You are on page 1of 15

World Development, Vol. 10, No. 9, pp. 813-827, 1982. 0305-750X/82/090813-15$03.

00/0
Printed in Great Britam. Pergamon Press Ltd.

Inflation, Interest Rates, and the Balance of


Payments during a Financial Reform:
The Case of Argentina

DONALD J. MATHIESON*
International Monetary Fund, Washington, D. C.

slumnary. - In order to evaluate the impact of recent financial reforms on the Argentine
economy, this paper presents the results of estimating a small, monthly structural model of the
Argentine economy which emphasizes the linkages between the financial system, inflation and
the balance of payments. The results are used to examine the portfolio interest rate elasticities
of both the fmncial and non-financial sectors, the determinants of the real levels of and spread
between the loan and deposit interest rates, and the responsiveness of inflation and the balance
of payments to Iarious policy measures.

1. INTRODUCTION the spread between lending and deposit rates


and examines the impact of the financial
While the number of financial reforms that reforms on inflation, the balance of payments
have been undertaken in developing countries and the financial markets. The final section
has increased significantly in the last few years, includes a summary of our results.
there is still considerable uncertainty about the
impact of such reforms on not only financial
markets but also growth, inflation and the 2. BASIC MODEL
balance of payments. To a significant degree,
this uncertainty is the result of the rather Prior to the financial reform, the Argentine
limited empirical evidence concerning the financial system was highly centralized. From
impact of these reforms’ which reflects both 1973 to June 1977, banks and non-bank
the absence of data on key variables (e.g. how financial institutions were required to hold
private sector investment is financed) and the their deposits to the account of the central
relatively short duration of some of the most bank. These institutions were paid a fixed
recent reforms. In Argentina and Chile, how- commission over the deposit rate on all deposits
ever, the monetary authorities have begun to transferred to the central bank’s account. The
collect and publish data on financial market banks’ loanable funds were provided by
variables which, at least on a monthly basis, advances and discounts from the central bank.
provide considerable information about the
effects of their financial reforms. The objective
of this paper is to utilize this new monthly *The author wishes to thank Tomas Balino and
data to estimate a small structural model of Ernest0 Gaba of the Central Bank of Argentina for
the Argentine economy which emphasizes the generously making available their loan and time
linkages between the financial system, inflation deposit interest rate series. Hernan Puentes, Frits van
and the balance of payments. Beek and Jose Braz suggested numerous data sources
The rest of this paper is divided int6 five and patiently described the institutional and regu-
sections. Section 2 describes the model’s basic latory structures of the Argentine financial system.
Thanks are also due to Kellett Hannah for his usual
theoretical structure, and Section 3 discusses excellent computational assistance. Sterie T. Beza,
the parameter estimates for this model obtained Ernest0 Hernandez-Cata and Mohsin Khan provided
from a sample of monthly data from March helpful comments on an earlier draft. The views ex-
1977 to December 1979. Section 4 considers pressed in this paper are the author’s own and do not
how the estimarion results can be used to necessarily represent those of the International Mone-
explain the behaviour of real interest rates and tary Fund.
814 WORLDDEVELOPMENT

Financial institutions were subject to a variety expected (or ermanent) level of real income
of restrictions, including control over the (Y”). Thus Xig =f,(i,)Y” for each asset i.’
composition of credit, interest rate ceilings on The existence of adjustment costs makes it
loans and deposits, and high required reserve unlikely that desired portfolio holdings will be
ratios. In March 1976, the new government maintained at each instant of time. House-
indicated that its policy objective was the holds and firms will nonetheless attempt to
decentralization of deposits and loans and the move towards this optimal portfolio mix. The
freeing of interest rates. The initial reform in desired change in the private sector’s portfolio
May 1976 allowed financial instituticns to holding of a given asset is assumed to take the
expand their operations with 30day certificates form of D In -Yi = yi[ln Xp - L In Xi] where
of deposit which carried freely negotiated In is the natural logarithm, LXi,t = Xi,t_r, and
interest rates and to use these funds to make D = the differential operator d/dt.
loans at market interest rates. In examining the non-bank sector’s portfolio
In June 1977, the decentralization of behaviour, this study will focus on the behaviour
deposits took place. This was accompanied by of four key assets: currency, time deposits,
the freeing of interest rates and the establish- broad money and bank loans. Holdings of
ment of a uniform reserve ratio of 45% on all currency (C) change according to
deposits. In the period rhrough mid-1980, there
has been rapid real growth of financial asset
holdings (especially time deposits), high nominal
and real (when adjusted for actual inflation)
lending and deposit rates, and a relatively large
spread between lending and deposit rates. In
addition, the 1977-1980 period witnessed a
- cr3(rG - 7re)+ In Ye (la)
significant decline in inflation and a sustained
balance-of-payments surplus which has primarily where3 P = price level
reflected large capital inflows. rre = expected rate of inflation
The overall impact of the financial reform ‘T = rate of return on time deposits
on growth, inflation and the balance of pay- rG = rate of return on government
ments can only be accurateiy identified within treasury biIls
the context of a general equilibrium model of u” = expected or permanent income.
the Argentine economy. Since our sample This implies that desired real holdings of
is composed of monthly data, there are certain currency rise with increases in the level of
variables such as investment expenditures for permanent income and the expected real rate
which there are no observations. Our model of return on currency and fall with higher real
thus focuses on the linkages between the yields on time deposits or government treasury
financial reform, interest rates, re31 financial bills. The expected real return on currency is
assets, inflation and the balance of payments defined as the negative of the expected rate of
that were generated by private bank and non- inflation.4 Since time deposits and government
bank sector portfolio adjustments. These treasury bills are viewed as substitutes for
linkages can best be described by first con- currency, a rise in the expected rate of return
sidering the portfolio behaviour of the private on these alternative assets would reduce desired
sector. currency holdings.
The behaviour of non-bank sector holdings
of time deposits (T) is given by
(a) The non-bank sector’s portfolio behaviour

It is useful to distinguish between the Din(a) = -y,[In($-Lln (:)I


portfolio behaviour of the bank and non-
bank sectors. The bank sector consists of the + XrZr with (2)
financial institutions, and the non-bank sector
is composed of firms and households. The non- = a4 - ag(- ne) + @rT - n’)
bank sector’s portfolio adjustments reflect
attempts to establish a preferred mix of assets --7f)+ln r’
and liabilities. The desired real holdings of any - &7(rG (24
asset or liability (Xf) are assumed to depend where Z, = a dummy variable reflecting the
on the vector of expected real returns ($) that decentralization of deposits.’ Desired real
can be earned on portfolio instruments and the holdings of time deposits increase whenever
THE CASE OF ARGENTINA 815

there is a rise in permanent income or in the The non-bank sector’s desired holdings of
expected real rate of return on time deposits. bank loans therefore would fall as the expected
In contrast, a higher real return on currency or real cost of bank loans rises, the expected real
government securities would lead to a decline cost of foreign loans falls, the expected yield
in desired holdings of real deposits. The presence on government securities declines, and as
of the yield on government treasury bills reflects permanent income is reduced. (~12 is assumed
the fact that the authorities have used this yield to encompass the real return on capital (taken
to provide a ‘floor’ under the time deposits rate. as a constant in the short run). The rG -rre
Broad money (M) equals the sum of currency term reflects the fact that firms and households
(c), demand deposits (A’) and time deposits (T), can always sell off their holdings of government
i.e. M = C + N + T.While we could work with securities to finance other purchases but are less
the individual demand functions, the concept likely to do so if the yield on such assets is
of an overall excess demand or supply of relatively high. oi4 is positive since foreign
monetary assets will be usefulin our formulation borrowing is viewed as an alternative to
of price and balance-of-payments behaviour. domestic borrowing.
This reflects the fact that currency, demand The expected cost of foreign funds is com-
deposits and time deposits are the most liquid posed of three elements: (1) the nominal cost
assets in the private non-bank sector’s portfolio of the foreign loan (+), (2) the expected
and thus are most likely to respond quickly to capital loss (gain) associated with any anticipated
changing portfolio preferences. Thus, the adjust- exchange rate depreciation (appreciation)
ment function for the overall stock of money is during the period of the loan (xe), and (3) the
cost imposed by any government capital
Dh(f)= [h($-Lln($]
y3 controls. In Argentina, government regulations
have affected not only the maturity structure
+ h2Z1, with of foreign liabilities but also the cost of forward
(3)
cover. For example, in October 1977, the
= CKa+ ag(- n’) + cr,,(rT - ne) authorities established a one-year minimum
maturity on foreign borrowing, and this was
subsequently increased to a two-year minimum
- arc3 -7T=)+ln P. (34 maturity in December 1977. The two-year
Since In (M/P)d reflects the sum of three minimum maturity requirement was not
individual demands, this implies that there eliminated until 1979. This type of capital
is some ambiguity regarding the signs of os control adds a significant risk premium to the
and ~1~0.For example, a rise in the time.deposit cost of foreign borrowing. This means that the
rate would increase the demand for time cost of such borrowing (expressed in local
deposits but reduce the demands for currency currency will equal rF + xe + p (where p is
and demand deposits. The oie term can thus be the risk premium induced by the minimum
positive (negative) if the change in the demand maturity requirement) rather than just rF + xe.
for time deposits dominates the change in the An additional capital control which had a
demands for currency and demand deposits. significant impact on the cost of foreign bor-
In addition to being a major holder of rowing was the establishment in May 1978
financial system liabilities, the non-bank sector of a deposit requirement on foreign borrowing.
(especially firms) is also a major borrower. The At that time, domestic borrowers were required
non-bank sector’s adjustment of its holdings of to deposit 20% of all foreign borrowing in zero
bank loans (B) is given by interest deposits in domestic currency. This
increased the cost of foreign
(rF + xe)/0.8. This requirement wasba\zz?g
Din(f) = -y,[ln ($-Lln(f)] in December 1978. Ignoring for the moment
the risk premium induced by the minimum
+ hsZ1, with (4) maturity requirement, this means that the cost
of foreign borrowing becomes 6i(rF + x=)/0.8,
cx13(rg - 7re)+ a14(&- ne) where 6, takes on the value 1 during periods
when the deposit requirement is in effect and
is zero otherwise.
+ %(rc -7P)fln r’ (W In addition to these capital control measures,
where rb = nominal cost of foreign borrowing the cost of forward cover also has been influ-
rB = nominal cost of domestic bank enced by government policies. From the
loans. beginning of our sample until July 1977, the
816 WORLDDEVELOPMENT

authorities offered forward cover on approved (1980) have recently argued, however, such an
foreign borrowing at a guaranteed swap rate. expectations structure is perfectly ‘rational’
During this period, the swap rate represented (represents an optimal forecasting technique)
the cost of forward cover. After July 1977, the whenever economic agents are uncertain about
absence of a well-developed forward market whether observed shocks to the economy are
meant that the private sector would measure permanent or transitory. In the Argentine
the cost of forward cover in terms of the economy, which is undergoing extensive
expected rate of depreciation of the exchange structural changes, such uncertainty is endemic.
rate (x’). Taken together, these factors imply When this is the case, all past observations on a
that the cost of foreign borrowing will be given variable are useful in determining the
given by permanency of past shocks. In Brunner et al.
(1980), it has also been argued that the size of
6 = (rF+xq(l-6i -8a)+Si(rF+P)
our pi and f12 will be positively related to the
IO.8 + b@F + rS> + Pl + P2 ratio of the variance of permanent shocks to
the variance of temporary shocks. Thus, if the
where rF = nominal foreign interest rate (in
ratio of the variance of permanent shocks to
% per month)
the variance of temporary shocks is low, then
rs = cost of central bank exchange
the 0, will be low, giving important weight to
guarantee in forward cover (in
past history. This means that the values of the
% per month)
xe = expected rate of depreciation of 0, which provide the best description of the
the exchange rate (in % per revision of exchange rate and price expectations
month) will also yield information about the relative
= 1 from S/78 to 12/78,0 otherwise variance of permanent and transitory shocks
Ei2 = 1 from 3177 to 7/77,0 otherwise in the Argentine economy.
Pi = risk premium induced by estab-
lishment of minimum maturities
of one Cpr) and two (pa) years. (b) The bank sector
Throughout our specification of non-bank
behaviour, the expected rate of inflation and Financial institutions make two important
the expected rate of depreciation of the simultaneous decisions: (1) what sources of
exchange rate have played important roles in funds they will attempt to utilize, and (2) what
determining the real rates of return on financial earning assets they will purchase. The sources
assets. To simplify, we will assume that the of funds include retained earnings, owners
private sector forms its exchange rate and price subscriptions, foreign borrowing, borrowing
expectations on the basis of past experience from the central bank and issuance of demand
with actual exchange rate and price movements. and time deposits. In the short run, we will
Thus take the owner’s commitment of funds as
given and assume that the use of the other
Dxe = &(Lx - Lxe) with 0 < pi < 1 (5) sources of funds depends on relative cost of
x = actual monthly rate of change of these funds and any restrictions the authorities
where
impose on their use. This means that the use
the exchange rate
L = lag operator (Lx, = xtwl) of source Si as a proportion of total funds (fl
D=l-L
will be taken as a function of the vector (?n)
of relative nominal costs of the various sources
and
Dne = f12(Ln - Ln”) with 0 <pa < 1 (6) of funds and the returns that can be earned
on bank assets. Nominal returns are used since
where n = actual rate of change in the bank profits are based on the differential
wholesale price index (per % per between the cost of their funds and the yield
month). on their assets. In addition, the banks’ utilization
One objective of our study will be to identify of a given source will be influenced by any
the values of & and & which best describe the government reguIations affecting such portfolio
revision of exchange rate and price expectations. selections. The vector of these restrictions will
It is often argued that this type of adoptive be denoted by g. Thus Si/F=fiB(iBpg). The
expectations structure is ‘irrational’ in the use of any given source of funds would decline
sense that it can imply extended periods during as its cost rises relative to other sources.
which there is a significant gap between actual At the same time the decision is taken as to
and expected price movements. As White the source of funds, banks also have to decide
(1980a) and Brunner, Cukierman and Meltzer on the earning assets to be purchased. The
THE CASE OF ARGENTINA 817

desired holdings of each asset Aj relative to In this formulation, total bank funds are
total bank assets (F’) will also be a function of defined to equal
the vector of the nominal returns on bank F = (1 -K)ZV+(l -K)T+BB+CA+ZO
assets and the cost of bank funds and any
government restrictions (g) on asset selection. (8)
Thus Aj/F = Q&B, g). The purchases of any where BB = banking system borrowing and
given asset will rise as its yield rises relative to advances from the central bank
other asset yields. CA = banking system capital account
In an economy such as Argentina’s where all IO = other sources (net) of banking
bank assets and liabilities (apart from owners’ system funds.
subscriptions) have relatively short maturities Since our sample covers the periods of both
(many loans are renegotiated every 30 days), it centralized and decentralized deposits, there
is assumed that banks are in a position to con- have been substantial changes in the sources of
tinually rearrange not only their sources of bank funds. Prior to the decentralization of
funds and asset holdings but also their loan and deposits, bank loanable funds came primarily
deposit rates so as to achieve their desired from central bank advances and their own
portfolio positions within the observation capital resources. In the post-decentralization
period. Short-run financial market equilibrium period, however, the much lower required
would be achieved when market interest rates reserve ratio meant that demand and time
adjust to ensure that banks’ desired holdings deposits became a much larger proportion of
of their portfolio assets and liabilities equal the disposable bank assets.
actual stocks being generated by non-bank The banks’ desired supply of time deposits
portfolio adjustments. Thus, while it is assumed is given by
that interest rates adjust so as to clear the
market in the short run, it is not assumed that = azo-crzl[rT-rEK-rB(l -K)]
the non-bank sector necessarily holds its
desired mix of portfolio assets at each instant - a22 [rT - rEK - rc 1
in time.
Under this market clearing hypothesis, the - (Yz3[rT - r,qK - rb]. (9)
short-run behaviour of the loan (rn) and time This means that the desired proportion of
deposit (IT) interest rates reflect the behaviour bank funds generated by issuing time deposits
of the non-bank sector demands for time will rise when there is a decline in the cost
deposits [equation (2)l and loans [equation of time deposits (adjusted for interest payments
(4)] and the banking system’s desired holdings
on required reserves), a higher return on either
of loans to the private sector and issuance
bank loans or government securities, or a rise
of time deposits. The desired supply of bank
in the cost of foreign funds.
loans to the private sector is given by
S

In E = or6 + (Yr,[rs(l -K) -r’r + &K] (c) Price behoviour


0
Portfolio disequilibrium in the non-bank
sector not only affects financial markets but
also spills over to affect inflation, output and
where K = required reserve ratio
the balance of payments. Since our analysis
r&?= interest paid on required reserves. is based on monthly data, data availability limits
Banks’ holdings of private sector loans are the types of variables that can be treated as
assumed to rise as the loan rate increases endogenous. Our efforts will focus on explaining
relative to the cost of domestic deposits,’ the linkages between financial markets and the
the cost of foreign funds, or the return on behaviour of prices and the balance of pay-
government securities. The impact of the ments.
government treasury bill rate reflects the Our analysis of prices is based on the
fact that government securities can substitute distinction between the domestic and foreign
for loans to the private Sector in banks’ port- components of the wholesale price index. The
folios. The supply function for bank loans is overall wholesale price index (P) will equal
based on interest rate differentials primarily
because bank profits are generated by the P = a&-$=P$-a= (10)
difference between the cost of bank funds and where Pr, = price index for domestic goods
the returns earned on bank assets. PF = price for foreign goods.
818 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Domestic goods are those produced locally. the overall government deficit and the variables
Foreign prices will equal world prices adjusted (e.g. government expenditures) that determine
for exchange rate and tariff (or quota) effects. its size. At this time, our model therefore only
The prices of domestic goods are assumed to includes a balance-of-payments equation. This
respond to both international price arbitrage makes it less likely that our equation will be
influences and domestic demand factors8 Thus free of simultaneous equation bias.
It is assumed that the balance of payments
PDE 1
Dln(P~fPp) = a26--27LIn - will be influenced by attempts to arbitrage
i PF 1 goods and security prices across countries and
+ oL2fdLIn (M/P) - In (M/P)dl + X4Z2 + X5Z3 by portfolio disequilibrium. In the long run,
goods market equilibrium will require that
(11)
domestic prices increase at the same rate as
where 22, Za= dummy variables (see Appendix world prices adjusted for any changes in the
2). The rate of increase of the prices of exchange rate and trade restrictions. Similarly,
domestic goods would rise relative to the steady-state equilibrium in the asset market
foreign rate of inflation (inclusive of the effects requires that domestic interest rates do not differ
of tariff and exchange rate changes) whenever from foreign interest rates plus the expected
the prices of domestic goods are sufficiently (as rate of depreciation of the exchange rate by
determined by el) below foreign prices. In more than the risk premium attached to lending
addition, domestic demand pressures, as to Argentine nationals by foreign financial insti-
measured by the excess suppiy of real money, tutions (i.e. interest rate parity must hold). In
can drive the domestic rate of inflation above the short run, any departures from either
the international inflation rate. The presence of relative purchasing power parity or interest rate
both international price arbitrage and monetary parity will lead to arbitrage flows and give rise
disequilibrium effects arise because the Argen- to changes in holdings of foreign exchange
tine economy is neither completely closed nor reserves (assuming the authorities are following
opened. While the Argentine authorities have a given exchange rate policy).
been gradually reducing trade barriers, domestic In addition, portfolio disequilibrium will
prices have not been perfectly aligned with affect decisions regarding trade and capital
foreign prices due to the effects of the remain- movements. Since monetary holdings represent
ing trade barriers and the fact that it takes time the most liquid assets, an excess supply (or
to develop the types of import and wholesale demand) of money is likely to have a strong
institutions that will quickly arbitrage any short-run impact on the balance-of-payments.
profit opportunities between foreign and The overall growth of Argentina’s stock of
domestic markets. international reserves is thus given by
DlnR = azg- OL~(DhPD-DhPF-C12)
(d) Balance ofpayments + cx31(rB -rb - E13) + osz(ln M d-LlnM)
+ xez, + h,Z&+ (12)
Portfolio disequilibrium can also affect the
state of the balance of payments. This will be This implies that the balance of payments will
especially true with regard to any excess supply improve whenever the domestic rate of infla-
of money. To reflect the relationship between tion (inclusive to the effects of changes in the
the excess money supply and the balance of exchange rate and trade restrictions), the
payments, it is important to recognize that the domestic loan rate rises relative to the foreign
domestic monetary base can be increased by interest rate (adjusted for both the expected
central bank purchases of either domestic or rate of depreciation of the exchange rate and
foreign assets. This implies that simultaneous any risk premium), and as any excess nominal
equation bias can only be avoided if the model demand for money is created.
contains (1) a balance-of-payments equation,
(2) an identity linking the money supply, 3. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
domestic credit and the balance of payments,
and (3) an equation explaining the behaviour of (a) Parameter estimates
domestic credit. This last equation requires
specification of the relationship between the Table 1 presents the empirical results for our
central bank’s issuance of domestic credit and model based on a sample of monthly data from
the determinants of the government deficit. March 1977 to December 1979. The estimates
Unfortunately, there is little monthly data on were derived by using a full information, maxi-
THE CASE OF ARGENTINA 819

Table 1. Parameter estimates for Argentina *

Equation Dependent variable Explanatory variable Parameter Estimate t-Ratio

(1) D In (C/F? Adjustment parameter 0.059 2.03


Constant 0.636 0.80
--ne 22.354 2.22
rT- ne 10528 2.05
ro-rrne
(2) Din VIP) Adjustment parameter 0.061 6.69
Constant 1.175 4.01
--ne -5.911 1.63
rT-# 30.989 6.01
ro --ne 30.466 4.23
Z, 0.013 1.04
(3) Adjustment parameter 0.039 2.95
Constant 1.390 6.33
--rre 1.393 1.61
rT-fi 4.861 2.65
ro- ne 2.892 1.91
Z, 0.016 2.68
(4) D In (B/P) Adjustment parameter 0.030 1.91
Constant 1.470 2.50
rg--ne 12.417 1.75
rk- 7re 6.807 1.51
ro-ti
Z, -0.002 0.18
(5) Xe 0.25
(6) 0.50
(7) L&p Constant 0.497 14.68
Ml -K) --IT+ ‘EK 5.509 9.41
rB-rG 1.020 5.67
‘B -rb
Constant 1.411 11.01
rT-rEK-rg(l -K) 15.164 7.25
‘T-rEK-rG 4.411 5.78
rT-rEK -rb
(10) In (P) Constant 1.001 2J99.08
PD 0.937 817.21
(11) D In @D/&d Constant 0.164 1.70

L m @DEI/&) 0.359 13.04


[L hl W/PI - ln omdl 11.550 2.98
Z2 -0.152 4.31
Z3 0.064 5.08
(12) DlnR Constant -0.030 1.77

D~PD -DhPp-•E,, 0.650 7.81


1.991 6.31
$$L.-L&fj 0.717 4.07
Z, 0.023 0.95
Z, 0.034 2.88

* All of the behavioural parameters are defined to be positive.


t Imposed.
t Chosen to maximize the value of the likelihood function (no standard error).

mum likelihood estimator (see Wymer, 1978, mates are generally of the anticipated sign and
for a discussion) that allowed for the im- significant.
position of the approximate cross-equation The private non-bank sector’s portfolio
restrictions. All of the demand and supply func- demands show a sharp distinction between the
tions are well identified and the parameter esti- short- and long-run responses to interest rate,
820 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 2. Elasticities*

Short-m Long-run
Dependent Explanatory elasticity ‘t elasticity
Equation variable variable (t-ratio) (t-ratio)

(1) In (C/P) -l+ 0.006 (0.49) 0.101 (0.50)


rT -0.045 (5.67) -0.758 (2.05)
-0.043 (5.67) -0.735 (2.05)
0.059 (2.03) l.O$
0.031 (2.92) 0.500 (2.81)
0.137 (12.46) 2.231 (6.01)
-0.130 (5.27) -;A$7 (4.23)
0.061 (6.69)
ln @f/P) 0.010 (2.82) 0:261 (5.51)
*T 0.014 (2.58) 0.350 (2.65)
-0.008 (1.99) -0.202 (1.91)
ln?e 0.039 (2.95) l.O$
(4) -iTe -0.003 (0.29) -0.093 (0.28)
rB -0.032 (3.27) -1.080 (1.75)
‘Z 0.014 (2.70) 0.464 (1.51)
0.014 (2.70) 0.475 (1.51)
In’%! 0.030 (1.91) 1.0%
(7) rB 0.743 (11.01) 0.743 (11.01)
rG -0.071 (5.67)’ -0.071 (5.67)
rk -0.070 i5.67) -0.070 (5.67)
rT --r,& -0.270 (9.41) -0.270 (9.41)
(8) f-B 1.557 (7.25) 1.557 (7.25)
rG 0.308 (5.78) 0.308 (5.78)
ri; 0.301 (5.78) 0.301 (5.78)
‘T -~EK -1.175 (8.55) -1.175 (8.55)

* Evaluated at sample means.


t The short-run elasticity is the product of the relevant explanatory variable parameter (ais) and the correspond-
ing adjustment parameter (r#) evaluated at the sample means.
$ Imposed.

inflation and expected income movements. on government treasury bills increased.


Desired real holdings of currency have respon- Although the effect of a higher expected real
ded positively to the expected real return on return on currency (CQ) is not significant, it is
currency (fl) and negatively to the expected of the opposite sign of that hypothesized. This
real returns on time deposits (TT- 7re) and could reflect the fact that a reduction in the
government treasury bills irG - ?re). As shown expected rate of inflation represented more
in Table 2, however, there was a much smaller than just a higher return on currency holdings
initial response to changes in Ile, rT, and rG and, in addition, implied that in general
than in the long run. For example, a 1% financial assets became more attractive as infla-
increase in the time deposit rate would initially. tion declined. The significant negative relation-
reduce real holdings of currency by only ship between time deposit holdings and the
0.045%. In the long run, this same change in rT expected real return on government securities
would induce an 0.76% reduction in real cur- implies that the Argentine authorities were suc-
rency holdings. To a significant degree, this cessful in using the government security rate to
reflects the relatively slow adjustment of actual provide a floor under the time deposit rate.
to desired holdings of currency. The adjustment The estimate of y2 indicates that the mean
of actual to desired real holdings of currency time lag involved in the adjustment of actual to
show a mean time lag of somewhat greater than desired real holdings of time deposits was about
18 months. 16 months. This relatively slow adjustment
Real non-bank sector holdings of time meant that the initial effects of an increase in
deposits increased whenever there was higher rG, rT or ne on aCtLId holdings of time deposits
expected income or a real return on time were relatively small (see Table 2). A 1%
deposits and fell whenever the expected return increase in rG, for example, yielded a reduction
THE CASE OF ARGENTINA 821

of real time deposit holdings of only 0.13% in interest rate elasticities in the short run. The
the short run vs a 2 .l% reduction in the long mean time lag implicit in the estimated adjust-
run. ment parameter (74) is over 33 months. This
Since broad money equals the sum of cur- relatively slow speed of adjustment results in a
rency, demand deposits and time deposits, our sharp distinction between the short- and long-
earlier theoretical discussion indicated that run interest rate elasticities. For example, in the
there was some ambiguity surrounding the signs long run, a 1% increase in the loan rate would
of the partial elasticities of the real demand for lead to a 1 .l% reduction in the real demand for
money with respect to the expected real returns loans. In the short run, however, such an
on currency (-ne) and time deposits (rT - rr”). increase in rB would result in only a 0.03%
Our estimation results nonetheless yielded reduction. This low short-run elasticity is con-
positive and significant coefficients for both [~a’ sistent with the view that such loans were
and ale. The composite elasticities implied by primarily used to provide working capital (see
the estimates of cr9, ala and al1 (see Table 2) McKinnon, 1973). As will be argued later, the
nonetheless indicate lower interest rate elastici- interest inelastic nature of the short-run
ties with reSpeCt to Changes in ?f, r~, and rG demand for bank loans played an important
than those suggested by the individual demands role in explaining the existence of a high real
for currency and time deposits. This reflects the loan rate in the Argentine financial system.9
fact that changes in asset yields induced some The proportion of total bank assets devoted
substitution amongst the components of M. For to loans to the private non-bank sector [equa-
example, whereas the real demand for time tion (7)1 was most sensitive to changes in the
deposits has a long run elasticity of 2.1 with loan rate and the net cost of time deposits but
respect to a 1% change in r~, the corresponding was considerably less responsive to changes in
elasticity for real holdings of broad money is the foreign loan rate or the treasury bill rate. A
only 0.4%. The lower elasticity for overall 1% increase in the loan rate would raise the pro-
money demand reflects the fact that a higher portion of total bank assets held as loans to the
rT not only induces larger real holdings of time private sector by 0.74%. In contrast, a 1%
deposits but small real holdings of currency and increase in the net cost of time deposits (rT-
demand deposits. Note, however, that a reduc- r&C) would lower BJF by only 0.27%.”
tion in the expected rate of inflation or an The proportion of total bank funds gener-
increase in the yield on time deposits will still ated via time deposits was quite responsive to
induce an increase in real holdings of broad the net cost of time deposits (rT- rj$), the
money. Although not highly significant, the cost of foreign funds (r-h), the yield on govem-
estimated value of or1 also indicates that a rise ment securities, and the loan rate. The
in the government treasury bill rate did lead to relatively high elasticity with respect to the net
a reduction in real money holdings. This pri- cost of time deposits (- 1 .I 75%) indicates a
marily reflected the movement out of time willingness to substitute other sources of funds
deposits. for time deposits whenever the cost of time
As with the individual demand for currency deposits increased. This proportion was also
and time deposits, the short-run elasticities of very responsive to increases in the loan rate
the overall demand for money were much (1.557%).
smaller than the long-run elasticities. A 1% As shown in Table 1, the likelihood function
reduction in the expected rate of inflation attains the maximum value when the adaptive
induced only a 0.01% initial increase in the expectations coefficient for exchange rate
demand for real money vs a 0.26% increase in expectations was assigned a value of 0.25 and
the long run. This reflected a mean time lag in the coefficient for price expectations was given
the adjustment of actual to desired broad the value of 0.50. This implied a mean time lag
money holdings of approximately 25 months. in the formulation of expectations of five
The private non-bank sector’s demand for months for the exchange rate and three months
bank loans is not as well estimated as the other for prices. As argued earlier, the somewhat
portfolio demand equations. Although the co- longer lag for exchange rate expectations could
efficients on the expected real cost of bank imply that the ratio of the variance of perma-
loans and foreign funds and the expected return nent shocks to the variance of transitory shocks
on government securities all have the correct is viewed as being lower than the corresponding
sign, they are not as highly significant as for the ratio for prices. This relatively low variance
other demand functions. These estimates none- ratio for exchange rate expectations may reflect
theless imply both a slow adjustment of actual the fact that the authorities followed a policy
to desired holdings of bank loans and low of preannouncing exchange rate changes toward
822 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

the end of our sample period, which would more successful than during the second two
have had the effect of reducing the variance of months.
permanent changes. The parameter estimates in the balance of
The price equations [ ( 10) and ( 1 I)] indicate payments equation indicate that price and
that both the overall and domestic goods price interest rate arbitrage and portfolio disequilib-
levels responded systematically to influences of rium factors have played important roles in
international price arbitrage and monetary dis- determining the short-run behaviour of the
equilibrium. From equation (lo), it is clear that balance of payments. For example, a 1%
domestic prices have received the largest weight increase in the domestic rate of inflation
in the overall price index (some 94%). The relative to the foreign inflation rate (adjusted
results for equation (11) imply that the prices for exchange rate and trade restriction changes)
of domestic goods responded not only to the would lead to a 0.65% reduction in the rate of
rate of change of foreign prices but also to any growth of the central bank’s accumulation of
departure of the prices of domestic goods foreign exchange reserves. There was an even
relative to foreign prices from a longer term more dramatic response to a change in the
equilibrium value (represented by er). As a interest rate differential between domestic and
result of this concurrent and lagged response, foreign interest rates. The estimate of ojl indi-
the price arbitrage process involved a mean time cates that a 100 basis point increase in the
lag of approximately three months between any domestic interest rate relative to the foreign
changes in foreign prices and the resulting cost of funds (adjusted for expected exchange
change in domestic prices. In addition to these rate movements) would lead to approximately a
price arbitrage effects, domestic prices have also 2% increase in the monthly rate of growth of
been influenced by any excess supply of Argentina’s stock of international reserves. This
money. is indicative of a significant interest rate
The dummy variables 22 and 23 reflect the elasticity for short-term capital flows.
effects of the four-month ‘price truce’ during Any excess supply of nominal money affec-
March-June 1977 when the authorities ted not only inflation but also the balance of
imposed limitations on price and wage increases payments. A 1% increase in any excess supply
in an effort to curb inflation. As can be seen of nominal money would result in a 0.72%
from the estimates of ho and As, this price truce reduction in the rate of growth of the central
was somewhat successful in slowing domestic bank’s stock of foreign exchange reserves.
inflation relative to foreign inflation although The estimate for the coefficient (X4) on the
the efforts during the first two months of the dummy variable (24) for the one-year mini-
truce (represented by 22) appear to have been mum maturity restriction on foreign borrowing
appears to be of the wrong sign. Ordinarily, one
would expect the imposition of such minimum
maturity requirement to reduce foreign borrow-
Table 3. Means-squarederrors of in-sampleforecasts,
ing and hence the accumulation of foreign
March 1977-December 1979*
exchange reserves. The positive sign on X4 may
Mean-squared Mean-squared reflect the fact, however that the one-year mini-
error of error of mum maturity (established in October 1977)
Variables static forecasts dynamic forecasts was quickly followed by a two-year minimum
maturity (in December 1977). Thus, it is
In C 0.075 1 0.8250 conceivable that in anticipation of even tighter
In T 0.275 3 0.2512 capital controls, the private sector increased its
In M 0.1335 1.4718 foreign borrowing in the period immediately
In B 0.1027 0.8872 following the establishment of the one-year
rBt 0.0109 0.0344 minimum maturity.
rTt 0.0092 0.008 1
In P 0.0698 0.3689 (b) In-sample forecasting efficiency
In PD 0.0744 0.4144
lllR 0.1885 15.4322 Table 3 provides information on the static
and dynamic in-sample forecasts using our
* In per cent.
model. The static forecasts utilize the actual
t Prediction errors on the interest rates are in units of
percentage points. Static and dynamic means-squared values of the exogenous variables and the lagged
errors as a proportion of the average interest rates are endogenous variables; whereas the dynamic
0.1253 and 0.3961% respectively for the loan rate and forecasts imply mean squared forecast errors of
0.1281 and 0.1132% respectively for the time deposit less than 1% for all variables. These are reason-
rate. ably small errors for monthly data which
THE CASE OF ARGENTINA 823

generally show much greater variability than tion. During our sample period, for example,
quarterly or annual data. The means-squared the average real ex post loan rate was 1.55% per
errors for the dynamic forecasts are somewhat month and the corresponding average real time
larger than those for the static forecasts. The deposit rate was 0.06% per month. As shown in
dynamic errors range from less than 1% to more Figures 1 and 2, however, there has been con-
than 15% (in the case of the level of foreign siderable variability in these real rates with
exchange reserves). The relatively large error for generally higher ex post real rates in the begin-
the balance-of-payments equation reflects the ning of the sample period than at the end.
fact that we have modelled only a subsector of It is also important to note that our esti-
the economy and have not captured the full mates of the average ex ante real loan and
feedback between the balance of payments and deposit rates are considerably lower, which
the financial and real sectors of the economy. reflects the fact that inflation has generally
been declining during our sample period and
that the expected rate of inflation is based on
4. THE IMPACT OF THE FINANCIAL past as well as recent inflation. The expected
REFORM real loan rate has averaged 0.9% per month
which is approximately only half the ex post
It is useful to consider what our empirical real loan rate. The ex ante real time deposit
results imply about two controversial aspects of rate was actually negative at - 0.5% per month.
the Argentine financial reform. First, why did Figures 1 and 2 also illustrate that here has
such high real interest rates appear during the been considerable variability in real interest
early stages of the financial reform? Second, rates with the ex ante real loan rate ranging
why did the spread between lending and from -2.1 to 4.0% per month and the expec-
deposit rates become so large at various times? ted real time deposit rate varying from - 3.4 to
It has been argued that in both Argentina 1.9% per month.
and Chile the freeing of interest rates resulted Another characteristic of the financial
in very high nominal and real rates of return reform process has been a large spread between
that discouraged capital formation and produc- the loan and time deposit rates. This spread has

Ex post real loon rote,, ,,/

March 1977 1978 I979 December


* The seosonolly adjusted nominal loon rote (ess the expected rote of inflotlon
+ The seosonolly adjusted nominal Loon rote Less the octuol rote of mflotfon

Figure 1. Ex post and ex ante real loan rate.


824 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

2 c
r
E
2 ’
$
a
‘; 0

z
&
a -I
1

-2

-3

-4
March 1977 1978 1979 December
* The seasanatly adjusted nominal deposit rate Less the expected rate of lnflotton
+ The seasonally adjusted nomlnat deposit rate Less the actual rate of inflation

Figure 2. Ex post and ex ante real deposit rates.

averaged 1.5% per month. This unadjusted Even if expected real interest rates have not
spread reflects the impact of both regulatory been ‘too’ high there are still the issues of why
and market factors. The authorities have influ- there has been such substantial variation in
enced this spread through changes in the these rates and why the net spread between the
required reserve ratio and the payment of deposit and loan rates has been relatively large.
interest on reserves. The resulting net spread is The answers to these questions he in the charac-
defined as the loan rate less the time deposit teristics of the Argentine portfolio demands
rate adjusted for the payment of interest on and supplies as well as in the types of regula-
required reserves (QK) divided by one minus tory changes that have occurred. In analysing
the required reserve ratio (rB - [r~ - QKI/ this issue, it is useful to distinguish between the
(1 -K). The division by 1 -K reflects the fact period immediately following the initial
that banks could only use 1 -K% of each peso reforms and the subsequent time period. During
of time deposit they received. This net spread the early stages of any financial reform which
for the period from June 1977 to December attempts to correct the distortions that have
1979 has tended to decline over the sample been created by past financial repression, one
period but has still averaged 1.3% per month. would have to expect a fair degree of interest
How can our results be used to explain the rate instability. This instability reflects the
presence of high real interest rates and the size fact that the newly liberalized financial system
of the net spread between lending and deposit would usually inherit from the repressed system
rates? First, it must be emphasized that, on an not only a history of high and variable inflation
expected basis, the real loan and deposit rates but also small initial real stocks of financial
do not seem to have been equally high. The assets (representing the response to highly nega-
expected real deposit rate has averaged a tive real yields on such assets), and a lingering
negative 0.5% per month and the real loan rate system of financial payments on reserves, and
less than 1% per month (approximately 11.4% limitations on entry and competition in the
on an annual basis). This real loan rate financial system).
primarily reflects the high real loan rates of the In the period starting early in 1978, the
early period of the financial reform. behaviour of the real rates of return and the net
THE CASE OF ARGENTINA 825

spread between lending and deposit rates were supplies of bank loans and time deposits
less affected by the inherited financial stocks implied a loan rate much more responsive than
and inflation experienced and more influenced the time deposit rate to changes in demand or
by the continuing regulatory reforms and the supply conditions. And in a system character-
nature of the interest elasticities of the private ized by an excess demand for real credit, one
sector’s portfolio demands and supplies of could therefore expect a significant departure
financial assets. The most crucial reforms have of the loan rate from the time-deposit rate.
been the gradual reduction of the required
reserve ratio and the payment of interest on 5. SUMMARY
reserves which have helped to reduce the gross
loan-time deposit interest rate spread. The This paper has described the results of esti-
influence of portfolio elasticities can be illustra- mating a small structural model of the Argen-
ted by considering the demand and supply of tine financial system, the price formation
bank loans. As shown in Table 2, the short-run process and the determinants of the overall
elasticity of the non-bank sector’s demand for balance of payments during its recent financial
bank loans was only - 0.03%. Similarly, the reform. Our results have indicated that move-
supply of bank loans had a higher but still ments in domestic interest rates, good prices
inelastic response of 0.74%. The presence of and the balance of payments have been strongly
relative inelastic demand and supply functions influenced by domestic portfolio preferences as
for bank loans meant that exogenous increases well as policy actions and foreign variables.
in the demand for loans could drive up the loan Differences between actual and expected infla-
rate quite sharply in the short run even though tion have implied that ex post real interest rates
the long-run response would be much more have been higher than e.x nnte (or expected)
moderate. real interest rates. The spread between the
The net loan-deposit rate spread was also deposit and lending rates has been influenced
influenced by the relatively interest inelastic not only by domestic financial policy (e.g. the
nature of the short-run demand for time reduction in the required reserve ratio and the
deposits (an elasticity of only 0.14%) combined payment of interest on reserves) but also by the
with a high supply elasticity on the part of elasticity characteristics of the demands and
banks (an elasticity of - 1 .18%). A rise in the supplies of bank loans and time deposits.
time deposit rate would not induce a very large Domestic price behaviour has been shown to
short-run increase in non-bank sector holdings reflect the effects of both international price
of time deposits but would result in a signifi- arbitrage and domestic monetary disequilib-
cant effort on the part of financial institutions rium. Similarly, the balance of payments has
to seek alternative (especially foreign) sources been influenced by international price and
of funds. interest rate arbitrage and monetary disequilib-
These characteristics of the demands and rium.
NOTES

1. See Fry (1980) for a study of recent empirical time deposits @T-Q+) it is multiplied by 1 - K to
and theoretical work in this area. reflect the fact that K% of each time deposit must be
held as reserves and cannot be used to acquire earning
2. This approach does not require that all asset assets.
yields influence each asset demand.
3. See Appendix 1 for a summary of notation. 8. See Khan and Knight (1980) for a similar formu-
lation.
4. Since interest is not paid on demand deposits in
Argentina, this is also taken as the expected real return 9. Arturo Brillembourg has suggested that another
on demand deposits. reason for the low interest rate elasticity could be the
existence of loan rationing by banks. While this is
5. See Appendix 2 for the definition of the various clearly a possibility, it should also reduce the interest
variables. elasticities of the banking system supply functions
which are significantly higher than those for the non-
6. This formulation assumes that borrowers are not
bank sector demand functions.
required to maintain compensating balances. William
White has indicated that at least until 1978 Argentine
borrowers were required to maintain compensatory 10. In estimating (7), we were confronted with a non-
balances of roughly 25%. Unfortunately, there is no linearity reflecting the fact that, in the expression
time series regarding this variable. See White (1980b) association with Q,,, r~ enters as the product
for a further discussion. rB(l -K). In order to avoid having to use a non-linear
estimator, the expression rg(l --K) was replaced by a
7. Note that when r~ is compared with the cost of Taylor’s series expansion about the sample mean.
826 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

REFERENCES

Brunner, K., A. Cukierman and A. H. Meltzer, Mathieson, D. J., ‘Financial reform and stabilization
‘Stagflation, persistent unemployment and the policy in a developing economy’, Jcurnal of
permanence of economic shocks’, Journal of Development Economics (September 1980). pp.
Monetary Economics (October 1980), pp. 467- 359-395.
492. Math&on, D. J., ‘Interest Rates and Monetary Aggre-
Fry, M. J., ‘Financial development and stabilization gates During a Financial Reform’, Internati&ml
models for fmancially repressed developing econo- Monetary Fund, DM/79/95 (26 December 1979).
mies’, paper presented at the American Economic McKlnnon, R. I., Money &d ‘Cbpital in Economic
Association Yeeting, Denver (5-7 September Development (Washington, D.C., The Brookings
1980). Institution, 1973).
International Monetary Fund, International Financial Shaw, E. S., Finnnctil Deepening in Economic
Statistics(Washington, D.C., various). Development (New York: Oxford University Press,
Khan, M. S. and M. D. Knight, ‘Stabilization Programs 1973).
in Developing Countries: A Formal Framework’, Tobin, J., ‘A general equilibrium approach to mone-
International Monetary Fund, DM/80/63 (29 Sep- tary theory’, Journal of Noney, Credit, and Bank-
tember 1980). ing (February 1969). pp. 15-29.
Knight, M. D. and D. J. Mathieson, ‘Economic Change Tobin, J. and W. Brainard, ‘Pitfalls in financial model
and Policy Response in Canada under Fixed and building’, American Economic Review (May 1968),
Flexible Exchange Rates’, International Monetary pp. 99-122.
Fund, DM/80/21 (21 Match 1980). White, W. H., ‘The Case For and Against “Disequilib-
Leff, N. H. and K. Sato, ‘Macroeconomic adjustment rium” Money’, International Monetary Fund,
in developing countries: instability, short-run DM/80/67 (30 September 1980a).
growth, and external dependence’, 77re Review of White, W. H., ‘The Importance of “Blocked” Compen-
Economics and Statistics (May 1980), pp. 170- sating Deposit Balances for Monetary Policy in
.“,.
1 /Y.
LDCS’, International Monetary Fund,. DM/8@15
Mathieson, D. J., ‘Financial reform and capital flows (27 February 1980b).
in a developing economy’, IMF Staff Papers (Sep- Wymer, C., Computer programs: resimul manual’, un-
tember 1979), pp. 450-489. published (March 1978).

APPENDIX 1: NOTATION

C = stock of currency ‘B = interest rate on bank loans


T = stock of time deposits Ye = expected (or permanent) income
N = stock of demand deposits rF = interest rate on foreign borrowing
M = stock of broad money (currency plus demand rb = interest rate on foreign borrowing plus expec-
deposits plus time deposits) ted rate of change in exchange rate plus any
5 = stock of bank loans risk premium
P = wholesale price level K = required reserve ratio
ng = expected rate of change of wholesale price level F = total bank funds
PO = domestic price component of wholesale price rE = interest rate paid on required reserves
index BB = banking system borrowing and advances from
PF = foreign price component of wholesale price the central bank
index CA = banking system capital accounts
rT = interest rate on time deposits OI = other sources of banking system funds
rc = interest rate on government treasury bills R = stock of international reserves (in US dollars).

APPENDIX 2: VARIABLE DEFINITIONS AND SOURCES

IFS = International Monetary Fund, International Broad money = sum of lines 14A, 24 and 25
Financial Statistics. The line numbers reported be- Price level (wholesale price index) = taken from
low refer to the page containing the Argentine ‘Precios al por Mayeor’ in ES. Overall price level
data. equals ‘Nivel General’. Domestic prices equal
ES = Mlnisterio de Economia, Instituto National de ‘National’, and foreign price equals ‘Importado’
Estadistica y Censos, EstadisticaMensual. Expected income = time trend for the Central Bank of
The stocks used in the analysis are the monthly Argentina’s quarterly real GDP series provided by
averages of the endof-month stocks given below. the Western Hemisphere Department of the Inter-
Currency = line 14A in IFS national Monetary Fund
Demand deposits = line 24 in IFS Bank loans = bank claims on the private sector (line
Time deposits = line 25 in IFS 22D, IFS-)
THE CASE OF ARGENTINA 827

Bank disposable assets = credit from the central bank = this is the swap forward exchange rate offered
(line, 26G, ZZra + capital ccounts (line 27A, IFS) by the central bank on forward borrowing (con-
+ other items net (line 27R, IFS) + (1 -K) verted to per cent per month) until 1 July 1977.
(N + T + G) where N is demand deposits, T is time Reported in First National Bank of Boston,News-
deposits, and G is government deposits (line 26D, letrer Argentina
IFS). K was set equal to 1 until May 1977 and then Interest uaid on reauired reserves against time deposits
took on the value of the actual required reserve = international Monetary Ft&d staff estimates.
ratio This rate excludes the rate charged on the loanable
Loan rate (in % per month) = loan rate on 36-day portion of demand deposits which was also estab-
loans. Obtained from the Central Bank of Argen- lished at the same time.
tina
Deposit rate (in % per month) = deposit rate on 30-
day certificates of deposits Obtained from the Dummy variables
Central Bank of Argentina
Government security rate (in % per month) = interest ,gJ = dummy for period of decentralization of de-
rate on 28day treasury bills. Obtained from the posits (1 in May 1977)
Western Hemisphere Department of the Inter- 22 = dummy for first two months of wage-price
nationaf Monetary Fund ‘truce (1 in March-April 1977)
Foreign interest rate (in % per month) = Eurodollar 23 = dummy for second two months of wage-price
deposit rate (converted to a monthly percentage ‘truce’ (1 in May-June 1977)
rate) given in line 60D of the United Kingdom page 24 = dummy. for impostion of one-year minimum
in IFS maturity on foreign borrowing (1 in October-
Central Bank Swap rate on forward foreign exchange November 1977).

You might also like