You are on page 1of 12

Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect

RESEARCH ARTICLE

Status and path of intergenerational transmission of poverty in


rural China: A human capital investment perspective

BAI Yun-li1, 2, ZHANG Lin-xiu2, 1, SUN Ming-xing1, 2, XU Xiang-bo1, 2

1
Key Laboratory of Ecosystem Network Observation and Modeling, Institute of Geographic Sciences and Natural Resources
Research, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100101, P.R.China
2
UN Environment Programme-International Ecosystem Management Partnership, Beijing 100101, P.R.China

Abstract
This paper focused on the intergenerational transmission of poverty in rural China by estimating the intergenerational
transmission of earnings and stated its mechanism from the perspective of human capital investment before children
participated in the labor market. The data used in this study were longitude data collected in 2 000 households of 100
villages among 25 counties across five provinces in 2005, 2008, 2012, 2016, and 2019. Qualitative and quantitative
methods were adopted. We found a significant intergenerational transmission of earnings in rural China, especially for the
pairs of father–children and parents–children. The intergenerational earnings’ elasticities were much less than those in
urban areas, which indicated better social mobility in rural areas than that in urban China. The children with parents who
could earn much were more likely to be invested before they participated in the labor market, gain a high education and
have more skills. Three cases further showed that the mechanism of human capital investment in children breaking the
intergenerational transmission of poverty and promoting social mobility.

Keywords: poverty, intergenerational transmission, human capital, rural China

Bank 2018), and most of them lived in developing countries.


Worldwide, the poverty rate in rural areas is 17.2% - more
1. Introduction than three times higher than that in urban areas (United
Nations 2020).
Poverty is the first global challenge under the sustainable
The biggest challenge for poverty alleviation is to
development goals set by the United Nations (2015).
break the intergenerational transmission of poverty (ITP),
According to the most recent estimates, 10% of the world’s
especially in developing countries. The ability to move up
population lived on less than US$1.90 a day in 2015 (World
the income ladder is a matter of fairness and has major
implications for poverty reduction (Breen and Jonsson 2005;
Kambourov and Manovskii 2009; Warzywoda-Kruszyńska
Received 20 February, 2020 Accepted 4 August, 2020 2013; Chetty et al. 2014; Narayan 2018). Most of the
Correspondence BAI Yun-li, Tel: +86-10-64889834, E-mail: ylbai.
ccap@igsnrr.ac.cn literature has focused on the ITP in the developed countries,
such as the United States, Canada, the United Kingdom,
© 2021 CAAS. Published by Elsevier B.V. This is an open and Spain (Rodgers 1995; Dearden et al. 1997; Blanden
access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://
creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/). and Gibbons 2006; Cardak et al. 2013; Duarte et al. 2018).
doi: 10.1016/S2095-3119(20)63373-1 However, the studies on the ITP in developing countries
BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091 1081

were rare and only recently appeared (Kabeer and Mahmud by adopting the OLS estimation method. The IV estimation
2009; Cooper 2010; Gong et al. 2012; Deng et al. 2013; Fan method has been adopted in some related studies. The
2016; Behrman et al. 2017; Wu et al. 2019). Notably, both common IV used in the literature was predicted earnings
absolute and relative social mobility is lower in low- and in parents’ occupations (Leigh 2007). The two-sample
middle-income countries compared with that in high-income instrumental variables approach was another common
countries, according to the report from the Global Database method that has been used to estimate ITP (Nicoletti and
on Intergenerational Mobility (Narayan et al. 2018). Ermisch 2008; Gong et al. 2012; Lefranc et al. 2014).
Most of the literature on ITP has focused on the When estimating the intergenerational transmission of
intergenerational transmission of family income or individual income or earnings, some characteristics affecting children’s
earnings (Atkinson et al. 1983; Solon 1992, 1999; Chadwick income or earnings are included in the model. Gender has
and Solon 2002; Pascual 2009; Cardak et al. 2013; Fan been proved to be an important trait influencing off-farm
2016; Qin et al. 2016). However, a few studies have used wage (Wang et al. 2016, 2019). The education, skill, and
the possibility of being poor (Rodgers 1995; Quisumbing physical health status were often included in the model to
2008). The previous studies measured the intergenerational control the impact of human capital on the off-farm wage
elasticity in income or earnings by specifying a linear (Kamga et al. 2013; Heckman et al. 2014; Wang et al. 2016,
regression equation between log income or earnings 2019). The experience usually measured by age was also
of children and log income or earnings of parents. The controlled in these studies. Previous studies found wage
significance and magnitude of intergenerational elasticity premium among different cities (Yankow 2006; Zhou et al.
in income or earnings depended on the definition of the 2018).
outcome variable and the different estimation methods in Researchers have found that human capital, including
the literature. education, health, and nutrition, was widely recognized as a
There are multiple definitions of family income and key mechanism for escaping from ITP (Glewwe et al. 1999;
individual earnings. Fan (2016) defined family income as Harper et al. 2003; Quisumbing 2008; Bird and Higggins
the total annual average income of the father and mother 2011; Room 2011; Gong et al. 2012; Qin et al. 2016; de
in at least three preceding years of the survey wave. Qin Vuijst et al. 2017; Duarte et al. 2018). Education, a critical
et al. (2016) took the average values of fathers’ annual indicator of human capital, has been widely mentioned for its
income in all sample waves as a proxy measure of fathers’ contribution to social mobility (Ruiz 2016). Poor health was
permanent income and yearly income as a measurement of the central issue faced by poor groups (Mackintosh 2001;
son’s income. The definition of individual earnings was more Freedman 2005). Bad health could be both an outcome
consistent than that of family income. It referred to wages, and a cause of poverty. Poverty created the situation in
bonuses, and other subsidies provided by the employer. which bad health was occurred and perpetuated, such
However, the measurement of earnings varied among these as low productivity and income, inadequate diets, unsafe
studies. Log of hourly earnings, log of weekly earnings, working and living environments, and reduction in long-term
log of monthly earnings, and annual earnings were usually investment (Grant 2005). But bad health also led to poverty
used to measure the son’s and father’s earnings (Atkinson through reducing income of adults when with increasing
et al. 1983; Hertz 2001; Cardak et al. 2013). Some studies expenditures on health care and through the long-term
have used the log of average earnings over several years irreversible effects on functional capabilities, including
of children and parents to alleviate potential biases induced ability to maximize returns on the acquisition of education
by income fluctuations and lifecycle effects (Osterbacka (Mayer-Foulkes 2003).
2001; Mazumder 2005; Lee and Solon 2006; Nicoletti and The key precondition for breaking the ITP is to clarify the
Ermisch 2008; Gong et al. 2012). For reviews, see Solon mechanism of ITP. The empirical studies on this topic have
(2002) and Black and Devereux (2011). been rare because of the limitation of long panel data. To our
Ordinary least squares (OLS) and instrumental variable knowledge, only several studies have investigated this topic
(IV) were usually used to estimate the intergenerational in China. Gong et al. (2012) estimated the intergenerational
transmission of income or earnings in the literature. OLS income elasticity for urban China by using the Urban
was the earliest and most widely used method (Solon Household Education and Employment Survey 2004 and the
1992; Hertz 2001; Osterberg 2001; Deng et al. 2013). For Urban Household Income and Expenditure Survey 1986–
example, Deng et al. (2013) used a one-year and average of 2004. Deng et al. (2013) estimated the intergenerational
three years of children’s incomes as independent variables income elasticities by using samples of urban China for
and corresponding income of parents as the key regressor the years 1999 and 2002. Fan (2016) investigated the
to estimate the intergenerational income elasticity with the intergenerational income association and its transmission
samples of urban households in China in 1999 and 2002 channels amid China’s economic transition period by using
1082 BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091

urban data from the Chinese Household Income Projects has been neglected in the literature.
in 1995 and 2002. Qin et al. (2016) studied the impact The remainder of the paper is organized as follows:
of human capital transmission across generations on the Section 2 introduces data and methods of this study.
intergenerational income mobility in urban and rural areas of Section 3 presents the results and discussion. Section
China using 1989–2009 China Health and Nutrition Survey 4 shows the mechanism of ITP. The conclusion is in
data. Wu et al. (2019) analyzed the regional differentiation Section 5.
characteristics of ITP and explored its impact mechanisms
based on a sustainable livelihood framework. Among these 2. Data and methods
studies, only Qin et al. (2016) used the sample including
rural households. 2.1. Sampling and data collection
The ITP in China, the biggest developing and most
populous country in the world, has been paid an increasing This paper used the panel data, namely, the China Rural
attention from scholars and policymakers. The Chinese Development Survey, collected by the authors. A multi-
central government is determined to eradicate absolute round survey was administered to 2 000 households and
poverty by 2020, in which preventing ITP was one of the village leaders of 100 villages in 25 counties across five
most important challenges (State Council 2015). The provinces in 2005, 2008, 2012, 2016, and 2019. The
new terms “Fu-er-dai” (children of rich families), “Guan-er- dataset was used widely to research the evolution of
dai” (children of government officials), and “Nong-er-dai” rural labor market, the intergenerational transmission of
(children of peasants) reflect the persistent influence of education and occupation, and the governance in rural
parents’ socioeconomic positions on their children. Some China (Wong et al. 2017; Zhang et al. 2018; Dong et al.
scholars have estimated intergenerational transmission 2019, 2020; Liu et al. 2019; Wang H J et al. 2020; Wang
elasticity from the perspective of income, education, W D et al. 2020; Zhuo et al. 2020). In the first round of
occupation, and self-employment business (Fan 2016; Qin the survey in 2005, each sample province was randomly
et al. 2016; Dong et al. 2019; Wang W D et al. 2020; Zhuo selected from China’s major agroecological zones. Finally,
et al. 2020). Jiangsu, Sichuan, Shaanxi, Jilin, and Hebei provinces
Despite the increasing attention on ITP in China, rigorous were selected.
study of this topic has been scarce in rural areas. Rural Five sample counties were then selected from each
areas hold 40.4% of the permanent residents in China and province in a two-step procedure. First, the enumeration
are the main targeted areas for poverty reduction because team listed all the counties in each province in descending
of the long-term existence of the urban–rural dual structure. order of per capita gross value of industrial output, which is
China is a critical case study for understanding the nature of a good predictor of the standard of living and development
social mobility during the transition from a socialist command potential and often more reliable than the net per capita
economy to a more market-oriented economy (Emran and income (Huang and Rozelle 1996). Second, five counties
Sun 2011). Therefore, focusing on breaking the ITP in per province were randomly selected from the resulting list.
rural China is important to narrow the socioeconomic gap From each selected county, the team selected sample
between urban and rural areas in China and contributes to townships and villages. Two townships were selected from
other developing countries. each county, comprising one from each of the two groups
This study attempts to estimate the ITP in rural China and per county: a “more well-off” group and a “poorer” group.
identify its mechanism from the perspective of human capital Following the same procedure, two villages per township
investment in the offspring before they participated the labor were selected. Finally, the survey teams randomly selected
market by adopting qualitative and quantitative methods. It 20 households from each village: eight participated
contributes to the literature from three perspectives. First, in the questionnaire survey and 12 participated in the
identifying the mechanism based on the human capital small group interview. We also conducted four rounds
investment before the offspring participate in the labor of follow-up surveys in 2008, 2012, 2016, and 2019. All
market using unique dataset. This study applies systematic of the households in following surveys participated in the
logic of human capital investment in schooling affecting the questionnaire survey.
capacity of earning wages after participating in the labor The survey team gathered detailed information on
market. Second, it provides additional empirical evidence on individual demographics and household characteristics
human capital influencing intergenerational mobility in rural in each wave of the survey. Individual demographic
areas of developing countries. Third, it considers skills as a characteristics included gender, birth year, years of
critical type of human capital when finding the mechanism schooling or the present grade, the number of siblings, and
of ITP, which is vital for the income of rural residents but birth order. The human capital of the individual comprised
BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091 1083

the skill status, such as the type of skills, the start and final of earnings from the father, mother, and parental average to
year of training for that skill, and physical health except for the child. For each child i in household h, we have:
formal schooling. The team also documented each laborer’s LogEarningih=α+βLogEarningdadih+γFih+εih (1)
employment status in the household, including whether they LogEarningih=α+βLogEarningmomih+γFih+εih (2)
had off-farm work; the months in a year, days in a month, and LogEarningih=α+βLogEarningavgih+γFih+εih (3)
hours in a day they worked off-farm; and the location and For convenience, we defined Earning as the hourly
occupation of the off-farm employment. More importantly, earnings of an individual child. Earningdad, Earningmom, and
we gathered information on the investment in an academic Earningavg represented the hourly earnings of the father,
year in schooling for the children in each wave of survey, mother, and the average of the parents, respectively. Hourly
including tuition fees, incidental fees, book fees, course earnings has often been used to reflect the ability to earn in
fees, and other fees related to schooling.1 the labor market. In this study, we calculated hourly earnings
This dataset helped us construct the earning pairs of by the total annual wages divided by the annual number of
parents and their children, which we used to analyze the hours of off-farm employment.
ITP, since the off-farm employment has been a major source F was a vector of other factors that may influence the
of income for households in rural China (NBSC 2019; Luo child’s hourly wage. These factors are years of schooling,
et al. 2020). We investigated the mechanism of ITP from gender (1=male), age (years), number of vocational
the perspective of human capital investment, according to qualification certificates, experience in the current industry
the information on years of schooling, skill training, physical (months), job location (1=within the county), self-reported
health, and the investment in schooling. physical health (1=health), and a set of provincial dummies
We mainly used the data collected in 2019 to conduct to capture regional factors that might affect the child’s wage.
quantitative analysis in this study. The sample in this The description of the variables is presented in Table 1. ε is
study was limited to the rural laborers engaged in off-farm the error term. Compared with models (1) and (2), model
employment and his/her children who had performed off- (3) had the advantage that it controlled assortative mating,
farm work in 2018 and had finished their education. Finally, avoided multicollinearity, and produced a more precisely
we obtained a sample of 322 pairs of fathers and their estimated coefficient.
children, 160 pairs of mothers and their children, and 102
pairs of parents and their children. Among these children, 3. Results and discussion
34, 60, and 16 of them were in school when we surveyed
in 2016, 2008, and 2005, respectively. The data supported 3.1. Descriptive statistics of children and their
our analysis of the relationship between human capital parent’s wage
investment and ITP. We also conducted case studies with
16 of the pairs to discuss the mechanism systematically Fig. 1 showed the hourly earnings of parents and their
because they had just started primary school in 2005 and children. According to our data, the average hourly earnings
have participated in off-farm employment since 2018. In of the children was 19.2 CNY in 2018. The father’s average
other words, we used the data from 2005 to 2019 to do hourly earnings was 16.8 CNY in the same year. The
mechanism analysis and case study with the information average earnings of the mother was 13.0 CNY. The average
on investment in education of the children before their earnings of father was approximately 1.3 times as much
participation in labor market. as the wage of mother in rural families, which was much
smaller than those in the literature (Li et al. 2013; Wang
2.2. Identification strategy et al. 2019). The finding indicated the healthy development
of the Chinese rural labor market.
Most economic analyses on the elasticity of intergenerational In Fig.  1, the hourly earnings of children increased
transmission of earnings or income have used the coefficient with the rise in the father’s hourly earnings, which implied
in the following intergenerational regression model. an obviously positive correlation between the earnings
Additionally, using Holmlund et al. (2011) and Pronzato of fathers and their children (Fig. 1-A). The correlation
(2012), who have studied the intergenerational transmission coefficient between hourly earnings of children and father’s
of education, as references, we employed three empirical hourly earnings was 0.118 (P<0.01, R2=0.02). However, the
specifications to examine the intergenerational transmission relationship between mothers’ and their children’s hourly

1
Amount of investment in formal schooling was not collected in 2012.
1084 BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091

Table 1 Description of the variables


Variable N Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max.
Log(Hourly earnings of children) 322 2.769 0.655 0.397 4.483
Log(Hourly earnings of father) 335 2.589 0.726 0.329 4.563
Log(Hourly earnings of mother) 164 2.262 0.629 0.351 4.364
Log(Average hourly earnings of parents) 105 2.496 0.521 0.397 3.794
Years of schooling of children 335 11.170 3.333 0 19
Gender of children (1=male) 335 0.803 0.398 0 1
Age of children (years) 335 27.875 6.101 20 48
Number of certificates of skill 335 0.752 0.605 0 3
Experience in current industry (months) 335 52.991 50.276 0 300
Job location (1=within the county) 335 0.391 0.489 0 1
Self-reported physical health (1=healthy) 335 0.985 0.121 0 1

Hourly earnings of children Fitted values


A B
Hourly earnings of children (CNY)

Hourly earnings of children (CNY)


120 120

100 100

80 80

60 60

40 40

20 20

0 0
0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100
Hourly earnings of father (CNY) Hourly earnings of mother (CNY)

C
120
Hourly earnings of children (CNY)

100

80

60

40

20

0
0 20 40 60 80 100
Average hourly earnings of parents (CNY)

Fig. 1 Relationship of hourly earnings between parents and their children.

earnings had a weak positive correlation compared with average hourly earnings of children and average hourly
that of the father and children (Fig. 1-B). The correlation earnings of parents was 0.027 and it was not significant
coefficient between hourly earnings of children and mother’s even at 10% level (R2=0.003).
hourly earnings was 0.018 and it was not significant even at
10% level (R2=0.002). This finding indicated that the hourly 3.2. OLS model of intergenerational transmission
earnings of the mother might have a slight influence on the of earnings
hourly earnings of her children. The correlation between the
average hourly earnings of parents and their children was According to the OLS estimation, there was a positive
also positive (Fig. 1-C). The correlation coefficient between relationship between parents’ and their children’s hourly
BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091 1085

earnings (Table  2). We found that the impact of the effect remained significant, and the magnitude increased
father–children transmission effect was 0.226 (P<0.01), to 0.373 (P<0.01) (row 3, column 9).
which meant that each 1% increase in the father’s hourly Children’s hourly earnings were also correlated with other
earnings would on average lead to an approximately 0.226% characteristics. Years of schooling of the children had a
increase in their children’s hourly earnings (row 1, column 1). significant positive effect on their hourly wage (P<0.01) (row
When we controlled individual characteristics, this effect 4, columns 3, 6, and 9). This finding was consistent with
reduced to 0.213 (P<0.01) (row 1, column 2). When we those in the literature, but the magnitudes of the coefficient
further controlled regional factors, we found the magnitude were larger in this study (Li et al. 2005; Zhang et al. 2008;
of the transmission effect declined to 0.202 (P<0.01) (row 1, Wang et al. 2019). It further indicated that human capital was
column 3). The mother’s hourly earnings had almost playing an increasingly important role in wage, which proved
no effect on their children’s hourly earnings, which was the healthy and equitable development of the Chinese labor
consistent with that in descriptive analysis. market. Males had much higher wages only in model (1)
However, the impact of parents’ average hourly earnings (P<0.01) (row 6, column 3). Although we considered the
on children’s hourly earnings was positive and much effects on the children’s hourly earnings on the basis of the
stronger than that of the father’s or mother’s alone. This background of the average earnings of a parent or parents,
result showed that each 1% increase of parents’ hourly there was no significant difference in the earnings between
earnings on average added approximately 0.287% of the male and female children (row 6, column 9). Age also
children’s hourly earnings (P<0.05) (row 3, column 7). When had a significant and positive effect on the hourly earnings
we further controlled other covariates, the transmission (P<0.01) (row 6, columns 3, 6, and 9). If the age increased

Table 2 Intergenerational transmission of earnings in rural China


Log(Hourly earnings of children)
Variable
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Log(Hourly earnings of father) 0.226*** 0.213*** 0.202***
(0.049) (0.046) (0.048)
Log(Hourly earnings of mother) 0.024 0.050 0.026
(0.101) (0.095) (0.095)
Log(Average hourly earnings of parents) 0.287** 0.365***0.373***
(0.119) (0.111) (0.118)
Years of schooling (years) 0.036*** 0.036*** 0.058*** 0.061*** 0.045** 0.043**
(0.011) (0.011) (0.019) (0.020) (0.019) (0.019)
Gender (1=male) 0.213** 0.219** 0.051 0.067 –0.018 –0.049
(0.088) (0.088) (0.133) (0.134) (0.129) (0.134)
Age (years) 0.023*** 0.022*** 0.040*** 0.041*** 0.050***0.052***
(0.006) (0.007) (0.011) (0.011) (0.011) (0.011)
Number of vocational qualification certificates 0.138** 0.138** 0.191** 0.179* 0.038 0.063
(0.058) (0.059) (0.096) (0.098) (0.097) (0.099)
Experience in the current industry (months) 0.001 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Job location (1=within the county) –0.165** –0.167** –0.439*** –0.417*** –0.175 –0.189
(0.070) (0.071) (0.125) (0.125) (0.121) (0.123)
Self-reported physical healthy (1=health) 0.565** 0.548** 1.060** 1.012** 0.909** 0.966**
(0.268) (0.271) (0.428) (0.440) (0.392) (0.406)
Sichuan 0.006 0.100 0.231
(0.103) (0.167) (0.153)
Shaanxi –0.075 –0.072 0.185
(0.099) (0.169) (0.160)
Jilin –0.084 0.170 0.148
(0.122) (0.208) (0.208)
Hebei –0.100 –0.248 0.012
(0.107) (0.182) (0.195)
Constant 2.185*** 0.378 0.489 2.713*** –0.196 –0.152 2.048*** –0.874 –1.087*
(0.132) (0.362) (0.385) (0.238) (0.580) (0.623) (0.303) (0.587) (0.648)
Observations 322 322 322 160 160 160 102 102 102
R-squared 0.062 0.204 0.208 0.000 0.239 0.264 0.055 0.349 0.371
***
Robust standard errors in parentheses. , P<0.01; **, P<0.05; *, P<0.1.
1086 BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091

1 year, hourly earnings rose approximately 0.022–0.052%. culture. This connection between the generations may bias
The number of vocational qualification certificates and job the results in a manner that tends to overstate the effect of
location had positive and negative effects on the hourly the parents’ earnings on their children. In other words, it is
earnings, only in models (1) and (2), respectively (rows 7 statistically significant that children following a similar path
and 9, columns 3 and 6). Self-reported physical health had to their parents, but the OLS model may describe this only
positive and significant effects on hourly earnings, implying as being a feature of intergenerational transmission rather
the vital role of human capital - on education and physical than a combination of similar genetics and family culture.
health - in the earnings. The family fixed effect (FFE) model is an effective method to
address this type of potential endogeneity (Dong et al. 2019).
3.3. Discussion on the results of OLS regression Due to the limited sample, we cannot use the FFE model to
estimate the transmission effect of parents’ earnings on their
Our study found that the estimated effects of the father’s children’s earnings while eliminating these other contributing
hourly earnings - consistent with in the literature - factors that affect both parents and their children.
demonstrated that higher-earning fathers increased their
children’s hourly earnings. The result was lower than 4. Mechanism of ITP
other studies that used the Chinese urban sample (Gong
et al. 2012; Deng et al. 2013). The implication was that 4.1. Parent’s earnings and the human capital of their
intergenerational mobility was higher for individuals born in children
rural parts of China, which was consistent with the logical
deduction of Gong et al. (2012). We attempted to find the mechanism of ITP by identifying
However, in the literature that has used an urban sample, the relationship between parent’s earnings and the children’s
a significant intergenerational transmission of income human capital because human capital have gradually
between mother and children was observed. For example, become the main determinant of the children’s earnings.
Deng et al. (2013) found that income persistence for the According to the literature, aspects of human capital were,
children–mother pairs was 0.340 for 1995 and 0.448 for for example, formal education in school, skills training, and
2002. Gong et al. (2012) found that the intergenerational physical and mental health. Due to the limitation of the
income elasticity of mother–son and mother–daughter was data, we were only able to identify the relationship between
0.369 and 0.338, respectively. The hourly earnings among parents’ earnings and formal education in school, skills
rural females were more homogeneous than that of males training, and physical health. The human capital of children
or that of urban females, which led to a slight effect on their was related to the whole-family characteristics. Thus, we
offspring’s hourly earnings. The small sample size may mainly analyzed the relationship between the average hourly
also have an effect. earnings of parents and the human capital of their children.
Although the results of our study showed that average In Table  3, average hourly earnings of parents were
hourly earnings of both parents played a stronger role than positively correlated with the years of formal schooling of
the father’s or the mother’s hourly earnings alone, the their children. If the average hourly earnings of parent’s
coefficient of the average hourly earnings of both parents increased by 1%, the years of formal schooling of their
was not comparable to the coefficients of the father’s or children increased by 1.367 years (row 1, column 1).
the mother’s hourly earnings individually. The average When we controlled other variables, such as gender,
hourly earnings of both parents when increased by 1% siblings, and birth order, that affected education, the
was equivalent to both the father’s and the mother’s hourly result remained robust (row 1, columns 2 and 3). We also
earnings increasing by 1%. Thus, both parents’ average observed a significant positive correlation between parents’
hourly earnings played a stronger role than either the average hourly earnings and the duration of skills training
father’s or the mother’s hourly earnings. Compared with of their children while controlling the covariates (row 1,
the relationship of father’s or mother’s and their children’s columns 5 and 6). However, no significant relationship
hourly earnings, the correlation of average hourly earnings was observed between the average hourly earnings of
of parents and their children controlled assortative mating, parents and the children’s self-reported physical health.
avoids multicollinearity, and produces more precisely The results indicated that high hourly earnings can be
estimated relationships. intergenerationally transmitted by improving the children’s
Potential endogeneity is a limitation of the OLS model. human capital, especially education and skills training.
In our case, this limitation affected our study when parents In other words, improving the human capital of children
and their children are linked by similar genetics and family facilitated breaking the of ITP.
BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091 1087

Table 3 Effect of parents’ earnings on the human capital of their children


Years of schooling of children Duration of skills training Self-reported physical health
Variable (years) (months) (1=health)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Log(Average hourly 1.367** 1.319** 1.324** 1.044 2.351* 2.909** 0.004 0.002 –0.009
earnings of parents) (0.580) (0.628) (0.647) (1.188) (1.357) (1.202) (0.016) (0.014) (0.017)
Gender (1=male) –1.833*** –1.840*** –2.889 –2.874 –0.028 –0.022
(0.657) (0.700) (2.503) (2.247) (0.021) (0.018)
Age –0.019 –0.017 0.092 0.117 0.001 –0.000
(0.050) (0.053) (0.097) (0.093) (0.001) (0.001)
Number of siblings –0.700 –0.717 2.539* 2.133 –0.009 0.000
(0.539) (0.545) (1.362) (1.489) (0.014) (0.011)
Birth order 0.590 0.588 0.717 0.610 –0.018 –0.017
(0.817) (0.853) (2.116) (2.085) (0.038) (0.038)
Sichuan 0.118 –3.295* 0.004
(0.829) (1.965) (0.005)
Shaanxi 0.142 1.616 –0.068
(0.861) (2.735) (0.049)
Jilin –0.069 –1.494 0.005
(1.455) (2.349) (0.007)
Hebei –0.018 –0.660 0.009
(1.055) (2.295) (0.014)
Constant 8.416*** 10.178*** 10.082*** 2.484 –3.890 –4.979 0.970*** 1.009*** 1.065***
(1.462) (2.802) (2.994) (2.913) (5.240) (5.284) (0.045) (0.026) (0.060)
Observations 105 105 105 105 105 105 105 105 105
R-squared 0.048 0.123 0.124 0.004 0.063 0.101 0.000 0.015 0.064
***
Robust standard errors in parentheses. , P<0.01; **, P<0.05; *, P<0.1.

Notably, the regressions did not demonstrate that 1 CNY, the schooling investment in 2007 and 2004 increased
the current average hourly earnings of a parent was a by 2.4 and 6.3%, respectively (P<0.1, P<0.05) (row 1,
determinant of their children’s human capital. However, columns 2 and 3).
according to the literature, the current earnings were
significantly affected by previous earnings (Durlauf 1996; 4.3. Case studies on ITP
Heckman and Vytlacil 1998; Geweke and Keane 2000;
Islam 2013). Thus, the children in families with current We exploited three cases to further analyze three types
high-earning parents will logically have high human capital. of ITP and their mechanisms. These three cases were
drawn from those who had just started primary school in
4.2. Parents’ earnings and their investment in the 2005 and participated in off-farm employment since 2018,
human capital of their children which supported us to clearly state the mechanism of
intergenerational transmission of earnings from the human
We further described the relationship between the earnings capital perspective. The three cases described the role of
of parents and the schooling investment in their children investment in human capital in escaping from ITP, being
before the children participated in the labor market to find caught in the ITP, and persisting intergenerational earnings.
their logical relationship. To achieve this objective, we All of these cases demonstrated the importance of
used the sample for which we have documented parents’ investment in children’s education and skill training
expenditure on schooling in each survey. Schooling before their participating in labor market. If the children
investment includes fees for tuition, incidentals, books, were invested in education or skill training more before
and courses and others, such as tutorial fees for courses. participating in labor market by their parents, they were
The results showed that parents’ hourly earnings had more likely to earn higher than their parents and had better
a positive significant correlation with the expenditure on social welfare, such as pension, medical insurance, and
schooling in each survey year; however, the sample was promotion opportunities. If the children were invested less
very small in each survey (Table  4). Specifically, the in education or skill training in their school period, they
schooling investment in 2015 increased by 1.9% if the hourly usually faced more challenges in obtaining a steady job
earnings of parents increased by 1 CNY (P<0.1) (row 1, in the formal sector and earning higher wages than their
column 1). If the hourly earnings of parents increased by parents. With the economic development and increasingly
1088 BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091

Table 4 Effect of parents’ earnings on the schooling investment in children


Log(Schooling investment in Log(Schooling investment in Log(Schooling investment in
Variable 2015) 2007) 2004)
(1) (2) (3)
Hourly earnings of parents 0.019* 0.024* 0.063**
(0.011) (0.013) (0.028)
Grade in the survey year 0.126*** 0.269*** 0.058
(0.035) (0.040) (0.071)
Sichuan –0.095 –0.829** 0.396
(0.305) (0.317) (0.448)
Shaanxi 0.017 –0.711** –0.214
(0.242) (0.317) (0.549)
Jilin 0.497*** –0.699
(0.172) (0.551)
Hebei –0.561* 0.264 –0.135
(0.318) (0.485) (0.285)
Constant 7.300*** 5.468*** 5.268***
(0.500) (0.437) (0.901)
Observations 34 60 16
R-squared 0.410 0.483 0.650
***
Robust standard errors in parentheses. , P<0.01; **, P<0.05; *, P<0.1.

competitive labor market, only the offspring was invested of parents and their children.
more than their parents, they might escape from or persist in Along with the intergenerational transmission of earnings,
the intergenerational transmission of earnings. The detailed human capital played a vital role in increasing the earnings
case stories are shown in Appendix A. of children. The regressions demonstrated that parents’
In Section 4, we combed for the paths of ITP by identifying earnings were positively and significantly correlated with the
the relationship of parents’ earnings and their children’s years of formal schooling and the duration of skills training of
final human capital before participating labor market their children. The results indicated that the high earnings
and estimating the impact of parents’ earnings on their would be intergenerationally transmitted by improving the
investment in children’s schooling when the children being children’s human capital, which helped break the ITP.
in school. This analysis went through the whole chain from Using the small sample with the information on the
children’s schooling to their labor participation. Using the schooling investment in the surveys, we performed
quantitative and qualitative methods, we proved the cycle quantitative analysis and found that parents’ earnings had
of parents’ income–human investment–offspring’s income a positive significant correlation with the expenditure on
using a uniform sample. The results implied that it was very schooling of the children. This finding implied that parents
difficult to escape from ITP for the children of poor families. with high earnings were more likely to invest their children’s
The visionary parents and enough money are the necessary human capital, which further improved the earnings of
rather than sufficient conditions. Although there is a formal their children. We explored three cases in our sample
financial aid system of education for poor families in rural by combining school history and current employment
China, the funding intensity and parents’ cognition of utilizing performance. The cases showed that investing in children’s
the funding to support children’s schooling, especially before human capital could accelerate their capacity to obtain a
entering college, are both the important factors affecting the high income and promotions.
final human capital outcomes. Compared with that in urban areas, the intergenerational
transmission of earnings in rural China was much lower,
5. Conclusion which indicated that the income mobility in rural areas was
higher. It implied that it was a breakthrough in focusing on
This paper used five waves of panel data with 2 000 intergenerational transmission of earnings in solving relative
households spanning more than 15 years to analyze poverty in China after 2020. It also showed that increasing
the intergenerational transmission of earnings. Using rural household income by investing education would gain
quantitative and qualitative methods, we found an obvious greater social benefits in rural areas since it promoted the
intergenerational transmission of earnings in rural China, upward mobility easier than that in urban China.
especially for the intergenerational transmission between In South Asia, Africa and developing countries in other
the earnings of father and children and average earnings parts of the world, parental background - especially
BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091 1089

income- matters the most for the prospects of the offspring. and schooling attainment and children’s human capital in
The findings of this study on China may help understand the Ethiopia, India, Peru, and Vietnam. Economic Development
ITP of other developing countries. Even though the next and Cultural Change, 65, 657–697.
generation’s economic status will depend on more factors Bird K, Higgins K. 2011. Stopping the intergenerational
transmission of poverty: Research highlights and policy
than education, such as the efficiency and fairness of factor
recommendations. Chronic Poverty Research Centre.
markets, education is likely to continue to play a key role
Black S E, Devereux P J. 2011. Recent developments in
in economic mobility across generations. Some measures
intergenerational mobility. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D, eds.,
implemented in China, like compulsory education law and Handbook of Labor Economics. North Holland Press,
the financial aid system of education for poor families, Elsevier, Amsterdam. pp. 1487–1542.
may be extended to other developing countries and may Blanden J, Gibbons S. 2006. The Persistence of Poverty Across
effectively help them break the ITP. Generations: A View from Two British Cohorts. The Policy
This was the first study to identify the ITP in rural China Press, Bristol.
from the perspective of analyzing the intergenerational Breen R, Jonsson J O. 2005. Inequality of opportunity in
transmission of off-farm earnings and found its mechanism comparative perspective: Recent research on educational
by using a mixed method based on long-term tracking attainment and social mobility. Annual Review of Sociology,
31, 223–243.
data. However, we did not identify the causal effect by
Cardak B A, Johnston D W, Martin V L. 2013. Intergenerational
using another method, such as FFE or IV, because of the
earnings mobility: A new decomposition of investment and
limited sample. Additionally, the multiple effects of human
endowment effects. Labour Economics, 24, 39–47.
capital investment on the children and their heterogeneous,
Chadwick L, Solon G. 2002. Intergenerational income mobility
such as on employment quality, family welfare, vocational among daughters. American Economic Review, 92,
promotion, and so forth, require further exploration. If the 335–344.
data are available, further research will produce valuable Chetty R, Hendren N, Kline P, Saez E, Turner N. 2014. Is the
information for literature. United States still a land of opportunity? Recent trends in
intergenerational mobility. American Economic Review,
Acknowledgements 104, 141–147.
Cooper E. 2010. Inheritance and the intergenerational
We acknowledge the financial supported by the National transmission of poverty in Sub-Saharan Africa: Policy
considerations. Working Paper, No. 159. Chronic Poverty
Natural Science Foundation of China (71903185 and
Research Centre.
71661147001), the Strategic Priority Research Program of
Dearden L, Machin S, Reed H. 1997. Intergenerational mobility
Chinese Academy of Sciences (XDA20010303), and the
in Britain. The Economic Journal, 107, 47–66.
National Social Science Fund of China (18ZDA005). We Deng Q H, Gustafsson B A, Li S. 2013. Intergenerational income
thank the Ph D students and research assistants of UNEP- persistence in urban China. Review of Income and Wealth,
International Ecosystem Management Partnership (UNEP- 59, 416–436.
IEMP) for collecting data. We appreciate the time and effort Dong Y Q, Bai Y L, Wang W D, Luo R F, Liu C F, Zhang L
of numerous local officials, village leaders, and farmers in X. 2020. Does gender matter for the intergenerational
our sample areas for their assistance with our survey. transmission of education? Evidence from rural China.
International Journal of Educational Development, 77,
Declaration of competing interest 102220.
Dong Y Q, Luo R F, Zhang L X, Liu C F, Bai Y L. 2019.
Intergenerational transmission of education: The case of
The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.
rural China. China Economic Review, 53, 311–323.
Duarte R, Ferrando-Latorre S, Molina J A. 2018. How to escape
Appendix associated with this paper is available on http:// poverty through education?: Intergenerational evidence in
www.ChinaAgriSci.com/V2/En/appendix.htm Spain. Applied Economics Letters, 25, 624–627.
Durlauf S. 1996. A theory of persistent income inequality.
References Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 75–93.
Emran S M, Sun Y. 2011. Magical transition? Intergenerational
Atkinson A B, Maynard A K, Trinder C G. 1983. Parents educational and occupational mobility in rural China:
and Children: Incomes in Two Generations. Heinemann 1988–2002. Working Paper. [2019-11-30]. https://www.
Educational Books. Heinemann, London. researchgate.net/publication/228295719_Magical_
Behrman J R, Schott W, Mani S, Crookston B T, Dearden K, Transition_Intergenerational_Educational_and_
Duc L T, Fernald L C H, Stein A D. 2017. Intergenerational Occupational_Mobility_in_Rural_China_1988-2002
transmission of poverty and inequality: Parental resources Fan Y. 2016. Intergenerational income persistence and
1090 BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091

transmission mechanism: Evidence from urban China. mobility in Japan among sons and daughters: Levels and
China Economic Review, 41, 299–314. trends. Journal of Population Economics, 27, 91–134.
Freedman L P. 2005. Achieving the MDGs: Health systems as Leigh A. 2007. Intergenerational mobility in Australia. Journal
core social institutions. Development, 48, 19–24. of Economic Analysis & Policy, 7, 1–28.
Geweke J, Keane M. 2000. An empirical analysis of earnings Li Q, de Brauw A, Rozelle S, Zhang L X. 2005. Labor market
dynamics among men in the PSID: 1968–1989. Journal of emergence and returns to education in rural China. Review
Econometrics, 96, 293–356. of Agricultural Economics, 27, 418–424.
Glewwe P, Jocoby H, King E M. 1999. Early childhood nutrition Li Q, Huang J K, Luo R F, Liu C F. 2013. China’s labor transition
and academic achievement: A longitudinal analysis. Journal and the future of China’s rural wages and employment.
of Public Economics, 81, 345–368. China & World Economy, 21, 4–24.
Gong C, Leigh A, Meng X. 2012. Intergenerational income Liu C F, Li Y, Li S P, Luo R F, Zhang L X, Haigist S, Hou J.
mobility in urban China. Review of Income and Wealth, 2019. The returns to education in rural China: Some new
58, 481–503. estimates. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource
Grant U. 2005. Health and poverty linkages: Perspectives Economics, 59, 1–20.
of the chronically poor. Department for International Luo R F, Liu C F, Gao J J, Wang T Y, Zhi H Y, Shi P F, Huang
Development Health Systems Resource Centre, London. J K. 2020. Impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic on rural
[2019-11-30]. https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/ poverty and policy responses in China. Journal of Integrative
media/57a08c97e5274a27b20012d1/other-grant-health.pdf Agriculture, 19, 2946–2964.
Harper C, Marcus R, Moore K. 2003. Enduring poverty and the Mackintosh M. 2001. Do health systems contribute to
conditions of childhood: Life-course and intergenerational inequalities? In: Leon D, Walt G, eds., Poverty, Inequality
poverty transmissions. World Development, 31, 535–554. and Health. Oxford University Press, Oxford. pp. 175–193.
Heckman J J, Humphries J E, Veramendi G, Urzua S. 2014. Mayer-Foulkes D. 2003. Market Failures in Health
Education, health and wages. Institute for the Study of and Education. Centro de Investigation Docencia
Labor, Bonn. [2019-10-26]. https://www.nber.org/system/ Economicas, Lomas de Santa Fé, Mexico. [2019-
files/working_papers/w19971/w19971.pdf 10-26]. http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/
Heckman J J, Vytlacil E. 1998. Instrumental variables methods download?doi=10.1.1.201.1325&rep=rep1&type=pdf
for the correlated random coefficient model. The Journal of Mazumder B. 2005. Fortunate sons: New estimates of
Human Resources, 33, 974–987. intergenerational mobility in the United States using social
Hertz T N. 2001. Education, inequality and economic mobility security earnings data. The Review of Economics and
in South Africa. University of Massachusetts. [2019-11-30]. Statistics, 87, 235–255.
https://scholarworks.umass.edu/dissertations/AAI3027205 Narayan A, Van der Weide R, Cojocaru A, Lakner C, Redaelli
Holmlund H, Lindahl M, Plug E. 2011. The causal effect of S, Mahler D G, Ramasubbaiah R G N, Thewissen S. 2018.
parents’ schooling on children’s schooling: A comparison Fair progress?: Economic mobility across generations
of estimation methods. Journal of Economic Literature, around the world. Equity and Development. World Bank.
49, 615–651. Washington, D.C. [2019-11-30]. https://openknowledge.
Huang J K, Rozelle S. 1996. Technological change: worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/28428/211210ov.
Rediscovering of the engine of productivity growth in China’s pdf?sequence=9
rural economy. Journal of Development Economics, 49, NBSC (National Bureau of Statistics of China). 2019.
337–369. China Statistical Yearbook. China Statistics Press,
Islam T M T. 2013. Childhood neighborhood conditions and the Beijing. (in Chinese)
persistence of adult income. Regional Science and Urban Nicoletti C, Ermisch J F. 2008. Intergenerational earnings
Economics, 43, 684–693. mobility: Changes across cohorts in Britain. Journal of
Kabeer N, Mahmud S. 2009. Imagining the future: Children, Economic Analysis & Policy, 7, 1–38.
education and intergenerational transmission of poverty in Osterbacka E. 2001. Family background and economic status in
urban Bangladesh. IDS Bulletin, 40, 10–21. Finland. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103, 467–484.
Kambourov G, Manovskii I. 2009. Occupational mobility and Pascual M. 2009. Intergenerational income mobility: The
wage inequality. Review of Economic Studies, 76, 731–759. transmission of socio-economic status in Spain. Journal of
Kamga B F, Kamga A K, Audibert M. 2013. Health and labour Policy Modeling, 31, 835–846.
income of wage earners and self-employed workers in Pronzato C. 2012. An examination of paternal and maternal
Cameroon. Working Paper. [2019-11-30]. http://ftp.iza. intergenerational transmission of schooling. Journal of
org/dp7324.pdf Population Economics, 252, 591–608.
Lee C, Solon G. 2006. Trends in intergenerational income Qin X Z, Wang T Y, Zhuang C. 2016. Intergenerational transfer
mobility. National Bureau of Economic Research. of human capital and its impact on income mobility: Evidence
Cambridge, MA. [2019-11-30]. https://www.nber.org/ from China. China Economic Review, 38, 306–321.
system/files/working_papers/w12007/w12007.pdf Quisumbing A R. 2008. Intergenerational transfers and the
Lefranc A, Ojima F, Yoshida T. 2014. Intergenerational earnings intergenerational transmission of poverty in Bangladesh:
BAI Yun-li et al. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2021, 20(4): 1080–1091 1091

Preliminary results from a longitudinal study of rural Wang W D, Dong Y Q, Luo R F, Bai Y L, Zhang L X. 2019.
households. Chronic Poverty Research Centre, London. Changes in returns to education for off-farm wage
[2019-10-26]. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1538923 employment: Evidence from rural China. China Agricultural
Rodgers J R. 1995. An empirical study of intergenerational Economic Review, 11, 2–19.
transmission of poverty in the United States. Social Science Wang X B, Han L H, Huang, J K, Zhang L X, Rozelle S. 2016.
Quarterly, 76, 178–194. Gender and off-farm employment: Evidence from rural
Room G. 2011. Social mobility and complexity theory: Towards China. China & World Economy, 24, 18–36.
a critique of the sociological mainstream. Policy Studies, Warzywoda-Kruszyńska W. 2013. Intergenerational
32, 109–126. transmission of poverty: A challenge for Poland. Baltic
Ruiz A C. 2016. The impact of education on intergenerational Region, 3, 59–66.
occupational mobility in Spain. Journal of Vocational Wong H L, Wang Y, Luo R F, Zhang L X, Rozelle S. 2017. Local
Behavior, 92, 94–104. governance and the quality of local infrastructure: Evidence
Solon G. 1992. Intergenerational income mobility in the United from village road projects in rural China. Journal of Public
States. American Economic Review, 82, 393–408. Economics, 152, 119–132.
Solon G. 1999. Intergenerational mobility in the labor market. World Bank. 2018. Poverty and shared prosperity 2018:
In: Orley C A, Card D, eds., Handbook of Labor Economics. Piecing together poverty puzzle. [2019-11-12]. https://
North-Holland, Amsterdam. pp. 1761–1800. www.worldbank.org/en/publication/poverty-and-shared-
Solon G. 2002. Cross-country differences in intergenerational prosperity
earnings mobility. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16, Wu X Y, Qi X H, Yang S, Ye C, Sun B. 2019. Research on the
59–66. intergenerational transmission of poverty in rural China
State Council. 2015. Firmly prevent the intergenerational based on sustainable livelihood analysis framework: A
transmission of poverty. [2019-12-16]. http://www.gov.cn/ case study of six poverty-stricken counties. Sustainability,
zhengce/2015-04/06/content_2843178.htm 11, 2341.
United Nations. 2015. Sustainable development goals: 17 goals Yankow J J. 2006. Why do cities pay more? An empirical
to transform our world. [2019-11-12]. http://www.un.org/ examination of some competing theories of the urban wage
sustainabledevelopment/zh/ premium. Journal of Urban Economics, 60, 139–161.
United Nations. 2020. Goal 1: End poverty in all its Zhang H Q, Zhang L X, Luo R F, Li Q. 2008. Does education
forms everywhere. [2020-01-12]. https://www.un.org/ still pay off in rural China: Revisit the impact of education on
sustainabledevelopment/poverty/ off-farm employment and wages. China & World Economy,
de Vuijst E, van Ham M, Kleinhans R. 2017. The moderating 16, 50–65.
effect of higher education on the intergenerational Zhou M, Luo T T, Zhao X L, Tan X T. 2018. The effect of city
transmission of residing in poverty neighbourhoods. scale on the migrant workers’ wage premium from the
Environment & Planning (A), 49, 2135–2154. perspective of education and job matching. Journal of
Wang H J, Zhao Q R, Bai Y L, Zhang L X, Yu X H. 2020. Poverty Agrotechnical Economics, 8, 35–43. (in Chinese)
and subjective poverty in rural China. Social Indicators Zhuo N, Ye C H, Ji C. 2020. Human capital matters:
Research, 150, 219–242. Intergenerational occupational mobility in rural China,
Wang W D, Bai Y L, Luo R F, Zhang L X. 2020. Do entrepreneurial Working Paper. CAER-IFPRI Annual Conference in 2018,
parents always have entrepreneurial children in rural China. Guangzhou, China.
China Rural Survey, 2, 47–67. (in Chinese)

Executive Editor-in-Chief HUANG Ji-kun


Managing Editor WENG Ling-yun

You might also like