You are on page 1of 300

Handbooks of Sociology and Social Research

Andrea Maurer Editor

Handbook of
Economic
Sociology for
the 21 Century
st
New Theoretical Approaches,
Empirical Studies and Developments
Handbooks of Sociology and Social
Research

Series Editor
Richard Serpe
Department of Sociology, Kent University, Kent, OH, USA
The handbook series includes the latest and up-to-date overviews on topics
that are of key significance to contemporary sociological and related social
science research. Several of the volumes discuss important topics from an
interdisciplinary social science perspective, covering sociology, anthropol-
ogy, psychology, and psychiatry. This prestigious series includes works by
some of the top scholars in their fields. These seminal works seek to record
where the field has been, to identify its current location, and to plot its course
for the future.
John D. DeLamater initiated this series with the encouragement of Howard
Kaplan in the early 2000s, and since then, under his aegis and constant effort,
it has published some stellar volumes by the top academics in their
specializations. DeLamater continued to be the series editor on this prestigious
series until his death in December 2017.
If you are interested in submitting a proposal for this series, please contact
senior editor, Shinjini Chatterjee: shinjini.chatterjee@springer.com.

More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/6055


Andrea Maurer
Editor

Handbook of Economic
Sociology for the
21st Century
New Theoretical Approaches,
Empirical Studies and Developments
Editor
Andrea Maurer
FB IV - Soziologie
Universitat Trier
Trier, Rheinland-Pfalz, Germany

ISSN 1389-6903 ISSN 2542-839X (electronic)


Handbooks of Sociology and Social Research
ISBN 978-3-030-61618-2 ISBN 978-3-030-61619-9 (eBook)
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9

# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021


This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or
part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of
illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way,
and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or
by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this
publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are
exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
The publisher, the authors, and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in
this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor
the authors or the editors give a warranty, expressed or implied, with respect to the material
contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains
neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This Springer imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature Switzerland AG.
The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland
Where We Came from, Where We Are, and
Where We Expect to Go: New Challenges
and Developments in Economic Sociology
Today

Society and economy are facing tremendous challenges these days. In the last
few decades, globalization has reached a new dimension; digitalization has
brought about new action patterns and organizational forms; crises have
changed how we look at the economy; and social inequalities have increased
greatly. We have observed variations in capitalism, a decline of centrally
planned economies, and a rise of markets accompanied by alternative forms
of coordination. Only recently have we recognized that China as well as parts
of Latin America have combined markets, state, and social ties in a new way
to reorganize economy. In modern Western economies, we see the challenge
of reaching sustainability while increasing economic output. A final challenge
comes from economic and societal crises. The most far-reaching economic
crises shook modern economic institutions, confidence in global markets, and
social structure in 2007–2008 and 2020. All in all, much has happened since
the turn of the century.
Economic sociology is facing a tremendous change, too. After it was
developed in the 1970s, successfully centered around the idea that social
factors matter for economic structure and outcome, more sociologists have
entered the research field coming from different backgrounds and asking
different questions. While the well-known program of new economic sociol-
ogy has been established as a branch of US sociology since the 1970s, the new
lines refer to recent and classic approaches of European thinking and sociol-
ogy. The founders of new economic sociology, Ronald Burt, James Coleman,
Mark Granovetter, Richard Swedberg, and Harrison White, have studied
social factors that support modern market exchange and entrepreneurship in
order to overcome the shortcomings of standard economic and sociological
theory. The newer approaches that have entered the field during the last two
decades take new perspectives and emphasize the various interrelationships
between economy and society. Some new lines adopt and widen the concept
of “social embeddedness.” Some of them bring in cultural factors and analyze
beliefs, values, conventions, or practices and how they shape economic
thinking and actions, while other newcomers focus on societal aspects, socio-
economic processes, and even economic forms such as market capitalism.
Whereas the mainstream of new economic sociology studies social relations
in modern markets, most of the newcomers take a more societal and critical
perspective such as socioeconomics and political economy, among others.

v
vi Where We Came from, Where We Are, and Where We Expect to Go: New Challenges. . .

At the beginning of the twenty-first century, economic sociologists are


reconsidering their origins, where they are now, and where they expect to go
in the future. The challenges described, along with these new developments,
demand a Handbook of Economic Sociology for the Twenty-First Century.
Not only have European sociological traditions been reinvented, but a young
international community of economic sociologists has emerged, giving rise to
new research topics, and questioning the initial perspectives. This handbook
aims to bring researchers together from different countries and traditions to
provide an overview of what is current cutting-edge research in the field of
economic sociology. It will also document which shoulders economic
sociologists stand on—to use the phrase once coined by Robert K. Merton.
The handbook also highlights what makes economic sociology special and an
attractive partner for other social scientists. It shows what we know about the
classical roots, draws a picture of what is going on in the field, and
demonstrates what questions might be of interest in the future.
The handbook is organized into two parts. Part I is concerned with theo-
retical approaches and developments, and Part II covers empirical studies and
topics that define special fields. The first part deals with foundational concepts
that redefined economic sociology at the end of the twentieth century and
looks at how reconsidering classical writings might work as a basis for future
work. Richard Swedberg, Gertraude Mikl-Horke, and Peter Marsden, three
well-known experts, demonstrate how the classical foundations still influence
economic sociology, and why they should be used in the future. Richard
Swedberg elaborates a guideline for using classics such as Alexis de
Tocqueville, Max Weber, or Karl Marx. Gertraude Mikl-Horke discusses
the different understandings of economic sociology in the writings of Max
Weber, Joseph A. Schumpeter, and Karl Polanyi, emphasizing a historical-
empirical orientation. Peter Marsden focuses on the work of James
S. Coleman and investigates the notion of social capital as a key tool for
economic sociologists. New lines of thought, which have been developed only
recently, are introduced in Part I as well. Andrea Maurer discusses how new
economic sociology could improve by collaborating with mechanism
approach for exploring how and why social factors shape economy. Pierre
François investigates the French tradition of institutionalism and how it
contributes to economic sociology by analyzing various institutions. Jens
Beckert and Timur Ergen explore how imaginations of the future influence
economic actions and processes, and thus, offer a new perspective. Jörg
Rössel, Patrick Schenk, and Sebastian Weingartner illustrate how the idea of
aestheticization influences markets and links societal processes to markets.
Uwe Schimank and Ute Volkmann emphasize how economic criteria have
spread out and how this process could be analyzed in the framework of
differentiation theory. All chapters provide deep sociological insights and
tools to analyze the modern economy and especially how society and econ-
omy are intertwined.
Part II illustrates that in the last few decades, much has happened in the
research field of economic sociology. Recent studies emphasize the social
constitution and structuration of particular markets, institutional settings and
innovation, alternative forms of organizing the economy, and how social
Where We Came from, Where We Are, and Where We Expect to Go: New Challenges. . . vii

movements and societal views influence the economy. In Part II, the first
subsection presents recent studies on the emergence and functioning of special
markets. This is done through empirical research on online markets by
Andreas Diekmann and Wojtek Przepiorka using experiments. Attention
markets are brought in by Philipp Bachmann and Gabriele Siegert studying
attention as a valuable resource in the digital age. Helge Mooshammer focuses
on informal markets using ethnographic methods and offering a lively picture
of informal markets in Bangkok, Moscow, Barcelona, and the former
Yugoslavia. Another strong line in economic sociology highlights social
and informal institutions and institutional change as a framework of economy.
This is shown in the second subsection in Part II. In her research, Sonja Opper
investigates the importance of private actors and local culture for institutional
change, mainly with reference to East Asia and Eastern Europe. Lucia Quaglia
outlines the gaps and weaknesses of the formal institutional governance
system in the EU—mainly the European Systemic Risk Board and the General
Council of the European Central Bank—when it comes to crises. Alberto
Veira Ramos and Tetiana Liubyva study attitudes of different social groups in
Ukraine toward socialism and markets to explain the slow pace of transfor-
mation after 1989. All chapters offer new insights on how social institutions
shape economic outcome and innovation.
In the third subsection in Part II, empirical results on alternative forms of
organizing production and consumption of goods and services are given.
Gilles Allaire analyzes the development of alternative food markets (AFD)
by describing them as a project of control defined by individual actors, social
movements, and NGOs. In his brand-new study on the interest-free digital
money introduced in Sardinia in 2010, Giacomo Bazzani gives evidence that
the social organization of digital money could be a way for communities to
overcome crises and for using their particular social capital. Isabell Stamm
describes groups as a form of social support for family firms and gives a new
interpretation of the notion of social embeddedness. In the fourth and final
subsection, Johannes Berger draws a picture of the history of modern capital-
ism, weighing its positive and negative sides. Sebastian Koos refers to the
challenge, in capitalist democracies, of reaching socially defined goals and of
improving social and corporate responsibility.
The collection of chapters demonstrates that economic sociology is a still
growing and highly inspiring research field. Moreover, the handbook shows
that researchers from all over the world are developing sociological
perspectives on essential economic issues. On the one hand, economic
sociologists aim at providing more realistic explanations, analyses, and empir-
ical studies of economic topics than standard economic theory. On the other
hand, they also claim to fill the gap left by modern sociologists who ignored
economic issues during the twentieth century and therefore missed one of the
most exciting topics in modern society. In this sense, both classical and new
developments in economic sociology contribute to a better understanding of
modern economy and of how to improve sociology.

University of Trier, Trier, Germany Andrea Maurer


Acknowledgments

Economic sociologists, as we all know, work in socially embedded and


institutionalized contexts. During the last few decades, a number of working
groups, partnerships, and national as well as international associations have
been established or reinvented. I want to thank all the colleagues who have
joined me in institutionalizing economic sociology in Germany, in Europe,
and in international associations. I am especially grateful to the ESA Research
Network “Economic Sociology” and the Section “Economic Sociology” of
the German Sociological Association (DGS).
I owe much to many fellow researchers, who have helped to make eco-
nomic sociology a lively research field and who supported my work on this
new handbook. I would also like to express my deepest appreciation to all the
authors who gave their ideas and contributed in many ways to make the
project enjoyable and successful. I would also like to express my appreciation
to Laura Lee, Susanna Nagel, Clemens Schmidt, and Lea Reinhardt for all the
detailed work on formatting, checking, correcting, and proofreading every
chapter. Their work, together with the well-established collaboration of
Springer VS and a new partnership with Springer Nature, has been the solid
ground for finalizing the project.
I want to dedicate the handbook to my beloved brother, Karl Maurer.

ix
Contents

Part I Theoretical Perspectives and Developments


1 The Classic Tradition in Economic Sociology . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Richard Swedberg
2 Austrian and German Classics as a Foundation? . . . . . . . . . . 19
Gertraude Mikl-Horke
3 James Coleman, Social Capital, and Economic Sociology . . . . 33
Peter V. Marsden
4 Social Factors in the Economy: New Economic Sociology
and the Mechanism Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
Andrea Maurer
5 A French Institutionalism in Economic Sociology? . . . . . . . . . 63
Pierre François
6 Transcending History’s Heavy Hand: The Future
in Economic Action . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
Jens Beckert and Timur Ergen
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
Jörg Rössel, Patrick Schenk, and Sebastian Weingartner
8 Economization: How Neo-Liberalism Took Over Society . . . . 113
Uwe Schimank and Ute Volkmann
Part II Empirical Studies and Research Topics
9 Trust and Reputation in Historical Markets
and Contemporary Online Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
Andreas Diekmann and Wojtek Przepiorka
10 How to Buy, Sell, and Trade Attention: A Sociology
of (Digital) Attention Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147
Philipp Bachmann and Gabriele Siegert

xi
xii Contents

11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle


of Informal Marketplaces . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159
Helge Mooshammer
12 Economic Change from an Institutional Perspective . . . . . . . 177
Sonja Opper
13 Financial Services Governance in the European
Union (EU) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 191
Lucia Quaglia
14 Attitudes Towards Free Market and Socialism in Ukraine:
Empirical Insights in the Context of Institutional
Transformation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 205
Alberto Veira-Ramos and Tetiana Liubyva
15 Alternative Food Networks and the Socialization of Food . . . 221
Gilles Allaire
16 Digital Money for Sustainable Communities: The Sardex
Case . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 237
Giacomo Bazzani
17 Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness of Entrepreneurial
Activity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 253
Isabell Stamm
Part III Societal Views on Economy
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic
System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 271
Johannes Berger
19 Social Responsibility in the Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 289
Sebastian Koos

Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 303
Part I
Theoretical Perspectives and Developments
The Classic Tradition in Economic
Sociology 1
Richard Swedberg

1 Introduction linked to other research and therefore cannot be


incorporated into the existing tradition. Who, for
Economic sociology is more than a century old, example, remembers today Erving Goffman’s
which means that it covers a huge amount of work in economic sociology (e.g., Goffman
material. Since the revival of economic sociology 1972, 1982)? Finally, and perhaps most impor-
in the mid-1980s, the literature in the field has tantly, some of the most valuable insights of
grown very quickly and become increasingly hard earlier researchers, which could be of great help
to survey for the individual researcher. What to today’s economic sociologists, have been
should one read and what can be disregarded? forgotten. This is the case with much of what
What is there to learn and what to ignore? These Weber says in his chapter on economic sociology
questions point to the problem of cumulation in in Economy and Society. It is also true, more
sociology (e.g., Gans 1992; Collins 1999; Abbott generally, for his interpretive sociology (Weber
2006). Here the general rule is (paraphrasing 1978).
Whitehead) that a science that hesitates to forget What should be kept and what can be forgotten
what is not worthwhile, is lost. The reason for this in a research tradition? This is obviously a key
is that unless a generally agreed upon tradition question for all sciences, and not easy to answer.
exists, which clearly states what is valuable, each One interesting answer, however, can be found in
individual researcher is faced with the task of C. Wright Mills’ idea of what he calls “the classic
making their way through a jungle of studies tradition” (see especially Mills 1960, 1–17). In
and deciding this on their own. this chapter, Mills’ notion will play a central part.
This has a number of negative consequences, While it is common among sociologists to refer to
which should be spelled out. First, it means that and praise the classics, Mills’ approach is differ-
the wheel will be periodically reinvented. How ent. First, by the term classic he means the general
many times have economic sociologists shown qualities of a work that make a study classic,
that the neo-classical economists’ ideas of profit regardless of whether these are found in contem-
maximization, rational choice, and in more gen- porary studies or in studies that are old enough to
eral terms, homo economicus are unrealistic? qualify as a classic in the conventional sense.
Another drawback is that new studies run the Secondly, he spells out what it is that makes a
risk of easily being forgotten, since they are not study classic; and on this point he has some
suggestive ideas.
As a concrete example of how Mills
R. Swedberg (*)
Cornell University, Ithaca, NY, USA envisioned the classic tradition in sociology, one
e-mail: rs328@cornell.edu can take his reader in sociology, Images of Man:
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 3
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_1
4 R. Swedberg

The Classic Tradition in Sociological Thinking manner. After a presentation of some of the peo-
(1960). As one would expect, it contains excerpts ple and works that are part of the classic tradition
from the works by sociologists such as Marx, in economic sociology, I will conclude by
Weber and Durkheim. However, it also contains outlining a few ways in which it is possible to
some writings by non-sociologists such as Walter work in the classic tradition and add to it.
Lippman, and by more recent sociologists such as
Karl Mannheim. In explaining what makes a
study a classic, Mills advances the following 2 The Classic Tradition
argument. In a classic you will find a model of
how something of consequence for society works, 2.1 Alexis de Tocqueville
which can inspire a number of different theories.
While the model itself cannot be tested, according Sociology became an academic discipline at the
to Mills, the individual theories can. Even if an end of the nineteenth century, but the sociological
individual theory turns out to be wrong, the origi- type of analysis, including economic sociology,
nal model will still stand; and it is this quality that goes further back. The early parts of the nine-
makes it a classic. teenth century are especially interesting thanks
Mills’ idea of what constitutes a sociological to the work of Tocqueville (1805–59) and Karl
classic is, to some extent, similar to what Robert Marx (1818–83). Both saw their analyses as a
K. Merton means by the Phoenix Phenomenon form of political economy and that the economy
(Merton 1984, 1091). According to Merton, there should be regarded as an organic part of society,
are a small number of sociological theses, which with links especially to the state. In brief, the split,
after being proven incorrect, reemerge like a which would later develop, between the way in
phoenix from the ashes. The best-known example which sociologists and economists view the econ-
of this is The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of omy did not yet exist. Tocqueville wrote two
Capitalism by Max Weber (1930). Unlike Mills, major works during his lifetime, one on the
Merton does not try to nail down the qualities that United States in the 1800s, Democracy in Amer-
make a classic into a classic. He is satisfied to ica (Tocqueville 2004), and one on the Revolu-
point out that sociologists should avoid the mis- tion of 1789 in France: The Old Regime and the
take of believing that every new piece of research Revolution (Tocqueville 1988). Both contain a
represents an improvement over what is already number of interesting analyses of the economy
known. Merton refers to this latter tendency as which, to repeat, was seen as an organic part of
“the fallacy of the latest word;” and it is clearly society (e.g., Swedberg 2009). Just as
part of Whig history or the tendency to look at the Tocqueville drew on several different sources
past exclusively from the perspective of what is for his analysis, including early forms of the
dominant today (Merton 1984, 1092). interview and the survey, he also viewed eco-
In the following pages I will try to be more nomic phenomena as the result of many different
precise than Mills and Merton in explaining why forces, such as work, greed, and emotions.
the works of Marx, Weber, and some others qual- Tocqueville’s work was undoubtedly
ify as contributions to the classic tradition in influenced by his vision of society as moving
economic sociology. I will argue that a classic from being controlled by an elite (aristocracy),
has something new to say on a number of differ- to the elite losing power to people in general
ent topics. It can transmit a strong vision in com- (democracy). This is also how he viewed the
bination with a research program; point to one or economy; there was a movement in the Western
several new economic phenomena; use a new world from a small aristocracy controlling most
type or a new source of data; introduce a new of the land, to common people owning increas-
method for collecting data or for analyzing these; ingly more of the land as well as other properties.
or transgress the boundaries of economic sociol- Tocqueville was also deeply concerned that the
ogy and neighboring sciences in a successful idea of equality, including economic equality,
1 The Classic Tradition in Economic Sociology 5

would become so strong in modern society that it better paid, in fact they were not. The reason was
would threaten the idea of freedom. something else: Americans enjoyed taking risks.
In his study of the French Revolution, They sailed even when the weather was bad,
Tocqueville provides a portrait of the tense always venturing ahead, in the hope of making
relations that existed in France between the social more money.
classes since the Middle Ages. He emphasized the The United States, in brief, had a profit-ori-
great impact that taxation has on the social struc- ented and entrepreneurial culture already in the
ture through the ways in which it is organized. In 1800s. Through his emphasis on the role that
this manner, he pioneered what would later be culture and emotions play in the economy,
called fiscal sociology. He also had many inter- Tocqueville made an important contribution to
esting things to say about the ways in which the economic sociology. His obsession with
confiscation of property, which took place during inspecting things for himself, and always using
the Revolution, affected the general morality of primary sources, even when secondary sources
the population, including the sense of honesty. were available, has also raised the bar for later
However, it is in his analysis of the generations of economic sociologists.
U.S. economy that Tocqueville made his most
important contribution to economic sociology.
He stressed that in the 1830s, when he visited 2.2 Karl Marx
the United States, the main culture of the country
(by which he meant the Northern states) was Like Tocqueville, Marx had a vision of how
already thoroughly commercial in nature. Here, economy and society are linked to one another;
as elsewhere in Democracy in America, neither can be understood without the other.
Tocqueville emphasized the entrepreneurial spirit While Tocqueville pointed to the movement
of the American population, which, in other from the elite to the common person, Marx saw
words, existed long before the country was the key to historical change in labor (cf. Lukács
industrialized. There were no peasants in the 1980; Marx 1990). In all societies one must work
United States, as there were in Europe, only for a living, according to Marx; this is an existen-
farmers. These farmers were not as deeply tial condition for individual beings. According to
attached to the land as peasants were attached in Capital, “labor . . . is a condition of human exis-
Europe. Americans took advantage of every tence which is independent of all forms of soci-
opportunity to sell goods. The same strong com- ety” (Marx 1990, 133). The focus on human labor
mercial spirit was everywhere. Americans liked and the need to make a living were related to
to make money and in the absence of a fully Marx’s materialistic view of human beings.
developed class system many opportunities While modern sociologists have tended to single
existed. The type of rigid classes, which out the relational nature of society, this was not
characterized feudalism in Europe, did not exist the case with Marx. People do not only interact
in the United States; and a new type of classes, with one another but also with nature. Long
with more open boundaries, was appearing. before Bruno Latour, Marx also understood the
Tocqueville also emphasized how much the importance of material objects for human beings.
Americans liked to take risks with their money, From the beginnings of history, Marx argued,
in the hope of making a profit. Failures did not people have organized themselves in groups.
deter them. Bankruptcy was not seen as There are those who exploit the work of others,
discrediting, as was the case in Europe. and those who are exploited. As history moves on
Tocqueville also noticed that when U.S. ships these two groups take on a number of different
sailed across the Atlantic, they were much faster forms; and technology plays an important role
than European ships. The reason for this had here. Yesterday’s masters and slaves eventually
nothing to do with the construction of the boats, became today’s capitalists and workers. The
nor that the sailors on the American ships were antagonism between capitalists and workers,
6 R. Swedberg

who constitute the two basic classes of capitalist Marx is also unique among economic
society, will eventually result in a revolution. In sociologists for his organic mix of a historical
communist society, property and work will be approach and an analytical perspective. It is not
shared in an egalitarian manner. easy to combine a diachronic and a synchronic
What characterizes capitalist society, approach in a single analysis, but Marx
according to Marx, is that everything is either a succeeded. There is also his call to action in his
commodity or turning into one. This includes the writings. One of his most famous quotes reads,
individual whose work now becomes something “philosophers have hitherto only interpreted the
that can be bought and sold, resulting in alien- world in various ways; the point is to change it”
ation and exploitation. Work creates surplus (Marx 1978, 144). One may or may not agree
value, which drives capitalist society. “Accumu- with this statement, but it is hard to find a more
late, accumulate! That is Moses and the proph- effective way of raising the issue of whether or
ets,” we read in Capital (Marx 1990, 742). While not knowledge of the economy should have a
the basic law of capitalism is simple enough, its practical value.
impact on society is not. Many different factors,
Marx explains, help to account for the uneven and
at times catastrophic course of capitalist society.
2.3 Max Weber
There are, for example, tendencies within a capi-
talist economy which push the capitalists to
In a formal sense, it was Max Weber who
increase exploitation. There also are factors that
founded economic sociology. It was he who first
make the workers grow in number and eventually
used the term economic sociology (Wirtschaftsso-
become radicalized.
ziologie) and who also provided the very first
Unlike Engels, Marx lacked personal knowl-
detailed account of what it studies and how to
edge of life inside the factories. He did however
approach the topic. From this time on, economic
locate one very rich empirical source on industrial
sociologists were also academics. Marx was a
work in England, namely the reports of the fac-
revolutionary and Tocqueville a politician; both
tory inspectors. These were full of details and
rejected the university as a place to work. Weber
figures on what was happening inside the
laid the academic foundation for economic soci-
factories and became an important source for
ology in Chap. 2 of Economy and Society. The
Capital. Marx described the ill-treatment and
size of this chapter is that of a small book; and it
exploitation of the workers with a realism that is
contains an extremely valuable presentation and
still hard to match. Marx’s second great source for
discussion of the basic concepts of economic
Capital was the literature of the economists.
sociology (Weber 1978, 63 ff.). Weber’s
Unlike Tocqueville who had only read a few
approach also differs from the broad, society-
works in political economy, Marx was an expert,
based analysis of the type one can find in
or rather, he turned himself into an expert after
Tocqueville and Marx. He preferred a consider-
arriving in London in 1849, where he settled
ably more narrow and academic approach,
down for good.
namely an economic sociology that could com-
What Marx wrote on economic theory is still
plement economics.
of great interest to economic sociologists. He
Weber essentially applied his interpretive soci-
should, for example, be credited with having
ology to economic phenomena, creating in this
developed a pioneering analysis of the way that
way an interpretive economic sociology. What is
the categories of economics have come into
distinctive about Weber’s type of sociology is the
being. He criticized the economists for using eco-
importance that is assigned to the element of
nomic concepts without understanding that these
meaning. When one studies the economy, one
presupposed the existence of very specific social
always has to consider the meaning with which
conditions.
the actors invest their actions. This means
1 The Classic Tradition in Economic Sociology 7

individuals since Weber rejected the idea that important aim of this project was to extend the
corporate entities can act. analysis in The Protestant Ethic to religions in
In the second chapter of Economy and Society, other parts of the world, such as Hinduism, Bud-
“Sociological Categories of Economic Action,” dhism, and Taoism in India, and China. Similar to
Weber outlines the basic concepts of economic Marx and Tocqueville, Weber did not limit his
sociology. In addition to the general sociological analysis to Europe.
concepts that are presented and discussed in Another important goal of Weber’s project on
Chap. 1, some new ones are added. The concept economic ethics was to draw attention to the role
of economic action should, for example, be of work. This was especially done in The Protes-
constructed in the following way. First, in order tant Ethic. Weber’s emphasis on the centrality of
for behavior to become an action, it has to be work in capitalism was not very different from
invested with a meaning. Second, this type of that of Marx. Marx, however, had viewed labor as
action is only social if it is oriented towards the motor of all economies, and emphasized how
other actors or to an order (Ordnung). Economic it had become a commodity in capitalism;
action also has to be peaceful to qualify as eco- Weber’s emphasis in The Protestant Ethic was
nomic action; and it is aimed at the satisfaction of quite different. He focused on the meaning of the
a desire for utilities. These utilities refer not only work to the individual, more precisely on work in
to the consumption of goods, which is the stan- the form of a calling. In capitalist society one has
dard goal of economic action, but also to profit. to work all the time; and work is never finished.
By adding profit Weber could include profit- Weber and Marx agreed, however, that modern
making in his concept of economic action. capitalism severely constrains the individual, and
In this way Weber laid a conceptual founda- in this sense impoverishes her life.
tion for his interpretive analysis of the economy,
which he also applied to a series of economic
phenomena in Chap. 2 in Economy and Society. 2.4 Joseph Schumpeter
All economies, he here says, are based on either
the principle of house-holding or that of profit- Weber’s idea of an economic sociology was not
making. The former is centered around the satis- followed up by many sociologists in Europe nor
faction of basic needs, the latter around making in the United States. But as always, there are
more money. A firm, for example, is a profit- exceptions; and one of these is Joseph
maker, while the family is a household. The medi- Schumpeter (1883–1950). Schumpeter quickly
eval manor and the welfare state are two other established himself as a brilliant young economist
examples of households. There are also economic of the Austrian school. By this time, it can be
phenomena that display a mixture of Weber’s two added, it was the rule in academia that economists
categories. A family firm, for example, has should work on the economy and sociologists on
elements of both profit-making and household; society.
and the neo-liberal state is a household that Schumpeter, however, did not feel that he had
encourages profit-making. to limit his views to economics in this sense, and
While Chap. 2 in Economy and Society early showed an interest in economic sociology
represents the theoretical part of Weber’s work and economic history. In order to understand
in economic sociology, the essays in his economic life, he argued, one has to go beyond
3-volume work Collected Essays in the Sociology economics of the type that existed in academia.
of Religion contain many of his most important Towards the end of his life, Schumpeter
studies in this field. The most famous of these is summarized his vision of the study of the econ-
The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. omy as one of social economics
It should, however, be pointed out that this study (Sozialökonomik). This type of economics draws
was part of a giant project on the economic ethic on four disciplines: economic theory, economic
of the world religions (Weber 1930). One history, economic sociology, and statistics
8 R. Swedberg

(Schumpeter 1954, 12 ff.). The primary task of with resistance is squarely sociological. What
economic sociology is to study economic Schumpeter had created can either be seen as a
institutions, and that of economic theory to ana- mix of elements from two academic disciplines,
lyze economic mechanisms (see also Schumpeter or as a very successful combination which
1951). Economic historians add the historical illustrates that a full analysis of economic
dimension to the analysis, and the statisticians phenomena must draw on elements from both
contribute a concern with data. economics and sociology. The same boundary-
During the early stage of his career, crossing tendency can be found in what has
Schumpeter wrote three articles that he referred always been Schumpeter’s most popular work,
to as his work in sociology. These dealt with Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy (1942).
taxation, social class, and imperialism This book consists of a series of essays in which
(Schumpeter 1991a, b, c). While all of these stud- Schumpeter deals with such topics as the nature
ies are well worth reading and studying today, the of democracy, how to make sense of Marx, and
article on taxation with its full program for a fiscal what modern socialism is like. The main focus of
sociology is of special importance. the work, however, is on contemporary capital-
But Schumpeter’s most interesting contribu- ism. In Schumpeter’s view, modern capitalism
tion to economic sociology cannot be found in was in deep trouble by the mid-1900s since the
any of these three essays. For this, the reader has capitalists had become too weak to stand up and
to turn to his most important contribution to eco- defend it. While the early capitalists had heartily
nomic theory, namely his theory of entrepreneur- embraced profit and property, modern managers
ship. In his late 20s Schumpeter had worked out and owners did not. As a result, the future of
the basic ideas for his famous theory of the entre- capitalism looked very gloomy to Schumpeter at
preneur, which can be found in The Economic the time of his death. This happened in 1950, long
Theory of Development (1934). Before before the revival of enthusiasm for capitalism
Schumpeter’s book on entrepreneurship was that Schumpeter longed for and that came with
published, economists had been unable to account neoliberalism.
for much of the dynamics of economic life since
they relied heavily on some form of equilibrium
analysis. Schumpeter broke this trend, even if he
2.5 Karl Polanyi
never succeeded in presenting a formal theory of
entrepreneurship. His verbal theory, however, is
Much of Schumpeter’s sensibility was formed by
impressive enough and still very suggestive.
what happened in Europe during World War I and
Schumpeter’s basic idea is that the entrepreneur
its aftermath. as opposed to Tocqueville, Marx,
creates a new combination of already existing
and Weber who were all part of the Old World.
elements. This results in a number of different
The same can be said about Karl Polanyi
types of innovations, such as new goods, new
(1886–1964), who, like Schumpeter, had grown
methods of production, and/or new markets.
up in the Austro-Hungarian Empire, only to see it
However, it is not enough to produce a good
disintegrate after World War I Polanyi had an
that represents an innovation, the entrepreneur
academic background, but not in economics. He
must also overcome the resistance against doing
learned economics on his own but never became
something new. This resistance is very strong,
an expert like Marx or Schumpeter. However, he
and can be found among the workers, among the
did have a deep interest in economic affairs; and
population at large, and in the mind of the entre-
this made it easy for him to work as an economic
preneur herself.
journalist. He worked as a journalist in Austria in
While it may be argued, as Schumpeter does,
the 1920s and early1930s; and his articles from
that the idea of combining economic resources of
these days represent an important part of
different types belongs to economics, it is none-
his work.
theless clear that the part of his analysis that deals
1 The Classic Tradition in Economic Sociology 9

Polanyi escaped to England in 1933 as the represented an innovation from the perspective
political situation in Austria became increasingly of economic sociology, which usually focused
tense. It was here that he transformed himself into on the period from the early 1800s and onwards.
a serious scholar. This is similar to what took Another innovation from this time was Polanyi’s
place in England with the young Marx, when he writings about Africa, a continent which no ear-
became the Marx of Capital. What Polanyi stud- lier economic sociologist had written about
ied in England, which turned him from a journal- (Polanyi 1966). Today’s student of economic
ist into a scholar, was economic history. What sociology will also want to read Polanyi’s study
especially fascinated him was the history of of the beginnings of economic thought in Classi-
early capitalism in England. He poured over cal Greece, “Aristotle Discovers the Economy”
books on the historical emergence of factory (Polanyi 1957). While modern economists view
workers and industrial capital. Adam Smith as the father of economics,
The main result of Polanyi’s research in according to Polanyi, it was Aristotle. Another
England was the work that was to become his result of Polanyi’s work from his anthropological
most famous, The Great Transformation (1944). period was his typology of economic action.
Its central theme is that the birth of capitalism had While Weber had argued that all economies
unleashed greed of a type that had never before were either profit-making entities or households,
existed in human history. It was a level of greed Polanyi introduced a different set of basic
that in Polanyi’s mind, would end up by tearing categories that described how key economic
human society apart and completely destroy actions in a society must be embedded or
nature. Capitalism was a threat to human beings anchored in society’s institutions. This can only
as a species; it was absolutely imperative that it be done in three ways: through reciprocity,
should be stopped. redistribution, or exchange.
However, there were also forces that countered Polanyi lacked both the encyclopedic knowl-
the onslaught of capitalism, and these were edge of Weber and the capacity Marx to meld
mainly the workers. Each time the capitalists historical and analytical perspectives. Contrary to
made a new attempt to squeeze more profit out Weber and Marx, however, Polanyi left a set of
of the workers, these responded with resistance in categories behind, which are extremely flexible
the form of strikes. According to Polanyi, there is and easy for today’s economic sociologist to
a general tendency in society to respond to the work with. These are embeddedness and the
activities of capitalists with a countermove, some- three modes of economic action reciprocity-
thing he termed the “double movement” (1944, redistribution-exchange. Exchange is linked to
part II). The results of the double movement, the institution of the market; redistribution to the
however, were not always positive. Many people institution of the state; and reciprocity to the
who had their livelihoods destroyed by capitalism institution of the family. There were also many
were not progressive. The emergence of fascism other topics, besides these three institutions,
and Nazism was an example of this (1944, part which can be analyzed with these categories.
III). In Polanyi’s view, the original impulse to There is a similar flexibility to the concept of
these extreme right-wing movements could be embeddedness.
traced to England in the 1840s, when capitalism It should also be noted that what all of
was unleashed for the first time. Polanyi’s studies have in common is a critical
Polanyi defined himself as an economic jour- attitude to the way modern markets operate. In
nalist in Austria and as an economic historian in his view, capitalist markets have been
England, but he turned into an economic anthro- dis-embedded from the rest of society and have
pologist in the United States in the 1940s. Draw- become a threat to humanity. As a consequence,
ing especially on the work by anthropologists, this type of market must be re-embedded in the
Polanyi started to write about economic life in social and political institutions of society. It is
pre-industrial societies (1966, 1968). This imperative not to think that the capitalist market
10 R. Swedberg

is the only type of markets that can work. This published in 1985 and which was to become the
idea is central to the thought of Polanyi, who manifesto of new economic sociology, “Eco-
famously referred to “our obsolete market men- nomic Action and Social Structure: The Problem
tality” in the title of one of his articles (Polanyi of Embeddedness” (Granovetter 1985). It is clear
1968). that Granovetter viewed his own work as being in
dialogue with economics, as evidenced by his
many references to Arrow, Williamson, and
2.6 Mark Granovetter other economists. In his manifesto for new eco-
nomic sociology, the term economic sociology is
Both Schumpeter and Polanyi were lone voices in however not to be found. Instead, Granovetter
a field that had more or less stalled as an academic viewed his article as a contribution to structural
enterprise after the death of Weber. It is true that sociology, by which he meant the network type of
an attempt was made in the 1950s and early 1960s analysis that his thesis adviser Harrison White
by Talcott Parsons and his student Neil Smelser to had helped to develop. In fact, what Granovetter
revive economic sociology, but it lacked intellec- seems to have taken as his primary aim was not so
tual force and did not gather much academic much to continue and add to the tradition of
support (e.g., Parsons and Smelser 1956; Smelser economic sociology, but to reform economic
1963). It was not till the mid-1980s that economic analysis in general, with the assistance of sociol-
sociology started to come alive again. This time it ogy. In an interview from this period, he stated for
came in a different shape that earned it the name example that what he hoped to accomplish with
new economic sociology. The strengths and the his work was to advance economic analysis itself,
weaknesses of the economic sociology that now and to do this by solving problems that the
came into being have much to do with its rela- economists had failed to grasp (Granovetter
tionship to the past. The insights in economic 1987).
sociology of Marx, Weber, and Tocqueville This, however, was not to be. The economists
were little known to the sociologists who now were not interested in meeting sociologists half-
took center stage and ushered in the new type of way, as Granovetter had hoped, something that
economic sociology. Instead, these sociologists forced him to, instead, turn his energy to devel-
relied heavily on the type of sociology that had oping economic sociology. He eventually also
developed in the United States during the twenti- redirected the rest of his work in sociology to
eth century. economic sociology. The attentive reader of his
Mark Granovetter (1943–) is the foremost new work in economic sociology will find a number of
economic sociologist and the author of a brilliant creative ideas, as well as solid empirical analyses.
dissertation using networks to explain why some Two of his most productive ideas from these
people succeed in getting a job while others do years are his theory of business groups and his
not (Granovetter 1974). Granovetter had origi- analysis of economic institutions as social
nally set out to explain why friends and family constructions (Granovetter 1994; Granovetter
can be of more help in this enterprise, than what and McGuire 1998). In a recent volume, entitled
fleeting contacts and acquaintances can. He, how- Society and Economy, Granovetter has
ever, found that the opposite to be true. The result summarized his theoretical approach
was expressed in the title of one of his most cited (Granovetter 2017).
articles, “The Strength of Weak Ties” A special mention should also be made of
(Granovetter 1973). Granovetter’s popularization of the term
Reading through Getting A Job (1974), the embeddedness, which he had borrowed from
book based on Granovetter’s dissertation, the Polanyi and which can be found in his 1985
reader is also struck by the author’s knowledge article. The concept of embeddedness was recast
of economics. One gets the same impression mainly with the help of networks. All economic
when reading the article that Granovetter actions, Granovetter argued, are embedded in
1 The Classic Tradition in Economic Sociology 11

social structures that are made up of networks. at the official economy, including such topics as
While his students have sometimes advocated a loans from banks and the rate of interest
quantitative approach to the idea of (Bourdieu et al. 1963). In today’s terms, The
embeddedness, Granovetter himself has Bank and Its Customers (which was never
continued to view it as an umbrella term, that is, completed and published) can be seen as a study
as a sensitizing type of concept that needs to be in economic literacy.
complemented by other concepts (Granovetter in Bourdieu was also the author of a hugely suc-
Krippner et al. 2004, 133). cessful study of consumption, called Distinction
(Bourdieu 1986). Less spectacular, but equally
penetrating, is his study of real estate from some
2.7 Pierre Bourdieu 20 years later, in which Bourdieu mapped out
how people think and how they approach the
New economic sociology did not, as mentioned, project of buying a house (Bourdieu 2005b).
try to anchor itself in the tradition of the economic The same powerful imagination that the reader
sociology of Tocqueville, Marx, and Weber. first encountered in the studies of Algeria is here
Instead, it created a number of contributions of directed at common people’s ways of thinking
its own, drawing mainly on various strands of and dreaming about owning a home. Bourdieu
sociology that were prominent in the 1980s in also analyzed the role of the state in the housing
the United States, such as structural sociology, market and showed how it had switched from
industrial sociology, sociology of consumption, supporting public housing to encouraging people
just to name a few. European economic to own their own house.
sociologists did something similar in the 1990s, Bourdieu’s commitment to certain political
even though it was heavily influenced by values was clearly mirrored in his critique of the
U.S. sociology at this time. French government. He is also the author of a
The work by Pierre Bourdieu is an exception number of short texts, in which he discusses vari-
to this trend. Trained in philosophy and close to ous economic questions of the day, such as the
ethnography, Bourdieu began his social science policies of the IMF, the European Central Bank,
work in Algeria and quickly displayed his great among others (Bourdieu 1998, 2003). Taken
potential as a sociologist. Bourdieu, however, together, these writings contain an early and
was more interested in general sociology than in insightful critique of neoliberalism.
any of its sub-areas, including economic sociol- According to Bourdieu, elements of this neo-
ogy; and this was especially true during his early liberalism could also be found in the new eco-
period. It is, however, possible to extract a distinct nomic sociology that had emerged in the United
analysis of the economy already from Bourdieu’s States. U.S. network sociologists were, for exam-
work in Algeria and view it as a contribution to ple, criticized for not understanding the role of
economic sociology. By proceeding in this way, power in the economy. They traced the
one will find a very interesting analysis of the way interactions of the actors with the help of
that Algerian peasants and workers looked at networks but failed to understand the way that
economic life, including their work. Two fine structural power operates in a field. During this
examples of this are Travail et travailleurs en period Bourdieu also wrote an important essay on
Algerie (Bourdieu 1963) and Algeria 1960 general economic sociology, in which he force-
(Bourdieu 1979). fully attacked the tendency of economists to ana-
Once Bourdieu had identified himself as a lyze economic life as if social relations did not
sociologist, he began to study all of society and exist. The economists’ view of human beings, he
its major institutions, including the economy. charged, is distorted and cannot be used for sci-
Together with two colleagues he, for example, entific purposes. “Homo economicus . . . is a kind
initiated a pioneering study of a bank, in which of anthropological monster” (Bourdieu
he focused on the way that common people look 2005a, 82).
12 R. Swedberg

2.8 Single Contributions they affect the issue of cumulation in economic


to the Classic Tradition sociology. There is a danger, for one thing, that
the wheel will be reinvented at regular intervals.
So far, in discussing the classic tradition in eco- New contributions may also be lost because they
nomic sociology, only major figures in economic will not be properly anchored in the classic
sociology have been discussed. However, a tradi- tradition.
tion consists of individual contributions, not of There are, however, studies in contemporary
individual people. The following question there- economic sociology that represent important
fore needs to be asked: do also single articles and contributions to the classic tradition. Most of
monographs produced by lesser figures belong to these do so by virtue of opening up new areas or
the classic tradition, as defined by Mills? The topics in the economy. One of these is the area of
answer is naturally yes. It should also be added finance or the sociology of finance. Studies in this
that while Mills exclusively speaks of what he genre often describe how some financial institu-
calls, models as making up the classic tradition, tion has come into being, how different financial
one may also want to add a few other forms that institutions operate, or what physical objects are
these contributions can take. One can, for exam- used in their operations such as computers and
ple, contribute to the classic tradition also by telephones. The leading scholar in this field is
introducing new methods, new types of data, Donald Mackenzie (e.g., Millo and MacKenzie
and/or new topics in economic sociology. 2003; MacKenzie 2006), Greta Kipper’s work on
Since the time of Weber, many important stud- the emergence and nature of financialization
ies of the economy have been carried out with the (Krippner 2012) should also be mentioned.
help of the following four innovations in the Another topic that has been opened up by
sociological method: the interview, participant today’s economic sociologists is that of children
observation, the modern survey and regression and their relationship to the economy. There are
analysis. These methods have been used to ana- currently studies on children and consumption, as
lyze such topics as life in the workplace, people’s well as studies on children’s work and their
consumer habits, and stratification (e.g., Gouldner socialization into the world of money. A
1954; Dalton 1959; Lazarsfeld 1959; Blau and pioneering work in this field is Pricing the Price-
Duncan 1967; Lazarsfeld et al. 1971; Moss less Child by Viviana Zelizer (1985). Drawing on
Kanter 1977). court records, which represent a rarely used
It is more difficult to single out individual source in economic sociology, she documents
studies from the years after the mid-1980s that how children in the past were valued in terms of
constitute contributions to the classic tradition in their labor and how today they are instead valued
economic sociology. One major reason for this is in terms of the emotions they evoke.
that these studies are much closer to today, some- Zelizer has also made another innovative addi-
thing that always makes it difficult to decide what tion to economic sociology, this time to money.
will last and what will not. Of the ones that will be In contrast to the general tendency of looking at
mentioned in the next few pages, posterity will money as something neutral and non-social, she
probably eliminate some and add a few others. has shown how money is often differentiated
There is also the additional problem that much of according to the purpose for which it is intended.
modern sociology, including economic sociol- Housewives may put aside some money for food,
ogy, has rather tenuous links to what was pro- other for the children, and so on (Zelizer 1994).
duced in sociology before the advent of There is no neutral money of the type that
U.S. mainstream sociology. The latter mainly economists speak of, according to Zelizer, only
emerged after World War II and is still very “social money.”
strong; and this has had some negative Finally, Zelizer has also helped to introduce
consequences which are worth mentioning since emotions into economic sociology, which was a
topic that had lain dormant since Tocqueville’s
1 The Classic Tradition in Economic Sociology 13

pioneering work. She has emphasized how England 1992; England and Folbre 2005; Correll
emotions and economic values do not represent et al. 2007; Zelizer 2013).
two separate spheres in people’s lives but inter- What has been written so far in this chapter
mingle and co-exist in various ways (e.g. Zelizer about single contributions by various economic
2007). Another powerful study of the role of sociologists only covers part of the richness of the
emotions in the economy can be found in The classic tradition in economic sociology. There are
Managed Heart (1983) by Arlie Hochschild. Air- also many other interesting monographs and
plane stewardesses, she shows, have to smile and articles, especially on individual topics, such as
look happy as part of their work. Bill collectors, markets or work, to just name two. Also,
in contrast, have to pretend to be angry and historians, anthropologists, economists and eco-
threaten people in order to make them pay. Both nomic journalists have made many excellent
perform a special type of emotional work, contributions to economic sociology in a broad
according to Hochschild. sense. The names of people such as Fernand
Another interesting addition to the classic tra- Braudel, Marcel Mauss, John Maynard Keynes,
dition can be found in the recent work on valua- Nancy Folbre, and Michael Lewis are a reminder
tion in economic life. Weber’s interest in the role of this.
of values in economic life, especially in his many It is also easy for someone who is interested in
volumes on the economic ethics of world economic sociology to read too much, which
religions, is foundational here. He did not, how- means that little energy is left over for one’s
ever, address the question of how a price is placed own contribution. In the concluding remarks,
on items that are hard to evaluate, such as art, where the issue of cumulation is taken up once
wine, or nature. This, however, is something that more, also this issue will be addressed. Some
recent economic sociologists have done (e.g., suggestions will be given for how to work in a
Beckert and Aspers 2011). practical way with just a few of the works in the
Something should also be said about a topic classic tradition in economic sociology.
that may well represent the most important con-
tribution of new economic sociology to the clas-
sic tradition, in the sense that it has a generality 3 Concluding Remarks
that goes well beyond specific economic topics.
This is the role of gender in the economy. There is So far in this chapter, the focus has exclusively
no general model for this, in the sense of been on the accumulation of knowledge in one
C. Wright Mills. Still, gender does play a role in particular subfield of sociology. One is however,
a huge number of economic phenomena and also justified in asking what this means for soci-
should therefore, in principle, be included in all ology as a whole. How exactly does the commu-
economic-sociological analysis. As to studies in nication of insights from economic sociology to
new economic sociology on the role of gender in sociology in general take place? Similarly, how
the economy, it is clear that some of the works are insights from sociology in general
already mentioned by Zelizer and Hochschild communicated to economic sociology? What
contain important contributions to this area as about insights from one subfield to another?
well (e.g., Hochschild 1989; Zelizer 2005). There is finally also the related issue of codifica-
Besides the topics that these two scholars have tion or the systematic arrangement of findings
analyzed, one can also mention male versus (Merton 1968, 155).
female work in the household, caring work, In trying to answer these questions, it should
unequal pay, under- and overrepresentation of first of all be noted that accumulation in sociology
men and women in various jobs, and the is currently mainly taking place in its subfields
mistreatment of pregnant women and mothers in (e.g., Collins 1999). It is also clear that most of
the labor force (the penalty of motherhood; e.g., the questions about cumulation, which have been
mentioned in this chapter, point well beyond its
14 R. Swedberg

primary concerns. Suffice it to say that some of I have nonetheless tried to outline three practical
the key figures in economic sociology have devel- ways in which this can be done. The two first were
oped models that are applicable to all of sociol- developed and taught by Robert K. Merton in his
ogy. This is the case with Tocqueville, Marx, and course on theorizing in sociology from the 1950s
Weber. There are also some insights in economic and 1960s (Swedberg 2019). The third comes
sociology that seem to be applicable to sociology from my own work with Schumpeter. All are
as a whole. As examples of this, one can mention applicable to economic sociology as well as to
Polanyi’s notion of embeddedness and sociology in general.
Schumpeter’s theory of entrepreneurship. The three ways of proceeding are called
Finally, a few words should be said about the respecification, reconceptualization, and recom-
need to strike a balance between how much one bination. A brief description of each follows:
needs to read in the classic tradition sociology,
and how much energy one should devote to
developing one’s own ideas. While a thorough 3.1 Respecification
knowledge of the whole classic tradition in eco-
nomic sociology is commendable, what may be All phenomena that are analyzed in sociology
more realistic for most people is to just acquaint must be empirically specified. Adding to or
themselves with most works in the classic tradi- subtracting from the current ways of doing this
tion, in combination with making an intense study is the job of respecification. What constitutes
of a few of these. Mastering a limited number of what sociologists call work has for example
models, as C. Wright Mills defines these, should been greatly expanded during the twentieth cen-
be part of the education of any economic sociolo- tury, with household chores being added. Should
gist. Students who are interested in entrepreneur- one also include the effort it takes to keep one’s
ship should also focus on Schumpeter’s model of own body healthy, as Hannah Arendt (1958,
the entrepreneur. Those who are interested in 96 ff.) has suggested? A phenomenon that, in
capitalism should also focus on the models of contrast, has shrunk in scope is that of class. In
Marx, Weber and Polanyi. All of these thinkers the work of Marx, class was a broad social, polit-
are very rich, and working through their key ical and economic category, while in modern
writings a few times is highly recommended. At stratification theory it has become a narrow
each reading one usually discovers several new sociological term.
ideas.
It is also clear that the most important way to
deal with the classic tradition is not to comment 3.2 Reconceptualization
on it, but to attempt to develop it further. This
means to actively use some of its ideas and Economic sociology has its own set of concepts,
insights, build on these, and try to go beyond from those discussed by Max Weber in Chap. 2 of
them. By proceeding in this way, one can com- Economy and Society to those that have been
bine the strength that comes from being part of a added in new economic sociology (see e.g. the
tradition with one’s own strengths and interests. list in Swedberg 2016). All of these can be added
The tradition is kept alive and is further devel- to or redefined, a bit like empirical phenomena
oped; and the individual researcher benefits from can be respecified. This is often done by changing
being part of it. the meaning of an existing concept, for example,
How exactly can this be done? How does one embeddedness. One can also take a concept in
take something from the classic tradition and add general sociology and focus on its economic part,
to it? Should this be done when working with the using say habitus to create economic habitus (e.g.,
empirical material or when trying to develop a Bourdieu 1979). There is also the strategy that
theoretical argument? It is not easy to give a Weber himself often used, namely, to take
concrete answer to this kind of questions. Below concepts from other sciences, change them a bit,
1 The Classic Tradition in Economic Sociology 15

and turn them into sociological concepts (e.g., Bourdieu, P. (1963). Travail et travailleurs en Algérie:
charisma). Etude sociologique. In P. Bourdieu (Ed.), Travail et
travailleurs en Algérie (pp. 257–562). Paris: Mouton.
Bourdieu, P. (1979). Algeria 1960: The disenchantment of
the world (R. Nice, Trans.). Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
3.3 Recombination Bourdieu, P. (1986 [1979]). Distinction: A social critique
of the judgment of taste (R. Nice, Trans.). London:
Schumpeter defined entrepreneurship and Routledge.
Bourdieu, P. (1998). Acts of resistance: Against the tyr-
innovation as a new combination of already
anny of the market. New York: New Press.
existing elements. In the classic tradition there Bourdieu, P. (2003). Firing back: Against the tyranny of
are a number of concepts and ideas that can be the market 2. London: Verso.
recombined into new and interesting Bourdieu, P. (2005a). Principles of an economic anthro-
pology (R. Nice, Trans.). In N. J. Smelser &
constellations. C. Wright Mills notes that “very
R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic soci-
many social theories seem to be, at least immedi- ology (2nd ed., pp. 75–89). New York and Princeton:
ately, the rather direct result of combining ideas Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University
which no one has previously thought of combin- Press.
Bourdieu, P. (2005b). The social structures of the economy
ing” (Mills 1960, 9). As an example, he mentions
(C. Turner, Trans.). Cambridge: Polity Press.
Marx’s theory of capitalism which was the result Bourdieu, P., Boltanski, L., & Chamboredon, J.-C. (1963).
of a combination of ideas from German philoso- La banque et sa clientèle: Eléments d’une sociologie
phy, British economics, and French socialism. du crédit. Unpublished manuscript. Paris: Centre de
Sociologie Européenne.
That these three ways of working with insights
Collins, R. (1999). Socially unrecognized cumulation. The
from the classic tradition in economic sociology American Sociologist, 30(2), 41–61.
all start with the prefix re is no accident. It Correll, S., Benard, S., & Paik, I. (2007). Getting a job: Is
indicates that while they represent ways of there a motherhood penalty? American Journal of
Sociology, 112(5), 1297–1339.
moving the analysis forward in new and interest-
Dalton, M. (1959). Men who manage: Fusions of feeling
ing ways, they are at the same time drawing on and theory in administration. New York: Wiley.
and grounded in a tradition. Other ways of deal- England, P. (1992). Comparable worth: Theories and
ing with the heritage of economic sociology are evidence. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
England, P., & Folbre, N. (2005). Gender and economic
no doubt possible, as well as necessary. The rea-
sociology. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The
son for mentioning this is that it is imperative for handbook of economic sociology (2nd ed.,
the healthy development of economic sociology pp. 627–649). New York and Princeton: Russell Sage
to be able to distinguish between what should be Foundation and Princeton University Press.
Gans, H. (1992). Sociological amnesia: The
kept alive and further developed, and what should
Noncumulation of normal social science. Sociological
be forgotten and discarded. A science that does Forum, 7(4), 701–710.
not care for its classic tradition is lost. Goffman, E. (1972 [1969]). Strategic interaction. In Stra-
tegic interaction (pp. 83–145). New York: Ballentine.
Goffman, E. (1982 [1967]). Where the action is. In Inter-
action ritual (pp. 149–270). New York: Akldine.
References Gouldner, A. (1954). Patterns of industrial democracy.
New York: The Free Press.
Granovetter, M. (1973). The strength of weak ties. Ameri-
Abbott, A. (2006). Reconceptualizing knowledge accumu-
can Journal of Sociology, 78(6), 1360–1380.
lation in sociology. The American Sociologist, 37(2),
Granovetter, M. (1974). Getting a job. Cambridge, MA:
57–66.
Harvard University Press.
Arendt, H. (1958). The human condition. Chicago: Uni-
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social struc-
versity of Chicago Press.
ture: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal
Beckert, J., & Aspers, P. (Eds.). (2011). The worth of
of Sociology, 91(3), 411–510.
goods: Valuation and pricing in the economy.
Granovetter, M. (1987). On economic sociology: An inter-
New York: Oxford University Press.
view with Mark Granovetter. Research Report from the
Blau, P., & Duncan, O. (1967). The American occupa-
Department of Sociology, Uppsala University, 1, 1–26.
tional structure. New York: Wiley.
16 R. Swedberg

Granovetter, M. (1994). Business groups. In N. J. Smelser empires (pp. 64–96). Chicago: Henry Regnery
& R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic Company.
sociology (2nd ed., pp. 453–475). New York and Polanyi, K. (1966). Dahomey and the slave trade: An
Princeton: Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton Uni- analysis of an archaic economy. Washington, DC:
versity Press. University of Washington Press.
Granovetter, M. (2017). Society and economy: Framework Polanyi, K. (1968). Our obsolete market mentality. In
and principles. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University K. Polanyi (Ed.), Primitive, archaic and modern
Press. economies (pp. 50–77). Boston: Beacon Press.
Granovetter, M., & McGuire, P. (1998). The making of an Schumpeter, J. A. (1934 [1912]). Theory of economic
industry: Electricity in the United States. In M. Callon development (R. Opie, Trans.). Cambridge, MA:
(Ed.), The Laws of the market (pp. 147–173). Oxford: Harvard University Press.
Blackwell. Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and
Hochschild, A. (1983). The managed heart: Commerciali- democracy. New York: Harper & Brothers.
zation of human feeling. Berkeley, CA: University of Schumpeter, J. A. (1951 [1949]). Communist manifesto in
California Press. sociology and economics. In Essays (pp. 182–295).
Hochschild, A. (1989). The second shift. New York: Cambridge, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Viking Penguin. Schumpeter, J. A. (1954). History of economic analysis.
Krippner, G. (2012). Capitalizing on crisis: The political London: Allen and Unwin.
origins of the rise of finance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Schumpeter, J. A. (1991a [1918]). The crisis of the tax
University Press. state. In The economics and sociology of capitalism
Krippner, G., et al. (2004). Polanyi symposium: A conver- (pp. 99–140). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
sation on embeddedness. Socio-Economic Review, 2 Schumpeter, J. A. (1991b [1919]). The sociology of
(1), 109–135. imperialisms. In The economics and sociology of capi-
Lazarsfeld, P. (1959). Reflections on business. American talism (pp. 141–219). Princeton: Princeton University
Journal of Sociology, 65(1), 1–31. Press.
Lazarsfeld, P., et al. (1971 [1933]). Marienthal: The Schumpeter, J. A. (1991c [1927]). Social classes in an
sociography of an unemployed community. London: ethnically homogenous environment. In The econom-
Routledge. ics and sociology of capitalism (pp. 230–83).
Lukács, G. (1980). The ontology of social being: Labour. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
London: Merlin Press. Smelser, N. J. (1963). The sociology of economic life.
MacKenzie, D. (2006). An engine, not a camera: How Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
financial methods shape markets. Cambridge, MA: Swedberg, R. (2009). Tocqueville’s political economy.
MIT. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Marx, K. (1978 [1845]). Theses on Feuerbach. In Swedberg, R. (2016). Theorizing economic sociology. In
R. Tucker (Ed.), The Marx-Engels reader (2nd ed., P. Aspers & N. Dodd (Eds.), Re-imagining economic
pp. 143–145). New York: Norton. sociology (pp. 34–54). Oxford: Oxford University
Marx, K. (1990 [1867]). Capital. Vol. 1 (B. Fowkes, Press.
Trans.). London: Penguin. Swedberg, R. (2019). How to make sociology out of data:
Merton, R. K. (1968). Social theory and social structure Robert K. Merton’s course in theorizing (Soc 213–14).
(Enlarged ed.). New York: Free Press. The American Sociologist, 50(1), 85–20.
Merton, R. K. (1984). The fallacy of the latest word: The Tocqueville, A. (1988 [1856]). The old regime and the
case of ‘pietism and science’. American Journal of revolution. Vol. 1 (A. Kahan, Trans.). Chicago: Uni-
Sociology, 89(5), 1091–1121. versity of Chicago Press.
Millo, Y., & MacKenzie, D. (2003). Constructing a mar- Tocqueville, A. (2004 [1835–40]). Democracy in America
ket, performing theory: The historical sociology of a (A. Goldhammer, Trans.). New York: The Library of
financial derivatives exchange. American Journal of America.
Sociology, 109, 107–145. Weber, M. (1930 [1904–5]). The protestant ethic and the
Mills, C. W. (Ed.). (1960). Images of man: The classic spirit of capitalism (T. Parsons, Trans.). London: Allen
tradition in sociological thinking. New York: George & Unwin.
Braziller. Weber, M. (1978 [1921/2]). Economy and society: An
Moss Kanter, R. (1977). Men and women of the corpora- outline of interpretive sociology (G. Roth et al.,
tion. New York: Basic Books. Trans.). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Parsons, T., & Smelser, N. J. (1956). Economy and soci- Zelizer, V. (1985). Pricing the priceless child: The chang-
ety: A study in the integration of economic and social ing social value of children. New York: Basic Books.
theory. New York: Free Press. Zelizer, V. (1994). The social meaning of money.
Polanyi, K. (1944). The great transformation. Boston: New York: Basic Books.
Beacon Press. Zelizer, V. (2005). Culture and consumption. In N. J.
Polanyi, K. (1957). Aristotle discovers the economy. In Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of eco-
K. Polanyi et al. (Eds.), Trade and market in the early nomic sociology (2nd ed., pp. 331–354). New York:
1 The Classic Tradition in Economic Sociology 17

Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton University


Research interest: Economic sociology and social theory,
Press.
with an emphasis on theorizing. He is currently working
Zelizer, V. (2007). The purchase of intimacy. Princeton:
on various topics in theorizing and economic sociology.
Princeton University Press.
Recent publications: Swedberg, Richard. 1998. Max
Zelizer, V. (2013). Economic lives: How culture shapes
Weber and the Idea of Economic Sociology. Princeton:
the economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Princeton University Press. Smelser, Neil J., and Richard
Swedberg, eds. 2005. The Handbook of Economic
Sociology. 2. Auflage. Princeton: Princeton University
Swedberg, Richard is professor emeritus at Cornell Uni-
Press. Original edition, 1994. Hedström, Peter, and
versity and lives in Stockholm, Sweden. He received an
Richard Swedberg, eds. 1998. Social Mechanisms. An
LLB juris kandidat at Stockholm University in 1970 and a
Analytical Approach to Social Theory. Cambridge: Cam-
PhD in sociology at Boston College in 1978. He was
bridge University Press. Swedberg, Richard. 2014. The
professor of sociology at Stockholm University during
Art of Social Theorizing. Princeton: Princeton University
1996–2001, and professor of sociology at Cornell Univer-
Press.
sity, USA, 2002–2019.
Austrian and German Classics
as a Foundation? 2
Gertraude Mikl-Horke

1 Economics and Sociology theory declined, and historical economics


in Europe at the Beginning transformed itself into diagnostic analyses of
of the Twentieth Century society and culture, while sociology was still not
widely recognized as an academic discipline at
In texts dealing with the history of economic this time.
sociology, one usually encounters names like Early economic thinking, as in the classical
Karl Marx, Emile Durkheim, Georg Simmel, economics of Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, or
Max Weber, Joseph Schumpeter, and Karl Jean Baptiste Say or in historical economics,
Polanyi figuring as classics in the field (see also which was dominant in the nineteenth century in
Chap. 1). They include a preponderance of German universities, paid attention to social
scholars whose origin lies in what is now aspects, albeit in different forms. It was when
Germany and Austria (see Biggart 2002; economists strove to develop a pure economic
Swedberg 1991a, 1996, 2003; Trigilia 2002). theory without the social, political, or historical
There are various reasons for this, which cannot encumbrances that there was mention of a field of
be dealt with here, but the turbulent political economic sociology. The British economist,
history in the first half of the twentieth century William Stanley Jevons, stated the need of devel-
and the economic condition of relative backward- oping such a discipline as a new branch of Mr.
ness of the central European region played a Spencer’s Sociology, which should serve as an
role (Gerschenkron 1962). In the first half of the auxiliary science for economics within an aggre-
twentieth century, questions of economic organi- gate field of economic sciences (Jevons 1879,
zation were at the forefront of public, as well xv). That statement, with which he invented the
as academic discussions, and politicians and concept of economic sociology as a subfield of an
intellectuals were concerned about the future independent science of sociology, marked the
development of the economy and the society beginning of the separation of economics and
amidst the turbulent political and social situation. sociology. In France, Durkheim’s sociology had
The discussions among economists took into con- acquired a certain recognition as a special field of
sideration not only the economic, but also the social sciences, and both Spencer and Durkheim
political and ideological aspects of various eco- had paid attention to economic matters within
nomic forms and organizations. Liberal economic their sociological systems. Thus, it would have
seemed more appropriate that Spencer or
G. Mikl-Horke (*)
Durkheim should be referred to as the founding
Vienna University of Economics and Business, Vienna,
Austria fathers of economic sociology. For France, any-
e-mail: Gertraude.Mikl-Horke@wu.ac.at way, currently there is a great tradition of
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 19
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_2
20 G. Mikl-Horke

economic sociology, or rather of sociological eco- establishment of a field of sociology as an alter-


nomics (Lebaron 2001). native socialist science. Especially those who had
Within the political, social, and intellectual written social reform on their banners, frequently
context of Germany and Austria, the meaning saw sociology as a science for promoting social
of sociology was still vague. It was more a reform (see Neef 2012). In both cases, the econ-
figure of speech or a perspective than a definite omy was basic for the understanding of society as
field of scientific research. Social thinking the object of sociology. For the Austrian
in Germany and Austria either took place economists, it was the theoretical logic of eco-
within the framework of the historically based nomics, for the socialist authors, it was the real
Volkswirtschaftslehre or in that of a Marxist or economic condition and organization that was
otherwise socialist understanding of the evolution foundational to the meaning of society. They
of the production relation. Historic and social understood economy and society as inseparable
perspectives also played a great role in the liberal from each other, society as the basis of the econ-
economic thought of Carl Menger and his omy and the economy as constituted by social
successors, in spite of their insistence on theory actions. This holds true also for Max Weber,
based on an individualistic methodology. Menger Joseph A. Schumpeter, and Karl Polanyi, who
and his successors assumed subjective rationality, figure most prominently in today’s economic
thereby, allowing for an indefinite range of sociology. On an international scale, they are
motives, while not reducing action to specific regarded as the thinkers who provided a concep-
economic motives or self-interest. tual foundation for the discipline. Georg Simmel,
German and Austrian economists, whether who comes closest to being a genuine sociologist
adhering to the historical approach or to a theo- with his formal sociology, is often mentioned as
retical one, did not eliminate social aspects from having made a contribution to economic sociol-
economics. This situation delayed the develop- ogy. However, in his case attention is mostly
ment of sociology as a consistent, independent restricted to his work on the philosophy of
discipline with an object of research of its own. money (Simmel 1900).
Consequently, still for some time to come a disci- There were many others in Germany and
pline of economic sociology, based on explicitly Austria who contributed to a social view of the
sociological methods and object definitions did economy. Among them were some who paid
not exist. attention to promoting a sociological view of the
When sociology was mentioned, it was economy, but who are almost unknown in inter-
connected with widely divergent meanings. national sociology circles or in economic sociol-
Thus, the economists of the Menger-school, who ogy in particular (see Köster 2011). In order to
were members of René Worms’ Institut de look for reasons why Weber, Schumpeter, and
Sociologie, referred to sociology and understood Polanyi became classics of economic sociology,
it as a science of society with individualistic eco- we will briefly look at their work, their ideas on
nomic theory as the core. Friedrich Wieser saw the economy, and its relation to society, pointing
economic theory as a way of preparing for the out what is of special importance from the per-
development of sociology and paid great attention spective of economic sociology (Sect. 2). Then I
to power. Ludwig Mises identified marginal eco- will refer to the changes that occurred in the
nomic theory with sociology, which he under- understanding of economic sociology in the
stood as a metascience based on the logic of course of its development (Sect. 3). Finally, I
action (Wieser 1927; Mises 1949; Mikl-Horke will discuss the relevance of the classics for an
2008). Another group, that used the concept of economic sociology that meets the challenges of
sociology, was the thinkers who strove for the our time (Sect. 4).
2 Austrian and German Classics as a Foundation? 21

2 Weber, Schumpeter, study of social and economic objects. Throughout


and Polanyi on Economy his life, he retained a strong foundation of histori-
and Society cal insight, as well as an awareness of the
necessity of empirical analysis for causal expla-
Max Weber, Joseph A. Schumpeter, and Karl nation, while subjecting analysis to the overall
Polanyi, all of them from Central Europe, were goal of understanding the cultural meaning
economists, at least with regard to their education (Kulturbedeutung) of actions and institutions
and/or their institutional positions, even though which he (Weber 1988a) called understanding
their interests went far beyond economic sociology (verstehende Soziologie).
concerns. They all shared a background of histor- Weber’s view on economics was close to that
ical economics, were well aware of Marx and of the Austrian school’s approach, which
other socialist thoughts, and were educated in coincided with his individualistic orientation
Austrian economic theory. These influences regarding the conception of social and economic
shaped their thinking about the economy and its action, as being subjectively meaningful. Weber
relation to society without the need to work from did not aim at contributing to the development of
within an independent discipline of sociology. economic theory. Instead, he saw the cultural
meaning of actions, institutions, and of economic
theory in close relation with the rationalization
process of Occidental culture. That led him to
2.1 Max Weber place means-ends-rationality of action as the
idealtypically modern form of acting. Economic
Max Weber looms prominently as a classic of action was also social action in Weber’s view
economic sociology, to whom a tradition is which he understood as subjectively meaningful,
attributed (Swedberg 1998; Maurer 2010). That reacting either to others or to the norms and
seems justified on the grounds that he himself, in institutions of society.
his later years, often used the concept of sociol- Taking up the concept of capitalism from Karl
ogy and the expression of sociological categories Marx, Weber analyzed the historical development
of the economy (Weber 1976, 31 ff.). However, of economic business practices and organization,
we shall see that sociology had a special meaning from earlier forms to the emergence of modern
for him. industrial capitalism. The characteristics of mod-
Although rooted in the historical school of ern industrial capitalism were, in his view, the
Volkswirtschaftslehre and influenced by the inter- rational organization of labor and the formal
est he took in Marx’ work, Weber shared with the methods of capital accounting (see also
economists, of what was known as the Vienna or Chap. 18). In a historical and realistic way, he
Austrian school, an individualistic approach to showed how the social structures and institutions
the economy and an emphasis on subjectively had come into being. Weber’s basic outlook was
meaningful action. He was engaged in the meth- an idealistic interpretation of history, which led
odological disputes of his time and aimed at him to focus on the impact of religion on the
overcoming the separation between historical development of capitalism. While not totally
and theoretical methodologies. He saw explana- rejecting Marx’ materialist view, he showed the
tion (Erklären) and understanding (Verstehen) as secular impacts of the Protestant Ethic on the
both necessary for research, and placed special development of the spirit of capitalism. He
emphasis on the conceptual instrument of the undertook comparative studies of world religions
idealtypes. The influence of his friend, Heinrich and their implications for economic thinking and
Rickert, and his cultural science (Kulturwis- acting in order to be able to explain and under-
senschaft) was of great importance for Weber stand why modern capitalism developed in
regarding his methodological standpoint, but Europe and America.
also for the perspective, which he applied to the
22 G. Mikl-Horke

Weber was also aware of the changes that concepts. However, the historical development
capitalism and culture were undergoing in his and cultural meaning of modern capitalism are
time. The emergence and the effects of large central to his definitions of objects and problems
organizations and bureaucratic tendencies led of social science. In this sense, Weber referred to
him to questions concerning the future develop- social economics (Sozialökonomik) and its objec-
ment of capitalism and of modern culture gener- tive in the introduction to the economics series
ally. His historical orientation and his emphasis (Grundriß der Sozialökonomik), which he
on ideas made him understand that the changes in co-edited (Weber 1988b). In this essay, he also
the real world imply changes in perception and stressed a historical and realistic approach that
cognition, which have consequences for concep- represented his fundamental orientation of social
tualization in the social sciences, too. Social sci- science and which should constitute the basis for
ence must change together with the changes in the a science of reality (Wirklichkeitswissenschaft)
real world, which means, above all, that its (Weber 1988b, 170 f). The orientation towards a
concepts must be constantly reformulated. In his cultural science (Kulturwissenschaft) that
opinion, economic theory was a cognitive con- underlies his work had inspired many to under-
struction based on ideal assumptions, made pos- take studies of the cultural meaning of capitalism,
sible by the historical process of the highlighting certain values and ideas that charac-
rationalization of thought, which he understood terize modern culture.
as being the underlying force of modern Talcott Parsons has brought Weber’s work to
European history. However, as such, theory is the attention of American social scientists since
also a product of history and must change the 1930s. In his book on Weber’s conception of
together with the changes in the real constellation social and economic organization, he presented it
of economic and social conditions, as well as with as economic sociology (Parsons 1937a, 1947,
the changes in perception, cognition, and valua- 30 ff.). In the US context, the interpretation of
tion. However, in Weber’s time the process of the Weber’s work emphasized his individual action
rationalization of thought and culture was still approach and the conception of modern industrial
progressing, and he was aware that it could pro- capitalism as a social and rational form of
duce ambivalent effects; it could even result in the organization.
destruction of individual freedom and lead to an The attention given to Weber in the English-
increase of social inequality. speaking world helped to make him well-known
In Economy and Society (Wirtschaft und in the international academic community, in
Gesellschaft), which was posthumously arranged which the American social sciences became
and published by Weber’s wife, Marianne Weber, dominant.
and later on by Johannes Winckelmann, the word
sociology appears in the first two fundamental
chapters, which Weber had written later than the
2.2 Joseph A. Schumpeter
rest of the chapters. The first chapter on sociolog-
ical categories constitutes, for many scholars,
Joseph A. Schumpeter began his career as a stu-
Weber’s sociology. It is, however, a very special
dent of Austrian economic theory at the Univer-
understanding of sociology, which does not refer
sity of Vienna. From early on he had an interest in
to discussions that were going on during his
social and historical issues and pursued this in
lifetime about the meaning of sociology. It takes
many studies also throughout his life. The influ-
no notice of Durkheim’s, or anyone else’s
ence of Marx, Weber and of his mentor, Friedrich
conceptions of sociology, but presupposes a
Wieser,1 had great impact on Schumpeter’s think-
meaning of its own. In his later work, Weber
ing. He was also influenced by the equilibrium
placed great emphasis on conceptualization, so
that the term, sociological acquired the methodo-
1
logical meaning of a stricter formulation of He was successor to Menger’s chair in Vienna.
2 Austrian and German Classics as a Foundation? 23

theory of Leon Walras, and in his time in Harvard study to the Business Cycles (Schumpeter 1939).
he focused strongly on neoclassical theory and The historical transition from a commercial soci-
formal methods. This constituted a contrast to ety to a capitalist society occurred historically due
his social and historical interests, but also resulted to the establishment of institutions that were
in distancing him from the representatives of favorable to individual initiative and risk accep-
Austrian economics in the US, especially from tance, thus enabling innovations and the
Ludwig Mises. His work retained, nevertheless, unfolding of the creative capacity of capitalist
many traits which are of importance for Austrian entrepreneurs. Schumpeter was, however, ambiv-
economics as well, especially an emphasis on alent in his evaluation of economic development;
action, and an interest in the dynamics of the he pointed out that the ascent and descent of
economic process. groups, families and individuals, as well as
In the second edition of his early work, The changes in forms of living, working, and think-
Theory of Economic Development (Schumpeter ing, often lead to disruptive effects on the econ-
1926), Schumpeter argued that the foremost task omy and the society, but he saw these
of economics was to explain the internal dynam- consequences as unavoidable for the sake of the
ics of the economic process. He understood the dynamic development of capitalism.
concept of development not in the sense of a In his later diagnostic essay, Capitalism,
gradual evolutionary process, influenced by Socialism, and Democracy (Schumpeter 1942),
external factors. Capitalism develops, as he Schumpeter saw the institutions that had been
explained, from within, by the spontaneous and the basis for the development of capitalism,
discontinuous occurrence of new combinations of undergoing changes due to the mechanization of
the means of production, for example, by techni- progress, which made the innovative, creative
cal innovations, new goods, new markets, new role of the entrepreneur obsolete. He foresaw
forms of organization, and/or new ways of that the rationalization and functionalization of
financing. In spite of this focus on the inner forces large-scale modern enterprises must unavoidably
driving the capitalist economy, Schumpeter result in the transition to some kind of socialism.
admitted that social, political, cultural, and histor- In this sense, although his argument is based on a
ical circumstances play a role, but they enter the different evaluative perspective, it is reminiscent
scene through their impact on the entrepreneur, of Marx’s prediction of the self-destruction of
the agent of economic dynamism. The entrepre- capitalism due to its very success.
neur is a prominent figure in Schumpeter’s think- Regarding his conception of the relation of
ing. He is not a representative of a social class, as economics and sociology, he followed the neo-
the capitalist was for Marx, but stands for a type classical view of drawing a clear line between the
of behavior that is creative and risk-taking, but two fields. He was aware, however, that economic
also economizing and displays a capacity for theory is not an end in itself, but constitutes a
leadership. His behavior is characterized by basis for economic analysis, which is oriented
non-institutionalized actions, through which the toward practical purposes. This requires taking
individual entrepreneur can even become the findings of economic history, statistics, and
alienated from his social environment. economic sociology into account, which means
The emphasis on the dynamics of change led that he, like Jevons, saw economic sociology as
Schumpeter to take a critical stance towards one of the economic sciences. Schumpeter was
Marx’s closed conception of class. He argued conscious, as was Weber, of the conditions that
that in the course of economic development, the underlie the production and the effects of eco-
structure and the composition of classes change nomic knowledge, and of the influence of ideol-
constantly by the ascent of some individuals or ogy. He dedicated an unfinished chapter entitled,
families and the descent of others. Like Marx, he Sociology of Economics, to this problem in his
saw crises as the normal characteristics of the posthumously published History of Economic
capitalist process and dedicated a voluminous Analysis (1954, 33 ff.). Schumpeter’s reception
24 G. Mikl-Horke

in sociology was focused on his sociological texts claim of economists who saw the market as a
(see Schumpeter 1991). His economic works are sort of natural law or logical principle that is in
also of relevance in this respect, because his con- operation in all societies. Instead, he understood
ception of economic theory was not a conven- the market economy as an historical system that
tional one, even though he had embraced remains in existence only as long as liberalism
neoclassical theory and methods (see also dominates the political system. The existence of
Swedberg 1991b). the market, therefore, is dependent on political
decisions and does not come about by itself.
Polanyi attributed great influence to historical
2.3 Karl Polanyi conditions, events, and political actions in shap-
ing economic organization. He pursued this in
In the 1920s the future of capitalism and the path historical and anthropological studies, which
to socialism were widely discussed. One of the became his major lines of research after his emi-
young intellectuals interested in socialism and its gration to England, and later to America. In stud-
transition from capitalism was Karl Polanyi, who, ies of ancient trade in various parts of the world,
in a discussion on socialist accounting with the he showed that the market logic is not applicable
liberal economist Ludwig Mises, defended the to pre-modern societies. He explained that the
possibility of socialism (Polanyi 1924). He economy for most of human history was embed-
suggested a concept of functional socialism that ded in society, and that economic behavior was
was somehow close to Guild socialist ideas, but inseparable from social, religious, and political
also contained insights into the functional differ- worldviews, values, and practices (Polanyi et al.
entiation of modern society, which later became a 1957). Land, labor, and money, then, did not
fundamental conception of sociology. In follow a special economic rationality, nor was
Polanyi’s opinion, the conflict of interest in the the economy represented by distinct institutions
economy does not lead to the development of or structures. Economic actions in premodern
antagonistic classes, pitted against each other, as societies were embedded in the forms of living,
Marx had described. Instead of a conflict between centered on the household as an economic, social,
different classes or groups, he perceived a conflict and emotional organization, or took place in the
between different positions or interests, which all context of reciprocal relationships or redistribu-
people have in common, namely, that of tive hierarchies. Markets, where they existed in
producers on one hand and consumers on the premodern societies, were local affairs, and
other hand, both sharing common goals. In his non-economic rituals, rules, and emotions
vision of a functional society, the goal of the pervaded the dealings.
economy is to achieve maximum productivity of The transition to market society brought a
goods, as well as to pursue social productivity disruption into this state of affairs and led to a
measured in terms of the common good and of reversal of the relation between society and the
social rights. Therefore, he argued that social economy by embedding society in the economy.
costs, caused by institutionalizing social rights, For the market to become systemic, as Polanyi
must enter into socialist accounting. concluded, economic rationality must become
Polanyi’s most well-known work is The Great distinct from other motives and ways of thinking.
Transformation (Polanyi 1944), in which he To turn land, labor, and capital into commodities
investigated the causes for the development of a and make the market into a mechanism, which
market economy in nineteenth century England. encompassed the whole of society, required a
This, he argued, came about through dis-embed- change in the way of thinking about the economy.
ding land, labor, and capital from their social and This came about when liberal economic theory,
cultural contexts by legal means and by political with its formal-logical model of the market,
decisions, and thereby gradually transforming replaced the substantivist perception of the econ-
society into a market society. He rejected the omy as the livelihood of man (Polanyi 1977). This
2 Austrian and German Classics as a Foundation? 25

emphasis on the effects of thinking demonstrates cultural meaning of economic phenomena.


that Polanyi attributed a strong performative Schumpeter explicitly referred to economic soci-
effect to theory for making the economy. ology in his History of Economic Analysis as one
Polanyi argued that in the real life of the peo- of the contextual disciplines within the group of
ple in modern societies the non-logical economic sciences. Polanyi turned to historical
dimensions are still present. This forces and anthropological studies of the economy but
individuals to live and act in two worlds, in one did not expressly aim at an economic sociology.
of market conditions and market logic, and in the All three, and many more in the same period,
other, dedicated to the concerns of everyday life. combined economic and social elements based
Polanyi pleaded for a return to a substantivist on an understanding of economics that included
understanding of the economy and for the recog- social, cultural, and historical elements.
nition of the embeddedness of economic actions In the first half of the twentieth century, there
in social, political, and everyday conditions. He were discussions taking place on the relation
emphasized the historically limited relevance of between economics and sociology, mostly under
market logic and saw another Great Transforma- the heading of socioeconomics or social econom-
tion under way, by which labor, as well as capital ics as a combinatory field (Åkerman 1938;
would have a say in economic decisions, thus Sombart 1930). Adolph Lowe called his concep-
introducing democracy into economic relations tion of a synthetic science based on middle
(Polanyi 2014, 214 ff.). principles, i.e., time-space related constructs
Polanyi had pointed to the difference between from both disciplines, economic sociology
premodern and modern societies and had (Lowe 1935). It should bridge the widening gap
challenged the claim of the general applicability between economics and sociology as the latter
of market logic, which he attributed only to the gradually acquired academic recognition. To pur-
modern economy (Polanyi 1968). In this analysis, sue this goal, he founded The American Journal
he did not differ fundamentally from Weber and of Economics and Sociology, together with Franz
Schumpeter. All three were conscious of the his- Oppenheimer in 1941. He was known among
torical relativity of economic thinking and orga- historians of economics as one of the reform
nization, as well as of the important role of ideas, economists, who sought to combine market the-
including scientific logic. Polanyi placed the ory with a socialist orientation. Lowe is, however,
economy in a wider context of time and hardly remembered today as one of the founders
differences of culture and ideological of economic sociology. His conception of eco-
preconditions, as Weber had, and he specially nomic sociology was that of a practical, political
emphasized political decisions and actions. In social science that combines structural and instru-
the 1960s, therefore, his work became the object mental analyses. In the US, sociology was devel-
of discussion among those within the political oping in a different way from what Lowe
sciences. In economic sociology, the relevance intended. This became clear in Talcott Parsons’
of Polanyi was recognized when criticism of neo- review of Lowe’s Economics and Sociology
liberalism set in and modern capitalism spread (Parsons 1937b). Although Parsons also intended
worldwide. to link economic and social theory, it was with
another aim in mind, that is, to develop a meta-
field of action sciences (Parsons 1937b; Parsons
3 The Changing Character and Smelser 1956). Lowe, henceforth, spoke of
of Economic Sociology political economy and not anymore of economic
sociology (Lowe 1965). However, for a long time
Weber used the concept of economic sociology, in Europe, economic sociology was still seen as a
but he referred also to social economics, symbiotic field of economics and sociology with
connecting the former with a conceptually stricter the aim of providing information for the decisions
approach, the latter with a broader view of the in economic policy (Fürstenberg 1956, 406).
26 G. Mikl-Horke

Sociology, as it gained recognition and aca- (Granovetter 1985). This differs from the concept
demic status, and introduced the American con- of Polanyi and came along at first without refer-
ception of empirical social science, turned away ence to his work. Embeddedness referred to a
from the traditionally close relation with eco- microsocial network approach and became in
nomic science, as well as from a practical, politi- this sense one of the core concepts of new eco-
cal orientation. Intent to prove its scientific nomic sociology. The emergence of
objectivity, sociology was focused on the theoret- neo-institutionalism also had an impact on eco-
ical construction of society as an object of its nomic sociology by adding normative, cultural,
own, in which the economy played a minor part and cognitive perspectives to the embeddedness
as an object of research, and from which history of markets (DiMaggio and Powell 1991). The
and polity were excluded. Another reason why outlook extended beyond the microsocial study
sociologists paid little attention to the economy of markets to embrace institutional, political, and
had to do with the highly formalized theory and comparative elements. However, in much of new
research in economics that made it difficult for economic sociology, the understanding of
non-economists to deal with economic aspects. institutions is that of neo-institutionalism and
For several decades after World War II, economic focuses on decision-making and on the organiza-
sociology, where it existed as an academic field, tional development of firms. Comparative studies
either dealt with the non-economic aspects in the of business systems or of the Varieties of Capi-
economy or focused on redundant criticism of talism caught the attention of many in the field of
their exclusion in neoclassical economic theory. economic sociology (Whitley 1992; Hall and
The core subjects of modern economy, as they Soskice 2001). This broadened the microsocial
figure in neoclassical economics, that is, the mar- orientation of new economic sociology, however,
ket, prices, competition, to mention a few, how- without relinquishing methodological individual-
ever, were not touched. ism, which constitutes an analogy to
The change in the political climate in the UK microeconomic the predominance within eco-
and the USA of the late 1970s and the 1980s, nomic theory (Beckert 1996). The concentration
which promoted a Chicago school view of a lib- on markets, moreover, seems to identify the econ-
eral market economy, influenced by the neoliber- omy with the market and private enterprise econ-
alism of the Mises-Hayek version of Austrian omy (Beckert 2003). There were studies on the
economics, brought a renewal of interest in eco- public sector, the household economy, the third
nomic sociology (Baron and Hannan 1994). As sector of nongovernmental and/or non-profit
the market advanced into the focus of public and organizations, the shadow economy, and even
political perspectives, sociologists felt it increas- on non-economic fields like culture, politics, reli-
ingly unsatisfactory to restrict their research to the gion, emotions, but this resulted often in seeing
contextual aspects of the economy. Instead, they these fields as markets. Criticism from those who
ventured to undertake a genuinely sociological do not want to look at the economy from a market
explanation of markets (Burt 1992; Granovetter and business perspective, led to introducing
1985; White 1981). This brought forth new eco- Polanyi’s alternative conception of
nomic sociology, spreading internationally from embeddedness, as well as recognizing the impor-
its origin in the US. It aimed at showing markets tance of his work for economic sociology
as constellations of social relations using the (Krippner 2001; Krippner et al. 2004). The field
method of network analysis (White 2002), studies of economic sociology was broadened by a new
of social structure and an individualistic concep- interest in the works of the classics, of Weber,
tion of economic action (Dobbin 2004; Guillèn Schumpeter, and Polanyi, and others who had
et al. 2002; Granovetter 1985, 2002). The concept applied a historical and transdisciplinary view to
of embeddedness that appeared in some of these the relation between economy and society. Mark
studies means that economic actions are seen as Granovetter, in particular, also integrated histori-
elements of the social structure of markets cal and anthropological dimensions (Granovetter
2 Austrian and German Classics as a Foundation? 27

2002). By returning to the study of the classics political, and cultural situation. If we look at
their relevance for the tradition of economic soci- their work, we must ask, in what way it can be
ology was established (Beckert and Zafirovski relevant for economic sociology today beyond its
2006; Granovetter and Swedberg 2001; Smelser historiographical interest. Economic sociology
and Swedberg 2005; Zafirovski 1999). today must tackle situations that are quite differ-
The main theme of Weber, Schumpeter, and ent both in the real world and in the social
Polanyi had been the development, the sciences. The concept of the economy, as it has
consequences and the future of capitalism or the evolved by the processes of industrialization,
market system respectively, and this concern had rationalization, and modernization to become
lingered on in discussions in Europe. In the 1990s modern Western capitalism, is being challenged
in the wake of the disintegration of the Soviet currently, but not by the transition to a bureau-
Union and the transformation of the successor cratic or socialist society, as Weber, Schumpeter,
states, the discussion about the future of capital- and others had thought. In the focus of the social
ism and its different forms was revived and sciences today are processes such as the transfor-
became a topic even in the USA, where the term mation of socialist economies into market
had previously had little meaning, being used as a economies in Central and Eastern Europe within
synonym for the market economy. Instead, stud- only a few decades (see also Chap. 12), or the
ies on capitalism and its changes were taken up transition processes in many parts of the world,
once again, mostly in the field of political changing traditional forms of economic behavior
sciences and political economy, but also in eco- to fit into a global capitalist system, as well as the
nomic sociology (e.g., Beckert 2016; Nee and counter-tendencies of nationalism and protection-
Swedberg 2005; Streeck 2016). ism. The conditions underlying, forming, and
After World War II, economic sociology was a changing the economy then and now differ
peripheral study within the discipline of sociol- greatly, but in both cases, there are profound,
ogy, concerned with the non-economic elements manifold, and often contradictory or ambivalent
in the economy or the application of sociological processes to consider.
concepts to economic phenomena. It gained new The globalization of production, trade, and
recognition by claiming to provide a sociological communication has changed some of the
theory of markets, thereby, dispelling the notion preconditions of economic organization. It has
of the self-regulating mechanism of the market by spread the practices and institutions of modern
showing that it is people and their actions, which capitalism on a worldwide scale. They often
make the markets, while at the same time focus- have disruptive effects on traditional economic
ing too much on markets and their microsocial practices and forms of living, sometimes leading
structure. In recent decades and under the impact to conflicts in which economic, social, political,
of globalization discourses, the pendulum swung and cultural-ideological elements mingle. The
back to concerns that had been already in the global expansion of Western forms of economy
center of interest at the beginning of the twentieth and society has led to responses emphasizing
century, that is, the changing character of modern differences of institutional, social, political, and
capitalism, the transformation of society, and the cultural conditions, but it has also led to criticism
cultural meaning of new developments. of and antagonism towards Western capitalism.
The Western way of working, of dealing with one
another, of organizing has come under critique,
4 The Relevance of the Classics and also the whole conception of scientific think-
ing, including the social sciences, is being
Weber, Schumpeter, and Polanyi were influenced challenged.
by the economic, social, and political situation of Huge multinational enterprises and powerful
their times, the methodological and scientific global internet firms control the field of competi-
discussions, and their perception of the social, tion globally. This has led to the diminishing
28 G. Mikl-Horke

power of the nation states over the economy, to Reading the works of the classics one gets the
which also the increase in the swiftness of finan- impression that they were driven by the desire to
cial transactions in the global markets for money understand what was going on in their time and
and capital has contributed. Schumpeter had society. It is perhaps this quality, which still
already seen the financial sector as the apex of makes reading their works so interesting. The
modern capitalism. Today the process of classic authors were not naïve as to the possibility
financialization has reached a level that of cognition of reality. They were certainly con-
endangers the real economy by unleashing an scious of the relativity and reflexivity of concepts,
increasingly wider gap of economic inequality. but they assumed a reality out there. Realism, for
The dynamism of capitalism resulting from the them, meant striving for cognition of the real
unrelenting striving for economic growth world by means of social science and possibly
endangers the environment and makes our planet approaching, though never reaching it. A realistic
less habitable for many people (see also science means finding questions corresponding to
Chap. 18). On the other hand, the conception of the changes and problems perceived, and chang-
the economy is gradually changing from a ing concepts and methods accordingly. There-
restricted one, concentrating on markets, firms fore, social science must be based on studies of
and business systems to a more varied perception, history, not in the sense of focusing on the past,
which takes diverse forms of economies, some but in the sense of paying attention to the pro-
traditional, some criminal, and some based on cesses that shape the future. Sociology must
solidarity into account. regain its historical orientation, which it has lost
What we mean by the concept of society has since the time of the classics, in spite of some
changed considerably because of the develop- recent revival of a historical sociology (see Mikl-
ment of worldwide, electronic communication Horke 2011, 13 ff.).
networks (social media) and the impact of digita- Taking history into consideration means
lization on the lives, relations, and perceptions of focusing on time processes, on events and
people. The increasing inequality, the persistence changes, and their consequences. The focus on
of poverty, the unemployment of many young structures cannot grasp the reality of the present
people, as well as the post-democratic, post-colo- that is only an imagined entity between past and
nial, or post-modern movements and the develop- future. Since high-speed changes and unforeseen
ment of new global conflicts on ideological, events seem to characterize our time more than
religious, and cultural grounds, the rise of nation- the time of the classics, the attention attributed to
alism and protectionism, have turned the econ- social structure must be complemented by
omy and societies into contested terrains. acknowledging processes and how they shape
Sociology cannot deal with all those problems, and change present conditions, as well as the
but it equally cannot content itself to focus only expectations for the future. The real social world
on its professionalism, on standardized methods is not presenting a consistent picture, because
of research and publication, on networking for there are contradicting elements and divergent
academic institutional success. This invariably perspectives pervading reality at any point in
places more focus on concepts, theories, and time. Reality, as well as its perception, is ambiva-
methods of research as an end in themselves, lent. The classics were aware of the ambivalence
and leads to losing sight of reality. of reality. Social science must take this into con-
In Weber’s view concepts and theories were sideration again and leave space for uncertainty.
instruments or guidelines to approach reality; A historical-realistic approach to society and
they were not ends in themselves. This was also economy leads to a broad view that does not stop
true for Schumpeter, apart from his more formal, at the frontiers of disciplines, for which the
theoretical works. Polanyi’s demand to return to a classics provide good examples. Weber is
substantivist way of thinking and speaking about claimed to be a classic by quite a number of
the economy reflects this realistic attitude. disciplines, from legal history, economic history,
2 Austrian and German Classics as a Foundation? 29

political science, the science of religion, to soci- survival and well-being of humanity, or better, of
ology. Schumpeter’s work touches on a wide all people on this earth, and, if possible, in coop-
range of fields from history, economics, social eration with them. To this end, economic sociol-
psychology, to sociology. Polanyi was combining ogy as a part of a developing global social
political issues, social themes, economic history, science, must be undertaken and must allow for
and economic anthropology. the discovery of ideas that can contribute to solv-
Currently in the social sciences, there is a ing the problems of our time by taking history and
growing recognition that the clear separation of the future into consideration.
disciplines is not conducive to solving the
problems of a changing society that is becoming
increasingly more complex, diverse, and References
dynamic. This results in demands for interdisci-
plinary studies and discourses, which in practice, Åkerman, J. H. (1938). Das Problem der sozialöko-
nomischen Synthese. Lund: Gleerup.
however, prove difficult because of the closure of
Baron, J. N., & Hannan, M. T. (1994). The impact of
theoretical languages. In this sense it is indeed economics on contemporary sociology. Journal of
necessary to Open the Social Sciences Economic Literature, 32, 1111–1146.
(Wallerstein et al. 1996). The call for interdisci- Beckert, J. (1996). What is sociological about economic
sociology? Uncertainty and the embeddedness of eco-
plinary studies has led again to discussions about
nomic action. Theory and Society, 25, 803–840.
the relationship between economics and sociol- Beckert, J. (2003). Beyond the market. The social
ogy, often under the heading of socioeconomics. foundations of economic efficiency. Princeton:
In the current, complex, global, social, and eco- Princeton University Press.
Beckert, J. (2016). Imagined futures. Fictional
nomic situation and its manifold interrelations
expectations and capitalist dynamics. Cambridge,
with social, political, cultural, ideological, tech- MA: Harvard University Press.
nological, and communication-related aspects, Beckert, J., & Zafirovski, M. (Eds.). (2006). International
social research must reach out farther and engage encyclopedia of economic sociology. London:
Routledge.
in exchanges with political economy, the political
Biggart, N. W. (Ed.). (2002). Readings in economic soci-
sciences, anthropology, and the historical ology. Malden, MA: Blackwell.
sciences, and moreover, with voices from the Burt, R. S. (1992). Structural holes. The social structure of
real world. competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
When we turn to the classics for guidance, we
DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (1991). The new institution-
cannot find it in the objects addressed or the alism in organizational analysis. Chicago: Chicago
problems raised, but rather in their historical con- University Press.
sciousness, their realistic perspectives, and their Dobbin, F. (Ed.). (2004). The new economic sociology: A
reader. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
wide range of interests that enabled an implicitly
Fürstenberg, F. (1956). Die soziologische Dimension
transdisciplinary approach, as well as in their wirtschaftstheoretischer Aussagen. Zeitschrift für die
recognition of the ambivalence of reality. In this gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 112(3), 398–409.
way their approaches can enable us to see how Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic backwardness in his-
torical perspective. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer-
our world and the perception of it have changed
sity Press.
and are changing, and how we can come closer to Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social struc-
grasping some instances of the reality of our own ture: The problem of Embeddedness. American Jour-
world. nal of Sociology, 91, 481–510.
Granovetter, M. (2002). A theoretical agenda for economic
Tackling the relation between economic and
sociology. In M. F. Guillèn et al. (Eds.), The new
social aspects of reality under the heading of economic sociology (pp. 35–59). New York: Russell
economic sociology means not so much applying Sage Foundation.
sociological concepts, theories, and methods, but Granovetter, M., & Swedberg, R. (Eds.). (2001). The
sociology of economic life (2nd ed.). Boulder:
taking a social stand towards the economy. This
Westview Press.
means remembering that the ultimate goal of sci- Guillèn, M. F., et al. (Eds.). (2002). The new economic
ence is to serve the livelihood of man, that is, the sociology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
30 G. Mikl-Horke

Hall, P. A., & Soskice, D. (2001). Varieties of capitalism. Polanyi, K., et al. (Eds.). (1957). Trade and markets in the
Oxford: Oxford University Press. early empires. Glencoe: Free Press.
Jevons, W. S. (1879). The theory of political economy (2nd Schumpeter, J. A. (1926 [1911]). Theorie der
ed.). New York: Kelley. wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (2nd ed.). Leipzig:
Köster, R. (2011). Die Wissenschaft der Außenseiter. Duncker & Humblot.
Göttingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht. Schumpeter, J. A. (1926 [1939]). Business cycles. A theo-
Krippner, G. (2001). The elusive market: Embeddedness retical, historical and statistical analysis of the capi-
and the paradigm of economic sociology. Theory and talist process. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Society, 30, 775–810. Schumpeter, J. A. (1926 [1942]). Capitalism, socialism
Krippner, G., et al. (2004). Polanyi symposium: A conver- and democracy. New York: Harper.
sation on embeddedness. Socio-Economic Review, 2, Schumpeter, J. A. (1926 [1954]). History of economic
109–135. analysis. London: Allen & Unwin.
Lebaron, F. (2001). Bases of a sociological economy: Schumpeter, J. A. (1926 [1991]). In R. Swedberg (Ed.),
From François Simiand and Maurice Halbwachs to The economics and sociology of capitalism. Princeton:
Pierre Bourdieu. International Journal of Contempo- Princeton University Press.
rary Sociology, 38, 54–63. Simmel, G. (1900). Philosophie des Geldes. Leipzig:
Lowe, A. (1935). Economics and sociology. London: Duncker & Humblot.
Allen & Unwin. Smelser, N. J., & Swedberg, R. (Eds.). (2005). The hand-
Lowe, A. (1965). On economic knowledge. Toward a sci- book of economic sociology (2nd ed.). New York and
ence of political economics. New York: Harper & Row. Princeton: Russel Sage Foundation and Princeton Uni-
Maurer, A. (Ed.). (2010). Wirtschaftssoziologie nach versity Press.
Max Weber. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sombart, W. (1930). Nationalökonomie und Soziologie.
Sozialwissenschaften. Jena: Fischer.
Mikl-Horke, G. (2008). Austrian economics and economic Streeck, W. (2016). How will capitalism end? Essays on a
sociology. Socio-Economic Review, 6, 201–226. failing system. London: Verso.
Mikl-Horke, G. (2011). Historische Soziologie–– Swedberg, R. (1991a). Major traditions of economic soci-
Sozioökonomie––Wirtschaftssoziologie. Wiesbaden: ology. Annual Review of Sociology, 17, 251–276.
VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften. Swedberg, R. (1991b). Introduction: The man and his
Mises, L. (1949). Human action. A treatise on economics. work. In J. A. Schumpeter (Ed.), The economics and
Hodge: London. sociology of capitalism (pp. 3–98). Princeton:
Nee, V., & Swedberg, R. (Eds.). (2005). The economic Princeton University Press.
sociology of capitalism. Princeton: Princeton Univer- Swedberg, R. (Ed.). (1996). Economic sociology.
sity Press. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Neef, K. (2012). Die Entstehung der Soziologie aus der Swedberg, R. (1998). Max Weber and the idea of eco-
Sozialreform. Frankfurt: Campus. nomic sociology. Princeton: Princeton University
Parsons, T. (1937a). The structure of social action. Press.
New York: McGraw-Hill. Swedberg, R. (2003). Principles of economic sociology.
Parsons, T. (1937b). Book review: Economics and sociol- Princeton: Princeton University Press.
ogy by Adolf Löwe. American Journal of Sociology, Trigilia, C. (2002). Economic sociology: State, market,
43, 477–481. and society in modern capitalism. Oxford: Blackwell.
Parsons, T. (1947). Weber’s ‘economic sociology’. Intro- Wallerstein, I., et al. (1996). Open the social sciences.
duction. In T. Parsons (Ed.), Max Weber. The theory of Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
social and economic organization (pp. 30–56). Weber, M. (1976 [1922]). Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft.
New York: Hodge. Grundriß der verstehenden Soziologie (5th ed.).
Parsons, T., & Smelser, N. J. (1956). Economy and soci- Tübingen: Mohr. [Weber, Max. 1978 [1921]. Econ-
ety: A study in the integration of economic and social omy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology.
theory. New York: Free Press. Edited by Guenther Roth et al. Berkeley CA: Univer-
Polanyi, K. (1924). Die funktionelle Theorie der sity of California Press; Weber, Max. 2019. Economy
Gesellschaft und das Problem der sozialistischen and society. A new translation. Edited by Keith Tribe.
Rechnungslegung. Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.].
Sozialpolitik, 52, 218–228. Weber, M. (1988a). Über einige Kategorien der
Polanyi, K. (1944). The great transformation. New York: verstehenden Soziologie. In M. Weber (Ed.),
Farrar & Rinehart. Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Wissenschaftslehre (7th ed.,
Polanyi, K. (1968). In G. Dalton (Ed.), Primitive, archaic pp. 427–474). Tübingen: Mohr. [Weber, Max 1949:
and modern economies . Essays. Garden City: Anchor. The Methodology of the Social Sciences. Edited by
Polanyi, K. (1977). In H. W. Pearson (Ed.), The livelihood Edward H. Shils and Henry A. Finch. New York: Free
of man. New York: Academic. Press.].
Polanyi, K. (2014). In G. Resta & M. Catanzariti (Eds.), Weber, M. (1988b). Die ‘Objektivität’ sozialwis-
For a new west. Essays, 1919–58. Cambridge: Polity senschaftlicher und sozialpolitischer Erkenntnis. In
Press. M. Weber (Ed.), Gesammelte Aufsätze zur
2 Austrian and German Classics as a Foundation? 31

Wissenschaftslehre (7th ed., pp. 146–214). Tübingen: Gertraude Mikl-Horke is a retired professor of general
Mohr. [Weber, Max 1949: The methodology of the and economic sociology at the Vienna University of Eco-
social sciences. Edited by Edward H. Shils and Henry nomics and Business Research topics: History of the social
A. Finch. New York: Free Press.]. sciences with special emphasis on Austria, social econom-
White, H. C. (1981). Where do markets come from? ics, economic sociology, industrial sociology, Japanese
American Journal of Sociology, 87, 517–547. society, and labor relations. Recent publications: Mikl-
White, H. C. (2002). Markets from networks. Socioeco- Horke, Gertraude. 2018. Zur Aktualität der Finanzso-
nomic models of production. Princeton: Princeton Uni- ziologie Rudolf Goldscheids. In Aktuelle Probleme der
versity Press. Finanzsoziologie, ed. Max Haller. Wien and Münster:
Whitley, R. (Ed.). (1992). European business systems. LIT. Mikl-Horke, Gertraude. 2017. Die Österreichische
Firms and markets in their national contexts. Schule der Nationalökonomie und die Wirtschaftsso-
London: Sage. ziologie. In Schlüsselwerke der Wirtschaftssoziologie,
Wieser, F. (1927). Social economics. New York: Adelphi. ed. Klaus Kraemer, and Florian Brugger, 135–44.
Zafirovski, M. (1999). Economic sociology in retrospect Wiesbaden: Springer VS. Mikl-Horke, Gertraude. 2011.
and prospect: In search of its identity within economics Historische Soziologie––Sozioökonomie––Wirtschaftsso-
and sociology. The American Journal of Economics ziologie. Wiesbaden: Springer VS. Mikl-Horke,
and Sociology, 58, 583–627. Gertraude.
James Coleman, Social Capital,
and Economic Sociology 3
Peter V. Marsden

I appreciate helpful comments from Derick Baum, Maleah Fekete, Mary Ellen Marsden,
and editor Andrea Maurer.

Foundations of Social Theory (Coleman 1990; Coleman’s conceptualization of social capital


hereafter FST) was the principal intellectual proj- is a key element of FST; broadly cast, it regards
ect of James S. Coleman’s long and distinguished social capital as any aspect of social structure that
career in social science, notwithstanding his can be employed as a resource toward the attain-
extensive and enduring impacts on other fields ment of valued ends. A quarter century after his
including education, mathematical sociology, death, Coleman’s (1988a) article about social
organization studies and social policy. FST’s the- capital has drawn more attention from other
oretical framework is rooted in the assumption scholars than any other of his many works; as of
that social phenomena are the outcome of early 2020 it had been cited more than 50,000
interactions among goal-oriented, self-interested times according to Google Scholar estimates.
actors situated within social contexts that shape Together with other related conceptualizations
and modify their actions. Coleman’s broadly of social capital, Coleman’s work has prompted
conceived rational choice approach sought to very rapid growth in research about both
incorporate and explain those settings, rather predictors and consequences of aspects of social
than assuming them away as some other models capital (Kwon and Adler 2014). This chapter
based on similar individual-level postulates do reviews Coleman’s ideas about social capital in
(see also Chap. 4). This framework served as his the context of FST, situates them within his
point of departure for analyzing sociological phe- empirical work on education, and provides
nomena; he also hoped that it would encourage selected illustrations of their use by researchers
better understanding of problems in economics by who study economic and organizational sociol-
directing attention to constraints that social struc- ogy. Different forms of social capital may
tural conditions impose on them (Coleman advance the fortunes of individual entrepreneurs
1994a). Coleman had a special interest in micro- or workers, as well as of organizations/firms and
to-macro problems in which multiple interdepen- collaborations among them.
dent individual actions combine in some manner
to produce a collective outcome, viewing these as
the most important and difficult problems for 1 Social Capital Defined
social science (Coleman 1986).
The expansive definition of social capital offered
by Coleman (1988a, 98) is that it “. . . is defined
P. V. Marsden (*)
Department of Sociology, Harvard University, by its function. It is not a single entity but a
Cambridge, MA, USA variety of different entities, with two elements in
e-mail: pvm@wjh.harvard.edu

# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 33


A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_3
34 P. V. Marsden

common: they all consist of some aspect of social Other sociologists employ understandings of
structures, and they facilitate certain actions of social capital suggesting, at least implicitly, that
actors . . . within the structure.” The reference to its scope is limited to informal elements of social
social structures indicates that social capital organization comprised of social network
resides in some sort of social relationship among channels.2 Lin and Erickson (2008, 4), for exam-
actors. Coleman later (1994a, 175) explains that ple, refer to “resources embedded in social
in using the term capital he refers to “a resource relations and social networks,” and Cook (2005,
or factor input that facilitates production, but is 8) advocates a similar definition. These authors
not consumed or otherwise used up.” His remark contend that their more specific definitions facili-
that social capital facilitates certain actions tate theoretical development and empirical work,
acknowledges its limited domain of applicability, in particular by making falsification possible. In
and he grants that—depending on circumstances the same vein, Burt (2005, 4) defines social capi-
within particular settings—social structural forms tal as “[t]he advantage created by a person’s loca-
can be liabilities as well as assets: “[a] given form tion in a structure of relationships,” suggesting
of social capital that is valuable in facilitating that research should focus on discerning the spe-
certain actions may be useless or even harmful cific network mechanisms involved; he identifies
for others” (Coleman 1988a, 98). He recognized brokerage (open networks) and closure (closed
that the social relations undergirding social capi- ones) as two of special importance.
tal are not unconditionally beneficial, referring at These definitions are largely aligned with one
times (e.g., Coleman 1988b, 14) to an overabun- another, apart from Coleman’s inclusion of for-
dance of social capital in past societies that cre- mal organizations—which certainly can be
ated oppressive social controls and normative conceived as networks—within the scope of
pressures that could stifle innovation. He also social capital (see also Burt 2005, 5). Many of
acknowledges social capital’s contingent effec- the specific forms of social capital Coleman
tiveness when he observes that solidary ties in identifies (e.g., norms, trust) depend in part on
closely-knit communities might “entangl the presence of specific patterns of network
[e] potential entrepreneurs in a net of obligations relationships. Coleman’s concept insists that
that keeps them hobbled to the past” in settings social capital arises only when networks assume
where a traditionalist ethic prevails (Coleman a form useful toward pursuing some end. Includ-
1994a, 176). ing organizations within the scope of social capi-
Elsewhere, Coleman (1988c, 392) describes tal was crucial given the prominent place that
social capital as “most generally, social organiza- Coleman accorded to deliberately-designed social
tion, including both the informal organization of structures in the project that led to FST. Indeed,
the sort described in the case of communities and he anticipates his later definition of social capital
formal organization.” Many of his examples refer when referring to organizations (corporate
to processes of informal organization,1 but his actors) as “vehicles through which [individual
social capital concept clearly encompasses any persons] could express and use their new-found
element of social structure that can further the power” (Coleman 1974, 27).3
capacity to act. Indeed, its informal and formal
elements can augment one another, as for exam- 2
See Adler and Kwon (2002, 20) for numerous other
ple when informal adaptations within formal
definitions. Putnam (2000, 19 f.) calls attention to repeated
organizational designs at once provide inventions of social capital, stating that “Coleman put the
individuals with certain advantages and improve term firmly and finally on the intellectual agenda.” Trigilia
organizational performance (e.g., Blau 1981). (2001, 428) makes a similar observation; see also Lin
(2001, Chap. 2).
3
Putnam (2000) regards voluntary associations as impor-
1
In Coleman (1994a, 170) he limits social capital to “any tant indicators of social capital that can contribute to civic
aspect of informal social organization that constitutes a engagement. Individual-group (two-mode) networks offer
productive resource.” a suitable approach to representing affiliations with
3 James Coleman, Social Capital, and Economic Sociology 35

Coleman was certainly aware of the breadth claim that these forms are exhaustive. A reflection
and generality of his social capital concept. He on his thinking about social capital (Sandefur and
thought its wide scope helped advance his objec- Laumann 1998) takes a different route to
tive of constructing theory that integrates rational illustrating the concept’s heterogeneity by
action assumptions with social structural settings. distinguishing different types of benefits it may
He writes (Coleman 1990, 304 f.) that his concep- offer: access to information, a capacity to influ-
tion of social capital groups together and blurs ence or control others, and social solidarity.
distinctions among several processes discussed
elsewhere in FST (see below). He notes its multi-
level applicability: “[social capital] aids in both 2.1 Trust
accounting for different outcomes at the level of
individual actors and making the micro-to-macro In FST (1990, Chaps. 5, 8), Coleman conceives of
transitions without elaborating the social- trust as a decision under risk, in which one party
structural details.” He regarded it as a useful tool (trustor) allows a second (trustee) to use some
for studies that employ qualitative indicators and resources without immediately receiving com-
analyses, expressing uncertainty as to its utility in pensation, in the expectation that the eventual
quantitative research. While he acknowledges gain from doing so will exceed the anticipated
that research might reasonably seek to understand loss incurred. He likens the trustor’s extension of
details of how resources residing in social struc- trust to issuing a credit slip or promissory note,
ture come to be useful, that was not his principal observing that it creates a reciprocal obligation on
concern; he seems to have viewed the idea pri- the part of the trustee.
marily as an interpretive device. Trust arises, then, in uncertain situations in
Apart from social capital’s potential—often in which any returns to the trustor materialize at
combination with other resources including some point in time after s/he transfers the
human and financial capital—to contribute to resources to the trustee. Uncertainties may exist
achieving valued ends, its relational locus, and over the magnitude of the gains and losses
the recognition that it may be effective only in involved, but Coleman contends that the trustor’s
certain domains, Coleman’s discussion also principal challenge lies in estimating the proba-
draws a distinction between structural and func- bility that the trustee will perform in good faith
tional aspects of social capital. Structural ones after the trustor relinquishes her/his resources.
refer to the presence of relationships (e.g., the The greater the absolute difference between the
formal designation of senior or peer mentors for estimated gain and the anticipated loss, the more
newly hired employees), functional ones to the crucial it is that the trustor make a high-quality
operational quality of those channels (e.g., the assessment of the probability that trust will be
frequency and depth of mentoring conversations). maintained. Alluding to loss aversion, Coleman
contends that potential trustors tend to overesti-
mate trustworthiness when the ratio of gains to
2 Some Forms of Social Capital losses is high and understate it when losses are
large relative to gains.
Coleman’s expository statements about social Numerous circumstances can affect the
capital (1988a, 1990) ground the idea via trustor’s assessment of a potential trustee, includ-
discussing several specific forms that it assumes. ing information disseminated by the latter. Sev-
All are rooted in underlying social relationships eral features of social relationships and social
arranged such that goal-oriented actors may settings can be key supports for trust. Ordinarily,
employ them productively. Coleman does not though not invariably (Smith 2005), trust will be
greater in stronger relationships than in weaker
organizations as network-based social capital (e.g., ones; a history of exchanges between two parties
Burchard and Cornwell 2018). certainly enables the trustor to make a more
36 P. V. Marsden

nuanced assessment of a potential trustee’s reli- diamond merchants to privately inspect expensive
ability, and often a relationship will not have goods prior to purchasing them, without
become strong unless the parties to it offer at providing bonds or other guarantees (Coleman
least some signs indicative of their trustworthi- 1988a). This occurred within a closely-knit,
ness to one another. Reciprocal relationships in ethno-religiously homogenous community in
which parties have mutual obligations to one which dense relationships and frequent interac-
another likewise promote trust. Relationships tion among members substituted for more cum-
entailing repeated exchange—as distinct from bersome formal insurance devices. Among other
one-time transactions—can increase a trustee’s exemplars (Coleman 1984) are long-term
incentive to prove trustworthy (see also Chap. 9). contracting arrangements within vertical produc-
Third party intermediaries who facilitate the tion networks as alternatives to vertical integra-
placement of trust may be additional supports. tion, and rotating credit associations within ethnic
Formal variants of these include brokers who communities that serve as alternatives to formal
create indirect trust relationships, arranging financial institutions. In these associations, the
transactions while providing assurances to both ongoing ties among members ensure a borrower’s
trustor and trustee. Both formal and informal creditworthiness, standing in for the credit
advisors who provide assessments of a party’s histories and related standards of reliability that
quality but do not participate directly in a transac- institutional lenders recognize.
tion themselves are common, letters of reference Cook (2005, 2015) outlines a relational under-
being a widespread example. Social settings in standing of trust that resembles Coleman’s in
which trustees are in competition with one many respects, contrasting it with generalized
another may serve to promote trust. trust, “a ‘default’ belief in the beneficial nature
Social density or closure is an element of sev- of humans in general” (2005, 9). She also
eral trust-enhancing mechanisms. Such settings highlights some of the limits of relational trust,
can enable potential trustors to make vicarious noting that excessive embedding of trust
assessments of trustworthiness by allowing them judgments within closed, homogenous networks
to observe or learn about a trustee’s performance may unduly limit the extent to which people
with respect to other trustors. Tightly- consider entering into potentially advantageous
interconnected community structures can deter exchanges. Cook questions whether trust can pro-
bad faith actions on the part of trustees via the vide a sufficient basis for cooperation and mutu-
rapid diffusion of information about trustee per- ally beneficial exchange on a large scale, calling
formance and reputations to potential trustors. attention to other devices and conditions for
Buskens and Raub (2002) argue that these accomplishing that. Among these are formal
social foundations for trust operate via two dis- contracting, organizational and legal incentive,
tinct mechanisms. Learning about a prospective control, or sanctioning systems, and institutional
partner’s past behavior can occur via experience legitimacy. Cook suggests that reputation systems
derived from past exchanges or information offer an alternative to relational trust in settings
disseminated through third-party connections. that lack closure such as e-commerce, as potential
Control over a partner can be realized either trustees are strongly motivated to guard their
through threats to terminate a dyadic trustor- reputations.
trustee relationship or the actual administration For his part, Coleman (1990) pointed to sev-
of sanctions within a broader network context. eral ways in which trust could prove disadvanta-
Coleman gave many examples of economic geous. As Cook suggests, strong trust among
phenomena that assign important roles to trust members of a subgroup can limit overall group
and the social organization that undergirds it performance to a locally optimal level rather than
(see also Chaps. 16 and 17 for recent examples a global maximum. Collusive trust among
from economic sociologists). Extensive trust can oligopolists may further their ends but be socially
facilitate economic exchanges, e.g., allowing harmful. Group performance may also be
3 James Coleman, Social Capital, and Economic Sociology 37

compromised if leaders prioritize trustworthiness information-sharing and cooperation they entail.


over capability when engaging members, as in A firm’s network contacts—including its prior
nepotistic arrangements. Unduly optimistic alliances with the partner in question, shared
extension of trust followed by its sudden and directors, and contacts with banks or other
contagious withdrawal can prompt panics of dis- investors—can offer information about the reli-
investment, as in bank runs or the breaking of ability of potential new partners, and reciprocally
stock market bubbles (Coleman 1984). provide the firm with information about its own
A study of consumer purchasing experiences conduct. He shows that when partners lack expe-
and preferences (DiMaggio and Louch 1998) rience with each other, firms often employ rela-
suggests a substantial role for trust relations. It tively strong but cumbersome devices to assure
found that buyers often prefer market transactions mutual cooperativeness—equity-based alliances
that involve previous acquaintances in some involving some form of shared ownership. Such
capacity, e.g. as sellers, dealers, or intermediary “cautious contracting gives way to looser
agents. This held especially for purchases of practices as partner firms build confidence in
goods—such as homes or used cars—having each other,” however (Gulati 1995, 105).
uncertain condition and quality (see also
Chap. 7 for more examples); buyers believe that
they will obtain more candid disclosure of infor- 2.2 Information Flows
mation from preexisting contacts.4 Related exper-
imental research (Buskens and Weesie 2000) Coleman (1988a) wrote comparatively little about
indicates that subjects are more apt to express information-related forms of social capital, but
trust in a used-car dealer when they are linked to indicates that acquiring new knowledge via social
the dealer via past purchases, shared affiliations, relations can be expeditious. He offers the exam-
or third-party contacts. ple of two-step communication flows and opinion
Among studies of conditions underlying trust leadership (e.g., Weimann 1994) in which an
in organizational settings is Burt and Knez’s actor relies on information relayed by
(1995) examination of features of relationships intermediaries who follow (and distill
and personal networks associated with more and developments in) a domain such as fashion or
less trust within a sample of managers. Subjects politics, rather than tracking it her-/himself.
were more apt to describe other managers as Obtaining advice about a specialized part of a
trustworthy when the relationships linking them vast medical literature from expert colleagues in
were stronger (closer, more frequent, longer- lieu of maintaining currency with it oneself
standing); to a lesser extent, tie strength also (Keating et al. 2007) is another instance.
increased the likelihood of deeming a contact Although Coleman’s presentation does not dwell
untrustworthy. Closure within a manager’s net- on the social structural basis of such information
work—connections via multiple third parties— flows, many of them would appear to depend on
tended to amplify expressions of both trust and network openness rather than closure: the recipi-
distrust. ent of the information forgoes forming a direct
Gulati’s (2007) studies of the formation of link to the information source, opting instead to
interfirm alliances—e.g., licensing agreements rely on an indirect relation to it via her/his better-
or joint research and development informed intermediary.
partnerships—assign a substantial role to trust. Much research in economic and organizational
Such interorganizational ties promise many sociology examines flows of information
benefits, but also expose partners to a risk that mediated by social networks in some depth, how-
the other party may make opportunistic use of the ever. Prominent within it is Burt’s (1992, 2005)
sustained research program on structural holes.
4
Interestingly, sellers prefer to avoid transacting with prior This highlights the information-access
contacts under these same conditions. advantages enjoyed by actors lying in brokerage
38 P. V. Marsden

positions: interstitial locations that connect others was easier5; at the same time, those in contact
otherwise-unlinked clusters of others. Such actors with wider arrays of other units also communicated
hold a “vision advantage” (Burt 2005, 58) by more readily, perhaps because of their greater expe-
virtue of their familiarity with diverse segments rience in addressing diverse audiences.
of a group, and are likely to become aware of and Assembling and sharing information are not the
appreciate opportunities for synthesis and crea- only problems actors face in managing it. When
tivity sooner than those whose networks are information is proprietary or otherwise confidential,
more firmly embedded within a particular sub- or when actors are collaborating in some clandestine
group. In an especially compelling intrafirm or counter-institutional activity, maintaining secrecy
study that invited managerial participants to set by limiting its diffusion can be vital. Under these
forth ideas for improving their subunit’s perfor- circumstances, cellular structures comprised of
mance, Burt (2004) demonstrates that managers loosely-coupled clusters can be advantageous;
with open networks that span structural holes such structures feature not only closure, but also
were more apt than those whose networks very high fragmentation or modularity. Coleman
exhibited greater closure to propose ideas that refers to student groups involved in the pre-1987
their superiors rated as having high potential South Korean democracy movement (see also
value to the firm. They were also more likely to Chang 2015 on both student and religious groups)
propose any idea at all, and to report discussing as an example of such arrangements. Additional
it with others. As well, those in positions that instances include price-fixing conspiracies within
facilitate such entrepreneurial actions tend to markets (e.g., Baker and Faulkner 1993), and crim-
receive greater individual benefits, including inal or terrorist networks (Gerdes 2015).
higher performance ratings, greater compensa-
tion, and more rapid promotion.
Other intrafirm information studies examine 2.3 Effective Norms
both features of particular dyadic relationships
and broader network properties. Following Coleman (1987, 1990) conceptualized norms
Granovetter (1973), Hansen (1999) argues that relationally, as understandings that some set of
weak relationships may facilitate a wide search beneficiary actors holds the right to control cer-
for useful knowledge, while strong ones (involv- tain actions of a set of target actors.6 Such
ing frequent contact and close collaboration) may understandings identify actions that “are regarded
ease its transfer. His study of an electronics by a set of persons as proper or correct, or
company’s projects that required actors to obtain improper and incorrect” (Coleman 1990, 242).
information from other units found that knowl- Proscriptive norms discourage or prohibit an
edge complexity was an important moderator. action, while prescriptive ones encourage or man-
When the information transferred was well- date that it be taken. Finding explanations of
codified, weaker inter-unit ties were associated behavior based on conformity to norms
with shorter project completion times; when the unsatisfying without an account of how norms
knowledge involved was tacit, stronger arise, Coleman sought to develop an understand-
relationships were more advantageous. Related ing of how and why a set of purposively-oriented
research on the ease of knowledge transfer
among employees of a research and development 5
The finding that closure can promote some kinds of
company (Reagans and McEvily 2003) reported knowledge transfer resonates with Centola’s (2018) dis-
that stronger relationships more readily conveyed tinction between simple and complex contagion processes.
information, especially when it was less codified. In simple ones, something spreads after a single contact
between a source and a prospective recipient; in complex
Those surrounded by closed, interconnected sets of
diffusion, transmission requires wide bridges that provide
contacts also indicated that communication with reinforcement via multiple channels.
6
The two sets can be identical, in which case a norm is said
to be conjoint; otherwise it is disjoint.
3 James Coleman, Social Capital, and Economic Sociology 39

individual actors might collaborate to establish need to be taken into account when designing
a norm. It assigns a large role to social structural incentive systems that seek to elicit optimal levels
conditions in making this micro-macro transition. of worker productivity.
Coleman contended that purposive actors can
be prompted to create a norm when two
conditions hold: (1) the action in question has 2.4 Organizations
either positive or negative spillover effects
(externalities) on others, and (2) control over the Using the term corporate actor to underline his
action cannot be achieved via social exchanges view that organizations are elements of society
between beneficiary and target actors.7 Addition- having both interests and action rights, Coleman
ally, a sanctioning system that serves to enforce a (1974, 1982, 1990, part III) wrote extensively
norm by rewarding conformity or penalizing about organizations as instruments that allow
violations must be present if the norm is to be ordinary persons to combine resources in pursuit
effective in shaping behavior (i.e., if beneficiary of a shared purpose. Corporate actors are
actors are to be able to exercise the rights of control constructed out of simple authority relations in
it confers). Developing such a system can be prob- which one actor grants rights to control her/his
lematic because applying sanctions is effortful; for actions within some domain to a second actor, in
an individual beneficiary, the costs of doing so anticipation of benefiting in some manner.
often exceed the benefits received when a target Elaborations of these that permit the second
complies with the norm.8 When social structures actor to delegate the exercise of those control
allow beneficiaries to communicate with one rights to a third-party agent allow for the devel-
another, however, this barrier may be overcome. opment of complex organizational structures.
Closed social structures linking them once again Distinguished by their specificity of purpose,
serve as a resource: these may, for example, facili- such deliberately-constructed organizations,
tate the monitoring of compliance to a norm; like- Coleman argued, have assumed an increasingly
wise, they may support shared provision of significant role in contemporary society, at the
low-cost sanctions such as shunning or publicizing expense of primordial groups like families and
a target’s reputation for noncompliance. Addition- communities as well as individual (natural)
ally, they may enable second-order exchanges that persons. In his view, individual life chances
create incentives for an individual beneficiary to have come to depend largely on the affiliations
administer more costly sanctions. someone has with corporate actors.
A widely known example of norms within After such an activity system is established, it
organizational settings arises when members of can serve as a resource for the individuals who
a workgroup establish an understanding about the jointly created it by accomplishing its manifest
appropriate amount of output to be produced, and purpose. Its efforts may also be diverted toward
subsequently enforce it using a number of infor- the achievement of the distinct objectives of the
mal sanctions (e.g., Roy 1952). Coleman (1994a) subordinate agents who operate it. In both of
cites this as an instance in which both conven- these senses corporate actors can provide social
tional cost-benefit criteria and the social structure capital for individuals. Coleman’s analyses sug-
gest that in practice, organizations often fail to
7 serve the interests of persons as well as they
Apart from bilateral exchanges, one form these might
take is that of an action rights bank that allows potential should. He observed that corporate actors develop
targets to purchase a limited supply of rights to take autonomous interests—distinct from those of
counter-normative actions. Proposals for carbon credit their founders/sponsors and agents alike—and
exchanges to limit greenhouse gas pollution are one exam-
that these can lead them to take actions that
ple; see Coleman (1987, 140).
8 harm natural persons. The relentlessness with
If a norm has been internalized, targets self-administer
sanctions. Socialization—or instilling an internal sanction- which they focus narrowly on pursuing particular
ing system—is also costly; see Coleman (1987). goals makes them prone to neglecting the
40 P. V. Marsden

negative side effects of their activities, such as forms of social capital may have an inegalitarian
environmental pollution. He argues that over character. Notably, however, Coleman and
time, corporate actors have acquired an increas- Hoffer’s research findings indicate that social
ingly large share of social power at the expense of capital may instead compensate for human capital
individuals, and that this has reduced individual deficits in some educational settings.
welfare. Others too discuss interactive effects of social
In FST (1990, 531) Coleman writes that capital and other resources.10 A notable example
“[c]orporate actors merit existence only insofar is a finding from Burt’s (1997) intrafirm study of
as they further the ends of natural persons.” He managers, that benefits associated with wide-
made many proposals to restructure organizations ranging networks—greater compensation and
such that they might better advance the interests more rapid upward mobility—were largest
of persons, including broadening control over among those who have few peers within their
their governance structures (e.g., codetermination rank and business function. These tended to be
as practiced in Germany or inclusion of consumer more senior managers in boundary-spanning
representatives on boards of directors) or roles. Burt contends that this is a result of the
strengthening the role and resources of outside fact that senior managers hold more unique
corporate directors. He suggested external audits, positions, face lower competition, and possess
amended tax laws, and maintaining competition less legitimacy, conditions that allow more room
among organizations as approaches that would for variations in their social capital to
manipulate environmental conditions in order to distinguish them.
increase their responsiveness. These and other
approaches to reasserting social control over cor-
porate actors would serve to better align their 4 Developing Social Capital
actions with those of natural persons, increasing
the extent to which they provide social capital that A basic postulate of FST is that social phenomena
benefits individuals.9 are the outcomes of purposive action on the part
of individual actors, and this of course applies to
the development of social structural forms. Since
3 Combination of Social Capital forming and maintaining social relationships is
and Other Resources costly, this logic implies that such structures will
arise when actors deem the net benefits of creat-
Economic production functions often combine ing them to be in their interest. Those who found
factors of production such as human and physical business organizations, for example, are in a posi-
capital multiplicatively rather than additively. tion to realize the value that an entrepreneurial
Coleman (1994b, 42) suggests that this also may venture yields (Coleman 1988c). In Coleman’s
apply to outcomes that result in part from social view, however, the social structures that provide
capital, observing for example (Coleman 1988c, social capital often produce public goods that
383) that a parent-child link will foster cognitive benefit actors other than those responsible for
development only when parental human capital is producing them. He cites parent-teacher
also present. His educational research (Coleman associations in schools as one example (Coleman
and Hoffer 1987, 231) draws on expectation 1990, 313); subgroups of parents contribute the
states and labeling theories in developing a theo- time, effort, and resources needed to create and
retical case for anticipating that those with greater maintain them, while their benefits extend to all
human capital will derive more advantages from families served by a school. Attempts to create
social capital; this suggests that at least some these and similar voluntary associations often fail

9 10
See Swedberg (1996) for more about Coleman’s thinking Kadushin (1983, 196) suggests that many if not most
about organizations and their redesign. network effects are contingent rather than direct.
3 James Coleman, Social Capital, and Economic Sociology 41

to surmount the collective action problem of social capital to which Coleman devotes much
highlighted by Olson (1965). For Coleman, this attention. He highlights the role of closure in
implies that the level of investment directed sustaining both effective norms and systems of
toward producing social capital is typically trust and obligation. As discussed above (see
lower than what would be socially optimal. Sect. 2), closure supports both the monitoring of
Social capital also may be found within adherence to normative expectations and the
already-existing social structures, however, if sanctioning of behaviors that contravene norms
these can be repurposed. An instance of this, or fail to satisfy obligations.
well-known in organization studies, is the reori- In discussing the role of social capital in local
entation of the March of Dimes—an association development, Trigilia (2001) suggests that
originally established to combat polio. After an governments may be able to redress the under-
effective anti-polio vaccine was developed, the supply of social capital identified by Coleman’s
organization might have disbanded; instead, the analysis. Avenues toward accomplishing this
efforts of its activity system were redirected include providing collective goods (e.g., business
toward improving maternal and child health services and other infrastructure) that can support
(Sills 1957). Key to this process of appropriation firm learning and competitiveness, as well as
are multi-stranded or multiplex relationships that encouraging cooperative rather than regressive
allow social resources developed in one setting to (collusive, rent-seeking) use of existing social
be used in others. In Coleman’s understanding, networks.
such re-use of existing social organization as
social capital is widespread: “most forms of social
capital are created . . . as a by-product of other 5 Social Capital and Education
activities” (Coleman 1990, 317). As a result,
access to social capital may be uneven and some- Much of the empirical research Coleman
what haphazard, dependent on the other elements conducted during his career was on educational
of social organization with which an actor attainment and equity, and their implications for
happens to be affiliated. This contributes to the social policy. He viewed educational systems as
social capital inequalities that are, in Kadushin’s instances of constructed social organization that
(2012) view, largely unexplored.11 Preexisting seeks to develop human capital, and he had a
social organization may also play an important long-standing concern with how to improve
role in developing new relationships. Burt (1992, the performance of educational organizations.
13) points to referrals as one of the principal The largest body of his empirical work invoking
information benefits of bridging structural holes the social capital concept was situated within this
in networks. Gulati’s (2007) discussion of the context.
formation of interorganizational relationships It appears that Coleman first used the term
identifies social network resources as both social capital in Coleman and Hoffer (1987), in
sources of information about potential partners, an effort to account for their findings that student
and of more textured experiential and reputational outcomes varied among U.S. public, Catholic,
data about their reliability. Actors who have more and independent private schools. Catholic schools
elaborate prior networks therefore are better posi- exhibited higher rates of achievement growth
tioned to assess the prospective benefits and than public schools in certain subjects and
drawbacks to extending them. retained students through graduation at much
Closed social structures—in which an actor’s higher rates than did schools in the other sectors;
direct contacts are also in direct contact with one such differences were greatest among socioeco-
another—can further the creation of certain forms nomically disadvantaged students. Coleman also
featured these differences in retention in his gen-
11
See, however, Lin (2000) on race and gender inequality eral discussion of social capital (Coleman 1988a).
in individual social capital. Well-known differences in educational outcomes
42 P. V. Marsden

related to family background factors can reflect students and parents. The emphasis on student
both familial financial resources and parental engagement in extracurricular activities found in
human capital. Coleman and Hoffer point to such schools is interpreted as one step toward the
both structural (e.g., presence of parents, number end of creating cohesion among students
of siblings) and functional (e.g., time spent with (Coleman 1988b).
children and parental educational aspirations)
features as aspects of family social capital. They
observe that human capital resources within a 6 Conclusion
family may be inconsequential when such social
capital is lacking. Social capital has certainly proven to be a fecund
Coleman and Hoffer attributed some concept, employed widely in studying diverse
differences in educational outcomes across school social science subjects including civic engage-
sectors to the greater community-level social cap- ment (Putnam 2000), development (Woolcock
ital to be found around Catholic—and more gen- 1998), health (Kawachi et al. 2008), immigration
erally religious—schools, asserting that (Portes 1995), inequality and stratification (Lin
“religious community is one of the few remaining 1999), and organizational analysis (Leenders
strong bases of functional community in modern and Gabbay 1999; Adler and Kwon 2002),
society which includes both adults and children” among others. James Coleman’s influential
(Coleman and Hoffer 1987, 215). Noting that all understanding of social capital has much in com-
schools provide custody for children and convey mon with other sociological conceptualizations
some cognitive and vocational skills, Coleman that define it as social network-related resources,
(1991) argues that religious schools have a capac- but is distinguished by his emphasis on the idea
ity to mold values via moral and character educa- that social networks must assume some useful
tion that is not found in other settings; parents and form in order to constitute social capital, by his
educators elsewhere cannot reach a consensus on stress on the micro-macro transitions that underlie
the direction it should take. Among other things, much social capital, and by his explicit grounding
this operates via social structures that promote of social capital on micro-foundations that
intergenerational closure: dense and mutual assume purposive action.
relations among parents, teachers, and children. Accompanying the upsurge in research invok-
Such structures, in turn, support the development ing social capital across these fields are numerous
of parent-teacher agreement about disciplinary critical examinations of the concept’s
standards and achievement-promoting norms. foundations; among well-known critiques are
Coleman and Hoffer also observed that such Portes (1998), Kadushin (2004, 2012), and
community-level social capital might compensate Adler and Kwon (2002). In closing, we call atten-
for deficits of human and/or social capital within tion to a few of the issues that these authors raise
families; they recognized that this would consti- about social capital. Some critics question the
tute an exception to ordinary situations in which aptness of the analogy drawn between economic
human- and social capital-based advantages tend forms of capital and elements of social structure.
to be cumulative. They suggested that this might In particular, they ask whether actors self-
be attributable to an egalitarian ethic within reli- consciously invest in social capital, building
gious communities. relationships in anticipation that they will receive
While many public schools serve residential instrumental returns in the future; Kadushin
communities that could offer a basis for similar opines that “most people probably derive imme-
solidarity, Coleman (1991) notes that neighbor- diate gratification from making friends” (2012,
hood ties have weakened. Independent private 166). Coleman’s emphasis on how the public
schools can draw on neither religious nor residen- goods character of much social capital
tial commonalities and must make deliberate disincentivizes deliberate investment in its pro-
efforts if they are to create social capital among duction, and on already-existing social
3 James Coleman, Social Capital, and Economic Sociology 43

organization as a common source of social capi- In particular, he provides accounts grounded in


tal, suggests some sympathy on his part for such individual action for how and why those
reservations. consequences arise. Presenting the idea in a man-
Many discussions of social capital have a ner that attracts such widespread attention and
somewhat celebratory tone, stressing the interest to it, however, is a considerable contribu-
positively-valued outcomes found to be tion in and of itself. By developing it in such a
associated with it. Portes (1998), among others, compelling way, elaborating its foundations, and
calls for a more balanced assessment that detailing its forms, Coleman markedly advanced
considers social capital’s less desirable a central purpose of FST: to more fully incorpo-
consequences, too. Among these are the exclu- rate a serious concern with social structure into
sion of outsiders when closed networks hoard transdisciplinary analyses of both social and eco-
opportunities, the tensions between social solidar- nomic phenomena.
ity and individual autonomy, the downward
pressures on aspirations that discourage individ-
ual achievement, and the effective use of social
References
capital to further socially undesirable ends.
Commenting on individual variability in access Adler, P. S., & Kwon, S.-W. (2002). Social capital:
to social capital, Kadushin writes that “social Prospects for a new concept. The Academy of Manage-
networks are essentially unfair” (2012, 168), ment Review, 27, 17–40.
often serving to maintain or even accentuate par- Baker, W. E., & Faulkner, R. R. (1993). The social orga-
nization of conspiracy: Illegal networks in the heavy
ticularistic advantages. Certainly some social electrical equipment industry. American Sociological
capital-related processes implicated in reward Review, 58, 837–860.
allocation within competitive arenas, e.g., nepo- Blau, P. M. (1981). Consultation among colleagues and
tism and insider trading, are readily seen as such. informal norms. In F. N. Kramer (Ed.), Perspectives on
public bureaucracy (3rd ed., pp. 110–127). Boston:
Coleman’s observations about social capital’s Little, Brown and Company.
limited scope, potential liabilities and inegalitar- Burchard, J., & Cornwell, B. (2018). Structural holes and
ian character indicate that he recognized some of bridging in two-mode networks. Social Networks, 55,
these limitations. 11–20.
Burt, R. S. (1992). Structural holes: The social structure of
Beyond these lie concerns about the novelty of competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
the social capital idea. Portes writes that “the set Press.
of processes encompassed by the concept are not Burt, R. S. (1997). The contingent value of social capital.
new and have been studied under other labels” Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 339–365.
Burt, R. S. (2004). Structural holes and good ideas. Ameri-
(1998, 21). Numerous authors point to prior stud- can Journal of Sociology, 110, 349–399.
ies of social networks as vectors that can transmit Burt, R. S. (2005). Brokerage and closure: An introduc-
valued resources, for example. Acknowledging tion to social capital. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
this does not, however, gainsay the important Burt, R. S., & Knez, M. (1995). Kinds of third-party
effects on trust. Rationality and Society, 7, 255–292.
advances made by recent theorizing and research Buskens, V., & Raub, W. (2002). Embedded trust: Control
conducted under the rubric of social capital. and learning. Advances in Group Processes, 19,
These works detail, clarify, and specify 167–202.
mechanisms through which social networks con- Buskens, V., & Weesie, J. (2000). An experiment on the
effects of embeddedness in trust situations: Buying a
vey value (Lin 2001; Burt 2005). used car. Rationality and Society, 12, 227–253.
Notwithstanding these concerns, the Centola, D. (2018). How behavior spreads: The science of
implications that social organization holds for complex contagions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univer-
many social and economic processes remain sity Press.
Chang, P. Y. (2015). Protest dialectics: State repression
underappreciated in many quarters. Coleman’s and South Korea’s democracy movement, 1970–9.
concept of social capital is much more than a Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
resonant label that highlights “the positive Coleman, J. S. (1974). Power and the structure of society.
consequences of sociability” (Portes 1998, 22). New York: W.W. Norton.
44 P. V. Marsden

Coleman, J. S. (1982). The asymmetric society. Syracuse, Gulati, R. (2007). Managing network resources:
NY: Syracuse University Press. Alliances, affiliations and other relational assets.
Coleman, J. S. (1984). Introducing social structure into New York: Oxford University Press.
economic analysis. The American Economic Review, Hansen, M. T. (1999). The search-transfer problem: The
74, 84–88. role of weak ties in sharing knowledge across organi-
Coleman, J. S. (1986). Social theory, social research, and a zation subunits. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44,
theory of action. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 82–111.
1309–1335. Kadushin, C. (1983). Mental health and the interpersonal
Coleman, J. S. (1987). Norms as social capital. In environment: A reexamination of some effects of
G. Radnitzky & P. Bernholz (Eds.), Economic imperi- social structure on mental health. American Sociologi-
alism: The economic approach applied outside the cal Review, 48, 188–198.
field of economics (pp. 133–155). New York: Paragon Kadushin, C. (2004). Too much investment in social capi-
House Publishers. tal? Social Networks, 26, 75–90.
Coleman, J. S. (1988a). Social capital in the creation of Kadushin, C. (2012). Understanding social networks:
human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, Theories, concepts, and findings. New York: Oxford
S95–120. University Press.
Coleman, J. S. (1988b). Social capital, human capital, and Kawachi, I., Subramanian, S. V., & Kim, D. (Eds.).
schools. Independent School, 48, 9–16. (2008). Social capital and health. London: Springer.
Coleman, J. S. (1988c). The creation and destruction of Keating, N. L., Ayanian, J. Z., Cleary, P. D., & Marsden,
social capital: Implications for the law. Notre Dame P. V. (2007). Factors affecting influential discussions
Journal of Law, Ethics & Public Policy, 3, 375–404. among physicians: A social network analysis of a
Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. primary care practice. Journal of General Internal
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Medicine, 22, 794–798.
Coleman, J. S. (1991). Changes in the family and Kwon, S.-W., & Adler, P. S. (2014). Social capital: Matu-
implications for the common school. University of ration of a field of research. The Academy of Manage-
Chicago Legal Forum, 153–170. ment Review, 39, 412–422.
Coleman, J. S. (1994a). A rational choice perspective on Leenders, R. T. A. J., & Gabbay, S. M. (1999). Corporate
economic sociology. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg social capital and liability. Boston, MA: Springer US.
(Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology Lin, N. (1999). Social networks and status attainment.
(pp. 166–180). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Annual Review of Sociology, 25, 467–487.
Press. Lin, N. (2000). Inequality in social capital. Contemporary
Coleman, J. S. (1994b). Social capital, human capital, and Sociology, 29, 785–795.
investment in youth. In A. C. Petersen & J. T. Lin, N. (2001). Social capital: A theory of social structure
Mortimer (Eds.), Youth unemployment and society and action. New York: Cambridge University Press.
(pp. 34–50). New York: Cambridge University Press. Lin, N., & Erickson, B. H. (2008). Theory, measurement,
Coleman, J. S., & Hoffer, T. (1987). Public and private and the research enterprise on social capital. In N. Lin
high schools: The impact of communities. New York: & B. H. Erickson (Eds.), Social capital: An interna-
Basic Books. tional research program (pp. 1–24). Oxford: Oxford
Cook, K. S. (2005). Networks, norms, and trust: The social University Press.
psychology of social capital. Social Psychology Quar- Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public
terly, 68, 4–14. goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA:
Cook, K. S. (2015). Institutions, trust and social order. In Harvard University Press.
E. J. Lawler, S. R. Thye, & J. Yoon (Eds.), Order on Portes, A. (Ed.). (1995). The economic sociology of immi-
the edge of chaos: Social psychology and the problem gration: Essays on networks, ethnicity, and entre-
of social order (pp. 225–244). New York: Cambridge preneurship. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
University Press. Portes, A. (Ed.). (1998). Social capital: Its origins and
DiMaggio, P., & Louch, H. (1998). Socially embedded applications in modern sociology. Annual Review of
consumer transactions: For what kinds of purchases do Sociology, 24, 1–24.
people most often use networks? American Sociologi- Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and
cal Review, 63, 619–637. revival of American community. New York: Simon &
Gerdes, L. M. (2015). Illuminating dark networks: The Schuster.
study of clandestine groups and organizations. Reagans, R., & McEvily, B. (2003). Network structure and
New York: Cambridge University Press. knowledge transfer: The effects of cohesion and range.
Granovetter, M. S. (1973). The strength of weak ties. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48, 240–267.
American Journal of Sociology, 78, 1360–1380. Roy, D. (1952). Quota restriction and goldbricking in a
Gulati, R. (1995). Does familiarity breed trust? The machine shop. American Journal of Sociology, 57,
implications of repeated ties for contractual choice in 427–442.
alliances. The Academy of Management Journal, 38, Sandefur, R. L., & Laumann, E. O. (1998). A paradigm for
85–112. social capital. Rationality and Society, 10, 481–501.
3 James Coleman, Social Capital, and Economic Sociology 45

Sills, D. L. (1957). The volunteers, means and ends in a Woolcock, M. (1998). Social capital and economic devel-
national organization: A report. Glencoe, IL: Free opment: Toward a theoretical synthesis and policy
Press. framework. Theory and Society, 27, 151–208.
Smith, S. S. (2005). “Don’t put my name on it”: Social
capital activation and job-finding assistance among the
black urban poor. American Journal of Sociology, 111, Marsden, Peter V. is Edith and Benjamin Geisinger Pro-
1–57. fessor of Sociology, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA
Swedberg, R. (1996). Analyzing the economy: On the United States of America.
contribution of James S. Coleman. In J. Clark (Ed.), Research topics: Organizations and work, public opinion,
James S. Coleman (pp. 313–328). London: Falmer social networks, survey research. Recent publications:
Press. Marsden, Peter V., Tom W. Smith, and Michael Hout.
Trigilia, C. (2001). Social capital and local development. 2020. Tracking U.S. Social Change over a Half Century:
European Journal of Social Theory, 4, 427–442. The General Social Survey at Fifty. Annual Review of
Weimann, G. (1994). The influentials: People who influ- Sociology 46: 109–134. Kalleberg, Arne L., and Peter
ence people. Albany: State University of New York V. Marsden. 2019. Work Values in the United States:
Press. Age, Period and Generational Differences. Annals of the
American Academy of Political and Social Science 682/1:
43–59.
Social Factors in the Economy: New
Economic Sociology and the Mechanism 4
Approach

Andrea Maurer

1 The Double-Face of Success proof of the importance of networks and


institutions in modern market economy. Since
Sociological studies on the economy have the 1970s, new economic sociologists have been
established an international research field during offering some important models and empirical
the last four decades. It was the underlying insights on network patterns that shape economic
research program of new economic sociology action and improve economic outcome. When
that inspired the re-establishment of sociological analyzing social factors in this way, scientific
perspectives on modern economy from the 1970s knowledge is offered to organize economy from
onward. We can call new economic sociology a a sociological point of view. In light of this, new
research program because it is defined by certain economic sociology is part of the wider program
principles, aims, and tools that come from the of the modern social sciences and explanatory
notion of sociology as an explanatory social sci- sociology.2 The essential idea is to provide empir-
ence. The key idea is to explore social factors in ically tested knowledge by investigating relations
the real social or economic world by taking in social reality in the form of causal models, so
individuals and social structure as key elements. that living conditions could be improved. Based
What made new economic sociology a successful on considerations about what makes social
research program was the concept of social sciences special, sociology was established by
embeddedness that asks for causal models1 that Max Weber and Emile Durkheim. Both defined
offer theses for how and why social relations
such as network patterns or institutions matter in
2
markets. So, at the core of new economic sociol- The modern social science approach, as it was introduced
ogy stands causal models that answer how and by proponents of the European Enlightenment such as
David Hume, Adam Smith, or John Locke assumes struc-
why particular social factors are used by
tural patterns in social reality which can be explained and
individuals to handle all types of uncertainty. reorganized by humans because of their ability to think
Empirical studies have been conducted to give logically, to sense empirically, and to act reasonably. Max
Weber later defined sociology as a social science offering
causal explanations based on the assumption that humans
1
This is not the place to go into the far-reaching debate on set meaning to the world and could act meaningfully. So,
causality. For an overview of recent lines of thoughts see social scientists can construct explanations by exploring
Little (1991) and for the herein adopted logic of causal the meaning of the individuals in a real context. For
explanations see Weber (1949). evidence reasons starting with the simple version of
means-end rationality works as guideline (Weber 1949).
A. Maurer (*) This kind of rational analyses was re-considered and has
University of Trier, Trier, Germany been developed from the 1980s on (Maurer 2016b; for a
e-mail: andrea.maurer@uni-trier.de more detailed description see Sect. 3).

# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 47


A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_4
48 A. Maurer

sociology as an explanatory social science; set out a clear course for the future (Smelser 1994,
Weber based his on the assumption of meaningful 36). Also, newcomers from different backgrounds
individual action and Durkheim based his on might be inspired by exploring where they came
macro laws (Smelser 1994). from and where they want to move on.
New economic sociology started as a variant In the next section, the principles and aims of
of action-based sociological explanations like new economic sociology, as it was established in
Weber, using the assumption of intentional indi- the 1970s and 1980s are reconstructed. It is
vidual actions related to real-empirical contexts. highlighted that causal models, which combine
Economic sociologists also aimed to explore individual and social levels and especially
which social factors improve economic outcome. explore mutual interrelationships between both
Surprisingly, not much thought was given to this levels, are an essential tool for further
methodological parallel and foundation after the developments of this research program. This is
successful start. Instead, new economic sociology based on the principle that causal models are
invented a research field, which, since that time, abstractions from the real world that highlight
has been attracting a lot of new concepts, coming how and why forms of social embeddedness
from a multitude of different backgrounds. So reduce uncertainty and therefore could and
recently, some economic sociologists began to should sometimes enriched to offer more realistic
ask what this openness and the many newcomers explanations for why social factors improve eco-
could mean to the original research program, and nomic outcome. In the third section the
how to investigate and develop the core program principles, recent developments, and main forms
(Fligstein 2015; Maurer 2021, 2020). In light of of explanatory sociology are outlined in order to
this, the chapter highlights the foundational gain a better understanding of the wider program
research program and evaluates ways of and of action-based explanations. It is shown that
collaborators for moving forward. Thus, those newer developments within this framework,
newcomers who share the essential goal of such as analytical mechanism approach, use
explaining social factors in modern economy more realistic models by linking action and struc-
and, therefore, are working on causal models tural levels and thereby slightly change the logic
using assumptions on the micro and macro levels, and form of action-theoretically based
should certainly be considered as collaborators. explanations. It is summarized, that proponents
Other approaches that enrich the research field by of action-based explanations can collaborate on
bringing in new perspectives, but which do not reflecting methodological rules and forms of
share the background, could also contribute, but constructing their theories as well as improving,
may explore their own lines of development.3 If systemizing, and sharing models. The conclusion
we know more about the background and the given in section four argues for taking new eco-
foundational program, we might find reasons for nomic sociology as a special variant of action-
the observed vagueness and loss of identity and based explanations and therefore, allowing it to
collaborate with other action-based approaches to
3 tackle methodological issues and build a pool of
As is well-known, sociology covers different methodo-
logical premises and is therefore multi-paradigmatic work- models using a theoretical guideline.
ing with a huge variety of concepts and dualisms such as
micro versus macro, grand theory versus middle range
concepts, ideal versus materialistic, explanatory versus
critical or understanding and so on. (Giddens and Turner
2 The Research Program of New
1987; Smelser 1988). Nowadays, we find proponents of Economic Sociology
nearly all the different sociological programs using a vari-
ety of concepts in the field of economic sociology. So, Economic sociology has made a lot of progress
reconstructing and outlining the backgrounds, aims, and
since the 1970s but needs to reconsider its
tools is an important task to organize the field and to
decipher how the different approaches could be developed principles, aims, and means in order to set out a
by working together or separately. course for the future. In the following section, it is
4 Social Factors in the Economy: New Economic Sociology and the Mechanism Approach 49

shown what defines new economic sociology as a gradually set aside in order to enhance realism
research program. by taking the social constitution of intentions into
account. (3) New economic sociology has been
integrated by the problem-driven perspective of
2.1 Background and Aims uncertainty and searching for social factors that
help individuals handle uncertainty when it
In their well-known The Handbook of Economic comes to exchange or investment in market
Sociology, Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg structures. In other words, the leading question
defined economic sociology as the application of has been how network patterns reduce uncertainty
sociological tools, models, and perspectives to in a huge variety of constellations. Accordingly,
economic issues. They not only defined new eco- also conventions, institutions, and valuation pro-
nomic sociology, they also highlighted that new cesses that establish or stabilize social
economic sociology needs to sharpen a sociolog- expectations have been highlighted and attracted
ical focus and to synthesize its theoretical findings many newcomers. Those newcomers introduce
in order to move forward (Smelser and Swedberg different action models for different reasons,
1994a, 20). In the late 1970s and early 1980s, e.g., they focus on human judgement (Hannah
Mark Granovetter introduced the notion of social Arendt, Lucien Karpik), on collective experiences
embeddedness in order to develop a sociological (Karl Marx, Pierre Bourdieu), or on interpretative
view of market economy. He also highlighted that acts (Berger and Luckmann).
the main shortcoming of classical views such as While new economic sociologists have been
neoclassical economic theory, new economic offering important new insights into social
institutionalism, Parsonianism, and Structural mechanisms that arise from networks, they have
Functionalism was the neglect of social relations. not spent much effort on elaborating the underly-
Instead, Granovetter has been calling for ing logic or forms of explanations. Granovetter
explanations that explore how and why social himself explored and empirically studied two
relations and institutions matter in modern econ- central models on how network patterns influence
omy due to their ability to reduce uncertainty. In economic outcome: weak ties and strong ties.
order to shed light on the importance of social However, he did not explicitly ask about method-
relations in modern economy he introduced the ological foundations or principles, or exactly
notion of social embeddedness. what the explored causal forces were. In his
This concept covers three main elements: early writings on labor markets, he highlighted
(1) Due to methodological reasons context- the strength of weak ties as a way of improving
related models that link both social and individual information flow between randomly connected
levels are preferred. (2) In order to improve real- people. The observed information effect of weak
ism, it is assumed that intentions as well as cog- ties is explained as an effect of numbers and
nitive aspects are shaped and changed by social distance; so, the distribution of information
context. Whereas founders of new economic soci- becomes quicker and more widespread, the more
ology, like Mark Granovetter,4 used rational different people are, the more people are
choice theory as a “working hypotheses” at the connected. So, every person means new or more
very beginning (see for this Burt 1982; information, and every network with more people
Granovetter 1985, 506). This principle was from different backgrounds offers more informa-
tion more quickly. Granovetter also emphasized
4
Early proponents of new economic sociology as well as strong ties as a way to improve trust; families,
those of the micro-macro movement, were linked to ethnic or religious groups, and regions are then
Harvard University and became more skeptical about seen as an important aspect in economic life
Parsonianism, Structural-Functionalism, variable sociol-
because they can stabilize trust when formal
ogy, and survey research due to the writings of Robert
K. Merton and Harrison White (see for an overview order does not work. The effect of trust-building
Swedberg 1990; see also Chap. 3). can be explained either due to monitoring and
50 A. Maurer

sanctioning related to cost and benefits or related economic sociology offers a special way to deal
to shared values and collective identity. with major controversial topics (see Weber
The notion of social embeddedness has been a 2019) linked to explanations in the social sciences
key for developing a sociological view on the and thus, established itself as a special variant of
economy and establishing the research field. The explanatory sociology working with action
main concern of new economic sociology is models but with more realistic ones.
exploring how and why social factors shape and Because new economic sociology assumes
support markets and business firms. One of the socially embedded individuals its models can be
most inspiring perspectives has been network widened by taking in mutual interrelationships,
analyses of markets, entrepreneurs, innovators, mainly between an individual’s intentions and
and managers (Burt 1980, 1992; Uzzi 1997; social context. The dualism between abstraction
Podolny 2001; Mizruchi 2004). Although rational and realism is answered by using context-related
choice was used quite often as a working hypoth- models that assume mutual interrelationships and
esis at an early stage, later on, proponents of new feedback loops between network patterns and
economic sociology elaborated structural-action intentions, and sometimes also between cognitive
models. The idea of exploring social contexts aspects—such as emotions, empathy, normative
from the view of individuals and their intentions beliefs, evaluation standards, or knowledge—and
was increasingly abandoned. Nevertheless, new context. Thus, explanations are more realistic
economic sociologists inspired sociological mar- while analytical strength and theoretical
ket models (Granovetter and Swedberg 1992; guidelines are weakened (see Fig. 4.1).
Swedberg 1994)5 and developed sociological The reinvention of new economic sociology
perspectives on modern economy. was deeply inspired by criticisms of standard
economic and sociological theory for using action
models such as Homo oeconomicus or Homo
2.2 Principles and Essential Tools: sociologicus, ignoring cognitive aspects and the
Causal Explanations social constitution of intentions on the one hand,
or decision-making processes on the other. Since
In the foundational writings of new economic then, researchers from Europe and the US
sociologists (Smelser 1963; Coleman 1985; restarted working on action models, forms, and
Granovetter 1990, 1992; Smelser and Swedberg logics of action-based explanations. New eco-
1994a, b) we find explorations of causal nomic sociology has been an important driver in
relationships described in simplified, abstract reinventing action-based explanations. Especially
models like those of the network approach. Eco- in the 1970s and 1980s, most proponents of
nomic sociologists criticized fallacies of pure action-based explanations worked more or less
macro theory and grand theory. Instead, new eco- explicitly, based on the assumption of rational-
nomic sociology, aimed at opening up black intentional actions. They asked how and why
boxes by offering causal explanations based in social networks or institutions shape actions by
context related models and assuming cognition influencing benefits and costs (Coleman 1994;
sometimes an important factor in sociological Hedström et al. 1998; Burt 2005). This can be
explanations (see Boudon 1996; Hedström called action-theoretically based explanations or
2005). In this sense, models can be found either rational situational analyzes.6 Those who empha-
in a general action law (action-theoretically based size context-related models (Swedberg 2005), or
models) or in context-related action models. If we
put new economic sociology in the light of the 6
history of the social sciences, we can see that new For differences and commonalities between pragmatism
and rational choice see Joas (1993) and Coleman (1986b),
and for a more recent debate on these approaches in light
5
For general overviews of network analyses, theories, and of economic sociology see Thévenot (2001) and
methods see Lin (2001). Maurer (2021).
4 Social Factors in the Economy: New Economic Sociology and the Mechanism Approach 51

social context
intentions of actors due to network patterns. Such causal models are
network patterns actions of individuals based on more realistic assumptions at the indi-
cognitive aspects
of actors
vidual level than those that rational choice theory
considers. They especially take interrelationships
Fig. 4.1 Models of social embeddedness. Source: Own between an individual’s intentions and network
Diagram patterns into account. Some new economic
sociologists, such as Mark Granovetter and
Harrison White, figure out how network patterns
structural theories of social action (Burt 1982; shape action orientation, motives, and even cog-
White 1992) aim to provide more realistic nitive abilities, or the identity of individuals. That
explanations than action-theoretically ones, espe- has motivated a lot of empirical studies. Due to
cially rational choice based approaches. Later the openness of the field, newcomers have been
one, some of the founders of new economic soci- able to join easily.
ology criticized rational choice theory for ignor- While founders of new economic sociology
ing or abstracting from the social constitution of focused on more realistic explanations, and there-
an individual’s motives. However, they accepted fore highlighted the social constitution of actors,
the aim to open up black boxes by detecting how some new lines of thought turned away from the
individuals and social factors are interrelated. It initial principle of exploring social factors in the
seems, that recently economic sociologists have economy. So, we find the so-called context-
lost sight of the core idea of interpreting social related models that explore the functioning and
constellations from an intentional point of view. effects of particular network patterns related to
Instead, more approaches have been attracted by intentions and cognitive aspects of individuals. In
the field, that do not, at first glance, directly this vein, causal action-based models are the cen-
contribute to the core research program or its tral tool of new economic sociology and the
principles. essential criteria when discussing how to develop
the research program. If we take new economic
sociology as a research program working on
2.3 Strengths and Shortcomings causal models that explore why social factors
influence modern economy, building a pool of
New economic sociology has been established such causal models is a way of moving forward.
successfully as a research program that inspired However, that is not supported by all newcomers
a broad research field since the 1970s onwards (Maurer 2016a).
and reinvented the challenge of building up socio- The opening of the core research program has
logical perspectives on economy. Within the core weakened the concept of social embeddedness as
program of new economic sociology, the perspec- an integrating foundation. Economic sociologists
tive since then has been to figure out how and could try to regain clear methodological
why social factors reduce uncertainty, and guidelines and research programs by discussing
thereby support economic action.7 The notion of ways to enhance and theorize old and new
social embeddedness was introduced and related models.
to uncertainty in capitalistic market economies.
The founders of new economic sociology have
mainly been working on causal models that 3 The Idea of Explanatory
explore mechanisms and processes that emerge Sociology and Action-Based
Explanations
7
Other studies focused on how network patterns improve
If we explore the methodological background and
entrepreneurship (Portes 1995), stabilize socio-economic
regions (Saxenian 1994; Crouch et al. 2004), or overcome typical forms of action-based explanations, our
economic crises (Maurer 2016a). understanding of what makes new economic
52 A. Maurer

sociology part of explanatory sociology and what of the intentions of individuals who are facing a
makes it special will improve. particular social reality.9
Sociologists reconsidered Max Weber’s idea
that social situations can be described from the
view of meaningful individuals, so that certain
3.1 Background and Methodological
action patterns make sense and can be explained.
Ideas of Action-Based
For example, according to Weber, actors follow
Explanations in Sociology
orders if they define rules and rulers as legitimate
in a context. As we all know, Weber transformed
After 1945, macro theories, especially Marxism
the general thesis of legitimate orders leading to
and Structural-Functionalism, which aim to
meaningful and expectable obedience into three
explain social phenomena by using general laws
abstract models that guide analyses of history, as
on the social level, were highly criticized because
well as the modern world to date. In other words,
no macro laws could be empirically proven, and
sociologists reconsidered the core principle, of
there were inherent shortcomings (Merton 1936;
modern social scientists, of working on causal
Boudon 1974).8 Social scientists started
models, which are abstractions from the real
rethinking the construction and logic of
world and offer causal explanations by taking
explanations and how to explore causal relations
individuals, due to their ability to act reasonably
in social reality. Robert K. Merton initiated the
and intentionally, as a point of reference. In this
reinvention of explanatory sociology working on
sense, social reality is interpreted from the angle
theories of middle range. Additionally, the notion
of individuals. Explanations of this kind mean
of situational logic as it had already been outlined
stating how individuals act in certain ways due
in the writings by Max Weber and Karl Popper
to the social embeddedness or context in a mean-
was reconsidered as a key element for sociologi-
ingful way. This notion in theorizing has led to
cal explanations. Situational analysis, in Weber’s
a reinvention of the general logic of action-based
use, emphasizes abstract models that explore the
explanations since the 1980s.
meaning situations have for individuals and what
actions are thereby to be expected. Such models
were thought to be enriched either due to empiri-
cal information, that is what Weber (1949) had in 3.2 Main Forms of Action-Based
mind, or to theoretical arguments stemming from Explanations in Sociology
the underlying action theory and adopting eco-
nomic theorizing (Lindenberg 1992). Proponents In response to the challenges of the postwar
of the explanatory approach often use the phase, not only the American but also European
assumption of rational action as a starting point sociologists were guided towards action based
for its analytical strength and for linking explanations in the 1970s. Attempts of action-
intentions and situational aspects in a fruitful theoretically-based models developed especially
way. So, the rational choice approach has been in the methodological framework of Critical
reaching out to all of the social sciences and has Rationalism by Karl Popper (Lindenberg et al.
spread throughout Germany, Europe, and the US, 1986). The idea of multi-level explanations,
inspiring new economic sociology until now. In detecting situational logics was successfully
this sense, the commonly shared notion of social
9
science explanations is to offer testable theses for Sociological classics Max Weber and Emile Durkheim
why social phenomena are to be expected because established sociology as a social science that explicitly
aimed to explain real social phenomena. Weber
emphasized using action models or types to take meanings
of individuals and empirical context into account. This has
8
For the classical criticism on pure macro perspectives been essential for action-based explanations using situa-
such as functional analyses and evolutionary theories see tional analyses that explore the social reality from the
Max Weber (2019, chap. 1). viewpoint of intentional or rational actors.
4 Social Factors in the Economy: New Economic Sociology and the Mechanism Approach 53

invented and inspired other forms of constructing While the founders of new economic sociol-
explanations, such as mechanism approach or ogy began by constructing their explanations
rational choice-based theories in sociology. based on the assumption of intentional actions,
The first attempts, in the US (Burt 1982; recently we see more concern over constructing
Coleman 1986a, b; Swedberg 2001) as well as more realistic models that, in consequence, dis-
in Europe (Collins 1975; Boudon 1979, 1987; miss the idea of exploring social constellations
Lindenberg 1986), constructed models based on from an intentional individual perspective.
rational choice theory in order to provide strong Today, one of the biggest challenges in sociology
causal theses that could be empirically tested. and economic sociology is reconsidering how to
Prominent proponents of explanatory sociology deal with realism when building causal models
took Methodological Individualism and the prin- and how to systemize models so that our knowl-
ciple of causal models seriously, and widely used edge improves.
rational choice theory as a micro-foundation at We can see that from the 1970s onward, the
the end of the twentieth century (Coleman 1986a; reinvention of action-based explanations was
Lindenberg 1992); visualized with the well- elaborated in two main forms, which come with
known bathtub or boot (Coleman 1990, 8, 10). two logics. One way to construct explanations is
Inspired by Max Weber and Robert K. Merton building models by abstraction from concrete
to make explanations more realistic than rational empirical contexts—content-related models or
choice-based models, researchers started to enrich middle range theories—, which were reinvented
action models and to focus on interrelationships by Robert K. Merton in the 1940s. Different
between intentions—or cognitive aspects—of scholars, like new economic sociologists, new
individuals and situations (see Fig. 4.1 in Sect. institutionalists, and proponents of mechanism-
2). This shift partially changed the logic of action- based explanations, among others, have adopted
based explanations and brought about new forms. this way from the 1980s onwards. Especially
At least two trajectories within action-based proponents of the analytical mechanism approach
approaches come from this. First, there is the take rational choice-based explanations as a spe-
attempt to use empirically described cial case. The other way to build action-based
intertwinements between all kinds of individual explanations is using a general action theory and
and social factors. Second, there is the attempt to exploring all kinds of social contexts in light of
use the logic of action-theoretically based the theory e.g., constellations of interests. James
explanations10 and to widen models step by Coleman did this based on rational choice theory
step, focusing mainly on more realistic and the concept of social rights by differentiating
assumptions on social factors. Some newcomers situations where individuals have the same or
in the field of economic sociology even combine complementary interests. Anthony Giddens used
both ways. For example, mechanism approach the assumption of individuals, minimizing fear
emphasizes different interplays between individ- and using the notion of structuration (see right
ual and social factors either empirically side of Fig. 4.2).
investigated (Weber 2019) or in logical What links new economic sociology to explan-
combinations of individual and social factors atory sociology is the aim of causal explanations.
(Hedström 2005). However, economic sociologists seek more real-
istic theories that cover the social change of
motives and action orientation. Mechanism-
based explanations are to some extent, a reaction
10
If rational choice theory is used as a micro-foundation to internal criticisms of rational choice
the guideline is interpreting different social situations in approaches (Hedström and Swedberg 1996;
light of the intentions—and most of all context-related
Hedström 2005) and work on all kinds of action
interests—of individuals. Cognitive abilities matter only
if they are important for defining expected costs and models. The important question lying ahead is,
benefits of actions. what could new economic sociology gain from
54 A. Maurer

social constellation mechanism models explanandum


action-based explanations cogs & wheels

Fig. 4.3 Mechanism-based explanations. Source: Own


grand Diagram
middle range theories
theory

mechanism- models of network action


context-related
models models
eg. Hedström,
patterns
eg. Granovetter,
theoretically
based
based explanations, mechanism models assume
eg. Weber, Merton
Boudon, Schelling Burt, White eg. Coleman,
Boudon, Blau that there are mutual interactions between the
social context and the individual’s intentions
Fig. 4.2 Forms of action-based explanations. Source: and beliefs (see Fig. 4.3).
Own Diagram Rational choice theory can be seen as a simple
model that explores how the actions of others
change the opportunity structure through a
debates on constructing explanations and work- change in costs and benefits (see Sect. 3.2)
ing on action models? while neglecting possible changes in beliefs and
intentions. Nevertheless, mechanism-based
explanations cover rational choice-based
3.3 Analytical Mechanism Approach explanations as special cases, but do not take
them as an analytical starting point. Proponents
The mechanism approach,11 that has emerged of the analytical mechanism approach are quite
recently, is also inspired by the aim of providing often linked to the micro-macro debate and action
causal explanations and of overcoming the fallacy models. Moreover, most current proponents of
of macro approaches and the shortcomings of analytical mechanism approach started working
rational choice theory. For most of new economic on the methodological background of action-
sociologists, middle range theories are based explanations and action-theoretically
highlighted as a way to move forward. Mecha- based approaches due to its analytical strength
nism models investigate interrelationships as a micro foundation. So, not surprisingly,
between individual and social levels in order to Robert K. Merton, Thomas Schelling, John
explore social processes and describe them in Elster, Raymond Boudon, and others have been
mechanism models, similarly to what new eco- studying forms of action-based explanations
nomic sociology does. The analytical mechanism intensely since the 1970s (see for a recent over-
approach is found in the DBO concept and view Maurer 2016b; Hedström and Ylikoski
explores all kinds of constellations of desires, 2010).
beliefs, and opportunity structure as well as the While economic sociologists primarily focus
social mechanisms and processes that are on how and why social context shapes
generated (see Fig. 4.3). Mechanism models individual’s actions and vice versa, mechanism
enhance realism through focusing on logical models focus on a variety of constellations of
interrelationships between the three factors and desires, beliefs, and opportunities. To explain
focus on the ways they are shaped and changed means then to explore mechanisms which emerge
by one another. In contrast to action-theoretically due to social constellations such as belief forma-
tion, self-fulfilling prophecy, or rational imitation.
11 Peter Hedström systemized social constellations
The term mechanism is often and widely used in
sciences Mayntz (2004) and with a special focus on soci- by assuming that some interrelationships or
ology Maurer (2016b). It gained a precise understanding mechanisms are more important in social life
within analytical sociology which uses mechanisms as a than others, because they trigger and drive social
metaphor for abstract causal explanations (Hedström processes through special wheels, resulting in a
2005; Hedström and Ylikoski 2010); therefore the term
analytical mechanism approach is used when refering to chain of events. Like Oliver Williamson (1996),
this approach. who theorized transaction costs, Peter Hedström
4 Social Factors in the Economy: New Economic Sociology and the Mechanism Approach 55

rumor on insolvency self-fulfilling mechanism bankruptcy 3.4 How Could New Economic
Di Dh
Aj Ai
Sociology and Analytical
Ah
Bi Bh Bx
Mechanism Approach Work
Together?
Fig. 4.4 Model of belief-mediation through actions of
others. Source: Hedström (2005, 59)
New economic sociology and analytical mecha-
nism approach stand for causal models that
explores mechanisms as logical constellations of explain social phenomena by considering
desires, beliefs, and opportunities. To investigate individuals and social structure as key elements
mechanisms, he emphasizes agent-based to enhance realism. New economic sociologists
simulations.12 Explanation means to point out take social relations, and especially network
why special mechanisms emerge due to a particu- patterns, and institutions as relevant factors that
lar constellation of DBO and what social pro- shape the actions of individuals and are shaped by
cesses arise from them. So, different them. New economic sociologists highlight
mechanisms of belief formation (see Fig. 4.4) mutual interrelationships between social and indi-
can be explored by investigating how the actions vidual levels, especially working on the social
of others shape and change beliefs and the action constitution of intentions. Consequently, new
patterns that arise. All types of belief-formation economic sociologists have silently abandoned
mechanisms enhance action-based explanations the idea of interpreting social structure from the
by bringing in the beliefs of individuals as a perspective of intentional actors. Therefore, the
causal force in social life, and by describing program is losing its integrational power and
when and how beliefs influence actions. theorizing. This is why systemizing models
Proponents of mechanism-based explanations needs to be reconsidered nowadays. Partnering
try to explore all kind of cogs and wheels to with analytical mechanism approach as a collab-
construct mechanism-based explanations. Thus, orator then helps deal with these issues and shows
for new economic sociologists it might be worth us that the initial research program could be
asking what particular mechanisms help enhance enhanced in two different ways by elaborating
the core program of NES. The analytical mecha- new logics and forms of action-based
nism approach offers a variety of mechanisms explanations. One way would be to start with a
that can be ordered for analytical reasons by the simple default model that is broadened by consid-
factors involved and the interrelationships which ering the rule of economic theorizing. The other
are detected. For example, mechanisms of belief- way would be to integrate one or more mecha-
formation can be taken as a special type of mech- nism models through empirical evidence or by
anism, from which other mechanisms such as a intuition.
change of desires by beliefs or a change in the
opportunity structure by beliefs might result. The
3.4.1 Using a Default Option
relevant wheel in a first initial step is belief for-
in the Framework of DBO
mation. So, systemizing mechanism models by
It is essential for economic sociologists to work
the in-built wheels or by exploring directions of
on the recent vagueness mentioned and to recon-
social change could be the basis for collaboration
sider the research program’s methodological
by sharing a pool of mechanism models that are
foundations and principles such as those of
more realistic than rational choice models are.
action-based explanations. They can help select
collaborators and discuss what direction to move
in and for what reasons. It has been argued that
collaboration with the analytical mechanism
12
Other researchers also use backward reconstruction of approach would make sense because both
empirical-historical processes to detect relevant approaches share the notion of action-based
constellations (Boudon 1998; Weber 2009).
56 A. Maurer

explanations and the related methodological New economic sociology could benefit from
background of modern social sciences; especially the idea of using and connecting models that
working on abstract causal models. They also progressively reveal and explain ongoing pro-
relate in some way to the underlying concept of cesses of network structuration. For example,
analyzing social situations from the viewpoint of illustrating a particular network, with its strong
actors. While the classics worked on rational sit- ties and shared professional standards, allows one
uational analyses using the guidelines to add to see actors asking for ideal goods, a strong
empirical information prior to the social factors reputation, or a change to a social action orienta-
that are assumed to influence actions of tion, while reaching out for collectivistic goods
individuals for different reasons, new economic such as the maintenance of the group. The well-
sociology and mechanism approach stepped away known effects of strong ties, especially in small
from this idea of economic theorizing. Enhancing groups that share common values such as the
models in an economic way, then, means to add Amish people, Protestant sects, or merchant
empirical information prior to the description of groups, are then explained as a result of an ongo-
social context. The analytical mechanism ing process of network patterns shaping
approach covers this idea but changes it through intentions of individuals and vice versa. Widen-
simple models that work as opportunity-driven ing models should help gain a better understand-
mechanisms on the one hand, and individual ing of how and why network patterns sometime
mechanisms of desire-belief-formation on the guide or direct actors to ideas, or to reach for
other hand. The models of belief formation can collectivistic goals, instead of maximizing egotis-
be broadened either by starting with other tic utility. It seems that in his early writings,
mechanisms or by exploring what processes one Granovetter worked in this way and constructed
mechanism such as belief formation (Rydgren more realistic explanations then classical socio-
2009) could set in motion. What new economic logical and economic theories had, by bringing
sociology can take away from mechanism back social relations. If new economic
approach is, therefore, to think about a default sociologists continue using the concept of social
option and to decipher wheels that drive pathways embeddedness, it will help to look at the analyti-
of change and naming trigger points, paths, and cal Mechanism Approach in order to get a deeper
crossroads that can be studied empirically. For understanding of what it means to make
example, if a sudden change in opportunities explanations more realistic and to keep to eco-
reduces the resources of particular actors, this nomic theorizing. Strengthening a sociological
improves the opportunities of others even more. view of modern economy means, above all, to
Thus, certain steps can be studied and explored by theorize network models so that the influence of
backward reconstruction, like Norbert Elias social relations is explored. Surprisingly, to date,
(2000) has done, to explain the emergence of only a little attention has been given to such
monopolies. If explanations explore wheels that methodological based considerations that claim
lead from one constellation to another, it is impor- to improve, systemize, and select models from
tant to state the main causal factors and to use other approaches within new economic
empirical information about why those particular sociology.
social factors become relevant. Analytical mech-
anism approach elaborates how and why social 3.4.2 Built-in Mechanism Models Such
processes emerge due to mechanisms brought as the Mechanism of Belief
about by particular constellations of desires, Formation
beliefs, and/or opportunities This covers the idea It is a worthwhile endeavor to consider theorizing
that starting from a single mechanism, a chain of and expanding network models based on the idea
events is set in motion by one or more wheels of economic theorizing, in order to choose and
(Maurer 2016b). build elements into mechanism models.
4 Social Factors in the Economy: New Economic Sociology and the Mechanism Approach 57

Mechanism models could explore additional patterns might trigger belief formation in uncer-
factors and interrelationships that are used in net- tain situations due to powerful actors or rational
work models, especially cognitive aspects, and imitation. Collaborating in this sense means that
intentions. Such models connect quite well to network models take models of belief formation
network models because they elaborate and that fit particular network patterns and figure out
explain ways in which network patterns could what assumptions, concerning the network
shape an individual’s cognition or beliefs. Explor- patterns, would enhance realism and help social
ing how and why network patterns shape beliefs scientists learn more about the way networks
could be an essential tool for making explanations cause and drive belief formation, and the other
more realistic. In analytical mechanism approach, way round. The remaining challenge is to provide
Peter Hedström detects several logical ways for theoretical arguments for why forms of networks
how and why beliefs are influenced. Using shape beliefs, in which ways, and to work on
models of belief formation in economic sociology theoretical links between different explanatory
could also be combined with other well-known steps so that chains of belief formation can be
models from sociology that explore different investigated and explored.
factors and ways, which lead to a change in
beliefs. By using network models it could be 3.4.3 How to Move Forward Through
assumed and empirically tested that such a Collaboration
change in beliefs is the result of direct observation If we take new economic sociology as a variant of
in small networks, particular positions in explanatory sociology that aims at providing
networks such as opinion leaders or brokers, more realistic explanations, we can suggest col-
adaptation based on groups with shared values, laboration with the analytical mechanism
or using tacit common knowledge when it comes approach. Both lines could work together by
to conventions or trigger points as described by reconsidering methodological principles, by
Thomas Schelling (see for this Tilly 1998; discussing the functions and forms of action-
Rydgren 2009). models, and by systemizing models so that both
Contrary to network analyses, the analytical camps could use the same pool. Sharing and
mechanism approach offers models based on the introducing mechanism models in new economic
DBO concept, assuming all kinds of logical sociology seems to be a milestone for enhancing
interrelationships, between an individual’s the initial program. We can conclude that
cognitions and opportunities, as explanatory collaborating with other proponents of action-
factors. The analytical mechanism approach based explanations could help enhance the initial
provides models that explore how beliefs are program by reconsidering methodological
changed or constituted in social processes such principles and by sharing, broadening, and
as belief formation, by observing actions of others improving models. One way to do so is to theo-
in bank runs. Those models of belief formation rize the concept of social embeddedness by
could also start by the simple assumption that starting with simple models. Another way would
actions of others change the opportunity structure, be to choose mechanism models such as belief
and thereby set complex processes in motion formation to build into network models. Both
covering the change of belief systems. One sim- ways would enhance the core idea of sociologists
ple case could be described by assuming that the constructing, improving, and sorting explanatory
change in the opportunity structure might cause models that could be used in different fields. The
new action patterns that are observed in a wrong model of belief formation might be worthy of
light, so that self-fulfilling mechanisms might consideration as an important tool. Models of
take place. Theorizing and expanding network belief formation offer theses about why network
approach with the help of mechanism models patterns, or other kinds of social embeddedness,
could also start by selecting a model of belief might change beliefs, which bring about typical
formation that assumes particular network processes and events. Last, but not least,
58 A. Maurer

economic sociology can work with the analytical some even gave up exploring causal relationships
mechanism approach when it comes to empirical in social life. This process is a big challenge to
studies and methods. For example, economic new economic sociology because it weakens the
sociologists and proponents of mechanism theoretical guideline and the original research
approach could work together on backward program and calls for the reconsideration of how
reconstructions of what had happened in concrete to explore function and effects of social factors in
situations, or develop and use agent-based the economy.
simulations and big data in order to explore trig- This chapter suggests reviewing social science
ger points and pathways (for a recent overview background and the methodological principles
see Hedström and Bearman 2009). and aims that once helped establish new eco-
nomic sociology as a research program. Seeing
it as a part of the social science approach and
4 How to Enhance a Sociological especially of action-based explanations helps dis-
Perspective on Modern cover shortcomings and evaluate who might con-
Economy tribute to a reconsideration and further
development of the core program. Only if we
The founders of sociology, Max Weber and have a clear understanding of the underlying
Emile Durkheim, started out to define sociology principles and aims of a research program such
as a social science that asks for causal as new economic sociology, can we investigate
explanations on the social world. Realism in this weaknesses and seek tools to deal with them. For
sense refers to the aim of exploring what is going a long time, the most important tools in new
on in social reality instead of constructing an economic sociology have been network models.
idealized world. The challenge of constructing Network models need to be theorized by other
empirical-related explanations was outlined in theories in order to provide causal explanations
the framework of explanatory sociology early for how and why particular network patterns help
on. The main methodological principle and form individuals deal with uncertain situations. One
of action-based explanations, Methodological way to theoretically found network models is
Individualism, was already outlined by Max using rational choice theory as a micro-
Weber (2019) and developed by Karl Popper foundation. Another way would be taking more
(1999) who introduced the notion of economic complex models of analytical mechanism
theorizing as a central principle. Economic approach (see also Chaps. 16 and 19), different
theorizing in action-based explanations means, kinds of institution and convention theories (see
first of all, focusing on social factors and also Chaps. 5, 12 and 13). All those models
providing better knowledge about how they provide explanations for why social factors sup-
work in reality. Another principle used in explan- port market exchange and offer testable theses
atory sociology is rational situational analyses about the mutual interrelationships between
that interprets context from the perspective social factors and intentions and cognitive aspects
of meaningful and intentional individuals. That of individuals. Mechanism models enhance net-
inspired action-theoretically based explanations work models because they add the concept of
in the 1970s and 1980s, using one general action precisely outlining interrelationships between
theory as a micro foundation. From the 1970s and social context and an individual’s desires or
1980s onward, criticisms of rational choice theory beliefs. Most of all, mechanism approach
as a general micro foundation rose, and highlights the idea that changes trigger other
sociologists in favor of realistic explanations changes, so that social dynamics emerge that
turned away from the logic of action theoretically lead to special phenomena. Explanations consist
based explanations. Instead, in sociology as well of theoretical models that are linked in a way, so
as in economic sociology, scholars started to that ongoing interrelationships are explored by
explore social life from a variety of viewpoints, particular wheels and pathways.
4 Social Factors in the Economy: New Economic Sociology and the Mechanism Approach 59

In light of this, improving action-based Boudon, R. (1979). Generating models as a research strat-
explanations has been the most important task egy. In P. H. Rossi (Ed.), Qualitative and quantitative
social research. Papers in honor of Paul F. Lazarsfeld
recently. Approaches that provide methodologi- (pp. 51–64). New York: Free Press.
cal rules to work on and enhance causal models or Boudon, R. (1987). The individualistic tradition in sociol-
offer relevant models are important collaborators. ogy. In J. C. Alexander, B. Giesen, R. Münch, & N. J.
All approaches in the framework of action-based Smelser (Eds.), The micro-macro link (pp. 45–70).
Berkeley: University of California Press.
explanations can be considered as reliable Boudon, R. (1996). The rational choice model: A particu-
partners, especially when they aim at constructing lar case of the cognitive model. Rationality and Soci-
realistic models that explore the function and ety, 8, 123–150.
effects of social factors in modern market econ- Boudon, R. (1998). Social mechanisms without black
boxes. In P. Hedström & R. Swedberg (Eds.), Social
omy. We have seen that recently new logics and mechanisms. An analytical approach to social theory
forms of causal models have been elaborated to (pp. 172–203). Cambridge: Cambridge University
be more realistic. In this sense, the analytical Press.
mechanism approach offers content and action- Burt, R. S. (1980). Models of network structure. American
Sociological Review, 6, 79–141.
related models that explore how complex social Burt, R. S. (1982). Toward a structural theory of action.
constellations cause macro phenomena. New York: Academic Press.
From the observation that many newcomers Burt, R. S. (1992). Structural holes. The social structure of
from different approaches have stepped into the competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Burt, R. S. (2005). Brokerage and closure. An introduction
field of economic sociology, the challenge has to social capital. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
arisen of rethinking the identity and future Coleman, J. S. (1985). Introducing social structure into
developments of the original research program. economic analysis. American Economic Review, 74
With this focus, other research programs could do (2), 84–88.
Coleman, J. S. (1986a). Microfoundations and
the same check on their aims and tools and choose macrosocial theory. General discussion. In
their way to develop. If we see new economic S. Lindenberg, J. S. Coleman, & S. Nowak (Eds.),
sociology as a particular line of sociological Approaches to social theory (pp. 345–363).
thinking, committed to causal explanations, we New York: University of California Press.
Coleman, J. S. (1986b). Social theory, social research and
can investigate essential aims and main tools in a theory of action. American Journal of Sociology, 91
the broader framework of action-based (6), 1309–1335.
explanations. To enhance the initial research pro- Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory.
gram means to outline how collaboration might Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Coleman, J. S. (1994). A rational choice perspective on
help to theorize and systemize models that economic sociology. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg
explore social factors in the economy. It was (Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology
shown that particularly those newcomers who (pp. 166–180). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
work on more realistic causal models are moving Collins, R. (1975). Conflict sociology. Toward an explan-
atory science. New York: Academic Press.
in a similar direction. Additionally, it was brought Crouch, C., Le Galès, P., Trigilia, C., & Voelzkow,
to light that reconstructing methodological H. (Eds.)., (2004). Changing governance of local
principles, essential goals, and main tools helps economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
investigate the core of a research program and its Elias, N. (2000). The civilizing process: Sociogenetic and
psychogenetic investigations. Malden, MA: Blackwell.
main tools and challenges. Thus, developing the Fligstein, N. (2015). What kind of re-imagining does eco-
initial research program means working on causal nomic sociology need? In P. Aspers & N. Dodd (Eds.),
models that explain how social factors shape Re-imagining economic sociology (pp. 301–315).
modern economy and society. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Giddens, A., & Turner, J. H. (Eds.). (1987). Social theory
today. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social struc-
ture. The problem of embeddedness. American Journal
References of Sociology, 91, 481–510.
Granovetter, M. (1990). The old and the new economic
Boudon, R. (1974). The logic of sociological explanation. sociology. A history and an agenda. In R. Friedland &
Harmondsworth: Penguin.
60 A. Maurer

A. F. Robertson (Eds.), Beyond the marketplace. Merton, R. K. (1936). The unanticipated consequences of
Rethinking economy and society (pp. 89–112). purposive social action. American Sociological
New York: Aldine de Gruyter. Review, 1, 894–904.
Granovetter, M. (1992). Problems of explanation in eco- Mizruchi, M. S. (2004). Network theory. In G. Ritzer
nomic sociology. In N. Nohria & R. G. Eccles (Eds.), (Ed.), Encyclopedia of social theory (pp. 534–540).
Networks and organizations. Structure, form, and London: Sage.
action (pp. 25–56). Boston: Harvard Business School Podolny, J. M. (2001). Networks as the pipes and prisms
Press. of the market. American Journal of Sociology, 107,
Granovetter, M., & Swedberg, R. (Eds.). (1992). The 33–60.
sociology of economic life. Boulder: Westview Press. Popper, K. (1999). All life is problem solving. Oxford:
Hedström, P. (2005). Dissecting the social. On the Routledge.
principles of analytical sociology. Cambridge: Portes, A. (1995). The economic sociology of immigration:
Cambridge University Press. Essays on networks, ethnicity, and entrepreneurship.
Hedström, P., & Bearman, P. (Eds.). (2009). The Oxford New York: Russell Sage.
handbook of analytical sociology. Oxford: Oxford Rydgren, J. (2009). Beliefs. In P. Hedström & P. Bearman
University Press. (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of analytical sociology
Hedström, P., & Swedberg, R. (1996). Social mechanisms. (pp. 72–93). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Acta Sociologica, 39, 281–308. Saxenian, A. L. (1994). Regional advantage: Culture and
Hedström, P., & Ylikoski, P. (2010). Causal mechanisms competition in Silicon Valley and route 128.
in the social sciences. Annual Review of Sociology, 36, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
49–67. Smelser, N. J. (1963). Sociology of economic life.
Hedström, P., Swedberg, R., & Udéhn, L. (1998). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Popper’s situational analysis in contemporary sociol- Smelser, N. J. (Ed.). (1988). Handbook of sociology.
ogy. Philosophy of the Social Sciences, 28, 339–364. Newbury Park: Sage.
Joas, H. (1993). Pragmatism and social theory. London: Smelser, N. J. (1994). Sociology. Cambridge, MA:
University of Chicago Press. UNESCO and Blackwell.
Lin, N. (2001). Social capital. A theory of social structure Smelser, N. J., & Swedberg, R. (Eds.). (1994a). The hand-
and action. In M. Granovetter (Ed.), Structural analy- book of economic sociology. Princeton: Princeton Uni-
sis in the social sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni- versity Press.
versity Press. Smelser, N. J., & Swedberg, R. (1994b). The sociological
Lindenberg, S. (1986). How sociological theory lost its perspective on the economy. In N. J. Smelser &
central issue and what can be done about it. In R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic soci-
S. Lindenberg, J. S. Coleman, & S. Nowak (Eds.), ology (pp. 3–26). Princeton: Princeton University
Approaches to social theory (pp. 19–24). New York: Press.
Praeger Publishers. Swedberg, R. (Ed.). (1990). Economics and sociology.
Lindenberg, S. (1992). The method of decreasing abstrac- Redefining their boundaries. Conversations with
tion. In J. S. Coleman & T. J. Fararo (Eds.), Rational economists and sociologists. Princeton: Princeton Uni-
choice theory. Advocacy and critique (pp. 3–20). versity Press.
Newbury Park: Sage. Swedberg, R. (1994). Markets as social structures. In N. J.
Lindenberg, S., Coleman, J. S., & Nowak, S. (Eds.). Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of eco-
(1986). Approaches to social theory. New York: nomic sociology (pp. 255–282). Princeton: Princeton
Russell Sage Foundation. University Press.
Little, D. (1991). Varieties of social explanation. An intro- Swedberg, R. (Ed.). (2001). Sociology and game theory.
duction to the philosophy of social science. Boulder: Contemporary and Historical Perspectives. Theory and
Westview Press. Society, 30, 301–335.
Maurer, A. (Ed.). (2016a). New perspectives on resilience Swedberg, R. (Ed.). (2005). Interest, concepts in the social
in socio-economic spheres. Wiesbaden and New York: sciences. Maidenhead: Open University Press.
VS Springer. Thévenot, L. (2001). Pragmatic regimes governing the
Maurer, A. (2016b). Social mechanisms as special cases of engagement with the world. In T. Schatzki, K. Knorr-
explanatory sociology: Notes toward systemizing and Cetina, & E. von Savigny (Eds.), The practice turn in
expanding mechanism-based explanation within soci- contemporary theory (pp. 56–73). London: Routledge.
ology. Analyse & Kritik. Journal of Social Theory, 38 Tilly, C. (1998). Durable inequality. Berkeley: Westview
(1), 31–52. Press.
Maurer, A. (2021). German economic sociol- Uzzi, B. (1997). Social structure and competition in inter-
ogy. Soziologische Revue, special issue Soziologie - firm networks. The paradox of embeddedness. Admin-
German speaking sociology, 2021, 39-52. istrative Science Quarterly, 42, 35–67.
Mayntz, R. (2004). Mechanisms in the analysis of micro- Weber, M. (1949). Essays in the methodology of the social
macro-phenomena. Philosophy of the Social Sciences, sciences (Transl. and eds. E. A. Shils & H. A. Finch).
34, 237–259. New York: Free Press.
4 Social Factors in the Economy: New Economic Sociology and the Mechanism Approach 61

Weber, M. (2009). The protestant ethic and the 'spirit' of


Research topics: Economic sociology, sociological theo-
capitalism. The Talcott Parsons translation. A Norton
ry, new institutionalism, mechanism approach, social
Critical Edition (Ed. R. Swedberg). New York: Norton
construction of markets, digitalization. Recent publica-
Original Edition.
tions: Maurer, Andrea. 2021. German Economic Sociol-
Weber, M. (2019). Economy and society. A new transla-
ogy. Soziologische Revue, Special Issue 2021: 39-52.
tion (Ed. and Transl. K. Tribe). Harvard: Harvard Uni-
Berlin: DeGruyter. Maurer, Andrea. 2016. Social Me-
versity Press.
chanisms as Special Cases of Explanatory Sociology:
White, H. C. (1992). Identity and control. A structural
Notes toward Systemizing and Expanding Mechanism-
theory of social action. Princeton: Princeton University
based Explanations. Analyse & Kritik, Special Issue
Press.
1/2016: 35–52. Maurer, Andrea. 2016. In Search of the
Williamson, O. E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance.
Golden Factor: Conceptualizing Resilience in the Frame-
New York: Oxford University Press.
work of New Economic Sociology by Focusing on
‘Loyalty’. In New Perspectives on Resilience in Socio-
Economic Spheres, ed. Andrea Maurer, 83–109. Wiesba-
Maurer, Andrea is professor of sociology with a focus
den: Springer VS. Maurer, Andrea. 2012. Economic
on economic sociology, University of Trier, Germany. She
Sociology: Bringing Back Social Factors. In Sociological
currently serves as chair of the Economic Sociology
Landscape: Theories, Realities and Trends, ed. Dennis
Research Network (ESA) and was chair of the German
Erasga, 77–100. IntechOpen.
Section of Economic Sociology from 2011–15.
A French Institutionalism in Economic
Sociology? 5
Pierre François

Among the many proposed approaches that arose because the rain dance was not properly executed
at the beginning of twentieth century to define (Hubert and Mauss 1985).
what sociology was and what its object was, the Defined in this broad sense, institutions have
idea that sociology was the science of institution played a crucial role in the development of con-
was explicitly set by the Durkheimians temporary economic sociology. This chapter will
(Fauconnet and Mauss 1971; Durkheim 1990). be devoted to the discussion of what can be retro-
The concept of institution may be used in the spectively designed the French version of institu-
definition of sociology, in part because it can be tionalism in economic sociology. A few remarks
used to designate a broad set of realities: should be made to explain this somewhat prob-
categories of thought, routine practices, but also lematic terminology. Almost no French economic
organizational forms may be described as sociologist has indeed defined himself as an
institutions. Relying on this Durkheimian tradi- institutionalist. Rather than using the terminology
tion, François (2011) gives a more precise defini- of institutions, French sociologists would use a
tion of what an institution is. He says that it is a lexicon filled with devices, equipment, tools, or
frame that makes the world a place which can be conventions. In spite of this terminological gap,
interpreted and where social actors can act. First, we think that at least part of the theoretical
an institution designs a set of rules, practices, or developments devoted to these terms can be
categories of thought that are stabilized. These related to the concept of institution, as we have
rules and practices are not dependent on those defined it (for a more systematic discussion, see
who use them; they were there before the users François 2011). In spite of their differences, these
and will continue after the users are gone. Second, approaches share a set of common assumptions.
an institution is shared within a group. Third, an They focus on micro-sociological situations, and
institution has a normative dimension; it says more precisely on market situations, where
what is right and what is wrong, what should be decisions need to be made in situations of uncer-
done and what should be avoided. Fourth, an tainty. Institutions such as devices, equipment,
institution is a priori. It is subtracted from the and conventions develop to make these decisions
verdict of experience. For example, if after a possible. The most influential theoretical
rain dance, the rain does not fall, it is not because developments of this French institutionalism
the institution (magic) does not work, it is took place during the 1990s. This is not to say
that there have been no discussions or
P. François (*)
developments since then, but the basic
Sciences Po, Centre de sociologie des organisations, Paris,
France propositions were set in 2000. These proposed
e-mail: pierre.francois@sciencespo.fr theories come from very different intellectual
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 63
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_5
64 P. François

backgrounds such as the sociology of professions, organization theory, especially when they discuss
Keynesian economics, Bourdieusian sociology, the links between institution on the one side, and
the history of statistics, and the science studies. action, agency, and entrepreneurship on the other
However, most of them converge on a set of (Bergeron and Castel 2016). A third locus of
intuitions which are in some ways close to each connection between French economic sociology
other, and therefore share the same blind spots. and new institutionalism has developed since
All these developments are by and large, inde- 2000, on more empirical grounds. A set of studies
pendent from those inspired by US new institu- was conducted to document the changes in firm
tionalism (Powell and DiMaggio 1991; strategies and organizations in France, over the
Greenwood et al. 2008), be it in the US or in last three decades (Viallet-Thévenin 2015;
Europe. While French institutionalists focused François and Lemercier 2016; Foureault 2018).
on market situations, US new institutionalists The purpose of these studies is explicitly to test
addressed classical questions dealing with the assumptions made by new institutionalists in
organizations. Meyer and Rowan (1977), and the US context (Fligstein 1990; Davis et al.
DiMaggio and Powell (1983) asked how firms 1994), and sometimes documented for European
or public administration converged to a set of countries as well (Fiss and Zajac 2004). A final
shared organizational principles. A classical contact point, certainly the most connected to new
answer of organization theory would be that institutionalist community, lies outside sociology.
these organizational principles have proven to Business scholars, who are barely connected to
be more efficient. New institutionalists proposed the sociological community in France, have
an alternative answer, as simple and as powerful published important contributions to new
as the efficiency hypothesis: organizations con- institutionalist literature (see, for example, Rao
verged towards a model, not because this model et al. 2003). Almost none of those discussions
was efficient, but because it was legitimate within are directly related to the debates and theories I
a certain space of inter-influence, which they identify as a French institutionalism. US new
called a field. institutionalism and French institutionalism have
The influence of new institutionalism has been almost nothing in common: their seminal empiri-
surprisingly low in France over the last three cal settings (market vs. organization), the scope of
decades. This influence is found in very specific their analysis (micro vs. macro) and their main
places. New institutionalist authors, especially methods (ethnographic methods vs. statistical
Neil Fligstein (1990, 2001), may be summoned analysis) are completely different. We will focus
by Bourdieu and Bourdieusian sociologists to here on the presentation and discussion of French
back their positions on certain topics. These institutionalism, setting aside the connections
topics include firms and their place in the between US inspired new institutionalists and
financialization process. Very few empirical stud- French economic sociology.
ies have been conducted in France on this process During the 1990s and the 2000s, a variety of
(for recent contributions in a Bourdieusian per- theories arose in a burgeoning French economic
spective, see Benquet et al. 2019). However, the sociology. Some of them presented arguments
somewhat rhetorical compatibility of new institu- which were similar in many ways (see Gadrey
tionalism and Bourdieusian perspectives does not 1994; Hatchuel 1995; Cochoy 2002). In order to
rely on the notion of institution, but rather on the keep the review short, we present the three most
concept of field. The discussion of institutional ambitious, systematic, and influential sets of
concepts is more central in another very different theories which were created at the time: econom-
branch of French sociology, the one identified ics of quality or economics of singularities, pro-
with the sociology of organizations in France. In posed by Lucien Karpik; economics of
this community of organization specialists, convention; and the performativity approach, as
discussions with new institutionalism are more developed by Michel Callon and his colleagues.
related to the most cutting-edge developments of
5 A French Institutionalism in Economic Sociology? 65

We shall end this review presenting the main trilateral relation between a customer, a producer
criticisms addressed to these theories. and, in this case, an adviser, sometimes called a
prescriber (see Hatchuel 1995). The adviser
makes it possible to create equivalence in the
1 Economics of Quality market between situations, which at first seemed
and Economics of Singularities difficult to compare. An important aspect that
makes the information reliable is that it is not, in
Between the late 1980s and the mid-2000s, this case, influenced by the producer, because one
Lucien Karpik proposed a set of important relies on the advice of a third party. The producer
contributions to the debate regarding the relations plays no role in defining the information the cus-
between quality and value, based on a couple of tomer will use to make his choice.
intuitions. First, when social actors are to make a Karpik calls this kind of market a market-net-
choice on a market, they face situations of high work (marché-réseau). He later developed a sys-
uncertainty. Second, devices develop to help tematic account of these situations where
them make choices (see Karpik 1989, 1996, assessing the quality of what the customer might
1999, 2002, 2010). receive is both crucial and difficult. In his article
Karpik started thinking about developing what published in 1996, Sociologie du travail and, later
would become an ambitious, systematic account on, in his (translated. 2010) systematic Economie
of what he initially called an economics of qual- des singularités of 2007, Karpik develops a typol-
ity, but which later became an economics of ogy of the situations where these choices might be
singularities, while working on the lawyer mar- made, and of the solutions, which he calls
ket. When someone needs to find a lawyer, he devices, that might arise to solve these problems.
faces a situation which is both dramatic (usually This typology crosses two dimensions. First,
one needs a lawyer when the stakes are high), and where does the uncertainty come from? Markets
uncertain. Then, the question is: How can one be can produce situations, where the customer does
sure that the lawyer he chooses will be trustwor- not know what he is buying, for two different
thy, committed, and competent? In a market situ- reasons. These two situations reproduce, in
ation as it is described by basic, neo-classical some way, a distinction close to the one proposed
economics, price should help you make a choice. by the economics of information (Stiglitz 1987),
However, within many markets, including that of between information asymmetry and moral haz-
lawyers, Karpik argues that price is not a reliable ard. In the first situation, the quality of what is
indicator on which one can base his choice. In bought is set once and for all, or rather, the
these markets, the price of what is received is less product one buys will not change, but its quality
important than the quality of the good or service is difficult to evaluate. If one buys a bottle of
one is seeking. So, in these markets, quality is not wine, or a CD of a piano player from the 1960s,
only crucial, it is also highly uncertain. In the the quality of the good is already set, but the
lawyer market, there is no system of public infor- customer ignores it before he tastes the wine or
mation that might help the client make his choice. listens to the CD. He might need help to make his
Even worse, the quality of the service is impossi- choice. In the second situation, the quality of what
ble to assess before the service is provided. Its is bought is uncertain, because it depends on the
quality greatly depends on the commitment of the reliability of the producer, and on his potential
producer on this specific transaction, and on the untrustworthiness. If the customer does not want
quality of his interactions with the client to buy a CD but goes to a concert, then the quality
(de Bandt and Gadrey 1994). In this situation, is not set. It depends on the commitment of the
clients do not rely on price to make their choice, pianist. Will he be inspired tonight? Will he even
but rather on the recommendations given by peo- show up? If the customer goes back to a restau-
ple they know. The market relation is no longer a rant, the quality of his dinner depends on the
relation between a customer and a producer, it is a commitment of the kitchen’s team and on the
66 P. François

quality of the food they obtained that morning at or to rank the producer selected (Teil 2001). So,
the market. In these two situations, devices will these principles might change over time, even
develop to help the customer make his choice. though the reputation of the guide is well
However, these devices obey different kinds of established, as Karpik demonstrated in the case
logic. Karpik calls the devices that are used in the of the Guide Rouge Michelin (Karpik 2000).
first situation judgement devices, and those peo- When the situation is uncertain because the
ple rely on in the second situation he refers to as producer might act as an opportunist, the cus-
trust devices. tomer can rely on trust devices. The personal
Karpik adds another criterion to this first trust device Karpik identifies is the same as the
dimension that helps him build his typology. personal judgement device, that being the
Are the devices, whether judgement or trust customer’s network. This is the same situation
devices, personal devices or impersonal devices? that Karpik analyzes in the market of lawyers.
In the first case (personal devices), the customer However, the customer might also rely on imper-
relies on advice and prescriptions, (i.e., sonal trust devices, which aim at neutralizing the
recommendations, given by people he personally consequences of opportunism, and therefore
knows and therefore trusts). When he relies on guarantee the execution of incomplete contracts.
abstract devices to make his choice such as a These normative devices, as Karpik calls them,
label, a brand, a charter, or a contract, these consist of both material and symbolic settings,
devices are said to be impersonal devices. Strictly which carry principles internalized by the partners
speaking, only impersonal devices can be of the exchange and associated to some explicit,
assimilated to institutions; but for the sake of the and by systematic social sanctions. They both
argument, we will develop the four cases Karpik differ from judgement devices, upon which one
identifies. can decide to rely on or not, and also from formal,
Judgements devices are those which help the explicit, compulsory rules. Karpik does not try to
customer make a choice when the quality is set give a systematic list of these devices (he refers to
but unknown. In this case, the customer might Williamson 1993), but he distinguishes several of
turn to his network, by asking someone he trusts them, based on their origin. The unilateral norm is
for advice. If he has a friend who is a wine defined by one of the partners of the exchange, a
connoisseur, he might ask which producer of professional oath, for example. The coproduced
Puligny-Montrachet he should chose. If the cus- norm relies on the co-construction of the norm by
tomer cannot rely on such a personal judgement the partners of the exchange. An example of this
device, then he could turn to impersonal judge- is seen in a contract where they deliberately and
ment devices. In this category, Karpik explicitly detail their mutual commitment, to
distinguishes three main kinds. First, there are restrict and control it. These devices arose, first
rankings. Their purpose is to make hierarchies and foremost, in markets for services such as the
publicly visible, and therefore available to every- market for lawyers, or in Business to Business
one. Second, there is appellation. In order to markets, where market relations are often stable
benefit from an appellation, a producer needs to and repeated (Sako 1992; Mariotti 2005).
respect a set of rules and criteria that help reduce
the uncertainty about quality. For example, what
kind of grapes are used to produce the wine, and 2 Economics of Convention
where were these grapes grown? The last kind of
impersonal judgement device that Karpik In the very same year that Karpik published his
identifies is the guide, whose soft authority offers first paper formalizing his économie de la qualité,
preferences and explanations. The many guides the French Revue économique published a special
available on the market offer a selection and a issue entitled, Economics of Conventions. The
ranking, and they differ from one another by the authors came from very different fields of exper-
set of criteria they use to produce their selection, tise and schools of thought. Some were
5 A French Institutionalism in Economic Sociology? 67

statisticians working in the French institute of behavior, we need to consider that, people rely
public statistics, the INSEE (F. Eymard- on conventions to make their choices when uncer-
Duvernay, L. Thévenot), others (also coming tainty is very high (Karpik called them devices).
from the INSEE) were economists formerly These conventions should be identified and
identified as heterodox regulationists described, and the way economy really works
(A. Orléan), while others were sociologists who should be reappraised.
had worked for decades with Bourdieu The second set of hypotheses comes from a
(L. Boltanski). They proposed a very broad, very different, more sociological background.
ambitious, and heterogeneous framework, based This sociological tradition devotes a great deal
on separate but complementary hypotheses com- of attention to the operation of classification,
ing from very different intellectual traditions. performed by scholars or by social actors on a
Among them, one can see an economic tradition, daily basis. One can relate this program of
related to Keynes, and a sociological one, relying, research to the anthropological work developed
among others, on Bourdieu. by Bourdieu on the operations of classification
The first set of hypotheses came from a radical which were produced by Kabyle in the 1960s in
reading of J.M. Keynes’ work. In an early contri- Algeria. This first set of results was used by
bution, Olivier Favereau proposed a reading of Boltanski to propose his analysis of the history
Keynes, which was very different from the pre- of the category of Cadres (Boltanski 1987), and at
sentation of his work in classical macro-economic that same time Desrosières and Thévenot devoted
handbooks (Favereau 1985, 1989). According to their work to the history of statistical categories
Favereau, the real project of Keynes went back to (Desrosières and Thévenot 1988; Desrosières
his dissertation later published as A Treatise on 2002). A series of intuitions emerged from these
Probability (Keynes 1973b). In this work, and in works, which the economics of convention devel-
later works as well (see, for example, the chap. oped and generalized. First, the systems of
XII of the General Theory Keynes 1973a), classifications are never natural. Even though
Keynes distinguishes between two kinds of they are used in such a way that their history is
situations where decisions are to be made. In the forgotten, they are always the result of choices
first situation, it is possible to establish a set of and debates that can be brought to light by a
possible futures, and to match this list with an systematic investigation. Second, these categories
assessment of their probability to occur. In this are never neutral. They are always political when
situation, it is possible to calculate this, and the they shed light on certain aspects of reality while
assumption of rationality made by neo-classical overshadowing others, hence making some
economists is valid. In the second situation, it is actions acceptable and others inconceivable.
impossible to propose a list of future scenarios Third, these categories help building
and then match it with probabilities of occur- equivalences between things that otherwise
rence: as Keynes puts it, “we simply do not would be incommensurable, while making other
know” (Keynes 1973a, 113 f.) and therefore it is comparisons impossible.
impossible to calculate. In this kind of situation, These two sets of hypotheses are more or less
how can a decision be made? If we are unable to present in the works which, for at least a decade,
follow the results of our calculation, Keynes developed a self-designed framework known as
argues, it is still possible to decide if one relies the economics of convention. Among the many
on convention, conceived as a stabilized and empirical (see, for example, Stanziani 2003) or
shared way of doing things, which Keynes some- theoretical (Batifoulier 2001) contributions to this
times refers to in the General Theory, as our stream of research, there are three seminal works
animal spirits. Using a very different path than which we will focus on. Eymard-Duvernay and
Karpik, Favereau comes to the same conclusion. Marchal dedicated their work to the conventions
Neo-classical economics is incomplete. If we are used to assess the quality of a candidate in the
to develop a general account of economic labor market. It is an exemplary piece of
68 P. François

empirical work, inspired by the program of the involves a group; it relies on a network. There
economics of convention. The problem raised by are no general, abstract, formal, or explicit rules
Eymard-Duvernay and Marchal (Eymard- or criteria the recruiter should rely on, but rather a
Duvernay and Marchal 1997, 2000; Marchal set of relations is used to collect information,
2015) is a very simple one. When one hires some- from one recruiter to the other. The recruiter acts
one for a job, how will the candidate’s compe- as a mediator. In the fourth convention, the inter-
tence be assessed? The main thesis of the book is action, the recruiter works to build a trust rela-
that evaluating a candidate’s competence can be tionship with the candidate. The evaluation is
done in many ways, using different scales or built upon a symmetric commitment in the rela-
criteria. The issue that researchers should focus tion, and the recruiter should be careful to get the
on, therefore, is not the intrinsic competences of signals (of competence, or reliability) the candi-
the candidates, but the way these competences are date sent to him. Once these conventions have
evaluated by those in charge of hiring. The book been described, the researchers identify the places
presents the conventions of competence that where these different conventions might be used,
Eymard-Duvernay and Marchal identified. These combined, and how they might enter in conflict,
conventions can be identified crossing two in the hiring processes.
dimensions. First, does the recruiter interact Eymard-Duvernay and Marchal’s contribution
directly with the candidates (through a network is exemplary of an empirical approach using the
or in informal interviews), or is recruiting done at economics of convention. It is also a micro-
arm’s length (using market matching techniques sociological approach, using dense ethnographic
or institutional criteria)? Second, are the data to analyze hiring processes. Another contri-
situations of recruitment based on individual bution, by Michael Storper and Robert Salais
interactions, or are they mediated through collec- (Storper and Salais 1997), also relies on the
tive devices, such as networks or institutions? framework of the economics of convention, but
If one crosses these two dimensions, four they use it to develop a theoretical macro-
conventions emerge. The first convention is economic approach. The problem Salais and
called the institution, where judgement is based Storper wanted to tackle is very close to the one
on explicit rules that organize the matching pro- addressed, a few years later, by Hall and Soskice
cess between general job description categories in their 2001 book, Varieties of Capitalism (Hall
(kinds of firms, or positions) and candidate and Soskice 2001). The problem is how to
qualifications and experience. These rules are account for the heterogeneity of national ways
not applied automatically. The recruiter interprets of organizing contemporary capitalisms, in a con-
them, acting as a regulator. The candidate is text of growing interdependence and slowing eco-
described in the lexicon of the institution by con- nomic growth. The authors ambitiously intend to
sidering the qualifications. When using the sec- answer this question based on a renewed concep-
ond convention, the market, the recruiter aims at tion of social action, that might avoid what
hiring someone on a strictly rational basis. He Granovetter (1985) would have called an under-
prospects as many candidates as possible and or over-socialized conception of the individual.
organizes their competition in order to optimize Social actors, they argue, are not these closed
the quality of the hired candidate. The recruiter is monads who might know, better than anyone
a breeder. His main problem is not to be fair, but else, what their interests are and how they should
to be efficient in his selection, according to simple attain them. However, they are also not cultural
criteria. The last two conventions no longer fools, whose actions are completely determined
involve abstract or general criteria and rules. by internalized norms. Because social actions
They are based on interpersonal relations and always need to be coordinated among each
therefore can no longer be considered as institu- other, they are always uncertain; hence, they
tion, according to the definition we gave in the need conventions on which they could rely.
introduction of this chapter. The third one still These conventions might concern many aspects
5 A French Institutionalism in Economic Sociology? 69

of economic life, and for Salais and Storper the circulation of knowledge. Equipped with this
choices made about elementary conventions deal- abstract and systematic set of tools, Salais and
ing with products qualities, technology, and mar- Storper compare national trade specialty cases:
ket uncertainty, combine to define what they call fashion and high technology in France, design-
worlds of production. intensive manufacturing and precision metal
Salais and Storper identified four worlds of work in northeast central Italy, and the high tech-
production. In the industrial world, the risk nology regions in the United States. They also
remains predictable and calculable, standardized analyze the role of industrial policies. According
products are produced in long production runs in to them, these policies should pursue different
order to achieve economy of scales. The market goals from one place to the other, since all the
world is organized to cope with situations highly different worlds of production are not supposed to
unpredictable, the products are still standardized converge towards a market world, under the
but the production cycle is much shorter so that it impulse of the State.
can be adapted in case of great changes in the The final important contribution we would like
demand. In the interpersonal world, economic to present is possibly the most influential: the
actors also face high uncertainty, but the products book published in 1991 by Luc Boltanski and
are much more specialized and are designed to Laurent Thévenot, De la justification (Boltanski
meet individual demands. Last, the world of intel- and Thévenot 2006). The book is an impressive
lectual resources faces a predictable and calcula- attempt to provide a systematic, theoretical frame-
ble risk, but develops specialized products and work devoted to the analysis of disputes between
services adapted to individual needs. Each of social actors. It deals with how they argue when
these worlds are characterized by a specific set they criticize each other’s positions and justify
of conventions, central to the organization of their own. How do they reach an agreement?
cooperation. For example, the authors identify How do they deal with the many situations
three kinds of conventions of work: the where it is simply impossible to reach an agree-
conventions of productivity, the conventions of ment? For the authors, these situations of disputes
wages and the conventions of unemployment. can be explained by the identification of typical
Taken altogether, these conventions define a ways of justifying one’s position, typical ways
way to adapt to economic risk either by duration they propose to describe as polities (cites). Each
of the work or by the workforce employed. In the of these polities is characterized by a set of typical
interpersonal world, the convention of wage answers which they provide to issues which were
defines a wage that is either fixed and attached identified. What do all members of the polity have
to the person, or related to the product, and the in common? What are the different positions
adaptation to economic risk depends on personal members can achieve within the polity? What is
responsibility. In the market world, the worker is the hierarchy of these positions? How can one get
a travailleur à la pièce1 and he is supposed to be from one position to the other? The hypothesis is
available. If there are wide economic variations, that this move is costly; it implies a sacrifice.
his work volume varies accordingly. In the indus- Using these dimensions, it is possible to identify
trial world, jobs are ranked in a classification of six different polities, which the authors typify,
positions and wages which define an internal using great texts of the philosophical traditions.
market, and unemployment develops only in In these texts, the principles underlying these
periods of serious economic crisis. In the world polities are supposed to be more explicit than
of intellectual resources, the worker is considered elsewhere: the inspired polity, based on Saint
to be an expert and the locus of an investment, so Augustin’s The City of God; the market polity,
the adjustment to economic shocks relies on the exemplified by Adam Smith’s The Wealth of
Nations; the civic polity, relying on Rousseau’s
1
The French travailleur à la pièce is a free-lance worker Social Contract; the industrial polity, as it can be
who is paid by the number of pieces produced. typified by Saint Simon; the polity of fame, which
70 P. François

can be characterized using Hobbes’ Leviathan; read as a very long post-script to On Justification.
and the domestic polity, drawn on Bossuet’s The purpose of Boltanski and Chiapello is two-
predications. fold. First, they describe a new way to justify
Boltanski and Thévenot’s purpose is not only contemporary capitalism and, more precisely,
to describe these polities, but also to propose a the role of managers within it. In the 1960s,
theory of how people engage these principles of managers justified their working for a firm
justice within a dispute. They distinguish two because it was necessary to satisfy the needs of
typical situations. In the first situation, two actors the customer; in the 1990s, work was supposed to
argue about how to assess a situation, but when be meaningful for the managers. This shift had
they agree on the relevant criteria used to assess organizational consequences. In the 1960s, the
the situation, they place themselves in the same job of a manager, who worked in a hierarchical
polity. In this case, the dispute might be settled by and bureaucratic area could make sense in and of
purifying the situation, in order words, by getting itself, in his own eye and in those of his
rid of all the elements, which are not directly colleagues. In the 1990s, it was no longer the
related to or coherent with the polity. In the sec- case: to make sense of his job, a manager needed
ond situation, the dispute is first about the rele- to be engaged in a project-based organization.
vant polity that should be mobilized to evaluate Hence, the new polity identified by the book is
the situation. For example, a poet who sells very called projective. The aim of the book is also to
few books is said to be little, according to the understand how new justifications emerge, and
market polity, but great in the polity of inspira- the role of criticism in this emergence. The justi-
tion, if he is recognized by his peers. Reaching an fication of the role of managers evolved from the
agreement in this second case might be more 1960s to the 1990s. Because the justification of
difficult than in the first one, since the actors the 1960s faced sharp criticism, the relationships
involved in the dispute should clarify the between the managers and their work evolved.
principles for evaluating the situation. Very Boltanski and Thevenot’s 1991 book has been
often, reaching this kind of agreement on compet- very influential, but is this the case of the eco-
ing principles is impossible, and settling of the nomics of convention at large? If one takes the
dispute goes through what the authors call a com- program of the 1989 special issue of the Revue
promise, in other words, a situation where the économique seriously, the situation might be
actors involved in a dispute agree to end it with- found as rather misleading, especially from the
out clarifying the principles on which the agree- perspective of an economist. What was supposed
ment is built. to be an alternative program, even more general
The somewhat rococo and sophisticated and broader than the orthodox, neo-classical par-
framework proposed by Boltanski and Thévenot adigm, did not shift the balance of power, not
has inspired many empirical works, including even in France, where over the last three decades
Chateauraynaud’s analysis of professional the influence of heterodox economists has consid-
disputes (Chateauraynaud 1991), Auray’s sociol- erably decreased, and where heterodox scholars
ogy of hackers (Auray 2013), and de Blic’s anal- have engaged into sometimes violent debates
ysis of financial scandals (de Blic 2005). On a (Postel and Sobel 2001; Amable and Palombarini
comparative and more macro-sociological 2005). In sociology, the situation is more bal-
ground, Lamont and Thévenot use this frame- anced. The most systematic attempt to provide a
work to systematically compare justification grand sociology, On Justification, has been
logics in France and in the United States (Lamont almost completely disowned by their authors
and Thévenot 2000). The most visible contribu- (see, for example, Thévenot 2006; Boltanski
tion extending Boltanski and Thévenot’s On Jus- 2011). However, the Economics of Conventions
tification remains the book written by Boltanski has been influential over the last two decades, in
and Chiapello, The New Spirit of Capitalism France and abroad, even though not in the form of
(Boltanski and Chiapello 2005), which can be a turnkey or all-inclusive theoretical system. It
5 A French Institutionalism in Economic Sociology? 71

provided a toolkit from which social scientists can it is framed by brands, rankings, or appellations.
pick and choose intuitions, which they can com- In other words, the characteristics of what is
bine with their own perspectives. In this way, the exchanged are always changing and negotiable.
posterity of the economics of convention is not so It is because these characteristics keep changing
different from Karpik’s writings. This may be so that a match between a specific customer and a
because their basic assumptions are quite close. specific supplier is possible. Analyzing a market,
Many economic sociological works published in therefore, consists in focusing on specific dyadic
French, especially when they deal with market relationships. Analyzing a market, then,
situations, considered these intuitions and presupposes an understanding of how a specific
concepts as classical propositions, in the best product can be successfully detached from some-
sense of the word. They are part of the basic one (the seller) and attached to someone else (the
toolkit of the economic sociologist. Be it to buyer).
study the market of undertaking (Trompette Callon and his colleagues claim to advocate
2008), of interior designers (Ollivier 2011), or of for a complete and radical change and yet, after
schools (Dronkers et al. 2010) the authors refer to getting rid of their rhetorical strategies, what they
conventions or devices that allow the actors to propose seems quite classical. When Callon
face situations of market uncertainty. The way explains that one should not analyze a market,
these conventions or devices are characterized but should rather focus on the way a product is
rely on empirical matters: sometimes, Karpik’s detached and attached from this or that actor, one
typology is more useful, sometimes convention- can wonder if he adds anything to the idea that, in
alist distinctions make more sense. a market situation, someone decides to sell some-
thing (to detach this product from oneself) and
someone decides to buy it (to become attached to
3 Economics of Qualities it), which is a rather trivial idea. More impor-
and Performativity tantly, Callon explains that the market process
through which the product is changed is a process
The last approach we would like to present was of qualification: the product evolves because it is
published a decade later than the seminal ranked, or evaluated, or assessed by what Karpik
intuitions of the economics of quality and of the would have called a device. At the end of the day,
economics of conventions. It identified the alleged the differences between Karpik and the
shared weaknesses of these two approaches and conventionalists on the one side, and Callon and
attempted to overcome them. For Callon and his his colleagues on the other side seem to be onto-
colleagues (Callon et al. 2000; Callon 2002), a logical at best, and maybe only rhetorical. Karpik
first weakness came from the fact that both and conventionalists consider social entities to be
Karpik and the conventionalists identified two stabilized at times, while Callon perceives these
kinds of situations. There were situations where entities as always being fluid. From a metaphysi-
it was possible to calculate, and situations where cal point of view, these differences of conception
uncertainty was too high to rely on probabilities matter. Their consequences, for an empirical soci-
to make a decision. For Callon, this distinction ology of economic life, are not so dramatic. What
was only possible if one perceives what is should be analyzed to understand how concrete
exchanged as a good with stable characteristics. market interactions actually evolve is quite close,
Instead, Callon explains that one should consider regardless of using Karpik, conventionalists, or
what is exchanged as a product, something with- Callon.
out set characteristics. The product is always Another weakness identified by Callon in the
engaged in an ongoing process of transformation, approach of Karpik, or of the conventionalists,
be it during the period of its production (in a comes from the fact that a distinction is made
factory, for example) or during its career in the between the kind of reasoning actors mobilize in
market, when it goes from hand to hand and when different situations. Sometimes it is possible to
72 P. François

calculate a price, or a quantity, and sometimes it is properly describes the economic reality, but
not, and then one relies on qualities. For Callon because it contributes to shape it.
and Muniesa (2005), this distinction is a formal This argument, which was already formulated
one at best. In each and every situation, one relies by Cournot (2001) or by Weber (2005), when it
simultaneously on prices and on quality to make comes to the relations between economics and the
up one’s mind, one calculates and evaluates economy, can be very powerful when mobilized
qualities. Moreover, in order to calculate or to to analyze some very specific markets, where the
evaluate quality, an economic actor needs to rely tools used to calculate prices rely on cutting-edge
on tools that support his decision. Callon and economics. This is the case, especially in finance,
Muniesa (2005) draw on this idea to propose an and this is where this argument has been exten-
enlarged conception of economic decision, they sively used and discussed (see, for example,
call calculation conceived in a very broad sense: Muniesa 2000; McKenzie 2006). The
Calculating does not necessarily mean performing performativity argument is very useful when it
mathematical or even numerical operations . . . Cal- comes to financial markets. It has been verified
culation starts by establishing distinctions between in other markets as well, such as the energy mar-
things or states of the world, and by imagining and ket (Reverdy 2014). It is less relevant, though,
estimating courses of action associated with those
things or with those states as well as their when it comes to many markets where the
consequences. By starting with this type of defini- connections between economics, as a theory,
tion (wide, but usual) of the notion of calculation, and economy as a set of practices, are much
we try to avoid the distinction (also conventional, looser, as is the case in so many markets.
but too sharp) between judgement and calculation
(Callon and Muniesa 2005, 1231). While the arguments of Karpik, the
conventionalists, or Callon, were very close to
One can, of course, wonder if taking a term each other and almost redundant, the
and broadening its definition in such a way, that performativity argument is much more specific.
its new meaning is in no way related to its usual Its main point is not to say that actors need tools
use is the best conceptual strategy (for sharp to help them make decisions, but rather to stress
criticism of these rhetorical practices see Gingras the fact that choosing to rely on this or that tool
1995). In the specific case of Callon and his makes a difference: it has consequences. Tools, in
colleagues, the most important consequence of other words, are not neutral. This point was
this concept has been to stress the importance of already stressed by conventionalists, but Callon
certain devices in specific situations (see Callon and his colleagues made it very clear on technical
1998). When they calculate (in the classical sense grounds and through precise mechanisms. How
of performing numerical operations), economic far can these devices be assimilated to
actors use devices that incorporate hypothesis institutions? As we proposed in the introduction,
and reasoning of economic theory. Therefore, one of the key dimensions of an institution is that
economic theory changes the reality: in Callon’s it is a priori. An institution is not a hypothesis; it is
lexicon, economic theory performs or transforms a frame. An institution helps frame the world; it is
economic reality (Callon 2007). The argument is not a hypothesis that should be tested. If it is
easy to grasp. When actors need to make a deci- proven wrong, it will be used nonetheless, at
sion, they may sometimes rely on devices that least for a while. Or course, in Callon’s concep-
incorporate economic theory. When they want to tion of performativity, models that shape the
calculate the price of a financial asset, they draw economy are supposed to emanate from scientific
on models that calculate this price, using a theories, and hence may be considered as a
hypothesis based in financial economics. Conse- hypothesis rather than an institution at times. In
quently, in these fields, the economy (as a set of this light, the way McKenzie and Millo (2003)
practices) may validate the predictions of eco- describe the use of the Black-Scholes formula in
nomics (as a discipline), not because economics the development of derivatives market is
illuminating. When the market for derivatives
5 A French Institutionalism in Economic Sociology? 73

started to (re)develop in the 1970s in Chicago, conflating the consequences (this institution is
two groups of traders competed with each other. there, therefore it helps to solve a problem) and
The younger traders used the Black-Scholes for- the causes (how this institution came into being
mula to elaborate their strategies. They beat the there). Only if one can prove that the institution
older ones, who had been trained as traders on the was developed to solve this problem, can the
grain market, and who completely ignored finan- function of the institution be assimilated to its
cial mathematics. After 10 years, at the beginning cause.
of the 1980s, old traders had almost all Another problematic dimension of functional-
disappeared, and all traders used the Black- ism is that it often goes together with an implicit
Scholes formula. However, they used it as an irenicism. This point has been made by Friedberg
institution: they had no reflexivity in their use of (1996) when he discussed the theory of Boltanski
the models, and they did not pay much attention and Thévenot (2006). Friedberg argued that when
to their conditions of validity. In 1987, a crisis hit actors take part in a dispute, they seldom engage
the market that completely changed the traders’ in the process described by Boltanski and
relation with the formula. They now knew that Thévenot. They do not confront their criteria of
using this formula might lead to a crash. There- judgement, nor do they try to purify the situation
fore, they decided to be much more careful, and if from all the elements which are external to the
the formula was not used as a hypothesis (the aim polities they refer to. They would rather engage in
of the traders was not to test it), it was nonetheless power relationships, and they solve the dispute
used in a much more reflexive way. based on their resources and their tactics. In other
words, conventions may not be as important as
conventionalists say, since they do not define the
4 Critics and Limits solutions most of the time, power does. The
arguments made by Amable and Palombarini
These three approaches have generated much (2005) formulated from a completely different
research and they are now part of the classical perspective (heterodox neo-Marxist economics),
toolkit of French economic sociologists. Since the make the same kind of point. Amable and
main texts of Karpik, of the conventionalists, and Palombarini stress the confusion, in the econom-
of Callon and his colleagues are available in ics of convention, of ethics and politics, on the
English, they can be read, discussed, and used one side, and of politics and normativity on the
by a wider audience all over the world. In spite other side. They also stress the conviction
of their usefulness, they have been facing three conventionalists share that dynamics of
main kinds of criticisms. institutions might be explained by the search of
The first criticism deals with the implicit func- consensus that spontaneously develops in a com-
tionalism implied by these approaches. This func- munity of moral individuals. Instead, Amable and
tionalism clearly appears in the way the Palombarini underscore the importance of con-
arguments of Karpik and of some flict. The idea of performativity, as it was devel-
conventionalists are formulated. In certain oped by Callon and his colleagues, has been
situations, actors face uncertainty (here is the criticized for the same reason. Mirowski and
problem); hence, institutions (devices, Nik-Khah (2007) explain that several conceptions
conventions) develop to help them face the situa- of what a market is, are involved in the develop-
tion (here is the solution). There is no doubt that, ment of a market. It is not economic theory per se
as many social entities, institutions have a func- that performs the market; rather, the market is
tion. Functionalism may be an analytical prob- transformed by some actors, who happen to
lem, if one thinks that because the function of refer to a specific theory. Market is not performed
something is identified, then one knows the why by theory; it is shaped by those who use theories
and the how (the cause) of this thing. In this case, to make their point and win the fight against their
as Durkheim (1990, 90) puts it, there is a risk of competitors. Focusing on economic theory is
74 P. François

focusing on a smoke screen, while the real explain why almost no studies were conducted
mechanisms, which imply power and conflict, to test whether the influence of the device was
are somewhere else. Such critics can be partly strong enough to overrule the determination of
internalized. For example, Boltanski and social class.
Thévenot identified cases where no agreement A final criticism can be recalled here, stressing
could be reached and where solving the dispute the fact that all these approaches are first and
involved negotiation, conflict, and power foremost descriptive. Karpik and the
relationships. The discussion is rather on what is conventionalists dedicated a lot of effort to
incidental and what is necessary in the analysis. If develop typologies that help classify the devices
90% of the cases rely on mechanisms which are or conventions. However, they do not explain
peripheral to the theoretical framework, then the where the power of these devices comes from.
framework might be judged as not being very Identifying the source of an institution’s power
useful. This criticism has been addressed to would help bring them into a causal relationship.
Boltanski and Thévenot: their theory is very How is it that, if Robert Parker grades this wine
sophisticated, but there might be a few situations 96/100 its price will rise; while if Pierre François
it helps one understand. If institutions only appear gives this wine the same grade, nobody cares?
as a way of dressing up conflicting interests and Here the weakness of French institutionalism
power relationships, then it should be said more connects to the research agenda of new institu-
explicitly. tionalism developed in the US (Hwang and
Another criticism addressed to these Powell 2005; Powell and Colyvas 2008). Because
frameworks stresses that they ignore class they focused mainly on macro or meso situations,
relationships. In some cases, this is explicit and often approached by statistical tools, new
deliberate. The first paragraphs of Boltanski and institutionalists lack a clear understanding of the
Thévenot’s On Justification warns the reader that way institutions and actions are linked to each
in the book, he will not find the usual concepts of other. In French institutionalism, this link is also
social sciences publications: no groups, no social missing. None of them, Karpik, conventionalists
classes. The same is true for Karpik’s approach. or Callon proposed an explicit theory of action
Karpik’s book aims at explaining how consumers that would explain the way devices, or
make their choices in a market. What he wants to conventions, connect to actions. Their under-
analyze has been a central issue for social standing of this link remains implicit and merely
scientists for a long time. To this question, behaviorist: in a situation of uncertainty, a device
together with Bourdieu’s Distinction (Bourdieu is there (stimulus) and the actor uses it (answer).
1984), the answer of sociologists is clear and Discussing both French and US institutionalism,
straightforward: the choices of the consumers François (2011) draws on Wittgenstein’s second
depend on their social class. These two philosophy to develop a framework that might
hypotheses can be discussed and confronted. explain how institutions and actions connect in a
When they make a choice in a market, do social more explicit and dynamic way. He suggests
actors rely on institutions, or on their habitus? considering that no social entity is by nature an
One, the social class hypothesis has been proven institution. A rule, a category, or a model is an
many times, while the idea that actors use institution only if, and only as long as, an actor
institutions has not been tested very much. decides to use it as such. According to
Much of the research dedicated to the analysis Wittgenstein, the power of the rule does not lie
of market devices does not focus on their effects in the rule itself; it is conferred to the rule by those
on consumers; rather they describe the device and who use it as a rule. Of course, those who confer
sometimes analyze the many choices and give the power to the rule they follow are sometimes com-
long story that led to the emergence of this or that pelled to do so. In this case, the power of the rule
device. This focus on the upstream of the institu- does not come from the rule, it comes from the
tion, rather than on its consequences, might entities (the police, the judge, the chief, powerful
5 A French Institutionalism in Economic Sociology? 75

groups, or the elite) that enforce rule. More gen- systematize mathematical finance in 1950s, in its
erally, however, if one wants to understand the theoretical framework and later in the tools that
power of a device, convention, or theory, then one rely on it, this confusion remains implicit, undis-
needs to understand the reasons why someone cussed, and permanent. This set of intuitions,
uses this device as a rule. This is what makes drawn on Wittgenstein, identify as the core of
the devices or conventions studied by French the problem, what is taken for granted by French
institutionalists so fascinating. One can barely institutionalists: why is it that one actor will fol-
identify any entities that force their users to rely low this institution? What transforms this device
on them as a rule. Placing the power of the insti- or convention into such a powerful tool?
tution outside the institution itself, while being The frameworks developed in the 1990s and in
willing to follow it, also means that an institution the 2000s by French economic sociologists are
may not always be as powerful as it seems. now part of the classical toolkit of economic
Ollivier (2011) shows that the certification pro- sociology. It helps clarify the importance of cer-
posed by a professional union of interior tain devices in specific situations, where relying
designers is used as an institution only for the on calculus is insufficient. It also helps distin-
newcomers in the labor market. When they are guish between the many kinds of devices that
in school, designers are convinced by the union might be mobilized by social actors. These ana-
that this certification will be an asset for their lytical decompositions are certainly the most use-
career. In their first years as professionals, they ful dimensions of these frameworks. Questions
try to rely on it, but they realize that it does not remain, nonetheless, that should not lead one to
make much difference: no customers pay any abandon these distinctions, but to articulate them
attention to it. Therefore, they abandon it. The with classical tools of social sciences such as
certification does not disappear completely, social classes, or to focus on the underlying
since new entrants in the labor markets have mechanisms that might explain their causal
been convinced to use it, before they realize, in power.
turn, that it is useless.
Following Wittgenstein’s conception of the
rule also helps understand where an institution
References
comes from, how it emerges, develops, and dies.
The grades Robert Parker gave at the beginning of Amable, B., & Palombarini, S. (2005). L’économie n’est
the 1980s did not change anything in the wine pas une science morale. Paris: Raisons d’agir.
market. At that time, Robert Parker was just a Auray, N. (2013). Enquète sur les Institutions. Le Hacker,
lawyer in a suburb of Baltimore. Robert Parker’s l’Etat et la Politique. Nice: Mémoire original d’HDR.
Batifoulier, P. (2001). Théorie des Convention. Paris:
grades became an institution only when actors Economica.
collectively started using these grades as an a Benquet, M., Bourgeron, T., & Reynaud, B. (2019).
priori criteria to decide which wine was good. Économie Politique de la Financiarisation. Actes de la
To explain the birth of an institution, one should Recherche en Sciences Sociales, 229(4), 4–13.
Bergeron, H., & Castel, P. (2016). Les Habits neufs du
not focus on the institution, but on those who use Néo-institutionnalisme? La Redécouverte de l’ordre
it. François and Frezal (2018), for example, Mésologique et de l’agency. L’Annee Sociologique,
explain how the conflation of hazard and hetero- 66(1), 31–72.
geneity in statistical reasoning became an institu- Boltanski, L. (1987). The making of a class. Cadres in
French society. Cambridge: Cambridge University
tion first in mathematical finance, then in the Press.
insurance industry. In the early stage of Boltanski, L. (2011). On critique: A sociology of emanci-
probabilities, this confusion was sometimes pation. Cambridge: Polity Press.
accepted, but sometimes rejected. It became Boltanski, L., & Chiapello, E. (2005). The new spirit of
capitalism. London: Verso.
largely invisible with the axiomatization Boltanski, L., & Thévenot, L. (2006). On justification:
conducted by Kolmogorov in the 1930s. Since Economies of worth. Princeton: Princeton University
this axiomatization was largely used to Press.
76 P. François

Bourdieu, P. (1984). Distinction: A social critique of the Favereau, O. (1985). L’incertain dans la “Révolution
judgement of taste. Cambridge: Harvard University Keynésienne”: L’hypothèse Wittgenstein. Economies
Press. et Sociétés. Série Oeconomica, 19(3), 29–72.
Callon, M. (1998). Introduction: The embeddedness of Favereau, O. (1989). Marchés Internes, Marchés Externes.
economic markets in economics. In M. Callon (Ed.), Revue Économique, 40(2), 273–328.
The laws of the markets (pp. 1–57). Oxford: Blackwell. Fiss, P. C., & Zajac, E. J. (2004). The diffusion of ideas
Callon, M. (2002). Pour en finir avec les Incertitudes. over contested terrain: The (non)adoption of a share-
Sociologie du Travail, 44(3), 261–267. holder value among German firms. Administrative Sci-
Callon, M. (2007). What does it mean to say that econom- ence Quarterly, 49(4), 501–534.
ics is performative? In F. Muniesa, D. McKenzie, & Fligstein, N. (1990). The transformation of corporate con-
L. Siu (Eds.), Do economists make markets? trol. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
(pp. 311–357). Princeton: Princeton University Press. Fligstein, N. (2001). The architecture of markets: An eco-
Callon, M., & Muniesa, F. (2005). Peripheral vision: Eco- nomic sociology of twenty-first-century capitalist
nomic markets as calculative collective devices. Orga- societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
nization Studies, 26(8), 1229–1250. Foureault, F. (2018). L’organisation de la Financiarisation.
Callon, M., Meadel, C., & Rabeharisoa, V. (2000). Revue Francaise de Sociologie, 59(1), 37–69.
L’économie des Qualités. Politix, 13(52), 211–239. François, P. (2011). Puissance et Genèse des Institutions:
Chateauraynaud, F. (1991). La Faute Professionnelle: Un Cadre Analytique. In P. François (Ed.), Vie et Mort
Une Sociologie des Conflits de Responsabilité. Paris: des Institutions Marchandes (pp. 39–79). Paris:
Métailié. Presses de Sciences po.
Cochoy, F. (2002). Une Sociologie du Packaging, ou l’âne François, P., & Frezal, S. (2018). Instituer l’incohérence.
de Buridan face au Marché. Paris: Presses L’amalgame aléa et Hétérogénéité dans le Secteur
Universitaires de France. Assuranciel. Sociologie du Travail, 60, 1.
Cournot, A.-A. (2001). Recherches sur les Principes François, P., & Lemercier, C. (2016). Financialization
Mathématiques de la Théorie des Richesses. Paris: French style (1979–2009). Changes in large firms and
Dunod. conversion of elites. Revue Française de Sociologie,
Davis, G. F., Diekmann, K. A., & Tinsley, C. H. (1994). 57(2), 269–320.
The decline and fall of the conglomerate firm in the Friedberg, E. (1996). Power and rules: The organizational
1980s: The deinstitutionalization of an organizational dynamics of collective action. Beatty: Avebury.
form. American Sociological Review, 59(4), 547–570. Gadrey, J. (1994). La Modernisation des Services
de Bandt, J., & Gadrey, J. (Eds.). (1994). Relations de Professionnels. Revue Française de Sociologie, 35(2),
Service, Marchés de Services. Paris: CNRS Editions. 163–195.
de Blic, D. (2005). Moraliser l’argent. Politix, 71(3), Gingras, Y. (1995). Un Air de Radicalisme. Actes de la
61–82. Recherche en Sciences Sociales, 108, 3–17.
Desrosières, A. (2002). The politics of large numbers. A Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social struc-
history of statistical reasoning. Cambridge: Harvard ture: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal
University Press. of Sociology, 91, 481–510.
Desrosières, A., & Thévenot, L. (1988). Les Catégories Greenwood, R., Oliver, C., Suddaby, R., & Sahlin-
Socioprofessionnelles. Paris: La Découverte. Anderson, K. (Eds.). (2008). The sage handbook of
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. (1983). The Iron cage organizational institutionalism. Thousand Oaks: Sage.
revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective Hall, P., & Soskice, D. (Eds.). (2001). Varieties of capital-
rationality in organizational fields. American Sociolog- ism: The institutional foundations of comparative
ical Review, 48(2), 147–160. advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Dronkers, J., Felouzis, G., & van Zanten, A. (2010). Edu- Hatchuel, A. (1995). Les Marchés à Prescripteur. In
cation markets and school choice. Educational A. Jacob & H. Vérin (Eds.), L’inscription Sociale du
Research and Education, 16(2), 99–105. Marché (pp. 205–225). Paris: L’Harmattan.
Durkheim, É. (1990). Les Règles de la Méthode Hubert, H., & Mauss, M. (1985). Esquisse d’une Théorie
Sociologique. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France. Générale de la Magie. In M. Mauss (Ed.), Sociologie et
Eymard-Duvernay, F., & Marchal, E. (1997). Façons de Anthropologie (pp. 3–142). Paris: Presses
Recruter. Le Jugement des Compétences sur le Marché Universitaires de France.
du Travail. Paris: Métailié. Hwang, H., & Powell, W. W. (2005). Institutions and
Eymard-Duvernay, F., & Marchal, E. (2000). Qui Calcule entrepreneurship. In S. A. Alvarez, R. Agarwal, &
Trop finit par Déraisonner: Les Experts du Marché du O. Sorenson (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship
Travail. Sociologie du Travail, 42(3), 411–433. research (pp. 201–232). Kluwer: Springer.
Fauconnet, P., & Mauss, M. (1971). La Sociologie: Objet Karpik, L. (1989). L’Economie de la Qualité. Revue
et Méthode. In M. Mauss (Ed.), Essais de Sociologie française de sociologie., 30(2), 187–210.
(pp. 6–41). Paris: Seuil. Karpik, L. (1996). Dispositifs de Confiance et
Engagements Crédibles. Sociologie du travail, 38(4),
527–551.
5 A French Institutionalism in Economic Sociology? 77

Karpik, L. (1999). French lawyers: A study in collective movement in French gastronomy. American Journal of
action, 1274–1994. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Sociology, 108(4), 795–843.
Karpik, L. (2000). Le Guide Rouge Michelin. Sociologie Reverdy, T. (2014). La Construction Politique du Prix de
du Travail, 42(3), 369–391. l’énergie. Paris: Presses de Sciences po.
Karpik, L. (2002). Que Faire des Singularités? Sociologie Sako, M. (1992). Prices, quality and trust: Inter-firm
du Travail, 44(3), 279–284. relations in Britain and Japan. Cambridge: Cambridge
Karpik, L. (2010). Valuing the unique: The economics of University Press.
singularities. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Stanziani, A. (Ed.). (2003). La Qualité des Produits en
Keynes, J. M. (1973a). The collected writings VII. The France (XVIIIè–XXè siècles). Paris: Belin.
general theory of employment, interest and money. Stiglitz, J. (1987). The causes and consequences of the
London: Macmillan. dependence of quality on prices. Journal of Economic
Keynes, J. M. (1973b). The collected writings VIII. A Literature, 25(1), 1–48.
treatise on probability. London: Macmillan. Storper, M., & Salais, R. (1997). Worlds of production.
Lamont, M., & Thévenot, L. (2000). Rethinking compara- The action framework of the economy. Cambridge:
tive cultural sociology. Repertoires of evaluation in Harvard University Press.
France and the United States. Cambridge: Cambridge Teil, G. (2001). La Production du Jugement Esthétique sur
University Press. les Vins par la Critique Vinicole. Sociologie du Tra-
Marchal, E. (2015). Les Embarras des Recruteurs. vail, 43(1), 67–89.
Enquête sur le Marché du Travail. Paris: Presses de Thévenot, L. (2006). L’action au Pluriel. Paris: La
l’EHESS. Découverte.
Mariotti, F. (2005). Qui Gouverne l’entreprise en Réseau? Trompette, P. (2008). Le Marché des Défunts. Paris:
Paris: Presses de Sciences po. Presses de sciences Po.
McKenzie, D. (2006). An engine, not a camera. How Viallet-Thévenin, S. (2015). Du champion national au
financial models shape markets. Cambridge: MIT champion international. Revue Francaise de Science
Press. Politique, 65(5), 761–783.
McKenzie, D., & Millo, Y. (2003). Constructing a market: Weber, M. (2005). La Théorie de l’utilité Marginale et la
The historical sociology of a financial derivatives “loi Fondamentale de la Psychophysique”. Revue
exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 109(1), Française de Sociologie, 46(4), 905–920.
107–145. Williamson, O. E. (1993). Calculativeness, trust and eco-
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized nomic organization. Journal of Law and Economics,
organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. 36(1), 453–486.
American Journal of Sociology, 83(2), 340–363.
Mirowski, P., & Nik-Khah, E. (2007). Markets made flesh:
Performativity, and a problem in science studies, aug- François, Pierre is a CNRS research professor in
mented with consideration of the FCC auctions. In Sciences Po, Paris (Centre de sociologie des
F. Muniesa, D. McKenzie, & L. Siu (Eds.), Do organisations). He is also the dean of the school of
economists make markets? (pp. 190–224). Princeton: research of Sciences Po, Paris.
Princeton University Press. Research topics: His main research topics concern the
Muniesa, F. (2000). Un Robot Walrasien. Cotation sociology of art (music and poetry) and of contemporary
Électronique et Justesse de la Découverte des Prix. capitalism. He is working on a historical sociology of
Politix, 52(4), 121–154. French firms and their managing directors from the
Ollivier, C. (2011). Naissance et Survie d’une Institution. beginning of the 19th century. Recent publications:
La Qualification Professionnelle des Architectes Dubois, Sebastien, and Pierre François. 2021. Introducing
d’intérieur. In P. François (Ed.), Vie et mort des Aesthetics Back in Status Analysis. The Case of French
institutions marchandes (pp. 195–223). Paris: Presses Contemporary Poetry. American Behavioral Scientist,
de Sciences po. 65/1. François, Pierre, and Sylvestre Frezal. 2018.
Postel, N., & Sobel, R. (2001). L’impensé de l’hétérodoxie Instituer l'incohérence. L'amalgame aléa et hétérogénéité
Économique Française. Les Temps Modernes, 615–6 dans le secteur assuranciel. Sociologie du travail 60/1.
(4), 321–346. François, Pierre, and Claire Lemercier. 2016. Financiali-
Powell, W. W., & Colyvas, J. A. (2008). zation French Style (1979–2009). Changes in Large Firms
Microfoundations of institutional theory. In and Conversion of Elites. Revue française de sociologie
R. Greenwood, C. Oliver, R. Suddaby, & K. Sahlin- 57/2: 269–320. François, Pierre. 2014. Ebbs and Flows of
Anderson (Eds.), The sage handbook of organizational French Capitalism. In The Power of Corporate Networks.
institutionalism (pp. 276–298). Thousand Oaks: Sage. A Comparative and Historical Perspective, eds. Thomas
Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. (Ed.). (1991). The new David, and Gerharda Westerhuis, 149–68. London:
institutionalism in organizational analysis. Chicago: Rouledge. François, Pierre. 2013. Career Paths and
The University of Chicago Press. Hierarchies in the Pure Pole of the Literary Field: the
Rao, H., Monin, P., & Durand, R. (2003). Institutional Case of Contemporary Poetry. Poetics 41/3: 501‑23.
change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle Cuisine as an identity
Transcending History’s Heavy Hand:
The Future in Economic Action 6
Jens Beckert and Timur Ergen

1 Introduction the investigation of long-standing puzzles in the


analysis of capitalist economies. As will become
The core theoretical developments in the new clear throughout our chapter, this action-
economic sociology to date concern meso- and theoretical focus shall by no means deny the
macro-level aspects, such as the role played by central explanatory importance of social
culture, groups, institutions, and networks in eco- structures in sociological analyses of the econ-
nomic life. With few notable exceptions (Etzioni omy. Rather, we shall demonstrate how concep-
1988; Swedberg 1998; Beckert 2002; Whitford tual work on the micro-level may produce new
2002), action theory, in particular, has not been at insights into how and when social structures play
the center of recent sociological theorizing of the a role in modern economies.
economy. In this vein, the central programmatic Unlike economic sociology and political econ-
argument of Granovetter’s (1985) seminal omy, expectations are a major explanatory factor
founding manifesto can well be summarized as a in economics. Since the late nineteenth century,
plea to challenge conventional economic theory economic explanations have had at their core the
not regarding models of action and decision- idea that economic outcomes emerge from the
making, but by emphasizing the influence of aggregation of forward-looking decisions made
social structures on economic outcomes by economic agents (Evans and Honkapohja
(Swedberg 1997, 162). 2015; Doganova 2018). In this sense, Andrew
The imagined-futures approach to economic Abbott (2005, 406) characterized typical eco-
sociology described in this chapter takes a decid- nomic explanations as “precisely the reverse of
edly different approach. Building on arguments the sociological ancestors’ plot, which looks back
about how actors form expectations, it at the causes funneling into a final result.
demonstrates how micro-level theory develop- Economists focus not on the end of a period, but
ment can form the basis of a productive research on its beginning; they study not the origins of an
agenda in economic sociology and contribute to outcome, but the descendants of a decision.”
Sociological approaches focusing on expectations
in the economy pursue a similar explanatory strat-
Authors in alphabetical order. For comments on earlier
drafts we thank Alexandra Hees, Marcin Serafin, and egy. They analyze how images of the future
Lisa Suckert. emerge and constitute social action. Compared
with more established explanatory approaches in
J. Beckert (*) · T. Ergen
economic sociology, sociological analyses of
Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies in Cologne,
Cologne, Germany expectations to date, represent an unconsolidated
e-mail: jb1@mpifg.de; te@mpifg.de and only loosely structured research field. As we
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 79
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_6
80 J. Beckert and T. Ergen

document in this chapter, the field is economic sociology and political economy stress
characterized, its youth notwithstanding by a the malleability of social action by the past. What
number of shared classics, common lines of argu- is more, explanations of social action highlighting
ment, and unifying research interests. actors’ orientation towards the future have often
We present the structure, potential been portrayed as overly parsimonious and con-
contributions, and challenges of the field in four textually simplistic. This was Emile Durkheim’s
steps. Section 2 lays out the main argument and (1984) strategy when he developed his analytical
situates it in the relevant literature. Section 3 program in opposition to that of Herbert Spencer.
highlights selected empirical applications to the “The past predetermines the future,” he polemi-
economy. Subsequently, we discuss core research cally summarized his approach to the role of
questions of an economic sociology focusing on social norms (Durkheim 1984, 302). Imagined-
expectations in Sect. 4. Finally, Sect. 5 futures approaches to economic sociology do not
summarizes the argument and speculates about deny the influence of history’s heavy hand
its future development. (Ikenberry 1994) on social outcomes. They rather
try to develop a genuinely sociological approach
to future-oriented action in capitalist economies
2 Uncertainty and the Social and map the interplay between the effects of
Constitution of Expectations social structures, past experiences, and future
orientations.
Unlike traditional societies, modern capitalist This approach is best summarized in contrast
societies are characterized by a perception of the to modern economic theory. While there exists a
future as contingent, malleable by actors, and rich lineage of thinking psychologically, and to
entailing open time horizons. As pointedly some extent sociologically, about the formation
described by Pierre Bourdieu, traditional peasant of expectations in economics (Keynes 1936;
communities typically live “in the very rhythm of Shiller 2019), modern financial and macroeco-
the world with which [they are] bound up” nomics, in particular, build on models of perfect
(Bourdieu 1979, 27). “Nothing,” Bourdieu foresight (e.g., Lucas and Sargent 1978).
(1979, 8) conjectured, “is more foreign to the Expectations in this influential view are individ-
pre-capitalist economy than representation of the ual beliefs about the future that make the best
future . . . as a field of possibles to be explored and possible use of all available information (Muth
mastered by calculation.” While possibly over- 1961). In this sense, rational expectations are
drawn in their stark juxtaposition (Tavory and determined by sets of information and are objec-
Eliasoph 2013), change from strongly scripted to tively correct. They emerge from the optimal way
predominantly open relationships to the future in of processing known information. While com-
the course of capitalist development is now a monly meant as simplifying assumptions to ease
widely shared historical diagnosis (see Beckert macroeconomic modelling, applications of ratio-
2016, Chap. 2). nal expectations-theory often entail plainly
Beckert (2016) has argued that this historical absurd depictions of economic foresight (Elster
transition in temporal orientations should be 2005), such as ordinary actors deciding on their
reflected in action theory, and especially in present consumption based on life-course
theories meant to explain economic action in optimization.
modern capitalist societies. As such, the By contrast, sociological approaches to the
imagined-futures approach to economic sociol- formation of expectations start not from informa-
ogy is historically situated. The analytical empha- tion, but from uncertainty. They diverge in two
sis on the future is in stark contrast to the temporal important respects from economic notions of
orientation stressed by conventional sociological rational expectations: in their emphasis on
explanations of economic action. As summarized expectations as cognitive devices and in their
by Abbott, quoted above, typical explanations in insistence that expectations emerge from social
6 Transcending History’s Heavy Hand: The Future in Economic Action 81

processes. Beckert (2016, see also Beckert and interpretative processes, it takes important cues
Bronk 2018) has developed the notion that a from phenomenological thought in sociology
significant share of expectations in modern capi- (Schütz 1932; Schütz and Luckmann 1975).
talist economies have a quasi-fictional quality. If A good example of the social constitution of
future economic outcomes are fundamentally expectations is provided by the literature on
uncertain, but set expectations are necessary for promises in technological development, which
economic decision-making and coordination, since the 1990s has highlighted the key role of
actors can typically be expected to rely on imag- shared expectations. In their early stages,
ined futures as cognitive devices to enable eco- emerging technological fields are home to
nomic action. Despite being known to be future-oriented sense-making activities. Much of
contingent projections in principle, imagined this dynamic consists of interpretative conflicts
futures are often treated as if they were reliable over the acceptance of the uncertain promises of
forecasts of coming economic outcomes. Much- the respective technologies. As has been shown
discussed examples of this process are macroeco- empirically, actors continuously try to nurture
nomic forecasts and point projections. Even shared expectations in order to route resources
though they continuously fail as mere forecasts, and developmental possibilities in their favor.
they reliably work as bases for decision-making Shared expectations can feed into self-fulfilling
in business and government (Pilmis 2018; prophecies and technological path dependencies
Reichmann 2018). This argument can be under- (van Lente 1993). The emphasis on the social
stood as a specification of the well-known constitution of expectations distinguishes socio-
Thomas-theorem (Thomas and Thomas 1928) in logical approaches, not just from models of ratio-
that beliefs about the future influence social nal expectations, but also from recent work in
action, irrespective of their objective correctness. behavioral economics. While such approaches
The second deviation builds on a related routinely acknowledge the presence of radical
observation. In many economic situations, the uncertainty, they focus on individual-cognitive
idea that the formation of expectations is a matter coping mechanisms, rather than on social pro-
of individuals projecting independent, quasi- cesses (Thaler 2000).
predetermined futures is misleading. If the shape Sociological analyses of the formation of
of the given future is itself influenced by the expectations aim to complement rather than com-
expectations actors hold when enacting it, pete with cultural, institutional, relational, and
forecasting activities gain a pragmatic character. structural theoretical programs in economic soci-
Rather than a mere cognitive activity, neatly ology. They are complementary in two ways.
separated from and preceding individual action, First, social structures often shape expectations.
the formation of expectations is an iterative social To give just two examples, social position and
process (Emirbayer and Mische 1998). embeddedness in communities have repeatedly
Expectations emerge from ongoing social pro- been shown to influence not just actors’ anticipa-
cesses in which actors articulate, negotiate, fight tory capabilities, but also their aspirations and
over, and provisionally adopt imaginaries of the hopes (Bourdieu 1979; Mische 2009; Bandelj
future to guide social action. As intersubjective and Lanuza 2018). To the same effect, the institu-
phenomena, expectations are typically embedded tional regimes of advanced capitalist societies
in narratives about the future (Mützel 2009; have been shown not strictly to determine firm
Garud et al. 2014). In its emphasis on the social, strategy, but to influence wider understandings of
processual, and practical constitution of what business models count as feasible, profit-
expectations, the imagined-futures approach is able, and realistic (Herrmann 2008). In both
strongly influenced by pragmatist, and especially cases, structures do not determine the concrete
Deweyan, thought (Strauss 1993; Joas 2005; content and forms of expectations, but act in a
Dewey 2008). In its focus on social structures as way similar to Max Weber’s (1946) switchmen in
structures of meaning and the social nature of that they pattern interpretative processes loosely.
82 J. Beckert and T. Ergen

Second, orientations towards an open future, was then forced to abandon its neoliberal agenda
imagination, and the social construction of and aid struggling sectors, in order to live up to its
expectations can be conceptualized as agents of promises of supporting domestic industry.
social change in thoroughly structured fields. In Finally, Suckert (2020) argues that imaginaries
the medium- to long-term, firms and markets in of the future identity of Great Britain invoked
capitalism are notoriously dynamic social by the recent campaign for Brexit narratively
formations. As developed by various literatures combine contradictory national traditions and
on innovation, pockets exist for the creative memories. Promises about Britain’s future eco-
reconstruction of the action situation in capitalist nomic identity creatively combined aspects from
societies––spaces for new imaginaries of the the country’s history and tradition. Along those
future that arguably are at the heart of this lines, a common theme of future imaginary
dynamic (Lester and Piore 2004; Stark 2009; focused empirical research is that cognitive
Ergen 2018). The macro-sociological question devices, ideas, cultural imprints, and theories do
of how to square the restlessness (Sewell 2008) not wholly work through a cognitive taken-for-
of modern capitalist economies with their well- granted channel. They are put into action on the
documented institutional and social basis of contingent interpretations of the situation,
embeddedness may be answered in part by the improvisation, and projections of the future
alternating temporal orientations of actors, (Swidler 1986).
organizations, and institutions (Beckert 2013).
Extending the micro-foundations of economic
sociology and political economy with a sociolog-
3 Expectations in Contemporary
ical concept of expectations can help to specify
Capitalism
how and when social structures influence eco-
nomic action. One way of conceptualizing the
To illustrate the general sociological usefulness of
relationship between expectations and cultural
analyses of expectations, this section briefly
patterns, for example, is to think of expectations
summarizes how they might help in thinking
as mediators of the influence of culture on social
about core spheres of economic activity in mod-
action. If cultural patterns influence how actors
ern capitalism. Drawing on Beckert (2016), we
interpret situations and formulate expectations,
schematically discuss the role of imaginaries of
rather than provide straightforward scripts for
the future in consumption, investment, and
behavior, culture’s influence is filtered through
innovation and underline the argument with
situational dynamics (Swidler 1986).
examples of empirical research.1 Our focus on
Three empirical examples may illustrate the
consumption, innovation, and investment is first
situational mediation of the influence of cultural
due to the richness of empirical research on the
patterns. Angeletti’s (2019) research shows how
role of expectations in these realms. Second, we
the use of economic models by French govern-
consider these fields to be particularly instructive
ment planners did not have straightforward per-
examples of how the investigation of expectations
formative effects. Economic models framed how
may help to understand the dynamic nature of
political actors thought about political feasibility
capitalist societies.
and economic possibility but left considerable
room for administrators to develop creative
strategies for economic governance. Ergen
(2019) shows how Ronald Reagan’s administra-
1
tion strategically used scenarios about national For reasons of space, we are highly selective in our
industrial decline to push tax reform through presentation of spheres of economic activity. The spheres
that would merit discussion, but which were left out,
Congress. Contrary to the assumptions of schol-
include the expectation-focused investigation of money,
arship on policy paradigms and the power of of labor and the production process, of the state and the
economic ideas (Hall 1989), the administration political system, and of organizations.
6 Transcending History’s Heavy Hand: The Future in Economic Action 83

3.1 Consumption personalities. Significant parts of contemporary


advertisement and marketing can be understood
Economic sociology has traditionally focused on as attempts to convey such promises of transcen-
the social constitution of consumption in its treat- dence for particular goods or brands, and thereby
ment of consumer behavior (Zukin and Smith constitute a specific form of future orientation of
Maguire 2004; Zelizer 2005). A large portion of consumers. Modern consumer societies are sig-
this research has tried to understand the workings nificantly constituted by systems that create
of specific products, categories, and markets, desires through promises and the planting of
especially regarding the influence of morality expectations (Illouz 2009).
and the problem of quality uncertainty (Karpik A further, more mundane way in which the
2010; Schiller-Merkens and Balsiger 2019). Very social analysis of expectations contributes to the
few studies have attempted to answer the more understanding of the dynamics of consumption is
fundamental question of how to explain the seem- found in the field of consumer confidence and
ingly endless demand for consumer goods and macroeconomic expectations. Expectations about
services that is historically unique to modern cap- future macroeconomic developments and their
italist societies. Anthropological, as well as his- effects on consumption have been at the core of
torical literatures have long argued that macroeconomic debates from Keynes’s General
premodern societies tended to minimize the effort Theory through to the rational expectations-
necessary for quasi-stagnant consumption, rather revolution of the 1970s and 1980s. Under
than maximize their consumption possibilities conditions of genuine uncertainty, optimistic or
(Campbell 1987). With few exceptions, answers pessimistic outlooks have less to do with avail-
to the puzzle of the dynamics of modern con- able information and their proper assessment.
sumer societies are based on the idea that modern Instead, they often take the form of general confi-
societies impute non-essential goods and services dence, and of emotionally charged animal spirits
with symbolic value, with socially shared mean- (Keynes 1936, 161; DiMaggio 2002). Sociologi-
ing capable of stimulating desires. Sociological cal research on the empirical distribution, emer-
classics such as Simmel (1957) and Veblen gence, and breakdown of consumer confidence
(1992), as well as Pierre Bourdieu (1984), represents a highly important research field.
strongly emphasized the positional value of con- Sociologists have recently demonstrated that con-
sumer goods to explain the dynamics of modern sumer confidence systematically varies by racial
consumer societies. Boltanski and Esquerre and ethnic background in the United States
(2017) have recently proposed the notion of the (Doherty Bea 2019), while economists are begin-
enrichment of goods for their charging with sym- ning to analyze narratives about the economy as
bolic qualities, in particular with historical independent variables in macroeconomic models
references, regional associations, and socio- (Shiller 2019).
cultural connotations.
The sociological analysis of expectations
contributes to this line of research. How can one 3.2 Investment
explain the fact that actors are willing to incur
costs, in terms of foregone leisure or savings, for The second component of aggregate demand,
the acquisition of such symbolic qualities? One besides private consumption, investment, is simi-
answer, developed by Beckert (2016, Chap. 8), larly affected by the dynamics of expectations.
suggests that the acquisition and possession of Capital, as well as financial investment in modern
goods promise to transcend the individual. Sym- economies is ultimately determined by
bolically charged goods gain their attraction from expectations about future profit streams. Hence,
a promise to connect individuals to society, spe- investors principally need to reckon with a multi-
cific social communities, regions, histories, or tude of uncertain future developments, such as
product development, future patterns of consumer
84 J. Beckert and T. Ergen

demand, competitors’ investments, government consumption, investment is often contingent on


policy, and broader social change, and this often a vague notion of investor sentiment and confi-
over a period of a decade or more. Given the dence. As can be shown empirically, swings in
complexity of the task and genuine uncertainty predominant narratives can change investment
over future developments, boundedly rational flows massively without preceding changes in
ways of decision-making have repeatedly been economic fundamentals. Along these lines and
shown to be key to understanding investment based on quantitative text analyses, Beckert and
decisions. Examples are investors’ reliance on Arndt (2019) show that the willingness to lend to
formal models, legitimating narratives, rules of the Greek state during the recent Euro Crisis
thumb, and herd behavior (Akerlof and Shiller reacted strongly to shifts in the narrative about
2009; Arjaliès et al. 2017). Greece’s situation in the trade press. Given their
Three strands of recent research focusing on importance for macroeconomic stability, such
the social formation of expectations contribute to expectational dynamics can become the object
the explanation of investment decisions. While of state intervention. Braun (2015, 2016) traces
differing in their empirical subjects and methods the expansion of expectation-management by
of analysis, they all emphasize the role of stories central banks as they increasingly run into
about the future in structuring attention and sense- problems of policy implementation. Findings
making regarding future profit opportunities. documenting the narrative constitution of investor
A first strand of research focusses on the confidence are not limited to financial markets.
future-oriented sense-making activities of market Giraudeau (2012, 2018) presents historical
actors. Individual industries as well as financial insight into the function, use, and abuse of busi-
markets are today equipped with dense ness plans in channeling investment. He shows
infrastructures that interpret market movements that the use of quantitative techniques allowed for
and endow them with shared meaning. Good the diminishing of doubts about the sustainability
examples of such infrastructures are specialized and future of the emerging DuPont venture
industry journals, roadmaps, surveys and among investors.
indicators published by trade associations, and A third strand of research shows how stories
financial analysts at banks and other financial about the future of products and sectors affect the
intermediaries. In this vein, Meyer et al. (2018) flow of investment to competing ventures.
show how global semiconductor manufacturing Influencing such stories hence becomes part of
has been shaped by collective efforts to roadmap the competitive process within and between firms
technological development along the supply and industries. Mützel (2009) shows how phar-
chain (see also Gawer 2000). In this line of maceutical firms competed for funding, niches,
research, Wansleben (2013) has shown how the and prestige in the emerging market for breast
Goldman Sachs-invented acronym BRICS cancer treatment with projected breakthrough-
(Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa) announcements in international trade journals.
helped create a new category of developing Ergen (2017) documents how competing actors
countries believed to be on the verge of rapid in the energy sector fought over support for the
growth. The expectations shaped through this nascent solar industry with competing narratives
new category henceforth structured global devel- about the future of the technology. This case also
opment discourse and investment flows. Based on highlights that expectations, even if commonly
an extensive ethnography, Leins (2018) has shared, do not necessarily have to have self-
demonstrated that financial analysts consciously fulfilling consequences. As observed repeatedly
use stories about possible futures to give meaning in the history of industrial production, shared
to unstable markets and hence boost investment. beliefs in rapid industrial development can be
A second strand of literature investigates the self-undermining if they lead to hesitancy in
narrative construction of investor sentiment. As investing in capital equipment (Rosenberg 1976).
mentioned above, in the context of private
6 Transcending History’s Heavy Hand: The Future in Economic Action 85

Compared with studies on private consump- opportunity structures, and scientific and techno-
tion discussed in the previous section, research on logical developments, resulting in the eventual
investment highlights that the social analysis of establishment of a massive public-private institu-
expectations is conducive to investigations of tional complex. Meikle (1995) has made a similar
power relations, conflicts, and relations of domi- argument. He shows how projections of the use of
nation. As pointed out early by Kalecki (1943), plastics in consumer goods production came to
expectations can be at the core of power dynamics symbolize the rise of consumer society and fueled
in capitalism. The ability to withhold resources at hopes of an end to the resource limitations on
will, on the basis of uncertainty about the future is economic growth after the Great Depression.
among the major sources of social power, often Jasanoff and Kim (2013) show how expectations
called structural power (Hacker and Pierson about nuclear development, and in particular the
2002). Beckert (2016) has suggested the notion thinking about opportunities and risks, were
of the politics of expectations to grasp the power shaped by national understandings of state-
struggles around imagined futures. society relationships, the law, and national
development.
A second line of empirical research
3.3 Innovation investigates the micropolitics of the social forma-
tion of expectations in technological develop-
The field of innovation is among the most obvi- ment. A path-breaking study in this field is van
ous candidates for an expectation-based eco- Lente’s (1993) history of the emergence of mem-
nomic sociology. It is in innovation processes brane technology. While almost an empty signi-
that modern societies most routinely debate fier at an early stage, interested actors tried to
uncertain long-term economic, social, and tech- promote the umbrella term of membrane technol-
nological change. Moreover, innovative activity ogy as a promising new field to safeguard
has long been described as not accessible to resources and public support. In the process,
models of rational action due to the problem of conflicts and the emergence of competing
conceptualizing deviance, ventures into the factions over the field’s possible futures signifi-
uncertain, and entrepreneurial imagination cantly shaped its development.
(Schumpeter 1912; Nelson and Winter 1977). Another often observed feature of the
Not surprisingly, sociological analyses of micropolitics of innovation processes is the prob-
expectations represent a comparatively well- lem of maintaining motivating imaginaries after
established field in innovation studies and the major commercial failures. Socio-technical
history and sociology of technology develop- imaginaries can survive for decades and even
ment. Research into imagined futures in centuries despite stagnant realization and major
innovation studies can roughly be subdivided failures. Good examples of permanently failing
into three lines. but resilient technological promises are the hydro-
First, innovations and associated socio- gen economy, solar energy, and nuclear fusion
technical imaginaries usually have deeper and reactors. A study detailing how developmental
longer-standing social origins. A broad literature communities try to manage expectations in the
on the social life of socio-technical imaginaries face of successive failures is Brown’s et al.
traces the history of specific technological (2006) study of promises of the medical potential
visions, their shifting support and form, and of stem cells. Repeatedly since the 1950s, actors
their final fulfilment or abandonment. A good have tried to distance their development efforts
example of this line of research is McCurdy’s discursively from earlier failed realizations to
(2011) history of American spaceflight. It maintain public faith in their projects.
documents how imagined opportunities and A third line of research differs from most his-
dangers perceived from fictional literature and torical innovation studies in that it does not look
societal discourse interacted with political primarily at how expectations are set, but at how
86 J. Beckert and T. Ergen

the future is opened up and uncertainty generated. 4.1 Where Do Expectations


Contrary to the early writings of Joseph Come from?
Schumpeter (1912) and much of recent economic
theory on the subject (Alvarez 1991), which stress A core question of all sociological analyses of
the individual entrepreneur, contemporary expectations deals with their origin and emer-
societies generate the majority of innovations in gence. As mentioned above, it is regarding the
teams, organizations, networks, and institutions. emergence of expectations in particular that the
Through in-depth case studies, Lester and Piore imagined-futures approach promises to be highly
(2004) have developed the idea that the character complementary to established sociological
of many of the most innovative institutions in explanatory programs. Expectations do not
contemporary societies is not centered on creating emerge out of thin air but from interpreted expe-
shared development goals, but on generating rience. If expectations are constituted intersub-
ambiguity and conversations between heteroge- jectively, social structures should be key to
neous functions. Universities, corporate understanding their emergence. Along these
laboratories dedicated to basic research, and lines, major efforts are currently under way
development teams are arguably designed to cre- among contemporary historians to construct
ate, rather than diminish uncertainty (Stark 2009; histories of the interplay between experience and
Herrigel 2017). Put differently, such arguments expectations (Levy 2017; Jakob et al. 2018).
point to the social constitution of an open future, Major sociological pathways towards answer-
rather than to attempts to foreclose it with the help ing questions of emergence are attempts to under-
of promises and narrative (Ergen 2018). stand variation in expectations between historical
periods and societies. Sociology has a rich tradi-
tion of analyzing changing understandings of
time, and in particular changes of the temporal
4 Questions and Perspectives
rhythms of social life in the course of moderniza-
of an Economic Sociology
tion (Zerubavel 1985; Elias 1992). Bourdieu
of Expectations
(1979) has developed ideas on the differences in
future orientations between traditional and mod-
Building on these exemplary insights into empir-
ern capitalist societies, and the related strains and
ical research, we now describe some of the core
conflicts of forced capitalist modernization
research questions, frontiers, and challenges of
through colonization. Observations of historical
the analysis of expectations in economic sociol-
ebbs and flows of specific expectations, promises,
ogy. Again, we are highly selective for reasons of
and orientations towards the future are particu-
space. We schematically discuss three major
larly abundant in historical political economy
research questions that we think are especially
today. Literatures on policy paradigms and domi-
well-suited to develop the sociological analysis
nant understandings of economic governance
of expectations theoretically, as well as bring it
point to the contingent character of ideas about
into discussion with other approaches in eco-
effective economic management (Hall 1989;
nomic sociology.2
Boyer 2018). This line of research has unearthed
a broad variety of political and structural
variables conditioning beliefs in the efficacy of
governance paradigms, such as state structures,
coalitional patterns, electoral regimes, and
national cultural traits (Gourevitch 1986; Hall
2
1989). At the same time, this literature has
A major concern that is omitted from this chapter is the
question of methodology, a discussion of which can be
highlighted the central importance of unsettled
found in a standalone paper (Beckert and Suckert 2020, times (Swidler 1986), such as bigger economic
see also the brief discussion below in the conclusion).
6 Transcending History’s Heavy Hand: The Future in Economic Action 87

crises, for creative sense-making and cognitive will. It is also probably safe to say that only an
reorientation (Blyth 2002). Recent historical and infinitesimally small array of expectations is
comparative research has tried to understand the effective in contemporary societies, compared
sequential dynamics between economic with the endless possibilities of imagining an
structures, political shifts, and expectations (see open future. If expectations are contingent
also Ergen 2017). Chwieroth and Walter (2019) interpretations of an unknowable future, what
argue that capitalist societies have increasingly makes some of them more persuasive than
been caught up in Minskian feedback loops others? Shiller (2019) has recently suggested
since the Great Depression of the 1930s. Increas- using epidemiological models of contagion to
ing aggregate holdings of wealth, expectations of understand the diffusion of economic narratives.
voters that governments protect that wealth in While the description of the shape and form of
times of crisis, and related moral hazards of finan- diffusion is certainly of prime interest to a sociol-
cial institutions may help explain the growing ogy of expectations, and might, at some point, be
financialization of capitalist economies. an important means of testing competing theories,
A second major pathway towards understand- we believe the theoretical groundwork on the
ing the emergence of expectations was also social mechanisms of diffusion and institutionali-
spearheaded by Bourdieu (1979). In multiple zation is particularly promising.
contexts he has argued that expectations are A first promising research field starts from the
socially stratified. This may be due either to observation that beliefs about the future in mod-
class-based differences in the alignment between ern societies are to a significant degree spread by
objective probabilities and aspirations or due to mass communication media (Shiller 2000). For
varying degrees of self-fulfilling aspirations. example, Beckert and Arndt (2019) show how
Challenging Bourdieu’s structuralist explanations news coverage of the Greek debt crisis drove
of expectations, Bandelj and Lanuza (2018) interest rates on Greek government bonds. Stud-
recently argued that embeddedness in ies of the internal logic, selection mechanisms,
communities may trump the effects of socio- and sense-making effects of mass media are sur-
economic background on young adults’ economic prisingly rare in economic sociology and political
aspirations. Such results resonate with the idea economy. While characterized by significant
that social structures shape, but do not determine, barriers to entry, due to the specialized nature of
expectations towards the future. Similar findings media studies, the case-specific, comparative, and
on the social structuration of the formation of historical workings of mass media in the forma-
expectations have been made for network tion of expectations hold great promise for socio-
structures (Prato and Stark 2013), racial back- logical studies (see Chap. 10).
ground (Doherty Bea 2019), popular culture A second research field concerns the role of
(McCurdy 2011), and broader cultural experts, intermediaries, and certified knowledge
understandings (Jasanoff and Kim 2013; Suckert (Pollock and Williams 2010, 2016). As
2020). documented extensively in economic sociology,
sociology of technology, and political economy,
knowledge in modern economies is constructed in
4.2 How Do Expectations Spread social systems of expertise, categories, and
and Gain Momentum? authority. Modern economies are densely
populated by organizations, the purpose of
A related problem concerns how expectations are which is the creation and dissemination of
diffused, gain the power to influence thought and expectations. Promissory organizations (Pollock
action, and become resilient. Emphasizing the and Williams 2010), such as forecasting
openness of the future in capitalist societies and institutes, consultancies, public relations
the imaginative capabilities of actors certainly agencies, and think tanks, provide economic
does not imply that expectations are malleable at actors with coordinating narratives about future
88 J. Beckert and T. Ergen

developments as well as with representations of resulting entanglements between public and pri-
the future role structure of markets. A good exam- vate actors in the notion of infrastructural power.
ple of the organized production of authoritative Another good example of the power dimension in
expectations are the activities of credit rating spreading expectations is Serafin’s (2019) study
agencies (Rona-Tas and Hiß 2011; Fourcade of taxi drivers’ resistance to market deregulation.
2017). Rating agencies’ assessments of While struggling to unite behind a common pro-
borrowers’ default risks have become a de facto jection of the dangers of unhampered market
standard on which actors throughout the global entry initially, taxi drivers formed a movement
financial system base their decisions. Credit behind charismatic figures, which was then able
ratings standardize and legitimize expectations to counter the projections of the future of the taxi
and help shift blame in case of disappointment. market brought forward by politicians and
Instances of similar processes of the creation of factions in favor of liberalization.
shared expectations can be found throughout While sociological studies of the emergence
modern economies. A particularly interesting and diffusion of expectations have become fairly
recent dynamic concerns the expansion of numerous in recent years, the fading away, break-
systems structuring the prediction of individuals’ down, and abandonment of imaginaries of the
behavior, such as the off-label use of credit future remain underexplored. Processes account-
ratings or the expansion of algorithmic systems ing for the death of expectations need not be
in governance and government (Rona-Tas 2017, mirror images of processes accounting for their
2020). emergence, and hence might require distinct
A third and related field concerns the role of explanations (Haffert and Ergen 2019). Two rare
social power in spreading expectations. Power is empirical studies focusing on the decline of
crucial for the diffusion of expectations because expectations by Beckert (2020) and Ergen
of two aspects. First, actors uttering predictions (2017) point to the fact that interruptions of
may be believed to be powerful enough to render validating experiences and stuttering signals of
the given prediction true, which can lead to self- eventual fulfilment may undermine promises
fulfilling prophecies. A good example of this and the momentum of related imagined futures.
process is ECB president Mario Draghi’s famous Beckert (2020) traces the recent decline of the
promise to do whatever it takes during the Euro political power of neoliberal ideas back to the
Crisis, which ended speculative attacks on the increasing elusiveness of promises of upward
currency without actual central bank social mobility in the early twenty-first century.
interventions. Second, actors may possess the
discursive resources to shift interpretations of
how the future will unfold. Modern corporations, 4.3 The Moral Economy
associations, and state agencies maintain elabo- of Expectations
rate professional repertoires to shape discourse.
While equally endemic in other economic Most theoretical arguments on the social consti-
domains, the professional management of tution of expectations in economic sociology treat
expectations has been singled out in research on them as predominantly cognitive phenomena,
central banks (Braun 2015; Wansleben 2018). In related to the problem of uncertainty. Yet,
line with our claim that the analysis of social projections of the future are regularly saturated
structures and expectations may be highly com- with normativity and values. A moral economy of
plementary, this area of research in addition expectations exists in modern capitalist societies.
shows that central banks’ ability to durably influ- Larger technological projections usually present
ence expectations in society requires specific themselves as utopias or dystopias. New
financial market structures. Hence, market approaches to economic governance commonly
structures serve as the infrastructure for policy include promises to overcome long-standing
implementation. Braun (2018) captures the social ills, and business models regularly promise
6 Transcending History’s Heavy Hand: The Future in Economic Action 89

to cure dysfunctional structures and practices. developed and the question of who shall partici-
The evaluative structures of expectations repre- pate in their creation are contested political issues.
sent a vast and understudied research field. How By documenting the rise and fall of the field of
do expectations become evaluatively charged? professional future studies, Andersson (2018) has
How do values, norms, and moral structures influ- shown how the formation of expectations was a
ence the emergence and spread of expectations core ideological battleground in Cold War soci-
and projective techniques? What does the preva- ety. Rival methods of forming expectations and
lence of evaluatively charged imaginaries of the developing scenarios were at their core shaped by
future in modern economies imply for theories of normative conflicts over who may claim control
the rationalization and dis-embedding of contem- over the future of the global order.
porary capitalism?
Knowledge about the relationship between
expectations and social values is particularly 5 Conclusion
important as it should help to situate the approach
in relation to classical accounts of the normative The analysis of expectations in economic sociol-
embedding of the economy. A good example of ogy is a comparatively young and unconsolidated
the insights gained from bringing together the two research field. Today it is driven mainly by theo-
approaches is Zaloom’s anthropological (2016, retical explorations and empirical projects, which
2019) research on the ethical roots of household experiment with data sources that indicate actors’
financial budgeting and planning. In a number of expectations and their influence on social pro-
contexts, she shows how methods of family cesses. While certainly not without potential
budgeting, and hence also families’ investment drawbacks, the field’s current experimental char-
activities in financial markets, respond to acter in terms of theory, method, and methodol-
projected models of an ethical life, for example ogy produces a considerable dynamism. As
regarding religious or intergenerational duties and outlined in this chapter, a number of loosely
responsible behavior. Closer investigation of the shared classics, research questions, and theoreti-
links between the cognitive and evaluative cal arguments structure the recent uptick of socio-
aspects of imagined futures may, in addition, logical interest in the future (Beckert and Suckert
help to develop the action-theoretical bases of 2020). To conclude, we want to highlight three
the sociological analysis of expectations. As wider frontiers of the research field: its connec-
Miyazaki and Swedberg’s (2017) work on hope tion to social theory, the methodology of studying
demonstrates, expectations charged with positive the future, and the quest for a macrosociology of
emotions and visions of a good life can exert the economy.
strong motivational and mobilizing effects on The first frontier concerns the connection of
actors and social groups. The motivating force the analysis of expectations to general economic
of aspirations and shared hopes for economic sociology and social theory. As touched on
emancipation has also been captured empirically above, knowledge of the connections between
in recent research on the illegal and informal expectations and traditional sociological explana-
economy. Dewey’s (2020) ethnography of the tory factors is largely of an exploratory and hypo-
informal apparel industry underlying Buenos thetical nature. What is more, there is little
Aires’s La Salada market demonstrates that systematic work on how sociological analyses of
shared aspirations can form the basis of the ongo- expectations may contribute to general social the-
ing reproduction of social order in markets (see ory. While contributions to the former issue can
also Chap. 11). be expected to result from scattered empirical
Studying the normative dimensions of research, the latter is a problem for systematic
expectations is a promising starting point to theoretical work. More general implications of a
understand the political facet of expectations. sociological understanding of expectations exist
The way in which large scale projections are regarding understanding social order and social
90 J. Beckert and T. Ergen

change in the economy, two constitutive issues interpretative efforts reliably be captured and
for economic sociology and sociology writ large. reconstructed? Similar to attempts in network
Sociological work on the problem of social order theory to conceptualize relational structures as
has traditionally been strongly shaped by an constituted through stories (White 1992;
emphasis on the past, which is true for both gen- Emirbayer and Goodwin 1994), imagined-futures
eral social theory and economic sociology approaches have often tried to capture sense-
(Granovetter 1985; Beckert 2009; Joas and making activities with the help of qualitative
Knöbl 2009). An absence of social norms, rela- analyses of discourse, such as firms’ written
tional structures, and cultural imprints brings to communications, media reports, and documented
the fore problems of coordination, collective speech and debate. As demonstrated by a number
action, and social conflict that would make of recent studies, such interpretative
orderly economic life impossible. One way in methodologies can potentially also be combined
which the analysis of economic expectations with quantitative methods of analysis, for exam-
might help in understanding social order may be ple on the basis of the large-scale hand- or
its emphasis on the intersubjective constitution of machine-coding of textual material. A key chal-
the action situation. As outlined above, the for- lenge for the empirical analysis of expectations in
mation of expectations can be thought of as a the economy is that expectations need not be
mediating process, rendering social structures explicated to be observable in their effects on
effective and shaping their effects on social economic life. Core assumptions about the stabil-
action. As pointed out in rational-actor modelling ity and orderly change of actors’ identities,
(Axelrod 1984), as well as in pragmatist writings relationships, and institutions arguably operate
(Whitford 2002), shared expectations can be at on a taken-for-granted level (Tavory and Eliasoph
the basis of durably cooperative relationships. 2013). Expectations about the future may also be
The interpretation of situations as situations of inscribed in material artifacts and tools, rather
joint gain, or of conflict and competition is cru- than made explicit. If structures of meaning
cially contingent on actors’ expectations about exist in a variety of forms and layers, and are
the future. Thus, the alignment and structuring more or less accessible for scholarly reconstruc-
of expectations can be thought of as essential for tion, there is a clear danger that studies may
the ongoing reproduction of social order in the privilege more accessible manifestations of
economy. A second way in which recognizing the expectations. What is more, it remains a challenge
role of expectations benefits theories of social for empirical research to establish causal links
order is that it provides an avenue for understand- between clearly articulated expectations and
ing social change. As outlined above in our their consequences for action and social structure
description of research on innovation, (Jerolmack and Khan 2014). Differentiating
realignments of expectations can be responsible empirically between the primacy of actors’
for actors’ deviations from established paths of interests, cultural beliefs, and expectations
social organization. The analysis of economic beyond reasonable doubt is extremely difficult,
expectations may have the potential to perform often futile, and requires careful research design.
as a theoretical bridge between the understanding Hence, analyses of expectations require a signifi-
of the social integration of economic action, and cant degree of methodological reflection and care
the social constitution of economic dynamism (see Beckert and Suckert 2020, for an elaboration
characteristic of capitalist societies. of the field’s methodological challenges).
The second frontier consists of methodological Third, the analysis of expectations promises a
challenges. In line with phenomenological sociol- path towards macro sociological insights into
ogy, the analysis of expectations in economic capitalist economies. The development of realis-
sociology implies a view of the economy that tic micro foundations for economic sociology
understands it as a complex structure of meaning. should not be mistaken as being oriented towards
How can structures of meaning and actors’ a primarily micro-oriented research program. As
6 Transcending History’s Heavy Hand: The Future in Economic Action 91

discussed above in the context of Pierre matters for global capitalism. Princeton: Princeton
Bourdieu’s work, the potential contribution of a University Press.
Alvarez, J. L. (1991). The international diffusion and
sociology of expectations to macrosociology institutionalization of the new entrepreneurship move-
should be obvious regarding the historical char- ment: A study in the sociology of organizational knowl-
acterization of economic action in capitalist edge. Doctoral Dissertation. Cambridge: Harvard
economies. Capitalist economies are University.
Andersson, J. (2018). The future of the world: Futurology,
characterized by a historically unique conception futurists, and the struggle for the post-cold war imagi-
of an open and malleable future (Beckert 2013). nation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
While there are clear leads for how a sociology of Angeletti, T. (2019). How economics frames political
expectations may contribute to modernization debates: Macroeconomic forecasting in the French
planning commissions. Socio-Economic Review, 2019.
theory and historical macrosociology, the field Arjaliès, D.-L., Grant, P., Hardie, I., MacKenzie, D., &
still holds a wealth of possibilities for compara- Svetlova, E. (2017). Chains of finance: How invest-
tive and historical research. The implications of a ment management is shaped. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
sociological notion of the formation of sity Press.
Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation.
expectations are less clear in contrast with macro- New York: Basic Books.
economics and its widespread reliance on the Bandelj, N., & Lanuza, Y. R. (2018). Economic
assumption of rational expectations. A developed expectations of young adults. Socius, 4, 1–23.
notion of the formation of expectations and its Beckert, J. (2002). Beyond the market: The social
foundations of economic efficiency. Princeton:
interplay with social structures should provide a Princeton University Press.
productive starting point to revisit major macro- Beckert, J. (2009). The social order of markets. Theory and
economic problems and theorems from a socio- Society, 38(3), 245–269.
logical perspective. Long-standing problems of Beckert, J. (2013). Capitalism as a system of expectations:
Toward a sociological microfoundation of political
macroeconomics, such as swings in consumer economy. Politics and Society, 41(3), 323–350.
confidence and investor sentiment, cyclical Beckert, J. (2016). Imagined futures: Fictional
movements of the economy, breakdowns of eco- expectations and capitalist dynamics. Cambridge:
nomic activity, and structural change are Harvard University Press.
Beckert, J. (2020). The exhausted futures of neoliberalism:
promising fields for a macrosociology of eco- From promissory legitimacy to social anomy. Journal
nomic activity. Equally promising are sociologi- of Cultural Economy, 13(3), 318–330.
cal inquiries into influential economic policy Beckert, J., & Arndt, L. (2019). The Greek tragedy.
convictions derived from modern macroeconom- Unpublished Manuscript. Cologne: MPIfG.
Beckert, J., & Bronk, R. (2018). An introduction to
ics, such as the neutrality of money and the “uncertain futures”. In J. Beckert & R. Bronk (Eds.),
crowding out of private investment by govern- Uncertain futures: Imaginaries, narratives and calcu-
ment expenditure. At their core, answers to such lation in the economy (pp. 1–36). Oxford: Oxford
questions require hypotheses about how University Press.
Beckert, J., & Suckert, L. (2020). The future as a social
expectations are formed and how they affect eco- fact. The analysis of perceptions of the future in soci-
nomic action. A sociologically rich notion of ology. Poetics. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.poetic.2020.
expectations should thus provide a starting point 101449
for a realistic macrosociology of the economy. Blyth, M. (2002). Economic ideas and institutional
change in the twentieth century. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Boltanski, L., & Esquerre, A. (2017). Enrichissement: Une
Critique de la Marchandise. Paris: Gallimard.
References Bourdieu, P. (1979). Algeria 1960. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Abbott, A. (2005). The idea of outcome in U.S. sociology. Bourdieu, P. (1984). Distinction: A social critique of the
In G. Steinmetz (Ed.), The politics of method in the judgement of taste. Cambridge: Harvard University
human sciences: Positivism and its epistemological Press.
others (pp. 393–426). Durham: Duke University Press. Boyer, R. (2018). Expectations, narratives, and socio-
Akerlof, G., & Shiller, R. J. (2009). Animal spirits: How economic regimes. In J. Beckert & R. Bronk (Eds.),
human psychology drives the economy, and why it Uncertain futures: Imaginaries, narratives and
92 J. Beckert and T. Ergen

calculation in the economy (pp. 39–61). Oxford: & R. Bronk (Eds.), Uncertain futures: Imaginaries,
Oxford University Press. narratives, and calculation in the economy
Braun, B. (2015). Governing the future: The European (pp. 298–318). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Central Bank’s expectation management during the Ergen, T. (2019). Wirtschaftliche Untergangsszenarien
great moderation. Economy and Society, 44(3), und neoliberale Reformen. Leviathan, 48, 119–152.
367–391. Etzioni, A. (1988). The moral dimension: Toward a new
Braun, B. (2016). Speaking to the people? Money, trust, economics. New York: Free Press.
and central bank legitimacy in the age of quantitative Evans, G., & Honkapohja, S. (2015). Economics of
easing. Review of International Political Economy, 23 expectations. In N. J. Smelser & P. B. Baltes (Eds.),
(6), 1064–1092. International encyclopedia of the social and behav-
Braun, B. (2018). Central banking and the infrastructural ioral sciences (pp. 5060–5067). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
power of finance: The case of ECB support for repo Fourcade, M. (2017). State metrology: The rating of
and securitization markets. Socio-Economic Review, sovereigns and the judgment of nations. In K. J. Mor-
2018. gan & A. S. Orloff (Eds.), The many hands of the state:
Brown, N., Kraft, A., & Martin, P. (2006). The promissory Theorizing political authority and social control
pasts of blood stem cells. BioSocieties, 1, 329–348. (pp. 103–127). Cambridge: Cambridge University
Campbell, C. (1987). The romantic ethic and the spirit of Press.
modern consumerism. Oxford: Blackwell. Garud, R., Schildt, H. A., & Lant, T. K. (2014). Entrepre-
Chwieroth, J. M., & Walter, A. (2019). The wealth effect: neurial storytelling, future expectations, and the para-
How the great expectations of the middle class have dox of legitimacy. Organization Science, 25(5),
changed the politics of banking crises. Cambridge: 1479–1492.
Cambridge University Press. Gawer, A. (2000). The organization of platform leader-
Dewey, J. (2008 [1922]). Human nature and conduct: An ship: An empirical investigation of Intel’s management
introduction to social psychology. The collected works processes aimed at fostering complementary
of John Dewey, volume 14, 1922. Carbondale: South- innovation by third parties. Doctoral Dissertation.
ern Illinois University Press. Cambridge: MIT.
Dewey, M. (2020). Making it at any cost: Aspirations and Giraudeau, M. (2012). Imagining (the future) business:
politics in a counterfeit clothing marketplace. Austin: How to make firms with plans? In P. Quattrone,
University of Texas Press. N. Thrift, C. McLean, & F.-R. Puyou (Eds.), Imagining
DiMaggio, P. J. (2002). Endogenizing “animal spirits”: organizations: Performative imagery in business and
Toward a sociology of collective response to uncer- beyond (pp. 213–229). London: Routledge.
tainty and risk. In M. F. Guillén, R. Collins, Giraudeau, M. (2018). Proving future profit: Business
P. England, & M. Meyer (Eds.), The new economic plans as demonstration devices. Osiris, 33, 130–148.
sociology (pp. 79–100). New York: Sage Foundation. Gourevitch, P. (1986). Politics in hard times: Comparative
Doganova, L. (2018). Discounting and the making of the responses to international economic crises. Ithaca:
future: On uncertainty in forest management and drug Cornell University Press.
development. In J. Beckert & R. Bronk (Eds.), Uncer- Granovetter, M. S. (1985). Economic action and social
tain futures: Imaginaries, narratives and calculation in structure: The problem of Embeddedness. American
the economy (pp. 278–297). Oxford: Oxford Univer- Journal of Sociology, 91(3), 481–510.
sity Press. Hacker, J. S., & Pierson, P. (2002). Business power and
Doherty Bea, M. (2019). Racial and ethnic differences in social policy: Employers and the formation of the
consumers’ economic expectations. Socius, 5, 1–17. American welfare state. Politics and Society, 30(2),
Durkheim, E. (1984 [1893]). The division of labor in 277–325.
society (G. Simpson, Trans.). London: Macmillan. Haffert, L., & Ergen, T. (2019). The symmetric fallacy:
Elias, N. (1992 [1984]). Time: An essay. Oxford: The dangers of symmetric reasoning in the social
Blackwell. sciences. Cambridge, MA: Center for European Stud-
Elster, J. (2005). Excessive ambitions. Capitalism and ies, Harvard University.
Society, 4, 1–30. Hall, P. A. (1989). The political power of economic ideas:
Emirbayer, M., & Goodwin, J. (1994). Network analysis, Keynesianism across nations. Princeton: Princeton
culture, and the problem of agency. American Journal University Press.
of Sociology, 99(6), 1411–1454. Herrigel, G. (2017). Experimentalist systems in
Emirbayer, M., & Mische, A. (1998). What is agency? manufacturing multinationals: German automobile
American Journal of Sociology, 103(4), 962–1023. and machinery industry examples. Unpublished Man-
Ergen, T. (2017). Coalitional cohesion in technology pol- uscript. Chicago: University of Chicago.
icy: The case of the early American solar cell industry. Herrmann, A. M. (2008). One political economy, one
MPIfG Discussion Paper 17/7. Cologne: MPIfG. competitive strategy? Comparing pharmaceutical
Ergen, T. (2018). The dilemma between aligned firms in Germany, Italy, and the UK. Oxford: Oxford
expectations and diversity in innovation: Evidence University Press.
from early energy technology policies. In J. Beckert
6 Transcending History’s Heavy Hand: The Future in Economic Action 93

Ikenberry, G. J. (1994). History’s heavy hand: Institutions Mützel, S. (2009). Koordinierung von Märkten durch
and the politics of the state. Conference Paper. Confer- narrativen Wettbewerb. Kölner Zeitschrift für
ence “New perspectives on institutions”, University of Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie Sonderband, 49,
Maryland, October 1994. 87–106.
Illouz, E. (2009). Emotions, imagination and consump- Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1977). In search of a useful
tion: A new research agenda. Journal of Consumer theory of innovation. Research Policy, 6, 36–76.
Culture, 9(3), 377–413. Pilmis, O. (2018). Escaping the reality test: How macro-
Jakob, M., Nützenadel, A., & Streb, J. (Eds.). (2018). economic forecasters deal with “errors”. In J. Beckert
Experience and expectation (Jahrbuch für Wirtschafts- & R. Bronk (Eds.), Uncertain futures: Imaginaries,
geschichte) (Vol. 59). Oldenbourg: De Gruyter. narratives and calculation in the economy
Jasanoff, S., & Kim, S.-H. (2013). Sociotechnical (pp. 124–143). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
imaginaries and national energy policies. Science as Pollock, N., & Williams, R. (2010). The business of
Culture, 22(2), 189–196. expectations: How promissory organizations shape
Jerolmack, C., & Khan, S. (2014). Talk is cheap: Ethnog- technology and innovation. Social Studies of Science,
raphy and the attitudinal fallacy. Sociological Methods 40(4), 525–548.
& Research, 43(2), 178–209. Pollock, N., & Williams, R. (2016). How industry analysts
Joas, H. (2005). The creativity of action (J. Gaines & shape the digital future. Oxford: Oxford University
P. Keast, Trans.). Cambridge: Polity Press. Press.
Joas, H., & Knöbl, W. (2009). Social theory: Twenty Prato, M., & Stark, D. (2013). Peripheral vision in finan-
introductory lectures. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer- cial markets: How attention networks shape valuation.
sity Press. Academy of Management Proceedings, 2013(1).
Kalecki, M. (1943). Political aspects of full employment. Reichmann, W. (2018). The interactional foundations of
The Political Quarterly, 14, 322–331. economic forecasting. In J. Beckert & R. Bronk (Eds.),
Karpik, L. (2010). Valuing the unique: The economics of Uncertain futures: Imaginaries, narratives and calcu-
singularities. Princeton: Princeton University Press. lation in the economy (pp. 105–123). Oxford: Oxford
Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, University Press.
interest and money. London: Macmillan. Rona-Tas, A. (2017). The off-label use of consumer credit
Leins, S. (2018). Stories of capitalism: Inside the role of ratings. Historical Social Research, 42(1), 52–76.
financial analysts. Chicago: University of Chicago Rona-Tas, A. (2020). Predicting the future: Art and
Press. algorithms. Socio-Economic Review, 18, 893–911.
Lester, R. K., & Piore, M. J. (2004). Innovation: The Rona-Tas, A., & Hiß, S. (2011). Forecasting as valuation:
missing dimension. Cambridge: Harvard University The role of ratings and predictions in the subprime
Press. mortgage crisis in the US. In J. Beckert & P. Aspers
Levy, J. (2017). Capital as process and the history of (Eds.), The worth of goods: Valuation and pricing in
capitalism. Business History Review, 91(3), 483–510. the economy (pp. 223–246). Oxford: Oxford Univer-
Lucas, R. E., & Sargent, T. J. (1978). After Keynesian sity Press.
macroeconomics. In After the Phillips Curve: Persis- Rosenberg, N. (1976). On technological expectations. The
tence of high inflation and high unemployment. Economic Journal, 86(343), 523–535.
Proceedings of a conference held at Edgartown, Schiller-Merkens, S., & Balsiger, P. (Eds.). (2019). The
Massachusetts, June 1978 (pp. 49–72). Boston: Fed- contested moralities of markets (Research in the soci-
eral Reserve Bank of Boston. ology of organizations) (Vol. 63). Bingley: Emerald.
McCurdy, H. E. (2011). Space and the American imagi- Schumpeter, J. A. (1912). Theorie der wirtschaftlichen
nation. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Entwicklung. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.
Meikle, J. L. (1995). American plastic: A cultural history. Schütz, A. (1932). Der sinnhafte Aufbau der sozialen
New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press. Welt: Eine Einleitung in die verstehende Soziologie.
Meyer, U., Schubert, C., & Windeler, A. (2018). Creating Wien: Springer.
collective futures: How roadmaps and conferences Schütz, A., & Luckmann, T. (1975). Strukturen der
reconfigure the institutional field of semiconductor Lebenswelt, Band 1. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp.
manufacturing. In H. Krämer & M. Wenzel (Eds.), Serafin, M. (2019). Powerful expectations: Symbolic capi-
How organizations manage the future: Theoretical tal, the reportability paradox, and the struggle over
perspectives and empirical insights (pp. 253–276). deregulation of the taxi market in Warsaw. Unpub-
Cham: Palgrave. lished Manuscript. Warsaw: Polish Academy of
Mische, A. (2009). Projects and possibilities: Researching Sciences.
futures in action. Sociological Forum, 24(3), 694–704. Sewell, W. H., Jr. (2008). The temporalities of capitalism.
Miyazaki, H., & Swedberg, R. (2017). The economy of Socio-Economic Review, 6(3), 517–537.
hope. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press. Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational exuberance. Princeton:
Muth, J. F. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of Princeton University Press.
price movements. Econometrica, 29(3), 315–335.
94 J. Beckert and T. Ergen

Shiller, R. J. (2019). Narrative economics: How stories go Zaloom, C. (2019). Indebted: How families make college
viral and drive major economic events. Princeton: work at any cost. Princeton: Princeton University
Princeton University Press. Press.
Simmel, G. (1957). Fashion. American Journal of Sociol- Zelizer, V. (2005). Culture and consumption. In N. J.
ogy, 62(6), 541–558. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), Handbook of economic
Stark, D. (2009). The sense of dissonance: Accounts of sociology (2nd ed., pp. 331–354). Princeton: Princeton
worth in economic life. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni- University Press.
versity Press. Zerubavel, E. (1985). Hidden rhythms: Schedules and
Strauss, A. L. (1993). Continual permutations of action. calendars in social life. Berkeley: University of
New York: Routledge. California Press.
Suckert, L. (2020). Return to what we were. Wirtschaft- Zukin, S., & Smith Maguire, J. (2004). Consumers and
straditionen und ökonomische Identität im Zuge der consumption. Annual Review of Sociology, 30(1),
Brexit-Kampagne. Leviathan. 173–197.
Swedberg, R. (1997). New economic sociology: What has
been accomplished, what is ahead? Acta Sociologica,
40(2), 161–182. Beckert, Jens is director of the Max Planck Institute for
Swedberg, R. (1998). Max Weber and the idea of eco- the Study of Societies in Cologne. In 2018 he was awarded
nomic sociology. Princeton: Princeton University the Gottfried Wilhelm Leibniz Prize for his work,
Press. reinvigorating the social sciences with an interdisciplinary
Swidler, A. (1986). Culture in action: Symbols and perspective, especially at the intersection of sociology and
strategies. American Sociological Review, 51(2), economics.
273–286. Research topics: Economic sociology, wealth and
Tavory, I., & Eliasoph, N. (2013). Coordinating futures: social inequality, organizations, sociological theory.
Toward a theory of anticipation. American Journal of Recent publications: Beckert, Jens. 2020. Markets from
Sociology, 118(4), 908–942. Meaning: Quality Uncertainty and the Intersubjective
Thaler, R. H. (2000). From Homo Economicus to Homo Construction of Value. Cambridge Journal of Economics
Sapiens. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1), 44/2: 285–301. Beckert, Jens. 2020. The Exhausted
133–141. Futures of Neoliberalism: From Promissory Legitimacy
Thomas, W. I., & Thomas, D. S. (1928). The child in to Social Anomy. Journal of Cultural Economy 13/3:
America: Behavior problems and programs. 318–30. Beckert, Jens, and Richard Bronk, eds. 2018.
New York: Knopf. Uncertain Futures. Imaginaries, Narratives, and Calcula-
van Lente, H. (1993). Promising technology. The dynam- tion in the Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
ics of technological developments. Doctoral Disserta-
tion. Twente: University of Twente. Ergen, Timur is a senior researcher at the Max Planck
Veblen, T. (1992). The theory of the leisure class. New Institute for the Study of Societies in Cologne. He works at
Brunswick: Transaction Publishers. the intersection of economic and historical sociology with
Wansleben, L. (2013). Dreaming with BRICs: Innovating a special focus on state intervention in the economy. His
the classificatory regimes of international finance. research investigates cartel and merger policy, energy
Journal of Cultural Economy, 6(4), 453–471. innovation, industrial and technology policy, and the his-
Wansleben, L. (2018). How expectations became govern- tory of the postindustrial society.
able: Institutional change and the performative power Research topics: Deindustrialization, economic sociol-
of central banks. Theory and Society, 47, 773–803. ogy, economic policy, historical sociology, innovation,
Weber, M. (1946). The social psychology of the world pragmatism, renewable energy technologies. Recent
religions. In H. H. Gerth & C. Wright Mills (Eds.), publications: Ergen, Timur, and Sebastian Kohl. 2019.
From Max Weber: Essays in sociology (pp. 267–301). Varieties of Economization in Competition Policy:
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Institutional Change in German and American Antitrust,
White, H. C. (1992). Identity and control. A structural 1960–2000. Review of International Political Economy
theory of social action. Princeton: Princeton University 26/2: 256–86. Haffert, Lukas, and Timur Ergen. 2019.
Press. The Symmetric Fallacy: The Dangers of Symmetric
Whitford, J. (2002). Pragmatism and the untenable dual- Reasoning in the Social Sciences. Cambridge, MA:
ism of means and ends: Why rational choice theory Center for European Studies, Harvard University. Ergen,
does not deserve paradigmatic privilege. Theory and Timur. 2018. The Dilemma Between Aligned Expecta-
Society, 31(3), 325–363. tions and Diversity in Innovation: Evidence from Early
Zaloom, C. (2016). The evangelical financial ethic: Dou- Energy Technology Policies. In Uncertain Futures:
bled forms and the search for god in the economic Imaginaries, Narratives, and Calculation in the Economy,
world. American Ethnologist, 43(2), 325–338. eds. Jens Beckert and Richard Bronk, 298–318. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
The Aesthetic Moment in Markets
7
Jörg Rössel, Patrick Schenk, and Sebastian Weingartner

1 Introduction terms of aesthetic criteria are associated with a


specific form of uncertainty. In the branch of
New economic sociology has a long-standing economics known as information economics, it
interest in the cultural significance of goods, has been argued that uncertainty about the quality
services, and exchange processes (Zelizer 1978, of goods is primarily caused by a lack of infor-
2005). This chapter will concentrate on a particu- mation about these goods. This is not the case for
lar kind of cultural attribution of meaning, aesthetic goods. The difference is that aesthetic
analyzing goods and services that are seen as judgments are socially constituted assessments,
having a primarily aesthetic quality. Examples so individual and collective aesthetic decisions
such as the fashion, film, music, art, or wine must be seen, to an especially high degree, as
markets show that these are highly relevant only ever having temporary validity. A skirt that
areas. This becomes even clearer if we consider is at the cutting edge of fashion today may be
the role of aesthetic features in the purchasing of hopelessly out of fashion tomorrow. Yet, aes-
ordinary consumer goods. In these areas, design thetic judgments are not fallible solely from a
and external appearance play an ever-greater role temporal perspective, but also in terms of
in competition on the market. The importance of differences between social groups. A musical
concepts such as the aestheticization of society or genre may be highly prized in one particular
the aestheticization of everyday life highlights the group but will certainly be denigrated in others.
increasing significance of aesthetic categories in This is why, in this chapter, we focus on
everyday decisions about buying, using, and dis- analyzing the processes of aesthetic judgment.
posing of products. In contrast, in contemporary The first area of interest is the symbolic distinc-
societies there tends to be less emphasis on instru- tion between objects that are accorded a particular
mental criteria focused purely on the functionality status (e.g., that of being a work of art) and
of goods and services (Rössel 2007). objects that are denied this status. The second,
This chapter aims to develop the hypothesis however, is the graded evaluation of these objects
that goods and services which are considered in as better or worse on a rating scale. These
questions are relevant not only for cultural sociol-
J. Rössel (*) · S. Weingartner ogy, which explores various kinds of cultural
University of Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland
values and cultural demarcations, but also for
e-mail: roessel@soziologie.uzh.ch;
weingartner@soziologie.uzh.ch economics and economic sociology, where
questions of the origin of values and prices are
P. Schenk
University of Lucerne, Lucerne, Switzerland central (Beckert 2011). Economic values also do
e-mail: patrick.schenk@unilu.ch not arise solely on the basis of isolated, individual
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 95
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_7
96 J. Rössel et al.

acts of judgment in exchanges, but in a social actions, and giving great prominence to individual
context, in which processes of aesthetic evalua- lifestyles (Featherstone 1987). In the German-
tion take place in different fields within society speaking countries, the theory of aestheticization
(Beckert and Rössel 2013). has been extensively elaborated by Gerhard
Our first step in the second section of this Schulze. His diagnosis of contemporary society
chapter will be to introduce the concept of the centers on the assertion that people in contempo-
aestheticization of everyday life, which is funda- rary societies are especially guided by an experi-
mental for the growing importance of aesthetic ential orientation (Erlebnisorientierung), which
criteria on markets. The second step will be to he regards as the consequence of a sustained
elucidate the key problem of uncertainty about period of prosperity, in contrast to the survival
the quality of goods with primarily aesthetic orientation in societies of scarcity (Schulze 1992,
criteria, and the third step will be to analyze the 41 ff., 1997, 84 ff.). One reason for this change is
process of evaluation for such goods and services. the massive upsurge in wealth and leisure
After developing the theoretical framework in (Schulze 1992, 54 ff., 1997, 85), which has drasti-
these three steps, we will present a number of cally reduced the material limitations on everyday
studies from our own research on the arts and life for a large number of people. Another reason,
the wine markets (Beckert and Rössel 2013; however, is the change in cultural values, since the
Beckert et al. 2018; Rössel et al. 2018; Schenk proliferation of options is partly caused by the
2020), to illustrate these theoretical perspectives, weakening of previously valid, normative
as powerful tools for economic sociology in the restrictions. Schulze, therefore, uses the term
twenty-first century. We summarize our results in Entgrenzung (the removal or dissolution of
seven concluding theses in the fourth section. boundaries or limits) to highlight the fact that
various kinds of boundaries limiting people’s
scope for action have opened up in recent decades
2 Theoretical Analysis of Markets as a result of modernization processes (Schulze
for Goods and Services 1997, 85 f.).
with Primarily Aesthetic The core of the concept of experiential orien-
Features tation is defined by the contrast between outward
and inward orientation (Schulze 1992, 38).
2.1 The Directions People’s actions are increasingly less focused on
of Aestheticization functional goals in the outside world and are
increasingly aimed at internal psychophysical
The cultural process of aestheticization forms a processes which can be interpreted as pleasant,
backdrop for the increasing focus on the aesthetic and therefore aesthetic experiences. Schulze is
features of goods and services (Featherstone 1987; not solely concerned with the historical growth
Schulze 1992; Charters 2006). A key aspect of this in consumer options and leisure in contrast to the
aestheticization is that the emphasis is not on the realm of work, but with a deeper distinction. He
strictly instrumental usefulness of an object, but sees the opposition between outward and inward
on the enjoyment of its beauty, its symbolic and orientation in consumer and leisure activities
aesthetic qualities, and the associated experiences themselves. In the case of externally oriented
(Charters 2006, 246). Typically, this also means consumption, the usefulness of a commodity can
that the corresponding objects are associated with be defined independently of the subject, while in
art, and their producers are treated as artists internally oriented consumption it can only be
(Charters and Pettigrew 2005). What is meant by judged by the individual actor (Schulze 1992,
the process of aestheticization is that, from a his- 427, 1997, 84). This is associated with a high
torical perspective, a comprehensive aestheti- degree of subjectively felt uncertainty. While it
cization of everyday life can be observed, is possible to develop clear quality criteria for
affecting an ever-greater number of objects and outwardly oriented consumption, this is much
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets 97

more difficult for inwardly oriented consumption. boundaries between high culture and popular cul-
Buying yourself a good pair of shoes is simple ture are becoming somewhat less rigid. In more
compared to the goal of finding a nice pair of nuanced studies on the field of film, however,
shoes (Schulze 1992, 431). This is connected to Baumann (2001, 2002) shows that the cinema
the next feature, the fact that experience-oriented film, traditionally classified as popular culture, is
action brings a high risk of disappointment. A undergoing a change of meaning in media cover-
piece of music that produced a pleasant experi- age. Over time, films have come to be seen less as
ence a few days ago can be felt to be dull and pure entertainment products, and more as works
uninspiring today. The relationship between of art. Thus, film is moving ever closer to high
experiential means and ends is therefore culture. This is apparent in terms from high-
extremely incalculable (Schulze 1997, 89 f.). culture discourses that align films with artworks,
The risk of disappointment, inherent in an experi- but also from the fact that critics and their
ential orientation, then brings us to the last aspect: positions are becoming much more crucial for
the fact that experience-oriented individuals are in the understanding of films (Shrum 1991;
search of new, less disappointing impressions to Baumann 2002). However, these processes of
provide variety (Schulze 1988, 85, 1992, 63 ff.). assimilation to high culture cannot be observed
Schulze’s diagnosis of the times is based on the for all cultural products. For example, Verboord
assumption that people’s experiential orientations (2011) shows in an international comparative
are not completely individualized but are socially study that fictional writing is being judged less
schematized. In his empirical study, three every- by high-culture standards, and is increasingly fol-
day aesthetic schemata of this kind emerge: the lowing an economic, market-oriented logic.
schemata of Hochkultur (high culture), of These studies show, in line with Schulze’s
Trivialkultur (literally trivial culture, i.e., reflections, that processes of aestheticization do
low-brow culture, entertainment for the masses) not have to be linear and move in a particular
and of Spannung (tension, excitement) (Schulze direction, but that there are various cultural
1992, 142 ff.). Just a few decades ago, Schulze repertoires of aestheticization.
argues, everyday aesthetics was marked by a In their analysis of the American gourmet
one-dimensional opposition between Hochkultur foodscape, Johnston and Baumann (2007)
on the one hand and Trivialkultur on the other; observe a trend, leading away from the traditional
now, however, the development of the Spannung culinary emphasis on French cuisine to a focus on
schema has led to a multidimensionality in the criteria of authenticity and exoticism. In their
space of everyday aesthetics (Müller-Schneider view, however, this does not mean a democrati-
1994). What is meant by this is a form of every- zation or a breaking down of hierarchies, but
day aesthetics focused on speed, physicality, and merely a change in the criteria for legitimate
action. Typical examples of the Spannung culture in aesthetic judgments about products. In
schema are rock and pop music, trips to the cin- contemporary societies, legitimate culture can be
ema, action films, and very physical forms of identified by the prioritizing of criteria of authen-
dancing (Schulze 1992, 153 f.). ticity, encompassing artisanal instead of industrial
Analyses of media have been especially useful production, contextualization in a local or
for tracing these processes of aestheticization. It regional setting, and an anti-commercial attitude,
becomes evident here that processes of aestheti- which distances itself from economic calculation.
cization can go in different directions, depending Further identifying features are an artistic/aes-
on their orientation towards everyday aesthetic thetic attitude, and an emphasis on the individual
schemata. For example, Janssen et al. (2011) are person of the producer, and the historical and
able to show that the coverage of arts and culture traditional connections of a product. In their anal-
in the quality newspapers is becoming more ysis of the discourse of the American gourmet
inclusive of popular culture, which belongs to scene, Johnston und Baumann (2007) are able to
Schulze’s Spannung schema, and that the empirically identify, in particular, the relevance
98 J. Rössel et al.

of (1) geographical connections, (2) artisanal pro- et al. 2001). Similarly, expert ratings of wine in
duction methods, (3) the personality of the indi- blind tastings exhibit only low intercorrelations
vidual producer, and (4) the embedding of the (Brochet 2001; Cicchetti 2007; Hodgson 2008).
production in history and tradition. This focus Quality assessments of wines by nonexperts show
on criteria of authenticity is becoming increas- a negative correlation with price, meaning that
ingly important for ever-larger sectors of markets wine consumers on average rate the quality of
offering products and services with primarily aes- high-priced wines lower than that of inexpensive
thetic features (Carroll 2015). wines (Goldstein et al. 2008). Generally, these
and many other experimental studies indicate
that consumers, when relying only on sensory
2.2 Aestheticization and Uncertainty characteristics, are not able to distinguish
between different levels of wine quality
Schulze’s reflections demonstrated very emphati- (D’Alessandro and Pecotich 2013), though wine
cally that the evaluation of goods, services, and experts do perform better in some respects
experiences has very shaky foundations and (Gawel 1997; Solomon 1997; Goldstein et al.
entails a high level of uncertainty. Consumer 2008).
judgments in the fields of wine and art can serve In short, products and services that are primar-
as empirical evidence of this. ily acquired because of their aesthetic features are
For the recipients and consumers of artistic characterized by a high level of uncertainty about
goods and services, it is extremely difficult to their quality. A central approach within econom-
assess their quality. In an enlightening experi- ics which deals with such uncertainties about
ment, Hawley-Dolan and Winner (2011) used quality is information economics (Stiglitz 1987;
paintings by professional artists on the one hand Riley 2001). In one of the classic publications
and by animals and children on the other hand as leading to the founding of this new branch of
stimuli. These were presented to art and non-art economics, Akerlof (1970) showed, in a model
students for evaluation. There were hardly any of the used car market, that in conditions of
differences between the assessments of the two asymmetric distribution of information (where
groups, with slightly less than two thirds of the the consumers know less about the quality of the
artworks presented being attributed to the correct vehicles on offer than the sellers), buyers are only
producers. While this value does differ signifi- willing to pay an average price. This in turn
cantly from a random evaluation (50% correct means that sellers of above-average-quality
attributions), it clearly shows people’s consider- goods withdraw from the market, which ulti-
able uncertainty when evaluating contemporary mately hampers the development of the market.
art. Therefore, Plattner (1996) also describes the To solve this problem, Akerlof raised the possi-
buyers of contemporary artworks as confused bility of introducing institutions to signal a certain
consumers, who would generally be unable to quality to the customers (Schneider 1997,
undertake any economic transactions without get- 117 ff.). These include guarantees from the
ting orientation from the quality judgments of manufacturers, brand names, or chains which rep-
actors in the art field. resent a certain level of performance. Shapiro
This uncertainty in assessing the quality of (1983) was able to show that, in markets where
products and services can also be discerned in customers have incomplete information about the
the field of food and especially wine. Several actual quality of products, creating a good reputa-
studies have shown that people are not very tion is a worthwhile investment strategy for
good at evaluating food, based solely on its sen- producers.
sory characteristics. For instance, an experimental In order to more precisely define the asymmet-
study with students of oenology from Bordeaux ric distribution of information during the
found that most of them were unable to distin- exchange of goods, three different types of
guish white from red wine just by taste (Morrot properties can be distinguished (Schneider 1997,
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets 99

84 ff.): Firstly, search properties, which can extent. Hence, these socially attributed features
already be evaluated by the consumers before cannot be straightforwardly slotted into the cate-
they purchase a product, (e.g., the color or gory system, developed in information economics
weight). Secondly, experience properties, which to describe the properties of goods, since uncer-
can only be ascertained after the good has been tainty about aesthetic judgments is not based on a
purchased, by consumption or use, (e.g., the lack of information, but on their social construc-
actual fit of a shoe, the taste of a new lemonade, tion. This also means, however, that quality
or the durability of a Teflon-coated pan). Thirdly, judgments themselves are dependent on pro-
so-called credence properties, which the con- cesses of social construction, which, as outlined
sumer cannot verify with any certainty either above, can vary across time and space as well as
before or after the purchase or only with great between social groups.
difficulty. Examples might be the local origin of
foodstuffs, or the guarantee of a particular ecolog-
ical method of cultivation for cereal crops. 2.3 How Is Aesthetic Quality
The theoretical criterion for distinguishing Attributed?
between these types of properties is obviously
whether and when consumers can acquire infor- In the following section we present two theoreti-
mation about them. In our view, however, the cal approaches to explain how quality judgments
uncertainty attendant on aesthetic evaluations come about: Karpik’s model of the economics of
does not depend on asymmetric information dis- singularities and Bourdieu’s model of the cultural
tribution and therefore, cannot be subsumed consecration of objects. Karpik's economics of
under the concepts of information economics, as singularities is not a theory about markets in
will now be demonstrated. Most features of an general, it is a theory about markets for singular
artwork can be ascertained when viewing it in the products, and products with aesthetic qualities
gallery, in the artist’s studio, or at an auction. usually belong to this category. Singular products
From an economic perspective, most of the constitute a specific class of products, which has
features of artworks must surely be regarded as been ignored in economic theory, according to
search properties since customers can assess the Karpik (Eloire 2010; Karpik 2011). Singular
objects and their characteristics before and during products are unique due to their structured multi-
purchase. How is this contradiction to be under- dimensionality. That is, each singular product is
stood? On the one hand, there are no information defined by a specific combination of attributes
asymmetries, as understood by information eco- and their interrelations. For example, according
nomics; on the other hand, there are obvious to the economics of singularities, Tenuta San
uncertainties on the part of consumers about the Guido was not judged (by the Wine Spectator)
aesthetic qualities of the products. Aesthetic to be the best wine of 2018 because it contains
evaluations of the beauty of an artwork or the elements of Cabernet Franc, some Tuscany, some
taste of a high-quality wine are not individual 2015, and some red, but due to the specific com-
judgments, but are, typically, socially bination of these attributes (or others).
constructed. If a random person declares that a Their uniqueness makes singular products
particular object is a work of art, or that a incommensurable. They do not easily lend them-
fermented grape juice is an excellent wine, this selves to comparisons (Heintz 2016). Moreover,
judgment has no social consequences unless other in markets for singular products, quality competi-
people, who are considered to be competent tion prevails over price competition (Karpik
judges, share and endorse these evaluations. 2010). Singular products are therefore not primar-
Thus, aesthetic judgments are social properties ily compared by price. Yet without comparison,
of products, which are only created by a social choice is not possible, so in theory no market can
consensus within certain groups or networks, and exist. How is this resolved? Karpik maintains that
are therefore, temporary to a particularly great singular products can be commensurated by
100 J. Rössel et al.

highlighting some attributes and neglecting order singular products along an ordinal scale
others. According to Karpik, then, markets for (Karpik 2011). Rankings do not provide substan-
singular products necessarily rely on judgments tive knowledge, only formal knowledge on the
about the quality of such products. The judgment relative position of products within a single hier-
establishes a certain point of view, enabling archy. Parker Points are an example. Hence, the
actors to compare otherwise incommensurable complexity of the quality of singular products is
products. condensed into a one-dimensional scale, incom-
However, in a market for singular products, mensurability is temporarily eliminated.
each point of view is contestable. Indeed, a mul- Appellations are “names associated with the
tiplicity of points of views is constitutive of this attributes and meanings that define singular
market (Karpik 2013). If this were not the case, products or families of singular products” (Karpik
de-singularization would become rampant, and it 2010, 45; Rodet 2012). In the wine market, this
would not be a market for singular products any- can be the name of the wine producer, the winery,
more. The awareness of different points of view a wine region, or a label, such as the appelations
further implies that commensuration is always d’origine contrôlée in France. Confluences are
just temporary, and quality is always techniques to channel consumers, entailing spa-
underdetermined. One might judge a singular tial arrangements of products in retail outlets or
product from a certain perspective, but in princi- selling techniques (Jourdain 2010). In the wine
ple a different perspective would be equally legit- market, consumers participate in wine tastings or
imate. A situation of radical uncertainty arises. tours of wine estates, complete with the custom-
Were the 250 dollars for the bottle of Tenuta ary visit to the on-site shop. Finally, there are
San Guido really justified, and if so, on what personal networks, which encompass strong and
grounds? This makes markets for singular weak ties, such as family members, friends,
products opaque. colleagues, or contacts (Felouzis and Perroton
To dissipate this opacity and to make 2007; Lefèvre 2015). This type of judgment
judgments, consumers need help, which is device “operate[s] by the circulation of the spo-
provided by judgment devices. Judgment devices ken word” (Karpik 2010, 45).
are cognitive artifacts (Aspers and Beckert 2011). Karpik’s typology makes a significant contri-
They offer focused, formatted, and credible bution to the sociology of valuation and evalua-
knowledge on the quality of singular products. tion by bringing together different types of
Knowledge contains implicit and explicit judgment devices, most often treated separately,
evaluations, providing reasons for choosing a in a theoretically grounded framework (Healy
product (Karpik 2013). Credible judgment 2011; Aspers 2018). Karpik understands his
devices are a necessary condition for the exis- typology as a tool for empirical research, and
tence of a functioning market for singular goods deems it sufficiently complete to analyze and
and services. explain the functioning of markets for
Karpik differentiates five types of judgment singularities (Karpik 2013). A major task for the
devices. Cicerones represent critics and analysis of a particular market, then, is to assess
guidebooks offering evaluations of singular the relative importance of these devices for (e)-
products (Eloire 2010). In the wine market, the valuation processes and for market outcomes,
expert Robert Parker, who publishes Parker’s: such as price and demand (Kraemer 2017). Yet,
“The Wine Buyer’s Guide,” is a formidable in line with the Weberian concept of ideal types,
example. Parker talks about the tradition of a Karpik (2010) also characterizes empirically
wine region, the personality of the wine producer, observable markets as regimes of economic coor-
and gives a detailed account of the flavors of a dination. The market for fine wine, for example,
wine. Cicerones, hence, provide substantive is built upon impersonal, substantial, and critical
knowledge without establishing a single order of devices. Karpik speaks of an authenticity regime.
worth. This is in stark contrast to rankings, which These devices respect the originality and
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets 101

authenticity of the product and empower behavior of actors in a field (Bourdieu and
consumers to make autonomous judgments. Con- Wacquant 1996, 124 ff.). Bourdieu is mainly
sequently, the market for fine wine is based on concerned with the extent to which actors possess
cicerones and appellations (Karpik 2013). three types of resources: economic, social, and
Rankings and confluences are expected to play a cultural capital (Bourdieu 1983; Fröhlich 1994,
subordinate role since they represent formal and 34 ff.). Although Bourdieu expands the classic
commercial devices, which de-singularize concept of capital, economic capital in the form of
products by ordering them on a one-dimensional money and property rights remains dominant in
scale and by channeling consumers to increase his concept. He uses social capital to refer to
profits. Personal networks are also likely to play people’s formal and informal networks of
a lesser role, since they are primarily relevant in relationships, which can be relevant for the acqui-
markets where no other credible judgment sition of other types of capital. Lastly, he
devices are available (Bessy and Chauvin 2013). differentiates between three forms of cultural cap-
While Karpik presents a specific model, ital: firstly, institutionalized cultural capital in the
focused on the uncertainty associated with singu- form of educational qualifications; secondly,
lar products, Pierre Bourdieu views the attribution objectified cultural capital in the form of objects
of aesthetic and other qualities to objects as a (pictures, books, musical instruments, musical
general social process, taking place in all social scores); and thirdly, embodied cultural capital.
fields. Similarly, to Luhmann’s theory of func- The latter refers to abilities, dispositions, and
tional differentiation, Bourdieu sees society as skills assimilated or absorbed by individuals,
differentiated into various subsystems; he which enable them to appreciate works of art,
considers the social space as being differentiated for example. Bourdieu is referring mainly to
into various spheres or social fields (Bourdieu and works of classic high culture, for which he uses
Wacquant 1996, 134; Kneer 2004). Unlike the term legitimate culture (Bourdieu 1982). Cul-
Luhmann, however, Bourdieu conceives of social tural capital, in particular, can take on different
fields as having only limited autonomy: firstly, he field-specific forms (Holt 1997). Possessing dif-
sees economic capital as dominant in modern ferent forms of capital allows actors access to the
societies, so even actors in non-economic fields field and opportunities to exert influence in it. So,
must, in some cases, be guided by the prevailing for Bourdieu these fields are always, in part,
economic logic (Bourdieu 1999, 341 f.). Sec- power structures and fields of conflict. The actors
ondly, the relative autonomy of the social fields strategically deploy their resources to improve
is historically variable. The autonomy of a field their position in the field and thus, also define
can be deduced from the degree to which actors the boundaries of the field. Whatever definition
within that field take their cues from hierarch- of a true artist or a true writer is accepted at any
izations and criteria that are internal to the field, given time (other terms could be substituted here:
and not from those outside the field, (e.g., eco- true scientist, true believer, the wine of the cen-
nomic criteria) (Bourdieu 1999, 344). In one tury, the ultimate smartphone) is the result of the
respect, however, the autonomy of social fields preceding conflicts between the different actors in
increases in a nearly linear manner: over time, the relevant field (Bourdieu 1999, 355).
fields accumulate their own history and an The fields of cultural production that are cen-
associated discourse. Actors are then required to tral for the attribution of aesthetic features mostly
exercise ever-greater reflexivity, if they are to display a bipolar structure: at one pole are the
position themselves appropriately in the field actors who are more strongly oriented towards
(Bourdieu 1999, 384 ff.). commercial success and gaining economic capi-
The defining feature of social fields is their tal, at the other pole are those who base their goals
objective structure, which is the result of the more on cultural criteria (Bourdieu 1999, 227 ff.).
distribution of key resources, which Bourdieu From Bourdieu’s perspective, an orientation
calls forms of capital, and which structures the towards commercial gain means that these actors
102 J. Rössel et al.

do not fully submit to the cultural criteria within knowledge about the codes and conventions rele-
the field and are more guided by external criteria vant in production. For many people from the
(Bourdieu 1999, 227 ff., 346). In contrast, the lower and middle social classes, works of con-
targeted reference group of the limited mode of temporary art are a source of confusion and mis-
production, oriented towards the internal criteria understanding, because they generally use their
of the cultural field, is a highly educated audience, everyday knowledge to decode these artworks
in extreme cases including only the producer’s (Bourdieu 1970). However, this everyday cultural
colleagues. In comparison to commercial capital only allows decoding of the surface mean-
products, products originating from the limited ing of artworks. This typically means that people
mode of production often place high demands from the lower and middle social classes mainly
on its audience, since the content can only be perceive artworks as beautiful if they represent
understood in a reflexive relationship to the his- things that can be regarded as beautiful them-
tory of the field (Bourdieu 1999, 237). The selves, such as an attractive woman or a sunset
objects, goods, and services discussed here are (Bourdieu et al. 1981; Bourdieu 1982). The for-
often avant-garde in character, making a con- mal and stylistic aspects of an artwork, which
scious break with the existing conventions of derive from its producer’s position in the history
perception and interpretation (Becker 1982) and of the artistic field and which are necessary for a
a deliberate effort to disconcert the audience. deeper understanding and therefore enjoyment of
The social fields of cultural production show a the artwork, remain hidden from these viewers
number of institutionalized roles that contribute to (Bourdieu 1970). Clearly the basis for an ade-
creating an object’s aura (Bourdieu 1999, 270 ff., quate appreciation of art, which also enables the
360 ff.).1 These range from the editor who viewer to enjoy it, is to have sufficient aesthetic
discovers an author, or the gallery-owner who competence or cultural capital, allowing for a
exhibits an artist to critics and decision-makers more fundamental decoding of an artwork.
in museums and cultural policy. An important, Besides repeated engagement with artworks, the
often overlooked point is that the consecration most important sources for the cultural capital
of an artist or an artist’s work is also dependent needed for this are, on the one hand, the education
on educational policy. Only when the reading of a system, and on the other hand, as a prerequisite
writer’s novels, or the interpretation of a visual for acquiring cultural capital in the education
artist’s objects, or a composer’s works has been system, the cultural climate in a person’s house-
included in the school curriculum have they hold of origin.
definitively arrived in the pantheon of the classics Although Bourdieu’s theory was primarily
(Bourdieu 1999, 237). It is also via the educa- developed for the reception of art, it is also trans-
tional institutions and the specific art-related pub- ferable to other fields. This applies both to the
lic spheres that the corresponding demand for art process of the aesthetic consecration of objects on
is created, on the one hand in the form of art the producer side, and to the consumption of
lovers, who populate the museums and galleries, goods and services, which is dependent on
and on the other hand in the form of collectors possessing a certain cultural capital. Pape
and art buyers, who actually demand artworks on (2012), for example, has been able to demonstrate
the art market. If we follow Bourdieu’s theory of this comprehensively for the German wine mar-
art reception, an adequate understanding of ket. It is clear, for instance, that the position of
artworks (and therefore one that gives enjoyment) actors in social space and their family socializa-
is only possible if a person has the corresponding tion have a significant influence on taste
dispositions (dry versus sweet wine), on evalua-
1
tion criteria (importance of artisanal production
Here we are focusing on Bourdieu’s presentation of the
methods), and on the main purchasing channels
artistic field. It would be possible, however, to produce
comparable representations for any field of cultural pro- chosen by consumers. In summary, this discus-
duction by exchanging the actors and institutions involved. sion of field theory shows that the quality of an
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets 103

aesthetic product is not determined by existing 3.1 How Does the Aesthetic
objective features but is constructed in the field- Discourse in the Wine Field
specific discourse. A substantial part of this is Develop?
conducted in the general mass media, regardless
of whether the topic is art in a narrower sense or What turns a bottle of fermented grape juice into a
other products with primarily aesthetic features. cult wine? As discussed in the course of this
These goods and services with their respective chapter, we are working on the theoretical
qualities attract a response in virtually all mass assumption that the evaluation of aesthetic
media, but in some cases, there are also field- products is not the result of exchange processes
specific media such as specialist journals, which on the market, but of the interactions of actors in
constitute the relevant field-specific public the relevant social world, in this case the wine
sphere. field. Different actors, however, have unequal
levels of influence. Their endowment with diverse
forms and different volumes of capital allows the
actors access to the field and diverging chances of
3 Empirical Examples
exerting influence in it. The accepted definition of
an icon wine, or of a high-status winemaker, is the
In this section we report results of empirical stud-
result of preceding conflicts and discourses
ies, that applied and tested the theoretical
between the different actors in the relevant field.
concepts, we developed and discussed in the pre-
In our view, the public discourses and mass media
vious sections. In Sect. 3.1 we study the aestheti-
play a special part in this process.
cization thesis on the empirical basis of wine
In order to investigate the role of the mass
reporting in two major German weeklies. In this
media in the process of aestheticization, using
section, we focus especially on Johnston and
the example of wine, we conducted an empirical
Baumann’s (2007) idea that aesthetic goods and
study of wine coverage in two German weekly
services are increasingly evaluated by criteria of
magazines, Der Spiegel and Die ZEIT, two par-
authenticity. In Sect. 3.2 we report on a study, that
ticularly influential actors of quality evaluation
analyzes Karpik’s model of judgement devices in
and cultural consecration from the German field-
its impact on consumers’ willingness to buy and
specific public sphere (Rössel et al. 2018). All
pay for fine wines. In Sect. 3.3. we switch to
articles on the topic of wine for the period from
Bourdieu’s field theory and present research
1947 to 2008 were included. The relatively long
results, that show the relevance of field-specific
period covered by the study allowed us to con-
processes of aesthetic consecration on price for-
sider several theses about the historical transfor-
mation on the art market. Finally, in Sect. 3.4. we
mation of cultural evaluation processes from the
take both the producer and the consumer side of
literature on cultural sociology. Firstly, the above-
the wine market into account and empirically
discussed theory of aestheticization, which
establish that a homology in aesthetic evaluation
postulates that evaluation processes are shaped
criteria between these two sides of the market
increasingly by aesthetic standards, while instru-
exists, thus supporting Bourdieu’s field model.
mental and economic aspects, in a narrower sense
Overall, these four studies illustrate the empirical
are attracting less attention. Secondly, there is the
usefulness of the theoretical approaches presented
claim that in the context of the globalization pro-
in Sect. 2 for economic sociology.
cess, the cultural discourse in the individual
countries is becoming more global in scope.
Thirdly, there is the assumption that the tradi-
tional separation between high culture and popu-
lar culture is eroding, and is being replaced by
new symbolic hierarchies, like authenticity. We
104 J. Rössel et al.

assume that the authenticity of aesthetic objects the demand for fine wine. Karpik’s theory thus
can be discerned from the use of criteria makes a valuable contribution to the explanation
emphasizing artisanal production, the natural of prices and demand (Schenk 2012; Kraemer
preconditions for this, regional and traditional 2017). However, the statistical findings for
integration, and the personalities of the individual Karpik’s characterization of the fine wine market
producers. as an authenticity regime are mixed (Healy 2011).
Our empirical study can largely confirm these In line with the theoretical expectations, cicerones
theses: wine is increasingly viewed as an aesthetic are substantially related to the demand for fine
object, while economic and instrumental wine. Personal networks play a subordinate role.
references have almost completely vanished In contrast to the theoretical arguments,
from the discussion. The globalization theory confluences are also strongly correlated with the
can also be confirmed: references to German demand for fine wine, while appellations are
wine are decreasing, while wine from the New unrelated to the purchase of the most expensive
World in particular is attracting more attention. wines. Rankings are relevant for lower-priced
Yet, contrary to all arguments about the end of wines, but also for the wines at the very top of
France’s dominance in the culinary world, the the price distribution. Thus, judgment devices are
esteem which French wines are given has not extremely important for explaining market behav-
diminished over time. Lastly, we can demonstrate ior for singular products, however, we do not find
that in the period of time under consideration, clear evidence to support Karpik’s notions of
authenticity came to play an ever more important ideal-typical markets, where certain combinations
role in the discourse on wine. This shows empiri- of judgment devices prevail.
cally, that in the contemporary field of wine, a Historical and institutional characteristics of
fermented grape juice is particularly likely to the German wine market provide a tentative
become a cult wine, without any change in its explanation for some of these unexpected
chemical composition, if, regardless of its prove- findings (Zhao 2008; Carter 2017). Although the
nance from a particular country, it is presented in market is increasingly characterized by a demand
the field-specific discourse as an aesthetic prod- for foreign wines, the demand for regional wines
uct, characterized by artisanal manufacture, spe- is still strong, especially in wine-producing
cial natural conditions of production, a specific regions (Pape 2012). This might explain the per-
winemaking tradition, and a winemaker who is vasive role of confluences (wine seminars and
comparable to an artist (Rössel et al. 2018). These wine tours) as a judgment device. Furthermore,
findings very clearly show that developments on the German wine market is characterized by the
the market could be influenced not only by the coexistence of two ranking devices, issued by two
growing aestheticization of products, but also by separate and competing institutions for quality
the specific direction of this aestheticization assessments: the official German wine classifica-
process. tion and a private association of wine producers
called Verband Deutscher Prädikatsweingüter
(VDP). According to previous studies, the former
3.2 The Use of Judgment Devices is more oriented towards the mass market,
to Overcome Quality Uncertainty employing a standardized method of wine testing
based on taste and chemical composition, while
Based on survey data on consumers in four Ger- the latter is restricted to fine wine, putting forward
man cities (Pape 2012), we studied the role of the a more holistic notion of quality akin to the
different judgment devices, which, according to French concept of terroir (Rössel and Beckert
Karpik, reduce the quality uncertainty connected 2013; Frick and Simmons 2013). The use of
to singular products (Schenk 2020). We found these ranking devices might yield different effects
that the use of different types of judgment devices at different points of the price distribution, and
is consistently and substantially correlated with not only in the lowest price segments, as the
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets 105

theory suggests. The impact of rankings on the is reduced. The formation of aesthetic evaluations
demand for fine wine reflects the particular land- and thus the reduction of uncertainty does not
scape of ranking devices in the German wine take place on the art market, but rather in the art
field. In sum, this implies that the economics of field, as the field theory of Bourdieu predicts. The
singularities takes too little of the historical and pricing of contemporary works of art therefore
institutional context into account when depends on the reputation of the artist and the
explaining the relative importance of judgment artworks, which is established by actors
devices in the demand for singular products participating in the artistic field of production,
(Zhao 2008; Healy 2011; Carter 2017). especially the field-specific arts media. We
The results show, furthermore, that the analyzed this idea using two databases,
demand for fine wine is not directly related to containing various indicators for the reputation
social distinction, once the use of judgment of the artists in the sample and prices for their
devices is taken into account. In line with work, one focusing on auction prices and one on
Karpik’s depiction, this indicates that consumers gallery prices. The auction database contains data
of singular products are highly reflexive and on 23 internationally renowned artists from
autonomous, making product choices based on German-speaking countries, following their
the knowledge provided by judgment devices activities in the art world from the start of their
(Howland 2013). However, the engagement with careers until the year 2000. The gallery database
judgment devices is, in turn, consistently and comprises information on 30 artists represented
substantially correlated with the social and nor- by galleries in Leipzig and Berlin catering to a
mative function of wine consumption. This national and international audience.
suggests that social actors do not seek to acquire We were able to use both of these databases to
knowledge on the quality of singular products systematically test and ultimately substantiate our
solely to counter radical uncertainty, as Karpik idea that the aesthetic reputation, established in
argues (Aspers and Beckert 2011). The users of the art field is crucial for the formation of prices
judgment devices also link external rewards and on the art market. Using two different databases,
symbolic group boundaries to the practice of fine however, also enabled us to test for differences in
wine consumption (Warde 2014). These social the relationship between artistic reputation and
functions might help to explain why consumers price formation on the primary (gallery) and sec-
become knowledgeable evaluators of singular ondary (auction) art market. Based on the data we
products, and how this relates to identity forma- collected from galleries, we were able to show
tion (Lamont 2012). The neglect of processes of that an artist’s accumulated reputation over the
distinction and their class foundations is a serious course of his or her career is of central impor-
blind spot in the economics of singularities tance. This result is explained by the specific
(Kraemer 2017), which is, however, addressed scripts that gallery owners follow in their pricing
in Bourdieu’s theory. strategies (Velthuis 2005). Auction price data, on
the other hand, revealed that among the more
specific reputation indicators, the most important
3.3 What Part Do Aesthetic Criteria is the recognition that comes through awards and
Play in Price Formation media coverage of the artist. This result is very
on the Art Market? convincing from the point of view of our theoret-
ical framework developed above, focusing on the
We conducted a study on the art market in public discourse about aesthetic qualities. For
Germany (Beckert and Rössel 2013), starting potential art purchasers, media attention given to
from the assumption developed above, that the an artist is a very accessible signal of artistic
problem of uncertainty is a dominant structural quality, which reduces the uncertainty associated
property of the market for contemporary art. A with purchasing a contemporary work of art. The
stable market can only develop if this uncertainty representation of an artist’s works and career in
106 J. Rössel et al.

the media lends legitimacy to individual works of developing taste. This symbolic capital can be
art. This gives prospective buyers reassurance transformed into economic capital in the form of
about the probable quality of past and future substantially higher prices on the market.
works by the same artist. This public awareness However, this indirect strategy of first gaining
does not arise independently of the artistic field, symbolic capital, which is afterwards transformed
but rather originates from assessments and into economic profits, is of course only one of two
activities inside the art world that create and pro- alternative economic strategies for wineries. The
mote an artist’s reputation and image. other strategy is a heteronomous orientation
towards direct economic gains and a strict focus
on the pre-existing demand in the market. Thus,
3.4 What Influence Do Aesthetic the analysis has shown that Bourdieu’s model of
Criteria Have on Behavior the chiastic structure of fields has considerable
in the Wine Market: Price power in explaining price differentiation between
Formation and Consumption? wineries.
Regarding the consumer side, we found that
Based on the assumption that the assessment of wine quality is interpreted differently according
wine quality is not simply a question of informa- to a person’s habitus. The perception of symbolic
tion about objective characteristics, but the result capital is shaped by the class positions of
of a process of social and cultural consecration, consumers. In the case of upper- and middle-
we studied the formation of prices on the German class consumers with high economic and cultural
wine market (Beckert et al. 2018). In our empiri- capital, symbolic positions from the autonomous
cal study, we analyzed data for 110 wineries and pole of cultural production fields enjoy a high
1071 wines, as well as data on wine consumers in level of legitimacy. Furthermore, our empirical
four German cities. The symbolic positions of the analysis of the consumption side of the market
wineries were ascertained from a content analysis has clearly indicated that middle- and upper-class
of their homepages. The information on consumers with a higher income, a higher level of
consumers was obtained from a population sur- education, and a strong familiarity with and
vey (see Sect. 3.2). knowledge of the wine field, due to their sociali-
Our empirical analysis of the production side zation are not only more oriented towards the
showed that the symbolic positions of wineries autonomous pole of the field in terms of sources
have a strong explanatory impact on the price of information, quality criteria, taste, and distri-
differences between them. This is a surprisingly bution channels, but are also prepared to pay
clear result since we captured only a narrow slice higher prices for a bottle of wine. Finally, they
of the vineyards’ symbolic positions by analyzing have a greater disposition to view wine consump-
only their webpage. Future research based on tion as a practice allowing for social distinction.
richer data could uncover even stronger effects. This strongly substantiates Bourdieu’s idea of a
Winemakers with symbolic positions, typical of homology between the hierarchic structure of
the autonomous pole in fields of cultural produc- fields of cultural production and the class hierar-
tion obtain significantly higher prices on the wine chy of the social space.
market compared to other wineries. Producers
with these symbolic positions make use of sym-
bolic capital, converting it into higher market
4 Summary
prices. Symbolic capital accrues especially to
wine producers who conceal their economic
We would like to conclude this chapter by
aims and produce wines with aesthetic
summarizing a few theses that we see as central
characteristics, which are depicted as difficult to
for the future analysis of markets for products and
drink because the consumer must first learn to
services with primarily aesthetic features.
appreciate them and must therefore work on
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets 107

1. The relevance of markets for primarily aes- judgments, which is based on their socially
thetic products and services is increasing. constructed nature.
This is not only the result of a shift in 4. As Akerlof (1970) showed, markets with radi-
structures of consumption towards classic cal uncertainty about the quality of the goods
goods and services defined by aesthetic and services offered, collapse. In our chapter,
features (Hörstermann 2016), but also of we have discussed two theoretical proposals
intensifying competition, based on aesthetic explaining mechanisms that reduce uncer-
design, in markets for classic consumer tainty for these markets: on the one hand
goods (Reckwitz 2012, 2017). The back- Karpik’s theory of singular products, on the
ground for these market developments is a other hand Bourdieu’s field theory. Thus, these
fundamental aestheticization of everyday life two theoretical approaches offer useful tools
in prosperous, post-materialist societies. The for the analysis of uncertainty on economic
analysis of aesthetic features of products and markets.
services is therefore steadily gaining impor- 5. Karpik assumes that in markets for singular
tance for economic sociology. products, which include the aesthetic products
2. In an analysis of reporting on the wine market discussed here, the judgment devices
in Germany over more than half a century (cicerones, rankings, appellations,
(1947–2008), we were able to convincingly confluences, personal networks) allow quality
trace the growing aestheticization of this prod- assessments to be made by consumers. He
uct (Rössel et al. 2018). Of course, wine is a assumes that in certain markets very specific
commodity that has always been mainly configurations of such judgment devices deter-
viewed in aesthetic terms. However, our anal- mine the reduction of uncertainty in a given
ysis was able to show that, at the beginning of market. A study of the wine market (Schenk
the twenty-first century, even the remaining 2020) was able to demonstrate that judgment
economic and instrumental aspects had been devices really are of substantial importance for
almost completely supplanted by aesthetic demand and pricing in this market. However,
aspects. We were also able to show that more the study did not find evidence that this market
attention is now being paid to authenticity is defined by an ideal-typical constellation of
criteria such as artisanal production, regional judgment devices as postulated by Karpik.
origin, and the personality of the winemaker. This suggests that market processes need to
One route taken by aestheticization is clearly be examined in closer connection to the histor-
leading towards authentic products. This is an ical, social, and geographical background in
increasingly important branch of economic which they are embedded, which may be able
sociology (Carroll 2015). to explain the specific role of particular judg-
3. Aesthetic evaluations of goods are, by their ment devices. Furthermore, Karpik’s econom-
very nature, associated with radical uncer- ics of singularities neglects the role of
tainty, since these assessments can always be distinction processes to explain the use of
fallible, be it over time or space, or across judgment devices. In sum, the strengths of
social groups (Rössel 2007). Karpik defined Karpik’s theory lie in the nuanced and
this uncertainty with the concept of the singu- differentiated analysis of the roles of particular
lar product, which is distinguished by its judgment devices, but the theory neglects the
unique combination of features. In contrast to wider social embeddedness of markets, which
the assumption made by information econom- are more comprehensively addressed in
ics (as a branch of economics), this uncertainty Bourdieu’s theory of social fields.
is not based on a kind of information asymme- 6. Bourdieu explains the emergence of aesthetic,
try between buyers and sellers, but merely on but also other evaluations as the result of a
the fundamental fallibility of aesthetic process of consecration that takes place in
108 J. Rössel et al.

social fields. This is associated with a powerful smartphones to interiors, are increasingly being
social theory for economic sociology. On the viewed and evaluated in aesthetic terms, even in
one hand, these fields are understood as the public discourse. They are increasingly more
structured fields of power and conflict; on the perceived as aesthetic objects, not only as goods
other hand, the hierarchy of the actors in these fulfilling an instrumental function. Therefore, we
fields is matched by a homologous social believe that it would be worthwhile to transfer the
structure of consumers. Bourdieu’s field the- theoretical instruments proposed here to markets
ory, therefore, makes it possible to explain not such as these.
only the genesis of symbolic attributions on
the producer side, but also the consumption
and reception of these attributions on the part
References
of consumers.
7. A study of price formation in the art market Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for “lemons”: Quality
(Beckert and Rössel 2013) was able to show uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly
that this is fundamentally dependent on the Journal of Economics, 84, 488–500.
aesthetic attributions in the field of art. The Aspers, P. (2018). Forms of uncertainty reduction: Deci-
sion, valuation, and contest. Theory and Society, 47(2),
commercial pricing processes should be 133–149.
understood as embedded, so to speak, in non- Aspers, P., & Beckert, J. (2011). Value in markets. In
commercial field contexts. It became clear that J. Beckert & P. Aspers (Eds.), The worth of goods:
the public discourse in the field and in the mass Valuation and pricing in the economy (pp. 3–38).
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
media play a particularly important role in Baumann, S. (2001). Intellectualization and art world
contemporary pricing processes. Comparable development: Film in the United States. American
results emerged from a study on the wine field Sociological Review, 66, 404–426.
(Beckert et al. 2018). The most noteworthy Baumann, S. (2002). Marketing, cultural hierarchy, and
the relevance of critics: Film in the United States,
finding here was that the structure of the fields 1935–80. Poetics, 30, 243–262.
leads to different pricing strategies among Becker, H. S. (1982). Art worlds. Berkeley: University of
wine producers. On the one hand there are California Press.
suppliers who operate at the autonomous pole Beckert, J. (2011). Where do prices come from? Sociolog-
ical approaches to price formation. Socio-Economic
of the field, following a strategy of symboli- Review, 9, 757–786.
cally distinctive products with high prices; on Beckert, J., & Rössel, J. (2013). The price of art. European
the other hand there are producers operating at Societies, 15, 178–195.
the heteronomous pole, who offer Beckert, J., Rössel, J., & Schenk, P. (2018). Wine as a
cultural product. Symbolic capital and price formation
standardized quality and follow a strategy of in the wine field. Sociological Perspectives, 60(1),
low prices and high market volume. This study 206–222.
was also able to show a homology with the Bessy, C., & Chauvin, P.-M. (2013). The power of market
social structure of wine consumption: it is intermediaries: From information to valuation pro-
cesses. Valuation Studies, 1(1), 83–117.
groups endowed with cultural and economic Bourdieu, P. (1970). Zur Soziologie der symbolischen
capital who are among the most important Formen. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.
consumers of distinctive and expensive wines. Bourdieu, P. (1982). Die feinen Unterschiede. Kritik der
gesellschaftlichen Urteilskraft. Frankfurt am Main:
In this chapter we have concentrated on the Suhrkamp.
analysis of the fields of art and wine. It is obvious, Bourdieu, P. (1983). Ökonomisches Kapital, kulturelles
Kapital, soziales Kapital. In R. Kreckel (Ed.), Soziale
however, that this approach can be transferred to Ungleichheiten (pp. 183–198). Soziale Welt,
numerous other products and markets which are Sonderband 2.
strongly characterized by aesthetic features, from Bourdieu, P. (1999). Die Regeln der Kunst. Genese und
music to cosmetic products and clothing. In addi- Struktur des literarischen Feldes. Frankfurt am Main:
Suhrkamp.
tion, however, other consumer goods with more Bourdieu, P., & Wacquant, L. (1996). Reflexive
instrumental functions, from cars and Anthropologie. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets 109

Bourdieu, P., Boltanski, L., Castel, R., Chamboredon, J.- Hawley-Dolan, A., & Winner, E. (2011). Seeing the mind
C., Lagneau, G., & Schnapper, D. (1981). Eine behind the art: People can distinguish abstract
illegitime Kunst. Die sozialen Gebrauchsweisen der expressionist paintings from highly similar paintings
Photographie. Frankfurt am Main: Europäische by children, chimps, monkeys and elephants. Psycho-
Verlagsanstalt GmbH. logical Science, 22, 435–441.
Brochet, F. (2001). Chemical object representation in the Healy, K. (2011). Judgement and distinction: Review
field of consciousness. Application presented for the symposium. Lucien Karpik: Valuing the unique. The
grand prix of the Académie Amorim following work economics of singularities. Socio-Economic Review, 9,
carried out towards a doctorate from the Faculty of 787–800.
Oenology. Talence Cadex: General Oenology Heintz, B. (2016). Wir leben im Zeitalter der
Laboratory. Vergleichung. Perspektiven einer Soziologie des
Carroll, G. R. (2015). Authenticity: Attribution, value, and Vergleichs. Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 45(5), 305–323.
meaning. In R. H. Scott & M. C. Buchmann (Eds.), Hodgson, R. T. (2008). An examination of judge reliability
Emerging trends in the social and behavioral sciences. at a major U. S. wine competition. Journal of Wine
An interdisciplinary, searchable, and linkable Economics, 3, 105–113.
resource (pp. 1–13). Hoboken: Wiley-Blackwell. Holt, D. B. (1997). Distinction in America? Recovering
Carter, E. (2017). For what it’s worth: The political con- Bourdieu’s theory of tastes from its critics. Poetics, 25,
struction of quality in French and Italian wine markets. 93–120.
Socio-Economic Review, 16(3), 479–498. Hörstermann, K. (2016). Der Wandel der Konsumstruktur
Charters, S. (2006). Aesthetic products and aesthetic con- in Deutschland. Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und
sumption: A review. Consumption, Markets and Cul- Sozialpsychologie, 68, 713–730.
ture, 9, 235–255. Howland, P. J. (2013). Distinction by proxy: The democ-
Charters, S., & Pettigrew, S. (2005). Is wine consumption ratization of fine wine. Journal of Sociology, 49(2–3),
an aesthetic experience? Journal of Wine Research, 16, 325–340.
121–136. Janssen, S., Verboord, M., & Kuipers, G. (2011). Compar-
Cicchetti, D. (2007). Assessing the reliability of blind wine ing cultural classification. In J. Rössel & G. Otte (Eds.),
tasting: Differentiating levels of clinical and statistical Lebensstilforschung (Sonderheft 51, Kölner Zeitschrift
meaningfulness. Journal of Wine Economics, 2, für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie) (pp. 139–168).
196–202. Wiesbaden: Springer.
D’Alessandro, S., & Pecotich, A. (2013). Evaluation of Johnston, J., & Baumann, S. (2007). Democracy versus
wine by expert and novice consumers in the presence distinction: A study of omnivorousness in gourmet
of variations in quality, brand and country of origin food writing. American Journal of Sociology, 113,
cues. Food Quality and Preference, 28(1), 287–303. 165–204.
Eloire, F. (2010). Une approche sociologique de la con- Jourdain, A. (2010). La construction sociale de la
currence sur un marché. Le cas des restaurateurs lillois. singularité. Une stratégie entrepreneuriale des artisans
Revue Française de Sociologie, 51(3), 481–517. d’art. Revue Française de Socio-Économie, 6(2),
Featherstone, M. (1987). Lifestyle and consumer culture. 13–30.
Theory, Culture & Society, 4, 55–70. Karpik, L. (2010). Valuing the unique: The economics of
Felouzis, G., & Perroton, J. (2007). Les “marchés singularities. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
scolaires”: Une analyse en termes d’économie de la Karpik, L. (2011). What is the price of a scientific paper?
qualité. Revue Française de Sociologie, 48(4), In J. Beckert & P. Aspers (Eds.), The worth of goods:
693–722. Valuation and pricing in the economy (pp. 63–85).
Frick, B., & Simmons, R. (2013). The impact of individual Oxford: Oxford University Press.
and collective reputation on wine prices: Empirical Karpik, L. (2013). Éléments de l’économie des
evidence from the Mosel Valley. Journal of Business singularités. In P. Steiner & F. Vatin (Eds.), Traité de
Economics, 83(2), 101–119. sociologie économique (pp. 163–206). Paris: PUF.
Fröhlich, G. (1994). Kapital, Habitus, Feld, Symbol. Kneer, G. (2004). Differenzierung bei Luhmann und
Grundbegriffe der Kulturtheorie Pierre Bourdieus. In Bourdieu. Ein Theorievergleich. In A. Nassehi &
I. Mörth & G. Fröhlich (Eds.), Das symbolische G. Nollmann (Eds.), Bourdieu und Luhmann. Frank-
Kapital der Lebensstile (pp. 31–54). Frankfurt am furt am Main: Suhrkamp.
Main: Campus Verlag. Kraemer, K. (2017). Lucien Karpik: Mehr Wert. Die
Gawel, R. (1997). The use of language by trained and Ökonomie des Einzigartigen. In K. Kraemer &
untrained experienced wine tasters. Journal of Sensory F. Brugger (Eds.), Schlüsselwerke der Wirtschaftsso-
Studies, 12, 267–284. ziologie (pp. 507–514). Wiesbaden: Springer
Goldstein, R., et al. (2008). Do more expensive wines taste Fachmedien Wiesbaden.
better? Evidence from a large sample of blind tastings. Lamont, M. (2012). Toward a comparative sociology of
American Association of Wine Economists. Working valuation and evaluation. Annual Review of Sociology,
Paper. Volume 16. 38(1), 201–221.
110 J. Rössel et al.

Lefèvre, N. (2015). Le marché du travail cycliste comme Kultur und Alltag (Soziale Welt, Sonderband 6)
économie des singularités. Sociologie du travail, 57(4), (pp. 71–92). Göttingen: Schwartz.
446–469. Schulze, G. (1992). Die Erlebnisgesellschaft. Kulturso-
Morrot, G., Brochet, F., & Dubourdieu, D. (2001). The ziologie der Gegenwart. Frankfurt am Main: Campus.
color of odors. Brain and Language, 79, 309–320. Schulze, G. (1997). Steigerungslogik und Erlebnisge-
Müller-Schneider, T. (1994). Von Schichten zu sellschaft. Politische Bildung, 30, 77–94.
Erlebnismilieus. Der Wandel der Milieustruktur in Shapiro, C. (1983). Premiums for high quality products as
der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Wiesbaden: DUV. returns to reputation. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Pape, S. (2012). Weinkonsum: Eine Studie zu sozialstruk- 98, 659–679.
turellen Determinanten und Lebensstilen im Feld des Shrum, W. (1991). Critics and publics: Cultural mediation
Weines. Wiesbaden: Springer Fachmedien Wiesbaden. in highbrow and popular performing arts. American
Plattner, S. (1996). High art down home. An economic Journal of Sociology, 97, 347–375.
ethnography of a local art market. Chicago: The Uni- Solomon, G. E. A. (1997). Conceptual change and wine
versity of Chicago Press. expertise. Journal of the Learning Sciences, 6, 41–60.
Reckwitz, A. (2012). Die Erfindung der Kreativität. Zum Stiglitz, J. E. (1987). The causes and consequences of the
Prozess gesellschaftlicher Ästhetisierung. Berlin: dependence of quality on Price. Journal of Economic
Suhrkamp. Literature, 25, 1–48.
Reckwitz, A. (2017). Die Gesellschaft der Singularitäten. Velthuis, O. (2005). Talking prices. Symbolic meanings of
Zum Strukturwandel der Moderne. Berlin: Suhrkamp. prices on the market for contemporary art. Princeton:
Riley, J. G. (2001). Silver signals: Twenty-five years of Princeton University Press.
screening and signaling. Journal of Economic Litera- Verboord, M. (2011). Market logic and cultural consecra-
ture, 39, 432–478. tion in French, German and American bestseller lists,
Rodet, D. (2012). Des dispositifs de jugement pour et par 1970–2007. Poetics, 39, 290–315.
les consommateurs? Les systèmes participatifs de Warde, A. (2014). After taste: Culture, consumption and
garantie du commerce equitable, de l’agriculture theories of practice. Journal of Consumer Culture, 14
biologique et des Amap. Revue Française de Socio- (3), 279–303.
Économie, 10(2), 199–217. Zelizer, V. (1978). Human values and the market: The case
Rössel, J. (2007). Ästhetisierung, Unsicherheit und die of life insurance and death in 19th century America.
Entwicklung von Märkten. In J. Beckert, R. Diaz- American Journal of Sociology, 84(3), 591–610.
Bone, & H. Ganßmann (Eds.), Märkte als soziale Zelizer, V. (2005). Circuits within capitalism. In V. Nee &
Strukturen (pp. 167–181). Frankfurt am Main: Campus R. Swedberg (Eds.), The economic sociology of capi-
Verlag. talism (pp. 289–322). Princeton: Princeton University
Rössel, J, & Beckert, J. (2012). Quality classifications in Press.
competition: Price formation in the German wine mar- Zhao, W. (2008). Social categories, classification systems,
ket (MPIfG Discussion Paper 12/3). Cologne: Max and determinants of wine Price in the California and
Planck Institute for the Study of Societies. French wine industries. Sociological Perspectives, 51
Rössel, J., & Beckert, J. (2013). Quality classifications in (1), 163–199.
competition: Price formation in the German wine mar-
ket. In J. Beckert & C. Musselin (Eds.), Constructing
quality. The classification of goods in markets. Oxford: Rössel, Jörg is professor of sociology, University of
Oxford University Press. Zurich, Switzerland.
Rössel, J., Schenk, P., & Eppler, D. (2018). The emer- Research topics: Economic sociology, sociological
gence of authentic products: The transformation of theory, consumption, culture, migration, transnationalism.
wine journalism in Germany, 1947–2008. Journal of Recent publications: Aidenberger, Amelie, Heiko Rauhut,
Consumer Culture, 18(3), 453–473. and Jörg Rössel. 2020. Is Participation in High-Status
Schenk, P. (2012). Review of Lucien Karpik (2010): Val- Culture a Signal of Trustworthiness? PlosOne 15/5: 1–23.
uing the unique. The economics of singularities. Schroedter, Julia, Jörg Rössel, and Emmanuela Chiappar-
Princeton: Princeton University Press. Kölner ini. 2020. Love Across Borders. On Population Struc-
Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie, 64 tures, Meeting Places and Preferences in a Globalizing
(2), 415–417. World. Journal of Comparative Family Studies 51/1:
Schenk, P. (2020). Can judgement devices explain the
18–58. Weingartner, Sebastian, and Jörg Rössel. 2019.
demand for fine wine? Manuscript. University of
Changing Dimensions of Cultural Consumption? Poetics
Lucerne.
74: 101345. Schenk, Patrick, Jörg Rössel, and Manuel
Schneider, C. (1997). Präferenzbildung bei Qualitätsunsi-
cherheit: Das Beispiel Wein. Berlin: Duncker & Scholz. 2018. Motivations and Constraints of Meat
Humblot. Avoidance. Sustainability 10: 3858. Rössel, Jörg, Patrick
Schulze, G. (1988). Alltagsästhetik und Lebenssituation. Schenk, and Dorothea Eppler. 2018. The Emergence of
Eine Analyse kultureller Segmentierungen in der Authentic Products. The Transformation of Wine Journal-
Bundesrepublik Deutschland. In H.-G. Soeffner (Ed.), ism in Germany, 1947–2008. Journal of Consumer
Culture 18/3: 453–73. Rössel, Jörg, and Patrick Schenk.
7 The Aesthetic Moment in Markets 111

Weingartner, Sebastian is a postdoctoral researcher in


2018. How Political is Political Consumption? The Case
Sociology, University of Zurich, Switzerland.
of Activism for the Global South and Fair Trade. Social
Research topics: Consumption, culture, digitization,
Problems 65/2: 266–84.
lifestyles, social inequality, sociological theory. Recent
publications: Weingartner, Sebastian. 2019. Führen
Schenk, Patrick is a postdoctoral researcher in sociol- mehrere Wege in die Oper? Die soziale Strukturierung
ogy, University of Lucerne, Switzerland. von Entscheidungsprozessen für den Kulturkonsum.
Research topics: Economic sociology, sociology of Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie
morality, markets, consumption, culture, technology. 75/1: 53–79. Weingartner, Sebastian, and Jörg Rössel.
Recent publications: Schenk, Patrick. 2019. A Matter of 2019. Changing Dimensions of Cultural Consumption?
Principle: Comparing Norm-Based Explanations for Fair Social Space and Space of Lifestyles in Switzerland from
Trade Consumption. Journal of Consumer Policy 42/3: 1976 to 2013, Poetics 74: 101345. Rössel, Jörg, and
397–423. Schenk, Patrick, Jörg Rössel, and Manuel Sebastian Weingartner. 2019. Rational Choice-Theorie in
Scholz. 2018. Motivations and Constraints of Meat der Kultursoziologie. In Handbuch Kultursoziologie,
Avoidance. Sustainability 10: 3858. Rössel, Jörg, Patrick Band 2: Theorien–Methoden–Felder, eds Stephan Moe-
Schenk, and Dorothea Eppler. 2018. The Emergence of bius, Frithjof Nungesser, and Katharina Scherke, 131–48.
Authentic Products. The Transformation of Wine Journal- Wiesbaden: Springer VS. Rössel, Jörg, Patrick Schenk,
ism in Germany, 1947–2008. Journal of Consumer and Sebastian Weingartner. 2017. Cultural Consumption.
Culture 18/3: 453–73. Rössel, Jörg, and Patrick Schenk. Emerging Trends in the Social and Behavioral Sciences.
2018. How Political is Political Consumption? The Case Wiley Online Library. Rössel, Jörg, and Sebastian
of Activism for the Global South and Fair Trade. Social Weingartner. 2016. Opportunities for Cultural Consump-
Problems 65/2: 266–84. Rössel, Jörg, and Patrick Schenk. tion. How is Cultural Participation in Switzerland Shaped
2018. Researching the Transformation of Wine Discourse by Regional Cultural Infrastructure? Rationality &
from 1974–2008 using Quantitative Content Analysis. Society 28/4: 363–85.
SAGE Research Methods Cases.
Economization: How Neo-Liberalism
Took Over Society 8
Uwe Schimank and Ute Volkmann

Western modernity is a functionally differentiated to satisfy this nomos in each value sphere; for the
capitalist society (Schimank 2015a). It consists of great majority nowadays, this polytheism is essen-
a plurality of a dozen spheres of action, each of tial for a good life in a good society.
which is governed by its own guiding value–– Against the background of this self-
with the capitalist economy as the society-wide understanding of Western modernity embodied
dominating sphere. Each of these value spheres in many institutional structures and cultural
(Weber 1958; Wertsphären) constitutes a social framings, the so-called neoliberal transformation
world in its own right, where very different of Western societies has, since the second half of
concerns are at stake: a concern for truth in sci- the 1970s, been a deep disturbance of taken-for-
ence, for justice in law, for newsworthiness in granted assumptions about how these societies
journalism, or for love in intimate relations, to actually work, and how we want them to work.1
name just a few. Protagonists of any of these One of the centerpieces of this transformation is
spheres insist on their particular sphere’s basic an economization of non-economic societal
autonomy and defend it against interferences spheres. Sometimes suddenly, organizations and
from other spheres. Moreover, in our everyday professions in the various societal spheres have
affairs we are well aware of the distinctiveness of been confronted with money issues either as
these spheres, and under normal circumstances, demands for cost reduction or as requests for
move without difficulty from one sphere to the profit-making. Non-profit organizations financed
other, as we shift roles from being a teacher at by the state such as schools, hospitals, museums,
work, a husband at home, a consumer in-between or legal courts have had to face budget cuts or
on our way home, and an art lover at the opera stagnating budgets despite increasing workload.
house in the evening. This functional differentia- For-profit organizations such as newspapers, pri-
tion of society translates into a polytheism (Weber vate TV stations, or commercial hospitals have
1958, 126 f.) of one’s personal conduct of life, been ordered, by their owners or shareholders, to
with every member of modern society being a bring about a higher return on investments. In this
plural actor (Lahire 2011), who is guided by way, economic considerations have become
different nomoi (Bourdieu 1999, 223 ff.). Each
one disposes of a different repertoire of practices 1
One can argue about whether neoliberalism may not be
the best term for what has happened, but it is widely used
U. Schimank (*) · U. Volkmann now. For an overview of what it means, as an alternative
University of Bremen, SOCIUM––Research Center set of ideas about a good society, see only Mudge (2008).
Inequality and Social Policy, Bremen, Germany Evans and Sewell (2013) give a brief but concise synopsis
e-mail: schimank@uni-bremen.de; Volkmann@uni- of how neoliberalism changed contemporary Western
bremen.de societies.

# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 113


A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_8
114 U. Schimank and U. Volkmann

much stronger or even predominant in formerly 1 Economized Modernity: A


non-economic societal spheres, to the disadvan- Functionally Differentiated
tage of the sphere’s own guiding values. Capitalist Society
These dynamics of economization have not
ended. On the contrary, tensions between One could ask why theories of functional differ-
sphere-specific values and economizing pressures entiation, of all sociological perspectives on mod-
of cost reduction or profit-making have risen to ern society, are the master key to understanding
date in many countries and most non-economic society-wide economization dynamics. The core
societal spheres.2 In the following interpretation proposition of differentiation theories about
of the manifestations, origins, and consequences Western modernity is the distinctiveness and
of current economization dynamics, sociological autonomy of each societal sphere.4 For instance,
theories of functional differentiation are used. In science is all about truth, and in the health care
the first section, it is shown why this theoretical system everything is done to cure the ill, no
perspective is especially suited to capture what matter what it costs. However, economization
economization means as an inherent feature of brutally shows: Money makes the world go
modernity. Building on this, in the second sec- round! In other words, economization dynamics
tion, an understanding is outlined of today’s contest, and in the end, could abolish functional
experiences of economization as a regime of com- differentiation. Economization is an unfriendly
petition with society-wide, massive effects. In the take-over of non-economic societal spheres by
third section, attention is drawn to the point that economic concerns. Precisely because
an on-going intensification of economizing economization is a bad surprise to differentiation
pressures leads to a creeping erosion of functional theories they are very good sensitizing
differentiation, which seems to have already perspectives to what economization means to
started in some countries and societal spheres. modern society. Recent economization dynamics
We cannot do justice here to national variants of have shown us more clearly than was known
societal spheres, nor can we consider specificities, before, that functional differentiation is not a
for instance, of health care compared to the sci- societal order which, once established, stabilizes
ence system. However, it is exactly the national itself to high solidity but rather, remains unstable
diversity, and sphere-specific diversity, on many fronts. The autonomy of the various
documented now in thousands of case studies, societal spheres, hard-won against the resistance
which calls for an analytical framework that of the churches, which fought for the maintenance
emphasizes the underlying commonalities.3 of medieval society-wide religious hegemony, in
later times has been repeatedly endangered either
by political assaults, most far-reaching in German
National Socialism, and in Russian state-
dominated socialism, or by economizing
pressures.
To understand more clearly what these
pressures mean for functional differentiation,
one must conceive it as a culturally framed
2
Accordingly, this is still a hot topic of public debates as institutionalized service provision. This view
well as a subject of many empirical studies. Besides combines two traditions of understanding func-
economization and neoliberalism, some other familiar tional differentiation. One tradition, which was
keywords are liberalization, deregulation, privatization,
managerialism, new public management, entrepreneurial-
ism, or marketization. These terms do not all have the same 4
See Schimank (1996) for a reconstruction of differentia-
meaning, but there are considerable overlaps. tion theories since the sociological classics, and Schimank
3
The following argument is based on the more extensive (2015b) for a brief overview that includes newer
elaboration in Schimank and Volkmann (2017). contributions.
8 Economization: How Neo-Liberalism Took Over Society 115

already alluded to, sees modern society as func- second tradition of differentiation theory
tionally differentiated into a dozen value spheres emphasizes the division of labor inherent to func-
(politics, armed forces, law, religion, art, science, tional differentiation. Indeed, the autonomy of
journalism, education, healthcare, sports, intimate any specialized sphere of action rests upon the
relations, and the economy) each of which is a existence of other spheres taking care of all the
sub-universe of meaning, constituted by the other concerns of human beings’ conduct of life.
supremacy of its own guiding value which serves If all spheres do their work, each sphere can
as a self-referential evaluative orientation of concentrate on perfecting its own service provi-
action. The guiding value formulates the summum sion—with its autonomy as a prerequisite. In this
bonum of all activities within the sphere, but this way, functional differentiation amounts to a plu-
summum bonum is not legitimized by any higher- ral simultaneous striving for perfection of sphere-
order end. It is taken rather, as an end in itself. specific service provisions.
Therefore, those who act under the spell of a Of course, manifold tensions and conflicts arise
particular sphere’s “illusio” (Bourdieu 1999, out of this arrangement. Still, despite such trade-
227 ff.)—such as scientists in the scientific sphere offs, the side-by-side autonomous service
or judges in the legal sphere—insist, above every- provisions of specialized societal spheres has pro-
thing else, on their sphere’s autonomy from all duced a level of quality and quantity unknown
interferences driven by other societal concerns. before (see also Chap. 18). Therefore, a well-
With its crucial insight into the necessity of working societal order of functional differentiation
autonomy of each sphere, this Weberian, can be assessed as an achievement, compared to
Luhmannian, as well as Bourdieusian view of other forms of differentiation as well as to deficient
functional differentiation, can become a forms of functional differentiation such as “blunted
one-sided, ideological legitimation of each differentiation,” (Colomy 1990, 470) which get
sphere’s protagonists, supporting their “legiti- stuck half way or are cut back again from an
mate indifference” (Tyrell 1978, 173 f., emphasis already reached state of full-blown differentiation.
omitted) regarding all other concerns. In order to “Blunted differentiation” is exactly what
avoid this bias, this view has to be complemented economizing pressure amounts to. Those affected
by the other, structural-functionalist tradition of by it are, first of all, the service providers,
differentiation theory, pioneered by Talcott organizations and their employees, in the various
Parsons. It has Seth Abrutyn (2016) as a recent, non-economic societal spheres such as hospitals,
new advocate who avoids many fatal flaws of schools, universities, TV stations, or public
Parsonianism. In this view, the analytical point administrations. Secondly, the users of these
of reference is the collectively arranged conduct services suffer from economization in the end, as
of life of human beings within society. Certain individual human beings in their conduct of life.
kinds of needs arise in this collective arrange- To explicate dynamics of economization of
ment, ranging from food and shelter to socializa- these service provisions the understanding of
tion and education, from conflict resolution and functional differentiation, outlined above, must
defense against violence to the confirmation of be combined with theories of capitalism for a
identity and experiences of transcendence. A concept of modernity as a functionally
functionally differentiated societal order responds differentiated capitalist society. In contrast to
to recurrent and widespread needs, initially and prevalent notions on both sides that functional
a-historically called “functional pre-requisites” of differentiation and capitalism are contradictory
society (Levy 1951), by the establishment of perspectives on modern society, its capitalist
specialized service productions, with each socie-
tal sphere focused on one kind of service.5 This
fallacy. What, for lack of space, cannot be reconstructed
here is the gradual and stumbling evolutionary emergence
5
This very brief exposition inevitably sounds like a func- of some fit between the services produced and the under-
tionalist deduction, which is not far from a functionalist lying needs (see Abrutyn 2016 for more details).
116 U. Schimank and U. Volkmann

character derives precisely from its functional these basic revenues of the tax state (Hickel
differentiation. On the one hand, functional dif- 1976) that most of the service provision costs
ferentiation brings about capitalism. On the other, of the non-economic societal spheres are paid.
though, capitalism shapes functional differentia- • Many service providers in non-economic soci-
tion in a fateful way, which is where etal spheres are vitally dependent upon being
economization comes into the picture. financed by the state, which often covers the
At first sight, the capitalist economy is just one largest part of their costs, including the salaries
societal sphere among others. The guiding value of their employees. This financing takes the
by which its protagonists—entrepreneurs, forms of institutional funding, generally regu-
managers, and firms—are directed is profit- lar subsidies, transfer payments, or project
making. Just as scientists are obsessed by their financing.6
pursuit of truth, capitalists are fixated on the pur-
suit of profit. However, as the offspring of func- Thus, regarding money, many service
tional differentiation, the capitalist economy has providers of non-economic societal spheres as
imprinted its imperatives on modern society. well as each individual human being are on a
What economic service providers need to pursue permanent drip feed coming from the economy.
their sphere’s guiding value has a society-wide This dependence has the effect, that simply by
top priority that cannot be ignored for long by earning and passing on greater or lesser amounts
protagonists of other spheres. This is the decisive of money, economic activities have the cumula-
difference compared with service providers from tive external effect of imposing greater or lesser
all other spheres. degrees of pressure, on all other societal spheres
The society-wide dominance of economic as well as on individuals, to economize. In every
concerns originates from the elevated position other sphere of society, it is necessary to be very
that the economy holds in the overall fabric of careful with any activity which might endanger a
interdependencies between societal spheres. It is firm’s money-making and the economic growth
the economy, and only the economy, which that results from it. Otherwise, tax revenues of the
provides all spheres of modern society with state, which finance large sectors of the other
money as a generalized resource for the acquisi- societal spheres, will drop as will employee
tion of everything that is needed in the various wages. Consequently, intensive cost pressure
service productions, particularly paying for the will be placed upon the budgets of hospitals,
labor force. A closer look at the money flows schools, research institutions, and social services
within modern society reveals that: as well as upon the budgets of households. Con-
• Only economic service providers recover their versely, the worse the situation is for economic
production costs by selling their services at a actors, the more important it is that they be
price which covers these costs, in contrast to allowed to earn money wherever they can, so
service providers of all other societal spheres, that in the sense of “collateral benefits” the situa-
such as hospitals, universities or public admin- tion can also improve for service providers in
istration. They cover only parts, mostly other spheres and for individuals. Thus, cost pres-
smaller parts, of their costs from user fees. sure is often accompanied by a pressure for com-
• Furthermore, prices for economic goods and modification so that, for instance, postal services
services not only cover the firms’ own produc- are privatized to offer investors new opportunities
tion costs, including salaries of employees, as for making profits.
well as profits to owners and shareholders, but In this way, every actor in all spheres of mod-
also taxes paid to the state. Besides business ern society is constantly dependent upon the pulse
taxes, there are income taxes as part of the
salaries paid by the firms, and taxes on con- 6
Or of compulsory insurances established by the state,
sumption, paid from the salaries. It is from such as the German unemployment or health care
insurance.
8 Economization: How Neo-Liberalism Took Over Society 117

of economic activity. Everyone knows that when welfare state, which consists of the services of
the economy weakens, all other societal needs many of the non-economic societal spheres such
served by the non-economic societal spheres are as education or health care, is related to the capi-
more and more qualified, and the autonomy of talist economy in a constellation of functional
these spheres becomes endangered. In good antagonism: two societal forces opposed to each
times, concerns about money are just one of vari- other in an arrangement of checks and balances
ous other-referential concerns, which actors in all so that each force sets limits to the destructive
societal spheres are subjected to, while pursuing potential of the other. This functional antagonism
their sphere’s guiding value. For instance, is asymmetric in favor of capitalist imperatives, as
scientists obey legal restrictions of their work, or every economic crisis demonstrates; and yet to
take political demands for more relevancy into date, the protagonists of capitalism have never
account. However, in the scientists’ view these been strong enough for a permanent and complete
are strictly secondary orientations of their prevention or elimination of all kinds of social
activities, which are primarily framed by their welfare.
sphere’s illusio. In the same way, economic To sum up this analytical framework, the cap-
considerations are always relevant, reminding italist economy is a mighty driving force against
scientists that they do not live in a land of milk functional differentiation, and the non-economic
and honey. When times become difficult though, societal spheres are the victims, but they are also
economic concerns quickly challenge the primacy forces of resistance. There is no pre-determined
of the respective sphere’s guiding value by outcome of this struggle, although it is true that
demanding primacy for themselves. Under these the cards are stacked against the requirements of
circumstances the other-referential concerns health care, education, science, and other
about a lack of money rise to the top of the agenda non-economic societal spheres.
everywhere, and the spheres’ guiding values are
at risk of being subordinated to money concerns.
It is an empirical question to calculate the
2 Economizing since
degree of economizing pressure over time in dif-
the Mid-1970s: The Logic
ferent countries and in different societal spheres,
of Compare and Replace!
and to discover, on the one hand, how often, and
for how long, this pressure increases above a
From this strongly simplified theoretical blueprint
critical threshold value, and, on the other hand,
of Western modernity, it is clear that
how frequent and long were the times when the
economization is a structurally built-in feature.
economizing pressure became practically imper-
The wave of economization, which started around
ceptible. If this economizing pressure finds no
the mid-1970s and is by no means over today, has
limits to its growth, it might become a self-
been more than the same old story again. In this
destructive force of modern society. However, in
section, this will be outlined in four steps. In a
modern Western societies a rescue mechanism
first step, attention is directed to the transforma-
was found in the last third of the nineteenth cen-
tion of “organized modernity” to a society “man-
tury under the pressure of growing social unrest.
aged by the markets.” This societal
It consisted of the establishment of social policy
transformation affects non-profit organizations
and its gradual expansion to the welfare state or
of service production in the non-economic socie-
some functional equivalent, as a counter-
tal spheres differently than it affects for-profit
mechanism to capitalist dynamics (Heimann
organizations, as will be shown in the following
1980). The safeguard of this counter-mechanism
two steps. Finally, a fourth step recapitulates the
has been the successful fight for political democ-
common underlying logic of the changes for non-
racy, so that the majority of the population can
profit as well as for-profit organizations.
demand that their life chances are improved
(Iversen and Soskice 2019). Thus, a democratic
118 U. Schimank and U. Volkmann

2.1 From “Organized Modernity” had begun to torment functional differentiation,


to a Society “Managed by but as the solution to the problem of irresponsible
the Markets” autonomy, built into functional differentiation.
He felt that less money (Luhmann 1983, 39), as
To begin with, economization came back as a bad a result of lower tax revenues from a weak econ-
surprise. No one had expected it to return any omy, cures the hypertrophic growth dynamics of
more, at least not to highly developed Western service provisions, be it public health care, public
countries. Most of them had had more than schools, public broadcasts, or public museums.
20 years of unparalleled strong, steady economic This was an entirely new view on the functional
growth since the early 1950s. In addition, the antagonism. If one adopts Luhmann’s perspec-
implementation of a national economic planning, tive, the focus is no longer on the welfare state
guided by Keynesian doctrine gave assurance that which corrects destructive economic dynamics.
states would be able to counteract all kinds of On the contrary, the capitalist economy represents
economic turbulences, and hence prevent the society-wide reason against unreasonable
strong economic crises which had plagued earlier aspirations, created by the various sphere-specific
capitalism. It seemed that the beast, indeed, had service providers of the welfare state. They are
been ultimately tamed. However, this turned out unreasonable because sooner or later they will
to be a short dream of everlasting prosperity, as overstrain even a strong economy.
Burkart Lutz (1984) called it, just after most What Luhmann did not take into consider-
dreamers had abruptly woken up. During that ation, though, was the possibility that this
exceptional golden age (Hobsbawm 1994, economizing pressure might become so strong
324 ff.) Parsons (1971) celebrated the final vic- that it would not stop at a point where the service
tory of functional differentiation. He praised this, provisions of non-economic societal spheres were
seemingly, firmly established structure of modern able to maintain a sustainable level. He failed to
society for its potential of an ever-expanding and realize that the pressure might increase beyond
ever-improving service provision by all societal that point, in the direction of nothing less than an
spheres. This allowed for a corresponding exten- unfriendly economic takeover of the command
sion of inclusion of all members of society into over these service provisions. Since then, many
the beneficiaries of the welfare state. Everybody observers have realized the potential danger of
should benefit more and more from all societal economization to functional differentiation. That
spheres; that seemed to be the motto from then on. was the second bad surprise: economization had
This high time of functional differentiation, in returned with a much stronger grip than ever
which economic constraints of non-economic before, on all kinds of service providers. It is
societal spheres appeared to no longer exist, was true that the sheer quantitative intensity of
already over when Luhmann (2013), 10 years economizing pressure had also been very high,
after Parsons, advised policy makers to shift perhaps even higher, in earlier periods of strong
from an expansionist to a restrictive mode of economic crises, to mention only the worldwide
policy making. Luhmann radicalized Parsons’ crisis of the late 1920s from which many
observation that service providers of all societal countries needed more than 20 years including
spheres, in their fixation on the respective guiding World War II to recover. Nevertheless, nowadays
values, cannot but strive for unlimited growth, there is a distinctively new quality of how
including continual improvements, of their economizing pressure is exerted on
services, an aspiration which fits to and stimulates non-economic societal spheres.
further the rising expectations of the users of In his study of the US economy, Gerald Davis
these services. In Luhmann’s view, this escalation (2009) concludes that from the late nineteenth
had to be stopped. Ironically, he saw century until the mid-1970s, periods of
economization not as the problem which again economization took place in an organizational
society, whereas now it occurs in a society
8 Economization: How Neo-Liberalism Took Over Society 119

managed by the markets. More precisely, the of avant-garde paintings by pointing out its
economization which started in the mid-1970s merits, as judged by the art world, this was
has quickly eroded organized modernity (Wagner accepted. So, if superior criteria of the respective
1993), where capitalist market forces were disci- value sphere were emphasized, cost
plined by large organizations, especially huge considerations were overruled. What was
corporations in the economy. This was a society expected from the service providers of the
of “markets and hierarchies” (Williamson 1975), non-economic societal sub-systems was only
with an emphasis on the and. Markets were per- that, if they had the alternative between two
ceived to need hierarchies, or organizations to measures of equal effectiveness, for instance two
function properly. In contrast, neoliberal moder- drugs given to a patient by a medical doctor, they
nity, which conquered organized modernity, should choose the less expensive one. In addition,
designed markets which no longer seemed to they were expected to reflect on whether there
need hierarchies as a functional complementarity, were luxury measures they could do without.
at least not in a short-term perspective. The Very soon, however, this proved to be insufficient
inventors and propagandists of this new fabric, in many cases. Accordingly, economizing
not only of the economy but also of society at pressures rose and became strict limitations of
large, were indeed capitalists with a short-term financial losses. At first, they were tolerated to
business ethos of take the money and run. some extent. In the end, a zero tolerance for any
Davis’ reasoning can be extended to losses was established. Along this trajectory, cost
non-economic societal spheres and their reduction became the guiding principle of perfor-
organizations, as will be shown in the next two mance, up to the point where the economizing
sections. pressure was experienced as increasingly more
painful by the service providers. When hospital
doctors cannot give seriously ill patients what is
2.2 Non-profit Organizations: Cost necessary from a medical point of view because
Reduction Through New Public costs are too high, or public theatres are closed
Management down because their paying audience is too small
and their budget subsidies from the state are cut
Economizing pressure in non-economic societal back, the respective sphere’s performance suffers
spheres is directed at the reduction of costs. This substantially; and service providers get a strong
kind of pressure arises firstly, whenever service feeling that they are in danger of betraying their
providers such as schools, hospitals, museums, or ethos tied to the respective value sphere for the
the army considerably or repeatedly overdraw sake of money-saving.
their budgets. Secondly, the pressure arises, In earlier periods of economizing, typical
when the state, as financial backer, dictates bud- reactions were many different cost-saving
get cutbacks on these service providers, or measures, which were dictated, at times in quite
thirdly, when they are denied budget increases, a brutal, hierarchical manner according to the
although more money is needed to satisfy a quan- logic of bureaucratic organizations. The most
titatively or qualitatively growing demand for important hierarchically imposed ways of cost
their services. Service providers have been reduction were reductions of service quantity or
confronted with all three situations with increas- quality, both were usually accompanied by a
ing frequency and severity since the mid-1970s. reduction of personnel or a prohibition of the
At the beginning, service providers were recruitment of more personnel. In addition, ser-
requested, in a friendly tone, to keep an eye on vice providers often tried to increase their
costs. However, no compromises regarding the incomes by increasing user fees, museum
particular sphere’s summum bonum were called entrance fees, for instance, or by increased
for. If the director of a state-financed museum, for donations from private sponsors. These tradi-
example, insisted on a very expensive exhibition tional instruments of cost reduction have not
120 U. Schimank and U. Volkmann

been done away with in the present era of journals, this is a quasi-market where perfor-
economizing, but now, have become part of a mance measurement determines income
much richer tool-kit which is conceived (Le Grand and Bartlett 1993). Quasi-markets,
according to a totally different logic called “new which are a predominant instrument of NPM,
public management,” (NPM) (OECD 1995; require the establishment of an audit society
Pollitt and Bouckaert 2000). Its basic principles (Power 1997) in which a systematic collection
show how organizational hierarchies are of service providers’ performance data takes
substituted by markets, or, more precisely: how place and this data is not only given to state
organizational hierarchies make use of markets authorities for their decisions on the allocation
and market-like arrangements. Thus, hierarchy of funds but also to users, in order to assist in
still governs, but now in an indirect manner. The directing their choice of providers.
visible hand (Chandler 1977) of organizational Compared to proper markets, the operation of
management and state authorities camouflages quasi-markets is based on extremely simplified
itself as the famous impartial invisible hand to user preferences. In proper markets, there is a
which cost reductions and their consequences plurality of users, who often have idiosyncratic
must now be attributed. This is motivated by the preference orders. One user wants the service as
calculation that competitive pressure is more cheap as possible, but quality is not as important,
effective in bringing about good performance while a second one wants the highest quality and
than hierarchical pressure, or than the internalized is willing to pay almost any price for that. A third
professional ethos of service providers. user insists on specific conditions, such as the
Essentially, NPM increases the external com- ecological harmlessness or a fair pay for the
petitive pressure on providers of a specific ser- employees, while a fourth user is particularly
vice, as well as within service providing interested in a quick delivery of the service. In
organizations, and builds up the competitive principle, there can be as many combinations and
strength of service providers. To the latter end, rank-orderings of preferences as there are users,
NPM places an emphasis on deregulation, and this complexity is represented in the prices
because an overly detailed regulation leaves they are willing to pay for the offered services. On
actors no room to maneuver within competitive a quasi-market, in contrast, actors, who are not
strategies. Instead of giving regulations, state even users, decide on a one size fits all perfor-
authorities turn to negotiated mission contracts mance formula. On the one hand, this radical
which formulate general performance goals, reduction of complexity seems to be inevitable
while giving service providers space for their because the hierarchical authority which installs
own strategies to reach these goals. In addition, the quasi-market cannot have an adequate over-
NPM strengthens hierarchical leadership within view of the real variety of user preferences. It can
organizations, because strong leaders are seen as only be hoped that at least some preferences,
a prerequisite of a competitive corporate actor. which are important to most users of the respec-
The competitive pressure itself is sometimes tive services are more or less met. On the other
affected by proper markets, when study fees, for hand, sometimes the hierarchical authority delib-
example, are introduced in the university system, erately neglects most user preferences, because it
and become a significant part of a university’s is of the opinion that it knows what is best for the
basic funds. This causes universities to compete users. Either way the risk is that quasi-market
for students. However, when part of the basic failures occur quickly. In a worst-case scenario,
funds is allocated to universities according to a the dangers of markets such as ruinous competi-
formula which measures relative perfor- tion, are combined with the evils of hierarchy
mance, using a fixed set of indicators such as such as narrowmindedness.
the amount of third-party funding, the number of NPM is propagated and perceived to be the
students finishing their studies in due time, and intelligent way to reduce costs without reducing
the number of publications in peer-reviewed essential elements of service quality or service
8 Economization: How Neo-Liberalism Took Over Society 121

quantity. On the contrary, proponents even claim cost reduction in the former, and increased
that NPM enhances quality, for instance, the profit-making in the latter. There are public
responsiveness of service providers to the needs museums or opera houses, on the one hand, and
of their users. Compared to earlier periods of commercial providers such as cinemas, private
economization, NPM amounts to an economizing musical theatres, publishing houses for literature,
pressure which is no longer predominantly or record companies for both classical as well as
implemented on the shop floor of service provi- pop music, on the other. With the nonprofit sector
sion directly by hierarchical command, but indi- being forced to make massive cuts in services, the
rectly by the hierarchical establishment of share of for-profit service providers has grown.
markets or quasi-markets for service providers. In still other societal spheres, which for a long
time had been dominated by nonprofit service
providers, a conspicuous drift towards
2.3 For-Profit Organizations: privatization occurred, with profit-making as a
Profit-Making by consequence. In many West-European countries,
Commodification the clearest cases of this are the health care
systems and public infrastructures. In the former,
Economizing pressure can go further than cost commercial hospital chains owned by investment
reduction. In for-profit organizations such as pri- funds have become ever stronger, taking over
vate newspapers, or radio and TV stations higher hospitals from local governments, from churches,
profits have been demanded by owners and or from charities. Often a symbolic price was
shareholders; and a number of nonprofit paid, because former owners were happy to get
organizations have been turned into for-profit rid of these organizations which were chronically
organizations via privatization, and the respective in deficit. Important infrastructures have been
service being turned into a commodity. The user privatized as well: railways, airlines, postal
no longer pays nothing or a small fee, which services, telecommunication, public housing,
financed only a small part of the service costs. and a number of municipal utilities.
Now, the user must pay a price which is higher Differently from cost reduction, commodifica-
than total costs, so that a profit remains.7 tion does not lead to a reduction of services. On
One of the non-economic spheres, journalism, the contrary, it requires an unleashing of service
has been run from the beginning as a branch of provision as a prerequisite for profit-making:
the capitalist economy. Newspapers have always • sometimes in terms of exclusive quality as
been for-profit firms. When radio and later televi- with private schools, which can hire the best
sion appeared on the scene, they were run by the teachers and pay them quite well. Conse-
state at the beginning; but very soon in many quently, these services are rather expensive,
countries private stations were established and so only a small minority of users is able and
often became the dominant service providers. In willing to pay for them;
Germany in the mid-1980s, government made a • sometimes in terms of quantity, which is based
law which allowed private radio and TV stations on an extended inclusion of users, as in private
to be established. Since then, private suppliers of radio and TV stations;
journalism have dominated radio and television • and sometimes in both dimensions, as in the
as well. Public broadcasting has had to adapt. case of commercially successful blockbuster
Other societal spheres such as the arts have art exhibitions, which attract a large number
been split for a long time into nonprofit and of visitors and still are taken serious by art
for-profit sectors, with economizing meaning critics and the art world in general.
7
In some cases, the state still subsidizes service provision, Thus, there can be win-win situations where
to a certain extent, in order to compensate for the users
who are unable to pay.
high profits tolerate high performance according
122 U. Schimank and U. Volkmann

to the sphere’s own criteria. Furthermore, to earn This is not necessarily motivated by massive dis-
high profits it is often necessary that considerable satisfaction, but is an instance of Thomas
respect must be paid to the sphere-specific guid- Schelling’s (1984, 15 ff.) “‘something better’
ing value. approach.” Even if one is quite satisfied, as long
However, the greatest risk of a commodified as there is a possibility of finding an even better
provision of non-economic services is, that when- alternative, one should invest time and energy
ever other opportunities to make profit look more into finding it. It is perhaps no coincidence that
promising, the money invested, for instance in a Schelling reacted, with this proposal at that time,
commercial hospital chain, will be shifted as soon when the transformation of organized modernity
as possible in that new direction, for example to a had just started, to Herbert Simon’s (1976, 80 ff.)
new internet service. In other words, investors famous earlier maxim of satisficing which
have no loyalty to the non-economic values expressed the typical way of thinking in
governing the respective service provisions. organized modernity: As long as things work
They do not care if a local, regional, or even fairly well, there is no reason to search for some-
national health care system has problems because thing better. Schelling’s precept, in contrast,
they suddenly abandon hospital business to promises the actor that more can be achieved;
re-invest their money more profitably elsewhere.8 neoliberal thinking demands that this ‘more’ be
Although these dynamics of commodification realized with no regard for established practices,
via privatization have differed in speed, scope, arrangements, or social relations.
and specific directions in all Western countries, Two steps of shopping around can be distin-
the general picture is roughly the same: profit- guished. The first one is to decide whether to
making has become an imperative on a substan- outsource some sub-task of the service provision
tial number of service providers in former or not. In this step an internal unit of the organi-
non-economic societal spheres. In these cases, zation competes with external alternatives (Sjurts
being increasingly managed by the markets refers 2006). If outsourcing is chosen, the second step of
not to quasi-markets established by state shopping around starts: external alternatives
authorities, but to proper markets. compete against each other. However, the first
step is kept in mind: external alternatives also
compete with a potential re-internalization of the
2.4 The Underlying Logic: “Divide et respective sub-task of service provision. Behind
Impera” Through Shopping the explicit motivation for shopping around,
Around which is the possibility of finding a better alterna-
tive, there is a much more important latent effect
The common underlying logic of cost reduction of “divide et impera” (Simmel 2009, 115 ff.). All
through NPM as well as profit-making through competitors are kept in permanent suspension: the
commodification is shopping around, more pre- one who is chosen at the moment cannot be sure
cisely the threat of shopping around.9 Shopping that this will remain so; the winner now, may be
around consists of a permanent search for poten- the loser next time.
tial better alternatives to the alternative at hand. The one logical outcome of shopping around
is what Davis describes as a hollow organization,
8 which has outsourced most components of the
In such moments of trouble, state authorities can have an
unexpected comeback as trouble-shooters called for by the service provision workflow because the internal
public. Unfortunately, they are quite often unprepared and units were outcompeted by external alternatives.
helpless in this role. However, the other logical extreme is also possi-
9
This colloquial phrase is adopted from Parsons (1970, ble: all internal units succeed in the competition
438 f.). He used it in the 1950s to describe patients who
with outside suppliers. Superficially, this outcome
show no loyalty to their medical doctors but permanently
look out for potential, better alternatives––a normatively looks as if nothing has happened; top manage-
disapproved behaviour at that time. ment made an empty threat. However, the threat
8 Economization: How Neo-Liberalism Took Over Society 123

is by no means empty, because it lingers 3 Societal Costs: Erosion


on. Instead of existing in a safe world where of Functional Differentiation
there are clear rules of mutual commitment, orga-
nizational units now find themselves on a perma- To the degree that shopping around has affected
nently contested market. The terms of trade individual employees in the way described,
between management and the members of the consequences for the autonomy of the
organization have dramatically changed. All non-economic value-spheres and their service
organizational members know that from then on, provisions are obvious. Individuals in precarious
they cannot rely on management any longer; they work situations are, for good personal reasons,
can only try to stay ahead of all potential less inclined to take a stand for the guiding
competitors.10 value of their societal sphere, against
In this way a dual organizational work force economizing pressures. On the contrary, under
has been created. There is a shrinking core work such circumstances scientists, for example, suc-
force and a growing periphery of marginal cumb to inappropriate research designs or falsify
workers, who have a precarious employment sta- results to have something to present according to
tus. The marginal workers’ existence performance criteria; medical doctors implement
demonstrates to those still at the core, that their suboptimal therapies or refrain from providing
days may be numbered. The most visible cases assistance to patients in need; school teachers
are those where shopping around has not accept class sizes which are unsuitable from a
remained a threat. More numerous, though, are pedagogical point of view; directors of art
instances where shopping around has worked museums present exhibitions of second-rate
effectively as a threat to bring about compliance paintings if only increasing visitor numbers can
with increased work pressure, including involun- be reached; and newspaper journalists serve their
tary part-time contracts with full-time work to do, readers’ craving for sensations to sell more
lower wages, less job security, and fewer newspapers and achieve higher advertising rates.
employee rights. If the threat suffices, the same A general disenchantment about one’s work and
effect is reached with lower transaction costs to its societal appreciation combines with fears of
the organization. All in all, stable membership risking one’s job or contract due to protesting
roles in formal organizations, one of the against the impositions to compromise standards
cornerstones of organized modernity (Luhmann and principles of health, truth, or education, in
1964), are losing ground. Fewer employees not order to save or to make money.
only in firms but also in non-economic A critical mass of employees who are not
organizations can count on having a secure job vulnerable to threats of shopping around is
(Le Gales and Scott 2009, 18 ff.).11 needed as a stronghold of the autonomy of the
non-economic societal spheres against
economization.12 The more shopping around
proliferates, the fewer firm defenders of the
non-economic value-spheres of modernity
remain. This nexus between functional

12
10
Of course, some opportunities of resistance against
To be sure, in many respects organized modernity was economizing remain in most cases. See, for example,
definitely no paradise for hierarchically subordinated orga- Anderson’s (2008) observations of micro-resistance at
nizational members; but when management was dissatis- universities and Volkmann (2019) for a systematic theo-
fied with an organizational unit its redesign, instead of retical exploration. However, often this resistance remains
outsourcing, was the usual reaction. an act of individuals taking a stand against outrageous
11
A similar diagnosis is made by Robert Castel (2003) in working conditions which serves their personal identity
his account of the rise and fall of what he calls the wage maintenance but is unable to defend standards of good
labour society. service provision.
124 U. Schimank and U. Volkmann

differentiation, on the one hand, and formal 10%, so that nine out of ten proposals get no
organizations, on the other, is not at all seen by funding, nine research teams performed a lot
Luhmann. of futile work. Even if some level of competi-
The increased vulnerability of the core person- tion may be helpful to motivate high perfor-
nel of service providers of non-economic societal mance, when the chances to be among the
spheres results in losses of efficiency and effec- winners are too small, frustration and fatalism,
tiveness of services documented in countless or deviant behavior, proliferate. These are
studies.13 There are three kinds of efficiency unsuitable conditions for high effectiveness
losses: of service provision.
• First, shopping around requires a massive
organizational expense of measuring and com- In addition to efficiency losses economizing
paring performance. A growing amount of the pressure produces three kinds of losses of
working time of hospital doctors and nurses is effectiveness:
needed for reporting duties; and the best • First, the range of services can be reduced in
researchers at universities are requested to several dimensions. For instance, if a city gov-
invest increasingly more time in evaluating ernment closes two of five public libraries or
project proposals and the overall performance reduces the operating hours, the quantity of
of their colleagues, to the detriment of their supply of these services decreases. This goes
own superior research work. More new along with social selectivities. Some groups of
professions such as quality managers and service users are more affected than others.
organizations such as evaluation or accredita- Families from lower classes cannot afford to
tion agencies have been established to imple- buy all the books that would help their children
ment this omnipresent auditing, with nobody get a good education. In terms of time, service
asking whether all these efforts are really reductions manifest themselves in longer lines
justified by their gains. One can imagine that and less time for each case.
instead of the desired increases of efficiency • Second, the quality of services can deteriorate.
and effectiveness of service provision, effi- Some drastic examples can be found in health
ciency has often decreased. care. As a consequence of being forced to cut
• Second, at some point, a striving for a higher costs, hospitals may recruit poorly trained per-
efficiency of service provision eats away sonnel which results in more medical
“organizational slack” (Cyert and March complications and even casualties. If tasks
1963, 41 ff.) which is important when bottle- that were previously done by medical doctors
neck situations occur. For example, personnel are delegated to nurses who are not trained for
reductions in a hospital can go so far, that in these tasks, there is again a higher risk for the
case of an influenza epidemic hospital patients. A special but very important kind of
administrators suddenly realize that many quality reduction is the declining
patients cannot be served adequately. In this innovativeness of service provision. For
way, gains in efficiency may result in intolera- instance, junior researchers in temporary
ble losses of effectiveness. positions, with unclear job perspectives are
• Third, one can ask under what conditions a taught a habitus of subaltern conformity,
winner takes all competition, which is brought which kills their potential for creative scien-
about by increasing economizing pressure, is tific ideas (Münch 2016, 418).
efficient at all. For example, if the success rate • Thirdly, losses of effectiveness of service pro-
at a funding agency for university research is vision may occur regarding its responsiveness
to user needs. Proponents of economizing
13
promised the exact opposite. They state that
A good overview of these effects with numerous
examples is given by Binswanger (2012).
whoever has to calculate costs or profits is well
8 Economization: How Neo-Liberalism Took Over Society 125

advised to take user needs into account. How- Within the political system, the most important
ever, this reasoning presupposes that users are economizing pressure moves towards an overall
able to assess the quality of service provision. cost reduction of government; and this pressure
Do patients, for example, know which kind of comes from the financial market, where
medical treatment helps them best? They more governments have to maintain or regain their
likely are “under-informed consumers” (Dill credit standing to be able to issue new govern-
and Soo 2004, 70 ff.) who can be manipulated ment bonds for the additional money they need
by fine words. Even if they are well-informed, beyond their tax income. This amounts to the
in quasi-markets others, usually state imperative of becoming a “consolidation state”
authorities, have decided on a very few user (Streeck 2015) that disciplines itself rigorously
preferences that are cared for, just as in social- regarding expenditures according to the creditors’
ist planned economies. expectations. The other side of the coin is that less
money remains for the democratic shaping of
If these losses of efficiency and effectiveness society, especially in welfare issues. However,
of service provision of the non-economic societal increasing, and not only temporary, financial
spheres increase, the critical point is eventually restrictions of government action are highly criti-
reached where they amount to an erosion of cal because, as mentioned, the democratic welfare
sphere-specific autonomy. This autonomy is com- state is the indispensable functional antagonism
mensurate to the degree that service providers can to capitalism, “saving capitalism from itself”
determine the quantity and quality of their (Klundt 2005). In other words, if democracy no
services. What are the criteria of service quality, longer functions as a result of a massive, perma-
and which amount of services for which kinds of nent, financial squeeze, society will be
users is needed? Efficiency losses manifest them- completely driven by capitalism run wild, which
selves immediately in reductions in the quantity means a further escalation of the erosion of func-
of services, indirectly also in quality reductions. tional differentiation.
Enforced reductions of effectiveness result in The second economization dynamic which
quality reductions. reinforces this de-democratization of politics
occurs in the sphere of journalism (Schimank
and Volkmann 2015). As was already mentioned,
in this societal subsystem economizing pressures
4 Perspectives move towards profit-making, especially by the
private radio and TV stations. Since they earn
Empirical evidence, when taken all together, most of their money from advertisements, and
points to an on-going erosion of functional differ- the price they can demand for advertisements
entiation regarding all non-economic societal depends on their audience ratings, what they
spheres. This raises the question: what can be must achieve is an increase in their audience.
done against it? Unfortunately, it gets even This, in turn, cannot be done by the attraction of
worse. The capability of democratic self-design additional persons, because almost everybody is
of functionally differentiated Western societies, already included in the daily reception of radio
in particular, a political defense of the and TV programs; the only thing that is possible
non-economic societal spheres against is to entice listeners and viewers to do that for
economization, depends critically upon the inter- more minutes and hours per day. If someone who
play of two societal spheres: politics and journal- spent 2 h a day listening to the radio and watching
ism. However, there may be a danger of an television can be captivated to tune in for 4 h, thus
acceleration of the dynamics of economization contributing to larger audiences of particular
by a fatal combination of economized politics programs, the radio or TV station makes more
and economized journalism. money with these programs. How can people be
motivated to devote more time to radio and TV
126 U. Schimank and U. Volkmann

programs? It will not be by the informational ongoing economizing of the non-economic since
content of the news: “When news departments the mid-1970s.
that derive most––or all––of their income from This, then, might be the final speculative
advertising seek to maximize audience, they must answer to the question posed at the beginning:
create content that attracts more than those who The new quality of contemporary economization
consume news primarily for information.” may be that it oversteps the point of no return,
(McManus 1994, 184) The main answer news beyond which the achievements of functional
providers have found to this critical question is differentiation are seriously endangered, includ-
that they attract more people by entertaining their ing the meta-achievement of the democratic wel-
audience. What an entertaining mode of presenta- fare state as the ultimate counter-principle to
tion of all kinds of journalistic news can achieve, economization. Admittedly, at the moment, only
regarding sports news, is captured in the motto: some manifestations of economization come near
“Attract the non-fan!” (Altheide and Snow 1979, to the point of no return. Most do not show such
220) In other words, people who are not really an advanced state. This may be due to the fact that
interested, still remain in the audience because it takes some time to reach that state, or it may be
they are entertained. that the promoters of economization, after
This imperative of entertainment increasingly reviewing the effects, show some understanding
shapes radio and television news as a conse- in the dysfunctionalities of an economization that
quence of the profit-making pressures they are goes too far. It could also be the case that the
subjected to. At least when a certain level of resistance against economization is still strong
entertainment is reached, the higher the entertain- enough to slow it down or put limits to it at
ment value of news is, the lower its information some point. However, there should be an aware-
value is. The consequence of this is, that members ness of what might happen if economization
of society, whose most important source of pressures increase further. The sociological anal-
knowledge about societal affairs is journalism, ysis presented here, by sketching possible future
will become increasingly less informed, as the crisis scenarios, deliberately uses the tone of a
economizing pressure on journalism increases warning (Clausen and Dombrowsky 1984).
and the reaction to this is more entertainment to Someone who articulates a warning does not
the detriment of the information. Society turns want it to become true; rather, he or she wants it
into what may be called an entertainment society to become a “self-altering prophecy” (Henshel
(Ralfs 1995) because the “non-fans”, those who 1978) by communicating it to those who can do
are not really interested in the reported news, something about it.
dominate the audience, as Neil Postman (1985)
already perceived some time ago, in his well-
known diagnosis that we are amusing ourselves
References
to death. It is no good news for democracy, if
there is no longer a well-informed citizen (Schütz Abrutyn, S. (2016). Institutional spheres: The macro-
1946) who is knowledgeable, competent, structure and culture of social life. In S. Abrutyn
strategically realistic, non-extreme, and a force (Ed.), Handbook of contemporary sociological theory
of resistance against capitalism run wild. We (pp. 207–228). Cham: Springer International.
Altheide, D. L., & Snow, R. P. (1979). Media logic.
now live in times of post-democracy (Crouch Beverly Hills: Sage.
2004) not only because the decision space of Anderson, G. (2008). Mapping academic resistance in the
politicians has shrunk dramatically as a result of managerial university. Organization, 15(2), 251–270.
the “consolidation state” but also because well- Binswanger, M. (2012). Sinnlose Wettbewerbe: Warum
wir immer mehr Unsinn produzieren. Freiburg:
entertained citizens are going to lose their Herder.
standards for a proper assessment of public Bourdieu, P. (1999). Rules of art: Genesis and structure of
affairs. Both developments, which go in the the literary field. Stanford, CA: Stanford University
same direction also have the same origin: an Press.
8 Economization: How Neo-Liberalism Took Over Society 127

Castel, R. (2003). From manual workers to wage laborers: gesellschaftstheoretischer Sicht. In P. Herder-Dorneich
Transformation of the social question. New & A. Schuller (Eds.), Die Anspruchsspirale: Schicksal
Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers. oder Systemdefekt? (pp. 28–49). Stuttgart:
Chandler, A. (1977). The visible hand: The managerial Kohlhammer.
revolution in American business. Cambridge, MA: Luhmann, N. (2013 [1981]). Political theory in the welfare
Belknap Press. state. Berlin: De Gruyter.
Clausen, L., & Dombrowsky, W. (1984). Warnpraxis und Lutz, B. (1984). Der kurze Traum immerwährender
Warnlogik. Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 13, 293–307. Prosperität: Eine Neuinterpretation der industriell-
Colomy, P. (1990). Divisions and Progress in differentia- kapitalistischen Entwicklung im Europa des 20.
tion theory. In J. C. Alexander & P. Colomy (Eds.), Jahrhunderts. Frankfurt/M: Campus.
Differentiation theory and social change: Comparative McManus, J. H. (1994). Market-driven journalism: Let the
and historical perspectives (pp. 465–495). New York: citizen be-ware? Thousand Oaks: Sage.
Columbia University Press. Mudge, S. L. (2008). What is neo-liberalism? Socio-Eco-
Crouch, C. (2004). Post democracy. Oxford: Polity Press. nomic Revue, 6(4), 703–731.
Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory Münch, R. (2016). Kapital und Arbeit im akademischen
of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Shareholder-Kapitalismus. Soziologie, 45(4),
Davis, G. (2009). Managed by the markets: How finance 412–440.
re-shaped America. Oxford: Oxford University Press. OECD. (1995). Governance in transition: Public manage-
Dill, D. D., & Soo, M. (2004). Transparency and quality in ment reforms in OECD countries. Paris: OECD.
higher education markets. In P. Teixeira et al. (Eds.), Parsons, T. (1970 [1951]). The social system. London:
Markets in higher education––Rhetoric or reality? Routledge.
(pp. 61–85). Dordrecht: Kluwer. Parsons, T. (1971). System of modern societies.
Evans, P., & Sewell, W. H. (2013). Neoliberalism: Policy Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.
regimes, international regimes, and social effects. In Pollitt, C., & Bouckaert, G. (2000). Public management
P. Hall & M. Lamont (Eds.), Social resilience in the reform: A comparative analysis. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
neoliberal era (pp. 35–68). Cambridge: Cambridge versity Press.
University Press. Postman, N. (1985). Amusing ourselves to death: Public
Heimann, E. (1980 [1929]). Soziale Theorie des discourse in the age of show business.
Kapitalismus: Theorie der Sozialpolitik. Frankfurt/ Harmondsworth: Penguin.
M.: Suhrkamp. Power, M. (1997). Audit society: Rituals of verification.
Henshel, R. L. (1978). Self-altering predictions. In Oxford: Oxford University Press.
J. Fowles (Ed.), Handbook of future research Ralfs, R. (1995). Die Unterhaltungsgesellschaft: Die
(pp. 99–125). Westport: Greenwood. Bedeutung der Unterhaltung in der gesellschaftlichen
Hickel, R. (Ed.). (1976). Die Finanzkrise des Steuerstaats. Kommunikation. Magisterarbeit: Universität
Suhrkamp: Frankfurt/M. Düsseldorf, Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut.
Hobsbawm, E. (1994). The age of extremes: A history of Schelling, T. C. (1984). Economic reasoning and the ethics
the world, 1914–91. New York: Vintage Books. of policy. In T. C. Schelling (Ed.), Choice and conse-
Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2019). Democracy and pros- quence: Perspective of an errant economist (pp. 1–26).
perity. Reinventing capitalism through a turbulent cen- Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
tury. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Schimank, U. (1996). Theorien gesellschaftlicher
Klundt, M. (2005). Saving capitalism from itself? Differenzierung. Opladen: Leske + Budrich.
Entstehung und Entwicklung sozialdemokratischer Schimank, U. (2015a). Modernity as a functionally
Wohlfahrtsstaatlichkeit. In Europäische Wohlfahrts- differentiated capitalist society: A general theoretical
staatlichkeit: Soziokulturelle Grundlagen und religiöse model. European Journal of Social Theory, 18,
Wurzeln, ed. Karl Gabriel, Jahrbuch für Christliche 413–430.
Sozialwissenschaften, 46, 129–146. Schimank, U. (2015b [2002]). Differentiation, social. In
Lahire, B. (2011). The plural actor. Cambridge: Polity J. D. Wright (Ed.), International encyclopedia of the
Press. social and behavioral sciences (Vol. 6, pp. 391–394).
Le Gales, P., & Scott, A. (2009). Die Wiederherstellung Oxford: Pergamon.
des Marktsubjekts. Berliner Journal für Soziologie, 19, Schimank, U., & Volkmann, U. (2015). Ökonomisierter
6–28. Journalismus: Erodiert funktionale Differenzierung zur
Le Grand, J., & Bartlett, W. J. (Eds.). (1993). Quasi- ‘Unterhaltungsgesellschaft’? In K.-D. Altmeppen et al.
markets and social policy. Basingstoke: Macmillan. (Eds.), Soziale Ordnung durch Kommunikation?
Levy, M. J. (1951). The structure of society. Princeton, NJ: (pp. 119–135). Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Princeton University Press. Schimank, U., & Volkmann, U. (2017). Das Regime der
Luhmann, N. (1964). Funktionen und Folgen formaler Konkurrenz: Gesellschaftliche Ökonomisierungs-
Organisation. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot. dynamiken Heute. Weinheim: Beltz Juventa.
Luhmann, N. (1983). Anspruchsinflation im Schütz, A. (1946). The well-informed citizen. Social
Krankheitssystem: Eine Stellungnahme aus Research, 71, 463–478.
128 U. Schimank and U. Volkmann

Simmel, G. (2009 [1908]). Sociology: Inquiries into the


2015. Modernity as a Functionally Differentiated Capi-
construction of social forms. Michigan: Brill.
talist Society. A General Theoretical Model. European
Simon, H. A. (1976 [1946]). Administrative behavior: A
Journal of Social Theory 18: 413–30. Schimank, Uwe.
study of decision-making processes in administrative
2015. Grundriss einer integrativen Theorie der modernen
organization. New York: Free Press.
Gesellschaft. Zeitschrift für Theoretische Soziologie 4:
Sjurts, I. (2006). Outsourcing und insourcing. In
236–68. Schimank, Uwe. 2015. New Public Management
Handelsblatt Wirtschaftslexikon (Band VIII,
as De-Professionalization: Conceptual Reflections with
pp. 4229–4233). Stuttgart: Schäffer-Poeschel.
Some Applications to School Teachers. In Restructuring
Streeck, W. (2015). The rise of the European consolida-
Welfare Governance: Marketization, Managerialism and
tion state. Köln: MPIfG Discussion Paper 15/1.
Welfare State Professionalism, eds. Tanja Klenk, and
Tyrell, H. (1978). Anfragen an die Theorie der
Emmanuele Pavolini, 183–99. Cheltenham: Edward
gesellschaftlichen Differenzierung. Zeitschrift für
Elgar.
Soziologie, 7(2), 175–193.
Volkmann, U. (2019). Gesellschaftliche Ökonomisierung
und die Gegenkräfte: Ein differenzierungstheoretischer Volkmann, Ute is teaching and research assistant, Uni-
Bezugsrahmen. In R. Graf (Ed.), Ökonomisierung: versity of Bremen, SOCIUM––Research Center Inequality
Debatten und Praktiken in der Zeitgeschichte and Social Policy, Mary-Somerville Str. 9, 28359 Bremen,
(pp. 29–54). Göttingen: Wallstein. Germany.
Wagner, P. (1993). A sociology of modernity: Liberty and Research topics: Sociological theory, diagnoses of our
discipline. London: Routledge. time, media, and economic sociology. Recent publica-
Weber, M. (1958 [1919]). Science as a vocation. Daeda- tions: Schimank, Uwe, and Ute Volkmann. 2017. Das
lus, 87(1), 111–134. Regime der Konkurrenz: Gesellschaftliche Ökonomisier-
Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies. ungsdynamiken Heute. Weinheim/Basel: Beltz Juventa.
New York: Free Press. Schimank, Uwe, and Ute Volkmann. 2019. Ge-
sellschaftstheorie und Gegenwartsdiagnosen: Verhältnis-
bestimmungen und Themenpanorama. In
Schimank, Uwe is professor of sociological theory, Uni- Gegenwartsdiagnosen: Kulturelle Formen gesellschaftli-
versity of Bremen, SOCIUM––Research Center Inequality cher Selbstproblematisierung in der Moderne, ed. Thomas
and Social Policy, Mary-Somerville Str. 9, 28359 Bremen, Alkemeyer, Nikolaus Buschmann, and Thomas Etzemül-
Germany. ler, 235–55. Bielefeld: transcript. Volkmann, Ute. 2017.
Research topics: Social theory, theories of modern Gegenwartsdiagnose: Öffentlich und/oder Soziologie? In
society, organizational and economic sociology, science, Öffentliche Soziologie. Wissenschaft im Dialog mit der
and higher education studies. Recent publications: Gesellschaft, eds. Brigitte Aulenbacher, Michael Bura-
Leibfried, Stephan, Kerstin Martens, and Uwe Schimank. woy, Klaus Dörre, and Johanna Sittel, 119–30. Frankfurt/
2019. Entangled Inequalities, a Disbalanced Welfare M: Campus. Volkmann, Ute. 2019. Gesellschaftliche
State, and Populist Challenges for Democracy. In Ökonomisierung und die Gegenkräfte: Ein differenzier-
Globalizing Welfare––An Evolving Asian-European Dia- ungstheoretischer Bezugsrahmen. In Ökonomisierung:
logue, eds. Stein Kuhnle, Per Selle, and Sven E.O. Hart, Debatten und Praktiken in der Zeitgeschichte,
315–32. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Schimank, Uwe. ed. Rüdiger Graf, 29–54. Göttingen: Wallstein.
Part II
Empirical Studies and Research Topics
Trust and Reputation
in Historical Markets and Contemporary 9
Online Markets

Andreas Diekmann and Wojtek Przepiorka

1 Introduction The condition for this reliance on the future behav-


ior of others is trust. Where trust is lacking, only
limited and rudimentary forms of sociality are pos-
Assume you intend to buy a second-hand laptop sible. In the extreme case of total distrust, the
from a seller on eBay. It has crossed your mind interactions of the partners must be restricted to a
that the laptop may have hidden defects or, even strictly controllable simultaneity of the
corresponding actions. The black-market situation
worse, that the seller may take your money with- provides an example. I must hold my goods firmly
out delivering the laptop. Would you be more in my right hand until I have grasped the goods of
likely to send your money to the seller in advance, the other person with my left hand. We both pull at
if the laptop was much cheaper than other offers, the same time and release the goods at the same
time (Popitz 1980, 78).
if the offer was from a registered computer-shop,
or if the seller had a large number of positive If an exchange between A and B is sequential,
customer ratings? Would you prefer to pay extra where A moves first, (e.g., sends money) and B
for your transaction to be handled by an escrow moves second, (e.g., delivers merchandise), it
service, which releases your payment to the seller becomes possible for B to fail to reciprocate A’s
once you confirm receipt of the laptop? Problems advance. In what follows, we call the first moving
of trust have hampered mutually beneficial party to the exchange (A), the truster, and we call
exchanges not only since the advent of the inter- the second moving party (B), the trustee. A trust
net. Heinrich Popitz (1980) formulated the trust problem exists in as far as it is uncertain whether
problem in his work on the normative construc- the trustee will return the advance the truster
tion of society as follows: made in expectation of a benefit (Coleman 1990,
Chap. 5).
A trust problem does not only arise if it is
This chapter is an extended version of Diekmann and uncertain whether the trustee will deliver at all,
Przepiorka (2016, 2019a). Section 5 also includes material but also if the agreed quality and/or quantity of
from Diekmann and Przepiorka (2019b). the exchanged good or service is not directly
observable. The trustee could deliver goods of
A. Diekmann (*)
ETH Zurich, Zürich, Switzerland an inferior quality, whereas the truster might
only recognize the quality after the conclusion
University of Leipzig, Leipzig, Germany
e-mail: diekmann@soz.gess.ethz.ch of the transaction. If the trustee knows the quality
of his goods, but the truster does not, until the
W. Przepiorka
Department of Sociology / ICS, Utrecht University, exchange is completed, the exchange situation is
Utrecht, Netherlands one of asymmetric information. The degree of the
e-mail: w.przepiorka@uu.nl

# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 131


A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_9
132 A. Diekmann and W. Przepiorka

information asymmetry can vary depending on 2 The Trust Problem and Its
the good. In the case of inspection goods, Solutions
unpacked food, for example, it is relatively easy
for the truster to determine the quality before the The trust problem arising in social and economic
exchange. In the case of experience goods, the exchange is often described with the trust game
quality only becomes apparent in the course of known from game theory (Dasgupta 1988; Kreps
use, often after a longer period of time. Second- 1990). In the trust game, if the truster does not
hand cars, dental crowns or beauty creams are trust the trustee, the exchange is refused and
examples of experience goods.1 neither of the actors gains anything, (i.e., the
We define the trust problem as the uncertainty payoff for both actors is zero). However, if the
regarding the trustworthiness and/or competence truster agrees to the exchange, thereby placing his
of the trustee that the truster faces. We define trust in the trustee, the trustee then has two
trustworthiness as the trustee’s intention to meet possibilities. The trustee can fulfil the agreement
the truster’s advance. We distinguish it from com- and both the truster and the trustee earn the gains
petence, which is the trustee’s ability (in terms of from trade (R). However, the trustee can also
skill and knowledge) to meet the truster’s abuse the truster’s trust. The trustee then gains
advance. Finally, we define trust as the truster’s an exploitation profit (T) and the truster suffers a
belief regarding the trustee’s trustworthiness loss (S). In the latter case, the truster’s position is
and/or competence based on which the truster even worse than it would have been without the
decides whether or not to make the advance. exchange. In the trust game, the trustee’s tempta-
That is, by trusting, the truster acts upon the tion to exploit the truster (T ) is larger than the
expectation that the trustee will abide by the gains from trade (R), the gains from trade are
agreement, for example, that a good will be deliv- larger than no earnings at all, and for the truster,
ered with a certain quality and in a certain quan- not earning anything is preferable to suffering a
tity, even though it is possible for the trustee to loss (S) from being exploited by the trustee
deviate from the agreement. (i.e. T > R > 0 > S). In a one-time-only trust
In what follows, we review the many ways game, a self-regarding trustee, who only
trust problems, inherent in economic exchanges, maximizes his or her own benefit, will always
have been tackled and studied in historical and abuse trust. As the truster can anticipate this
contemporary markets, as well as in offline and move he or she will refuse to place their trust. In
online markets. We thereby focus on solutions the Nash equilibrium2 of the trust game, both
provided by opportunities for reputation forma- actors come away empty handed, although both
tion and draw on evidence from various could have benefitted from the trust-based
disciplines of the social and behavioral sciences. exchange.
Our chapter contributes to a better understanding The social dilemma (Kollock 1999) inherent to
of the advantages and disadvantages of reputation social and economic exchanges (formally
formation as a mechanism for promoting cooper- described as a trust game) can, in principle, be
ation in markets. It also points out some solved in three ways: first, by means of repeated
promising directions for future research. exchanges; second, by institutional regulation of
the exchanges; and third, by reputational
incentives. Combinations of these solutions also
exist. For example, institutions can intentionally
1
An instructive field study on dentists was conducted by
2
Gottschalk et al. (2019). Twenty-eight per cent of A Nash equilibrium is a combination of strategies, such
180 dentists in the canton of Zurich, Switzerland, that no actor has an incentive to deviate (to switch to an
suggested one to six unnecessary fillings (with an average alternative strategy) as long as all other actors stick to their
cost of 250 Swiss Francs—about 250 US$—per filling) to strategies. In other words, a unilateral change of strategy
healthy study participants. does not pay off in a Nash equilibrium.
9 Trust and Reputation in Historical Markets and Contemporary Online Markets 133

or as a side product create opportunities for long- customers, whereas “rubber-growers generally
term exchange relations or reputation building prefer to trade continuously with one buyer”
(see also Chap. 12). (Siamwalla 1978, 43; see also Geertz 1979, who
It is known from game theory (Fudenberg and observes a similar mechanism in Moroccan
Maskin 1986), simulation experiments (Axelrod bazaar economy).
1984), and behavioral experiments (Rapoport and In a behavioral experiment simulating the sit-
Chammah 1965; Dal Bó 2005) that in repeated uation on the rice and rubber markets described
social dilemma situations, as well as in repeated by Siamwalla (1978), Kollock (1994) shows that
trust games, cooperation can arise under certain different market relationships arise, depending on
conditions, even among self-regarding actors. A the degree of information asymmetry. In his
central condition is the shadow of the future experiment, Kollock varies the degree of uncer-
(Axelrod 1984), a figurative expression for the tainty about the quality of the goods. In the con-
subjective probability that, in a series of trol condition buyers and sellers are informed
exchanges, a further interaction will take place about the quality. In the experimental condition
between the same actors. If this probability the seller alone is informed, and the buyer learns
exceeds a critical level, cooperation can evolve. the quality of the goods only after purchasing
In other words, long-term exchange relations are them. Four subjects in the role of buyers and
more cooperative.3 four subjects in the role of sellers deal with each
The importance of repeated exchange relations other over 20 rounds. The sellers can offer goods
was already observed by the anthropologist at the quality and price of their own choosing. In
Bronisław Malinowski. In Crime and Custom in the experimental condition the sellers can adver-
Savage Society, the classic study on the Trobriand tise the quality of their goods but are not required
peoples, Malinowski (1926, 22) describes how to be honest. The results show that in the experi-
“the inland village supplies the fishermen with mental condition (as compared to the control
vegetables: the coastal community repays with condition): (1) buyers more frequently deal with
fish.” As Malinowski (1926, 25) further explains, the same seller, (2) buyers’ assessment of sellers’
exchange dyads emerge in this process, “every trustworthiness varies more strongly, (3) sellers
man has his permanent partner in the exchange.” make a greater effort to acquire a good reputation,
The same actors deal repeatedly with one another and (4) the quality of the goods traded is lower, on
and can thus develop a lasting exchange relation. the average (Kollock 1994).
Long-term exchange relations can also provide a There are institutional solutions to the trust
solution for the trust problem arising from asym- problem we have outlined above. Solutions
metric information. Siamwalla (1978) analyses include contract law, which regulates economic
rice and rubber markets in Thailand. The quality exchanges in contemporary societies. It is, of
of rice is immediately recognizable by the expert. course, widely recognized that taking legal action
However, in the case of raw rubber, the produc- involves costs and uncertainties. So, problems
tion process plays a decisive part. The quality of arising between trading partners, who are repeat-
raw rubber can only be ascertained after several edly engaged in business transactions are usually
months of use. Hence, rice can be characterized as settled outside of court (Macaulay 1963). It may
an inspection good and rubber as an experience be useful, therefore, to distinguish between two
good. The different degrees of information asym- types of institutional regulations of markets:
metry lead to different market relationships. In the (1) exogenous institutions equipped with formal
rice market a producer deals with changing sanctioning powers, such as state authorities, and
(2) endogenous, self-organized institutions
3
(Ostrom 1990; Greif 2006). Self-organized
In terms of game theory, cooperative equilibrium
solutions to the trust problem can be promoted
strategies exist in a repeated game, if the probability of
meeting one’s interaction partner again is sufficiently high by means of commitments, such as the payment
(see, for example, Osborne 2009, Chap. 15). of a deposit. One example is the rent deposit,
134 A. Diekmann and W. Przepiorka

which the landlord receives from the tenant and about the past. A trustor’s decision to trust is
which the tenant receives back from the landlord based on information about past experiences
at the end of the tenancy, provided the property is with the trustee. In control, actors consider their
left in good condition. The interplay between influence on a future course of action. A trustor’s
exogenous and endogenous institutions for the decision to trust is based on their power to inflict
regulation of markets in modern societies is also negative sanctions on the trustee in case their trust
exemplified by the mortgaging process involved is abused. In dyadic embeddedness learning and
in the purchase of property. The property is mort- control apply to the situation in which the same
gaged to the bank, but after the entry in the land two interaction partners meet repeatedly; trust and
register, conflicts are settled by the legal cooperation are maintained via direct reciprocity
institutions provided by the state. In the case of (Gouldner 1960; Trivers 1971; Axelrod 1984). In
property acquisition, the mortgage interest issued network embeddedness, learning and control
by the bank would be substantially higher if apply indirectly, while trust and cooperation are
exogenous, trust-building institutions did not maintained via indirect reciprocity (Nowak and
exist. Sigmund 2005; Milinski 2016). In network
While the expectation of repeated exchanges embeddedness, learning is based on the informa-
creates a shadow of the future, reputation refers to tion transferred by third parties about a certain
the shadow of the past. Reputation carries infor- trustee, and control is based on the truster’s pos-
mation about the perceived and rated activities of sibility to induce third parties to inflict negative
a person or organization (trustee) with third sanctions on a trustee (also see Buskens and Raub
parties. If the transaction history of a trustee is 2002).
known, cooperative exchanges can occur between Long-term exchange relations, self-organized
self-regarding and rational actors in an analogy to institutional rules and reputational incentives are
repeated exchange relations, provided that the three forms of organizational assurances which
trustee is interested in maintaining a good reputa- can promote the evolution of cooperation without
tion. It has been shown by means of game theo- state intervention and can thus be characterized as
retic models that reputational incentives can promoting order without law (Ellickson 1991).
create the basis for cooperative behavior, even if Unsurprisingly, examples of the functioning of
it is unlikely that the same trading partners will these mechanisms can also be found in prehistoric
meet again in the future. Under certain conditions, and historical societies, in which state authority is
cooperative strategies of trusters and trustees can weak or entirely absent (North 1977).
arise in a Nash equilibrium (Kreps 1990;
Milgrom et al. 1990).
Social capital, social networks and, generally, 3 Reputation and Markets
the social embeddedness of market participants, in Historical
are fundamental concepts in the social sciences in and Contemporary Societies
general, as well as in economic sociology in par-
ticular (Coleman 1990; Granovetter 1992; Nee In the evolution of mankind, reputation has
2005; Diekmann 2007; Beckert 2009; Przepiorka always played an important part in maintaining
2014). In light of these concepts, reputation can the cohesion of societies. In Dunbar’s (2003)
be described as a form of social embeddedness, prehistoric communities, reputation was
and its causes and consequences can be more communicated through language, (i.e., spoken
precisely grasped with the help of game theory information about third parties or gossip), in
and behavioral experiments. Buskens and Raub very much the same way as in contemporary
(2013) deal with various forms of social informal groups. Language makes it possible to
embeddedness and how it can promote coopera- pass on information on the deeds and misdeeds of
tion through the two mechanisms of learning and others. In this way, individuals’ reputations can
control. In learning, actors consider information be built or possibly even destroyed in large
9 Trust and Reputation in Historical Markets and Contemporary Online Markets 135

groups; Dunbar speaks of around 150 members of Greif (1989) and Milgrom et al. (1990)
prehistoric communities (see also Milinski 2016). analyzed various forms of self-organized
In laboratory experiments, the spread of informa- institutions which promoted economic exchange
tion about group members’ reputation through based on reputational incentives. The economic
gossip has been shown to promote cooperative historian, Avner Greif, examined the reputation
exchanges (Sommerfeld et al. 2007; Feinberg system created by Maghrebian merchants in the
et al. 2014), and does so in a more efficient way eleventh century. Paul Milgrom, Douglas North
than other forms of peer-sanctioning (Guala and Barry Weingast analyzed the Lex Mercatoria,
2012; Grimalda et al. 2016; Wu et al. 2016). which regulated trade at the Champagne fairs in
Economic historians have described the twelfth and thirteenth centuries. These case
institutionalized forms of communicating infor- studies make the importance of reputation for
mation about reputation in social and economic economic exchange apparent and are highly
exchanges from antiquity to modern times. Temin instructive for game theoretic argumentation.
(2013) deals with the grain market in ancient Therefore, we will take a closer look at these
Rome. A “peer-monitoring system” (Temin two studies.
2013, 106) and the documentation of the Jewish merchants had settled in North Africa
quantities and prices of business deals reduced in the eleventh century, predominantly in Tunisia.
merchants’ risks of being deceived by their agents These Maghrebian traders were active in long-
in long-distance trade. The annona, a kind of distance trade, which was, however, burdened
authority responsible for the supply of grain, by great uncertainty. The sea voyage from Egypt
could punish fraudulent agents and exclude to Sicily lasted from thirteen to fifty days and the
them from trade. Apart from the institutional price of goods fluctuated greatly. The merchants
regulations, agents were interested in maintaining had agents at the destination of the goods, who
their reputations. The unloading of the ships in looked after their sale. The agents had informa-
the harbor of Ostia and the further transportation tion that the merchants did not have. This was a
of the grain to Rome was the task of specialized situation involving both asymmetric information
guilds, which paid careful attention to the reputa- and exchanges with potentially large returns.
tion of their members. Agents could fraudulently inform the merchant
A mixed form of various institutional of a lower selling price than the one that was
regulations involving enforceable contracts, as actually realized in the sale of the goods, and
well as reputation resulting from pocket the difference. However, the agent had
recommendations or the membership in guilds, an incentive to act honestly in order to continue
reduced the risk of agents deceiving their working for the merchant in the future. If the
customers. In the late medieval Hanseatic city of agent acted dishonestly, the merchant would no
Lübeck, Burkhardt (2010) finds a change in the longer employ him. This mechanism only func-
structure of long-term relations among the Bergen tioned, however, if the dishonest activities of the
travelers, (merchants who traded with the Norwe- agent came to the merchant’s knowledge. In fact,
gian city of Bergen). Burkhardt’s analysis of the Maghrebian merchants formed a coalition, the
commercial networks reveals the dominance of members of which observed the following rules:
family relations in the fourteenth century. How- first, they informed each other about dishonest
ever, by the second half of the fifteenth century, agents. Second, an agent who cheated, not only
these family networks were disappearing. lost his position with the merchant, but was never
According to Burkhardt the reason was that again offered employment by any other member
institutions, such as clubs, guilds and of the coalition. The fact that agents and
brotherhoods had emerged, which provided alter- merchants did not belong to different social clas-
native solutions to the trust problem by enabling ses and often switched roles, also played a part. A
merchants to build a good reputation. merchant could act as an agent for another mer-
chant. As a consequence, and because of the third
136 A. Diekmann and W. Przepiorka

rule, attempted fraud could not only cost him his had a personal interest in observing the rules.
wage as an agent but also the profits from his The interplay of various individual incentives
activities as a merchant. Third, a fraudulent has been analyzed by Milgrom et al. (1990) in
agent who operated as a merchant could be an abstract model comprising the main features of
cheated by the other merchants of the coalition the Lex Mercatoria. Their analysis reveals that a
with impunity. An agent thus had a great interest self-organized reputation system must fulfil four
in acting honestly, as he would otherwise lose conditions to promote cooperation and an effi-
both his future wage as an agent as well as his ciently functioning market: (1) Norm violators
profits as a merchant. Thus, the double incentive must be punished. (2) Traders must be informed
ensured honest actions to the benefit of all parties. about the behavior of others in earlier
Maghrebian Mediterranean trade only came to an transactions. (3) Traders must provide informa-
end with the expansion of trade from the Italian tion on the behavior of their trading partners after
city states and the conquests of the Bedouins in a transaction. (4) Traders must comply with the
North Africa at the end of the eleventh century judges’ verdicts. Milgrom et al. (1990) apply
(Greif 1989). game theory to examine the incentive problem
Traders in the Champagne fairs (Milgrom et al. regarding the maintenance of a reputation system
1990) also faced trust problems, as the traded that would promote cooperative market
goods were often delivered after payment, and transactions between traders. It turns out that
both the quality and the quantity could be subject observing the rules of the Lex Mercatoria is,
to dispute. The Champagne fairs were of preemi- under certain conditions, an equilibrium strategy.
nent importance for trade in Europe of the twelfth These conditions include the information costs
and thirteenth centuries. In contrast to the reputa- and the profit from a single act of fraud. If these
tion system maintained by the Maghrebian two factors do not exceed a certain level, the
merchants, the information about traders’ market participants will have a personal interest
reputations in these fairs was communicated by in playing by the rules.
specialized actors who kept a record of disputed These case studies clearly show that the
transactions while, at the same time, reputation mechanism can promote cooperative
administering justice. Merchants or local officials market transactions. Moreover, they show that
worked as private judges, who received informa- self-organized reputation systems can be
tion about disputed transactions and provided maintained without state intervention, as long as
information on particular traders upon request it is in all the actors’ own interest to observe
and in return for a fee. These private judges certain rules.
could also pass judgment and impose penalties As with the Roman professional guilds (Temin
in case of a dispute. However, they were unable to 2013) or the Lübeck Bergen Travelers (Burkhardt
impose penalties outside of the fairs. Why, then, 2010) reputation can be acquired through mem-
should a trader accept the judge’s verdict and pay bership in a recognized social group or organiza-
a penalty after returning to his hometown? A tion. The membership in a religious community
good reason was the maintenance of his reputa- can also confer reputation, particularly when
tion and the prospect of good business. Traders admission to the religious community is
with a bad reputation were excluded from trade or accompanied by strict rules and tests, and when
could only participate under worse conditions potential business partners know that the
than traders with a good reputation. members of the community adhere to honest busi-
The Lex Mercatoria, which developed out of ness conduct. The Amish people in North Amer-
the merchant law of the Champagne fairs and ica can easily receive credit because the banks
other trade centers of medieval Europe, was pri- know that the credit agreements are virtually
vate law. Violations of the rules could not be always kept. A banker with fifteen years of expe-
punished under the sanctioning powers of state rience with the evangelical community said, “I
officials. Consequently, all market participants never lost a dime lending to the Amish” (Kraybill
9 Trust and Reputation in Historical Markets and Contemporary Online Markets 137

2001, 257; Diekmann 2007, 49). In his study on history and business conduct of a customer or
The Protestant Sects and the Spirit of Capitalism, business partner (Djankov et al. 2007). Anyone
Max Weber (2002) reports on various who applies for a loan, buys a new mobile phone
observations which clearly show that membership or car will come across a contract clause which
in a religious group not only fulfils religious permits the bank, mobile provider or car dealer,
needs but also may have the important side effect respectively, to do a credit check by obtaining
of attributing business reputation (Voss 1998). information from a CRA. CRAs, such as
On a train journey, Weber meets a travelling Experian, operate globally and collect individual
salesman who assures him, “‘Sir, for my part consumer information from different sources,
everybody may believe or not believe as he (e.g., credit payment histories, public records on
pleases; but if I saw a farmer or a businessman bankruptcies and court judgements). Based on
not belonging to any church at all, I wouldn’t trust this information, CRAs calculate individual credit
him with fifty cents’” (Weber 2002, 128). scores, which are increasingly used by borrowers
Weber’s observations at the baptism of a new to assess lenders’ creditworthiness (Einav et al.
member of a Baptist community are also highly 2013). The similarity to the Lex Mercatoria’s
informative: system of notaries, which kept a register of all
‘. . . once [he is] baptized he will get the patronage known transactions, is apparent. The notaries’
of the whole region and he will outcompete every- registers contained reports on the trustworthiness
body.’ Further questions of ‘why’ and ‘by what of merchants the same way as today’s credit
means’ led to the following conclusion: Admission bureaus do. The same principles are applied;
to the local Baptist congregation follows only upon
the most careful ‘probation’ and after closest only the means of communication have changed.
inquiries into conduct going back to early child- Technological progress has drastically reduced
hood (Disorderly conduct? Frequenting taverns? the cost of acquiring and sharing information
Dance? Theatre? Card Playing? Untimely meeting and has increased the speed at which information
of liability? Other Frivolities?) The congregation
still adhered strictly to the religious tradition. can be accessed.
Admission to the congregation is recognized as an
absolute guarantee of the moral qualities of a gen-
tleman, especially of those qualities required in 4 Reputation in Online Markets
business matters. Baptism secures to the individual
the deposits of the whole region and unlimited
credit without any competition. He is a ‘made In online trade, trust problems arise due to the
man.’ (Weber 2002, 129 f.) anonymity of market participants, who often
interact with each other over large geographic
Three characteristics make a person’s reputa-
distances and across national borders (also see
tion credible and effective in this case. First,
admission to the community only takes place Przepiorka 2013). Most of their transactions are
one-time-only, that is, only a small proportion of
after careful examination and with the agreement
business deals conducted on platforms, such as
of the members of the community. Second, mem-
bership cannot be faked so the reputation cannot eBay, comprise repeated encounters between the
same traders (e.g., Diekmann et al. 2014).
be falsely acquired. Third, the membership and
hence the attestation of the ethical quality of all According to the Nash equilibrium, predictions
the business partners is known (see also of the standard trust game, one-time-only
exchanges between online traders should not
Diekmann et al. 2009).
In secular societies we hardly ever rely on take place; online markets should not exist
membership in a religious community when giv- (Güth and Ockenfels 2003). However, online
markets are a growth sector.
ing credit or choosing business partners.
Specialized reputation firms such as credit To a large extent, the popularity and success of
online markets can be attributed to the implemen-
bureaus, aka credit reference agencies (CRAs),
tation of decentralized reputation systems, made
collect and provide information on the credit
possible by the development of internet
138 A. Diekmann and W. Przepiorka

technology (Kollock 1999; Resnick et al. 2000). Today’s online market platforms offer great
A person who buys something on eBay, for opportunities to study the way reputation systems
instance, is asked to rate the seller after the trans- function unobtrusively on a large scale. However,
action. These ratings (positive and negative) process data obtained from online markets only
make up the interaction history of a seller, reflects traders’ behavior and, as such, does not
which can be accessed online anywhere in the reveal much about these traders’ motives or
world, at no cost, and within seconds. Since it is beliefs. The way reputation systems function is
time consuming and cognitively demanding to also studied in laboratory experiments (e.g.,
read and interpret the entire interaction history Bohnet et al. 2005; Kuwabara 2015; Abraham
of a seller, a reputation index is calculated, et al. 2016). Bolton et al. (2004) compare three
which informs potential buyers of the number market structures: a market with one-off
and the percentage of a seller’s positive ratings. transactions and changing partners (stranger mar-
The cost of acquiring this information, a central ket); a market with repeated transactions with the
factor in the reputation model of the Lex same partner (partner market); and a stranger
Mercatoria (Milgrom et al. 1990), is virtually market in which transaction partners are informed
zero. Moreover, in contrast to the Lex Mercatoria, about each other’s decisions in previous
as well as modern credit bureaus, online rating transactions (rating market). Trust and coopera-
systems are decentralized, whereby the costs of tion were higher in the rating market than in the
providing information are also reduced stranger market, but the highest level of coopera-
(Dellarocas 2003). tion was achieved in the partner market. A reason
In anonymous online markets with a reputa- for the difference between the partner market and
tion system, buyers will trust and pay sellers with the rating market was that subjects are distrustful
a good reputation more; in the case of sellers with when they interact with a partner who does not
a poor reputation buyers will demand a discount, yet have an interaction history. This result also
(i.e., they will bid lower amounts in auctions) to shows that for market entrants, establishing a
compensate for the risk they take when dealing good reputation may pose a problem. However,
with unknown sellers. Using econometric building a good online reputation must be costly
methods, Diekmann et al. (2014) have estimated in order to deter fraudulent traders from entering
the price increase in the case of positive ratings the market or re-entering under a new pseudonym
and the price reduction in the case of negative after a fraudulent transaction (Friedman and
ratings based on more than 13,000 auctions of Resnick 2001). Market entrants with honest
mobile phones and 180,000 auctions of DVDs. intentions must thus accept lower prices to build
A significant effect on the selling price is their reputation; once they have built a good
revealed, whereby positive ratings have a smaller reputation, they will be compensated for their
effect on price increases than negative ratings initial investment by the higher prices they can
have on price reductions. This outcome is consis- charge for their goods (Shapiro 1983).
tent with a large number of empirical studies Buyers can protect themselves against fraud
(e.g. Kollock 1999; Dellarocas 2003; Resnick by taking into account sellers’ reputations when
et al. 2006; Diekmann et al. 2009) and shows choosing the sellers they want to buy from.
that sellers have a financial incentive to invest in Sellers, however, do not generally have the option
a good reputation. They are, in particular, inter- to choose buyers. How, then, can sellers protect
ested in avoiding negative ratings because nega- themselves against buyers with poor payment
tive ratings are most detrimental to business. morale? The solution is simple. Sellers determine
Since this can be achieved primarily by means the mode of payment, so that they are able to
of honest transactions, fraudulent sellers have a make the second move and deliver the goods
reduced incentive to participate in online trade in only after having received a buyer’s payment.
the first place. Payment modalities can be ordered by the degree
to which they favor the seller. The rank order with
9 Trust and Reputation in Historical Markets and Contemporary Online Markets 139

decreasing seller power is (1) payment in of retaliating. Hence, a side effect of the
advance, (2) cash upon mail delivery, (3) cash two-sided rating system is the inflation of positive
on pick up, (4) cash upon delivery (in person), ratings. In other words, although the reciprocal
and (5) mail delivery on account. In a study by rating system of eBay may have helped to over-
Diekmann et al. (2009) on mobile phone auctions come the free rider problem in feedback provi-
in the Swiss online market Ricardo.ch, 25% of the sion, it boosted the amount of positive ratings
transactions were carried out by cash in advance possibly leading to biased evaluations (Dellarocas
and 70% by cash upon delivery. It also turned out and Wood 2008). However, it was possible to
that the reputation of the seller correlated with overcome this problem by means of a change in
seller’s power. The better a seller’s reputation the rating system. In 2007 eBay essentially
the more likely the seller was to determine a shifted to a one-sided system of buyer ratings,
payment mode in his or her favor. This effect is but even after the system change, the proportion
also shown in secondary online markets for game of rated transactions remained very high (Bolton
cards. Kollock (1999) reports an example of a et al. 2013).
market in which the norm developed that the In a similar vein, RentACoder.com, an online
exchange partner with a worse reputation had to platform where people can offer their program-
initiate the exchange by sending his or her card to ming jobs to programmers (Snijders and Weesie
the exchange partner first. 2009), revised its rating system in May 2005. The
The workings of decentralized reputation platform used an open, double-sided rating sys-
systems depend crucially on traders rating each tem before this date, but changed it to a double-
other after finished transactions. Although the sided blind system thereafter. Surprisingly, feed-
submission of a rating by a buyer after receipt of back decreased only slightly, while there was a
the merchandise requires very little effort, it is by tremendous decline in strategic rating (Bolton
no means a matter of course that ratings are made et al. 2013). In general, data from internet markets
to a large extent. The sum of all ratings constitutes offer social science researchers rich opportunities
the collective good reputation that is subject to a to study the impact of institutional rules on human
free rider problem (Bolton et al. 2004). If traders behavior.
spared themselves the trouble and provided no The results of these studies support the
feedback, the rating system would deteriorate hypothesis that a majority of buyers is not only
and with it the entire market. However, a little motivated by strategic considerations but also by
bit of reciprocity and altruism beyond the self- other motives. For example, strong reciprocity
interest of the homo oeconomicus can get an (Gintis 2000)––the tendency to respond to posi-
anonymous online market with a reputation sys- tive actions positively and to negative actions
tem up and running (Bolton et al. 2013; negatively, even when these responses involve a
Diekmann et al. 2014). Reciprocity is one reason cost––seems to be common enough in online
for giving positive feedback to a seller with whom trades to guarantee a sufficient proportion of
one is highly satisfied because of the high quality ratings.4
of the goods or the rapid processing of the trans-
action. Many buyers are also inclined to punish a
seller who delivers poor quality goods, with a
4
negative rating (Resnick et al. 2000). In the case Based on a theory driven analysis of hundreds of
thousands of rating events obtained from eBay, Diekmann
of two-sided rating systems, there are also strate-
et al. (2014) show that strong reciprocity, but also altruism
gic motives for leaving feedback (Dellarocas et al. (Becker 1976) and strategic motives (Dellarocas et al.
2004). If the seller and the buyer can rate each 2004), are important drivers of online traders leaving feed-
other, one gladly gives a positive rating in order to back after finished transactions. Other motives such as
warm glow altruism (Andreoni 1990) or indirect reciproc-
receive the same from the other. At the same time,
ity (Nowak and Sigmund 2005) may also play a role in
traders will be more cautious with negative traders leaving feedback but turned out to be difficult to
ratings as the trading partner has the possibility identify with observational data (Diekmann et al. 2014).
140 A. Diekmann and W. Przepiorka

In their analysis of the Lex Mercatoria, others is carried out in total anonymity (Christin
Milgrom et al. (1990) do not assume the existence 2012; Bartlett 2014; Barratt and Aldridge 2016).
of any altruism or norms of honorable traders. As with eBay, finished transactions are rated by
The rise of the honorable merchant could be a the customers and to this extent provide informa-
consequence of, but is not a necessary precondi- tion on honest dealers.5 Although none of the
tion for, the proper functioning of a market with a traders in cryptomarkets for illegal goods could
reputation system. In the analysis by Milgrom ever take legal action to uphold their rights before
et al. (1990), the assumption of self-interest a state court, trade in cryptomarkets flourishes
suffices, since all actors have an incentive to nonetheless (Soska and Christin 2015).
play by the rules. However, this is not the case Recent findings corroborate that a good seller
with online markets. There are no material reputation is at least as important for business
incentives to provide ratings. If all online traders success in cryptomarkets, as it is in surface web
corresponded to the image of the homo markets such as eBay. Using data of illegal drug
oeconomicus, online markets would not emerge. transactions in the cryptomarket Silk Road 1.0
Online markets can only function if a certain (Christin 2012), Przepiorka et al. (2017) analyzed
proportion of traders employ reciprocal behavior. the effect of buyer ratings on sellers’ business
Only if a certain proportion of traders are success. They found that sellers with a better
motivated by strong reciprocity, and possibly rating history charged higher prices and sold
other types of other-regarding preferences, can their merchandise faster than sellers with a bad
reputation systems function without additional or no rating history (see also Hardy and Norgaard
incentives. 2016). Anonymous traders in cryptomarkets do
Thus far, we have been primarily concerned not, however, rely solely on ratings. There is also
with three elements which promote cooperation an escrow service, which protects buyers by
among anonymous traders in online markets: releasing the payment to the seller only upon
(1) the reputation system, (2) the payment mode confirmation of receipt of the merchandise by
and (3) the notion of reciprocity. As a fourth the buyer. The combination of reputational
element, institutional rules must be added to this incentives and institutional precautions literally
list. Many online markets offer an escrow service, promotes order without law (Ellickson 1991).
particularly when larger sums of money are Reputation contributes decisively to the rela-
involved. While the power of the seller is tively smooth processing of millions of
strengthened by payment in advance, the avail- transactions in online markets, even in markets
ability of an escrow service shifts power back to for illegal goods in the dark web. Without a
the buyer. Finally, and as a fifth element, we reputation system, online markets in which anon-
should call to mind that all transactions are sub- ymous actors do business over large geographic
ject to contract law. It is possible to take a fraud- distances would fail on account of the problem of
ulent trading partner to court, although this takes asymmetric information (Akerlof 1970). Unsur-
time, money and effort. prisingly, reputation systems have spread rapidly
It is, however, remarkable that the four on the internet, in particular, in online markets,
elements of self-organized cooperation alone are but also in the form of review platforms of
sufficient to enable economic transactions. This is services, hotels, car sharing agencies, hospitals,
demonstrated by the fact that numerous and universities, among others.
cryptomarkets, markets for illegal goods, function
on the dark web (Bradbury 2014). The dark web
is only accessible by means of encryption soft-
ware that obliterates all traces of the actors. In
cryptomarkets, such as Silk Road, AlphaBay or 5
The dark web also helps civil rights activists and
Evolution, trade with hacked user accounts, journalists living in dictatorial regimes to communicate
forged passports, illegal drugs, weapons, among freely.
9 Trust and Reputation in Historical Markets and Contemporary Online Markets 141

5 The Downside of Reputation reputation systems, the reliability of the informa-


Systems tion and the rating procedures are core issues.
In online markets the construction of a bogus
Reputation systems can promote cooperation in reputation involves costs, as fees are charged for
illegal activities as much as in legal online every transaction. A trader can pursue a policy of
markets. In the same way as mafia structures are building up a reputation with a number of small
strengthened by strict cooperation norms, (e.g., business transactions (whitewashing) and then act
the obligation to secrecy, the omertà), reputation fraudulently in a big transaction. The strategy can
systems also help markets for illegal goods pay off if the profit from the fraud exceeds the
achieve a high degree of successful transactions cost of building up the reputation. Counter
(Hardy and Norgaard 2016; Przepiorka et al. measures are, however, available. In the case of
2017). large transactions, customers are well advised to
Reputation is always based on perception, but make use of the escrow service. Moreover, a
perception can be deceptive. This is true for gos- seller makes him- or herself seem suspicious if,
sip and tittle-tattle, and equally so for online rep- to exaggerate a bit, he or she makes a hundred
utation indices. In particular, a good reputation deals with the sale of chewing gum and then
can also be faked to a certain extent. This used to offers a Ferrari for sale with payment in advance.
be called swindling, but is nowadays termed rep- It is important that potential customers are not
utation management. For example, companies or only informed about the evaluations of past
authors of books sold by Amazon may pay for transactions but also about the size of the deals.
services praising their products (Flood 2012; Apart from the question of fraudulent reputa-
Arthur 2013). There is also the possibility of tion building, there is a further problem in con-
hiring reviewers to give negative ratings to com- nection with decentralized reputation systems. In
peting products. Examples of such services can be the case of experience goods, deficiencies might
found on the online platform Fiverr.com. only be recognized by consumers after some time,
Recently, Amazon sued fake reviewers who if at all. If, for example, a toy bought in an online
were active on this platform (Kirchner and auction, releases toxic chemicals which the buyer
Beyer 2016). By now, specially programmed cannot notice, this serious deficiency will not of
algorithms or bots are able to generate like clicks course be reflected in the buyer’s rating of the
on social media such as Facebook or YouTube seller. Deficiencies which can only be established
(Clark 2015). In certain domains it may be even by means of special tests and material analysis
simpler to fabricate favorable evaluations. Who require expert evaluation by institutions such as
knows whether hotel ratings really come from food inspection or consumer safety agencies. In
guests or whether they have been commissioned these cases, decentralized ratings alone are, there-
by the hotel owners? Rating agencies, which fore, by no means sufficient and must be
decide on the quality of securities, are paid by supplemented by the evaluations of experts.
the issuers, with the result that questionable In spite of all the reservations and problems
collateralized debt obligations are awarded a Tri- they give rise to, decentralized rating systems are
ple A, the highest possible rating. Finance experts evidently successful. They have spread rapidly in
put at least part of the blame for the 2008 financial online markets, not only on the internet. The
crisis on these agencies. Not only is a fraudulently concept of a reputation society is perhaps rather
acquired reputation a problem, but also the exaggerated, but it makes clear that more and
destruction of honestly acquired reputation. This more corners of our society are being pervaded
can take the shape of mobbing among by quantifying reputation systems. Reputation is
schoolchildren or the destruction of the reputation also being increasingly quantified in the field of
of a competing product on the market through science. A large number of digital archives exist
negative, fake reviews. Thus, in general, for alongside the Web of Science. Google Scholar,
RePEc, Research Gate, and Academia.edu all
142 A. Diekmann and W. Przepiorka

publish indices and attribute reputations. Recruit- their conformist behavior in political affairs.
ment committees, for example, often use these There is no doubt that people will respond. Public
performance scores to select candidates for an opportunism and retreat into the private sphere
academic position. Hence, citations, the impact will increase; intrinsic motivation might be
factor of journals, the h-index and other indices crowded out, and people will likely game the
increasingly determine the careers of researchers, system when trying to boost their scores (for
who adapt their behavior to the requirements of critical essays on the digital revolution see
these indices. Reputation can create social order Helbing 2015). There is also the danger of mas-
and promote cooperative behavior, but it can also sive misdirection and undesirable side effects
have unintended, negative consequences. For from reputation systems outside markets, espe-
example, public quality rankings of physicians, cially if reputation systems are non-transparent
introduced to improve treatment quality, may or misused by companies or governments for
induce these physicians to avoid sick patients, their own purposes.
because sick patients are more likely to negatively Whether and to what degree reputation
affect their scores (Werner and Asch 2005). Insur- systems promote the welfare of society depends
ance companies, employers, banks and many on the purpose of the scores and their
other companies will increasingly use data about consequences for market participants and
the reputation of citizens for their decisions, but citizens. It also depends on the quality of the
also may abuse it. Coleman’s (1982) criticism of information measured with the individual
the asymmetrical society is gaining new relevance indicators. More systematic research into the
with regard to the power of large corporations that working of reputation systems, into their interac-
have data of millions of people at their disposal. tion with individuals’ preferences and constraints,
Credit agencies thus condense information into as well as into the consequences of reputation
credit scores that not only take into account the systems for society at large is necessary. The
payment history of consumers, but also socio- analysis of reputation systems in past and present
demographic information and the payment societies does show that in markets for goods and
behavior of neighbors. As a result, an honest services, whether online or offline, reputation can
consumer, who has always behaved in accor- help solve problems of asymmetric information
dance with the contract, receives a point deduc- and in this way promote cooperative and mutually
tion because his neighbors have low scores. beneficial trade.
When a bank grants a loan, this person is then
confronted with less favorable credit conditions.
This also has distribution policy effects, because
References
people in poorer residential areas pay higher
mortgage interest rates than people in wealthy Abraham, M., Grimm, V., Neeß, C., & Seebauer,
neighborhoods. Regulation is necessary for such M. (2016). Reputation formation in economic
markets; above all, transparency must also be transactions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Orga-
created through the disclosure of scoring nization, 121, 1–14.
Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for ‘lemons’: Quality
algorithms. As the above example illustrates, uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly
scoring systems can lead to massive collateral Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.
damage; O’Neill (2016) calls them Weapons of Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to
Math Destruction. public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. Eco-
nomic Journal, 100(401), 464–477.
In nightmarish dimensions, monitoring and Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation.
reputation systems of citizen scores are currently New York: Basic Books.
being tested in China and may be introduced to a Barratt, M. J., & Aldridge, J. (2016). Everything you
large extent in the coming years. The life chances always wanted to know about drug cryptomarkets*
(*but were afraid to ask). International Journal of
of millions of people will then depend on ques- Drug Policy, 35, 1–6.
tionable assessments of their good conduct and
9 Trust and Reputation in Historical Markets and Contemporary Online Markets 143

Bartlett, J. (2014). The dark net: Inside the digital under- reputation systems. Working Paper 205. MIT Center
world. London: Melville House. for Digital Business.
Becker, G. S. (1976). Altruism, egoism and genetic fitness: Diekmann, A. (2007). Dimensionen des Sozialkapitals. In
Economics and sociobiology. Journal of Economic A. Franzen & M. Freitag (Eds.), Sozialkapital:
Literature, 14(3), 817–826. Grundlagen und Anwendungen. Sonderheft 47/2007
Beckert, J. (2009). The social order of markets. Theory and Der Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsy-
Society, 38(3), 245–269. chologie (pp. 47–65). Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für
Bohnet, I., Huck, S., Harmgart, H., & Tyran, J.-R. (2005). Sozialwissenschaften.
Learning trust. Journal of the European Economic Diekmann, A., & Przepiorka, W. (2016). Reputation in
Association, 3(2–3), 322–329. Märkten. In A. Maurer (Ed.), Handbuch der
Bolton, G. E., Katok, E., & Ockenfels, A. (2004). How Wirtschaftssoziologie (pp. 241–255). Wiesbaden:
effective are electronic reputation mechanisms? An Springer VS.
experimental investigation. Management Science, 50 Diekmann, A., & Przepiorka, W. (2019a). Trust and repu-
(11), 1587–1602. tation in markets. In F. Giardini & R. Wittek (Eds.),
Bolton, G. E., Greiner, B., & Ockenfels, A. (2013). Engi- The Oxford handbook of gossip and reputation
neering trust: Reciprocity in the production of reputa- (pp. 383–400). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
tion information. Management Science, 59(2), Diekmann, A., Jann, B., & Wyder, D. (2009). Trust and
265–285. reputation in internet auctions. In K. S. Cook,
Bradbury, D. (2014). Unveiling the dark web. Network C. Snijders, V. Buskens, & C. Cheshire (Eds.), eTrust:
Security, 2014(4), 14–17. Forming relationships in the online world
Burkhardt, M. (2010). The German Hanse and Bergen: (pp. 139–165). New York: Russell Sage.
New perspectives on an old subject. Scandinavian Diekmann, A., Jann, B., Przepiorka, W., & Wehrli,
Economic History Review, 58(1), 60–79. S. (2014). Reputation formation and the evolution of
Buskens, V., & Raub, W. (2002). Embedded trust: Control cooperation in anonymous online markets. American
and learning. In E. J. Lawler & S. R. Thye (Eds.), Sociological Review, 79(1), 65–85.
Group cohesion, trust and solidarity. Vol. 19: Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & Shleifer, A. (2007). Private
Advances in group processes (pp. 167–202). credit in 129 countries. Journal of Financial Econom-
Amsterdam: JAI. ics, 84(2), 299–329.
Buskens, V., & Raub, W. (2013). Rational choice research Dunbar, R. I. M. (2003). The social brain: Mind, language,
on social dilemmas: Embeddedness effects on trust. In and society in evolutionary perspective. Annual
R. Wittek, T. Snijders, & V. Nee (Eds.), The handbook Review of Anthropology, 32, 163–181.
of rational choice social research (pp. 139–165). Einav, L., Jenkins, M., & Levin, J. (2013). The impact of
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. credit scoring on consumer lending. RAND Journal of
Christin, N. (2012). Traveling the Silk Road: A measure- Economics, 44(2), 249–274.
ment analysis of a large anonymous online market- Ellickson, R. C. (1991). Order without law: How
place. arXiv: 1207.7139. neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge: Harvard Univer-
Coleman, J. S. (1982). The asymmetric society. Syracuse, sity Press.
NY: SyracuseUniversity Press. Feinberg, M., Willer, R., & Schultz, M. (2014). Gossip
Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. and ostracism promote cooperation in groups. Psycho-
Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard Uni- logical Science, 25(3), 656–664.
versity Press. Friedman, E. J., & Resnick, P. (2001). The social cost of
Dal Bó, P. (2005). Cooperation under the shadow of the cheap pseudonyms. Journal of Economics & Manage-
future: Experimental evidence from infinitely repeated ment Strategy, 10(2), 173–199.
games. American Economic Review, 95(5), Fudenberg, D., & Maskin, E. (1986). The folk theorem in
1591–1604. repeated games with discounting or with incomplete
Dasgupta, P. (1988). Trust as a commodity. In information. Econometrica, 54(3), 533–554.
D. Gambetta (Ed.), Trust: Making and breaking coop- Geertz, C. (1979). Suq: The bazaar economy in Sefrou. In
erative relations (pp. 49–72). Oxford: Basil Blackwell. C. Geertz, H. Geertz, & L. Rosen (Eds.), Meaning and
Dellarocas, C. (2003). The digitization of word of mouth: order in Moroccan society: Three essays in cultural
Promise and challenges of online feedback analysis (pp. 123–225). Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
mechanisms. Management Science, 49(10), versity Press.
1407–1424. Gintis, H. (2000). Strong reciprocity and human sociality.
Dellarocas, C., & Wood, C. A. (2008). The sound of Journal of Theoretical Biology, 206(2), 169–179.
silence in online feedback: Estimating trading risks in Gouldner, A. W. (1960). The norm of reciprocity: A pre-
the presence of reporting bias. Management Science, liminary statement. American Journal of Sociology, 25
54(3), 460–476. (2), 161–178.
Dellarocas, C, Fan, M., & Wood, C. A. (2004). Self- Granovetter, M. (1992). Problems of explanation in eco-
interest, reciprocity, and participation in online nomic sociology. In N. Nohria & R. G. Eccles (Eds.),
Networks and organizations: Structure, form, and
144 A. Diekmann and W. Przepiorka

action (pp. 25–56). Boston: Harvard Business School Milinski, M. (2016). Reputation, a universal currency for
Press. human social interactions. Philosophical Transactions
Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval of the Royal Society B, 371, 20150100.
trade: Evidence on the Maghribi traders. Journal of Nee, V. (2005). The new institutionalisms in economics
Economic History, 49(4), 857–882. and sociology. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.),
Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern The handbook of economic sociology (pp. 49–74).
economy. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Press. North, D. C. (1977). Markets and other allocation systems
Grimalda, G., Pondorfer, A., & Tracer, D. P. (2016). in history. The challenge of Karl Polanyi. Journal of
Social image concerns promote cooperation more European Economic History, 6, 703–716.
than altruistic punishment. Nature Communications, Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, K. (2005). Evolution of indi-
7, 12288. rect reciprocity. Nature, 437(7063), 1291–1298.
Guala, F. (2012). Reciprocity: Weak or strong? What O’Neill, C. (2016). Weapons of math destruction: How big
punishment experiments do (and do not) demonstrate. data increases inequality and threatens democracy.
Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 35(1), 1–15. London: Penguin Books.
Güth, W., & Ockenfels, A. (2003). The coevolution of Osborne, M. J. (2009). An introduction to game theory
trust and institutions in anonymous and (International ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
non-anonymous communities. In M. J. Holler, Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution
H. Kliemt, D. Schmidtchen, & M. E. Streit (Eds.), of institutions for collective action. Cambridge, UK:
Jahrbuch für neue politische Ökonomie Cambridge University Press.
(pp. 157–174). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck. Popitz, H. (1980). Die normative Konstruktion von Gesell-
Hardy, R. A., & Norgaard, J. R. (2016). Reputation in the schaft. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.
internet black market: An empirical and theoretical Przepiorka, W. (2013). Buyers pay for and sellers invest in
analysis of the deep web. Journal of Institutional Eco- a good reputation: More evidence from eBay. Journal
nomics, 12(3), 515–539. of Socio-Economics, 42(C), 31–42.
Helbing, D. (2015). Thinking ahead: Essays on big data, Przepiorka, W. (2014). Reputation in offline and online
digital revolution, and participatory market society. markets: Solutions to trust problems in social and eco-
Cham: Springer. nomic exchange. Economic Sociology, the European
Kirchner, S., & Beyer, J. (2016). Die Plattformlogik als Electronic Newsletter, 16(1), 4–10.
digitale Marktordnung. Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 45 Przepiorka, W., Norbutas, L., & Corten, R. (2017). Order
(5), 324–339. without law: Reputation promotes cooperation in a
Kollock, P. (1994). The emergence of exchange structures: cryptomarket for illegal drugs. European Sociological
An experimental study of uncertainty, commitment, Review, 33(6), 752–764.
and trust. American Journal of Sociology, 100(2), Rapoport, A., & Chammah, A. M. (1965). Prisoner’s
313–345. dilemma: A study of conflict and cooperation. Ann
Kollock, P. (1999). The production of trust in online Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
markets. In E. J. Lawler & M. W. Macy (Eds.), Resnick, P., Zeckhauser, R., Friedman, E., & Kuwabara,
Advances in group processes (Vol. 16, pp. 99–123). K. (2000). Reputation systems. Communications of the
Amsterdam: JAI Press. ACM, 43(12), 45–48.
Kraybill, D. B. (2001). The riddle of Amish culture. Resnick, P., Zeckhauser, R., Swanson, J., & Lockwood,
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. K. (2006). The value of reputation on Ebay: A con-
Kreps, D. (1990). Corporate culture and economic theory. trolled experiment. Experimental Economics, 9,
In J. E. Alt & K. A. Shepsle (Eds.), Perspectives on 79–101.
positive political economy (pp. 90–143). Cambridge, Shapiro, C. (1983). Premiums for high quality products as
MA: Cambridge University Press. return to reputation. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Kuwabara, K. (2015). Do reputation systems undermine 98(4), 659–680.
trust? Divergent effects of enforcement type on Siamwalla, A. (1978). Farmers and middlemen: Aspects of
generalized trust and trustworthiness. American Jour- agricultural marketing in Thailand. Economic Bulletin
nal of Sociology, 120(5), 1390–1428. for Asia and the Pacific, 29(1), 38–50.
Macaulay, S. (1963). Non-contractual relations in busi- Snijders, C., & Weesie, J. (2009). Online programming
ness: A preliminary study. American Sociological markets. In K. S. Cook, C. Snijders, V. Buskens, &
Review, 28(1), 55–67. C. Cheshire (Eds.), eTtrust: Forming relationships in
Malinowski, B. (1926). Crime and custom in savage soci- the online world (pp. 166–185). New York: Russell
ety. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. Sage Foundation.
Milgrom, P. R., North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1990). Sommerfeld, R. D., Krambeck, H.-J., Semmann, D., &
The role of institutions in the revival of trade: The law Milinski, M. (2007). Gossip as an alternative for direct
merchant, private judges, and the champagne fairs. observation in games of indirect reciprocity.
Economics and Politics, 2(1), 1–23. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of
the USA, 104(44), 17435–17440.
9 Trust and Reputation in Historical Markets and Contemporary Online Markets 145

Soska, K., & Christin, N. (2015). Measuring the longitu- SSRN: Retrieved December 28, 2019, from https://doi.
dinal evolution of the online anonymous marketplace org/10.2139/ssrn.3036573
ecosystem. In 24th Usenix security symposium (Usenix
security 15) (pp. 33–48). Washington, DC: USENIX
Association. Diekmann, Andreas is professor emeritus of sociology
Temin, P. (2013). The Roman market economy. Princeton, at ETH Zurich, Switzerland, and senior professor at the
NJ: Princeton University Press. University of Leipzig, Germany.
Trivers, R. L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Research topics: Theory of social cooperation and
Quarterly Review of Biology, 46(1), 35–57. experimental game theory, environmental and population
Voss, T. (1998). Vertrauen in modernen Gesellschaften. sociology, methods of empirical social research. Recent
Eine spieltheoretische Analyse. In R. Metze, publications: Przepiorka, Wojtek, and Andreas Diek-
K. Mühler, & K.-D. Opp (Eds.), Der Transformation- mann. 2020. Binding Contracts, Non-Binding Promises
sprozess: Analysen und Befunde aus dem Leipziger and Social Feedback in the Intertemporal Common-Pool
Institut für Soziologie (pp. 91–129). Leipzig: Leipziger Resource Game. Games 11: 5. Bruderer Enzler, Heidi,
Universitätsverlag. and Andreas Diekmann. 2019. All Talk and No Action?
Weber, M. (2002 [1920]). The Protestant ethic and the Environmental Impact and Pro-Environmental Behavior:
Spirit of capitalism. Oxford: Blackwell. Correlations to Income and Environmental Concern.
Werner, R. M., & Asch, D. A. (2005). The unintended Energy Research and Social Science 51: 12–19. Diek-
consequences of publicly reporting quality informa- mann, Andreas, and Wojtek Przepiorka. 2016. “Take One
tion. Journal of the American Medical Association, for the Team”! Individual Heterogeneity and the Emer-
293(10), 1239–1244. gence of Latent Norms in a Volunteer’s Dilemma. Social
Wu, J., Balliet, D., & van Lange, P. A. M. (2016). Gossip Forces 94/3: 1309–33. Berger, Joel, and Andreas
versus punishment: The efficiency of reputation to Diekmann. 2015. The Logic of Relative Frustration:
promote and maintain cooperation. Scientific Reports, Boudon's Competition Model and Experimental Evi-
6, 23919. dence. European Sociological Review 31/6: 725–37.
Diekmann, Andreas, and Wojtek Przepiorka. 2015.
Punitive Preferences, Monetary Incentives and Tacit
Coordination in the Punishment of Defectors Promote
Internet Resources Cooperation in Humans. Scientific Reports 5: 1–10.
Przepiorka, Wojtek is assistant professor at the depart-
Arthur, C. (2013). How low-paid workers at ‘Click Farms’ ment of sociology/ICS, Utrecht University, Netherlands.
create appearance of online popularity. Retrieved Research topics: Analytical sociology, economic sociol-
August 2, 2013, from https://www.theguardian.com/ ogy, game theory, organizational behavior, computation
technology/2013/aug/02/click-farms-appearance- social sciences, experimental methods, meta-analysis,
online-popularity replication. Recent publications: Gambetta, Diego, and
Clark, D. B. (2015). The bot bubble: How click farms have Wojtek Przepiorka. 2019. Sharing Compromising Infor-
inflated social media currency. Retrieved April mation as a Cooperative Strategy. Sociological Science 6:
21, 2015, from https://newrepublic.com/article/ 352–79. Horne, Christine, and Wojtek Przepiorka. 2019.
121551/bot-bubble-click-farms-have-inflated-social- Technology Use and Norm Change in Online Privacy:
media-currency Experimental Evidence from Vignette Studies. Informa-
Diekmann, A., & Przepiorka, W. (2019b). Die Expansion tion, Communication & Society. Przepiorka, Wojtek, and
digitaler Märkte und die dunklen Seiten von Andreas Diekmann. 2018. Heterogeneous Groups Over-
Reputationssystemen. In Nicole Burzan (Ed.), come the Diffusion of Responsibility Problem in Social
Komplexe Dynamiken globaler und lokaler Norm Enforcement. PLOS ONE 13/11: 1–18. Przepiorka,
Entwicklungen. Verhandlungen des 39. Kongresses Wojtek, and Christine Horne. 2019. How Can Consumer
der Deutschen Gesellschaft für Soziologie in Göttingen Trust in Energy Utilities Be Increased? The Effectiveness
2018. Retrieved from http://publikationen.soziologie. of Prosocial, Pro-Environmental, and Service-Oriented
de/index.php/kongressband_2018/issue/view/33 Investments as Signals of Trustworthiness. Organization
Flood, A. (2012). Sock puppetry and fake reviews: Publish & Environment 33/2: 262–84. Przepiorka, Wojtek,
and be damned. Retrieved September 4, 2012, from Charlotte Rutten, Vincent Buskens, and Aron Szekely.
https://www.theguardian.com/books/2012/sep/04/ 2019. How Dominance Hierarchies Emerge from Con-
sock-puppetry-publish-be-damned flict: A Game Theoretic Model and Experimental
Gottschalk, F. C. H., Mimra, W., & Waibel, C. (2019). Evidence. Social Science Research 86: 102393.
Health services as credence goods: A field experiment.
How to Buy, Sell, and Trade Attention: A
Sociology of (Digital) Attention Markets 10
Philipp Bachmann and Gabriele Siegert

1 The Emergence of Attention basic principle of attention markets. In addition


Markets to advertising, politics and the press began to
attract attention using pictures, slogans,
By the end of the nineteenth century, more and headlines, and provocations. The more people
more people in the industrialized world were became accustomed to them, the shriller and
benefitting from economic growth. With an louder these efforts became.
increase in wages and wealth, a new social class Between 1927 and 1940, while Benjamin was
emerged: the bourgeoisie. Its members could working on the Arcades Project, many attempts
spend money on products and services beyond to attract attention were still intuitive. It was
the satisfaction of their primary needs. What Edward L. Bernays (1928) who first claimed
needs came up? New needs would have to be that attention could be manufactured, thus, the
awakened first. In cities, shop owners and opinions of the masses could be influenced and
companies began attempting to win consumer controlled by an intellectual and economic elite.
favor, which, if nothing else, resulted in At the time, he referred to this as propaganda, a
complaints about the emergence of term that would only later fall into disrepute.
advertisements. In his unfinished Arcades Proj- Bernays connected Sigmund Freud’s theory of
ect, which literarily captured the developments of unguarded driving forces with empirical research
capitalism and emerging shopping arcades in methods of the social sciences in development at
Paris, Walter Benjamin lamented the many adver- that time, particularly those of market research
tising messages. “Locust swarms of print, which (Bernays 1928, see also Bernays 1971). Today’s
already eclipse the sun of what city dwellers take fields of advertising and public relations have
for intellect, will grow thicker with each grown apart from one another; in industrialized
succeeding year” (Benjamin 2002, 456). Here, nations, the demand for press products
Benjamin recognizes targeted disturbance as a skyrocketed, as did spending on propaganda,
advertising, and public relations (Reinhardt
P. Bachmann (*) 1993, 35 ff.). In short, a large media industry
Institute of Communication and Marketing (IKM), emerged with its own attention markets (Siegert
Lucerne University of Applied Sciences and Arts, and Brecheis 2017, 74).
Lucerne, Switzerland
The objective of this chapter is to examine
e-mail: philipp.bachmann.01@hslu.ch
attention markets from a sociological point of
G. Siegert
view. From the perspective of economic sociol-
Department of communication and media research
(IKMZ), University of Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland ogy (see Swedberg 1987; Smelser and Swedberg
e-mail: g.siegert@ikmz.uzh.ch 1994; Steiner 1995, 176) this is appropriate
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 147
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_10
148 P. Bachmann and G. Siegert

because attention is a social phenomenon that, in discussing attention markets rather than media
modern society, is traded in markets on an indus- markets reveals the important role played by cre-
trial scale. For Franck (1998), attention is even ativity in attracting attention. Recipients are flexi-
more important than money and power—the typ- ble beings who, as Friestad and Wright’s (1994)
ical subjects of sociology. He writes, “Attention model of persuasion knowledge demonstrates,
by other people is the most irresistible of drugs. have the power to ensure that unwanted attempts
To receive it, outshines receiving any other kind to influence them come to nothing. Therefore,
of income. This is why glory surpasses power and public relations and advertising must use a great
why wealth is overshadowed by prominence” deal of creativity to attract recipients, to influence
(Franck 1999, see also Franck 1998, 10). Simi- them in a strategic manner. Yet our chapter
larly, Davenport and Beck highly value the social concludes that digitalization led to “hypercompet-
and economic relevance of attention. “Those who itive markets” (Hollifield 2006) with countless
do not have it want it. Even those who have it communicators and a plethora of content compet-
want more. You can trade it, you can purchase ing for our attention. Moreover, the interplay of
it. People work to preserve and extend what they big data, data mining, and artificial intelligence
have already . . . and attention can be converted raises the question of whether the gloomy
into other currencies” (2001, 3). diagnoses of externally controlled recipients,
What distinguishes a sociological analysis of like those formulated by the Frankfurt School,
attention markets? Sociological theory, our (e.g., Adorno 1963; Marcuse 2002), are justified.
starting point, claims to provide consistent Based on our framework, we reach the conclusion
answers to four basic questions. (1) What is social that despite sophisticated technologies and per-
action? (2) How does social order come about? suasion techniques, one should not forget that
(3) What causes social change? (4) How is the humans are more than mere targets; they can see
present to be interpreted? We apply these basic through sophisticated manipulation strategies
questions to attention markets. This chapter’s after a while.
research questions are as follows: (a) To what
extent is the generation of attention a social
action? (b) How do markets emerge in which 2 Defining Attention
something as fleeting as attention is traded? (c) and Attention Markets
What causes change in attention markets? and (d)
How are attention markets currently changing 2.1 Attention as an Economic
through digital transformation? Commodity
To answer the four questions, we first concep-
tualize attention as an economic good and a social In the most general sense, markets are social
relation. Based on Simmel’s Sociology of Money, structures that allow buyers and sellers to
we demonstrate that attention, unlike many other exchange goods, services, or information.
goods and services, cannot be easily expressed in Money, as the key facilitator of exchange in com-
monetary terms. Since attention takes place in the plex market structure, is so integral that we cannot
minds of other people, the amount and quality of imagine modern markets without money and
attention are difficult to measure, as Franck also currencies. Is attention really an economic com-
shows in his Economics of Attention. It is shown modity? To what extent is it possible for attention
that, in practice, attention buyers and dealers use to be traded in a market?
stopgap measures; they do not trade actual atten- In his Sociology of Money, published in 1900,
tion, but media reach, as a substitute, because its Georg Simmel conceptualized money as a
amount and quality are easier to measure. Media “generalized medium of interaction”. Money,
are institutions that bundle attention, which is according to Simmel, is the purest symbol of
why, in research and practice, attention markets modern society. “Only money, in terms of its
appear in the form of media markets. However, pure concept, has attained this final stage; it is
10 How to Buy, Sell, and Trade Attention: A Sociology of (Digital) Attention Markets 149

nothing but the pure form of exchangeability” At about the same time, Walter Benjamin
(Simmel 2004, 128). As a generalized medium pointed out in his Arcades Project (1927–40)
of interaction, money is constitutive for attention that a specific disturbance is necessary to capture
markets. The role of money in modern societies someone else’s attention, especially in the public
cannot be overestimated, as Harari emphasizes, domain. It is a targeted disturbance that aims to
“Money is the most universal and most efficient trigger the mental engagement of another,
system of mutual trust ever devised” (2014, 201). unknown person. Combining ideas from Schutz
Following the perspective of a generalized media and Benjamin, we can argue that under market
of interaction, Davenport and Beck conceptualize conditions, the generation of attention is no lon-
attention as a currency itself. Attention is today’s ger the basso continuo of social action, but
“real currency of businesses and individuals” becomes the first violin. Moreover, the “technical
(2001, 3). reproducibility” (Benjamin 1969), and now also
It is true that attention, like money, can be the digital reproducibility of media content leads
considered a measure of what gives value to to many disturbances, which far exceed people’s
goods, but, unlike money, attention has a low mental capacities. This results in a fundamental
direct exchangeability. While money is tempo- economic problem, which remains unchanged
rally and socially indifferent and, thus far, can since Benjamin’s time. The fields of economics
be stored, attention is difficult to store, whether and politics, as well as culture and religion, each
by the owner or the buyer (Ghosh 1997; have a respective interest in the fact that spatially,
Dahinden 2001; Siegert 2001b, 115). Even Dav- temporally or socially distant people direct their
enport and Beck acknowledge, “attention is mental engagement to particular stimuli of infor-
focused on a particular item of information” mation. In other words, in modern attention
(2001, 20). Therefore, the conceptualization of markets, everyone refuses to play second fiddle.
attention as a currency can be rejected for now; Economist and cognitive psychologist,
in contrast to money, attention lacks exchange- Herbert A. Simon, defines attention in a similar
ability (Beck 2001). As Goldhaber stated, way as Benjamin. He speaks of stimuli instead of
“Money flows to attention, and attention flows disturbances, “Attention, then, refers to the set of
much less well to money” (1997, 7). Thus, the elements that enter into consciousness at any
question remains open, as to whether attention is given time” (Simon 1997, 102). He came to the
a good that buyers and sellers can exchange for same conclusion, regarding modern society.
money or not. In an information-rich world, the wealth of infor-
Franck points out that, for a long time, science mation means a dearth of something else: a scarcity
has been and still is struggling with the economics of whatever it is that information consumes. What
of attention, because attention is an immaterial information consumes is rather obvious; it
consumes the attention of its recipients. Hence, a
thing that occurs within people and thus cannot wealth of information creates poverty of attention
be measured or weighed. If its quantity and qual- (Simon 1971, 40 f.).
ity cannot be measured, it cannot be easily
converted into money (1998, 22 f.). To open a What communication scholars call informa-
sociological analysis, we argue that attention is tion overload (Blumler 1980) is simply a classic
not only an intangible thing that occurs within shortage to economists; the demand for attention
people but also one that occurs between people. is greater than the supply (Goldhaber 1997;
In other words, all social action is based on the Falkinger 2007).
generation of attention, which is thus a social We can conclude that attention is not a cur-
phenomenon. According to Campo, it was Alfred rency because it is not a generalized medium of
Schutz in the late 1920s who revealed that atten- interaction. Instead, attention seems to be a
tion is the “basso continuo” (figured bass) of all non-generalizable commodity; it is bound to a
social actions (2015, 118). particular item of information and is thus difficult
to exchange. The first research question, to what
150 P. Bachmann and G. Siegert

extent is the generation of attention a social falling asleep en masse, nor allowing your minds to
action, can be answered as follows: all social wander. In truth, even if you had been paid a huge
sum, this would be most difficult, and if you did it,
action is based on the generation of attention. it would be a testament more to your own deep
However, in immediate social contexts, attention sense of principle than to a general condition in
is generally not an independent social action; on which another roomful of similar people could be
the contrary, attention is the figured bass of expected to do equally well (Goldhaber 1997, 7).
interactions. However, under market conditions, Consequently, the amount and quality of atten-
attention is not a side aspect anymore, but rather a tion cannot be expressed in monetary terms
scarce commodity. In modern society, the gener- either, there is a conversion dilemma between
ation of attention through communication media, money and attention. The price uncertainty that
over great distances of time and space is the basic ensues is highly unsatisfactory for market players
resource for achieving society’s economic, politi- (see Siegert 2001a, b). Thus, market players who
cal, cultural, and religious goals, among others. buy and sell must utilize tricks or tools. Instead of
trading hard-to-measure attention, they convert it
into media reach, which is a quantifiable measure.
2.2 The Constitution of Attention Advertising has established the thousand-contact
Markets price (CPT), which reveals the amount of money
that must be spent on an advertising campaign to
Due to the imbalance between the technical repro- reach 1000 people of a target group, visually or
ducibility of media content on the one hand, and audibly. Similarly to standardized container
people’s limited processing capacity on the other, dimensions, which ensure the efficient trade of
attention, particularly that of wealthy or otherwise goods, CPT is a standard measure that regulates
influential people, has become a scarce commod- the conversion of money and attention between
ity. High prices are usually paid for scarce principals and attention merchants. It is generally
commodities, which is an economic incentive to clear to those involved that merely disseminating
mass production and trading. The development of particular pieces of information does not guaran-
attention markets encounters a fundamental prob- tee mental commitment. To say, write or picture
lem: attention is something fleeting, hidden, something in the public domain does not mean
something that takes place inside another that the target audience hears, reads or sees
person’s mind. In social proximity, people with it. However, because media reach can usually be
empathy and patience can develop a precise idea measured easily and in a standardized manner,
of what is happening in the mind of another and thus expressed in monetary units, these tem-
person, although some sociologists and porary measures, stopgap measures, have
philosophers, like Niklas Luhmann, would dis- dominated the market for a long time (see
pute this. Human consciousness functions as a Sommer and Marty 2015).
closed system that is neither externally visible From a sociological perspective, the second
nor alterable (Luhmann 1995). Regardless of research question, how do markets emerge in
one’s position, something else is crucial to the which something as fleeting as attention is traded,
present analysis; the greater the distances in time can be answered as follows: Attention markets
and space between humans, the more the problem arise because market players spend their money
of other minds inevitably arises. Over great where they believe it will be the most useful,
distances of time and space, the amount and qual- where they expect the highest return on their
ity of attention generated cannot, or at best very investment. The objective of market players in
superficially, be recognized and measured. As attention markets is what Turow calls “achieving
Goldhaber (1997) explained in a speech: a good share of mind” among the target groups
If money could reliably buy attention, all I would (2009, 201); people should develop positive
have to do is pay you the required amount and you opinions toward products, services, politicians,
would keep listening carefully through all that, not
10 How to Buy, Sell, and Trade Attention: A Sociology of (Digital) Attention Markets 151

companies, and so forth, and act accordingly, traumatic void where he would have the chance
especially when purchasing and voting. However, to wonder and to think” (2002, 250). This idea
a good share of mind as well as cause-and-effect lives on through Zygmunt Bauman, who,
relationships in advertising are difficult to mea- according to Rattansi, is “best understood as a
sure. Since it is barely possible to determine the latter-day representative of the German Critical
good share of mind and thus express attention in Theory” (2017, 4). “The phenomenon of brain-
monetary terms, media reach (thousand-contact washing is eminently present nowadays in both
price) is traded as a proxy. Here, McQuail states, propaganda and commercial advertising––though
“The fact of attention often matters more than the hiding under the politically correct names of
quality of attention (which can rarely be ade- ‘advertising,’ ‘broadcasting,’ ‘public relations,’
quately measured)” (2010, 72). Attention markets downright to ‘information service’” (Bauman
and media markets represent an amalgam, the and Donskis 2016, 37).
components of which cannot be separated. Other social theorists highlight that humans
are not just targets, but reflective beings,
(e.g. Giddens 1984). With reference to attention
2.3 Social Change: Attention, Media, markets, Friestad and Wright’s model of persua-
and Persuasion Markets sion knowledge is instructive. Its basic assump-
tion is that humans have a broad repertoire of
The conversion dilemma between attention and knowledge and techniques to sabotage unwanted
money represents one reason an economics of the attempts to influence them. Recipients do not
media has established itself rather than an econ- accept clumsy, obvious attempts to influence
omy of attention (Franck 1998). This media econ- them. With time, they can also see through
omy does not focus on hard-to-reach public sophisticated manipulation strategies. “All people
attention, but on directly observable public com- are ‘moving targets’ whose knowledge about per-
munication, or more precisely, on the economic suasion keeps changing. In the ‘game’ of persua-
and social limitations of public communication sion, the persuasion knowledge of the players
(see Picard 2003, 301; Meier et al. 2010, 242). changes developmentally and historically”
A focus on public communication, or the pro- (Friestad and Wright 1994, 22).
duction and trade of media reach, may lead to the Like the arms race between developers of
assumption that the targets are merely passive malicious software and developers of anti-virus
recipients of stimuli; principals and merchants software, there is a kind of arms race between
need only slip a particular item of information to generators, dealers, and recipients of attention,
relevant target groups, and this information would constituted in efforts to escape and expose the
then achieve the desired effect in the recipient’s attention stimuli and accompanying attempts at
consciousness. Even in the social sciences, this persuasion. To keep pace with this arms race, the
idea of passive, externally controlled recipients highest level of creativity is demanded of atten-
has long been prevalent, especially from members tion generators and dealers. The stimuli required
of the Frankfurt School. In the tradition of Walter to generate media attention should not be
Benjamin, for example, Theodor W. Adorno recognized by the targets as a disturbance. Not
claimed that consumerism in capitalism means surprisingly, according to von Rimscha, “Creativ-
the best manipulated audience blinds itself to ity is a core value in all areas of media produc-
evil of its own free will if one surrenders to his tion” (2017, 109). As Goldhaber exemplified in
will, the best prepared audience blinds the bad his speech:
(1963, 57). Herbert Marcuse also saw the recipi- Someone who wants your attention just can’t rely
ent as a “one-dimensional man” asserting “[t]he on paying you money to get it, but has to do more,
mere absence of all advertising and of all has to be interesting, that is must offer you illusory
indoctrinating media of information and enter- attention, in just about the same amounts as they
tainment would plunge the individual into a
152 P. Bachmann and G. Siegert

would if you had instead been paying money to attention markets, and the changes in attention
listen to them (Goldhaber 1997, 7). markets.
Regarding attention markets, two professions Generating attention is a component of any
have emerged to generate attention. These two social interaction, in which one captures the men-
have developed different strategies with a com- tal focus of another by means of a disturbance.
mon interest in purposefully and systematically Thus, attention is a relational construct; without
attracting attention: advertising and public providing information on why or how an actor
relations. Much has already been written about generates attention, one cannot speak of attention
their similarities and differences (e.g. Siegert and (see Siegert and Brecheis 2017, 8 ff.). In modern
Brecheis 2017, 30 ff.). Advertisers try to place societies, attention is conveyed over great
messages in the right environments to attract distances of time and space by means of mass
attention to the interests of their clients. A high media and communication technologies. Because
level of creativity is required to ensure these media content is technically easy to reproduce,
messages are not ignored, which can be there is a plethora of strategic attempts to attract
demonstrated, although not exclusively, in the attention of relevant audiences. Not every
humorous campaigns, or by advertising in intended information transfer reaches its destina-
unusual places. Another complementary strategy tion. The limited processing capacity of human
is to place attention stimuli where targets do not consciousness creates an economic scarcity. This
perceive persuasive messages to be a disturbance. is especially true since these goals are agile; target
Generating attention here works particularly well. groups do not consist of passive recipients of
Traditionally, public relations professionals try to stimuli, but are rather, reflexive beings with a
accommodate their messages in editorial broad repertoire of knowledge and techniques to
reporting through a deliberate awareness of the avoid undesired disturbances. Certain
selection, presentation and logic of interpretation professions, which cultivate this scarcity, have
of the editorial media (see, e.g. Bernays 1947; emerged over the last decades and have defined
Baerns 1987; Bentele and Nothhaft 2008). public relations and advertising as a professional
So, we have a first answer to our third ques- generation of attention. The professional genera-
tion. Human targets of attention strategies are not tion of attention is a specific form among human
passive recipients of media stimuli, but reflexive activities. It is essentially characterized by strate-
beings who constantly adapt their knowledge and gic planning, delivery and evaluation of informa-
abilities to avoid or sabotage unwanted attempts tion dissemination to other people and target
to capture their attention or to persuade them. groups by professionals. This information is a
Generators of and dealers in attention must be type of persuasive communication that, in the
creative to attract attention in a systematic, con- interests of one’s own organization or of the cli-
stant, and demonstrable way. The need to inno- ent, raises awareness among target groups to
vate results in highly variable structures of influence and trigger actions, especially purchase
attention markets. and choice. To meet the moving goals, profes-
sional generators of attention embed the persua-
sive messages in a communication environment,
so that the targets do not perceive these messages
2.4 An Economic-Sociological as disturbances. Advertisers place messages in an
Framework of Attention Markets advertising-friendly environment, such as edito-
rial media, which recipients consume voluntarily
Economic and sociological thought on attention and purposefully. Public relations experts apply
and attention markets can now be combined the selection, presentation, and logic of interpre-
coherently to answer the questions regarding tation of journalistic media to their messages, the
attention as a social act, the constitution of subject of journalistic reporting.
10 How to Buy, Sell, and Trade Attention: A Sociology of (Digital) Attention Markets 153

3 Attention Markets ideas (see Stalder 2018, 3 ff.). We have argued


in the Digital Age that, under market conditions, the generation of
attention is no longer merely a part of social
We can use our sociological framework to answer action, but rather, becomes a commodity.
the fourth and final question of how digital trans- Targeted disturbances, in the form of advertising,
formation is changing attention markets. Numer- for example, are a solution and a problem for
ous bestselling, critical nonfiction books deal attention merchants; disturbances must not be
with the consequences of the digital transforma- perceived as such, by target groups. Why is this
tion these days. Although authors concern them- important? It seems that successful platforms,
selves with a variety of digital technologies, their such as Facebook and YouTube solve this funda-
work has one thing in common; they perceive mental dilemma of attention markets by
digital transformation as a disruption in the his- leveraging users’ social action. Platforms use
tory of humanity. For example, Brynjolfsson and algorithms to evaluate which communicators
McAfee (2014) speak of the Second Machine their users follow, and which content they like
Age. Additionally, bestselling books on digitiza- and share voluntarily. Unlike traditional
tion have an ominous undertone. Ford (2016), for institutions, these platforms do not attempt to
example, warns of mass unemployment; Pariser address the information overload as a hierarchy.
(2011) of intellectual isolation; O’Neil (2016) of Instead, their algorithms convert one aspect of the
inequality and the deconstruction of democracy; users’ social action into the platforms’ main prod-
Harari (2018) of digital dictatorship; Zuboff uct. Rather than acting as a gatekeeper, the plat-
(2019) of total surveillance; and Bostrom (2014) form determines which target group receives
even predicts the end of the world as a result of an which content via an interaction of user behavior
emergent digital superintelligence. These and algorithms. In this interaction, attention is
evocations of anxiety are reminiscent, in some increasingly directed to communicators and con-
respects, of the gloomy diagnoses and predictions tent, which are not perceived as a targeted distur-
of critical theory on the culture industry, within bance. Instead, the recipients demand the content
which the public is seen as blind, uncritical, cul- voluntarily. In this context, Shaw (2012) refers to
tural consumers. decentralized gatekeeping (see also Wallace
Felix Stalder’s perspective (2018) on the 2018).
peculiarities of digital culture is much more This leads us to answer how social order arises
illuminating for our purposes. In his book, The on the internet. Considering that the wealth of
Digital Condition, Stalder shows how social information and the poverty of attention are two
action is increasingly shaped by digital sides of the same coin, Simon saw “a need to
technologies; how the internet exists despite mas- allocate that attention efficiently among the over-
sive information overload; and how the interplay abundance of information sources that might con-
of technical and social feedback mechanisms sume it” (1971, 40 f.). This allocation problem is
causes constant social change (see Stalder further exacerbated by the digital transformation
2018). We combine our economic-sociological (Davenport and Beck 2001; Chan-Olmsted and
framework of attention markets with Stalder’s Wolter 2018). Stalder (2018) states that no classi-
analysis of digital transformation. cal institution, no library, no archive, no editorial
According to Stalder (2018), social action is office is capable of even approximately
embedded in ever-more-complex communication channeling and organizing the information over-
technologies in the digital environment. As a load. In the digital environment, successful
result, people are increasingly confronted with a companies are those which have algorithms that
new digital culture. According to Stalder, digital make it possible to automate cultural activity,
transformation is ultimately accompanied by the which previously was an exclusive domain of
erosion of established institutions, certainties and humans (see Stalder 2018, 104 ff.). Instead of
channeling and organizing the information
154 P. Bachmann and G. Siegert

themselves, which leads to costs, they simply longer just a specific form of human action, which
provide platforms for others to do this. Therefore, is essentially characterized by someone’s strate-
Srnicek conceives platforms as a new type of gic planning, delivery, and evaluation of informa-
firm, because they allocate attention efficiently tion transfer to relevant target groups. Persuasive
by monopolizing, extracting, analyzing, and information transfer is increasingly automated. In
using large amounts of user data. User groups this context, Bachmann (2019) argues that future
are not only consumers but also “advertisers, public relations and advertising providers who
service providers, producers, suppliers, and even use big data, data mining, and artificial intelli-
physical objects” (Srnicek 2017, 43). Hence, the gence to manage data flow most effectively will
overabundance of information is no longer a cost- be successful in targeting actions, especially
factor for platforms, but the source of their wealth purchase.
instead. When considering social order, we have Finally, we attempt to answer the fourth ques-
noticed that attention markets arise because mar- tion. The effect of digital transformation on atten-
ket players spend their money where they find it tion markets is undisputed. However, the
most useful, where they expect the highest return innumerable bestsellers’ inherent penchant for
on investment. Platform operators offer their pay- doom and gloom presumably reveals less about
ing clientele much more than media reach. digital transformation than it does about the fact
McQuail’s statement, the “fact of attention, that apocalyptic predictions themselves can gen-
often matters more than the quality of attention erate a lot of attention, even in the digital age. Yet
(which can be adequately measured)” (2010, 72) despite ever-more-sophisticated technologies and
may be considered obsolete in the digital environ- persuasion techniques, one should not forget that
ment. Chan-Olmsted and Wolter reveal that humans are more than mere targets. They are
media experts stress the importance of attention reflexive beings who, over time, learn to thwart
quality, simple counting is not enough nowadays unwanted attempts to persuade and capture their
(2018, 17). Srnicek indicates that the more users attention, even though these attempts are very
interact with a site or app, the more information is sophisticated. If one takes the idea of humans as
collected about them via cookies and other means reflexive beings seriously, it will raise skepticism
(2017, 57). Not only can digital platforms mea- about the gloomy diagnoses and predictions of
sure the quality of attention, they can even better externally controlled recipients. Not every infor-
predict attentional behavior. For example, Zuboff mation transfer will reach its intended destination
(2019) refers to Facebook’s loyalty prediction in the future.
service that predicts which customers are at risk,
explaining, “The idea is that predictions can trig-
ger advertisers to intervene promptly, targeting 4 A Concluding Remark
aggressive messages to stabilize loyalty and thus
achieve guaranteed outcomes by altering the In this sociological analysis of attention markets,
course of the future” (Zuboff 2019, 279). The we refer to Simmel’s Sociology of Money for the
decisions as to where to invest money are not preliminary insight that attention is not a cur-
only automated in the digital environment but rency; unlike money, attention does not meet
are increasingly affected by artificial intelligence. certain requirements for exchangeability. Atten-
This brings us to the question of social change. tion is neither temporally, nor socially indifferent
Stalder (2018) portends that the algorithms of and thus far cannot be stored. In light of digital
successful platforms are not static but dynamic. transformation, perhaps this statement must be
Powerful algorithms are able to incorporate real- questioned. In his summary of Franck’s Economy
time feedback to improve their performance of Attention, van Krieken argues that attention
(Stalder 2018, 109). This also affects the classical “becomes a currency when it becomes, like
attention professions of advertising and public money, abstract, comparable, a system of equiva-
relations. Professional attention generation is no lence, quantifiable, and measurable in the form of
10 How to Buy, Sell, and Trade Attention: A Sociology of (Digital) Attention Markets 155

circulation forges, audience rating, sales figures, Benjamin, W. (2002 [1982]). The Arcades project. Transl.
hits, likes, views, downloads, followers, and so into English by Howard Eiland and Kevin
McLaughlin. New York: Belknap Press. [Walter Ben-
on” (2019, 5; see also Franck 2005, 103). jamin 1982 Das Passagen-Werk. Frankfurt am Main:
Our analysis has shown that not only can Suhrkamp.]
attention be measured more accurately in the dig- Bentele, G., & Nothhaft, H. (2008). The intereffication
ital age than ever before; it can even be predicted model: Theoretical discussions and empirical
Research. In A. Zerfass, B. van Ruler, &
with higher accuracy. Smart devices open up K. Sriramesh (Eds.), Public relations research.
possibilities of measurements based on the num- European and international perspectives and
ber of followers, clicks, shares, likes, and so on, innovations (pp. 33–47). Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für
as well as completely new possibilities of Sozialwissenschaften.
Bernays, E. L. (1928). Propaganda. New York: Horace
automated monitoring. According to Zuboff, Liveright.
Amazon has filed a patent for a voice-sniffer Bernays, E. L. (1947). The engineering of consent. The
algorithm that can be “integrated into any device Annals of the American Academy of Political and
and responds to hot words such as ‘bought,’ ‘dis- Social Science, 250, 113–120.
Bernays, E. L. (1971). The emergence of the public
like,’ or ‘love’ with product and service offers” relations counsel: Principles and recollections. The
(2019, 269). Although attention has not yet been Business History Review, 45, 296–316.
given to the properties of money in the digital age, Blumler, J. (1980). Information overload: Is there a prob-
the question remains as to whether attention has lem? In E. Witte (Ed.), Human aspects of telecommu-
nication (pp. 229–263). New York: Springer.
already become close to currency, as it can be Bostrom, N. (2014). Superintelligence. Paths, dangers,
measured so accurately and in a timely and strategies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
individualized manner. Brynjolfsson, E., & McAfee, A. (2014). The second
machine age: Work, progress, and prosperity in a
time of brilliant technologies. New York: Norton.
Campo, E. (2015). Relevance as social matrix of attention
in Alfred Schutz. Società Mutamento Politica, 6(12),
References 117–148.
Chan-Olmsted, S. M., & Wolter, L.-C. (2018). Perceptions
Adorno, T. W. (1963). Kann das Publikum wollen. In and practices of media engagement: A global perspective.
A. R. Katz (Ed.), Vierzehn Mutmaßungen über das International Journal of Media Management, 20(1), 1–24.
Fernsehen (pp. 55–60). München: Deutscher Dahinden, U. (2001). Informationsflut und Aufmerksam-
Taschenbuch Verlag. keitsmangel: Überlegungen zu einer Sozialökonomie
Bachmann, P. (2019). Public relations in liquid modernity: der Aufmerksamkeit. In K. Beck & W. Schweiger
How big data and automation cause moral blindness. (Eds.), Attention please. Online-Kommunikation und
Public Relations Inquiry, 8(3), 319–331. Aufmerksamkeit (pp. 39–55). München: Reinhard
Baerns, B. (1987). Öffentlichkeitsarbeit oder Fischer.
Journalismus? Zum Einfluß im Mediensystem Davenport, T. H., & Beck, J. C. (2001). The attention
(2. erweiterte Auflage). Köln: Verlag Wissenschaft economy: Understanding the new currency of busi-
und Politik. ness. Brighton, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Bauman, Z., & Donskis, L. (2016). Liquid evil. Falkinger, J. (2007). Attention economies. Journal of Eco-
Cambridge: Polity Press. nomic Theory, 133(1), 266–294.
Beck, K. (2001). Aufmerksamkeitsökonomie: Die Ford, M. (2016). The rise of the robots: Technology and
Funktion von Kommunikation und Medien. In the threat of mass unemployment. New York: Basic
K. Beck & W. Schweiger (Eds.), Attention please. Books.
Online-Kommunikation und Aufmerksamkeit Franck, G. (1998). Ökonomie der Aufmerksamkeit: Ein
(pp. 19–37). München: Reinhard Fischer. Entwurf. München: Carl Hanser.
Benjamin, W. (1969 [1935]). The work of art in the age of Franck, G. (2005). Mental capitalism. In M. Shamiyeh &
mechanical reproduction. Edited by Hannah Arendt. DOM Research Laboratory (Eds.), What people want:
Transl. into English by Harry Zohn. Proofed and Populism in architecture and design (pp. 98–115).
Corrected by Andy Blunden. Berlin and New York: Basel: Birkhäuser.
Schocken and Random House. [Benjamin Walter 1935 Friestad, M., & Wright, P. (1994). The persuasion knowl-
L’œuvre d’art à l’époque de sa reproduction edge model: How people cope with persuasion
mécanisée. Zeitschrift für Sozialforschung V, 40–68.] attempts. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(1), 1–31.
156 P. Bachmann and G. Siegert

Giddens, A. (1984). The constitution of society. Outline of Routledge. [Georg Simmel 1900 Philosophie des
the theory of structuration. Cambridge: Polity Press. Geldes. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.]
Harari, Y. N. (2014). Homo Sapiens: A brief history of Simon, H. A. (1971). Designing organizations for an
humankind. New York: Harper Collins. information-rich world. In M. Greenberger (Ed.),
Harari, Y. N. (2018). 21 lessons for the 21st century. Computers, communication, and the public interest
London: Jonathan Cape. (pp. 37–52). Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins University
Hollifield, C. A. (2006). News media performance in Press.
hypercompetitive markets: An extended model of Simon, H. A. (1997). Administrative behavior. A study of
effects. The International Journal on Media Manage- decision-making processes in administrative
ment, 8(2), 60–69. organizations (4th ed.). New York: Free Press.
Luhmann, N. (1995 [1984]). Social systems (J. Bednarz, Smelser, N. J., & Swedberg, R. (1994). Introducing eco-
Jr. with D. Baecker, Trans.). Stanford: Stanford Uni- nomic sociology. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg
versity Press. [Niklas Luhmann 1984 Soziale Systeme: (Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology
Grundriß einer allgemeinen Theorie. Frankfurt am (pp. 3–25). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Main: Suhrkamp.] Sommer, C., & Marty, L. (2015). The role of media brands
Marcuse, H. (2002 [1964]). One-dimensional man. Studies in media planning. Journal of Media Business Studies,
in the ideology of advanced industrial society. With an 12, 185–203.
introduction by Douglas Kellner. London: Routledge. Srnicek, N. (2017). Platform capitalism. Cambridge: Pol-
McQuail, D. (2010). McQuail’s mass communication the- ity Press.
ory (6th Revised ed.). London: Sage. Stalder, F. (2018). The digital condition (V. A. Pakis,
Meier, W. A., Trappel, J., & Siegert, G. (2010). Trans.). Cambridge: Polity Press.[Felix Stalder 2016
Medienökonomie. In H. Bonfadelli, O. Jarren, & Kultur der Digitalität. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.]
G. Siegert (Eds.), Einführung in die Publizistikwis- Steiner, P. (1995). Economic sociology: A historical per-
senschaft (pp. 239–270). Bern: Haupt. spective. The European Journal of the History of Eco-
O’Neil, C. (2016). Weapons of math destruction: How big nomic Thought, 2, 175–195.
data increases inequality and threatens democracy. Swedberg, R. (1987). The sociology of markets. Current
New York: Crown. Sociology, 35, 105–119.
Pariser, E. (2011). The filter bubble: What the internet is Turow, J. (2009). Media today: An introduction to mass
hiding from you. New York: Penguin Press. communication (3rd ed.). New York: Routledge.
Picard, R. G. (2003). Media economics. In R. Towse (Ed.), Van Krieken, R. (2019). Georg Franck’s ‘the economy of
The handbook of cultural economics (pp. 301–305). attention’: Mental capitalism and the struggle for atten-
Cheltenham: Edward Elg. tion. Journal of Sociology, 55(1), 3–7.
Rattansi, A. (2017). Bauman and contemporary sociology: Von Rimscha, B. M. (2017). The economic value of crea-
A critical analysis. Manchester: Manchester University tivity. How much, for whom, and what for. In K.-D.
Press. Altmeppen, C. A. Hollifield, & J. van Loon (Eds.),
Reinhardt, D. (1993). Von der Reklame zum Marketing: Value-oriented media management. Decision making
Geschichte der Wirtschaftswerbung in Deutschland. between profit and responsibility (pp. 109–118).
Berlin: Akademie Verlag. Wiesbaden: Springer.
Shaw, A. (2012). Centralized and decentralized gatekeep- Wallace, J. (2018). Modelling contemporary gatekeeping.
ing in an open collective. Politics and Society, 40(3), Digital Journalism, 6, 274–293.
349–388. Zuboff, S. (2019). The age of surveillance capitalism. The
Siegert, G. (2001a). Ökonomisierung der Medien aus fight for the future at the new frontier of power.
Systemtheoretischer Perspektive. Medien & London: Profile Books.
Kommunikationswissenschaft, 49, 167–176.
Siegert, G. (2001b). Der Januskopf der Aufmerksamkeit.
Überlegungen zur medienökonomischen Verortung
von Aufmerksamkeit zwischen knappen Gut und Internet References
universeller Währung. In K. Beck & W. Schweiger
(Eds.), Attention please. Online-Kommunikation und
Aufmerksamkeit (pp. 109–120). München: Reinhard Franck, G. (1999). The economy of attention. Telepolis
Fischer. 7. Retrieved December 07, 1999, from https://www.
Siegert, G., & Brecheis, D. (2017). Werbung in der heise.de/tp/features/The-Economy-of-Attention-
Medien- und Informationsgesellschaft: Eine 3444929.html
Kommunikationswissenschaftliche Einführung Ghosh, R. A. (1997). Economics is dead, long live eco-
(3. Auflage). Wiesbaden: Springer VS. nomics! A Commentary on Michael Goldhaber’s ‘The
Simmel, G. (2004 [1900]). The philosophy of money. attention economy’. First Monday, 5, 1–10. Retrieved
Edited by David Frisby. Transl. into English by Tom May 05, 1997, from https://journals.uic.edu/ojs/index.
Bottomore and David Frisby from a first draft by php/fm/article/view/529
Kaethe Mengelberg (3rd Enlarged ed.). London:
10 How to Buy, Sell, and Trade Attention: A Sociology of (Digital) Attention Markets 157

Goldhaber, M. H. (1997). The attention economy and the Siegert, Gabriele is a full professor of communication
net. First Monday, 4, 1–10. Retrieved April 07, 1997, studies and media economics at the Department of Com-
from https://firstmonday.org/article/view/519/440 munication and Media Research (IKMZ), University of
Zurich, Switzerland. Her research interests deal with
media economics, media management and advertising.
Bachmann, Philipp is lecturer at the Institute of Com- Recent publications: Siegert, Gabriele, and Dieter
munication and Marketing (IKM) at the Lucerne Univer- Brecheis. 2017. Werbung in der Medien- und Informa-
sity of Applied Sciences and Arts, Switzerland. tionsgesellschaft: Eine kommunikationswissenschaftliche
His research interests focus on strategic communica- Einführung. 3. Auflage. Wiesbaden: Springer VS. Siegert,
tion, corporate social responsibility, media management, Gabriele et al. 2017. Commercial Communication in the
and new technologies. He studied political science, Digital Age. Berlin: De Gruyter. Siegert, Gabriele et al.
sociology as well as media and communication sciences 2016. Handbuch Werbeforschung. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag
at the Universities of Göttingen, Stockholm and Leipzig für Sozialwissenschaften. Siegert, Gabriele et al. 2015.
Handbook of Media Branding. Basel: Springer Interna-
and achieved the magister degree in 2011. From 2011 to
tional Publishing.
2016, he worked as a research and teaching assistant at
Gabriele Siegert has served as president of the Swiss
the University of Fribourg in Switzerland and obtained his Association of Communication and Media Research, as
doctorate in 2016. He was senior research and teaching member of the Swiss Federal Media Commission and as
associate at the Institute of Mass Communication and member of editorial and advisory boards. Since 2016, she
Media Research (IKMZ), University of Zurich, from 2016 has served as Deputy President and Vice President
to 2019. Education and Student Affairs at the University of Zurich.
Right to the City, Right to the Market:
The Global Struggle of Informal 11
Marketplaces

Helge Mooshammer

Since the turn of the millennium, an expanding economic actors and tap into their entrepreneurial
range of formal-informal linkages, such as taxa- capacities.
tion of the informal sector and the creation of In this chapter, I will examine how these
informal jobs by state institutions, has markedly differences are indicative of the current tensions
impacted both the perception and operation of around the development of novel forms of
informal markets. Often triggered by political formal-informal linkages, especially around new
upheaval, economic destabilization, migratory forms of economic governance, which go beyond
movements and new labor situations, informal state-oriented notions of how to generate political
markets shape a form of alternative economic order and economic growth. My key aim is to
governance wherever and whenever institutional sketch a nuanced picture of the motivations,
protocols have come to a deadlock. With the practices, and effects of these divergent
informal sector estimated to account for more approaches to economic informality. Drawing
than half of all economic activity worldwide,1 a on findings of long-term research into the political
more decisive engagement with economic infor- pressure on informal markets carried out in col-
mality by the world’s governing bodies is increas- laboration with a global network of sociologists,
ingly being seen as critical to achieving a more anthropologists, architects, and activists over
sustainable form of global development. How- more than 15 years (Mörtenböck and
ever, current policy approaches are still torn Mooshammer 2012, 2015, 2016, 2019;
between framing informality as the root problem, Mörtenböck et al. 2015), I will seek to exemplify
being a “drag on growth”, as a Latin America- how the spectrum of policy engagement with
focused World Bank report put it (Perry et al. informal trade is applied to different physical
2007, 1), and attempting to recognize people marketplaces. Specifically, I will reference case
involved in the informal economy as valid studies from around the world to illustrate distinct
strategies of engagement with informal markets,
ranging from forced closure or relocation of
1
An ILO report put the number even higher, stating that marketplaces, to infrastructural improvement of
according to its calculations 2 billion workers, or 61 per- market facilities, or appropriation of entrepre-
cent of the worlds employed population, were in informal neurial undertakings. In doing so, I aim to articu-
employment (ILO 2018, 13).
late a basic typology of spatio-economic policies
H. Mooshammer (*) that are shaping the role of informal markets in
Goldsmiths, University of London, London, UK contemporary urban development.
TU Wien, Vienna, Austria
e-mail: helge.mooshammer@tuwien.ac.at

# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 159


A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_11
160 H. Mooshammer

1 Contested Sites of Exchange public order. Outmoded infrastructure, tax eva-


sion, violations of trade regulations, product
Markets are one of society’s most prevalent and counterfeiting, non-transparent business
diverse sites of exchange. They are the meeting relationships, health risks, unregulated employ-
point for a fluctuating circle of individuals where ment agreements, trespass and traffic obstruction
economic, cultural and social concerns intersect. are only some of the many shortcomings which
What holds a market together is its claim to con- are attributed to informal markets.
stitute a locus of multiple forms of agreement. In Seen against the backdrop of the globalization
Greek antiquity, the agora, a centrally located of world trade, the increase of the urban popula-
city square, was regarded as a site for political, tion and unprecedented levels of international
religious, and juridical assembly, as well as a migration, another picture has emerged since the
marketplace and a place for consultations involv- 1990s, in which the dual logic of the worldwide
ing the community of citizens (polis). It was the spread of informal markets can be discerned.
place in which the public gathered, and the char- Reorganizing politically imposed conditions,
acter of the public sphere was negotiated on many informality is a response to, and yet dependent
levels. The development of the modern state has on formal societal structures. However, informal-
seen a separation of the spaces, in which politics ity also exists independently, producing its own
are conducted, from the spaces in which markets social, economic, and cultural spheres. Within
operate and capital flows are regulated. This has, this tension, the definition and ascription of infor-
in turn, blurred the entanglement of different mality has increasingly become a strategic ele-
forums of civil assembly and of economic ment in a global struggle for economic access to
resource allocation. In the current phase of neo- the processes operating at the lower end of the
liberalism, this spatial separation is contributing economic pyramid, in particular (Roy 2010).
to an ongoing concealment of the interrela- When the anthropologist, Keith Hart, first
tionships between political and economic forces. coined the term “informal economy” in his article
At the same time, the state and private capital are on Informal Income Opportunities and Urban
increasingly operating outside their respective, Employment in Ghana, in 1973, he was motivated
established repertoires of action in order to lay in part by dissatisfaction with the ignorance of
claim to market spaces and steer them, in specu- hegemonic economic discourses and the concep-
lative terms. tual failure of western categories to grasp a sig-
In this context, different evaluations are made nificant share of the world’s economic goings-on
of the legitimacy and quality of the operations of (Hart 1973). Since then, among the many things
individual markets, depending on prevailing that have changed in global economic politics is a
political, ideological, and cultural circumstances. surging interest in informality, its varying
Today, places of public trade operate alternately conditions, ramifications, and potentials. Hence,
as sites of social opening and reinvention, as one of the most urgent tasks for research in soci-
forums of reconciliation and integration, as eco- ology, as well as in architecture, urban anthropol-
nomic security nets for immigrant workers, and as ogy, and globalization studies is to address what
sites of ethnic stigmatization and the enslavement is at stake in the politics of informality, in the age
of marginalized population sectors. In accordance of global markets. How can we identify, analyze,
with whatever strategic interests are pursued, and engage with the competing interests that are
these attributions are used as a basis for directing today’s political framing and applica-
facilitating some business activities while tion of the concept of informality in different
endeavoring to repress others that are classified parts of the world?
as illegal, dirty, or backward. The alleged infor- From such a practice-oriented perspective, it
mality of these non-conforming markets is linked becomes possible to assess how, during the
to a lack of modernity, legality, profitability, or course of the last decades, the concept of infor-
mality has developed from a simply structured
11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle of Informal Marketplaces 161

economic situation into a figure that encompasses that investigate the developmental impact of
all the complexities emerging from the globaliza- hybrid governance arrangements (Sassen 2014),
tion process. The operative dimension of infor- the distinctive needs of
mality, which is central to these investigations, entrepreneurial vs. survivalist informal actors
thus points not only to an abstract, (Linehan 2007; see also Stamm in this hand-
one-dimensional plan of action, but also to a book), and the changing forms of integrating
field of forces, spread across the world, in which informal vendors into economic growth and
different milieus of actors, interests, and civic participation (Lund and Skinner 2004).
aspirations unfold at different sites, on varying While being grounded in site-specific analyses
scales. This field is a vehicle of the global econ- of the governance effects of formal-informal
omy, as well as a site of everyday struggles and linkages (bricolage, synergy, composition, hybrid
step-by-step development of alternative governance, among others), the broad direction of
interconnections. this approach draws on emergent theoretical work
Crucial for any research into the contemporary around the nexus between formal and informal
fate of informal marketplaces is the recognition economic practices, including New Institutional
that there is no clear-cut binary of formal and Economics, network analysis, global commodity/
informal economic conduct. Both terms reflect value chains, legal pluralism, subaltern politics,
particular roles assigned within a continuous eco- and post-Foucauldian conceptions of power
nomic fabric. Although often characterized by beyond the state (Feige 1990; Nadvi 2004;
uneven power relations (Simone 2010), the dis- Spivak 2004; Latour 2005; Ong 2006;
tinction between formal and informal is not nec- Wojkowska 2006; Easterling 2014). By embrac-
essarily synonymous with the disparity between ing such a trans-disciplinary perspective, I seek to
the wealthy and the poor. There is informality move beyond essentialist debates and reach a
from above, just as there is informality from more nuanced understanding of the dynamic
below (Ribeiro 2006); there is elite informality, interactions of spatio-economic integration, trans-
just as there is subaltern informality (Roy 2005). national capital flows, institutional processes, and
There are also degrees of planning, order, bottom-up restructuring (see also Opper in this
deliberations, and protocols in informal markets, handbook). Finally, while focusing on contempo-
just as there are in formal markets. Indeed, recent rary aspects and phenomena of global economic
changes in global economic operations, particu- realignment, addressing key notions, such as
larly in the wake of the 2007/08 financial crisis, as co-production, bottom/base of the pyramid,
well as ongoing technological and operational multi-stakeholder networks, to name a few, I
advances, have brought about an increased feel it is imperative to also situate the transforma-
informalization of all areas of commerce, trade tion of informal marketplaces within historical
and work. My argument is that in order to gain a trajectories of strategic urban transformation,
better understanding of the patterns of economic colonial exploitation, and political resistance.
informality and empower public debates about The hitherto dominant interpretation of
policy approaches, it is necessary to acknowledge manifestations of economic informality and
that the idea of an informal economy is already associated proposals, as to how structural deficits
entailed in the institutional effort to organize soci- of the informal sector can be overcome, have so
ety along formal lines.2 far prioritized demands on academic research to
This attempt to engage with the ambiguities estimate the size of the informal economy.3
surrounding the spread of informality is substan-
tially informed by recent discourses in architec-
3
tural, urban, economic, and geographical studies This has notably helped to lay the foundation for policies
formulated by agencies trying to improve the conditions of
informal workers such as the ILO (International Labor
Organization) and NGOs such as WIEGO (Women in
2
See, for instance, Hart (2012). Informal Employment: Globalizing and Organizing),
162 H. Mooshammer

Placing an emphasis on the relations of economic diverse range of policy strategies involved in the
informality with other domains as well as current incorporation of the informal economy, but also
practices of (in)formalization (McFarlane 2012), I to identify decisive modes of spatial planning
propose shifting the focus of such estimations intervention employed in their implementation.
from measuring the size of the informal sector to For the purpose of clarity, I suggest grouping
developing an analytical matrix, which captures these partly overlapping, partly competing
the dynamics of strategic interventions in the strategies into four distinct types (Fig. 11.1),
informal economy. In this chapter, I am interested which can be described as follows:
in how the term integration often masks a range
A. Forced closure of informal markets (shut-
of extra-market processes, ideologically biased
down of trade, eviction of vendors)
goals, and purpose-driven interventions, which
B. Relocation of informal markets (relocation of
are central to the ongoing creation of a global
informal trade to peri-urban environments)
market and economic standardization (Humphrey
C. On-site infrastructural improvement (water,
and Skvirskaja 2012).
sanitary facilities, service, transport,
Architecture is politics in physical form. It
maintenance)
provides a material foil, the life cycles of which,
D. Appropriation of the entrepreneurial energy
can be examined and contextualized. Tracing and
of informal markets (privatization,
interpreting the temporal and spatial trajectories
commodification)
of ongoing transformations of informal
marketplaces can create entry points for capturing What I am interested in here is to lay out an
and narrating the different degrees of integration analytical matrix to assess policy interventions in
involved, and the policies pursued in the informal marketplaces, by way of identifying and
incorporation of informality into mainstream eco- articulating interrelations between spatial trans-
nomic activity. Pursuing a comparative reading formation processes and economic policy
of spatial transformations of informal markets can frameworks. In what ways do different types of
pave the way to identify different degrees and spatial intervention correlate with varying
forms of integration, as well as corresponding degrees of economic incorporation, while also
social and economic policies. Articulating being shaped by regional tendencies, and other
patterns of spatial intervention can make their demographic, social, and cultural dynamics?
correlation with a network of state and non-state Building on existing models of investigating gov-
actors, communities of interests, economic ernance implications of formal-informal linkages
powers, conflicts, and deals, tangible on a local, through typologies of governance transformation,
regional, and global level. e.g., replacement, undermining, support, compe-
tition (Helmke and Levitsky 2004), or comple-
mentary, accommodating, substitutive,
2 Spatial Interventions competing (Grzymala-Busse 2010), I aim to
in Informal Markets extend this conceptual framework by adding the
as Economic Policy Indicators four distinctive spatial dimensions outlined
above: closure, relocation, improvement, and
In accordance with this approach, l will touch on appropriation.
various cases of informal markets in order to What is at stake in these endeavors is making
explore the scope, intersections and tensions of spatial interventions in informal marketplaces
ongoing processes of incorporating informality. legible, as catalysts of hybrid economic gover-
When looking at these and many other related nance. By exemplifying, rather than representing
sites, it becomes possible not only to identify a the diversity of informal marketplaces currently
being transformed into hubs of formal economic
which grew out of a research network at the Harvard activity, I will now discuss each type of spatial
Kennedy School. transformation alongside a specific case study in
11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle of Informal Marketplaces 163

closure relocation improvement appropriation


(shutdown of trade, (water, sanitary of entrepreneurial
(of trade to peri-urban
facilities, service, energy (privatization,
eviction of vendors environments)
transport, maintenance) commodification)

Fig. 11.1 Spatial interventions in informal markets. Source: Author

order to trace particular patterns of economic systems prevalent in the former West. With the
incorporation, which can be distinguished from dissolution of the Soviet Union and the integra-
other types of intervention. tion of its trade into a global market, countless old
shipping containers became redundant and were
recycled as low expense infrastructure for storage
space, logistics services, public amenities, shops
3 Forced Closure: Moscow’s
and market stalls, be it as a temporary setup or as
Cherkizovsky Market
an ad-hoc solution to deliver public services in
new residential areas.
The first case study is an example of the forced
Against this backdrop, the sprawl of vast con-
closure of informal markets. What is notable with
tainer markets, after 1989 in this changing region
this type of intervention is how disputes regarding
was certainly not an anomalous phenomenon.
the spatial conditions (overcrowding, lack of san-
The modular design, strength and adaptability of
itation, and fire hazards) of informal markets
shipping containers made them well suited to use
affected by this mode of radical transformation
as low-cost, multi-story structures that could
have been strategically linked with ideological
accommodate a wide range of businesses, from
attitudes (anti-immigrant, nationalistic, and
service providers to wholesale and retail traders
pro-liberal markets to name a few). There is a
of all kinds. They also allowed for the easy,
recognizable pattern to the political rhetoric
flexible expansion of market areas. As long as
accompanying the enforced clamp-down on oth-
vacant land was available, more rows of stacked
erwise successful markets, which positions them
containers could be added, combining sale units
as extra-legal goings-on that need to be reined in.
on the ground and storage units on top. Some of
At its peak, the Cherkizovsky Market in the
these informal marketplaces, such as the Seventh-
northeast of Moscow was one of the most impor-
Kilometer Market on the outskirts of Odessa or
tant nodes of informal trade across much of East-
the Dordoi Bazaar in Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan have
ern Europe and Eurasia. The market’s layered
reached the size of several dozen hectares of land,
history provides extensive material for multiple
with thousands of vendors vying to sell
interwoven readings. It was also one of the most
low-priced goods. While these markets are still
elaborate and expansive examples of a container
operating, others, such as Moscow’s
market, a spatial typology typical of the kind of
Cherkizovsky Market had to give into pressures
anarchic urbanism that spread rapidly after the
from landowners, politicians, lobby groups, and
collapse of the Eastern Block, the key assets of
investors and were dismantled to make way for
which were speed and unhindered appropriation.
more profitable operations.
While unitization had played an important role in
Built of row after row of stacked containers,
the Soviet Union’s policy of mass production, its
with alleys covered with vaulted Perspex, the
container standards were incompatible with
164 H. Mooshammer

Cherkizovsky Market, by the time it was finally basic necessities of life, the Cherkizovsky Market
dismantled in 2009, had grown into fifteen became a repeatedly contested site of cultural
specialized trading areas. At that stage, the market belonging where attempts to reconstruct a
occupied an area three times the size of the Krem- Russian national identity encountered the com-
lin and had completely engulfed the old plex realities of a globalized migration-economy.
Izmailovo Stadium at its center. The market’s The progressive commercialization, of even the
owners were among Russia’s new billionaires, tiniest niches, generated a large number of
while at the lower end of the new market- unforeseen spaces for micro-cultural
economy scale, it provided a habitat for thousands negotiations, such as the space used by 3000
of migrants from Tajikistan, Uzbekistan, China, Mountain Jews from the Caucasus, for whom a
and Southeast Asia, who worked as stall-minders, 200-square-feet room, laid out with carpets and
carriers and tea-sellers 7 days a week. They slept located between the shoe storerooms and the
in the metal storage containers on top of stored sportsmen’s and women’s toilets in the caverns
goods or in the cellars of the stadium. In this state of the stadium stands, served as a synagogue.
of modern slavery, they were not only at the Like the majority of the hundreds of thousands
mercy of exploitative employers but also of arbi- of people whose lives were inextricably tied to the
trary police behavior and gangs of young thugs market, they, too, were both marginalized and
roaming the streets of Moscow. As a result, many transformed into targets of a global tug-o-war
of them never dared to venture more than a few over cultural identity. To some, they are blacks,
100 m from the market, which had morphed into a to some they are not orthodox enough, while
city within the city. some doubt whether they are Jews at all.
Both ends of its 20-year existence were In August 2006, a bombing at the market,
marked, on the one hand, by a process of step- carried out by the Russian radical nationalist
by-step adaptation of spatial possibilities on the group Spas, killed thirteen people and left
ground, and on the other, by intervening 53 badly wounded. One month later, the vice-
directives coming from the top of the national speaker of Moscow City Council announced that
government. Initially, Cherkizovsky Market was the market would be closed at the end of 2006.
a product of the politics of individual initiatives While the owners’ good contacts with the govern-
promoted by Perestroika. Under its banner, ment and the mayor led to repeated delays in
members of the Russian State University of Phys- implementing these plans, a ruling to restrict the
ical Education (RGUFK) began to use its grounds share of foreign workers at markets to 40 per cent,
and buildings commercially. In June 1989, Sergei which came into effect in April 2007, had a sig-
Korniyenko and a collective of enthusiasts leased nificant impact on Cherkizovksy Market, as it did
the stadium buildings. Under the terms of the on many other Eurasian trading places. From
contract, the spectator stands and the sports fields Moscow to Vladivostock, there were reports of
were to be made available for events such as the markets collapsing completely. On June 29, 2009,
Spartakiade 2000. The remaining spaces, such as the market was finally shut down by Russia’s
those beneath the stands, could be used for com- consumer watchdog, Rospotrebnadzor. Among
mercial purposes. the reasons cited were 464 alleged violations of
Originally, the stadium was conceived as an fire safety regulations and the results of earlier
arena for mass performances, demonstrating the raids that had unearthed 6000 containers of coun-
superiority of the political order of the Soviet terfeit goods. According to a number of interna-
Union. With the rapid expansion of the market, tional media reports, growing alienation between
the idea of parade grounds for revolutionary tanks former close allies Moscow Mayor Yuri Luzhkov
and patriotic armies gave way to thousands of and the oligarch Telman Ismailov, whose AST
carriers and tea-sellers swarming along the end- Group operated many markets, caused by the
less labyrinth of its mile-long halls to keep this latter’s very public economic flirtation with Tur-
trading organism alive. As a place of trade in the key, may have contributed to the market’s sudden
11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle of Informal Marketplaces 165

closure. This lockdown took many of the 100,000 Meanwhile, many Asian traders moved to the
migrant workers by surprise, and they suddenly 8000-stall Sadovod Market, situated further out,
found themselves locked out with no access to next to Moscow’s ring road and established more
their trading stock. Stallholders and suitcase permanently around the announced closure of the
traders protested for days outside the locked mar- Cherkizovky Market in 2008. Sadovod Market is
ket gates. A group of Vietnamese market workers now considered to be Russia’s largest market,
trying to block a nearby highway were arrested operating in a very similar manner to
and given deportation orders. Immediate crisis Cherkizovsky Market in terms of both its eco-
talks between Chinese officials and the Russian nomic and spatial organization.
government about the implications of the closure
for the 60,000 strong Chinese community
involved in the market led to arrangements for 4 Market Relocation: Bangkok’s
traders to withdraw their stock from the market at Talad Rot Fai
regulated times. Russia and China expressed their
mutual interest in establishing a standardized, While efforts to shut down informal markets
transparent, and convenient trade environment. focus on redirecting the nominal volume of infor-
Work to dismantle the market began in mal economic operations, relocation programs
September 2009, and on October 20, 2009, seek to utilize informal traders as helpful
Moscow Mayor Yuri Luzhkov signed a decree facilitators of this trade flow, albeit under highly
on a revised listing of Moscow’s markets that no altered and much more controlled circumstances.
longer included the Cherkizovsky Market. On Such policies of peripheral incorporation typi-
that day, the Cherkizovsky Market officially cally involve a convergence of legal and policy
ceased to exist. instruments with particular spatial typologies
While the official rhetoric accompanying the (design, functional layout, financing, building
closure of the market promoted a return of the site contracts, operational management). Relocation
to its proper use as a space where people could measures often target interstitial markets, taking
devote themselves to physical culture, the advantage of niche opportunities, which might be
emerging leitmotif in the RGUFK’s concept for spatial, (e.g., underutilized strips of land situated
the site emulates the global pattern of turning between larger developments) but might also be
stadium grounds into high-value real estate. The temporal, (e.g., night or dawn markets occupying
numerous development proposals that have been land outside main business hours).
put forward for this substantial tract of land have Informal markets are masters of adaptability.
included ambitious plans for using the stadium as Insofar as informality can be defined at all, a
a venue for the 2018 FIFA World Cup. Echoing formative and characteristic dimension of infor-
the spatial logic of the market in which rows of mal markets is their ability to escape regulation,
containers hugged the oval shape of the stadium as well as the grip of authorities. This is primarily
like the rings of an onion, the design proposed for due to the creative ways in which informal
the World Cup included an iconic center piece markets take hold of situations outside the stan-
formed by the sweeping curve of a new outer dard course of things. As a place of direct
building block running parallel to the stands, exchange, markets rely on the provision of a
supporting a new roof and rising up spectacularly physical meeting ground where buyers and
to its northern tip. By 2019, 10 years after the vendors can come together. Given the economic
dismantling of the market and the removal of precariousness at the heart of informal
thousands of stacked shipping containers, none economies, which impedes investment in any-
of those grand schemes had materialized and the thing long-term, informal markets are thus depen-
area surrounding the old Soviet stadium remained dent on the appropriation of available spaces.
a barren wasteland, crisscrossed only by a few Forced to seek out gaps in the urban fabric, infor-
short-cuts to the neighboring blocks of flats. mal markets take on a plethora of different forms.
166 H. Mooshammer

While many occupy spatial margins or the its early years but always remained in the heart of
interstices between different land uses and zones Bangkok’s political district. In 1982, to make
of authority, informal markets also avail them- space for Bangkok’s bicentennial celebrations, it
selves of communal gathering spaces during was moved to its current site, a fenced-in, 35-acre
times when such spaces are not subject to formal lot on the grounds of the State Railway of
uses or control. Thailand’s former golf course near Chatuchak
The interstices in which informal markets Park. In the historical context, this flea market
emerge and become concentrated are above all, program may seem paradoxical, given that in the
the spatial effects of in-between opportunities. twentieth century most emerging economies
Yet, while space is one of the core components sought to ban street trade as incompatible with
in the making of cities, one of the most essential the aesthetics of a modern Western-style state.
resources keeping cities afloat, and their most However, while the de-facto dictatorship of
transformative capital is their people. The Phibunsongkhram is credited with the moderniza-
fluctuating conglomerations of people, character- tion of Thailand, his policies were also driven by
istic of today’s exploding metropolises, catalyze a an explicitly nationalist agenda. Establishing one
multitude of interstitial market formations. Build- flea market per town was meant to encourage
ing nodes of provisional networks, interstitial people to purchase primarily Thai products and
markets turn into infrastructures themselves, to cut imports, specifically from China, thus
providing crucial support at the bottom strata of securing Thailand’s independence from neigh-
globalization. In their spatial proliferation, they boring powers.
index the manifold links between informality, the Today, the JJ, together with many of
needs of transient populations, and the excesses Bangkok’s other street markets, is often regarded
of urban economic transformation. as out of sync with Thailand’s progression
It is testimony to the markets’ enduring capac- towards a globally integrated, advanced con-
ity to generate hubs of commonality that people sumer economy. The aspiring youngsters
not only flock to them to satisfy basic needs but populating the city’s high-end malls are perceived
also choose to spend their leisure time there. The to be much more in line with Thailand’s avowed
city of Bangkok with its rich array of markets is a mission to become the region’s model capitalist
case in point: informal trade is so engrained in state, than the uncontrollable mayhem of a
Bangkok’s urban fabric that virtually every congested market where operations result in
neighborhood features a line of vendors selling rubbish-filled streets and an undesirable listing
street food, cheap textiles, or household goods, in the USTR’s yearly Special 301 reports.4 Yet,
rendering street market consumption one of the in the shadow of the JJ a new kind of market
most mundane routines of Thai everyday life. On typology has emerged, which might well prove
the other hand, Bangkok also boasts one of the capable of meeting the challenges presented by a
largest weekend markets in the world. The monopolized market of global corporate chains; a
Chatuchak Market, or JJ for short, is reputed to market culture fostered by a new generation of
attract 200,000 visitors every Saturday and young entrepreneurial creatives that fuses issues
Sunday. As a shopping and leisure destination it
competes with Bangkok’s high concentration of
4
spectacular super-brand malls such as the Central In conjunction with separately published annual results
of a so-called Out Out-of-Cycle Review of Notorious
World Mall and the Siam Paragon Mall.
Markets, yearly Special 301 reports are released by the
The origins of the JJ date back to 1948, when Office of the United States Trade Representative (USTR)
the then Prime Minister, Plaek Phibunsongkhram, under Sect. 301 of the Trade Act of 1974 and list physical
promoted a policy of one flea market per town. In marketplaces around the world that are deemed notorious
for violating the intellectual property rights of US
Bangkok, the first flea market was initially held
companies and individuals. For the 2019 issues see
on the open field of Sanam Luang, right next to https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/2019_Special_301_
the Grand Palace. It was relocated several times in Report.pdf.
11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle of Informal Marketplaces 167

of identity and occupation in a self-styled atmo- Consuming and buying at the market paves the
sphere of productivity and enjoyment. way for spending time with friends and
Initially located approximately 500 m from the experiencing a sense of cultural belonging.
JJ, the celebrated hipster mecca of Talad Rot Fai Aesthetics play a key role in establishing this
has brought Bangkok to the forefront of a global sense of counterculture. In the case of Talad Rot
phenomenon of bottom-up creative cities, that is Fai, it is vintage chic with a specific focus on
usually associated with highly contested gentrifi- Americana that provides the basis for reciprocal
cation processes in the centers of old power such recognition. With most of the goods on offer
as New York, London or Berlin. The market’s being customized or simply scarcely sourced, the
name, Talad Rot Fai (Train Market), refers to the market’s flavor of uniqueness does not rely on
original site of the market, a former rail yard original craft production. What matters is that
featuring a paved rectangular open space backed Talad Rot Fai, as a kind of Gesamtkunstwerk
by disused railway carriages and flanked by two (an artistic synthesis addressing all senses)
rows of cargo depots. The market was the brain- provokes a captivating feeling of community
child of two antique dealers, who in July 2010, that is shared by both sellers and buyers. The
seeking to expand their business, leased a nine- conviction that both groups contribute to the
acre site from the State Railway of Thailand making of the place is essential for this new
(SRT) for a period of 3 years. Unable to fill the type of social economy to prevail. As the roles
vast warehouses with their own merchandise, of traders and customers become blurred, busi-
they started offering spaces to fellow traders. ness activities and enjoyment become inter-
The terrain was subsequently divided up into changeable. This supposed dissolution of value
retro boutiques and arts, crafts and furniture stores hierarchies and the backgrounding of profit
interspersed with the odd display of vintage cars interests allows the market to be embraced as a
and car accessories. A significant proportion of connective cultural framework.
the buildings were left undeveloped, which added Nowadays, while the vast JJ flea market sells
to the site’s sense of discovery. predominately cheap goods or mass-produced
At the heart of the original Talad Rot Fai, knick-knacks aimed at tourists, much of which
occupying the former head offices of the railway is sourced from China, the Talad Rot Fai engages
yard, sat Rod’s, a restaurant/bar/music venue run with the global market in a very different way. At
by one of the market’s founders that blended this market, globalization refers less to the global
smoothly into his antique shop in the warehouse circulation of goods than to embracing a global
section. This combination of entertainment and cultural vocabulary of teenage lifestyles. Ameri-
trade at Rod’s set the tone for turning the Train can retro provides the basis for appropriating a
Market into one of Bangkok’s favorite places to globally as well as locally oriented identity of
hang out. Promising a good time is central to creative expression and a self-made environment,
Talad Rot Fai’s continuing appeal at its new both socially and economically. Responding to a
venue, where Rod’s still operates, and the main global taste for individual style, customized fash-
reason why an avant-garde scene of young ion replaces indistinguishable Chinese mass pro-
fashionistas gathers at the market. The magic of duction. In a perhaps unintended way, the young
Talad Rot Fai lies in its spatial logic of long rows entrepreneurs at Talad Rot Fai can be seen as
of brightly colored gazebo-type stalls, selling perpetuating Phibunsongkhram’s 1948 policy of
customized fashion items such as T-shirts, economic independence through a flea market
shoes, glasses, jewelry, and other accessories, culture, albeit in a very different fashion; one
which stretch between food stalls and pop-up based not on references to a national folklore
bars at either end. Here, the emphasis is not on but on a fusion of global styles and iconographies.
hunting for the best deal but rather on doing the When the 3-year lease for the former rail yard
walk along the stalls from one bar to another, expired in June 2013, the market was shut down
which becomes a ritual of cultural communality. and the grounds immediately dug up for work on
168 H. Mooshammer

the new SRT Red Line. In anticipation of this attractive neighborhoods benefitting both vendors
development, the proprietors had already and visitors, as well as the city and its economy as
established a sister site in Srinakarin near the a whole. Of particular interest in this context is to
Suvarnabhumi Airport in the east of the city, to understand which actors commission, design, and
which the entire market has now been moved. manage such spatial interventions, for which the
However, while the original market’s attraction high-profile redesign of Barcelona’s ancient
was based, to no small extent, on the ambience of Encants Vells flea market has become a flagship
its old, abandoned and worn out buildings, this example.
second, bigger version of Talad Rot Fai is an The urban typology of public markets is
entirely new structure located on a brownfield regaining interest amongst politicians and
site on the outskirts of the city. Comprised of investors alike. The economic changes of recent
standardized light-weight metal structures, it has years have not only contributed to a worldwide
been decorated with retro-style mock-ups, includ- spread of informal markets, but also brought with
ing a replica pagoda and a gateway flanked by them a surprising reappraisal of historical
two kitsch brass warrior statues, making it resem- marketplaces. In modernist, traffic-oriented
ble more a village-themed shopping outlet than an urban planning, prevalent for much of the past
underground market. It is still called the Train century, public marketplaces have often been
Market even though its new site no longer has attributed only marginal economic relevance.
anything to do with trains. Instead, its new neigh- While some cases were deemed worthy of protec-
bor is the massive 500-yard-long Seacon Square tion as cultural heritage, harboring potential as a
shopping mall and entertainment center. Yet, this tourist attraction, more often than not, they were
fake reincarnation of the original aesthetics at the regarded as an outmoded form of urban provision
new Talad Rot Fai site is less an expression of a and a burden on municipal budgets. The resurgent
counterfeit culture, but is indicative of a widely interest in markets as engines of urban regenera-
shared attitude toward economic development, tion has intensified significantly since the fall-out
which seeks to capture and maintain the original of the global financial crisis of 2007–08. This
entrepreneurial energy of informal activities, trend has partly been fueled by the festivalization
albeit in a much more controlled and regulated of public space but is also linked to the demand to
environment. This hegemonic framework is fur- foster new hybrid economic environments which
ther echoed by the way in which this change of generate growth while shifting risks from
urban context, from the hustle-and-bustle of a authorities to resident populations. The informal
central transport hub to a mono-functional shop- sector plays a major role in this quest for risk
ping area at the periphery, has become a staple of mitigation. Flea markets, in particular, are a
many market relocation programs, whether vol- long-standing example of such formal/informal
untary or involuntary, around the world. arrangements. While the market managers present
a respectable facade consistent with most formal
requirements by the authorities, businesses of the
5 Old Site, New Market: Encants individual stall holders are, in essence, informal
Vells, Barcelona enterprises, whether they focus on single-
handedly operated imports or the selling of
The third type of intervention, improvement of home baked cupcakes.
informal markets through onsite infrastructural One of the most dazzling examples of such a
investment, takes the active involvement of pub- contemporary appropriation of the cultural values
lic authorities, in efforts to take certain levels of of markets is the centuries-old Encants Vells in
economic integration a significant step further. Barcelona, a former open-air market, which was
Such urban development policies propose a relocated to a new and twice as large market hall,
win-win situation in which increased efficiency, in the fall of 2013. Encants Vells is considered to
hygiene, and order will result in safer and more be one of the oldest markets in Europe. Its origins
11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle of Informal Marketplaces 169

can be traced back to the thirteenth century, when the market a popular meeting place for the grow-
it took place in various churchyards of the medie- ing migrant population of Barcelona. Along the
val city. Back then, a key function of the market pedestrian links to the nearby metro station,
was to auction off estates of recently deceased which crossed the vast roundabout of Plaça de
citizens in order to generate cash flows for the les Glòries Catalanes, a few hawkers usually lin-
bereaved and help to pay off any remaining debts. gered, selling socks from cardboard boxes or
Even today, on Mondays, Wednesdays, and pieces of second-hand clothing strung across the
Fridays, excess goods from warehouse torn fences that encircled this otherwise deserted
liquidations, bankruptcies or other one-off island, which was engulfed by thundering traffic.
sources are sub-mastered, (i.e., auctioned off) Although these hawkers were small in numbers
among the registered dealers, who later sell and only occupied the fringes of the market, their
these goods at the flea market held in the very high visibility to passers-by was often channeled
same space. In the first half of the nineteenth into political and media pressure for a redesign of
century, these auctions merged with the Fira de the entire area (see also Morén-Alegret et al.
Bellcaire, which had developed outside the city 2016, 107).
walls during the Napoleonic occupation years. In In a city as colorful as Barcelona, Plaça de les
1928, after several relocations in connection with Glòries Catalanes embodies a particularly striking
the world exhibitions of 1888 and 1929, the then piece of failed urban planning. As the crossing
combined auction and flea market moved to a site point of the broad streets of Meridiana, Diagonal
on the edge of Plaça de les Glòries Catalanes, two and Gran Via de Les Corts Catalanes, Ildefons
miles east of the city center, which remained its Cerdà’s master plan of 1859 envisaged the Plaça
permanent home for the next 85 years. de les Glòries Catalanes as a new center of urban
Subsequent alterations of surrounding road expansion toward the northeast. However, the
levels caused the market to sit in a sunken pit. route of the existing railway line to France
On both sides of Carrer del Dos de Maig, which interfered with the planned intersection of major
formed the central artery of Encants Vells, steps axes and diagonals so unfavorably that within the
led down to a row of sheet-metal stalls, offering basic orthogonal grid, an area of nine-hectares
mainly household and hardware goods. In the remained undefined and over the course of many
open space to the west, the famous auctions and years served all sorts of unglamorous uses, from
subsequent flea markets were held. With its dense freight sheds to Second World War shelters to the
array of curious assortments of goods, the horizon market of Encants Vells. While the location of the
accentuated by rows of palm trees and a huge market within the no-man’s-land of Les Glòries
neon sign rising against the sky, it was this secured the survival of the market for a long time,
open-air part of the market that shaped the popu- the unresolvedness of its urban setting increas-
lar image of Encants Vells. In contrast, the plot to ingly added to the pressure on its particular mode
the east of Carrer del Dos de Maig was occupied of doing things, as the surrounding areas got
by rows of fixed walk-in market booths, which spruced up one after the other. Following the
clustered around smaller irregular-shaped open urban renewal schemes initiated in the run-up to
spaces and which were primarily catering to the 1992 Summer Olympics, the subsequent
buyers of furniture, sanitary appliances, bedding, extension of the Avinguda Diagonal to the sea
and other home accessories. To the north, border- provided the starting signal for a whole wave of
ing the Camp de l’Arpa del Clot residential areas, high-profile monumental architecture now dot-
most of the stalls belonged to textile and cloth ting the area. Iconic structures such as the
traders, who often leased warehouses in the Forum building by Herzog & de Meuron or the
adjoining former factory buildings to support Torre Agbar by Jean Nouvel are meant to usher in
their swift trade. Over the last decades, this plen- a profound transformation of the working class
tiful supply of cheap new goods, especially neighborhood of Poblenou (New Village) into a
textiles and household goods, had helped make
170 H. Mooshammer

new innovation district marketed by the brand arena of action. One side of the triangular plot
name 22 @. has been kept completely open, providing an
The Plaça de les Glòries Catalanes was chosen uninterrupted view of the Torre Agbar to the east.
by the city administration as the focus of social The undisputed highlight of the whole design,
and economic dynamization of the entire area, however, is the facetted canopy roof, held up by
which should inspire new urban practices for the thin steel columns at an airy height of 16 yards. Its
future. Started in 2003, the process to transplant underside is entirely covered with highly reflec-
Encants Vells to a new site on the other side of tive gold-tinted metal panels—as praised in
Plaça de les Glòries Catalanes initially faced sub- numerous marketing material—making the
stantial resistance from major sections of the mar- whole kaleidoscope of market activity visible at
ket vendors. However, a compromise plan a glance. With 375,000 square feet, the new mar-
adopted in 2007, which included the prospect of ket offers space for more than twice as many
significant organizational and spatial retailers and, according to the Municipal Market
improvements, ultimately helped win a majority Office (IMMB), attracts up to 100,000 visitors per
for handing over the original site and allowing the week. The new market hall occupies a front row
development of a grand new Central Park. position in this line-up of spectacular architecture,
According to the plans of the competition- which in addition to the Torre Agbar includes the
winning team of Agence Ter and Ana Coello Catalan National Theatre, the Music Auditorium
Llobet, the emblematic elevated motorway has and the Design Museum. Joining this parade of
been replaced by an urban canopy that is sup- long-established building typologies of civic
posed to improve the urban microclimate and pride demonstrates how popular marketplaces
create a new hybrid eco-system. While the park have markedly moved up a notch within the hier-
was opened to the public in 2019, completion of archy and repertoire of urban planning oriented
the entire remodeling of Plaça de les Glòries toward stimulating economic growth through cul-
Catalanes is envisaged for 2021. tural assets.
The new market hall of Encants Barcelona/La In this sense, the shift of Encants Vells from
Fira de Bellcaire on the southwestern corner of outside to inside also marks the shift from infor-
the square itself was already inaugurated in mal exploitation to formalized investment. Thus,
September 2013 and formed an important step the newly constructed market hall not only
in the radical transformation of Les Glòries. The provides a roof over head for dealers who were
design, which has also received much attention in previously unprotected against arbitrary weather.
professional circles, frames the market activities It also opens up more direct access to the
as an all-senses spectacle. Market visitors are led innovation potential of markets as incubators of
along ramps, which are lined with stalls and dou- new business ideas. The geometric layout of the
ble back on themselves like a Möbius strip. On new building, with its sharply delineated zones
the lower ramps, rows of tables are set up in front and different types of booth models (78 business
of roller shutter cabinets that provide some stor- boxes, 156 fixed sales desks, 39 auction spaces,
age space. This is where most of the textile, shoe 2 bars, 1 restaurant, and 6 food stalls), also serves
and housewares sellers have moved to. On the the municipal market administration as a kind of
upper and more rearward ramps, rows of walk-in spatial control board to steer the socio-economic
booths sit next to each other, representing proper orientation of the market. While the old open-air
shops that are mostly occupied by antique and market, for instance, had only two food stalls
furniture dealers. On the lowest level, right in catering to both traders and buyers alike, the
the center of the new market hall, one finds the new curated mix of businesses also boosts an
80,000 square feet open area dedicated to the exquisite seafood kiosk and a hip sandwich
auction routines in the morning and taken over shop, the latter proudly announcing that they
by the actual flea market during the day. From the only use buns from the city’s most famous bak-
upper ramps, visitors can look down into this ery, when assembling their signature hot dog. It is
11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle of Informal Marketplaces 171

said that almost all original dealers have moved of November 1995 granted special status to this
from the old to the new location, but there is an disputed territory around the town of Brčko. Its
unmissable change in the market’s character. It is future was to be decided in an international arbi-
not just the spatial setting that has changed but the tration process. It was placed under the auspices
purpose of the market itself. of a special supervisor from the Office of the High
Representative (OHR) of the international com-
munity of states for Bosnia and Herzegovina.
6 Arizona Market: Top-Down Soon afterwards the local checkpoint at the
Appropriation of Survival Arizona Corridor (the code name given to the
Economies north-south link between Bosnia and Croatia by
IFOR/SFOR troops) evolved into an informal
The fourth type of intervention exemplifying the meeting place where cigarettes and agricultural
wide and often contradictory spectrum of interre- products were traded, and coffee was served on
lated spatial and economic integration, which I the roadside. It is said that in 1996 the local
want to address in this chapter, refers to often commander decided to encourage initial
highly elaborated measures seeking to appropri- encounters between members of the different eth-
ate the entrepreneurial energy of informal nic communities by establishing a free-trade
markets. One of the most charged examples of zone, with the aim of consolidating peace.
this strategy is the case of the so-called, Arizona SFOR soldiers levelled several hectares of farm-
Market that had sprung up in post-war Bosnia and land, cleared the area of mines, and supplied
Herzegovina, involving a repeatedly violent building materials. In next to no time, the largest
wholesale privatization of the original informal informal market for goods in southern Europe
markets and their transformation into corporately arose on the side of the road opposite the check-
managed shopping malls. point: with wooden huts, improvised stalls, smug-
Located not far from the north Bosnian town gled goods, and pirate copies of brand-name
of Brčko, the Arizona Market was once one of goods. Textiles, food, electronic products, build-
southeastern Europe’s busiest marketplaces, com- ing materials, cosmetics, car accessories, and CDs
prising 2500 stalls on an area covering forty could all be purchased at favorable prices there,
hectares, receiving three million visitors a year, with the cheapest goods available directly from
and employing directly or indirectly an estimated the lorries that had brought them.
100,000 people. Apart from these statistics, what Decisive to the continued development of the
distinguished the market depended on Arizona Market was the fact that, unlike most
participants’ perspectives and interests, and other informal markets, its development was
these differed considerably. For some, it was a supported by locally stationed armed forces. In
model of a multi-ethnic community, for others it the years that followed, the convergence of eco-
was the largest open-air shopping mall in the nomic activities at the site and the self-
Balkans, while still others experienced it as a organization of this gray trade area were extolled
hell on earth. The differences in perspective as a model for promoting the sustained develop-
depend upon which of the numerous stages and ment of communications and community
transformations of the Arizona Market that one is structures between former wartime enemies
referring to. (Jašarević 2007, 287). The simple market
The strip of land occupied by the present facilities and mobile sales units were soon
Arizona Market is a part of the war zone that supplemented by the first houses, presaging the
was fiercely fought over by Serbian, Croatian, emergence of a self-organized urbanization pro-
and Bosnian Muslim units because of the strate- cess on the site. However, as time went on, the
gic position that it assumed after bars and motels operating in these huts and
Bosnia-Herzegovina left the federal state of houses started to accommodate a form of trade
Yugoslavia in 1991. The Dayton Peace Accords that made it increasingly difficult to sell the
172 H. Mooshammer

success story of peace based on the market econ- cause, the maxim of achieving reconciliation by
omy, at an international level. At the Arizona taking economic measures came dangerously
Market, the real money was made through prosti- close to fomenting an ethnic conflict as a result
tution and human trafficking of women and girls, of what was seen as an arbitrary allocation of
who were being brought in from Eastern Europe. economic options.
According to reports, they were rounded up on The most striking thing about this strategy to
the streets and resold like cattle from one bar regain control over the Arizona Market, which
owner to the next (Haynes 2010). ultimately culminated in the ceremonial opening
On October 26, 2000, the international com- of a new shopping center in the presence of the
munity (OHR, OSCE, UNMIBH, and SFOR) Principal Deputy High Representative, the US
announced a package of measures designed to Ambassador, Donald S. Hays, on November
purge the Arizona Market of such illegal 11, 2004, was the way the international commu-
activities. These measures focused on regulation, nity, which exercised political territorial control,
licensing, and taxation as well as on the planned and an international investor co-operated in
relocation of the market by June 2001 to a new privatizing the public domain of the market. The
site that would offer all the necessary facilities transformation of the informal market into a shop-
and safety features. In February 2001, the super- ping center signaled a critical turning point,
visor ordered the closure of the existing market. revealing the limits of converting between formal
In December of that year, ItalProject, an Italian- and informal systems. The spontaneous evolution
Bosnian-Serbian consortium, won a tender to of a public-urban space in the shape of an infor-
establish and operate a new market. The consor- mal market surrounded by transporters and huts
tium signed a 20-year lease agreement with the was replaced by parking spaces with ticket
district administration that granted it the right to barriers at their entrances. The coming together
retain 100 per cent of rental income from the of diverse cultures was now regulated by fixed
market for a period of 17 years, in return for opening hours and private security guards.
developing the infrastructure of the site. The proj- In only 10 years, the Arizona Market was
ect envisaged investing 120 million euro under transformed from a space of bare survival into a
the supervision of the Eufor (EU) to develop a center of ubiquitous consumption. What had once
modern trade infrastructure on an area initially been a mere border guard outpost became a post-
comprising 650,000 square feet. In a later phase metropolitan territory. Hopes that the Arizona
of development, a complexly structured eco- Market might become a model for a self-
nomic and trade base for the entire southern organized town were dashed when a market
European area was to be established that would arose which had its existence and development
include multiplex cinemas, hotels, casinos, and a far more extensively tied to the presence of the
conference center. international defense force than initially
Italproject offered existing traders the oppor- suggested by the generous gesture to bulldoze a
tunity to rent or buy stalls in module-like rooms. few fields. The UNHCHR attributed the mount-
Resistance by landowners and traders to this total ing crisis surrounding Arizona Market at the turn
takeover was met with compulsory of millennium––evidenced most starkly in the
dispossessions. This response was justified with huge increase in prostitution and trafficking in
the argument that it was in the public interest to women––among other things to the presence of
ensure that the district administration of Brčko over 30,000 peacekeepers in BiH (Rees 1999).
complied with the agreements made with Bosnia was not so much a transit country as a
Italproject. Demonstrations and road blockades destination for women who were victims of traf-
staged to oppose the demolition of the old site ficking. The SFOR troops were not only
were cleared by the police. As most of the customers but allegedly also took a share of the
landowners affected were Croatians who sought profits accrued from smuggling and corruption.
the support of nationalist groups to assert their The solution, based on the model of urban
11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle of Informal Marketplaces 173

renewal developed in the USA in the 1960s. informal marketplaces. How, on the one hand, do
(In this model a district was declared a problem expansive capital interests increasingly target
area and thus large-scale expropriation in the economies of poverty as frontiers of investment
name of the public interest was permitted.) It and accumulation (Roy 2010; Hart 2012)? How,
was fostered by the transformation of the legal on the other, does the spreading of novel entrepre-
system in the Brčko district with the help of legal neurial cultures (P2P marketplaces, social entre-
advisers financed by USAID (US Agency for preneurship, gig economy, new intimate
International Development). economy, among others) animate a changing cli-
Another decade down the road, after the cele- mate of development policies both in contempo-
brated opening of its redevelopment, the Arizona rary urban economies in the Global North, as well
Market seems to have become stuck in a similar as in top-tier emerging economies in the Global
state of limbo as the whole of Bosnia South (Mörtenböck et al. 2015). Only by embrac-
Herzegovina. Having been on the frontline of ing such broad perspectives can we truly advance
conflicts over global spheres of influence, the our understanding of how informal and formal
deadlock of the post-Dayton territorial divisions economic practices come to blend into new
has left much of the country side-lined and repeat- kinds of hybrid economic governance (Strazzari
edly falling behind the development of its and Kamphuis 2012; Sassen 2014).
neighbors. Virtually none of the plans announced
for the creation of a trans-regional trade and com-
merce hub have materialized. The site of the 7 Conclusion
original Arizona Market (Arizona 1), where
hundreds of wooden huts once formed a tarpaulin Informal markets have become a vital part of
and metal-roofed bazaar, still resembles nothing cities around the world. From the new mega-cities
more than a few levelled-off fallow fields. A few of the Global South to the old centers of political
warehouses have been added at the rear of the and economic power, they form complex sites of
so-called Arizona 2, a hybrid piece of prototypical negotiation between multiple political demands,
turbo architecture that fueled speculation about a social actors, and environmental constraints.
consolidated and urbanized nucleus of trade in a Spurred by deregulation and accelerating global
region marred by conflict and deregulation, and flows, they are, in many instances, tolerated as
that is now squeezed between the old and the new shock-absorbers of widening social divisions.
site of the market. The Trade City of China build- Yet, whenever these markets show signs of
ing occupying the north-eastern section of the establishing realms of their own, more often
Arizona Market’s central roundabout, which was than not, official rhetoric has painted them as a
supposed to play a major role in establishing threat to social and economic order, a response by
Brčko as a key hub in the distribution of imports government-directed demolition or relocation
from China to wholesalers and retailers, stands often follows.
uncompleted, its concrete lions looking on as the However, since the 2007–08 global financial
steel frame slowly rusts away. crisis which has intensified the quest for alterna-
What the diverse outcomes of these cases tive approaches toward triggering innovation and
highlight is the continuous need for open debates economic growth, we are also seeing increased
around the form and direction of how economic interest across the political spectrum in accessing
informality should intersect with local the potential of the informal economy by
environments, national policies, and suprana- integrating its entrepreneurial energies, assets,
tional actors, especially for discussions about and networks into wider economic circuits.
how this process is to be managed and controlled, Attesting to this growing interest, the develop-
and by whom. These discussions will have to ment of many informal markets, including those
consider key shifts in global economic conduct discussed above, has been characterized by a
and their impact on the current transformation of variety of attempts at integration. Besides
174 H. Mooshammer

juridical measures (trade licenses, rights of use, What these developments point to is that the
among others), financial measures (access to growing interaction between the formal and infor-
credit, poverty alleviation, for example), and mal spheres has a transformative effect on both,
organizational measures (access to piped water, leading to a formalization of the informal sector
electricity supply, and agreements with informal and an informalization of the formal economy.
workers’ unions, among others) such attempts The ongoing spatial transformation of informal
often revolve around spatial organization. The markets is not only indicative of these macro-
range of spatial interventions has thus extended economic changes. Due to their proliferation,
from the forced removal and relocation of infor- informal markets also play an instrumental role
mal markets to urban fringes or the dispersal of in the generation of new economic climates, in
market activities into other neighborhoods. Inter- some cases, signifying generative activity
vention ranges in measures of active support, through alternative knowledge and use of city
which in turn can cover a broad spectrum from services; land and livelihood strategies (Evers
the simple demarcation of dedicated areas, which and Seale 2015), and, in others, an expansion of
do not interfere with formal business, to the allo- the market economy’s reach into new territories,
cation of new trading spaces in newly erected particularly within the framework of markets run
permanent market halls, where improved by the poor in developing countries (Roy 2010).
facilities are provided on a fee-for-service basis Regarding this, informal markets are important
(Mörtenböck et al. 2015). It is worth noting here sites of negotiation where new forms of interac-
that street vendors, even though they are the ones tion (shaped by technological and organizational
most affected by the regulation and management changes) are explored between state and non-state
of informal trade, are rarely considered in actors pursuing different political and economic
decision-making processes (Bhowmik 2005). interests (Guha-Khasanobis et al. 2006; Altman
Many integration projects are still governed by 2008).
an authoritative, paternalistic concept of
realigning the workings of informal economic
activities and making them fully compliant with
References
the requirements of the formal economy (Roever
2006; Chen 2007). Altman, M. (2008). Formal-informal economy linkages,
These dynamics need to be viewed against the employment growth and development initiative.
background of globalization which, in conjunc- Pretoria: Human Sciences Research Council.
tion with the recent economic crisis and emerging Bhowmik, S. K. (2005). Street vendors in Asia. Economic
and Political Weekly, 40(22), 2256–2264.
forms of self-organized, peer-to-peer economies, Chen, M. A. (2007). Rethinking the informal economy:
has substantially altered the relationship between Linkages with the formal economy and the formal
the formal and informal sector, both conceptually regulatory environment. DESA working paper no. 46.
and practically (Mörtenböck and Mooshammer Easterling, K. (2014). Extrastatecraft: The power of infra-
structure space. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
2019). This change has been reflected in a revised Evers, C., & Seale, K. (Eds.). (2015). Informal urban
understanding of the informal economy as an street markets. London: Routledge.
alternative, multi-faceted mode of economic gov- Feige, E. (1990). Defining and estimating underground
ernance outside state regulation (Meagher 2013). and informal economies: The new institutional eco-
nomics approach. World Development, 18(7),
It is also reflected in the recent rise of self- 989–1002.
employment and increasing state support for Grzymala-Busse, A. (2010). The best laid plans: The
start-ups, micro-businesses, social entrepreneur- impact of informal rules on formal institutions in tran-
ship, and peer-to-peer industries in countries of sitional regimes. Studies in Comparative International
Development, 45(3), 311–333.
the Global North (2012 JOBS Act in the USA) as Guha-Khasanobis, B., et al. (Eds.). (2006). Linking the
well as the Global South (micro-lending, formal and informal economy: Concepts and policies.
crowdfunding). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
11 Right to the City, Right to the Market: The Global Struggle of Informal Marketplaces 175

Hart, K. (1973). Informal income opportunities and urban Mörtenböck, P., & Mooshammer, H. (2019). The art of
employment in Ghana. The Journal of Modern African crafting formal-informal linkages. In E. Dürr &
Studies, 11(1), 61–89. J. Müller (Eds.), The popular economy in Urban
Haynes, D. F. (2010). Lessons from Bosnia’s Arizona Latin America: Informality, materiality, and gender
market: harm to women in a neoliberalized postconflict in commerce. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.
reconstruction process. University of Pennsylvania Nadvi, K. (2004). Globalisation and poverty: How can
Law Review, 158, 1779–1829. global value chain research inform the policy debate?
Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal institutions IDS Bulletin, 35(1), 20–30.
and comparative politics: A research agenda. Ong, A. (2006). Neoliberalism as exception. Durham:
Perspectives on Politics, 2(04), 725–740. Duke University Press.
Humphrey, C., & Skvirskaja, V. (Eds.). (2012). Post-Cos- Perry, G. E., et al. (Eds.). (2007). Informality: Exit and
mopolitan cities. New York: Berghahn Books. exclusion. Latin American and Caribbean studies.
ILO (International Labour Organization). (2018). Women Washington, DC: World Bank.
and men in the informal economy: A statistical picture Rees, M. (1999). Markets, migration and forced prostitu-
(3rd ed.). Geneva: ILO. tion. Relief and Rehabilitation Network Newsletter, 14,
Jašarević, L. (2007). Everyday work: Subsistence econ- 2–3.
omy, social belonging and moralities of exchange at a Ribeiro, G. L. (2006). Economic globalization from
Bosnian (Black) Market. In X. Bougarel et al. (Eds.), below. Etnográfica, 10(2), 233–249.
The New Bosnian Mosaic. London: Ashgate. Roever, S. (2006). Street trade in Latin America: Demo-
Latour, B. (2005). Reassembling the social: An introduc- graphic trends, legal issues, and vending
tion to actor-network-theory. Oxford: Oxford Univer- organizations in six cities. WIEGO urban policies
sity Press. programe, 6 October 2006.
Linehan, D. (2007). Re-ordering the urban Archipelago: Roy, A. (2005). Urban informality: Toward an epistemol-
Kenya vision 2030, street trade and the battle for ogy of planning. Journal of the American Planning
Nairobi City Centre. Aurora Geography Journal, 1, Association, 71(2), 147–158.
21–37. Roy, A. (2010). Poverty Capital: Microfinance and the
Lund, F., & Skinner, C. (2004). Integrating the informal Making of Development. London: Routledge.
economy in urban planning and governance. Interna- Sassen, S. (2014). Expulsions: Brutality and complexity in
tional Development Planning Review, 26(4), 413–465. the global economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer-
McFarlane, C. (2012). Rethinking informality: Politics, sity Press.
crisis, and the city. Planning Theory & Practice, 13 Simone, A. M. (2010). City life from Jakarta to Dakar:
(1), 89–108. Movements at the crossroads. London and New York:
Meagher, K. (2013). Unlocking the informal economy. A Routledge.
literature review on linkages between formal and Spivak, G. C. (2004). Righting wrongs. The South Atlantic
informal economies in developing countries. WIEGO Quarterly, 103(2–3), 523–581.
working paper no. 27. Strazzari, F., & Kamphuis, B. (2012). Hybrid economies
Morén-Alegret, R., et al. (2016). Inter-group perceptions and statebuilding: On the resilience of the extralegal.
and representations in two Barcelona neighborhoods: Global Governance: A Review of Multilateralism and
Poble sec and Sagrada Família compared. In F. Pastore International Organizations, 18(1), 57–72.
& I. Ponzo (Eds.), Inter-group relations and migrant Wojkowska, E. (2006). Doing justice: How informal jus-
integration in European cities: Changing tice systems can contribute. Oslo: United Nations
neighborhoods, IMISCOE research series. Heidelberg: Development Programme.
Springer.
Mörtenböck, P., & Mooshammer, H. (2012). Informal
market worlds: Instruments of change. Scapegoat
Journal Architecture, Landscape, Political Economy, Internet References
04, 203–220.
Mörtenböck, P., & Mooshammer, H. (Eds.). (2015). Infor-
mal market worlds: The architecture of economic USTR (Office of the United States Trade Representative).
pressure––ATLAS. Rotterdam: nai010 Publishers. (2019). Special 301 report. April 2019. https://ustr.
Mörtenböck, P., et al. (Eds.). (2015). Informal market gov/sites/default/files/2019_Special_301_Report.pdf
worlds: The architecture of economic pressure–– [2020.01.01].
READER. Rotterdam: nai010 Publishers. Hart, K. (2012). The informalization of the world econ-
Mörtenböck, P., & Mooshammer, H. (2016). From urban omy. Keynote lecture for the 24th conference of the
talent to commodity city: Marketplaces in the informal societa’ Italiana di Economia Pubblica, Pavia, 24–-
economy. In J. Darling & H. F. Wilson (Eds.), Encoun- 25 September 2012. http://thememorybank.co.uk/
tering the city: Urban encounters from Accra to 2012/10/17/the-informalization-of-the-world-econ
New York. London: Routledge. omy/ [2020.01.02].
176 H. Mooshammer

Helge Mooshammer is an architect and cultural theorist


Peter and Helge Mooshammer, eds. 2021. Platform
based at Goldsmiths, University of London, and TU Wien. Urbanism. Rotterdam: nai010 Publishers. Mörtenböck,
He has led a range of international research projects Peter and Helge Mooshammer, eds. 2020. Data Publics:
around questions of post-capitalist economies and urban Public Plurality in an Era of Data Determinacy. London:
informality. He is one of the founding directors of the Routledge. Mörtenböck, Peter and Helge Mooshammer,
Centre for Global Architecture, an interdisciplinary initia- 2016. Visual Cultures as Opportunity. Berlin: Sternberg
tive established to study the planetary changes affecting Press. Mörtenböck, Peter, Helge Mooshammer, Teddy
spatial production today. Cruz, and Fonna Forman, eds. 2005. Informal Market
Research topics: Informal markets, social transformation, Worlds: The Architecture of Economic Pressure, ATLAS
urban speculation, architecture of finance, informalization & READER. Rotterdam: nai010 Publishers.
of urban economies. Recent publications: Mörtenböck,
Economic Change from an Institutional
Perspective 12
Sonja Opper

In theory, the causal relation between institutions suddenly seemed malleable by reshaping the
and economic change is straightforward (North institutional structure.
and Thomas 1973; North and Weingast 1989; Coincidentally, the collapse of the Soviet
North 1990). Institutions, which are the humanly Union and the transition of Central and Eastern
devised incentives and constraints organizing Europe, China, and Vietnam offered the much-
social and economic life (North 1990), shape needed opportunity to put institution building to a
individual behavior and thereby influence the large-scale practical test. In 1996, the World
direction of economic change. Whether Bank’s annual World Development Report,
economies grow, stagnate, or decline is to a con- published under the roadmap title, From Plan to
siderable extent explained by the institutional Market, mirrors the initial enthusiasm of the early
structure organizing and guiding economic and mid-1990s. Yet twenty years later, its 2017
action. The logic is simple and compelling. report, Governance and the Law, ponders why
Institutions that encourage and reward productive “policies that should be effective in generating
entrepreneurship lead to growth and economic positive development outcomes are often not
development, whereas, institutions that reward adopted, are poorly implemented, or end up
unproductive activities, such as rent-seeking and backfiring over time”, and calls for rethinking
corruption, will undermine rather than increase “the process by which state and non-state actors
economic growth (Baumol 1990). interact to design and implement policies” (World
In the heyday of new institutionalism, when Bank 2017, 2).
Ronald Coase (in 1991) and Douglass North I have three goals in this chapter. First, I will
(in 1993) in short sequence, received the Nobel briefly summarize some of the unforeseen
Prize in Economics, getting the institutions right challenges to institution building for economic
became the new mantra in development and eco- growth. Second, on a more positive note, I will
nomic policy. With neoclassical growth theory highlight unexpected development outcomes: the
struggling to explain persistent poverty and emergence of bottom-up institutional changes,
inequality despite massive investments in aid, and the development and viability of second-
technology, and human capital, new institutional- best institutions. Both developments rely on pri-
ism offered a new perspective. Human behavior vate actors rather than state actors. Third, I will
highlight recent work exploring how social con-
text, networks, and local culture influence these
S. Opper (*)
institutional transitions.
Department of Management and Technology, Bocconi
University, Milan, Italy
e-mail: sonja.opper@unibocconi.it

# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 177


A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_12
178 S. Opper

1 Limits of Institution Building differences in historical, legal, and structural


starting conditions, and domestic stakeholder
In preparing large-scale reforms across former conflicts deepened some of the implementation
planned economies, academic and political dis- problems (World Bank 1996).
course largely agreed on the role of the state as the More importantly, the emergence and proac-
central arbiter of change. The standard prescrip- tive creation of market institutions was simply not
tion, according to the Washington Consensus, well understood. Much of the early work of
combined market liberalization, privatization, studying the evolution of modern economic
and stabilization policies (World Bank 1996). If institutions had focused on the limitation of sov-
consistently implemented and predictably ereign power, the introduction of formal laws,
maintained, this reform triad should reduce trans- and third party enforcement, as central
action costs to create the much-needed individual prerequisites of the development of modern
incentives for private investments. Ultimately, it economies (North and Thomas 1973; North and
would turn former planned economies into Weingast 1989; North 1990). Systematic research
thriving market economies. There was less agree- into the emergence of institutions and institu-
ment on reform sequencing and timing. One tional change intensified only around the turn of
option was to implement as many market the century, when the initial enthusiasm for insti-
institutions as possible in a short timespan (i.e., tution building ebbed (Greif and Laitin 2004;
shock therapy, as exemplified by Poland’s reform North 2005; Greif 2006).1
program; see Sachs and Woo 1994). The other Historic pathways toward developing anony-
option was to initiate gradual reforms, enabling mous markets, economies of scale, and long-
economic and political actors to test and explore distance trade bear little resemblance to the
appropriate institutions (i.e., gradualism, often realities of institutional change of the late twenti-
associated with China’s evolutionary reform eth and early twenty-first centuries. Historically,
policies; see Murrell 1995). formal institutions have developed organically,
As usual, getting the institutions right proved building on emergent business practices, local
to be more complex and costly than anticipated. norms, and culture. In this process, formal laws
Most reforms were located somewhere on the typically emerged in response to shifting local
continuum between shock therapy and gradual- demands. Acemoglu et al. (2005) describe how
ism. It is true that new laws and regulations can be the growth of Atlantic trade, after 1500,
modeled after international best practices, hence empowered merchant groups across Europe to
the illusion that fast results are possible. How- demand better property rights. Similarly,
ever, being able to identify the key incentives and England’s Glorious Revolution in 1688, typically
constraints that have fostered growth and eco- interpreted as the beginning of codified property
nomic change in well-developed market protection and the restraint of state power (North
economies (e.g., Keefer and Knack 1997; Hall and Weingast 1989) followed, rather than pre-
and Jones 1999; Rodrik et al. 2004) is not the ceded, increasing de facto security of property
same as understanding how to establish effective and fiscal income from 1600 on (Clark 1996).
private property rights protection and governance Institutions were formalized once there was suffi-
mechanisms. Negative short-term effects cient public support to turn standard practice into
followed initial liberalization policies, including a formal legal code, protected and enforced by the
sharp drops in production, high unemployment sovereign. Of course, this does not imply that “the
rates, and hyperinflation. These areas of friction beliefs and institutions that evolve through time
were not only attributable to unavoidable adjust- will produce economic growth” (North 1994,
ment processes of the real and monetary sector.
Country specifics such as geography (e.g., coastal 1
For a recent review of studies documenting economic
access or proximity to high-growth countries), and institutional change through history, see
Hillmann (2013).
12 Economic Change from an Institutional Perspective 179

363). Many countries developed inefficient between 1978 and 1995) and a reduction in infant
institutions. Notwithstanding, history supports mortality by 11.1% (World Bank 1996). This is
Axelrod’s (1986) notion that laws are typically not evidence that slow, moderate reforms are
preceded by respective behavioral norms. more effective. It is, however, a useful reminder
Today’s transition and reform countries face to move beyond exploring state action and to
an entirely different task. They seek to blend incorporate complementary elements into
efficiency-enhancing formal institutions with analyses of institutional change and economic
established, often contradictory, local norms, development.
customs, and traditions. The risk of institutional
mismatches is high. New labor laws may not fit
the existing social security system; new banking 2 Lessons from Unlikely Winners
regulations conflict with traditional procedures of
money lending; and property reforms assume the A closer look at reforms in these unexpectedly
existence of established markets for land and real successful reform countries is informative. This
estate as well as related legal services. The situa- section will focus on two elements that have
tion resembles institutional transfers of the eigh- facilitated reforms in a way that textbook knowl-
teenth and nineteenth centuries, when colonizers edge could not have predicted: bottom-up institu-
transplanted laws and regulations into alien insti- tional reforms, as opposed to state-orchestrated
tutional systems. Berkowitz et al. (2003) show top-down reforms, and the temporary utility of
that legal transplants do not carry the risk of second-best institutions.
short-term friction only at the implementation
stage. The nature of the transplant process also
has long-term ramifications. Countries that were 2.1 Institutional Change from Below
either familiar with basic principles of the
imported law or in a position to adjust foreign It seemed obvious, that institutional change must
legal codes to be in line with local norms and be orchestrated in a top-down manner, with
common practice developed more effective legal politicians and state representatives passing laws
institutions and higher standards of legality than and regulations. However, the dynamic develop-
countries that simply imported foreign laws. ment of institutions in many emerging economies
In 1996, the World Bank’s annual report demonstrates that grassroots activities can play an
presented a striking analysis. It compared important role in shaping and redefining
twenty-eight transition economies across Europe institutions from within the system. Successful
and Asia in terms of their progress in economic local experiments, originally initiated to serve
liberalization, privatization, and institutional and community needs, attracted imitators that helped
social policy reforms (including reforms of laws spread novel institutions and organizational forms
and legal institutions). The countries that to neighboring communities and those further
registered the greatest progress showed only afield. Many of these developments started out
modest growth rates. In contrast, China and as illegal or semi legal local practices. Legaliza-
Vietnam, the least ambitious countries in terms tion followed, once institutional innovations dif-
of institutional reforms, recorded the highest GDP fused and gained sufficient public support to push
growth rates during the late 1980s and governments to acknowledge their legitimacy.
mid-1990s. It is easy to disregard the data by This often involved extending and revising
pointing to the dramatically lower development reigning political ideologies and reform goals. In
level in East Asia at the outset of reforms. Yet effect, these developments replicated the emer-
China and Vietnam also outperformed most tran- gence of political and economic institutions in
sition economies in terms of monetary stability, the West.
and scored high in terms of increasing life expec- The vital contributions made by grassroots
tancy, (with an increase of 2.1 years in China innovations tend to be underestimated. Early
180 S. Opper

processes of institutional emergence are typically increase following a shift to private production
overlooked in official records. They only become quickly encouraged richer communities to follow
visible once formal policy statements legitimate suit (Dikötter 2016). Bai and Kung’s (2014)
their existence. These bottom-up activities are by quantitative analysis confirms Dikötter’s account
no means marginal. The Hungarian historian, that a nationwide variation in decollectivization
Istvan Rév (1987, 342) claimed that, “from a efforts was largely explained by the localities’
closer look, all the important and long-lasting dependence on state support and their experience
economic and social reforms in all the Central of poverty during the Great Leap Forward.
European countries appear as nothing but the Localities that had suffered more during the
legalization of already existing illegal and semi Great Leap Forward were faster to return to fam-
legal practices. What seems to be the work of the ily farming and eager to abandon the institutional
professional reformers . . . is in fact the conse- rules of collectivism. When the central govern-
quence of continuous atomized resistance.” ment finally endorsed these spontaneous land
China’s reforms offer numerous examples of relocations in 1982–83 and officially dissolved
how institutional entrepreneurship at the grass- China’s people’s communes, de facto decollecti-
roots level influenced national-level policy vization was moving forward and, in some
reforms. The abandonment of the people’s com- provinces, had even been completed (Kelliher
mune system is a good example. Though often 1992; Dikötter 2016).
heralded as an ingenious political decision to start The social-movement-like spread of land relo-
liberalization policies in the countryside, agricul- cation had consequences reaching far beyond the
tural land reforms emerged from a bottom-up agricultural sector. With productivity unleashed,
social movement (Kelliher 1992; Zhou 1996). surplus labor was freed from agricultural tasks
Early efforts to silently reprivatize collective pro- and sought more productive non-agricultural
duction date back to the early 1950s (Zhou 1996) employment. By marketing their produce in free
and gained momentum during the Cultural Revo- markets, peasants were able to accumulate mod-
lution (1966–76), when private actors, with either est savings, which they invested in sideline pro-
active local state support or silent acquiescence, duction. Initially, these manufacturing activities
brought increasing shares of land under house- served local agricultural needs and household
hold production (Kelliher 1992; Zhou 1996; consumption. However, with consumer goods in
Dikötter 2016). Well into the second half of the short supply, rural entrepreneurs started to cater to
Cultural Revolution, these local episodes of col- urban demand in nearby metropolitan regions.
lective action were still short-lived and repeatedly Businesses quickly outgrew the officially
suppressed as capitalist reactionary behavior. approved size of seven salaried workers. Thriving
However, after Lin Biao’s death in 1971, a weak- underground factories developed long before the
ened party-state could no longer control rural state acknowledged private forms of industrial
resistance. The Cultural Revolution created production. Private enterprise once again pushed
millions of enemies, ready to take their fate into the boundaries of what was politically and ideo-
their own hands. Disillusioned local party logically desirable.
representatives and government officials were Nee and Opper (2012) offer a detailed account
also ready to replace ideological vision with prag- of the development of China’s emergent private
matism and production goals. Local officials took firm economy. Although standard institutions
the lead in redistributing land from collective to such as the effective protection of private prop-
private production. Some of these transfers were erty rights were not in place, while the state
conducted openly, while others maintained the continued to prioritize state-owned and state-
fiction of collective production by turning over controlled public firms throughout the first
certain production shares to local officials. While decades of economic reforms, more than five
poor localities were the first to experiment with million private firms had registered by the time
various land reforms, the rapid productivity the government finally enacted its first Private
12 Economic Change from an Institutional Perspective 181

Property Rights Law in 2007 (China Statistical the risk of experimenting with novel, partly ille-
Bureau 2008). The bottom-up movement of insti- gal, but certainly illegitimate institutional
tutional and organizational change followed a arrangements. Second, with a growing number
simple pattern (Nee and Opper 2012; see specifi- of innovators, positive network externalities
cally Chaps. 2 and 4). First, the gradual liberal- from cooperation norms lower the institutional
ization opened up profitmaking opportunities switching costs for imitators, drawing in more
outside the socialist production system, which risk-averse followers. Third, the state’s interest
were large enough to attract entrepreneurial talent in maintaining and defending the institutional
and start-up investments. Once successful, status quo must be sufficiently weak, so that the
imitators followed and mimicked pioneering innovators’ probability of being penalized for
entrepreneurs, building local clusters of sellers semi legal or illegal activities is sufficiently small.
and buyers organized around specific industries Both China’s land reforms and the rise of a
and supply chains. As clusters developed and private firm economy fit this account. While the
cooperation intensified, commonly accepted busi- first condition was in place all along, the second
ness norms emerged that substituted the lack of and the third were largely absent or only tempo-
formal institutions and property rights protection, rarily present during the pre-reform period. It was
thereby drawing in even more followers. Once a only at the end of the Cultural Revolution that the
critical movement was reached, local and national personal risk of participating in private land
policymakers had little choice but to adjust redistribution declined and local governments
national rules and regulations. were no longer interested in defending and
China is not unique. The rise of a new maintaining the old institutional order (Dikötter
entrepreneurial class followed a similar pattern 2016). The economic decline of people’s
in Vietnam. As soon as markets were liberalized, communes during the Great Leap Forward and
entrepreneurs started their own businesses while the Cultural Revolution had made it clear that the
formal protection of private property rights was collective production system impeded the much-
either absent or ineffective (McMillan and Wood- needed increase in agricultural production. Local
ruff 1999). Neither of these examples suggests governments took an acquiescent, if not actively
that bottom-up institutional reforms happen supportive, role in fostering local economic
whenever there is room for efficiency gains. If growth. The collective production system of
this were the case, poverty would be less persis- people’s communes had finally become self-
tent. The central point is that even large-scale undermining (Greif 2006).
institutional changes, such as the return to family Once labor migrated from agricultural to
farming or the shift to private manufacturing, do non-agricultural production, the same develop-
not require top-down initiatives. It is often ment of a private firm economy gained momen-
through searching for better solutions at grass- tum (for details, see Nee and Opper 2012). First,
roots level, through local experimentation, and the draw of changing careers was high, as agri-
through competition between alternative cultural household income remained low and
solutions that viable institutional arrangements alternative employment channels were unavail-
are identified. able, or restricted due to the country’s strict
An important question for future research is policies regulating rural to urban migration.
when to expect powerful reforms from the general Starting a small-scale business—whether legally
population rather than the state. In other words, protected or not—offered an attractive route to
when do private actors cooperate to carry out increase household income. Second, the proxim-
institutional innovations, despite collective action ity of like-minded actors made production outside
problems (Olson 1965)? Three factors deserve the planned economy possible. Third, sanctions
attention (Nee and Opper 2012, 28 ff.; see also of capitalist activities were moderate, as local
DellaPosta et al. 2017). First, expected individual government developed an active interest in new
utility gains must be substantial in order to accept business activities, to generate fiscal income and
182 S. Opper

local employment channels. Government officials arrangements (Rodrik 2008), responding to an


also found new rent-seeking opportunities. By environment, blending institutions of the old and
offering entrepreneurs protection and access to new systems. A good example is China’s post-
politically controlled resources such as licenses, reform, rural industrialization, which relied
land lease rights, capital, and scarce raw heavily on the formation of so-called township-
materials, local bureaucrats became part of the village enterprises (TVEs). Formally, these were
entrepreneurial success story (see Krug and collective firms. Some portion of these were actu-
Hendrischke 2008 on coordination between ally owned and managed by local townships or
local firms and government). It is consistent villages (Walder 1995; Peng 2001). Another sub-
with this account that China’s private firm econ- stantial share of these firms were de facto private
omy first emerged in rural areas and in relatively firms, called red-hat firms, which sought to
poor communities. secure formal protection from political discrimi-
nation by being officially registered and viewed
as publicly owned. One strategy for private firms
2.2 A Case for Second-Best Solutions was to affiliate with a collective firm and to use its
formal registration, stationery, and address to sig-
A central feature of gradual reforms is the tempo- nal a collective identity, while internally operating
rary co-existence of old and new institutions. One as a private firm (Kelliher 1992; Zhou 1996,
institutional structure does not replace another, Chap. 5).
but new institutional elements are incorporated Following standard predictions of property
while established institutions are still in place. rights theory (Demsetz 1967), TVEs should
Such hybrid institutional environments pose spe- have failed, given their non-exclusive property
cific challenges. A closer look at China’s econ- rights (Walder 1995; Peng 2001). Whether firms
omy is instructive (see Naughton 2007): the were run as true collective firms or as red-hat
government allowed entrepreneurs to register pri- firms, local officials could interfere in manage-
vate, rural firms as early as 1987; yet formal ment decisions, prioritize non-economic goals,
private property protection was not in place until and extract rents for either public use or personal
2007. Product markets were liberalized, but capi- gain. With no personal investments by managers
tal, land, and urban labor markets remained under or local officials, overconsumption, underinvest-
tight state control. Labor contracts were ment, and managerial slack should have followed.
introduced as early as 1986, but a corresponding Yet the TVEs of the 1980s and 1990s grew rap-
Labor Contract Law covering rural and urban idly and became the main provider of non-state
residents was not introduced until 2008. State- employment in rural China. Between 1978 and
owned banks were turned into commercial 2005 total employment increased from 28.3 mil-
banks as early as 1986, but the state held majority lion to 142.8 million employees in rural China
shares to maintain direct control over large parts (China Statistical Bureau 2006).
of the credit market. The state’s trade monopoly How could TVEs become a major driver of
was abandoned, but contract and competition economic change and development? A number of
laws were not in place until 1999 and 2008, factors matter. First, TVEs were producing for
respectively. Stock markets were introduced in private markets and operated outside the state’s
the early 1990s, but remained a vehicle for planning system. This allowed local firms to flex-
incorporating state-owned firms, with the major- ibly produce and market consumer goods in
ity of shares held by the state. A small and response to shifting demand. TVEs also benefited
medium enterprise board was not in place from an abundant pool of cheap and unskilled
until 2004. labor, a resource freed by China’s return to house-
What looked like probable failure turned out to hold farming. While state-owned enterprises were
be an economic success. Why? The answer lies in still burdened by lifelong employment guarantees
the emergence of second-best institutional and social costs, TVEs could rely on local
12 Economic Change from an Institutional Perspective 183

contract labor recruited outside the country’s privatization and reorganization of TVEs was
labor allocation system. In short, TVEs were certainly costly. Yet as Xu et al. (2014) convinc-
able to capitalize on the country’s partly reformed ingly argue, TVEs served as a critical transitional
economic system. organizational form in the shift from public forms
The flexibility to participate in market of production to private production. As public
exchange, however, would not have been suffi- firms were already established during the
cient to be economically successful. Walder pre-reform period, TVEs enjoyed sufficient iden-
(1995) points out that the crucial institutional tity overlap with the old system of state-owned
innovation was the hardening of budget enterprise production to be perceived as legiti-
constraints of China’s local governments. With mate. Legitimized as part of the establishment,
fiscal decentralization in place, local governments TVEs participated in increasingly liberalized
no longer received negotiable budget markets, pursued profits, and used contract
appropriations from superior government levels labor. Though TVEs were often private firms in
and thus, relied on local fiscal revenues. Unlike disguise, or operated as if they were private, the
officials in Hungarian collectives or cadres of the displayed public nature conferred sufficient legit-
commune and brigade enterprises of the Maoist imacy to experiment with new business practices,
era, local officials became keenly interested in in an increasingly market-oriented environment.
investing in profitable firms and running viable By providing on-site rural employment for more
industrial enterprises. Of course, local officials than 100 million underemployed farmworkers,
still used TVEs for rent-seeking activities and TVEs helped reduce rural poverty and rural-
personal gain. TVEs also still benefited from urban migration, and they helped develop and
softer budget constraints than private enterprises. urbanize China’s countryside. Employees
Cross-subsidization between community- received basic training, learned manufacturing
operated TVEs granted some financial flexibility, skills, and were often able to save enough to
allowing communities to bail out, at least short start their own small-scale businesses. In brief,
term, weaker enterprises experiencing liquidity TVEs were able to provide venues for employ-
constraints. The crucial point is that there was a ment and large-scale income generation during a
financial limit to managerial slack and misman- time when private investors and privately run
agement (Peng 2001). In the medium and long enterprises still lacked formal approval from
run, local officials could not afford to operate state and private audiences. It is highly unlikely
TVEs under soft budget constraints, which, that private investors, lacking status and legiti-
according to Kornai (1992), was the ultimate macy could have operated at a comparable scale
cause of the failure of the Hungarian experiment in the early years of China’s gradual transition.
with collective firms. In this way, TVEs were Xu et al. also reason that the gradual transition
often able to outperform the privileged state- toward private production would not have been
owned enterprises (Peng 2001). The decline of successful without the TVE as a transitional orga-
TVEs only began once private firms formally nization helping to bridge the contradictory
competed on a level playing field, as signaled by ideologies of the old socialist and new market
the 2004 Constitutional Amendment and the 2007 systems (2014, 519). Their empirical evidence
enactment of the country’s first Property Rights from a multi-population study of state-owned
Law. Interest in collective forms of production collective and private firms operating between
declined, especially in light of the higher produc- 1998 and 2006 supports their claim. As the den-
tivity of private forms of production (Jin and Qian sity of collective firms increases, communities
1998). experience decreasing exit rates of private firms.
Was the TVE a necessary detour? TVEs were Further evidence also suggests that private firms
clearly a second-best institution. Would the will eventually replace TVEs as a transitional
immediate shift to private production have been form. The higher the community density of pri-
more cost-efficient? One could think so. The vate firms, the higher the exit rate of TVEs.
184 S. Opper

Second-best solutions, such as the rise of the 615) notes, “it is striking that institutional change
TVE as a transitional form of production are is much less understood . . . as stemming from the
unlikely to fit different institutional environments force of other social structures, (i.e., social
and cultural contexts. Without the country’s new networks or cognitive frames) and their impact
fiscal revenue system, TVEs would have faced a on the power of actors interested in the preserva-
similar fate to collective firms in pre-reform tion of existing institutional rules or their
Hungary and China. What the example change.” Here the focus will be on the structure
demonstrates, however, is that best-practice of social networks and local culture as important
institutions are not required to induce economic factors in shaping cognitive frames and belief
change. Moreover, second-best institutions may systems. Social networks and local culture are
offer appropriate, feasible, and often transitional somewhat mutually interdependent, but follow-
alternatives that foster further institutional ing standard practice in the related literature, I
changes. A question for governments and will offer brief individual accounts.
practitioners is how to identify and incentivize
the development of second-best solutions (see
also Rodrik 2008). China’s example highlights 3.1 Social Networks
the role of community competition and
decentralized authority in fostering institutional Social networks matter for economic growth and
reforms and experiments. It is also likely that development. In closed networks, in which most
the government’s evolutionary approach, contacts are mutually connected with one another,
stretching reforms over multiple decades, has bad business behavior is likely to be noticed and
inadvertently given private actors and lower- sanctioned by others, so that the risk of trusting
level government officials more leeway to partic- others declines and in-group cooperation appears
ipate in crafting the new business environment less risky (Coleman 1988, 1990). Open networks,
than initially intended. in contrast, include bridge ties that connect across
social clusters. They lack high in-group trust but
have the advantage of providing quick access to
3 Social Context Matters new information and ideas, resources, and busi-
ness opportunities. While both network styles
Though the above examples of bottom-up institu- have advantages, individuals embedded in open
tional innovation and emergence of second-best networks tend to perform better and are more
institutions are encouraging, both are context creative and innovative (Burt 2005; see Burt
dependent. Many economies have never et al. 2013). This is a general observation applica-
witnessed comparable forms of dynamic institu- ble across advanced and transition economies in
tional change leading to robust economic growth. the West and East (for an overview, see Burt
As with best-practice institutions, the rise of alter- 2019). The relative importance of social
native forms of governance is context specific. networks, especially those involving state actors,
Therefore, it is useful to explore which conditions may be even higher in dynamic environments
have enabled or even accelerated the type of undergoing institutional change, since social
transformations just described. I will not attempt networks can secure access to government-
a comprehensive account of potential contingen- controlled resources and substitute for various
cies. I will intentionally leave aside the often- safeguard mechanisms, typically provided by for-
discussed role of political systems, forms of mal institutions (Peng and Luo 2000; Nee and
state governance, and military power. These Opper 2012, Chap. 9).
pose obvious constraints on private actor However, social networks provide not only
activities. Instead, I will focus on social contin- resource and information access but also the
gencies, which only recently entered the analysis social fabric to organize institutional innovation
of institutional change. In fact, as Beckert (2010b, (Peng 2004; Nee and Opper 2012). Without
12 Economic Change from an Institutional Perspective 185

social support from like-minded actors, institu- in line with their expanding needs for resources,
tional entrepreneurs would not be able to break specialized skills, and bureaucratic and political
away from commonly accepted forms of business support. Both qualitative studies mention network
conduct to organize economic activities, openness and a noticeable network churn as
bypassing mainstream institutional arrangements. observable network qualities but have no quanti-
It would also be impossible to encourage and tative evidence. Burt and Burzynska (2017) ana-
gather a sufficiently large number of followers lytically corroborate these narratives.
to press for regulatory adjustments accommodat- The average entrepreneurial network is neither
ing institutional changes at the grassroots level. extremely open nor extremely closed. Further and
The stylized images of economic advantage very much against common stereotypes of doing
associated with different network styles suggest business in China, entrepreneurs do not lean
that extreme forms of closure and openness are heavily on family members and their closest kin.
unlikely to provide grounds for robust institu- Most network contacts are former and current
tional innovation. Overly closed networks, with professional ties, as well as old friends and
few contacts outside of the social group, may be acquaintances. This does not imply that the clos-
well-positioned for building trust and coopera- est ties, immediate and extended family or
tion, yet distrust in those not belonging to the friends, are not relevant. They play a crucial, yet
same group is likely to impede the discovery of temporary role at the founding stage of the firm.
different forms of doing business. The inward Burt and Opper (2017) refer to these networks of
orientation of closed networks also reduces the multiple ties of family and close friends as
chances of developing economies of scale and cocoons. Once the firm is up and running, further
long-distance exchange. At the other end of the business development requires a growing number
continuum, extremely open networks with sparse of technical and managerial skills, which calls for
and infrequent mutual contacts lack the safe envi- broader and more open business networks. Using
ronment that allows for institutional experiments the same network data from 2012 together with
that specifically push the boundaries of the information on firm survival five years later, Zhao
established order. Though individuals embedded and Burt (2018) support the argument that closed
in open social structures may have access to a family networks have only temporary utility.
host of new ideas, resources, and information, They find that entrepreneurs who successfully
breaking away from what is formally codified as developed their networks from a cocoon to an
legitimate action becomes too risky, without the open network structure had the highest likelihood
support of trusted and like-minded actors. of survival five years after the initial data collec-
Closer inspection of the type of social tion. Those who continued to rely on their initial
networks underlying China’s transformative cocoon tended to perform worse.
change from below is consistent with these Besides the importance of the network struc-
assertions. Business networks that have helped ture around the individual entrepreneur for busi-
pioneering start-up entrepreneurs build viable ness development, the diffusion of institutional
business operations tend to include a high propor- and organizational innovations also hinges on
tion of contacts known for many years and trusted the larger population network of villages,
for their integrity. Yet these networks are neither townships, and larger administrative units. Peng
closed nor static. Building on a wealth of (2004) presented one of the first aggregate-level
interviews conducted with private and state actors analyses, demonstrating the role of population
in the Lower Yangzi region, Krug and networks in explaining the spread of institutional
Hendrischke (2008, 99) note that entrepreneurial innovation. Equipped with data from 366 villages,
networks “accept and screen members for their Peng (2004) uncovered a significant association
ability to contribute to existing and future assets.” between the strength of kinship networks, and the
Similarly, Nee and Opper (2012) find that diffusion and success of new private firms as an
entrepreneurs select and renew network contacts accepted organizational form. Kinship networks,
186 S. Opper

measured as the relative importance of the stron- and Rowan’s (1977) earlier work on organiza-
gest kin in each village, were positively correlated tional forms discusses the impact of rationalized
with the number of village firms and the business myths and taken-for-granted scripts on the desir-
success of these companies (as measured by the ability of distinct institutional and organizational
total workforce employed in private firms). There forms. The limiting role of culture is also reflected
was no direct evidence of the exact mechanism in North’s (2005) later work, which shifted atten-
linking kinship networks to firm success, but trust tion to the importance of belief systems and cog-
and kin solidarity are likely supporting factors in nition in explaining institutional development
an environment that lacks legal safeguard pathways. If anything, the policy recommenda-
mechanisms and formal political protection. It is tion for practitioners is to be mindful of national
useful to note, that the focus on kinship is not to and local culture when designing and
be mistaken for a measure of network structure or implementing institutional reforms.
closure. In this study design, kinship is more Yet culture is more than a filter, constraining
likely a correlate of homophyly and structural and limiting efforts of exogenous change,
similarity, qualities that tend to produce trust whether initiated internally or as part of intersoci-
and a spirit of cohesion. In a more recent study, ety institutional transfers. Swidler’s (1986) cul-
Dai and colleagues (2019) presented related tural toolkit approach offers a useful starting
findings. They employed birth-county-based point. Following Swidler’s definition (1986,
community networks and found a significant 273), culture is a set of “symbols, rituals, and
link between population density and the local world-views, which people may use in varying
diffusion of private firms. Similar to Peng’s ear- configurations to solve different kinds of
lier study, the results support the idea that local problems.” Reference to varying configurations
social interactions, homogeneity, and enforceable of cultural elements is crucial, as it allows one to
trust foster the diffusion of innovative organiza- see “culture’s causal significance not in defining
tional forms and corresponding institutions. ends of action, but in providing cultural
components that are used to construct strategies
of action” (Swidler 1986, 273). In a similar fash-
3.2 Culture ion, Rao and Giorgi (2006, 273) define cultural
logics as “the socially constructed, historical pat-
Because culture is not easily malleable, it has tern of material practices, assumptions, values,
traditionally not been considered in the analysis beliefs, and rules by which individuals produce
of institutional change and human behavior. and reproduce their material subsistence, organize
Sociologists share a long-held resistance to time and space, and provide meaning to the social
explaining differences in behavior in cultural reality.” In both accounts, culture is not limited to
terms (see Patterson 2001 for a discussion). a filtering function, which selects distinct institu-
Economists tend to see culture as a filter through tional development trajectories. Culture provides
which the outcome of formal institutional change a reservoir of practices, strategies, and organizing
is modified and, in extreme cases, rendered inef- principles that can be readily deployed to create
fective (North 1994). In Williamson’s (2000) and develop new forms of cooperation. Beckert’s
institutional framework, culture is part of a (2010a) interpretation of culture as a form of
system’s social embeddedness, which constrains attraction mirrors the potentially positive role
and shapes institutions by defining the opportu- culture can play in advancing institutional
nity space of what is regarded as socially accepted change. The argument is simple: if institutional
or unacceptable. Along these lines, Greif (1994, innovation is consistent with local culture or if
914) highlights how cultural beliefs can explain innovation is mindful of “what people are ‘good
the forestalling of successful intersociety adop- at’” (Swidler 2008, 615), institutional innovators
tion of institutions, and the persistence of ineffi- are likely to find strong local support, helping
cient institutions. In a related argument, Meyer advance change dynamics. If, to the contrary,
12 Economic Change from an Institutional Perspective 187

institutional innovations are inconsistent with the new private firm economy replicates historical
local beliefs and cultural logics, institutional patterns of entrepreneurship. Their study also
reforms are likely to be stalled or rendered inef- suggests that the deployment of cultural frames
fective. However, this is not an automatic pro- does not depend on hands-on experience of
cess. Institutional entrepreneurs actively relate to preexisting practices in the recent past. It is suffi-
cultural components to generate a common social cient for agents of change and their respective
understanding of the legitimacy of local audience to draw on a shared cultural heritage of
innovation. preexisting beliefs and practices to culturally
It is easy to see why the negative view of legitimize code-breaking forms of institutional
culture as a filter, rather than as an attraction, and organizational innovation.
prevails in economic institutionalism. Economists
tend to emphasize the state as the central arbiter of
institutional change, and top-down reforms, often 4 Conclusion
guided by international best practice, have an
inherent risk of colliding with local cultural The variable success of institutional transitions
logics. Bottom-up innovators, in contrast, natu- and reforms over the last twenty years has dra-
rally deploy local knowledge and available cul- matically changed how we think about institu-
tural components as they experiment with tional reforms and economic change. Simple
preexisting beliefs and practices to renew existing prescriptions handed out in the early 1990s have
institutional structures. lost some of their appeal. At the same time, the
The bottom-up developments described in this large-scale transitions in Central and Eastern
chapter illustrate the close association between Europe and East Asia have broadened
local cultural logics and successful institutional perspectives to encompass various alternative
change. In their effort to break away from social- strategies. I draw three lessons: first, the
ist production, institutional entrepreneurs intui- challenges of formal institutional change will
tively returned to preexisting forms of doing remain pronounced, as long as we have no better
business that facilitate broader social acceptance understanding of the idiosyncratic development
and help turn local innovation into a social- pathways of developed economies and how their
movement-like dynamic. In doing so, innovators institutions evolved. Second, bottom-up reforms
did not stop at replacing collective forms of farm- initiated at the grassroots level can offer produc-
ing and production with simple forms of small- tive complements to top-down reforms. Third,
scale family businesses, as commonly found second-best institutions have a place in reform
before 1949. Instead, they developed family strategies, especially if they induce further insti-
firms into modern capitalist organizations tutional change, as private and state actors search
registered as joint-stock or limited liability for more efficient solutions. None of these pro-
companies, some even listed shares on the cesses is sufficiently captured without under-
country’s new stock exchanges (see Nee and standing the social context. Whether or not
Opper 2012, Chap. 5). The crucial advantage of societies will develop bottom-up institutional
the initial return to common forms of family changes or hybrid forms of doing business
production, both in farming and manufacturing depends to a considerable extent on the social
was the perceived familiarity with long- structure and culture around private and state
established, traditional modes of production. actors.
Opper and Andersson (2019) corroborate these Why have we seen so many positive
observations. Building on provincial level data developments in East Asia and Central Europe,
documenting early forms of entrepreneurial while innovative and productive institutional
activities observed during the Ming solutions remain scarce in Sub-Saharan Africa
(1368–1644) and Qing Dynasties (1644–1911), (Fafchamps 2004)? There are no simple answers
the authors show that the spatial distribution of to this crucial question. Currently, we do not
188 S. Opper

know enough about the interplay between institu- Burt, R. S. (2005). Brokerage and closure. Oxford: Oxford
tional change, social structure, and culture in the University Press.
Burt, R. S. (2019). Network disadvantaged entrepreneurs:
emergence and transition of economic systems. Density, hierarchy, and success in China and the West.
We simply have very limited empirical work to Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 43(1), 19–52.
draw on. This is not primarily because combined Burt, R. S., & Burzynska, K. (2017). Chinese
research designs pose unresolvable challenges. entrepreneurs, social networks, and guanxi. Manage-
ment and Organization Review, 13(2), 221–260.
What is more pertinent is the traditional disciplin- Burt, R. S., Kilduff, M., & Tasselli, S. (2013). Social
ary divides across the social sciences, as well as network analysis: Foundations and frontiers on advan-
distinctions within the disciplines interpreting tage. Annual Review of Psychology, 64(1), 527–547.
markets as either institutions or networks Burt, R. S., & Opper, S. (2017). Early network events in
the later success of Chinese entrepreneurs. Manage-
(Williamson 1985; White 2002; for a review, ment and Organization Review, 12(3), 497–537.
see Beckert 2010b). Future research will need to China Statistical Bureau. (2006). China state statistical
examine the intersection between networks and yearbook 2006. Beijing: Statistics Press.
institutions more closely. Field experiments China Statistical Bureau. (2008). China state statistical
yearbook 2008. Beijing: Statistics Press.
studying the diffusion of new informal practices Clark, G. (1996). The political foundations of modern
are likely to be productive, but comparative economic growth: England, 1540–1800. Journal of
designs are also needed to distinguish between Interdisciplinary History, 26, 563–588.
idiosyncratic phenomena and general Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of
human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94,
mechanisms. 95–120.
Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundation of Social Theory.
Acknowledgements I am grateful to Riksbankens Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Jubileumsfond for my sabbatical grant, and to the Center Dai, R., et al. (2019). The community origins of private
for East Asian Studies at the University of Chicago for enterprise in China. The institute of economic devel-
hosting me as an Associate. Comments by Ronald S. Burt opment working paper series no. dp–320. Boston
are gratefully acknowledged. University.
DellaPosta, D., Nee, V., & Opper, S. (2017). Endogenous
dynamics of institutional change. Rationality and Soci-
ety, 29(1), 5–48.
Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights.
References The American Economic Review, 57(2), 347–359.
Dikötter, F. (2016). The silent revolution: Decollecti-
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2005). The vization from below during the cultural revolution.
rise of Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change, and The China Quarterly, 227, 796–811.
economic growth. American Economic Review, 95(3), Fafchamps, M. (2004). Market institutions and
546–579. sub-Saharan Africa: Theory and evidence. Cambridge,
Axelrod, R. (1986). An evolutionary approach to norms. MA: MIT Press.
American Political Science Review, 80(4), 1095–1111. Greif, A. (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of
Bai, Y., & Kung, J. K.-s. (2014). The shaping of an society: A historical and theoretical reflection on col-
institutional choice: Weather shocks, the great Leap lectivist and individualist societies. Journal of Political
Famine, and agricultural Decollectivization in China. Economy, 102(5), 912–950.
Explorations in Economic History, 54, 1–26. Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern
Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, economy: Lessons from medieval trade. Cambridge:
unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Cambridge University Press.
Economy, 98(5), 893–921. Greif, A., & Laitin, D. D. (2004). A theory of endogenous
Beckert, J. (2010a). Institutional isomorphism revisited: institutional change. American Political Science
Convergence and divergence in institutional change. Review, 98(4), 633–652.
Sociological Theory, 28(2), 150–166. Hall, R. E., & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries
Beckert, J. (2010b). How do fields change? The produce so much more output per worker than
interrelations of institutions, networks, and cognition others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1),
in the dynamics of markets. Organization Studies, 31, 83–116.
605–627. Hillmann, H. (2013). Economic institutions and the state:
Berkowitz, D., Pistor, K., & Richard, J.-F. (2003). Eco- Insights from economic history. Annual Review of
nomic development, legality, and the transplant effect. Sociology, 39, 251–273.
European Economic Review, 47(1), 165–195.
12 Economic Change from an Institutional Perspective 189

Jin, H., & Qian, Y. (1998). Public versus private owner- discipline. American Journal of Sociology, 106(5),
ship of firms: Evidence from rural China. Quarterly 1338–1370.
Journal of Economics, 113(3), 773–808. Peng, Y. (2004). Kinship networks and entrepreneurs in
Keefer, P., & Knack, S. (1997). Why don’t poor countries China’s transitional economy. American Journal of
catch up? A cross-national test of an institutional Sociology, 109(5), 1045–1074.
explanation. Economic Inquiry, 35, 590–601. Peng, M. W., & Luo, Y. (2000). Managerial ties and firm
Kelliher, D. (1992). Peasant power in China: The era of performance in a transition economy: The nature of a
rural reform in China, 1979–89. New Haven: Yale micro-macro link. Academy of Management Journal,
University Press. 43(3), 486–501.
Kornai, J. (1992). The socialist system: The political econ- Rao, H., & Giorgi, S. (2006). Code breaking: How
omy of communism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univer- entrepreneurs exploit cultural logics to generate insti-
sity Press. tutional change. Research in Organizational Behavior,
Krug, B., & Hendrischke, H. (2008). Framing China: 27, 269–304.
Transformation and institutional change through Rév, I. (1987). The advantages of being atomized: How
coevolution. Management and Organization Review, Hungarian peasants coped with collectivization. Dis-
4(1), 81–108. sent, 34(3), 341–345.
McMillan, J., & Woodruff, C. (1999). Interfirm Rodrik, D. (2008). Second-best institutions. American
relationships and informal credit in Vietnam. Quarterly Economic Review, 98(2), 100–104.
Journal of Economics, 114(4), 1285–1320. Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004).
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geog-
organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. raphy and integration in economic development. Jour-
American Journal of Sociology, 83(2), 340–363. nal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165.
Murrell, P. (1995). The transition according to Cambridge, Sachs, J., & Woo, W. T. (1994). Structural factors in the
Mass. Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 164–178. economic reforms of China, Eastern Europe and the
Naughton, B. (2007). The Chinese economy. Transitions Former Soviet Union. Economic Policy, 9(18), 101–145.
and growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Swidler, A. (1986). Culture in action: Symbols and
Nee, V., & Opper, S. (2012). Capitalism from below. In strategies. American Sociological Review, 51(2),
Markets and institutional change in China. 273–286.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Swidler, A. (2008). Comment on Stephen Vaisey’s
North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and Socrates, Skinner, and Aristotle: Three ways of think-
economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni- ing about culture in action. Sociological Forum, 23(3),
versity Press. 614–618.
North, D. C. (1994). Economic performance through time. Walder, A. G. (1995). Local governments as industrial
The American Economic Review, 84(3), 359–368. firms: An organizational analysis of China’s transi-
North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of eco- tional economy. American Journal of Sociology, 101
nomic change. Princeton: Princeton University Press. (2), 263–301.
North, D. C., & Thomas, R. (1973). The rise of the western White, H. C. (2002). Markets from networks: Socioeco-
world: A new economic history. Cambridge: nomic models of production. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Cambridge University Press. University Press.
North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of
commitment: The evolution of institutions governing capitalism. New York: Free Press.
public choice in 17th century England. Journal of Williamson, O. E. (2000). The new institutional econom-
Economic History, 49(4), 803–832. ics: Taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public Literature, 38(3), 585–613.
goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: World Bank. (1996). From plan to market. Washington,
Harvard University Press. DC: World Bank Publishing.
Opper, S., & Andersson, F. N. G. (2019). Are entrepre- World Bank. (2017). Governance and the law.
neurial cultures stable over time? Historical evidence Washington, DC: World Bank Publishing.
from China. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 36 Xu, D., Jane, W. L., & Qian, G. (2014). Organizational
(4), 1165–1192. forms and multi-population dynamics: Economic tran-
Patterson, O. (2001). Taking culture seriously: A frame- sition in China. Administrative Science Quarterly, 59
work and an Afro-American illustration. In L. E. (3), 517–547.
Harrison & S. P. Huntington (Eds.), Culture matters: Zhao, C., & Burt, R. S. (2018). A note on business survival
How values shape human progress (pp. 202–218). and social network. Management and Organization
New York: Basic Books. Review, 14(2), 377–394.
Peng, Y. (2001). Chinese villages and townships as indus- Zhou, K. (1996). How the farmers changed China: Power
trial corporations: Ownership, governance, and market of the people. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
190 S. Opper

Sonja Opper is professor at the Department of Manage- Connection and Disconnection: Still a Success Factor for
ment and Technology, Bocconi University, Italy. From Chinese Entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurship Theory and
2005 to 2020 she was the Gad Rausing professor of eco- Practice 44/6: 1199–1228. Opper, Sonja, Victor Nee,
nomics and business in China at Lund University, Sweden. and Håkan J. Holm. 2017. Risk Aversion and Guanxi
Research topics: Institutional change, organizational Activities: A Behavioral Analysis of CEOs in China.
change and behavior, social networks. Recent publica- Academy of Management Journal 60/4: 1504–30.
tions: Burt, Ronald S., and Sonja Opper. 2020. Political
Financial Services Governance
in the European Union (EU) 13
Lucia Quaglia

1 Introduction regional regulatory regimes, the EU is by far the


most advanced, because its legislation is legally
The global financial crisis that began in the binding in the member states and it provides the
United States (US) in late 2007 and subsequently framework for national financial services regula-
spread worldwide brought the political salience of tion, to a large extent. Moreover, the European
financial governance into the spotlight. The crisis Commission is in charge of monitoring the imple-
underscored the need for fit for purpose financial mentation of EU rules in the member states; the
regulation and supervision. It also highlighted European Court of Justice has jurisdiction over
how financial instability can spread quickly compliance with those rules. The EU was
across national borders due to the globalization severely affected by the crisis, prompting an
of finance. The regulation of financial services intense regulatory debate on the revision of
has become increasingly complex, because of existing rules and the adoption of new regulatory
the large number of cross-border financial measures in the EU (Moloney 2012; Quaglia
institutions that often exploit regulatory gaps, to 2012, 2014; Kudrna 2016).
engage in risky activities. Moreover, there is a This chapter examines financial services gov-
variety of international, regional, transnational, ernance in the EU before, and primarily, after the
and national bodies involved in rule-making and crisis. This is an important and timely research
monitoring (Helleiner 2014). The multi-level topic for three main reasons. First, the EU is one
governance of financial services is characterized of the largest jurisdictions worldwide. It is
by two main interrelated regulatory issues: the increasingly active in shaping global financial
interaction between rule-making processes in rules in international fora (Posner 2009; Mügge
multiple arenas, and the coexistence of the rule- 2014; Quaglia 2014) and is also active in
making outputs of various arenas. exporting its rules to other countries, notably
The multi-level governance of financial through the mechanism of equivalence (Quaglia
services is complicated further in regional 2015). Second, EU rules provide the framework
jurisdictions, such as the European Union (EU), for national regulation in the member states, to a
where an extra, supranational level of regulation large extent. Third, in the aftermath of the global
exists, alongside that taking place in national, financial crisis, the EU undertook significant reg-
international, and transnational arenas. Amongst ulatory reforms concerning a variety of financial
services. The chapter begins with a review of the
main theoretical approaches that have been used
L. Quaglia (*)
University of Bologna, Bologna, Italy to account for the evolution of financial services
e-mail: lucia.quaglia@unibo.it governance in the EU. It then provides an
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 191
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_13
192 L. Quaglia

overview of financial services regulation in the These accounts have emphasized the role of the
EU prior to the global financial crisis, followed by Commission in the making of financial regula-
an outline of the regulatory changes enacted in the tion, even though this policy area was, and still
EU after the crisis. The fourth section discusses is closely guarded by the member states. After the
the Banking Union, which was one of the EU’s crisis, the Commission was very much on its back
main responses to the sovereign debt crisis in the foot, especially during the unfolding of the sover-
euro area, which followed the international finan- eign debt crisis in the euro area (Hodson 2013).
cial crisis. The fifth section discusses the Capital However, it played an important role in proposing
Markets Union and Brexit. the Banking Union (Epstein and Rhodes 2016),
together with the European Central Bank
(De Rynck 2015; Chang 2018), and later on, in
2 Theoretical Approaches launching the project of the Capital Markets
to Financial Services Union (Quaglia and Howarth 2018). These
Governance in the EU projects were then negotiated by the member
states.
Public policy and the political economy literature A third business-led explanation focused on
on financial services regulation in the EU have the role of the private sector in promoting
developed different approaches on the subject. European financial market integration (Bieling
Story and Walter (1997) stressed the intergovern- 2003; Macartney 2009; Mügge 2010). These
mental character of the negotiations on financial works emphasized either the structural power of
market regulation in the EU, in the 1980s and transnational capital or the lobbying activities of
1990s (see also Busch 2008). Indeed, their work financial institutions, which captured the public
regarded financial market integration as the battle authorities in various ways. First, there was the
of the systems, whereby the member states were economic capture, given the size and importance
keen to set EU rules that were in line with their of the financial sector in certain countries and the
domestic regulatory approach, while at the same economic resources available to industry for lob-
time not creating comparative disadvantages or bying. Second, there was the intellectual capture,
adjustment costs to national industry and the based on the high level of expertise and technical
national public authorities. Several works that knowledge at the disposal of the private sector,
examined post-crisis regulation in the EU also and often tapped into by the regulators them-
took an intergovernmental approach (Fioretos selves (Baker 2010; Bell and Hindmoor
2010; Quaglia 2011; Howarth and Quaglia 2015a, b, 2016). In the aftermath of the interna-
2013; Schimmelfennig 2015). Their argument is tional financial crisis, the financial industry was
that the configuration of national financial less influential than it had been in the past, and
systems shaped member states’ preferences mostly had to fight a rearguard battle in order to
concerning the reform of financial regulation in limit the extent of post-crisis reforms, which were
the EU, including the establishment of the Bank- costly for industry (Woll 2013; James 2016).
ing Union (Howarth and Quaglia 2016; Donnelly Finally, some authors have taken an ideational
2018a, b; Schild 2018). Although with notable approach. To begin with, some works have
exceptions, the new rules were generally resisted pointed out that in the 1980s and 1990s a
by the UK, Ireland, Luxembourg, the Nordic dominating paradigm for financial services regu-
countries, but were strongly supported by France, lation emerged internationally and in the main
Germany, Italy, and Spain. jurisdictions, including Europe. In the EU, regu-
A second explanation has viewed the latory liberalism came to dominate EU financial
European Commission as the core supranational regulation from the mid-1990s onwards, until the
actor, which was driving financial market integra- outbreak of the global financial crisis (Mügge
tion prior to the crisis (Posner 2005; Jabko 2006). 2012). Quaglia (2010) pointed out two main
13 Financial Services Governance in the European Union (EU) 193

competing coalitions of interests and ideas, which 3 The Pre-Crisis Framework


were struggling to shape financial regulation in for Financial Regulation
the EU in the 2000s: the market-making coalition in the EU
and the market-shaping coalition. The market-
making coalition, led by the UK, also included In approaching the final stage of the Economic
Ireland and the Nordic countries. The market- and Monetary Union (EMU) in 1999, and in the
shaping coalition, led by France, included Italy, first decade after the introduction of the euro, the
other Mediterranean countries and, in several pace of financial market integration quickened;
instances, Germany. After the crisis, the main and financial services governance underwent sig-
line of division tended to fall between the nificant changes in the EU (Grossman and
market-shaping coalition on the one side, and Leblond 2011). The Financial Services Action
the market-making coalition, which also included Plan proposed by the Commission in 1999, and
the financial industry, on the other (Quaglia subsequently endorsed by the member states,
2012). envisaged the completion of the single financial
The main argument used by the coalition, market through a set of legislative measures that,
which was eager to tone down the EU’s regu- in many cases, aimed at maximum
latory response, was that the proposed rules harmonization. These measures mainly focused
were over-prescriptive, intrusive, and potentially on securities markets and insurance, and found
protectionist. The rules were actively sponsored their way into several EU directives. Following
by France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and other this, attention shifted to post-trading, in particu-
members of the market-shaping coalition, lar, payment services, and the clearing and settle-
because they were seen as necessary to safeguard ment of securities. In the same period, new
financial stability and protect investors. Some of accounting rules were issued by the EU, basically
these rules, such as those concerning hedge fund adopting the international standards issued by the
managers, credit rating agencies, and over the International Accounting Standards Board
counter derivatives, also embodied the deeply (Posner 2010; Leblond 2011).
ingrained Continental dislike of casino capital- Certain financial entities, such as hedge funds
ism, which was seen as serving the fortunes of the and rating agencies, as well as certain financial
City of London. products, in particular, derivatives, were not
To sum up, the main theoretical approaches to regulated in the EU prior to the global financial
financial services governance in the EU highlight crisis. In the early 2000s, some member states,
various sets of powerful actors in financial most clearly Germany, as well as parts of the
services governance. According to the intergov- European Parliament, had encouraged
ernmental approach, the key players are states, to discussions concerning the regulation of hedge
be precise, the national governments of the main funds at the EU level. However, the Commission,
member states. According to the supranational and especially, the Irish Commissioner for the
approach, the key shapers of financial services Internal Market, Charles McCreevy, had ruled it
governance are EU technocracies, due to the fact out, and the UK, which hosted 4/5 of hedge funds
that financial regulation is very technical. For the managers in Europe, had opposed it (Fioretos
business-led approach, the most powerful actors 2010; Quaglia 2011). Neither France nor
are financial markets, to be precise, large transna- Germany successfully raised the issue of
tional forces in the financial industry. Finally, for regulating rating agencies in the EU.
the ideational approach, the most powerful actors In order to facilitate the completion of the
are those who manage to articulate the most per- single market in financial services, the framework
suasive, however, not necessarily the best ideas, for financial regulation and supervision in the EU
whether national governments, bureaucrats, or was reformed in the early 2000s, when the
private financial actors. Lamfalussy reforms were enacted in banking,
194 L. Quaglia

securities markets, and insurance (Mügge 2010; the banking sector as well as in securities markets.
Quaglia 2010). Basically, the main innovation The EU framework for financial supervision was
introduced by the Lamfalussy reforms was the also reformed.
fact that the implementing measures of level
1 financial services legislation (which was
co-decided by the Council of Ministers and the 4.1 Banking Regulation in the EU
European Parliament) were to be adopted by the
Commission. This was done through the Capital requirements for banks have traditionally
comitology process, which involved committees been regarded as one of the main instruments to
of member states representatives (the so-called ensure the stability of the banking sector, and
level 2 committees). Committees of national hence, financial stability tout court. In 1988, the
regulators were established to advise the Com- Basel Committee on Banking Supervision
mission on the adoption of legislative measures (BCBS) issued the Basel I Accord on Interna-
(the so-called level 3 committees). They also had tional Convergence of Capital Measurement
implementation tasks and could adopt non-legally and Capital Standards, which was updated by
binding standards and guidelines (Coen and the Basel II Accord in 2004. Over time, these
Thatcher 2008; Quaglia 2008). These committees soft international rules have been incorporated
were the Committee of European Banking into legally binding national legislation in more
Supervisors; the Committee of European than one hundred countries. In the EU this has
Securities Regulators; and the Committee of been done through the capital requirements
Insurance and Occupational Pension Supervisors. directives (CRD). In the wake of the crisis, the
In the making of EU financial services regula- Basel III Accord was agreed on by the BCBS in
tion prior to the crisis, the UK (Posner and Véron December 2010. The new rules provided a more
2010) and the most competitive part of the finan- restrictive definition of what counted as capital.
cial industry (Mügge 2010; Macartney 2010) They also increased the risk weight of several
were highly influential for a variety of reasons. assets in the banking book and introduced capital
To begin with, the UK and the US hosted the buffers. These rules set up a leverage ratio, as well
main global financial centers, and each had a as outlined international rules on liquidity man-
large financial industry. The financial sector in agement. All in all, the new rules increased the
the UK was particularly large when compared to proportion of capital that had to be of proven loss-
the rest of the economy. Their policy-makers, absorbing capacity, (i.e., core tier one equity cap-
therefore, had widely recognized financial exper- ital), and were to be phased in gradually from
tise, and were regarded as providing state-of-the- January 2013 to 2019. Once the Basel III Accord
art regulations. Moreover, British policy-makers was signed, the process of incorporating it into
invested a considerable amount of technical and EU legislation began in earnest.
human resources in order to shape the regulatory In July 2011, the EU Commission adopted the
debate in the EU. In addition, the UK and the US CRD IV legislative package, designed to replace
hosted large banks that had the resources to lobby the CRD III with a directive that governed the
policy-makers domestically and internationally access to deposit-taking activities and a regulation
(Baker 2010). that established prudential requirements for credit
institutions. After its approval, the directive was
to be transposed by the member states in a way,
4 The Post-Crisis Framework that was suitable to their own national environ-
for Financial Regulation ment. It contained rules concerning the taking up
in the EU and pursuit of the banking business; the
conditions for the freedom of establishment, and
After the global financial crisis, a host of new the freedom to provide services; the supervisory
regulatory measures were adopted by the EU in review process; and the definition of competent
13 Financial Services Governance in the European Union (EU) 195

authorities. The directive also incorporated two given. In the case of prevention, banks were
elements of the Basel III Accord, namely, the required to draw up recovery plans, and resolu-
introduction of two capital buffers on top of min- tion authorities were required to prepare resolu-
imum capital requirements. The EU regulation tion plans, both at a group level and for individual
contained prudential requirements for credit institutions within the group. Authorities could
institutions and investment firms. It covered the require a bank to change its legal or operational
definition of capital, increasing the amount of structures to ensure that it could be resolved with
own funds that banks needed to hold, as well as the available tools. Financial groups could enter
the quality of those funds; it introduced the liquid- into intra-group support agreements in the form of
ity coverage ratio and a leverage ratio, subject to loans, or the provision of guarantees. The frame-
supervisory review. The use of a regulation, work envisaged early supervisory intervention,
which, once approved, would be directly applica- whereby the authorities could require banks to
ble without the need for national transposition, implement measures, which were set out in the
was designed to ensure the creation of a single recovery plan, and would have the power to
rule book in the EU. appoint a special manager at a bank for a certain
While negotiating the new capital period.
requirements, British policy-makers favored strict The harmonized resolution tools and powers
rules on capital and liquidity (James 2016). In outlined in the directive were designed to ensure
contrast, French and German policy-makers that national authorities, in all member states, had
supported softer rules. These member states, the a common toolkit and roadmap to manage the
European Parliament, and the European Commis- failure of banks. Amongst the tools considered,
sion called for taking European specificities into there was the bail-in tool, whereby banks would
account when incorporating the Basel III rules be recapitalized, where shareholders would be
into the CRD IV, thus reopening some of the wiped out or diluted, and creditors would have
issues that had caused friction within the BCBS. their claims reduced or converted to shares. Res-
Indeed, the negotiations of this legislation were olution colleges were to be established under the
slowed down by different national preferences leadership of the group resolution authority, with
across the member states, which, in turn, were the participation of the European Banking
due to the expected effects of the new rules on Authority (EBA), discussed below. The EBA
their banking systems (Howarth and Quaglia was to facilitate joint actions and act as a binding
2013). The CRD IV was criticized for modifying mediator if necessary.
the Basel III standards in ways that met EU mem- The legislation envisaged the creation of reso-
ber state demands. lution funding, which would raise contributions
The CRD was designed to make banks more from banks. These contributions would be pro-
resilient to financial stress. However, the financial portionate to their liabilities and risk profiles, but
crisis also demonstrated that new rules on bank they would not be used to bail out a bank. There
recovery and resolution were needed, due to the was a link between this piece of legislation and
fact that during the crisis, several banks had to be the directive on the deposit guarantee scheme,
bailed out with public funds. In June 2012, the which provided funding for the protection of
Commission adopted a legislative proposal for retail depositors. Member states were allowed to
bank recovery and resolution (BRRD), designed merge these two funds, provided that the scheme
to avoid government bailout of large banks in the remained in a position to repay depositors in case
future. The scope of the proposal’s application of failure. The Commission noted that ideally, a
was the same as the CRD discussed above, single pan-European fund should be established
hence it applied to all credit institutions, as well with a pan-European resolution authority to man-
as certain investment firms. The proposal distin- age its disbursal, but the absence of a single
guished between powers of prevention, early European banking supervisor and insolvency
intervention, and resolution that regulators were regime would make this unworkable at that
196 L. Quaglia

stage (Nielsen and Smeets 2017; Quaglia and the Commission withdrew the proposal, noting
Spendzharova 2017). the lack of progress and foreseeable agreement
The third area of post-crisis banking reform on the issue. Moreover, the Commission argued
had to do with bank structure. In early 2012, the that the main objectives of the proposed regula-
European Commission appointed a High-level tion had already been addressed by other regu-
Expert Group headed by the former governor of latory measures in the banking sector.
the central bank of Finland, Erkki Liikanen, to
examine structural reforms that would directly
affect the structure of individual banks, and the 4.2 Securities Markets Regulation
market as a whole. In January 2014, the European in the EU
Commission presented a draft regulation on
Structural Measures to Improve the Resilience Prior to the crisis, credit rating agencies (CRAs)
of EU Credit Institutions. The proposal contained were regulated internationally by a voluntary
a ban on proprietary trading of financial Code of Conduct issued by International Organi-
instruments and commodities. Exemptions were zation of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) in
provided for financial instruments issued by 2004, and revised in the wake of the crisis in
sovereigns, multilateral development banks, and 2008. The EU had considered, but then ruled
certain international organizations. On the one out specific EU rules on CRAs prior to the inter-
hand, the proposal significantly eased the national financial crisis. After the crisis, the Reg-
recommendations of the 2012 Liikanen Report ulation on CRAs was agreed on by the EU in less
on bank structures, so that banks were not auto- than a year. According to the new rules, all CRAs,
matically required to split their lending operations which had ratings that were used in the EU,
from risky trading activities. Reportedly, this soft- needed to apply for registration in the EU. They
ening of the proposal was ascribed to the lobby- also had to comply with rules designed to prevent
ing efforts of banks, elected officials, and any conflict of interest in the rating process and to
regulators in France and Germany (Hardie and ensure the quality of the rating methodology, as
Macartney 2016; Spendzharova 2016; Howarth well as the quality of the ratings. CRAs, operating
and James 2019). in non-EU jurisdictions, could issue ratings to be
On the other hand, the new rules, if adopted, used in the EU, provided that their countries of
would have forced a significant restructuring of origin had a regulatory framework which was
big banks, such as Deutsche Bank and BNP recognized as equivalent to the one put in place
Paribas. The proposed legislation was to apply by the EU, or were endorsed by an EU-registered
only to Europe’s thirty largest banks, albeit hold- CRA. In 2011, the Regulation on CRAs was
ing over 65% of total EU banking assets. The amended. Since ratings issued by a CRA could
Commission’s proposal gave countries like be used by financial institutions throughout the
France and Germany leeway to avoid splitting EU, the Commission proposed a more centralized
up their big universal banks into separate system for the supervision of CRAs. The newly
deposit-taking investment banking operations, created European Securities and Markets Author-
which would be riskier. In fact, in several EU ity (ESMA, discussed below) was entrusted with
member states, there was political unease over exclusive supervisory powers over the CRAs,
breaking up big banks and giving a competitive registered in the EU, including European
advantage to large non-EU rivals. There was also subsidiaries of US-headquartered CRAs, such as
strong opposition from the financial industry. The Fitch, Moody, and Standard & Poor. The ESMA
European Parliament, which had the power of was given powers to request information, to
co-decision with the Council of Ministers on launch investigations, and to perform on-site
this piece of legislation, was also opposed, but inspections.
was internally divided. Eventually, after more The attempt to regulate hedge funds in the EU
than 2 years of stalemate, in November 2017, was given new momentum by the financial crisis.
13 Financial Services Governance in the European Union (EU) 197

In June 2009, the European Commission The reporting of all transactions would be man-
presented a proposal for the draft directive on datory and would provide supervisory authorities
Alternative Investment Fund Managers with the full picture of these markets.
(AIFMs), which included managers of hedge EMIR was considered a critical piece of legis-
funds, private equities funds, and real estate lation by the Commission as well as the member
funds, covering quite a broad range of financial states, in order to meet their G20 commitments at
entities. The main sponsors of the directive were the September 2009 Pittsburgh summit. It was
France, Germany, and Italy, whereas the UK, initially conceived by the Commission as a direc-
some Northern countries and AIFMs reluctantly tive, but it was quickly changed and became a
agreed to it, and then only after some of its most regulation. This distinction is important because,
controversial provisions were watered down (see as explained above, regulations are enacted into
Buckley and Howarth 2010; Quaglia 2011; Woll law with immediate effect in EU member states,
2013). After intense lobbying from industry in the with no discretion over their interpretation. The
US and the UK, the draft directive was partly EMIR was driven by the Commission with sup-
revised and an agreement between the Council port from Germany and France. The British gov-
of Ministers and the European Parliament was ernment was generally in favor, but opposed
eventually reached in late October 2010. The certain elements of the proposed legislation (see
directive was due to enter into force in 2013. It Buckley et al. 2012). The final Level 1 text of the
introduced a legally binding authorization and regulation was agreed on by the Council of
supervisory regime for all AIFMs in the EU, Ministers and the European Parliament in March
irrespective of the legal domicile of the alternative 2012. Afterward, the ESMA drafted the Level
investment funds being managed. So, AIFMs 2 rules that supported the Level 1 regulation.
needed authorization from the competent author- This piece of legislation was complemented by
ity of the home member state and were required to the revision of the Markets in Financial
report important data systemically to supervisors. Instruments Directive (MiFID II) which was
The directive set up a European passport for designed to offer greater protection to investors
AIFMs. An AIFM which had been authorized in and to bring more transparency into the trading
its home member state would be entitled to sell its securities and, especially, into derivatives.
funds to professional investors in other member
states, and national authorities would not be per-
mitted to impose additional requirements. 4.3 Financial Supervision in the EU
Prior to the global financial crisis, derivatives
were unregulated in the EU. In September 2010, The global financial crisis revealed the
the Commission proposed the European Market weaknesses of existing macro-prudential over-
Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR). This proposed sight in the EU and the inadequacy of
legislation aimed to ensure the transparency of nationally-based supervisory models in
over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives transactions, overseeing integrated financial markets with
and to reduce the risks associated with these cross-border operators. It exposed shortcomings
products by shifting the clearing of OTC in the consistent application of European Com-
derivatives to central counterparties (CCPs), munity law as well as insufficient cooperation
whenever possible. These CCPs would reduce between supervisors in exchanging information
counterparty risks because they act as during a crisis. In 2009, a group of high-level
intermediaries between sellers and buyers of practitioners and financial experts, chaired by
derivative products. They would ensure the sol- the former governor of the Banque de France,
vency of their participants by requesting deposits produced a report on the issue, which was
and margin calls. The proposed regulation named after the chair of the group (de Larosière
involved the creation of harmonized rules for Group). Building on the de Larosiere’s report, in
CCPs and EU supervision of trade repositories. September 2009, the Commission put forth a
198 L. Quaglia

series of legislative proposals for the reform of the Council in December 2012, foresaw that the ECB
micro- and macro-prudential framework for would be ‘responsible for the overall effective
financial supervision in the EU. The Commission functioning of the SSM’ and would have ‘direct
proposals were eventually agreed upon by the oversight of euro area banks’. This supervision,
Council of Ministers and the European Parlia- however, would be differentiated and the ECB
ment in the autumn of 2010. would carry it out in ‘close cooperation with
The main institutional innovations were the national supervisory authorities.’ The regulation
establishment of the European Systemic Risk establishing the SSM also permitted the ECB to
Board, its chair to be elected by and from the step in, if necessary, and supervise any of the
members of the General Council of the 6000 banks in the euro area. The SSM applied
European Central Bank (ECB). This board only to the euro area member states and to the
would be in charge of monitoring macro- non-euro area member states that decided to join
prudential risk. There was also the transformation the Banking Union.
of level three Lamfalussy committees of national The SSM eventually agreed on involving a
regulators into independent authorities with legal compromise on the distribution of supervisory
personality. It would also handle an increased power between the ECB and the national compe-
budget and have enhanced powers. Three newly tent authorities. Direct ECB supervision, through
created bodies, namely the European Banking joint supervisory teams, was to cover only those
Authority; the European Insurance and Occupa- banks with assets exceeding €30 billion or those
tional Pension Authority; and the European having assets representing at least 20 per cent of
Securities Markets Authority. They were charged their home country’s annual GDP. The thousands
with the tasks of issuing binding technical of smaller, less significant banks headquartered in
standards and promoting stronger cooperation the euro area would continue to be under the
between national supervisors (Hennessy 2014). direct supervision of the competent national
authorities, but according to harmonized rules
and practices. This compromise of two-level
5 The Banking Union supervision reflected, above all, the demands of
the German government, which opposed transfer-
The Banking Union was one of the main EU’s ring supervisory responsibilities of the country’s
responses to the sovereign debt crisis in the euro regional public savings banks (Sparkassen) and
area. This crisis began in 2010, following the co-operatives to the ECB (Howarth and Quaglia
international financial crisis. In June 2012, the 2016).
President of the European Council, the President In July 2013, the Commission proposed the
of the Eurogroup, the President of the Commis- establishment of the Single Resolution Mecha-
sion, and the President of the ECB presented an nism (SRM), designed to complement the SSM.
interim report titled, Towards a Genuine Eco- Most of the intergovernmental negotiations
nomic and Monetary Union. The Van Rompuy concerned the decision-making process in the
report, which was also known as the Four SSM and the establishment of the Single Resolu-
Presidents Report, proposed what later became tion Fund (SRF) financed by bank levies, which
known as the Banking Union. The project of the were raised at the national level. The Commis-
Banking Union was subsequently endorsed by the sion, supported by French, Spanish and Italian
European Council and the euro area summit in policy-makers, wanted to be given the final
June 2012. power to decide whether to place a bank into
The first component of the Banking Union to resolution and determine the application of reso-
be set up was the Single Supervisory Mechanism lution tools. However, German policy-makers
(SSM) (Glöckler et al. 2016). The final agreement argued that the Single Resolution Board (SRB)
on the SSM, which was reached by the European should be given this power, and insisted on
13 Financial Services Governance in the European Union (EU) 199

setting up the SRF through an intergovernmental Van Rompuy Report issued in December 2012
agreement among the participating member states only made reference to the Agreement on the
(Howarth and Quaglia 2016). Harmonization of National Resolution and
In March 2014, an intergovernmental agree- Deposit Guarantee Frameworks. German
ment was reached on the establishment of the policy-makers criticized the EDIS as an unaccept-
SRM. As advocated by German policy-makers, able step towards debt mutualization. In contrast,
the SRB would be responsible for the planning policy-makers in France and in the euro area
and the resolution of cross-border banks, as well periphery regarded the EDIS as the final pillar of
as those directly supervised by the ECB. National the Banking Union, being necessary to severe the
resolution authorities would be responsible for all doom loop between banks and sovereigns. The
other banks, except banks which required access ECB regarded the EDIS as an important compo-
to the SRF. Moreover, the SRF, financed by bank nent of the Banking Union, but one that could be
levies raised at the national level, would initially implemented at a later date (Howarth and Quaglia
consist of national compartments that would be 2016).
gradually merged over 8 years. The SRF The issue came back to the policy agenda in
embodies all the controversial characteristics of June 2015, when supranational actors, including
the Banking Union, given its partly intergovern- ECB president Mario Draghi and Commission
mental, partly supranational character. The Regu- President Jean-Claude Juncker, endorsed the cre-
lation on the Single Resolution Mechanism ation of the EDIS in the Five Presidents’ Report
(SRM) was adopted in conjunction with the on the future of the euro. In the autumn of 2015,
Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive the Commission proposed the EDIS for bank
(BRRD), which harmonized resolution deposits in the euro area as the third pillar of the
instruments and powers in the EU. The BRRD Banking Union. The Commission’s proposal
and the SRM Regulation introduced a new instru- would, as a first step, involve the establishment
ment in bank resolution, the bail-in, which sub- of “a mandatory reinsurance scheme that would
stantially reduced the need for public funding to contribute under certain conditions when national
bail out banks (Nielsen and Smeets 2017). Thus, deposit guarantee schemes are called upon.” It
the SRM would be fiscally neutral. The instru- would, in effect, act as a backstop to national
ment of the bail-in was to enable banks to with- deposit guarantee schemes. This initiative took
stand financial stress by imposing losses on place despite explicit German opposition. As in
creditors (bail-in), without resorting to state- the case of the creation of the SRF, the intergov-
funded recapitalization (bail-out). ernmental discussion on the creation of the EDIS
The missing component of the Banking Union pitted countries’ interests against each other. On
was, what later became to be known as the one hand were the interests of the countries
European Deposit Insurance Scheme (EDIS) expected to make net contributions to common
(Donnelly 2018a, b; Howarth and Quaglia rescue funds, either coming from taxpayers or
2018). In June 2012, the interim Van Rompuy from banks. On the other hand were the interests
Report (a.k.a. Four Presidents’ Report) report of the countries that expected to be the principal
mentioned the need to set up an EDIS. The Com- recipients (Donnelly 2018a, b). Negotiations are
mission had prepared a draft proposing a new ongoing at the time of writing.
agency, the European Deposit Insurance and Res- Finally, the credibility of the SRM/SRF and
olution Authority (EDIRA), which would control the EDIS was linked to the possibility of
a new European Deposit Guarantee and Resolu- accessing a common fiscal backstop. Given the
tion Fund. Due to German opposition, the pro- fact that the use of the ESM was subject to una-
posal for the EDIRA was removed and the final nimity, German policy-makers enjoyed a veto on
Commission document A Roadmap Towards any decision to engage in direct bank recapitali-
Banking Union was released. Thus, the final zation. Under the rules established for the direct
200 L. Quaglia

recapitalization of banks, euro area member states 6 The Capital Markets Union
agreed that a bank’s creditors should absorb and Brexit
appropriate losses before ESM funds could be
accessed. These appropriate losses were defined The idea of the Capital Markets Union was first
by the BRRD’s rules on the bail-in. Moreover, mentioned in October 2014, in the Political
ESM rules required a bank’s home government to Guidelines of the then newly appointed President
initially contribute at least twenty per cent of the of the European Commission, Jean-Claude
recapitalization and then ten per cent from 2017 Juncker. According to the Commission, the Capi-
onward. German policy-makers, joined by tal Markets Union would “improve [the]
Austrian, Dutch and Finnish policy makers financing of the economy . . . cut the cost of
insisted that ESM funds could not be used to raising capital, notably for SMEs, and help reduce
cover legacy problems. Hence, the fiscal backstop [the] very high dependence on bank funding. This
did not materialize when the Banking Union was would also increase the attractiveness of Europe
set up (Howarth and Quaglia 2016). Subse- as a place to invest” (European Commission
quently, in late 2018 the member states in the 2014, 8). In February 2015, the Commission
Council of Ministers reached a general agreement published the Green Paper, Building a Capital
on the use of the ESM as a backstop to the SRF, Markets Union, on which responses from inter-
further details are to be negotiated in due course. ested parties were invited. At that stage, the Capi-
Overall, the Banking Union was set up in a tal Markets Union was a mixed bag, it was a long
timely fashion between 2012 and 2014. However, shopping list of things to do in order to complete
it was incomplete and asymmetric in three main the single financial market and boost the EU’s
aspects. First, member states governments capital markets (Moloney 2016). In September
retained their vetoes on the mutualization of 2015, the Commission put forth an Action Plan
national funds and continued to have an important for the Capital Markets Union, together with a
say on the use of resolution funds in the SRM. A package of two legislative proposals to promote
rather complex compromise was reached securitization. Furthermore, the Commission
concerning the resolution process in the SRB. began preparing a proposal for the revision of
Second, the EDIS was not set up. Third, no com- the Prospectus Directive and the Solvency II
mon fiscal backstop was established, albeit prog- Directive. Finally, it opened a consultation on
ress is underway at the time of writing. Most of venture capital and social entrepreneurship
the intergovernmental negotiations on the core funds, a consultation on covered bonds in the
components of the Banking Union basically EU, as well as a call for evidence on the EU
boiled down to distributional conflicts in two regulatory framework for financial services.
dimensions: the centralization of decision- The member states reached an agreement on the
making, and the allocation of costs via risk- securitization proposal in a matter of weeks, but
sharing in the Banking Union. The discussions the European Parliament refused to fast-track
pitted expected net contributors against those the proposals, mainly because left-leaning
expected to be the principal recipients. Thus, parliamentarians called for a thorough review in
compromises between the two coalitions were order not to revive pre-crisis excesses (Quaglia
sought during the negotiations. The institutional et al. 2016).
design eventually set up for the Banking Union The European Commission was the main pol-
was closer to the preferences of the German icy entrepreneur in the Capital Markets Union
led-coalition, as far as risk-sharing was (Quaglia and Howarth 2018), which was enthusi-
concerned. However, German policy-makers astically supported by the UK. Those member
had to make concessions concerning the transfer states with the most well-developed and
of decision-making to the EU/euro area level diversified financial sectors, including Ireland,
(Schild 2018). the Netherlands, Sweden, and Luxembourg
13 Financial Services Governance in the European Union (EU) 201

joined the UK. These member states unequivo- From 2017 onwards, the Capital Markets
cally supported the market liberalization agenda Union has lost momentum because of Brexit. In
in the Capital Markets Union. The main continen- fact, the UK which has by far, the largest financial
tal countries, notably France and Germany, sector in the EU, and the second largest in the
expressed their reservations concerning the Capi- world, decided to leave the EU. Furthermore,
tal Markets Union and so did some of their home London was the only real international financial
country players, (e.g., domestic banks and invest- center in the EU at that time. Some argue that the
ment firms). Instead, the most competitive parts Capital Markets Union does not make much sense
of the financial industry, the main transnational without the UK. Others argue that Brexit makes
players, such as large banks engaged in securiti- the Capital Markets Union all the more necessary.
zation, insurance companies, and the international At any rate, in the short and medium term, the
financial centers in the EU, first and foremost the main challenge concerning financial services gov-
City of London, supported the proposal for the ernance in the EU is Brexit, specifically,
Capital Markets Union. The new measures the implications that the UK’s departure from
designed to promote securitization would benefit the EU will have for market integration, (i.e., the
the large banks based in the UK, but also those in cross-border financial flows) between the UK and
France, Germany, the Benelux countries, Italy, the EU27, as well as the supervision of financial
and Spain. Small banks would also benefit from entities that operate across the English Channel.
the new proposed legislation on securitization, Following the general elections in December
but the large banks would benefit the most, as 2019, the UK is set to leave the EU by the end
they are the most engaged in shadow banking of January 2020. After that, there will be an
(Quaglia et al. 2016). eleven-month transition period, during which the
Of all EU member states, the UK had the UK will continue to be subject to EU rules and
most to benefit from the financial liberalization remain a member of the single market and
and diversification promised in/by the project on customs union. In the meantime, the UK and the
the Capital Markets Union, given the diversity EU will negotiate their future trading relationship.
of its financial sector, and in particular, the high
concentration of wholesale market activity, pri-
vate equity, and hedge funds. Given the 7 Conclusion
implications of the Banking Union for the single
financial market, the Capital Markets Union was This chapter has examined financial services gov-
deliberately framed as an initiative to comple- ernance in the EU, focusing mainly on the
ment the Banking Union, and ultimately, to reforms enacted following the international finan-
complete EMU, even though the Capital cial crisis and the sovereign debt crisis in the euro
Markets Union involved all twenty-eight mem- area. The analysis has not only pointed out the
ber states. Some commentators interpreted the intergovernmental dynamics of many
Capital Markets Union, in part, as an attempt to negotiations concerning financial regulation in
repair the strained relations between the UK and the EU, but also the role of supranational
the euro area. It did this by giving “a political institutions, in particular in agenda setting. The
signal to strengthen the Single Market as a proj- financial industry has also been influential in
ect of all 28 Member States” (Ringe 2015, 4), shaping the EU’s financial rules, albeit less so in
not only of the euro area countries, but also in an the wake of the crisis. The regulatory changes
area where the UK had a clear competitive enacted as a response to the two consecutive
advantage. Thus, the Capital Markets Union crises were mostly incremental and affected cer-
was designed to attract especially the UK, as tain financial services more than others. However,
well as those member states that had not joined taken together, this multitude of incremental
the Banking Union and/or EMU, but first and changes amounted to a considerable reform of
foremost the UK. financial services governance post-crisis.
202 L. Quaglia

References Euro area. Journal of European Public Policy, 24(8),


1135–1153.
Grossman, E., & Leblond, P. (2011). European financial
Baker, A. (2010). Restraining regulatory capture? Anglo-
integration: Finally the great leap forward? Journal of
America, crisis politics and trajectories of change in
Common Market Studies, 49(2), 413–435.
global financial governance. International Affairs, 86
Hardie, I., & Macartney, H. (2016). EU ring-fencing and
(3), 647–663.
the defence of too-big-to-fail banks. West European
Bell, S., & Hindmoor, A. (2015a). Masters of the universe,
Politics, 39(3), 503–525.
slaves of the market. Harvard: Harvard University
Helleiner, E. (2014). The status quo crisis: Global finan-
Press.
cial governance after the 2008 Meltdown. Oxford:
Bell, S., & Hindmoor, A. (2015b). Taming the city? Ideas,
Oxford University Press.
structural power and the evolution of british banking
Hennessy, A. (2014). Redesigning financial supervision in
policy amidst the great financial meltdown. New Polit-
the European Union, 2009–13. Journal of European
ical Economy, 20(3), 454–474.
Public Policy, 21(2), 151–168.
Bell, S., & Hindmoor, A. (2016). Structural power and the
Hodson, D. (2013). The little engine that wouldn’t: Supra-
politics of bank capital regulation in the United King-
national entrepreneurship and the Barroso commission.
dom. Political Studies, 65(1), 103–121.
Journal of European Integration, 35(3), 301–314.
Bieling, H.-J. (2003). Social forces in the making of the
Howarth, D., & Quaglia, L. (2013). Banking on stability:
new European economy: The case of financial market
The political economy of new capital requirements in
integration. New Political Economy, 8(2), 203–223.
the European Union. Journal of European Integration,
Buckley, J., & Howarth, D. (2010). Internal market gesture
35(3), 333–346.
politics? Explaining the EU’s response to the financial
Howarth, D., & Quaglia, L. (2016). The political economy
crisis. Journal of Common Market Studies Annual
of banking union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Review, 48(s1), 119–141.
Howarth, D., & Quaglia, L. (2018). The difficult construc-
Buckley, J., Howarth, D., & Quaglia, L. (2012). Internal
tion of a European deposit insurance scheme: A step
market: The ongoing struggle to “protect” Europe from
too far in Banking Union? Journal of Economic Policy
its money men. JCMS, 50, 99–115.
Reform, 21(3), 190–209.
Busch, A. (2008). Banking regulation and globalization.
Howarth, D., & James, S. (2019). The politics of bank
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
structural reform: Business power and agenda setting
Chang, M. (2018). The creeping competence of the
in the UK, France and Germany. Business and Politics,
European Central Bank during the Euro Crisis. Credit
1–27.
and Capital Markets: Kredit und Kapital, 51(1),
Jabko, N. (2006). Playing the market: A political strategy
41–53.
for Uniting Europe, 1985–2005. Ithaca: Cornell Uni-
Coen, D., & Thatcher, M. (2008). Network governance
versity Press.
and multi-level delegation: European networks of reg-
James, S. (2016). The domestic politics of financial regu-
ulatory agencies. Journal of Public Policy, 28(1),
lation: Informal ratification games and the EU capital
49–71.
requirement negotiations. New Political Economy, 21
De Larosière Group. (2009). The high level group on
(2), 187–203.
financial supervision in the EU, 25 February, Brussels.
Kudrna, Z. (2016). Financial market regulation: Crisis-
De Rynck, S. (2015). Banking on a union: The politics of
induced supranationalization. Journal of European
changing Eurozone banking supervision. Journal of
Integration, 38(3), 251–264.
European Public Policy, 23(1), 119–135.
Leblond, P. (2011). EU, US and international accounting
Donnelly, S. (2018a). Power politics, banking union and
standards: A delicate balancing act in governing global
EMU. London: Routledge.
finance. Journal of European Public Policy, 18(3),
Donnelly, S. (2018b). Advocacy coalitions and the lack of
443–461.
deposit insurance in banking union. Journal of Eco-
Macartney, H. (2009). Variegate neo-liberalism:
nomic Policy Reform, 21(3), 210–223.
Transnationally oriented fractions of capital in EU
Epstein, R. A., & Rhodes, M. (2016). The political dynam-
financial market integration. Review of International
ics behind Europe’s new banking union. West
Studies, 35(2), 451–480.
European Politics, 39(3), 415–437.
Macartney, H. (2010). Variegated neoliberalism: EU
European Commission. (2014). A new start for Europe:
varieties of capitalism and international political econ-
My agenda for jobs, growth, fairness and democratic
omy. London: Routledge.
change. Strasbourg: Political Guidelines for the next
Moloney, N. (2012). The legacy effects of the financial
European Commission.
crisis on regulatory design in the EU. In E. Ferran,
Fioretos, O. (2010). Capitalist diversity and the interna-
J. Hill, N. Moloney, & J. C. Coffee (Eds.), The regu-
tional regulation of hedge funds. Review of Interna-
latory aftermath of the global financial crisis. Interna-
tional Political Economy, 17(3), 696–723.
tional corporate law and financial market regulation
Glöckler, G., Lindner, J., & Salines, M. (2016). Explaining
(pp. 111–202). Cambridge: Cambridge University
the sudden creation of a banking supervisor for the
Press.
13 Financial Services Governance in the European Union (EU) 203

Moloney, N. (2016). Capital markets union: Ever closer Quaglia, L., & Spendzharova, A. (2017). The conundrum
union for the EU financial system? European Law of solving “too big to fail” in the European Union:
Review, 41(3), 307–337. Supranationalization at different speeds. Journal of
Mügge, D. (2010). Widen the market, narrow the compe- Common Market Studies, 55(5), 1110–1126.
tition: Banker interests and the making of a European Quaglia, L., & Howarth, D. (2018). Policy narratives on
capital market. Colchester: ECPR. capital markets union. Journal of European Public
Mügge, D. (2012). From pragmatism to dogmatism: EU Policy, 25(7), 990–1009.
governance, policy paradigms, and financial melt- Ringe, W.-G. (2015). Capital Markets Union for Europe:
down. New Political Economy, 16(2), 185–206. A political message to the UK. Law and Financial
Mügge, D. (Ed.). (2014). Europe and the governance of Markets Review, 9(1), 5–7.
global finance. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Schild, J. (2018). Germany and France at cross purposes:
Nielsen, B., & Smeets, S. (2017). The role of the EU The case of Banking Union. Journal of Economic
institutions in establishing the Banking Union. Collab- Policy Reform, 21(2), 102–117.
orative leadership in the EMU reform process. Journal Schimmelfennig, F. (2015). Liberal intergovernmentalism
of European Public Policy, 25(9), 1233–1256. and the Euro area crisis. Journal of European Public
Posner, E. (2005). Sources of institutional change: The Policy, 22(2), 177–195.
supranational origins of Europe’s New Stock Markets. Spendzharova, A. (2016). Regulatory cascading:
World Politics, 58(1), 1–40. Limitations of policy design in European banking
Posner, E. (2009). Making rules for global finance: Trans- structural reforms. Policy and Society, 35(3), 227–237.
atlantic regulatory cooperation at the turn of the mil- Story, J., & Walter, I. (1997). Political economy of finan-
lennium. International Organization, 63, 665–699. cial integration in Europe: The battle of the systems.
Posner, E. (2010). Sequence as explanation: The interna- Manchester: Manchester University Press.
tional politics of accounting standards. Review of Inter- Woll, C. (2013). Lobbying under pressure: The effect of
national Political Economy, 17(4), 639–664. salience on European hedge fund regulation. Journal
Posner, E., & Véron, N. (2010). The EU and financial of Common Market Studies, 51(3), 555–572.
regulation: Power without purpose? Journal of
European Public Policy, 17(3), 400–415.
Quaglia, L. (2008). Committee governance in the financial Lucia Quaglia is professor of political science at the
sector in the European Union. Journal of European University of Bologna, Italy. She was professor of political
Integration, 30(3), 565–580. science at the University of York (2012–17) and awarded
Quaglia, L. (2010). Governing financial services in the various research fellowships.
European Union. London: Routledge. Research topics: Financial governance, finance,
Quaglia, L. (2011). The “old” and “new” political econ- macroeconomic governance, Economic and Monetary
omy of hedge funds regulation in the European Union. Union, Banking Union. Recent publications: Quaglia, L.
West European Politics, 34(4), 665–682. (2020) The Politics of Regime Complexity in International
Quaglia, L. (2012). The “old” and “new” politics of finan- Derivatives Regulation, Oxford University Press. James,
cial services regulation in the European Union. New Scott, and Lucia Quaglia 2020. The UK and Multi-level
Political Economy, 17(4), 515–535. Financial Regulation: From the Crisis to Brexit. Oxford:
Quaglia, L. (2014). The European Union and global finan- Oxford University Press. Dannreuther, Charlie, Scott
cial regulation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Lavery, and Lucia Quaglia. 2019. Brexit and the Future of
Quaglia, L. (2015). The politics of “third country equiva-
British Capitalism. New Political Economy (special
lence” in post-crisis financial services regulation in the
issue). Bulmer, Simon, and Lucia Quaglia. 2018. The
European Union. West European Politics, 38(1),
167–184. Politics and Economics of Brexit, Journal of European
Quaglia, L., Howarth, D., & Liebe, M. (2016). The politi- Public Policy (special issue). Howarth, David, and Lucia
cal economy of European Capital Markets Union. Quaglia. 2016. The Political Economy of Banking Union.
Journal of Common Market Studies Annual Review, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
54(s1), 185–203.
Attitudes Towards Free Market
and Socialism in Ukraine: Empirical 14
Insights in the Context of Institutional
Transformation

Alberto Veira-Ramos and Tetiana Liubyva

1 Introduction: General Attitudes category of respondents that increased the most


Towards Capitalism between 1994 and 2016 is those who support
and Socialism in Ukraine neither socialism nor capitalism (from 20% to
32%). Support for socialism remains relevant
In 2020, almost three decades after independence, but is decreasing in significance (from 22% to
six different presidents have been elected by 14%).
the Ukrainian people in free elections. Several These trends suggest that reforms approved to
governments have been in charge of adapt the Ukrainian economy to a free market
implementing reforms and several constitutional environment did not contribute much to increas-
reforms were approved. The geopolitical direc- ing support for capitalism among the Ukrainian
tion of Ukraine as a nation has changed dramati- population over the past decades. Since support
cally more than once. Such intense sociopolitical for Soviet past has not gained ground either,
history, contrasts with an apparently slow process many Ukrainians are found in an ideological no
of transformation of the Ukrainian economy and man’s land.
institutions, as well as the reluctance of a decreas- This anomy is also observed when Ukrainians
ing, though still significant part of the population give their opinions on how much they feel aligned
to embrace the institutional arrangements with different political movements. According to
associated with liberal democracies and free mar- Fig. 14.2, most Ukrainians do not identify with
ket values. any political movement. Answers such as “I do
Data from the Ukrainian Society Survey sug- not understand these trends,” “I have not decided
gest that many Ukrainians still hold an ambiva- yet” or “None” represent almost 60% of the
lent attitude towards capitalism. Figure 14.1 interviewed population in 2018. However, a
shows that at least 13% to 14% of respondents more subtle distinction between communism,
support such an economic system. Almost a quar- socialism and social-democracy reveals a clear
ter (23–24%) declare to support capitalism, as trend toward decreasing support for communism
much as socialism (to avoid a conflict). Yet the and increasing support for social-democracy. The
other political movement that is recognized by a
growing number of respondents is the national-
A. Veira-Ramos (*)
democratic movement. It seems that political
Carlos III University of Madrid, Madrid, Spain
e-mail: alberto.veira@uc3m.es movements that are classics in Western Europe
are not necessarily those that will be adopted by
T. Liubyva
Institute of Sociology of National Academy of Sciences of most Ukrainians as the main vectors of their
Ukraine, Kyiv, Ukraine political self-reference.
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 205
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_14
206 A. Veira-Ramos and T. Liubyva

Attitudes of respondents towards Capitalism or Socialism


in 1994 and 2016
50%

40%

30%

20%

10%

0%
I support the I support the I support both I support Other Hard to tell
proponents of proponents of of them to neither
socialism capitalism avoid conflict

1994 2016

Fig. 14.1 Some political forces want Ukraine to choose the way of socialism, others desire the way of capitalism. What
is your personal attitude towards these forces? Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Author’s Calculations

Support of respondents towards political ideologies in


1994 and 2018
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%

1994 2018
Fig. 14.2 Within the political spectrum, there are several that you most support. Source: Ukrainian Society Survey.
partially independent political movements. The following Author’s Calculations
list gives several such movements. Please choose the one
14 Attitudes Towards Free Market and Socialism in Ukraine: Empirical Insights. . . 207

The decrease of support for the Communist Indeed, Ukraine constitutes one paradigmatic
ideology is confirmed by results shown in example of a society displaying low trust in the
Fig. 14.3. Yet the significant decrease in the political institutions that emerged after the col-
level of trust people have in the Communist lapse of the Soviet regime (Mishler and Rose
Party (from 15% to 5% between 1994 and 2018) 1994; Dogan and Higley 1998). This apparent
is not compensated by a proportional increase bleak landscape should not hide the fact that
in people’s trust of political parties in general. mafias were cited in first place, unrivaled by any
Moreover, trust in the Ukrainian parliament, other category only until 2004. After the Orange
Verkhovna Rada, has also decreased. Transition revolution, entrepreneurs and leaders of political
into a new institutional and economic context parties are also seen as groups that participate in
implies relegation of old values and ideologies. shaping of the Ukrainian state. One may consider
However, it seems that most Ukrainians are not two options for combating the mafias and crimi-
automatically adopting a new set of values or nal elements, which, according to large share of
ideologies to replace the former ones. the Ukrainian public opinion, are shaping the
A plausible explanation for the persistent future of the country. First, is the return to a
lack of trust in newly created institutions after planned economy, with total government control
independence, as well as the lack of popular and second, the implementation of liberal reforms
alignment with ideologies typical of liberal to ensure a free market environment with equal
democracies is that following the collapse of opportunities. The main contribution of this chap-
the Soviet regimes, governmental performance ter is to analyze several items from the Ukrainian
declined as opportunism and malfeasance reached Society Survey, thus giving insight concerning
critical points (Nee and Swedberg 2005). In line which path Ukrainian people are leaning towards.
with this viewpoint is the widespread perception To do so, we will rely on theoretical perspectives
revealed by the Ukrainian Survey data, shown in developed to explain institutional trust and put
Fig. 14.4, that the country, including political them to the test.
representatives, is managed by oligarchs and The development of trust (or the absence
mafias. thereof) towards political institutions of societies

Percentages of respondents who trust or


somewhat trust the cited institutions in 1994
and 2018
50%

40%

30%

20%

10%

0%
Trust Communist Party Trust political parties Trust Verkhovna Rada

1994 2018

Fig. 14.3 How much do you trust . . .? Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Author’s Calculations
208 A. Veira-Ramos and T. Liubyva

Social groups shaping the Ukrainian state according to


respondents to the Ukrainian Society survey
50% Workers
Peasants
40% Inteligentsia
Entrepreneurs/Bussines men
30%
Managers of state enterprises
20% Leaders of political parties
Military
10%
Police/Security personnel

0% Judges/Prosecutor
Mafias and criminal elements

Fig. 14.4 In your opinion, which of the following social groups play a powerful role in shaping the Ukrainian state?
Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Authors Calculations

in transformation can be approached from a paths for economic development are more
cultural and institutional perspective. Cultural diverse, and therefore, more suitable for insightful
perspectives emphasize the importance of early research, as we will show in the following
life socialization (Almond and Verba 1963; sections of this chapter.
Putnam 1993; Inglehart 1997) while institutional
approaches highlight the performance and utility
of institutions (Dasgupta 1988; Coleman 1990). 2 Description of the Data (The
Mishler and Rose (2001) distinguished, within Ukrainian Society Survey)
each perspective, a micro and macro variant, lead-
ing to the establishment of four testable The Ukrainian Society Survey was carried out by
hypotheses. Macro-cultural theories emphasize the Institute of Sociology of National Academy of
the importance of national traditions and leave Sciences of Ukraine starting from 1992 under the
little room for variations among individuals. direction of Natalia Panina and Evgenii
Micro-cultural theories allow for variations Golovakha, heads of the research program. Its
between individuals, derived from different data track the public opinion of the Ukrainian
socialization experiences. The macro-institutional population and they have been used repeatedly
approach points to the aggregate performance of to shed light on the sociological reality of Ukraine
institutions that enhance economic growth and and its reluctant transformation (Golovakha
limit corruption as being the key elements that 1996; Golovakha and Panina 2003, 2008, 2009;
can promote institutional trust. The micro- Golovakha et al. 2020).
institutional perspective corrects the former, The survey was conducted annually until
indicating that individual evaluations of institu- 2006, later biennially in even years. The question-
tional performance are conditioned by personal naire consists of two parts: the monitoring section
preferences and experiences. In this chapter we (core questions) and the rotating section.
use this theoretical framework to study the evolu- Indicators relate to the following topics: eco-
tion of positive attitudes towards private entre- nomic situation, political situation, legal aware-
preneurship or towards the return to a planned ness and social protest, social ethics, conflicts and
economy. Unlike trust in political institutions, trust, interethnic relations, language and religion,
attitudes of Ukrainians towards these different social well-being and public moods, health and
14 Attitudes Towards Free Market and Socialism in Ukraine: Empirical Insights. . . 209

social support, leisure, local living conditions, regions invited these friends or relatives to live
ecological situation, financial state, work and with them in the same settlement. Thus, the sur-
employment, education, transportation and com- vey confirms the official reports claiming that
munication, and social change. most IDPs settled in Kyiv, government-controlled
The sample size of each survey amounts to areas of the Donetsk and Luhansk regions, and
1800 respondents representing the adult popula- other Eastern regions next to the conflict zone
tion of Ukraine (18 years and older). Sampling is (Kharkiv, Dnipro, Zaporizhzhia). At the same
three-staged, stratified, and random with quota time, such redistribution of respondents indicates
screening in the last phase. In the first stage, relevant presence of IDPs in other regions, among
localities are selected in the geographical regions. respondents in survey data after 2014. Residents
In the second stage, specific postal addresses are of Donbas or Crimea who answered the survey in
chosen at convenient highway routes and/or other regions of Ukraine may have brought in
crossroads. In the third stage, respondents are some of their former regionally specific features,
chosen. The quota screening of respondents in especially in opinion questions. At the same time,
the final stage by sex and age is performed. All the percentage of these types of respondents is
the surveys are conducted using the self- estimated to be no more than 4–5% and therefore
administered method, where respondents would not significantly influence results.
completed the questionnaires by themselves.
Starting in 2014, fieldwork was not carried out
in Crimea, or in non-government-controlled areas 3 The Evolution of Attitudes
of the Donetsk and Luhansk regions. Sample size Towards Private
of the survey did not change though. The survey Entrepreneurship and Support
was redistributed among other regions of Ukraine. of Socialism
Data from 2014 were collected in June–July, after
the occupation of Crimea and the beginning of the To identify changes in attitudes towards private
hybrid war in Donbas, before main military entrepreneurship, we used two items included in
engagements in Ilovaysk and at Donetsk airport. the Ukrainian Society Survey: (1) the level of
Internally displaced persons (IDPs), those who approval of Ukrainians for the development of
left occupied territories (both Crimea and private business, and (2) the percentages of
Donbas) and registered in other parts of Ukraine those who declare they would like to start their
had opportunities to be included in the sample. own business. To measure support for a return to
Estimated number of IDPs in Ukraine varied dur- a government-controlled economy we rely on the
ing the war years. The number of registered IDPs item, which explicitly poses the question to
in the territory of Ukraine, according to Ministry interviewees of what should be the role of the
of Social Politics data (February 2019) is more government in regulating the economy. The
than 1.3 million,1 in comparison to August 2016 results of these analyses are presented in the fol-
of 1.7 million. Some IDPs were not registered, lowing sections.
but this share is relatively small.2 No explicit
question is included in the survey to identify
IDPs, but 18.9% of respondents in 2018 reported 3.1 The Evolution of Attitudes
they had friends or relatives who moved from the Towards Private
conflict zone in Donbas to other territories in Entrepreneurship
Ukraine. Up to 18.7% of respondents in Kyiv
City and 14.5% of respondents in government- The evolution of the answers to the questions
controlled territories of Donetsk and Luhansk “What is your attitude towards the development
of private business in Ukraine?” and “Would you
1
See https://www.msp.gov.ua/news/16745.html. like to start your own business?” included in the
2
For more information see http://iom.org.ua/sites/default/ survey until 2014, and displayed in Figs. 14.5 and
files/nms_round_9_ukr_press.pdf. 14.6, reveal that attitudes towards private
210 A. Veira-Ramos and T. Liubyva

Attitudes towards private business in Ukraine


100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

0%

Completely disapprove Disapprove more than approve


Difficult to say Approve more than disapprove
Completely approve
Fig. 14.5 What is your attitude towards the development of private business in Ukraine? Source: Ukrainian Society
Survey. Author’s Calculations

Would you like to start your own business?


100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

0%
2004 2005 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

No Probably no Difficult to say Probably yes Yes

Fig. 14.6 Would you like to start your own business? Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Author’s Calculations
14 Attitudes Towards Free Market and Socialism in Ukraine: Empirical Insights. . . 211

Table 14.1 Respondents declaring to be in favor of the development of private business (%)
Social groups 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Primary education 29.8 29.5 27.5 32.5 30.0 29.3 39.0 38.1 37.3 38.0 46.2
Secondary 50.1 52.0 53.5 61.3 52.4 53.0 58.4 53.1 57.9 52.1 59.8
Vocational 50.1 56.7 54.1 62.3 60.1 59.8 58.8 58.5 57.1 55.3 60.7
University 59.0 64.2 67.9 74.9 73.0 67.1 68.3 65.6 71.9 69.5 68.5
Employed in public sector 45.7 47.9 44.9 55.3 51.1 53.6 56.9 55.7 54.5 50.3 62.3
In private sector 73.6 68.8 72.0 74.3 66.8 60.3 71.2 66.3 64.0 62.7 69.0
In both sectors 56.3 68.8 75.0 76.9 57.1 37.9 56.3 71.7 80.0 61.4 68.3
Not employed 35.8 39.0 38.1 44.0 38.8 37.3 47.8 45.8 47.5 45.7 54.3
Life depends more on myself 51.7 57.1 63.6 67.7 54.4 54.9 67.3 59.0 60.0 56.2 68.6
The same on me and on external 52.6 55.0 57.7 61.3 58.4 58.7 62.2 63.8 57.9 57.4 65.6
conditions
More on external conditions 38.2 39.3 38.2 44.6 40.7 37.0 48.4 48.3 49.6 48.1 54.8
Poor (not enough for food) 29.5 23.9 49.4 32.4 32.7 35.4 56.9
Enough for food only 42.5 42.4 45.1 44.2 49.8 45.3 54.0
Enough for meagre living 60.0 51.3 62.0 61.7 57.9 58.6 65.2
Enough for all necessities 63.6 63.6 68.6 64.3 61.3 58.7 66.9
Enough for savings 75.6 56.3 70.6 66.2 66.2 78.4 74.7
Lives in a village 39.8 39.5 46.5 45.8 44.2 46.8 56.8
Town up to 250,000 52.5 50.4 61.1 57.4 58.4 50.5 58.6
City 250,000 to 500,000 48.8 48.9 58.0 64.5 55.4 53.2 57.7
City over 500,000 57.0 53.4 63.2 58.5 63.3 63.9 73.3
Employer 80.8 60.7 77.4 72.7 68.2 72.4
Self-employed 56.5 67.3 69.5 76.3 69.0 70.1
Employee 56.0 53.6 64.2 59.2 59.2 66.3
Unemployed 37.3 47.4 47.5 45.0 54.3
Hard to tell 47.1 48.3 57.4 43.2 55.9
Total 43.8 46.2 45.4 52.3 48.3 47.1 56.4 55.4 54.5 52.6 61.5
Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Author’s calculations. Figures for uneven years are not shown for sake of space but
could be made available upon request. Blank spaces mean that the corresponding item was not included in the survey in
the given year up to 2005

entrepreneurship became more positive over time. possible answers rank from “Poor, not enough for
The decrease of those disapproving of the devel- food” to “Enough for all necessities and savings,”
opment of private business is very clear. If as can be seen in Tables 14.1, 14.2, and 14.3.
approval rates did not increase more pro- Additionally, one indicator of “locus control” is
nouncedly, it is due to the persistent high also used. This item classifies respondents
percentages of those who had some difficulties depending on whether they believe life depends
expressing a clear opinion on the matter. more on themselves or more on external
To understand the nature of these trends, we conditions.
split the sample into categories according to dif- For the sake of simplicity, we present the
ferent criteria such as education, social class, results after combining the two groups replying,
employment status, place of residence and birth “completely approve” and “approve more than
cohort. It should be mentioned that given the disapprove” to the question about the develop-
complexity of ascribing individuals to categories ment of private business. Similarly, we also com-
of social class, which are typical in western bined those who replied “yes” and “probably yes”
countries (Simonchuk 2010, 2011, 2020) we to the question about starting one’s own business.
utilized one item of the survey, as a proxy for According to a micro-institutional theoretical
social class, to which respondents replied describ- perspective, there should be significant
ing the financial situation of the household. The differences between groups of individuals,
212 A. Veira-Ramos and T. Liubyva

Table 14.2 Respondents that would like to start their own business (%)
Social groups 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Primary education 22.6 25.0 24.1 28.5 28.5 37.5
Secondary 51.4 51.6 46.4 54.6 48.9 47.0
Vocational 50.7 49.3 51.0 55.0 48.1 50.8
University 56.0 55.2 56.7 63.5 57.8 57.8
Employed in public sector 43.5 44.3 43.8 48.2 41.8 45.1
In private sector 62.9 68.5 63.4 65.7 60.7 68.0
In both sectors 34.5 47.6 62.0 65.0 52.3 78.6
Not employed 29.8 33.3 33.2 38.7 35.6 36.9
Life depends more on myself 53.8 57.3 58.1 61.5 56.7 56.9
The same on me and on external conditions 50.1 50.5 50.7 48.5 49.5 55.3
More on external conditions 30.7 37.7 37.3 44.0 38.3 44.0
Poor (not enough for food) 22.6 39.5 27.9 37.8 36.6 51.4
Enough for food only 34.7 37.7 34.4 41.1 38.1 44.2
Enough for meagre living 43.4 48.6 47.3 52.0 50.4 51.0
Enough for all necessities 62.7 51.9 60.4 60.1 52.7 57.5
Enough for savings 68.1 67.1 68.8 72.7 58.8 68.4
Lives in a village 36.3 40.1 38.5 38.4 39.6 48.1
Town up to 250,000 42.5 46.3 47.9 53.8 47.2 50.1
City 250,000 to 500,000 44.9 47.5 56.6 58.9 43.6 43.5
City over 500,000 45.3 51.8 45.9 51.4 53.5 57.5
Employer 78.6 80.6 85.3 63.6 65.5 62.5
Self-employed 74.3 74.1 84.0 82.4 74.8 62.5
Employee 48.6 53.8 54.6 51.2 58.3 47.4
Unemployed 29.1 33.2 39.0 35.9 36.9 32.7
Hard to tell 34.3 41.3 57.4 38.3 50.0 51.6
Total 41.4 45.6 45.9 49.3 45.7 50.6
Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Author’s calculations. Figures for uneven years are not shown for sake of space but
could be made available upon request and only for 2005

resulting from their different personal or not employed. As expected, a higher degree of
experiences. Favorable attitudes towards locus control is also associated with higher sup-
institutions, which are characteristic of the new port to private business. Data shown in
socio-economic context of free markets are Table 14.2, concerning willingness to start a busi-
expected to be stronger, more deeply rooted ness reveals exactly the same patterns.
among social groups that have benefitted the It is well to note that while positive attitudes
most from the transformation of the Ukrainian towards private entrepreneurship increased
economy. remarkably amongst those social groups which
The data from the Ukrainian Social Survey were initially more reluctant towards it, these
confirm all the expectations derived from the positive attitudes stagnated or even decreased
micro-institutional approach. Those with higher amongst those groups initially more in favor of
education, higher financial status and living in private entrepreneurship. Concerning the former
more urbanized areas were more inclined to group, such results may be interpreted as evi-
approve private business than those with lower dence that individual socialization experiences,
education, fewer financial resources and those as proposed by micro-cultural theories, are also
living in rural areas. Additionally, those playing a role in the reshaping of attitudes and
employed in the private sector showed more pos- beliefs of the Ukrainian society, making younger
itive attitudes towards the development of private generations increasingly more favorable towards
business than those employed in the public sector private entrepreneurship regardless of their
14 Attitudes Towards Free Market and Socialism in Ukraine: Empirical Insights. . . 213

Table 14.3 Respondents declaring to be in favor of a return to planned economy (%)


Social groups 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016
Primary education 40.2 40.8 36.3 38.4 36.6 43.9 28.8 20.7
Secondary 25.2 30.3 31.3 34.1 31.3 33.0 29.5 29.7
Vocational 25.5 23.9 32.2 27.1 33.6 34.2 27.7 28.2
University 16.0 19.2 21.6 22.5 22.0 22.1 21.2 22.0
In public sector 26.8 29.2 27.9 26.6 31.9 35.8 27.9
In private sector 16.9 21.5 20.0 23.9 25.3 26.8 19.8
In both sectors 16.3 27.6 30.5 12.2 20.5 18.2 22.0
Not employed 37.2 38.6 37.0 35.7 36.4 39.3 31.7
Life depends more on myself 26.3 27.4 24.7 28.8 25.7 29.3 27.6 21.8
The same on me and on external conditions 21.8 21.9 22.4 22.2 28.9 31.9 19.0 21.3
More on external conditions 34.5 39.6 37.3 33.8 36.7 37.3 30.9 30.1
Poor (not enough for food) 45.2 57.2 41.8 38.2 37.8 53.0 31.1 36.6
Enough for food only 32.1 34.7 38.8 39.9 37.6 37.8 28.0 28.8
Enough for meagre living 19.6 25.7 24.3 22.8 27.9 29.7 25.7 21.8
Enough for all necessities 22.5 24.8 24.0 23.6 29.7 28.6 27.0 23.4
Enough for savings 17.1 22.9 10.3 20.8 19.7 30.8 17.7 10.2
Village 30.1 36.6 31.1 31.9 34.6 37.0 27.4 33.5
Town up to 250,000 27.3 28.9 30.8 29.2 30.5 35.2 28.1 24.0
City 250,000 to 500,000 31.7 34.0 29.6 27.0 29.1 31.0 28.0 29.2
City over 500,000 27.8 26.3 27.8 26.9 31.9 30.0 22.1 26.1
Employer 3.8 14.3 23.3 12.1 18.2 24.1 18.8
Self-employed 29.2 16.8 21.5 25.5 26.7 26.2 21.3
Employee 22.9 26.0 23.6 28.4 29.2 21.5 21.9
Unemployed 39.0 37.4 36.6 39.7 31.7 31.1
Hard to tell 41.4 33.3 25.9 34.8 33.3 19.4
Total 29.4 31.8 30.1 29.1 31.9 34.0 26.6 25.7
Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Author’s calculations. Figures for uneven years are not but could be made available
upon request. Blank spaces for 2003 and 2005 and when the item was not included in the survey the given year

position in the society. Concerning the latter towards private entrepreneurship. It can also be
group, this could be due to a ceiling effect or to observed that initial levels of support for private
disenchantment with the slow pace at which entrepreneurship from the different cohorts did
reforms were implemented and economic growth not vary much over time. This puzzling finding
below expectations. constitutes a challenge for the interpretation of
results already presented. If attitudes towards pri-
vate entrepreneurship remained rather constant
3.1.1 The Generational Gap
for all cohorts, what could be the reason for the
When doing research in former socialistic
changes observed in Figs. 14.6 and 14.7 and
countries, one must take into consideration the
Tables 14.1 and 14.2? One plausible explanation
generational divide that differentiates those
to reconcile both findings would stem from
cohorts socialized under communism from those
assuming that changes in attitude amongst certain
who did not experience it during their early adult-
social groups may have been driven to a great
hood. Indeed, attitudes of respondents of different
extent by generational replacement. Changes in
birth cohorts, shown in Figs. 14.7 and 14.8, indi-
the Ukrainian society could be viewed, therefore,
cate that there was an important generational gap,
as a function of changes in the composition of the
as one would expect from a micro-cultural per-
population, rather than a function of how people
spective. The younger generations showed signif-
changed their attitudes over time. The decreasing
icantly higher levels of acceptance and support
214 A. Veira-Ramos and T. Liubyva

Respondents in favor of developing private business by


birth cohort (%)
100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

0%
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

1900-1945 1946-1959 1960-1969

1970-1979 1980-1989 1990-2000

Fig. 14.7 Evolution of favorable attitudes towards private business by birth cohort. Source: Ukrainian Society Survey.
Author’s Calculations

Respondents who would like to start their own business


by birth cohort (%)
100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

0%
2004 2005 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

1900-1945 1946-1959 1960-1969


1970-1979 1980-1989 1990-2000

Fig. 14.8 Evolution of willingness to start a business by birth cohort. Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Author’s
Calculations
14 Attitudes Towards Free Market and Socialism in Ukraine: Empirical Insights. . . 215

number of individuals who belong to older 3.2 Support to Socialism


cohorts (the group more hostile to the develop-
ment of private business), combined with the The Ukrainian Society Survey between 2002 and
corresponding increase in the number of 2017 included the question, “What do you think
individuals belonging to the youngest generations is the government’s role in regulating the econ-
(those more in favor of private business), could omy?” It allows people to answer, amongst other
explain not only a significant part of the increase options, that “the return to planned economy with
in the part of the population that favored private complete government control is a necessity”. We
business, but also the relatively slow pace at interpret this to be a strong indicator of support of
which such change is occurring. It also allows the former socio-economic system. The results
for one to assess the apparent irreversibility of from the data analysis shown in Fig. 14.9
such a trend. Trends observed for categories of revealed that a quite steady 25–30% of
people who are on average less inclined to sup- respondents chose this option and there was little
port private entrepreneurship could be explained variation observed over time. Also, almost half of
partly by generational replacement or by the the population thought that combination would
process of adjusting to institutional changes as work best, and the government should have a
well. In fact, the process of adjusting to institu- role in market practices. This also showed accep-
tional change could be reinforced by generational tance of both models by the Ukrainian
replacement as younger cohorts of adult population.
respondents had already been socialized under Differences between social groups on their
the new institutional context. The generational aggregate support to a potential return to a system
replacement mechanism was coherent with the of planned economy seemed to decrease over
data showing that positive attitudes towards entre- time between the different social categories.
preneurship grew among the social groups which However, convergence did not occur around the
were initially less favorable towards private entre- lower initial values shown by social groups which
preneurship. Convergence was observed around were less inclined to support central planned
the relatively high levels of acceptance shown by economy. Those included the more highly
the social groups that were initially more favorable educated and those employed in the private sec-
to this institution. However, stagnation and slight tor, with higher incomes and living in more
decreases of favorable attitudes towards private urbanized areas. In fact, support of a return to a
entrepreneurship observed amongst the higher planned economy increased amongst those
educated, for instance, could not be explained. initially less favorable to it and decreased
Results from plotting birth cohort versus amongst those initially more in favor of it. Thus,
variables reflecting attitudes towards private differences between groups on this matter
entrepreneurship showed differences that were decreased over the years converging to interme-
more consistent with the micro-cultural diate values.
approaches than with the macro-cultural theories. These apparently puzzling results, in principle
Younger generations, socialized under the new inconsistent with the trend towards higher accep-
institutional arrangements, displayed significant tance of private entrepreneurship, which was
differences compared to older cohorts that described above, can be explained by considering
remained constant over time. This was despite that there is a decreasing proportion of individuals
the fact that they shared the same national cultural answering, “difficult to say”. Thus, both options,
background and lived under the same historical “return to planned economy” and “government
context of socio-economic transformation. More- role should be minimized” or “government
over, generational divide seemed to decrease should combine control and market practices”
amongst the three youngest generations while grew at the expenses of the latter. What is more
remaining salient compared to the oldest ones. complicated to explain is that the growth of
216 A. Veira-Ramos and T. Liubyva

Attitudes towards adequate role of government in regulating


the economy
100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

0%
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2017

Difficult to say
A return to planned economy with complete government control is a necessity
Government control should be combined with market practices
The government’s role must be minimized – the market regulates everything

Fig. 14.9 What do you think is the government’s role in regulating the economy? Source: Ukrainian Society Survey.
Author’s Calculations

partisans of a planned economy occurred amongst with higher expectations, who had higher educa-
those social groups which were more favorable to tional degrees.
the development of private business. In contrast,
support for a return to a planned economy
3.2.1 The Generational Divide
decreased sharply amongst all social groups
Plotting answers to this item by birth cohort, we
which were initially more favorable to this option:
observe the importance of the generational divide
the unemployed, more poorly educated and with
in Fig. 14.10. As expected, (see also Brik and
lower financial status.
Shestakovskyi 2020) older generations,
Combining these results with those from pre-
socialized under the Soviet regime were more
vious tables, one might infer that two processes
inclined to support the return to planned economy
were underway. On the one hand, privileged
than the younger ones were. The evolution over
groups were experiencing some disenchantment
time reflects trends towards convergence until
with the pace at which economic improvement
2014. Salient ups and downs can be partly
was developing in Ukraine, thus, shattering their
explained by sociopolitical events. Events like
expectations and causing some to lean towards
the Orange Revolution of 2004 conceded conver-
support of a strong government. On the other
gence towards lower acceptance to planned econ-
hand, socialization with new values and beliefs,
omy. The return of pro-Russian candidate, Viktor
characteristics of the new institutional
Yanukovich, to power in 2010 provoked
arrangements, were affecting the opinion of
increasing polarization between cohorts. Events
those less privileged and, in principle, more nos-
which occurred during 2014 (Euromaidan)
talgic of the former political regime. In other
again triggered a convergence towards decreas-
words, timid improvements of the standard of
ing support for a planned economy, but after two
living were perceived with less disenchantment
years differences between the cohorts widened
amongst the less privileged than amongst those
again.
14 Attitudes Towards Free Market and Socialism in Ukraine: Empirical Insights. . . 217

Respondents who think a return to planned economy is a


necessity by birth cohort (%)
100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

0%
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2017

1900-1945 1946-1959 1960-1969


1970-1979 1980-1989 1990-2000
Fig. 14.10 Evolution of support to a planned economy by birth cohort. Source: Ukrainian Society Survey. Author’s
Calculations

argue that the lack of improvement of governance


4 Concluding Remarks
performance with democratic institutions
explained the slow decrease of negative attitudes
The data analyzed can hardly be used as evidence
towards private entrepreneurship and the persis-
in support of macro-cultural theories because
tent positive attitudes towards a return to a
there are significant differences within Ukrainian
planned economy, particularly amongst the older
society related to attitudes towards planned econ-
cohorts.
omy and private entrepreneurship. Despite com-
Differences observed between social groups
mon cultural background, significant differences
based on birth cohort, educational attainment,
are observed between various social groups in
financial status, employment situation, place of
their level of support towards the development
residence or locus control are better explained
of private business, or the return to a planned
by micro-cultural and micro-institutional theories.
economy.
From a micro-cultural approach, the differences
Concerning the validity of the macro-
between generations in their attitudes towards
institutional approaches, salient and persistent
private entrepreneurship and planned economy
differences between social groups in their
can be attributed to different socialization pro-
attitudes towards private entrepreneurship and
cesses that individuals went through in their
planned economy do not correspond with the
early lives. The persistence of such generational
observed, almost unanimous, low trust in political
divides can be seen as solid evidence in support of
institutions or the widespread negative evaluation
this perspective, particularly when changes
of aggregate government performance (Veira-
towards higher acceptance of private entre-
Ramos and Golovakha 2020). According to the
preneurship and decreased support for a return
macro-institutional approach, only improved
to planned economy were observed amongst
institutional performance can override low trust
social groups which initially displayed the most
inherited from past deceptive experiences and
negative attitudes to the former and the most
socialization. From this perspective one could
218 A. Veira-Ramos and T. Liubyva

positive ones to the latter. Change caused by Ramos, T. Liubyva, & E. Golovakha (Eds.), Ukraine
generational replacement is coherent with this in transformation (pp. 35–53). Cham: Palgrave
Macmillan.
approach, though not sufficient to explain all the Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory.
observed variations. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
The micro-institutional perspective would Dasgupta, P. (1988). Trust as a commodity. In
argue that an increased tendency towards capital- D. Gambetta (Ed.), Trust: Making and breaking coop-
erative relations (pp. 49–72). Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
ism is based on the individual’s personal Dogan, M., & Higley, J. (Eds.). (1998). Elites, crises and
experiences. A growing number of individuals the origins of regimes. Lanham, MD: Rowman &
who, over the past decades, experienced the Littlefield.
benefits of the market economy more intensely, Golovakha, E. (1996). Transformiruyushcheyesia
Obshchestvo. Opyt Sociologicheskogo Monitoringa v
though timid, would be the source of changes. Ukraine [Transforming society. Experience of socio-
Differences observed between social groups are logical monitoring]. Kyiv: Institute of Sociology of
entirely consistent with this approach. However, NAS of Ukraine.
explaining the evolution of the attitudes of differ- Golovakha, E., & Panina, N. (2003). Post-Soviet deinsti-
tutionalization and formation of new social institutions
ent groups over time requires complementary in Ukraine. In E. Golovakha (Ed.), Ukrainian socio-
insight, as mentioned above, provided by the logical review 2000–01 (pp. 12–34). Kyiv: Institute of
micro-cultural perspective. Sociology of the National Academy of Sciences of
The Ukrainian society has been undergoing Ukraine.
Golovakha, E., & Panina, N. (2008). Post-Soviet anomie:
great transformations triggered by timid Specifics of leaving the state of anomie demoralization
improvements in the standard of living, genera- in Russia and Ukraine. Obshhestvennye nauki i
tional replacement, and changes in the sovremennost [Social Sciences and Modernity], 6,
sociodemographic composition of its population. 5–10.
Golovakha, E., & Panina, N. (2009). Main stages and
Social groups which are more in favor of private tendencies in transformation. In E. Golovakha (Ed.),
entrepreneurship and more hostile to return to Ukrainian sociological review 2006–07 (pp. 3–24).
planned economy are growing. Such mechanism Kyiv: Institute of Sociology of the National Academy
of social change may cause these transformations of Sciences of Ukraine.
Golovakha, E., Liubyva, T., & Veira-Ramos, A. (2020).
to not be very visible but, at the same time, makes Introduction: Ukrainian society under reluctant
them irreversible. Ambivalence and division transformation and institutional duality. In A. Veira-
about which path to undertake transforms into Ramos, T. Liubyva, & E. Golovakha (Eds.), Ukraine in
intense political competition, which in turn, transformation (pp. 1–18). Cham: Palgrave
Macmillan.
results in frequent changes of government. This Inglehart, R. (1997). Modernization and postmoder-
path may not be the fastest towards a complete nization: Cultural, economic and political change in
transformation of the Ukrainian society, but per- 41 societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
haps it allows different layers of the population to Mishler, W., & Rose, R. (1994). Support for parliaments
and regimes in the transition toward democracy in
participate in the process and not feel excluded eastern Europe. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 19,
from political life. This has certainly contributed 5–32.
to reinforce the sentiment of national unity over Mishler, W., & Rose, R. (2001). What are the origins of
the decades (Veira-Ramos and Liubyva 2020), political trust? Testing institutional and cultural
theories in post-communist societies. Comparative
despite the numerous episodes of political Political Studies, 34(1), 30–62.
turmoil. Nee, V., & Swedberg, R. (2005). Economic sociology and
new institutional economics. In C. Ménard & M. M.
Shirley (Eds.), Handbook of new institutional econom-
ics (pp. 789–818). Boston, MA: Springer.
References Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic
traditions in modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Almond, G. A., & Verba, S. (1963). The civic culture. University Press.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Simonchuk, E. (2010). Class action: Tendencies of forma-
Brik, T., & Shestakovskyi, O. (2020). Attitudes about tion of the social classes in Ukraine. Ukrainian Socio-
privatization and the shadow of communism: logical Review, 2011, 20–56.
25 Years of anti-market scepticism. In A. Veira-
14 Attitudes Towards Free Market and Socialism in Ukraine: Empirical Insights. . . 219

Simonchuk, E. (2011). Dynamika Sotsial’no-klasovoyi Alberto Veira-Ramos is assistant professor at the Carlos
Struktury u Postradyans’kiy Ukrayini [Dynamics of III University of Madrid, Spain.
social-class Structure in Post-Soviet Ukraine]. Research topics: Demography of the labor market in
Ukrayins’ke Suspil’stvo. Dvadtsyat’ Rokiv European societies, the occupational distribution of
Nezalezhnosti. Sotsiologichnyy Monitoring, 68–83. immigrant population in Spain, social changes in Ukraine.
Simonchuk, E. (2020). The dynamics of class structure in Recent publications: Veira-Ramos, Alberto, Tetiana
post-Soviet Ukraine. In A. Veira-Ramos, T. Liubyva, Liubyva, and Evgenii Golovakha, eds. 2020. Ukraine in
& E. Golovakha (Eds.), Ukraine in transformation Transformation: From Soviet Republic to European
(pp. 55–90). Cham: Palgrave Macmillan. Society. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan. Fedakova, Denisa,
Veira-Ramos, A., & Golovakha, E. (2020). Empirical evi- and Alberto Veira-Ramos. 2019. Job Security across
dence of persistent institutional duality in Ukraine. In Europe: Predictors of Subjective Job Security in Northern,
A. Veira-Ramos, T. Liubyva, & E. Golovakha (Eds.), Southern, and Central European Countries. Central
Ukraine in transformation (pp. 19–34). Cham: European Societies on the Map of Europe 5/1: 100–17.
Palgrave Macmillan. Schmelzer, Paul, and Alberto Veira-Ramos. 2018. Out-
Veira-Ramos, A., & Liubyva, T. (2020). Ukrainian comes of Unemployment Episodes during early Career for
identities in transformation. In A. Veira-Ramos, Mismatched Workers in the United Kingdom and
T. Liubyva, & E. Golovakha (Eds.), Ukraine in trans- Germany and the Mediating Effects of Education and
formation (pp. 203–228). Cham: Palgrave Macmillan. Institutions. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility
55: 99–108.

Internet References Tetiana Liubyva works at the Institute of Sociology of


National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine, Ukraine.
Research topics: Impact planning and assessment of
USTR (Office of the United States Trade Representative).
social projects, social changes in Ukraine, media literacy.
(2019). Special 301 report. April 2019. https://ustr.
Recent publications: Veira-Ramos, Alberto, Tetiana
gov/sites/default/files/2019_Special_301_Report.pdf
Liubyva, and Evgenii Golovakha, eds. 2020. Ukraine in
[2020.01.01].
Transformation: From Soviet Republic to European
Hart, K. (2012). The informalization of the world econ-
Society. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan. Murrock, Erin, Joy
omy. Keynote lecture for the 24th conference of the
Amulya, Mehri Druckman, and Tetiana Liubyva. 2018.
Societa’ Italiana di Economia Pubblica, Pavia, 24–25.
Winning the War on State-Sponsored Propaganda:
September 2012. http://thememorybank.co.uk/2012/
Results from an Impact Study of a Ukrainian News
10/17/the-informalization-of-the-world-economy/
Media and Information Literacy Program. Journal of
[2020.01.02].
Media Literacy Education 10/2: 53–85.
Alternative Food Networks
and the Socialization of Food 15
Gilles Allaire

1 Introduction accomplished form of public governance (by the


public). The representation of citizens, as
Since the 1990s, the developing global economy informed consumers, assumes that these citizens
has undergone important changes in market are dependent on the market for their sustenance
structures and governance regimes, which entail and personal services.
the ways of competition and coordination among The principal features of these changes encom-
economic actors, businesses, professions, social pass: (i) the internationalization of food provision
movements, the states, international agencies, and systems; (ii) a quality turn and services turn in
local governments. Trade liberalization and the production and markets; (iii) an appropriation or
decline of institutional prices in the agro-food privatization of public food production resources,
sectors, resulting from national agricultural policy both upstream with the patenting of genes, and
reforms, were driving forces for a change in the downstream with the design of intangible
then prevailing competition regimes in major qualities related to modes of production, circula-
value chains and regional economies. Contractual tion, or delivery (Allaire 2004, 2013); (iv) the
regulation by voluntary standards partly multiplication of market quality standards and of
substituted state regulations. One important fea- standard setting organizations (Allaire 2010);
ture of this change was that quality mattered as and, finally, (v) a de-professionalization of agro-
source of competition within firms, market food chains, which accompany upscaling of
segments, and regions, which implies contentious markets. This evolution allowed for affirming
institutional rearrangements. Quality can be various policies in developed and emergent
referred to by using two apparently opposite countries, as well as developing multi-actor
conceptualizations. One is the emerging of reflex- initiatives, both at the international and local
ive consumers, and even proactive consumers in levels.
contested markets, (e.g., tobacco, genetics, adver- Alternative Food Networks (AFNs), as a con-
tising), or advocating alternative practices. The ceptual framework, came into the field to distin-
other conceptualization is the emergence of guish food networks connecting territories,
informed consumers, not necessarily reflexive, products, and people as identities, which claimed
which allows market efficiency according to the to be alternatives to conventional food provision-
neoliberal rhetoric, that sees in the free market an ing systems or alternatives to dominant food sup-
ply chains. The conceptual boundaries of
alternativeness and localness are vague and con-
G. Allaire (*)
Institut National de la Recherche Agronomique, Toulose, troversial. Since the 1990s, a growing body of
France research directed towards these so-called
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 221
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_15
222 G. Allaire

alternatives has developed. While local food towards a more sustainable agriculture, however,
networks and specific quality products had been cannot be observed” (Krausmann and Langthaler
cast aside as remnants or marginal phenomena in 2019, 93).
the shadow of food industrialization, they were The understanding of these phenomena
seen proliferating alongside the liberalization of stimulates one to rethink the functioning of
agricultural policies. However, those are not the markets and how market hegemony develops.
same as the previous family and community Alternatives are not outside the market economy.
networks. They also involve different social On the contrary, they bring new goods (ethical
experiences and jurisdictional contexts. Today, and care values) into the relentless movement of
even farmers’ markets and farm direct sales are commoditization of all the resources for human
instituted and regulated. life, and at the same time they participate in the
The concept of AFNs covers a wide variety of reappraisal of these values by creating new social
phenomena related to product qualification and relations. A restricted focus on alternative food
market identities: organic, fair trade, geographical hides the global food economy and politics.
indications, and regional, local, quality, artisanal, Browsing the literature on AFNs, we first will
natural, ethnic, and premium specialties, even examine conceptual dynamics and how the alter-
today urban agriculture, and types of market orga- native initiatives are integrated in the theories of
nization, from transnational standards (organic, transformation of food systems or regimes. After
fair trade, and specific corporate quality schemes) that, we will consider political economy issues
to various forms of short food supply chains. regarding the concept of food regime, the debate
Several collective books, special journal issues, around the quality turn and the conventionaliza-
and often cited papers refer to this heterogeneous tion of alternatives, and the nested markets the-
variety. ory. Finally, we will propose a conceptual
AFNs are presented as responses to the crises framework for addressing markets as control
of conventional, intensive, and productivist agri- projects, quality as social order, and regimes of
culture, and also as a response to a growing social competition.
demand, supported by popular media, for a wider
variety of distinctive food, as well as a demand
for health security. They claim to reintroduce 2 How to Position Alternatives
ethical, human values into the world of food, in Social Change
moving against its industrialization. In the terms
of Campbell (2009), food from somewhere This section explains the contrasts in the devel-
contends against food from nowhere. Neverthe- opment of AFNs, which can be related to two
less, several authors discussed the claims of historical processes. On one hand, there is a social
AFNs and questioned the nature of demand relating to the rising of revenues, level of
alternativeness. education, and individualization of social behav-
An obvious divergence exists between the ior; on the other hand, the demand or quest for the
popularity of AFNs which benefit from large diversity of experiences, and mobility. We see a
media coverage and their weight in the global claim for sovereignty, generally interpreted as
food economy, and their social and ecological moral or ethical behaviors, in these quests.
impacts. Krausmann and Langthaler (2019) For food markets, two decisive movements
noted recently, that in western industrialized have occurred since the 1970s: the supermarket
countries, the rise of the food from somewhere revolution and consumer movements (see also
segment and the increasing demand for organic Koos in this handbook). These prompted the
produce (organic farmland has expanded to development of mass food production and
roughly 4% currently). They concluded a study markets. Downstream actors gradually take over
on agriculture and food trade in a socio-ecological from upstream actors, in directing innovation. In
perspective by stating that “a fundamental shift the context of overproduction, a service logic
15 Alternative Food Networks and the Socialization of Food 223

rapidly developed including ready-made foods, states serve capital. This, to me, is the distinctive
the catering industry, nutrition advisors, and all organizing principle by which corporate rights have
been elevated over the sovereign rights of states
the services regarding standard setting and infor- and their citizens—the World Trade Organization
mation technologies. Since the 1990s this market- (WTO) rules (among other ongoing trade
ing logic along with the social transformation of agreements) made this clear” (McMichael
modes of life contributed to reshape food sociali- 2016, 649).
zation, and to the emergence of AFNs. We will This move is particularly illustrated by agricul-
examine theoretical approaches addressing this tural research, where agrochemical and seed
emergence. companies now control a large part of the
activities, even in public institutions. They do
this partly by the development of non-state or
2.1 Food Regimes hybrid standard setting organizations, which
reflect compromises around quality conventions
Harriet Friedmann and Philip McMichael (Daviron and Allaire 2018).
introduced Food Regimes (FR) to “explore the Whether or not such a regime was currently in
role of agriculture in the development of the capi- place, was an issue of debate (McMichael 2009).
talist world economy, and in the trajectory of the From Friedmann’s perspective, “we have not yet
state system” (1989, 93). They proposed this con- seen the full-scale (hegemonic) establishment of a
cept to “link international relations of food pro- [new] food regime” (2005, 231). She suggests
duction and consumption to forms of that a corporate-environmental food regime “is
accumulation broadly distinguishing periods of emerging as part of a larger restructuring of capi-
capitalist transformations since 1870” (ibid., 95). talism” and in order to understand the present
The contrast between extensive and intensive transformation, she proposes shifting “the focus
capitalist accumulation distinguishes the first of analysis of past food regimes toward periods of
two food regimes described. They are a British restructuring instead of periods of stability” (ibid.,
centered food regime, ranging from 1870–1929, 231). She argues that
and a US dominated regime from 1947–73. This “regimes appear less as static structures and more
approach was developed in numerous studies as provisional compromises among some of the
published in journals such as Sociologia Ruralis contending social actors, who manage to create a
new interpretive frame in common. . . . Times of
and Journal of Peasant Studies. Several authors
contention offer real choices of direction. More
announced the emergence of a third food regime than one compromise is always possible. Social
since the 1990s, more often referred to as corpo- movements play a key role, both in unfolding crisis
rate (McMichael 2009), but also as neoliberal and in emerging relations of wealth and power. The
emblem of quality standards, which is presently
(Burch and Lawrence 2009) or corporate-envi-
reconfiguring relations among social movements,
ronmental (Friedmann 2005). transnational corporate food supply chains,
Free markets and competition are seen as the governments and international organizations,
organizing principles of this third food regime, in appears to be the basis for new and contending
frames, and thus for one of several possible new
contrast to the previous two. The principle for the
regimes” (ibid., 236).
first would have been empire, and for the second
the State. The result would be the creation of a In light of this, we can consider social reactions to
truly globalized agriculture, seen as a transna- stalemates and to the damages of the Fordist
tional space, integrated by commodities markets agricultural model, including a search for energy
under the power of supply chain managers. efficiency, change in the geography of food, and
According to McMichael transformations of the institutional settings of
“In contradistinction to previous food regimes
markets.
constructed by hegemonic British and US states,
the food regime under neoliberalism
institutionalizes a hegemonic relation whereby
224 G. Allaire

2.2 Quality Turn Product designs are debated and negotiated


and Conventionalization among various types of actors, private or govern-
of Emerging Alternatives mental, scientific experts or NGO representatives,
being specialized or not. Due to the predominance
What is known in the literature as the quality turn of supermarkets and the increasing role of the
appears to be one aspect of the emergence of a media in the circulation of quality
third FR. In numerous studies and in diverse representations, Allaire and Daviron (2006) pro-
manners this turn was related to the rise of the posed calling this new configuration the market
service economy; the transformation of media regime. International multi-party forums
consumers; the change in trade circuits; reformed produce standards for sustainable development,
food policies; and new technologies for food while social movements, which have acquired
processing and provision. The shift towards ser- an international base, promote a moral economy.
vice economy was not the point which was most While in a first period, from the mid-1990s to
studied in the context of the quality turn. This the beginning of the 2000s, alternative food
shift has included the development of new inter- systems were put on the research agenda for
mediary industries that has gained a strategic their distinction from conventional systems,
importance in food channelling and has included thereafter, this simple distinction was called in
a new type of governance regime. Knowledge question. Proponents of AFNs claim (i) that the
services have included qualification procedures production and consumption of food through
(audits, patents pertaining to design and business AFNs are closely tied together spatially, econom-
models). ically, and socially; (ii) that AFNs redistribute
In our view, the quality turn is not limited to value through the network against the logic of
the emergence of AFNs, even if we take these commodity markets; (iii) that they substitute
alternative networks in the broadest sense, it trust against the outbreak of food scare and the
includes quality assurance schemes under corpo- loss of confidence in industrial food; (iv) and that
rate control. This turn relates to all current forms they create new forms of political association and
of institutional restructuring of markets that mobi- food governance. Even so, AFNs rapidly come
lize a multitude of public and private standards under critical scrutiny. More than simply a
(in B2B relations), or voluntary standards, that springboard for the construction of more equita-
inform the consumer (Reardon et al. 2001; ble and sustainable food systems, AFNs were
Fulponi 2006). Under pressure from the retail considered as social re-stratification of consump-
sector, which aims at covering itself vis-à-vis tion (Verhaegen 2012).
consumers, third-party certification (TPC) has According to Forssell and Lankoski, the liter-
been introduced in many areas of retail procure- ature often addresses a specific type of AFN or a
ment contracts. In Europe, for example, an inven- specific sustainability-related issue, “it is hard to
tory compiled for the European Commission in form a clear overall picture of the sustainability
2010 lists more than 440 different systems, most promise of AFNs” (2015, 63). Nevertheless, the
of which were established in the previous decade, authors argue that indirect impacts of learning and
for a wide range of marketing public standards participation in reflexive networks may be highly
have been developed since the creation of the significant for sustainability. Yet the reference to
European Single Market (1992). Hatanaka et al. social movements and the reflexive consumer is
(2005, 354) argue that TPC “reflects a broader not enough to isolate true AFNs, since social
shift from public to private governance” and the movements interfere with capitalist firm
growing power of supermarkets to regulate the strategies.
global agro-food system. These authors state that After the pioneering work of Julie Guthman
TPC “also offers opportunities to create alterna- (see Guthman 2004), who analyzed agribusiness
tive practices” (ibid.). involvement in the Californian organic sector, the
so-called conventionalization thesis was
15 Alternative Food Networks and the Socialization of Food 225

documented regarding organic food production divergence of the perceived ways of reaching
and marketing, fair trade (Staricco 2016), and the objective of the organic movement, and also
other alternatives. This thesis denies so-called of reaching effective compromises within the
AFNs the qualification as alternatives but, it was component of the movement.1
challenged as the only interpretation of food Geographical Indications (GI) which have
economy dynamics. What is at stake here, is the existed since the nineteenth century, have been a
signification of the concept of alternativeness. It marketing label, used in the wine and spirit
is worth persisting in qualifying AFNs as sectors by large firms since the beginning. The
alternatives if we simply define alternative as a adoption of the WTO TRIPS Agreement2 and its
promise of difference (Le Velly 2017). Moreover, provisions for GIs has extended the range of
in our view, the controversy on the conditions of countries implementing the GI protection, in par-
the promise achievement is part of the identities ticular in the South. This extension of GI-related
of these alternatives. initiatives introduced new concerns for the imple-
In Western Europe, the organic movement mentation of GI rights. It concerned the quality
emerged in the 1920s, as a radical criticism of turn in two manners. In codes of practice quality
industrial society and science. As soon as the specifications, where sustainability concerns took
enlargement of this movement began (in the a rising place, were added to the criterion of the
1970s), there was a fight among the producers area of production. The GI label was also
between an economic, and a moral and ecological extended to products other than wine, especially
points of view. However, the majority, if not all, to cheese and meat. Rural policies in Europe (and
was seeking recognition and when the EU set a then in the South by FAO projects) promoted GI
specific regulation (1991) the various as a way of local development. Generally, such a
components of the organic movement standardization procedure assumes market
participated in building and implementing the upscaling. While some examples of success can
regulation in collaboration with scientific experts. be exhibited, there were failures when localized
A consensus established itself on a market proj- systems were unable to support production
ect, specified by a public label and certification upscaling. Thus, we can say nowadays, that this
procedures. The development of accredited certi- policy was an attempt to conventionalize
fication bodies, on a large scale, tended towards localized food systems, and that parts of these
divesting the organic movement of the property systems found ways to survive outside this label.
of conception of organic practices, but not In the case of local food, there is no specific
completely. Unity of the movement is maintained social movement promoting the idea. However,
by the existence of an international, today this term is abundantly present in media
non-governmental federation (IFOAM) and the magazines, private strategies, and policies. The
setup of additional labels by local networks concept of local food includes both community-
which seek to by-pass the conventionalization based box schemes and local supermarkets.
processes (Allaire 2016; Poméon et al. 2018).
While conventionalization is denounced inside
the movement as a threat to the organic products’ 1
According to IFOAM (2007): “The development and
specific identity and of a collapse of the professionalization of the organic sector, accompanied by
increased international trade has called for third party
corresponding remunerative market, the market
certification to become the norm in most developed
is still there, expanding. In one sense this existen- organic markets; nevertheless, Participatory Guaranty
tial threat is part of the organic movement iden- Systems have never stopped to exist and serve organic
tity. Conventionalization reflects a differentiation producers and consumers eager to maintain local
economies and direct, transparent relationships.”
in the domain of organic food supply chains, long 2
The TRIPS (Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Prop-
or short, and of marketplaces (producer market vs
erty Rights) Agreement is Annex 1C of the Agreement
supermarkets). Behind the material and logistic establishing the World Trade Organization, signed in
differentiation of supply chains, one finds the Marrakesh, Morocco on 15 April 1994.
226 G. Allaire

Conventionalization arises from the upscaling the role of agriculture in society” (van der Ploeg
of alternative markets, and the recognition of et al. 2012, 136–37).
AFNs in rural policies. Conventionalization the- It was not always acknowledged that the pro-
sis questions the frontier between AFNs and duction of new services needs the construction of
wider market infrastructures, as does the theory new markets. As these authors highlighted, the
of nested markets. diversification coming with new products and
services is accompanied by the creation of new
markets, which are governed in distinctive ways
2.3 Nested Markets alongside or within the general agricultural and
food markets.
European farmers, among others, have increas- Significantly different cases of nested markets
ingly responded to the squeeze on agricultural are studied in the book edited by Hebinck et al.
prices and to their instability, due to liberalization (2015): (1) institutional or public markets, (e.g.,
by the development of multifunctional farms pro- public program in Brazil against poverty);
ducing a range of new products and services such (2) local food, using very different situations: in
as agro-tourism, landscape management (envi- one case local producers sell at a price below
ronmental services), and on-farm processed supermarkets (the dominant system presenting
products. Multifunctional farms and alternative important transaction costs), in the other the
modes of production are associated with the idea short chains do not necessarily offer the consumer
of resistance assimilated with peasant autonomy. a price advantage, but rather a service; (3) specific
European researchers introduced AFNs and their quality food, including GIs, organic, and fair
promises, in the debates about the design of rural trade.
development policies. This took place in the con- According to van der Ploeg “the mainstream
text of the reform of the Common Agricultural markets and these emerging nested markets com-
Policy (CAP). Multifunctionality was debated as pose a highly heterogeneous whole that is cur-
competing rationale and objective to redirect rural rently characterized by several, often contrasting,
development strategies and policies. Finally, the trends and trajectories” (2015, 36). He proposes a
rural development pillar of the CAP (in 2000) was conceptual framework for understanding how
justified by the provision of public goods from these new markets are nested within the wider
private land, essentially environmental good markets. The argument refers to both institutional
practices, and notably the conversion to organic and economic integration of the food markets,
farming was subsidized as an environmental (the latter via the price system). Nested market
service. prices are set according to the prices of
Van der Ploeg et al. (2012) recognized com- commodities; however, the pricing procedure is
mon features in rural policies, in different independent. This view is different both from a
contexts (Europe, Brazil, China) and related dualistic approach of economic development as
them to the principle of sustaining newly well as from the thesis of the mainstreaming or
emerging nested markets. Previous policies were. absorption of alternatives and social critique in
the dominant system. It raises the question of
“focused on creating the conditions (for example,
by providing credit, seeds, and infrastructure)
which competition regime allows both the disso-
under which farmers could increase production ciation and the nesting of these particular
and the surpluses be effectively delivered to the markets.
urban economy . . . Current rural development Van der Ploeg also states that, “two strategic
policies are distinctively different. They have
emerged in countries that are characterized by
factors underlie the development and mainte-
abundantly productive and rapidly growing agri- nance of these nested markets: the distinctiveness
cultural sectors. They do not only aim to strengthen of the circulating products and services and the
agricultural growth. Instead they aim at redefining common-pool nature of the key resources that
15 Alternative Food Networks and the Socialization of Food 227

make up the socio-material infrastructure.”3 In the global food market is cracked as a dry land-
this concept, socio-material infrastructure scape. While food systems, whatever their scale,
means “the set of specific artefacts and rules that are subject to an overarching set of requirements
are used to channel flows of good and services and rules, bypasses are always experienced, espe-
between places and people” (van der Ploeg 2015, cially in transition periods.
24). These extraordinary markets can nest in Bypass ways are competition avoidance
wider markets because they bridge real economy strategies. They are behaviors to protect the actors
structural holes. The imperfections of the general from the competition on mass markets. Grouiez
commodity markets are interpreted as structural and Koleva (2018) analyzing the transformation
holes, which are opportunities for collective of the dairy industry in the post-communist
action to search for a bypass. A structural hole economies of Bulgaria and Russia, highlight two
“is identical to the absence of social relations” avoidance strategies with different time frames:
(van der Ploeg 2015, 28). Historically, the (i) taking opportunist short-term advantage on a
bridging of structural holes often results in the speculative market; and (ii) targeting protected
construction of new markets (ibid.). Private market segments (nested markets), alongside the
standard-setting organizations are developing as general mass market. A western European firm
an institutionalized solution to global problems, became a dominant actor in this industry and
which arise when international conventions or achieved integration of the dairy industry in the
national regulation are absent. They also develop global mass market by diffusing institutional
as a way of getting around WTO rules, thus rules. The strong market power gained by inter-
limiting the states’ ability to enforce production national businesses left little room for local
requirements over the products they import. operators. However, some of the latter were able
A large majority of food circulation is regional to resist this pressure. Two very different
or local. Only about 15% of all the food produced opportunities seized by local independents
in the world today crosses international borders. processors are described for creating nested
According to Krausmann and Langthaler, in markets, alongside the newly dominant mass mar-
2010, it was only 12% of all harvested crops, ket channeled by supermarkets. Both are
but food trade was on a fast rise. “[S]ince 1961 connected to a local demand constituted by peo-
global exports of agricultural products have ple rejecting western supermarkets. One channels
increased from 0.17 Gt/yr. to 1.4 Gt/yr. in 2016, the local production by exploiting a social-
that is, at a much faster pace than production. The material infrastructure sustained by the resilience
share of exports in harvested crops has doubled” of local institutions. The other takes advantage of
(2019, 87). While this rise of trade does not the low prices of the international market of milk
cancel out local transactions, national markets in powder to produce cheap products for the poor
the WTO era were interconnected and subjected local population. While the first way can claim
to finance as the 2008 crisis showed, and the bearing the social virtues of van der Ploeg’s
whole remaining 85% (not crossing the borders) nested market, the impacts of the second way
is still part of the world market. Van der Ploeg are more controversial. This one suggests that
views the world market as “a metaphor that is speculative and even mafia business are also
used to describe global modes of governance that: bridges over market chasms.
(1) impose one and the same set of global The analysis presented by Grouiez and Koleva
regulations and parameters on transactions, wher- has a large generality. Avoidance strategies are
ever and whenever they take place, and that generally searched for in order to resist conven-
(2) simultaneously centralize the value flows tionalization, even in the case of alternative
through a few nodes” (2015, 27). Nevertheless, markets, as we have seen for organic food and
geographical indications. Poméon et al. (2018)
3
Common-pool resources refers to the work of Elinor show two types of avoidance strategies from
Ostrom (1990). organic standard regime conventionalization: by
228 G. Allaire

multiplying private (collective) labels; and by develop, and (2) the market dynamics are given
radical change of the certification system, (Partic- by political projects. “Processes within the market
ipatory Guaranty Systems). reflect two types of political projects; the internal
firm power struggle and the power struggle across
firms to control markets” (Fligstein 1996, 659).
3 Markets as Social Orders To name these struggles, Fligstein borrows the
and Competition Regimes concept of control project from White (1992).
Control conceptions, although related to cultural
Economic sociology distinguishes two levels of and political projects, are not external to the mar-
market order analysis. Stable expectations formed ket economic order. Instead, prevailing
by socialized actors constitute the building blocks conceptions of control form a market institutional
of market institutions, while the notion of the regime, under given governance structures. The
order of markets refers to the institutional social material infrastructures supporting nested
arrangements in which coordination problems markets are stabilized by shared conceptions of
can be solved, and markets stabilized. According control as they are for mass markets.
to Fligstein, there are two sources of instability of Conceptions of control gather conventions of
market orders: (1) the tendency of firms to under- productivity regulating the struggle for the orga-
cut one another’s prices, and (2) “the problem of nization of productive structures, and conventions
keeping the firm together as a political coalition” of quality, which relate to the struggle among
(1996, 659). economic actors to control product design.4
The term, competition regime in the current According to Fligstein, once a conception of con-
economic literature refers to international trade trol is dominating a specific market or polity, it is
regulations (tariffs and other barriers), and to collective and thus a fallible instrumental
competition law at the national or sectoral level. resource. When distinguishing the two levels of
In microeconomics competition regime covers power struggles, within and between firms,
the patterns of a firm’s strategic behavior (quan- Fligstein had industries dominated by big firms
tity and price objectives). We will consider com- in mind. However, depending on the type of
petition regimes in a broader sense. Competition industry, on the legal forms of entrepreneurship,
regimes are the sets of institutions which control and on the cooperation instruments, there are
competition within market spaces and create these other protagonists in setting control projects in a
spaces. They consist in representations and rules, given market. There are multiple social scenes
governed at different levels of the society, which where conceptions of control are confronted.
identify transaction formulas. Conventions of Even in the case where a supply chain is managed
cooperation are not only a limit to competition, by a captain company, there are numerous
but also are necessary to socially authorize com- stakeholders and intermediaries participating in
petition. They can be distinguished according to standard setting and in communication. We can
historical periods, economic areas, branches, and also see multiple, committed actors that cross firm
industries, and according to particular market borders such as professional bodies, communities
domains. of practice, and various types of cultural and
political alliances (social movements).

3.1 Markets as Control Projects


4
The market as politics metaphor developed by Fligstein did not refer explicitly to the concept of con-
Fligstein combines two arguments: (1) modern vention. Convention theory (Thévenot 2006) is used to
analyze the varieties of food markets, particularly in
state-building rests on the creation of the institu-
France. For the circulation and mobilization of convention
tional conditions for the functioning of markets; theory in the Anglo-Saxon agrofood literature see Cheyns
working rules in place allow new markets to and Ponte (2018).
15 Alternative Food Networks and the Socialization of Food 229

Fligstein used “a social movement metaphor to Integration and diversification strategies are
characterize action in markets during market cre- innovation processes that engage collective and
ation or crisis” (1996, 657). When markets public resources in the building of socio-material
emerge or transform, the action in the market infrastructures. Therefore, economic actors
setting is to promote and obtain collective adhe- engage, especially in transition phases, in
sion on ideas, as in political struggles. Market negotiations to pool resources. Competition
struggles regarding conceptions of control strategies available locally depend on local col-
involve social movements across value chains. lective capacities to cooperate, as well as on the
Beyond chain specific technical, social, and eco- global institutional context.
logical debates, (e.g., the Round tables for sus-
tainable standards in several sectors as soya, palm
oil, cocoa, forest, establishing the design of 3.2 Change in Competition Regime
standards and communication models), the qual-
ity forums are at stake, those which are not chain Competition regime is defined by a combination
specific (labor and gender issues, corporate social of market institutions that delimits domains of
responsibility, or climate). Some organizations, cooperation and domains of competition in a spe-
groups, or collectives, which are parts of social cific market or field. Market differentiation and
movements in transition periods and which strug- stabilization processes in general depend on the
gle to represent these movements, are integrated creation and management of two common pool
in governance structures as holders of collective resources systems: collective innovation capacity
interests during the phase of stabilization. This is and collective reputation; this is not a prerogative
the case of trade-unions, farmers’ or consumers of the nested markets. Dervillé and Allaire
associations, and diverse non-governmental (2014), studying the impact of the deregulation
organizations. of the European dairy market in mountainous
Focusing on firm organization, Fligstein states areas in France, found three different regional
that the actors “simultaneously use two internal production systems corresponding to three
principles of organization to indirectly control regional competition regimes, all characterized
competition: (1) integration and (2) diversification by a specific combination of coordination
which is often accompanied by producing multi- instruments. Market liberalization destabilizes
ple divisions in the organization” (ibid., 659). strongly regional competition regimes, which
Diversification implies creating or entering new depend on the generic resources provided by sec-
markets to increase the probability of firm sur- toral national public policies. In these regimes,
vival; Fligstein recalls the classic Chamberlin the risk of delocalization of production is high.
(1933) argument on quality differentiation as a That is buffered by regional competition regimes,
process of creating markets. We argue for an which mobilize specific coordination instruments,
enlargement of the analysis of the interplay of namely strong inter-professional governance
these two principles to include all forms of eco- structures of specific local production systems
nomic organization, even in the structuring of protected by a European label (AOP). These spe-
alternative markets and food channels. The two cific systems can be categorized as AFNs and
principles of integration and diversification go regional competition regimes which support
together. A small or even large enterprise, a them as nested market immaterial infrastructures.
farm or a producer group are never alone to These systems are confronted with conventional-
engage in diversification; facilities are needed in ization, which weakens the regional capacity to
terms of productive resources (specific inputs, resist delocalization.
skilled workforce, and property rights), in terms Regional competition regimes result from the
of selling social-material infrastructures, and in creation, pooling, and management of collective
terms of communication models (Brunori 2007), resources. These resources are essentially intangi-
and media. These are requirements for success. ble. Regional innovation strategies, business
230 G. Allaire

models, standards, and governance structures are governance structure can paralyze individual ini-
indeed collective working rules elaborated by tiative. This is viewed as a threat to the collective
market actors, which they agree to respect, in identity.
order to benefit from a stable environment. If the differentiation in markets is inefficient, it
Regional competition regimes and global compe- is the consequence of a lack of integrative
tition regimes are interactive; the global institu- capacities and a defect in the governance
tional context shapes the available regional structures or in their hierarchy, which are
competition strategies, and local solutions to symptoms of a crisis of the dominant conception
coordination problems are dispersed, thus of control. What threatens market identities is the
transforming the global institutional framework proper functioning of a standardization regime. A
over time. standard is dispersed by the process of imitation,
if its use is legitimated, and if the diffusion of the
standard carries some social signification or proj-
3.3 The Place of the Collectives ect. A written standard does not have a significa-
tion per se, but in relation to a doctrine of quality
Two common pool resources systems are crucial control as well as market control. The shared
for market stabilization and differentiation pro- quality representation among market participants
cesses, namely governance structures and collec- assimilates the specifications and the heuristic
tive reputation, or rather a guaranty of a stable content of the standard, giving it strength, but
market position by social visibility through the also its fallibility. If its significance is weakened,
media. The first one is constituted by all the a standard loses its efficiency and its value. The
collective structures which contribute to elaborate market can turn abruptly to panic as food scares
production and market solutions. What is shared demonstrate. Crises of confidence and panic are
is knowledge. The innovative capacity of a group not specialties of finance, but indeed, threaten all
depends on its capacity to collect and process intangible qualities. It is one of the causes of
information in its domain of action. The flux of developing alternatives as bypasses.
the resources system is the solutions which are
discovered. These include improvement of pro-
ductive models, innovation supports, and collec- 4 Quality as an
tive competencies, as well as relations with local Institutional Order
and regional authorities (Dervillé and Allaire
2014). Quality standards are common models and share
The second is the collective reputation, intangible resources. While, for a specific market
concerning a group, a product, or an area, which or for a stage of market economy, quality reflects
is subjected to social dilemma. Numerous empir- the conceptions of the most organized and pow-
ical studies related to Geographical Indication erful forces. Quality relates to a proper institu-
value chains or other types of specific value tional sphere, controlling the rules of exchange.
chains suggest that, in the case of market up As markets, qualities are social constructions. In
scaling, differentiation of products, bearing col- one aspect quality standards spread as institu-
lective reputation, can become unreadable and tional responses to accountability issues, in com-
standard specifications and classification systems peting ways. Cultural and moral dimensions of
can lose their efficiency due to losing significance quality are highlighted by sociologists, while
in a larger space. The limitation of innovation can economists generally consider quality as an
be a provisory solution to maintain reputation, but issue of information distribution among market
a paradox enters the scene, which is the opposite participants. Qualification is a process of the inte-
of the opportunism generally seen as a cause of gration of knowledge. Qualification refers to a
collective action failure. When change implies double differentiation of goods: by ordering the
several levels of coordination, a strong good properties and by the process of naming
15 Alternative Food Networks and the Socialization of Food 231

itself. This process depends on two rival rational and the means of transmission of the disease,
myths (Allaire and Wolf 2004): (1) the reduction that solution did not work. When tests became
of qualities to a set of knowable, physical, func- available, due to state action, the material organi-
tional, or relational properties; (2) the quality as zation of the market chain had to be reorganized;
having an essential nature or identity. In these and finally, the whole European system of control
two ways, the potentially infinite manners of see- of sanitary standards was changed due to the
ing items are reduced to identifiers capable of developments of that crisis. Market globalization
being used as categories. enlarges the scope of the crises of quality.
Contemporary research in mainstream eco-
nomics for food quality signaling builds on a
4.1 Alternative Qualification distinction between search, experience, and cre-
Paradigms dence goods such as goods which cannot be
assessed by experience. The first categories are
The two alternative paradigms distinguished by related to the first way of classifying items by
Allaire and Wolf (2004), which are embraced and their properties, while the credence issue does
pursued as projects by competing networks, can not concern intrinsic properties but their causes
help to characterize alternative conceptions of or their effects in their entirety. These credence
control. The decomposition paradigm gives valu- attributes are transcendent in qualifying a product
able representations of innovation that is founded from outside. A buyer of organic food, for exam-
on the collection of highly detailed data obtained ple, has confidence in the certification scheme for
through continuous automated monitoring at all organic products, otherwise the market for
stages of production and marketing. The identity organics would not exist. However, this is not
paradigm corresponds to a transcendental form of the reason why the consumer buys organics; the
knowing. We find the two paradigms at play in belief, which is the reason why organics are cho-
framing standards as well as in the struggle for the sen, is related to saving the planet and through
standards setting regulations. This is what Tim this, preserving the consumer’s own health. The
Lang and Michel Heasman (2004) call food credence issue is in the adhesion to such ideas and
wars. They distinguish between a life sciences in the legitimacy of the media which
integrated paradigm, which refers to the first transport them.
myth (from GMOs to fortified food, including In situations where experts can cheat, err, or
the precaution principle as a policy instrument simply fail due to lack of knowledge, reputation,
introduced after the food scares of the 1990s), and or certification mechanisms are viewed as guar-
an ecologically integrated paradigm, which anty of the expertise in term of capacities of the
refers to the second myth. experts to which the credence issue is translated.
No procedure can rely on perfectly decompos- However, the basis of the issue of credence for a
able methods or on any generality, which market to develop is not fundamentally in the
introduces potential organizational slack. Failure certification of the expertise of producers or
in qualification does not happen for a recognized experts. It relates to the intangible part of any
property or a stabilized procedure, but rather for standard. Behind the intrinsic expertise of a pro-
emergent concerns, especially in crisis situations. fessional or behind the intrinsic measurable
Only the progression of the crisis reveals the properties of a product, the credence issue relates
nature of the failure. For example, the Mad Cow to the social relevance of the service it provides
crisis in Europe started with the revealing of a (for example being organically produced), it
critical, emergent property of certain mad cows. relates to a quality doctrine, the sharing of beliefs
The problem initially came from a lack of knowl- and ideas related to a conception of control.
edge. A first solution was to isolate the source by
labelling the origin of the animals. However,
because a polemic developed over the causes
232 G. Allaire

4.2 Quality Regimes Tripartite acculturation mechanisms, certain movements of


Standard Regime and Crises opinion can provoke rapid reversing of values
putting the concerned market in trouble. With
Busch (2018) distinguishes four components to any heuristic criticism, the ambivalence of market
the changes in the food economy: first, a new de knowledge reappears, called quality crisis. While
facto internationalized standards regime; second, certification provides information in the sense that
the extension of assembly line technologies to given properties are made explicit, it can also
much of the agri-food chain; third, a New Taylor- completely fail in this role when buyers’ concerns
ism, and fourth, the rise of Big Data, which are substituted. Incremental changes in certifica-
permits all of this to become real. Every actor in tion procedures generally are not sufficient to
the supply chain is expected to conform to a wide respond to a quality crisis, which interrupts the
and ever-growing variety of legal and de facto working of any standard. Food scares demon-
standards. A tripartite standard regime (TSR), strate that the whole multi-scaled system of gov-
developed in the last few decades as specific ernance, including professional, scientific, and
institutions, named a triple transformation, administrative competencies, is challenged when
linking standards, certifications, and quality crises occur.
accreditations (Loconto et al. 2012). This regime Certification systems compete on reliability.
developed in a transversal way within different While the legitimacy of TPC is mainly based on
industries, but also by transnational its claimed independence, this independence was
organizations, and it concerns alternatives in the denied by several authors, confirming that a TPC
conventionalization phases. What the TSR does is is above all, an instrument to control competition,
establish a private global system of governance working in stable conceptions of control. Partici-
that extends far beyond that of individual firms. A patory Guaranty Systems are becoming signifi-
new form of sector delimitation emerges cant regarding AFNs, but the TSR regime and
corresponding to identity quality standard TPC still concern nested markets since contended
markets. The development of the tripartite strategies permit their integration in wider
standards regime of market regulation rests on markets.
the development of a new cultural environment,
both in the sense of complementary changes in
conceptions of control and in the sense of new 4.3 Markets Regimes, Towards
institutional arrangements, in terms of common- a Media Regime
pool-resources, property rights, and governance
instruments. Historical distinction can be made in considering
The stabilization of creeds in legitimated and institutional regimes of market building. Allaire
shared heuristics is a key aspect of the stabiliza- and Daviron (2006) distinguished the merchant,
tion of quality conventions. However, the industrial, and media market regimes. The recent
heuristics which sustain standards can fail transformations in the food economy can be con-
because the dynamics of markets make it impos- strued as a shift away from an industrial market
sible to come up with a permanent solution to the regime (the modern strategies and policies for
problems of classification of quality values that food socialization), towards a media regime (neo-
would ensure perfectly stable market liberal socialization).
nomenclatures. The evolving experiences of From local markets and from the merchant
actors are challenging shared value orderings, as companies which were assuring long distance
well as does the price competition, which is trade, the competences to qualify products have
always challenging cooperative arrangements. moved to professions and modern state
While the transformation of quality heuristics administrations with the industrialization of agri-
can be incremental over a long period of time by culture and food processing. Several institutional
conditions were needed for the diffusion of
15 Alternative Food Networks and the Socialization of Food 233

industrial models as an historical form of food technology of market observation to bear, which
socialization. These conditions encompass the includes the circulation of the debates on public
principle of grading for commodities traded at a issues that goes with the proliferation and
distance (primarily corn), future markets, and also opening-up of quality forums.
the adequate distribution of cultural resources to
diffuse industrial production models, and to adapt
the principle of grading to enlarge markets. The 5 Conclusive Considerations
nationalization of agricultural markets during the
second food regime, both in the sense of market While alternativeness is not a precise concept,
growth nationwide and of the installation of alternative food signals more global changes in
national trade barriers, corresponds generally the food economy. Alternatives considered in the
with the organization of productive sectors in AFN framework encompass product identity,
which governance structures and dominant con- market channels, quality assurance responsibility,
ception of control are anchored and in which and socio-material infrastructures for food social-
professional and administrative competences are ization. The change in the global competition
articulated. regime including the quality and service turn,
In the new media regime, these competences tripartite standard regime, and nested market
are distributed in hybrid networks, mingling vari- develops into contentious and complementary
ous sorts of knowledge. This proposition to con- strategies. The post-World War II compromise
sider a new market regime converges with the regarding food provisioning was based on the
idea of the construction of a tripartite standards modernization of agriculture, involving States,
regime. The role of media is becoming firms, and farmers’ professional organizations.
recognized. As highlighted by Phillipov, “at the Reformed agricultural and food policies involve
intersection of food politics, media texts and new actors, consumers, ecologists, local
everyday material practices, we are seeing governments, taxpayers, NGOs, situated outside
media’s increasing power as a key actor in food the previous professional spheres and specialized
systems debates and as a motor of food system networks.
transformation” (2019, 2). Transactions under the Stressing global change is also to highlight
media regime tend to be controlled by failures and struggles. We did that by considering
publicization. Markets are information the inequalities in the distribution of the
processing, which supposedly takes account of competences to control markets, the contingency
the various information sources, and thus is sup- of institutional changes, and the communality of
posed to make markets efficient. Recent financial competition avoidance strategies, which profit
crises, developing after the 1990s, have from failures in the extending mass market. Two
demonstrated that financial markets are not effi- conditions, in terms of competition regime, were
cient in this regard. Food scares have shown to be necessary for the development of
demonstrated that it is the same for the food new markets, which may or may not claim to be
markets in the media regime. Institutional alternative. The first is the formation of coalitions
economists argue that financial evaluation is the in order to create innovative capacities as com-
outcome of a logic of opinion and mimetic mon pool resources. Even if numerous studies
choices (Aglietta and Orléan 1982). The evalua- have been developed to identify and analyze the
tion of qualities in the media regime is likewise a common pool resources in multiple domains
logic of opinion. Many procedures that make up material and immaterial, there is a strong resis-
new marketing devices provide publicity for the tance on the part of economists and politicians to
firms’ results, for the product tests, or for the recognize that condition. The second is the role of
characteristics and impacts of public policies, social movements in circulating institutional
well beyond professional and specialist circles. innovations, in a context of crisis of democratic
The media regime brings a whole social society.
234 G. Allaire

In the current market order, alongside domi- (Eds.), Ecology, capitalism and the new agricultural
nant conceptions of how markets perform, there economy: The second great transformation
(pp. 71–94). London: Routledge.
are necessary alternative views, and avoidance Daviron, B., & Allaire, G. (2018). Alternative sketches of
strategies. There are several ways for different a second great transformation. In G. Allaire &
new markets to emerge, differing by their B. Daviron (Eds.), Ecology, capitalism and the new
protagonists, their visions of the future, and their agricultural economy: The second great transforma-
tion (pp. 276–290). London: Routledge.
social and ecological impacts, but integrated in Dervillé, M., & Allaire, G. (2014). Change of competition
transforming economies. regime and regional innovative capacities: Evidence
from dairy restructuring in France. Food Policy, 49
(1), 347–360.
Fligstein, N. (1996). Markets as politics: A political cul-
References tural approach to market institutions. American Socio-
logical Review, 61(4), 656–673.
Aglietta, M., & Orléan, A. (1982). La Violence de la Forssell, S., & Lankoski, L. (2015). The sustainability
Monnaie. Paris: Presses Universitaires de Frances. promise of alternative food networks: An examination
Allaire, G. (2004). Quality in economics: A cognitive through “alternative” characteristics. Agriculture and
perspective. In M. Harvey, A. McMeekin, & Human Values, 32(1), 63–75.
A. Warde (Eds.), The qualities of food (pp. 61–93). Friedmann, H. (2005). From colonialism to green capital-
Manchester: Manchester University Press. ism: Social movements and emergence of food
Allaire, G. (2010). Applying economic sociology to under- regimes. New directions in the sociology of global
stand the meaning of “quality” in food markets. Agri- development. Research in Rural Sociology and Devel-
cultural Economics, 41(1), 167–180. opment, 11, 229–267.
Allaire, G. (2013). The multidimensional definition of Friedmann, H., & McMichael, P. (1989). Agriculture and
quality. In L. Augustin-Jean, H. Ilbert, & the state system: The rise and decline of national
N. Saavedra-Rivano (Eds.), Geographical indications agricultures, 1870 to the present. Sociologia Ruralis,
and international agricultural trade: The challenge for 39(2), 93–117.
Asia (pp. 71–90). London: Palgrave. Fulponi, L. (2006). Private voluntary standards in the food
Allaire, G. (2016). Que Signifie le “Développement” de system: The perspective of major food retailers in
l’Agriculture Biologique? Innovations Agronomiques, OECD countries. Food Policy, 31(1), 1–13.
51, 1–17. Grouiez, P., & Koleva, P. (2018). Transforming the dairy
Allaire, G., & Daviron, B. (2006). Régimes d’Institution- sector in post-communist economies: Actors and
nalisation et d’Intégration des Marchés: Le Cas des strategies. In G. Allaire & B. Daviron (Eds.), Ecology,
Produits Agricoles et Alimentaires. SympoScience, capitalism and the new agricultural economy: The
101–114. second great transformation (pp. 243–255). London:
Allaire, G., & Wolf, S. A. (2004). Cognitive Routledge.
representations and institutional hybridity in agrofood Guthman, J. (2004). The trouble with “organic lite” in
systems of innovation. Science, Technology and California: A rejoinder to the “conventionalization”
Human Values, 29(4), 431–458. debate. Sociologia Ruralis, 44(3), 301–316.
Brunori, G. (2007). Local food and alternative food Hatanaka, M., Bain, C., & Busch, L. (2005). Third-party
networks: A communication perspective. Anthropol- certification in the global agrifood system. Food Pol-
ogy of Food S2. icy, 30(3), 354–369.
Burch, D., & Lawrence, G. (2009). Towards a third food Hebinck, P., Schneider, S., & van der Ploeg, J. D. (Eds.).
regime: Behind the transformation. Agriculture and (2015). Rural development and the construction of new
Human Values, 26(4), 267–279. markets. London: Routledge.
Busch, L. (2018). The new autocracy in food and agricul- Krausmann, F., & Langthaler, E. (2019). Food regimes
ture. In G. Allaire & B. Daviron (Eds.), Ecology, and their trade links: A socio-ecological perspective.
capitalism and the new agricultural economy: The Ecological Economics, 160, 87–95.
second great transformation (pp. 85–110). London: Lang, T. E., & Heasman, M. (2004). Food wars: The
Routledge. global battle for mouths, minds, and markets.
Campbell, H. (2009). Breaking new ground in food regime London: Earthscan.
theory: Corporate environmentalism, ecological Le Velly, R. (2017). Sociologie des Systèmes Alimentaires
feedbacks and the “food from somewhere” regime. Alternatifs: Une Promesse de Différence. Paris:
Agriculture and Human Values, 26(4), 309–319. Presses des Mines.
Chamberlin, E. (1933). The theory of monopolistic compe- Loconto, A., Stone, J. V., & Busch, L. (2012). Tripartite
tition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. standards regime. In The Wiley-Blackwell encyclope-
Cheyns, E., & Ponte, S. (2018). Convention theory in dia of globalization (pp. 2044–2051). Malden, MA:
anglophone agri-food studies: French legacies, circula- Blackwell Publishing.
tion and new perspectives. In G. Allaire & B. Daviron
15 Alternative Food Networks and the Socialization of Food 235

McMichael, P. (2009). A food regime genealogy. The economic sociology (pp. 111–115). London:
Journal of Peasant Studies, 36(1), 139–169. Routledge.
McMichael, P. (2016). Commentary: Food regime for Verhaegen, E. (2012). Les reseaux agroalimentaires
thought. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 43(3), alternatifs: transformations globales ou nouvelle seg-
648–670. mentation du marche? In D. Van Dam (Ed.),
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution Agroecologie: Entre pratiques et sciences sociales
of institutions for collective action. New York: (pp. 265–279). Dijon, France: Educagri editions.
Cambridge University Press. White, H. C. (1992). Identity and control. Princeton, NJ:
Phillipov, Michelle. 2019. Introduction. In Alternative Princeton University Press.
food politics. From the margins to the mainstream,
eds. Michelle Phillipov, and Katherine Kirkwood,
1–19. London: Routledge.
van der Ploeg, J. D. (2015). Newly emerging, nested Internet Resources
markets: A theoretical introduction. In P. Hebinck,
S. Schneider, & J. D. van der Ploeg (Eds.), Rural IFOAM. (2007). Participatory guarantee systems: Shared
development and the construction of new markets vision, shared ideals. www.ifoam.org [05.02.2020].
(pp. 16–40). London: Routledge.
van der Ploeg, J. D., Jingzhong, Y., & Schneider,
S. (2012). Rural development through the construction Gilles Allaire is directeur de recherches honoraire,
of new nested markets: Comparative perspectives from Institut National de la Recherche Agronomique, France.
China, Brazil and the European Union. Journal of Research topics: Political economy, markets institu-
Peasant Studies, 39(1), 133–173. tions and functioning, economy of common pool
Poméon, T., Loconto, A., Fouilleux, E., & Lemeilleur, resources, analysis, and assessment of rural and environ-
S. (2018). Organic farming in France: Alternative proj- mental policies. Recent publications: Allaire, Gilles, and
ect or conventionalization? In G. Allaire & B. Daviron Benoit Daviron, eds. 2018. Ecology, Capitalism, and The
(Eds.), Ecology, capitalism and the new agricultural New Agricultural Economy: The Second Great Transfor-
economy: The second great transformation mation. London and New York: Routledge. Allaire,
(pp. 207–226). London: Routledge. Gilles. 2018. The Ambivalent Capitalist Socialization of
Reardon, T., Codron, J.-M., Busch, L., Bingen, J., & Agriculture. In Ecology, Capitalism and the New
Harris, C. (2001). Global change in agrifood grades Agricultural Economy: The Second Great Transforma-
and standards: Agribusiness strategic response in tion, eds. Gilles Allaire, and Benoit Daviron, 2018–48.
developing countries. The International Food and London and New York: Routledge. Allaire, Gilles. 2019.
Agribusiness Management Review, 2(3–4), 421–435. L’ambivalence des communs. Développement Durable et
Staricco, J. I. (2016). Towards a fair agro-food regime? A Territoire 10/1: 1–20. Allaire, Gilles, Julie Labatut, and
Regulationist reading of the fairtrade system. Revue de Germain Tesnière. 2018. Complexité des communs et
la régulation [Online], 20. régimes de droits de propriété: le cas des ressources
Thévenot, L. (2006). Convention school. In J. Beckert & génétiques animales. Revue d’Economie Politique 128:
M. Zafirovski (Eds.), International encyclopedia of 109–35.
Digital Money for Sustainable
Communities: The Sardex Case 16
Giacomo Bazzani

1 Introduction: The Emergence and used together with all other elements of digi-
of Digital Money tal life, especially with digital platforms (e.g.,
Google, Facebook, Airbnb, eBay). Today, digital
The main innovation within the money field in the platforms and digital monies can link all aspects
twenty-first century is the spreading of digital of our life together (Khera 2019, 6). Digital iden-
monies. In pre-modern and in modern times, tity, social media, financial investments,
monies were mainly analogical: coins represented e-commerce, health records, crowd founding,
the quantity and the value of the metal from and instant messaging are just some examples.
which they were made. Also, the banknotes, Digital platforms operate thanks to the presence
which are not made of precious metal, gained of digital money, but at the same time, they also
and maintain their value because they represent influence the nature and the social uses of money
the exact imprint of the original mold owned by itself.
the central authority. They keep their value Money already has a great influence on social
because they are analog to the mound surface. dynamics in its analogical form. Analogical
Paper currencies can be transported and money was crucial in influencing social interac-
exchanged much more easily than coins, and tion in modern cities in the nineteenth century
each one may also express the value of a huge (Simmel 2004) and also in contributing to the
amount of coins. However, digital monies realize long-term process of rationalization of modern
much more than banknotes in money usage. They societies (Weber 1978). However, the emergence
can move instantly from one side of the globe to of digital money poses new challenges to the
the other, thanks to the Internet. They are also understanding of the relationship between
used without deteriorating over the years. Digital money and society. Contemporary sociological
money seems to overcome many of the problems research on money relies on two main approaches
of analogical money. The information regarding to explain the reciprocal influence between
the ownership and value of the money is trans- money and society that have been synthesized in
lated into the digital form of the binary code the homogeneity and differentiation tendencies
which provides more stability and reliability, (Dodd 2012). Homogeneity comes from the polit-
less counterfeiting, and the facility of storage. ical will of the modern states to impose money
Digital money can also be easily connected to hegemony over the territories, in order to raise
taxes and impose sovereignty (Ingham 2004).
Powerful countries still struggle for monetary
G. Bazzani (*)
Florence University, Florence, Italy hegemony in the globalized world (Cohen
e-mail: giacomo.bazzani@unifi.it 2012). The creation of the Euro monetary union
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 237
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_16
238 G. Bazzani

or the dollarization of South American countries and public regulation, along with controversial
are clear examples of this tendency towards mon- effects (see Maurer et al. 2013; Karlstrøm 2014;
etary homogeneity.1 On the other hand, money Kethineni et al. 2018; Dodd 2018; Hayes 2019).
proliferation and differentiation continue even Not only do digital monies challenge the trend
under the political control of the national states. toward money homogeneity, but also the tradi-
From a micro-perspective, Zelizer (1989, 1995, tional understanding of the cultural specific diver-
2010) describes the processes of earmarking: sification of money use and value. CCs are
there are local, familiar, and individual ways to usually seen as a byproduct of community efforts
use money that change over time and may shape to satisfy their needs and reach their sustainability
what money is. At the same time, over the last goals, (i.e., economic development, redistribu-
30 years at the local level, money differentiation tion, environment). They are mostly considered
has continued with the creation of 4500 comple- the outcome of a collective movement for social
mentary currencies (CCs), community credit, and change (economic activism, see Forno and
alternative financial systems (Blanc 2013). These Graziano 2014; Bosi and Zamponi 2015), but
systems have brought a large variety of currencies not its origin. On the contrary, when money
into being, which have sought to address a wide meets digital platforms it can also contribute to
range of specific aims and objectives, in the cul- shaping new forms of social ties and collective
tural, governmental, economic, social, and envi- action (Sessions 2010). Social interaction,
ronmental areas (Place and Bindewald 2015). mediated by digital platforms is able, for exam-
How do these tendencies towards money homo- ple, to easily include or exclude members and to
geneity and money differentiation change with encourage or discourage new trust relationships
the advent of digital money? (Bennett 2008; Nelms et al. 2018). Even in the
With digital platforms and the digital econ- more impersonal forms of digital money, like
omy, Apple, Google, Facebook, and Amazon Bitcoin, the related digital platforms for social
are the tech giants that may pose serious interactions among users create new communities
challenges to state sovereignty over money and of users (Dodd 2018; Swartz 2018). The influence
its hegemonic tendency. The Libra, for example, of digital money in social ties is the new chal-
was created in 2019 by Facebook, hoping it lenge to the traditional culturalist explanation of
would become a global means of payment money diversification. From this perspective,
(Taskinsoy 2019). If Facebook users start to use money diversification is not only an effect of
Libra, the group of private companies running different cultural backgrounds, but money itself
Libra would quickly become something similar is able to shape values and practices (Evans 2009;
to the most important central banks of the world. Bazzani 2020a, b).
At the time of writing, however, it seems that Although there are many CCs that support the
Libra will not be implemented, due to legal creation of new communities (Seyfang 2018), the
restrictions and the fear of politicians and central chapter focuses on a successful example, the case
bankers of losing the money control (Murphy and of Sardex CC, a digital money created in Sardinia
Stacey 2019). However, the advanced coding (IT) in 2010 with a powerful capacity to create a
processes, used for Libra and other new community with common goals and shape
cryptocurrencies, provide the technical possibility social interaction. Sardex money, as well as many
of creating money outside a central political other types of money, is imbued with a utopian
authority. The success of Bitcoin money is a view of society (Dodd 2015) that directed the
clear example of the capacity digital money has founders towards the definition of specific
to overcome state limits, brave political authority money features and functioning. This money
was created to support the socio-economic devel-
1 opment of their region, through encouraging
Dollarization refers to the situation in which a country
substitutes its own currency with the US dollar (Melvin cooperation among entrepreneurs, and favoring
1988). local exchanges of goods and services. The social
16 Digital Money for Sustainable Communities: The Sardex Case 239

effects of this digital money exceed the traditional companies that can spend it buying products or
understanding of cultural money diversification services from other companies belonging to the
and suggest the consideration of how the rise of Sardex network. Interest is not applied to the
digital money may shape individual behavior, debts or the credits in Sardex. Sardex, like older
values, and social dynamics. The second section CCs LETS and the Switzerland WIR, for exam-
introduces the Sardex history, its characteristics, ple, (see Amato and Fantacci 2013), cannot be
functioning, and regulation. In the third section converted in euro. The zero-interest rate of Sardex
the Sardex social effects are presented, in particu- stimulates the exchange of goods and purchases.
lar, how Sardex money triggers specific social Indeed, there are no advantages for a company to
mechanisms (selection, monitoring and sanction- keep a surplus in its Sardex balance because no
ing, signaling, and belief formation) that shape a interest is gained. Companies pay Sardex Ltd an
different type of social interaction and build a annual fee to be part of the network. This fee
new community aimed towards the production varies between 200 € for small cooperatives to
of collective goods. Sardex money creates a 3000 € for large companies. Sardex Ltd has a
form of hybrid community between the two clause in its statutes that all profits must be
main community models, the Greek community, reinvested in the company (Dini et al. 2015, 27).
and the monastic community, thanks to its capac- Sardex Ltd operates as a commercial consultant,
ity to create a we-ness and define a common goal. promoting the network and the entry of new
The fourth section discusses how the Sardex firms. The network now has more than 3500
experience can be considered a form of transfor- companies involved, with relevant growth rates.
mative democratic experimentalism toward It also has developed 15 other regional networks
sustainability, that relies on a theory of money in other Italian regions. Similar experiences are
far from the traditional monetarism of contempo- being developed in France, Spain, and the UK
rary monetary policies. The limits and the (for a detailed presentation of the Sardex experi-
challenges posed by digital money are also ence, see Bazzani 2020a).
discussed, namely the risks of the techno-levia- Sardex Ltd is organized in different areas of
than or digital kleptocracy. The conclusion activity: ICT team, media team, research and
argues that digital monies may have completely development team, and advisory team. The most
different effects than the classical, sociological innovative department of Sardex Ltd is the broker
accounting of modern money, which turns the service that provides a call center service for
social world into an arithmetic problem. Digital members and a general supervision of the Sardex
money may create new communities and shape a market by the head of the broker service.
form of social interaction based on a high level of Members can call the broker service for support
trust, a sense of familiarity, and social support. to find suppliers of specific goods or services they
Creating money is a terraforming operation that need, or to obtain qualified advice on the market
requires a new sociological agenda to investigate trends or suggestions for marketing strategies.
money as social ties. With a specific request of a product from a mem-
ber, the broker service can provide the quotes, or
ask the firms to contact the member directly. The
2 The Case of Sardex Money broker service has access to the Sardex digital
platform, where all transactions in Sardex can be
Sardex is a CC founded in 2010 in Sardinia monitored. Thanks to this, the broker service:
(IT) by a group of young friends, who had (1) evaluates companies for entry into the net-
emigrated for study or work. Sardex money is a work and proposes their initial credit line;
currency with the same value as the euro but (2) grants special lines of credit to companies
based on mutual credit that can be used by firms for investments or daily business; (3) monitors
affiliated with the Sardex network. The homonym member accounts which show few exchanges
company, Sardex Ltd, manages the lending ser- and suggest possible marketing strategies.
vice with about 55 employees. Credit is granted to
240 G. Bazzani

The broker service aims at a Sardex dynamic of individuals” (Irwin 2016, 265). The concept
market where members have a good number of offers a visible dimension to the broader forces of
transactions and are content to remain in the society that influence and link individuals
Sardex network. The broker service and the together (ibid., 248 f.). At the community level,
rules for how Sardex operates produce a velocity the abstract idea of society takes a tangible form,
of money circulation that is eight times faster than and social constraints coming from the material,
euro circulation (Littera et al. 2014). Section 3 historical, educational, normative, and imagina-
will present how Sardex money can influence tive contexts can be traced by the researcher, and
social relationships during transactions and how their interrelation can clearly be observed (Keller
it can create a new form of community among 2003; Cresswell 2015).
members.2 In this broad area of studies, a common
denominator in the concept of community refers
to “locale, common ties, and social interaction”
3 The Sociological Analysis where “relationships are closer than casual
of Sardex Money relationships because the group shares some com-
mon goals, values, and perhaps a way of life that
The concept of community is one of the most reinforce each other, creates positive feelings, and
widespread and controversial concepts in social results in a degree of mutual commitment and
sciences research, and also in philosophy.3 Some responsibility” (Bruhn 2011, 13 f.). Community
scholars suggest that, given the different concepts members share spatial or mental boundaries and
and usages associated with the term, it is actually also coordinate social action in light of common
not possible to have a shared definition in the goals, but the conditions and mechanisms that
academic debate (Day 2006; Bell and Newby transform the co-presence of individuals in a
2012); that would imply its uselessness for ana- place, into a community are diverse. In Western
lytical purposes. At the same time, the concept of history, there are two main models of community:
community remains central in studies of globali- the Greek and the Christian types of community.
zation, hyper-individualism, rising inequality, This section will present the two models of com-
and related counter-movements, often munity and will show how Sardex money
overlapping with the term neighborhoods and contributes to the creation of a new type of com-
whole fields of urban and rural sociologies munity, which is a hybrid of the two models.
(Gottdiener and Hutchison 2006; see also
Mooshammer in this handbook). This complexity
is due to the concept of community “is one that 3.1 The Construction of Locality
addresses the essential nature of association, of and Commonality
cultural cohesion, and of the territorial cohesion
In the Greek tradition, the spatial commonality of
2
The analysis uses 37 semi-structured interviews done in place in a city is the basis of the contractual
2017 with entrepreneurs (E.) member of the Sardex net- process that forged Greek society. In Aristotle,
work and 11 interviews with the Sardex management and
employees of different areas of activity. The sample of
the individual and the community were in a recip-
firms was differentiated by the number of employees, rocal relationship, embodied in the deliberative
business sector, year of entry in Sardex, proximity to the activity (Trott 2014). Civic rituals, religious
regional capital, and peripheral area. Interviews were ceremonies and festivals occurred in common
conducted by the author, took place in person, and were
transcribed. The evaluation included coding and
places of the city; they shaped the form of the
categorizing, for details and for the complete analysis of individual belonging to the collectivity and, in
the interviews see Bazzani (2020a). this way, they created the community. Culture,
3
Hillery found 94 definitions of community (1955). For an norms, and rules were forged and transmitted
introduction to the different uses of the concept see Keller
(2003), Irwin (2016).
16 Digital Money for Sustainable Communities: The Sardex Case 241

through these rituals and with the law.4 Money (Webber 1963; Wellman 1992). When the
was very important in the development of the boundaries of the community move from a
Greek polis because it “facilitated the trade and space of places and geographical border to a
dramatically increased the scope of items that space of flows (Castells 2000), belonging to the
could be traded” (Swedberg 2003, 135) both community can often be chosen or avoided or be
with community members and with foreigners. limited to a specific task (Colombo et al. 2001).
The borders of the Greek city-state defined the This is a community of a different nature than the
boundaries of the community that, together with community defined on a geographical base and
rules, manifested a web of social possibilities and ascribed status. This community offers a different
constraints, where specific forms of repeated experience of community to the individuals.
social interaction could take place. Community based on interest or ideology, for
The nature of the boundaries of the community example, can change over the life course of the
changed with the modern process of massive community and it can also be strategically chosen
urbanization of the population.5 The community and achieved, while a geographical community
belonging to modern cities does not necessarily may have more rigid norms for entry or exit, that
coincide with the border of the human settlement makes that more similar to an ascribed status. In
anymore, but within the same spatial border dif- the space of flows, it is common for people to
ferent communities may take place, in the form of belong to different, multiple communities (Cra-
a community of interests or values. With the ven and Wellman 1973). However, even in this
advent of the information age and digital space, context, communities continue to be supportive
the community may also be displaced and dis- for individuals (Wellman and Wortley 1990;
persed in the form of the digital community (Plant Wellman 1992, 1999). Indeed, in the community,
2004). In this context, the local dimension of the presence of common ties means the presence
community is not a geographical area, but much of strong ties, (i.e., related to the presence of
more a set of boundaries and belongings that intimacy, kinship, friendship, neighborhood, or
could still represent a territory, but they can also to belongings of a different nature), which make
be defined by the sharing of a religion, an ideol- people feel close to each other (Campbell and Lee
ogy, a knowledge, an interest, or a passion 1990) or which can provide various kinds of
social support (Fischer 1982; Wenger 1992).
4
The jointly spatial and political nature of the Greek The constitution of achieved communities can
community is evident also in the etymology of the word be favored by the virtual/real places created by
politics that comes from the Greek polis that means city- digital monies and digital platforms, where
states, while ethics comes from ethea that means habitats,
repeated social interaction can take place. Sardex
and, more in general “‘society’ stems from socius,
signifying ‘sharing’—and sharing is done in a common money has this capacity of creating a common
place” (Casey 1997, xiv; cit. in Irwin 2016, 250). place where repeated social interaction takes
5
Classical sociologists described this process with differ- place under specific rules.
ent emphases and expectations. For Durkheim (1997)
urbanization and labor division represent the shift towards
a big community linked together by the organic solidarity,
while for Marx (1926) the community continues to be the 3.2 The Sardex Functioning
local dimension of a larger form of association in society. for a Different Social
Tönnies (1955) sees the advent of modern society as a real Relationship
change in the nature of association: in the past communi-
tarian form (Gemeinschaft), social ties were primarily
based on shared values, emotions and direct reciprocity, Entry into the Sardex network of members is free
while in modern society (Gesellschaft) they are based on of charge, but it is subject to the acceptance of the
interests and contractualism. Simmel (1971) and Weber contractual rules about how the network functions
(1958) also recognize this shift but they treated the two
and the evaluation of their prospective level of
poles as a typology that allows the observation the
characteristics of modern form of association and social network transactions in the firm complementarity.
action (for an introduction, see Irwin 2016). The broker team of Sardex evaluates the potential
242 G. Bazzani

supply and demand of goods and services of a 2009, 2015). Given the rapid circulation of infor-
new firm and its complementarity with the ongo- mation within the Sardex network, horizontal
ing Sardex market (for details, see Bazzani 2020a, monitoring carried out by members can lead to a
Chap. 3). This type of evaluation and selection fast-reputational sanctioning through word of
procedure is necessary to ensure that membership mouth or the Sardex members’ Facebook page.
brings economic benefits to the firms; new Reputational sanctioning on the Facebook page
members must be able to immediately buy the can shatter a firm’s credibility, and as a result, its
goods and services they require from the network business within the Sardex network. The
and to find potential buyers for their goods and Facebook page is followed daily by many
services. members who use it to publicize, or search for
The selection of members developed by discounts or special offers on goods and services
Sardex sets the boundaries of the Sardex network in Sardex. A post or a comment that raises doubt
and offers a competitive advantage to those as to whether a member has behaved correctly can
selected (Elias 2000; Maurer 2016).6 The com- rapidly destroy, in a generally permanent way, the
petitive advantage, due to the entrance selection member’s chance of transacting within the
mechanism, is confirmed by the presence of long network.
exchange networks that cross Sardinia (Iosifidis Thanks to this monitoring and sanctioning
et al. 2018). It is very unlikely that such long system, being a member of the Sardex network
exchange networks, sometimes 100 miles long, is perceived by entrepreneurs as a guarantee of
would be used outside the Sardex network, espe- high reliability. The reliability signal is so effec-
cially for small quantities of supplies. tive that entrepreneurs report how, from the very
The Sardex network also has a system of mon- first meeting, the relationship with other members
itoring and sanctioning which is useful in is different. Joining the Sardex network immedi-
supporting market exchange with a high level of ately creates a sense of familiarity and closeness
trust among members. Sardex Ltd monitors among entrepreneurs, that is different from ordi-
transactions and constantly collects feedback nary commercial relationships.
from members with the broker team call center We have made many friends with Sardex customers
(see Diekmann and Przepiorka in this handbook). who have also come from far away . . . Sardex
Exclusion is the most radical sanction, in the case unites us and this creates a closer relationship
of serious misconduct against other members. from the first meeting. Even with euro customers
we have a wonderful relationship but in Sardex we
The sanctioning mechanism, however, is effec- have formed a ‘clan’, let’s call it that: a new way of
tive thanks to the monitoring system that approaching (E. 10).
discourages misconduct (Burt and Knez 1995).
The initial diversity of relationships is subse-
Monitoring in Sardex is not carried out solely by
quently transformed with greater ease into friend-
Sardex Ltd monitoring, but also through peer
lier relations than in the euro market. The
monitoring. As in the case of the Greek polis,
revocation of clan relationships provides a good
the boundaries of the network facilitate occasions
idea of how much network membership
for repeated interaction; direct communication
transforms the nature of economic relations
and repeated interaction creates the conditions
between entrepreneurs. Normal commercial
for horizontal monitoring and fostering coopera-
relations are characterized by strong competition
tion (Ostrom et al. 1992; Sally 1995; Baldassarri
and sometimes by opportunistic behavior, which
means entrepreneurs tend to be very detached and
6 distrustful in commercial relations. The clan rela-
The selection made by Sardex, unlike the selection
between feudal lords described by Elias, will never result tionship avoids the initial distrust and places the
in one company monopolizing an entire economic sector potential competitor outside the group to which
because the broker management intentionally operates to they belong; the other members are natural allies
provide multiple offers in each sector, to ensure members
within the market. The signaling effect of
have freedom of choice.
16 Digital Money for Sustainable Communities: The Sardex Case 243

network membership becomes a guarantee of reli- has commissioned . . . Sardex has turbo-charged
ability, and a facilitator of economic initiatives my business! . . . Before I used to hope clients
would call me now, I hope they won’t because I
(Bacharach and Gambetta 2001; Beckert 2005). am behind in deliveries, I have to ask them to wait
Members perceive the presence of an ethical (E. 4).
code of conduct among members that stabilizes
the behavioral expectations of alter, and makes it These interactions provide members the feel-
easier to strike economic deals, and carry out ing of not being alone and of having social sup-
transactions. The high level of reliability port for their economic interactions. The next
accorded to alter within the Sardex network sub-section presents how this diverse social inter-
allows entrepreneurs to accept terms of payment, action creates common goals, and a form of col-
which would normally be considered too risky to lective action aimed towards the creation of
be accepted within the euro market. This form of collective goods.
cooperation is unrealistic to entrepreneurs in the
euro market.
Monitoring, sanctioning, and signaling are 3.3 The Emergence of We-ness
mechanisms that support a high level of trust and Collective Action
among Sardex network members (Sartori and
Dini 2016), and facilitate their economic After the Greek polis, the second main historical
transactions and social relations.7 These effects model of community is the monastic community
of the Sardex network are confirmed both from coming from the medieval Christian conception
quantitative data of the business of firms in the of Augustine and Thomas Aquinas. The
Sardex network as well as by the perceptions of boundaries of the community were not limited
the entrepreneurs. The use of Sardex increases by geographical borders, as in the Greek case.
business of the firms. The average increase fol- Notwithstanding monks often lived isolated
lowing Sardex membership is 23% for the num- from the rest of the social context, the boundaries
ber of customers and 26% for revenue.8 The of their community transcended and overcame the
increase in business with the Sardex currency is walls of the monastery, and the geographical
highly significant, especially in the light of the borders of the city, until they embraced a univer-
widespread economic recession and the weak sal community of faith (Keller 2003). The reli-
performance of the parallel euro market. After gious life of pray and work (ora et labora) was
the 2008 economic crisis, the Sardinian GDP brought about in commonality of faith and for the
shrank by 9.1% (Banca d’Italia 2018, 13). The common good of all humanity. In the Christian
data are consistent with entrepreneurs’ form of community, the nature of the common
perceptions regarding the performance of their ties still resides in material artifacts as in the
businesses after becoming members of the Sardex Greek case, (i.e., the Greek public places and
network, especially for small firms: the Christian monastery), but the common
In Sardex I have a very long waiting list, I program “belonging” is also strongly supported by ideals
jobs for clients seven months ahead because I have that transcend the locality. However, the Greek
so much work. . . . My first customer was a jeweler and the Christian conception of community both
in a nearby town for whom I did 5,000 Sardex of show the capability of creating the we-ness of a
work and he is still waiting for me for other work he
common belonging among individuals, and of
setting collective goals. The Greek polis was
7
The moment in which the given trust is reciprocated from able to forge a commonality among individuals,
the partner, by doing what is expected, is the basic element where individual goals were not opposed but
of cooperative behavior (Gambetta 1988; Cook 2001).
8
moderated by the local community in light of
Both values are net of the estimated euro-to-Sardex sub-
collective goals. In the life of prayer in the mon-
stitution effect of 13% of customers and 11% of revenues
of the total increase recorded (for details see Bazzani astery, individual efforts were also guided
2020a). towards collective goals (the salvation of lives
244 G. Bazzani

and souls), but they were not limited to the local of the euro. The Sardex currency is often used in a
community, rather they embrace the whole of context where traditional credit has disillusioned
humanity.9 In both cases, the greatest honor for entrepreneurs; indeed, many Sardinian firms have
individuals came from the ability to put common no access to bank credit. The banking system is
good above individual gain (Keller 2003), and no longer seen as supporting local economic
through this, when people perceive that everyone development. However, entrepreneurs see Sardex
is cooperating towards a common goal, the sense and its limited circulation, as the currency’s
of community develops (McMillan and Chavis explicit support for developing local businesses:
1986). Sardex provides benefits for our territory because
Sardex members perceive relations with other the money stays here, with salaries and taxes. The
member entrepreneurs differently from relations greater the number of Sardinian companies work-
with entrepreneurs who use only euros. Members ing, the greater the benefits for Sardinia (E.19).
observe that economic relations are conducted Entrepreneurs still consider Sardex primarily
differently in Sardex, and this leads them to char- as a tool for increasing their company’s business
acterize other members as trustworthy, desirous but, once they use the Sardex currency, almost
of reciprocity in their transactions, and of foster- half the entrepreneurs interviewed, began to asso-
ing the Sardex project. These beliefs, formed by ciate it with ethical goals linked to the collective
observing the behavior of others, are then used to benefits they recognized as being derived from
categorize the whole network of members in sim- the Sardex project. Although it could well be true
ilar terms (Rydgren 2009). Exchanges in Sardex that increased circulation and use of the euro
are perceived by entrepreneurs as fair and sup- would result in collective economic benefits,
portive, but they think those interactions also entrepreneurs tend to associate the use of the
have a redistributive capability between small euro with exclusively individual benefits (becom-
and big firms and support the local community. ing wealthier), or onerous obligations, such as
In the euro market, large companies have far more paying bank interest and taxes. The Sardex
effective marketing tools at their disposal than money creates opportunities because business
smaller companies, but in the Sardex network, activity is not seen as being entirely guided by
the same marketing tools are available to all entrepreneurs’ individual interests, but it is also
companies, both large and small. Many micro- perceived as being guided by collective interests.
businesses make strategic use of the marketing The currency’s modus operandi allows
resources offered by the Sardex network, and entrepreneurs to address ethical issues, tradition-
successfully increase their sales. Small businesses ally confined to non-economic, philanthropic
think that these resources give them the chance to issues through their normal business activity:
compete more effectively with larger companies.
In Sardex it’s different, I don’t know why, but an
In this sense, they interpret the effects of the atmosphere of trust and collaboration is created. It
Sardex currency as a redistribution of resources is as if there were a common mission which does
for competitiveness between small and large not exist in any other type of commercial activity.
businesses. This common mission is developing our region
through the participation of its residents: I know
Sardex users develop specific beliefs regarding that what I spend here in Sardinia will remain in
the role of Sardex currency in the economic sys- Sardinia (E.34).
tem, comparing its operation and impact with that Those who think of their children are pleased their
region benefits from the [Sardex] network. Those
who join the network and understand it realize its
9
The Christian conception of community is not far from value for our region (E.2).
the idea of global community described by Bauman
(2001a, b). Here, space and time become less relevant for
The benefits attributed to the Sardex currency
determining the chance of social interaction in rich go beyond mere individual and network gains;
countries and, in this way, locality is not the source of they include a collective benefit extended to the
community anymore.
16 Digital Money for Sustainable Communities: The Sardex Case 245

geographical boundaries of the area where the will discuss to what extent this form of commu-
currency circulates. Doing business in Sardex nity, aimed at a collective goal, can be considered
allows the emergence of a new we-ness, which a sustainable community.
is able to contribute to a collective interest of the
region’s socio-economic development.
This common goal can also be seen in the 4 Money for (Un)Sustainable
entrepreneurs who enthusiastically support the Communities
Sardex project. Some entrepreneurs become
promoters of the Sardex currency among their Like community, the exact meaning of the con-
contacts, even when they will obtain no direct cept of sustainability is also highly debated, but it
economic advantage. If the new company mem- remains a keyword in the planning of future
bership of the Sardex network is not expected to policies, and in many academic debates (Meyer
create opportunities for trade, (i.e., because it 2009). As in the case of the agenda for sustainable
belongs to a different economic sector), the pro- development of the United Nations (2015), a
motional activity engaged in by members towards sustainability program refers to a well-advised
the new entry is more similar to a form of prose- use of limited natural resources, together with
lytism or propaganda, close to the activism of the development of the economic and social
political party volunteers: resources necessary to guarantee wealth, public
There is a really nice toy shop, I talked to [the solidarity, and democracy. In particular, the
owner] for a year to persuade him to join and now sustainability agenda aims to satisfy these needs
he is really happy. Now he complains that he would of the present generation, but not at the expense of
have liked to join the network earlier. I always future generations. Different perspectives of
advise trying it for a year, if you realize that it
doesn’t work for you, then don’t renew your mem- social change are developed within the broad
bership. But they have all remained, even the umbrella of sustainability, often connected to dif-
creche. Our creche and kindergarten are both in ferent ideological standpoints. Adloff and Neckel
Sardex (E.18). (2019) suggest considering three ideal types of
This entrepreneur has become a real promoter sustainability approaches that are connected to
of the Sardex network in his neighborhood. Nei- different social structures, practices, and
ther his family, nor his business use the kinder- imaginations: the imaginaries of sustainability as
garten or the toy shop, but he encouraged them modernization, transformation, or control.
both, together with other companies, to join the According to this framework, the Sardex case
network. This entrepreneur believes that develop- would be classified as a form of transformative
ing the Sardex network is intrinsically positive. In democratic experimentalism, because money
the eyes of entrepreneurs such as these, the functioning is designed to encourage new and
regional economic system becomes a real collec- alternative forms of social ties and economic
tive good to which they believe they should dedi- operations. However, the transformative capacity
cate time and energy: of money is not an exclusive property of Sardex.
People who project the functions of money
I use the broker service for finding companies and
for proposing companies for network membership. always imbue money with an ideology related to
This happens naturally, no money is exchanged for society in general, and to the social ties in partic-
this, it is all done because we believe in the project ular. The sum of an ideal view of society, with an
and we want it to grow (E.22). abstract action model of social interaction often
Within the network there are also occasions, produces money that tries to carry a utopian soci-
though far more sporadic, in which using the ety forward (Dodd 2015). Money organizes social
Sardex money generates the development of interaction and exchanges with a precise set of
prosocial behaviors, which go beyond the rules; an action model of social interaction is
boundaries of the economic system. Section 4 always necessary to design money functioning.
It can span from the selfish utilitarianism of a
246 G. Bazzani

monetarist approach to the egalitarianism and fair cooperation, not competition among users, and it
behavior embedded in Ruskin’s Labour money also redirects the long chain of the global markets
(Ruskin 1928; Dodd 2015, 82). to the short chain at the local level. This selection
Both Sardex and the ordinary modern state of a production chain, which favors small local
money are imbued with utopianism. In the main- businesses at the expense of larger companies is
stream monetarist approach adopted by central perceived as an effect of the Sardex currency,
banks for managing money supply, money also which helps support the regional economy:
supports the building of an ideal society. Money Reasoning in euros is mostly a reasoning of conve-
is considered a commodity, like other goods that nience, while the reasoning in Sardex is a project
need to circulate freely in the market to produce which grows together with the community. In our
an affluent society. The market competition, sector there are small food-producing companies
with quality products which promote their territory.
supported by the free circulation of money, By choosing to buy the products of these
should bring the best aggregate utility to the companies, we complete the production chain,
citizens in the long-term. This model of money from the producer to the customer, describing that
functioning relies on the utilitarian action model: land, that product, that company, promoting them
together with our region (E.22).
individual and firms’ efforts for profit should
produce the best possible outcomes for Entrepreneurial activity and collective action
consumers with the decreasing of prices and the towards a common goal are forms of social action
emergence of products with better quality. This that are traditionally kept separate: the collective
expected long-term collective benefits, legitimate benefits are expected as a consequence of market
money functioning and also the secondary effects efficiency and money free circulation.
such as unemployment or rising inequalities.10 Entrepreneurs using Sardex think that using the
Nevertheless, the outcomes of this idea of Sardex currency brings collective benefits to their
money functioning and the related policies are region. In other words, it can be argued that
controversial (Amsden 2001). This idea of the entrepreneurs associate company business
nature and of the effects of money circulation conducted in Sardex as an economic activity
still backs monetary policy of central banks with values that traditionally are extraneous to
(Beckert 2016). It produces economic forecasting the company’s economic activities:
(MacKenzie et al. 2007) and this causes real The product my restaurant offers works really well
effects with the implementation of the related with Sardex because it is a new way of understand-
economic policies (Çal{şkan and Callon 2009).11 ing the world and managing money. It is an ethi-
Sardex utopianism is very different from the cally correct world. Just look—Sardex invests in
marketing and the workforce, not in multinationals.
monetarist perspective and utilitarianism They are not speculative investments that only
connected to it. Sardex money fosters benefit a few people, Sardex by its nature benefits
everyone (E.20).

10
For Polanyi, this idea of self-regulated market with While the euro is perceived as belonging to a
expected long-term benefits implied a “stark utopia.” kind of impersonal global market, and regulated
“Such an institution could not exist for any length of by impersonal authorities, Sardex currency is per-
time without annihilating the human and natural substance
ceived as having clear collective goals connected
of society; it would have physically destroyed man and
transformed his surroundings into a wilderness. Inevitably, to the regional community. This type of commu-
society took measures to protect itself: but whatever nity supports the decrease in wealth inequality
measures it took impaired the self-regulation of the market,
disorganized industrial life, and thus endangered society in
yet an other way.” (2001, 3) political European integration as secondary effects. Unfor-
11
The four freedoms of movement of money, goods, tunately, unexpected negative political consequences are
services, and persons are at the heart of the European emerging: nationalism rises in European countries as well
integration project, and specifically, of the European mon- as unexpected redistribution effects (Matthijs and Blyth
etary union and the euro (Emerson 1992). This mechanism 2015; Streeck 2015; see Veira-Ramos and Tetiana
should bring, the building of a European identity and a real Liubyvaand in this handbook for the case of Ukraine).
16 Digital Money for Sustainable Communities: The Sardex Case 247

and increases the level of social capital, as other cost and incentives. Digital money tracks every
social institutions do (Putnam 2000; Putnam et al. transaction and the carbon emissions could be
2003). However, in this case, the community does easily (dis)counted in the payment price.
not pre-exist nor is it the effect of civic participa- The total transparency of the market
tion or other social institutions producing social transactions stored in the database of digital
capital. The Sardex community is created only monies offers a very powerful tool for monetary
through the use of this specific type of money.12 policy, as well as for economic and social
The capacity to bring economic activity and policies.15 State taxation, for example, can be
economic outcomes much closer to a local, tangi- easily collected directly during the transaction
ble level is a clear merit of the Sardex function- and also, if necessary, change over the time and
ing. However, other dimensions of sustainability be diversified at regional, local, and individual
still remain uncovered. For example, while levels for specific policy purposes. However,
with Sardex the community becomes more resil- along with this powerful tool for social coordina-
ient, cohesive and coordinated, it is still not clear tion also rises the risk of its despotic use by the
whether or to what extent it can support goals that authorities, which has been already identified as
overcome the local dimension of community.13 risk of the techno-leviathan (Dodd 2018, 44) or
Indeed, Sardex money transforms the individual the digital kleptocracy if the data are owned by
aim to profit in a broader collective socio- few private companies, as in the case of tech
economic development of the region, but it is giants promoting the Libra (Khera 2019, 7).
not clear to which extent digital money may While the main problem raised by the interna-
include collective aims, which are not restricted tional financial markets is the risk of taking
to a geographical area. This is a challenge that money out of the control of political, democratic
many local communities have started to consider, authorities, digital money, to the contrary, would
especially regarding climate change.14 The allow the monetary authority to obtain perfect
experiences of digital communities show how information on economic transactions and a
they may have a broad range of goals (Plant potentially enormous influencing capability on
2004) and also how they can mobilize real col- markets. This ability, of course, also brings the
lective movements (Cumbers et al. 2008). New risk of an excess of control over individual free-
digital monies could include broad global aims, dom. However, the issue seems much more
(e.g., reduction of carbon emissions) through, for related to the quality of democratic control than
example, the simple traditional tools of monetary to the chances of tracking transactions which is
offered by the digital money.16 Totalitarianism,
12
Notwithstanding it could be argued that Sardinian com- surveillance, and exploitation, which are possible
munity already existed before the coming of Sardex effects of big data (Rao 2019), are also possible
money due to established close kinship ties (Pinna 1971), without big data. Meanwhile, big data and digital
it is evident how the we-ness and the common goal of the platforms are used also by anarchist groups (e.g.,
Sardex community do not exist in parallel to economic
activity with euro money. Moreover, the development of with the Bitcoin project). However, it is evident
similar experiences in different contexts support the thesis that the chance of social control, in such cases, is
of the exogenous creation of the community (Bazzani facilitated and requires fewer resources. In the
2020a). case of the social credit system in China, for
13
There are two main risks connected to the local
boundaries of community: one is the exclusivity provided
by a real sense of belonging (Miller 1990) and the second
15
is the effects of constraint over individual freedom (Etzioni Sardex money experimented as a tool for digital pay-
1998). For the distinction between bridging and bonding ment of social subsidies in the city of Sassari. In this
communities see Putnam (2000). experiment, social subsidies could not be used, for exam-
14
See, for example, the cases of New York City, under its ple, for gambling.
One NYC 2050 program, or Bristol which established the 16
The access of the fiscal authorities to all the bank
Bristol SDG Alliance working to raise awareness about the accounts and their transactions is already not far from the
SDGs in the city, or the Helsinki City Strategy 2017–2021. market transparency of digital money.
248 G. Bazzani

example, Liu talks about algorithmic governance numbers” (ibid., 448).17 The possibility of mone-
(2019, 31). The increasing availability of personal tary calculation (Weber 1978, 81) of the social
data needs an even advanced form of democratic world frees individuals from pre-modern
control. social ties.
Digital money brings this calculative social
world at its extreme consequences because it
5 Conclusion: Money became, not only calculable but also coded in
as a Social Tie the binary form. As a main paradox of the social
change, after this binary coding, the social world
The risks and new possibilities embedded in digi- shaped by digital money started to become less
tal money suggest the need for a neutral distance abstract. Sardex money reconnects individuals
for investigating the phenomenon. Money is and reinforces social ties with a sense of
imbued with utopia and creates rules, norms, familiarity, trust, and social support that is mostly
and also collective aims. Sardex money shares a due to its functioning, and the easy connection
utopian view of mutual-credit and cooperation, between digital money and digital platforms.
and it can develop a new community and collec- However, Simmel noted that also for modern
tive action for the region’s socio-economic devel- money when
opment. The change in beliefs regarding how the barter is replaced by money transactions a third
economic system functions gives rise to an factor is introduced between the two parties: the
unusual interpretation of the link between eco- community as a whole, which provides a real value
nomic activity and collective well-being. corresponding to money. The pivotal point in the
interaction of the two parties recedes from the
Zelizer has shown how values and social direct line of contact between them, and moves to
practices shape money functioning and its effects the relationship which each of them, through his
(1995, 2010), while the Sardex case suggests that interest in money, has with the economic commu-
money functioning can shape social practices and nity that accepts the money (Simmel 2004, 176).
constitute a new community. This evidence Both Sardex and modern money introduce a
encourages one to investigate how digital monies new community into the social interaction, which
may shape social interaction and change society. would not exist without money. However, while
“Money is not a ‘commodity’ which stands in a the community described by Simmel weakens
relatively stable relationship to other social ties, the Sardex community reinforces
commodities, nor is it merely a reflection, sym- them. Much more, in the Sardex case, the rules
bolic representation, or signifier of an underlying of money circulation create new social ties, and
existing ‘reality’ of economic relations. Rather, it collective actions that do not exist without this
is a social relation based upon definite and partic- money. Sardex allows strong trust relationships
ular social structural conditions of existence” among members and a form of social coordina-
(Ingham 1996, 523). tion, that is the pre-condition of a new type of
Modern state money was a primary tool to free money “claim upon society” (ibid.).
individuals from ascribed status and norms With digital money, thanks to its binary nature
related to community ties, because “the complete and its connection with digital platforms, third
heartlessness of money is reflected in our social parties may easily be inserted into the social
culture, which is itself determined by money” interaction of the economic exchange; these
(Simmel 2004, 347). Money as a unit of account third elements connect the two parties which
can turn the social world into an arithmetic prob- form a bigger context. The binary nature of digital
lem, through “regulating both individual and
social relations as calculative functions. Their 17
Also, Zelizer stresses how money “may well ‘corrupt’
cognitive ideal is to conceive of the world as a
values into numbers” (1989, 347). That money is not
huge arithmetic problem, to conceive events and culturally neutral, and that this non-neutrality influences
the qualitative distinction of things as a system of the exchanges is well described also by Dodd (1994, 13).
16 Digital Money for Sustainable Communities: The Sardex Case 249

money and its connection with digital platforms Bazzani, G. (2020a). When money changes society: The
facilitates the introduction of third parties into the case of Sardex money as community. Wiesbaden:
Springer VS.
social interaction associated with economic Bazzani, G. (2020b). Money as a tool for collective action.
exchange; these third parties connect the social Partecipazione e Conflitto, special issue. Rethinking
interaction of the economic exchange to a wider Money, Rebuilding Community, 13(1), 438–461.
context. In this sense, producing money is a Beckert, J. (2005). Trust and the performative construction
of markets. MPIfG Discussion Paper 05/8. Cologne:
terraforming operation (Zimmer 2017, 329) that Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.
shapes society. The advent of Sardex, as well as Beckert, J. (2016). Imagined futures: Fictional
other digital monies, offers the occasion to under- expectations and capitalist dynamics. Cambridge,
pin a new sociological agenda for the study of MA: Harvard University Press.
Bell, C., & Newby, H. (2012). Sociology of community: A
money as the origin of specific forms of social collection of readings. London: Routledge.
relation. While contemporary monetary policies Bennett, L. (Ed.). (2008). Civic life online: Learning how
generally deal with inflation and credit cost, a digital media can engage youth. London: MIT Press.
new sociological research agenda should investi- Bosi, L., & Zamponi, L. (2015). Direct social actions and
economic crises: The relationship between forms of
gate money as a source of a specific form of social action and socio-economic context in Italy.
ties. Digital money can influence social dynam- Partecipazione e conflitto, 8(2), 367–391.
ics; it can balance competition and cooperation; it Bruhn, J. G. (2011). The sociology of community
can have redistribution effects; and forge the connections. Dordrecht: Springer.
Burt, R., & Knez, M. (1995). Kinds of third-party effects
boundaries and the goals of new communities. on trust. Rationality and Society, 7(3), 255–292.
What if money would be imbued and planned Çal{şkan, K., & Callon, M. (2009). Economization, Part 1:
with a view of a sustainable future? Shifting attention from the economy towards processes
of economization. Economy and Society, 38(3),
369–398.
Campbell, K. E., & Lee, B. A. (1990). Gender differences
in urban neighboring. The Sociological Quarterly, 31
References (4), 495–512.
Castells, M. (2000). The rise of the network society.
Adloff, F., & Neckel, S. (2019). Futures of sustainability Oxford: Blackwell.
as modernization, transformation, and control: A con- Cohen, B. J. (2012). The future of global currency: The
ceptual framework. Sustainability Science, 14(4), Euro versus the Dollar. London: Routledge.
1015–1025. Colombo, M., Mosso, C., & DePiccoli, N. (2001). Sense
Amato, M., & Fantacci, L. (2013). Saving the market from of community and participation in urban contexts.
capitalism. Cambridge: Polity. Journal of Community & Applied Social Psychology,
Amsden, A. H. (2001). The rise of “The Rest”: Challenges 11, 457–464.
to the west from late-industrializing economies. Cook, K. (Ed.). (2001). Trust in society. New York:
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Russell Sage Foundation.
Bacharach, M., & Gambetta, D. (2001). Trust in signs. In Craven, P., & Wellman, B. (1973). The network city.
K. S. Cook (Ed.), Trust in society (pp. 148–184). Sociological Inquiry, 43, 57–88.
New York: Russel Sage Foundation. Cresswell, T. (2015). Place: An introduction. Chichester:
Baldassarri, D. (2009). Collective action. In P. Hedström Wiley.
& P. Bearman (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of analyt- Cumbers, A., Routledge, P., & Nativel, C. (2008). The
ical sociology (pp. 391–418). Oxford: Oxford Univer- entangled geographies of global justice networks.
sity Press. Progress in Human Geography, 32(2), 183–201.
Baldassarri, D. (2015). Cooperative networks: Altruism, Day, G. (2006). Community and everyday life. London:
group solidarity, reciprocity, and sanctioning in Routledge.
Uganda Producer Organizations. American Journal of Dodd, N. (1994). The sociology of money: Economics,
Sociology, 121(2), 355–395. reason and contemporary society. Cambridge: Polity
Banca d’Italia. (2018). Economie Regionali. L’economia Press.
delle Regioni Italiane nel 2017. Roma: Banca d’Italia. Dodd, N. (2012). Money: The Wiley-Blackwell encyclo-
Bauman, Z. (2001a). Community: Seeking safety in an pedia of globalization (1st ed.). Malden, MA:
insecure world. Cambridge: Polity. Blackwell.
Bauman, Z. (2001b). The individualized society. Dodd, N. (2015). Utopianism and the future of money. In
Cambridge: Polity. P. Aspers & N. Dodd (Eds.), Re-imagining economic
250 G. Bazzani

sociology (pp. 79–102). Oxford: Oxford University Liu, C. (2019). Multiple social credit systems in China.
Press. Economic Sociology the European Electronic Newslet-
Dodd, N. (2018). The social life of Bitcoin. Theory, Cul- ter, 21(1), 22–32.
ture & Society, 35(3), 35–56. MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F., & Siu, L. (2007). Do econo-
Durkheim, É. (1997 [1893]). The division of labour in mist make markets? On the performativity of econom-
society. New York: Free Press. ics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Elias, N. (2000 [1939]). The civilizing process: Marx, K. (1926 [1852]). The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis
Sociogenetic and psychogenetic investigations. New Bonaparte (E. Paul & C. Paul, Trans.). London: Allen
Jersey: Wiley-Blackwell. and Unwin. [Karl Marx 1852 Der achtzehnte Brumaire
Emerson, M. (1992). One market, one money: An evalua- des Louis Bonaparte. Die Revolution: Eine Zeitschrift
tion of the potential benefits and costs of forming an in zwanglosen Heften 1.]
Economic and Monetary Union. Oxford: Oxford Uni- Matthijs, M., & Blyth, M. (Eds.). (2015). The future of the
versity Press. Euro. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Etzioni, A. (Ed.). (1998). The essential communitarian Maurer, A. (2016). Social mechanisms as special cases of
reader. Oxford: Rowman & Littlefield. explanatory sociology: Notes toward systemizing and
Evans, M. S. (2009). Zelizer’s Theory of money and the expanding mechanism-based explanation within soci-
case of local currencies. Environment and Planning, 41 ology. Analyse & Kritik, 38(1), 31–52.
(5), 1026–1041. Maurer, B., Nelms, T. C., & Swartz, L. (2013). When
Fischer, C. S. (1982). To dwell among friends. Berkeley: perhaps the real problem is money itself! The practical
University of California Press. materiality of Bitcoin. Social Semiotics, 23(2),
Forno, F., & Graziano, P. (2014). Sustainable community 261–277.
movement organisations. Journal of Consumer Cul- McMillan, D. W., & Chavis, D. M. (1986). Sense of
ture, 14(2), 139–157. community: A definition and theory. Journal of Com-
Gambetta, D. (1988). Trust: Making and breaking cooper- munity Psychology, 14, 6–22.
ative relations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Melvin, M. (1988). The dollarization of Latin America as a
Gottdiener, M., & Hutchison, R. (2006). The new urban market-enforced monetary reform: Evidence and
sociology (3rd ed.). Boulder: Westview Press. implications. Economic Development and Cultural
Hayes, A. (2019). The socio-technological lives of Change, 36(3), 543–558.
Bitcoin. Theory, Culture & Society, 36(4), 49–72. Meyer, J. W. (2009). World society. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
Hillery, G. A. (1955). Definitions of Community: Areas of versity Press.
Agreement. Rural Sociology, 20, 111–125. Miller, D. (1990). Market, state and community. Oxford:
Ingham, G. (1996). Money is a social relation. Review of Clarendon Press.
Social Economy, 54(4), 507–529. Nelms, T. C., Maurer, B., Swartz, L., & Mainwaring,
Ingham, G. (2004). The nature of money. Cambridge: S. (2018). Social payments: Innovation, trust, bitcoin,
Polity. and the sharing economy. Theory, Culture & Society,
Iosifidis, G., Charette, Y., Airoldi, E., Littera, G., 35(3), 13–33.
Tassiulas, L., & Christakis, N. A. (2018). Cyclic motifs Ostrom, E., Walker, J., & Gardner, R. (1992). Covenants
in the Sardex Monetary network. Nature Human with and without a sword: Self-governance is possible.
Behaviour, 2(11), 822–829. American Political Science Review, 86, 404–417.
Irwin, M. D. (2016). The concept of community as theo- Pinna, L. (1971). La Famiglia Esclusiva: Parentela
retical ground: Contention and compatibility across e Clientelismo in Sardegna. Bari: Laterza.
levels of analysis and standpoints of social processes. Place, C., & Bindewald, L. (2015). Validating and improv-
In S. Abrutyn (Ed.), Handbook of contemporary socio- ing the impact of complementary currency systems
logical theory (pp. 247–268). Cham: Springer. through impact assessment frameworks. International
Karlstrøm, H. (2014). Do libertarians dream of electric Journal of Community Currency Research, 19,
coins? The material embeddedness of Bitcoin. 152–164.
Distinktion: Journal of Social Theory, 15(1), 23–36. Plant, R. (2004). Online communities. Technology in Soci-
Keller, S. (2003). Community: Pursuing the dream, living ety, 26(1), 51–65.
the reality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Polanyi, K. (2001 [1944]). The great transformation: The
Kethineni, S., Cao, Y., & Dodge, C. (2018). Use of bitcoin political and economic origins of our time. Boston:
in darknet markets: Examining facilitative factors on Beacon Press.
bitcoin-related crimes. American Journal of Criminal Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and
Justice, 43(2), 141–157. revival of American Community. New York: Simon &
Khera, R. (2019). Aadhaar: Uniquely Indian dystopia? Schuster.
Economic Sociology the European electronic newslet- Putnam, R., Feldstein, L., & Cohen, D. J. (2003). Better
ter, 21(1), 4–12. together: Restoring the American Community.
Littera, G., Sartori, L., Dini, P., & Antoniadis, P. (2014). New York: Simon & Schuster.
From an idea to a scalable working model: Merging Rao, U. (2019). Biometric IDs and the remaking of the
economic benefits with social values in Sardex. In Indian Welfare State. Economic Sociology the
Inaugural WINIR Conference, 11–14 September European Electronic Newsletter, 21(1), 13–21.
2014, Greenwich, London.
16 Digital Money for Sustainable Communities: The Sardex Case 251

Ruskin, J. (1928). Time and tide, and munera pulveris. Zelizer, V. (1995). The social meaning of money: Pin
London: Macmillan. money, paychecks, poor relief and other currencies.
Rydgren, J. (2009). Beliefs. In P. Hedström & P. Bearman New York: Basic Books.
(Eds.), The Oxford handbook of analytical sociology Zelizer, V. (2010). Economic lives: How culture shapes
(pp. 72–93). Oxford: Oxford University Press. the economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Sally, D. (1995). Conversation and cooperation in social Press.
dilemmas. Rationality and Society, 7, 58–92. Zimmer, Z. (2017). Bitcoin and potosí silver historical
Sartori, L., & Dini, P. (2016). From complementary cur- perspectives on cryptocurrency. Technology and Cul-
rency to institution: A micro-macro study of the Sardex ture, 58(2), 307–334.
mutual credit system. Stato e Mercato, 36(2), 273–304.
Sessions, L. F. (2010). How offline gatherings affect
online community members: When virtual community
members meetup. Information, Communication, and Internet Resources
Society, 13(3), 375–395.
Seyfang, G. (2018). Working outside the box: Community Blanc, J. (2013). Community and complementary
currencies, time banks and social inclusion. Journal of currencies, practices and research: state of the art. In
Social Policy, 33(1), 49–71. Unrisd Conference International Symposium on
Simmel, G. (1971). On individuality and social forms: Potential and Limits of Social and Solidarity Economy:
Selected writings. Chicago: University of Chicago Special Session on Alternative Finance and Comple-
Press. mentary Currencies. Geneva: International Labour
Simmel, G. (2004 [1900]). The philosophy of money. Organization. Retrieved May 6–8, 2013, from http://
(T. Bottomore, & D. Frisby, Trans.). London: www.unrisd.org/sseconf/
Routledge. [Georg Simmel 1900 Philosophie des Dini, P., van der Graaf, S., & Passani, A. (2015). Socio-
Geldes. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.] economic framework for BOLD stakeholders.
Streeck, W. (2015). Why the Euro divides Europe. New OpenLaws.eu Deliverable D2.3.d1, European Com-
Left Review, 95, 5–26. mission. Retrieved November 19, 2019, from http://
Swartz, L. (2018). What was Bitcoin, what will it be? The eprints.lse.ac.uk/62819/
techno-economic imaginaries of a new money technol- Murphy, H., & Stacey, K. (2019). Where it all went wrong
ogy. Cultural Studies, 32(4), 623–650. for Facebook’s Libra. Financial Time. Retrieved
Swedberg, R. (2003). Principles of economic sociology. October 15, 2019, from https://www.ft.com/content/
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 6e29a1f0-ef1e-11e9-ad1e-4367d8281195
Tönnies, F. (1955 [1887]). Community and association. Taskinsoy, J. (2019). Facebook’s Project Libra: Will
London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Libra sputter out or spur Central Banks to introduce
Trott, A. M. (2014). Aristotle on the nature of community. their own unique cryptocurrency projects? Available
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. at SSRN. Retrieved July 20, 2019, from https://ssrn.
Webber, M. W. (1963). Order in diversity: Community com/abstract¼3423453
without propinquity. In L. Wingo (Ed.), City and United Nations. (2015). Transforming our world: the 2030
space: The future use of urban land (pp. 23–54). Agenda for Sustainable Development. Retrieved
Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press. February 11, 2020, from https://
Weber, M. (1958). The city. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. sustainabledevelopment.un.org/post2015/
Weber, M. (1978 [1922]). Economy and society. Berkley, transformingourworld/publication
CA: University of California Press. [Max Weber 1922
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Tübingen: Mohr.]
Wellman, B. (1992). Which types of ties and networks Giacomo Bazzani is research fellow and adjunct profes-
provide what kinds of social support. In E. Lawler, sor of sociology at Florence University, Florence, Italy.
B. Markovsky, C. Ridgeway, & H. Walker (Eds.), Research topics: Money, uncertainty, sustainability,
Advances in group processes (Vol. 9, pp. 207–235). prosocial behavior. Recent publications: Bazzani, Giaco-
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. mo. 2020. When Money Changes Society. The Case of
Wellman, B. (Ed.). (1999). Networks in the global village. Sardex Money as Community. Wiesbaden: Springer
New York: Routledge. VS. Bazzani, Giacomo. 2020. Money as a Tool for
Wellman, B., & Wortley, S. (1990). Different strokes from Collective Action. Partecipazione e Conflitto, special
different folks: Community ties and social support. issue: Rethinking Money, Rebuilding Communities. A
American Journal of Sociology, 96(3), 558–588. Multidimensional Analysis of Crypto and Complementary
Wenger, G. C. (1992). Help in old age—Facing up to Currencies 13/1. Vignoli, Daniele, Giacomo Bazzani,
change: A longitudinal network study. Liverpool: Raffaele Guetto, Alessandra Minello, and Elena Pirani.
Liverpool University Press. 2020. Uncertainty and Narratives of the Future: A
Zelizer, V. (1989). The social meaning of money: “Special Theoretical Framework for Contemporary Fertility. In
monies”. American Journal of Sociology, 95(2), Analyzing Contemporary Fertility, ed. Robert Schoen.
342–377. London: Springer.
Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness
of Entrepreneurial Activity 17
Isabell Stamm

1 Introduction group that collectively engages in an entrepre-


neurial venture. These groups and the rules on
Economic sociology theoretically and empirically how they form and maintain boundaries are a
uncovers the social structuring of economic specific aspect of the institutional environment
actions, sheds light on the institutionalization of of entrepreneurial activity and one that has not
economic practices, or points towards the social received systematic attention in economic sociol-
construction of markets (Swedberg 2003; Smelser ogy (Harrington and Fine 2006). One reason for
and Swedberg 2005; Maurer 2017). In short, eco- this oversight may be the focused attention that
nomic sociology strives to understand the social other units of analysis such as markets, networks
embedding of economic actions. The sociological and organizations have received in economic
treatment of entrepreneurship feeds into this sociology, which has left the particularities of
overall framework by viewing entrepreneurship small groups in a blur. In this chapter, I suggest
as an institutionally embedded economic action that a way of bringing this blur to focus is to pay
(Weber 1988; Swedberg 2003). Institutions, more attention to the variety of small groups in
which are commonly referred to as agreed upon their institutional settings which are coordinating
and generalized rules of the game (Streek and entrepreneurial activity.
Thelen 2005), shape and provide direction for This overall endeavor requires the consider-
entrepreneurial activities. These entrepreneurial ation of two conceptual directions. First, there is
activities can change industries, markets and a need to revisit the link between social groups
even institutions (Schumpeter 1980; Aldrich and and entrepreneurial activity, as Granovetter
Fiol 1994; Dorado 2005), and as such are drivers (1985, 1995), Aldrich and Zimmer (1986) or
of economic welfare and capitalist dynamic. Portes and Sensenbrenner (1993) previously
The most recent twist in a sociology of called for. Research on the social embedding of
entrepreneurship highlights entrepreneurship as entrepreneurial action as an economic action,
future-oriented activity bundles and especially as however, either remains on a micro-level pointing
a collective action of entrepreneurial groups to the relevance of an individual entrepreneur’s
(Thornton 1999; Ruef 2010; Stamm et al. 2019). position in structures of power relations, gender
In this setting, entrepreneurial activity goes along relations, or networked social capital for entrepre-
with the formation and maintenance of a small neurial activity (Bruni et al. 2004; DeClercq and
Voronov 2009; McKeever et al. 2015). The other
I. Stamm (*)
possibility is that research on the social embed-
“Entrepreneurial Group Dynamics”, Technische
Universität Berlin, Berlin, Germany ding of entrepreneurial action focuses on, as the
e-mail: isabell.stamm@tu-berlin.de comparative capitalism literature illustrates,
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 253
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_17
254 I. Stamm

mainly the institutional environment of The discussion will proceed as follows: The
organizations rather than the people involved in starting point forms a cursory overview of key
creating, owning, and managing these arguments put forward in a sociology of entre-
organizations (Streek 1997; Hall and Soskice preneurship (Sect. 2). Next, I enhance the concept
2001). Second, there is a need to acknowledge of entrepreneurial groups utilizing insights from
the diversity of small groups involved in entrepre- group sociology and argue that various forms of
neurial activity and supported by specific entrepreneurial groups exist that navigate group
institutions. An often-cited example is migrant formation and maintenance in their respective
entrepreneurship that feeds from institutional institutional settings (Sect. 3). I continue by
rules in ethnic groups (Aldrich and Zimmer illustrating the link between entrepreneurial
1986; Granovetter 1995). More recently, Lehrer groups and their institutional setting, with the
and Celo (2016) demonstrates how small groups examples of entrepreneurial families in German
of German family members are closely linked in family capitalism and start-up ventures in the
their entrepreneurial activity, and that this link is Berlin start up field (Sect. 4). For each of them,
maintained and protected by a particular institu- I discuss the character of the specific form of the
tional setting that they refer to as familial sector. entrepreneurial group and ways of member selec-
Adding to this, Lehrer and Celo (2016) suggest tion and exclusion as maintained and protected by
that this familial sector co-exists in bifurcation the institutional environment. Finally, the discus-
and symbioses with other sectors supporting dif- sion returns to a macro-level perspective and
ferent types of entrepreneurial activity in the same brings both forms of entrepreneurial groups and
economy. Hence, different varieties of entre- their respective environment into a comparative
preneurship can exist (Dilli et al. 2018). perspective (Sect. 5). By doing so, the usefulness
In this chapter, I will develop both directions. and limitations of an entrepreneurial group lens
More specifically, I suggest paying more attention to enrich the economic sociology understanding
to small groups engaged in coordinating entrepre- of heterogeneous forms of entrepreneurial activ-
neurial activity as they form a distinct social unit, ity is highlighted.
beyond the organization. In contrast to
Granovetter’s (1995) use of the term entrepre-
neurial group, which refers to the subpopulation 2 The Role of Groups
of ethnic entrepreneurs, I use the term as in a Sociology
suggested by Ruef (2010) to refer to a small of Entrepreneurship
number of individuals providing financial, timely
and emotional contributions. Yet, I seek to The sociological discourse on entrepreneurship
expand upon Ruef, not only by supposing that derives its origins from classic writers such as
these groups continue to exist beyond the emer- Weber, Sombart, or Schumpeter and has
gence of an organization, but also by enriching remained a lively, but never a large or even dom-
this concept with key insights from a sociology of inant stream of research within economic and
small groups (Fine 2010, 2012b). I further argue organization sociology. At the same time, the
that there are multiple forms of small groups, and sociological perspective on entrepreneurship has
this variation matters in order to identify and continuously influenced the large and interdisci-
understand various forms of entrepreneurial plinary research field of entrepreneurship
groups that may co-exist within an economy but (Aldrich 2005, 452). The sociology of entre-
are maintained and protected through particular preneurship has raised key questions such as:
institutional settings. As such, this discussion will Under what conditions can entrepreneurial
contribute to an explanation of how differing actions occur? In what ways do entrepreneurs
institutional environments may foster varying reproduce and challenge existing social orders?
entrepreneurial activity. How do entrepreneurs recruit engagement by
employees, investors, and customers in their
17 Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness of Entrepreneurial Activity 255

ventures? Finally, how do entrepreneurial pro- Embracing a sociological perspective, how-


cesses vary across time and place? In the follow- ever, these same early works voice an unease
ing, I will briefly elaborate upon key arguments about such a strong individualization of entre-
and conceptual directions put forward by the preneurship (Aldrich 2005; Ebner 2010).
sociology of entrepreneurship, which have Schumpeter suggests that being an entrepreneur
changed and morphed the very definition of entre- is only an episode in one’s life course, and
preneurship. The goal of this section is to set the entrepreneurs can only temporarily be distin-
stage for the remainder of the chapter, in which I guished from managers or capitalists
will then attend to the latest twist in a sociology of (Schumpeter 1980, 116). Consequently, he turns
entrepreneurship by studying small groups as to studying bundles of activities and arrives at his
collective actors engaged in the entrepreneurial famous definition that entrepreneurship is a
process.1 recombination of production factors to create
something new, even though he allows for the
degree of newness to be rather small (Schumpeter
1980, 240). Both Weber and Sombart state how
2.1 Unease About the Individualized
such entrepreneurial activity bundles themselves
Entrepreneur
are a product of socio-historical change. Hence, to
understand entrepreneurship by zooming in on
Early works in economic sociology express a
the sequence of activities is incomplete as long
fascination with heroic, mostly male, individuals
as economic dynamics, in their institutional envi-
who single-handedly turn inventions into
ronment, are overlooked (Sombart 1987; Weber
innovations, take on risks, and strive to increase
1988). This image also has sustainably influenced
wealth (Aldrich 2005; Ebner 2005; Deutschmann
entrepreneurship research. In fact, a process view
2008). Despite the differences in their
of entrepreneurship has turned out to be the dom-
approaches, Max Weber (1988), Werner Sombart
inant approach in this interdisciplinary research
(1987), and Joseph Schumpeter (1980) share an
field (Gartner 1988; Moroz and Hindle 2012).
understanding of the entrepreneur as a physical
This approach carries forward the unease about
person, equipped with specific cognitive
an over-individualized view of entrepreneurship,
competences and character traits, who has
even claiming at times that asking, “who is the
internalized meritocratic and capitalist values,
entrepreneur—is the wrong question” (Gartner
and has the ability to mobilize resources. The
1988).
entrepreneur, as embodied in Andrew Carnegie,
Benjamin Franklin, or John D. Rockefeller, is an
economic actor who realizes imagined tasks with
2.2 Entrepreneurship
little compromise but lots of enthusiasm. This
as Future-Oriented Activity
ideal has deeply influenced conceptual and empir-
Bundles
ical approaches to entrepreneurs (Swedberg
2000).
In accordance with Schumpeter, scholars largely
view entrepreneurship not as a single act, but
1
This section, hence, does not provide an encompassing rather a series of interlinked activities that occur
overview of the development of the sociology of entre- over time and that are aimed at getting new things
preneurship (as e.g., Aldrich (2005) does). Rather it
done (Lumpkin and Dess 1996; Swedberg 2000,
focuses on selected arguments needed to understand the
ensuing discussion of the institutional embeddedness of 2009). For Schumpeter, such entrepreneurial
entrepreneurial groups. I will not touch upon the large and activities and their new things can even have the
influential idea of institutional entrepreneurship, which power to destroy existing institutions. There are,
focuses on how embedded actors generate new institutions
however, considerably differing conceptions of
by crafting and implementing organizational forms and
practices that break with established institutions what these new things actually are. From a social
(DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Battilana 2006). science view, two conceptions, organizational
256 I. Stamm

emergence, and entrepreneurial opportunity, are entrepreneurs are actually doing, many different
particularly relevant. bundles of activities have been uncovered. These
activities occur in a variety of sequences, and
2.2.1 Organizational Emergence nascent entrepreneurs follow no fixed sequence
The currently dominant literature suggests that of activities (Carter et al. 1996; Aldrich 2005).
the process of getting new things done brings Further, initial attempts for business founding can
about organizational emergence (Aldrich 2005; be followed by lengthy gestation periods before
Davidsson et al. 2008; Hjorth et al. 2015). intensive activities begin, if they do so at all
Hence, entrepreneurship is a process in which (Aldrich 2005). An essential common feature of
activities are coordinated. The venture is these entrepreneurial activities seems to be that
organized to the degree that a goal-directed activ- founders behave as if their imagined venture was
ity system, or in others words an organization a reality (Gartner et al. 1992). They offer a con-
emerges and enters the population of vincing interpretation of reality, an attractive
organizations (Gartner 1985; Aldrich and Ruef vision of the possible future, and a prescription
2006). Accordingly, this stream of research of how to reach that vision. By producing and
looks at the activity patterns during the early directing such future images, founders may con-
phases of founding, called nascent entrepreneur- vince others of the tangible reality of their venture
ship, up to the early years of an organization. It (Aldrich 2005).
embraces the idea that charisma and informal
organizing can transform into formal bureaucracy 2.2.2 Entrepreneurial Opportunity
and authority systems, and that this formalization An alternative reading of entrepreneurship as a
eventually undermines entrepreneurial activity process does not emphasize organizational emer-
(Sombart 1987; Weber 1988; Ebner 2005, 265). gence as the new thing, but rather some degree of
This view further considers existing organiza- innovation through creating, discovering, and
tional forms within a population of organizations exploiting opportunity (Shane 2007; Alvarez
that entrepreneurs can either imitate or innovate and Barney 2010). In this setting, entrepreneur-
(Aldrich and Ruef 2006). From this perspective, ship connects closely to the capacity to break with
entrepreneurship has become synonymous with old orders or at least discover niches and holes
organizational emergence; the term entrepreneur within existing orders. Entrepreneurship also
is used interchangeably with founder. While the entails the proofing of prove endurance and resil-
largely management dominated field of entre- ience whilst following through with the venture.
preneurship studies tends to focus on particularly Within this stream of research, a recent develop-
successful start-ups, also known as unicorns, or ment emphasizes the performative character of
on high-tech industries, mostly in order to derive entrepreneurship. Strongly influenced by practice
best practices, a social science view on entre- theoretical thinking (e.g., Bourdieu 1977;
preneurship seeks to encompass all forms and Schatzki 1996; Reckwitz 2002), this view
kinds of new business foundings (Brüderl et al. suggests that entrepreneurship––or rather
1992; Aldrich 2005; Welter et al. 2016). In this entrepreneuring––is an “ongoing practice of cre-
context, some exceptional, collaborative, and atively organizing people and resources
multi-year research projects have been according to opportunity” (Johannisson 2011,
implemented such as the Munich Founder 137). Entrepreneuring arises in the flow of events;
Study, the Panel-Study of Entrepreneurial Devel- it is a sequence of orchestrated activities carried
opment in the USA, or the Global Entrepreneur- out by socially constructed entrepreneurs
ship Monitor. (DeClercq and Voronov 2009; Gartner 2010;
This stream of research provides insights into Vestrum 2014). This growing trend adheres to
demographics of entrepreneurship and its diver- and enhances a storytelling aspect of entre-
sity, as well as the complexity of the business- preneurship. Johannisson (2011) argued that
founding process. In terms of what it is that entrepreneurs, as storytellers and communicators,
17 Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness of Entrepreneurial Activity 257

come to be viewed as dependable figures in the regular coordination of entrepreneurial activity


capitalist economic system. They utilize (Granovetter 1995; Ferrary and Granovetter
strategies of encouraging other people’s beliefs 2009).
in their competence and trustworthiness. At the These studies on monitoring activities during
same time, this approach reminds us that organizational emergence illustrate tie formation
entrepreneurial storytelling is grounded in a prac- and more specifically the formation of entrepre-
tical awareness of entrepreneurs performing in a neurial groups during this process (Munich
specific institutional setting (Garud et al. 2018). Founder Study, PSED, GEM). Ruef (2010)
In summary, entrepreneurship can be suggests an understanding of entrepreneurship
described as activity bundles directed towards an as a recruitment process in which focal
imagined future that involves the creation of entrepreneurs convince others to provide capital,
something new. Drawing from Beckert’s (2016) their labor capacity or emotional support in pur-
understanding of imagined futures, one could suing an entrepreneurial venture (Ruef 2010;
argue that entrepreneurs, although constrained Klotz et al. 2014). Hence, in the process of entre-
by their social embedding, draft and narrate fic- preneurship not only do organizations emerge,
tional expectations that convince others to pro- but entrepreneurial groups arise, morph, and
vide credit, invest in their ventures or purchase reproduce.2 (Granovetter 1995; Thornton 1999;
their products or services, among other actions. Ruef and Lounsbury 2007; Thornton et al.
Such imagined futures, built into the process of 2011). Ruef (2010) shows that the vast majority
entrepreneurship, play a key function in moving of new ventures in the US is carried forward by
and directing capitalist dynamics (Harrington groups that are predominantly based on strong tie
2017). relationships. Entrepreneurial groups consist of
spouses, siblings, parents and their children,
friends, and former colleagues. They are mostly
2.3 Entrepreneurship as Collective dyads and triads but are sometimes larger small
Action (Re)producing Groups groups. When forming venture collaborations,
entrepreneurs seek allies among their most trusted
Looking at the activity bundles during the early confidants and in their further recruitment of busi-
start-up phase of a venture from a network per- ness partners, capital, employees, or customers
spective yielded further important insights to a they utilize the network relationships available
sociology of entrepreneurship. Departing from to them. Given that such networks differ
his social structural view on economic activity, depending on the social position of the involved
Granovetter suggested that entrepreneurs utilize members (Granovetter 1985), we can expect, as
two kinds of social relationships, for very differ- Ruef suggests, to find differing recruitment
ent reasons (Granovetter 1985, 1995; Ferrary and patterns and multiple pathways of entrepreneurial
Granovetter 2009). By leveraging social relations groups (Ruef 2010). Considering such a relational
with acquaintances (weak ties) they induce new demography approach can explain why entrepre-
knowledge into the entrepreneurial process, neurial groups are often homogenous in many
which is vital for obtaining new resources (capi- aspects (gender, age, education, like-
tal, employees, but also other material resources). mindedness), but considerably different forms of
It helps identify new opportunities and provides entrepreneurial groups can exist parallel to each
input for drafting future visions (Granovetter other (Stamm et al. 2019). Moreover, such
1985). In this sense, entrepreneurs engage in
bridging between disassociated networks. By
2
leveraging regular interactions with family In the interdisciplinary entrepreneurship literature such
small groups engaged in venture creation are often referred
members, friends, and strong ties or colleagues,
to as entrepreneurial teams or new venture teams. In the
entrepreneurs use trust and solidarity generated in following, I will use the term entrepreneurial groups as
strong ties, two key ingredients that enable a suggested by Ruef, but I will expand on its meaning.
258 I. Stamm

entrepreneurial groups do not suddenly disappear (Schäfers 1999; Harrington and Fine 2006; Fine
after organizational emergence. They form dis- 2012b). From this vantage point, entrepreneurial
tinct social units that differ from but intertwine groups are “aggregations of persons who recog-
with the organization. Such entrepreneurial nize that they constitute a meaningful social unit,
groups can also not be equalized with the ethnic, interact on that basis, and are committed to that
friendship, or family communities they may be social unit” (Fine 2012b, 21). They feature a
embedded in. shared history, an ideo-culture, and a shared pros-
Embracing entrepreneurial groups as a distinct pect on the future (Fine 2012b).
social unit that is intertwined with, but different The bundled and consecutive activities of
from the organization, requires the acceptance of group members constitute their joint pathway,
entrepreneurial groups as economic actors in their during which they share experiences and identify
own right, and are embedded in institutional themselves as contributors to the venture. Mean-
environments that go beyond just the attached ing derives not from interaction as such, but
organization. In any case, a sociological under- through continuing references that historicize the
standing of entrepreneurial group dynamics group and a group style that filters and localizes
overcomes the equation of a venture with organi- collective representations (Fine 2010, 2012a,
zational emergence (Aldrich and Ruef 2006; Ruef 168). Within the group, interactions routinize
2010; Jin et al. 2017), but also considers that such and a system of knowledge, beliefs, behavior,
a venture can be a matter of wealth and job and customs forms what Fine refers to as ideo-
creation (Welter et al. 2016), or a generational culture (Fine 2012a, b). A solidified ideo-culture
spanning family project (Nordqvist and Melin creates boundaries, separating insiders from those
2010). Hence, group members can act collec- who stand outside the realm of collective knowl-
tively under the pressure to earn an income and edge (Fine 2010, 2012a). Entrepreneurial groups
create their own jobs. They strive to increase their are sites of activity, identification, and social
economic and/or social wealth, dream of relations supporting a shared vision of creativity,
emancipating themselves or driving change but they are also fragile as career trajectories of
(Welter et al. 2016). group members may veer in different directions
(Fine 2012b, 168). Over time not only may
participants of groups change, but also the very
3 The Dual Problem of Solidarity definition of the group may change, which makes
membership fluid (Fine and Harrington 2004,
The concept of entrepreneurial groups ultimately 352). Finally, entrepreneurial groups also believe
classifies the idea of entrepreneurs being heroic in a common future as a social unit, which
individuals as a myth (Harper 2008). This provides expectations of continuity or may sug-
approach also exceeds the dominant process gest the possibility of change. As mentioned
understanding in entrepreneurship by suggesting above, the joint drafting of fictional expectations
that entrepreneurship is a collective action is also key to entrepreneurial activity and guides
(Lounsbury 1998; Thornton 1999; Ruef and economic actions.
Lounsbury 2007). Nevertheless, knowledge If one applies such a small group perspective
about the inner workings of entrepreneurial on the collective action of entrepreneurship,
groups remains cursory, which prohibits probing Ruef’s (2010) idea of varying recruitment
into the connections between forms of entrepre- patterns can be grasped as differences in the way
neurial groups and the logics, roles, and rules groups select their members and draw boundaries.
these groups follow in their local contexts. In order to understand these differences, the con-
In order to further develop a sociology of ceptual idea of a dual problem of solidarity that
entrepreneurship, I suggest connecting the con- has been described for ethnic entrepreneurship
cept of entrepreneurial groups more closely to a (Aldrich and Zimmer 1986; Aldrich and
sociological perspective on small groups Waldinger 1990; Granovetter 1995), is instructive
17 Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness of Entrepreneurial Activity 259

and, as I suggest, could be used as a guiding minorities, and furthers trust within the commu-
principle to understand group member formation nity. In the formation of an entrepreneurial group,
and maintenance in respective institutional the position of being part of an immigrant minor-
settings more generally. ity can allow for ethnic ties to be seen as trust-
Granovetter (1995) suggests that drawing from worthy and also to influence inclusion tendencies.
trust relationships is particularly important for the In this case, ethnicity then becomes the dominate
coordination of economic activity under uncer- source of trust, which may or may not overlap
tainty. As noted above, entrepreneurs first turn with other strong tie relationships (such as being
to trusted relationships in order to recruit family members). Minority communities face dis-
employees, financial capital, material resources, crimination, which actually nurtures inclusion
or simple advice. It is on the grounds of trust tendencies of community members as trust
relationships that entrepreneurial groups select beyond the clearly defined boundary of the
their members and maintain their boundaries. minority community falls of sharply (Granovetter
Based on these observations, Granovetter (1995) 1995).
suggests a dual problem of solidarity: building While Granovetter (1995) has described the
small groups on insufficient solidarity leads to a role of ethnicity to solve the dual problem of
failure of trust, while uncontrolled solidarity solidarity in certain institutional settings, he
results in excessive non-economic claims suggests that other communities, which are not
constraining entrepreneurial activity. An as easily identified, may fulfill similar functions
entrepreneurial group’s pathway of including cer- in the entrepreneurial process. He calls economic
tain members while excluding or not even sociologists to consider the nexus between social
approaching others can be seen as a strategy to groups and entrepreneurial activity in various
deal with the dual problem of solidarity and can institutional settings (Granovetter 1995). The
eventually bring about balanced solidarity. These general point raised here is that conditions,
inclusions and exclusions are a case of embedded which raise the salience of group identity and
agency, allowing for some strategic decision boundaries, play a key role in understanding the
making within an institutionally structured complex balance of inclusion and exclusion in the
setting.3 formation and maintenance of entrepreneurial
In the case of immigrant minority groups.
communities4 such as Chinese, Korean, Japanese,
or Philippine communities, sociologists of entre-
preneurship have illustrated how the constructed 4 Two Types of Entrepreneurial
ethnic identity influences member selection and Groups, Two Sets
boundary maintenance in entrepreneurial groups of Embeddedness
(Aldrich and Zimmer 1986; Aldrich and
Waldinger 1990; Granovetter 1995). Ethnicity as Based on the previous considerations, entrepre-
a shared home culture offers norms of proper neurial groups aggregate a small number of
behavior, creates social identity among immigrant individuals, who recognize that they constitute a
meaningful social unit through continued refer-
3
ence to their shared history, who interact on the
Granovetter uses the terms coupling and decoupling,
basis of negotiated roles and rules forming a
whereas I refer to inclusion and exclusion in order to
differentiate the terms from their meaning in organization distinct ideo-culture, and who draft a shared pro-
theory and to emphasize the crafting of group boundaries. spective future. Entrepreneurial groups form in
4
Granovetter uses the term ethnic group in the sense of a intertwinement with their respective institutional
larger social group sharing an ethnic identity. I substitute context and hence, we can reasonably assume that
his use of ethnic group with the term community in order to
depending on which form of small groups they
avoid confusion, with a different understanding of group
that I will use for the remainder of this chapter: groups in refer to in the institutional fabric, various types of
the sense of small groups. entrepreneurial groups exist. In the following, I
260 I. Stamm

will depart from the example of ethnic entre- organizations more resilient to financial market
preneurship and will apply the idea of inclusion demands (Lehrer and Celo 2016).
and exclusion in the formation and reproduction Lehrer and Celo (2016) argue further that these
of entrepreneurial groups. I will also suggest two characteristics of entrepreneurial families are
other forms of entrepreneurial groups: entrepre- embedded in a familial sector in German econ-
neurial families and start-up teams that co-exist omy, (i.e., the presence of institutions to promote
within the German economic system and corre- and protect closely held family ownership). They
spond to two very different sets of embedding. identify three key elements constituting this set of
embedding. First, entrepreneurial families mainly
adhere to the organizational practice of using
4.1 The Entrepreneurial Family retained earnings to finance the development of
in German Family Capitalism their business venture. Second, banks are
expected to be providers of occasional loans and
In entrepreneurial families, as a form of entrepre- protectors of a family’s privacy rather than being
neurial group, selected family members jointly a strategic partner in investments (see also Deeg
engage in entrepreneurial activity. Their shared 2010). Third, politics and inheritance taxes are
experience pertains to prior and ongoing exceptionally benevolent to long-term family
interactions within the family and to their joint engagement in business ownership (see also
engagement in the business. They establish an Beckert 2008; Carney et al. 2014). All of these
ideo-culture that is distinct from the family and factors influence and support an inclusion of fam-
that has effects on organizational structures and ily members in entrepreneurial groups during
cultures. The group’s ideo-culture and its imag- group formation and reproduction.
ined future draws from institutional roots around The line of argument put forward by Lehrer
family solidarity, transgenerational transfer, or and Celo (2016) is convincing and marks an
family status in local institutions. important advance in economic sociology. At
Gómez-Mejía and colleagues emphasize that the same time, the authors remain very much
for entrepreneurial families the success of the focused on the firm and market coordination and
venture is subordinate to the fulfillment of the continue to ignore important aspects of the insti-
family’s financial, social, and affective needs tutional environment under which such family
(Gomez-Mejia et al. 2015). Through their members engage collectively in entrepreneurship.
engagement in entrepreneurial activity, entrepre- I suggest that digging into the depth of family
neurial families seek to support the involved institutional settings will help unveil another set
households and want to accumulate wealth, but of explanatory factors, which protect and help
they mainly seek to build identity, ensure family maintain entrepreneurial families as a specific
influence, and increase their local social status form of entrepreneurial groups.
(Gómez-Mejía et al. 2007; Welter et al. 2016). Particularly interesting from the perspective of
Based on previous research in finance, Lehrer and entrepreneurial families are family ideals, which
Celo (2016) emphasize that the overriding finan- not only rest on the family’s emotional or educa-
cial strategy of family firms is to avoid tional function but include ways of coordinating
jeopardizing family control through dependency activity. German families operate in an institu-
on external providers of credit or financial equity. tional environment that, for many decades and
This characteristic feature of entrepreneurial up until recently, has embraced the male-
families steers their inclusion and exclusion breadwinner ideal for organizing the family
movements in the formation and reproduction of (Pfau-Effinger 2004). At the center of this ideal,
the group towards selected family members, who which is rather traditional in comparison to
are protected from outside influences. This pat- Northern European countries, is the task differen-
tern does not only empower entrepreneurial tiation between spouses with the male part taking
families within the organization, but makes their on the task of earning an income and the female
17 Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness of Entrepreneurial Activity 261

part caring for home and the off-spring (Grunow turns into an important issue. As Beckert (2008)
et al. 2006). For many decades, this image was elaborated, the German legal and taxation code
engraved in cultural gender norms and formed a has a tradition of viewing property as family
key reference point in the social welfare system in property and the legal owner as trustee for the
Germany (Fagnani 2012). Although this ideal has estate of the clan. Both legal regulations of
been discredited in the rise of gender equality and bequests and inheritance law create favorable
a dramatic shift in the social policy making, actual conditions for transgenerational support in conju-
task differentiation among the majority of Ger- gal families, which makes transfer of business
man couples is changing slowly (Fagnani 2012). ownership within the family more attractive than
This organizational aspect of the family in outside the family. Klein (2004) suggested that in
Germany suggests that family members share their way of retaining ownership within the fam-
tasks in order to contribute to the overall well- ily, entrepreneurial families would mimic
being of the family. Hence, when starting an European aristocratic families. Plate et al. (2011)
entrepreneurial venture in such an institutional illustrated a number of historic cases, where capi-
environment, family members are expected to tal spread across the family network. Yet, this is
support, maintain, or improve the family status only part of the story. In fact, having most of the
quo. This institutional context nourishes inclusion family wealth tied to a business makes it hard to
tendencies of entrepreneurial families, resting fulfill the norm of bequeathing equally to all
ownership of the business in the hand of a small descendants. German inheritance law ensures
group of spouses and/or siblings. that all children will receive a mandatory portion,
Furthermore, institutionalized rules of inter- which can result in the need to sell the business in
generational transfer within families in Germany order to create enough liquid capital to pay
effect the way entrepreneurial families view their non-involved parts of the family. Bohler and
venture as spanning generations, and hence, the Hildenbrand (1997) as well as Breuer (2009)
way they reproduce the entrepreneurial group remind us of the tradition among farming
within the family. As research on intergenera- families, waiving their property rights to protect
tional transfers has shown, in vivo transfers usu- family wealth from being broken into nonfunc-
ally follow the ideal of provision for family tional pieces, which could also be observed in
members in need, while postmortem transfers other entrepreneurial families.
are expected to consider all offspring with equal The relevance of distinction and discrimina-
parts (Albertini et al. 2007). Up until the end of tion of entrepreneurial families in their local
the tenure of the founding family members, the communities which fosters exclusion seems
venture thus provides resources and privileges worth mentioning in this context. Previous
that can be utilized to support family well-being research has emphasized that family owners feel
or help family members in times of economic especially obliged to cultivate a good reputation
hardship. The venture may further be seen as a in the local community (Colli 2013; Deephouse
steppingstone enabling future generations to and Jaskiewicz 2013). Given that there are usu-
move into professional careers. Although the ally few entrepreneurial families in a local com-
majority of entrepreneurial families do not engage munity and that entrepreneurship offers a way of
in joint entrepreneurial activity across social upward mobility for those less educated or
generations,5 for those that do, bequeathing with less training, including those educated and
trained outside a European context, engagement
5
Remarkably, most research on entrepreneurial families in entrepreneurial activity makes entrepreneurial
pronounces a long-term outlook of their engagement and families a distinct part of the local community
the wish that the business will be passed on across (Granovetter 1995). Not all entrepreneurs are suc-
generations (Le Breton-Miller and Miller 2006; Colli
cessful at creating the need to uphold an image of
2013). However, this generalization seems biased towards
large family firms and does not keep up with the heteroge- the respectable entrepreneur to the public and
neity of entrepreneurial families. dealing with precarious situations in the privacy
262 I. Stamm

of the entrepreneurial group. In the case of wealth Schjoedt et al. 2013). Start-up teams commonly
accumulation entrepreneurial families may feel rest upon friendship or collegial ties, yet the type
envied and estranged from their local of tie in this constellation is less relevant as it
communities, again leading to exclusion. The becomes coded with a layer of strong working
identification of entrepreneurial families as a dis- relationships. Hence, start-up teams may very
tinct sub-group within their local community may well consist of brothers or friends, but key to the
be another driver for entrepreneurial families to shared past, ideo-culture, and prospective future
continue to partner with selected family members. of this entrepreneurial group is their work rela-
To sum up, while the ideal of the family being tionship.6 This relationship follows the ideal of a
a task differentiated solidarity community and project team that creatively, intensely, and tem-
institutionalized rules around generational trans- porarily works together to realize a set goal. Start-
fer support inclusion of selected, but not all fam- up teams engage in collective action to succeed
ily members in entrepreneurial families, the social with their venture idea, but also for the experience
status of entrepreneurial families in reference to of being in a start-up project in the sense of a
their local community supports exclusion of other career sequence and a personal challenge.
potential collaborators. These features of the insti- Such start-up teams are typically associated
tutional context of families thus mark additional with an entrepreneurial ecosystem (Brown and
factors, which are able to explain the specificity of Mason 2017; Spigel 2017), a term frequently
entrepreneurial families as entrepreneurial used to describe an organizational field centered
groups. In these groups the co-engagement with around new venture creation (DiMaggio and
family members and closely held ownership mark Powell 1983; Aldrich and Ruef 2006), in which
the content of their joint history, shape their ideo- start-ups hold close connections to each other as
culture and the idea of intergenerational succes- well as to university, community, and financial
sion as a prospective future. actors. I will refer to such entrepreneurial
ecosystems as new venture fields. For the Silicon
Valley, as most famous and successful of such
4.2 The Start-Up Team in the Berlin new venture fields, researchers have emphasized
New Venture Field that start-up teams operate in regional density,
with flat hierarchies and frequent social
In contrast, start-up teams, as another form of interactions turning informal networks into an
entrepreneurial group, select team members on important success factor (Swedberg 2003). In
the basis of creating a functioning meritocratic her in-depth study on the Silicon Valley,
work team. Their shared experience pertains to Saxenian (1996) argued further that this new ven-
prior, and especially to ongoing interactions of ture field is an exceptional case formed by a local
working jointly on a new venture project. They culture of shared understandings and practices,
establish an ideo-culture centered around group which values high competition and risk-taking
dynamics, complementary competences, and a (Saxenian 1996; Gold 2018). Advancing a
temporary character of their joint engagement. social-structural argument, Ferrary and
The group’s ideo-culture and imagined future Granovetter (2009) describe the heterogeneity of
draw from institutional roots around new forms agents and the multiplexity of agent relations in
of work and exit-orientation. As I will argue in the the Silicon Valley as constitutive and nurturing
following, such start-up teams are also closely for start-up teams (e.g., an entrepreneur moves
intertwined with a distinct set of institutional from being a start-up team member to mentor or
embedding. The term start-up team, or new ven-
ture team, usually refers to a team of co-founders 6
Remarkably, family ties are not fully alien to the Berlin
that have financial stake in an entrepreneurial
new venture field as the case of the Samwer brothers, the
venture and co-work in the endeavor of bringing founders of Zalando and owners of the equity investment
their founding idea to fruition (Lechler 2001; firm Rocket Internet, famously illustrates.
17 Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness of Entrepreneurial Activity 263

surrogate entrepreneur to angel investor and university context, mainly scientists who seek to
back). Within this complex network, they elabo- commercialize their findings by participating in
rate upon the relevance of venture capitalists in public funding programs. While both rest upon a
the embedding of start-up teams in the field start-up team, the embedding of these teams
(Ferrary and Granovetter 2009). The success of differs (2020). Start-Ups supported by equity cap-
a venture not only depends on its innovativeness, ital are part of a dense entrepreneurial community
but on its embedding in the complex network with vivid, informal exchange, multiplexity of
which grants access to financial resources, poten- agents, and a key role for venture capitalists. At
tial team members and expert knowledge (Ferrary the same time, start-ups spinning out of university
and Granovetter 2009). incubators and state actors form a second and
In Germany, a number of such new venture somewhat removed network.
fields are emerging in Rhein-Ruhr, Stuttgart, Nevertheless, Berlin start-up teams share some
Munich, Hamburg, and Berlin, which in some essential features that become obvious in their
ways seek to imitate the Silicon Valley, but are group formation process (Ucbasaran et al. 2003;
bound to local infrastructure, networks, and cul- Cooney 2005). The initial team formation is set
ture. I will limit my discussion to research on the on the creation of a functioning work team.
Berlin start-up scene, which developed after the Strong social relationships between team
unification of East and West Germany in 1989, members are common and come with a number
hence it is much younger than the Silicon Valley, of advantages but are not essential to the forma-
and today is ranked as one of the top three new tion of a functioning team. While most start-up
venture fields in Europe (Ernst and Young 2019). teams are comprised of two founders who have
Most of the activities of start-up teams are locally been friends or colleagues for several years, other
clustered around Mitte and Friedrichshain- teams emerge from a random meeting of
Kreuzberg, two neighboring districts in the center acquaintances within the start-up community or
of Berlin. According to the Berlin Start-Up Mon- within the scientific community (Scheidgen
itor (2018), almost half of the surveyed start-ups 2019). The fact that start-up teams can form
operate in software and software development, even on the basis of acquaintances suggests that
fin-tech, and online marketplaces. The Berlin in the process of team formation the initial tie
start-up scene is dominated by male academics becomes coded with a strong work-based rela-
in their mid-30s. About 84% of the entrepreneurs tionship that then serves as an anchor point for
surveyed in the Berlin Start-Up Monitor (2018) the joint entrepreneurial activity. Anecdotes about
hold an academic degree, mainly in management the work-spirit during this initial phase form an
or economics, but also in computer science, math- important reference point for the development the
ematics, or engineering. team’s social identity. Work norms and fictional
In her study on the Berlin new venture field, expectations about new digital work appear to be
Scheidgen (2019, 2020) describes that start-up central institutional anchor points maintaining
teams profit from the agglomeration of young, start-up teams as particular form of entrepreneur-
often international professionals, linked to four ial groups.
universities, entrepreneurial education programs, A second stage in the group formation of start-
public funding for start-up activities, and a num- up teams encompasses team enlargement
ber of co-working spaces, incubators, and (Vanaelst et al. 2006; Scheidgen 2019). The ini-
accelerators. Characteristic for the start-up scene tial start-up team searches for and actively selects
are regular events providing opportunity for additional team members, which can include
informal and formal networking. According to another co-founder, a surrogate entrepreneur, or
Scheidgen (2020), what is peculiar to the new an angel investor. The additional team members
venture field in Berlin is the low degree of inte- should bring in an outside perspective, a commer-
gration between start-ups supported by equity cial experience or managerial skills
capital and those start-ups spinning out of a complementing the existing skill set of the team
264 I. Stamm

that faces the challenges of a pitch-culture, the Finally, start-up teams act within
need to write up a business plan, and master the institutionalized rules of an exit-orientation
dependence of digital infrastructure (Clarysse and (DeTienne and Cardon 2012), which support a
Moray 2004; Vanaelst et al. 2006). As Scheidgen project-logic of their joint engagement (Boltanski
(2019) proposes, the difference between start-ups and Chiapello 2003) and represent an entirely
supported by equity and start-ups spinning-off the different approach to group reproduction than
university context is the influence of private succession in entrepreneurial families. For equity
equity investors on the one hand and state funded capitalists, supporting new ventures is only tem-
programs on the other. In both cases, however, porarily relevant and aims at realizing a return of
the start-up team considers assumed expectations investment at a given point. Similarly, start-up
of financial field actors in their selection of addi- members enter a team on temporary terms until
tional team members. For some start-up teams a set goal has been achieved or they move on to
this means catering to anticipated expectations other professional or private projects (Wennberg
of venture capitalists, blueprints communicated et al. 2010). This finitude of the start-up team
in the entrepreneurial field, and learned customs. materializes in the co-founder contract, which at
For others this means catering to formalized the moment of founding an organization already
requirements set by public funding programs anticipates the case of a team member exit
(mainly the EXIST program) (Scheidgen 2019). (Breugst et al. 2015). The exit-orientation in
In both cases, the enlarged start-up team is start-up teams thus seems to be driven by finan-
comprised of the initial work team supported by cial market actors but also maintained and
team members fulfilling anticipated strategic field nourished by destandardized and projectified
functions (Lim et al. 2013). ideas of work and career.
Anticipated expectations of venture capitalists To sum up, while the ideal of a functioning
and funding policies both imply ideas about how work team and the anticipation of an investor’s
an ideal start-up team should look. These ideas expectations support inclusion of selected team
include a minimum and maximum number of members in start-up teams, a prescribed group
such team members and suggest that they should size, an implied need for complementary skills,
include heterogeneous expertise (Ebner 2010). and an exit-orientation support exclusion of team
This implied image about start-up teams seems members from other network actors. A further
to be biased towards highly trained professionals examination of the institutional origins of the
and prior entrepreneurial experience, turning implied images of start-up teams in the new ven-
team expansion into a rather exclusive and ture field appears to be necessary to explain how,
demanding act. We can reasonably assume that aside from the key role of equity capital actors,
this ideal has institutional predecessors as it this form of entrepreneurial group is created and
strongly resembles typical images about maintained.
partnerships in industrial firms led by a manage-
ment and technical executives, who were often
brothers, although empirical research is lacking. 5 Variety of Groups, Variety
Further, investors look at the dynamic within the of Entrepreneurial Activity
group as a key factor to assess whether they trust a
team to succeed in the market or not. Contrary to The two forms of entrepreneurial groups––
family capitalism, where the family is granted the entrepreneurial families and start up teams––
freedom of going through stretches of conflict, or each represent solutions to Granovetter’s dual
disharmony, the presenting of a friendly and func- problem of solidarity. By creating an alliance of
tioning group dynamic appears to be an essential family members engaged in entrepreneurial activ-
assessment criterion applied to start-up teams by ity, entrepreneurial families draw from the trust
the start-up field. and solidarity contained in family relationships.
The expectation of sharing tasks among family
17 Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness of Entrepreneurial Activity 265

members, waiving rules of generational transfer, are family firms (Gottschalk and Keese 2014).
and discrimination on the basis of social status However, as we have seen in this discussion, the
drive inclusion of family members and exclusion involvement of multiple family members in an
from the wider kinship network as well as other entrepreneurial group does not yet qualify this
social groups within the local community. Start- group to be an entrepreneurial family. In
up teams on the contrary, create a functioning co-existence with entrepreneurial families, start-
work team as a basis for trust and solidarity. A up teams are flourishing in the Berlin start up field
potential lack of solidarity is filled on the grounds and across other regions in the country.
of social cohesion within the team, a belief in a In light of this discussion, entrepreneurial
termed future, and the strategic fulfillment of field groups can be seen as an intermediate analysis
expectations about the team. Inclusion and exclu- unit. They open up an understanding of the social
sion in start-up teams considers harmonious work embedding of entrepreneurship towards highly
relations, complementary competences, and the relevant institutional arenas such as the family
temporary character of their co-engagement. or work teams, which have thus far been
Although both forms of entrepreneurial groups overlooked. A small group perspective on entre-
are socially constructed, start-up teams appear preneurship not only acknowledges entrepreneur-
strikingly more vulnerable to manipulative inter- ial groups as drivers of capitalist dynamics, but
vention from the new venture field. also draws attention to the emergence and
Putting entrepreneurial families and start-up morphing of such social forms.
ventures in juxtaposition underlines that the type
of tie (strong or weak, family or friends) is not
relevant per se, for entrepreneurial group forma- References
tion and maintenance. Rather, it is the family or
the work team as a reference of solidarity that is Albertini, M., Kohli, M., & Vogel, C. (2007). Intergenera-
embraced in the history, ideo-culture, and pro- tional transfers of time and money in European
Families: Common patterns—different regimes?
spective future of the group. These references of
European Journal of Social Policy, 17(4), 319–334.
solidarity are protected and supported by the Aldrich, H. E. (2005). Entrepreneurship. In N. J. Smelser
respective institutional setting. The relationship & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic
between entrepreneurial group and its social sociology (pp. 451–477). Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni-
versity Press.
embeddedness differs from, but is strongly related
Aldrich, H. E., & Marlene Fiol, C. (1994). Fools rush in?
to, the embeddedness of the respective attached The institutional context of industry creation. Academy
organizations (i.e., family firms and new of Management Journal, 19, 645–670.
ventures) as they coordinate activity on markets. Aldrich, H. E., & Ruef, M. (2006). Organizations
evolving. London: SAGE.
The discussion further illustrates how within
Aldrich, H. E., & Waldinger, R. (1990). Ethnicity and
one variant of capitalism, the German coordinated entrepreneurship. Annual Review of Sociology, 16,
market economy, multiple forms of entrepreneur- 111–135.
ial groups are linked to their respective institu- Aldrich, H. E., & Zimmer, C. (1986). Entrepreneurship
through social networks. California Management
tional settings that co-exist and successfully
Review, 33, 3–23.
nurture entrepreneurial activity. In the case of Alvarez, S. A., & Barney, J. B. (2010). Entrepreneurship
Germany, entrepreneurial families are still seen and epistemology: The philosophical underpinnings of
as the dominant form of entrepreneurial groups the study of entrepreneurial opportunities. Academy of
Management Annals, 4(1), 557–583.
(Berghoff 2006; Lehrer and Celo 2016). As an
Battilana, J. (2006). Agency and institutions: The enabling
indicator of German family capitalism, empirical role of individuals’ social position. Organization, 13
studies often refer to the dominance of owner- (5), 653–676.
managers (who are often supported by Beckert, J. (2008). Inherited wealth. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
non-owning family members) and ownership
Beckert, J. (2016). Imagined futures: Fictional
closely held within one family, some even stating expectations and capitalist dynamics. Cambridge,
that more than 90% of all businesses in Germany MA: Harvard University Press.
266 I. Stamm

Berghoff, H. (2006). The end of family business? The Deephouse, D. L., & Jaskiewicz, P. (2013). Do family
Mittelstand and German capitalism in transition, firms have better reputations than non-family firms?
1949–2000. Business History Review, 80, 263–295. An integration of socioemotional wealth and social
Bohler, K. F., & Hildenbrand, B. (1997). identity theories. Journal of Management Studies, 50,
Landwirtschaftliche Familienbetriebe in der Krise. 337–360.
Münster: Lit Verlag AG. DeTienne, D. R., & Cardon, M. S. (2012). Impact of
Boltanski, L., & Chiapello, È. (2003). Der neue Geist des founder experience on exit intentions. Small Business
Kapitalismus. Konstanz: UVK-Verlag. Economics, 38(4), 351–374.
Bourdieu, P. (1977). Outline of a theory of practice. Deutschmann, C. (2008). Der Typus des Unternehmers in
Cambridge Studies in Social and Cultural Anthropol- wirtschaftssoziologischer Sicht. In A. Maurer &
ogy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. U. Schimank (Eds.), Die Unternehmen der Gesell-
Breuer, F. (2009). Vorgänger und Nachfolger: Weitergabe schaft: Gesellschaftstheoretische Zugänge zum
in institutionellen und persönlichen Bezügen. Wirtschaftsgeschehen (pp. 40–62). Wiesbaden: VS
Göttingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht. Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.
Breugst, N., Patzelt, H., & Rathgeber, P. (2015). How Dilli, S., Elert, N., & Herrmann, A. M. (2018). Varieties of
should we divide the Pie? Equity distribution and its entrepreneurship: Exploring the institutional
impact on entrepreneurial teams. Journal of Business foundations of different entrepreneurship types
Venturing, 30(1), 66–94. through ‘varieties-of-capitalism’ arguments. Small
Brown, R., & Mason, C. (2017). Looking inside the spiky Business Economics, 51(2), 293–320.
bits: A critical review and conceptualisation of DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The iron cage
entrepreneurial ecosystem. Small Business Economics, revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective
49(1), 11–30. rationality in organizational fields. American Sociolog-
Brüderl, J., Preisendörfer, P., & Ziegler, R. (1992). Sur- ical Review, 48(2), 147–160.
vival chances of newly founded business Dorado, S. (2005). Institutional entrepreneurship,
organizations. American Sociological Review, 57(2), partaking, and convening. Organization Studies, 26
227–242. (3), 385–414.
Bruni, A., Gherardi, S., & Poggio, B. (2004). Doing gen- Ebner, A. (2005). Entrepreneurship and economic devel-
der, doing entrepreneurship: An ethnographic account opment: From classical political economy to economic
of intertwined practices. Gender, Work and Organiza- sociology. Journal of Economic Studies, 32(3),
tion, 11(4), 406–429. 256–274.
BSM. (2018). Berlin start up monitor. Google for Ebner, A. (2010). Varieties of capitalism and the limits of
Entrepreneurs and Bundesverband Deutsche Startups entrepreneurship policy. Journal of Industry, Competi-
e.V. tion and Trade, 10(3–4), 319–341.
Carney, M., Gedajlovic, E., & Strike, V. (2014). Dead Ernst and Young AG. (2019). Start-up-Barometer
money: Inheritance law and the longevity of firms. Europa: Analyse der Kapitalfinanzierung
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practise, 38(6), europäischer Start-ups. St. Gallen: Ernst and Young
1261–1283. AG.
Carter, N. M., Gartner, W. B., & Reynolds, P. D. (1996). Fagnani, J. (2012). Recent reforms in childcare and family
Exploring start-up sequences. Journal of Business Ven- policies in France and Germany: What was at stake?
turing, 11, 151–166. Comparative Child and Family Policy, 34(3),
Clarysse, B., & Moray, N. (2004). A process study of 509–516.
entrepreneurial team formation: The case of a Ferrary, M., & Granovetter, M. (2009). The role of venture
research-based spin-off. Journal of Business Ventur- capital firms in Silicon Valley’s complex innovation
ing, 19(1), 55–79. network. Economy and Society, 38(2), 326–359.
Colli, A. (2013). Family firms between risks and Fine, G. A. (2010). The sociology of the local: Action and
opportunities: A literature review. Socio-Economic its public. Sociological Theory, 28, 355–376.
Review, 11, 577–599. Fine, G. A. (2012a). Group culture and the interaction
Cooney, T. M. (2005). What is an entrepreneurial team? order: Local sociology on the meso-level. Annual
International Small Business Journal, 23(3), 226–235. Review of Sociology, 38, 159–179.
Davidsson, P., Delmar, F., & Wiklund, J. (2008). Entre- Fine, G. A. (2012b). Tiny publics: A theory of group action
preneurship and the growth of firms. Cheltenham: and culture (Russell Sage Foundation Series on Trust).
Edward Elgar. Russell Sage Foundation: New York.
DeClercq, D., & Voronov, M. (2009). Toward a practice Fine, G. A., & Harrington, B. (2004). Tiny publics: Small
perspective of entrepreneurship. International Small groups and civil society. Sociological Theory, 22(3),
Business Journal, 27(4), 395–419. 341–356.
Deeg, R. (2010). Industry and finance in Germany since Gartner, W. B. (1985). A conceptual framework for
reunification. German Politics and Society, 28, describing the phenomenon of new venture creation.
116–129. Academy of Management Review, 10, 696–706.
17 Groups Matter: Social Embeddedness of Entrepreneurial Activity 267

Gartner, W. B. (1988). Who is the entrepreneur? Is the performance: A meta-analysis. Entrepreneurship The-
wrong question. American Journal of Small Business, ory & Practice, 41(5), 743–771.
12(4), 11–32. Johannisson, B. (2011). Towards a practice theory of
Gartner, W. B. (2010). A new path to the waterfall: A entrepreneuring. Small Business Economics, 36(2),
narrative on a use of entrepreneurial narrative. Interna- 135–150.
tional Small Business Journal, 28(1), 6–19. Klein, S. (2004). Familienunternehmen: Theoretische und
Gartner, W. B., Bird, B., & Starr, J. (1992). Act as if: empirische Grundlagen (2. Auflage ed.). Wiesbaden:
Differentiating entrepreneurial from organizational Gabler.
behavior. Entrepreneurship, Theory & Practice, 16, Klotz, A. C., Hmieleski, K. M., Bradley, B. H., &
13–32. Busenitz, L. W. (2014). New venture teams: A review
Garud, R., Gehman, J., & Giuliani, A. P. (2018). Why not of the literature and roadmap for future research. Jour-
take a performative approach to entrepreneurship? nal of Management, 40(1), 226–255.
Journal of Business Venturing Insights, 9(2), 60–64. Le Breton-Miller, I., & Miller, D. (2006). Why do some
Gold, B. (2018). Silicon Valley start-ups and corporate family businesses out-compete? Governance, long-
innovation: Approaches to resolve the innovator’s term orientations, and sustainable capability. Entre-
dilemma. Wiesbaden: Springer Gabler. preneurship Theory & Practice, 30, 731–746.
Gómez-Mejia, L. R., Haynes, K. T., Núnez-Nickel, M., Lechler, T. (2001). Social interaction: A determinant of
Jacobson, K. J. L., & Moyano-Fuentes, J. (2007). entrepreneurial team venture success. Small Business
Socioemotional wealth and business risks in family- Economics, 16(4), 263–278.
controlled firms: Evidence from Spanish olive oil Lehrer, M., & Celo, S. (2016). German family capitalism
mills. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52(1), in the 21st-century: Patient capital between bifurcation
106–137. and symbiosis. Socio-Economic Review, 14(4),
Gómez-Mejia, L. R., Patel, P. C., & Zellweger, T. M. 729–750.
(2015). In the horns of the dilemma: Socioemotional Lim, J. A. Y., Busenitz, L. W., & Chidambaram,
wealth, financial wealth, and acquisitions in family L. (2013). New venture teams and the quality of busi-
firms. Journal of Management, 44(4), 1369–1397. ness opportunities identified: Faultlines between
Gottschalk, S., & Keese, D. (2014). Die subgroups of founders and investors. Entrepreneurship
volkswirtschaftliche Bedeutung von Familienun- Theory & Practice, 37(1), 47–67.
ternehmen. München: ZEW Stiftung Lounsbury, M. (1998). Collective entrepreneurship: The
Familienunternehmen. mobilization of college and university recycling
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social struc- coordinators. Journal of Organizational Change Man-
ture: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal agement, 11(1), 50–69.
of Sociology, 91(3), 481–510. Lumpkin, G. T., & Dess, G. G. (1996). Clarifying the
Granovetter, M. (1995). The economic sociology of firms entrepreneurial orientation construct and linking it to
and entrepreneurs. In A. Portes (Ed.), The economic performance. The Academy of Management Review, 21
sociology of immigration: Essays on networks, ethnic- (1), 135–172.
ity, and entrepreneurship (pp. 128–165). New York: Maurer, A. (Ed.). (2017). Handbuch der Wirtschaftsso-
Russell Sage Foundation. ziologie. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Wiesbaden: VS
Grunow, D., Hofmeister, H., & Buchholz, S. (2006). Late Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.
20th-century persistence and decline of the female McKeever, E., Jack, S., & Anderson, A. (2015). Embed-
homemaker in Germany and the United States. Inter- ded entrepreneurship in the creative re-construction of
national Sociology, 21(1), 101–131. place. Journal of Business Venturing, 30(3), 50–65.
Hall, P., & Soskice, D. (Eds.). (2001). Varieties of capital- Moroz, P. W., & Hindle, K. (2012). Entrepreneurship as a
ism: The institutional foundations of comparative process: Toward harmonizing multiple perspectives.
advantage. New York: Oxford University Press. Entrepreneurship, Theory & Practice, 36(4), 781–818.
Harper, D. A. (2008). Towards a theory of entrepreneurial Nordqvist, M., & Melin, L. (2010). Entrepreneurial
teams. Journal of Business Venturing, 23(6), 613–626. families and family firms. Entrepreneurship &
Harrington, E. B. (2017). Fraud and fantasy: Toward a Regional Development, 22(3–4), 211–239.
new research agenda for economic sociology. Review Pfau-Effinger, B. (2004). Socio-historical paths of the
symposium. Socio-Economic Review, 15(1), 241–258. male breadwinner model––An explanation of cross-
Harrington, E. B., & Fine, G. A. (2006). Where the action national differences. The British Journal of Sociology,
is: Small groups and contemporary sociological theory. 55(3), 377–399.
Small Group Research, 37(1), 1–16. Plate, M., Groth, T., Ackerman, V., & von Schlippe,
Hjorth, D., Holt, R., & Steyaert, C. (2015). Entrepreneur- A. (2011). Große deutsche Familienunternehmen:
ship and process studies. International Small Business Generationenfolge, Familienstrategie und Unterneh-
Journal, 33(6), 599–611. mensentwicklung. Göttingen: Vandenhoeck &
Jin, L., Madison, K., Kraiczy, N. D., Kellermanns, F. W., Ruprecht.
Russell Crook, T., & Xi, J. (2017). Entrepreneurial Portes, A., & Sensenbrenner, J. (1993). Embeddedness
team composition characteristics and new venture and immigration: Notes on the social determinants of
268 I. Stamm

economic action. In American Journal of Sociology, Swedberg, R. (2000). The social science view of entre-
98, 1320–1350. preneurship: Introduction and practical applications. In
Reckwitz, A. (2002). Toward a theory of social practices: R. Swedberg (Ed.), Entrepreneurship: The social sci-
A development in culturalist theorizing. European ence view (Oxford Management Readers) (pp. 7–39).
Journal of Social Theory, 5(2), 243–263. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ruef, M. (2010). The entrepreneurial group: Social Swedberg, R. (2003). Principles of economic sociology.
identities, relations, and collective action (Kauffman Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Foundation Series on Innovation and Entrepreneur- Swedberg, R. (2009). Schumpeter’s full model of entre-
ship). Princeton: Princeton University Press. preneurship: Economic, non-economic and social
Ruef, M., & Lounsbury, M. (Eds.). (2007). The sociology entrepreneurship. In R. Ziegler (Ed.), An introduction
of entrepreneurship. Amsterdam: Elsevier. to social entrepreneurship: Voices, preconditions,
Saxenian, A. L. (1996). Regional advantage: Culture and contexts (pp. 77–106). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Thornton, P. H. (1999). The sociology of entrepreneur-
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ship. Annual Review of Sociology, 25, 19–46.
Schäfers, B. (1999). Entwicklung und Grundlegung der Thornton, P. H., Ribeiro-Soriano, D., & Urbano,
Gruppensoziologie. In B. Schäfers (Ed.), Einführung D. (2011). Socio-cultural factors and entrepreneurial
in die Gruppensoziologie: Geschichte, Theorien, activity. International Small Business Journal, 29(2),
Analysen (pp. 19–36). Wiesbaden: Quelle und Meyer. 105–118.
Schatzki, T. R. (1996). Social practices: A Wittgensteinian Ucbasaran, D., Lockett, A., Wright, M., & Westhead,
approach to human activity and the social. Cambridge: P. (2003). Entrepreneurial founder teams: Factors
Cambridge University Press. associated with member entry and exit. Entrepreneur-
Scheidgen, K. (2019). Social contexts in team formation: ship Theory and Practice, 28(2), 107–128.
Why do independent start-ups and university spin-offs Vanaelst, I., Clarysse, B., Wright, M., Lockett, A., Moray,
form teams differently? Historical Social Research, 44 N., & S’Jegers, R. (2006). Entrepreneurial team devel-
(4), 42–74. opment in academic spinouts: An examination of team
Scheidgen, K. (2020). Degrees of integration: How a heterogeneity. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,
fragmented entrepreneurial ecosystem promotes differ- 30(2), 249–271.
ent types of entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurship & Vestrum, I. (2014). The embedding process of community
Regional Development. ventures. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development,
Schjoedt, L., Monsen, E., Pearson, A., Barnett, T., & 26(7–8), 619–644.
Chrisman, J. J. (2013). New venture and family busi- Weber, M. (1988). Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionsso-
ness teams: Understanding team formation, composi- ziologie. UTB. Religionswissenschaft 1488–90.
tion, behaviors, and performance. Entrepreneurship Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).
Theory and Practice, 37(1), 1–15. Welter, F., Baker, T., Audretsch, D. B., & Gartner, W. B.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1980 [1942]). Kapitalismus, (2016). Everyday entrepreneurship: A call for entre-
Sozialismus und Demokratie. 5. Auflage. preneurship research to embrace entrepreneurial diver-
Uni-Taschenbücher 172. München: Francke. sity. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 41(3),
Shane, S. A. (2007). A general theory of entrepreneurship: 311–321.
The individual-opportunity Nexus. New horizons in Wennberg, K., Wiklund, J., DeTienne, D. R., & Cardon,
entrepreneurship. Elgar: Cheltenham. M. S. (2010). Reconceptualizing entrepreneurial exit:
Smelser, N. J., & Swedberg, R. (Eds.). (2005). The hand- Divergent exit routes and their drivers. Journal of
book of economic sociology. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Business Venturing, 25(4), 361–375.
University Press.
Sombart, W. (1987 [1902]). Der moderne Kapitalismus.
Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot. Isabell Stamm is head of the research group “Entrepre-
Spigel, B. (2017). The relational organization of entrepre- neurial Group Dynamics,” Technische Universität Berlin,
neurial ecosystems. Entrepreneurship Theory & Prac- Germany.
tice, 41(1), 49–72. Research topics: Economic sociology, Mittelstand, en-
Stamm, I., Cruz, A. D., & Cailleut, L. (2019). Entrepre- trepreneurship, small groups. Recent publications:
neurial groups: Definition, forms and history. Histori- Stamm, Isabell, Allan Discua Cruz, and Ludovic Cailleut.
cal Social Research, 44(4), 7–41. 2019. Entrepreneurial Groups––Definition, Forms and
Streek, W. (1997). The German economic model: Does it Historic Change. Historical Social Research 44/4: 7–41.
exist? Can it survive? In C. Crouch & W. Streek (Eds.), Stamm, Isabell, Fabian Bernhard, and Nicole Hameister.
Political Economy of Modern Capitalism: Mapping 2019. Empirische Befunde zu Unternehmerfamilien in
Convergence and Diversity (pp. 33–54). London: Deutschland. In Soziologie der Unternehmerfamilie, eds.
SAGE. Heiko Kleve, and Tobias Köllner, 115–41. Wiesbaden:
Streek, W., & Thelen, K. (2005). Introduction: Institu- Springer VS. Barbera, Francesco, Isabell Stamm, and
tional change in advanced political economies. In Rocki DeWitt. 2018. Entrepreneurial Legacies and
W. Streek & K. Thelen (Eds.), Beyond continuity: Transgenerational Entrepreneurship in Family Firms:
Institutional change in advanced political economies From Imprinting to Imagined Futures. Family Business
(pp. 1–39). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Review 31/3: 352–78.
Part III
Societal Views on Economy
Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an
Economic System 18
Johannes Berger

1 Introduction capitalism. Nevertheless, with the gradual imple-


mentation of the capitalist form of production and
Capitalism is best understood as an organizational distribution of goods, an entirely new form of
form of the economy in which privately owned economic organization has emerged. It differs
enterprises employ workers, with the aim of fundamentally from the former ways of produc-
making a profit by selling the commodities, tion and has become the predominant, if not the
which are produced by using wage labor, on only form of economic activity in the world
markets for goods and services. To clarify this today.
definition, a worker is any person employed by a The central task for social science research is
company against the payment of a salary. These to find an answer to the question: Why, of all
companies can be the private property of possible forms of economic activity, does this
entrepreneurs who manage the business of the particular one dominate world economy today?
company, or they can be companies financed by Following Max Weber and Joseph Schumpeter, I
investors and directed by managers on behalf of see the answer to this question, in the unique
the investors. Not only the manufacturing sector capacity of this economic system to provide
is included in this entirely new kind of economic large masses of the population with goods of
organization, but trade and banking as well. daily use, on a constantly rising scale. Capitalism,
Excluded is only the government as a it is claimed, performs this task more efficient
non-market producer.1 than any other economic system.
All the elements mentioned in this definition: In order to understand this unique capacity, it
private property, markets, commodities, and is indispensable to take a closer look at the insti-
wage labor existed long before the emergence of tutional structure of this system. I will focus on
this question in Sect. 2. Section 3 will deal with
1
Cf. System of National Accounts 2008, 63: “Fundamen- the issue of why capitalist economies are so
tal to the distinction between corporations and government exceptionally successful in producing economic
is the basis on which production is undertaken. growth. In spite of the overwhelming success of
Corporations produce for the market and aim to sell their
this completely new form of economic activity,
products at economically significant prices. Prices are said
to be economically significant if they have a significant its emergence and worldwide implementation has
effect on the amount that producers are willing to supply been accompanied by ongoing criticism which
and the amounts purchasers wish to buy.” highlights its downsides and emphasizes the
disadvantages, instead of the advantages,
J. Berger (*)
University of Mannheim, Mannheim, Germany connected with it. This criticism not only refers
e-mail: jberger@mail.uni-mannheim.de to the economic side of this novel form of
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 271
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_18
272 J. Berger

organizing the economy (e.g., inequality, unem- epochs of ancient history (ibid. 15), and as I may
ployment, poverty, and exploitation of workers), add, entire epochs in the history of other cultures.
but also to its detrimental social and cultural Throughout this chapter, I deliberately limit the
effects. Since the 1970s, criticism concerning term modern capitalism to the particular type of
the degradation of the natural environment has capital valorization mentioned by Weber. The
gradually come to the fore. Since the search for capitalist economic order of modern times,
alternatives is fueled by this criticism, Sect. 3 will based on contractual labor, is unique in a double
also deal with the question of whether socialism is sense. It is a late and improbable product of
a plausible alternative to the predominant eco- development, not a logical step on a scale of
nomic form, and whether it is able to cure the economic forms. It is also the result of a histori-
ills of capitalism. Today the critique of capitalism cally unique constellation of structures and forces
and its future prospects focuses on two major that only existed in early modern Europe.2
issues: stagnation tendencies on the one hand, Modern capitalism comes with a radical
and environmental destruction on the other change of economic life. This transformation
hand. Problems of this kind will be addressed in and fundamental innovation only become appar-
Sect. 4. In the final section, I will discuss the pros ent when the capitalist enterprise is placed at the
and cons of non-socialist reforms of capitalism. center of the analysis.3 Even an economy in
which only small independent producers
exchange goods with each other (Marx’s simple
2 Main Features of a Capitalist commodity production) would still be covered,
Economy for example, by the definition of capitalism as a
private-decentralized economic system. How-
2.1 Rational Organization ever, what distinguishes modern capitalism from
of Formally Free Labor all previous forms of capitalist economic activity
is the employment of wage earners by the owners
The capitalist organization of the economy is a of a monopoly of means of production (capital).
late product of development; this applies at least Marx was aware of that. The consequences of this
to modern capitalism, (in the spirit of Weber). new form of work organization at the firm level,
There have been debates as to whether or not and on the level of the economy were his life-long
the economy was already capitalistically concern.
organized in antiquity (Weber 1924 among As to the fundamental importance of the use of
others), and whether or not this form of organiza- labor power as a commodity in capitalist
tion may have existed in other parts of the world enterprises, Max Weber followed Marx. The
even before the European expansion (see Occident, Weber (1920, 7) writes, knows in mod-
e.g. Collins 1997). When considering this issue, ern times a different type of capitalism that
one realizes that everything depends on the defi- nowhere else on earth existed: the rational-
nition of the term capitalist, which, as Weber capitalistic organization of (formally) free labor.
emphasizes, can naturally be carried out in many Unlike Marx, Weber no longer focuses the analy-
different ways (see Weber 1924, 13). If one does sis of capitalism on exploitation, but on the ratio-
not limit the concept of capitalist economy, nal organization of work. However, both agree
Weber continues, to a certain type of capitalist
exploitation: the exploitation of alien labor by
2
contract with the free worker but allows it to Weber (1981, Chap. 4) and Schluchter (1991, Chap. 10).
apply everywhere where objects of possession, The prerequisites for the emergence of modern capitalism
include particular innovations in the field of law, e.g., the
being exchanged in market transactions, are
separation of private and business assets, which remained
used by private individuals for the purpose of completely unknown in antiquity (Weber 1924, 22).
economic acquisition, then nothing is more solid 3
Cf. Sombart (1916, 6): The least that must be in existence
than a rather extensive capitalist imprint of entire to be able to speak of capitalism is a capitalist enterprise.
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic System 273

that in modern capitalism, labor is only formally 2.2 The Capitalist Firm: A Rational
free. It would be materially free if the design of Organization?
working conditions was the responsibility of the
employees themselves. However, the freedom to As mentioned above, the rational organization of
conclude contracts gained through the abolition labor on the grounds of rational technology (see
of bondage does not guarantee the owners Weber 1980, 323) is the element that
of labor power, the freedom to decide on the use distinguishes modern capitalism from the ancient
of their assets. With the rental of this commodity, forms of adventurer and predatory capitalism. Not
of human labor, to the firm, the right to do so is only does this kind of capitalism need a judiciary
transferred to the firm’s management. Weber and administration whose functioning can be
seems to put even more emphasis on this central rationally calculated (ibid. 322), but the modern
feature than Marx does. “The formal right of a forms of enterprise are themselves bureaucratic
worker,” he writes (Weber 1978, 729), “to enter organizations, the continued existence of which
into any contract whatsoever with any employer lies in the hands of a professionally trained pri-
whatsoever does not, in practice, represent for the vate civil service. According to Weber, work, in a
employment seeker even the slightest freedom in capitalist enterprise, is rationally organized for
the determination of his own conditions of work several reasons. (a) As a formal organization,
and it does not guarantee him any influence on the company is characterized by target-
this process.” orientation, bureaucratic coordination and rule
“Nowhere else on earth”: The radical change binding instead of personal arbitrariness. Even if
of all social relations, people were accustomed to, it was irrational from a macroeconomic point of
which modern capitalism has brought with it, view to replace the market with the plan as a
cannot be emphasized more strongly. Until the coordinating instrument, it would be quite ratio-
middle of the eighteenth century, there was prac- nal from a microeconomic point of view to pro-
tically no improvement in the living conditions of ceed according to a plan. (b) Capital accounting
the great mass of the population, and only then ensures the formal rationality of economic activ-
would the constant growth of the economy ity (Weber 2019, 182) because it provides both
become the sign of the era. The world-historical the entrepreneur and the financiers with an over-
significance of this innovation is underestimated view of the state of the business. (c) Ideally, the
if, in an effort not to be exposed to the accusation choice between the various investment options is
of Euro-Centrism, many students of economic made on the basis of internal economic
development insist on observing developments considerations only (maximizing the expected
comparable to those in modern Europe, in regions profit) and not on the basis of considerations
outside Europe. The radical nature of this change alien to the economic system. (d) The labor
is underestimated if one sees, in accordance with force is selected on the basis of performance and
the new economic history, the decisive willingness alone––any quotation would limit the
innovation merely in the establishment of secured rationality of the enterprise. (e) With the threat of
property rights. In the same vein it is often dismissal, firm managers finally have an instru-
overlooked that it was ultimately the operation ment at their disposal to get maximum effort out
of capitalist enterprises on the grounds of private of their workers (cf. Weber 2019, 281). When
property rights, which was the basis for escaping discussing the competition of economic systems,
hunger and early death (cf. Fogel 2004).4 one can see that the great historical alternative to
the capitalist organization of the economy,
namely, socialism lost the competition due to its
4
In the transition from a traditional to a capitalist mode of
production, hunger and misery were increasing among the
working population. However, in the long run, wage labor living of the wage dependent population. See also Drèze
is the safest way to access food and raise the standard of and Sen (1989).
274 J. Berger

lack of a similarly effective instrument for solving theoretical interest. “Capitalism,” Schumpeter
the problem of labor incentives. (1939, 223) wrote very decidedly, “is a form of
The question arises, to what extent is this private property economy in which innovations
analysis of the capitalist enterprise as a rational are carried out by means of borrowed money,
organization of formally free labor still valid which in general, though not by logical necessity,
today? Weber’s image of the capitalist economy imply credit creation.”6 Granting credit to
needs to be corrected in two ways. Firstly, it businessmen and thereby their indebtedness, not
stands out that in the concept of the enterprise, the rational organization of work, is the essential
as a bureaucratic organization, there is actually no element of economic process (Schumpeter 1934,
place for the entrepreneur. “If human nature felt 149). It is done solely “for the purposes of
no temptation to take a chance, no satisfaction innovation.” In order to be able to pay his debts,
(profit apart) in constructing a factory, a railway, the entrepreneur is compelled to implement such
a mine or a farm, there might not be much invest- innovations. Only such successful innovations
ment merely as a result of cold calculation,” can ultimately explain the basic characteristics
Keynes (1936, 150) said. Without entrepreneurial of the capitalist economy that a fee is paid perma-
boldness, which is irrational from the point of nently for loan capital (Weber 2019, 188) and,
view of the calculation of expected values, there what is more, can be paid at all.
is no investment activity. This activity if success-
ful, creates new job opportunities, enriches the
consumer world with new products, and changes
2.3 The Labor Market
the face of cities and landscapes. However, if
business speculation does not pay off, the seed
Modern capitalism is linked to the existence of a
is sown for an economic crisis.
labor market on which labor power is exchanged
Even before Keynes, Schumpeter emphasized
for money.7 As is the case for all markets under
the role of entrepreneurship. The entrepreneur’s
modern conditions, it is also true for this market,
task is “to change the course of the process”
that the exchange transaction is money-mediated.
(Schumpeter 1934, 121) or “to enforce new
Historically, the modern labor market is a latter
combinations by withdrawing work and soil
day product of development. It was only with the
services from their usual uses” (ibid. 140). Thus,
abolition of the poor laws in England, in 1834
the main achievement of the entrepreneur is
(Polanyi 1957, Chap. 8) that a labor market was
transcending “the most ordinary run within
enforced nationwide. With the abolition of sup-
given production functions” and combining
port for the poor, the only way for the displaced
factors in a new way (Schumpeter 1939, 88).5
population to secure their livelihood was to offer
Secondly, in order to be able to carry out his
their labor for sale on labor markets. The labor
new combinations, “the entrepreneur needs pur-
market is thus based on the double freedom of the
chasing power ... He can only become an entre-
workers: they are legally free and they are
preneur by becoming a debtor before”
liberated (Marxists would say robbed) from own-
(Schumpeter 1934, 148). No other economic
ership of means of production that could
entity, by its very nature, is a debtor in the same
sense. Thus, it is no longer the relationship
between capital and labor, but rather, the relation- 6
Schumpeter thus understands capitalism as money econ-
ship between the entrepreneur as borrower and omy, just as Marx and Max Weber did before him but
the capitalist as lender, that moves to the center of unlike neoclassical economics. Money is not a veil that
lays itself over real conditions, but an essential element of
economic activity in capitalism.
5
“It is leadership rather than ownership that matters. The 7
Wallerstein (1979), defines capitalism as a system for
failure to see this ... is the common fault of both the making profit, regardless of the type of labor, (e.g., planta-
economic and the sociological analysis of the classics tion economy, slave labor, wage labor) on which it is
and of Karl Marx” (Schumpeter 1939, 103 f.). based.
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic System 275

guarantee them a livelihood, independent of the employee allows the employer to specify, at a
labor market. later date after the writing of the contract, the
Both the labor market itself and the goods effort that is required of him. As Simon (1957)
traded on it differ from other markets (and has pointed out, this artificial arrangement has
goods) in some unique ways. The commodity advantages for both sides and is chosen precisely
traded on labor markets is not exactly labor, but for this reason: The employer does not have to
labor power; more precisely, the worker’s com- negotiate a new contract every time the tasks
mitment to put his labor at the service of capital change and can determine the service to be
for a limited period of time. This implies a com- provided at a time when he has a better overview
mitment to follow the employer’s orders. Marx’s of what is required for operational purposes.
political economy of capitalism is entirely based The rule of capital is condensed into the right
on this distinction between labor power and labor. to complete an incomplete contract. This right lies
This distinction was still present for Weber, too. It with the entrepreneur, because only he possesses
has only been lost in economic approaches that the necessary business assets. The employees,
speak of the market economy instead of capital- with their consent to the employment contract,
ism and see the securing of property rights as the have relinquished all rights to control production
central prerequisite of the market economy. How- (cf. Hart 1995). The employee is paid a higher
ever, capitalism differs from market economy by wage for this submission to the command of cap-
highly concentrated distribution of private prop- ital than would be the case of a pure sales con-
erty rights. While recent institutional economics tract. However, this arrangement lays the grounds
has highlighted the fundamental importance of for conflicts that may cause inefficiencies, as well
private property for economic activity,8 it has as lead to the whole arrangement being called into
not insisted on the difference between a capitalist question. If employees anticipate that the
economic system and a system of private property employer will make decisions that are exclusively
rights, nor has neoclassical economics that alleg- in the company’s interest, which the latter is enti-
edly dispenses with institutions altogether, tled to do under the employment contract, and
focused on this difference. The equal distribution ignore their distinctive interests, they will react
of business property would be just as hostile to with restraint and perform less than they would in
capitalism as the abolition of private property by a situation of mutual trust. The resulting potential
means of collectivization. The indispensable pre- downward spiral was addressed by Fox (1974).
requisite of a capitalist economic system is the
existence of a class of persons for whom it is
optimal (optimal in the sense of making the best 2.4 A Closed System of Markets
of the situation) to terminate an employment con-
tract (see Roemer 1988). Only with the establishment of labor markets is it
The employment contract itself also has char- possible to establish a closed system of markets.
acteristic features that distinguish it from both a The company obtains all factor services required
simple sales contract and a standard service con- for production by entering factor markets and
tract, which usually provide for the delivery of then sells its products on commodity markets.
goods or services in return for a certain payment. The commodity form, a figure already known to
An employment contract greatly resembles a antiquity, thus becomes universal in capitalism.
lease. Incompleteness is characteristic of it. The Sraffa (1960) characterized the capitalist mode of
production as “the production of commodities by
means of commodities.” In this respect, it is a
truly autopoietic system (Luhmann 1988) that is
able to decouple itself from its environment in
8
The textbook by Furubotn and Richter (1998) provides a important matters, based on its self-reference.
good overview of this field of research. Although sociological system theory regards all
276 J. Berger

subsystems of modern society as functionally met by means of enterprise activities (cf. Weber
differentiated, there is no better place to study 1981, 238).9 A capitalist firm is, first and fore-
what this means in concrete terms, than in the most, a rational undertaking, and it ensures that the
example of the modern economy. In the course consumption needs of the population are met.
of the establishment of the capitalist mode of Employment in enterprises provides the vast
production, economic and political spheres start majority of the population with the necessary
to diverge. In the pre-capitalist era, they were still means to purchase goods produced by enterprises.
more or less intertwined. The political domination The labor market thus becomes the central instru-
of the country and its people included economic ment for integrating the population into the econ-
domination as well. Before the dawn of moder- omy. Capitalism, as Plumpe (2019) stressed, is a
nity, the organization of production was not kind of economy for the lower classes, not for the
sharply separated from the exercise of lordly wealthy. It is also worker-friendly, to the contrary
power. Today, on the other hand, state territorial of Marx’s theory of exploitation, seeing capitalism
rule has no longer any economic connotations. At as hostile to workers.
the same time, the economy is free not only from The central components of this innovation at
political but also from communal ties. the organizational level, the employment contract
Polanyi (1957) lamented the result of this pro- and the orientation towards profitability, have been
cess that he described as disembeddedness. He the subject of criticism, which has not ceased to
did not gain a real understanding of the date. The employment contract is criticized for
advantages of this detachment, nor did his subjecting the employees to the dictates of the
followers. Disembeddedness can be seen in the entrepreneur, on the one hand, and for the exploi-
fact that a capitalist firm (despite different tones tation resulting from this subjection, on the other
of the German Works Constitution Act), typically hand. The orientation towards profitability is
speaking, is not a community. The employment criticized because of its blindness towards other
relationship is largely exempt from objectives assumed to be of higher value. The
communalization with the entrepreneur. In any critics overlook, however, that the employment
case, this is true in a large historical comparison contract is entered into voluntarily and is advanta-
with bonded labor and especially with slave labor. geous for both contracting parties, otherwise it
Since then, the callous cash payment (Communist would not be agreed upon. In addition, they also
Manifesto) has more or less shaped the employ- overlook the fact that the focus on profitability
ment relationship. It follows that, unlike slavery does not amount to unrestrained greed for gain. It
and serfdom, the reproduction and rearing of chil- belongs in the cultural-historical nursery that this
dren have been separated from the naïve definition is abandoned once and for all.
emplyment relationship and have become a pri- Boundless greed for gain is not in the least equal
vate matters concern for employees. to capitalism, and even further from its spirit (see
Weber 1920, 4). Despite this plea, the majority of
contemporary critics of capitalism still adhere to
3 Capitalism and Modern this naïve definition.10
Economic Growth

3.1 Structural Innovations 9


It is not necessary for the entire range of products to be
at the Company Level provided by firms organized in this way. Self-employment
in retail, crafts and professions (doctors and lawyers), as
In the previous section, I focused on the capitalist well as public enterprises, also contribute to the supply of
goods and services.
enterprise in elaborating the structural 10
Weber continues stating that capitalism can almost be
innovations that came into the world with capital-
identical with taming, at least with rational tempering, of
ism. Capitalism, as Weber stressed, is present this irrational drive (Weber 1920, 4). Under conditions of
where the needs of large groups of people are full competition, the most that can be achieved with the
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic System 277

This institutional innovation for covering Angus Deaton summarizes the essence of this
everyday needs was invented and realized for worldwide success as “the greatest escape ...
the first time in Western Europe; from there it from poverty and death,” which human history
spread throughout the world. Today, with a few has ever experienced (Deaton 2013, 23). The
exceptions (North Korea and Venezuela, for foundations for this success were laid in the
example), the vast majority of the world’s Enlightenment and the Industrial Revolution.
countries have adopted the capitalist mode of Building on these foundations, “living standards
production. It occurs in many variants, which [have] ... increased by many times, life spans have
may differ according to the degree of state control more than doubled, and people live fuller and
or the sectors left to this mode of production. better lives than ever before” (ibid. 23).12
However, it is always a conceptual characteristic
that the coverage of these needs, at least in the
field of consumer goods for daily needs, is left to
3.2 Growth as the Main Achievement
capitalist firms. The remaining question is how to
of Capitalism
explain its unique success. Nations are quite capa-
ble of making a choice between different forms of
The profoundly improved provision of the popu-
economic organization and of enshrining this
lation with everyday goods and the dramatic
choice, as in their constitution, for example. In a
increase in life expectancy would not have been
post-colonial world, the implementation of this
possible without a reliably growing economy,
form of economic activity is no longer the result
that is, precisely without the basic feature of capi-
of a foreign imposition. On the contrary, not the
talist economies that has fallen into such disrepute
market economy but a centrally planned economy
in the post-growth literature. There are certainly
was often imposed as the dominant form of eco-
dark sides to this process, particularly social
nomic organization. The principle, to meet the
inequality and environmental pollution. Different
needs of large groups of the population by capi-
population groups have participated in the growth
talist firms employing workers on the firms’ own
successes in many different ways, especially
account was not imposed by Western imperialism
within the rising economies. Fairytale wealth,
on non-Western cultures, but was chosen by their
greed and addiction to enrichment are
own political leadership after the end of imperial-
concentrated among groups of people associated
ism, and the failure of costly experiments with
with the political leadership of the countries.
socialism in nations such as China, India, and
However, it would be quite wrong to assume
Russia.
that inequality, for example, continues to grow
This must have something to do with the inher-
globally. On the contrary, the rise of China and
ent advantages of this form of organization. They
India has helped to reduce global economic
consist in promising a production of the social
inequality over the last two decades.13
product that is as waste-free as possible,11 the
inclusion of the large majority of the population
in the economy through the offer of job
12
opportunities, and the constantly improving pro- Frey offsets the long-term economic successes of tech-
vision of consumer goods to the population. nological innovations since the Industrial Revolution
against the suffering and privations to which the groups
of people directly affected were exposed, above all,
pursuit of profit is avoiding losses after settlement of all through the loss of jobs. “The ‘Great Escape’ ... didn’t
contractual payment obligations. immediately turn the cottage of the commoner into a
11
The extent to which this promise is fulfilled, in countries Garden of Eden” (2019, 8).
13
that organize their economies on a capitalist basis, is not Twenty years ago, this contention was still controver-
under discussion here. But it would be premature to con- sial, whereas, to my knowledge, it is widely accepted
clude from the fact of environmental pollution that the today. Two outstanding examples of the rich literature on
economy is its central cause. For the market-based solution this subject are Firebaugh (2003) and Bourgignon (2015).
to the pollution problem, see Sect. 4.2. For an overview see Berger (2019a).
278 J. Berger

A growing economy is a prerequisite for giv- growth is ultimately based, apart from favorable
ing the vast majority of the population a chance to circumstances, such as the availability of cheap
escape poverty and early death. Societies of the energy.15 The research distinguishes between
West initially demonstrated this and countries like immediate and ultimate causes. The decisive, ulti-
China or India have followed. The only economic mate cause is the enforcement and safeguarding
form with a built-in mechanism for growth is of property rights. Investors in a business must be
entrepreneurial profitability capitalism. sure of being protected from fraud and theft; of
Schumpeter (1942) clearly saw that. The mere being able to have their rights upheld in court; and
fact, he writes, that during the capitalist period of having the tax system leave at least enough of
production grew steadily on average “does not in the potential return to retain incentives to invest.
itself provide a sufficient link between the perfor- The decisive, immediate causes are the multipli-
mance and the capitalist engine.” Rather, “there is cation of the inputs of capital and labor on the one
an understandable relation between the capitalist hand, and technological progress on the other.
order and the observed rate of increase in output” Economies that have reached a state of steady
(ibid. 72). It would be wrong to account for the state, (in which the input ratio of capital and
latter “by a sequence of favorable circumstances labor remains constant), will only grow if there is
unconnected with the mechanism of private enter- technological progress. However, even before this
prise” (ibid. 81). state is reached, technological progress is crucial,
Schumpeter describes this mechanism by as it is already included in new capital goods,
means of two characteristics: first, the reduction which replace used-up capital goods. In any case,
of motives as a prerequisite for rationalizing technological progress must always be
decisions. “Both business success and business implemented at the corporate level. Enterprises
failure are ideally precise” (ibid. 74). The relevant are pursuing technological progress in order not
point of view is not the suppression of motives to be outperformed by competitors. “New knowl-
other than economic ones, but that the capitalist edge, new inventions, and new ways of doing
order creates a “schema of motives that is unsur- things are the key to progress” (Deaton 2013, 9).
passed in simplicity and force” (ibid. 73). Second, This is the central message of empirical growth
in contrast to common, stereotyped criticism, it is research.
simply not true that “private profits ..., both in No other economist has more sharply
themselves and through the distortion of the eco- highlighted or more decisively emphasized tech-
nomic process they induce, are always a net loss nological progress as the ultimate source of eco-
for all excepting those who receive them” (ibid. nomic development than Schumpeter. For the
76). The classics of political economy, especially private sector enterprises and their employees
Adam Smith,14 have made this view disappear, who are subject to the dictates of technologi-
but in the literature, which is critical of growth, cal progress, this dictate entails enormous psy-
this thought has returned with a vengeance. chological costs on those subjected to it. In
While cost accounting and profit orientation abstract terms, there is certainly a choice to
guarantee a comparatively waste-free, or avoid this constraint and dispense with techno-
low-waste, consumer-oriented economy, they do logical progress in its different forms (new pro-
not guarantee that the growth rate of total produc- duction methods or new products). A country,
tion is permanently positive. Decades of empiri- however, which as a whole avoided this con-
cal growth research have shown on which factors straint, would eventually degenerate into a
museum of technology.

14
The pursuit of private benefits leads to a better supply of
consumer goods to each and every person. This is perhaps
15
the most powerful idea of Smith’s Wealth of Nations See Hemmer and Lorenz (2004) for a textbook presenta-
(Smith 1950). tion of the methods and results of this branch of research.
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic System 279

3.3 The Socialist Alternative investment and employment for each company.
Such a system had been implemented in the state-
In the last section, I concurred with Schumpeter’s socialist countries of the Eastern bloc in the past.
view that “the capitalist process, not by coinci- Just as capitalism did not prevail purely by
dence but by virtue of its mechanism, progres- chance, socialism did not perish purely by
sively raises the standard of life of the masses . . . chance, or because of envy or enmity of the
One problem after another of the supply of Western world, but due to systemic reasons. I
commodities to the masses have been success- see them facing two insoluble problems: Informa-
fully solved by being brought within the reach tion problems on the one hand, and agency
of the methods of capitalist production” problems on the other. By the former, I mean
(Schumpeter 1942, 68). To be sure, Schumpeter fundamental deficiencies in information, which
is absolutely silent on the potentially negative inevitably make it impossible to draw up a plan.
consequences of this success. (I will come back By the latter I mean principal-agent problems.
to these problems in Sect. 4.) Prior to this, I want These consist in the uncertainty of the principal
to back up to the argument of the superiority of a as to whether the agent is actually acting in the
capitalistically organized economy regarding principal’s interests and not in his own personal
growth by including alternative forms of econ- interests. Such problems are also omnipresent in
omy in the analysis. Functional explanations like capitalist economies, but they can be solved more
this demand, among other factors, that the same easily in this form of production, than they can be
result could not be achieved by other means. I in the context of state socialism.
limit the consideration of these alternatives to Information problems have been highlighted,
state socialism on the one hand, and cooperative most notably by Friedrich von Hayek (1948,
or self-managed market socialism on the other. Chaps. IV and VII), as the cause of the economic
The question then is whether these alternative inferiority of socialism. Von Hayek, as well as
forms are either at least as efficient as the capital- von Mises, did not regard socialism as impossi-
ist economic system or not. If they are not, do ble, but only as not being a rationally calculable
they achieve other economic or non-economic system. Such information problems arise for
goals that are considered valuable, but which are every central planner on two fronts: The determi-
neglected in a capitalist system? It goes without nation of consumer wishes and the lack of knowl-
saying that this examination in a short article can edge concerning the firms’ technical possibilities
only be rather cursory.16 for creating the product required by the plan. In
order to rationally plan the economy, the central
3.3.1 State Socialism planners would have to know all possible
State socialism is generally understood as an eco- combinations of production factors in every firm
nomic system characterized by the socialization for every single product of the economy, for
of the means of production and the coordination different output quantities. In addition, rational
of the activities on the firm level by a plan. How- planning would require perfect insight into the
ever, consumers are free in their choice of con- preferences of households and therefore how
sumer goods. A centrally drawn up plan households would choose between the various
determines the amount and type of output, conceivable consumption structures.17 In order
to solve the task of setting up a plan and ensuring
16 that it is realized, the central planner would not
Between the poles of capitalism and socialism there are
many mixed forms, including the social market economy. only have to be omniscient, but also omnipotent
A more recent and detailed presentation of alternatives to and above all benevolent. In short, he would have
capitalism is Corneo (2017). Corneo, unlike this contribu- to possess God-like qualities.
tion, defines capitalism as a system of private property and
market exchange, thus making no distinction between a
market economy and capitalism. For the reasoning put
17
forward here, however, this distinction is essential. Cf. Corneo (2017, Chap. 6).
280 J. Berger

Agency problems occur at three places in state 246) and thus suffocate all freedom in a bureau-
socialism. They have parallels in capitalist eco- cracy that was no longer tamed by any counter
nomic systems but can be solved there in a forces. The process of separating workers from
system-compliant way. John Roemer has put the means of production would thus continue.
these problems in a nutshell: The socialization of the means of production
Communist societies faced principal-agent and their transfer to state ownership would not
problems in three important types of relationships: change the exclusion of the workers from man-
between managers and workers in factories and agement decisions. Economic inequality is
collective farms; between government planners expected to decrease, but, due to lower efficiency,
and firm managers; and between the public and
the planners. Managers must try to get workers to it will be accompanied by lower income per per-
carry out their production plans, planners must try son. This is not an attractive perspective for those
to get managers to carry out the planning bureau’s subject to such a system.
plan, and the planners, in a socialist regime, are Due to the importance of the assertion of
supposed to be agents doing the best they can for
their collective principal, the public (Roemer 1994, exploitation in the history of the critique of capi-
38). talism, I will deal with it in more detail at this
point––in place of the many other critiques. After
Since the threat of dismissal as a means of all, the transition to socialism was motivated by
discipline is absent in socialism, there are few the hope of ending exploitation, which was seen
incentives for employees to follow the directives as constitutive for capitalism. The complaint
of management. You pretend to pay me, and I concerning exploitation is based on a fact, which
pretend to work, was a common attitude to work can hardly be denied: Typically, workers do more
in socialist economies. As long as the manage- work per day, week or year than they get back in
ment realistically expects that non-viable the goods they can buy from their wages.18
enterprises will be rescued by the state budget
Exploitation consists in the systematic difference
for overriding reasons, the incentives to fulfill between the working time that an individual
the plan are weak (cf. Kornai 1992, Sect. 8.4:
employee performs and the working time that he
soft budget constraint). The planning bureau’s
receives back in the form of wage payments. In
orientation towards consumer wishes fails, not
macroeconomic terms, this is reflected in the dif-
only due to the lack of information about these
ference between the net product of the economy
wishes, but also because such wishes are not a
measured in amounts of labor and the share of the
given in a socialist system. Consumer tastes are
net product, which is also measured in amounts of
generally suspected of being false desires to be
labor, received by employees. The rest goes to the
changed by socialist education.
capitalists as profit. Positive profits are then the
From an efficiency point of view, state social-
final proof of the existence of exploitation.
ism scores very poorly. It is, perhaps, an attractive
Such evidence, however, suffers from several
choice if other objectives are to be achieved
weaknesses at the same time. Firstly, they paint a
through the collective organization of the econ-
picture of the entrepreneur as though he did noth-
omy. Such goals are the liberation of work from
ing else than allow the workers access to his
the dictates of capital and its replacement by
means of production in return for a wage payment
democratic forms of economic activity; the aboli-
which is lower than the product of labor. This is
tion of the worker’s separation from the means of
an extremely naïve picture of entrepreneurship,
production; distributive justice; and, above all,
the termination of exploitation. However, there 18
This does not need to apply to all workers. Whether
is nothing to suggest that socialism will make
wage labor implies exploitation depends on the level of
workers freer, more equal or more autonomous. wage payment. Under the validity of the Marxian Funda-
According to Weber, socialism would only com- mental Theorem (exploitation is the sole source of profit)
plete the expropriation of all workers through the company profits would then only be possible if the
millions paid to the top management result from their
expropriation of private owners (Weber 2019,
exploitation of the low-income earners.
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic System 281

which has been criticized, particularly by firms, the employees may have graduated rights
Schumpeter. Not only does the entrepreneur pro- of participation, at the least, this is not excluded.20
vide productive technology, on the basis of which The hopes associated with this producer
it is possible for the workers to produce a product socialism are directed towards the abolition of
that is higher than their wages, he also works authority at the firm level as the main evil of
himself and in this role has a claim to the capitalist business organization.21 To the extent
entrepreneur’s wage. Profits are not an income that worker-governed firms are strictly aligned
without a service in return.19 Secondly, there is with market signals, this objective is subject to
no type of economy in which the direct producers narrow limits. Two disadvantages have to be
receive the entire net product. Marx (1970) in his accepted in order to achieve the objective of the
Critique of the Gotha Program has already seen it liberation of labor.
that way. Any growing economy must divert part Firstly, decision-making in an economic
of its net product for investment purposes. Then democracy is much more difficult than in an
merely the fact that in capitalism, decisions about owner-managed business or in a corporation
the use and the amount of the investment are where the management is responsible to the
made by the management remains open to cri- owners of the capital. In the case of controversial
tique. However, those who engage in such a cri- decisions regarding qualifications and income,
tique overlook the fact that the growth success of particularly when the workforce is not homoge-
capitalist economies is based precisely on this neous but diverse, there will be protracted
separation of roles. decision-making processes. These can jeopardize
consensus. There is no guarantee at all that
decisions taken in a plenary meeting will some-
3.3.2 Cooperative Socialism
how be better than decisions taken by
Cooperative socialism does not perform any bet-
management.
ter in the two perspectives mentioned here: effi-
Secondly, the distinction between profit
cient organization of the economy and
income and wage income, typical for capitalist
achievement of objectives in dimensions beyond
enterprises, and the associated separation of
efficiency. Its key feature is not submission to a
roles is blurred. Contrary to what is expected of
centrally established plan, but operational self-
the supporters of company self-administration,
administration and coordination of firm decisions
this is by no means always advantageous. During
by markets. In principle, all decisions assigned to
an economic downturn, employees have to forego
management in a capitalist firm are transferred to
their income from profits. Like independent
the employees. Which particular issues are espe-
entrepreneurs, they must bear the business risk.
cially the subject of a collective decision and how
The advantage of role separation in capitalist
decision-making is organized can either be deter-
operations is precisely that the risks are unequally
mined by state legislation or left to the companies
distributed. Risk-averse persons will prefer a
themselves. The two extremes are that everything
fixed salary to a variable salary depending on
is discussed and decided on in plenary meetings
the business situation. In the economic literature
of the workforce or that everything is delegated to
defending market socialism, it is often assumed,
an elected management. However, the greater the
without hesitation that employees would prefer a
powers of management, the closer it becomes to a
mixture of a lower salary and greater operational
normal capitalist business. Even in capitalist
freedom and self-determination to a combination

20
Cf. only the employee participation rights, typical of
19
It might be said that exploitation is the genuine achieve- capitalism in the Federal Republic of Germany.
ment of the entrepreneur. “The misery of being exploited 21
By contrast, the central planning of production aimed at
by capitalists is nothing compared to the misery of not providing the population with consumer goods is labeled
being exploited at all,” Joan Robinson (1962, 45) noted. consumer socialism.
282 J. Berger

of less self-determination and a higher salary. The have foreseen, and it has thus completely
simple fact that self-governing companies are, up revolutionized the living conditions of the broad
to now, restricted to a niche existence in the mass of the population that had been customary
market economy speaks against this assumption. for centuries. This constant improvement of the
In addition, there are particular problems in deter- living conditions was not, however, accompanied
mining the wages for a heterogeneous workforce by an equally constant increase in inequality. The
and in investing in an uncertain future. Gini coefficient of net equivalent household
Depending on the qualification structure of the income today in Germany is around 0.3, the
employees, the decision on the income of the same as it was at the beginning of the 1960s.
individual groups of employees will vary. It is Such a value means that two arbitrarily chosen
not even clear which criteria should be used to incomes differ on average by about 1080 euros.23
decide on the level of pay (e.g., equal pay for all This too is an amount that does not seem alarm-
or incentive wages). As far as future-orientated ingly high, but such a judgment depends on the
investments are concerned, older workers will be social values, held by the observer.24
reluctant to support decisions of this type if the However, growth rates have fallen from
return on such investments comes after their decade to decade, from an average of 8.2% in
period of employment has expired. the first decade after the founding of the German
Republic to a meager 0.9% between 2000 and
2010.25 In 2009, output fell by 5.6%, the largest
4 Future Prospects in the history of the German economy. In the
following 2 years, the economy recovered from
It seems, the capitalist economy has established this slump with growth rates of 4.1% and 3.7%
itself worldwide because of the lack of convinc- respectively. However, thereafter, these rates
ing alternatives to it. However, true as this may remained below 2% in real terms. In 2018, growth
be, it does not include an eternal guarantee for the amounted to 1.5%, a figure that is still surpris-
existing system. It could be, firstly, that this sys- ingly good in the long term; in addition, the lower
tem no longer reliably performs exactly the ser- the growth rates are, the more the widespread
vice on which its superiority and attractiveness criticism of growth loses its persuasive power.
are based: the reliable and continuous increase of The numbers seem to speak for themselves.
the output of goods. Secondly, it could be that the Before drawing hasty conclusions from them,
negative side effects, slowly but surely, outweigh however, it should be remembered that the long-
the successes at some point. Finally, it could be term growth of the world’s most developed econ-
that the demand for this particular achievement omy, the USA, was only 1.8% per capita. So, at
decreases with increasing wealth. best, only an even further downward move from
this value could be regarded as proof of darkening

4.1 Does Growth Come to an End? 23


This follows from the definition of the Gini coefficient:
G ¼ Δ/2μ, with Δ ¼ the mean difference of income and a
In Germany, for example, gross domestic product value for μ, the average net income in Germany, of 1800
euros. See Berger (2019a, Appendix A3).
per capita increased more than fivefold in real 24
The Gini coefficient, like all measures of inequality,
terms between 1950 and 2012, despite economic ignores the question of whether differences in income are
slumps and the decline caused by reunification.22 justified or unjustified.
It has continued to grow in recent years. Overall, 25
Figures for the USA: Real per capita economic growth
the standard of living of almost all population in the USA was 2.35% between 1970 and 1980, 2.23%
groups has risen to an extent that no one could between 1980 and 2000 and only 0.8% between 2000 and
2010. The deceleration called for in the post-growth camp
has also taken place in the USA. However, the growth
22
Information on the long-term development of the rates (in constant dollars of 2010 after the Great Recession
industrialized countries is available and very well of 2009 between 2010 and 2018 in constant dollars of
highlighted by Max Roser (www.ourworldindata.org). 2010 once again reached 2.2% on average).
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic System 283

growth prospects. Piketty (2014), for example, interest rates. To fuel inflation instead, by means
expects the advanced economies to grow by of monetary policy is not a feasible policy
1–1.5% in the future. Even if growth of this because of the threat of undermining financial
magnitude is below the long-term average, it stability. In such a situation, massive fiscal
should not be equated with stagnation, thus giv- interventions alone would offer a way out. How-
ing rise to corresponding fears. Growth would ever, governments would not want to do this due
still be of considerable magnitude. to unfounded fears of raising national debt.
Due to the potential threat to economic and Summers defines stagnation as a situation in
political stability posed by declining growth rates, which negative real interest rates are required to
fears of a long-lasting stagnation are widespread. balance savings and investments in a growing
Regarding the explanation of this phenomenon, economy. A more traditional view, shared by
supply-theoretical and demand-theoretical John Start Mill and Karl Marx, is to envisage a
approaches are at odds with each other. Gordon stationary economy that would be free from the
(2012) substantiates corresponding fears with a need for growth and its consequences for
supply-theoretical argument. A lack of break- everyone’s lifestyle. Keynes painted such a sta-
through investments is the ultimate reason for tionary economy in the most beautiful colors, in
the age of modern economic growth coming to which poverty was finally defeated because of
an end, according to Gordon. Since the pond of economic growth in the past. “For the first time
economically usable technical innovations is since his creation, man will be faced with his real,
practically empty, technologically feasible his permanent problem––how to use his freedom
growth is reduced.26 The developed countries from pressing economic cares, how to occupy the
first, but after them also the countries that today leisure, which science and compound interest (!)
still grow at rates far above those of the mature will have won for him, to live wisely and agree-
countries of the West, will enter a period of stag- ably and well” (1972, 328). Provided that essen-
nation. Summers (2015) also fears a period of tial parameters of the social structure do not
sustained stagnation in the USA and the change, (e.g., the employment rate must remain
Eurozone. However, he does not blame the constant) and there is no competition between
supply-side for this fear, but substantiates his countries, so, growth driven by technological
classically Keynesian argument with a lack of progress as a tested means of conflict resolution
demand from the private sector for capital could actually be dispensed with. Then one would
goods. On this line of thought, the final reason be able to say farewell to the age of capitalist
of secular stagnation is a chronic excess of saving growth with The Moor has done his guilt, the
over investment.27 Moor can go (Friedrich Schiller).
Today, negative real interest rates are neces- This Brave New World would be a world with-
sary to bring actual growth closer to the already out the need for growth.28 The latter is currently
lower potential growth. In order to achieve this fed primarily by two sources: the ageing of the
objective, the monetary policy instrument of low- population and public debt. Only societies with
ering nominal interest rates is no longer available, growing economies can grow out of the national
as nominal interest rates could not fall below the debt and provide their growing army of
zero lower bound on nominal interest rates pensioners with the means to live on, without
because of the alternative of holding cash at zero cutting the incomes of the gainfully employed.
How will the economy grow if the population
26
Brynjolfsson and McAffee (2014) firmly contradict this
diagnosis. 28
Easterlin (1981, 16) is much more skeptical about these
27
A capitalist system works smoothly if “the workers prospects: “While it would be pleasant to envisage a world
spend what they get, and capitalists get what they free from the pressure of material want ... a more realistic
spend.” (An aphorism attributed to Michael Kalecki by projection for the developed countries is of a world caught
Joan Robinson.). on a ‘hedonic treadmill’.”
284 J. Berger

stops growing and technological progress slows increase is not identical to the decrease of a
down? Population growth is a highly effective quantity.31
stimulus to the capitalist economy, which unlike It is also not the case that the state of the
any other, is designed to provide a growing pop- natural environment, in all dimensions, that is,
ulation with consumer goods from televisions to air, water, and soil is increasingly deteriorating
cars, to new homes. The basic problem with tech- in all zones of the earth. For example, air quality
nological progress is that it does not happen on its in Germany has improved over the past 25 years
own, but must be generated by investment in (Federal Environment Agency, press release of
research and development. The central question 7 November 2018). This certainly does not
here is whether the truly great inventions that mean that it has already reached a level which is
stimulate growth have not all already been made not harmful to health. Nevertheless, the regional
(see Gordon 2012). improvement in this area is an example of the fact
that even when an ecological factor is taken into
account, the assessment of the actual status and
4.2 Negative Effects of Economic the development of public welfare can be quite
Growth positive.
Today, apocalyptic fears about the future of
Currently, the very general idea that the negative mankind are driven primarily by news of increas-
effects of economic growth are slowly but surely ing global warming. According to a new study by
destroying its positive effects is mainly fed by the Potsdam Institute for Climate Research, the
environmental policy arguments. Other reasons, earth is approaching a historical heat record; his-
such as the social or cultural consequences of torical, because in the last 3 million years the
growth, are much more controversial.29 However, earth’s temperature has never been more than
offsetting the harmful effects of environmental 2 above the pre-industrial level. With an uninter-
pollution against the positive effects of economic rupted emission of greenhouse gases, however,
growth in terms of employment and increased the atmosphere could be heated up by more than
incomes is anything but easy. One possibility 2 . As alarming as this news may be, it is no
would be to supplement the system of national reason to condemn, on a whim, a way of business
accounts in environmental economic terms.30 I organization that ultimately has overcome hunger
am not aware of any calculation indicating that and early death (Fogel 2004). The economic
the gross domestic product corrected for environ- exploitation of technical innovations by
mental factors will shrink from year to year if the entrepreneurs that formed the core of the capital-
burden on the environment is taken into account. ist system to date can be used for solving envi-
Probably the increase is smaller, but a weaker ronmental problems as well.
If the problem is the perpetual emission of
greenhouse gases, and therefore not the increase
of the national product per se, then its solution
does not lie in the dismissal of this economic
29
It is, for example, worthwhile checking whether the method by abstaining from further growth, but
popular claim can be maintained that egoism and competi- rather in the consistent application of the
tive thinking are spreading, whereas solidarity and cooper-
ative behavior are on the retreat. Which kind of data would
back this claim? Would these tendencies, if confirmed, 31
Environmental economic calculations depend on many
indicate a definite boundary of the dominant economic preliminary decisions on which, if I am right, there is no
system? Finally, do such developments, provided they consensus at all. The main problem is to find a common
exist, really have their roots in the economic system or denominator for calculating the positive and negative
rather in the much broader process of the rationalism of effects of a growing economy on human welfare. Gross
Western culture? domestic product is not in itself a welfare indicator, but
30
For an overview of the corresponding approaches, see only a component of a more comprehensive index of
Federal Statistical Office, Germany (2014). human welfare.
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic System 285

economic principle on which the success of this to increase the national product pointless is not a
form of economic activity is based. In concrete contemporary one, but looks back on a venerable
terms, this means that the consumption of envi- tradition. John Stuart Mill painted the utopia of a
ronmental resources must have appropriate mon- stationary economy, Karl Marx defined commu-
etary costs, that is to say it is subject to prices that nism (as opposed to socialism) by decoupling
at least approximately correspond to the damage consumption from previously performed labor.
caused by the use of these resources. Whether or In an essay, written in 1930, John Maynard
not zero emissions are achieved by this means Keynes saw the time come when man would be
depends on how they are designed, but it is possi- free for the first time from pressing economic
ble, in any case, to limit the emission of environ- cares and could use his lifetime for more joyful
mentally harmful greenhouse gases according to things. Keynes speculated that this state could be
political targets. This requires, however, that not reached in about 100 years after the writing of his
only the production of the national wealth be essay. That would be in the year 2030.
taken into consideration, but also its final con- Unfortunately, that is not what it looks like at
sumption. The example of the energy sector in the moment. In global terms, the absolute num-
particular shows that its environmental problems bers and the percentage of people living in abso-
do not arise mainly at the point of the extraction lute poverty have fallen drastically, but are still so
of fossil fuels, but in the consumption of these high that global economic growth is indispens-
substances by consumers. There are two ways of able. In addition, the difficulties of the lower
managing this consumption in a market economy: income groups in the developed countries to
by (1) levying a CO2 tax or (2) issuing tradable cope with their income are also so substantial,
emission permits for consumption sectors such as particularly in view of rising energy and housing
transport, for example.32 In an intellectual climate prices that turning away from growth appears to
of viewing the market economy as the root of all be a luxury for the better off. Keynes was confi-
evil, such instruments will have hard times.33 dent that with the devaluation of the accumulation
of wealth “great changes in the code of morals”
(Keynes 1972, 329) would occur. Even if this
were true regarding the wealthy classes, to expect
4.3 A Lacking Demand for Growth?
it from the lower income strata is not only de
facto, but also morally built on sand.
The idea that economic output could one day
reach a level that would make any further efforts

32
5 Non-socialist Reforms
William Nordhaus relies more on a Pigou-tax.
“According to Nordhaus’ research, the most efficient rem-
of Capitalism
edy for the problems caused by greenhouse gas emissions
would be a global scheme of carbon taxes that are uni- The question arises as to whether the deficits,
formly imposed on all countries” (The Royal Swedish described above, can be remedied by means of
Academy of Sciences: The Prize in Economic Sciences
non-socialist reforms. The critics of capitalism do
2018).
33 not even agree on the components of the capitalist
Tirole (2017, Chap. 9) argues for a single carbon price to
meet the climate challenge. “The first priority of future economy that are primarily responsible for
negotiations ought to be an agreement to establish a uni- problems such as economic crises, income
versal carbon price compatible with the objective of no inequality and unemployment. Is it the market,
more than a 1.5 to 2 degree Celsius increase in average
global temperatures” (Tirole 2017, 229). For reasons of
the monetary system, the banking system, the
space, I cannot elaborate on other developments that alleg- creation of credit money by banks, the antagonis-
edly threaten the sustainability of capitalist systems, such tic relations of production, or in a tradition dating
as the threat of job loss caused by a new wave of automa- back to Plato private property? The Marxist tradi-
tion or the threat to the stability of capitalist economies
tion predicted the uprising against private prop-
originating from the increasing importance of an
inherently unstable financial sector. For the former prob- erty, and, as a result, the collapse of capitalism
lem see Frey (2019), for the latter, Minsky (1982). and the transition to socialism. In fact, however,
286 J. Berger

socialism has collapsed, while private property in which the separation of managers and the man-
and the capitalist type of economy based on it aged would be overruled. Vogt (1986) developed
have proved surprisingly stable. As has been the main features of such an economy. In it,
argued above, this is no coincidence. This form workers exchange lower wages for more freedom
of economy does not guarantee distributive jus- of domination.34 The proposal is entirely based
tice, but it does guarantee efficiency in the use of on a manifest interest of the workers in the free-
resources. For example, with the threat of dis- dom of domination. However, workers’ self-man-
missal, the capitalist enterprise has a very simple agement can be much more strenuous than the
and effective instrument at its disposal to secure mild dictate of a temporally, objectively and
the employees’ motivation. A socialist economy, socially limited submission to authority.
on the other hand, can only rely on the intrinsic Finally, a typical feature of capitalist enterprise
motivation of the members of the work collective, is fixed remuneration, regardless of whether the
that is, their willingness to set aside their personal firm is flourishing or threatened to go bankrupt.
interests (less strenuous work) in favor of corpo- Wages are contractual income, profits a residual
rate interests. That is a fragile foundation. income that only accrues after all contractual
Efficiency advantages speak for the enforce- obligations have been fulfilled. Weitzman
ment and lasting dominance of the capitalist (1984) has outlined a model in which employees
mode of production. An organization of the econ- are paid at least partially in profit shares (if profits
omy beyond the use of dependent employment in accrue at all) in addition to a fixed basic wage.
profit-oriented enterprises would only be more Such a remuneration scheme would at least par-
likely if the economic system could be adjusted tially eliminate the separation of two types of
on three fronts: the compulsion to work, the real income, typical of capitalist firms: contractual
subsumption under capital (Marx 1970), and the income and residual income. The question
wage form as a remuneration scheme. The com- remains whether this is truly an attractive option
pulsion to work would cease if all (adult) citizens for workers. In conclusion, one can speculate
were to receive a basic income that would secure with Weber (1988, 60) about the chances of
their livelihood, regardless of whether they were replacing the principle of private economic prof-
employed or not, whether they were in an emer- itability and, as a consequence, the dictates of cost
gency situation or whether they could earn a degression, with some form of communal eco-
living for themselves. Van Parijs (1995) viewed nomic solidarity. In any case, the change in
the granting of an unconditional basic income for values necessary for this end cannot be planned.
all as the direct transition from capitalism to com- What speaks for entrepreneurial capitalism is that
munism (directly, without first taking a detour via it is in a better position than any other system to
socialism). Indeed, the decoupling of supply the masses with ever increasing and inno-
contributions to the social net product and access vative consumer goods without further destroying
to consumer goods is a fundamental feature of the environment. In light of that, there are good
communism. Not only the increase of the tax reasons to believe that for the foreseeable future
burden and the probable decrease of the motiva- the capitalist form of the economy will prevail.
tion to work, both with the consequence that the
national product, from which the basic income is Acknowledgement I’m grateful to Andrea Maurer, Ulf
to be financed, will shrink, speak against a basic Kadritzke and Peter Preisendörfer for helpful comments.
The chapter draws on some of my former writings (see
income on a sufficiently high level, but above all Berger 2014, 2019b).
the ethics of the work society, still in force. Ethics
is at odds with the idea that people who are able to
work, participate in the national product, without 34
Similarly, Meade states (1976, 16 f.): “citizens could
contributing to its production.
freely choose between high prosperity with low participa-
Subordination to the command of capital tion in the large-scale enterprises and low prosperity with
(Marx) would disappear in a laborist economy high participation in the small-scale co-operatives”.
18 Capitalism: On the Past and Future of an Economic System 287

References Kornai, J. (1992). The socialist system. The political econ-


omy of communism. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Luhmann, N. (1988). Die Wirtschaft der Gesellschaft.
Berger, J. (2014). Kapitalismusanalyse und Kapitalis-
Frankfurt: Suhrkamp.
muskritik. Wiesbaden: Springer essentials.
Marx, K. (1970 [1875]). Critique of the Gotha Programme.
Berger, J. (2019a). Wirtschaftliche Ungleichheit. Zwölf
In K. Marx & F. Engels (Eds.), Selected works (vol. III,
Vorlesungen. Springer VS: Wiesbaden.
pp. 13–30). Moscow: Progress Publishers.
Berger, J. (2019b). Warum Kapitalismus? Berliner Journal
Meade, J. E. (1976). The just economy. London: Allen &
Sonderband Große Transformation? Zur Zukunft
Unwin.
moderner Gesellschaften, 75–95.
Minsky, H. P. (1982). The financial-instability hypothesis:
Bourgignon, F. (2015). The globalization of inequality.
Capitalist processes and the behavior of the economy.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
In C. P. Kindleberger & J.-P. Laffargue (Eds.), Finan-
Brynjolffson, E., & McAffee, A. (2014). Race against the
cial crises: Theory, history, and policy (pp. 13–47).
machine: How the digital revolution is accelerating
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
innovation, driving productivity, and irreversibly
Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century.
transforming employment and the economy.
Belknap: Cambridge, MA.
New York: W.W. Norton.
Plumpe, W. (2019). Das kalte Herz. Kapitalismus: Die
Collins, R. (1997). An Asian route to capitalism: Religious
Geschichte einer andauernden Revolution. Berlin:
economy and the origins of self-transforming growth
Rowohlt.
in Japan. American Sociological Review, 62, 843–865.
Polanyi, K. (1957 [1944]). The great transformation. The
Corneo, G. (2017). Is capitalism obsolete? A journey
political and economic origins of our time. Boston:
through alternative economic systems. Cambridge,
Beacon.
MA: Harvard University Press.
Robinson, J. (1962). Economic philosophy.
Deaton, A. (2013). The great escape. Health, wealth, and
Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.
the origins of inequality. Princeton: Princeton Univer-
Roemer, J. E. (1988). Free to loose. An introduction to
sity Press.
Marxist economic philosophy. Cambridge, MA:
Drèze, J., & Sen, A. (1989). Hunger and public action.
Harvard University Press.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Roemer, J. E. (1994). A future for socialism. London:
Easterlin, R. A. (1981). Why isn’t the whole world devel-
Verso.
oped? The Journal of Economic History, 41(1), 19.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934 [1911]). The theory of economic
Firebaugh, G. (2003). The new geography of global
development. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University
income inequality. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer-
Press.
sity Press.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles. A theoretical,
Fogel, R. W. (2004). The escape from hunger and prema-
historical, and statistical analysis of the capitalist pro-
ture death, 1700–2100. Europe, America and the Third
cess. New York: McGraw-Hill.
World. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and
Fox, A. (1974). Beyond contract. Work, power and trust
democracy. New York: Harper & Brothers.
relations. London: Faber and Faber.
Simon, H. A. (1957 [1942]). A formal theory of employ-
Frey, C. B. (2019). The technology trap. Capital, labor
ment relation. In H. A. Simon (Ed.), Models of man.
and power in the age of automation. Princeton:
Social and rational (pp. 183–195). New York: Wiley.
Princeton University Press.
Schluchter, W. (1991). Religion, politische Herrschaft,
Furubotn, E. G., & Richter, R. (1998). Institutions and
Wirtschaft und bürgerliche Lebensführung: Die
economic theory. The contribution of the new institu-
okzidentale Sonderentwicklung. In Religion und
tional economics. Ann Arbor: The University of
Lebensführung Band II (pp. 382–504). Frankfurt:
Michigan Press.
Suhrkamp.
Gordon, R. J. (2012). Is U.S. economic growth over?
Smith, A. (1950 [1776]). The wealth of nations, London:
Faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds.
Penguin. . Engl. Orig. 1776.
NBER Working Paper Nr. 18315.
Sombart, W. (1916). Der moderne Kapitalismus.
Hart, O. (1995). Firms, contracts and financial structure.
Historisch-systematische Darstellung des gesamteuro-
Oxford: Clarendon Press.
päischen Wirtschaftslebens von seinen Anfängen bis
Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order.
zur Gegenwart. Zweiter Band. München: Duncker &
South Bend, IN: Gateway Editions.
Humblot.
Hemmer, H.-R., & Lorenz, A. (2004). Grundlagen der
Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of commodities by means of
Wachstumsempirie. München: Vahlen.
commodities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment,
Statistisches Bundesamt. (2014). [Federal Office of Statis-
interest and money. London: Macmillan.
tics, Germany]. Umweltnutzung und Wirtschaft.
Keynes, J. M. (1972 [1930]). Economic possibilities for
Bericht zu den umweltökonomischen
our grandchildren. In Essays in persuasion. The col-
Gesamtrechnungen.
lected writings of John Maynard Keynes, Band
IX (pp. 321–332). London: MacMillan.
288 J. Berger

Summers, L. H. (2015). Demand side secular stagnation. 2013. General Economic History. (Transl. Frank
American Economic Review, 105(5), 60–65. Knight). Mansfield: Martino Publishing.]
Tirole, J. (2017). Economics for the common good Weber, M. (1988). Methodologische Einleitung. In
(S. Randall, Trans.). Princeton: Princeton University Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Soziologie und Sozialpolitik
Press. (pp. 1–60). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.
Van Parijs, P. (1995). Real freedom for all. What Weber, M. (2019). Economy and society. A new transla-
(if anything) can justify capitalism? Oxford: Clarendon tion. (Trans. and ed. K. Tribe). Cambridge, MA:
Press. Harvard University Press.
Vogt, W. (1986). Theorie der kapitalistischen und einer Weitzman, M. L. (1984). The share economy: Conquering
laboristischen Ökonomie. Campus: Frankfurt/M. stagflation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Wallerstein, I. (1979). The rise and future demise of the Press.
world capitalist system: Concepts for comparative
analysis. In The essential (pp. 71–105). New York:
The New Press.
Weber, M. (1920). Vorbemerkung. In Gesammelte Internet References
Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie (S. 1–16). Tübingen:
J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).
Weber, M. (1924). Agrarverhältnisse im Altertum. In System of National Accounts 2008. New York 2009.
Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Sozial- und Wirtschafts- Retrieved from January 2020, from http://www.
geschichte (pp. 1–288). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck. unstats.un.org
Weber, M. (1978 [1922]). Economy and society. An out- The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences: The Prize in
line of interpretive sociology (Transl. and ed. G. Roth Economic Sciences 2018. Retrieved from October
& C. Willich) Berkeley: University of California Press. 11, 2019, from https://www.nobelprize.org/prizes/
Weber, M. (1980). Parlament und Regierung im economic-sciences/2018/summary/
neugeordneten Deutschland. In Gesammelte politische
Schriften (pp. 306–443). Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr. [Max
Weber 1994. Parliament and Government in Germany Johannes Berger is professor emeritus at the University
under a New Political Order. In Political Writings. of Mannheim, Germany.
Texts in the History of Political Thought (Transl. and Research topics: Theory of society, economic sociol-
ed. Peter Lassmann and Ronald Speirs, pp. 130–271. ogy, social change in industrial societies, social inequal-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.] ity. Most recent publication: Berger, Johannes. 2019.
Weber, M. (1981 [1923]). Wirtschaftsgeschichte: Abriss Wirtschaftliche Ungleichheit. Zwölf Vorlesungen. Wies-
der universalen Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte. baden: Springer VS.
4. Aufl. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot. [Max Weber
Social Responsibility in the Economy
19
Sebastian Koos

1 The Age of Responsibilization boycotts of large corporations, like Shell, Nestlé,


or Nike. Similarly, on the corporate side, the
In recent decades affluent capitalist democracies consideration of social and environmental issues
have faced far reaching economic and political such as Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) is
changes and challenges. The current COVID-19 on the rise (Brammer and Millington 2003; Vogel
pandemic, the global financial crises, a decline in 2006; Gjølberg 2009; Kinderman 2012; Lim and
labor unionism (Ebbinghaus and Visser 1999), Tsutsui 2012). Businesses have started to publish
welfare state retrenchment (Korpi 2003), and sustainability reports, apply environmental man-
globalization (Held et al. 1999) have all put the agement standards (e.g., ISO 14001), participate
postwar economic order of embedded liberalism in public initiatives concerned with human devel-
under pressure (Ruggie 1982). As a consequence, opment (e.g., Global Compact), and increasingly
many view civil society and the private assump- contribute resources to provide collective goods.
tion of social responsibility as a viable solution to All these developments manifest a rise and diffu-
the declining capacity of states and social partners sion of responsible economic action in market
in economic governance (European Commission economies. Although there are many other phe-
2001; Ruggie 2004). This development is nomena in which morality interferes with eco-
reflected in a shift of corporate conduct and con- nomic orthodoxy (Zelizer 1979; Healy 2000), in
sumption patterns across affluent democracies this chapter I focus exclusively on issues of
towards a market for virtue (Vogel 2006). Other responsibility in production, or more generally
observers have called this a moralization of in profit making, and consumption since argu-
markets (Stehr et al. 2006), or the age of responsi- ably, both actions constitute the core of modern
bilization (Shamir 2008). capitalism (Smelser and Swedberg 1994).
Consumers increasingly use their purchasing Economic action here will be understood as
power to voice their political, environmental, or responsible if it does not harm the common good,
ethical interests (Beck 2000; Scammell 2000; and thus, has no direct or indirect negative effects
Micheletti et al. 2004; Boström et al. 2005; on third parties (Campbell 2007). Arguably such
Harrison et al. 2005b). This is illustrated not responsible economic action is often related to
only by rising sales of environmental and fair extra monetary, transaction, or opportunity
labeled goods, but also through widespread costs. In a more common parlance, responsible
economic action refers to a way of consuming or
S. Koos (*)
running a business which is also directed towards
Department of Politics and Public Administration,
University of Konstanz, Konstanz, Germany the well-being of others or the common good
e-mail: sebastian.koos@uni-konstanz.de (Beckert 2005). From a sociological perspective,
# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 289
A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9_19
290 S. Koos

such action is of central interest, in that, it ‘utilities,’” which, in his perspective, includes
challenges the rigid assumptions of the behavioral both householding and profit-making (Swedberg
model of homo economicus in the only domain 1998). For sake of simplicity in this chapter I will
where pure formal rationality, carried out by mainly focus on two types of economic actions:
solely self-interested utility maximizing actors, the purchase of goods and services by individuals
seems to hold true, namely the economy of mod- as an integral aspect of householding, as well as
ern market societies (Smith 1974; Fligstein 2001). business related actions by corporations. These
Therefore, the question arises of how to make can be distinguished by the type of actor, individ-
sense of socially responsible action in such a ual versus corporate, as well as the orientation,
context. provisioning versus profit seeking, and the
To answer this question, I discuss micro- and embedding of both in different social contexts.
macro-theoretical explanations of responsible The question that renders economic action
economic action as well as existing empirical responsible, needs to be discussed in the context
research. On the level of actors, I discuss models of broader sociological debates on morality and
of action, which allow for the disentanglement of responsibility. Generally, in a sociological under-
the theoretical mechanisms that drive responsible standing morality refers to some basic principles
economic action. On the context level, I draw on and norms in a given community or society about
institutional and social movement theories as well right or wrong in human conduct (Hillmann
as culture and globalization to highlight 2007). Morality can be either understood as a
dimensions of the contextual embeddedness of normative or descriptive concept (Jähnichen
responsible economic action. I will first introduce 2008). In the former, ethical standards are
the concept of responsible economic action. negotiated by drawing on, for instance, deonto-
Thereafter, I present both actor and context cen- logical or utilitarian reasoning. In the later per-
tered theoretical approaches to explain responsi- spective, moral norms are understood as variable
ble economic action, before reviewing exiting and observable. Thus, individuals internalize cer-
empirical studies. I conclude by discussing how tain values and norms, regarding just or unjust,
economic sociology and the concept of responsi- right or wrong, which were learned in socializa-
bility can help address the grand challenges of the tion and manifest in social action (Kohlberg
twenty-first century. 1981). In a sociological understanding moral
behavior can then be defined as actions that are
carried out in “accordance with some principle
2 Defining Responsible Economic which is oriented (also) toward the well-being of
Action others or the common good and is followed even
if it demands to forgo additional personal profit or
What renders action responsible? How can such utility” (Beckert 2005, 7).
actions be defined for economic actors? First, I As an alternative to the concept of morality,
start by elaborating on what economic action is, responsibility has gained growing prominence
before turning to the issue of how morality and regarding all kinds of economic activities (Carroll
responsibility in sociological terms should be 2008). From a philosophical perspective, respon-
conceived. Scholars generally describe the econ- sibility is a relational concept, which connects a
omy as encompassing all activities that relate to subject with an object which must be cared for,
the production, distribution, exchange, and con- based on normative criteria provided by an
sumption of scarce goods and resources (Smelser authority (Heidbrink 2011, 190). Three main
and Swedberg 2005). According to Max Weber forms of responsibility can be discerned (ibid.,
(1978, 63) economic action is “any peaceful exer- 191). In the ethical sense, actors can be held
cise of an actor’s control over resources which is responsible for the consequences of their actions
in its main impulse oriented towards economic according to some moral principles. In a judicial
ends.” Such action is propelled by “a desire for understanding, responsibility points to the
19 Social Responsibility in the Economy 291

sanctionability of actions based on existing law. definitions that focus on costs or chances of sur-
Finally, in the social sense, responsibility refers to vival (Piliavin and Charng 1990, 29). Margolis
the voluntary assumption of certain actions, based (1982, 15), for instance, defines behavior as altru-
on social expectations. From a sociological per- istic if “the actor could have done better for him-
spective, according to Coleman, “responsible self had he chosen to ignore the effect of his
behavior can be defined as that which takes into choice on others.” The difference between
account the interests and rights of others” responsibility and altruism is the orientation of
(Coleman 1990, 556). the former towards a common principle or shared
The concept of responsibility has proven espe- norm, which at first glance does not need to be
cially useful in issues of economic ethics for at costly. However, I argue, that responsible eco-
least two reasons. First, it allows one to distin- nomic action is always associated with some
guish and balance different dimensions of respon- additional cost to ensure that negative
sibility such as economic, legal, and ethical issues externalities are avoided. From a behavioral per-
(Carroll 1999). Secondly, the intended and unin- spective, economic action can be defined as
tended consequences of purposeful action responsible if it avoids any harm to third parties
become much more central and precarious, (e.g., or to the common good. On markets, this involves
supply chains of multinational companies), due to additional (monetary, transaction, or opportunity)
increasing complexities in global market costs, beyond markets prices, to ensure collective
economies. Since responsibility focuses on the goods are not affected. In this sense, responsible
consequences of actions, it is therefore, better consumption would take place when people pay a
equipped to address these unintended surplus for goods to ensure that minimum labor
consequences, than the concept of morality standards in less developed countries are met.
(Heidbrink 2011; Heidbrink and Schmitt 2011). Both definitions are plagued by two issues to
I will zoom in to provide a better understand- different degrees, namely normativity and circu-
ing of what constitutes responsibility using the larity. The question of normativity (1) refers to
example of consumption. In extant literature, con- the fact that one has to define what morality or
sumption is understood as responsible either by responsibility actually means in a specific context
focusing on the consequences of, or the and point in time. A drastic example of this prob-
motivations for consumption (OECD 2002; lem would be the boycott of Jewish shops in Nazi
Micheletti 2003; Harrison et al. 2005a; Sassatelli Germany. For an arguably large number of people
2006; Devinney et al. 2010). In the former, con- at that time, boycotting Jewish shops seemed
sumption is seen as responsible if it seeks to avoid surprisingly unproblematic in moral terms.
negative externalities, or to bring about social Thus, boycotting Jews and buying German back
change. In the later, responsible consumption is then, might have even been perceived as forms of
based on certain values, attitudes, and norms of responsible consumption. However, such dis-
justice or benevolence. Such definitions can be crimination and violation of universal human
called psychological since they refer to the rights is an obvious example of immoral or irre-
motivations or aims of a specific type of individ- sponsible consumption behavior. Yet, what
ual action. In a parsimonious psychological or constitutes morality and responsibility? What
interest-based definition, economic action would product is a good product? These questions are
be understood as responsible if actors take the difficult to answer without engaging in a norma-
public consequences of their private economic tive discussion of what is right or wrong. The
actions into account. issue of circularity (2) poses an equally severe
One alternative to the dominant psychological problem. Most definitions of moral economic
definitions can be found in the behavioral eco- action refer to the purpose, aim, or motivation of
nomics literature on altruism. Rather than defin- a consumption or production decision as the basic
ing altruistic behavior by actors’ other-regarding definitional criteria. Thus, the good intention
motives, economists and socio-biologists prefer renders the action responsible. However, since
292 S. Koos

motivations form an important part of the theorists, the precondition for speaking of rational
explanations for such behavior, such definitions action is that actors maximize their individual
run the risk of mixing explanandum and utility by instrumentally deciding on the least
explanans and therefore employ circular costly means to reach a given end (Elster 1989;
argumentation. Hedström and Swedberg 1996). Thus, actors have
These problems cannot be easily resolved by a set of egoistic, self-interested preferences and
using either a psychological or a behavioral are fully informed about objective constraints. By
approach. To some degree, normativity can be balancing preferences and constraints, they
avoided by adhering to prescriptive statements choose the one alternative of action that
of desirable outcomes, provided by representative maximizes their utility (Opp 1999, 174). The
political institutions such as governments or the assumptions of the neo-classical or rational
United Nations (UN). For example, if the UN choice (RC) model of human action have been
defines sustainable development as one of its widely criticized for being atomistic (Granovetter
main goals, this can be used as a benchmark 1985), too narrow (Opp 1999; Boudon 2003), or
according to which responsibility of economic plainly unrealistic (Margolis 1982; Etzioni 1988).
action can be assessed. Circularity could be Yet, according to Granovetter, although “the
avoided by focusing on the outcome of action assumption of rational action must always be
such as reduced use of pesticides, increased problematic, it is a good working hypothesis
wages, or fewer accidents, rather than on its that should not easily be abandoned”
motives. (Granovetter 1985, 506).
Many sociological action theories have been
developed in response to the issues of the classi-
3 Explaining Responsible cal RC model of action. In a critique of the nar-
Economic Action row model, Opp (1999) suggested a wide version
of rational choice. He relaxes the rigid
Under which conditions do individual and corpo- assumptions of RC, allowing all kinds of
rate economic actors take into account the constraints, which are also subjective, and
consequences of their actions for public goods? preferences which are also non-egoistic, to enter
Economic Sociology has stressed the the utility function. In a different criticism of the
embeddedness of action, pertaining to the struc- narrow version of RC, Boudon (1998, 2003)
tural, cultural, and political context of economic develops a cognitivist model of action, of which
interaction. Starting from a critique of the rational rational choice is only one special version. In
action perspective, I first discuss different socio- Boudon’s understanding, the core of action can
logical action theories (Boudon 2003; Hedström be constituted either by instrumental rationality
2005). Subsequently, the concept of contextual (RC), by cognitive rationality, or axiological
embeddedness (Zukin and DiMaggio 1990) is rationality.1 Thus, actions do not necessarily fol-
outlined, and its openness to integrate context low a cost-benefit analysis (instrumental rational-
specific theories that focus on social change in ity), but are undertaken because an individual
explaining the emergence of social responsibility holds some belief to be likely, true (cognitive
in the economy is discussed. rationality) or fair, good, or unfair (axiological
rationality), and has strong reason to believe so

3.1 Action Theoretical Approaches 1


Affective and traditional action, as in Weber’s (1978)
classical ideal types, should also be considered here.
The classical rational choice theory employs far While traditional or routine types of action might, to
some degree, be subsumed under cognitive reason espe-
reaching assumptions of human agency, which
cially affective behavior, can hardly be reduced to
render the explanation of responsible economic Boudon’s model, since, at least in its ideal-type, it is by
action problematic. For most rational choice definition, not cognitive (Schimank 2005, 44).
19 Social Responsibility in the Economy 293

(Boudon 1998, 826). This is not congruent with New Economic Sociology (Smelser and
Opp’s wide version of RC. Boudon (2003) Swedberg 2005). It was popularized by Mark
concludes that efforts to include values and Granovetter (1985) in a critique of the atomistic
beliefs in wide versions of rational action theories perspective of both the neoclassical model and
may not always be suitable, for actors draw on Parsons’ normativistic approach to social action.
values and norms, but not necessarily to increase According to Granovetter (1985) action needs to
their individual utility. Rather actors rely on them be understood and explained in its structural
because they believe that they are true or just embeddedness in social networks to overcome
evaluations based on shared ideas, moral the over- and under-socialized understandings of
convictions, and normative beliefs. action. In an older account, Polanyi (1963) uses
The outlined theories share the two most com- the term embeddedness with a different meaning.
mon denominators of social action theories In The Great Transformation, he describes the
(Rössel 2008, 233): desires (or in the corporate dis- and re-embedding of the market-economy
case, interests) and opportunities (Elster 1989; in society as a double movement, using a rather
Opp 1999). Hedström (2005) adds beliefs as a institutional understanding of embeddedness
third component to these two elements. In his (Beckert 2007). Zukin and DiMaggio (1990)
simple DBO model, Hedström assumes that draw on these approaches and provide an
action can be explained by certain constraints, encompassing typology of four kinds of
desires or interests, and beliefs. In this model, embeddedness of economic action: structural,
individual and corporate action is firstly under- cognitive, cultural, and political. The first type
stood as being purposeful; thus, actors have cer- refers to Granovetter’s notion of actors as
tain desires and interests which provide reasons connected through different kinds of interper-
for their action. Secondly, the choice of actions is sonal relationships. The structures and positions
limited by resources and costs (Elster 1989). within such networks are crucial in providing
Thirdly, they have beliefs “as proposition information and opportunities for action (e.g.,
(s) about the world held to be true” (Hedström Granovetter 1973). The second form, cognitive
2005, 38). embeddedness, refers to patterns of cognitive pro-
Such a concept of action seems open enough cesses like limits to rationality, as studied by
to integrate all kinds of individual and contextual psychologists (e.g., Simon 1955). Thirdly, cul-
determinants, like value orientations, institutions, tural embeddedness denotes the role of shared
or culture. At the same time, it is specific enough meanings and understandings, which shape indi-
to provide an understanding of the mechanisms vidual perceptions, values, and repertoires of eco-
that connect macro contexts to individual action. nomic action (e.g., Zelizer 1979). Finally,
Furthermore, the basic elements of these models political embeddedness refers to the struggle
can also be found in social psychological over power, manifested in institutions, like the
approaches, like the theory of planned behavior state or corporatist arrangements, that impact eco-
(Ajzen 2005), which is frequently used in studies nomic decisions and processes (e.g., Siaroff
of consumer behavior, and in political science 1999; Hall and Soskice 2001). This chapter
theories, like the civic voluntarism model (Verba focuses especially on the last two meanings of
et al. 1995). embeddedness, which will be termed contextual
embeddedness here. Yet, the notion of
embeddedness in its different meanings can only
3.2 Contextual Embeddedness serve as a starting point, which as a heuristic,
provides a research perspective. Thus, more spe-
Having discussed a sociological action theory, I cific theories need to be added that allow one to
now turn to the concept of embeddedness and grasp the explanatory mechanism at work
the context of responsible economic action. (Beckert 2011).
Embeddedness is one of the core concepts of the
294 S. Koos

The contextual embeddedness of responsible corporations as a result of the global


economic action has been acknowledged by a ungovernability stemming from economic global-
multitude of theoretical approaches, stemming ization and its discontents (Gjølberg 2009). On
from political science, sociology, business man- the other hand, globalization leads to the diffusion
agement, and economics (Beck 2000; Micheletti of CSR as a new institutionalized myth (Hiß
2003; Campbell 2006; Crouch 2006; Matten and 2006).
Moon 2008; Seyfang 2009). In her seminal book The post-modernization approach focuses on
on political consumerism, Micheletti (2003) the process of value change as a driver of alterna-
distinguishes at least four macro theoretical tive ways of political participation. From this
explanations for the emergence of and national perspective, increasing economic affluence
differences in responsible consumption practices: paralleled by a perceived scarcity of mostly non-
governance changes, post-modernization, ecolog- material higher order needs result in a societal
ical, and reflexive modernization. Other scholars value change from materialism to post-
(Scammell 2000; Harrison et al. 2005a; Scherer materialism (Inglehart 1997). The rising share of
and Palazzo 2008) emphasize the effect of glob- post-materialist citizens in a country leads to a
alization for both responsible consumption shift from price-quality considerations in con-
and CSR. Furthermore, macro theoretical sumption to demands for environmentally
explanations of corporate responsibility often friendly and fair produced goods and services.
use institutional explanations (Hiß 2006; Matten In his myriad writings on reflexive moderniza-
and Moon 2008; Kinderman 2012). Others have tion, Beck (1994, 1996, 1998) assumes an
emphasized the importance of social movements epochal change from first to second
(Balsiger 2010; Dubuisson-Quellier 2013). (or reflexive) modernity, which can be
According to the governance approach, gov- characterized by the process of individualization
ernment failure has led to the search for new and by an increase in manufactured risks (risk
governance solutions, which require cooperation society). With the advent of reflexive modernity,
between the state, civil society, and economic he associates the emergence of a new form of
actors in order to provide a new steering capacity politics, termed subpolitics. The “concept of
in a complex globalized world (Micheletti 2003, ‘subpolitics’ refers to politics outside and beyond
6). The emergence of new policy instruments, the representative institutions of the political sys-
like eco labeling schemes, can be seen as a gov- tem of nation-states” (Beck 1996, 18). From this
ernance innovation which propel the rise of green perspective, individual actions achieve political
consumerism (Mol et al. 2000; Jordan et al. 2004; significance by engaging a political frame of ref-
Boström and Klintman 2008). Similarly, the erence in all kinds of decisions in everyday life
emergence of CSR has been driven by new gov- (Holzer and Sorensen 2003). Thus, consumption
ernance initiatives like the United Nations Global becomes politicized as “citizens are discovering
Compact, or the Global Reporting Initiative that the act of purchase can always and every-
(Bartley 2007; Lim and Tsutsui 2012). In a where be a direct ballot-paper” (Beck 2000, 70).
more general perspective, globalization is seen Two processes are of critical relevance here: indi-
as a process which deprives citizens and their vidualization and globalization, which “are in fact
organized representations of political power two sides of the same process of reflexive mod-
(Norris 2002). The drivers of this process are ernization” (Beck 1994, 14). Individualization
multinational enterprises and supra-national means that actors are dissolved of the classical
institutions which gain influence (Harrison et al. social formations, like family, class, or occupa-
2005a). Consumers react by using their purchas- tion and forced to assemble their own biography.
ing power to signal political interest (Scammell “This type of individualization does not remain
2000; Beck 2000). The globalist hypothesis is private: it becomes political in a definite new
also reflected in the CSR literature. On the one sense,” by inducing politics into everyday life
hand, NGOs and consumers put pressure on transactions (ibid., 16). Globalization works as a
19 Social Responsibility in the Economy 295

catalyst, accelerating these processes by the Such opportunities can be provided by political
“intensification of worldwide social relations systems but can also come through market and
which link distant localities in such a way that industry structures (Koos 2012b). Mobilizing
local happenings are shaped by events occurring structures refers to formal organizations or infor-
many miles away and vice versa” (Giddens mal networks, that enable collective action (King
1990, 64). 2008). Finally, social movements propagate men-
Other scholars adopt an institutionalist per- tal frames which may motivate actors to assume
spective on responsible economic action. Espe- responsibility for collective goods, for instance,
cially in the research on corporate responsibility, by constructing new valuation devices for ethical
a number of studies focus on the embeddedness consumption (Dubuisson-Quellier 2013).
of CSR in institutions of the political economy In sum, macro theoretical explanations of
that constitute different national business responsible economic action focus on processes
systems, varieties of capitalism, and worlds of of social change like modernization, individuali-
welfare (Esping-Andersen 1990; Whitley 1990; zation or globalization, changes in the gover-
Hall and Soskice 2001). Inspired by diverse insti- nance structures, the impact of political
tutional theories, two contradictory hypotheses, institutions, and the mobilization by social
institutional mirror versus substitute, have been movements. Most of the theories or hypotheses
proposed on the role of institutions. On the one do not provide a precise mechanism which relates
hand, Matten and Moon (2008) claim that in the context to individual responsible action. As
liberal market economies and residual welfare will be discussed in the next section, there is little
states, explicit forms of CSR substitute for miss- empirical research that empirically tests these
ing institutional arrangements. On the other hand, explanations.
Campbell (2007) develops an institutional mirror
perspective arguing that coordinated market
economies and extensive welfare states provide
4 Empirical Studies of Social
the regulative and ideational basis for business
Responsibility in the Economy
commitment to social responsibility. Responsible
consumption product labels have been seen as
I will first discuss empirical studies that focus on
new policy institutions (Jordan et al. 2004).
micro-sociological explanations, before turning
Boström and Klintman (2008) suggest eco labels
to context specific empirical studies. A large
as a new type of institution that guides green
number of empirical studies on responsible con-
consumerism, an argument which is somewhat
sumer and corporate action are exploratory or
similar to the governance argument discussed
descriptive and do not test theories at all
above. Yet, Boström and Klintman (2008) focus
(Micheletti et al. 2004; De Bakker et al. 2005;
on how labeling institutions emerge and not how
Harrison et al. 2005b).2 Those studies that draw
they affect consumer behavior.
on a theoretical model, in the case of responsible
A final perspective focuses on social
consumer action, often apply the theory of
movements as driving forces of responsibi-
lization. Social movement approaches attempt to
explain the prerequisites for collective action that 2
For the field of CSR research De Bakker et al. (2005,
aims at achieving social change. We can see the 300) report that almost 89.8% of all articles on corporate
social responsibility and corporate social performance are
application of the so-called political process
solely descriptive (37%), prescriptive (14.3%), conceptual
model, which takes political opportunity (13.5%) or exploratory (25%). Only 10.2 % are predictive
structures, mobilizing structures, and framing in empirically testing theoretically grounded hypotheses.
processes into consideration (King 2008). Oppor- In the field of responsible consumption research, a look at
two major edited books by Harrison et al. (2005a) and
tunity structures relate to the external, or rather
Micheletti et al. (2004) reveals that in the former only 1out
political, conditions that make coordinated collec- of 14 articles and in the later only one out of 16 articles are
tive action more likely to emerge and succeed. predictive.
296 S. Koos

planned behavior (Shaw 2005; Ozcaglar- 2007; Andorfer and Liebe 2012; Sunderer and
Toulouse et al. 2006; De Pelsmacker and Rössel 2012). Yet, most of these studies also
Janssens 2007) and only more recently have confirm the importance of certain constraints
they applied a wide rational choice approach and resources, or the subjective perceptions and
(Sunderer and Rössel 2012). Boudon’s related beliefs about them (Hughner et al. 2007;
cognitivist model has not yet been applied to Andorfer and Liebe 2012). The research on
this type of action. In the theory of planned organic food consumption emphasizes the variety
behavior any action is seen firstly as a conse- of beliefs in what the term organic actually means
quence of the intention to act, which again is to consumers. For example, a large number of
conceptualized as a function of specific attitudes, people belief that organic food is healthier, tastes
subjective norms, and behavioral controls (Ajzen better, is safer, better for the environment and the
2005). The factors include certain beliefs regard- local economy, even though the first three claims
ing the planned behavior, specific attitudes, the lack scientific support (Hughner et al. 2007,
consideration of the expectations of others 101 ff.).
towards an action, and subjectively perceived Research on CSR is by far narrower, when
external constraints of the situation. Because linking theory with an empirical approach. Most
Fair Trade consumption is unlikely to be driven studies here focus on the business case for CSR,
by self-interest, Shaw (2005) adds ethical self- that is the link between the social and the financial
identity and ethical concern to better account for performance of a firm (Kurucz et al. 2008). Thus,
the ethical dimension of Fair Trade. Shaw and following a narrow rational choice model, firms’
colleagues find empirical support for these responsible business practices are explained by
dimensions, yet the tests are based on a conve- their positive impact on profit. Empirical results
nience sample and therefore, are not representa- on this relationship are inconclusive. While
tive (Shaw 2005; Ozcaglar-Toulouse et al. 2006). Orlitzky et al. (2003) in a meta-analysis find
Other studies find that the perceived difficulties in support for a positive effect of a firm’s social
getting such products due to high price or lack of performance on its financial revenue, Schreck
availability constrain the intention to purchase (2011) in an econometrically advanced approach
Fair Trade products (Uusitalo and Oksanenen cannot detect any relationship at all. Other studies
2004; Becchetti and Rosati 2007). Sunderer and focus on a broader, yet still mostly structural set
Rössel (2012) use a wide rational choice model to of indicators, like ownership structure, company
explain the frequency of fair trade consumption, size, or managerial discretion (Adams and
considering subjective (e.g., perceived lack of Hardwick 1998; Navarro 1988). Only rarely are
shopping opportunities) and objective constraints the actual motives of managers and CEOs taken
(household income), as well as three different into consideration to explain CSR (Hemingway
types of moral motives, which are fair trade con- and Maclagan 2004). Overall, the empirical stud-
sciousness, expected moral utility, and personal ies on CSR find firm size, profit, and private
moral norms. The authors find that, both subjec- ownership robust determinants of corporate
tive constraints and all three types of moral responsible activities.
motives have a significant impact on fair trade While most studies consider the theoretical
consumption. Household income, however, does importance of contexts, due to data limitations
not have a statistically significant effect. contextual determinants are often neglected
In fact, one of the most consistent findings of empirically. According to Andorfer and Liebe
all studies on responsible consumption is the (2012, 428) “there is a need for additional cross-
importance of certain moral orientations or post- national studies that consider differences in mar-
materialist (or universalist) values (Opp and ket structures and cultural traits.” In a similar
Roehl 1990; Thøgersen and Ölander 2002; Stolle fashion Thøgersen (2010, 171) claims that
et al. 2005; Ozcaglar-Toulouse et al. 2006; De existing research has an “unfortunate individual-
Pelsmacker and Janssens 2007; Hughner et al. istic and individualizing bias,” neglecting the
19 Social Responsibility in the Economy 297

“macro structural conditions that frame and con- using different measures for CSR, show that cor-
strain individual choices.” Therefore, I now turn porate responsibility mirror the dominant national
to the contextual embeddedness of responsible logics of corporatism, neo-liberalism, or public
economic action. welfare (Midttun et al. 2006; Gjølberg 2009).
Different from the actor-centered research Other studies find that CSR is rather a substitute
outlined above, there are few studies that seek for institutional arrangements of political econ-
systematic empirical evidence for macro theoreti- omy, widespread in liberal market economies
cal explanations of responsible economic action.3 but of only marginal importance in coordinated
The few existing studies, however, often arrive at ones (Jackson and Apostolakou 2010; Kinderman
contradictory results. In the following I will first 2012). In a different study, Koos (2012a) finds
discuss the comparative research on consumer that corporatist and welfare institutions interact in
and thereafter, the research on corporate a way so that CSR can be seen as both a substitute
responsibility. and a mirror of existing institutional
Regarding responsible consumption, a couple arrangements. Regarding globalization, Gjølberg
of studies focus on the impact of the political (2009) finds that countries with a large share of
culture, especially on aggregate levels of multinational corporations and high foreign direct
generalized trust (Sønderskov 2009; Neilson and investment are more likely to have high CSR
Paxton 2010). Neilson and Paxton (2010) report a engagement.
positive impact of regional levels of generalized In sum, little empirical research addresses the
trust on individual political consumption. How- contextual embeddedness of responsible eco-
ever, Sønderskov (2009) does not find any impact nomic action, highlighting the need for more
of aggregate levels of generalized trust regarding comparative research in this field.
organic food consumption. Similarly, neither
aggregate levels of education, nor affluence
impact the per capita consumption of organic 5 Grand Challenges,
groceries. Only a post-materialist culture has a Responsibility and Economic
statistically significant impact in his study. Yet, Sociology in the Twenty-First
Koos (2011, 2012b) in two studies, finds that the Century
economic opportunity structures, such as national
affluence, and the structure of retailing systems Over the last decades, responsibility has become
are most important in explaining political and an important concept, due to several changes
sustainable consumption. (Smith 2003; Scherer and Palazzo 2011). Most
In the CSR literature, only a few comparative importantly, globalization and the trans-
empirical studies focus on the impact of national nationalization of supply chains has shifted the
institutional arrangements of the political econ- locus of production from well-governed countries
omy and the level of globalization. Some studies, and regulated labor markets to places that suffer
from a lack of governance. At the same time,
3 corporations have become immensely powerful
Moreover, most empirical studies that focus on responsi-
ble consumer behavior and CSR fail to provide the theo- and large, sometimes having assets comparable
retical mechanism which relates the macro level to micro to government budgets. This was paralleled by an
action. Midttun et al. (2006) address the relationship information revolution, providing easy, inexpen-
between old institutional forms for the embedding of the
sive, and fast access to media, and information
economy, like welfare states, and new forms, like CSR.
Differing between weaker and stronger institutional from all around the world through the internet.
embeddedness, they do not provide a rationale of how These processes shifted the focus from
the old forms impact the new forms. Yet, without such a governments to corporations and consumers as
mechanism, the strong correlation between welfare capi-
responsible economic actors. Yet, as has been
talism, corporatism, and CSR in Scandinavia remains
ambivalent, for it cannot be pinpointed as to what exactly shown in this chapter there are important limits
drives this relationship. to the assumption of economic responsibility.
298 S. Koos

Firstly, the market for virtue (Vogel 2006) is more thoroughly understood. Second, while
strongly limited by economic opportunities, economists and political scientists have
which differ across countries. Second, the com- emphasized the ability of markets to address cli-
plex historically grown institutional arrangements mate change, some economic sociologists have
of modern capitalism provide rather stable provided important insights into the difficulties of
worldviews, norms, and beliefs which are condu- markets as forms of economic governance (e.g.,
cive to civic economic responsibility in only Engels 2006). Third, as this chapter has shown,
some cases (Koos and Sachweh 2019). Third, economic sociology has also something to say on
being based on unequally distributed financial the difficulty for consumers and corporations to
means, responsible consumption reproduces assume responsibility (Koos 2012a, b). While
social inequality in civic participation. Further- responsibility in economic action is always some-
more, political consumption might be used to what precarious, under specific conditions it
foster undemocratic or irresponsible goals, might help solve collective good problems,
lacking democratic legitimacy. Finally, on the whereby consumers, corporations and civil soci-
corporate side, CSR potentially comes with the ety might gain, if such action complements the
bitter flavor of paternalistic patronage (De Geer economic governance by the state and organized
et al. 2009). Moreover, used as a political argu- interest (Bartley et al. 2015). Therefore, responsi-
ment, the voluntary assumption of economic bility seems to be an important concept in
responsibility by firms might even contribute to addressing pressing social problems from an eco-
the further regress of the welfare state nomic sociology perspective, since it connects
(Kinderman 2012). economic action to its consequences for the
Societies in the twenty-first century have been broader common good.
and still are confronted with many grand
challenges or wicked problems. Such challenges
are characterized by involving high levels of com-
References
plexity, uncertainty, and evaluative struggles
affecting a large number of people, often on a Adams, M., & Hardwick, P. (1998). An analysis of corpo-
global scale (Ferraro et al. 2015). Problems such rate donations: United Kingdom evidence. Journal of
as climate change, pandemics, global migration, Managment Studies, 35(5), 641–654.
or social inequality are often inherently related to Ajzen, I. (2005). Attitudes, personality and behavior (2nd
ed.). Berkshire: Open University Press.
the organization and functioning of the global Andorfer, V. A., & Liebe, U. (2012). Research on fair
economy, markets, and economic action. Tack- trade consumption: A review. Journal of Business
ling these challenges therefore involves a better Ethics, 106(4), 415–435.
understanding and explanation of how the econ- Balsiger, P. (2010). Making political consumers: The tac-
tical action repertoire of a campaign for clean clothes.
omy works. Arguably, economic sociology has an Social Movement Studies, 9(3), 311–329.
important role to play here in three different ways: Bartley, T. (2007). Institutional emergence in an era of
by providing a critical understanding of evalua- globalization: The rise of transnational private regula-
tion struggles, by analyzing markets as gover- tion of labor and environmental conditions. American
Journal of Sociology, 113(2), 297–351.
nance mechanisms, and by identifying the Bartley, T., Koos, S., Samel, H., Setrini, G., & Summers,
conditions for responsible economic action. N. (2015). Looking behind the label: Global industries
First, economic sociology has already started and the conscientious consumer. Bloomington:
addressing the problems of valuation and evalua- Indiana University Press.
Becchetti, L., & Rosati, F. C. (2007). Global social
tion, as well as of uncertainty in the constitution preferences and the demand for socially responsible
and development of markets (e.g., Beckert 1996). products: Empirical evidence from a pilot study on
Yet, struggles on how global issues are framed, fair trade consumers. The World Economy, 807–836.
understood, and evaluated, how this in turn is Beck, U. (1994). The reinvention of politics: Towards a
theory of reflexive modernization. In U. Beck,
absorbed by markets, and affects social inequality A. Giddens, & S. Lash (Eds.), Reflexive
and environmental preservation still needs to be
19 Social Responsibility in the Economy 299

modernization: Politics, tradition and aesthetics in the Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory.
modern social order (pp. 1–55). Cambridge: Polity Cambridge: Belknap Press.
Press. Crouch, C. (2006). Modelling the firm in its market and
Beck, U. (1996). World risk society as cosmopolitan soci- organizational environment: Methodologies for study-
ety? Ecological questions in a framework of ing corporate social responsibility. Organization Stud-
manufactured uncertainties. Theory, Culture & Soci- ies, 27(10), 1533–1551.
ety, 13, 1–32. De Bakker, F. G. A., Groenewegen, P., & Den Hond,
Beck, U. (1998). Wie wird Demokratie im Zeitalter der F. (2005). A bibliometric analysis of 30 years of
Globalisierung möglich? Eine Einleitung. In U. Beck research and theory on corporate social responsibility
(Ed.), Politik der Globalisierung (pp. 7–66). Frankfurt and corporate social performance. Business and Soci-
am Main: Suhrkamp. ety, 44(3), 283–317.
Beck, U. (2000). What is globalisation? Cambridge: De Geer, H., Borglund, T., & Frostenson, M. (2009).
Cambridge University Press. Reconciling CSR with the role of the corporation in
Beckert, J. (1996). What is sociological about economic welfare states: The problematic Swedish example.
sociology? Uncertainty and the embeddedness of eco- Journal of Business Ethics, 89, 269–283.
nomic action. Theory and Society, 25, 803–840. De Pelsmacker, P., & Janssens, W. (2007). A model for
Beckert, J. (2005). The moral embeddedness of markets. fair trade buying behaviour: The role of perceived
MPIfG Discussion Paper 6. quantity and quality of information and of product-
Beckert, J. (2007). The great transformation of specific attitudes. Journal of Business Ethics, 75,
embeddedness. Karl Polanyi and the new economic 361–380.
sociology. MPIfG Discussion Paper 1. Devinney, T. M., Auger, P., & Eckhardt, G. M. (2010).
Beckert, J. (2011). Die Sittlichkeit der Wirtschaft: Von The myth of the ethical consumer. Cambridge:
Effizienz- und Differenzierungstheorien zu einer Cambridge University Press.
Theorie wirtschaftlicher Felder. MPIfG Working Dubuisson-Quellier, S. (2013). A market mediation strat-
Paper 11/8. egy: How social movements seek to change firms’
Boström, M., Føllesdal, A., Klintman, M., Micheletti, M., practices by promoting new principles of product val-
& Sørensen, M. P. (2005). Political consumerism: Its uation. Organization Studies, 34(5–6), 683–703.
motivations, power, and conditions in the nordic Ebbinghaus, B., & Visser, J. (1999). When institutions
countries and elsewhere. Copenhagen: Nordic Council matter: Union growth and decline in Western Europe,
of Ministers. 1950–95. European Sociological Review, 15(2),
Boström, M., & Klintman, M. (2008). Eco standards, 135–158.
product labelling and green consumerism. Elster, J. (1989). Nuts and bolts for the social sciences.
Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Boudon, R. (1998). Limitations of rational choice theory. Engels, A. (2006). Market creation and transnational rule-
American Journal of Sociology, 104(3), 817–828. making: The case of CO2 emissions trading. In M.-L.
Boudon, R. (2003). Beyond rational choice theory. Annual Djelic & K. Sahlin-Andersson (Eds.), Transnational
Review of Sociology, 29, 1–21. governance: Institutional dynamics of regulation.
Brammer, S., & Millington, A. (2003). The evolution of Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
corporate charitable contributions in the UK between Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare
1989 and 1999: Industry structure and stakeholder capitalism. Oxford: Polity Press.
influences. Business Ethics: A European Review, 12 Etzioni, A. (1988). The moral dimension. Towards a new
(3), 216–228. economics. New York: The Free Press.
Campbell, J. L. (2006). Institutional analysis and the para- European Commission. (2001, July). Promoting a
dox of corporate social responsibility. The American European framework for corporate social responsibil-
Behavioral Scientist, 49(7), 925–937. ity. Green Paper.
Campbell, J. L. (2007). Why would corporations behave in Ferraro, F., Etzion, D., & Gehman, J. (2015). Tackling
socially responsible ways? An institution theory of grand challenges pragmatically: Robust action
corporate social responsibility. The Academy of Man- revisited. Organization Studies, 3, 363–390.
agement Review, 32(3), 946–967. Fligstein, N. (2001). The architecture of markets.
Carroll, A. B. (1999). Corporate social responsibility: Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Evolution of a definitional construct. Business and Giddens, A. (1990). The consequences of modernity.
Society, 38(3), 268–295. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Carroll, A. B. (2008). A history of corporate social respon- Gjølberg, M. (2009). The origin of corporate social
sibility: Concepts and practices. In A. Crane, responsibility: Global forces or national legacies.
A. McWilliams, D. Matten, J. Moon, & D. Siegel Socio-Economic Review, 7(4), 605–637.
(Eds.), The Oxford handbook of corporate social Granovetter, M. (1973). The strength of weak ties. Ameri-
responsibility (pp. 19–46). Oxford: Oxford University can Journal of Sociology, 78(6), 1360–1380.
Press.
300 S. Koos

Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social struc- Jordan, A., Wurzel, R. K. W., Zito, A. R., & Brückner,
ture: The problem of embeddedness. The American L. (2004). Consumer responsibility-taking and
Journal of Sociology, 91(3), 481–510. eco-labeling schemes in Europe. In M. Micheletti,
Hall, P. A., & Soskice, D. (2001). Varieties of capitalism: A. Follesdal, & D. Stolle (Eds.), Politics, products,
The institutional foundations of comparative advan- and markets. Exploring political consumerism past
tage. New York: Oxford University Press. and present (pp. 161–180). Transaction Publishers:
Harrison, R., Newholm, T., & Shaw, D. (2005a). Introduc- New Brunswick.
tion. In R. Harrison, T. Newholm, & D. Shaw (Eds.), Kinderman, D. (2012). ‘Free us up so we can be responsi-
The ethical consumer (pp. 1–8). London: SAGE. ble!’ The co-evolution of corporate social responsibil-
Harrison, R., Newholm, T., & Shaw, D. (2005b). The ity and neo-liberalism in the UK, 1977–2010. Socio-
ethical consumer. London: SAGE. Economic Review, 10(1), 29–57.
Healy, K. (2000). Embedded altruism: Blood collection King, B. (2008). A social movement perspective of stake-
regimes and the European Union’s donor population. holder collective action and influence. Business &
American Journal of Sociology, 105, 1633–1657. Society, 47(1), 21–49.
Hedström, P. (2005). Dissecting the social: On the Kohlberg, L. (1981). The philosophy of moral develop-
principles of analytical sociology. Cambridge: ment: Moral stages and the idea of justice. Essays on
Cambridge Universit Press. moral development. San Francisco, CA: Harper &
Hedström, P., & Swedberg, R. (1996). Rational choice, Row.
empirical research and the sociological tradition. Koos, S. (2011). Varieties of environmental labelling,
European Sociological Review, 12, 127–146. market structures, and sustainable consumption across
Heidbrink, L. (2011). Der Verantwortungsbegriff der Europe: A comparative analysis of organizational and
Wirtschaftsethik. In M. S. Aßländer (Ed.), Handbuch market supply determinants of environmental-labelled
Wirtschaftsethik (pp. 188–197). Stuttgart: Metzler. goods. Journal of Consumer Policy, 34(1), 127–151.
Heidbrink, L., & Schmitt, I. (2011). Das Prinzip der Koos, S. (2012a). The institutional embeddedness of social
Konsumentenverantwortung: Grundlagen, responsibility: A multilevel analysis of smaller firms’
Bedingungen und Umsetzungen verantwortlichen civic engagement in Western Europe. Socio-Economic
Konsums. In L. Heidbrink, I. Schmitt, & B. Ahaus Review, 10(1), 135–162.
(Eds.), Die Verantwortung des Konsumenten. Über Koos, S. (2012b). What drives political consumption in
das Verhältnis von Markt, Moral und Konsum. Frank- Europe? A multi-level analysis on individual
furt am Main: Campus. characteristics, opportunity structures and globaliza-
Held, D., McGrew, A. G., Goldblatt, D., & Perraton, tion. Acta Sociologica, 55(1), 37–57.
J. (1999). Global transformations: Politics, economics Koos, S., & Sachweh, P. (2019). The moral economies of
and culture. Cambridge: Polity Press. market societies: Popular attitudes towards market
Hemingway, C. A., & Maclagan, P. W. (2004). Managers’ competition, redistribution and reciprocity in compara-
personal values as drivers of corporate social responsi- tive perspective. Socio-Economic Review, 17(4),
bility. Journal of Business Ethics, 50(1), 33–44. 793–821.
Hillmann, K.-H. (2007). Moral. In K.-H. Hillmann (Ed.), Korpi, W. (2003). Welfare-state regress in Western
Wörterbuch der Soziologie (pp. 589–590). Stuttgart: Europe: Politics, institutions, globalization, and
Alfred Kröner Verlag. Europeanization. Annual Review of Sociology, 29(1),
Hiß, S. (2006). Warum übernehmen Unternehmen 589–609.
gesellschaftliche Verantwortung? Ein soziologischer Kurucz, E. C., Colbert, B. A., & Wheeler, D. (2008). The
Erklärungsversuch. Campus: Frankfurt am Main. business case for corporate social responsibility. In
Holzer, B., & Sorensen, M. P. (2003). Rethinking A. Crane, A. McWilliams, D. Matten, J. Moon, &
subpolitics: Beyond the ‘Iron Cage’ of modern poli- D. Siegel (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of corporate
tics? Theory, Culture & Society, 20(2), 79–102. social responsibility (pp. 83–112). Oxford: Oxford
Hughner, R. S., McDonagh, P., Prothero, A., Shultz, C. J., University Press.
II, & Stanton, J. (2007). Who are organic food Lim, A., & Tsutsui, K. (2012). Globalization and commit-
consumers? A compilation and review of why people ment in corporate social responsibility: Cross-national
purchase organic food. Journal of Consumer analyses of institutional and political-economy effects.
Behaviour, 6(2–3), 94–110. American Sociological Review, 77(1), 69–98.
Inglehart, R. (1997). Modernization and postmoder- Margolis, H. (1982). Selfishness, altruismn and rational-
nization: Cultural, economic, and political change in ity. A theory of social choice. Chicago: Cambridge
43 societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press. University Press.
Jackson, G., & Apostolakou, A. (2010). Corporate social Matten, D., & Moon, J. (2008). “Implicit” and “Explicit”
responsibility in Western Europe: An institutional mir- CSR: A conceptual framework for a comparative
ror or substitute? Journal of Business Ethics, 94(3), understanding of corporate social responsibility. Acad-
371–394. emy of Management Review, 33(2), 404–424.
Jähnichen, T. (2008). Wirtschaftsethik. Stuttgart:
Kohlhammer.
19 Social Responsibility in the Economy 301

Micheletti, M. (2003). Political virtue and shopping. & J. Brewer (Eds.), Consuming cultures. Global
Individuals, consumerism, and collective action. perspectives (pp. 219–250). Oxford: Berg.
New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Scammell, M. (2000). The internet and civic engagement:
Micheletti, M., Follesdal, A., & Stolle, D. (2004). Politics, The age of the citizen consumer. Political Communi-
products, and markets. Exploring political consumer- cation, 17(4), 351–355.
ism past and present. New Brunswick: Transaction Scherer, A. G., & Palazzo, G. (2008). Globalization and
Publishers. corporate social responsibility. In A. Crane,
Midttun, A., Gautesen, K., & Gjølberg, M. (2006). The A. McWilliams, & D. Matten (Eds.), The Oxford hand-
political economy of CSR in Western Europe. Corpo- book of corporate social responsibility (pp. 413–431).
rate Governance, 6(4), 369–385. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mol, A., Lauber, V., & Liefferink, D. (2000). The volun- Scherer, A. G., & Palazzo, G. (2011). The new political
tary approach to environmental policy. Joint environ- role of business in a globalized world: A review of a
mental policy-making in Europe. Oxford: Oxford new perspective on CSR and its implications for the
University Press. frim, governance, and democracy. Journal of Manage-
Navarro, P. (1988). Why do firms give to charity? Journal ment Studies, 48, 899–931.
of Business Ethics, 61(1), 65–93. Schimank, U. (2005). Die Entscheidungsgesellschaft.
Neilson, L. A., & Paxton, P. (2010). Social capital and Komplexität und Rationalität der Moderne.
political consumerism: A multilevel analysis. Social Wiesbaden: VS Verlag.
Problems, 57(1), 5–24. Schreck, P. (2011). Reviewing the business case for cor-
Norris, P. (2002). Democratic phoenix. Reinventing porate social responsibility: New evidence and analy-
political activism. Cambridge: Cambridge University sis. Journal of Business Ethics, 103(2), 167–188.
Press. Seyfang, G. (2009). The new economics of sustainable
OECD. (2002). Towards sustainable household consump- consumption. Seeds of change. Houndmills: Palgrave
tion? Trends and policies in OECD countries. Paris: Macmillan.
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Shamir, R. (2008). The age of responsibilization: On
Development. market-embedded morality. Economy and Society, 37
Opp, K.-D. (1999). Contending conceptions of the theory (1), 1–19.
of rational action. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 11 Shaw, D. (2005). Modelling consumer decision making in
(2), 171–202. fair trade. In R. Harrison, T. Newholm, & D. Shaw
Opp, K.-D., & Roehl, W. (1990). Repression, micromobi- (Eds.), The ethical consumer (pp. 137–153). London:
lization, and political protest. Social Forces, 69(2), SAGE.
521–547. Siaroff, A. (1999). Corporatism in 24 industrial
Orlitzky, M., Schmidt, F. L., & Rynes, S. L. (2003). democracies: meaning and measurement. European
Corporate social and financial performance: A meta- Journal of Political Research, 36(2), 175–205.
analysis. Organization Studies, 24(3), 403–441. Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational
Ozcaglar-Toulouse, N., Shiu, E., & Shaw, D. (2006). In choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1),
search of fair trade: Ethical consumer decision making 99–118.
in France. International Journal of Consumer Studies, Smelser, N. J., & Swedberg, R. (1994). The sociological
30(5), 502–514. perspective on the economy. In N. J. Smelser &
Piliavin, J. A., & Charng, H.-W. (1990). Altruism: A R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic soci-
review of recent theory and research. Annual Review ology (pp. 3–26). Princeton: Princeton University
of Sociology, 16, 27–65. Press.
Polanyi, K. (1963). The great transformation. The politi- Smelser, N. J., & Swedberg, R. (2005). Introducing eco-
cal and economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon nomic sociology. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg
Hill Beacon Press. (Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology
Rössel, J. (2008). Conditions for the explanatory power (pp. 3–25). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
life styles. European Sociological Review, 24(2), Smith, A. (1974). Der Wohlstand der Nationen. Eine
231–241. Untersuchung seiner Natur und seiner Ursachen.
Ruggie, J. G. (1982). International regimes, transactions, München: Deutscher Taschenbuch Verlag.
and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar eco- Smith, C. N. (2003). Corporate social responsibility:
nomic order. International Organization, 36(2), Whether or how? California Management Review, 45
379–415. (4), 52–76.
Ruggie, J. G. (2004). Reconstituting the global public Sønderskov, K. M. (2009). Different goods, different
domain: Issues, actors, and practices. European Jour- effects: Exploring the effects of generalized social
nal of International Relations, 10(4), 499–531. trust in large-N collective action. Public Choice, 140
Sassatelli, R. (2006). Virtue, responsability and consumer (1), 145–160.
choice. Framing critical consumerism. In F. Trentmann
302 S. Koos

Stehr, N., Henning, C., & Weiler, B. (2006). The Zukin, S., & DiMaggio, P. (1990). Introduction. In
moralization of the markets. New Brunswick: Transac- S. Zukin & P. DiMaggio (Eds.), Structures of capital:
tion Publishers. The social organization of the economy (pp. 1–36).
Stolle, D., Hooghe, M., & Micheletti, M. (2005). Politics Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
in the supermarket: Political consumerism as a form of
political participation. International Political Science
Review, 26(3), 245–269. Sebastian Koos is assistant professor of corporate social
Sunderer, G., & Rössel, J. (2012). Morality or economic responsibility at the department of politics and public
interest? The impact of moral motives and economic administration and member of the cluster of excellence
factors on the purchase of fair traded groceries. Inter- on The Politics of Inequality at the University of
national Journal of Consumer Studies, 36, 244–250. Constance. He served as chair of the Economic Sociology
Swedberg, R. (1998). Max Weber and the idea of eco- Research Network (ESA) from 2015 to 2019.
nomic sociology. Princeton: Princeton University Research topics: Economic sociology, organization
Press. studies, and political sociology, more specifically,
Thøgersen, J. (2010). Country differences in sustainable corporate social responsibility, sustainable and political
consumption: The case of organic food. Journal of consumerism, political economy, social movements, and
Macromarketing, 30(2), 171–185.
social inequality. Recent publications: Koos, Sebastian,
Thøgersen, J., & Ölander, F. (2002). Human values and
and Patrick Sachweh. 2019. The Moral Economies of
the emergence of a sustainable consumption pattern: A
panel study. Journal of Economic Psychology, 23(5), Market Societies: Popular Attitudes Towards Market
605–630. Competition, Redistribution, and Reciprocity in Com-
Uusitalo, O., & Oksanenen, R. (2004). Ethical consumer- parative Perspective. Socio-Economic Review 17/4:
ism: A view from Finland. International Journal of 793–821. Frangi, Lorenzo, Sebastian Koos, and Sinisa
Consumer Studies, 28(3), 214–221. Hadziabdic. 2017. In Unions We Trust! Analysing
Verba, S., Schlozman, K., & Brady, H. E. (1995). Voice Confidence in Unions across Europe. British Journal of
and equality: Civic voluntarism in American politics. Industrial Relations 55/4: 831–58. Koos, Sebastian, Triin
Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Vihalemm, and Margit Keller. 2017. Coping with Crises:
Vogel, D. (2006). The market for virtue: The potential and Consumption and Social Resilience on Markets. Interna-
limits of corporate social responsibility. Washington: tional Journal of Consumer Studies 41/4: 363–70. Koos,
Brookings Institution. Sebastian. 2016. Die organisierte Vermarktlichung der
Weber, M. (1978 [1921]). Economy and society. Moral und die Moralisierung der Märkte. Eine vergle-
Berkeley: University of California Press. [Max Weber ichende Analyse der Fair-Handelsbewegung und der
Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck
Entstehung ethischen Konsums in Europa. Berliner
1921/2.]
Journal für Soziologie 26/2: 171–99. Bartley, Tim,
Whitley, R. (1990). Divergent capitalisms: The social
structuring and change of business systems. Oxford: Sebastian Koos, Hiram Samel, Gustavo Setrini, and Nick
Oxford University Press. Summers. 2015. Looking Behind the Label: Global
Zelizer, V. (1979). Human values and the market: The case Industries and the Conscientious Consumer. Blooming-
of life insurance and death in 19th century America. ton: Indiana University Press.
American Journal of Sociology, 84(3), 591–610.
Index

A E
Action-based explanations, 48, 50–59 Economic and Monetary Union (EMU), 193, 198, 201
Action theories, 52, 53, 58, 79, 80, 292, 293 Economic informality, 159, 161, 162, 173
Advertising, 123, 126, 147, 148, 150–154, 221 Economics of conventions, 64, 66–71, 73
Analytical mechanism approach, 48, 53–59 Economics of quality, 64–66, 71
Austrian school, 7, 21 Economics of singularities, 64–66, 99, 105
Entrepreneurship, v, 8, 14, 15, 64, 173, 174, 177, 180,
B 187, 200, 208–218, 228, 253–261, 265, 274, 280
Banking Union, 192, 198–201 European Union (EU), vii, 172, 191–202, 225
Benjamin, W., 147, 149, 151 Expectations, 28, 35, 40, 41, 49, 79–91, 104, 118, 125,
Bottom-up institutional change, 177, 187 131, 132, 134, 212, 213, 216, 228, 243, 257, 258,
Boudon, R., 55 263–265, 291, 296
Bourdieu, P., 11, 49, 64, 67, 74, 80, 81, 83, 86, 87, 91, 99,
101–103, 105–107, 113, 115 F
Field theory, 102, 103, 105
C Finance, 12, 72, 75, 116, 141, 191, 227, 230, 260
Capitalism, v, vii, 4, 6–9, 14, 15, 21–28, 68, 70, 82–86, 89, Financial services, 191–201
115–118, 125, 126, 137, 147, 151, 193, 205–208, Food supply chains, 221–223, 225
218, 223, 253, 254, 260–262, 264, 265, 271–286,
289, 295, 297, 298 G
China, v, 7, 84, 142, 164–167, 173, 177–185, 226, 247, Globalization, v, 27, 103, 104, 160, 161, 166, 167, 174,
277, 278 191, 231, 240, 289, 290, 294, 295, 297
Classes, 5, 6, 8, 14, 23, 24, 74, 75, 99, 102, 105, 106, 123,
124, 135, 147, 169, 181, 211, 275, 276, 285, 294 H
Classics, v, vi, 3–15, 19–29, 56, 80, 83, 89, 98, 101, 102, Hart, K., 160, 161, 173
107, 114, 133, 149, 205, 229, 254, 278
Coleman, J.S., v, vi, 33–43, 50, 53, 131, 134, 142, 184, I
208, 291 Identities, 50, 51, 59, 82, 90, 105, 115, 123, 164, 167, 182,
Communities, vi, vii, 22, 34, 36, 39, 42, 64, 73, 80, 81, 83, 183, 221, 222, 225, 230–233, 237, 259, 260, 263
85, 87, 133–137, 160, 162, 165, 167, 171, 172, Informal economies, 89, 159–162, 165, 173, 174
179, 180, 182–184, 186, 197, 222, 228, 237–249, Informal markets, vii, 159–163, 165, 166, 168, 171–174
258, 259, 261–263, 265, 276, 290 Information economics, 95, 98, 99, 107
Conception of control, 228, 230, 231, 233 Innovations, vi, vii, 8, 9, 12, 15, 23, 34, 82, 85–86, 90,
Confidence, v, 37, 83, 84, 91, 224, 230, 231 170, 173, 179, 185–187, 194, 222, 229–231, 237,
Consumption, vii, 7, 11, 12, 80, 82–85, 96, 97, 99, 102, 255, 256, 272–274, 276–277, 283, 284, 294
105–108, 116, 166, 172, 180, 223, 224, 276, 279, Institutional innovations, 179, 181, 183–186, 198, 233,
285, 289–291, 294–298 277
Convention of quality, 223, 232 Institutionalism, vi, 49, 63–75, 177, 187
Convention theories, 58, 228 Institutional rules, 134, 139, 140, 180, 184, 227, 254
Institutional transitions, 177, 187
D Institution building, 177–179
Digital money, vii, 237–249 Investments, 41, 42, 49, 69, 82–85, 89, 91, 98, 113, 121,
Digital transformation, 148, 153, 154 138, 150, 154, 165, 168, 170, 173, 177, 178, 181,

# Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021 303


A. Maurer (ed.), Handbook of Economic Sociology for the 21st Century, Handbooks of Sociology and
Social Research, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-61619-9
304 Index

182, 195–197, 201, 237, 239, 246, 260, 262, 264, R


273, 274, 279, 281–284, 297 Ratings, 38, 88, 95, 98, 125, 131, 138–141, 155, 193, 196
Rating systems, 138, 139, 141
K Rational choice approaches, 33, 52, 53, 296
Karpik, L., 49, 64–67, 71–74, 83, 99, 100, 103–105, 107 Reputations, 36, 39, 56, 66, 98, 105, 106, 131–142,
229–231, 261
L Responsibilities, vii, 69, 198, 229, 233, 240, 273, 289–298
Luhmann, N., 101, 118, 123, 124, 150, 275 Review platforms, 140

M S
Markets, v–vii, 8–11, 13, 23–28, 37, 38, 47, 49–51, 58, Sardex money, 238–248
63–75, 82–84, 88, 89, 95–108, 117–123, 125, Schumpeter, J.A., vi, 7–8, 10, 14, 15, 19–22, 25, 27, 85,
132–142, 147–155, 159–174, 177–183, 188, 86, 253–255, 274, 278, 279
192–194, 196–198, 200–201, 205–218, 221–234, Self-organized cooperation, 140
239, 240, 242–244, 246, 247, 253, 260, 264, 265, Self-organized economies, 279
271–277, 279, 281, 282, 285, 289–291, 295–298 Simmel, G., 19, 20, 83, 122, 148, 154, 237, 241, 248
Mechanism, 24, 27, 54–58, 117, 132, 133, 135, 136, 186, Singular products, 99–101, 104, 105, 107
191, 198, 199, 215, 218, 242, 278, 279, 293, 295 Social actions, 20, 51, 56, 68, 79–82, 90, 148–150, 153,
Mechanism approach, vi, 47–59 240, 246, 290, 293
Merton, R.K., vi, 4, 14, 49, 52–54 Social capital, vi, vii, 33–43, 101, 134, 247, 253
Middle range theories, 53, 54 Social change, 53, 55, 82, 84, 89, 90, 148, 151–154, 209,
Migration, 160, 181, 183, 298 218, 222–228, 238, 245, 248, 291, 292, 295
Mises, L., 20, 23, 24 Social factors, v, vi, 47–59
Modernization, 27, 86, 91, 96, 166, 233, 245, 294, 295 Socialization, 12, 39, 208, 212, 216, 217, 221–234
Moralities, 5, 83, 289–291 Social networks, 34, 37, 41–43, 50, 134, 184–186, 293
Sociological explanations, 26, 48, 50, 52, 80
N Sociology of groups, 254
Neoliberalism, 8, 11, 25, 26, 114, 160, 223 States, v, 3–5, 7, 9–11, 24, 27, 40, 56, 69, 70, 72, 83, 86,
Norms, 21, 34, 38–39, 41, 42, 66, 68, 80, 89, 90, 136, 88, 113, 115–122, 124–126, 133, 134, 136, 140,
139–141, 178, 179, 181, 240, 241, 248, 259, 261, 151, 153, 159–162, 164, 166, 167, 171, 173, 174,
263, 290, 291, 293, 296, 298 177–185, 187, 191–201, 207–209, 221, 223, 224,
226, 227, 229, 231–233, 237, 238, 246–248, 255,
O 263, 264, 273, 276–281, 284–286, 289, 293–295,
Online markets, vii, 131–142 298
Organic farming, 226 Sustainability, v, 84, 224, 225, 238, 239, 245, 247, 285,
Organizations, vii, 19–27, 33, 34, 36, 39–41, 43, 64, 69, 289
70, 82, 86, 87, 90, 113, 115, 117, 119–124, 134,
136, 152, 161, 165, 174, 183, 187, 196, 221–223, T
227–229, 231–233, 253, 254, 256–260, 264, 265, Trust, 34–37, 41, 49, 66, 68, 131–142, 149, 184–186, 207,
271–274, 276, 277, 280, 281, 284, 286, 295, 298 208, 217, 224, 238, 239, 242–244, 248, 257, 259,
264, 265, 275, 297
P
Peer-to-peer economies, 174 W
Performativity theory, 64, 71–73 Weber, M., vi, 3, 4, 6–9, 11–14, 19–25, 27, 28, 47, 48, 52,
Popper, K., 52, 58 53, 55, 58, 81, 113, 137, 237, 241, 248, 253–256,
Private actors, vii, 88, 177, 180, 181, 184 272–274, 276, 280, 286, 290, 292
Private firm economy, 180–182, 187 Western societies, 113, 117, 125
Project logics, 264 White, H.C., 49
Wittgenstein, L., 74, 75
Q
Quality turn, 221, 222, 224–226

You might also like