You are on page 1of 18

Vol. 26, No. 3, March 2017, pp. 491–508 DOI 10.1111/poms.

12648
ISSN 1059-1478|EISSN 1937-5956|17|2603|0491 © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

On the Same Page? How Asymmetric Buyer–Supplier


Relationships Affect Opportunism and Performance
Ver
onica H. Villena
Department of Supply Chain & Information Systems, Smeal College of Business, The Pennsylvania State University,
412 Business Building, University Park, Pennsylvania 16802, USA, vhvillena@psu.edu

Christopher W. Craighead
Department of Marketing and Supply Chain Management, Haslam College of Business, University of Tennessee,
311 Stokely Management Center, Knoxville, Tennessee 37996, USA, craighead@utk.edu

esearch on buyer–supplier relationships (BSRs) has often focused on only one side of the relationship and, thus, has
R tended to overlook asymmetries. Yet, a buyer (supplier) may often deal with a bigger supplier (buyer) or one that
has higher levels of trust, respect, and reciprocity. Therefore, we examined how two types of asymmetries—size and rela-
tional capital—affect perceived opportunism and performance. We used dyadic data from 106 buyers and their matched
suppliers gathered from a survey and an archival database. The results demonstrate that the degree and direction of both
asymmetries affect the BSR. Our results also reveal that an imbalance of relational capital in a firm’s favor may have the
opposite effect from that intended. In other words, the firm’s counterpart perceives more, rather than less, firm oppor-
tunism. The results also suggest that a buyer observes lower benefits in the presence of size asymmetry, whereas the sup-
plier’s perception of benefits is unaffected. Thus, our research represents a significant step forward in understanding BSRs
and asymmetries by (i) bringing attention to two key asymmetries inherent in BSRs and (ii) showing that these asymme-
tries are not unidirectional in their influence on perceived opportunism and performance.
Key words: buyer–supplier relationship; perceived opportunism; size asymmetry; relational capital asymmetry;
performance
History: Received: January 2015; Accepted: August 2016 by Vinod Singhal, after 4 revisions.

(Cousins et al. 2006) and how to rebuild it (Wang


1. Introduction et al. 2014). Scholars have also examined how RC
Our greatest strength as a human race is our positively affects performance (Sarkar et al. 2001),
ability to acknowledge our differences—our whereas others are starting to unpack relational capi-
greatest weakness is our failure to embrace them. tal’s “dark side” (Villena et al. 2011, Zhou et al.
Judith Henderson, composer 2014).
While size and relational capital are important fac-
Buyer–supplier relationships (BSRs) are comprised tors in our understanding of BSRs, we are not focus-
of both economic and social exchanges. Within eco- ing on them per se. As the opening quote suggests, our
nomic exchanges, one of the more salient factors is efforts are centered on the relative amount of each. That
the firm’s size (Sheth 1973). Researchers have is, we are focusing on size and relational capital asym-
unpacked size in BSRs, including how it influences metries because an imbalance in size often exists
both the use of information sources within the buy- between buyers and suppliers (Lee and Johnsen 2012,
ing process (Moriarty and Spekman 1984) and the Thomas and Esper 2010), and because the same level
adoption of integrating technologies (Hart and Saun- of trust between buyers and suppliers may actually
ders 1997). Relative to social exchanges, relational be quite uncommon (Brower et al. 2009, Korsgaard
capital is a more latent factor referring to trust, et al. 2015). Also, the two asymmetries complement
reciprocity, and respect that actors develop with each each other in that size is structural and salient while
other through a history of interactions (Kale et al. relational capital is behavioral and latent. Thus, juxta-
2000). In fact, relational capital is a key factor in fos- posing these asymmetries allows us to more fully
tering buyer–supplier interactions with the goal of examine how they affect economic and social
creating relational “rents” (Dyer and Singh 1998). exchanges.
Scholars have devoted considerable effort in examin- In a growing body of knowledge, scholars have
ing BSRs’ relational capital, including how to build it started unpacking some asymmetries in BSRs (see
491
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
492 Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

Table 1 Representative Literature on Asymmetry in Buyer–Supplier Relationship

Asymmetry
Reference dimension(s) Method Major findings
Qualitative
Johnsen and Ford (2008) Size Eight case studies with small textile Proposed various coping mechanisms of smaller suppliers to
suppliers (one side) manage their larger buyers’ size imbalance
Thomas and Esper (2010) Asymmetry Interviews of eight supply chain Proposed that asymmetry’s effects in BSRs were not
in general professionals in three large retailers unidimensional; Proposed several mechanisms to manage
(one side) asymmetry
Lee and Johnsen (2012) Size Five in-depth case studies of large Proposed three stages of relationship development in the
buyers and small/medium-sized presence of size asymmetry: exploratory, developing, and stable
suppliers (both sides)
Quantitative
Kumar et al. (1995) Dependence Survey of automobile dealers (one side) Degree of interdependence asymmetry found negatively related
to commitment and trust, and positively relate to conflict
Anderson and Weitz (1989) Power Survey of distribution representatives Degree of power imbalance found to be negatively related to
(one side) continuation and trust
Gulati and Sytch (2007) Dependence Survey of component buyers (one side) Theorized degree and direction of asymmetry found that buyers
with an advantageous position receive fewer benefits from the
relationship
Nyaga et al. (2013) Power Survey of a single high-tech firm and Degree of mediated power asymmetry was negatively linked to
multiple suppliers (both sides) performance, but inconclusive in its association with adaptation
and collaboration
Brinkhoff et al. (2015) Dependence Survey of buying companies (one side) Degree of dependence asymmetry is negatively related to project
success

Table 1 for a summary). While this asymmetry litera- Accordingly, we theorized via transaction cost eco-
ture is informative, several areas warrant attention. nomics (Williamson 1973, 1985) and the relational
First, only a few studies (e.g., Nyaga et al. 2013) have view (Dyer and Singh 1998) that two key asymme-
captured actual asymmetry via dyadic data because tries—size and relational capital—affect perceived
of methodological challenges (Roh et al. 2013). Yet, opportunism and performance. We focused on each
we believe that examining actual asymmetry pro- asymmetry’s degree (i.e., relative difference) and direc-
vides insights that would otherwise be incomplete. tion (i.e., whether the focal firm has a higher level
Second, with few notable exceptions (e.g., Gulati and than its partner or vice versa). To avoid contexts
Sytch 2007), research has examined the degree of where “little is at stake,” we theorize within dyads in
asymmetry without capturing the direction of asym- which the supplier is perceived to be critical1 to the
metry, with the latter purportedly being influential buyer. Within this context, we believed asymmetries
(Ross et al. 1997). Third, although select studies (e.g., would play a prominent role because of inherent
Villena and Cheng 2016) have started to examine strategic vulnerabilities (Spekman 1988). We used
BSRs in more complex ways, little effort has been dyadic data—106 buyers and their matched suppliers
made to examine how various asymmetries affect collected from a survey and an archival dataset—and
behaviors and performance within the dyad. For analyzed our hypotheses with two complementary
example, while case studies have examined size analyses.
asymmetry (Lee and Johnsen 2012, Thomas and Our research makes several contributions to the
Esper 2010), none of them have explicitly linked size study of BSRs and asymmetries. First, our research
asymmetry to opportunistic behavior. Finally, there is features an asymmetry (relational capital) that has
a notable absence of studies focusing on asymmetries been identified as needing exploration (Korsgaard
involving relational capital such as trust. In reviewing et al. 2015, Tomlinson et al. 2009). Our results reveal
the literature on trust, Korsgaard et al. (2015) noted, that a buyer or supplier that perceives a higher level of
“Of the varying perspectives on dyadic trust, argu- relational capital than its counterpart may be per-
ably the least attention has been paid to trust asym- ceived as more (rather than less) opportunist, thereby
metry” (p. 17). Thus, we examined the following challenging the traditional view of investing in rela-
research questions: Do asymmetries in size and rela- tional capital as a key to deterring perceived oppor-
tional capital increase or decrease perceived oppor- tunism (Dyer and Singh 1998). Second, we extend the
tunism within a dyad? Do these asymmetries theorizing and analyzing beyond the degree to include
ultimately impede or enable performance within a the direction of size and relational capital asymme-
dyad? We sought insight into our research questions tries; thus, adding to the few studies that do so (Gulati
from both sides of the relationship. and Sytch 2007). Third, we show that from the buyer’s
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society 493

perspective, the two asymmetries may be a perfor- approach the exchange vary significantly. Larger com-
mance liability rather than an asset. A buyer perceives panies tend to have more formal, bureaucratic commu-
lower benefits whether the buyer is bigger or smaller nication channels and specialized personnel in their
and when the supplier has higher relational capital. business exchange than their smaller counterparts do
From the supplier’s perspective, these two asymme- (Claycomb and Frankwick 2004). This misalignment of
tries’ influence on performance is less clear with only communication and expertise could be disturbing to
suppliers with higher levels of relational capital per- the smaller party, who could thereby interpret the lar-
ceiving improvements to performance. ger partner’s approach as opportunistic—even if it is
not intended to be (Weber and Mayer 2014). Second,
given that the supplier is critical, there has likely been
2. Theory and Hypotheses investment in non-trivial relationship-specific assets.
Figure 1 illustrates our theoretical model containing Exchange uncertainty becomes paramount in the pres-
both asymmetries and their associations with per- ence of these specific assets, which could ultimately
ceived opportunism and performance. foster more perceived opportunism (Williamson 1996).
The smaller company could suspect the larger com-
2.1. Asymmetries and Perceived Opportunism pany (whether the buyer or the supplier) of attempting
2.1.1. Perceived opportunism. Opportunism is self- to extract more value from the relational assets (Wil-
interest seeking with guile (Williamson 1973). In our liamson 1996). For example, larger companies may
context, we define it as the firm’s perception that its capitalize on their more expansive resource endow-
partner is violating norms affirmed over the course of ments to gain more (and perhaps better) information
the relationship (Jap and Anderson 2003, Macneil pertinent to the economic exchange (Moriarty and
1981). While opportunism may be manifested in Spekman 1984). This advantage, in turn, could create a
many ways (Wathne and Heide 2000), its negative perception that the larger company is coming to the
effects are well established in the literature (Crosno exchange “armed” to negotiate for more of the rela-
and Dahlstrom 2008). We propose that larger firms tional investment’s value (Williamson 1996). Finally,
and those firms with higher relational capital perceive size asymmetry may create a disproportionate level of
less partner opportunism, but are perceived as more vulnerability whereby the larger company may use its
opportunist by their partners. bargaining power2 in the exchange to gain control over
its smaller partner (Crook and Combs 2007).
2.1.2. Size Asymmetry and Perceived Oppor- In light of the above discussion, if the balance of
tunism. We conjecture that size asymmetry would size favors the buyer (henceforth referred to as size
likely serve as a catalyst for uncertainty within the asymmetry—buyer or SIZEA-Buyer), the supplier
exchange. This uncertainty would ultimately foster a will perceive more buyer opportunism. Given that the
smaller partner’s perception of the larger partner’s smaller supplier is critical, the potential for an expro-
opportunism in at least three ways (Williamson 1985). priation effect exists (Rokkan et al. 2003), whereby the
First, size asymmetry may culminate in interpretive bigger buyer seeks to gain more value from the smal-
uncertainty stemming from the two partners’ varying ler supplier’s critical resources/expertise specific to
cognitive frames (Weber and Mayer 2014). Even the the relationship (Williamson 1996). The buyer could
very nature in which larger vs. smaller companies be attempting to gain control over the smaller

Figure 1 Theoretical Model

Size Asymmetry-Buyer H1 Perceived Buyer Opportunism (supplier)


Size Asymmetry-Supplier Perceived Supplier Opportunism (buyer)
H2
H3

Relational Capital Asymmetry-Buyer Buyer Performance (buyer)


Relational Capital Asymmetry-Supplier Supplier Performance (supplier)
H4

Note: The respondent for our dependent variables is indicated in parenthesis.


Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
494 Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

supplier’s critical resource endowment (Casciaro and 1988). Thus, the buyer would be more prone to sus-
Piskorski 2005). This attempt would be disturbing pect supplier opportunism. Hence,
from the supplier’s perspective as the supplier may
have made considerable investments to develop such H1C. Size asymmetry—buyer is negatively related to
specific assets (Thompson 1967). Thus, the buyer’s perceptions of supplier opportunism.

H1A. Size asymmetry—buyer is positively related to the H1D. Size asymmetry—supplier is positively related to
supplier’s perceptions of buyer opportunism. the buyer’s perceptions of supplier opportunism.

Conversely, if the size balance favors the sup- 2.1.3. Relational Capital Asymmetry and Perceived
plier (henceforth referred to as size asymmetry— Opportunism. Relational capital has consistently
supplier or SIZEA-Supplier), we now argue that been found to deter opportunistic behavior (Wathne
the supplier would perceive lower buyer opportu- and Heide 2000). Yet, parties’ perceptions of rela-
nism. While the differences in size and exchange tional capital do not always converge (Korsgaard
approaches would give rise to interpretive uncer- et al. 2015, Tomlinson et al. 2009). We refer to this
tainty (Weber and Mayer 2014), the bigger supplier imbalance as relational capital asymmetry and con-
would perceive itself to be less vulnerable and thus jecture that it may undermine the relational capital’s
be less prone to suspect opportunism. For example, benefits, depending on the direction (Ross et al.
the bigger supplier would perceive the smaller 1997).
buyer’s behavior as more collaborative (i.e., both Our overarching conjecture is that a firm with
parties working for mutual interest) as it has the higher relational capital perceives less partner
capacity of rewarding or punishing the smaller opportunism, but is perceived as more opportunist
buyer (French and Raven 1959). The larger supplier by its partner. If the focal firm has more relational
would be cognizant of its resources’ critical nature capital than the partner, the focal firm perceives less
(Williamson 1996), yet would also recognize that its partner opportunism, partly because of the “halo
relative size could be a safeguard from the buyer effect”—that is, the focal firm views the partner’s
seeking control of its resource endowment (Casciaro actions through a positive lens (Kim et al. 2010,
and Piskorski 2005). In essence, the larger supplier Kumar et al. 1995). In essence, the focal firm would
would perceive a bonding effect (Rokkan et al. view the partner’s actions as more collaborative
2003), thereby not perceiving the smaller buyer as given its higher level of trust, reciprocity, and
behaving opportunistically. In sum, aware of the respect toward the partner. For example, if the part-
disproportionate level of vulnerability in the ner tries to persuade the focal firm to accommodate
exchange (Williamson 1973), the supplier tends to its needs, the focal firm may perceive the partner as
perceive less buyer opportunism. Thus, being forthright (rather than opaque) about expres-
sing its needs, sharing knowledge and working
H1B. Size asymmetry—supplier is negatively related to toward mutual benefit (Dyer and Singh 1998). Con-
the supplier’s perceptions of buyer opportunism. versely, if the partner has a higher level of relational
capital than the focal firm, the focal firm would per-
When the role is reversed—the buyer perceives ceive more partner opportunism. Herein, the focal
supplier opportunism; we conjecture the direction of firm may begin to suspect partner interactions as
size asymmetry’s effect on opportunism would be having a “hidden agenda” or as attempting to gain
consistent as above. However, the supplier’s critical- more “leverage” within the relationship. Thus, while
ity would affect the nuances of our theorizing. For the partner may view engagement as reciprocity
example, a larger buyer (SIZEA-Buyer) would be cog- (i.e., a give-and-take to create mutual benefit), the
nizant of its supplier’s critical status. Yet, the buyer focal firm with low relational capital may not share
would also recognize its size leverage and view it as a this view (i.e., no give—just take) (Korsgaard et al.
deterrent to the smaller supplier’s taking advantage 2015).
of its critical status (Casciaro and Piskorski 2005). If the buyer has a higher level of relational capital
Thus, the buyer would perceive that the supplier than the supplier (henceforth referred to as rela-
would be less prone to behave opportunistically. Con- tional capital asymmetry—buyer or RCA-Buyer), the
versely, a smaller buyer (inherent in SIZEA-Supplier) supplier may perceive buyer actions as opportu-
would recognize its larger supplier’s leverage (Crook nism. For example, the buyer may offer regular vis-
and Combs 2007) combined with the larger supplier’s its to the supplier’s plants and provide training in
specific assets (Thompson 1967). This recognition quality/process improvement. The buyer may see
would culminate in the smaller buyer’s heightened this offer as an effort to have a close interaction
awareness of its strategic vulnerabilities (Spekman with the supplier, while the supplier who does not
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society 495

share the same perception of relational capital may H2C. Relational capital asymmetry—buyer is negatively
be suspicious. Ultimately, the supplier may fear that related to the buyer’s perceptions of supplier opportu-
the buyer would eventually expropriate any result- nism.
ing cost reductions from buyer actions (Rokkan
et al. 2003). The lack of a shared view of relational H2D. Relational capital asymmetry—supplier is posi-
capital is particularly troubling in that the supplier tively related to the buyer’s perceptions of supplier oppor-
(being critical) may have certain technology, knowl- tunism.
edge, and processes that the buyer needs. Thus, the
supplier may view the buyer’s regular visits as a 2.2. Asymmetries and Performance
means to obtain this knowledge as opposed to shar- 2.2.1. Firm Performance. We also explore whether
ing knowledge in order to create relational rents the two types of asymmetries have an impact on the
(Dyer and Singh 1998). Similarly, the supplier may buyer’s and supplier’s performance. Both parties col-
perceive other relational approaches (e.g., informa- laborate with their ultimate goal being to learn from
tion sharing) in the same manner. In other words, one another in order to improve their capabilities
the supplier may perceive that the buyer is strategi- (Kale et al. 2000). However, an imbalance of either
cally manipulating the dependence within the rela- size or relational capital can affect the gains they aim
tionship (Bacharach and Lawler 1981). Thus, we to achieve from the relationship. Central to our argu-
predict the following: ment is that larger firms and firms with higher level
of relational capital will perceive improved benefits
H2A. Relational capital asymmetry—buyer is positively and vice versa.
related to the supplier’s perceptions of buyer opportu-
nism. 2.2.2. Size Asymmetry and Firm Performance. We
posit that size asymmetry directly affects perfor-
Conversely, if the supplier has more relational capi- mance for the same logical and theoretical reasons as
tal than the buyer (henceforth referred to as relational with opportunism. A larger buyer may perceive
capital asymmetry—supplier or RCA-Supplier), we greater benefits from the relationship because it
argue that the supplier will perceive less buyer oppor- believes it is driving the nuances of how the
tunism. The supplier would recognize its non-trivial exchange occurs and, thus, is better enhancing its
relationship investments while simultaneously per- capabilities via the supplier’s critical assets. Conver-
ceiving the relationship favorably. This combination sely, a smaller buyer will take precautions to reduce
would create a sense of comfort with the buyer’s its vulnerabilities in dealing with its larger supplier
actions and would perceive them with little suspicion. (Nyaga et al. 2013). The supplier, being critical, may
Thus, have key assets and personnel to meet the buyer’s
needs (Thompson 1967). Yet, the larger supplier may
H2B. Relational capital asymmetry—supplier is nega- prefer to minimize interactions with its smaller cus-
tively related to the supplier’s perceptions of buyer oppor- tomer because it may not count a big portion of its
tunism. business. Thus, the smaller buyer may perceive the
relationship with a bigger supplier less favorably.
When the role is reversed—that is, the buyer per- Hence,
ceives supplier opportunism; we conjecture the
direction of relational capital asymmetry’s effect on H3A. Size asymmetry—buyer is positively related to the
opportunism would be consistent as above. How- buyer’s perceptions of performance.
ever, the supplier’s criticality would affect the nuan-
ces of our theorizing. For example, buying H3B. Size asymmetry—supplier is negatively related to
companies with higher perceptions of relational the buyer’s perceptions of performance.
capital (RCA-Buyer) may interpret supplier actions
to build non-trivial relationship investments as reci- When the perspective is reversed in terms of the
procity with a focus on creating relational rents supplier’s perceptions, we recognize a potential com-
(Dyer and Singh 1998)—in turn, perceiving lower plicating “pressure” relative to the supplier’s percep-
levels of supplier opportunism. Conversely, those tion of performance. Within the very nature of buyer–
buying firms with lower perceptions of relational supplier exchanges, the supplier strives to meet the
capital (RCA-Supplier) may view supplier actions buyer’s needs and demands by outperforming its riv-
with suspicion, questioning whether the supplier als—other potential suppliers. Also, BSRs’ underlying
seeks to take advantage of its non-trivial invest- structure is often sequential—suppliers try to meet
ments. Thus, the supplier would be viewed as more the customer’s needs rather than the other way
opportunist. Hence, around (Thompson 1967, Crook and Combs 2007).
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
496 Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

We suspect this situation could alter the supplier’s Ibericos (SABI) database (similar to the COMPUSTAT
perception of the value gained. Yet, notwithstanding database in the United States).
this competing view, we believe our theoretical and
logical arguments discussed above will hold. There- 3.1.1. Survey Data. To select our sample firms, we
fore, we predict the following: identified 801 firms in diverse manufacturing sectors
from the SABI database. We deliberately excluded
H3C. Size asymmetry—buyer is negatively related to service firms (e.g., consulting services) and small
the supplier’s perceptions of performance. firms (<10 employees). Developing a survey instru-
ment with well-established scales, we pilot tested it
H3D. Size asymmetry—supplier is positively related to making minor modifications where necessary. To
the supplier’s perceptions of performance. ensure conceptual equivalence, we created the instru-
ment in English, translated it into Spanish, and then
2.2.3. Relational Capital Asymmetry and Firm translated it back into English (Hoskisson et al. 2000).
Performance. Similarly, asymmetry in relational In December 2011, we sent the survey to 801 firms,
capital directly affects performance, but this effect along with a cover letter explaining the study’s pur-
depends on the direction. For example, if the buyer pose and the criteria for selecting a supplier (i.e., criti-
has higher relational capital, it will perceive the rela- cal to each company’s operations). We requested that
tionship as an asset in which both parties have joined respondents have the chosen supplier as a reference
efforts to achieve objectives. More broadly, consider- point for completing the survey and named a contact
ing how relational capital affects the perception of at the supplier firm. We received 206 usable
opportunism, the directional hypotheses related to responses, for a response rate of 25%. Upon receiving
relational capital asymmetry and performance are the buyer survey, we sent a customized survey to the
driven by the same logic. Thus, designated supplier. We received 118 supplier sur-
veys, for a response rate of 57%. Because of missing
H4A. Relational capital asymmetry—buyer is positively data, we ended with 106 dyads.
related to the buyer’s perceptions of performance. To ascertain whether buyer and supplier respon-
dents were knowledgeable about the relationship
H4B. Relational capital asymmetry—supplier is nega- between their firms, we followed two steps. First, in
tively related to the buyer’s perceptions of performance. our survey instrument, we asked respondents to spe-
cify how long they had been involved in the focal rela-
When the perspective is reversed in terms of the tionship. Buyer respondents averaged 9.5 years of
supplier’s perceptions, we again recognize that the experience working with the chosen supplier, while
potential pressure to satisfy the buyer’s needs may supplier respondents averaged 10 years of experience
affect the supplier’s performance. Yet, we believe that working with the buyer. Second, we requested in the
our asymmetry arguments will prevail. Thus, consid- cover letter that respondents be responsible for sup-
ering how relational capital affects the supplier’s per- plier relationships in their organizations. The most
ception of opportunism, the directional hypotheses common titles for buyer respondents included supply
related to relational capital asymmetry and perfor- chain director, purchasing manager, purchasing coor-
mance are driven by the same logic. Hence, dinator, and operations coordinator, while for sup-
plier respondents it included director, sales director,
H4C. Relational capital asymmetry—buyer is negatively account manager, and operations coordinator. The
related to the supplier’s perceptions of performance. final respondents were diverse in terms of company
size, age, and industry.
H4D. Relational capital asymmetry—supplier is posi-
tively related to the supplier’s perceptions of performance. 3.1.2. Archival Data. We collected archival data
on participating buyers and suppliers from the SABI
database and used the data in three ways. First, we
triangulated survey and archival measures. The test
3. Method results showed some consistency between survey-
3.1. Research Design based and 2011 SABI-based information for buyers
We collected survey and archival data from 106 buy- (number of employees: r = 0.42, p < 0.001; years in
ing companies and their matched suppliers operating business: r = 0.30, p < 0.01) and for suppliers (num-
in Spain during 2011–2012. We pilot tested the survey ber of employees: r = 0.32, p < 0.01; years in business
with a group of four academics and five practitioners r = 0.52, p < 0.001). Second, we calculated size asym-
in the supply chain area. The archival data were metry and several control variables. To calculate size
extracted from the Sistemas de An alisis de Balances asymmetry, we used sales volume registered in the
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society 497

2011 SABI dataset. To calculate the two control vari- To calculate our asymmetry variables, we first mea-
ables (i.e., recent past performance and environmen- sured relational capital and size for both buyers and
tal uncertainty), we used the 2006 to 2011 SABI suppliers. Relational capital (RC) was measured using
datasets (more details are provided in the measure- five items adapted from Kale et al. (2000) that cap-
ment subsection). Third, we checked nonresponse tured the extent to which the firm perceived that the
bias (Lambert and Harrington 1990) by examining relationship with its partner was characterized by
mean differences in responding (n = 206) and nonre- close interactions, trust, friendship, respect, and reci-
sponding (n = 595) buying firms using the 2011 SABI procity. Each side reported its own internal percep-
data. The t-statistics were not significant for the num- tion of relational capital. Coefficient alpha for RCbuyer
ber of employees (t = 1.01, p = 0.30), years in business and RCsupplier were 0.83 and 0.76, respectively. Next,
(t = 0.93, p = 0.35), return on assets (t = 0.74, we used the spline method to calculate the value of
p = 0.45), or return on equity (t = 0.68, p = 0.49). To RCbuyer  RCsupplier and named it RCA-Buyer. Then
complement this approach, we used the survey data we recoded this variable to equal (RCbuyer 
to examine the mean difference for responding RCsupplier) if RCbuyer > RCsupplier and zero otherwise.
(n = 106) and nonresponding (n = 100) supplier We calculated RCA—Supplier the same way. Our sam-
firms. Between these groups, the results showed no ple returned 24 dyads in which a buyer held a higher
significant difference in relationship length (t = 1.18, level of relational capital, 66 dyads in which a sup-
p = 0.23), type of product supplied within the rela- plier did, and 16 with symmetric values. Buyers and
tionship (t = 0.40, p = 0.68), or equity involvement suppliers were not far apart in their RC levels: 68%
(t = 1.60, p = 0.12). were within one scale point of each other, but their
differences ranged up to two scale points. This differ-
3.1.3. Common Method Bias (CMB). Following ence scale’s reliability was 0.76.3
Podsakoff et al. (2012), we implemented several We followed this same approach for size asym-
remedies for CMB. For procedural remedies, we pro- metry using firm sales extracted from the 2011 SABI
tected respondent anonymity, reduced item ambigu- dataset. This objective measure was right-skewed;
ity during the pretest, separated the measures of the thus, we calculated the sales’ logarithmic value.
predictors and criterion variables, and obtained data Our sample returned 70 dyads in which a buyer
from two groups of respondents (buyers and suppli- was larger (SIZEA-Buyer) and 36 dyads in which a
ers) and from two sources (survey and the SABI data- supplier was larger (SIZEA-Supplier). Only 27% of
set). For statistical remedies, we triangulated the the dyads had buyer and suppliers within one scale
survey-based data with SABI-based data and ensured point, while the difference ranged up to seven
there was no significant difference in demographic points.
information. We also measured the dependent vari- We measured opportunism using items adapted
ables from one side of the relationship while indepen- from Wuyts and Geyskens (2005) and from Jap and
dent variables were calculated as the difference Anderson (2003). We created two constructs: buyer
between both sides’ scores. These steps reduced, but opportunism (assessed by the supplier) and supplier
did not completely eliminate, the potential for CMB. opportunism (assessed by the buyer) with alpha coef-
ficients of 0.92 and 0.91, respectively. Their correlation
3.2. Measurement Development and Assessment was moderately significant (r = 0.16; p = 0.09). To
Consistent with previous supply chain and marketing measure firm performance, we adapted a scale from
studies (Gulati and Sytch 2007, Nyaga et al. 2013, Roh Kale’s et al. (2000). We created two constructs: buyer
et al. 2013, Ross et al. 1997), we used a spline method. performance and supplier performance. Alpha coeffi-
This method calculates the difference (i.e., degree) of cients were 0.82 and 0.80, respectively, whereas their
scores between a buyer and its supplier regarding a correlation was not significant (r = 0.08, ns). See
relationship attribute and, subsequently, differenti- Table 2 for all constructs’ items.
ates which of the two parties has a higher level (i.e., We also included three types of control variables—
direction). This method allowed us to explore possible organizational, relationship, and market characteris-
variations in the effects of the buyer’s and the suppli- tics. The organizational characteristics included recent
er’s size and relational capital that would not be past performance as well as research and develop-
uncovered in focusing only on the degree of asymme- ment (R&D) capabilities of both buyers and suppliers.
try by taking the difference of the scores’ absolute The first set came from the 2009–2011 SABI databases,
value (Kumar et al. 1998). Also, we theorized that while the second came from a detailed analysis of the
firm opportunism is heavily influenced by who is big- companies’ annual reports and websites. Recent past
ger or has the higher level of relational capital. Thus, performance was measured using average ROA for
a single-variable approach capturing only degree and 2009–2011. More profitable firms may devote more
ignoring direction would have been inadequate. resources to improving their capabilities and,
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
498 Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

Table 2 Measurement Items.

Measurement items CR AVE a Coefficient SE p-value


Relationship duration: Please indicate how long (in years) your firm and the chosen supplier have been working together (Kale et al. 2000, Poppo et al.
2008)
Equity involvement: Please indicate whether the structure of the relationship with the chosen supplier is equity (1) or non-equity (0) (Kale et al. 2000)
Customized product: Please indicate if the product transacted within the relationship with the chosen supplier is customized (1) or standard (0) (Modi and
Mabert 2007)
Buyer dependence: How many potential satisfactory suppliers does your company have for the product transacted with the chosen supplier? (Gulati and
Sytch 2007)
Supplier dependence: What percentage of total product the supplier manufactures does your company buy? 0–5%(1), 6–15%(2), 16–30%(3), 31–50%(4),
>50%(5) (Modi and Mabert 2007)
Supplier relational capital(supplier): Please indicate the extent to which the relationship is characterized by 0.84 0.58 0.83
(Kale et al. 2000)
A close personal interaction 0.74 0.04 0.00
Mutual respect 0.69 0.05 0.00
Mutual trust 0.87 0.03 0.00
Friendship† – – –
Reciprocity 0.72 0.05 0.00
Buyer relational capital(buyer): Please indicate the extent to which the relationship is characterized by 0.79 0.49 0.76
(Kale et al. 2000)
A close personal interaction 0.62 0.06 0.00
Mutual respect 0.75 0.05 0.00
Mutual trust 0.81 0.05 0.00
Friendship† – – –
Reciprocity 0.61 0.06 0.00
Buyer opportunism(supplier): Please indicate the extent to which the buying firm would often 0.91 0.59 0.91
(Jap and Anderson 2003)
Take advantage of the relationship†
Hide important information from us 0.77 0.04 0.00
Exaggerate its needs to get what it desires 0.78 0.04 0.00
Use shared norms of reciprocity to further its own interest 0.85 0.02 0.00
Alter facts to get what it wanted 0.84 0.03 0.00
Use know-how existing in the relationship opportunistically 0.83 0.03 0.00
Do anything within its means to get a larger share of the gains from the relationship 0.75 0.04 0.00
Supplier opportunism(buyer): Please indicate the extent to which the supplier would often 0.92 0.68 0.92
(Jap and Anderson 2003)
Take advantage of the relationship†
Hide important information from us 0.72 0.04 0.00
Exaggerate its needs to get what it desires 0.90 0.02 0.00
Use shared norms of reciprocity to further its own interest 0.90 0.02 0.00
Alter facts to get what it wanted 0.84 0.03 0.00
Use know-how existing in the relationship opportunistically 0.83 0.03 0.00
Do anything within its means to get a larger share of the gains from the relationship 0.77 0.04 0.00
Buyer performance(buyer): Please indicate the extent to which (during the last three years) 0.83 0.62 0.82
(Kale et al. 2000)
Your company has acquired, exchanged, and combined key information/knowledge within the 0.75 0.05 0.00
relationship
Your company has acquired some critical capabilities/skills from the relationship 0.73 0.05 0.00
The relationship has enhanced your existing capabilities/skills 0.87 0.04 0.00
Supplier performance(supplier): Please indicate the extent to which (during the last three years) 0.83 0.62 0.80
(Kale et al. 2000)
Your company has acquired, exchanged, and combined key information/knowledge within the 0.68 0.06 0.00
relationship
Your company has acquired some critical capabilities/skills from the relationship 0.71 0.05 0.00
The relationship has enhanced your existing capabilities/skills 0.94 0.04 0.00

(respondent): The respondent is indicated in parentheses. AVE: Average Variance Explained; CR: Composite Reliability; a: Cronbach’s alpha.
*Confirmatory factor analysis (CFA) results: v2 = 474.83, df = 284, RMSEA = 0.07, SRMR = 0.06, CFI = 0.90, TLI = 0.89.

Items dropped after CFA.

therefore, perceive fewer benefits from inter-firm rela- department (value of 1) or not (value of 0). Firms with
tionships (Hill and Rothaermel 2003, Levinthal and strong R&D capabilities may enjoy more power and,
March 1981). R&D was measured with a dummy vari- consequently, perceive more benefits (Johnsen and
able indicating whether the firm had an R&D Ford 2008).
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society 499

The relationship characteristics included relation- Yt ¼ bo þ b1t þ a; ð1Þ


ship length, equity involvement, product type, buyer
dependence, and supplier dependence. Such informa- where y = net industry sales, t = year, and a =
tion was gathered only from buyers to maximize the residual.
supplier’s response rate. Relationship length measured To assess our variables’ validity and reliability, we
the number of years the two companies had been computed composite reliability (CR), average vari-
working together (Poppo et al. 2008). Long-term part- ance extracted (AVE), and Cronbach’s alpha. The CR
ners can cultivate processes and routines that facili- values (in the range of 0.79–0.92), AVE (in the range
tate achieving goals set for the relationship. We also of 0.49–0.68), and Cronbach’s alpha (in the range of
asked the buyer whether it had any equity involvement 0.76–0.92) exceeded the minimum limit indicated in
with the supplier. Buyers and suppliers that share previous research (Hair et al. 2010). Using confirma-
some equity (e.g., belonging to the same parent firm) tory factor analysis (CFA), we also tested the mea-
may have more incentive to achieve established goals surement by including all items from both buyer and
rather than to misbehave (Kale et al. 2000). We cre- supplier data. The model’s estimation indicated an
ated a dummy variable coded as 1 if equity was acceptable fit: v2 = 474.83, df = 284, RMSEA = 0.07,
involved and 0 otherwise. We also controlled for pro- SRMR = 0.06, CFI = 0.90, TLI = 0.89 (Hu and Bentler
duct type. If the product exchanged is more custo- 1999). The results show that all items’ standardized
mized, both parties may be more interested in coefficients were highly significant, indicating the
teamwork to achieve the desired properties and less constructs exhibited convergent validity. The mea-
interested in misbehaving. We created a dummy vari- surement items are reported in Table 2.
able, customized product, which was assigned the value
of 1 if the product was customized and 0 otherwise.
We also controlled for both buyer and supplier
4. Results
dependence. If the buyer is highly dependent on the 4.1. Hypothesis Testing
supplier, it is more willing to invest relational capital Table 3 presents descriptive statistics and correla-
and less interested in misbehaving (Gulati and Sytch tions. We examined the data for violations of assump-
2007, Krajewski et al. 2005). Asking the buyer how tions of normality and multicollinearity (Cohen et al.
many potential satisfactory suppliers it had for the 2003). All variables approximated normal distribution
product, we named this variable buyer dependence. A except the relationship length and firm size, which
higher number of satisfactory suppliers indicates were transformed by taking their logarithm. To
lower dependence, and vice versa. For supplier depen- address multicollinearity, we calculated the variance
dence, we asked the buyer what percentage it buys of inflation factor (VIF) for all regression equations. The
total products the supplier manufactures. We created highest VIF was 1.66, well below a common rule-of-
a variable that received the value of 1 if 0–5%, 2 if thumb cutoff of 10 (Kutner et al. 2004). To test our
6–15%, 3 if 16–30%, 4 if 31–50%, and 5 if >50%. The hypotheses, we used hierarchical regression analysis.
higher percentage of total supplier production the Tables 4 and 5 present the results of buyer/supplier
buyer bought would indicate a higher supplier perceived opportunism and buyer/supplier perfor-
dependence (Modi and Mabert 2007). mance, respectively. These tables report the incre-
We controlled for market conditions for both ments to adjusted R2 at each step, each regression
buyers and suppliers. Market unpredictability estimates equation’s significance, unstandardized beta coeffi-
the degree of irregularity in an overall pattern of cients, and robust standard errors.
environmental change that a firm faces in its industry First, we assessed the four asymmetry variables’
(Child 1972). The parties operating in highly uncer- direct effects on buyer/supplier opportunism (see
tain markets may limit benefits or leverage the trust Table 4). Model 2 shows the results for buyer oppor-
within their relationship (Villena et al. 2016). Follow- tunism. SIZEA-Buyer was positively and significantly
ing previous studies (Delacroix and Swaminathan associated with buyer opportunism (B = 0.10;
1991, Krishnan et al. 2006), we first identified the p < 0.05), rendering support to H1a. The SIZEA-Sup-
firm’s industry sector (using the classification that plier’s coefficient was not significant; thus, H1b was
Spain’s National Institute of Statistics created) as not supported. The results show that RCA-Buyer was
registered in the 2011 SABI database. We then calcu- positively associated with buyer opportunism
lated the industry’s sales value from 2006 to 2010 to (B = 0.30; p < 0.05), supporting H2a, and that RCA-
reflect market unpredictability in 2011, using the Supplier was negatively associated with it (B = 0.25,
2006–2011 SABI databases. Market unpredictability p < 0.001), supporting H2b. As presented in Model 4,
was the coefficient of alienation (1  R2) of 2011 the results for supplier opportunism show that
industry sales’ regression on the five preceding years’ SIZEA-Buyer was negatively associated with supplier
industry sales as expressed in Equation (1): opportunism (B = 0.08; p < 0.05), providing support
500

Table 3 Descriptive Statistics and Correlation

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19
1 Buyer past
performance
2 Supplier past 0.10
performance
3 Buyer R&D 0.02 0.02
4 Supplier R&D 0.01 0.07 0.03
5 Customized product 0.09 0.12 0.16 0.15
6 Relationship length 0.05 0.13 0.11 0.13 0.14
7 Equity involvement 0.07 0.10 0.04 0.01 0.05 0.11
8 Buyer dependence 0.11 0.22* 0.05 0.07 0.02 0.04 0.01
9 Supplier 0.01 0.03 0.12 0.09 0.33** 0.05 0.06 0.22*
dependence
10 Buyer market 0.09 0.06 0.04 0.13 0.04 0.09 0.01 0.06 0.04
unpredictability
11 Supplier market 0.01 0.15† 0.04 0.08 0.13 0.12 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.38**
unpredictability
12 SIZEA-Buyer 0.13 0.04 0.06 0.28* 0.24* 0.11 0.15 0.05 0.10 0.16† 0.10
13 SIZEA-Supplier 0.11 0.04 0.04 0.34* 0.24* 0.01 0.02 0.08 0.04 0.02 0.23* 0.50*
14 RCA-Buyer 0.03 0.01 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.15 0.11 0.05 0.05 0.09 0.24*
15 RCA-Supplier 0.02 0.01 0.10 0.05 0.08 0.04 0.19* 0.01 0.09 0.01 0.09 0.09 0.02 0.40*
16 Buyer opportunism 0.09 0.17† 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.04 0.19* 0.03 0.02 0.11 0.22* 0.17 0.11 0.12 0.23*
17 Supplier 0.03 0.07 0.05 0.03 0.15 0.01 0.04 0.11 0.05 0.11 0.10 0.15 0.06 0.05 0.16† 0.16†
opportunism
18 Buyer performance 0.01 0.26* 0.02 0.09 0.11 0.15 0.18* 0.01 0.11 0.02 0.12 0.06 0.12 0.08 0.24* 0.05 0.06
19 Supplier 0.12 0.08 0.01 0.03 0.04 0.15 0.03 0.04 0.21* 0.06 0.10 0.07 0.15† 0.21* 0.16† 0.16† 0.01 0.08
performance
Mean 1.30 1.36 0.04 0.43 0.33 2.55 0.05 2.96 2.44 0.48 0.47 1.34 0.75 0.13 0.50 1.63 1.89 3.75 3.87
SD 0.68 0.73 0.10 0.50 0.47 0.72 0.22 1.75 1.55 0.22 0.17 1.50 1.29 0.33 0.53 0.72 0.82 0.73 0.77

It should be noted that both the buyer and supplier past performance is quite low due to the economic downturn (i.e., high unemployment and no growth) that occurred during the 2009–2011 period in
Spain. N = 106. †p < 0.10, *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society 501

Table 4 Results of Regression Models for Opportunism

Buyer opportunism(supplier) Supplier opportunism(buyer)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

B SE B SE B SE B SE
Intercept 1.80*** 0.37 1.78*** 0.37 1.98* 0.50 1.78* 0.71
Firm control variables
Buyer recent past performance 0.11 0.08 0.07 0.08 0.06 0.08 0.08 0.08
Supplier recent past performance 0.13† 0.07 0.11 0.07 0.04 0.08 0.03 0.08
Buyer R&D 0.17 0.55 0.50 0.39 0.33 0.60 0.17 0.65
Supplier R&D 0.01 0.16 0.09 0.15 0.06 0.16 0.07 0.16
Relationship control variables
Relationship length 0.05 0.08 0.10 0.08 0.05 0.11 0.02 0.10
Equity involvement 0.52 0.40 0.33 0.40 0.15 0.24 0.14 0.24
Customized product 0.01 0.18 0.06 0.18 0.16 0.18 0.10 0.17
Buyer dependence 0.01 0.04 0.01 0.04 0.06 0.05 0.08† 0.05
Supplier dependence 0.01 0.06 0.01 0.06 0.02 0.05 0.01 0.05
Market control variables
Buyer market unpredictability 0.01 0.28 0.20 0.28 0.78* 0.34 0.65† 0.37
Supplier market unpredictability 0.72* 0.34 1.12*** 0.32 0.65 0.52 0.36 0.54
Main Effects
SIZEA-Buyer H1a (+) 0.10* 0.05 H1c () 0.08* 0.05
SIZEA-Supplier H1b () 0.06 0.07 H1d (+) 0.02 0.06
RCA-Buyer H2a (+) 0.30* 0.16 H2c () 0.37 0.25
RCA-Supplier H2b () 0.25*** 0.09 H2d (+) 0.42** 0.15
R2 10.6% 22.6% 8.40% 16.3%
R adjusted square 3.40% 9.4% 1.60% 3.5%
F change 3.36*** 2.15†

We report one-tailed test for hypothesized variables when the coefficients are in the direction of the hypothesis, two-tailed test otherwise. Also, the
respondent is indicated in parentheses. N = 106. †p < 0.10, *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001. Values highlighted in bold correspond to hypotheses.

for H1c. RCA-Supplier was positively associated with analysis (Edwards 2002; Shanock et al. 2010). We first
supplier opportunism (B = 0.42; p < 0.01), supporting ran polynomial regressions4 and assessed the
H2d. No support was found for H1d and H2c. assumptions, as suggested by Edwards (2002). In six
Next, we assessed the four asymmetry variables’ out of eight regressions, there was a significant
direct impact on buyer/supplier performance (see change in R2 between a control-only model and a full
Table 5). For buyer performance (Model 2), the results model as reported in Equation (2). When size asym-
show that SIZEA-Supplier (B = 0.10; p < 0.05) and metries were independent variables, supplier oppor-
RCA-Supplier (B = 0.28; p < 0.05) decreased buyer tunism and supplier performance did not meet this
performance, providing full support for H3b and criterion and, thus, were excluded. For the remaining
H4b. No support was found for H3a and H4a. Inter- six equations, we calculated four surface values (a1,
estingly, SIZEA-Buyer was significant (B = 0.14; a2, a3, and a4) based on the coefficients of our polyno-
p < 0.01), but in the opposite direction we had theo- mial regression equation (see footnote 4). a1 repre-
rized. For supplier performance, only RCA-Supplier sents the slope of perfect agreement—those situations
was moderately significant (B = 0.23; p = 0.06), pro- in which both the buyer and supplier share the same
viding partial support for H4d. level of relational capital (RCbuyer = RCsupplier) or are
similar in size (Sizebuyer = Sizesupplier). If a1 is signifi-
4.2. Post hoc Analysis cant and positive (negative), the outcome variable
Difference scores are widely used in studies of fit and increases (decreases) as both independent variables
agreement in several fields, such as marketing (e.g., RCsupplier and RCbuyer) increase. The line of
(Anderson and Weitz 1992, Ross et al. 1997), manage- agreement’s curvature related to the outcome variable
ment (Gulati and Sytch 2007) and more recently, sup- is represented by a2. A significant and positive (nega-
ply chain (Brinkhoff et al. 2015, Roh et al. 2013). tive) a2 indicates a convex (concave) surface along the
However, scholars have suggested potential method- line of perfect agreement. The line of incongruence’s
ological threats associated with this approach slope is represented by a3—those situations in which
(Edwards 2002, Edwards and Parry 1993). Thus, to RCbuyer = RCsupplier or Sizebuyer = Sizesupplier, rep-
overcome the spline method’s limitations, we con- resenting the discrepancy’s direction (e.g., RCbuyer is
ducted a polynomial regression with response surface higher than RCsupplier or vice versa). In our case, a
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
502 Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

Table 5 Results of Regression Models for Performance

Buyer performance(buyer) Supplier performance(supplier)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

B SE B SE B SE B SE
Intercept 3.66** 0.33 4.19** 0.37 3.13 0.34 3.03 0.35
Firm control variables
Buyer recent past performance 0.03 0.08 0.02 0.08 0.15† 0.09 0.15 0.09
Supplier recent past performance 0.20 0.13 0.21 0.14 0.06 0.11 0.06 0.11
Buyer R&D 0.05 0.48 0.01 0.40 0.38 0.41 0.28 0.42
Supplier R&D 0.21 0.15 0.26† 0.15 0.12 0.15 0.16 0.15
Relationship control variables
Relationship length 0.01* 0.00 0.01* 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00
Equity involvement 0.38** 0.13 0.38** 0.15 0.01 0.27 0.10 0.27
Customized product 0.05 0.17 0.08 0.14 0.09 0.15 0.07 0.16
Buyer dependence 0.02 0.04 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.04 0.00 0.04
Supplier dependence 0.08 0.04 0.08† 0.04 0.10 0.05 0.08 0.05
Market control variables
Buyer market unpredictability 0.40 0.33 0.25 0.30 0.24 0.39 0.20 0.38
Supplier market unpredictability 0.49 0.53 0.48 0.51 0.05 0.43 0.07 0.43
Main effects
SIZEA-Buyer H3a (+) 0.14** 0.05 H3c () 0.01 0.06
SIZEA-Supplier H3b () 0.10* 0.05 H3d (+) 0.05 0.06
RCA-Buyer H4a (+) 0.01 0.17 H4c () 0.10 0.17
RCA-Supplier H4b () 0.28* 0.13 H4d (+) 0.23† 0.15
R2 15.7% 23.9% 13.4% 16.6%
R adjusted square 5.5% 10.8% 3.0% 3.1%
F change 2.37* 0.82

We report one-tailed test for hypothesized variables when the coefficients are in the direction of the hypothesis, two-tailed test otherwise. Also, the
respondent is indicated in parentheses. N = 106. †p < 0.10, *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001. Values highlighted in bold correspond to hypotheses.

significant positive (negative) a3 indicates that the out- between RCbuyer and RCsupplier or between Sizebuyer
come variable is higher when the discrepancy is such and Sizesupplier. A significant positive (negative) a4
that RCbuyer is higher than RCsupplier (RCsupplier is indicates a convex (concave) surface. Table 6 includes
higher than RCbuyer) than vice versa. a4 represents the the results and the formulas for a1, a2, a3, and a4.
line of incongruence’s curvature as related to the out- To assess whether the asymmetry’s direction and de-
come variable and indicates the degree of discrepancy gree matter, we created surface plots for those cases in

Table 6 Results of Response Surface Analysis for Relational Capital and Size Asymmetry

Relational capital (RC) asymmetry Size asymmetry

Supplier Supplier
Buyer opportunism opportunism Buyer performance performance Buyer opportunism Buyer performance

Coefficient t Coefficient t Coefficient t Coefficient t Coefficient t Coefficient t


(SE) (SE) (SE) (SE) (SE) (SE)
a1 0.75*** 3.89 0.73*** 3.04 0.45* 2.13 0.81*** 3.47 0.18* 2.05 0.01 0.12
(0.19) (0.24) (0.21) (0.23) (0.09) (0.09)
a2 0.00 0.00 0.05 0.14 0.32 1.00 0.36 1.01 0.14* 2.34 0.06 0.94
(0.30) (0.37) (0.32) (0.35) (0.04) (0.06)
a3 0.67*** 3.16 0.17 0.60 0.39† 1.64 0.87*** 3.34 0.04 0.45 0.03 0.37
(0.21) (0.26) (0.24) (0.26) (0.09) (0.08)
a4 0.56† 1.84 0.15 0.40 0.04 0.11 0.28 0.80 0.02 0.26 0.12* 2.05
(0.30) (0.37) (0.36) (0.35) (0.07) (0.06)

The polynomial regression is as follow: Y1 = b0 + control variables + b1 9 RCbuyer + b2 9 RCsupplier + b3 9 RC2buyer + b4 9 RCbuyer 9 RCsupplier +
b5 9 RC2supplier.
RC could be replaced with Size. Coefficients, standard errors (in parenthesis), and t-statistics are reported. Standard errors (SE) were calculated based on
the guidelines by Shanock et al. (2010). †p < 0.10, *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.
a1 = b1 + b2: The slope of the line of perfect agreement; a2 = b3 + b4 + b5: the curvature along the line of perfect agreement.
a3 = b1  b2: The slope of the line of incongruence; a4 = b3  b4 + b5: the curvature along the line of incongruence.
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society 503

which either a3 or a4 was significant. In all of the fig- higher than RCsupplier (area B) than vice versa (area A).
ures, the line of perfect agreement is represented with Interestingly, the curvature along the line of incongru-
the solid line (CD line) while the line of incongruence ence as related to buyer opportunism increases more
(our focus) is represented with the dotted line (AB sharply as the degree of discrepancy increases. This
line). finding provides further support for H2b and H2a.
For relational capital asymmetry, a3 is significant for Figures 3 and 4 illustrate buyer and supplier per-
buyer opportunism (Figure 2), buyer performance formance, respectively. The figures show that perfor-
(Figure 3), and supplier performance (Figure 4) while mance is highest when both parties share similar high
a4 is significant only for buyer opportunism. Figure 2 levels of relational capital (area C). This result is con-
illustrates that buyer opportunism’s lowest level is sistent with past studies suggesting that relational
achieved when buyers and suppliers share similar capital is beneficial (Dyer and Singh 1998), but note
high values of relational capital (area C). This finding that this case occurs only if both parties have a similar
is consistent with past studies that suggest relational high level of relational capital. Figure 3 shows that
capital is a deterrent to buyer opportunism (Wang buyer performance increases when the discrepancy is
et al. 2013), but only if both parties share symmetric such that RCbuyer is higher than RCsupplier (area B)
levels of high relational capital. Buyer opportunism compared to when RCsupplier is higher than RCbuyer
increases when the discrepancy is such that RCbuyer is (area A), providing support for H4a and H4b. As
shown in Figure 4, supplier performance increases
when the discrepancy is such that RCsupplier is higher
Figure 2 Perceived Buyer Opportunism as Predicted by Perceived
Buyer Relational Capital-Perceived Supplier Relational
than RCbuyer (area A) compared to when RCbuyer is
Capital Discrepancy higher than RCsupplier (area B), providing support for
H4d and H4c.
5
Perceived For size asymmetry, a4 is significant for buyer per-
Buyer formance (Figure 5). Figure 5 shows that size asym-
Opportunism
4 metry’s degree (rather than direction) is more
relevant; that is, buyer performance suffers equally
3 when a size imbalance is in favor of the buyer (area
A) or the supplier (area B). Thus, this result supports
2
H3b but not H3a.
C Overall, the results of the response surface analysis
B are consistent with those of the spline method. For
A
1 2
1 instance, H2a, H2b, H3b, H4b, and H4d are sup-
2 1 D 0
0 -1
-1
-2 -2 Relational CapitalBuyer ported. Also, both methods’ results are consistent for
SIZEA-Buyer’s effect on buyer performance (H3a) in
Relational CapitalSupplier
the opposite direction we had theorized. The major
BO= + 0.004*RCbuyer -0.712*RCsupplier -0.24*RC2buyer+ 0.287*RCbuyer*RCsupplier -0.039 *RC2supplier
differences between the two methods are that with
the response surface analysis; we gained support for
H4a and H4c, but lost support for H1a, H1c, and H2d.
Figure 3 Buyer Performance as Predicted by Perceived Buyer
Relational Capital–Perceived Supplier Relational Capital Table 7 summarizes the results of our 16 hypotheses,
Discrepancy

5
Figure 4 Supplier Performance as Predicted by Perceived Buyer
Relational Capital–Perceived Supplier Relational Capital
Buyer Discrepancy
Performance
4 5

Supplier
Performance
3 4

3
2
C
B 2 2
A 1 C
1 0
2 Relational B 2
1 -1 A 1
0 D CapitalBuyer 1 0
-1 -2 Relational
Relational CapitalSupplier -2 2 1 -1
D CapitalBuyer
Relational CapitalSupplier 0 -1 -2
-2
BP= Constant-0.42*RCbuyer +0.05*RCsupplier +0.23*RC2buyer+ 0.14*RCbuyer*RCsupplier +0.23 *RC2supplier SP= Constant-0.03*RCbuyer +0.80*RCsupplier -0.13*RC2buyer+ 0.04*RCbuyer*RCsupplier -0.44 *RC2supplier
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
504 Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

identifying those that are significant based on one or only when both parties share similar levels of high
two methods and those that are not significant based relational capital. Our results also reveal that a buyer
on both methods. or supplier with a higher level of relational capital
than its counterpart may be perceived as more oppor-
tunist. That is, an imbalance of relational capital in the
5. Discussion focal firm’s favor may have the opposite effect from
Our study contributes to the nascent, but growing that intended—its counterpart perceives more, rather
research on asymmetries in BSRs. As have other than less, firm opportunism. This is an interesting
researchers (Gulati and Sytch 2007, Nyaga et al. 2013, dichotomy relative to relational capital and its effects
Thomas and Esper 2010), we find that asymmetries on perceived opportunism, contributing to our under-
exist in BSRs and that their presence has profound, standing that more relational capital is not always
complex implications. We focus on two types of desirable (Villena et al. 2011). In fact, our results sug-
asymmetries—relational capital and size—that are rel- gest that one party’s well-intentioned relational capi-
evant to BSRs. We are unaware of any other study tal endeavors can actually increase the other party’s
that has tried to unpack two important, yet distinct, concern regarding opportunism if that party does not
forms of asymmetry related to perceived opportunism perceive the same level of relational capital.
and performance using dyadic data. Thus, in many Regarding size asymmetry, the results show that if
ways, our research is in “unchartered waters” in the buyer is bigger, it perceives less supplier oppor-
terms of our theorizing, research design, and analysis. tunism and the supplier perceives more buyer oppor-
tunism; however, this is not the case if the supplier is
5.1. Asymmetries and Perceived Opportunism bigger. Our findings show a stronger impact of rela-
Past studies have consistently shown that relational tional capital asymmetry on buyer opportunism than
capital reduces opportunistic behavior (Dyer and Chu on supplier opportunism. In other words, suppliers
2003, Liu et al. 2009, Tangpong et al. 2010, Wang (compared to buyers) are more sensitive to this
et al. 2013). Our results confirm that this is the case impact. One potential reason is that suppliers (despite
being critical) are still sellers and, thus, have more to
Figure 5 Buyer Performance as Predicted by Buyer Size–Supplier Size lose from further dealings than buyers do. Both
Discrepancy results provide some evidence of how the upstream
5
(supplier) or downstream (buyer) position within the
Buyer relationship influences the relational capital and size
Performance asymmetries’ impact on perceived opportunism.
4
Could the imbalance position affect the prominence
of interpretive uncertainty (Weber and Mayer 2014)
3 by altering the underlying cognitive frames and, thus,
the perceptions of partner opportunism? Overall, we
2
believe this finding and conjecture are noteworthy
C and should be unpacked in future research.
B 2
A 1
1 0
2 -1
5.2. Asymmetries and Performance
1 D -2 SizeBuyer
SizeSupplier
0
-1 Overall, our results suggest that supplier performance
-2
is largely unaffected by size asymmetries. One poten-
BP= Constant -0.01*Sizebuyer +0.02*Sizesupplier -0.004*Size2buyer+0.09*Sizebuyer*Sizesupplier -0.03*Size2supplier tial reason is that suppliers (in an upstream position)

Table 7 Summary of Results

Buyer’s perceptions of Supplier’s Perceptions of

Asymmetry types Supplier opportunism Performance Buyer opportunism Performance


If the buyer is larger (SIZEA-Buyer) (H1c) +(H3a)* +(H1a) (H3c)
If the supplier is larger (SIZEA-Supplier) +(H1d) (H3b) (H1b) +(H3d)
If the buyer has more relational capital (RCA-Buyer) (H2c) +(H4a) +(H2a) (H4c)
If the supplier has more relational capital (RCA-Supplier) +(H2d) (H4b) (H2b) +(H4d)
Both methods significant
Both methods not significant
Spline method only significant
Response surface method only significant

*Both methods show that SIZEA-Buyer has a negative (rather than a positive as theorized) association with buyer performance.
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society 505

try to satisfy their customers and meet performance establishing a new requirement to avoid its supplier’s
expectations regardless of customer size. Also, our suspicion that this new requirement will unilaterally
theorizing that the buyer would perceive more favor- favor the account manager’s company.
able performance when it is bigger was not sup- Bigger buyers should recognize that they may be
ported. In fact, our results are opposite from what we viewed as more opportunistic although they view less
predicted, revealing that bigger buyers observe fewer opportunism in their smaller (critical) supplier.
benefits in their dealings with smaller suppliers. Fur- Again, transparency in all buyer actions is para-
ther, our results suggest that buyers perceive fewer mount. Furthermore, buyers, whether bigger or smal-
benefits if working with bigger suppliers. That is, ler than their counterparts, should be aware of
buying companies observe reduced performance reduced benefits from their supplier relationships.
when they are larger or smaller, perhaps offering a Conversely, suppliers perceive no influence on per-
boundary to our understanding of asymmetry’s direc- formance regardless of whether they are bigger or
tion (Gulati and Sytch 2007, Ross et al. 1997). smaller than their counterparts. Thus, buyers and
Also, the results show that if suppliers have higher suppliers should be in tune with these differences
levels of relational capital, buyers observe reduced and perhaps use a different “lens” through which to
benefits, whereas suppliers perceive slightly evaluate the benefits of working together. For
improved benefits. In short, our study suggests that instance, a sourcing manager could anticipate bigger
asymmetries in size and relational capital are perfor- benefits if working with smaller suppliers; however,
mance liabilities for buyers while asymmetry in rela- that manager would eventually realize that the chal-
tional capital could be an asset for suppliers. We hope lenges (e.g., more uncertainty) of working with smal-
that future research delves more deeply into these ler suppliers could overcome the anticipated benefits.
unexpected results. Such research would be particu- In contrast, an account manager will always try to sat-
larly enlightening if juxtaposed with our results rela- isfy the customer’s demands regardless of whether
tive to perceived opportunism. this customer is a smaller or larger player.
When analyzing the results of performance and
opportunism in tandem, we found that RCA-Supplier 5.4. Limitations and Future Research
catalyzes a positive supplier perception (of lower Opportunities
buyer opportunism) and a negative buyer perception The results of this research need to be considered in
(of lower firm performance). Thus, RCA-Supplier can the context of its limitations. First, we studied two key
be viewed as a “double-edged sword.” In essence, complementary types of asymmetry. However, other
our results suggest that this asymmetry is viewed asymmetries may be worthy of exploration—for
both favorably and negatively depending on whether instance, asymmetry of power with its various
it involves the upstream or downstream partner. This sources (e.g., technical capabilities) (Krajewski et al.
finding echoes our earlier thoughts that in addition to 2005). Furthermore, examining the interrelations
the influence of asymmetries’ degree and direction, among asymmetries could be fruitful. For instance,
the firm’s position in the dyad could trigger varying could size asymmetry be an antecedent of trust asym-
perceptions of the same asymmetry. metry? Second, we invested great effort into collecting
archival and survey data from both parties. However,
5.3. Managerial Implications we used a cross-sectional design and the dynamics of
Given the frequency of imbalances in size and rela- BSRs’ change. For instance, perceptions of trust could
tional capital, managers should extend efforts to un- change over time (Jap and Anderson 2007); thus,
cover and manage them in key BSRs—especially future studies should examine how symmetries
relational capital asymmetry, which is more latent evolve. Third, our research did not explore specific
and complex. If not effectively managed, this asset mechanisms for managing asymmetric BSRs or for
can become a liability in the form of perceived oppor- mitigating their negative consequences. Such infor-
tunism. The two main messages for managers are (i) mation would be very informative for managers.
not to assume, and act as if, there is a shared level of Fourth, our empirical setting included buyers and
relational capital and (ii) to recognize that initiatives their critical suppliers. Thus, our results should be
to build relational capital can backfire if the other used with caution when considering other types of
partner is not on the same page. Managers should BSRs (e.g., transactional relationships in which rela-
thus seek more transparency in their actions and tional capital would be minimal and size differences
invest company resources wisely. For example, a might be even greater). Fifth, we examined the effect
sourcing manager should seek to avoid ambiguity in of size and relational capital asymmetries on the
negotiations, lest the supplier perceives vagueness as firm’s benefits of developing new capabilities and
an attempt to hide buyer opportunism. Likewise, an skills from the relationship. However, asymmetries
account manager should be more transparent when may also have an impact on financial performance. Of
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
506 Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

2
course, this impact may require a context in which a We recognize that size is not the only factor that influ-
dyad could play a key role in overall firm-level per- ences bargaining power (cf. French and Raven 1959), but
formance (e.g., sole supplier of a critical commodity). it is an important one in an exchange.
3
Sixth, we acknowledge that we could not entirely Some critics of the spline method have noted that one of
the problems with difference scores is that the method
eliminate endogeneity. Clearly, measuring the related
could suffer from reduced reliability (Edwards 2002). Fol-
constructs (relational capital, opportunism, and per-
lowing Peter et al. (1993), we calculated our difference
formance) is fraught with challenges. Most notably, r21 r11 þr22 r22 2r12 r1 r2
the measures cannot completely decouple these scale’s reliability as follows: rD ¼ r21 þr22 2r12 r1 r2
; were
related constructs, meaning that some of the relation- r11 and r22 are the reliabilities of each of the two compo-
ships found could arguably be tautological. Our nent scores, and r12 s the correlation of the two scores.
transparent multi-method and dyadic analysis The difference score’s reliability exceeds the threshold of
approach attempted to address this argument; but 0.70.
4
Due to space limitations, we do not provide the polyno-
future research, perhaps longitudinal or detailed
mial regressions’ results. An example of our regression
cases, could further tease out these complex relation- equation is as follows:
ships. Seventh, the AVE value of our construct of rela-
tional capital on the buyer’s side reached 0.49 while Y1 ¼ b0 þ controlvariables þ b1  RCbuyer þ b2
the cutoff was 0.50. Also, Figure 4 shows a saddle  RCsupplier þ b3  RC2buyer þ b4  RCbuyer
region between performance and relational capital for
 RCsupplier þ b5  RC2supplier : ð2Þ
suppliers, which should be further explored in future
studies. Finally, our analysis was based on a sample where Y can be supplier opportunism, buyer oppor-
of companies operating in Spain. Future research tunism, supplier performance, or buyer performance. The
could use a more diverse sample and, more interest- surface values are then calculated as follows: a1 = b1 + b2:
ingly, compare across countries. the slope of the line of perfect agreement;
a2 = b3 + b4 + b5: the curvature along the line of perfect
agreement a3 = b1  b2: the slope of the line of incongru-
6. Concluding Thoughts ence; a4 = b3  b4 + b5: the curvature along the line of
The buyer–supplier relationship literature is a rich, incongruence.
informative body of knowledge. Yet, much of it views
only one side of the relationship and, thus, fails to
capture important differences relative to the degree, References
direction, and position of BSR imbalances. While we Anderson, E., B. Weitz. 1992. The use of pledges to build and sus-
have taken a step further in exploring two important tain commitment in distribution channels. J. Mark. Res. 29(1):
asymmetries—size and relational capital, we believe 18–34.
additional scholarly efforts are warranted. Thus, we Anderson, E., B. Weitz. 1989. Determinants of continuity in con-
ventional industrial channel dyads. Market Sci. 8(4): 310–323.
believe that this study’s epigraph should resonate
Bacharach, S. B., E. J. Lawler. 1981. Bargaining: Power, Tactics and
with scholars and managers alike—we need to con- Outcomes. Jossey-Bass Inc., San Francisco.
tinue acknowledging and embracing asymmetries as € Ozer,
Brinkhoff, A., O. € G. Sargut. 2015. All you need is trust? An
they very well could be our greatest strength in fully examination of inter-organizational supply chain projects.
and truly understanding the dynamics of buyer–sup- Prod. Oper. Manag. 24(2): 181–200.
plier relationships. Brower, H. H., S. W. Lester, M. A. Korsgaard, B. R. Dineen. 2009.
A closer look at trust between managers and subordinates:
Understanding the effects of both trusting and being trusted
on subordinate outcomes. J. Manage. 35(2): 327–347.
Acknowledgment Casciaro, T., M. J. Piskorski. 2005. Power imbalance, mutual
We are grateful to Sandy Jap, Qiong Wang, Lance Ferris, dependence, and constraint absorption: A closer look at
and Kaitlin Wowak for comments and suggestions on ear- resource dependence theory. Adm. Sci. Q. 50(2): 167–199.
lier versions of this manuscript. We are grateful to Vinod Child, J. 1972. Organizational structure, environment and perfor-
mance: The role of strategic choice. Sociology 6(1): 1–22.
Singhal, the senior editor, and two reviewers for their con-
structive comments and guidance that helped us signifi- Claycomb, C., G. L. Frankwick. 2004. A contingency perspective
of communication, conflict resolution and buyer search effort
cantly improve our manuscript. The first author would like
in buyer-supplier relationships. J. Supp. Chain Manag. 40(4):
to thank Elena Revilla for her assistance in data collection. 18–34.
Cohen, J., P. Cohen, S. G. West, L .S. Aiken. 2003. Applied Multiple
Notes Regression/Correlation Analysis for the Behavioral Sciences, 3rd
1 edn. Erlbaum, Mahwah.
In many situations the supplier may be viewed as critical.
Cousins, P. D., R. B. Handfield, B. Lawson, K. J. Petersen. 2006.
For example, the supplier could be a sole-source provider Creating supply chain relational capital: The impact of formal
of an important commodity or supply a high percentage and informal socialization processes. J. Oper. Manag. 24(6):
of the buyer’s total needs for a component. 851–863.
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society 507

Crook, T. R., J. G. Combs. 2007. Sources and consequences of bar- Krishnan, R., X. Martin, N. G. Noorderhaven. 2006. When does
gaining power in supply chains. J. Oper. Manag. 25(2): 546–555. trust matter to alliance performance? Acad. Manag. J. 49(5):
Crosno, J. L., R. Dahlstrom. 2008. A meta-analytic review of 894–917.
opportunism in exchange relationships. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. Kumar, N., L. K. Scheer, J.-B. E. Steenkamp. 1995. The effects of
36(2): 191–201. perceived interdependence on dealer attitudes. J. Mark. Res.
Delacroix, J., A. Swaminathan. 1991. Cosmetic, speculative, and 32(3): 348–356.
adaptive organizational change in the wine industry: A longi- Kumar, N., L. K. Scheer, J.-B. E. Steenkamp. 1998. Interdepen-
tudinal study. Adm. Sci. Q. 54(2): 631–661. dence, punitive capability, and the reciprocation of punitive
Dyer, J. H., W. Chu. 2003. The role of trustworthiness in reducing actions in channel relationships. J. Mark. Res. 35(2): 225–235.
transaction costs and improving performance: Empirical evi- Kutner, M.H., C. Nachtsheim, J. Neter. 2004. Applied Linear Regres-
dence from the United States, Japan, and Korea. Organ. Sci. sion Models. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, Boston, MA.
14(1): 57–68. Lambert, D. M., T. C. Harrington. 1990. Measuring nonresponse
Dyer, J. H., H. Singh. 1998. The relational view: Cooperative strat- bias in customer service mail surveys. J. Bus. Logisti. 11(2): 5–25.
egy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Lee, C.-J., R. E. Johnsen. 2012. Asymmetric customer–supplier
Acad. Manag. Rev. 23(4): 660–679. relationship development in Taiwanese electronics firms. Ind.
Edwards, J. R. 2002. Alternatives to difference scores: polynomial Mark. Manage. 41(4): 692–705.
regression and response surface methodology. F. Drasgow, N. Levinthal, D., J. G. March. 1981. A model of adaptive organiza-
W. Schmitt, eds. Advances in Measurement and Data Analysis. tional search. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2(4): 307–333.
Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, 350–400.
Liu, Y., Y. Luo, T. Liu. 2009. Governing buyer–supplier relation-
Edwards, J. R., M. E. Parry. 1993. On the use of polynomial ships through transactional and relational mechanisms: Evi-
regression equations as an alternative to difference scores in dence from China. J. Oper. Manag. 27(4): 294–309.
organizational research. Acad. Manag. J. 36(6): 1577–1613.
Macneil, I. R. 1981. Economic analysis of contractual relations: Its
French, J. R., B. Raven. 1959. The bases of social power. In D. shortfalls and the need for a rich classificatory apparatus.
Cartwright, A. Zander, eds. Group Dynamics. University of Northwestern Law Review 75(2): 1018–1063.
Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI.
Modi, S. B., V. A. Mabert. 2007. Supplier development: Improving
Gulati, R., M. Sytch. 2007. Dependence asymmetry and joint supplier performance through knowledge transfer. J. Oper.
dependence in interorganizational relationships: Effects of Manag. 25(1): 42–64.
embeddedness on a manufacturer’s performance in procure-
Moriarty, R. T., R. E. Spekman. 1984. An empirical investigation
ment relationships. Adm. Sci. Q. 52(1): 32–69.
of the information sources used during the industrial buying
Hair, J. F., W. C. Black, B. J. Babin, R. E. Anderson. 2010. Multi- process. J. Mark. Res. 21(2): 137–147.
variate Data Analysis. Pearson College Division, Upper Saddle
Nyaga, G. N., D. F. Lynch, D. Marshall, E. Ambrose. 2013. Power
River, NJ.
asymmetry, adaptation and collaboration in dyadic relation-
Hart, P., C. Saunders. 1997. Power and trust: Critical factors in ships involving a powerful partner. J. Supp. Chain Manag.
the adoption and use of electronic data interchange. Organ. 49(3): 42–65.
Sci. 8(1): 23–42.
Peter, J. P., G. A. Churchill Jr., T. J. Brown. 1993. Caution in the
Hill, C. W., F. T. Rothaermel. 2003. The performance of incumbent use of difference scores in consumer research. J. Cons. Res.
firms in the face of radical technological innovation. Acad. 19(4): 655–662.
Manag. Rev. 28(2): 257–274.
Podsakoff, P. M., S. B. MacKenzie, N. P. Podsakoff. 2012. Sources
Hoskisson, R. E., L. Eden, C. M. Lau, M. Wright. 2000. Strategy in of method bias in social science research and recommenda-
emerging economics. Acad. Manag. J. 43(3): 249–267. tions on how to control it. Annu. Rev. Psychol. 63: 539–569.
Hu, L. T., P. M. Bentler. 1999. Cutoff criteria for fit indexes in Poppo, L., K. Z. Zhou, T. R. Zenger. 2008. Examining the condi-
covariance structure analysis: Conventional criteria versus tional limits of relational governance: Specialized assets, per-
new alternatives. Struct. Eq. Model. Multi. J. 6(1): 1–55. formance ambiguity, and long-standing ties. J. Manage. Stud.
Jap, S. D., E. Anderson. 2003. Safeguarding interorganizational 45(7): 1195–1216.
performance and continuity under ex-post opportunism. Man- Roh, J. A., J. M. Whipple, K. K. Boyer. 2013. The effect of single
agement Sci. 49(12): 1684–1701. rater bias in multi-stakeholder research: A methodological
Jap, S. D., E. Anderson. 2007. Testing a life-cycle theory of cooper- evaluation of buyer-supplier relationships. Prod. Oper. Manag.
ative interorganizational relationships: Movement across 22(3): 711–725.
stages and performance. Management Sci. 53(2): 260–275. Rokkan, A. I., J. B. Heide, K. H. Wathne. 2003. Specific invest-
Johnsen, R. E., D. Ford. 2008. Exploring the concept of asymme- ments in marketing relationships: Expropriation and bonding
try: A typology for analysing customer–supplier relationships. effects. J. Mark. Res. 40(2): 210–224.
Ind. Mark. Manage. 37(4): 471–483. Ross, W. T., E. Anderson, B. Weitz. 1997. Performance in princi-
Kale, P., H. Singh, H. Perlmutter. 2000. Learning and protection pal-agent dyads: The causes and consequences of perceived
of proprietary assets in strategic alliances: Building relational asymmetry of commitment to the relationship. Management
capital. Strateg. Manag. J. 21(3): 217–237. Sci. 43(5): 680–704.
Kim, K. K., S.-H. Park, S. Y. Ryoo, S. K. Park. 2010. Inter-organiza- Sarkar, M. B., R. Echambadi, S. T. Cavusgil, P. S. Aulakh. 2001.
tional cooperation in buyer–supplier relationships: Both per- The influence of complementarity, compatibility, and relation-
spectives. J. Bus. Res. 63(8): 863–869. ship capital on alliance performance. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 29(4):
Korsgaard, M. A., H. H. Brower, S. W. Lester. 2015. It isn’t always 358–373.
mutual a critical review of dyadic trust. J. Manag. 41(1): Shanock, L. R., B. E. Baran, W. A. Gentry, S. C. Pattison, E. D.
47–70. Heggestad. 2010. Polynomial regression with response surface
Krajewski, L., J. C. Wei, L.-L. Tang. 2005. Responding to schedule analysis: A powerful approach for examining moderation
changes in build-to-order supply chains. J. Oper. Manag. 23(5): and overcoming limitations of difference scores. J. Bus. Psy-
452–469. chol. 25(4): 543–554.
Villena and Craighead: Buyer–Supplier Asymmetries
508 Production and Operations Management 26(3), pp. 491–508, © 2016 Production and Operations Management Society

Sheth, J. N. 1973. A model of industrial buyer behavior. J. Market. Wang, Q., J. J. Li, W. T. Ross Jr, C. W. Craighead. 2013. The inter-
37(4): 50–56. play of drivers and deterrents of opportunism in buyer–sup-
Spekman, R. E. 1988. Perceptions of strategic vulnerability among plier relationships. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 41(1): 111–131.
industrial buyers and its effect on information search and Wang, Q., C. W. Craighead, J. J. Li. 2014. Justice served: Mitigat-
supplier evaluation. J. Bus. Res. 17(4): 313–326. ing damaged trust stemming from supply chain disruptions.
Tangpong, C., K.-T. Hung, Y. K. Ro. 2010. The interaction effect of J. Oper. Manag. 32(6): 374–386.
relational norms and agent cooperativeness on opportunism in Wathne, K. H., J. B. Heide. 2000. Opportunism in interfirm rela-
buyer–supplier relationships. J. Oper. Manag. 28(5): 398–414. tionships: Forms, outcomes, and solutions. J. Market. 64(4):
Thomas, R. W., T. L. Esper. 2010. Exploring relational asymmetry 36–51.
in supply chains: The retailer’s perspective. Int. J. Physi. Dis- Weber, L., K. Mayer. 2014. Transaction cost economics and the cog-
tribu. Logisti. Manag. 40(6): 475–494. nitive perspective: Investigating the sources and governance of
Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in Action: Social Science Bases interpretive uncertainty. Acad. Manag. Rev. 39(3): 344–363.
of Administrative. McGraw-Hill, New Brunswick, NJ. Williamson, O. E. 1973. Markets and hierarchies: Some elementary
Tomlinson, E. C., B. R. Dineen, R. J. Lewicki. 2009. Trust congru- considerations. Am. Econ. Rev. 63(2): 316–325.
ence among integrative negotiators as a predictor of joint- Williamson, O. E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. The
behavioral outcomes. Int. J. Confl. Manag. 20(2): 173–187. Free Press, New York.
Villena, V. H., L. Cheng. 2016. The benefits and downsides of Williamson, O. E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. Oxford
common supply chain partners. Acad. Manag. Proceed. 1(1): University Press, New York, NY.
10673. Wuyts, S., I. Geyskens. 2005. The formation of buyer—supplier
Villena, V. H., E. Revilla, T. Y. Choi. 2011. The dark side of relationships: Detailed contract drafting and close partner
buyer–supplier relationships: A social capital perspective. selection. J. Market. 69(4): 103–117.
J. Oper. Manag. 29(6): 561–576. Zhou, K. Z., Q. Zhang, S. Sheng, E. Xie, Y. Bao. 2014. Are rela-
Villena, V. H., T. Y. Choi, E. Revilla. 2016. Revisiting interorgani- tional ties always good for knowledge acquisition? Buyer–
zational trust: Is more always better, or could more be worse? supplier exchanges in China. J. Oper. Manag. 32(3): 88–98.
J. Manage. Available at https://doi.org/10.1177/01492063
16680031.

You might also like