You are on page 1of 20

Managing Financial Distress and Valuing Distressed Securities: A Survey and a Research

Agenda
Author(s): Kose John
Source: Financial Management, Vol. 22, No. 3 (Autumn, 1993), pp. 60-78
Published by: Wiley on behalf of the Financial Management Association International
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3665928 .
Accessed: 13/06/2014 15:09

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Wiley and Financial Management Association International are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve
and extend access to Financial Management.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Financial Distress Special Issue

Managing Financial Distress


and Valuing Distressed Securities:
A Survey and a Research Agenda
Kose John,Special Issue Editor

Kose John is Charles WilliamGerstenbergProfessorof Bankingand Finance


at the SternSchool of Business,New YorkUniversity,New York,New York.

0 The role of high leveragein corporaterestructuringand in understandinghow firmsdeal with financialdistress.A


the popularityof junk bonds (original-issue, high-yield very active academic literaturehas developed in recent
bonds) have been importantaspects of the corporatefi- years on variousaspects of dealing with financialdistress
nance scene in the 1980s. As more and more firms have and the privateand court-supervisedmechanisms of re-
defaulted on their debt and filed for bankruptcyin the solving default.At the same time, investorshave become
recent recession, financial economists, financial manag- increasinglyconcernedaboutdefaultriskand valuationof
distressed securities incorporatingthe institutionalreali-
ers, andlegal scholarshavebecome increasinglyinterested
ties of troubled debt restructuring.The purpose of this
special issue is to showcasenew empiricaland theoretical
I wish to thank Teresa A. John for permission to draw from earlier
researchon these topics, i.e., managingfinancialdistress
collaborativework on financial distress. I am also grateful to several
and valuing corporatesecuritiesincorporatingpayouts in
colleagues and friendsand otherresearcherswho reviewedmanuscripts
for the special issue andprovidededitorialadvice, especially Ed Altman, troubledreorganizations.While the literatureon the first
Mitch Berlin, Steve Brown, Allan Eberhart, Stuart Gilson, Edie topic, broadly defined, has become quite extensive in
Hotchkiss, Ed Kane, Ron Masulis, Jeff Netter,Tony Saunders,Lemma recentyears,the literatureon the second topic is still in its
Senbet, Bruce Tuckman,Gopala Vasudevan,and KarenWruck. I also
infancy.New researchon these topics is presentedin the
acknowledgehelpful discussions with them on the topics of this survey.
I am immenselygratefulto JamesAng, the Editorof FinancialManage-
nine papersthat appearin this special issue.
ment for enormousencouragement,supportand guidanceon all aspects The purposeof this surveyarticle is to summarizeand
of this special issue. synthesize the recent research in the areas of financial
60

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
JOHN/ MANAGING
FINANCIAL
DISTRESS 61

distress, asset and debt restructuring,bankruptcyand val- examples of hardcontracts.Commonstock and preferred
uationof distressedsecurities.1The new researchfeatured stock are examplesof soft contracts.Here, even thoughits
in this special issue is also surveyedhere. Additionally,I claimholdershave expectationsof receiving currentpay-
present an agenda for future research in the areas of outs fromthe firmin additionto theirownershiprights,the
financial distress, design of contractsand proceduresto level and frequency of these payouts are often policy
deal with it, and techniquesfor the valuationof corporate decisions made by the firm.2These payouts can be sus-
securities and contractsincorporatingstrategiesand out- pendedand/orpostponedbasedon the availabilityof liquid
comes induced by the legal system governing breach of resourcesremainingin the firm aftersatisfying the claims
contractualpromises. of the hardcontracts.
The rest of the paperis organizedas follows. In Section The assets of a firm also have a naturalcategorization
I, a simple conceptualframeworkfor managingfinancial based on liquidity.Cash or cash-like (marketable)securi-
distressis presentedwhich providesa scheme for organiz- ties areliquidassets.Long-terminvestments(suchas plant
ing the survey. Theoretical work and recent empirical and machinery)which may only produceliquid assets in
evidence on asset restructuringis summarizedin Section the futuremay be called "hard"assets.
II. Recent theory and evidence on privatedebt restructur- The above categorizationsof the financingcontractsof
ing (debtworkouts)is collected in Section III.Theoretical a firm and its assets give rise to a naturaldefinition of
andempiricalworkon the formalbankruptcy(Chapter11)
financial distress.A firm is in financialdistressat a given
processis reviewedin SectionIV.Efficiencyaspectsof the point in time when the liquid assets of the firm are not
currentU.S. bankruptcyprocedure,the design of an opti- sufficient to meet the currentrequirementsof its hard
mal procedureand proposals for bankruptcyreform are
contracts.Since financialdistressresultsfrom a mismatch
discussed there. In Section V, the valuationof corporate
between the currentlyavailableliquid assets and the cur-
securities and contractswith significant probabilitiesof
rent obligationsof its "hard"'financialcontracts,mecha-
default (triggeringrenegotiationand legal resolution) is
nisms for managingfinancialdistressrectifythe mismatch
discussed. Each of these sections includes a brief survey
of relevantexisting literature,an overview of the papersin by either restructuringthe assets or restructuringthe fi-
this special issue which fall in thatarea,and some sugges- nancing contracts,or both.
On the asset side, the hard assets can be wholly or
tions for futureresearch.Section VI containsan agendafor
furtherresearchand concludingremarks. partiallyliquidatedto generateadditionalliquid assets to
meet the currentobligations.However,prematureliquida-
tion of illiquid assets results in the destructionof going-
I.ManagingFinancialDistress: A Model concernvalue and involves the cost of liquidation.If this
The financing contractsof a firm can be loosely cate- avenueis pursuedto deal with financialdistress,the value
gorized into hardand soft contracts.An exampleof a hard lost due to prematureliquidationof assets representsthe
contractis a coupondebtcontractwhich specifies periodic cost of managingfinancialdistress.
paymentsby the firmto the bondholders.If thesepayments Anotherset of mechanismsto deal with financial dis-
are not made on time, the firm is considered to be in tress involves restructuringthe financial contracts. One
violation of the contractand the claimholdershave speci- mechanismis to negotiate with the creditorsand restruc-
fied and unspecifiedlegal recourseto enforcethe contract. ture the terms of the hard contractssuch that the current
Contracts with suppliers and employees may be other obligation is either reducedto an amountwhich is closer
to the cash currentlygeneratedby assets, or deferredto a
'The literatureon financial distress, asset and debt restructuring,and later date. Anothermechanismis to replace the hardcon-
bankruptcyhas now become very extensive and I do not intendthis to be tract with soft securities with residual ratherthan fixed
an exhaustivesurveyof it. See JohnandJohn[70] and SenbetandSeward
[102] for other recent surveys. Wruck [116] also surveys in detail a
selected subset of empirical papers in the area. The area of financial 2Evenequitycontractsassociatedwith certainorganizationalformsmay
distress and resolutionmechanismsis closely relatedto that of optimal have mandatorypayoutrequirementsmakingit "harder"thanthose in the
design of contractsand securities, and to that of capital structure.The corporateform. For example, a real estate investmenttrust(REIT)must
Summer1993 issue of FinancialManagementfeaturesa special issue on distributeat least 95% (90% prior to 1980) of its net annual taxable
"SecurityDesign"editedby FranklinAllen. Forsurveyson thetheoretical income, excluding capitalgains and certainnoncashtaxable income, to
literatureon optimal securitydesign, see Allen [4], Allen and Gale [5], shareholders.Damodaran,John,andLiu [37] studychanges in organiza-
Allen and Winton[6], and HarrisandRaviv [57]. Foran excellent survey tional forms and document that financial distress and choice over the
of the modem literatureon capital structure,see Harrisand Raviv [58]. restrictivenessof the associatedequity contractare majordeterminants.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
62 FINANCIAL / AUTUMN1993
MANAGEMENT

payoffs. In general, debt restructuringinvolves replacing defaults.As we discussed above, suboptimalliquidations


an existing debt contract by a new contract with (i) a can occur also following liquidity-induceddefaults.Debt
reductionin the requiredinterestor principalpayments, restructuringmay be a solution. Mechanismswhich facil-
(ii) extension of maturity,or (iii) placement of equity itate debt restructuring(privateor court-supervised)will
securities (common stock or securities convertible into reducethe costs of prematureliquidationfollowing liquid-
common stock) with creditors.Under the new contract, ity defaults. However, the same mechanismswill reduce
thereis less financialdistress. inefficiencies following a strategic default, encouraging
A thirdmode of financialrestructuringis to raise addi- such defaults. The ex ante efficiency of the debt restruc-
tional currentliquidity by issuing new financial claims turingmechanismswill dependon the relativeimportance
of these two effects. HartandMoore [60], HarrisandRaviv
against future cash flows generatedby the assets, which
may avoid or reduceprematureliquidationof these assets. [59], and Bolton and Scharfstein [28] develop related
Here, even though the original hard contract was left arguments.
unaltered,the structureof financingclaims was alteredby In additionto incompletecontracting,asymmetricin-
thenew financingundertaken.Whenthe new claims issued formationbetween debtorsand creditorsabout the value
have a softercontractor longermaturity,the new package of the assets (ongoing firmvalue or liquidationvalue) can
of financingclaims are less onerouson the firm,resolving frustratemutuallybeneficialdebt renegotiation(see, e.g.,
financialdistress. Giammarino[52]). As Brown [30] points out, when there
It should be pointed out that both asset restructurings is symmetricinformationbetweenmanagementandcred-
and debt restructuringscan be accomplishedprivatelyor itors, a privateworkoutis always successful. Many of the
theoreticalmodels in the area examine the consequences
througha formalcourt-adjudicated process.Exactlywhich
method is implementedto reorganizea financially dis- of incompletecontractingandasymmetricinformationon
the efficiency of contractingand the mechanismsto man-
tressed firm depends on the relativecosts and benefits of
each mechanism.In a scenariowith completecontracting, age financialdistress arisingfrom breachof the termsof
the contract.
i.e., a complete state-contingentset of contracts are al-
lowed by the legal system, an initialdesign of contractcan I will use the framework developed above to next
be madesuchthattherequiredfinancingcanbe undertaken organize the survey of the theory and evidence on asset
avoiding any prematureliquidation of assets. In other restructuring(Section II), privatedebt restructuring(Sec-
tion III) and the formalbankruptcyprocess (Section IV).
words, the choice of initial contract would precludede-
faults of the type discussed above due to shortages of
liquidity, or it will be renegotiatedto avoid suboptimal
liquidations. However, in practice, the admissible con-
II.Asset Restructuring
tractsare incomplete.Often,outside investorsor the court As outlined in the general frameworkdeveloped in
system do not have the detailed informationrequiredto Section I, one set of mechanisms to deal with financial
enforce many contracts. For example, the currentcash distressinvolvesrestructuringthe asset side of the balance
availablemay not be observableto these outside parties, sheet to generatesufficientcash to meet the requirements
which would make contracts specifically contingent on of the hardcontracts.Assets can be sold (eitherpiecemeal
thesecash flows hardto enforce.Managersmayhave some or in their entirety) to other firms or new management
scope to divertsome of the cash flows to managerialperks teams. Asset sales can be accomplished privately or
on their favorite (but unprofitable)projects, etc. In the throughcourt-supervisedstages either duringbankruptcy
extreme, if managerscan appropriateall the cash flows, reorganization(Chapter 11 of the BankruptcyCode) or
then the managerswould always choose to defaultstrate- underthe liquidationprocess(Chapter7 of the Bankruptcy
gically anddivertthe cash to themselves.Of course, cred- Code). Each of these alternativeshas differentcosts at-
itors would anticipatethis andrefuse to lend. As Hartand tached to them. Whether asset restructuringis actually
Moore [60] argue, one possible resolution is to give the usedto managefinancialdistresswoulddependon its costs
creditors, following nonpayment (default), the right to relativeto those of financialrestructuring.3
liquidateassets andappropriatethe proceedsfromliquida-
tion within limits specified by the contract.Since liquida- 3Therole of asset restructuringin improvinginvestmentincentiveswhen
tion of assets results in loss of future cash flows to the risky debt is outstandinghas been analyzedby John [761 and John and
managers,the threatof liquidationwould deter strategic John[77]. John[76] providesa theoreticalrationalefor value gains from

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
JOHN/ MANAGING
FINANCIAL
DISTRESS 63

Shleifer and Vishny [104] study the liquidity costs John and Vasudevan[74] obtain severalempiricalim-
associatedwith interfirmasset sales promptedby financial plications:
distress.4In identifyingthe determinantsof marketliquid- (i) Successful completion of debt workouts should
ity, they focus on (i) fungibility(i.e., the numberof distinct resultin increasedstock pricesandincreasedcom-
uses and users for a particularasset), (ii) participation bined firm value. Chapter 11 filings should pro-
restrictions(e.g., regulationson foreign acquisitions,anti- duce a negativeannouncementeffect. Firmswhich
trustrestrictions),and (iii) creditconstraintsin the indus- privatelyrestructuretheirdebt have higher going-
try.They arguethatthe pricereceivedin a distresssale may concern value when comparedto firms which file
have large liquiditydiscounts if the entireindustryis in a for Chapter 11. Average time spent by firms in
downturn.In an illiquid secondary market,the costs of Chapter 11 reorganizationsis more than that in
asset restructuringare likely to be high, and financial workouts(Gilson, John, and Lang [55] document
restructuringmay provide the dominant mechanisms of evidence consistentwith these predictions).
dealing with financialdistress. (ii) Asset sales by distressedfirms to make debt pay-
In an integratedmodel of asset and debt restructuring, ments have a positive effect on stock prices. This
John and Vasudevan[74] examine how the cost of asset is consistentwith the empiricalevidence in Lang,
sales, the currentliquidity position of the firm, and the Poulsen, and Stulz [87].
option value of its equity determinethe choice between a
(iii) Deviations from absolute priority are higher in
private workout (with or without some asset sales) and workoutsthan that in Chapter11 reorganization.
filing for the formalChapter11 process, possibly seeking Write-downsarelower in workouts.This is consis-
debtor-in-possession(DIP) financing. Since asset sales tent with Franksand Torous[48].
may extinguish some of the option value of equity, there
is an endogenous cost of asset sales to equityholders(in (iv) Write-downs in prepackagedbankruptcyfilings
additionto the costs of illiquiditydiscussedby Shleiferand will be lowerthanordinaryChapter11 reorganiza-
Vishny [104]). When the combinedcosts of asset liquida- tion.
tions arehigh, the firmmay file for Chapter11 bankruptcy (v) The payoffs to bondholdersmonotonicallyincrease
and seek new financingas DIP financingwhich has prior- in the indirectcosts of bankruptcy.
ity over existing debt. To determinethe expected payoffs The frameworkof Section I, in characterizingfinancial
to equity underthe differentalternatives,the reorganiza-
distress as a mismatch between the currently available
tion process itself (both workouts and Chapter 11) is
liquid assets and the current obligations of its "hard"
modelled as an alternatingoffer bargaininggame with financialcontracts,suggeststhatafterfinancialdistresshas
asymmetricinformation,where the equityholdersare bet- occurred,managingit involvescorrectingthe mismatchby
ter informedthanthe bondholdersor thejudge (in Chapter either increasingthe liquidityof the assets (throughasset
11). Based on the allocation of value in equilibrium,the sales) or decreasingthe "hardness"of the debt contracts
outcomes include privaterestructuringwith and without
(throughdebt renegotiation).However,before the firm is
asset sales, andChapter11 filings with DIP financing.The in financialdistressit can design the structureandthe form
time spentin the Chapter11 reorganizationis endogenous of its debt contractsand choose its leverage and liquidity
to the model and one of the possible outcomes is a "pre- policies suchthatits costs of financialdistressarereduced.
packaged"bankruptcywith a speedy reorganization. Opler [97] andJohn [75] study these issues empiricallyin
theircontributionsin this special issue. Leveragedbuyouts
have been increasinglyfunded in ways which appearto
spin-offs and asset sales and characterizesthe optimal allocation of the reduce the risk and cost of financial distress. Leveraged
pre-spin-off debt. John and John [77] demonstrateconditions for the
optimalityof limited recourseprojectfinancingarrangements.
buyout financing methods include the use of specialist
4Asset sales in bankruptcymay have some advantagesover those done sponsors, strip financing, covenants which require that
privatelyoutsideformalbankruptcyproceedings.Purchasingassets from excess cash flows be paid to debtholdersand debt provis-
a financiallydistressedfirmis less riskyin Chapter11 becauseasset sales ions which allow deferralof interestpaymentsin periods
are executed by a court orderand are thus free from legal challenge. In of financialdistress.Opler [97] documentsthe prevalence
addition, if the seller subsequentlyfiles for Chapter11, the buyer may
have to returnthe assets as "avoidablepreference"or "fraudulenttrans-
of these innovative financing techniques and estimates
fer."Giventhe materialcosts of beingchallengedor cancelled,asset sales their impacton the risk-adjustedcost of debt in 63 LBOs
in Chapter11 may be preferredby potentialbuyers. which occurredin 1987 and 1988. The results show that

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
64 FINANCIAL / AUTUMN1993
MANAGEMENT

sponsorshipby an LBO specialist lowers the weighted restructuringby firms in distress.All of the above papers
averagecost of LBO debt and the imputedcost of capital document that asset sales are frequentlyused by finan-
by roughly 60 basis points. In addition, debt provisions cially distressedfirmsin theirsample.Brown,James,and
which allow deferralof interestpaymentson junior debt Mooradian[3 1] find thatfirmswhich sell assets aredistin-
and which maintaina minimum bond value are used in guishedby multipledivision or multiplesubsidiaryopera-
many of the LBOs in the sample. While these provisions tions.Conversely,most of thefirmswhichdo not sell assets
do not lower financingcosts, theiruse indicatesthatLBO operate only a single division. They also find that the
capital structuresare designed to avoid the need for debt announcementof asset sales elicits insignificantabnormal
workoutsor Chapter11 proceedingsin periodsof financial stock returns.However,the announcementeffect is posi-
distress. tive for the subsetof seller firms which also subsequently
Given the above characterizationof financial distress, avoidbankruptcy.Lang,Poulsen,andStulz [87] document
a firm with high costs of financialdistress will reduce its that the abnormalreturnis higher for sellers who use the
exposure in two ways: (i) increase the liquid component proceedsfrom asset sales for retiringdebt. Asquith,Gert-
of its assets, and (ii) reducethe extent of its hardcontracts ner, and Scharfstein[15] conclude that asset sales are an
(such as debt). Based on this argument,John [75] postu- importantmeans of avoiding bankruptcy.They find that
lates (i) a positive relationshipbetweencorporateliquidity only threeout of 21 companiesthatsell over 20% of their
assets go bankrupt.
and distresscosts, and (ii) a negativerelationshipbetween
The overall evidence seems to suggest that although
leverageanddistresscosts.5A majorcomponentof distress
asset sales are used to deal with financialdistress,in most
costs is the costs of illiquidityof assets.Thesecosts include
cases they are used in conjunctionwith debtrestructuring.
costs of distressed asset sales and loss of going-concern
value in liquidations.Some new proxies are proposedfor
the costs of illiquidity and the indirectcosts of financial III.PrivateDebt Restructuring
distress. These include Tobin's q, R&D and advertising Informal reorganizationof corporatefinancial struc-
expenditures,an index of asset specificity and an index of turesthroughdebtrestructuringsandprivateworkoutscan
the probabilityof bankruptcy.The liquidityratio is docu- be used to "soften"the hardcontractswhich caused finan-
mentedto be positivelyrelatedto these proxiesof financial cial distress. Consistent with the model of Section I, to
distresscosts. It is negatively relatedto proxies for alter-
remedy financial distress the firm will reduce or defer
nate sources of anticipatedliquidity such as intermediate
payments on its debt contractsor replace debt with soft
cash flows, debt financing, length of cash cycle and the securitieshavingresidualratherthanfixedpayoffs.Wecan
collateral value of assets. Total debt is also negatively define a debt restructuringas a transactionin which an
relatedto Tobin's q and asset specificity as well as mea- existing debt contractis replacedby a new contractwith
sures of intermediatecash flows. Long-termdebt is also (i) a reductionin the requiredinterest or principalpay-
negativelyrelatedto proxies for alternatesourcesof antic- ments, (ii) extension of maturity,or (iii) placement of
ipated liquidity such as intermediatecash flows, debt equity securities(common stock or securitiesconvertible
financing,length of cash cycle and the collateralvalue of into common stock)with creditors.Privatedebtrestructur-
assets.Totaldebt is also negativelyrelatedto Tobin'sq and ing is surveyedin this section, and debt reorganizationin
asset specificity as well as measuresof intermediatecash a court-adjudicated formalbankruptcyprocessis surveyed
flows. Long-termdebt is also negativelyrelatedto Tobin's in Section IV.
q and asset specificity. Overall, the evidence is strongly Haugenand Senbet [61], [62] arguethatcapitalmarket
consistent with the hypothesized relationshipsbetween mechanismscould accomplishthe restructuringof prob-
corporateliquidityand financialdistresscosts, andcorpo- lematic hard contractsand replacing them with a softer
rate leverageand financialdistresscosts. mix. They arguethat the transactionscosts of these "pri-
Brown, James, and Mooradian[31], Asquith,Gertner, vate" mechanisms are small and should form an upper
and Scharfstein [15], Lang, Poulsen, and Stulz [87], bound on the costs of managingfinancialdistress.Jensen
Hotchkiss [64], and Ofek [96] presentevidence of asset [67], [68] has also arguedthat since these privaterestruc-
turingsrepresentan alternativeto formalbankruptcypro-
5Thenegativerelationshipbetween leverageand distresscosts has been
ceedings, it pays to "privatize"bankruptcyif this informal
documentedin severalearlierstudies,e.g., TitmanandWessels[105]. See mechanism is cost-efficient. Roe [100] has also made
John[75] for a summaryof this researchanda completelist of references. similarargumentsin the legal literature.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
FINANCIAL
JOHN/ MANAGING DISTRESS 65

A simpleconceptualframeworkis developedin Gilson, In these cases, the tenderingbondholdersarealso askedto


John, and Lang [55] to determine the choice between vote to change or eliminate the existing debt covenants.
private restructuring and formal bankruptcy process, The acceptanceof the exchangeddebt is madeconditional
which is based on two factors.Let AC be the cost saving on approvalof the consent solicitation by the required
by choosing the first alternativeover the second. If AC is majority. In these cases, the consent solicitation is so
positive, by choosing the firstalternative,the firm'sclaims designedthatthe benefitsof nonparticipationareexceeded
can be restructuredto leave each of the originalclaimants by the loss from holding onto the old bonds strippedof
better off (they share the incrementalvalue AC collec- covenants. Kahan and Tuckman [81] and Gertner and
tively). The largeris AC,the strongerarethe claimholders' Scharfstein[50] analyzethe holdoutproblemsin exchange
incentivesto settle privately.However,the privatealterna- offers and consent solicitations.
tive will be adoptedonly if thereis unanimousagreement Gertnerand Scharfstein[50] have predictionsfor the
on how to shareAC. Impedimentsto reachinga settlement effect of workoutsand consent solicitationson the invest-
on a private restructuringcan be (i) holdout problems ment decisions of financiallydistressedfirms. They con-
encounteredwhen a firm's debt is held by a large number cludethatinvestmentincentivesarenot typicallyimproved
of diffuse creditors, (ii) informationalasymmetriesthat by debt workouts.Kahanand Tuckman[81] analyze con-
can arise betweenpoorly informedoutsidecreditorsand a sent solicitations and empirically examine bondholder
better informedmanageror insiders of the firm, and (iii) wealth effects on announcementsof consent solicitations.
conflicts among differentgroupsof creditors. When the bondholdersact atomistically,i.e., on theirown
(without forming coalitions), it is shown that coercive
consent solicitations may be necessary for a successful
A. HoldoutProblem covenant change. The evidence, however, is that bond
Achieving an agreementamongcreditorsoutsideof the prices increaseon announcementof consent solicitations.
formalbankruptcyprocess will dependupon what type of This suggeststhatbondholdersmay collude andact coher-
debt is restructured,e.g., privatedebt or public debt. The ently in the face of coercive consent solicitations.
restructuringof publicdebtis governedby the TrustInden-
ture Act of 1939, which requiresunanimousconsent of
every bondholder to change the maturity,principal or B. InformationalAsymmetry
coupon rate of interestin the bond indenture.Such strin- Often, corporateinsidersand managementknow more
gent votingrulesprecludea debtrestructuringin whichthe aboutthe value of the firm,its assets, its futurecash flows,
core terms of widely held public debt can be changed. etc., than outside investors, including creditors.In such
Consequently,almostall restructuringsof publicdebttake cases, asymmetricinformationexists between corporate
the form of an exchange offer. insidersandcreditors,such thatthe creditorscannotprop-
An exchange offer and the resultingholdout problem erly evaluate the new package of claims proposed in a
can be understoodbased on the frameworkdeveloped in workout.They also believe that the debtor-management
Section I. In an exchange offer,the bondholdersare given may misrepresentthe value of the firm. Giammarino[52]
the option to exchange their old bonds for a package of models such a scenarioand shows that the creditorsmay
new securities(often includingsome form of equity). The actually reject mutually beneficial private restructuring
idea here is to swap the existing "hard"contract for a andchoose, in equilibrium,a court-imposedproposalwith
"softer"mix. Since participationis optional, individual the attendantdeadweightcosts. In other words, informa-
bondholdersmay choose to "hold out"in the expectation tionalasymmetrycan thwartan agreementfor an attractive
that their bonds would be more valuable (in the post- settlement.Brown [30], on the other hand, examines the
exchange, less-distressedfirm) than the new package of choice between privateworkoutsand the bankruptcypro-
securities. Since all bondholdershave similar incentives cess in a symmetricinformationsetting.By modellingthe
(assumingthatthey do not collude), the exchange offer is rules of the court-adjudicatedprocess, Brown [30] shows
likely to fail. The termsof the new packetof securitiesare that the equilibriumalways involves a successful private
often set to coerce participation.Coercive techniquesare workout.
used by corporationsto implement successful exchange John and Vasudevan [74] analyze the firm's choice
offers. Exchange offers are often accompaniedby modifi- between workouts(possibly with asset sales) and Chapter
cation of the covenants of the original bonds through a 11 filing (with subsequent DIP financing) in a setting
techniqueknownas consentsolicitationsor exit covenants. wherethereis asymmetricinformationbetweenthe corpo-

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
66 FINANCIAL
MANAGEMENT
/ AUTUMN1993

rate insiders and the creditors/courts.The details of the The economic reasoning underlyingthese findings is
model andresultsarediscussedin Section II. Gertner[49] suggestedby the model of Section I and the frameworkof
also examinesthe signallingrole of the securitiesissued in Gilson, John, and Lang [55] summarizedearlier in this
distresseddebtrestructurings.6See also MyersandMajluf section. On the asset side, intangibleassets proxy for the
[95]. destructionof going-concernvalue which would occur if
financial restructuringfails and asset restructuringis re-
quired.In fact, Gilson, John,andLang [55] use the differ-
C. Coalitionsand Conflicts ence between marketvalue and the replacementcost of
Fora typicalfirmwith a complex capitalstructurethere assets (scaled by replacementcost) as the proxyvariable.
are severalgroupsof claimants,includingdifferentclasses The value saved (AC) if the firm maintains operating
of debtholders,tradecreditors,stockholders,management,
continuity through a workout is higher, the higher the
etc. Even when the privatereorganizationcosts are less
proportionof intangibleassets. Factors(ii) and (iii) above
thanotheralternatives(leaving a largeraggregatevalue of affect the probabilitythat a settlement is reached in the
assets), its distributionamongthe variousclaimantscould bargainingprocessleadingto a successful workout.Firms
be criticalto a successful debt restructuring.The bargain- with banksas dominantcreditorscan moreeasily renego-
ing issues involvedin modelingthe intergroupconflicts of tiate their debt because banks are more sophisticatedand
interests and coalition formation have been studied in less numerousthan other kinds of creditors,resulting in
Bulow andShoven [34], GertnerandScharfstein[50], Hart fewer holdouts.Similarly,conflicts of interestamong dif-
and Moore [60], John and Vasudevan[74], Harris and ferentclasses of creditorsaremoremanageablethe smaller
Raviv [59], Kaiser [82], Walzer [106], and Bergmanand the numberof distinctcreditorclasses.
Callen [20], [21]. These conflicts of interest can lead to
Gilson, John, and Lang [55] also provide evidence on
distortationsin investment(underinvestment,overinvest- the principaltermsof restructuringthe debt for the firms
ment and excessive continuationor liquidation).Details in their sample. As mentionedearlier,debt restructuring
will be discussed in Section IV.B. on the efficiency of the
involves "softening"the hardcontractby reducinginterest
bankruptcyprocess. or principal payments, extending the debt maturity or
distributingequity securitiesto creditors.In about73% of
D. EmpiricalEvidenceon DebtWorkouts all successful workouts,there is a reductionin promised
Gilson, John, and Lang [55] was the first systematic paymentson the debt. In about74%of successful restruc-
turings,new equitysecuritiesaregiven to creditors.Exten-
empirical study of debt workouts. They investigate the sion of maturityis only observed in 49% of workouts.
incentives of financially distressed firms to restructure
Differentclasses of debt also appearto be restructuredon
theirdebtprivatelyratherthanthroughformalbankruptcy.
substantiallydifferentterms.Approximately49% of bank
They analyze the experienceof 169 publicly tradedcom-
debt restructuringsprovide for an extension of maturity,
panies that experienced severe financial distress during
1978-1987. Eighty of these firms successfully avoided compared with only 6.7% of restructuringsof publicly
tradeddebt;this latterresultis consistentwith firmsoffer-
bankruptcyby restructuringtheirdebt out of courtand 89
ing shorter-maturity debt in exchangeoffers to discourage
firmswereunsuccessfulin workingouttheirdebtprivately
holdouts (see the section on holdouts above). Although
and filed underChapter11 of the U.S. BankruptcyCode.
The studyfinds thatthe asset characteristicsand financial 51.4% of bank debt restructuringsresult in bank lenders
characteristicsjointly determinethe firm'schoice between receivingequityin thefirm,holdersof publiclytradeddebt
are given equity securities 86.7% of the time. The latter
informaland formal reorganizationmechanisms(as sug-
difference is a likely consequence of various legal and
gested in ourmodel of Section I). More specifically,finan-
cial distress is more likely to be resolved throughprivate regulatoryfactors that make it costly for banks to hold
workouts,when (i) a greaterproportionof the firm'sassets large amountsof equity in publicly tradedcompanies.7
are intangible,(ii) a greaterproportionof its debt is bank
debt, and (iii) the firm has fewer lenders (fewer distinct 71Inparticular,banks are constrainedfrom holding significantblocks of
classes of debt outstanding). stock in other firms by Section 16 of the Glass-SteagallAct, the Bank
Holding CompanyAct and the FederalReserve Board's RegulationY.
Temporaryexceptions may be grantedwhen stock is obtainedin a debt
6White[1 15] also studiesthe choice between liquidationversuscontinu- workout.Moreover,banks must divest theirstockholdingsafterapprox-
ation in an asymmetricinformationsetting. imately two years, althoughextensions are possible. Second, creditors

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
JOHN/ MANAGING DISTRESS
FINANCIAL 67

Gilson, John,and Lang [55] also documentsome mea- sales and capital expenditurereductions are commonly
sures of the relativecosts of workoutsversus Chapter11. used by firmsin financialdistress;(ii) banksrarelyforgive
The average length of time spent by 89 firms in Chapter principalon outstandingloans or providenew financingin
11 is over20 months;the averagelengthof the 80 workouts a workout;and (iii) workout of public debt throughex-
is about 15 months.The differencein costs is significantly change offers is an importantdeterminantof the success
higherin the 30 cases in the Gilson-John-Langsamplethat of the overall workout.
involvedprivaterestructuringof publicly tradeddebt. The Hoshi, Kashyap,and Scharfstein[63] explore the role
average time for exchange offers (which is the common of main-bankrelationshipsin reducingthe costs of finan-
mechanismfor restructuringpublic debt) in the sample is cial distressin Japan.They presentevidence thatJapanese
just under seven months. Gilson, John, and Lang [55] firms in industrialgroups - those with close financial
provide the only availableevidence on the direct costs of relationshipsto their banks, suppliers,and customers-
privateworkouts.The offer-relatedcosts of these exchange invest more and sell more than nongroupfirms. Parallel
offers, on average,is only 0.65% of the book value of the resultsarefound for nongroupfirmswhich do have strong
assets. By contrast,the averagelegal andprofessionalfees ties to main banks.
reportedin the Chapter 11 process range from 2.8% to Gilson [54] documentsthat corporatedefault leads to
7.5% of total assets. Gilson, John, and Lang [55] also significantchanges in the ownershipof firms' equity and
provide indirect evidence of the relative costs of formal the allocationof rights to managecorporateresources.In
and informal reorganizationsusing evidence from stock his sample of 111 firms in financialdistressduring 1979-
returns.To the extent that workoutsare less costly than 1985, banklendersfrequentlybecome majorstockholders
Chapter 11, both shareholdersand creditorsshould gain or appointnew directors.On average,only 46% of incum-
when debtworkoutssucceed.The Gilson-John-Langstudy bent directorsremainwhen bankruptcyor debt restructur-
documents that shareholdersof companies that success-
ing ends. Directors who resign hold significantly fewer
fully worked out their debt realized an average 41% in- seats on otherboardsfollowing theirdeparture.Common-
crease in stock value over the period of workout (i.e., stock ownershipbecomes more concentratedwith large
startingwith announcementof the default),net of general blockholdersand less with corporateinsiders.Gilson [53]
market movements. On the other hand, firms which at- documents changes in top managementfollowing finan-
tempteda workoutbut failed and filed for Chapter11 had cial distress (52% annualturnover)which is significantly
an average cumulative stock return of -40% over the
higher than that for a random sample (12%) and that
restructuringperiod ending with the Chapter11 filing. At categorizedas poorly performingbut not financiallydis-
least partof the 81%differencein these returnsrepresents tressed(19%).
the market'sestimate of relativecost savings between the
Brown, James, and Mooradian[32] examine debt re-
two mechanisms.8Theyalso findthatthemarketis capable
structuringsmade by financially distressed firms under
of predictingthe outcome of the workoutattempt.
asymmetricinformation.Their model of public debt ex-
In subsequentwork, Asquith,Gertner,and Scharfstein
change offers predictsthat firms with unfavorableprivate
[15], Brown, James, and Mooradian[32], and Franksand informationwill offerequityclaimsto convincebondhold-
Torous[48] examinedebtworkoutsfurther.Asquith,Gert-
ers thatthe firm'sprospectsare poor. However,when the
ner, and Scharfstein[15] examine workoutsof 102 firms
private lender is well-informed,offering equity in a re-
which issued junk bonds and then subsequentlyencoun-
tered financial distress. Their findings include: (i) asset structuringconveys favorableprivateinformationto out-
siders. Consistent with their analysis, they find positive
averageabnormalreturnsaroundthe reorganizationsthat
offer equity to privatelenders and senior debt to public
can be held legally liable to other claimholdersif the firm's financial
conditiondeterioratessubsequentto theirassuminga controllinginterest
debtholders. In contrast, they find significant negative
in the firm and exercising"undueinfluence"over its business(Douglas- averageabnormalreturnswhen privatelendersareoffered
Hamilton [41]). For recent analyses of the optimalityof banks holding senior debt and public lenders are offered equity. Franks
equity in borrowingfirms, see Berlin,John,and Saunders[24] andJohn, and Torous[48] examinemanyaspectsof workoutswhich
John, and Saunders[79]. See also Johnand John [71].
were examinedin Gilson, John, and Lang [55]. They also
8A fraction of this 81% difference may also representemerging new
find that(i) less liquid andless solvent firmsenterChapter
information,i.e., the firmsultimatelyfiling Chapter11 aresystematically
less profitableafter attemptsat restructuringbegan. Such information 11 andthat,consequently,write-downsof creditors'claims
may come out graduallyover the restructuringperiod. are larger in Chapter 11 comparedto workouts,and (ii)

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
68 FINANCIAL / AUTUMN1993
MANAGEMENT

deviations from the rules of strict absolute priorityrule in the contractexplicitly.However,the bankruptcyproce-
(APR) are largerin workouts.9 dures are implicitlya partof every contractand affect the
allocationof resourcesjust like the financialcontracts.For
IV.The Chapter 11 Process example, formal bankruptcyproceduresestablish the al-
ternativeto a privateworkoutsettlementandhence affect
An alternativemechanism for dealing with financial
the natureof such settlements(see John and Vasudevan
distressis the formal,court-supervisedbankruptcyprocess
[74] and Gilson, John, and Lang [55]). Bankruptcyrules
(of financialrestructuring)governedby Chapter11 of the
U.S. BankruptcyCode. Although in the previous section may affect investmentpolicy, extent of liquidation and
we highlightedthe relatively lower direct costs of work- operating decisions through their effects on bargaining
outs comparedto bankruptcy,the formalprocesshas bene- outcomes. The availability of funds for investment,the
fits as well as costs. Some of the benefits are as follows: capital structuresandthe type of investmentschosen may
all be influenced by bankruptcy rules. Therefore,
(i) The automatic stay provision of the Bankruptcy
Code protects the firm from creditorharassment designing efficient bankruptcyproceduresis important.
A largebody of researchon the efficiency of the bank-
while it reorganizes.
ruptcy process focuses on its effects on the investment
(ii) The less restrictivevoting rulesin Chapter11 make
policy of the firm. Two types of investmentdistortions
it easier to get a reorganizationplan accepted.
arisewhenthe firmis in financialdistress.Whenriskydebt
(iii) The BankruptcyCode allows the firm to issue new is outstanding,equityholdersrefuse to contributecapital
debt that is senior to all "prepetition"debt. Such for positive net present value investments because the
debtor-in-possession(DIP) financing is valuable returns will accrue largely to bondholders.This is the
because the firmcan borrowon cheapertermsthan underinvestmentproblemstudiedby Myers [94], and sub-
withoutit.
sequently by John and Kalay [72]. The second problem
(iv) The interest on prepetitionunsecureddebt stops (introduced by Jensen and Meckling [69]) is that
accruingwhile the firmis in bankruptcy,freeingup equityholdersmay overinvestin riskyprojects,i.e., under-
scarce cash. For a detailed discussion of the fea- take risky but negative net present value projects when
tures of the Chapter11 process, see Gilson, John, risky debt is outstanding. Problems of risk-shifting or
and Lang [55] or White [113], [114]. excessive continuationare differentmanifestationsof the
An emergingliteraturein law andfinancequestionsthe same problemof overinvestment.
optimalityand efficiency of the existing bankruptcyreor- Bulow and Shoven [34] and White [111], [112] were
ganizationprocess and proposesalternativesystems. This among the first to point out thatthe featuresof the bank-
literatureis surveyedin Section IV.A.EberhartandSenbet ruptcycode will affect investmentdecisions by distressed
[43] contributeto this literature.The empiricalevidence firms. Bulow and Shoven [34] and White [111], [112]
on the Chapter11 process and its efficiency is surveyedin argue that the coalition of equity and the bank makes
Section IV.B. A summary of Bi and Levy [26] is also continuation decisions based on its private gains from
includedthere.Aspects of financialdistressamongbanks restructuring.This decisionto continueor to liquidatemay
andturnaroundstrategiesarealso discussedin thatsection, not be efficient. Coordinationproblemswhich arise in the
along with the contributionsof DeGennaro, Lang, and presenceof multiplecreditorsareanalyzedin Gertnerand
Thomson [38] and Barrowand Horvitz [17]. Scharfstein[50] and Bolton and Scharfstein[28]. Gertner
and Scharfstein[50] arguethat the benefit of bankruptcy
A. Efficiencyof the BankruptcyProcedure is that, in Chapter 11, unanimity of debtholdersis not
Financial contracts specify how resources are to be requiredto effect changes in the debt contract.This miti-
allocatedbetween investorsand firms.Bankruptcyproce- gates holdoutproblemsand, along with the otherfeatures
dureswhich governthe breachof contractualpromisesare of currentbankruptcylaw (automaticstay and violations
generally containedin the legal system and not specified of absolutepriorityrule), tends to increaseinvestment.
The net benefit of such increasedinvestmentdepends
on the incentives generated by the characteristicsof
9The absolute priority rule (APR) states that creditorsshould be fully
contracts-in-place,such as maturitystructure,covenants
compensatedbefore shareholdersreceive any portion of the bankrupt
firm'svalue.Recentempiricalstudies,however,have shownthatthis rule and the priorityof privateversus public debt. The Bank-
is seldom followed (see Section IV.B.). ruptcyCode improvesefficiency when underinvestmentis

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
JOHN/ MANAGING
FINANCIAL
DISTRESS 69

a problem(e.g., when the firmhas short-termpublic debt, the argumentsover valuationand liquidationare avoided,
senior bank debt, and the public debt has senioritycove- the risk-shiftingincentives in investmentpolicy induced
nants). by APR allocation will remain prior to entering bank-
Berkovitchand Israel[22] show thatfirmsfacing over- ruptcy.To strikea balance between conflicting efficiency
investmentincentives are more likely to file for Chapter objectives, White [113] proposes biasing the allocation
11 protection,while firms facing underinvestmentincen- towardsequity and managementdeviatingfrom strictad-
tives aremore likely to renegotiatein a workout.Bebchuk herence to APR (similar in spirit to Eberhartand Senbet
[19] points to more acute incentives to overinvestin the [43]). Zender[117], Aghion andBolton [1], andKalayand
presence of deviationsfrom absolutepriorityrules, when Zender[83] deriveoptimalcontractsunderwhich control
firms are not in financialdistress. of the firm is transferredand claims are adjustedwhen
Eberhartand Senbet [43] demonstratein a contingent performanceis sufficientlypoor.The above studies really
claims framework,thatAPR violationsplay an important address the question of an efficient process of resolving
role in amelioratingthe shareholder/bondholder agency financial distress, given the firm is in financial distress.
conflict. Specifically, departuresfrom the APR mitigate However a bankruptcyprocess which resolves financial
the incentivefor shareholdersto increasethe risk of finan- distress efficiently is only consideringhalf the picture.If
cially distressedfirms.Moreover,the effectiveness of this resolutionof defaultis maderelativelycostless thenit may
mitigation increases as the firm approachesbankruptcy encouragedefaulttoo often andraisingfinancingformany
and as traditionalmethods,such as conversionprivileges, worthwhileprojectsmay become difficult.In otherwords,
lose effectiveness. Berkovitchand Israel [22], and Kalay there may be a tension between efficiency of ex post
and Zender[83] make relatedarguments. resolution of default and ex ante contractualefficiency.
Most of the papers summarizedabove take the bank- This has to be a considerationin the design of an optimal
ruptcy procedure as a given and examine its effect on bankruptcylaw.11
aspects of investmentefficiency. Anothergrowing litera- A relatedpoint is that optimal bankruptcylaw cannot
ture has begun to address issues of optimal design of be analyzed independentlyof optimal security design.
bankruptcyrules.Bebchuk[18], White [113], Bradleyand After all, bankruptcylaw specifies rules governing the
Rosenzweig [29], Aghion et al [2], Zender[117], Aghion breachof stipulatedcontractualtermsin specific financial
and Bolton [1], Kalay and Zender [83], Harrisand Raviv contracts. For example, debt contracts specify the
[59], Altman [12], Easterbrook[42], Merton [91], and debtholder'sinvestment,the specific paymentsto which
Berkovitch, Israel, and Zender [23] are attempts in this he is entitled, and covenantsincludingconstraintson the
direction. borrower's behavior (see John and Kalay [72]). Bank-
Roe [100], Bebchuk [18], White [113], Bradley and ruptcyrules specify the legal proceduresto be followed if
Rosenzweig [29], and Aghion et al [2] containproposals the promisedpaymentsare not made or if the covenants
of reformwhich involve implementinga "textbook"pro- are violated. Therefore,design of an optimalbankruptcy
cedureof selling the firmanddividingthe proceedsamong procedure should be viewed in combination with the
creditorsand old equityholdersaccordingto the APR. The broaderproblemof optimalcontractdesign.
new owners of the firm would make decisions about HarrisandRaviv [59] takean importantfirststep in this
whetherto continueoperationsor liquidateandwhetherto directionof designingan optimalbankruptcyprocedureas
retain the old managersor to replace them. They would a part of an overall contractdesign problem. They ap-
choose the alternativeswith the highest value. An advan- proachthe problemof contractdesign as one of choosing
tage of these proposalsis thatthe firm would end up with a game to be played among the partiesto the contractas
an all-equitycapital structureat the end of the bankruptcy opposed to choosing a contingentallocations scheme. In
procedure which would avoid the waste and delays of anenvironmentof incompletecontracting(wherethereare
intergroupconflictsandprotractedbargaining.10Although restrictionson the kinds allocationschemes which can be
enforced), the allocations of resourcescan sometimes be
loAghion,Hart,and Moore [2] and Altman [12] contain evaluationsof
some of these reformproposals.Easterbrook[42] arguesthatthe cost of
liquidationsandauctionsmay be largeenoughtojustify the currentcostly 1"Bolton and Scharfstein[28] use this trade-offin their analysisof some
bankruptcyprocess. Roe [101], Baird [16], Bebchuk [18], Bradleyand aspects of debt structure:the numberof creditorsa company borrows
Rosenzweig [29], and Weiss [110] criticize the existing bankruptcy from; the allocationof security interestamong creditors;the intercredit
procedure. covenantsgoverningrenegotiationof debt contracts.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
70 FINANCIAL
MANAGEMENT
/ AUTUMN1993

improvedby designing a game in which players respond Whendebtis restructured


increasingequityorconvertible
to actions and/or statementsmade by other players. The components,the incentivefeaturesin the compensation
improvementis possible because equilibriumstrategies, structureshould be significantly increased. Gilson and
and hence outcomes, can depend on aspects of the envi- Vetsuypens[56] documentempiricalevidence consistent
ronment even though allocation schemes contingent on with these predictions.
such aspects are not enforceable.
The setting of the Harrisand Raviv model, similar to
thatin HartandMoore [60], is thatof an entrepreneurwho
B. EmpiricalEvidenceon the Chapter11
needs outside financing for a positive net present value Process
project.The cash flows generatedare appropriableby the The empiricalwork on the formal bankruptcyprocess
has been primarily on (i) direct and indirect costs of
entrepreneurbut not the proceeds from liquidation of
assets. The threat of seizing and liquidating the firm's bankruptcy,(ii) announcementeffects of bankruptcyfil-
assets (whicheliminatesa correspondingfractionof future ings, (iii) deviations from absolute priorityrule, and (iv)
cash flows) is the only way to induce the entrepreneurto efficiency of bankruptcyreorganizations.
pay out cash to investors. Since liquidation is strictly The legal, administrativeandadvisoryfees thatthe firm
suboptimalin every state of the world, an optimal bank- bears as a direct result of entering and undergoingthe
ruptcyprocedurewouldbe one whichminimizestheextent formalbankruptcyprocesshave been called "directbank-
of liquidation while providing sufficient payouts (cash ruptcy costs." Warner [108], [109] studies 11 railroad
and/orliquidationproceeds)to induceinvestorsto contrib- bankruptciesduring 1933 to 1955 and finds the average
ute the requiredcapital. Harrisand Raviv [59] show that directcosts to be about5.3% of firm'smarketvalue at the
debt with a bankruptcycourtwhich can impose violations time of the bankruptcyfiling. Ang et al [14] investigatea
of APR is a Pareto improvementrelative to contracts sample of 86 firms that filed for bankruptcy(and eventu-
without a bankruptcycourt.The additional,limited state- ally liquidated)in the WesternDistrict of Oklahomabe-
tween 1963 and 1979. Theyreportmeanandmediandirect
contingency achieved by the presence of a bankruptcy
court is shown to be sufficientto achieve optimal alloca- costs (as a percentage of total liquidationproceeds) of
tions in the Harrisand Raviv [59] environment.12 7.5% and 1.7%, respectively. More recently, Ferris,
Berkovitch, Israel, and Zender [23] argue that bank- Jayaraman,andMakhija[46] reportlargerdirectadminis-
trative costs of bankruptcyfor small firms, based on a
ruptcy law with a managementbias (which places the
managerin a favorablebargainingposition in renegotia- sampleof liquidationsand reorganizationsthatwere filed
tions) plays a role in providing the manager with the during 1981-1991 in the U.S. BankruptcyCourt(Western
correctex ante decision-makingincentives.Withoutsuch District of Tennessee). Their mean (median) costs are
a commitmentfeature of the bankruptcylaw, managers 27.73% (0.91%) of the assets reportedat the initiationof
will underinvestin developing firm-specifichumancapi- bankruptcy,and 41.49% (25.65%) of the total disburse-
ments at the end of the process. For reorganizations,they
tal.
find thatthe mean (median)costs are 21.55% (1.88%) of
JohnandJohn [78] studythe dynamicsof top-manage-
the reportedassets, and 15.10%(3.41%) of the total dis-
ment compensationin firms going throughfinancial dis-
bursements.These are higher than previously reported
tress. They arguethatthe amountand structureof external
estimates for reorganizationsby small and large firms.
claims outstandingaffect the design of top-management
Weiss [109] analyzes a sample of 37 firms that filed for
compensation.If the externalclaim is riskydebt,top-man-
bankruptcybetween 1980 and 1986, and finds average
agementcompensationshouldhave incentivefeaturesand directcosts to be 2.9%of the book value of assets priorto
pay-performancesensitivitythataredecreasingin the debt
filing.
ratioof the firm.When the firm is in financialdistress,the
Indirectcosts of bankruptcyareopportunitycosts aris-
pay-performancesensitivity should be extremely low.
ing from suboptimalactions associated with bankruptcy,
e.g., the firmlost its firstmoveradvantagein developinga
'2Inthe HarrisandRaviv [59] environment,any legal structurewhich can new productto a competitorwhen it was going throughthe
induce the additional(possibly limited) state-contingencyin outcomes
formal bankruptcyprocess. Lost sales and competitive
will accomplishthe optimalallocation,with a correspondingcontract.In
this sense, theirsolutionis not specific enoughto pinpointthe"attractive" advantage,higher operatingcosts, lost investmentoppor-
featuresthat a good bankruptcyprocedureshouldhave. Furtherwork is tunities,and loss of consumerconfidence are all potential
requiredin this area. indirectcosts. Gilson, John, and Lang [55] argue that all

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
DISTRESS
FINANCIAL
JOHN/ MANAGING 71

value lost throughdestructionof going-concernvalue rep- ber of recent studies document that APR is frequently
resentsindirectbankruptcycosts. They use "marketvalue violated in Chapter11 reorganizationsand informaldebt
+ replacementcosts"as a proxyfor these costs. Altman[8] restructurings,e.g., see Franksand Torous[47], Eberhart,
measuresthe differencebetween the earningsrealized in Moore, and Roenfeldt [44], and Weiss [109]. Eberhart,
each of the three years priorto bankruptcyand earnings Moore, and Roenfeldt [44] find that APR violations ac-
that could have been expected at the beginningof each of countfor 7.6%of the totalamountpaidout to all claimants
those years, to compute indirectcosts of bankruptcy.All and that they are anticipatedby investorsex ante. Franks
deviations of actual profits from their expected counter- and Torous[48] documentthatthe rateof APR violations
partsaredenotedas indirectcosts of bankruptcy.Although is largerin informalworkouts(+9%) comparedto that in
a good startingpoint, such a definitionwould include all Chapter11 reorganizations(+4%).
deviations from expected profits (even those which are Betker [25] explores the cross-sectionaldeterminants
unrelatedto financing). of equity's deviationfrom absolutepriorityin 75 Chapter
A numberof studies document a significant negative 11 reorganizations.EmpiricalevidenceindicatesthatAPR
abnormal return (around -16%) on announcement of deviation is larger when: the firm is closer to solvency;
bankruptcyfiling (e.g., Clarkand Weinstein[35], Gilson, bankshold fewer claims; the CEO holds more shares;the
John,and Lang [55], and Eberhart,Moore, and Roenfeldt firm'soriginalCEOis retainedor replacedfrom inside the
[44]). Bankruptcy announcement effects on the share firm;and CEO pay and shareholderwealth are positively
prices of competingfirmshave been investigatedby Lang related.See also LoPuckiand Whitford[89].13
and Stulz [86] (and in a small sample earlierby Aharony
and Swary [3]). Lang and Stulz [86] document that the Systematic empirical evidence on the efficiency of
bankruptcyreorganizationswould be importantto the
equity value of competing firms in the industry of the
study of mechanismsfor managingfinancialdistressand
bankruptfirm decreasedon the averageby one percentat
the time of bankruptcyannouncement.However,the stock understandingthe design of optimal bankruptcyproce-
dures. Hotchkiss [64], [65] contain the only available
prices of competing firms with low leverage in highly
evidence on the post-reorganizationperformanceof firms
concentratedindustriesincreasedby 2.2%.
In this special issue, Bi and Levy [26] examine the emerging from Chapter11. In Hotchkiss [65], she exam-
ines the performance of 197 public companies which
announcement effect of bond downgradings on stock
prices of downgradedfirms.Theirresultsprovideinsights emergedfrom Chapter11 bankruptcy.Almost 40% of the
into the dynamicsof the ratingprocess used by the rating samplefirmscontinueto experienceoperatinglosses in the
two years following bankruptcy,while over 16%file for
agencies, Moody's and Standard& Poor's. Their results
show thatthe averageabnormalreturnof the subsampleof Chapter11 for a second time. Managementoften retains
firms which subsequentlyfile for Chapter11 bankruptcy substantialinfluence over restructuringdecisions during
is significantlymore negativethanthe matchingsampleof bankruptcy,and frequentlyis not replaceduntil a plan of
firms which had a similardowngradingbut did not file for reorganizationhas been confirmed. The continued in-
Chapter11. Althoughthe authorsinterprettheirresultsto volvement of pre-bankruptcymanagementin the restruc-
signify that the market'sinformationis finer than that of turingprocess is stronglyassociatedwith poor post-bank-
the ratings agency, it may have more to do with the ruptcy performance. The substantial number of firms
dynamics of the ratingsprocess. If the ratings agency is emergingfrom Chapter11 which are not viable or which
conservativein their downgradings,such that the down- need furtherrestructuringsuggeststhattheremay be a bias
gradings are done in multiple stages, then the marketis towardcontinuationof unprofitablefirms. The evidence
simply reactingappropriatelyto the informationwhich is does not indicatethatthe Chapter11 reorganizationplays
already available to the market and the rating agency, an effective role in rehabilitatingdistressedfirms.
althoughnot fully reflectedin the partialinitialdowngrad-
ing. 13Anumberof theoreticalstudies (see, e.g., Brown [30], Giammarino
According to the absolute priorityrule (APR) of allo- [52], John and Vasudevan[74], and Bergman and Callen [20], [21])
cating the value of a bankruptfirm, the senior claimants suggestthatAPRviolationsare,in fact,rationalresponsesby bondholders
and the courts to debtor-managementbargainingpower engenderedby
receivetheirfull contractualpromisedpaymentbeforeany
the formalreorganizationprocess. Harrisand Raviv [59] arguethatAPR
class with a morejuniorclaim receives anything.Although violations may be partof an optimallydesigned bankruptcyprocedure.
APR is followed strictlyin Chapter7 liquidations,a num- See also Eberhartand Senbet [43].

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
72 FINANCIAL / AUTUMN1993
MANAGEMENT

Massive numbers of insolvencies have plagued the which have defaultedon theirdebt and/orfiled for protec-
thriftindustry(savings& loans (S&Ls)andmutualsavings tion underChapter11 bankruptcyas approximately$20.5
banks)throughoutthe 1980s and into the 1990s, which has billion ($42.6 billion in face value). Securitieswhichyield
led to the depletionof the governmentfund establishedto a minimum ten percent over comparablematurityU.S.
insure the deposits in these institutions.The costs of re- Treasurybonds, i.e., 16.6% or above, are estimated to
solving the thriftinsurancemess are estimatedto be $125 amountto $71 billion in parvalue (with severalissuersand
billion to $150 billion. Unlike industrialfirms in financial 600 issues) and about$37 billion in marketvalue. Adding
distress, which undertakeasset and/ordebt restructuring, privatedebt with public registrationrights, privatebank
thriftsoften operatein an insolventconditionfor extended debt and tradeclaims of defaultedand distressedcompa-
periods.DeGennaro,Lang,andThomson[38] andBarrow nies bringsthe totalbook value of defaultedanddistressed
and Horvitz [17] examine turnaroundstrategiesused by securitiesto $284 billion (marketvalue, $177 billion).14
troubledthriftsand theireffectiveness. Althoughthe markethas attracteda lot of attentionfrom
DeGennaroet al [38] examine a sample of 300 large investors, researchon models of valuationfor securities
insolventthrifts,of which 24%recoveredbetweenthe end with significantprobabilityof default is still preliminary.
of 1979 andthe end of 1989. They contrastthe turnaround Altman [9] underscoresthe institutionalfactorsof default,
strategiesadoptedby these recoveredinstitutionsto those restructuringandbankruptcyreorganizationsas important
used by thriftsthatfailed. When the crisis surfacedin the in valuing these securities.However,the existing models
early 1980s, these recoveringfirms operatedin a fashion of high-yield bonds do not explicitly incorporatethese
similarto failing firms.However,in the mid-i1980s,recov- factors in the valuationmodels. This is an importantarea
ering thriftspursuedrisk-minimizingstrategieswhile the for furtherresearch.
nonrecoveringthrifts pursued risky, high-growth strate- An importantingredientof valuationwhich has been
gies. They find no evidence thatmanagersof nonrecover- examined in the existing literatureis the probabilityof
ing thriftsconsumed more perquisitesthan their counter- default. Numerous studies have developed models that
parts. estimate the probabilityof default. Market-relatedmea-
Barrowand Horvitz [17] examine the performanceof sures of bond default probabilitieshave complemented
insolventthriftsunderthe ManagementConsignmentPro- traditionalcredit techniques which concentrateon firm-
gram (MCP). MCP was adopted,in 1985, by the Federal specific aspects of bonds. Creditquality upon initial issu-
Savings and Loan InsuranceCorporation(FSLIC) in an ance, that for seasoned bonds, bond rating changes over
attemptto minimize the acute adverseincentiveproblems time driven by changes in default probabilities,actual
present when insolvent thrift institutionsare allowed to default rate of bonds, have all been documented (see
continue in operation.The new managementteams, se- Altman [7], [10], and Altman,Eberhart,and Zekavat[13]
lected by federalregulatorsandcompensatedon a contract for a review of this literature).Altman, Eberhart,and
basis, were expectedto maintainservice to depositors,and Zekavat[13] studythe severityof defaultfor91 firms(with
improve the condition of the thrift's books and records, 232 bonds) that defaultedand emerged from Chapter 11
while more permanentsolutionswere explored. betweenJanuary1980 andJuly 1992.They documenttotal
The evidence indicates that the chances of the MCP losses investorswouldhave incurredif they boughta bond
institutions recovering to solvency were significantly at issuance and held it until completion of bankruptcy
lower than the chances of similarlyinsolvent institutions reorganization.
thatwere allowed to operateoutside of directgovernment Many of the previousstudies (see Altman [10, Ch. 6])
control.The authorsarguethatthis is a consequenceof the estimate the unconditionalprobabilitythata firm will file
absence of a profit motive and the induced conservative bankruptcy.These studiesgenerallyanalyzematchedsam-
strategiesunderMCP. ples of bankruptandnonbankruptfirms,using accounting
informationand other firm characteristicsas explanatory
V.Valuationof Distressed Securities
As the numberand diversity of financially distressed 14Theseestimatesare from Altman [11]. Altman[9], 11] also describes
firmshave increased,the marketfor distressedfirms'debt the market for these securities and analyzes their performance.The
Altman-MerrillLynch & Co. Index of Defaulted Debt Securities(mar-
andequitysecuritieshas capturedthe interestof the invest-
ket-weightedmeasureof 233 differentdefaultedsecuritiesfrom 89 firms)
ment community.As of August 31, 1992, Altman [11] is reported on a monthly basis by Merrill Lynch and also on the
estimates the marketvalue of the debt securitiesof firms Bloombergsystem. See also Altman [10].

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
FINANCIAL
JOHN/ MANAGING DISTRESS 73

variables.Gilson, John, and Lang [55] estimate the prob- option pricing theory to value corporateliabilities with
ability of Chapter 11 conditional on the firm being in various contractualfeatures. Merton [90] examined the
financialdistress.They studyhow asset andliabilitystruc- risk structureof interestrates and Ingersoll [66] used this
tures help predict whether financial distress is resolved correspondenceto valueconvertibleandcallablecorporate
througha privateworkoutor throughformal bankruptcy liabilities. These arejust two examplesof the valuationof
underChapter11. corporatesecuritieswhich may be addressedusing option
A contributionin this area is made by Coats and Fant pricing theory (see Park and Subrahmanyam[98] for a
[36]. They apply a "neuralnetwork"to the estimationof surveyof this literature).
the futurefiscal healthof corporations.The distinctadvan- While the insights offered by this researchare import-
tages of this new methodology for recognizing arbitrary ant,the abilityof this approachto explainthe yield spreads
discriminatingpatternsin financial data are highlighted. between corporate bonds and comparable default-free
The commonly used tool for classificationand prediction Treasurybondshas been questionedin recentpapers.The
is a multiple discriminantanalysis (MDA) of financial empirical findings of Jones, Mason, and Rosenfeld [80]
ratios. But the MDA technique has limitations deriving indicatethatexisting contingentclaims pricingmodels do
from its relianceon the assumptionsof linearseparability, not generatethe levels of yield spreadswhich one observes
multivariatenormality,andindependenceof the predictive in practice.Over the 1926-1986 period, the yield spreads
variables. A neural network, being free from such con- on high-gradecorporates(AAA-rated)rangedfrom 15 to
215 basispointsandaveraged77 basispoints;andtheyield
strainingassumptions,is able to achieve superiorresults.
The neuralnetworkmodel in theirpaperuses the Cascade- spreadson BAAs (also investment-grade)rangedfrom 51
Correlationapproachin Fahlmanand Lebiere [45]. to 787 basis points, and averaged 198 points. Kim,
An importantdeterminantof the value of distressed Ramaswamy,and Sundaresan[85] show that the conven-
securities is the lack of liquidity and marketability(see tional contingent claims model due to Merton [90] is
Altman [10]). This is also an importantinstitutionalfactor unableto generatedefaultpremiumsin excess of 120 basis
which has not been incorporatedinto the valuationmodels points, even when excessive debt ratios and volatility
of distressedsecurities.Shulman,Bayless, andPrice [103] parametersare used in the numericalsimulation.
take an importantstep in this direction.They examine the The contingentclaims models mentionedabove do not
determinantsof yields, relativeto Treasuries,for an exten- incorporatemany real world institutionalfeatures of de-
sive sampleof individual,seasoned,high-yieldbonds.The faultandthe Chapter11 bankruptcy.The settingallows for
no frictions as in Miller and Modigliani [93]. The typical
impactof defaulton yield spreadsfor individualhigh-yield
bonds is incorporatedusing a default model which pro- boundaryconditionused in these models to denote bank-
duces an expected probabilityof default for each bond. ruptcyis thatof strictabsolutepriorityrule triggeredwhen
Default risk, along with marketabilityrisk and otherchar- firm value falls below the promisedprincipalpayment.15
The entire firm value without any liquidation costs is
acteristics on yield spreads is modelled using a factor
assumed to be passed to bondholders in default. This
analytic (LISREL)technique.The empiricalresults indi-
cate that both marketabilityrisk and default risk are im- assumption is at odds with reality in several important
ways: (i) as definedin Section I, the cash-flow criterionof
portantin explaining yield spreadsfor high-yield bonds. default happens when the currentliquidity of the firm is
Additional refinements among criteria discussed in this
inadequateto meet its currentobligations, say, required
paper should lead to a more rigorousanalysis of market-
coupon payments; (ii) asset liquidationsinvolve signifi-
ability and betterpricing of high-yield bonds. cant costs of liquidityandloss of going-concernvalue (see
Since default risk and the losses to bondholders in
Section II); (iii) there are importantstrategic aspects to
default are importantdeterminantsof high-yield debt, a
defaults,debtrenegotiations(in privateworkoutsor Chap-
large traditionalliteraturehas focused on the probability ter 11 reorganizations)and liquidationswhich affect allo-
of defaultfrom asset andliabilitycharacteristicsand other
cation of value (see Section III); (iv) there are significant
financialratios of the firm. However,these techniquesdo
deviationsfrom absolutepriorityrule in the allocationsin
not value completely the defaultrisk definedby the prob-
the bankruptcyprocess (see Section IV.B.).These institu-
ability of default as well as the payout at default. The tional features of default and its resolution should be
correspondencebetween the option to defaultin corporate
bondsunderlimitedliabilityandstock options,recognized
in Black and Scholes [27], led to many applicationsof the 15Geske [51] considerscoupon defaults,as well.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
74 FINANCIAL
MANAGEMENT
/ AUTUMN1993

incorporatedinto valuationmodels of securitieswhich are poorerperformance?How do these strategiesaf-


in distress or have a high probabilityof distress. To my fect firm performanceafter distress and/orbank-
knowledge, none of the existing models accomplish this ruptcyreorganization?17 (See Section II.)
task. (ii) Thereis some documentedevidencethatthe nature
Kim, Ramaswamy,and Sundaresan[85] take an im- of the debt contract,the complexity of the capital
portantstep in this direction.They incorporatefeature(i) structure, the number of creditors involved,
above into their model and focus on the default risk of whetherthe debt is publicor privatedebt andwhat
coupons in the presence of dividends and interest rate fractionof debt is bankdebt, are all factorswhich
uncertainty.Numerical solutions are employed to show could affect the success of a relatively low-cost
thatthe resultingyield spreadsare sensitiveto interestrate
privateworkout.Empiricalwork relatingfeatures
expectationsbut not to the volatility of the interestrates. andinnovationsin financialcontractingto the costs
Interactionbetween call provisions and default risk in
and difficulty of resolving default would be inter-
determiningyield spreadsis explicitly analyzed to show
thatthe call provisionhas a differentialeffect on Treasury esting. Theoreticalwork in this area is not exten-
sive and further work is needed.18 The general
issues relative to corporateissues. They also show that
theirmodel is capableof generatingyield spreadsconsis- problem is that of optimal security design with
tent with levels observedin practice. particularemphasis on renegotiatingthe contract
in certaincontingencies.Inmanyinterestingcases,
Longstaff and Schwartz [88] present a simple frame-
the reductionof costs in ex post renegotiationmay
workof valuingriskydebt wherethey allow for deviations
come at the expense of ex ante contractualineffi-
from APR. They are able to derive simple closed-form
valuationexpressionsfor riskyfixed-rateandfloating-rate ciency. For example, if resolution of default is
debt as well as for interest-rateswaps where one or both made less costly, the incentive effect of the debt
of the counterpartiesmay default.16Their model also contractmay also be weaker.These trade-offsmay
generates credit spreads similar to actual credit yield interesting results. (See Sections III and
spreads. IV.A.)
(iii) Our knowledge of workoutsof public debt is pre-
VI.An Agenda for FutureResearch liminary. What are the features of an optimally
designeddistressedexchangeoffer?Whatlegal or
and Conclusions
regulatoryreform can improve the prospects for
Some promisingareasandtopics for futureresearchare
publicdebtworkouts?Whatrolecan marketmech-
suggestedby the currentliteraturesurveyedin Sections II, anisms play to facilitate painless renegotiationof
III,IV,andV.They arelisted below withthe corresponding public debt?On all these questions,both theoreti-
section indicatedin parentheses. cal andempiricalworkis needed.(See SectionIII.)
(i) What is the relationshipbetween the structureand
(iv) The role of banks in facilitatingdebt workoutsor
characteristicsof the assets and the natureof the
externalclaims used for financing?For example, relatively costless Chapter 11 reorganizations
needs furtherstudy. If the bank is an informed
should assets with high cost of liquidation,organ-
creditorit may have a special role in the manage-
ized in a single division (as opposed to multiple
ment of financial distress (existing evidence is
divisions),with a high degreeof focus, be financed
with softer contracts?Should the contractinclude mixed). Comparisonswith othercountriessuch as
featuresto facilitatelow-cost debtworkouts?What Japanand Germanywhere the banksplay a more
arethe dynamicsof asset sales andliquidationsfor active role would be fruitful.The role of banks in
a firm going throughfinancial distress, workouts debt restructuringmay bear in importantways on
and/or formal bankruptcyprocess? Should the the current debate on "universalbanking," i.e.,
more liquid assets be sold earlieror the ones with whether banks should be allowed to underwrite

16Brown and Smith [33] consider two innovations,market-to-market 17Hotchkiss[64] exploressome aspectsof the dynamicsof asset sales and
swaps andforwardrate swaps, as mechanismsfor managingdefaultrisk post-bankruptcyperformanceof firms.
in swaps,andfind thatthe formermanagesriskmost effectively.See also 'sSee Diamond[39], [40] andBolton andScharfstein[28] for theoretical
Ramaswamyand Sundaresan[99]. work in this directionand Opler [97] for empiricalwork.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
FINANCIAL
JOHN/ MANAGING DISTRESS 75

securitiesand/orhold equityin borrowingfirms.19 optimal bankruptcyprocedure.Furtherempirical


(See Section III.) work relatingpost-reorganizationperformanceof
(v) What is the role of managementand the board of firms with specific featuresof the Chapter11 pro-
directorsin financial distress?There is some evi- cess would also be fruitful(see Hotchkiss[64] and
dence to suggest (a) managerialturnoverin finan- Section IV.B.).
cially distressedfirms is significantlyhigher than (ix) A systematic study of strategicbankruptcyfilings
poorly performing but nondistressed firms; (b) is yet to be done. (See Section IV.B.)
managerialactions do not seem to be responsible (x) What are the public policy aspects of corporate
for Chapter11 filings;20and (c) incumbentman- limited liability,default, financialdistress and re-
agersoften retaintheirjobs throughthe Chapter11 organization?What are the social costs? Should
process until confirmationof the reorganization debtfinancingbe encouragedby the social planner
plan. Furtherwork is needed to sort out several by giving it preferentialtax treatment(i.e., tax
issues: (a) Is the increasedmanagerialturnoverin
deductibilityof interestpayments)?See John and
financialdistressproductive?(b) Why does finan- Senbet [73] and Miller [92].
cial distress, ratherthan declines in performance
below presettargetlevels, triggermanagementre- (xi) It has been noted thatvaluationof debt and equity
securities with significant probabilityof default
placement? (c) Are managerial compensation
structuresdesigned to provide the correct incen- and/or bankruptcyis a promising area for future
research.The existing models do not incorporate
tives in financial distress?What are the incentive
effects of financial distress on management,and payouts to these claims being determinedby the
strategic aspects of the methods of resolution of
consequently,on investment,productivity,and ef- default (such as workoutsand/orChapter11 reor-
ficiency? (See Sections IV.A. and IV.B.)
ganization).Evaluationof investmentstrategiesin
(vi) A systematic study of sources and strategies of distressedsecurities(which may involve accumu-
financing while in financial distress, including lating a controllingshareof bonds and participat-
debtor-in-possession(DIP) financing, is yet to be ing in the negotiationsas a dominantplayerand/or
done. (See Section IV.B.)
acquiringcontrol in the reorganizedfirm) is also
(vii) Design of an optimal bankruptcyprocedureis a interesting.Valuationof distressedsecurities and
challenging avenue for furtherwork. The import- designing investmentstrategiesin these securities
ance of ajoint solutionto the problemof designing areresearchareasof high promise.(See SectionV.)
an optimal securityand an optimal legal structure I have surveyed the fairly extensive theoretical and
to resolve breach of contractualterms has been
empirical literatureon the mechanismsfor managingfi-
discussed in Section IV.A. Althoughan important nancial distress and resolving default in Sections II, III,
stephas been takenin HarrisandRaviv [59], many and IV. Althoughmuchhas been learned,many important
important aspects of the problem remain. (See aspectsrequirefurtherstudy.The literatureon valuationof
Section IV.A.) distressedsecuritiesis surveyedin Section V. Developing
(viii) On the empiricalside, a systematiccomparative models for valuationof distressedsecuritiesand strategies
study of the featuresandefficiency characteristics for investing in them, incorporatingstrategic aspects of
of the bankruptcyprocedurein the differentcoun- default and resolution, is a promising area for futurere-
tries(UnitedStates,Japan,Germany,U.K., France, search.
Netherlands,etc.) is yet to be done. Insights from
such research will facilitate conceptualizing an
References
1. P. Aghion and P. Bolton, "An 'IncompleteContracts'Approachto
19Berlin,John,and Saunders[24] andJohn,John,and Saunders[79] are Bankruptcyand the OptimalFinancial Structureof the Firm,"Re-
theoreticalmodels of universalbanking.Section III.D. surveysrelevant view of EconomicStudies (July 1992), pp. 473-494.
empiricalevidence on debt workouts. 2. P. Aghion, O.D. Hart,andJ. Moore,"TheEconomicsof Bankruptcy
20Khannaand Poulsen [84] studyboth the kind and perceivedqualityof Reform,"JournalofLaw, Economics,& Organization,forthcoming
decisions managers take over a three-yearperiod prior to their firm 1993.
making a Chapter 11 filing. Based on comparisons with a matched 3. J. Aharony and I. Swary, "ContagionEffects of Bank Failures:
sample,they concludethatexogenousfactors,andnot managerialincom- Evidence from CapitalMarkets,"Journal of Business (July 1983),
petence or their self-serving decisions, led to the bankruptcyfiling. pp. 305-322.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
76 FINANCIAL
MANAGEMENT
/ AUTUMN1993

4. F Allen, "The ChangingNatureof Debt and Equity:A Financial 26. K. Bi and H. Levy, "MarketReaction to Bond DowngradingsFol-
Perspective,"in Are the DifferencesBetweenEquityand Debt Dis- lowed by Chapter 11 Filings," Financial Management (Autumn
appearing?, R.W. Kopcke and E.S. Rosengren (eds.), Conference 1993), pp. 156-162.
Series No. 33, 1989, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1990, pp. 27. F. Black and M. Scholes, "The Pricing of Options and Corporate
12-38. Liabilities,"Journal of Political Economy (January/March1973),
5. F. Allen and D. Gale, FinancialInnovationand RiskSharing,Cam- pp. 637-659.
bridge,MA, MIT Press, forthcoming1994. 28. P. Bolton and D.S. Scharfstein,"OptimalDebt Structurewith Mul-
6. E Allen and A. Winton,"CorporateFinancialStructure,Incentives tiple Creditors,"UnpublishedManuscript,MIT, 1993.
and OptimalContracting,"UnpublishedManuscript,Northwestern 29. M. Bradleyand M. Rosenzweig, "The UntenableCase for Chapter
University,1992. 11,"YaleLawJournal (March1992), pp. 1043-1095.
7. E.I. Altman, CorporateFinancial Distress, New York,John Wiley 30. D. Brown,"ClaimholderIncentiveConflictsin Reorganization:The
& Sons, 1983. Role of BankruptcyLaw," Review of Financial Studies (Spring
8. E.I. Altman, "A FurtherEmpiricalInvestigationof the Bankruptcy 1989), pp. 109-123.
Cost Question,"Journal of Finance (September 1984), pp. 1067- 31. D. Brown,C. James,andR. Mooradian,"AssetSales by Financially
1089. DistressedFirms,"UnpublishedWorkingPaper,Universityof Flor-
9. E.I. Altman,"Investingin DistressedSecurities,"TheAltman/Foot- ida, 1991.
hillReport on theAnatomyof DefaultedDebt and Equities,Foothill 32. D. Brown,C. James, and R. Mooradian,"TheInformationContent
Group, 1990. of Distressed RestructuringsInvolving Public and Private Debt
10. E.I. Altman, "DistressedSecurities,"Chicago,IL, ProbusPublish- Claims," Journal of Financial Economics (February 1993), pp.
ing, 1991. 93-118.
11. E.I. Altman, "The Market for Distressed Securities and Bank 33. K.C. Brown and D.J. Smith, "DefaultRisk and Innovationsin the
Loans,"TheAltman/FoothillReportII, FoothillGroup, 1992. Design of InterestRate Swaps,"Financial Management(Summer
12. E.I.Altman,"Evaluatingthe Chapter11 Bankruptcy-Reorganization
1993), pp. 94-105.
Process,"ColumbiaBusinessLaw Review(March 1993), pp. 1-25. 34. J. Bulow and J. Shoven, "The BankruptcyDecision," Bell Journal
13. E.I.Altman,A.C. Eberhart,andK. Zekavat,"Do PriorityProvisions
of Economics(Autumn 1978), pp. 437-456.
Protect a Bondholder's Investment?,"Unpublished Manuscript,
35. T. Clarkand M. Weinstein,"TheBehaviorof the CommonStock of
New YorkUniversity,1993.
BankruptFirms,"Journal of Finance (May 1983), pp. 489-504.
14. J. Ang, J. Chua, and J. McConnell, "The AdministrativeCosts of
36. P.K.Coats and L.F. Fant,"RecognizingFinancialDistress Patterns
CorporateBankruptcy:A Note,"Journalof Finance (March1982),
Using a Neural Network Tool," Financial Management(Autumn
pp. 219-226. 1993), pp. 142-155.
15. P. Asquith,R. Gertner,and D. Scharfstein,"Anatomyof Financial
37. A. Damodaran,K. John, and C.H. Liu, "FinancialDistress, Free
Distress: An Examination of Junk-Bond Issuers," Unpublished
Cash Flow and Changes in OrganizationalForm," Unpublished
Manuscript,MIT and Universityof Chicago, October 1991.
16. D. Baird,"TheUneasy Case for CorporateReorganizations,"Jour- Manuscript,New YorkUniversity,March 1992.
38. R.P.DeGennaro,L.H.P.Lang,andJ.B.Thomson,"TroubledSavings
nal of Legal Studies(January1986), pp. 127-147.
and Loan Institutions:TurnaroundStrategies Under Insolvency,"
17. J.M. Barrowand P.M. Horvitz, "Responseof Distressed Firms to
Financial Management(Autumn1993), pp. 163-175.
Incentives:ThriftInstitutionPerformanceUnder the FSLIC Man-
39. D. Diamond,"Debt MaturityStructureand LiquidityRisk,"Quar-
agementConsignmentProgram,"Financial Management(Autumn
terlyJournalof Economics(August 1991), pp. 709-737.
1993), pp. 176-184.
18. L. Bebchuk, "A New Approach to CorporateReorganizations," 40. D. Diamond, "Seniorityand Maturityof Debt Contracts,"Journal
HarvardLaw Review(February1988), pp. 775-804. of FinancialEconomics (June 1993), pp. 341-368.
19. L. Bebchuk,"TheEffects of Chapter11 and Debt Renegotiationon 41. M. Douglas-Hamilton,"CreditorLiabilities Resulting From Im-
Ex Ante CorporateDecisions," UnpublishedManuscript,Harvard properInterferencewith the Managementof a FinanciallyTroubled
Debtor,"BusinessLawyer(June 1975), pp. 343-365.
UniversityLaw School, 1991.
20. Y. Bergmanand J. Callen, "OpportunisticUnderinvestmentin Debt 42. F. Easterbrook,"Is CorporateBankruptcyEfficient?,"Journal of
FinancialEconomics(October 1990), pp. 411-417.
Renegotiations,and CapitalStructure,"Journal of Financial Eco-
nomics (March 1991), pp. 137-171. 43. A.C. Eberhartand L.W. Senbet,"AbsolutePriorityRule Violations
21. Y. Bergman and J. Callen, "Rational Deviations from Absolute and Risk Incentives for Financially Distressed Firms,"Financial
PriorityRules,"UnpublishedManuscript,HebrewUniversity,1992. Management(Autumn1993), pp. 101-116.
22. E. Berkovitchand R. Israel, "The BankruptcyDecision and Debt 44. A.C. Eberhart,W. Moore, and R. Roenfeldt,"SecurityPricingand
ContractRenegotiations,"UnpublishedManuscript,University of Deviationsfromthe Absolute PriorityRule in BankruptcyProceed-
Michigan, 1991. ings," Journal of Finance (December 1990), pp. 1457-1470.
23. E. Berkovitch, R. Israel, and J. Zender, "The Design of Bankruptcy 45. S.E. Fahlman and C. Lebiere, "The Cascade-Correlation Learning
Law: The Case for Management Bias in Bankruptcy Reorganiza- Architecture," Technical Report: CMU-CS-90-100, Carnegie Mel-
tions," Unpublished Manuscript, University of Michigan, 1992. lon University, February 1990.
24. M. Berlin, K. John, and A. Saunders, "Should Banks Hold Equity in 46. S.P. Ferris, N. Jayaraman and A.K. Makhija, "Direct Costs of Bank-
Borrowing Firms?," Unpublished Manuscript, New York University, ruptcy: Evidence from Filings of Liquidations and Reorganizations
July 1992. by Small Firms, 1981-1991," Unpublished Manuscript, Georgia
25. B. Betker, "Equity's Bargaining Power and Deviations from Abso- Institute of Technology, 1993.
lute Priority in Chapter 11 Bankruptcies," Unpublished Manuscript, 47. J. Franks and W. Torous, "An Empirical Investigation of U.S. Firms
Ohio State University, 1993. in Reorganization," Journal of Finance (July 1989), pp. 747-770.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
FINANCIAL
JOHN/ MANAGING DISTRESS 77

48. J. FranksandW.Torous,"HowFirmsFarein WorkoutsandChapter 71. K. John and T.A. John, "PrivateCorporateFunding," The New
11 Reorganizations,"UnpublishedManuscript,Universityof Cali- Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, McMillianPress Ref-
fomrniaat Los Angeles, January1991. erence Books, 1992.
49. R. Gertner,"CapitalStructureSignallingin DistressedDebtRestruc- 72. K. John and A. Kalay, "Costly Contractingand Optimal Payout
turings,"UnpublishedManuscript,Universityof Chicago, 1991. Constraints,"Journal of Finance (May 1982), pp. 457-470.
50. R. Gertner and D. Scharfstein, "A Theory of Workoutsand the 73. K. John and L.W. Senbet, "LimitedLiability,Tax Deductibilityof
Effects of ReorganizationLaw," Journal of Finance (September CorporateDebt and Public Policy, UnpublishedManuscript,New
1991), pp. 1189-1222. YorkUniversity,1989.
51. R. Geske, "The Valuationof CorporateLiabilities as Compound 74. K. John and G.K. Vasudevan,"Bankruptcyand Reorganization:A
Options,"Journal of Financial and QuantitativeAnalysis (Novem- Theory of the Choice Between Workoutsand Chapter11," Unpub-
ber 1977), pp. 541-582. lished Manuscript,New YorkUniversity,December 1992.
52. R. Giammarino,"TheResolutionof FinancialDistress,"Reviewof 75. T.A. John,"AccountingMeasuresof CorporateLiquidity,Leverage,
Financial Studies (Spring 1989), pp. 25-47. and Costs of FinancialDistress,"Financial Management(Autumn
53. S.C. Gilson, "ManagementTurnoverand FinancialDistress,"Jour- 1993), pp. 91-100.
nal of Financial Economics(December 1989), pp. 241-262. 76. T.A. John,"Optimalityof Spin-Offsand Allocation of Debt,"Jour-
54. S.C. Gilson, "Bankruptcy,Boards,Banks,and Stockholders,"Jour- nal of Financial and QuantitativeAnalysis (March 1993), pp. 139-
nal of Financial Economics(October 1990), pp. 355-388. 160.
55. S.C. Gilson, K. John, and L. Lang, "TroubledDebt Restructurings: 77. T.A. John and K. John, "Optimalityof Project Financing:Theory
An EmpiricalStudyof PrivateReorganizationof Firmsin Default," and EmpiricalImplicationsin Financeand Accounting,"Reviewof
Journal of Financial Economics (October 1990), pp. 315-353. QuantitativeFinance and Accounting(January1991), pp. 51-74.
56. S.C. Gilson and M.R. Vetsuypens,"CEO Compensationin Finan- 78. T.A. Johnand K. John,"Top-Management Compensationand Cap-
ital Structure,"Journalof Finance (July 1993), pp. 949-974.
cially DistressedFirms:An EmpiricalAnalysis,"Journalof Finance
79. T.A. John,K. John,and A. Saunders,"UniversalBankingand Firm
(June 1993), pp. 425-458.
57. M. Harris and A. Raviv, "Optimal Security Design: A Survey," Risk-Taking,"Journalof Bankingand Finance, forthcoming1994.
80. E.P. Jones, S.P. Mason, and E. Rosenfeld, "ContingentClaims
UnpublishedManuscript,NorthwesternUniversity,1990.
58. M. HarrisandA. Raviv,"TheTheoryof CapitalStructure,"Journal Analysis of CorporateCapital Structure:An EmpiricalInvestiga-
tion,"Journal of Finance (July 1984), pp. 611-625.
of Finance (March 1991), pp. 297-356.
81. M. KahanandB. Tuckman,"Do BondholdersLose fromJunkBond
59. M. Harrisand A. Raviv, "The Design of BankruptcyProcedures,"
CovenantChanges?,"Journal of Business (October1993).
Unpublished Working Paper, Northwestern University, October 82. K.M. Kaiser,"A Model of Chapter11 Reorganizationwith Asym-
1991.
metric Informationand Delay," UnpublishedManuscript,North-
60. O. Hart and J. Moore, "Default and Renegotiation:A Dynamic
westernUniversity,November 1990.
Model of Debt,"UnpublishedManuscript,MIT,May 1989.
83. A. Kalay andJ. Zender,"BankruptcyandStateContingentChanges
61. R. Haugen and L.W. Senbet, "The Insignificance of Bankruptcy
in the Ownershipof Control,"UnpublishedManuscript,University
Costs to the Theory of Optimal Capital Structure,"Journal of
of Utah, 1992.
Finance (June 1978), pp. 383-393.
84. N. Khannaand A.B. Poulsen, "Managersof FinanciallyDistressed
62. R. Haugenand L.W. Senbet,"Bankruptcyand Agency Costs:Their
Firms:Villains or Victims?,"UnpublishedManuscript,University
Significanceto the Theoryof OptimalCapitalStructure,"Journalof of Michigan, 1992.
Financial and QuantitativeAnalysis (March1988), pp. 27-38.
85. I.J.Kim, K. Ramaswamy,and S. Sundaresan,"Does DefaultRisk in
63. T. Hoshi, A. Kashyap,and D. Scharfstein,"The Role of Banks in
Coupons Affect the Valuationof CorporateBonds?: A Contingent
Reducing the Costs of Financial Distress in Japan,"Journal of Claims Model," Financial Management(Autumn 1993), pp. 117-
Financial Economics (October 1990), pp. 67-88. 131.
64. E. Hotchkiss,"Does Chapter11 Lead to EfficientInvestmentDeci- 86. L.H. LangandR.M. Stulz,"ContagionandCompetitiveIntra-indus-
sions?,"DoctoralDissertation,New YorkUniversity,March 1992. tryEffectsof BankruptcyAnnouncements:An EmpiricalAnalysis,"
65. E. Hotchkiss,"ThePost-BankruptcyPerformanceof FirmsEmerg- Journalof Financial Economics(August 1992), pp. 45-61.
ing from Chapter11,"UnpublishedManuscript,New YorkUniver- 87. L. Lang, A. Poulsen, and R.M. Stulz, "Asset Sales, Leverage,and
sity, 1992. the Agency Costs of ManagerialDiscretion,"Journal of Financial
66. J.E. Ingersoll,Jr., "A Contingent-ClaimsValuationof Convertible Economics,forthcoming1994.
Securities,"Journal of Financial Economics (May 1977), pp. 289- 88. F.A. Longstaff and E.S. Schwartz,"ValuingRisky Debt: A New
322. Approach,"UnpublishedManuscript,University of California at
67. M.C. Jensen, "Active Investors, LBOs, and the Privatizationof Los Angeles, 1992.
Bankruptcy," Journalof AppliedColporateFinance (Spring 1989), 89. L. LoPucki and W. Whitford,"BargainingOver Equity's Share in
pp. 35-44. Reorganizationof Large Publicly Held Companies,"Universityof
68. M.C. Jensen, "CorporateControl and the Politics of Finance," PennsylvaniaLaw Review (November 1990), pp. 125-196.
Journalof AppliedCorporateFinance (Summer 1991), pp. 13-33. 90. R.C. Merton,"OnPricingof CorporateDebt: The Risk Structureof
69. M.C. Jensen and W.H. Meckling, "Theoryof the Firm:Managerial InterestRates,"Journalof Finance (May 1974), pp. 449-469.
Behavior,Agency Costs andCapitalStructure,"Journal of Financial 91. R.C. Merton, "No-FaultDefault: A Possible Remedy for Certain
Economics (December 1976), pp. 305-360. DysfunctionalConsequencesof CorporateLeverage,"Unpublished
70. K. JohnandT.A. John,"Copingwith FinancialDistress:A Survey," Manuscript,HarvardUniversity,December 1991.
Financial Markets,Institutionsand Instruments(December 1992), 92. M.H. Miller,"Leverage,"Nobel MemorialPrizeLecture,The Royal
pp. 63-78. Swedish Academyof Sciences, Stockholm, 1990.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
78 FINANCIAL
MANAGEMENT
/ AUTUMN1993

93. M.H. Miller and F. Modigliani,"The Cost of Capital,Corporation 105. S. Titmanand R. Wessels, "TheDeterminantsof CapitalStructure
Finance and the Theory of Finance,"American EconomicReview Choice,"Journalof Finance (March 1988), pp. 1-19.
(June 1958), pp. 261-297. 106. S.R. Walzer,"A Model of Reorganizationin Chapter 11 Bank-
94. S.C. Myers, "Determinantsof CorporateBorrowing,"Journal of ruptcy,"UnpublishedManuscript,StanfordUniversity,1991.
Financial Economics (November1977), pp. 147-176. 107. J. Warner,"Bankruptcy,AbsolutePriority,andthe Pricingof Risky
95. S.C. Myers and N. Majluf, "CorporateFinancingand Investment Debt Claims,"Journal of Financial Economics (May 1977), pp.
Decisions When FirmsHave InformationInvestorsDo Not Have," 239-276.
Journalof Financial Economics(June 1984), pp. 187-221. 108. J. Warner,"BankruptcyCosts:SomeEvidence,"Journalof Finance
96. E. Ofek,"CapitalStructureandFirmResponseto PoorPerformance: (May 1977), pp. 337-347.
An EmpiricalAnalysis,"Journal of Financial Economics, (August 109. L. Weiss, "BankruptcyResolution:Direct Costs and Violation of
1993), pp. 3-30. Priority of Claims," Journal of Financial Economics (October
97. T.C. Opler, "ControllingFinancial Distress Costs in Leveraged 1990), pp. 285-314.
Buyouts With FinancialInnovation,"Financial Management(Au- 110. L. Weiss, "BankruptcyJudgesOversteppingTheir Bounds:Com-
tumn 1993), pp. 79-90.
mentary,"Unpublished Manuscript,Tulane University, February
98. S.Y. Parkand M.G. Subrahmanyam,"OptionFeaturesof Corporate 1991.
Securities" in Financial Options.:From Theorxyto Practice, Dow
111. M.J.White,"PublicPolicy TowardBankruptcy:Me-FirstandOther
Jones Irwin, 1990.
Priority Rules," Bell Journal of Economics (Autumn 1980), pp.
99. K. RamaswamyandS. Sundaresan,"TheValuationof FloatingRate 550-564.
Instruments:Theoryand Evidence,"Journal of Financial Econom- 112. M.J. White, "BankruptcyCosts and the New BankruptcyCode,"
ics (December 1986), pp. 251-272.
Journalof Finance (May 1983), pp. 477-487.
100. M. Roe, "Bankruptcyand Debt: A New Model for Corporate
113. M.J. White, "The CorporateBankruptcyDecision," Journal of
Reorganization,"ColumbiaLaw Review(April 1983), pp. 527-602. EconomicPerspectives(Spring 1989), pp. 129-151.
101. M. Roe, "The Voting Prohibitionin Bond Workouts,"Yale Law
114. M.J. White, "Bankruptcy,Liquidation and Reorganization,"in
Journal (December 1987), pp. 232-279.
Handbookof ModernFinance, D.E. Logue (ed.), Warren,Gorham
102. L.W. Senbet and J. Seward, "FinancialDistress, Bankruptcyand
& Lamont,1990.
Reorganization,"in Finance Handbook,R. Jarrow,V. Maksimovic, 115. M.J.White,"CorporateBankruptcyas a FilteringDevice,"Unpub-
andW.Ziemba(eds.), Amsterdam,NorthHollandPublishers,forth-
lished Manuscript,Universityof Michigan, 1992.
coming 1994.
103. J. Shulman,M. Bayless, and K. Price, " Marketabilityand Default 116. K. Wruck,"FinancialDistress,Reorganization,andOrganizational
Influenceson the Yield Premiaof Speculative-GradeDebt,"Finan- Efficiency,"Journal of Financial Economics (October 1990), pp.
419-444.
cial Management(Autumn 1993), pp. 132-141.
104. A. Shleiferand R. Vishny,"LiquidationValuesand Debt Capacity: 117. J. Zender, "OptimalFinancial Instruments,"Journal of Finance
A MarketEquilibriumApproach,"Journal of Finance (September (December 1991), pp. 1645-1663.
1992), pp. 1343-1366.

This content downloaded from 185.44.79.22 on Fri, 13 Jun 2014 15:09:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like