You are on page 1of 19

World Development Vol. 29, No. 2, pp.

209±227, 2001
Ó 2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/01/$ - see front matter
PII: S0305-750X(00)00098-X

Social Capital and the Environment


JULES PRETTY and HUGH WARD *
University of Essex, Colchester, UK
Summary. Ð For as long as people have managed natural resources, they have engaged in collective
action. But development assistance has paid too little attention to how social and human capital
a€ects environmental outcomes. Social capital comprises relations of trust, reciprocity, common
rules, norms and sanctions, and connectedness in institutions. Recent years have seen remarkable
advances in group formation, with in the past decade some 408,000±478,000 groups emerging with
8.2±14.3 million members in watershed, irrigation, micro®nance, forest, and integrated pest
management, and for farmers' research. A new typology describes the evolution of groups through
three stages, and indicates what kinds of policy support are needed to safeguard and spread
achievements. Ó 2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words Ð social capital, participatory organizations, natural resource management

1. COLLECTIVE ACTION AND THE Palmer, 1976; Jodha, 1990; Netting, Stone, &
ENVIRONMENT Stone, 1990; Ostrom, 1990; Pretty, 1995a, 1998;
Kothari, Pathak, Anuradha, & Taneja, 1998).
For as long as people have managed natural In this paper, ®rst, we link social and human
resources, they have engaged in forms of capital formation in rural communities with
collective action. Farming households have improvement in natural capital, reviewing the
collaborated on water management, labor relevant theoretical literature and bringing
sharing and marketing; pastoralists have co- together previously scattered evidence from
managed grasslands; ®shing families and their case studies. We show how social and human
communities have jointly managed aquatic capital, embedded in participatory groups
resources. Such collaboration has been institu- within rural communities has been central to
tionalized in many forms of local association, equitable and sustainable solutions to local
through clan or kin groups, traditional leader- development problems. Going beyond the
ship, water users' groups, grazing societies, existing literature, we develop a typology of
women's self-help groups, youth clubs, farmer such groups by their degree of maturity, de®ned
experimentation groups, church groups, and in terms of their potential for self-de®ning and
labor-exchange societies. self-sustaining activity. We argue that whether
Although constructive resource management groups progress toward maturity is likely to be
rules and norms have been embedded in many related to the availability of social capital
cultures and societies, from collective water locally, but also to appropriate inputs from
management of Egypt, Mesopotamia and government and voluntary agencies.
Indonesia to herders of the Andes and dryland In some contexts, the loss of local institutions
Africa; from water harvesting in Roman north has provoked natural resource degradation. In
Africa and southwest North America to shift- India, the loss of management systems for
ing agriculture systems, it has been rare for the common property resources has been a critical
importance of such local groups and institu-
tions to be recognized in recent agricultural
and rural development. In both developing and * We are very grateful to Bruce Frank, Diana Carney,
industrialized country contexts, policy and Arjan de Haan, David Lawrence, Andy Norton, Jethro
practice has tended to be preoccupied with Petit, and Norman Upho€, together with two anony-
changing the behavior of individuals rather mous referees, for their comments on related material
than of groups or communities. As a result, and/or earlier drafts of this paper, and their insights on
agriculture has had an increasingly destructive the issues contained. Final revision accepted: 8 July
e€ect on the environment (Huxley, 1960; 2000.
209
210 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

factor in the increased overexploitation, poor natural capital (nature's goods and servicesÐ
upkeep, and physical degradation observed cf. Costanza et al., 1997) tends to be at least
over the past half century. Jodha's (1990) now partially a public goodÐmore correctly, they
classic study of 82 villages in seven states found are complex mixtures of public, club and
that only 10% of villages still regulated grazing private goods 2 and so rarely have a market
or provided watchmen compared with the value. Public goods are goods or services which
1950s; none levied grazing taxes or had penal- when consumed by a group member cannot be
ties for violation of local regulations; and only withheld from other members of the group, or
16% still obliged users to maintain and repair when consumed still can be consumed by other
common resources. members of the group (Taylor, 1982; Ostrom,
Elsewhere in India, private ownership or 1990, 1996).
operation of surface and ground water use for Like all public goods, it is dicult to say who
irrigation has generally replaced collective is at fault when natural capital declines. With-
systems (Pretty, 1995a; Singh & Ballabh, 1997; out rules, individuals tend to overuse and
Kothari et al., 1998). Again, the result is underinvest in it: they are tempted to take the
substantial degradation of natural resourcesÐa bene®t without contributing anything them-
classic example of an n-person prisoner's selvesÐin e€ect, to free-ride (Hardin, 1968).
dilemma (Ostrom, 1990). The future for natural When such public goods and services are
resources and for the many rural households considered free and so valued at zero, the
that rely on them is bleak in the absence of market signals that they are only valuable when
these disappearing institutional structures. converted into something else. 3 So the pro®t
At the same time as local institutions have from converting a forest into timber is counted
disappeared, so the state has increasingly taken on the nation's balance sheet, but all the lost
responsibility for natural resource manage- services (wild foods, fodder grasses, climate
ment, largely because of a mistaken assumption regulation, biodiversity) tend not to be
that these resources are mismanaged by local subtracted. Social institutions based on trust
people (Ostrom, 1990; Scoones, 1994; Pretty & and reciprocity, and agreed norms and rules for
Pimbert, 1995; Leach & Mearns, 1996; Pretty & behavior, can mediate this kind of unfettered
Shah, 1997; Ghimire & Pimbert, 1997). But a private action.
variety of studies of rural development have It is clear that new thinking and practice are
shown that when people are well organized in needed, particularly to develop forms of social
groups, and their knowledge is sought, incor- organization that are structurally suited for
porated and built upon during planning and natural resource management and protection at
implementation, then they are more likely to local level. This usually means more than just
sustain activities after project completion (de reviving old institutions and traditions. More
los Reyes & Jopillo, 1986; Cernea, 1987, 1991; commonly, it means new forms of organiza-
Pretty, 1991; Upho€, 1992; Pretty, Thompson, tion, association and platforms for common
& Kiara, 1995; Bunch & L opez, 1996; Roling & action. The past decade has seen a growing
Wagemakers, 1997; Singh & Ballabh, 1997; recognition of the e€ectiveness of such local
Upho€, Esman, & Krishna, 1998; Pretty, groups and associations for sustainable envi-
1995a, 1998). ronmental and economic outcomes.
One study of 25 completed World Bank
agricultural projects found that continued
success was associated clearly with local insti- 2. SOCIAL CAPITAL
tution building (Cernea, 1987). Twelve of the
projects achieved long-term sustainability, and There has been a rapid growth in interest in
it was in these that local institutions were the term ``social capital'' in recent years
strong. In the others, the rates of return had all (Bourdieu, 1986; Coleman, 1988, 1990;
declined markedly, contrary to expectations at Putnam, 1993, 1995; Carney, 1998; Flora, 1998;
the time of project completion. Outcomes were Grootaert, 1998; Ostrom, 1998; Pretty, 1998;
unsustainable where there had been no atten- Scoones, 1998; Upho€, 1998). The term
tion to institutional development and local captures the idea that social bonds and social
participation. 1 norms are an important part of the basis for
Many nonsustainable systems have emerged sustainable livelihoods. Its value was identi®ed
because of the public good aspects of the by Jacobs (1961) and Bourdieu (1986), later
environment. Unlike conventional capital, given a clear theoretical framework by Cole-
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 211

man (1988, 1990), and brought to wide atten- can be an important part of achieving positive
tion by Putnam (1993, 1995). Coleman environmental outcomes (Platteau, 1997). 7
describes it as ``the structure of relations
between actors and among actors'' that
(c) Common rules, norms and sanctions
encourages productive activities. These aspects
of social structure and organization act as
Common rules, norms and sanctions are the
resources for individuals to use to realize their
mutually agreed or handed-down norms of
personal interests. 4 Local institutions are
behavior that place group interests above those
e€ective because ``they permit us to carry on
of individuals. They give individuals the con®-
our daily lives with a minimum of repetition
dence to invest in collective or group activities,
and costly negotiation'' (Bromley, 1993).
knowing that others will do so too. Individuals
As it lowers the costs of working together,
can take responsibility and ensure their rights
social capital facilitates co-operation. People
are not infringed. Mutually-agreed sanctions
have the con®dence to invest in collective
ensure that those who break the rules know
activities, knowing that others will also do so.
they will be punished.
They are also less likely to engage in unfettered
These are sometimes called the rules of the
private actions that result in negative impacts,
game (Taylor, 1982), or the internal morality of
such as resource degradation. Although there
a social system (Coleman, 1990), the cement of
are already many di€erent descriptions of social
society (Elster, 1989), or the basic values that
capital, 5 we identify four central aspects:
shape beliefs (Collins & Chippendale, 1991).
relations of trust; reciprocity and exchanges;
They re¯ect the degree to which individuals
common rules, norms and sanctions; connect-
agree to mediate or control their own behavior.
edness, networks and groups.
Formal rules are those set out by authorities,
such as laws and regulations, while informal
(a) Relations of trust
ones are those individuals use to shape their
own everyday behavior. Norms are, by
Trust lubricates co-operation. It reduces the
contrast, preferences and indicate how indi-
transaction costs between people, and so
viduals should act; rules are stipulations of
liberates resources. Instead of having to invest
behavior with positive and/or negative sanc-
in monitoring others, individuals are able to
tions. A high social capital implies high ``in-
trust them to act as expected. This saves money
ternal morality,'' with individuals balancing
and time. It can also create a social obliga-
individual rights with collective responsibilities
tionÐtrusting someone engenders reciprocal
(Etzioni, 1995).
trust. There are two types of trust: the trust we
have in individuals whom we know; and the
trust we have in those we do not know, but (d) Connectedness, networks and groups
which arises because of our con®dence in a
known social structure. Trust takes time to Connectedness, networks, and groups and
build, but is easily broken (Gambetta, 1988; the nature of relationships are a vital aspect of
Fukuyama, 1995), and when a society is social capital. There may be many di€erent
pervaded by distrust, cooperative arrangements types of connection between groups (trading of
are unlikely to emerge (Baland & Platteau, goods, exchange of information, mutual help,
1998). 6 provision of loans, common celebrations
(prayer, marriages, funerals)). They may be
(b) Reciprocity and exchanges one-way or two-way, and may be long-estab-
lished (and so not responsive to current
Reciprocity and exchanges also increase conditions), or subject to regular update.
trust. There are two types of reciprocity Connectedness manifests itself in di€erent
(Coleman, 1990; Putnam, 1993). Speci®c reci- types of groups at the local levelÐfrom guilds
procity refers to simultaneous exchanges of and mutual aid societies, to sports clubs and
items of roughly equal value; and di€use reci- credit groups, to forest, ®shery or pest
procity refers to a continuing relationship of management groups, and to literary societies
exchange that at any given time may be unre- and mother and toddler groups. It also implies
quited, but over time is repaid and balanced. connections to other groups in society, from
Again, this contributes to the development of both micro to macro levels (Upho€, 1993;
long-term obligations between people, which Grootaert, 1998; Woolcock, 1998; Rowley,
212 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

1999). 8 Connectedness, therefore, has ®ve ele- explicit attention to social and human capital.
ments: Regulations and economic incentives are
(i) Local connectionsÐstrong connections commonly used to encourage change in
between individuals and within local groups behavior, and include establishment of strictly
and communities. protected areas, regulations for erosion control
(ii) Local±local connectionsÐhorizontal or adoption of conservation farming, economic
connections between groups within commu- incentives for habitat protection, and pesticide
nities or between communities, which taxes (Pretty et al., 2000). But there is consid-
sometimes become platforms and new erable evidence to show that though these may
higher-level institutional structures. change behavior, there may be little or no
(iii) Local±external connectionsÐvertical positive e€ect on attitudes. Farmers commonly
connections between local groups and exter- revert to old practices when the incentives end
nal agencies or organizations, being one-way or regulations are no longer enforced. 9
(usually top-down) or two-way. The social and human capital necessary for
(iv) External±external connectionsÐhori- sustainable and equitable solutions to natural
zontal connections between external agen- resource management comprise a mix of exist-
cies, leading to integrated approaches for ing endowments and that which is externally-
collaborative partnerships. facilitated. External agencies or individuals can
(v) External connectionsÐstrong connec- act on or work with individuals to increase their
tions between individuals within external knowledge and skills, their leadership capacity,
agencies. and their motivations to act. They can act on or
Even though some agencies may recognize the work with communities to create the conditions
value of social capital, it is common to ®nd not for the emergence of new local associations
all of these connections being emphasized. For with appropriate rules and norms for resource
example, a government may stress the impor- management. If these then lead to the desired
tance of integrated approaches between di€er- natural capital improvements, then this again
ent sectors and/or disciplines, but fail to has a positive feedback on both social and
encourage two-way vertical connections with human capital.
local groups. A development agency may Although there is now emerging consensus
emphasize formation of local associations that social capital and human capital mani-
without building their linkages upward with fested in groups does pay (Narayan & Pritchett,
other external agencies that could threaten the 1996; Rowley, 1999), there are surprisingly few
successes. studies that have been able to compare group
In general, the more linkages the better; two- with individual approaches in the same context
way relationships are better than one-way; and (most have observed changes over time, with
linkages subject to regular update are generally changing performance of groups being
better than historically-embedded ones. compared with earlier performance of individ-
Rowley's (1999) study of social capital in sub- ual approaches). 10
Saharan Africa found a loose relationship For farmers to invest in these approaches,
between connectedness and wealth, but they must be convinced that the bene®ts
causality was unclear: ``did well connected derived from group or joint or collective
people become rich or rich people able to a€ord approaches will be greater than those from
to be well-connected.'' There may be cases, individual ones. External agencies, by contrast,
however, where a group might bene®t from must be convinced that the required investment
isolation, because it can avoid costly external of resources to help develop social and human
demands. capital, through participatory approaches or
adult education, will produce sucient bene®ts
to exceed the costs (Grootaert, 1998; Dasgupta
3. SOCIAL AND HUMAN CAPITAL AS & Serageldin, 2000). 11
PREREQUISITES FOR NATURAL Ostrom (1998) puts it this way: ``participat-
CAPITAL IMPROVEMENTS ing in solving collective-action problems is a
costly and time consuming process. Enhancing
To what extent, then, are social and human the capabilities of local, public entrepreneurs is
capital prerequisites for long-term improve- an investment activity that needs to be carried
ments in natural capital? Natural capital can out over a long-term period.'' For initiatives to
clearly be improved in the short-term with no persist, the bene®ts must then exceed both these
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 213

Table 1. Some bene®ts of social capital manifested in groupsa


Country Impacts
Kenya Government group-based soil conservation program has run contemporaneously
alongside nongroup based farmers, with farmers organized into soil conservation
committees outperforming those working alone on a range of criteriaÐmaize yields are
50±100% greater, fodder availability was greater, there were more trees and greater
diversity of crops grown; groundwater recharge had led to reappearance of springs; and
real wage labor rates had doubled.
Philippines Government's national irrigation program organized farmers into groups and compared
performance with those farming aloneÐfarmers in irrigation groups get 19% more rice
yield; contribute more to system costs and maintenance, and are more likely to see their
suggestions incorporated into irrigation design.
Nepal The Small Farmer Development Project worked with group formation, and compared
outcomes with control communities (with no groups); farmers in groups achieved 10±
15% higher cereal yields, 70% higher milk yields, 40% higher income, and communities
as a whole had higher adult literacy rates, more children at school, greater adoption of
family planning, and greater numbers of people vaccinated.
Denmark Farmers in the 620 crop protection groups show greater reductions in pesticide use (both
doses and frequency of applications) and in costs then those working alone.
United States Members of the Practical Farmers of Iowa perform better than nonmembers in the same
region; but those organized into groups within PFI outperform individual members even
more: yields are roughly the same, but group members use 52% less nitrogen and 65%
less pesticide.
Australia 45 rice check groups of some 15±30 members each have been organized since 1986 in
New South Wales, with members consistently outperforming regional rice yields by 24%
(8.4 t/ha).
a
Sources: Just (1998); PFI, 1995; Harp, Boddy, Shequist, Huber, & Exner (1996); Lacy (1997); MOA/MALDM
(1988±99); Pretty (1995a); Pretty (1995b); Admassie, Mwarasomba, & Mbogo (1998); Bagadion & Korten (1991);
Rahman (1984).

costs and those imposed by any free-riders in attendance and voting patterns in the USA
the group-based or collective systems (Table 1). (Putnam, 1995), but these are being replaced by
Clearly, not all forms of social capital are new forms of social capital, such as communi-
good for everyone. A society may be well ty-based organizations, cross-denominational
organized, have strong institutions, have churches and new public±private partnerships
embedded reciprocal mechanisms, but be based (Sirianni & Friedland, 1997). Thus the total
not on trust but on fear and power, such as social capital may not be the key indicatorÐ
feudal, hierarchical, racist and unjust societies membership in the national Federation of
(Knight, 1992). Formal rules and norms can Women's Clubs in the United States is down by
also trap people within harmful social a half since the 1960s, but newer women's
arrangements. Again a system may appear to groups have addressed issues such as domestic
have high social capital, with strong families violence that were previously not dealt with in
and religious groups, but contain some indi- old forms of social capital (CPN, 1999).
viduals with severely depleted human capital It is important, therefore, to distinguish
through abuse or conditions of slavery or other between social capital embodied in such groups
exploitation. Some associations can also act as as sports clubs, denominational churches,
obstacles to the emergence of sustainable live- parent-school associations and even bowling
lihoods. They may encourage conformity, leagues, and that in resource-oriented groups
perpetuate adversity and inequity, and allow concerned with watershed management, micro-
certain individuals to get others to act in ways ®nance, irrigation management, pest manage-
that suit only themselves (Olson, 1965; Taylor, ment, and farmer-research. It is also important
1982). to distinguish social capital in contexts with a
Some types of social capital are known to be large number of institutions (high density) but
on the decline, such as bowling leagues, church little cross-membership and high excludability,
214 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

with that in contexts with fewer institutions but be of similar small rather than large size (as
multiple, overlapping membership of many predicted by Olson, 1982), typically with 20±30
individuals. active members (40 for micro®nance). This puts
The CPN (1999) focus on the types of social the total involvement at some 8.2±14.3 million
capital that ``enhance capacities to solve public people. Most groups show the collective e€ort
problems and empower communities'' rather and inclusive characteristics that Flora and
than just quantitative increases or decreases in Flora, 1993 identify as vital for improving
social capital. This is an important distinction community well-being and leading to sustain-
for the challenges of sustainable development. able outcomes. In these groups, social capital is
In the face of growing uncertainty (e.g., econ- both operational and e€ective.
omies, climates, political processes), the
capacity of people both to innovate and to (a) Watershed and catchment management
adapt technologies and practices to suit new groups
conditions becomes vital. Some believe uncer-
tainty is growingÐif it is, then there is greater Governments and nongovernmental organi-
need for innovation. An important question is zations (NGOs) have increasingly come to
whether forms of social capital can be accu- realize that the protection of whole watersheds
mulated to enhance such innovation (Boyte, or catchments cannot be achieved without the
1995; Hamilton, 1995). willing participation of local people. Indeed for
Another issue is the notion of path-depen- sustainable solutions to emerge, farmers need
dence (a term used by Putnam to imply a to be suciently motivated to want to use
degree of historical determinism). It is now resource-conserving practices on their own
appreciated that social capital can increase with farms. This in turn needs investment in partic-
use. Under certain circumstances, the more it is ipatory processes to bring people together to
used, the more it regenerates. Social capital is deliberate on common problems, and form new
self-reinforcing when reciprocity increases groups or associations capable of developing
connectedness between people, leading to practices of common bene®t.
greater trust, con®dence and capacity to inno- This realization led to an expansion in
vate. So, can social capital be created where it programs focused on micro-catchmentsÐnot
has been missing, and can it lead to positive whole river basins, but areas of probably no
environmental outcomes? more than several hundred hectares, in which
people know and trust eachother. The resulting
uptake has been extraordinary, with most
4. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON LOCAL programs reporting substantial yield improve-
GROUPS FOR NATURAL RESOURCE ments, often of the order of 2±3 fold. At the
IMPROVEMENT same time, most also report the substantial
public bene®ts, including groundwater
Recent years have seen an extraordinary recharge, reappearance of springs, increased
expansion in collective management programs tree cover and microclimate change, increased
throughout the world, described variously common land revegetation, and bene®ts for
by such terms as community management, local economies. We estimate that some 50,000
participatory management, joint manage- watershed and sustainable agriculture groups
ment, decentralized management, indigenous have been formed in the past decade in
management, user-participation, and co-man- Australia, Brazil, Burkina Faso, Guatemala,
agement. Honduras, India, Kenya, Niger, and the USA
These advances in social capital creation (Pretty, 1995b; IATP, 1998; Bunch, 1999;
have been centred on participatory and delib- Hinchcli€e, Thompson, Pretty, Guijt, & Shah,
erative learning processes leading to local 1999; F. Shaxson, S. Hocombe, A. Mascaretti,
group formation in six sectors: watershed/ personal communication 1999; National
catchment management; irrigation manage- Landcare Programme, 1999; Pretty & Frank,
ment; micro-®nance delivery; forest manage- 2000).
ment; integrated pest management; and
farmers' research groups. 12 In the past decade, (b) Irrigation and water users' groups
we estimate that 408,000±478,000 new groups
have arisen in these sectorsÐmostly in devel- Although irrigation is a vital resource for
oping countries (Table 2). Most have evolved to agriculture, water is rarely used eciently and
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 215

Table 2. Social capital formation in natural resource management sectors (selected countries only)ab
Country and programme details Numbers of local
groups
Watershed and Catchment Groups
ÐIndiaÐprograms of state governments and NGOs in Rajasthan, Gujarat, 30,000
Karnataka, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, Andhra Pradesh
ÐBrazilÐ275,000 farmers in 3 southern states adopted zero-tillage and conser- 15,000±17,000
vation farming as part of microbacias (watersheds) groups
ÐAustraliaÐnational Landcare programme with about one third of farmers in 4,500
landcare, waterwatch and coastcare groups
ÐKenyaÐMinistry of Agriculture catchment approach to soil and water 3,000-4,500
conservation
ÐHonduras/GuatemalaÐNGO programmes for soil and water conservation and 700±1,100
sustainable agriculture
ÐUSAÐfarmer-led watershed initiatives 1,000
ÐBurkina Faso/NigerÐwater harvesting programmes 3,000

Irrigation water users' groups


ÐSri LankaÐGal Oya and Mahaweli authority programs 33,000
ÐNepalÐwater users groups as part of government programs 5,000±8,000
ÐIndiaÐparticipatory irrigation management in Gujarat, Maharashtra, Tamil 1,000
Nadu and Orissa
ÐPhilippinesÐNational Irrigation Administration turned over 1.2 m ha to local 3,500±5,000
management groups
ÐPakistanÐwater users' association in Punjab and Sindh 14,000

Micro®nance institutions
ÐBangladeshÐGrameen Bank nationwide 50,000
ÐBangladeshÐProshika groups 75,000
ÐPakistanÐAga Khan Rural Support Programme in Northern Areas 2,600
Ð12 Countries (Nepal, India, Sri Lanka, Vietnam, China, Philippines, Fiji, Tonga, 127,000±170,000
Solomon Islands, Papua New Guinea, Indonesia and Malaysia) with wide variety
of bank and NGO programs

Joint and Participatory Forest Management


ÐIndiaÐjoint forest management and forest protection committees in all states 15,000
ÐNepalÐforest users'groups 5,300

Integrated Pest Management


ÐIndonesia (1 million graduates trained in rice and vegetable IPM programmes 18,000±36,000
with farmer ®eld schools), Vietnam, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, China, Philippines,
India (a further 800,000 trained)Ðnot all remain in groups

Farmers Groups for Research and Experimentation


ÐKenyaÐorganic farming groups 185
ÐColombiaÐfarmer research committees 250
ÐDenmarkÐpest management groups 620
ÐNetherlandsÐfarmer study groups for horticulture and arable 500

Total 408,000±478,000
a
The group structures for micro®nance institutions in these countries are assumed to be the ``center'' groups (30±40
members), and not the 5 member subgroups.
b
Sources: see text for references.

e€ectively. Without regulation or control, water waterlogging, drainage and salinity problems.
can easily be overused by those who have But where social capital is well-developed, then
access to it ®rst, resulting in shortages for tail- local water-users' groups with locally-devel-
enders, con¯icts over water allocation, and oped rules and sanctions are able to make more
216 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

of existing resources than individuals working permitted use rights for certain products. But
alone or in competition. The resulting impacts, governments have not been entirely successful
such as in the Philippines and Sri Lanka, typi- in protecting forests. In India, for example, less
cally involve increased rice yields, increased than half of forests remain under closed cano-
farmer contributions to design and mainte- pies, with the remainder in various stages of
nance of systems, dramatic changes in the e- degradation (SPWD, 1992). But recent years
ciency and equity of water use, decreased have seen growing recognition among govern-
breakdown of systems and reduced complaints ments that they cannot hope to protect forests
to government departments (de los Reyes & without the help and involvement of local
Jopillo, 1986; Bagadion & Korten, 1991; communities. This means the granting of rights
Ostrom, 1990; Upho€, 1992; Cernea, 1993; to use a range of timber and nontimber
Singh & Ballabh, 1997; Upho€ et al., 1998). 13 produce, and allocation of joint responsibility
for protecting and improving degraded land.
(c) Micro®nance institutions The most signi®cant changes have occurred
in India and Nepal, where experimentallocal
One of the great recent revolutions in devel- initiatives in the 1980s so increased biological
oping countries has been the development of regeneration and income ¯ows that govern-
credit and savings systems for poor families. ments issued new policies for joint and partic-
They lack the kinds of collateral that banks ipatory forest management in 1990 (India) and
typically demand, appearing to represent too 1993 (Nepal). These encouraged the involve-
high a risk, so having to rely on money-lenders, ment of NGOs as intermediaries and facilita-
who charge extortionate rates of interest. A tors of local group formation. There are now
major change in thinking and practice occurred nearly 20,000 forest protection committees and
when professionals began to realize that it was forest users' groups in these two countries,
possible to provide micro®nance to groups, and managing some 1.85 million hectares of forest,
so ensure high repayment rates. When local mostly with their own rules and sanctions
groups are trusted to manage ®nancial resour- (Malla, 1997; Shrestha, 1997, 1998; SPWD,
ces, they can be much more ecient and e€ec- 1998; Raju, 1998). 14 Bene®ts include increased
tive than banks. fuelwood and fodder productivity, improved
The Grameen Bank in Bangladesh was the biodiversity in regenerated forests, and income
®rst to help people ®nd a way out of the credit growth among poorest households. Old atti-
trap. It helps women to organize into groups, tudes are changing, as foresters come to
and lends to these groups. The Grameen Bank appreciate the remarkable regeneration of
now has more than two million members in degraded lands following community protec-
34,000 villages, who are organized into tion, and the growing satisfaction of working
subgroups of ®ve members, which are joined with, rather than against, local people (though
together into 40-member centers (Grameen some 31 million hectares of forest are still said
Trust, 1999, passim). Elsewhere in Bangladesh, to be degraded in India).
the NGO Proshika has helped to form some
75,000 local groups. Such ``micro®nance insti- (e) Integrated pest management and farmer ®eld
tutions'' are now receiving worldwide promi- schools
nence: the 57 micro®nance initiatives (in Nepal,
India, Sri Lanka, Vietnam, China, Philippines, Integrated Pest Management (IPM) is the
Fiji, Tonga, Solomon Islands, Papua New integrated use of a range of pest (insect, weed
Guinea, Indonesia and Malaysia) analyzed for or disease) control strategies in a way that
the Bank-Poor `96 meeting in Malaysia have reduces pest populations to satisfactory levels
5.1 million members in some 127,000±170,000 and is sustainable and nonpolluting. Inevitably
groups, who had mobilized US$132 million in IPM is a more complex process than relying on
their own savings (Fernandez, 1992; Gibbons, spraying of pesticides: it requires a high level of
1996). human capital in the form of analytical skills
and understanding of agro-ecological princi-
(d) Joint and participatory forest management ples; it also requires cooperation between
farmers. Recent years have seen the establish-
In many countries, the forests are owned ment of ``farmer-®eld schools'' (FFS) (``schools
and/or managed by the state. In some cases, without walls,'' in which a group of up to 25
people are actively excluded; in others some are farmers meets weekly during the rice season to
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 217

engage in experiential learning) and farmers' 5. THE MATURITY OF GROUPS AND


groups for IPM (Kiss & Meerman, 1991; SOCIAL AND HUMAN CAPITAL
Matteson, Gallagher, & Kenmore, 1992; TRANSFORMATIONS
Eveleens et al., 1996; van de Fliert, 1997;
Kenmore, 1999). It is clear that there has been a quite
The FFS revolution began in South East remarkable emergence of social capital mani-
Asia, where research on rice systems demon- fested in groups and associations worldwide.
strated that pesticide use was correlated with Some natural resource sectors are being trans-
pest outbreaks rice (Kenmore, Carino, Perez, formed: such as forest management in India,
Dyck, & Gutierrez, 1984). 15 The loss of natu- with 15,000 forest protection committees, or
ral enemies, and the free services they provided participatory irrigation in Sri Lanka with
for pest control, was a cost that exceeded the 33,000 groups. Some countries or regions are
bene®ts of pesticide use. The program of FFS is being transformed: a third of all Australian
supported by FAO and other bilateral devel- farmers are members of 5000 Landcare groups;
opment assistance agencies and has since and there are some 1.8 million Southeast Asian
spread to many countries in Asia and Africa farmers engaged in sustainable rice manage-
(Kenmore, 1999; Desilles, 1999; Jones, 1999). ment.
At the last estimate, some 1.8 million farmers The fact that groups have been established
are thought to have made a transition to more does not, however, guarantee that resources
sustainable rice farming as a result. FFS have will continue to be managed sustainably or
given farmers the con®dence to work together equitably. What happens over time? How do
on more sustainable and low-cost technologies these groups change, and which will survive or
for rice cultivation. But it is not clear how terminate? Some will become highly e€ective,
many graduates remain connected up in local growing and diversifying their activities, whilst
groups. We assume that only 25±50% of the 1.8 others will struggle on in name only. Can we
million graduates remain in groups. say anything about the conditions that are
likely to promote resilience and persistence?
There is surprisingly little empirical evidence
(f) Farmers' groups for co-learning and research about the di€ering performances of groups
(though see Bunch & L opez, 1996 for Hondu-
The normal mode of agricultural research ras and Guatemala; Bagadion & Korten, 1991
has been to experiment under controlled for Philippines; Upho€ et al., 1998 for Sri
conditions on research stations, with the Lanka; Krishna & Upho€, 1999 for Rajasthan,
resulting technologies being passed to farmers. India; and Curtis, van Nouhays, Robinson, &
In this process, farmers have little control, and MacKay, 1999 for Australia). These variously
many technologies do not suit them, thus show reasonably normal distributions from
reducing the eciency of research systems. low-performing to mature high-performing
Farmers' organizations can, however, make a groups, or very skewed distribution to either
di€erence. They can help research institutions end. 16
become more responsive to local needs, and can Many models have been developed to
create extra local value by working on tech- describe changes in social and organizational
nology generation and adaptation. Self-learn- structures, commonly characterizing diversity
ing is vital for sustainable agriculture, and by in structure and performance according to
experimenting themselves, farmers increase stages or phases. 17 Some of these focus on
their own awareness of what does and does not organizational development of business or
work. There have been many innovations in corporate enterprises, with a particularly strong
both industrialized and developing countries, emphasis on the life cycles of groups (cf.
though generally the numbers of groups in each Mooney & Reiley, 1931; Stinchcombe, 1965;
initiative tend to be much smaller than in Greiner, 1972; Child & Keiser, 1981; Handy,
watershed, irrigation, forestry, micro®nance 1985). Others focus on the phases of learning,
and IPM programs (Pretty, 1995a,b; Harp et knowing and world-views through which indi-
al., 1996; Oerlemans, Proost, & Rauwhost, viduals progress over time (cf. Argyris &
1997; van Weperen & R oling, 1995; van Sch on, 1978; Habermas, 1987; Collins &
Veldhuizen, Waters-Bayer, Ramirez, Johnson, Chippendale, 1991; Lawrence, 1999). Moreover
& Thompson, 1997; Just, 1998; Braun, 2000; some point to the types of participation that
Pretty & Hine, 2000). development organizations engage in while
Table 3. Three stages in the evolution of groups according to 15 criteria
218

Stage 1 Stage 2 Stage 3


Reactive-dependence Realisation-independence Awareness-interdependence
1. Worldviews and sense-making
1.1 Sense-making ÐIndividuals in group tend to be ÐIndividuals and group looking ÐGroup self-determined and shap-
looking backÐmaking sense of old inwardsÐmaking sense of new ing reality by looking forward
realities reality
1.2 Views of change ÐFear of change ÐAdjusting to change ÐExpect change as a norm
1.3 Attitudes and values ÐNo signi®cant change in attitudes, ÐRealisation of new capacities ÐCritical re¯ection and abstract
beliefs and values conceptualisation lead to new in-
sights
2. Internal norms and trust
2.1 Rules and norms ÐTend to be externally imposed or ÐDevelopment of own rules and ÐEvolution and strengthening of
derived norms rules and norms
2.2 Recognition of group value ÐSome recognition that group has ÐMembers increasingly willing to ÐGroup likely to express social
value to achieve something new invest in group itself value of group
2.3 Sharing ethic Some sharing of ideas, but tendency ÐSharing within group common ÐSharing to and from external
to mistrust the new actors
3. External links and networks
3.1 Horizontal ÐFew or no links with other groups ÐLinks with other groups ÐGroups capable of promoting
spread and initiating new groups
3.2 Vertical ÐLinks one way (from above to ÐRealization that information can ÐGroups well-linked to many
below) ¯ow upward external agencies and strong enough
to resist external power
3.3 External facilitators ÐGroup relies on external facilita- ÐNew role for facilitators, such as ÐFacilitators no longer needed
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

tors to sustain group activities con¯ict resolution


4 Technologies and improvements
4.1 Environmental aspects ÐEco-eciency-reducing costs and ÐRegenerationÐmaking best of ÐRedesign according to basic
damage natural capital ecological principles
4.2 Source of technologies ÐWaits for external solutions-hop- ÐRealization that solutions must be ÐInternal and external solutions
ing for a new silver bullet internally generated
4.3 Capacity to experiment ÐSome experimentation and adop- ÐCollective planning for experi- ÐExperimentation leads to adapta-
tion mentation; some innovations tion and innovation
5 Group life span
5.1 Reason for being ÐInitiated by external agency or ÐGrouping successfully achieve ÐGroups now engaged in di€erent
emerging planned activities activities
5.2 Resilience ÐBreakdown easy ÐBreakdown possible after ÐUnlikely to breakdown-passed a
achievement of initial goals threshold
5.3 Variability ÐGroups with same program look ÐGroups diverge ÐGroups look completely di€erent
the same from each other
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 219

interacting with their clients, partners or tendency at this stage is to focus on eco-e-
subjects (cf. Roling, 1988; Pretty, 1995b; World ciency by reducing costs and damage: in agri-
Neighbors, 1999). culture, for example, this will mean the
These models have ®ve things in common: adoption of reduced-dose pesticides and targe-
ÐThey describe how transformations in hu- ted inputs, but not yet the use of regenerative
man and social capital occur, but not neces- components.
sarily why.
ÐThey are essentially progressive, indicat- (b) Stage two: realization-independence
ing that one stage can lead to another.
ÐProgression is not taken to be inevitable, The second stage sees growing independence,
with outcomes being regression (going back combined with a realization of new emerging
to the previous stage), stagnation or arrested capabilities. Individuals and groups tend to
development (remaining at one stage), and look inwards more, beginning to make sense of
extinction (organizations may fail or termi- their new reality. Members are increasingly
nate). willing to invest their time in the group itself as
ÐOrganizations in higher or later stages are trust grows. Groups at this stage begin to
taken to be more resilient (capable of resist- develop their own rules and norms, and start to
ing shocks and stresses), and more adaptive look outwardÐthey develop horizontal links
(capable of innovating), and so have lower with other groups and realize that information
mortality rates. ¯owing upward and outward to external
ÐAll relate some measures of group matu- agencies can be bene®cial for the group.
rity to performance and outcomes, with high With the growing realization that the group
or later stages being associated with greater has the capacity to develop new solutions to
maturity. existing problems, individuals tend to be more
We have developed a new typology to describe likely to engage in active experimentation and
the evolution of social and human capital sharing of results. Agricultural approaches, for
manifested in groups. We propose that groups example, start incorporating regenerative tech-
can be found to be at one of three stages: nologies to make the best use of natural capital
Reactive-Dependence; Realization-Indepen- rather than simple eco-eciency. Groups are
dence; and Awareness-Independence, and that now beginning to diverge and develop individ-
these stages can be di€erentiated according to ual characteristics. They are stronger and more
15 criteria clustered in ®ve themes (see Table 3): resilient, but still may eventually breakdown if
ÐWorldviews of members. members feel they have achieved the original
ÐInternal norms and trust. aims, and do not wish to invest further in
ÐExternal linkages and networks. achieving new ones.
ÐTechnologies and improvements.
ÐGroup lifespan. (c) Stage three: awareness-interdependence

(a) Stage one: reactive-dependence This stage involves a ratchet shift for
groupsÐthey are very unlikely to unravel or, if
When groups form, they do so to achieve a they do, individuals have acquired new world-
desired outcome. This is likely to be in reaction views and ways of thinking that will not revert.
to a threat or crisis, or as a result of the Groups are engaged in shaping their own
prompting of an external agency. They tend at realities by looking forward (bringing forth a
this stage to be looking back, trying to make new worldÐcf. Maturana & Varela, 1982), and
sense of what has happened. There is some the individual skills of critical re¯ection (how
recognition that the group has value, but rules we came here) combined with abstract
and norms tend to be externally-imposed or conceptualization (how would we like things to
borrowed. Individuals are still looking for be) means that groups are now expecting
external solutions, and so tend to be dependent change and are more dynamic.
on external facilitators. There is an inherent Individuals tend to be much more self-aware
fear of changeÐreally members would like of the value of the group itself (the value of
things to return to before the crisis arose and social capital). They are capable of promoting
the need to form a group occurred. spread of new technologies to other groups,
For those groups concerned with the devel- and of initiating new groups themselves. They
opment of more sustainable technologies, the want to stay well linked to external agencies,
220 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

and are suciently strong and resilient to resist creation, and to ensure the transition is made
external powers and threats. 18 Groups are from dependence to interdependence, which in
more likely to come together in apex organi- turn helps to build assets. The danger is not
zations, platforms or federations, to achieve going far enough, and being satis®ed with any
higher level aims. At this stage, agricultural partial progress: as Ostrom (1998) puts it:
systems are more likely to be redesigned ``creating dependent citizens rather than entre-
according to ecological principles, no longer preneurial citizens reduces the capacity of citi-
adopting new technologies to ®t the old system, zens to produce capital.'' The costs of
but innovating to develop entirely new systems. development assistance will also inevitably
This typology suggests important relation- increaseÐit is not costless to establish new
ships between maturity and social capital. Are organizations. It is clear that more will have to
groups endowed with social capital more likely be invested on public social goods to get more
to proceed to maturity, or can they become improvements in natural capital.
arrested because social capital is a form of But group-based approaches that help build
embeddedness that prevents change? Does social and human capital are not alone su-
feedback occur between maturity and social cient conditions for achieving sustainable live-
capital? If so, is it positive (e.g., success with a lihoods and local economies. Policy reform is
new sustainable practice spills over into success an additional and necessary condition for
for others, or create new opportunities for shaping the wider context, so as to make it
cooperation), or negative (e.g., changes in more favorable to the emergence and suste-
worldview and technology could unsettle nance of local groups. There have been some
traditional practices, erode trust, and make notable examples of such policy support in
existing networks redundant)? recent years:
An important, and as yet unanswered, ques- ÐIn India and Nepal, the granting in the
tion is whether this typology is a construct that early 1990s by national governments of ac-
accurately describes discrete stages, or whether cess rights and concessions to forest prod-
there is in reality a continuum of steady change. ucts for community groups was
We suspect real-life situations represent a great fundamental to the emergence of 20,000
diversity of degrees of more or less of several new users'groups.
indicators at each stage. We suspect, however, ÐIn Indonesia, the banning of 57 pesticides
that there are likely to be one or more distinct in 1986 combined with the establishment of
thresholds or ratchets along the continuum. a national farmer-®eld school programme
Groups and individuals at stage 3 appear was vital in launching the successful rice-
unlikely to regress to a previous stage, as IPM program.
worldviews, philosophies and practices have ÐIn Sri Lanka, the adoption of participa-
fundamentally changed. But groups at stage 1 tory irrigation management with water
are unstable and could easily regress or termi- users'groups became national policy in 1988.
nate without external support and facilitation. ÐIn Kenya, the success of the government's
These issues raise further questions about soil conservation program has clearly fol-
what can or should external practical and lowed new government policy from the late
policy agencies doÐcan they create the condi- 1980s that permitted community groups to
tions for take-o€ towards maturity when there plan and prioritize for themselves.
is little social capital? How best should they ÐIn Australia, the government's decade of
proceed in encouraging transformations that Landcare (launched in 1989) helped propel
will lead to sustained progress? landcare groups to the centre of farming
and rural communities.
ÐThe emergence of micro®nance institu-
6. POLICY CHALLENGES tions primarily targeted at the poorest and
excluded groups is in part due to policy re-
What, then, can be done both to encourage forms permitting groups to receive credit
the greater adoption of group-based and themselves act as the collateral.
programmes for environmental improvements, Equally, though, there are many cases where
and to identify the necessary support for a lack of policy reform, or even discriminatory
groups to evolve to maturity? Clearly, interna- policies, have meant disruption or degradation
tional agencies, governments, banks and NGOs of institutions and programs concerned with
must invest more in social and human capital making progress toward sustainability. In parts
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 221

of the Philippines, for example, many tenant These policy issues also raise further ques-
farmers' groups who have improved their local tions. What will happen to state-community
natural capital through sustainable agriculture relations when social capital in the form of
have found that this has simply encouraged local associations and their federated bodies
landlords to take back the formerly degraded spread to very large numbers of people?
farm without paying compensation for the Will the state colonize these groups, or will
improvements. new broad-based forms of democratic gover-
One way to ensure the stability of social capital nance emerge? How can policy-makers
is for groups to work together by federating to protect existing programs in the face of new
in¯uence district, regional or even national threats?
bodies. This can open up economies of scale to Important questions also relate to the groups
bring greater economic and ecological bene®ts. themselves. ``Successful'' programs may falter if
The emergence of such federated groups also individuals start to ``burn-out''Ðfeeling that
makes it easier for government and NGOs to investments in social capital are no longer
develop direct links with the poor. This can in paying. It is vitally important that policy-
turn result in greater empowerment of poor makers and practitioners continue to seek ways
households, as they better draw on public servi- to provide support for the processes that both
ces. Such interconnectedness between groups is help groups to form, and help them mature
more likely to lead to improvements in natural along the lines that local people desire and
resources that regulatory schemes alone (R oling need, and from which natural environments
& Wagemakers, 1997; Baland & Platteau, 1999). will bene®t.

NOTES

1. In Malaysia, water users' associations were ``estab- worth (at least, those that can be costed in economic
lished carefully, patiently and successfully, taking into terms) (Pimentel et al., 1995; Daily, 1997). Costanza et
account farmers' resource needs, their willingness to al. (1997) study of the aggregate value of the world's
cooperate, the physical location of their plots'' (Cernea, ecosystem services, estimate it to be in the range US$16±
1987). The endurance of these associations after the 54 trillion per year.
project completed was the single most important factor
in ensuring the continued bene®ts to farmers. In 4. This economic metaphor has drawbacks in relation
contrast, the negative rate of return of an agricultural to social capital: relationships are not entirely oriented
project in Benin was caused by the disintegration of the toward material gain. Other bene®ts generated through
cooperatives developed for the cultivation of oil palm. social capital may include enhanced spiritual well-being,
These had been imposed on the farmers and run by a a sense of identity and belonging, the pleasure of
parastatal with no self-management delegated to farm- friendship, honor, social status and prestige. It is
ers. The farmers also opposed the organizational important, therefore, to take account of the cultural,
arrangements imposed on them, so when these moral, ethical and spiritual dimensions in which such
collapsed, the technical innovation (growing of oil palm) assets are embedded (Benton, 1998).
collapsed, too.
5. A problem with the term social capital, like many
2. Many environmental goods are complex mixtures of others in current vogue (such as ``sustainable develop-
public, club and private goods that are jointly supplied. ment'' or ``participation''), is that it is dicult to ®nd
Club goods are those that are indivisible and ``outsiders'' agreement on exactly what it is. Since the appearance of
are often excluded from the bene®ts. Not all environ- the Putnam thesis on Italian society and other commen-
mental goods are excludable, though, such as the taries on the decline of social capital in the United States
bene®ts of preserving the ozone layer, which cannot be (Putnam, 1993, 1995, 1996), a wide range of di€erent
con®ned to club members (Sandler, 1997). contributions have been made on the concept of social
capital, with some clearly seeing little use for the term
3. Although it is impossible to give an absolute value (cf. Fine, 1998). Some have sought to deconstruct the
to some aspects of natural capitalÐthe atmosphere, for Putnam thesis (Levi, 1996; Harriss & de Renzio, 1998).
example, has in®nite value to usÐit is instructive to see Some have emphasized the importance of problem-
how much the services that come from the capital are solving and how only certain types of social capital
222 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

contribute to this (Boyte, 1995; Sirianni & Friedland, due to the program interventions. It seems likelyÐbut
1997). Some have analyzed the values of organizational other factors may have been equally or more important,
density and intensity, and the value of associational such as changes in policies, technologies or labor
activity (Cernea, 1993; Narayan & Pritchett, 1996; markets.
Ward, 1998), while others distinguish between structural
and cognitive aspects (Upho€, 1998), or the relations 11. The World Bank's internal ``Learning Group on
between social capital and entrepreneurial social infra- Participatory Development'' conducted a study to
structure (Flora, 1998). Some are concerned with the use measure the comparative bene®ts and costs of partic-
of the term ``capital,'' as it appears to imply that only ipatory versus nonparticipatory projects (World Bank,
monetary measures of society are important (Benton, 1994). The principal bene®ts were found to be
1998), or that there is complete substitutability (Bour- increased uptake of services; decreased operational
dieu, 1986) between types of capital. Some indicate how costs; increased rate of return; and increased incomes
participatory processes that encourage co-learning can of stakeholders. But it was also found that the costs of
lead to social capital accumulation (Pretty, 1995b; participation were greater, notably that the total sta€
Norton & Stephens, 1995; R oling & Wagemakers, time in the design phase (42 projects) was 10±15%
1997), while others point to the ``dark side'' of social more than non-participatory projects, and that the
capital, in that it can mean exclusion as well as inclusion total sta€ time for supervision was 60% more than
(Portes & Landolt, 1996). nonparticipatory projects (loaded at front end). The
costs were primarily for convincing borrowers of value
6. Fukuyama (1995) emphasizes the fundamental value of participation; for conducting extensive institutional
of trust for the progress of large, democratic and assessments; for building capacity and social institu-
corporate organizations. Trust is seen to arise when tions; for running interactive workshops and making
communities share sets of moral values so as to create ®eld visits; and for negotiating between stakeholder
expectations of honest behavior. groups.

7. Rose (1995) draws attention to the Russian proverb 12. Other important advances in social capital crea-
``it's better to have one hundred friends than 100 tion not dealt with here include groups for drinking
roubles'' in his study of Russian people's high trust water provisions (e.g., 13,500 groups in C^
ote d'Ivoire),
and reciprocity among immediate social networks, but food consumer groups (e.g., 25,000 teikei and sanchoku
high distrust and disconnectedness with higher-level groups in Japan), ®shery management (e.g., 8,400
institutions. ®shing cooperatives in India) and wildlife management
groups (e.g., in Zimbabwe) (cf. Baland & Platteau,
8. High social capital implies a likelihood of multiple 1996)
membership of organizations and links between groups.
It is possible to imagine a context with large numbers of 13. Lam, 1998 analysis of 150 irrigation systems in
organizations, but each protecting its own interests with Nepal (reported in Ostrom, 1998) indicates that ``irriga-
little crosscontact. Organizational density may be high, tion systems that are governed by farmers themselves...
but intergroup connectedness low (Cernea, 1993). A deliver more water to the tail end of the system and have
better form of social capital implies high organizational higher productivity than those... governed by the Nepal
density and crossorganizational links. Department of Irrigation'' (Ostrom, 1998).

9. This is not to say that regulations have no e€ectÐ 14. The growth of forest users' groups in Nepal
without them, farmers, rural communities and consum- illustrates the rapidity of this new movement: in 1988
ers would be exposed to many more types of toxic there was one FUG; in 1990, about 90; in 1993 there
pesticide, for example, than is currently the case. were 469 groups; and by 1997, this had grown to 5316
(Malla, 1997).
10. It is clear from the extent of group-based programs
that something is working. But, in most cases, it is not 15. Pesticide use has since been positively correlated
possible to say exactly what is the added value of the with pest outbreaks in other systems, such as maize and
social capital formed, as most comparisons can only be vegetables in Australia (cf. Heisswolf, Houlding, &
of a ``before-and-after'' nature. Something did not work, Deuter, 1996; Scholz, Monsour, & Zalucki, 1998).
and now it does, and so we can draw assumptions about
the likely reasons. But the question of attribution is 16. An analysis of 112 villages of Honduras and
always dicult with such changes over time. We can Guatemala found that 20±35% of communities were
never be sure as to what extent the measured changes are highly e€ective; 40±50% were in the middle; and about
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 223

25±30% were low performers. The best communities (iii) Argyris and Schon's (1978) four stages of learn-
were associated with continued yield increases long after ing: from propositional to single loop and double-
the sustainable agriculture project terminated; the low loop, to higher order epistemic;
performers showed no real change after project termi- (iv) Child and Keiser's (1981) four stages of business
nation, though agricultural yields were signi®cantly development model;
better than those of farmers not in groups or part of (v) Handy's (1985) four stages of groups: forming,
the programme (Bunch & L opez, 1996; Bunch, 1999). storming, norming and performing;
In the Philippines, only about 3% of irrigators' asso- (vi) Habermas' (1987) focus on cognition: technical,
ciations have entered into full turnover contracts in practical and emancipatory cognition;
which they manage all the processes of irrigation (vii) R
oling's (1988) classi®cation of extension in four
management and distribution; 37% have entered main- stages: persuasive, informative, formative, and
tenance contracts; and 60% are engaged in systems emancipatory extension;
operation, but still requiring substantial external (viii) Pretty's (1995a) seven levels of participation:
support (Bagadion & Korten, 1991). In Sri Lanka, manipulative, passive, consultative, bought, func-
autonomous, isolated irrigation groups perform least tional, interactive and to self-mobilization;
well; those with narrow vertical linkages but no (ix) World Neighbors' (1999) four stages to identify
horizontal ones performed next; while those with the nature of the wider development process; initia-
multiple horizontal and vertical linkages performed tion; co-management; accompaniment; and auton-
best (Upho€ et al., 1998). In Australia, Victorian omy;
landcare groups answering a survey were found to be (x) Lawrence's (1999) typology of learning: teaching,
mostly highly e€ective (Curtis et al., 1999). In Rajas- teaching and training; adult education; adult learn-
than, Krishna and Upho€'s (1999) development of a ing; to perspective integration (ontological apprecia-
social capital index for 64 rural communities showed a tion).
normal distribution.
18. It is often part of the rhetoric of development that
17. These typologies relating to the evolution and external agencies should have an ``exit strategy'' Ða
maturity of groups include: time or rationale for leaving local people to continue on
their own. This is a mistaken idea based only on the
(i) Mooney and Reiley's (1931) ®ve stages of group notion of groups moving from dependence to indepen-
life-cycles: emergence, growth, maturity, decline and dence. In practice, mature groups never want external
death; agencies to leaveÐthey wish to make the best use of all
(ii) Greiner's (1972) ®ve stages for group life-cycles: the linkages that they have developed. The external
entrepreneurial, collectivity, delegation, formalisa- agency, however, may need to exit for ®nancial or
tion, and collaboration; administrative reasons.

REFERENCES

Admassie, Y., Mwarasomba, L. I., & Mbogo, P. (1998) Baland, J.-M., & Platteau, J.-P. (1999). The ambiguous
The sustainability of the catchment approach-induced impact of poverty on local resource management.
measures and activities. Nairobi, Kenya: National World Development, 27(5), 773±788.
Soil and Water Conservation Programme, Ministry Benton, T. (1998). Sustainable development and the
of Agriculture. accumulation of capital: Reconciling the irreconcil-
Argyris, C., & Schon, D. (1978). Organisational learning. able. Mimeo. Department of Sociology, University
Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. of Essex: Colchester.
Bagadion, B. J., & Korten, F. F. (1991). Developing Bourdieu, P. (1986). The forms of capital. In J.
irrigators' associations: A learning process approach. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research
In M. M. Cernea (Ed.), Putting people ®rst. Oxford: for the sociology of education. Westport CT: Green-
Oxford University Press. wood Press.
Baland, J.-M., & Platteau, J.-P. (1996) Halting degrada- Boyte, H. (1995). Beyond deliberation: citizenship as
tion of natural resources: Is there a role for rural public work. Paper delivered at PEGS conference,
communities?. New York: Clarendon Press. February 11±12, 1995. Civic Practices Network at
Baland, J.-M., & Platteau, J.-P. (1998). Division of http://www.cpn.org.
the commons: A partial assessment of the Bromley, D. (1993). Common property as metaphor:
new institutional economics of land rights. Amer- Systems of knowledge, resources and the decline of
ican Journal of Agricultural Economics, 80(3), 644± individualism. The common property digest 27, 1±8.
650. Hyderabad: Winrock and ICRISAT.
224 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Braun, A. (2000). Participatory approaches to research practices? Bellagio Conference Center, Italy, April
and development: Comite de Investigaci on Agricola 26±30.
Local (CIAL). Bogata, Colombia: CIAT. Elster, J. (1989). The cement of society: A study of social
Bunch, R. (1999). Learning how to make the soil grow. order. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
In M. McDonald, K. Brown (Eds.), Issues and Etzioni, A. (1995). The spirit of community: Rights
options in the design of soil and water conservation responsibilities and the communitarian agenda. Lon-
projects. Proceedings of a workshop held in Llan- don: Fontana Press.
dudno, Conwy, February 1±3, University of Wales, Eveleens, K. G., Chisholm, R., van de Fliert, E., Kato,
Bangor. M., Thi Nhat, P., & Schmidt, P. (1996). Mid term
Bunch, R., & L opez, G. (1996). Soil recuperation in review of phase III reportÐThe FAO intercountry
Central America: Sustaining innovation after inter- programme for the development and application of
vention. Gatekeeper Series SA 55. London: Sustain- integrated pest management control in rice in South
able Agriculture Programme, International Institute and South East Asia. GCP/RAS/145-147/NET-AUL-
for Environment and Development. SWI. Rome: FAO.
Carney, D. (1998). Sustainable rural livelihoods. London: Fernandez, A. (1992). The MYRADA experience: Alter-
Department for International Development. nate management systems for savings and credit of the
Cernea, M. M. (1987). Farmer organisations and insti- rural poor. Bangalore: MYRADA.
tution building for sustainable development. Regio- Fine, B. (1998). The World Bank and social capital: A
nal Development Dialogue, 8, 1±24. critical skinning. Mimeo. London: SOAS.
Cernea, M. M. (1991). Putting people ®rst (2nd ed.). Flora, C. B., & Flora, J. L. (1993). Entrepreneurial
Oxford: Oxford University Press. social infrastructure: a necessary ingredient. The
Cernea, M. M. (1993). The sociologist's approach to Annals of the American Academy of Political and
sustainable development. Finance and Development Social Science, 529, 48±55.
(December), 11±13. Flora, J. L. (1998). Social capital and communities of
Child, J., & Keiser, A. (1981). Development of organ- place. Rural Sociology, 63(4), 481±506.
isations over time. In P. C. Nystrom, & W. H. Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust: The social values and the
Starbuck, (Eds.), Handbook of organisational design. creation of prosperity. New York: Free Press.
Adapting organisations to their environments (Vol. 1). Gambetta, D. (Ed.) (1988). Trust: making and breaking
Oxford: Oxford University Press. cooperative relations. Oxford: Blackwell.
Civic Practices Network. (1999). At http://www.cpn.org. Ghimire, K., & Pimbert, M. (1997). Social change and
Coleman, J. (1988). Social capital and the creation of conservation. London: Earthscan Publications.
human capital. American Journal of Sociology 94, Gibbons, D. S. (1996). Resource mobilisation for maxi-
S95±S120 (Suppl.). mising MFI outreach and ®nancial self-suciency.
Coleman, J. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Boston, Issues Paper No. 3 for Bank-Poor `96 conference,
MA: Harvard University Press. December 10±12, Kuala Lumpur.
Collins, C. J., & Chippendale, P. J. (1991). New wisdom: Grameen Trust. passim. Mirpur Two, Dhaka 1211,
The nature of social reality. Sunnybank, Queensland: Bangladesh.
Acorn Publications. Greiner, L. (1972). Evolution and revolution as organ-
Costanza, R., d'Arge, R., de Groot, R., Farber, S., isations grow. Harvard Business Review 50 (July±
Grasso, M., Hannon, B., Limburg, K., Naeem, S., August).
O'Neil, R. V., Parvelo, J., Raskin, R. G., Sutton, P., Grootaert, C. (1998). Social capital: The missing link.
& de van den Belt, M. (1997). The value of the World Bank Social Capital Initiative Working Paper
world's ecosystem services and natural capital. No 5. Washington DC: The World Bank.
Nature, 387, 253±260. Habermas, J. (1987). Theory of communicative action:
Curtis, A., van Nouhays, M., Robinson, W., & Critique of functionalist reason (Vol. II). Oxford:
MacKay, J. (1999). Exploring landcare e€ectiveness Polity Press.
using organisational theory. Paper to International Hamilton, N. A. (1995). Learning to learn with farmers.
Symposium for Society and Natural Resources, July. Ph.D Thesis. Wageningen Agricultural University,
University of Queensland, Brisbane. Netherlands.
Daily, G. (Ed.). (1997). Nature's services: Societal Handy, C. (1985). Understanding organisations.
dependence on natural ecosystems. Washington, DC: Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.
Island Press. Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons.
Dasgupta, P., & Serageldin, I. (Eds.) (2000) Social Science, 162, 1243±1248.
capital: a multiperspective approach. Washington, Harp, A., Boddy, P., Shequist, K., Huber, G., & Exner,
DC: World Bank. D. (1996). Iowa, USA: An e€ective partnership
de los Reyes, R., & Jopillo, S. G. (1986). An evaluation of between the practical farmers of Iowa and Iowa
the Philippines participatory communal irrigation State University. In L. A. Thrupp (Ed.), New
program. Quezon City: Institute of Philippine Cul- partnerships for sustainable agriculture. Washington
ture. DC: WRI.
Desilles, S. (1999). Sustaining and managing private Harriss, J., & de Renzio, P. (1998). Missing link or
natural resources: the way to step out of the cycle of analytically missing? The concept of social capital.
high-input agriculture. Paper for conference on Mimeo. London: Development Studies Institute,
sustainable agriculture: New paradigms and old London School of Economics..
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 225

Heisswolf, S., Houlding, B. J., & Deuter, P. L. (1996). A Lawrence, D. (1999). Stages of adult learning. Mimeo.
decade of integrated pest management (IPM) in Brisbane: Queensland Department of Primary Indus-
Brassica vegetable cropsÐthe role of farmer partic- tries.
ipation in its development in southern Queensland, Leach, M., & Mearns, R. (1996). The lie of the land.
Australia. In A. Sivapragasam, W. H. Loke, A. K. London: Routledge.
Hussan, G. S. Lim (Eds.), The management of Levi, M. (1996). Social and unsocial capital: A review
diamondback moth and other crucifer pests. Proceed- essay of Robert Putnam's making democracy work.
ings of Third international workshop, Kuala Lum- Politics and Society, 24(1), 45±55.
pur, October 29±November 1. Kuala Lumpur: Malla, Y. B. (1997). Sustainable use of communal
Malaysian Agricultural Research and Development forests in Nepal. Journal of World Forest Resource
Institute. Management, 8, 51±74.
Hinchcli€e, F., Thompson, J., Pretty, J., Guijt, I., & Matteson, P. C., Gallagher, K. D., & Kenmore, P. E.
Shah, P. (1999). Fertile ground: The impacts of (1992). Extension of integrated pest management
participatory watershed management. London: IT for planthoppers in Asian irrigated rice. In R. F.
Publications. Denno, T. J. Perfect (Eds.), Ecology and the
Huxley, E. (1960). A new earth: An experiment in management of planthoppers. London: Chapman
colonialism. London: Chatto and Windus. and Hall.
IATP. (1998). Farmer-managed watershed program. At Maturana, H. R., & Varela, F. J. (1982). The tree of
http://www.iatp.org. knowledge: The biological roots of human understand-
Jacobs, J. (1961). The life and death of great American ing. Boston and London: Shabhala Publications.
cities. London: Random House. MOA/MALDM (1988±99). Annual and quarterly reports
Jodha, N. S. (1990). Common property resources and of catchment approach for soil conservation. Nairobi,
rural poor in dry regions of India. Economic and Kenya: Soil and Water Conservation Branch, Minis-
Political Weekly, 21, 1169±1181. try of Agriculture, Livestock Development and
Jones, K. (1999). Integrated pest and crop management in Marketing.
Sri Lanka. Paper for Conference on Sustainable Mooney, J. D., & Reiley, A. C. (1931). Onward industry.
agriculture: new paradigms and old practices? Bella- New York: Harper.
gio Conference Center, Italy, April 26±30. Narayan, D., & Pritchett, L. (1996). Cents and sociabil-
Just, F. (1998). Do soft regulations matter? Paper ity: Household income and social capital in rural
presented to Expert Meeting The externalities of Tanzania. Policy Research Working Paper 1796.
agriculture: What do we know? European Environ- Washington DC: The World Bank.
ment Agency, Copenhagen. National Landcare Programme (1999). At http://
Kenmore, P. E., Carino, F. O., Perez, C. A., Dyck, V. www.dpie.gov.au/landcare.
A., & Gutierrez, A. P. (1984). Population regulation Netting, R. McC., Stone, M. P., & Stone, G. (1990).
of the brown planthopper within rice ®elds in the Kofyar cash cropping: Choice and change in indig-
Philippines. Journal of Plant Protection in the enous agricultural development. Human Ecology, 17,
Tropics, 1(1), 19±37. 299±399.
Kenmore, P. E. (1999). IPM and farmer ®eld schools in Norton, A., & Stephens, T. (1995). Participation in
Asia. Paper for Conference on Sustainable Agricul- poverty assessments. Environment Department. Pa-
ture: New Paradigms and Old Practices? Bellagio pers No. 020. Washington DC: The World Bank.
Conference Center, Italy, April 26±30. Oerlemans, N., Proost, J., & Rauwhost, J. (1997).
Kiss, A., & Meerman, F. (1991). Integrated pest Farmers'study groups in the Netherlands. In L. van
management in African agriculture. World Bank Veldhuizen, A. Waters-Bayer, R. Ramirez, D. A.
Technical Paper 142. Washington DC: World Bank. Johnson, J. Thompson (Eds.), Farmers' research in
Knight, J. (1992). Institutions and social con¯ict. Cam- practice. London: IT Publications.
bridge: Cambridge University Press. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: public
Kothari, A., Pathak, N., Anuradha, R. V., & Taneja, B. goods and the theory of groups. London: Harvard
(1998). Communities and conservation: Natural re- Press.
source management in South and Central Asia. New Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations:
Delhi: Sage. Economic growth, stag¯ation and social rigidities.
Krishna, A., & Upho€, N. (1999). Operationalising New Haven: Yale University Press.
social capital: Explaining and measuring mutually Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution
bene®cial collective action in Rajasthan, India. of institutions for collective action. New York: Cam-
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. bridge University Press.
Lacy, J. (1997). Experiences of rice-check discussion Ostrom, E. (1996). Crossing the great divide: Copro-
groups after 12 years. In Proceedings of second duction synergy and development. World Develop-
Australasia paci®c extension conference: Managing ment, 24(6), 1073)±1087.
changeÐbuilding knowledge and skills (Vol. II), 224± Ostrom, E. (1998). Social capital: A fad or fundamental
227, Albury, New South Wales. Asia Paci®c Exten- concept? Bloomington, In: Center for the Study of
sion Network. Institutions, Population and Environmental Change,
Lam, W. F. (1998). Governing irrigation systems in Indiana University.
Nepal: Institutions infrastructure and collective action. Palmer, I. (1976). The new rice in Asia: Conclusions from
Oakland, CA: ICS Press. four country studies. Geneva: UNRISD.
226 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Pimentel, D., Harvey, C., Resosudarmo, P., Sinclair, K., Anuradha, & Taneja, B. (1998). Communities and
Kunz, D., McNair, M., Crist, S., Shpritz, L., Fitton, conservation: Natural resource management in South
L., Sa€ouri, R., & Blair, R. (1995). Environmental and Central Asia. New Delhi: Sage.
and economic costs soil erosion and conservation Roling, N. R. (1988). Extension science: information
bene®ts. Science, 267, 1117±1123. systems in agricultural development. Cambridge:
Platteau, J.-P. (1997). Mutual insurance as an elusive Cambridge University Press.
concept in traditional communities. Journal of Devel- Roling, R N. R., Wagemakers, M. A. (Eds.) (1997).
opment Studies, 33(6), 764±796. Social learning for sustainable agriculture. Cam-
Portes, A., & Landolt, P. (1996). The downside of social bridge: Cambridge University Press.
capital. The American Prospect, 26, 18±21. Rose, R. (1995). Russia as an hour glass society: a
PFI (Practical Farmers of Iowa) (1995). Shared visions. constitution without citizens. East European Consti-
Report to the W K Kellogg Foundation. By Gary tutional Review, 4(3), 34±42.
Huber. PFI, Iowa. Rowley, J. (1999). Working with social capital. London:
Pretty, J. (1991). Farmers' extension practice and Department for International Development.
technology adaptation: agricultural revolution in Sandler, T. (1997). Global challenges: an approach to
17±19th century Britain. Agriculture and Human environmental economic and political problems. Cam-
Values, VIII, 132±148. bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Pretty, J. (1995a). Regenerating agriculture: Policies and Scholz, B. C. G., Monsour, C. J., & Zalucki, M. P.
practice for sustainability and self-reliance. London: (1998). An evaluation of selective Helicoverpa armi-
Earthscan Publications; Washington, DC: National gera control options in sweet corn. Australian Jour-
Academy Press; Bangalore: ActionAid and Vikas. nal of Experimental Agriculture, 38, 601±607.
Pretty, J. (1995b). Participatory learning for sustainable Scoones, I. (1994). Living with uncertainty: new directions
agriculture. World Development, 23(8), 1247±1263. in pastoral development in Africa. London: IT Publi-
Pretty, J. (1998). The living land: Agriculture food and cations.
community regeneration in rural Europe. London: Scoones, I. (1998). Sustainable rural livelihoods: a
Earthscan Publications. framework for analysis. IDS Discussion Paper 72.
Pretty, J., & Pimbert, M. (1995). Beyond conservation University of Sussex, Brighton.
ideology and the wilderness myth. Natural Resources Shrestha, K. B. (1997). Community forestry: policy,
Forum, 19(1), 5±14. legislation and rules. Paper presented at national
Pretty, J., & Shah, P. (1997). Making soil and water workshop on community forestry and rural develop-
conservation sustainable: from coercion and control ment, July 24±26. Nepal: Lalipur.
to partnerships and participation. Land Degradation Shrestha, B. (1998). Involving local communities in
and Development, 8, 39±58. conservation: the case of Nepal. In A. Kothari, N.
Pretty, J., & Frank, B. R. (2000). Participation and Pathak, R.V. Anuradha, & B. Taneja. Communities
social capital formation in natural resource manage- and conservation: Natural resource management in
ment: Achievements and lessons. In Plenary paper South and Central Asia. New Delhi: Sage.
for International Landcare 2000 Conference. Mel- Singh, K., & Ballabh, V. (1997). Cooperative manage-
bourne, Australia. ment of natural resources. New Delhi: Sage.
Pretty, J., & Hine, R. (2000). The promising spread of Sirianni, C., & Friedland, L. (1997). Civic innovation and
sustainable agriculture in Asia. Natural Resources American democracy. Civic Practices Network at
Forum (UN), 24, 107±121. http://www.cpn/org.
Pretty, J., Thompson, J., & Kiara, J. K. (1995). SPWD (1992). Joint forest management: Concepts and
Agricultural regeneration in Kenya: the Catchment opportunities. New Delhi: Society for the Promotion
Approach to soil and water conservation. Ambio, of Wastelands Development.
XXIV(1), 7±15. SPWD (1998). Joint forest management update. New
Pretty, J., Brett, C., Gee, D., Hine, R., Mason, C. F., Delhi: Society for the Promotion of Wastelands
Morison, J. I. L., Raven, H., Rayment, M., & van Development.
der Bijl, G. (2000). An assessment of the total Stinchcombe, A. (1965). Social structure and organisa-
external costs of UK agriculture. Agricultural Sys- tions. In J. G. March (Ed.), Handbook of organisa-
tems 65(2), 113±136. tions. Chicago: Rand McNally.
Putnam, R. D., Leonardi, R., & Nanetti, R. Y. (1993). Taylor, M. (1982). Community anarchy and liberty.
Making democracy work: civic traditions in modern Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Upho€, N. (1992). Learning from Gal Oya: Possibilities
Putnam, R. (1995). Bowling alone: America's declining for participatory development and post-Newtonian
social capital. Journal of Democracy, 6(1), 65±78. science. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Putnam, R. D. (1996). The strange disappearance of Upho€, N. (1993). Grassroots organisations and NGO
civic America. The American Prospect 24 (Winter); in rural development: opportunity with diminishing
also at http:www.cpn/org/prospect/24/24putn.html. stakes and expanding markets. World Development,
M. Rahman (Ed.). (1984). Grass-roots participation and 21(4), 607±622.
self-reliance. New Delhi: Oxford and IBH Publica- Upho€, N. (1998). Understanding social capital: learn-
tion. ing from the analysis and experience of participation.
Raju, G. (1998). Institutional structures for community In I. Serageldin, & P. Dasgupta (Eds.), Social
based conservation. In A. Kothari, N. Pathak, R. V. Capital. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND THE ENVIRONMENT 227

Upho€, N., Esman, M.J., & Krishna, A. (1998). Reasons Ward, H. (1998). State, association, and community in a
for success: Learning from instructive experiences in sustainable democratic polity: towards a green asso-
rural development. West Hartford, Conn.: Kumarian ciationalism. In F. Coenen, D. Huitema, & L. J.
Press. O'Toole (Eds.), Participation and the quality of
van de Fliert, E. (1997). From pest control to ecosystem environmental decision making. Dordrecht: Kluwer
management: how IPM training can help? Paper Academic Publishers.
presented to international conference on ecological Woolcock, M. (1998). Social capital and economic
agriculture. Chandigarh, India. development: towards a theoretical synthesis and
van Veldhuizen, L., Waters-Bayer, A., Ramirez, R., policy framework. Theory and Society, 27, 151±208.
Johnson, D.A., & Thompson, J. (Eds.), Farmers' World Bank (1994). The World Bank and participation.
research in practice. London: IT Publications. Report of the Learning Group on Participatory
van Weperen, W., & R oling, N. (1995). Integrated Development. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
arable farming in the Netherlands. Hetveranderings- World Neighbors (1999). The cycle and actors of the
proces (The change process). Wageningen, Nether- development process. Oklahoma City, OK: World
lands. Neighbors.

You might also like