You are on page 1of 9

134 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Learning from Enron


Simon Deakin and Suzanne J. Konzelmann*

This paper argues that the Enron affair has been misunderstood as a failure of monitoring,
with adverse consequences for the drafting of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Higgs report.
Where Enron’s board failed was in misunderstanding the risks which were inherent in the
company’s business plan and failing to implement an effective system of internal control.
Enron demonstrates the limits of the monitoring board and points the way to a stewardship
model in which the board takes responsibility for ensuring the sustainability of the company’s
assets over time.

Keywords: Enron, corporate governance, shareholder value, non-executive directors, monitor-


ing board

Introduction: Enron as corporate tions made in the Higgs Review of Non-


governance failure Executive Directors (Higgs, 2003) for changes
to the Combined Code. Higgs and Sarbanes-
Oxley, then, are entirely consistent with the
F inancial scandals have long been one of
the main drivers of change in company
law (Lee, 2002). In the case of Enron, the
idea which, above all others, informed late
twentieth-century capitalism in the common
response of lawmakers to the company’s col- law world, namely that corporations exist to
lapse during in the final months of 2001 was further the interests of their shareholders.
immediate and far-reaching. The Sarbanes- In this paper we take a closer look at the
Oxley Act, adopted by the US Congress events surrounding Enron’s fall with a view to
in the summer of 2002, is the most signi- assessing whether the response which it has
ficant measure of federal securities and cor- elicited is justified. We argue that while there
porate law since the New Deal legislation of were serious conflicts of interest at the board
the 1930s. In many respects, Sarbanes-Oxley and senior management levels in the period
is a mirror image of Enron: the company’s running up to the company’s bankruptcy,
perceived corporate governance failings are these conflicts were not the principal reason
matched virtually point for point in the prin- for its fall. More relevant, from a corporate
cipal provisions of the Act (see Ribstein, 2003). governance point of view, was the failure of
The guiding assumption of the new law is that Enron’s board and management to take
Enron’s fall was brought about by conflicts of responsibility for the risks inherent in the
interest on the part of its senior managers and company’s business plan, in particular the use
by a lack of oversight on the part of its board of special purpose entities (SPEs) and related
*Address for correspondence: and advisers. As a result, the Act imposes rules forms of so-called “structured finance”. It was
Centre for Business Research, aimed at enhancing the independence of the misuse of these forms of off-balance sheet
Judge Institute of Manage-
ment, University of Cam- directors and auditors, with the objective of financing and the need to correct their initial
bridge, Trumpington Street, more precisely aligning managerial behaviour mis-reporting in the company’s accounts
Cambridge CB2 1AG, UK. Tel: with the interests of shareholders. The same which destroyed market confidence in Enron;
01223 765320; Fax: 01223
765338; E-mail: s.deakin@cbr. objective underlies UK responses to the cor- the conflicts of interest which led to the enrich-
cam.ac.uk porate scandals, including the recommenda- ment of certain corporate officers, while

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004. 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford,


Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004 OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
LEARNING FROM ENRON 135

egregious, were incidental to the company’s ual risk across the market as a whole, which it
failure. was then able to hedge by entering into swaps
The circumstances of Enron’s fall should be and similar arrangements with dealers on
seen in a wider context. As its fortunes rose, in recognised futures exchanges.
particular during the second half of the 1990s, As an energy trader, Enron had a compara-
Enron was celebrated in the financial press tive advantage over its rivals from the finan-
and in business school case studies because it cial sector: because it owned and operated
was seen to embody an agenda for the mod- physical plant, it was in a position to hold
ernisation of the corporation. Enron’s man- energy supplies in its own right as a protection
agers understood and applied the language of against movements in market prices. As an
“core competencies”, “asset lite” balance sheets industry insider, it also had an informational
and “virtual integration”. Enron was also, advantage in forecasting regional and sectoral
famously, the company which claimed above shocks. As a result, it could claim to be both a
all others to be “laser focused on earnings per “market maker” (in the sense of supplying
share”. Its fall inevitably resonates, then, with liquidity to an existing market) and a
widely expressed concerns about the effects “creator” of altogether new types of products,
of the dominance of the “shareholder value” using legal and contractual “technologies” to
norm in Anglo-American corporate gover- develop and trade mechanisms of risk man-
nance (Kennedy, 2000; Mitchell, 2001; Bratton, agement which had not previously existed. As
2002; Millon, 2002; Deakin and Konzelmann, Jeffrey Skilling, initially the head of Enron’s
2003). Yet this aspect of the debate is almost energy trading business and later (briefly) its
entirely missing from the public policy dis- CEO, put it, “[we are] a company that makes
course surrounding Sarbanes-Oxley and markets. We create the market, and once it’s
Higgs. Is it possible that policymakers are created, we make the market” (quoted in Culp
learning the wrong lesson from Enron? and Hanke, 2003, p. 7).
Enron’s business strategy was, as it put it,
“asset lite” [sic] in the sense that it sought to
combine the minimum level of ownership and
Virtual integration and “asset lite”: operation of plant which was necessary to
Enron’s business plan maintain a physical market presence, with the
development of ever more sophisticated risk
The business strategy which Enron’s man- management techniques. Enron was heavily
agers developed in the course of the 1990s was leveraged for much of the 1980s and 1990s as
based on the exploitation of novel forms of a result of the loans initially taken on at the
risk management in the energy supply chain. time of the merger which created the company.
Enron began life from the merger of two utility “Heavy” assets such as pipelines, power sta-
companies in the mid-1980s and, for the next tions and reservoirs represented fixed costs
ten years, enjoyed steadily rising profitability and a potential drain on the company’s prof-
as it exploited the opportunities which arose itability and its capacity to manage debt.
from the deregulation of US energy markets Trading derivatives contracts, on the other
(Fusaro and Miller, 2002). In addition to own- hand, did not (in theory, at least) involve such
ing several interstate gas pipelines, Enron a high degree of fixed capital investments.
ran a natural gas and electricity transmission Thus the optimal combination was one in
business and a retail supply arm dealing which a relatively small investment in physi-
directly with energy users. When, after 1985, cal assets was combined with an extensive
access to gas pipelines was deregulated, Enron market-making “overlay”. The “asset lite”
developed a gas trading business offering approach implied that, by these means, a
various types of derivatives (forward con- higher rate of return could be achieved than
tracts and options) to its customers. through a more traditional asset structure.
The emergence of futures markets for gas This meant, in turn, moving from a “vertically
supply created the possibility of “spread” or integrated” form of organisation to one in
“basis trading”, which exploited the difference which different firms in the supply chain were
between prices in spot markets and futures linked through “virtual integration” based on
markets. Enron’s head start in gas trading the contractual management of risks:
enabled it to act as a market maker for parties
on either side of the supply chain; it would The fundamental advantage of a virtually inte-
therefore act as a counterparty to trades on grated system is you need less capital to provide
both sides of the exchange, in effect taking its the same reliability . . . It’s very hard to earn a
profits in the form of the spread between bid compensatory rate of return on a traditional
prices and offer prices. By acting for both asset investment . . . In today’s world, you have
sides, Enron confined its exposure to the resid- to bring intellectual content to the product, or

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004


136 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

you will not earn a fair rate of return. . . . were not only highly volatile, but in which it
(Skilling in BusinessWeek Online February had no physical presence and no specialised
2001, quoted in Bratton, 2002, p. 1292) knowledge of the kind which would give it a
comparative advantage. But the disappear-
There is an argument for saying that energy ance of its working credit and the collapse of
derivatives provided markets with much support from lenders around this time were
needed liquidity in the period following liber- also linked to the unravelling of accounting
alisation (see Culp and Hanke, 2003, p. 6). devices which it had used to shift heavy
However, this must be set against allegations and/or volatile assets off its balance sheet.
that the company was involved in attempts to This was the less acceptable side of “asset lite”.
manipulate energy prices in a number of states
including California, and claims that, from
early on in the existence of its energy trading
arm, the company’s earnings from derivatives Enron’s accounting: “intelligent
were being misstated in ways which concealed
its true position (for discussion, see Partnoy,
gambling”
2003, ch. 10). Until such time as evidence from Enron took advantage of US accounting rules
Enron’s bankruptcy proceedings or elsewhere which enable companies to set up corporate
may show otherwise, it seems reasonable to vehicles, so-called special purpose entities
accept that Enron’s energy trading business or SPEs, to manage assets off balance sheet.
was both legitimate and useful. But even on In essence, these rules allow companies to
this basis, there were considerable risks for the engage in a form of risk-spreading. The return
company. on an asset can be maximised, and risk min-
An “asset lite” strategy requires a number of imised, by transferring it to an SPE which
preconditions to be met if it is to be success- must at some point repay the debt which it has
ful (Culp and Hanke, 2003, p. 15). First, the incurred to the vendor company. An outside
company must have access to considerable investor comes in to supply external capital
resources of liquid capital if it is to be able to and share the risk with the vendor, in
service its obligations as a counterparty to exchange for which it also gets to share in the
transactions in which it simultaneously ser- high rate of return which the SPE can provide.
vices both buyers and sellers in the chain of It is a basic principle of modern company
supply. Secondly, and relatedly, it must enjoy law and accounting practice that the accounts
an unblemished reputation with the banks of parent and subsidiary companies in the
and credit rating agencies on which it ulti- same group should be consolidated. Other-
mately depends for its supply of liquid capital. wise, it is a fairly simple matter to shift assets
Thirdly, in order to maintain its comparative between parent and subsidiary in such a way
informational advantage as a market maker, it as to give a misleading impression to share-
needs to maintain a physical presence in the holders of the state of their respective balance
sectors in which it operates as a trader. The sheets. This principle has been recognised for
architects of Enron’s strategy were well aware over half a century in developed economies
that being able to meet these conditions was and was introduced as a response to some of
the basis for the company’s competitive the more egregious accounting scandals which
position: accompanied the Great Crash of 1929 and the
In Volatile Markets, Everything Changes but economic depression of the 1930s (for the UK
Us. When customers do business with Enron, side of this story, see Lee, 2002).
they get our commitment to reliably deliver their The rules on SPEs give every appearance of
product at a predictable price, regardless of marking a fundamental departure from the
market condition. This commitment is possible principle of consolidation. The US Generally
because of Enron’s unrivalled access to markets Accepted Accounting Principles (US GAAP)
and liquidity . . . Market access and information provide that the assets and liabilities of an SPE
allow Enron to deliver comprehensive logis- do not need to appear on the balance sheet of
tical solutions that work in volatile markets the vendor company which has set it up, as
or markets undergoing fundamental changes, long as two conditions are satisfied: the
such as energy and broadband. (Enron Annual outside investor must supply at least 3 per
Report, 2000, quoted in Bratton, 2002, p. 1291) cent of the total working capital of the SPE,
and, in addition, must be in a position to
Enron’s bankruptcy came about in the autumn control the disposition of the asset or assets
of 2001 when each of these conditions, in turn, which are transferred to the SPE. The 3 per
ceased to hold. In part this can be attributed to cent figure was introduced by the SEC in 1991.
its decision to start offering derivatives con- It was meant to represent the minimum
tracts in markets, such as broadband, which acceptable investment which was compatible

Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


LEARNING FROM ENRON 137

with the notion of a genuine transfer of risk of duced by a subcommittee of Enron’s own
the kind which would occur in the leasing board in the weeks following the company’s
transactions which at that time represented bankruptcy. Additional material emerged in
the most common situation in which SPEs several weeks of hearings before Congress and
were used. Moreover, the original letter issued through the publication of a Senate subcom-
by the SEC presented the 3 per cent figure as mittee report in July 2002, which provided a
indicative only: it was thought that “a greater blow by blow account of alleged failings of
investment may be necessary depending on Enron’s board (Senate Subcommittee, 2002).
the facts and circumstances, including the As bankruptcy proceedings began in New
credit risk associated with the lessee and the York in the winter of 2002, the court placed
market risk factors associated with the leased several thousand pages of documents relating
property” (Partnoy, 2003, p. 81). However, in to the company’s collapse on a website with
the course of the 1990s, meeting the 3 per cent public access. The extent of disclosure and
threshold came to be seen as sufficient in itself its focus on what the board knew contrast
for complying with US GAAP; today, struc- sharply with the much more limited inquiry
tured finance transactions using SPEs have a carried out by the Financial Services Author-
combined annual value of trillions of dollars. ity (FSA, 2003) into the near collapse of the
In the course of the 1990s, Enron set up leading UK engineering and telecoms com-
several thousand companies which, thanks to pany, Marconi, in 2002; we still know little
the rules of US GAAP on SPEs and so-called about the circumstances under which the deci-
“equity accounting”, did not count as its sub- sions which led to Marconi’s difficulties were
sidiaries and whose accounts therefore did not reported to and approved by its board (see
need to be consolidated with its own. The use Plender, 2003, ch. 5, for one of the few
of SPEs and equity affiliates enabled Enron to informed accounts).
replace potential liabilities (risky or heavy As the Powers report put it, “the Raptors
investments with the potential to be a drain on were designed to make use of forecasted
the company) with assets (promissory notes future growth of Enron’s stock price to shield
issued to Enron by its own SPEs) and earnings Enron’s income statement from reflecting
(income streams generated as the SPEs repaid future losses incurred on merchant invest-
to Enron the debts incurred as a result of the ments” such as the Rhythms shares (Powers et
initial asset transfer). al., 2002, p. 98). However, “[t]his strategy of
None of this was a problem in practice, and using Enron’s own stock to offset losses runs
none of it contravened accounting principles counter to a basic principle of accounting and
or the rules of corporate law, until the late financial reporting: except under limited cir-
1990s when the company entered into a series cumstances, a business may not recognise
of transactions for which no genuine outside gains due to the increase in the value of
investor could be found. In the case of the its capital stock on its income statement”
SPE known as Chewco, the “investment” was (Powers, 2002, p. 98). Put slightly differently,
made in the form of a bank loan which Enron a company should not be able to present
guaranteed. Attempts were made to dress up an increase in its share price as additional
the loan as an equity holding, but, in essence, earnings simply with the aim of generating
the bank in question was not putting up any a further increase in that same share price.
risk capital and so the deal was a sham. However, this was precisely what Enron did
Further sets of entities, the LJM and Raptor in the case of the Raptors, and had been doing
SPEs, were capitalised through a combination for several years; as long ago as 1996, its CFO,
of bank loans and Enron common stock. These Andrew Fastow, had made a virtue of the
SPEs were used to take on extremely volatile practice (see Partnoy, 2003, p. 303).
investments, including shares in a dotcom Enron’s share price, at this point in the late
company (the “Rhythms transaction”), which 1990s, was enjoying enormous growth, in
Enron had booked as assets on its balance large part because of a perception that it was
sheet using “mark to market accounting”. If a “new economy” company. Capitalising the
these assets were to decline in value, Enron LJM and Raptor SPEs with Enron shares must
faced a potential loss on its balance sheet. This therefore have seemed a low-risk option.
in turn represented a risk to its credit rating. Clearly, it was only low risk as long as the
The existence of these transactions was dis- share price continued to rise as it had done
closed, as required, in Enron’s annual reports, for the previous decade. Like all other “new
but in a manner which was less than clear and economy” companies, Enron’s shares began to
did not avert to the essentially sham nature of fall from early 2000 as the result of the burst-
the deals. The further details which are now ing of the dotcom bubble. There was little or
available were first revealed in the Powers nothing Enron could do about this. But as
report, a several hundred page document pro- the share price steadily declined through the

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004


138 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

spring and summer of 2001, it looked increas- J.P. Morgan, and a planned merger with rival
ingly likely that the LJM and Raptor SPEs energy trader Dynegy (which was called off as
would default on their obligations to Enron. the scale of Enron’s debts became clear) failed
To make things even worse, no attempt had in November 2001. As a result, the company
been made to take out a separate “hedge” on entered Chapter 11 bankruptcy on 2 Decem-
the deals in question by transacting for a third ber. Its shares, which had once traded at over
party to take the risk of default. Essentially $90, then stood at less than $1 each.
this was because the assets concerned (the
Rhythms stock and similar financial invest-
ments) were simply too “large and illiquid” (in
effect, too risk-prone) to be hedged in the Conflicts of interest, risk
normal way (Powers et al., 2002, p. 100). management and the role
Enron’s fall was probably unavoidable once of the board
the sham SPE transactions began to unravel in
the autumn of 2001. Chewco was the first SPE The role of the conflicts of interest which have
to be wound up and the LJM and Raptor trans- since been the focus of much attention and
actions then followed. In each case Enron’s debate must be seen against the backdrop of
auditor, Arthur Andersen, having initially ap- the company’s final months. The most serious
proved the deals, now told the company of the conflicts related to the involvement of
that they were incompatible with accounting Enron corporate officers in setting up and
principles. In each case, the balance sheets of running some of the sham SPEs with which
the SPEs had to be consolidated with that of the company dealt. Michael Kopper, a senior
the parent company. The result was that employee in the finance section of the com-
earnings going back several years had to be pany, ran the Chewco SPE through a series
restated and liabilities which had previously of limited partnerships and companies which
been concealed in the SPEs had to be reported he controlled; his involvement was not dis-
on Enron’s balance sheet. The earnings restate- closed to the board. Fastow ran the LJM SPEs
ments ran into several hundred million dollars and was prominently involved in several of
and the revaluation of assets and liabilities led the entities used as part of the Raptor transac-
to an overall reduction in the company’s tions, as were a number of more junior Enron
worth of several billion dollars. employees in accounting and finance posi-
These restatements and revaluations would tions. Fastow’s involvement in the LJM deals
not in themselves have bankrupted Enron. Its was not only disclosed to the board, at a
annual revenues (in the sense of cash flow) at meeting which took place in 1999, but the
this point were in the tens of billions of dollars board approved of his participation, following
and while its pre-tax earnings (in the sense of a recommendation to this effect from the then
profits) were much less than this (around $1.5 CEO and Chairman, Ken Lay.
billion in the five quarters to the autumn of Fastow and Kopper were not members of
2001), even with the Raptor restatements, it Enron’s board. However, as senior employees
would not have ended up reporting a loss. and, in Fastow’s case, a designated senior
However, the events of autumn 2001 shook officer of the company, they owed fiduciary
market confidence, which had already been duties to Enron. Self-dealing – acting on both
undermined by Skilling’s unexplained resig- sides of the deal – is potentially a breach of
nation as CEO in August of that year. At the the fiduciary duty of loyalty which a director
end of October 2001, Moody’s Investor Ser- or senior employee owes to the company.
vices downgraded Enron’s long-term debt, in However, fiduciary duty laws can, in effect, be
direct response to the announcement of earn- waived. In the context of a listed company
ings restatements. Other credit rating agencies such as Enron, approval by the board will
followed their example. As Enron’s credit almost certainly suffice. With a dispersed
status declined (eventually falling below shareholder base it is impracticable to require
investment grade level), debts automatically shareholder approval in such a case, and cor-
fell due and liabilities accumulated under the porate law generally does not insist upon it.
terms of its loan covenants. The effect, as Fastow’s involvement was, however, disclosed
Skilling later put it, was like that of a “run on to shareholders in Enron’s annual report for
the bank”. This was more than just the result 2000, after the transactions were undertaken
of “a simple flaw in treasury management” but well before the company’s difficulties
(Plender, 2003, p. 175); Enron’s entire strategy began. While his role in the LJM deal would
depended upon being able to maintain the have been a breach of Enron’s own code of
confidence of the credit and capital markets. ethics had the board not waived it on Lay’s
Efforts to save the company through a last- advice, the code was not legally binding and
minute line of credit from the investment bank the board did, in this event, give its approval.

Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


LEARNING FROM ENRON 139

The Powers Report implies that the board ered, namely those affecting senior managers,
was either misled, or simply not informed, the auditors and the non-executive directors.
about Kopper’s role in Chewco. It also indi- The main charge against the senior managers
cates that the board was not informed of the relates to the self-dealing and stratospheric
large sums which Fastow, Kopper and others remuneration which accompanied the setting
received for managing the SPEs which they set up of the sham SPEs. However, while the sums
up. Fastow received $30 million in return for paid to Fastow and his immediate colleagues
his part in this. It was only in October 2001, for running the SPEs were enormous even by
when the deals were falling apart, that the the standards of late 1990s corporate America,
board asked and learned about the extent the sums diverted did not bankrupt Enron.
of Fastow’s remuneration. Following this, it The real damage was indirect; when the
decided to suspend him from his employment deals set up by Fastow were unravelled,
with Enron. It is far from clear that Fastow investor and creditor confidence in the
committed any legal wrong in not notifying company was undermined at a critical time.
the board, since the sums in question were not From this perspective (and with the obvious
received in his capacity as Enron’s CFO. It is, benefit of hindsight), it could be said that
however, difficult to explain why the board the board made a mistake in waiving the
made no earlier inquiry on the matter. ethics code. However, the earnings restate-
The report of the Senate Subcommittee was ments which upset the markets were brought
much more critical of Enron’s board than the about not by Fastow’s conflicts of interest, but
Powers Report had been. The Subcommittee by the quite separate issue of the need to take
accused board members of allowing own con- account of Andersen’s belated decision that
flicts of interest to get in the way of their the relevant transactions did not comply with
monitoring role. In particular, it argued that US GAAP.
nearly all of the non-executive directors were It must also be remembered that much of
conflicted because they received substantial the news which hurt Enron in 2001 did not
payments as consultants in addition to their involve any breach of the no-conflicts rule.
directors’ fees. In addition, some members of Members of Enron’s senior management team
the board received indirect compensation in had each profited by tens (sometimes hun-
the form of gifts made by Enron to their uni- dreds) of millions of dollars from cashing in
versities and hospitals. Part of the reaction to share options at a time when the company’s
Enron since its fall has been to regard such share price was falling and its future looked
connections with suspicion. As we noted uncertain. The sums raised by these means
above, both the Sarbanes-Oxley Act in the US dwarf even Fastow’s $30 million. When the
and the Higgs Review of Non-Executive sales were revealed in the autumn of 2001,
Directors in the UK went out of their way to there was an outcry and allegations of illegal
stress the need for genuine independence on insider dealing were made, but these have yet
the part of non-executives. to be borne out. On one view, Enron executives
In the same vein, Arthur Andersen LLP, were simply doing what many managers in
Enron’s auditors, has been blamed for failing new economy companies did in the late 1990s:
to act with the necessary independence in its they cashed in share options in a falling
dealings with Enron. Andersen received fees market before it was too late.
not just for auditing, but also for consultancy There is also substantial evidence to cast
services; and it engaged in regular exchanges doubt upon the claim that Andersen was
of employees with Enron. It earned substantial prevented from acting by its own conflicts
fees, tens of millions of dollars, from organis- of interest. We know from the report of the
ing the SPE transactions which were to prove Senate Subcommittee that in 1999 Andersen
most costly to the company. Enron’s legal told Enron’s audit committee that the com-
advisers, Vinson and Elkins, were also directly pany’s accounting practices were “at the
involved in arranging these transactions. The edge” of acceptable practice (Senate Sub-
view that Enron and other corporate scandals committee, 2002, p. 12). In internal com-
owed much to the decline in the professional munications during 2000, Andersen partners
standards of the legal and accounting “gate- characterised Enron as a “maximum risk”
keepers” during the 1990s (Coffee, 2002) is client. Its managers were said to be “very
behind several of the new Sarbanes-Oxley pro- sophisticated and enter into numerous com-
visions, such as those relating to the regular plex transactions and are often aggressive
rotation of accounting partners responsible for in structuring transactions to deal with
auditing company accounts. derived financial reporting objectives”. An
How should we assess the charge that con- Andersen lawyer said that it was “ridiculous”
flicts of interest brought Enron down? Three to characterise Enron’s accounting practices
different sets of conflicts need to be consid- as “mainstream” (Senate Subcommittee, 2002,

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004


140 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

pp. 17–19). Whatever the extent of Andersen’s In the course of Congressional hearings, and
involvement in and encouragement of Enron’s again in reply to the findings of the Senate
accounting strategy, it seems that Andersen Subcommittee, Enron directors argued that
regarded Enron as an atypical client with the they had been either misled or not informed
potential to cause harm to the audit firm itself, by senior managers of the essentially sham
as proved to be the case. nature of the SPE deals. Even if important
Nor is it convincing to see the failure of facts were kept from the board, however, this
Enron’s board as stemming from conflicts of argument for disclaiming responsibility sits
interest on the part of the non-executive direc- uneasily with the board’s responsibility for
tors. Reputationally, the directors had much internal control. One of the core principles of
more to lose from Enron’s fall than they could Anglo-American corporate governance is that
ever gain from consultancy payments and (in the words of the UK Combined Code, para.
charitable donations. Once evidence of the D2) “the board should maintain a sound
company’s perilous position began to emerge system of internal control to safeguard
in the autumn of 2001, they were highly active shareholders’ investment and the company’s
in attempting to resolve the situation, only to assets”. If the board does not put in place the
find that there was virtually nothing they procedures by which it can obtain the infor-
could do by that stage. Since the bankruptcy, mation which it needs to make the necessary
they have had to endure public obloquy and a assessment of business risks, the failure to do
Senate inquisition; and the possibility of per- so is, in the final analysis, its own. In the UK,
sonal liability for breach of the duty of care the basic obligation in paragraph D2 has been
cannot be ruled out. amplified by the Turnbull report (ICAEW,
The charge against the board is, or should 1999) and, in a significant move, one of the less
be, a quite different one: Enron’s directors remarked on provisions of Sarbanes-Oxley,
failed to make an appropriate assessment of section 404, now requires an annual disclosure
the risks to which the company was exposed. stating how the board has fulfilled its respon-
Enron was engaged in what an Andersen sibility not simply for maintaining an effective
partner called “intelligent gambling” (Senate internal control structure but also for evaluat-
Subcommittee, 2002, p. 19). The “asset lite” ing its operation.
strategy was a fundamentally precarious one Enron’s board was ultimately responsible
which depended for its success on a contin- not simply for the company’s high risk
gent combination of circumstances. Although accounting policy but also for a human
it was preeminent in the energy trading resources strategy which made it more likely
market, Enron faced growing competition than not that it would never receive the
from new entrants. Margins in derivatives and information it needed about the company’s
options trading are notoriously tight; to be accounting practices. In line with what passed
profitable, Enron had to generate considerable (then and since) for conventional wisdom on
volumes of business. It was far from unsuc- the need to incentivise employees, Enron oper-
cessful in this, hence its position as one of the ated a version of “rank and yank”, under
largest US corporations in term of revenues. which a fifth of its employees was regularly
But earnings were only ever a relatively small demoted or dismissed on the basis of per-
proportion of the cash flows generated from formance rankings drawn up by peers and
the company’s trades. It also seems that those superiors. Those who stayed the course were
profits which were recorded may well have well rewarded with stock options and perfor-
been massaged over a period of years by the mance-based increments. Under these circum-
use of SPEs (see Partnoy, 2003, pp. 325–330). stances, it is not surprising that the employees
Moreover, the misuses of SPEs which trig- engaged by Andrew Fastow with the task of
gered the company’s downfall were not iso- setting up the Chewco and Raptor SPEs
lated incidents. The use of off-balance sheet appear to have made no protest about the con-
financing had been endemic within Enron flicts of interest to which these transactions
for several years and was an integral part of gave rise, nor to have complained of the risk
a business strategy which depended for its they represented to the company’s well being.
success on creating the illusion of earnings Nor is it a surprise that these particular
growth. The board, while not aware of the employees were also extremely well rewarded
degree to which senior managers were enrich- for their roles in facilitating the relevant
ing themselves, was informed not just about transactions.
the SPE transactions which were later to lead As it turned out, it is clear that in the
to the company’s downfall; as we have seen, absence of an effective channel of communi-
it was also told by Andersen that they cation from the board to the wider organisa-
“pushed limits” and were “at the edge” of tion of the company, both the company’s
acceptability. assets and the investments of its shareholders

Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


LEARNING FROM ENRON 141

were being put on the line. Moreover, the employees were subjected to a ruthlessly
outcome produced real victims. Those affected administered system of performance appraisal
were not just the beneficiaries of the mainly which led to demotions and firings for those
public sector pension funds who had invested with low rankings. Treating employees as
heavily in Enron stock, but also the many a readily disposable asset in this way may
employees of Enron itself, who were even have been entirely consistent with the goal of
more exposed than the pension funds were to creating a “virtual corporation”, but it also
fluctuations in the company’s fortunes, thanks served to increase the risk of a catastrophic
in part to a “pensions blackout” which pre- failure of information and accountability of
vented them from moving their section 401(k) the kind which ensued in the autumn of
pension plans into alternative investments 2001. In this situation, it is likely that no
during the autumn of 2001. Appropriately amount of extra monitoring by the board of
enough for a would-be virtual corporation, it its senior managers would have made any
was these employee-shareholders who came difference.
to bear the residual risk of the company’s It has been said that Enron is “an embar-
failure; few of them were sufficiently senior rassment” for the model of the monitoring
in the organisation to have had stock option board on which so much reliance has been
plans of the kind which senior managers were placed by corporate governance reformers
continuing to exercise at the same time as the (Gordon, 2002, p. 1241). Sarbanes-Oxley
pensions blackout was in force. The most and Higgs, in their different ways, aim to
severe consequences of the failure of internal strengthen the model by insisting, among
control were felt by those who had neither other things, on stronger guarantees of
voice nor exit available to them. independence for non-executive directors. But
if the argument put forward here is correct,
this strategy is likely to be of limited value
and perhaps even counter-productive. What-
Conclusion: Enron and the limits of ever else their failings may have been,
the monitoring board Enron’s non-executive directors were as well
qualified as almost any group of outsiders
The Enron affair raises a number of funda- could have been to judge the regulatory
mental issues concerning the current trajectory and business risks which arose from the
of Anglo-American capitalism, in particular company’s operations. That they failed to do
the role of deregulation in destabilising energy so is testimony to the complexity of the mon-
markets and financial markets. Here we have itoring task. In a deregulated and liberalised
focused on a narrower but still important set market environment, the risks of competitive
of issues which arise from the characterisation failure on the part of listed companies are
of Enron as a failure of corporate governance. greater than they have ever been. This places
If anything good is to come out of this failure, non-executives, in particular, in an unenvi-
it lies in the capacity of the regulatory system able position: when companies fail, they will
to draw the right lessons. increasingly be held accountable, either
Here, the omens are not promising. Enron’s through the harm done to reputations or in
fall has been widely seen in terms of the inabil- extreme cases through litigation; but, as out-
ity of its board to effectively monitor what its siders, they will often lack the knowledge and
managers were doing, with conflicts of inter- experience to have made a difference to the
est identified as the root cause of this failure. outcome.
But while there may well have been fraud at The goal of making the task of non-
Enron, and conflicts of interest, these were not executives a meaningful one is linked to the
the sole or even the principal reason for the wider issue of how to define the objectives of
company’s collapse. Instead, Enron appears to corporate governance. In the end, Enron’s
have been a case of mismanagement of corpo- “laser focus” on shareholder value helped
rate risk. Enron collapsed because of a sys- neither its board nor, paradoxically, its share-
temic failure in which the company’s business holders. The idea that directors should be
plan and its accounting policy were impli- stewards of the company’s assets with a view
cated. The company’s managers pursued a to ensuring its sustainability over time rather
strategy of minimising its fixed costs with the than simply the representatives of the share-
aim of boosting its share price. In the end it holders is still, perhaps, regarded as heterodox
was only a short step from being “asset in corporate governance circles, such is the
lite” to using SPEs to manipulate earnings power of shareholder value. The true lesson of
and conceal debts. At the same time, the Enron is that until the power of the share-
company’s human resource strategy militated holder value norm is broken, effective reform
against a culture of transparency and trust. Its of corporate governance will be on hold.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004


142 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Acknowledgements Lee, A. (2002) Law, Economic Theory and Corpo-


rate Governance: The Origins of Legislation on
This work was first presented at a CIBAM Company Directors’ Conflicts of Interest,
conference on Corporate Governance held in 1862–1948, PhD Thesis, University of Cambridge.
Cambridge on 1 March 2003. We are grateful Millon, D. (2002) Why is Management Obsessed
with Quarterly Earnings and What Can be Done
for comments received on that occasion and About It? George Washington Law Review, 70,
from the referees and editors of this issue. 890–920.
Mitchell, L. (2001) Corporate Irresponsibility:
America’s Newest Export. New Haven, CT: Yale
References University Press.
Partnoy, F. (2003) Infections Greed. How Deceipt and
Bratton, W. (2002) Enron and the Dark Side of Risk Corrupted the Financial Markets. London:
Shareholder Value, Tulane Law Review, 76, Profile.
1275–1361. Plender, J. (2003) Going off the Rails. Global Capital
Coffee, J. (2002) Understanding Enron: It’s About the and the Crisis of Legitimacy. London: Wiley.
Gatekeepers, Stupid. Columbia Law and Econom- Powers, W., Troubh, R. and Winokur, H. (2002)
ics Working Paper no. 207. Report of Investigation by the Special Investigative
Culp, C. and Hanke, S. (2003) Empire of the Sun: An Committee of the Board of Directors of Enron Corp.
Economic Interpretation of Enron’s Energy Business. February 1 2002. Counsel: Wilmer, Cutler & Pick-
Policy Analysis no. 470. Washington, DC: Cato ering, Houston, TX.
Institute. Ribstein, L. (2003) Market vs. Regulatory Responses
Deakin, S. and Konzelmann, S. (2003) After Enron: to Corporate Fraud: A Critique of the Sarbanes-
An Age of Enlightenment? Organization, 13, Oxley Act 2002, Journal of Corporation Law, 28,
583–587. 1–67.
FSA (2002) Final Notice to Marconi plc, 11 April 2003. Senate Subcommittee (2002) The Role of the Board
London: Financial Services Authority. (Available of Directors in Enron’s Collapse. Report prepared
at http://www.fsa.gov.uk). by the Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations
Fusaro, P. and Miller, R. (2002) What Went Wrong at of the Committee on Governmental Affairs, United
Enron. London: Wiley. States Senate. Report 107-70, 107th Congress,
Gordon, J. (2002) What Enron Means for the Man- 2d Session, July 8 2002. Washington, DC: US
agement and Control of the Modern Business Senate.
Corporation: Some Initial Reflections, University
of Chicago Law Review, 69, 1233–1250. Simon Deakin is Robert Monks Professor of
Higgs, D. (2003) Review of the Role and Effectiveness Corporate Governance, Centre for Business
of Non-Executive Directors. London: HM Treasury.
Research, Judge Institute of Management,
ICAEW (1999) Internal Control. Guidance for Directors
on the Combined Code. London: Institute for Char- University of Cambridge
tered Accountants in England and Wales. Sue Konzelmann is Reader in Corporate Gov-
Kennedy, A. (2000) The End of Shareholder Value: ernance, Clore Management Centre, School of
Corporations at the Crossroads. Cambridge, MA: Management and Organisational Psychology,
Perseus. Birkbeck, University of London.

“When directors fail in their duties . . . the company (and shareholders) are on the rocky
road to ruin – sometimes at breakneck speed.” Samantha Suen ‘Duties and responsibilities’,
Company Secretary, 13 (10), October 2003, p. 4.

Volume 12 Number 2 April 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004

You might also like