You are on page 1of 79

The Battle for Brains:

How to Attract Talent


Simone Bertoli, Herbert Brücker, Giovanni Facchini,
Anna Maria Mayda and Giovanni Peri

XI European Conference on “Brain Gain and Brain Drain”


Pisa, May 23 2009

1
“I want to emphasize that to address the shortage of
scientists and engineers, we must do both – reform
our education system and our immigration policies.
If we don’t, American companies will simply not
have the talent they need to innovate and compete.”
Bill Gates, Testimony at the U.S. House of Representatives Committee
on Science and Technology on March 12, 2008

2
1 Introduction

 OECD countries increasingly realize the economic


rationale for skill-selective immigration policies
 However, only few countries have immigration
policies which systematically select highly skilled
immigrants in place at present
 Immigration policy reforms are characterized by a
status quo bias, which may change against the
background of skill-biased technological change,
increasing specialization on human capital intensive
activies and aging in the future

3
Key questions

 Which economic, legal and institutional factors


determine highly skilled migration?
 What is the impact of the brain gain on economies
in receiving countries?
 Why do so few countries adopt skill-selective
immigration policies at present?
 What will happen if the “battle for brains” unfolds
in the future? Do we need a coordination of
immigration policies?

4
Contents

 The evolution of skill-selective immigration policies


 Stylized facts on the brain gain
 Determinants of the brain gain
 Economic benefits from the brain gain
 The political economy of skill-selective
immigration policies
 Looking into the future: What happens if the
“battle for brains” unfolds?

5
2 Skill-selective immigration
policies
Two approaches
 “Immigrant driven” systems
 The immigrant is selected on basis of desirable
attributes, and he/she is admitted without necessarily
having a job offer. Typically they use point systems
 “Employer driven” systems
 The highly skilled worker is admitted only if he/she
has received an offer of employment

6
Immigrant driven systems

 Point based systems first introduced in CA in 1967,


then in AUS (1989) and NZ (1991)
 To be admitted migrants needs to meet a “pass rate”
 Typically points are attributed to five criteria
 Education
 Occupation
 Work experience
 Language proficiency
 Age
 Additional criteria are prior work in destination country;
education acquired in destination country, settlement
stipulations etc.

7
Employer driven systems

 Employers are key players. They sponsor


application for admission of a foreign worker
 Typically they need to carry out a labour
market test, to establish the non-availability
of a similarly skilled domestic worker
 Example: H1B visa program in USA

8
Skill selective policies in EU

 EU “blue card” initiative


 Attempt to draft a common policy to attract highly
skilled foreign immigrants, but only limited in scope.
In particular, no coordination in terms of setting
specific admission criteria
 But some steps forward
 Common broad criteria to qualify for admission under highly
skilled immigration program
 While movement within the EU of blue card holder is limited
for first two years, it becomes more open thereafter

9
EU latecomers

 UK implemented two-tier point system in 2008. Under


Tier 1 highly skilled can apply without job offer, under
Tier 2 medium and high skilled with job offer at hand
 Germany has devised a “green” card program to
attract highly skilled workers from abroad, but
quota has never been filled
 Italy does not have a policy to actively select highly
skilled workers. Only specific program in place is
focused on domestic helpers and care workers
 Spain has introduced quota system in 1993, which
targets specific occupations/sectors experiencing a
shortage. But this policy measure has been completely
overshadowed by illegal immigration

10
Evidence from fRDB data base:
Skill-selective policy reforms
3
Average 14 OECD Countries
1 0 2

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005


year

Source: Own compilation based on fRDB data base on immigration policies.


11
Evidence from UN survey data

 In 2007 UN have carried out survey of member


countries governments to investigate nature of policies
in place towards skilled immigrants
 Officials in only five countries (Bhutan, Botswana,
Jordan, Saudi Arabia and UAE) report to have policies
in place to reduce inflows of highly skilled workers
 59% of respondents report to have policies to maintain
current inflows of highly skilled, and 25% of
respondents report instead policies which are aimed at
increasing the number of skilled immigrants
 The battle for talents is beginning!

12
3 The size of the brain gain
 We address six questions:
 How big is the global pool of talent?
 Which OECD countries gain, which countries lose
talent through migration?
 Is the immigrant population favourably skill-selected
with respect to the home and host population?
 Is the admission of foreign students an important
gateway for highly skilled immigration?
 Do we observe at the top of the skill and occupational
distribution different patterns?
 Do highly skilled immigrants earn less than highly
skilled natives?
13
Data sources and limitations
 New data sets provide information on tertiary
educational attainment of immigrants by country
of origin relative to host and home population
 Docquier/Marfouk (2006); Beine et al. (2007); Defoort (2009)
 Derived from census and LFS data
 Problems
 Rough classification of highly skilled education level
 Human capital partially or entirely acquired in host
countries (“educational inlanders”)
 Limited transferability of human capital
 Latest data refer to 2000/01 census
 Complementary information on top of skill and
occupational distribution from census and OECD
sources used here

14
The global pool of talent

 About 338 million people with tertiary education


 191 million in high income countries
 29% of 25+ home population
 56 million in upper middle income countries
 12% of 25+ home population
 80 million in lower income countries
 5% of 25+ home population
 12 million in low income countries
 3% of 25+ home population
 Share of high income countries declines and
that of emerging economies increases
(e.g. South and East Asia)
15
Declining share of rich countries in
global pool of highly skilled, 1975-2000
70.00
share of source country group in stock of high skilled immigrants

60.00

50.00

high income countries


40.00
upper-middle income coountries

lower-middle income countries


30.00
low income countries

20.00

10.00

0.00
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

Source: Own calculations based on Defoort (2009).


16
Who wins, who loses?
 Almost 80 % of all highly skilled immigrants in the
OECD live in US, AUS, CA, UK and NZ
 Only 7 out of 30 OECD countries receive more highly
skilled immigrants from OECD countries than they
send to other OECD countries
 Only US, CA and AUS receive substantially more
highly skilled immigrants than they send abroad
 Countries without skill-selective immigration policies
and average or below average per capita GDP are
main losers in the competition for talent among OECD
countries
 MEX, POL
 ITA, DE, KOR, JAP but also UK

17
Immigrants with tertiary education,
2001
12,000,000
immigrants with tertiary education (persons)

10,000,000

8,000,000 all origin countries


OECD-30
6,000,000

4,000,000

2,000,000

LX
FR

N
SW Z

CZ
US
CA

UK
DE

M E
G X

DK
CH

N
NL

L
AT

PT
S

TK

NO E

E
K
R
E

PO
N

E
AU

IR

IC
IT
ES

JA

SV
FI
HU
KO
Source: Beine et al. (2007).

18
Immigrants with tertiary education,
2001
12,000,000
immigrants with tertiary education (persons)

10,000,000

8,000,000 all origin countries


OECD-30
6,000,000

4,000,000
Italy: 142,000, of which
58,000 from OECD
2,000,000

LX
FR

N
SW Z

CZ
US
CA

UK
DE

M E
G X

DK
CH

N
NL

L
AT

PT
S

TK

NO E

E
K
R
E

PO
N

E
AU

IR

IC
IT
ES

JA

SV
FI
HU
KO
Source: Beine et al. (2007).

19
Difference between highly skilled
immigrants from and highly skilled
emigrants in OECD-30, 2001
4,000,000
net difference between OECD immigrants and emigrants

3,500,000

3,000,000

2,500,000

2,000,000
(persons)

1,500,000

1,000,000

500,000

R
LX

H L

EX
H

Z
N
AT
FR

PT
S
S
A

BE

E
K

P
K

TK

P
A
E

KO L

K
E

PO
N

C
U

IC

IR
R

U
SV

ES

JA
AU

IT
O
C

SW

U
FI

M
-500,000

G
N

-1,000,000

-1,500,000
Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007). 20
Difference between highly skilled
immigrants from and highly skilled
emigrants in OECD-30, 2001
4,000,000
net difference between OECD immigrants and emigrants

3,500,000

3,000,000

2,500,000
Italy: 58,000 highly skilled
2,000,000 immigrants from OECD-
30, but 395,000 nationals
(persons)

1,500,000
in OECD-30
1,000,000

500,000

0
R

R
S

LX

H L

E
E
P

E
L

EX

K
H

Z
N
AT
FR

PT
S

BE

TK

A
E

PO
N

C
U

IC

IR
R

U
SV

ES

JA
AU

IT
O

KO
C

SW

U
FI

M
-500,000

G
N

-1,000,000

-1,500,000
Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007). 21
Difference between highly skilled
immigrants and highly skilled emigrants
(approximation)
12,000,000
Difference of highly skilled immigrants and highly skilled

10,000,000

8,000,000

6,000,000
emigrants

4,000,000

2,000,000

L
R

R
S

LX

EX
N Z

Z
SW L
FR

N
S
A

BE

K
A
AT

PT
TK
E

PO
N

R
AU

IC

IR
ES

JA
SV
U
C

U
IT
O

KO
U
FI
C

M
G
H
-2,000,000

Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007). 22


Difference between highly skilled
immigrants and highly skilled emigrants
(approximation)
12,000,000
Difference of highly skilled immigrants and highly skilled

10,000,000

8,000,000 Italy: receives 142,000 highly


skilled immigrants from all
6,000,000 countries, but sends 395,000
emigrants

highly skilled nationals alone to


4,000,000 other OECD countries

2,000,000

L
R

R
S

LX

EX
N Z

Z
SW L
FR

N
S
A

BE

K
A
AT

PT
TK
E

PO
N

R
AU

IC

IR
ES

JA
SV
U
C

U
IT
O

KO
U
FI
C

M
G
H
-2,000,000

Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007). 23


Favourably skill selected?

 Share of highly skilled in immigrant population


exceeds that in home country population by a
factor of 3.4 at OECD average
 Share of highly skilled in immigrant population
exceeds that in host country population by a factor
of 1.3 at OECD average
 Countries with skill-selective immigration policies
and (relatively) poor countries achieve favourable
skill bias of immigrant population, countries
without skill-selective immigration policies and
average income levels much less so
24
Immigrants in % of population with
tertiary education, 2001
50
immigrants in % of population with tertairy education

45

40

35

30

25

20

15

10

L
S

FR

BE

E
TK

EX

R
L

AT

PT
H

A
E
N

PO
N
IR

IC

JA
AU

ES

IT
SW

FI
C

KO
M
G

H
N

Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007).


25
Immigrants in % of population with
tertiary education, 2001
50
immigrants in % of population with tertairy education

45

40

35

30

25

20

15 Italy: 2.3%
10

L
S

FR

BE

E
TK

EX

R
L

AT

PT
H

A
E
N

PO
N
IR

IC

JA
AU

ES

IT
SW

FI
C

KO
M
G

H
N

Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007).


26
Selection bias of immigrant population
relative to home population (1 = neutral)
9
Index: weighted ratio of high skilled share in immigrant

8
i=N smh ,i
7 I1 = ∑ mi
snh,i
and home country population

6
i =1

0
EX

LX

E
Z

Z
R

FR

N
L

L
A
K
S

E
E

BE

TK

K
PT

AT
A
E
N

PO
N

C
C
U
U

AU

IR
IC

R
JA

ES

SV
IT

U
SW

FI
KO

H
N

Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007). 27


Selection bias of immigrant population
relative to home population (1 = neutral)
9
Index: weighted ratio of high skilled share in immigrant

8 i=N smh ,i
7 I1 = ∑ mi
i =1 snh,i
and home country population

4 Italy

0
EX

LX

E
Z

Z
R

FR

N
L

L
A
K
S

E
E

BE

TK

K
PT

AT
A
E
N

PO
N

C
C
U
U

AU

IR
IC

R
JA

ES

SV
IT

U
SW

FI
KO

H
N

Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007). 28


Indicator: share of tertiary educated in immigrant population/
share of tertiary indicated in host country population

0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
M
EX
TK
IR
E
IC
E
U
K
KO
R
PT
AU
S
PO
L
D
E
JA
P
C
H
N
O
R
ES
P
SW
E
C
A
G
R

Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007).


E
I2 =

IT
A
s
s

FI
N
n
h

h
m

N
L
N
Z
H
U
N
BE
FR
Selection bias of immigrant population

U
relative to host population (1 = neutral)

S
AT
O
EC DK
D
-3
0
29
Indicator: share of tertiary educated in immigrant population/
share of tertiary indicated in host country population

0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
M
EX
TK
IR
E
IC
E
U
K
KO
R
PT
AU
S
PO
L
D
E
JA
P
C
H
N
O
R
ES
P
SW
E
C
A
G
R

Source: Own calculations based on Beine et al. (2007).


E
I2 =

IT
A
s
s

FI
N
n
h

h
m

N
L
N
Z
H
U
N
BE
Italy

FR
Selection bias of immigrant population

U
relative to host population (1 = neutral)

S
AT
O
EC DK
D
-3
0
30
Competition for foreign students

 Receiving countries can benefit from foreign students even


if not all costs for studies can be recuperated
 Human capital and other skills (language proficiency, cultural and
social skills) well adapted to host country labour markets
 More and more countries facilitated immigration of foreign
students and eased labour market access
 Bologna process and harmonization of admission of third-country
students in EU
 Trend of increasing tuition fees and some countries discriminate
against foreign students (AUS, CH, NL, UK) but ease admission
procedures at same time
 All in all, surge of foreign students particularly in advanced
and research related programmes

31
Foreign students in % of all
enrolled students, 1998-2006
share of foreign nationals in % of all students 25

enrolment in advanced programmes


20
enrolment in all tertiary education programmes

15

10

0
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Source: Own calculations based on OECD (2009).


32
At the top of the skill distribution
 Concentration of immigrants at top of skill
distribution is higher than that at tertiary
education level
 Canada: immigrant share of 24% at tertiary education
level, but 51% at PhD level
 USA: immigrant share of 11.3% at tertiary education
level, but 27% at PhD level
 Immigrant share in top management (ISCO 1) and
top professional (ISCO 2) occupations is equal to
share in tertiary education group, but is below that
of share at the very top of skill distribution

33
Immigrants in % of 25+ population
with PhD and university degree, 2001
share of immigrants in host country population of respective

60

50
PhD completed university degree
40
education level

30

20

10

0
CA FR USA UK ESP DE
Source: Own calculations based on IPUMS international and national census data. 34
Immigrants in % of 25+ population
by occupational status, 2001
share of immigrants in 25+ population by occupational status

25

20
top management occupations (ISCO 1)

top professional occupations (ISCO 2)


15

10

0
CA FR USA NL ESP

Source: Own calculations based on IPUMS international and national census data. 35
The native-immigrant wage gap

 Large literature on assimilation of immigrants into host


country labour markets (e.g. Chiswick, 1978; Borjas, 1987;
Jasso/Rosenzweig, 1985)
 Limited evidence at top of skill distribution
 Hunt (2009) finds for US that foreign university and PhD
graduates (i) perform better than natives in terms of
wages, patents, papers and start ups, but (ii) perform
worse than natives once we control for field of study
 We find descriptive evidence that wages of foreign-born
PhD graduates are higher than that of natives in the US
and below that of natives in Canada

36
Annual wage income of PhD
graduates in USA, 2000
90,000

Foreign-born
80,000

70,000
Natives
60,000

50,000
US Dollar

40,000

30,000

20,000

10,000

0
25 to 29 30 to 34 35 to 39 40 to 44 45 to 49 50 to 54 55 to 59 60 to 64
Age

Source: Own calculations based on IPUMS international and national census data.
37
Annual wage income of PhD
graduates in Canada, 2000
90,000

80,000

70,000
Natives
60,000

Foreign-born
Canadian Dollar

50,000

40,000

30,000

20,000

10,000

0
25 to 29 30 to 34 35 to 39 40 to 44 45 to 49 50 to 54 55 to 59 60 to 64
Age
Source: Own calculations based on IPUMS international and national census data.
38
4 Determinants of highly
skilled migration
 Objective: to study the determinants of highly skilled
migration decomposing them between:
 wage differentials across countries
 immigration laws in receiving countries
 other policy variables in receiving countries
 Method: analyzing (i) determinants of total migration and
(ii) of selection of highly educated relative to less educated
based on gravity equation
 Findings: Important role of wage differentials and of
skill-selective immigration policies, welfare benefits and
labour market institutions are less important

39
Data
 Migration flows from 74 sending into 14 OECD destination
countries, 1980-2005 (OECD 2009, Mayda 2009)
 Using the Docquier et al. (2007) data set for calculating
educational levels
 Using the fRDB (2007) data base for calculation of
changes in immigration legislation along 6 dimensions
 Others: GDP per capita, wage premium, generosity of
welfare benefits, R&D expenditure

40
Annual inflows into OECD-14
in % of population, 1980-2005
Total of 14 OECD receiving countries

.6
Yearly flow as % of population
.3 .4 .2 .5

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005


year

41
Empirical framework

 Total migration equation:


ln modt = Dot + Dd + β1 Wdt + β2 Xod + β3 Ydt + eodt, [1]

 Selection equation:
ln mHodt – ln mLodt = D’ot + β1 (WHdt -WLdt) + β’2 Xod
+ β’3 Ydt + e’odt, [2]
 modt : total flow of migrants from country o to country d in year t
 mHodt : flow of tertiary educated,
 mHodt : flow of primary educated
 Dot : push-factors (we control for but don’t focus on them)
 Dd : destination country fixed effect
 Wdt,, WHdt –WLdt : wages and wage premium in receiving country
 Xod : bilateral fixed effects
 Ydt : factors in receiving countries such as immigration laws
42
Wages and wage premium

total migration selection


pre-tax after tax after tax after tax, FE
median wage: wd 0.063*** 0.060*** -- --
(0.014) (0.012)
wage premium: whd - wld 0.01** 0.04**
(0.005) (0.02)
controls YES YES YES NO
bilateral fixed effects NO NO NO YES
observations 22,662 22,662 5,486 5,486
Notes: Controls are log distance, land border, same language and colonial ties.--
***,**, * denote 1%-, 5%- and 10% significance levels.

43
Immigration legislation
total migration selection
(1) (2) (1) (2)
median wage: wd 0.054*** 0.051*** -- --
wage premium: whd - wld -- -- 0.015*** 0.016***
pro-skilled policies -0.08 -- 0.11*** 0.12***
restricted benefit access -0.07*** -0.08*** 0.08*** 0.08***
asylum -0.09*** -0.09*** 0.02 --
requirements for entry 0.01 -- -0.01 --
requirements for residency -0.04 -- -0.01 --
undocumented -0.02 -- -0.02 --
bilateral fixed effects YES YES YES YES
observations 22,662 22,662 5,419 5,419
Notes: ***,**, * denote 1%-, 5%- and 10% significance levels.
44
Labour market institutions and benefits
total immigration selection
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
median wage: wd 0.08*** 0.09*** 0.09** -- -- --
wage premium: -- -- -- 0.02** 0.01 0.01
whd - wld
minimum wages -4.33*** -3.14*** -2.88** 0.88 1.46** 1.64**
employment -0.36** 0.47 0.10 -0.57*** -0.55*** -0.54***
protection
welfare benefits -- 0.42 0.41 -- -0.08 -0.08
ímmigration laws NO NO YES NO NO YES
bil. fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES
observations 6,544 6,486 6,387 2,376 1,689 1,689
Notes: ***,**, * denote 1%-, 5%- and 10% significance levels.
45
R&D expenditures

total migration selection


(1) (2) (1) (2)
median wage: wd 0.07*** 0.07*** -- --
wage premium: whd - wld -- -- 0.03*** 0.01*
R&D expenditure -2.43*** -2.33*** 1.29*** 0.23
immigration laws NO YES NO YES
bilateral fixed effects YES YES YES YES
observations 20,335 20,335 5,320 5,320
Notes: ***,**, * denote 1%-, 5%- and 10% significance levels.

46
Summarizing

 Significant effect of skill-premium


 Increasing college premium by 10,000 $ would increase inflow
of highly educated relative to less educated by 40%

 Significant effect skill selective immigration policies


 Pro-skilled immigration laws increase selection of highly skilled
immigrants leaving total immigration flows unaffected

 Significant effect of laws limiting welfare benefit access


 Reduce total immigration flows and increase share of highly skilled
 Generous welfare benefits, employment protection and
low R&D spending may all worsen the skill selection of
immigrants, but their effects are imprecisely estimated
and not robust

47
5 Benefits of the brain gain
 We estimate impact of total immigration and
its share of highly educated on employment,
capital accumulation, productivity and income per
person in the receiving country
 We use “push-factors” identified before to capture
the part of immigration that is driven by “push-factors”
and hence can be considered as a supply shock to
receiving country
 We analyze short- and long run impact
 For the short run, we also focus on the impact
when immigration takes place in a recession

48
Production function approach
 Destination country production function
α 1−α
Ydt = Ad t K L d t dt
[1]
 Change of total income over time
∆Yd t ∆Ad t ∆K d t ∆L [2]
= +α + (1 − α ) d t
Yd t Ad t K dt ∆L d t
 Effect of total immigration (∆F/POP) and share of highly educated
immigrants h on each component of production X (X is A, L, K):
∆X dt ∆Fdt
= Dt + γ X + β X hFdt + edt [3]
X dt Popdt
 Once we know these effects we can use the formula above to
calculate impact on total income and income per capita:

∆Yd t Yd t − ∆Popd t Popd t [4]

49
Instrumental variable strategy
 In estimating the impact of immigration rates on
factors and productivity of receiving country we
instrument them with those obtained from prediction
 Flow equation from previous section which omits country
of destination variables (wages and policies)
 Only push factors interacted with fixed bilateral
migration costs drive variation in these constructed
flows
 Hence, these flows are reasonably exogenous with
respect to destination country economic conditions

50
Short- and long-run effects
(2SLS estimates)
Short run Long run
Explained variable: total highly total highly
immigration skilled immigrati skilled
rate share on rate share
∆ L/L 1.03*** 0.03** 0.99*** 0.13***
∆ Empl./Empl. 1.23*** 0.03*** 1.14*** 0.07***
∆ K/K 1.42*** 0.04*** 1.25*** 0.17***
∆ k/k 0.14 0.02 0.11 0.09
∆ A/A -0.11 0.02 -0.18 0.01
∆ gdp/gdp 0.60*** 0.01 0.49*** 0.01
observations 336 70
Notes: ***,**, * denote 1%-, 5%- and 10% significance levels.

51
Impact of immigration in recessions
Specification: Basic 2SLS
Normal Times Bad Times:
Output gap>-1 per cent Output gap<-1 per cent
Explanatory Immigration rate Share of tertiary Immigration rate Share of tertiary
variable: educated educated
∆ L/L 1.60** 0.04** 0.72 0.027**
(0.23) (0.01) (0.14) (0.012)
∆ Employment/ 1.55** 0.03** 1.20** 0.01
Employment (0.19) (0.01) (0.11) (0.01)
∆ K/K 1.55** 0.05** 1.42** 0.03**
(0.32) (0.02) (0.20) (0.01)
∆ Capital per Worker/ -0.01 0.016 0.22 0.022*
Capital per Worker (0.22) (0.017) (0.17) (0.12)
∆ A/A -0.11 0.007 -0.16 0.016
(0.10) (0.008) (0.22) (0.02)
∆ GDP per Person/ 1.02** 0.01 0.33** 0.002
GDP per person (0.19) (0.008) (0.15) (0.008)
Observations 336

52
Summary of findings
 Total immigration does not displace native employment
nor decreases native wages in short- or long run.
 The skill intensity of immigration has a positive
additional effect on employment and capital
accumulation
 This positive additional effect is present in the short-
as well as in the long run
 This effect is present even when skilled immigrants enter
the receiving country in bad economic times
 The positive employment-investment effect may result
from complementarities of highly educated or from a
positive productivity effect in presence of elastic labour
supply of natives

53
6 Explaining the status quo bias
in skill-selective immigration policies
 We address the puzzle why so few countries adopt
skill-selective immigration policies although potential
gains are high
 We apply a framework where immigration polices
are explained by the interaction of ‘demand’ and
‘supply’ factors
 We first analyze whether attitudes towards high
skilled-immigration can be explained by self-interest
of individuals
 We then explain policy outcomes by aggregating
individual preferences employing a median voter
and a pressure group model
54
Elements of a political economy model

pressure groups, political „demand side“


voters’ preferences on
parties, of immigration
immigration policy grass-roots movements
policy
(A)
(B)

Immigration policy outcomes

„supply side“
policymaker preferences institutional structure of of immigration
government policy
(C)
(D)

55
Understanding individual attitudes
The labour market channel
 Factor proportions theory: If immigrants are more
skilled than natives on average, then skilled natives
will lose and unskilled natives will benefit,
and vice versa
 Therefore, individual skill should be negatively
correlated with pro-immigration attitudes in countries
characterized by a high share of skilled immigration --
and positively correlated with pro-immigration attitudes
in countries characterized by a high share of unskilled
immigration

56
The welfare state channel
 Tax adjustment model: per capita benefits
remain constant, but tax rate changes
 Rich individuals are most affected by benefits
from skilled and losses from unskilled immigrants
 Thus, individual income is positively correlated with
pro-immigration preferences in countries with skilled
immigration and vice versa
 Benefit adjustment model: per capita transfers
change, but taxes remain constant
 Poor individuals are most affected by benefits and
losses
 Thus, individual income is negatively correlated with
pro-immigration preferences in countries with skilled
immigration and vice versa
57
Empirical implementation
 Ordered probit model:
Yid* = β1 agei + β2 malei + β3 educi + β4 educi× shd +
+ β5 incomei + β6 incomei× shd + ... + εid

 Yid* : outcome variable which measures pro-skilled attitudes


by 5 categories;
 educi : education level of individual i,
 incomei : earnings of individual i,
 Shd : share of high-skilled immigrants in immigrant population of
destination country d.
 Shd approximated by GDP per capita (Roy hypothesis).
 Data I: 1995 and 2003 waves of National Identity Module
of International Social Survey Programme (ISSP).
 Data II: 2002/03 wave of the European Social Survey
(ESS).
58
Explaining individual attitudes I
Ordered probit model with country dummies, 2003 ISSP wave
Dependent variable: all countries western-type
Pro immigration opinion welfare states
(1) (2) (3) (4)
education 0.057*** -0.223*** -0.697*** -0.808***
education × log gdp -- 0.028*** 0.074*** 0.084***
log income 0.052*** -0.084 1.783** 2.049*
log income × log gdp -- 0.014 -0.1667** -0.192*
age, male, citizenship, YES YES YES YES
parents’ citizenship
other controls NO NO NO YES
observations 23,801 23,801 17,943 10,956
Pseudo R2 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.07
Notes: ***,**, * denote 1%-, 5%- and 10% significance levels.
59
Explaining individual attitudes II
Ordered probit model with country dummies, 2002/3 ESS wave
Dependent variable:
Pro skilled immigration opinion (1) (2) (3)
education -0.060*** -0.071*** -0.061***
real income -- 0.008** 0.015**
age, male, citizenship YES YES YES
other controls NO NO YES
Observations 38,785 30,975 25,378
Pseudo R2 0.01 0.01 0.02
Notes: ***,**, * denote 1%-, 5%- and 10% significance levels.

60
From individual preferences to
immigration policy

 Median voter model


 Benhabib (1996), Ortega (2005),
Facchini and Mayda (2008)
 Interest group model
 Facchini and Willmann (2005),
Facchini, Mayda and Mishra (2009)

61
Does the median voter rule?
 We find no correlation between between the policy
on high skilled immigration and the opinion of the
median voter on skilled immigration using the median
of the pro skilled immigration variable in the ESS data
set
 The same result emerges if we use the mean of
the same variable
 Comparing this finding with that in Facchini and
Mayda (2008) on total immigration, the median
voter model appears to work much better in
explaining overall immigration policies as
compared to skill-selective immigration policies
62
Evidence for pressure groups?
 Substantial anecdotal evidence suggesting that interest
groups are actively involved in shaping policies towards
immigration
 In the US, professional associations representing
highly-qualified native workers have played an
important role in limiting inflows of foreign skilled
migrants
 For example, recently, the Institute of Electrical and
Electronics Engineers (IEEE) has been active in
demanding a reduction in both the number of H1B visas
for highly skilled professionals and L1 visas for highly
skilled intra-company transferees.
 Similarly, “…the profession of medicine exerts a
significant influence on the rate of skilled migration of
foreign physicians” (Glied and Sarkar 2009).

63
Evidence for pressure groups?
 At the same time, there is ample evidence on the
efforts of pro-immigrant lobbies – representing the
business sector – in shaping migration policy.
 For example, during the boom of the late nineties,
Silicon Valley entrepreneurs trooped in front of
Congress asking for an increase in the number of H1B
visas for highly skilled professionals, and warning of a
looming Y2K disaster if the large number of foreign
engineers and computer scientists they requested was
not allowed to enter the country (Goldsborough 2000).

64
Lobbying expenditures on
immigration
-2
Number of H1B visas as a ratio of natives (in logs)

388 898
426
-4

579
387
899 347
357
807
348399 726
-6

487
806
627 588467 226
598
848 206448 367
888
488
477669
356 546
468 868 617
489 879
859
857
869
216386836 377 418
716
696
616 326 808376 417
606586
-8

408
469 319 556
637 317 626 607
236316 856 567
318
358
478 618609
116 407
378
746 308
456
309 337587
698
697
656
659849
658596
409 817
126 608 858105 476
668619 688
527 896
679
657 246 816
916416
336
647 536
636 667 419
-10

687 338458
516
526 686
699
689 406 457
346
646
306 578
826 307
-12

846
936

-10 -5 0 5
Lobbying expenditures for immigration as a ratio of natives (in logs)

(mean) lgh1b Fitted values


65
Union membership and H1B visas
-2
Number of H1B visas as a ratio of natives (in logs)

388
898
426
-4

579
387
899 347
357
807
726
-6

487 348
467 399
806449
627 226 588
436
848 367
448 379 206 598
488 568 888
477
437 669 546
356
879 459 869 857
868836 468
489 386 859
617
716 429 466 377
418 216
696808
616 417 326 586 376
-8

736 606236
318
626856 469 319
567
358 446 317 408 556
618607
637 746 609 116478 316
308 407 378 337 476
698
656 439
309
438 697 409 587597 456
858849
608
619
668
659
126105817
658
688 596
679 896 527
657 816
647 536 419 246636 416
916 336 506
-10

667
687 338
686689699 458
346 526 457 516
406
646
306 578
826 307
-12

846
936
906

0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Union membership rates

(mean) lgh1b Fitted values

66
Impact of interest groups on
H1B visas
dependent variable: log(H1B visas/native workers) Coeff. SE
log (lobbying expenditure/native worker) 0.182*** 0.065
union membership rate -3.623*** 1.292
log output -0.114 0.181
unemployment rate 1.661 4.323
log price 1.112 2.165
log capital 0.009 1.151
log FDI 0.107 0.066
shocks -4.892** 2.444
log (US wages) 9.834*** 2.951
log (US workers) -0.169 0.198
observations 120
R2 0.34
67
What explains the status quo bias?

 According to our analysis, skilled native workers


organized in interest groups are vocal and effective in
reducing number of visas for skilled migrants
 Policymakers might be reluctant to increase skilled
immigration for two alternative reasons:
 Increasing the number of skilled immigrants may involve
higher total immigration since unskilled immigrants come no
matter what, to which public opinion is opposed
 If public opinion is willing to absorb only a limited number of
immigrants, then increasing skilled immigration reduces the
number of unskilled immigrants, which will disappoint
powerful sectors relying in unskilled labour (agriculture,
construction, textile and apparel)

68
7 Looking into the future

 The policy equilibrium may shift towards more skill-


selective immigration policies for three main reasons
 Skill-biased technological change
 Increasing specialisation on human capital activities
 Ageing and shortages of highly skilled labour particularly in
the EU
 This shift will be structural and not marginal
 The combined population of AUS, CA and NZ comprises less
than 100 millions, that of the EU almost 500 millions
 Highly skilled immigrants will stem predominantly from
emerging and developing economies in the future
(e.g. South and East Asia)

69
Will this competition exhaust the
global pool of skilled labour?
 If the “battle for brains” unfolds, it will affect destination and
sending countries
 More specifically, it will redistribute costs and benefits of
public investment in higher education between sending
and receiving countries, which may in turn undermine
capabilities and incentives to invest in higher education
and hence reduce the global pool of highly skilled labour
 However, increasing migration opportunities for the highly
skilled may raise private incentives to invest in education
and hence increase the global pool of highly skilled labour

70
Predictions from
two-country models
 An increased mobility of skilled workers between identical
countries reduces public investment in education, and the
average level of schooling of migrants (Justman and Thisse,
1997; Demange et al., 2008)
 An increased mobility of skilled workers from poor to rich
countries will reduce public spending in education which
offsets higher private incentives to invest in education,
such that the overall share of higher educated individuals
in the population of sending countries declines (Docquier
et al., 2007)

71
Modelling the “Battle for Brains”
 Building on Docquier et al. (2008) and Stark and Wang
(2002) we consider the impact of migration on (i) public
and (ii) private incentives to invest in education
 We propose a three-country game, where two identical
destination countries determine their optimal immigration
policies, and one sending country sets the level of an
educational subsidy
 The sending country governments subsidizes education through
lump-sum taxes levied on domestic workers who did not
migrate
 Destination countries set a quota to attract foreign workers
with a high level of education, as education gives rise to a
positive intra-generational externality on labour markets

72
Main features of the model

 Migration is driven by higher wages that prevail at


destination for all skill groups since destination countries
are technically superior
 Still, the government - and the would-be migrants - do not
internalize the positive externalities connected to the
education of its own workers that arise in the two
countries of destination
 This - together with the willingness to avoid the raise in
taxes that is required to balance the budget - pushes down
the socially optimal level of the subsidy, driving up the
private cost of education

73
Impact of a higher immigration quota

MC(p2)

MC(p1)

MB(p2)

MB(p1)

hc(p2) hc(p1) hc

74
Results

 An increased demand for skilled migrants raises both the


expected private return to education, and its private cost
 The latter effect prevails, lowering the equilibrium level of
education, as long as the domestic social return to
education exceeds the foreign private return
 The Nash equilibrium of the game between destination
countries results in an inefficient immigration quota, since
it does not incorporate the negative externality that one
country imposes on the other one via the reduction in the
human capital of migrants

75
Is this empirically relevant?

 The fiscal costs of the emigration of the highly skilled are


substantial
 Emigration of highly skilled from India to US amounts to 2.5% of
fiscal revenues there (Desai et al., 2009)
 Immigration of doctors from Ghana saved UK training costs of
£64.5 million
 Share of private funding and tuition fees in education
expenditure increase with emigration of skilled labour
(Bray, 2000; Docquier et al., 2008; Johnstone, 2004)
 Thus, it is likely that more competition of the highly
skilled will results in reduced public investment in
education and, hence, increase private costs for
education
76
Summary

 The Battle for Brains resembles the famous Tragedy of the


Commons, as an uncoordinated setting of immigration
policies can lead to an unsustainable overexploitation of
the global pool of talents
 A policy shift towards skill-selective immigration policies
should hence not overlook its impact on sending countries
 Matching the shift towards skill-selective immigration
policies with a reduction in public funding of higher
education at destination could prove to be seriously short-
sighted

77
8 Conclusions
 Only few OECD countries systematically adopt a skill-
selective immigration policy
 Only few OECD countries which are characterized by (i) a
high per capita income, (ii) skill-selective immigration
policies and (iii) (often) English language are net receivers
of talent
 The share of highly skilled individuals in the immigrant
population increases with (i) wage premium, (ii) skill-
selective immigration policies, while (iii) the impact of
welfare benefits, labour market institutions and R&D
expenditures is not robust
 Total immigration does not replace native workers nor
reduce wages. Highly skilled immigration creates
additional positive effects for employment and capital
accumulation, but does not increase TFP
78
8 Conclusions
 Despite their positive aggregate effects, highly skilled
immigration is not welcomed by all groups. We find that
educated individuals are less favourable towards highly
skilled immigration (labour market channel), while
individuals with a higher income are more favourable (tax
adjustment welfare channel).
 While the median voter model can hardly explain present
patterns of skill-selective immigration policies, we find
evidence that organized pressure groups from both the
unions/professional organisations and employers
effectively affect immigration policies
 An intensified “battle for brains” may however result in an
unsustainable overexploitation of the global pool of talent
 Policy coordination can hence increase welfare in both
receiving and sending countries
79

You might also like