You are on page 1of 5

Evil Is the Root of All Money

By NOBUHIRO KIYOTAKI AND JOHN MOORE*

A traditional view of money is that it lubri- pledge all of their future income. For moral-
cates trade when there is no double coincidence hazard reasons, there may be an upper bound,
of wants. The classic example, due to Knut u1 , say, on the fraction of future income that a
Wicksell (1934), has three types of agents, and debtor D can credibly commit to repay.
three physically distinct commodities. Type I We also place emphasis on limits to the re-
wants a commodity supplied by type II, type II salability, or negotiability, of paper. In the ex
wants a commodity supplied by type III, and ante market, D is free to issue his paper to any
type III wants a commodity supplied by type I. of many potential creditors, promising to make
Thus, no pair of agents wants each other’s com- a future delivery (up to D’s commitment limit).
modity. In the absence of a well-functioning But between the date of issue and the date of
market, money allows the agents to trade bilat- delivery, an initial creditor C may not be able to
erally: an agent accepts money not for its own resell D’s paper on to a third party, C9, at least
sake, but because he can exchange it for what he not quickly, at a fair price. For example, after
wants. One of the three commodities could the date of issue, C may have privately learned
serve as money; or an outside object, such as something about D, and adverse selection
Ž at money, might be used. causes the market for “second-hand” paper to
To justify why the agents cannot simply trade break down. Alternatively, it may take time for
their commodities through a market, there must a new creditor C9 to verify the authenticity of
be some physical trading friction. Search or the paper; or the outsider C9 may be less able
matching frictions are often invoked, but unfor- than the insider C to enforce D’s promise, in-
tunately noncompetitive models of this kind, sofar as D gets locked in with C ex post. What-
though ingenious and elegant, are difŽ cult to ever the reason (asymmetric information, delay
incorporate into a standard macroeconomic in veriŽ cation, or special leverage), the conclu-
framework. Moreover, to us, it is not clear that sion is broadly the same: after D’s paper has
physical trading frictions are indispensable to been initially issued, it may not be fully liquid.
monetary theory. At one extreme, where the paper cannot be
resold, D in effect makes only a bilateral com-
I. Two u ’s: Borrowing and mitment, to deliver to the agent who buys his
Resalability Constraints paper at the date of issue. At the other extreme,
where the paper is perfectly resalable, D makes
Our approach to modeling money places lim- a multilateral commitment, to deliver to any
ited commitment center stage, rather than phys- bearer of his paper, and the paper can circulate.
ical trading frictions. We assume a perfectly Let u2 be an indicator of resalability: u2 equal to
competitive environment where agents freely 0 corresponds to paper that cannot readily be
meet and trade in a marketplace, but debtors resold; u2 equal to 1 corresponds to paper that
who issue IOUs (paper) cannot necessarily can. The mnemonic is that the subscript 1 on u1
corresponds to the initial sale of paper, and the
subscript 2 on u2 corresponds to a subsequent
* Kiyotaki: Department of Economics, London School resale.
of Economics, Houghton Street, London, WC2A 2AE, The two constraints need to be thought about
United Kingdom; Moore: Departments of Economics, Uni- separately. The Ž rst constraint, the borrowing
versity of Edinburgh, 50 George Square, Edinburgh constraint, has received attention in the macro-
EH8 9JY, United Kingdom, and London School of Eco-
nomics. We thank Edward Green, Martin Hellwig, Bengt economics literature. A number of moral-hazard
Holmstrom, Narayana Kocherlakota, Robert Townsend, and stories have been invoked to rationalize why
Neil Wallace for very helpful discussions. people face borrowing constraints. The second

62
VOL. 92 NO. 2 FRAMEWORKS FOR MONETARY ECONOMICS 63

constraint, the resalability constraint, has re- eryone’s u1 equals 1, the values of u2 are
ceived much less attention in the formal litera- irrelevant.
ture, but we think is just as important.1 This is no longer true if there is less than full
bilateral commitment. To illustrate what might
II. A Three-Date Example happen, let us make the stark and asymmetric
assumption that, although each type-I agent can
We see the lack of double coincidence of make a full bilateral commitment to deliver at
wants as an essential part of any theory of date 3, type-III agents default on any promise to
money, but not necessarily over physically dis- deliver at date 2. In other words, u1 equals 1 for
tinct commodities. Rather, the emphasis can be type-I agents but equals 0 for type-III agents.
on dated goods. Consider an intertemporal ver- Now the question of resalability matters.
sion of Wicksell’s triangle, with three dates, 1, Suppose type-I agents can make only bilateral
2 and 3, and a single, non-storable good at each commitments. That is, suppose their paper can-
date. There are three types of agents (I, II and not be resold: their u2 equals 0. Then the econ-
III) with an equally large number of each type. omy collapses to autarky, because type-III
An agent of type I wants to consume goods at agents have nothing to offer at date 1, and type-I
date 1 but is endowed with date-3 goods. An agents cannot sell their paper to type-II agents
agent of type II wants to consume goods at date who do not want date-3 goods. We assume that
2 but is endowed with date-1 goods. An agent of everyone gets a small beneŽ t from consuming
type III wants to consume goods at date 3 but is their endowment; there are no gifts.3
endowed with date-2 goods. The situation is rescued, though, if type-I
Now, to overcome the lack of double coinci- agents can make multilateral commitments, so
dence of wants, it is enough to suppose that that their paper can be resold: their u2 equals 1.
each type-I agent can make a full bilateral com- Markets open at dates 1 and 2. Initially, at date
mitment to deliver date-3 goods to someone 1, type-II agents use their endowments of goods
who buys his paper at date 1, and that each to buy type-I agents’ paper promising to deliver
type-III agent can make a similar commitment (to the bearer) date-3 goods. Then, at date 2,
to deliver date-2 goods (i.e., it is enough to type-II agents resell this paper to type-III
suppose that u1 equals 1 for each agent of types
I and III). In the date-1 market, everyone trades
their endowment for what they want, and the though, there is no need to examine the trading mechanism
Ž rst-best is achieved. After date 1, there is no in this much detail.
need for markets to reopen, because there are no 3
We also assume that, although a type-I agent can make
further gains from trade. In particular, the type- a (bilateral) commitment to deliver his own date-3 endow-
ment, he cannot commit to deliver anyone else’s endow-
III agents who purchase type-I agents’ paper at
ment, in particular, a type-III agent’s date-2 endowment. If
date 1 hold on to it until it matures at date 3. It he were able to make such a commitment, the Ž rst-best
does not matter whether this paper is resalable could be achieved by means of the following trades. At date
at date 2, since there is no need for it to be 1, type-II agents trade their endowments for promises by
resold. type-I agents to deliver at date 2. At date 2, type-III agents
trade their endowments for promises by type-I agents to
In short, if there are no borrowing constraints deliver at date 3; and then type-I agents use these goods to
then an Arrow-Debreu market that opens only at redeem their promises to type-II agents. Finally, at date 3,
date 1, achieves a Ž rst-best allocation.2 If ev- type-I agents use their endowments to redeem their prom-
ises to type-III agents. In effect, the type-I agents are acting
as middlemen: all trades are conducted through them. To
rationalize why a type-I agent can commit to deliver his
1
Our approach is related to the long tradition of model- own goods but not anyone else’s, consider an economy in
ing money and liquidity in economies with transactions which “endowments” are in fact returns on physical assets,
costs (see Joseph Ostroy and Ross Starr, 1990). and the agent can commit to deliver (at least part of) the
2
The date-1 market need not be centralized through an return on his own assets by offering the assets as security: if
auctioneer. Instead agents can make bilateral deals: type-II he defaults, his creditors can seize them. However, he
agents use their endowment to buy paper from type-III cannot offer other people’s assets as security. This is the
agents, who in turn use these goods to buy paper from type-I basis for the stationary production economy we discuss in
agents. In the absence of any physical trading frictions, Section III.
64 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2002

agents, in exchange for goods. Finally, at date 3, we think that it is a fruitful starting point for a
the paper is redeemed: type-III agents collect theory of money. Hence the title of this paper:
goods from type-I agents. Everyone ends up “Evil Is the Root of All Money.” Evil is a strong
with what he wants, and the Ž rst-best is word. If the moral category is thought too se-
achieved. vere for something as mild as breaking a prom-
The type-II agents do not buy the type-I ise, then the title might be changed to “Distrust
agents’ paper at date 1 because they intend to Is the Root of All Money” (see Douglas Gale,
keep it until maturity at date 3: they do not want 1982 [chapters 6 and 7]).
to consume date-3 goods. Rather, they buy it
because they expect to resell it at date 2. The III. A Stationary Model
paper acts as inside money: privately issued
securities used as a medium of intertemporal From the above three-date, deterministic ex-
exchange. It provides liquidity, the means of ample we learn that a theory of money (inside
short-term saving: by type-II agents between money) need not depend on an inŽ nite horizon,
dates 1 and 2, and by type-III agents between or on the presence of uncertainty.
dates 2 and 3. That said, the three-date example has serious
Notice that, thanks to the resalability of the limitations. To address quantitative macroeco-
type-I agents’ paper, the fact that type-III agents nomic issues, a model with a longer time hori-
cannot be trusted is not a problem, because at zon is required: macroeconomic data do not
date 2 they pay for their purchases of paper naturally correspond to a model with an initial
using their endowments of goods, in a spot or a terminal date. In addition to having more
transaction. symmetry across periods, it would be natural to
This illustrates a very general idea. The have more symmetry across agents. As the ex-
power of one agent to make a multilateral com- ample stands, there is no justiŽ cation for why
mitment can substitute for a lack of trust in type-I agents can commit but type-III agents
other agents. We believe that this is the key to cannot. Finally, if we want to allow for the
explaining why the circulation of inside money possibility that Ž at money circulates along with
can be essential to the smooth running of an inside money, then we need an inŽ nite horizon,
economy.4 to sustain beliefs.
The question of trust arises so sharply in this In Kiyotaki and Moore (2000, 2001) we con-
example because we have switched from phys- struct a stationary model based on a symmetric
ically distinct commodities to dated goods— variant of the three-date example. The model is
from the type dimension to the time dimension. of a production economy, rather than exchange;
In Arrow-Debreu, these two dimensions are but there is still no uncertainty. InŽ nitely-lived
treated on a par: trust is ignored. Implicitly, it is agents undertake a sequence of projects. A
assumed either that all economic agents are project fully employs an agent for three periods,
entirely trustworthy or that the auctioneer has from the initial investment through to Ž nal com-
adequate power to enforce all promises. pletion; no one can operate overlapping pro-
We think that factoring in a lack of trust, jects. In a symmetric equilibrium, start times are
placing a limitation on the degree of commit- evenly distributed, so that in effect there are
ment, is of primary importance. In particular, three populations indexed by whether an agent
invests at dates 1, 4, 7, ... , or dates 2, 5, 8, ... ,
or dates 3, 6, 9, ... . An agent starting a new
4 project at date t can borrow against a fraction u1
A number of papers model the circulation of private
securities in environments with physical trading frictions, of the date t 1 2 output. Someone buying such
such as spatial separation or matching frictions. For models paper can resell a fraction u2 at date t 1 1.
of inside money with spatial separation, see, for example, Aside from u1 and u2 , the model is entirely
Robert Townsend and Neil Wallace (1987), Scott Freeman standard: investment costs are convex in the
(1996), and Costas Azariadis et al. (2000). For matching
models of inside money, see, for example, Ricardo Caval-
scale of the project; everyone gets a concave
canti et al. (1999), Cavalcanti and Wallace (1999), and utility from daily consumption, and discounts
Stephen Williamson (1999). the future; markets are competitive. Here, u1
VOL. 92 NO. 2 FRAMEWORKS FOR MONETARY ECONOMICS 65

corresponds to the borrowing constraint of an will eventually drive out non-interest-bearing


agent starting a new project; it measures the Ž at money.
degree of bilateral commitment he can make to There are countervailing forces, however,
an initial creditor. The fraction u2 corresponds which our model ignores. First, the demand for
to the resalability constraint facing the initial liquidity may be rising as fast as the supply.
creditor in the next period; it measures the debt- Second, Ž at money may be complementary to
or’s degree of multilateral commitment. inside money, rather than a substitute, given that
It is interesting to see how the two constraints inside money is almost always a promise to pay
feed into each other. On the one hand, remem- in cash. Third, cash will always be useful to
ber that in the three-date exchange example if people who want to conceal their nefarious ac-
there were no borrowing constraints, resalabil- tivities, like drug dealers, because it leaves no
ity would not matter. More generally, in our electronic trail. If, in due course, crime turns out
stationary production economy we Ž nd that, to be the only reason why people hold cash,
even though there may be less than full bilateral then evil will still be the root of all money, but
commitment, if there is enough, then multilat- for different reasons than the ones we have
eral commitment is not needed; the economy outlined above.
works well without inside money. SpeciŽ cally,
we show that if u1 is higher than some critical IV. Auctioneers, Planners, and Judges
value u*1 , itself strictly less than 1, then the
economy achieves the Ž rst-best. We have argued that money lubricates trade
On the other hand, we Ž nd that, if paper can when there is a lack of double coincidence of
circulate as money because there are no resal- wants, but not necessarily over physically dis-
ability constraints, then the economy works tinct commodities. The great advantage of
well even though people may not be able to switching to dated goods, and not having to
borrow very much (i.e., even though the supply model physical trading frictions, is that one can
of paper is not very great). The critical value u*1 , breathe the pure oxygen of perfect competition.
which is sensitive to u2 , is lower for higher The terms of trade for paper, both new and
values of u2. A little multilateral commitment second-hand, are determined in a marketplace.
goes a long way. One may want to posit an auctioneer whose
For u1 below u*1 , the economy is short of job is to Ž nd the market-clearing prices. Beyond
liquidity. Paper that can be resold, liquid paper, that, however, an auctioneer has no further role.
is issued at a higher price than paper that can- She cannot enforce agents’ long-term commit-
not; illiquid paper has to offer a higher return to ments. We assume that she herself cannot be
compensate for the inconvenience of having to trusted to make commitments, for otherwise she
hold it for two periods, until it matures. There is could usefully supply the economy with addi-
a liquidity premium. Other symptoms of a li- tional liquidity.5 More generally, no planner can
quidity shortage are that steady-state output and be trusted, either to keep her own promise to
investment are lower than in a Ž rst-best al- deliver goods in the future or to punish other
location. Furthermore, consumption paths are people for breaking their promises. In our
jagged rather than smooth. world, planners can always be bribed not to
If the liquidity shortage is severe enough (u1 carry out a punishment.
and u2 low enough), then there is a role for Ž at
money to circulate alongside liquid paper. No-
tice that we are not imposing a special role for
Ž at money here (as, say, in a cash-in-advance 5
For example, she could assume the middleman role
model). Rather, there is an endogenous need for played by type-I agents in the sequence of trades given in
additional liquidity in the form of Ž at money. In footnote 3. Incidentally, in the standard Arrow-Debreu
terms of the model, our prediction is that, as framework, agents are assumed to commit fully, and the
auctioneer has no need to take a position in the market (e.g.,
technological developments, and changes to le- to supply paper). It is only when there is limited commit-
gal and Ž nancial structures, cause u1 and u2 to ment that a trustworthy auctioneer could usefully contribute
rise, the increase in the supply of inside money additional commitment power to the economy.
66 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2002

We also assume that there is no gain from Cavalcanti, Ricardo; Erosa, Andres and Tem-
keeping a record of individual histories, because zelides, Ted. “Private Money and Reserve
each agent can always start anew, with a fresh Management in a Random-Matching Model.”
identity. In other words, there is anonymity.6 Journal of Political Economy, October 1999,
This rules out collective arrangements in which, 107(5), pp. 929 – 45.
for example, people are disciplined not to re- Cavalcanti, Ricardo and Wallace, Neil. “A Model
nege on promises for fear of being subsequently of Private Bank-Note Issue.” Review of Eco-
shut out of the market by everyone else (as in nomic Dynamics, January 1999, 2(1), pp.
Timothy Kehoe and David Levine [1993]). 104 –36.
At Ž rst glance, anonymity seems at odds with Freeman, Scott. “The Payments System, Liquid-
the idea that agents can issue paper promising to ity, and Rediscounting.” American Economic
pay out in the future. However, in our stationary Review, December 1996, 86(5), pp. 1126–38.
model with production, promises are secured Gale, Douglas. Money in equilibrium. Cam-
against physical capital, not human capital. If an bridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press,
entrepreneur, who has previously issued paper, 1982.
were to abscond, he would have to leave behind Kehoe, Timothy and Levine, David. “Debt-
his productive assets; they cannot be stolen. The Constrained Asset Markets.” Review of
holders of his paper would then assume owner- Economic Studies, October 1993, 60(4), pp.
ship of those assets. Of course, the entrepre- 865–88.
neur’s speciŽ c human capital would be lost, Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro and Moore, John. “Inside
which explains why creditors are unable to get Money and Liquidity.” Mimeo, London
more than a fraction u1 of the returns, where u1 School of Economics, 2000; revised, Claren-
is strictly less than 1. don Lectures, University of Oxford, 2001.
This presupposes that there is a legal system Kocherlakota, Narayana. “Money is Memory.”
in place to verify the authenticity of a paper Journal of Economic Theory, August 1998,
claim. Judges are able and can be trusted to 81(2), pp. 232–51.
distinguish legitimate from forged paper. (How- Kocherlakota, Narayana and Wallace, Neil. “In-
ever, like an auctioneer or a planner, a judge complete Record-Keeping and Optimal Pay-
cannot be trusted to provide the economy with ment Arrangements.” Journal of Economic
additional liquidity or to punish someone who Theory, August 1998, 81(2), pp. 272–89.
breaks a promise.) Anyone buying second-hand Ostroy, Joseph and Starr, Ross. “The Transac-
paper also has to verify its authenticity, which tions Role of Money,” in Benjamin Friedman
slows down the speed of transaction. As we and Frank Hahn, eds., Handbook of monetary
have suggested, delay in veriŽ cation is one jus- economics, Vol. I. New York: North-Holland,
tiŽ cation for why u2 is strictly less than 1. 1990, pp. 3– 62.
Townsend, Robert and Wallace, Neil. “Circulat-
REFERENCES ing Private Debt: An Example with a Coor-
dination Problem,” in Edward Prescott and
Azariades, Costas; Bullard, James and Smith, Neil Wallace, eds., Contractual arrange-
Bruce. “Private and Public Circulating Liabil- ments for intertemporal trade. Minneapolis,
ities.” Mimeo, University of California–Los MN: University of Minnesota Press, 1987,
Angeles, 2000. pp. 105–20.
Wicksell, Knut. Lectures on political economy.
London: Routledge, 1934 [English transla-
tion of 1901 work].
6
On the importance of anonymity for monetary theory,
Williamson, Stephen. “Private Money.” Journal
see Narayana Kocherlakota (1998) and Kocherlakota and of Money, Credit, and Banking, August 1999,
Wallace (1998). 31(3), pp. 469–91.

You might also like