You are on page 1of 12

International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

International Business Review


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ibusrev

Resource curse impacts on the co-evolution of emerging economy


institutions and firm internationalization
Charles Funk a, *, Len J. Treviño b, Juliet Oriaifo c
a
Department of Management and Marketing, College of Business and Management, Northeastern Illinois University, 5500 North Saint Louis Avenue, Chicago, IL, 60625,
United States
b
Department of Management Programs, College of Business, Florida Atlantic University, 777 Glades Road, Fleming Hall (FL-24), Boca Raton, FL, 33431, United States
c
College of Business and Economics, North Carolina A&T State University, 1601 East Market Street, Greensboro, NC, 27411, United States

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: We investigate natural resource “curse” impacts on co-evolutionary relationships between emerging economy
Resource curse institutions and firm internationalization. We discuss how these relationships challenge and extend IB institu­
Institutional theory tional research using three predominant resource curse characteristics (boom and bust cycles with related public
Organizational co-evolution
discourse and “Dutch Disease” with associated manufacturing sector investment crowd-out). These character­
Emerging economies
State-owned enterprises
istics alter regulative, normative and cognitive institutional impacts on state- and privately-owned firm inter­
nationalization during an emerging economy’s resource curse. We develop propositions describing these
processes using oil and gas, manufacturing and service sector examples in several emerging economies. We
discuss our theoretical contributions to the resource curse and international business literatures and outline
future research directions.

1. Introduction literature in the international business (IB) domain is largely limited to


macroeconomic (country-level) research (see Dieleman & Sachs, 2008;
Over the past two decades, economic development scholars have Funk & Treviño, 2017; Narula, 2018; Shapiro, Hobdari, & Oh, 2018).
explored the “resource curse” phenomenon, or the tendency for natural This is unfortunate, as the curse has damaged economic and social in­
resource-abundant countries to underperform on economic and insti­ stitutions in key resource-driven emerging economies (e.g., Brazil and
tutional development indicators (Auty, 1993, Frankel, 2010). This focus Venezuela) and the internationalization of their privately-owned (POEs)
is justified, as 69 percent of people in extreme poverty live in countries and state-owned enterprises (SOEs) (Buckley, Doh, & Benischke, 2017;
fitting the definition of resource-cursed and 80 percent of historically Grøgaard, Rygh, & Benito, 2019; Lyons & Kiernan, 2015). The curse’s
resource-driven economies have per capita incomes below global aver­ negative human welfare impacts and substantial IB research interest in
ages (McKinsey Global Institute, 2013). The human cost of this phe­ emerging economy firm internationalization (George, Schillebeeckx, &
nomenon has been further explored in sociology (Watts, 2001), Liak, 2015; Grøgaard et al., 2019) underscores the importance of
anthropology (Gilberthorpe & Rajak, 2017) and other social science explicating the curse’s impact on the co-evolution of emerging economy
literatures, revealing resource curse effects on human agency and institutions and their firms’ ability to internationalize their operations.
community relations in developing countries (Papyrakis, 2017). These The oil and gas industry remains very important for SOE interna­
effects include exacerbating poverty in communities near resource tionalization. It ranks among the top five global industries with SOE
extraction areas (Hilson, 2012) and stimulating gender inequality and shares and it includes a growing trend of previously domestic emerging
social fragmentation (Macintyre, 2003). Additionally, state/corporate economy SOEs seeking natural resource access in foreign markets
enterprise tensions with indigenous populations in mineral-rich coun­ (Cannizzaro & Weiner, 2018; Grøgaard et al., 2019). These SOEs and
tries have resulted in social dislocation and conflict (Watts, 2001). their home countries are particularly vulnerable to resource curses,
Although understanding the resource curse’s impact on economic leading Ross (2012): 1) to state that “…petroleum-which accounts for
growth and development in resource-abundant economies is highly more than 90 percent of the world’s minerals trade-produces the largest
developed (See Papyrakis, 2017 for a review), the resource curse problems for the greatest number of countries. The resource curse is

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: c-funk@neiu.edu (C. Funk), trevinol@fau.edu (L.J. Treviño), joosuji@ncat.edu (J. Oriaifo).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ibusrev.2020.101753
Received 25 February 2019; Received in revised form 20 August 2020; Accepted 24 September 2020
Available online 23 October 2020
0969-5931/© 2020 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

overwhelmingly an oil curse.” SOEs from non-oil-related manufacturing and/or service industries
Emerging economy governmental institutions usually control access (Krugman, 1987; Murshed, 2004). This environment can also encourage
to oil and gas reserves via their SOEs. Indeed, majority-owned SOEs negative discourse from workers in these industries.
produce oil and gas in 16 of the 23 emerging economies listed in the To address these unanswered questions and build on the growing
International Monetary Fund’s (IMF) 2015 World Economic Outlook interest in the resource curse and emerging economy POE/SOE inter­
(IMF, 2015). This represents approximately three-quarters of emerging nationalization activities (George et al., 2015; Grøgaard et al., 2019) our
economy production and one-third of world production (Natural research objective is to explain how the three resource curse charac­
Resource Governance Institute, 2019; U.S. Energy Information Data­ teristics affect co-evolutionary relationships between resource-cursed
base, 2019), thus limiting the role of foreign MNEs in such production. emerging economy institutions and firm internationalization. We focus
Recent research finds that oil-abundant countries tend to attract less on the natural resource and tradable (other manufacturing and tradable
FDI, such that a one percent increase in the ratio of oil rents to country service) emerging economy sectors because they comprise the most
GDP reduces greenfield projects by approximately three percent (Car­ likely sectors from which emerging economy firms internationalize. We
ril-Caccia, Milgram-Baleix, & Paniagua, 2019). This is also true for our conceptualize our arguments using oil and gas industry examples
study’s emerging economy examples, where SOEs provide over 80 % of because the resource curse literature strongly emphasizes extractive
oil and gas production. Therefore, emerging economy SOEs are natural resources and because significant emerging economy firm
becoming increasingly multinational (Shapiro et al., 2018), seeking internationalization impacts come from oil and gas SOEs.
capability-enhancing opportunities abroad (e.g., technology transfer, Our research extends institutional co-evolution literature in
know-how, better consumer products and enhanced size/reputation emerging economies by theorizing that the three resource curse effects
internationally) that home market POEs and SOEs can use to foster alter emerging economy co-evolutionary relationships between firm
broad economic and social development, innovation and additional firm internationalization and institutions. This notion has received periph­
internationalization (Benito, Rygh, & Lunnan, 2016; Luo & Tung, 2007). eral attention in IB literature, as institutional theory suggests that home
Accordingly, IB research investigating resource curse impacts on country institutions are important in shaping firms’ strategic decisions
co-evolving relationships between emerging economy institutions and (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Kostova, Roth, & Dacin, 2008; Murtha &
their internationalizing SOEs could help develop robust and consistent Lenway, 1994), including international activities and performance
policies for achieving those outcomes. (Buchanan & Marques, 2018; He & Cui, 2012). We also build on Treviño
The IB field has produced significant work covering home market et al.’s (2008) work that conceives institutionalization as a process that
institutional impacts on emerging economy MNE competitiveness in can enhance legitimacy through Scott’s (1995) regulative, normative
domestic and other emerging and developed economies (Geleilate, and cognitive institutional pillars. Finally, our propositions evaluate and
Magnusson, Parente, & Alvarado-Vargas, 2016; Rodrigues & Dieleman, extend IB, economic and sociological ideas by examining the relation­
2018; Treviño, Thomas, & Cullen, 2008; Wright, Filatotchev, Hoskisson, ship between emerging economy institutional quality and the resource
& Peng, 2005). Regarding co-evolution, research has examined curse (Cuervo-Cazurra, Ganitsky, Luo, & Mezias, 2016; Papyrakis,
emerging economy institutional relationships with SOE internationali­ 2017). These effects are unexplored concerning the institutional pro­
zation (Cui & Jiang, 2012; Clegg, Voss, & Tardios, 2018; Estrin, Meyer, cesses and country-specific mechanisms of co-evolution of firm inter­
Nielsen, & Nielsen, 2016; Finchelstein, 2017; Grøgaard et al., 2019; nationalization and institutions in resource-cursed environments.
Liang, Ren, & Sun, 2015; Meyer, Ding, Li, & Zhang, 2014; Rodrigues & Below we review the resource curse literature, its human develop­
Dieleman, 2018; Wang, Hong, Kafouros, & Wright, 2012). However, ment policy implications in emerging economies, and the institutional
there is a dearth of research that explains resource curse effects on impacts of resource curse-related boom/bust cycles, windfall rents and
co-evolving relationships between emerging economy institutions, oil Dutch Disease (e.g., manufacturing crowd-out). We then discuss insti­
and gas SOE internationalization, and the internationalization of POEs tutional co-evolution research, focusing on emerging economy multi­
and SOEs in non-extractive industries. national enterprises (EMNEs) and their home country institutions.
The lack of micro- (firm) and meso- (industry) level resource curse Following, we consider these effects via work on the co-evolution of
research leaves unaddressed three predominant characteristics of emerging economy institutions and SOE internationalization that in­
resource-cursed emerging economies that can profoundly affect re­ corporates Scott’s (1995) regulative, normative and cognitive institu­
lationships between institutions and firm internationalization. The first tional pillars. Our propositions integrate this work to explore how the
two characteristics are commodity price volatility-driven “boom and three resource curse characteristics affect co-evolutionary outcomes for
bust” economic cycles (notably in “extractive” industries, such as oil and emerging economy firm internationalization, given the normative,
gas) for resource-driven emerging economies. If government policy re­ regulative and cognitive processes underpinning each institutional
sponses to these cycles resemble those of non-cursed emerging econo­ pillar. Finally, we describe our work’s contributions, limitations and
mies, curse severity and resulting public discourse can be amplified, future research directions.
debilitating firm internationalization efforts therein. Thus, resource-
driven emerging economies must carefully consider these impacts 2. Literature review
when developing fair and efficient allocation policies for large “wind­
fall” rents across the curse’s ‘boom’ and ‘bust’ stages. Additionally, as 2.1. Economic, institutional and social development impacts of the
natural resources are considered a ‘public good’ owned by the emerging resource curse
economy’s citizens, government mishandling of rents during these two
stages can heighten negative public discourse and actions. Internation­ Auty (1993) coined the term “resource curse” to explain why
alizing SOEs must also consider their public reputation and discourse resource-rich economies often underperform non-resource based coun­
stemming from business activity and from social/managerial ties with tries. Most scholars agree that extractive (e.g., gold, oil, diamonds)
potentially corrupt emerging economy institutions. Public involvement rather than diffuse (e.g., agriculture) resources drive most resource
can range from heightened media monitoring and discourse concerning curses (Bulte, Damania, & Deacon, 2005). While natural resource dis­
windfall collection and allocation to violent actions by groups coveries would seemingly benefit emerging economies, the associated
perceiving unfair windfall distribution or by others that are simply financial “windfalls” are often accompanied by government misman­
opportunistic, unlawful or corrupt. agement, embezzlement, foreign corporate opportunism, crowding-out
Third, the resource-cursed emerging economy’s oil obsession can of investment in and high prices for other goods and services. Severe
result in “Dutch Disease” as local currency inflation and institutional economic downturns can ensue when global commodity price volatility
corruption increase outward FDI (OFDI) ‘crowding-out’ in POEs and turns the resource ‘boom’ into a ‘bust.’ At their worst, resource curses

2
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

leave nations with conflict, corruption, poverty and environmental institutions into regulative (institutions that guide behavior by moni­
problems (Mittelman, 2017). toring and enforcing laws and regulations), normative (institutions that
Most resource curse research is in economics, with early studies guide behavior via social, professional and organizational obligations)
addressing mineral boom crowding-out effects on a country’s economic and cognitive (institutions that guide behavior with “taken-for-granted”
diversification and trade openness. “Dutch Disease” research, for rules and meanings that limit beliefs and actions) pillars provide addi­
example, revealed how price changes following mineral discoveries can tional clarity and suggest how MNEs and home country institutional
lead to inflation and shift factors of production toward natural re­ processes might co-evolve (Scott, 1995; Treviño et al., 2008).
sources. These effects tend to reduce exports and decrease non-resource-
related industry competitiveness (Corden & Neary, 1982). Notably, 2.3. Emerging economy institutions and EMNE internationalization
government efforts to neutralize these impacts with sovereign wealth
funds have mainly been effective in open societies with strong fiscal The co-evolution of relationships between emerging economy in­
institutions and an independent media (Frynas, 2017). In fact, recent stitutions and their EMNEs can create both advantages and disadvantages
IMF testing found that these “special fiscal institutions” do not signifi­ when EMNEs expand to other emerging and/or developed economies.
cantly affect government spending growth during oil boom periods or For example, many EMNEs become accustomed to home country insti­
the correlation between such spending and oil revenues (Ossowski, tutional contexts with limited capital markets, missing institutions, poor
Villafuerte, Medas, & Thomas, 2008). Other studies demonstrated a regulatory climates, rigid labor markets, and high corruption. When
negative relationship between mineral resource abundance and internationalizing, EMNES adapt to these constraints using non-market
long-term economic growth, and crowding-out effects from negative resources (e.g. networks, business group affiliations and state interven­
links between mineral resources and trade openness, physical capital tionism) and developing more flexible management styles (Cuervo-Ca­
investments, bureaucratic efficiency and inflation (Papyrakis, 2017). zurra et al., 2016; Gaur, Kumar, & Singh, 2014). These co-evolutionary
Finally, macroeconomic studies relate mineral resource abundance to capabilities can lower EMNE transaction costs and confer a transferable
debt overhang (e.g., using reserves as international debt collateral-see competitive advantage when entering other emerging economies with
Manzano & Rigobon, 2001) and international commodity price vola­ similarly weak institutions (Wright et al., 2005).
tility, thus causing macroeconomic fluctuations and foreign investment For developed economy competitiveness, however, home countries
uncertainty (Van Der Ploeg & Poelhekke, 2009). without robust and innovative infrastructures (e.g., educational, R&D
The resource curse literature also discusses the negative human investment/tax and legal) can restrict their EMNEs’ technology and
development and institutional impacts that governments of mineral-rich innovation capabilities versus rival MNEs (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2016;
nations perpetuate when lacking policies to protect non-mineral related Luo & Tung, 2007). For example, an EMNE’s co-evolutionary response
industries (Auty, 1993). Mineral resources can weaken pro-development of using business groups to overcome the lack of effective home country
institutions by encouraging rent-seeking and corruption, undermining legal institutions could hinder developed economy operations, where
democracy (e.g., enabling authoritarian regimes to remain in power via intellectual property laws may restrict firm cooperation/collusion.
oppression or income redistribution), encouraging violent conflict, and EMNEs may also struggle to meet strict governance requirements for
diminishing human development (e.g. education-related) and sustain­ transparency, ownership, and board functioning that are non-existent
ability indicators (Bulte et al., 2005; Papyrakis, 2017; Ross, 2001). domestically (Wright et al., 2005).
Alternatively, recent studies increasingly consider how “good” in­ Intrusive home governments might also assert control over EMNEs’
stitutions can turn a curse into a ‘blessing’ by supporting secure property developed market activities. Rodrigues & Dieleman’s (2018) Brazilian
rights and low corruption, encouraging equitable accrued rent distri­ extractive sector study found that state hybrid EMNEs may accelerate
bution, improving resource windfall management and stimulating eco­ escape internationalization (Witt & Lewin, 2007) during industry boom
nomic diversification and investment (El Anshasy & Katsaiti, 2013; periods to counter governmental attempts to reduce their autonomy.
Ossowski et al., 2008; Sarmidi, Law, & Jafari, 2014). Finally, foreign Conversely, these firms may be forced to pursue ‘hesitant de-in­
multinationals and even small local operators performing resource ternationalization’ during bust periods, curtailing international opera­
extraction in developing countries can exacerbate resource curses via tions in favor of domestic priorities.
environmental damage, social disruption and reduced positive spillovers Despite these challenges, EMNEs have successfully pursued co-
(Gilberthorpe & Banks, 2012; Hilson & Laing, 2017). evolving relationships with developed economies by reverse-
innovating domestic products for developed economy consumers
2.2. Institutional co-evolution in emerging economies (Govindarajan & Ramamurti, 2011), establishing global supply chain
partnerships with developed country MNEs (Luo & Tung, 2007) and/or
Co-evolutionary theory has been used to explain the impact of acquiring technologically sophisticated developed economy firms to
environmental selection and managerial adaptation in organization- absorb tacit knowledge (Witt & Lewin, 2007).
environment relationships (Baum & Singh, 1994; Lewin & Volberda, Even institutional reforms at home may not always translate to
1999). McKelvey (2002) delineated five necessary and sufficient con­ performance improvements abroad, as EMNEs may incur restructuring
ditions for organizational co-evolution to occur: 1) the existence of costs when incorporating such reforms (Hoskisson, Johnson, Tihanyi, &
‘heterogeneous agents’, such as firms and government institutional ac­ White, 2005). Geleilate et al. (2016) found that enhanced domestic
tors; 2) firm capabilities for adaptation and learning; 3) firm capabilities capital markets and property rights enforcement did not significantly
for interaction and mutual influence; 4) the presence of a higher-level improve EMNE international performance. Likewise, improved home
constraint, the adaptation to which motivates the co-evolutionary pro­ labor market flexibility impaired EMNEs’ multinationality-performance
cess; and 5) the presence of an initiating event. Our work views resource relationship, perhaps due to increased competition for talent and diffi­
curse stages as initiating events that impact how emerging economy culties in transferring human resource knowledge abroad. Improved
institutions and emerging economy firm internationalization co-evolves. home corruption controls can also reduce an EMNE’s competitive
Co-evolutionary concepts can also describe how MNE-institutional advantage when facing corruption in other emerging economies
relationships result in shared social construction of home country (Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008).
institutional environments (Cantwell, Dunning, & Lundan, 2010; Kos­
tova et al., 2008). While a country’s institutional environments pro­ 2.4. Emerging economy institutions and SOE internationalization
foundly affect MNE structures and technologies, MNEs contribute to
generating new ‘rules of the game’ (North, 1990) by influencing those Internationalizing SOEs face unique home and host country pres­
same institutions. Within this framework, the organization of sures and management objectives when compared to POEs

3
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

(Cuervo-Cazurra, Inkpen, Musacchio, & Ramaswamy, 2014; George SOE behavior will favor domestic rent-seeking strategies because of the
et al., 2015; Grøgaard et al., 2019). Institutional co-evolution cogently controlling presence of political/government employees within the
explains this literature, as emerging economy SOEs must respond to SOE’s management structure. When these institutional controls are
regulative, normative and cognitive institutional legitimacy pressures strong, the discretion of independent, professional managers will be
from both their home and host countries (DiMaggio & Powell, 1991). more in evidence, and SOEs will tend to act similarly to POEs by
Regarding home country regulatory institutions, SOEs must conform to exploiting their firm- and country-specific advantages through interna­
state-created laws and rules regarding their investment and activities tionalization (Estrin et al., 2016).
abroad. Normative institutional legitimacy at home may mean fulfilling
obligations to home government political ideologies or strategies, as 3. Propositions
these institutions may define and regulate “appropriate” actions for
societal members (Rodrigues & Dieleman, 2018; Scott, 1995; Treviño We utilize Scott’s (1995) institutional pillars as the theoretical
et al., 2008). Cognitive institutional legitimacy at home may mean foundation for our propositions. These pillars describe a country’s
successfully navigating the shared perceptions and expectations of institutional profile and provide a framework for human interaction via
various home constituencies (in government and in the general public) formal and informal behavioral constraints. These implicit “rules of the
concerning the SOE’s internationalization objectives. These could game” in a country’s institutional mosaic affect firm transaction costs in
include projecting foreign political influence/power, obtaining needed the country and incentivize or dis-incentivize the range of strategies
resources, or expanding markets to enhance domestic wealth (Cuer­ available (North, 1990; Treviño et al., 2008). Accordingly, we consider
vo-Cazurra et al., 2014; Treviño et al., 2008; Wang et al., 2012). how these institutions co-evolve with firm internationalization strate­
For the host country, complying with local rules and regulations is gies in resource-cursed emerging economy environments (Cuervo-Ca­
important to maintain regulative institutional legitimacy. Maintaining zurra & Genc, 2008; Luo & Wang, 2012).
normative institutional legitimacy, however, may be more difficult. In Utilizing Treviño et al. (2008), we characterize the institutional
particular, advanced economy host countries may be more culturally “rules of the game” (North, 1990) as specific normative, regulative and
distant and their operational norms may involve adhering to both local cognitive institutional processes that co-evolve with firm internation­
rules and those of non-governmental organizations, such as the World alization initiatives in resource-cursed emerging economies. All three of
Bank and the IMF. Cognitively, host country governments and public a nation’s institutional pillars can influence outward FDI through these
institutions may see foreign SOEs as attempting to exercise economic processes, sequentially or simultaneously, though not necessarily
control over and possibly threaten the security interests of the host equally. We use the resource curse and emerging economy interna­
country (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014; Meyer et al., 2014). tionalization literatures (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2016; Frankel, 2010;
SOEs can co-evolve with these institutions through various adaptive Papyrakis, 2017) to consider how institutional process quality in­
actions. For example, SOEs could pursue joint ownership with host fluences curse-related impacts on co-evolutionary institution/firm
country firms if strong regulatory restrictions on inward and outward internationalization relationships. We define institutional process
FDI exist in home and host countries. Such structures can mitigate quality as the extent to which normative, regulative and cognitive
institutional costs at home and attain institutional legitimacy abroad institutional policies and actions supporting co-evolution with firm
(Cui & Jiang, 2012). internationalization can attenuate or eliminate the resource curse’s
Normatively, economic and institutional pressures can force SOEs to negative impacts within a nation. For example, economics research
alter their internationalization strategies in response to home country supports industry sector diversification within a nation to limit the
obligations. For example, Brazilian mining firm Vale de- curse’s negative effects (reduced employment, GDP, etc.) on that nation
internationalized in response to declining industry performance, (Frankel, 2010). Hence, higher quality normative institutional processes
increasing nationalist political ideology at home and pressure to support include those supporting such diversification (e.g., government inter­
domestic governmental priorities (Liang et al., 2015; Rodrigues & national investment support in diverse domestic industry sectors
Dieleman, 2018). Alternatively, emerging economy SOE responses to abroad). These processes can be unique to the existing economic and
host country normative pressures may range from isomorphic, via social environments during a nation’s resource curse and should be
conforming to local and international standards-setting organizations measureable via the extent of the curse’s effect on a nation’s broader
(Cuervo-Cazurra, 2015), to strategic, via OFDI into weak institutional economic measures.
environments that the SOE is better-equipped to handle (Clegg et al., For normative and regulative institutional pillars, we apply well-
2018; Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014). known institutional processes from emerging economy internationali­
Cognitively, co-evolutionary actions by emerging economy SOEs zation literature to describe institution/firm co-evolution in a resource-
attempt to balance home country beliefs that internationalization will cursed environment. Hence, normative co-evolutionary institutional
create economic and national/political benefits with host country con­ processes involve firm alignment with government internationalization
cerns regarding economic and political exploitation (Grøgaard et al., ideology and/or political strategy (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014; Rodri­
2019; Meyer et al., 2014). For example, resource-seeking SOEs may opt gues & Dieleman, 2018; Wang et al., 2012) and regulative
for acquisition entry modes to enhance their home country’s stock of co-evolutionary institutional processes involve firm alignment with
valuable technology and knowledge (Clegg et al., 2018). However, host regulatory internationalization restriction/restraint and/or government
country stakeholders may view this action as threatening national investment/disinvestment. For the cognitive institutional pillar, we take
competitiveness and security and therefore respond with regulation and an interdisciplinary approach by integrating social/anthropological
restrictions (Sauvant, 2010). A co-evolutionary response to such pres­ institutional concepts concerning public discourse during a resource
sures might be a partial acquisition that allows the SOE to maintain a curse (Gilberthorpe & Rajak, 2017) with cognitive concepts in the
low profile, avoid conflicts with local stakeholders, and leverage the emerging economy firm internationalization literature (Wang et al.,
legitimacy of a local co-owner (Cui & Jiang, 2012; Meyer et al., 2014). 2012). Hence, cognitive co-evolutionary institutional processes involve
SOEs can experience faster internationalization and greater diversi­ firm alignment with positive/negative public internationalization
fication when their home countries undertake more direct (e.g., sub­ discourse. We use several specific emerging economy examples to
sidies, regulatory support, long-term loans) vs. indirect (e.g., market and illustrate the wide variation in how these institutional processes of our
private investor-related) support (Finchelstein, 2017). Concomitantly, theoretical model are operationalized. Finally, Table 1 summarizes
high levels of state ownership and institutional instability at home tend institutional process quality’s moderating role in our relationships, and
to reduce the SOE’s propensity for developed market expansion. When Fig. 1 identifies key mechanisms driving co-evolutionary relationships
normative, regulative and corporate governance institutions are weak, of emerging economy institutions and firm internationalization.

4
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

3.1. Resource curse boom stage effects even public discourse by appealing to their normative ideologies of
enhanced foreign influence and international status via OFDI initiatives.
In the resource curse boom stage, normative institutional processes, Brazil’s SOE Petrobras provides an example of how such co-optation
in the form of government ideologies and political strategies, drive the fosters state-driven corruption. After a significant 2007 oil discovery,
creation of regulative policies and investment rules. These processes the company ostensibly sought to fulfill normative ideological objectives
then co-evolve with cognitive institutional processes concerning public of domestic oil windfall retention and enhanced international image by
discourse, sentiments and actions. Lastly, the three pillars’ institutional purchasing a refinery in Pasadena, Texas. This purchase was found to be
processes impact SOE and/or POE internationalization initiatives. part of a multi-billion-dollar political bribery scheme pursued by the
For emerging economies with weak and/or corrupt normative and company even though 70 % of its board members (including its chair­
regulative institutions, a large economic windfall from a resource curse person) were appointed by the Brazilian government (Cahen, 2015).
boom stage can drive processes that worsen curse severity by weakening These emerging economy examples show that normative institu­
the rule of law and fostering bureaucratic mismanagement and cor­ tional processes supporting ideologies of windfall mismanagement or
ruption. The windfall’s magnitude also affects cognitive institutional political corruption can limit firm internationalization benefits. Like­
processes, raising public expectations and discourse that the windfall wise, normative institutional processes supporting careful resource
will fund needed infrastructure projects and public wage enhancement management can enhance internationalization benefits.
(Gilberthorpe & Rajak, 2017). For emerging economies with strong in­
Proposition 1a. Normative institutional process quality positively in­
stitutions, however, positive normative and regulative institutional
fluences how resource curse financial windfalls affect the co-evolution of
processes can transform cognitive discourse and blunt the windfall’s
emerging economy normative institutions and firm internationalization.
potential negative effects.
3.1.2. Regulative institutional processes
3.1.1. Normative institutional processes
As with the normative pillar, institutional process quality impacts
In an emerging economy, a resource curse boom stage is not
regulative institutional co-evolution with SOE and/or POE internation­
conducive to ‘escape’ internationalization for SOEs or POEs because it
alization during a resource curse. These processes should translate
increases institutional focus on local resource extraction and revenue
normative ideologies into concrete firm internationalization directives,
generation that greatly benefits the country (Frankel, 2010; Rodrigues &
but they could also be distorted by political strategy and/or corruption.
Dieleman, 2018). With normative institutional processes supporting
While the boom stage financial windfall usually supports less regulative
windfall use that benefits the emerging economy’s overall social and
restriction and additional foreign investment, the windfall’s impact on
economic structure, SOE and/or POE internationalization aligned with
corrupt or inept institutional actors can alter such investment support.
this ideology is encouraged. When normative institutional processes are
Examples from Indonesia, Venezuela and Malaysia are instructive in this
predominantly focused on garnering oil windfall revenues for public
instance.
expenditure, SOE and POE internationalization is either non-existent or
Indonesia’s state-owned oil company, Pertamina, initially followed a
limited to foreign investments that maximize domestic production.
normative ideology of domestic diversification via regulative actions of
Malaysia and Mexico’s internationalization actions exemplify this
spending oil boom revenues and short term foreign debt on energy and
phenomenon.
non-energy related domestic industries. Much of its international in­
Malaysia’s normative government ideology emphasized the finite
vestment focused on technology-based joint ventures to support do­
nature of the country’s oil reserves. Therefore, regulative actions sup­
mestic oil production. These large investments ended abruptly when
ported the internationalization of their state-owned oil company, Pet­
Pertamina defaulted on its international debt after a 1970’s ‘oil price
ronas, to establish a Southeast Asian presence for domestic supply needs.
shock.’ The Suharto government that subsequently controlled the
With relatively well-established manufacturing OFDI, oil windfalls were
company followed a more conservative normative ideology regarding
used to boost government-linked service sector (mostly financial)
oil windfalls and foreign investment, taking regulative actions to reduce
internationalization to approximately 56 % of national OFDI. Although
oil revenue dependence and limit foreign energy and manufacturing
the resource curse is not completely neutralized (see Doraiswami, 2015),
investment. By the 2000’s, only two privately-owned business groups
these normative and regulative institutional internationalization pro­
(Salim and Lippo) could be considered large emerging economy MNEs in
cesses can also further domestic development in education, agriculture
Indonesia (Carney & Dieleman, 2011), with Pertamina just beginning a
and manufacturing (Lee, Lee, & Yeo, 2017).
gradual internationalization.
Mexico’s contrasting normative ideology considered their 100 %
Indonesia’s normative and regulative “hesitant internationalization”
state-owned oil company, Pemex, predominantly a tax revenue gener­
strategy (Rodrigues & Dieleman, 2018) contrasts Venezuela’s, where oil
ator for public expenditures. Accordingly, restrictive regulative institu­
windfall revenues of SOE PDVSA have been used to support a normative
tional processes effectively limited the company’s strategic focus to
political strategy of funding social programs to keep socialist regimes in
domestic production. With infrequent infrastructure renewal and mini­
power (Movchan, Zotin, & Grigoryev, 2017). Like Mexico, PDVSA pur­
mum technology investments, early internationalization processes
sued strong domestic production with little POE internationalization
established alliances that provided additional knowledge and capabil­
investment. Unlike Mexico, however, PDVSA purchased 23 refineries in
ities for domestic production (Ramirez-Cendrero & Paz, 2017). This
eight countries, co-evolving with a government regulative policy of
rendered post-boom stage social and economic development
securing markets for Venezuelan oil (Corrales, Hernandez, & Salgado,
unsustainable.
2020) and possibly for evading Venezuelan taxes (Lopez-Morales,
Some emerging economy SOEs can increase their influence on
Gonzalez-Barragan, Maldonado de Luna, Velez De-Alba, & Muller-Jasso,
normative ideology and regulative actions in corrupt domestic envi­
2017). Consistent government intervention in company business prac­
ronments by specializing in unproductive processes favoring ‘grabber-
tices also drove poor management hires and insufficient investment to
friendly institutions’ (Mehlum, Moene, & Torvik, 2006). An SOE’s ties
upgrade technological capabilities, giving PDVSA the dubious distinc­
with local institutions and/or state actors can therefore be an important
tion of experiencing declining production during a boom period (Corrales
lobbying capability for internationalization investments. These ties
et al., 2020). With the boom ended, PDVSA must now follow regulative
might be obtained via cronyism (Dieleman & Sachs, 2008) or by poli­
directives to withdraw from foreign operations (Ludeña, 2016).
ticians serving on the SOEs board of directors and/or appointing com­
As stated earlier, Malaysia achieved impressive results from Petro­
pany management (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014). As resource-cursed
na’s internationalization and in using the company’s windfall revenues
countries tend to use oil booms to increase spending on investment
to diversify and internationalize non-oil manufacturing and services
projects (Frankel, 2010), SOE managers can co-opt political actors and

5
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

(Lee et al., 2017). While completing these normative ideological goals oil windfall rents in an adverse economic environment. A “procyclical”
helped the country avoid a resource curse, the government’s pursuit of fiscal policy encourages windfall spending on wages for an increasing
ethnic inequality, evident in the regulative actions that fostered inter­ government worker population and/or capital spending on large infra­
national success of government-linked banking organizations (Dor­ structure projects. Foreign debt may also be used to amplify windfall
aiswami, 2015), remains a cognitive institutional concern and is revenues. Additionally, corrupt governments may use windfall rents to
discussed below. prolong their power, reduce dissent and limit democracy calls by
increasing military/internal security expenditures, reducing taxes and
Proposition 1b. Regulative institutional process quality positively in­
increasing public goods spending (i.e. rentier effects-see Ross, 2001).
fluences how resource curse financial windfalls affect the co-evolution of
Commodity price volatility, possibly related to a broader economic
emerging economy regulative institutions and firm internationalization.
downturn, reverses this trend and can cause severe political, economic
and social problems. Bust stage normative and regulative institutional
3.1.3. Cognitive institutional processes
process issues also impact cognitive institutions, as a surge in negative
The cognitive institutional pillar in a country reflects widely shared
public discourse further constrains government action (Frankel, 2010).
social knowledge and cognitive structures (schemas, frames and infer­
In short, weak institutions and/or institutional voids that are common to
ential sets) that influence how people understand, categorize and
emerging economies can exacerbate a resource curse bust stage, while
interpret a particular phenomenon (Kostova, 1997). These cognitive
effective governance can aid nations in avoiding the more severe bust
structures are issue- and/or domain-specific, guiding shared beliefs and
stage effects.
actions toward what is typical or taken-for-granted in a country (Treviño
et al., 2008). Scott (1995) believed that cognitive institutions could lead
3.2.1. Normative and regulative institutional processes
to isomorphism for institutional actors via processes that encourage the
Normative and regulative institutional processes for firm interna­
imitation of activities that have strong cultural support.
tionalization developed in the curse’s boom stage are challenged in the
Oil abundance in many emerging economies provides a domain
bust stage. Commodity price declines can curtail or even reverse inter­
where cognitive structures characterizing the resource curse paradigm
nationalization expenditures based on the emerging economy’s oil
can drive a “discourse of development” imposing particular normative
revenue dependence and its pursuit of boom stage revenue stabilization
values. Resource investments can create a dominant popular discourse
activities via budget actions, conservative debt policies, and/or the
of progress, growth and economic sovereignty, leading to jobs, mobility,
establishment of a reserve fund (Usui, 1997). On the one hand, an ide­
entrepreneurial opportunity and patronage connections. These expec­
ology supporting the international influence of ‘national champion’ type
tations are based on an environment of good governance, transparency
SOEs may be slowed or completely reversed by home government
and possibly liberalization or privatization, transformations that may be
intervention or disinvestment (Ludeña, 2016). As in the boom stage,
unrealistic given the nature and history of political control in the
state and firm corruption also strongly impact internationalization ide­
country. Thus, when these development and modernization expecta­
ologies and strategies.
tions encounter weak institutions with wealth mismanagement,
On the other hand, internationalization ideologies supporting non-
inequality and lost opportunity, public resentment, hostility and conflict
oil manufacturing and service sector SOEs and POEs may enjoy over­
may obtain (Gilberthorpe & Rajak, 2017).
seas investment stability (Corrales et al., 2020) rather than “escape”
Therefore, public evaluation and support of using resource curse
internationalization from weak institutions (Witt & Lewin, 2007). For
financial windfalls for firm internationalization is significantly influ­
instance, Indonesia conservatively used boom stage oil revenues for
enced by normative ideological and regulative processes regarding such
manufacturing and service sector diversification and excess oil revenue
internationalization. For example, Pertamina’s default on its interna­
deposits, which later helped to avoid severe economic problems and
tional debt garnered cognitive Indonesian public support for a conser­
maintain gradual firm internationalization during commodity price
vative internationalization ideology that applied mainly to large,
downturns (Usui, 1997). In contrast, large international oil refining in­
government-connected service industry firms. In Mexico, a normative
vestments by Venezuela’s PDVSA had to later be reversed to support
ideology regulating Pemex as the government’s revenue supplier
domestic social programs during commodity price market reductions
resulted in cognitive public suspicion of long-term international alli­
(Corrales et al., 2020; Ludeña, 2016). Even Brazil, with strong ‘national
ances or investments that allocate funds away from government coffers
champion’ ideologies and sector diversification strategies, had to reduce
(Ramirez-Cendrero & Paz, 2017). Venezuela’s cognitive public senti­
international investments during a mid-2010’s commodity bust because
ment is similar for PDVSA, although foreign investment is welcomed if it
of oil windfall revenue mismanagement and Petrobras corruption issues
benefits domestic production (Corrales et al., 2020). Lastly, the excep­
(Lenton, 2017). In short, normative and regulative institutional process
tionalism ideology surrounding Brazil and Malaysia’s ‘national cham­
quality regarding boom stage financial windfalls strongly impact the
pions’ Petrobras and Petronas, respectively, initially garnered
co-evolutionary processes of those same institutions and firm interna­
substantial positive cognitive public discourse and drove manufacturing
tionalization during the bust stage.
industry international investments. As discussed below, however, these
positive sentiments were later changed due to ethnic inequalities in Proposition 2a. Boom stage normative and regulative institutional process
Malaysia and corruption in Brazil (Cahen, 2015; Doraiswami, 2015; quality positively influences how resource curse-related economic downturns
Inkpen, 2016). Overall, emerging economy cognitive institutions tend to affect the co-evolution of emerging economy normative institutions and firm
support firm internationalization investments that further normative internationalization.
ideologies of foreign influence and/or enhanced domestic benefits (such
Proposition 2b. Boom stage normative and regulative institutional pro­
as industry diversification or additional domestic revenue).
cess quality positively influences how resource curse-related economic
Proposition 1c. Normative and regulative institutional process quality downturns affect the co-evolution of emerging economy regulative institutions
positively influence how resource curse financial windfalls affect the co- and firm internationalization.
evolution of emerging economy cognitive institutions and firm
internationalization. 3.2.2. Cognitive institutional processes
The development discourse of the resource curse assumes a type of
3.2. Resource curse bust stage effects exceptionalism of resource abundant states defined by their mineral
wealth. This exceptionalism translates into a common “expectation of
The resource curse bust stage results mainly from normative and modernity” in the resource-cursed country’s political structures, eco­
regulative institutional processes that misuse or mismanage boom stage nomic relations, and environmental landscape. When the resource boom

6
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

turns into a bust, this common narrative is “turned to decades of betrayal Proposition 2c. Boom stage normative, regulative and cognitive institu­
and disappointment” (Gilberthorpe & Rajak, 2017: 193). With reduced tional process quality positively influences how resource curse-related eco­
state institutional support and strong negative public discourse, the nomic downturns affect the co-evolution of emerging economy cognitive
government’s normative obligations tend to focus on domestic prior­ institutions and firm internationalization.
ities. Accordingly, an SOE’s close ties with the political regime constrain
its internationalization expansion during the resource curse bust stage 3.3. Dutch Disease and tradable industry sector effects
(Marano, Tashman, & Kostova, 2017; Transparency International,
2011). This includes SOE subsidiaries in foreign markets, which may be A number of resource-rich countries have avoided the resource curse
required to curtail activities to support domestic economic objectives by investing in location advantages that nurture inter-industry linkages
(Rodrigues & Dieleman, 2018). Interestingly, negative public discourse and avoid over-specialization in oil assets and capabilities. These link­
surrounding the resource curse seems to arise more from issues of ages can potentially support multiple users across industry sectors and/
resource equity and allocation than from whether or not a country is or create horizontal effects that initiate new value chains in non-
perceived as quantitatively “beating” the curse. This seems to be extractive sectors (Narula, 2018).
particularly true for emerging economies. As our previous country examples illustrate, however, many
The development of negative discourse during a resource curse is emerging economies, have not seen their extractive sectors lead eco­
evident in Venezuela and Brazil. In Venezuela, normative and regulative nomic development. The macroeconomic effects of Dutch Disease,
institutional processes surrounding oil windfall misuse/mismanagement combined with weak domestic firms, weak institutions and poor location
caused bust stage economic and social problems, driving negative public advantages, cause extractive sector firms to operate in enclaves with
discourse that in turn led to reduced firm internationalization. limited local linkages (Narula, 2018). Absent these linkages, Dutch
In Brazil, an economic windfall from commodity sales to China led to Disease and its associated “crowding out” effects can foster a lack of
short-sighted policies and increased government spending in anticipa­ ‘learning by doing’ (i.e. industry spillover) benefits and national
tion of future revenues. Leaders deferred addressing a weak political manufacturing base erosion during resource booms. This can also result
system and a bureaucracy supporting interventionist state capitalism, in hysteresis, an irreversible loss of sector competitiveness in the
leading to corruption and diminished business innovation (Lyons & country, even when economic conditions normalize after a boom and
Kiernan, 2015). However, China’s recent economic problems drove a bust cycle subsides (Krugman, 1987; Murshed, 2004). Hysteresis can
shrinking Brazilian economy and reductions or outright state interven­ linger across both stages of the resource curse, blunting emerging
tion in foreign investments. This resource curse boom and bust cycle economy manufacturing capabilities at home while imposing economic
mirrored a similar experience from the 1980s, causing the country’s hardship on the poorest members of society. For example, Dutch Disease
media and public to revive an old adage: “‘Brazil is the country of the shrunk the agricultural and manufacturing sectors of Mexico and
future…and always will be’” (Smith, Valle, & Schmidt, 2015). In short, Venezuela (Peck & Chayes, 2015; Usui, 1997). Below we use these and
the failure of formal, regulative institutions (i.e. governments) to create two other emerging economy examples to explore how institutional
economic progress led to the rise of informal, cognitive institutions that process quality influences the impact of curse-related Dutch Disease on
created alternative scripts and schema to describe the state of affairs. co-evolving relationships between normative, regulative and cognitive
Over time, these scripts became “taken-for-granted” public beliefs about institutional processes and firm internationalization.
reality (Berger & Luckman, 1966; Funk & Treviño, 2017).
In sharp contrast are examples of negative cognitive institutional 3.3.1. Normative and regulative institutional processes
processes in Indonesia, Malaysia, Colombia and Argentina, countries Some emerging economies use consistent and direct state regulative
that are generally considered to have “beaten” the resource curse. institutional processes supporting a normative ideology of rapid inter­
Indonesia beat the curse with a conservative fiscal program and limited nationalization and sector diversification for their national champion
international investments. However, the privately-owned Salim Group, firms and industries. Other countries use less interventionist regulative
one of the country’s few major emerging multinationals, encountered processes in specific regions and sectors to influence market conditions
mob violence due to its normatively-driven crony relationship with the and allow more gradual firm internationalization (Finchelstein, 2017).
Suharto regime (Dieleman & Sachs, 2008). Malaysia used Petronas’ oil Resource curse-driven Dutch Disease can distort and hinder these
windfall revenues to fund manufacturing and services sector diversifi­ co-evolutionary processes. For example, Mexico’s normative ideologies
cation and internationalization. Yet, these regulative actions allegedly and regulative processes supported maintaining the flow of oil revenues
followed a normative political ideology of favoring the country’s ruling to finance public projects and personnel while eschewing foreign and
(government-linked) and dominant ethnic group (Doraiswami, 2015). tradable sector investments (Usui, 1997). These curse-related institu­
Finally, Colombia and Argentina are both seen as neutralizing the curse tional processes resulted in Dutch Disease because both state- and
via partially privatizing their oil industries for international investment. market-driven forms of internationalization were neglected. Only later
This normative ideology has caused ongoing armed conflict in Colombia (partly due to the establishment of the North American Free Trade
among various groups who believe they have a claim to oil wealth Agreement) did large, privately owned multinationals like Cemex and
(Dunning & Wirpsa, 2004). In Argentina, a return to normative American Movil venture abroad (Zavaleta-Vazquez & Wise-Lozano,
nationalistic ideas led to the partial ‘re-nationalization’ of the 2016).
state-owned oil company, YPF (Waterworth & Bradshaw, 2018), which Venezuela, while still focused on domestic oil revenue, allows in­
in turn led to lower company performance. While beyond the scope of ternational investments that support those revenues and the incumbent
our research, these cases legitimize the idea that social, anthropological socialist government. Like Mexico, economic diversification at home
and psychological “markers” should complement political and economic and via internationalization has largely been ignored (Rosales & San­
measures to determine when a country experiences a resource curse chez, 2018). Hence, both Mexican and Venezuelan normative and
(Gilberthorpe & Rajak, 2017). Regarding our research, boom stage regulative institutional processes have driven falling national produc­
normative and regulative institutional processes clearly drive the tivity in extractive and tradable sectors.
development of cognitive institutional structures and processes in Indonesia’s government, in contrast, followed a “balanced budget”
resource-cursed emerging economies. When these cognitive processes normative policy, utilizing their oil windfall for government deposits
impact firm internationalization activities, a co-evolutionary relation­ and repaying foreign debt. Any government spending favored a
ship among the three institutional processes and firm internationaliza­ normative strategy of agricultural and non-oil industry development
tion can develop. while enhancing private, tradable sector growth. OFDI was also con­
servative, as the internationalization activities of Pertamina were

7
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

restricted and only the largest tradable sector business groups (Salim diversification and a threat of Dutch Disease where none previously
and Lippo) were encouraged (Lecraw, 1993). This combined broad existed (Doraiswami, 2015; Lee et al., 2017; World Bank, 2011). Hence,
sector diversification and ‘hands-off’ approach toward non-oil sector poorly conceived and enacted regulative and normative institutional
internationalization allowed Indonesia to avoid the Dutch Disease. processes regarding Dutch Disease can alter cognitive structures of
Brazil’s aeronautical industry national champion, Embraer, illus­ public discourse and sentiment. Overall, the above-described cognitive
trates how curse-related Dutch Disease can alter a normative and processes co-evolve firm internationalization and future institutional
regulative institutional environment of direct support. Along with processes in each of the three pillars.
regulative institutional processes, such as subsidies and tax incentives
Proposition 3c. Institutional process quality dynamism positively in­
(Schneider & Ioris, 2018), the state pursued a normative ideology of
fluences how resource curse-related Dutch Disease affects the co-evolution of
international influence by forming a national development bank
emerging economy cognitive institutions and firm internationalization.
(BNDES) to fund firm internationalization. However, two resource curse
boom/bust cycles occurred that shifted normative ideology and regu­
lative processes away from international influence and sector diversifi­ 3.4. Co-evolution process illustration
cation in favor of domestic public spending. The first resource curse in
the 1980s sharply reduced state support, and state control of Embraer In Table 1 below we summarize institutional process quality’s role in
fell to 6.8 %. The second resource curse that followed the world financial relationships between resource curse boom, bust and Dutch Disease
crisis in the early 2010s severely constrained government support of stage effects and the co-evolution of emerging economy institutions and
R&D, subsidies, and export incentives. This resulted in Embraer’s firm internationalization. As the Table and our propositions describe,
planned sale to Boeing in 2018. process quality of the three institutional pillars effectively moderates
These examples show how Dutch Disease can change the quality of resource curse effects on co-evolution in each curse stage.
normative and regulative institutional processes that initially support Additionally, Fig. 1 below situates institutional process quality in a
firm internationalization. cyclical model, illustrating how the resource curse impacts the mecha­
nisms through which the co-evolution of emerging economy institutions
Proposition 3a. Normative institutional process quality positively in­
and firm internationalization occurs. We use McKelvey’s (2002)
fluences how resource curse-related Dutch Disease affects the co-evolution of
“necessary and sufficient” conditions for organizational co-evolution to
emerging economy normative institutions and firm internationalization.
ground the mechanisms in our model. Firms and government in­
Proposition 3b. Regulative institutional process quality positively in­ stitutions are the “heterogeneous agents” with capabilities for learning,
fluences how resource curse-related Dutch Disease affects the co-evolution of adaptation, interaction and mutual influence, and resource curse im­
emerging economy regulative institutions and firm internationalization. pacts act as conducting events and higher level constraints. Under these
conditions, we posit six sequential mechanisms that ignite the
3.3.2. Cognitive institutional processes co-evolutionary relationship.
As curse-driven Dutch Disease lingers across the curse’s boom and First, the misalignment between the resource curse severity and
bust stages, stage-driven changes in the quality of normative, regulative contextual information and data (economic, social, political, etc.)
and cognitive institutional processes can affect public discourse. The regarding the ability of nations, industries and firms to successfully
perceived legitimacy of these changes can co-evolve socially obtained handle curse effects forms an initial, emergent mechanism (Porter,
knowledge and resulting cognitive structures, which in turn can also co- 2006) that drives a search among institutions and firms for intentional
evolve the reputation and actions of internationalizing firms (Kostova, solutions to combat the curse. The initial misalignment acts as a moti­
1997; McKelvey, 2002; Treviño et al., 2008). In short, Dutch Disease can vator of change in the second co-evolutionary mechanism, the existing
have varying impacts on how emerging economy public discourse and levels of institutional corruption and/or expertise in dealing with
firm internationalization co-evolves. resource curse environments. Third, changes to these levels drive insti­
For example, Venezuela’s PDVSA pulled back international in­ tutional process quality, a key mechanism in developing international­
vestments based on altered normative policies and regulative actions ization policy responses for each institutional pillar, as detailed in
concerning Dutch Disease and public outcry. Mexico’s Pemex, however, Table 1 and in our Propositions. Fifth, institutional internationalization
has only recently pursued more international investment (partly to policy responses are causal mechanisms for firms to interpret and react
counter Dutch Disease) based on slowly changing public perceptions of to policies, given their levels of institutional interaction and influence.
international interference (Stojanovski, 2012). The final co-evolutionary mechanism is the actions and policies
Although well-developed sector diversification reduced overall comprising the firm’s internationalization response, which impact
Dutch Disease impacts in Brazil, Petrobras’ actions during Brazil’s resource curse severity and national/industry/firm contexts.
resource curse periods significantly impacted other industries and the The Brazilian example in Proposition 1a manifests these mechanisms
public. When the company’s corruption scandal and poor management in a negative co-evolutionary relationship, as the mismanagement of a
decision-making impaired its reputation and ability to raise capital, boom stage windfall is partly attributable to 70 % of Petrobras’ board
Petrobras compensated by increasing gasoline prices. This resulted in seats being occupied by (possibly corrupt) government actors. While the
strong negative public discourse and state-mandated price subsidies that country’s ostensible normative internationalization ideology enhanced
ultimately required the company to sell foreign and domestic assets its international influence and status, high levels of institutional cor­
(Lenton, 2017). Regulative institutional actions to sell Embraer have ruption drove lower institutional quality processes that supported
also proven controversial, as the country’s populist political party sued buying a Texas refinery to advance bribery activities. This windfall
to block the sale because it harmed Brazil’s national sovereignty (Tangel misuse fostered more severe curse effects for Brazil (especially when the
& Wall, 2018). The sale was ultimately cancelled in April 2020. These boom stage became a bust stage), driving negative public discourse
examples evidence a lingering Dutch Disease that negatively co-evolved concerning both government institutions and Petrobras (Cahen, 2015;
regulative, normative and cognitive institutional relationships with both Lyons & Kiernan, 2015).
Petrobras’ and Embraer’s international expansion initiatives. In contrast, Malaysia’s boom stage experience evinces relatively
In Malaysia, ethnic favoritism in oil windfall allocation (including positive co-evolutionary mechanisms, as a conservative normative ide­
the internationalization of government-linked companies) has contrib­ ology of securing domestic oil industry supply motivated SOE (Petro­
uted to negative public discourse concerning economic and social nas’) internationalization in support of non-oil industry sectors.
inequality of ethnic minority populations. These issues are causing a Institutionally, this conservative context, coupled with relatively low
“brain drain” of minority populations in the country, reduced sector corruption levels, enhanced normative and regulative institutional

8
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

Table 1
Resource Curse Effects on the Co-Evolutionary Relationships of Emerging Economy Institutions and Firm Internationalization: The Role of Institutional Process
Quality.
Resource Curse Impact on Co-Evolution of Normative Institutional Processes Regulative Institutional Processes Cognitive Institutional Processes
Stage (Major Effect) Emerging Economy (Internationalization Ideology/ (Regulative Internationalization (Positive/Negative Internationalization
Institutional Processes and Political Strategy) Restriction/Restraint) Discourse)
Firm Internationalization

Boom (Financial Positive: Enhances co- Higher quality enhances co- Higher quality enhances co- Higher quality normative and regulative
windfall) P1 evolutionary evolutionary internationalization evolutionary internationalization processes support positive
internationalization (P1a) (P1b) internationalization discourse (P3a),
enhancing co-evolutionary
internationalization

Bust (Economic Negative: Impairs co- Higher quality Boom stage Higher quality Boom stage Higher quality Boom stage normative,
downturn) P2 evolutionary normative and regulative processes normative and regulative processes regulative and cognitive processes reduce
internationalization reduce negative co-evolutionary reduce negative co-evolutionary negative internationalization discourse
internationalization impacts (P2a) internationalization impacts (P2b) (P3b), reducing negative co-evolutionary
internationalization impacts

Dutch Disease Negative: Impairs co- Higher quality reduces negative co- Higher quality reduces negative co- Increasing normative, regulative and
(Impaired evolutionary evolutionary internationalization evolutionary internationalization cognitive institutional process quality over
Diversification) internationalization impacts (P3a) impacts (P3b) resource curse stages reduce negative
P3 internationalization discourse (P3c),
reducing negative co-evolutionary
internationalization impacts

Fig. 1. Resource Curse Effects on Co-Evolutionary Mechanisms of Emerging Economy Institutions and Firm Internationalization (based on McKelvey, 2002).

process quality, co-evolving both extractive and non-extractive sector research has investigated institutional and firm internationalization
internationalization and ultimately blunting negative resource curse response impacts on resource curse severity and national/industry/firm
effects. For the firm, higher quality institutional processes co-evolved contexts (Frankel, 2010; Papyrakis, 2017; Ross, 2001). Existing IB
the mechanisms driving Petronas’ internationalization actions and research discusses co-evolutionary relationships among firms, in­
windfall sharing, thus reducing the curse’s negative environmental im­ stitutions and firm internationalization (Cantwell et al., 2010; Cuer­
pacts (Lee et al., 2017). vo-Cazurra et al., 2016; Kostova et al., 2008; Rodrigues & Dieleman,
The model also illustrates the necessity of considering our work as a 2018) and how firm/institutional corruption drives institutional quality
complementary yet integral theoretical addition to existing (and prob­ (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014; Dieleman & Sachs, 2008; Rodrigues &
ably new) research in IB, economics and development to fully under­ Dieleman, 2018; Wang et al., 2012; Wright et al., 2005). Finally, existing
stand the curse’s impact on the co-evolution of emerging economy economics and development work considers institutional corruption’s
institutions and firm internationalization. Specifically, our theory ex­ role in shaping curse severity and national/industry contexts (El
plains how institutional process quality can shape institutional inter­ Anshasy & Katsaiti, 2013; Ossowski et al., 2008; Ross, 2001; Sarmidi
nationalization responses to the curse, which in turn has a strong co- et al., 2014). Future IB research in this area would be useful as studies
evolutionary effect on the firm’s internationalization response and the covering curse impacts from institutional and firm corruption are
curse’s resulting environmental impact. Economics and development minimal.

9
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

4. Discussion discourse concerning socially responsible resource curse windfall allo­


cation and the home country benefits of firm internationalization.
We expand IB’s limited contribution to the resource curse literature
by exploring the curse’s effects on the co-evolution of emerging econ­ 5. Limitations and future research
omy institutions and their firms’ internationalization, which is an
important component of emerging economy economic and social Although our work elucidates resource curse impacts on co-evolving
development. Our contributions to IB-related resource curse literature institutional processes and firm internationalization in several different
are threefold. emerging economies, sustained academic debate continues concerning
First, we augment existing macro-level (country) approaches exam­ the larger questions of how resource curses emerge, when and where
ining resource curse impacts on economic development with meso- they exist and how they are solved (Papyrakis, 2017). Additionally,
(economic/social institutions, industries) and micro- (individual firm) institutional corruption influences over firms vary with resource curse
level approaches in resource-driven emerging economies. Our novel severity, government type, state/private ownership, national culture,
theoretical model illustrates the curse’s impact on co-evolutionary re­ etc., requiring more nuanced empirical research using individual and
lationships between economic and social institutions and the interna­ multiple country settings. This is evident in our discussions of various
tionalization of oil industry SOEs and non-oil POEs. This expansion of countries that have apparently “beaten” the curse but still exhibit some
the literature to the internationalization domain is an important area of negative features, especially in the cognitive institutional pillar.
inquiry, especially considering the recent focus on the activities and More empirical work is also necessary to better understand public
benefits of SOE internationalization (Benito et al., 2016; Cuervo-Cazurra discourse-related curse effects on the co-evolution of emerging economy
et al., 2014). institutions and firm internationalization. Berger and Luckman (1966)
Second, we are unaware of any other research that explores the saw language as the fundamental carrier of “taken-for-granted”, socially
processual relationship between institutional pillars and the resource available “stocks of knowledge” that define the logic of institutional
curse. Our research builds on Treviño et al.’s (2008) process-oriented order. Institutional actors use language in co-evolutionary processes for
approach to institutionalization by explaining how resource curse understanding and habitualizing activities, describing common experi­
characteristics change co-evolutionary relationships between emerging ences retained in the institution’s collective consciousness, and
economy regulative, normative and cognitive institutional processes and conveying institutional knowledge across generations. Analyzing
firm internationalization. We also develop a novel concept, institutional discourse could provide a “coherent framework” to investigate processes
process quality, to better capture these relationships. underlying resource curse-related institutionalization and co-evolution
Third, to our knowledge, our model is the first to examine the eco­ (Parker, 1992; Phillips, Lawrence, & Hardy, 2004) and firm-level
nomic and social impacts of resource curse through the co-evolutionary internationalization (Treviño & Doh, 2020). Emerging economies and
lens of emerging economy institutional processes and firm internation­ EMNEs could use these analyses to develop improved legitimation
alization. Institutional support for such internationalization can benefit strategies (Vaara & Tienari, 2008) for counteracting the resource curse’s
emerging economy governments (via foreign market influence, legiti­ negative reputational impacts.
macy and asset security), industries (via new innovations and skills) and
living standards (via increased employment and technical training op­ 6. Conclusion
portunities) (Benito et al., 2016; Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014; Luo &
Tung, 2007). However, our work reveals that the curse’s boom, bust and We challenge and extend prior IB, economics and social science
Dutch Disease stages can hinder firm internationalization by altering research by unraveling how the unique characteristics of resource-
institutional processes, policies and beliefs (Treviño et al., 2008). cursed emerging economies (e.g., extreme boom/bust cycles, large
Finally, we add to Cuervo-Cazurra’s (2012) ‘Goldilocks Debate’ economic ‘windfalls’ and negative public discourse, and industry
concerning whether explanations of EMNE phenomena could be sup­ crowding-out effects from the Dutch Disease) impact the co-evolution of
ported by existing IB theories. Although Cuervo-Cazurra (2012) asserted emerging economy institutions and their firms’ internationalization.
that SOEs’ non-business objectives limit the application of IB theory, we While empirical work is still necessary, our emerging economy examples
demonstrate that Scott’s (1995) institutional pillars can explain how the convey why and how a nation’s institutional pillars, SOEs and POEs
resource curse moderates co-evolutionary relationships between enact processes that impact resource curse severity. These processes may
emerging economy institutions and their SOEs’ internationalization. include establishing corrupt institutional ties to pursue increased natu­
ral resource rents via unproductive, non-market activities instead of
4.1. Firm and institutional policy implications fostering more robust capability development. Both mismanagement
and corrupt ties can thwart the co-evolution of emerging economy in­
Our research enjoins emerging market policy-makers and their firms stitutions and firm internationalization, ultimately diminishing human
to build robust co-evolutionary relationships via institutional processes development improvements (innovation, job creation, higher per capita
that are “immune” to de-internationalization pressures over all three income, enhanced know-how) that internationalization can bring.
resource curse stages (Funk & Treviño, 2017). For example, normative Our results motivate consideration of policy actions in tradable and
and regulative processes should support ‘patient’ EMNE investment natural resource sectors to maintain the co-evolution of emerging
capital to moderate volatility across the curse’s boom, bust and Dutch economy institutions and firm internationalization over the resource
Disease stages (Finchelstein, 2017), market-based governance reforms curse’s boom and bust stages. Such policies include regulative, norma­
to enhance foreign investor confidence (Organization for Economic tive and cognitive institutional initiatives that assure equitable resource
Cooperation and Development (OECD, 2006), and transparency in na­ curse windfall distribution and, by application, enhanced reputations of
tional budget and commodities fund administration to discourage do­ emerging economy SOEs and their governments. Again, further inves­
mestic rent-seeking opportunities (see Frankel, 2010). Additionally, tigation of these initiatives is needed to clarify their role in building
normative institutional support of international revenue and resource sustained economic, political and social institutions that can enhance
governance transparency agreements (such as the multi-stakeholder economic and human capital development in resource-cursed emerging
Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative) can enhance SOE legiti­ economies.
macy abroad, and EMNEs can utilize their ties with home country
governmental actors to lobby for more pro-market rules and norms of Declaration of Competing Interest
behavior (Cuervo-Cazurra, 2015). These regulative and normative
institutional initiatives can in turn alter public beliefs and cognitive The authors report no declarations of interest.

10
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

References Funk, C. A., & Treviño, L. J. (2017). Institution building in retreat: The effects of co-
devolution on MNE-emerging economy relationships. Cross-Cultural & Strategic
Management, 24, 436–453.
Auty, R. M. (1993). Sustaining development in mineral economies: The resource curse thesis.
Gaur, A. S., Kumar, V., & Singh, D. A. (2014). Resources, institutions, and
London: Routledge.
internationalization process of emerging economy firms. Journal of World Business,
Organizational hierarchies and evolutionary processes: Some reflections on a theory of
49, 12–20.
organizational evolution. In Baum, J. C., & Singh, J. V. (Eds.), Evolutionary dynamics
Geleilate, J. G., Magnusson, P., Parente, R. C., & Alvarado-Vargas, M. J. (2016). Home
of organizations, (pp. 3–20). (1994) (pp. 3–20). New York: Oxford University Press.
country institutional effects on the multinationality-performance relationship: A
Benito, G. R. G., Rygh, A., & Lunnan, R. (2016). The benefits of internationalization for
comparison between emerging and developed market multinationals. Journal of
state-owned enterprises. Global Strategy Journal, 6, 269–288.
International Management, 22, 380–402.
Berger, P. L., & Luckman, T. (1966). The social construction of reality. London: Penguin.
George, G., Schillebeeckx, S. J., & Liak, T. L. (2015). The management of natural
Buchanan, S., & Marques, J. C. (2018). How home country industry associations
resources: An overview and research agenda. The Academy of Management Journal,
influence MNE international CSR practices: Evidence from the Canadian mining
58(6), 1595–1613.
industry. Journal of World Business, 53, 63–74.
Gilberthorpe, E., & Banks, G. (2012). Development on whose terms? CSR discourse and
Buckley, P. J., Doh, J. P., & Benischke, M. H. (2017). Towards a renaissance in
social realities in Papua New Guinea’s extractive industries sector. Resources Policy,
international business research? Big questions, grand challenges and the future of IB
37, 185–193.
scholarship. Journal of International Business Studies, 48, 1045–1064.
Gilberthorpe, E., & Rajak, D. (2017). The anthropology of extraction: Critical
Bulte, E. H., Damania, R., & Deacon, R. T. (2005). Resource intensity, institutions and
perspectives on the resource curse. The Journal of Development Studies, 53, 186–204.
development. World Development, 33, 1029–1044.
Govindarajan, V., & Ramamurti, R. (2011). Reverse innovation, emerging markets and
Cahen, F. R. (2015). Internationalization of state-owned enterprises through foreign
global strategy. Global Strategy Journal, 1, 191–205.
direct investment. Journal of Business & Management, 55(6), 645–659.
Grøgaard, B., Rygh, A., & Benito, G. R. G. (2019). Bringing corporate governance into
Cannizzaro, A. P., & Weiner, R. J. (2018). State ownership and transparency in foreign
internationalization theory: State ownership and foreign entry strategies. Journal of
direct investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 49(2), 172–195.
International Business Studies, 50, 1310–1337.
Cantwell, J., Dunning, J. H., & Lundan, S. M. (2010). An evolutionary approach to
He, X., & Cui, L. (2012). Can strong home country institutions foster the
understanding international business activity: The co-evolution of MNEs and the
internationalization of MNEs? Multinational Business Review, 20, 352–375.
institutional environment. Journal of International Business Studies, 41, 567–586.
Hilson, G. (2012). Poverty traps in small-scale mining communities: The case of sub-
Carney, M., & Dieleman, M. (2011). Indonesia’s missing multinationals: Business groups
Saharan Africa. Canadian Journal of Development Studies, 33, 180–197.
and outward direct investment. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 47(1),
Hilson, G., & Laing, T. J. (2017). Guyana gold: A unique resource curse? The Journal of
105–126.
Development Studies, 53, 229–248.
Carril-Caccia, F., Milgram-Baleix, J., & Paniagua, J. (2019). Foreign direct investment in
Hoskisson, R. E., Johnson, R. A., Tihanyi, L., & White, R. E. (2005). Diversified business
oil-abundant countries: The role of institutions. PLoS One, 14(4), e0215650. https://
groups and corporate refocusing in emerging economies. Journal of Management, 31,
doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0215650 Accessed March 22, 2020.
941–965.
Clegg, J., Voss, H., & Tardios, J. A. (2018). The autocratic advantage:
Inkpen, A. C. (2016). The rise and fall of Petrobras. Thunderbird school of global management
Internationalization of state-owned multinationals. Journal of World Business, 53(5),
case No. A03-15-0015.
668–681.
International Monetary Fund. (2015). World economic outlook, October, 2015.
Corden, W. M., & Neary, J. P. (1982). Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small
Washington, D.C: International Monetary Fund Publication Services.
open economy. The Economic Journal, 92, 825–848.
Kostova, T. (1997). Country institutional profiles: Concept and measurement. Academy of
Corrales, J., Hernandez, G., & Salgado, J. C. (2020). Oil and regime type in Latin
management best paper proceedings, 180–189.
America: Reversing the line of causality. Energy Policy, 142, 111347. https://doi.org/
Kostova, T., Roth, K., & Dacin, M. T. (2008). Institutional theory in the study of
10.1016/j.enpol.2020.111347 Accessed May 10, 2020.
multinational corporations: A critique and new directions. The Academy of
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2012). How the analysis of developing country multinational
Management Review, 33, 994–1006.
companies helps advance theory: Solving the Goldilocks debate. Global Strategy
Krugman, P. (1987). The narrow moving band, the Dutch Disease and the competitive
Journal, 2, 153–167.
consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: Notes on trade in the presence of dynamic scale
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2015). The co-evolution of pro-market reforms and emerging market
economies. Journal of Development Economics, 27, 41–55.
multinationals. In L. Tihanyi, E. R. Banalieva, T. M. Devinney, & T. Pedersen (Eds.),
Lecraw, D. J. (1993). Outward direct investment by Indonesian firms: Motivation and
Advances in international management, volume 28: Emerging economies and
effects. Journal of International Business Studies, 24(3), 589–600.
multinational enterprises (pp. 71–94). Bingley, U.K: Emerald Group Publishing
Lee, C., Lee, C. G., & Yeo, M. (2017). Determinants of Singapore’s outward FDI. In C. Lee,
Limited.
& S. Sermcheep (Eds.), Outward foreign direct investment in ASEAN. Singapore: Yusof
Cuervo-Cazurra, A., & Genc, M. (2008). Transforming disadvantages into advantages:
Ishak Institute.
Developing country MNEs in the least developed countries. Journal of International
Lenton, M. (2017). Brazil’s petrobras: Not dead after all. Americas Quarterly, 11(4).
Business Studies, 39, 957–979.
Americasquarterly.org. http://americasquarterly.org/content/petrobras-isnt-dead-
Cuervo-Cazurra, A., Ganitsky, J., Luo, Y., & Mezias, J. (2016). Global strategy and
yet. Accessed 7 July 2018.
emerging markets. Academy of International Business Insights, 16, 3–6.
Lewin, A. Y., & Volberda, H. W. (1999). Prolegomena on coevolution: A framework for
Cuervo-Cazurra, A., Inkpen, A., Musacchio, A., & Ramaswamy, K. (2014). Governments
research on strategy and new organizational forms. Organization Science, 10,
as owners: State-owned multinational companies. Journal of International Business
519–534.
Studies, 45(8), 919–942.
Liang, H., Ren, B., & Sun, S. L. (2015). An anatomy of state control in the globalization of
Cui, L., & Jiang, F. (2012). State ownership effect on firms’ FDI ownership decisions
state-owned enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies, 46, 223–240.
under institutional pressure: A study of Chinese outward-investing firms. Journal of
Lopez-Morales, J. S., Gonzalez-Barragan, A. R., Maldonado de Luna, A., Velez De-
International Business Studies, 43(3), 264–284.
Alba, E. A., & Muller-Jasso, A. R. (2017). Internationalization of state MultiLatinas: A
Dieleman, M., & Sachs, W. M. (2008). Coevolution of institutions and corporations in
multi-case study in the oil sector. International Journal of Business Economics and
emerging economies: How the Salim group morphed into an institution of Suharto’s
Management, 4(4), 65–81.
crony regime. Journal of Management Studies, 45, 1274–1300.
Ludeña, M. P. (2016). Multinational enterprises from Latin America: Investment
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Institutional
strategies and limits to growth and diversification. Transnational Corporations Review,
isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological
8(1), 41–49.
Review, 48, 147–160.
Luo, Y., & Tung, R. L. (2007). International expansion of emerging market enterprises: A
Introduction. In DiMaggio, P. D., & Powell, W. W. (Eds.), The new institutionalism in
springboard perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 38, 481–498.
organizational analysis, (pp. 1–38). (1991) (pp. 1–38). Chicago: University of
Luo, Y., & Wang, S. L. (2012). Foreign direct investment strategies by developing country
Chicago Press.
multinationals: A diagnostic model for home country effects. Global Strategy Journal,
Doraiswami, A. (2015). Has Malaysia really escaped the resource curse? A closer look at
2, 244–261.
the political economy of oil revenue expenditures and management. Resources Policy,
Lyons, J., & Kiernan, P. (2015). wsj.comHow Brazil’s China-driven commodities boom went
45, 98–108.
bust.. August 27. http://www.wsj.com/articles/how-brazils-china-driven-
Dunning, T., & Wirpsa, L. (2004). Oil and the political economy of Conflict in Colombia
commodities-boom-went-bust-1440728049. Accessed 1 September 2015.
and beyond: A linkages approach. Geopolitics, 9(1), 81–108.
Macintyre, M. (2003). Petztorme women: Responding to change in Lihir, Papua New
El Anshasy, A. A., & Katsaiti, M.-S. (2013). Natural resources and fiscal performance:
Guinea. Oceania, 74, 120–134.
Does good governance matter? Journal of Macroeconomics, 37, 285–298.
Manzano, O., & Rigobon, R. (2001). Resource curse or debt overhang? NBER working paper
Estrin, S., Meyer, K. E., Nielsen, B. B., & Nielsen, S. (2016). Home country institutions
No. 8390. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
and the internationalization of state-owned enterprises: A cross-country analysis.
Marano, V., Tashman, P., & Kostova, T. (2017). Escaping the iron cage: Liabilities of
Journal of World Business, 51(2), 294–307.
origin and CSR reporting of emerging market multinational enterprises. Journal of
Finchelstein, D. (2017). The role of the state in the internationalization of Latin American
International Business Studies, 48, 386–408.
firms. Journal of World Business, 52, 578–590.
McKelvey, B. (2002). Managing coevolutionary dynamics. In Paper presented at the 18th
Frankel, J. A. (2010). The natural resource curse: A survey. National Bureau of Economic
EGOS conference.
Research Working paper 15836. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
McKinsey Global Institute. (2013). Reverse the curse: Maximizing the potential of resource-
Research.
driven economies Accessed 16 February 2017 www.mckinsey.com/mgi.
Frynas, J. G. (2017). Sovereign wealth funds and the resource curse: Resource funds and
Mehlum, H., Moene, K., & Torvik, R. (2006). Institutions and the resource curse. The
governance in resource-rich countries. In D. Cumming, G. Wood, I. Filatotchev, &
Economic Journal, 116, 1–20.
J. Reinecke (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of sovereign wealth funds (pp. 123–144).
Oxford, U.K: Oxford University Press.

11
C. Funk et al. International Business Review 30 (2021) 101753

Meyer, K. E., Ding, Y., Li, J., & Zhang, H. (2014). Overcoming distrust: How state-owned Schneider, A., & Ioris, R. (2018). Uneven and combined: The boom-bust of emerging
enterprises adapt their foreign entries to institutional pressures abroad. Journal of power development as seen through Embraer. World Time Magazine, 4(1), 218–245.
International Business Studies, 45(8), 1005–1028. Scott, W. R. (1995). Institutions and organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Mittelman, M. (2017). The resource curse Accessed 3 February 2017 https://www. Shapiro, D., Hobdari, B., & Oh, C. H. (2018). Natural resources, multinational enterprises
bloomberg.com/quicktake/resource-curse. and sustainable development. Journal of World Business, 53, 1–14.
Movchan, A., Zotin, A., & Grigoryev, V. (2017). Managing the resource curse strategies of Smith, M., Valle, S., & Schmidt, B. (2015). The betrayal of Brazil. Bloomberg. May 8. www.
oil-dependent economies in the modern era. Moscow: Carnegie Endowment for bloomberg.com/news/features/2015-05-08/brazil-s-massive-corruption-scandal-ha
International Peace. sbitterness-replacing-hope. Accessed September 1, 2015.
Murshed, S. M. (2004). When does natural resource abundance lead to a resource curse? EEP Stojanovski, O. (2012). Handcuffed: An assessment of Pemex’s performance and strategy.
Discussion Paper 04-01. London: International Institute for Environment and In D. G. Victor, D. R. Hults, & M. C. Thurber (Eds.), Oil and governance: State-owned
Development. governance and world energy supply (pp. 280–333). Cambridge, U.K: Cambridge
Murtha, T. P., & Lenway, S. A. (1994). Country capabilities and the strategic state: How University Press.
national political institutions affect multinational corporations’ strategies. Strategic Tangel, A., & Wall, R. (2018). Boeing to take over Embraer’s commercial jet business
Management Journal, 15, 113–129. Accessed November 11, 2019 https://www.wsj.com/articles/boeing-to-take-over-b
Narula, R. (2018). Multinational firms and the extractive sectors in the 21st century: Can razils-embraer-commercial-jet-business-1530790672.
they drive development? Journal of World Business, 53, 85–91. Transparency International. (2011). Promoting revenue transparency: 2011 report on oil
Natural Resource Governance Institute. (2019). The national oil company database and gas companies Accessed 23 March 2018 www.transparency.org.
Accessed March 18, 2020 www.resourcegovernance.org. Treviño, L. J., & Doh, J. P. (2020). Internationalization of the firm: A discourse-based
North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: view. Journal of International Business Studies. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-020-
Cambridge University Press. 00344-8.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). (2006). Case studies Treviño, L. J., Thomas, D. E., & Cullen, J. (2008). The three pillars of institutional theory
of good corporate governance practices. Companies circle of the Latin American corporate and FDI in Latin America: An institutionalization process. International Business
governance roundtable. Washington: OECD-IFC (World Bank). Review, 17, 118–133.
Ossowski, R., Villafuerte, M., Medas, P. A., & Thomas, T. (2008). Managing the oil revenue U. S. Energy Information Database. (2019). International energy statistics Accessed 3/19/
boom: The role of fiscal institutions. International Monetary Fund Occasional Paper 2020 www.eia.gov.
Number 260. Washington, D.C: International Monetary Fund Publication Services. Usui, N. (1997). Dutch disease and policy adjustments to the oil boom: A comparative
Papyrakis, E. (2017). The resource curse-what we have learned from two decades of study of Indonesia and Mexico. Resource Policy, 23(4), 151–162.
intensive research: Introduction to the special issue. The Journal of Development Vaara, E., & Tienari, J. (2008). A discursive perspective on the legitimation strategies in
Studies, 53, 175–185. multinational corporations. The Academy of Management Review, 33(4), 985–993.
Parker, I. (1992). Discourse dynamics: Critical analysis for social and individual psychology. Van Der Ploeg, F., & Poelhekke, S. (2009). Volatility and the U. Resource curse. Oxford
London: Routledge. Economic Papers, 61, 727–760.
Peck, S., & Chayes, S. (2015). The oil curse: A remedial role for the oil industry. Washington: Wang, C., Hong, J., Kafouros, M., & Wright, M. (2012). Exploring the role of government
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. involvement in outward FDI from emerging economies. Journal of International
Phillips, N., Lawrence, T. B., & Hardy, C. (2004). Discourse and institutions. The Academy Business Studies, 43(7), 655–676.
of Management Review, 29, 635–652. Waterworth, A., & Bradshaw, M. J. (2018). Unconventional tradeoffs? National oil
Porter, T. B. (2006). Coevolution as a research framework for organizations and the companies, foreign investment and oil and gas development in Argentina and Brazil.
natural environment. Organization & Environment, 19(4), 479–504. Energy Policy, 122, 7–16.
Ramirez-Cendrero, J. M., & Paz, M. J. (2017). Oil fiscal regimes and national oil Watts, M. (2001). Petro-violence: Community, extraction and political ecology of a
companies: A comparison between Pemex and Petrobras. Energy Policy, 101, mythic commodity. In N. L. Peluso, & M. Watts (Eds.), Violent environments (pp.
473–483. 189–212). London: Cornell University Press.
Rodrigues, S. B., & Dieleman, M. (2018). The internationalization paradox: Untangling Witt, M. A., & Lewin, A. Y. (2007). Outward foreign direct investment as escape response
dependence in multinational state hybrids. Journal of World Business, 53, 39–51. to home country institutional constraints. Journal of International Business Studies, 38,
Rosales, A., & Sanchez, M. (2018). The energy politics of Venezuela. In K. J. Hancock, & 579–594.
J. E. Allison (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of energy politics Accessed May 20, 2020 World Bank. (2011). Malaysia economic monitor: Brain drain. Bangkok, Thailand: The
www.oxfordhandbooks.com. World Bank.
Ross, M. L. (2001). Does oil hinder democracy? World Politics, 53, 325–361. Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R. E., & Peng, M. W. (2005). Strategy research in
Ross, M. L. (2012). The oil curse: How petroleum wealth shapes the development of nations. emerging economies: Challenging the conventional wisdom. Journal of Management
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Studies, 42, 1–33.
Sarmidi, T., Law, S. H., & Jafari, Y. (2014). Resource curse: New evidence on the role of Zavaleta-Vazquez, O. H., & Wise-Lozano, J. A. (2016). Emerging MNEs successfully
institutions. International Economic Journal, 28, 191–206. operating in international markets: The cases of some Mexican MNEs. In M. A. Khan
Sauvant, K. P. (2010). Is the United States ready for foreign direct investment from (Ed.), Multinational enterprise management strategies in developing countries (pp.
emerging markets? The case of China. In K. P. Sauvant, W. A. Maschek, & 152–175). Hershey, PA: IGI Global.
G. McAllister (Eds.), Foreign direct investments from emerging markets. New York:
Palgrave Macmillan.

12

You might also like