this paper): final section of this paper); for brevity,
they may be termed allocations which are
The range of ambiguity in an individual
usefulfor institutional purposes.
financial accounting amortization charge
2. A totally ambiguous allocation may
usually will equal the total historical cost
be useful to an entity if this allocation
of the related input.
serves the purposes of that entity; it also
This situation (in which any amortization may be useful if it serves a common pur-
of a nonmonetary input from zero to com- pose of two or more entities. Whatever
plete write off is as defensible as any the size of the range of ambiguity, if those
other) will for brevity be designated as one individuals and groups who are affected
of total amzbiguity in the related allocation. by an allocation have similar enough pur-
poses in common to override any conflicts
SIGNIFICANCE OF THIS CONCLUSION
of their separate interests, they may find
But how significant is this? Are there it possible to develop mutually useful allo-
circumstances in which totally ambiguous cations. These kinds of allocations, char-
allocations are useful to recipients of ac- acterized by a community of interest and
counting data? The rest of this paper designated mutually satisfactory allocations,
suggests that totally ambiguous alloca- are discussed below.
tions can be useful in some situations and
AdNd EXAMPLE
for some purposes. Unfortunately, though,
it will turn out that this demonstration A simple example may be used to il-
does not alter the severe conclusions of lustrate two things simultaneously: first,
SAR ,'3. that the range of ambiguity in the con-
Allocations which are totally ambiguous tribution allocation is at least as large
yet perhaps useful may be classified into as the combined interaction effect and,
two broad categories :' second, that entities with a sufficient com-
1. Some totally ambiguous allocations munity of interest can develop mutually
are embodied in law s, regulations, and satisfactory allocations even when the
custom. When an entity is required by an related ranges of ambiguity are large. The
external authority to allocate, the result- particular allocation situation illustrated
ing allocation automatically is useful to is one in which the range of ambiguity,
the entity (regardless of how large the though substantial, is not total. Such a
allocation's range of ambiguity may be) situation gives a clear insight into the
merely because it satisfies that require- nature of the ambiguity in contribution
ment. For example, if tax regulations pre- allocations. For simplicity, the example
scribe that depreciation allocations be chosen utilizes only two interacting inputs
made, such allocations are thereby ren- and does not involve an amortization
dered useful; similarly, if authoritative allocation. However, all of the following
custom requires that manufactured in- ' This is for convenience in exposition, not for rigor;
it is likely that these categories overlap.
ventories be reported at "cost," the neces-
I Committee on Foundations of Accounting Measure-
sary allocations will be useful even if they ment, American Accounting Association, "Report of the
are totally ambiguous. Cases of this kind Committee on Foundations of Accounting Measure-
ment," THE AccoTNT-IG REvIEw, Supplement to Vol.
are discussed in the report of the American XLVI, 1971, pp. 1-48.

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Thomas: Arbitrary Allocations 475

illustrated points may be extended with- Comparison of methods (2) and (3)
out modification to the more severe and demonstrates that the range of ambiguity
complicated allocation situations which in this allocation is at least as large as the
are encountered in financial accounting.6 entire combined interaction effect of $2.00
Let us suppose that two graduate stu- per hour; this will always be true of con-
dents Fast and Slow, have been hired to tribution allocations.7
grade an examination at a rate of Method (2) is to Slow's short-term
500 per
paper. (For reasons that will become ap- financial advantage. It attributes the
parent later, it is also assumed that Fast entire combined interaction effect to him
is married.) Working alone, Fast can by a calculation which parallels that of the
grade five papers an hour; working alone, marginal analysis (something which should
Slow can grade three papers an hour. For make method (2) even more attractive to
efficiency, each has "specialized" in grad- Slow, since such reasoning is widely re-
ing part of the examination; this allows spected in contemporary accounting the-
them, working together, to grade twelve ory). Slow could defend method (2) quite
papers per hour. The separate effects of as forcefully as Fast could defend any
Fast and Slow on physical output may be alternative allocation approach. Of course,
perceived as five and three papers an hour, Fast could defend method (3) equally well
respectively; net revenues and total reve- against any alternative that was proposed
nues are identical, and the two students' by Slow.
separate effects on net revenues will be
DEVELOPMENT OF A MUTUALLY
$2.50 (50OX5) and $1.50 (50OX3) per
hour. Total revenues are $6.00 (50#X 12) SATISFACTORY ALLOCATION
per hour, resulting in a combined inter- For the purposes of this paper, however,
action effect of $2 .00 ($6.00 -$2.50 - $1.50) the most important thing to recognize is
per hour. that in practice the two graders usually
How shall Fast and Slow divide the total would manage to agree upon a mutually
$6.00 per hour between them? SAR #3 satisfactory method of allocation. This
contends that in situations like this (where process is much too complicated for its de-
two or more inputs interact to produce tails to be discussed here; besides, only a
an output) there will be no single, con- summary of it is needed to support the
clusiv ely defensible, answer. The table conclusions that are reached in the next
indicates a few possibilities. section. In this example, ignorance of the
other grader's capacities ordinarily would
WAYS tN Wincn rt $6.00 PEi HouR MIGIT
BE ALLOCATED BETWEEN FAST AND SLOW
be a factor in reaching a mutually satisfac-
Fast Slow
tory allocation, but four other factors seem

1. Split thewhole amount 50/50... $3.00 $3.00 'I am grateful to Wadsworth Publishing Company,
2. Attribute 7 papers per hour to Inc., for its permission to paraphrase some of what fol-
Slow, on the bsis that if he quit, lows from the author's forthcoming accounting prin-
total output would drop from 12 ciples textbook to be published in 1972.
to 5 papers per hour ........... 2.50 3.50 7 Technically, once the two graduate students have
3. Attribute 9 papers per hour to agreed to grade the exam, the minimum amount which
Fast, on the basis that if he quit, must be paid to either grader is whatever it will take
total output would drop from 12 to keep him grading. This might be less than $1.50 per
to 3 papers per hour ........... 4.50 1.50 hour for Slow or $2.S0 per hour for Fast; therefore in
4. Attribute each grader's separate theory the range of ambiguity could exceed an amount
effects to him, then split the inter- equal to the combined interaction effect. But in actual
action effect 50/50 ............. 3.50 2.50 business situations forces of competition should prevent
5. Split the whole amount in pro- the range of ambiguity from exceeding the combined
portion to each grader's separate interaction effect in this way (except, possibly, in the
effects ........................ 3.75 2.25 very short run).

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
476 The Accounting Review, July 1971

involved, too. First, people who work to- whose total advantage is maximized by
gether day after day (as graduate students that allocation, or who is constrained to
often do) develop various mutual goals accept it. Other entities will find the allo-
which are best furthered by co-operation; cation unsatisfactory (unless, of course, in
excessive emphasis on purely financial their judgment the gap between the results
interests can jeopardize other, nonfinancial, of the allocation method actually employed
interests. Second, even on strictly financial and those of whatever allocation method
grounds it may not pay either grader to be- would be to their maximum over-all ad-
come so greedy that the other will refuse to vantage is not material).
team with him on future projects. (This
will be true even from Fast's standpoint if APPLICATION TO FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING
Slow is more efficient on other jobs.) Third, Certain qualities or characteristics make finan-
there seem to be pervasive institutional cial information useful. Providing information
that has each of these qualities is an objective of
pressures which encourage individuals who
financial accounting. These qualitative objectives
are in the same station of life to share are relevance, understandability, verifiability,
things fairly equally. Finally, in the grad- neutrality, timeliness, comparability, and com-
ers' situation, bargaining may take place pleteness.
between what resemble two duopolists. * * *

(There is an extensive amount of theoreti-Neutrality. Neutral financial accounting infor-


mation is directed toward the common needs of
cal literature about this kind of bargain-
users and is independent of presumptions about
ing.)
particular needs and desires of specific users of the
The reader is asked to notice, though, information. Measurements not based on pre-
that if Fast and Slow reach a mutually sumptions about the particular needs of specific
users enhance the relevance of the information to
satisfactory allocation here, it is either be-
common needs of users. Preparers of financial
cause they have common goals which over-
accounting information should not try to increase
ride their short-run financial interests, or
the helpfulness of the information to a few users
because in some sense Society constrains to the detriment of others who may have opposing
the bargaining process. interests.10
Perhaps Fast and Slow agree that a
We may conclude by contrasting these
50/50 split would be fair. The resulting al-
graders with individuals who are affect-
location then will be useful to them de-
ed by financial accounting's allocations.
spite the fairly large ($2.00) range of am-
biguity.8 However, from the standpoint of
I Several individuals who have responded to SAR
someone else who does not share their com- J3 in private correspondence have gone further and
would contend that the allocation would not be arbi-
mon goals, or who is not subject to the
trary from the standpoint of Fast and Slow, either. I
same social constraints, this 50/50 alloca- have no real objections to saying this as long as it is
recognized that "arbitrary" is being used here in a
tion may be quite unsatisfactory. For ex-
limited sense which differs from the more general sense
ample, let us suppose that Mrs. Fast is employed in SAR #3.
trying to raise three children on a graduate ' An important parallel situation arises here with
transfer prices. For instance, a transfer price may be
student's earnings and doesn't give two mutually satisfactory to a parent company and its
hoots for Slow; from her point of view the foreign subsidiary, yet be unsuitable from the stand-
points of other affected parties in the host country-see
50/50 allocation may be unsatisfactory, 'Transfer Prices of the Multinational Firm: When Will
even though it is satisfactory to her hus- They be Arbitrary?" forthcoming in Abacus.
10 Basic Concepts and Accounting Principles Underly-
band.9 ing Financial Statements of Business Enterprises, State-
In general, allocations with large ranges ment of the Accounting Principles Board No. 4 (Ameri-
can Institute of Certified Public Accountants, October,
of ambiguity may be useful to an entity 1970), pages 10 and 37.

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Thomas: Arbitrary Allocations 47 7

There are substantial differences between analysis in this paper is correct, financial
the two cases. First, most financial ac- accounting cannot be neutral in this sense
counting allocations are totally ambiguous. because it usually cannot provide mutually
Second, individuals and groups whose in- satisfactory allocations (except for institu-
terests are affected by financial account- tional purposes, as defined earlier)."1 But
ing's allocation practices (hereafter desig- if this is so it follows that much of financial
nated the affected entities) are not in the accounting's traditional social justification
position that Fast and Slow were to de- and much of its traditional role in legitimiz-
velop mutually satisfactory allocations by ing social institutions are at least partly
bargaining. Nevertheless, we have seen founded on illusion.'2
that even total ambiguity need not always
be a barrier. There appears to be a slow
APPENDIX
process in lieu of bargaining whereby the
interests of affected entities often are even- THE RANGE OF AMBIGUITY IN THE
tually reflected in generally accepted ac- AMORTIZATION OF AN' INDIVIDUAL
counting principles. One may still ask, INPUT DURING AN INDIVIDUAL
accordingly, whether the totality of af- ACCOUNTING PERIOD
fected entities might manage to develop
What follows is an attempt to demon-
mutually satisfactory allocations, or
strate that usually the range of ambiguity
whether the financial accountant might
in an individual amortization charge will
develop these for the affected entities.
The prospects are not encouraging. So-
ciety's guidance to the affected entities 11 One reviewer of an earlier version of this paper com-
mented that this will depend upon how these alloca-
seems to discourage co-operation, sharing tions are used and upon how resourceful the users are
things evenly, and so forth; instead, maxi- in compensating for the limitations of the allocations.
It is worth emphasizing again that if financial account-
mization of immediate financial advantage ing is to be independent of the desires of special inter-
is encouraged. Moreover, there are rela- ests it must report data which are mutually satisfactory
to contending affected entities, and that the limitations
tively few common goals to be advanced encountered
by usually are ones of total amnbiguitv. At
entities partially sacrificing their financial present, many of financial accountings readers cope
with (or at least tolerate) such ambiguity. But the
interests. Part of the problem here is that probable explanations of this are not especially com-
too many individuals and groups are af- forting: reliance upon nonaccounting data instead of
accounting's allocations, acquiesence to present rules
fected by financial accounting reports. because of institutional compulsion or because they
Consequently, a sense of community is provide the "only game in town," ignorance of the
ambiguity or of its extent, or indifference to the alloca-
difficult to develop. Finally, there are tion because the reader's interests are unaffected by it
abundant current and potential sources of (or because he is unaware of any effect). Similarly, if
someone is tolerating a possible error of six hours in his
conflict between affected entities in which Match one concludes either that he is using some other
different allocation decisions will favor the timepiece, has despaired of learning the time, is un-
aware of the ambiguity, or simply doesn't care what
interests of one set of contending parties time it is. Finally, of course, some readers cope with
over those of others. financial accounting's allocation rules because they are
lucky, clever, or powerful enough to benefit from these
Thus, the chances of financial accounting rules or to influence development of rules which favor
developing mutually satisfactory alloca- their own financial interests.
" In contrast, the allocations that are employed in
tions are at a minimum. This is serious, managerial accounting often need to be satisfactory- only
since financial accounting's traditional role to a single user or to a small number of users who share
common purposes. I tentatively conclude, therefore,
has been as a kind of general-purpose re- that accounting's allocation problems do not always
porting which supposedly is neutral with have as serious consequences in managerial accounting
as they do in financial accounting. Further research
respect to conflicts among its users. If the seems warranted.

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
478 The Accounting Review, July 1971

be total-will be at least as great as the equals the difference between the input's
historical cost of the related nonmonetary total net-revenue contributions and its
input. The reader is warned that what cost:
follows is tentative and subject to refuta- p

tion. Let: R(.4j) = nij-Hj.


R(X) = the range of ambiguity in any
allocation, X Were there no ambiguity in the contribu-
j=any input to the firm, j=l, tion allocations, the range of ambiguity in
the amortization charge for input j in
i=any accounting period, i= 1, period i would equal the range of ambig-

2, *, P uity in the amortization allocation. To the


Ni,= the total net revenue of the extent that there is ambiguity in the con-
firm in period i that was gen- tribution allocations with respect to input
erated by input j alone, or in j, R(ACj) will be greater than or equal to
combination with other inputs R(Aj), since one cannot reduce total am-
nij= the net revenue contribution biguitv by additional ambiguity.
of inputj in period i, as deter- This paper argues that the range of
mined bvZ the contribution al- ambiguity in the contribution allocation of
location period i with respect to inputj equals the

sij= the separate effects of input j combined interaction effect in period i of


in generating Nii input j and all other inputs with which it
interacts:
Iii= N.i minus the separate effects
of all inputs which generate
R(C ij) = I.ij
Nir-the combined interac-
tion effect in period i of input Therefore, n,, may vary anywhere from
j and all other inputs with s,, to (sj+Ij,). Since each R(Cj) is inde-
which it interacts to produce pendent of each other, G n I, may var
net revenues anywhere from E-1 sj to DD1 (sij+ ij).
Hi= the historical cost of input j Looking to the most extreme case, if for
R(Cij) = the range of ambiguity in the each i, Itjj=S,,+Iji, then:
contribution allocation in per- p

iod i, with respect to the R(Aj) = > (siq + Ij) - Ij.


i -i
amount allocated to inputj
R(Aj)=given nij for each period, theNow the total range of ambiguity in the
range of ambiguity in the amortization charge for input j in period i
amortization allocation for must encompass this case, along withall
input j other cases resulting from varying allo-
R(A Cjj) =the range of ambiguity in the cations of the Ni,,'s to the nih's. Accord-
amortization charge for input ingly, R(ACj) itself cannot be less than
j in period i. 2.',i (S +Iq)-HJ:
This notation is used only to clarify the P P

matters to be discussed; what follows R(ACj) > E (Sq) + E (I~j) - Hi.


1-i i-1
should not be regarded as a mathematical
proof. SAR #3 evidenced that the range of But SAR #3 argues that the combined
ambiguity in the amortization allocation interaction effects of most inputs in any

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Thomas: Arbitrary Allocations 479

period usually are substantial: most of the That is, the range of ambiguity in the
total net revenues of the firm are such in- amortization of any given input for any
teraction effects and most inputs interact given accounting period usually will be at
with most other inputs. Because of this it least as large as the historical cost of that
seems very likely that for most inputs input. This in turn implies that anything
.1 (Iij) will be at least twice as large as from zero amortization to complete write-
Hi, and that: off ill be appropriate for the input in any
R(ACij) Hi. given period.

This content downloaded from 152.172.159.14 on Thu, 12 Jul 2018 04:13:57 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like