You are on page 1of 11

Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Ecological Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon

Analysis

The Post-growth Challenge: Secular Stagnation, Inequality and the Limits to T


Growth
Tim Jackson
Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity (CUSP), University of Surrey, Guildford, Surrey, GU2 7XH, UK

A B S T R A C T

Critics have long questioned the feasibility (and desirability) of exponential growth on a finite planet. More recently, mainstream economists have begun to suggest
some ‘secular’ limits to growth. Declining growth rates have in their turn been identified as instrumental in increased inequality and the rise of political populism.
This paper explores these emerging arguments paying a particular attention to the dynamics of secular stagnation. It examines the underlying phenomenon of
declining labour productivity growth and unpacks the close relationships between productivity growth, the wage rate and social inequality. It also points to the
historical congruence (and potential causal links) between declining productivity growth and resource bottlenecks. Contrary to some mainstream views, this paper
finds no inevitability in the rising inequality that has haunted advanced economies in recent decades, suggesting instead that it lies in the pursuit of growth at all
costs, even in the face of challenging fundamentals. This strategy has hindered technological innovation, reinforced inequality and exacerbated financial instability.
At the very least, this paper argues, it is now time for policy to consider seriously the possibility that low growth rates might be ‘the new normal’ and to address
carefully the ‘post-growth challenge’ this poses.

‘[The GDP] measures everything… except that which makes life Political responses to the Club of Rome were striking. Over the next
worthwhile.’ decade or so, politicians of almost every hue stood up to repudiate the
Robert Kennedy, 1968. report. US President Ronald Reagan saw fit to insist on several occa-
sions that there are ‘no limits to economic growth, because there are no
limits to human ingenuity’,1 an argument which owes more to rhetoric
1. Introduction
than to logic. The economist Kenneth Boulding, giving evidence to a US
House of Representatives Select Committee hearing responded differ-
The pursuit of economic growth has been a defining feature of the
ently. ‘Anyone who believes that exponential growth can continue in-
global economy for well over half a century (Coyle, 2014; Philipsen,
definitely on a finite planet,’ he remarked, ‘is either a madman or an
2015; Victor and Dolter, 2017). Growth narratives are evident in every
economist’ (Boulding, 1973).
sphere: economic, secular, social and political. Indeed, their prevalence
The final decades of the twentieth century saw the central issue
and centrality in political discourse is so pronounced that it is credible
largely relegated to questions about the speed and efficiency with
to speak of something like a ‘growth fetish’ (Stiglitz, 2009; Hamilton,
which it would be possible to ‘decouple’ economic growth from its
2003) – a predominant, often unquestioned assumption that economic
material impacts and thereby avoid the need to transform the economic
expansion is an irreducible good without which social progress is im-
system itself. Ecological modernisation (Von Weizsäcker et al., 1995;
possible.
Mol, 2001) – and then later eco-modernism (Breakthrough 2015) –
Critics of this view also have a long pedigree. Robert Kennedy's
prevailed as the politically acceptable response to the question of re-
speech (cited above) at the University of Kansas in March 1968, fifty
source and environmental limits and the deeper critique of growth-
years ago this year, remains both resonant and prescient of the ensuing
based economics was kept alive largely through marginal voices such as
critique (Jackson, 2018). The publication of the Club of Rome's Limits
those of economists like Daly (1977), Waring (1988) and Douthwaite
to Growth report (Meadows et al., 1972) four years later established the
(1992), supported at times by a parallel argument about the social
resource and environmental parameters of the growth critique. Their
limits to growth (Easterlin, 1974; Hirsch, 1977; Layard, 2005).
analysis too has stood the test of time (Turner, 2008; Jackson and
It is probably fair to say that these ‘marginal voices’ enjoyed a little
Webster, 2016).

E-mail address: t.jackson@surrey.ac.uk.


1
‘Remarks at Convocation Ceremonies at University of South Carolina, September 20th 1983. Online at: http://www.reagan.utexas.edu/archives/speeches/1983/
92083c.htm.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.10.010
Received 23 June 2018; Received in revised form 14 September 2018; Accepted 7 October 2018
0921-8009/ © 2018 Published by Elsevier B.V.
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

more attention during and after the ‘dot com’ recession at the turn of longer available to developed countries? What if sluggish demand was
the millennium.2 But in the decade that has passed since the financial not caused by cyclical underinvestment or debt overhang, inevitable
crisis of 2008, there has been a much more pronounced resurgence of echoes from the 2008 financial crisis? What if it represented a more
interest in the growth critique from a variety of different perspectives entrenched change in underlying economic fundamentals? Could an era
(D'Alisa et al., 2014; O'Neill et al., 2018; Jackson, 2009, 2017; Raworth, of falling growth rates in advanced economies (Fig. 1) be the ‘new
2017; Fioramonti, 2015; Victor, 2008/2018). A deeper recognition of normal’?
environmental and social limits has certainly played some part in this Summers attributed the slow-down over recent decades to ‘under-
more recent debate (Rockström et al., 2009). But a fascinating new consumption’ by households in the context of rising personal debt and
dimension has arisen. As economic uncertainty continued to haunt the heightened political risk. Others believed the problems arose from the
most developed countries, some mainstream economists were prepared supply side. According to Say's Law, ‘supply creates its own demand’:
to flirt with the idea that lower growth rates were not simply a tem- making things provides people with income which they must then
porary or cyclical phenomenon in the wake of the crisis. The term spend back into the economy. As long as the supply potential of the
‘secular stagnation’ – first coined in the 1930s – has been revived to economy continues to grow, so the argument goes, there should be no
describe a decline in the rate of economic growth in advanced nations bottlenecks on growth; the problem must be with the supply potential
that appears to be only partly to do with the financial conditions of of the economy. The US economist Robert Gordon suggested that the
2008 and to have its roots in factors that predate the crisis by several slowdown in growth was a result of a decline in the pace of innovation.
decades at least. As the futurist Martin Ford (2015) has suggested, there Many of the big technological advances of the last two centuries are
are ‘good reasons to believe that the economic goldilocks period has now over, he argued. Taken together with six ‘deflationary headwinds’
come to an end for many developed nations.’ Low and perhaps de- including: an aging population, rising inequality, and the ‘overhang’ of
clining growth rates may be here to stay. consumer and government debt, Gordon (2012, 2016) suggested that
The aim of this paper is to explore this phenomenon in more detail the era of easy growth for advanced economies was over.
and to understand some of its most serious implications. Section 2 Responding to the supply side explanation, Summers invoked a kind
discusses the evidence for a slow-down in the growth rate. Section 3 of ‘inverse Say's Law’: namely, that a lack of demand could itself create
explores one particular aspect of this dynamic, namely the role of la- a lack of supply. John Maynard Keynes had shown how Say's Law could
bour productivity growth, and speculates on the link between this go wrong, once the demand for money and financial assets came into
phenomenon and evidence of the declining energy return on energy the picture. If people hoard money or use it to buy (or speculate in)
investment. Section 4 elaborates on some of the most important impacts financial assets, then incomes never find their way back in as demand
of the decline, particularly in terms of rising inequalities in income and and the simple equivalence between supply growth and demand growth
wealth. Finally, Section 5 draws the threads of the analysis together to is broken. For reasons similar to those highlighted by Keynes, Summers
propose both a particular interpretation of recent ‘crises of capitalism’ argued that a slowdown in demand, combined with increasing invest-
and an escape route from them. ment in financial assets would divert funding away from productive
Specifically, my argument is this: the rising inequality and political investment. This was the underlying cause of a diminished supply po-
instability witnessed recently in advanced economies is neither an ac- tential. Creating more and more cheap money (through low interest
cidental aftermath of the financial crisis nor an inevitable result of rates and quantitative easing, for instance) cannot solve this problem,
declining growth rates. Rather, these phenomena are a direct con- he argued, because cheap money only encourages more speculative
sequence of continuing to cling to the ‘growth fetish’, at a time when lending.4
economic (and resource) fundamentals are pointing in a different di- Whatever the balance between supply and demand side factors, the
rection. The ‘post-growth’ challenge of the title is not so much about global implications of a ‘secular stagnation’ are now beginning to be-
trying to ‘turn growth off’ but rather about protecting social progress come clear (Fig. 1). In the mid-1960s, the trend growth in per capita
and environmental integrity in the face of what some well-known GDP (shown by the solid line in Fig. 1) was over 4% per annum, By
economists are now prepared to call the ‘new normal’ (Summers, 2014; 2016, it had fallen substantially from its mid-1960s peak to little more
Galbraith, 2014; Storm, 2017). than 1% per annum. The decline was not always uniform. Following the
second oil crisis in the early 1980s, there was a partial recovery of the
trend growth rate. A similar recovery is visible towards the end of the
2. Confronting Secular Stagnation scenario period, in the wake of the financial crisis. It is yet to be seen
whether this latter recovery heralds a new era of higher growth for the
In November 2013, five years after the collapse of Lehman Brothers, OECD nations. The analysis in the following section casts some doubt
the former World Bank chief economist and US Treasury Secretary on that possibility. But a simple linear extrapolation over the last five
Larry Summers gave a speech to the International Monetary Fund's decades (see the dotted line in Fig. 1) suggests there may be no growth
annual research conference which sent something of a shock wave at all in the per capita income of the OECD countries within less than a
through the audience. He suggested that the slow growth rates and decade.
continuing uncertainties of the post-crisis years were not just temporary
after-effects of the financial crisis itself. ‘The underlying problem may
be there forever,’ he said (Summers, 2014; FT, 2018). 3. The Productivity Puzzle
Summers was certainly not the only, or the first, commentator to
make such a claim.3 But he was certainly the most well-known econ- Behind the decline in per capita growth rates lies another yet more
omist to do so. The repercussions were profound. It suddenly became telling statistic: the trend in labour productivity growth. Fig. 2 reveals
acceptable to ask previously unthinkable questions. What if the rates of that the pattern in labour productivity growth is similar to that for the
growth expected by economists and so desired by politicians were no growth in per capita GDP (Fig. 1), but with some notable differences.
There is no partial recovery in the growth rate following the second oil
crisis, only a slowing down of the decline. Furthermore, there is nothing
2
I am grateful to an anonymous reviewer for pointing this out to me. in the way of an upturn during the final years. Labour productivity was
3
The term ‘secular stagnation’ had first been coined by Alvin Hansen in his growing at only 0.6% per year in 2016, only a little over half the growth
Presidential Address to the American Economic Association in 1938 (Hansen,
1939) to describe a situation in which economic fundamentals pointed to ser-
4
ious problems for the growth paradigm. For a useful overview of the more re- See for instance: https://www.cbpp.org/blog/summers-lack-of-demand-
cent debate see the collection of essays edited by Teulings and Baldwin (2014). creates-lack-of-supply.

237
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

Fig. 1. Growth rate in OECD GDP per ca-


pita: 1966–2016.
Source: Author's calculations from World
Development Indicators Database (WB,
2017); moving trend calculated using HP
Filter with lamda = 100. (The Hodrick-
Prescott (HP) filter is a statistical tool used
to remove the cyclical component of mac-
roeconomics data and expose the under-
lying long-term trend. See for example:
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hodrick%
E2%80%93Prescott_filter. The value of the
parameter lamda chosen for this analysis is
typical for time series data with an annual
frequency. Note that the linear trend asso-
ciated with the HP filter is the same as the
linear trend associated with the underlying
data.)

Fig. 2. Labour productivity growth in the


OECD: 1971–2016.
Source: Author's calculations using data
from OECD database: https://data.oecd.
org/lprdty/gdp-per-hour-worked.htm;
moving trend calculated using HP Filter
with lamda = 100. Extrapolation of the
linear trend suggests that labour pro-
ductivity growth reaches zero by 2028.

rate in GDP per capita. GDP per capita would always be equal to the growth rate in labour
These differences between the GDP per capita growth and the un- productivity. It is evident from Figs. 1 and 2 that this is not the case.
derlying labour productivity growth have important implications. Labour productivity growth has declined faster than growth in the per
Labour productivity is defined here as the GDP generated (on average) capita GDP. Mathematically, this means either that the workforce
by each hour of labour worked in the economy, that is the GDP divided participation rate has risen over time or else that the average number of
by the total hours worked in the economy. The total hours worked in hours worked by each worker in the economy is increasing.
the economy can be characterised as the average hours worked by each In fact, both of these things have happened at different times during
person in the workforce multiplied by the number of people in the the last half a century or so. Until recently, the average hours worked
workforce. The number of people in the workforce can also be written had been declining across most the OECD but participation rates had
as the population multiplied by a ‘workforce participation rate’. increased, allowing the growth rate in GDP per capita to decline more
A little mathematics reveals that the GDP per capita is equal to the slowly than the decline in labour productivity growth. Since the fi-
labour productivity multiplied both by the workforce participation rate nancial crisis, there has been an increase in the average hours worked
and the average number of hours worked by each member of the across many advanced economies, including the UK and the US. People
workforce. If the workforce participation rate and the average hours are working longer hours in order to sustain their desired income levels
worked were to remain constant, the GDP per capita would be directly
proportional to the labour productivity.5 In this case, the growth rate in
(footnote continued)
average by each member of the work force, then it follows first that
5
If lp is labour productivity, N is the workforce, P is the population, n = N/P GDP = lp ∗ h ∗ N and therefore that GDP per capita = GDP/P = (lp ∗ h ∗ N)/
is the workforce participation rate and h is the number of hours worked on P = lp ∗ h ∗ n. When h and n are constant, GDP is directly proportional to lp.

238
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

(OECD, 2017). Fig. 2 suggests that, on current trends, labour pro- First, it is plausible that the two successive oil crises themselves had
ductivity growth will decline to zero across the OECD by around 2028. something to do with a subsequent suppression of the growth rate.
In about a decade, it is entirely possible that per capita GDP growth Trend labour productivity growth peaked at over 4% shortly before the
could only be achieved by having a greater proportion of the population first oil crisis. By the time of the second oil crisis in 1980, it had fallen to
in the workforce or by having people work on average for longer hours. barely 2.5%. Meanwhile the price of oil (Fig. 4) had reached the
This finding is particularly puzzling in the face of a completely equivalent of $100/bbl (measured in today's money). Conventional
opposite proposal, namely that advances in technology (specifically, in wisdom would certainly suggest some link between these phenomena.
artificial intelligence and robotisation) are poised to make such massive Price rises for a fundamental good such as energy would have a pro-
increases in labour productivity that vast swathes of the current found impact on economic growth by increasing the costs of business
workforce, far from being asked to work for longer, will find themselves and depressing people's real spending power. The global economic
redundant because there is no longer enough work for human beings to slowdowns in 1974/5 and 1981/2 are usually attributed to the oil price
do (Avent, 2016; Ford, 2015). The jury is still out on where (in which shocks. A subsequent collapse of the oil price suggests that the crises
sectors) this displacement is most likely to occur, when it is likely to themselves had little to do with the question of underlying resource
arrive and the extent to which it will be a good or a bad thing for the scarcity. Yet the question is clearly relevant and points us towards the
economy as a whole (Susskind, 2017; Autor and Salomons, 2017). The second potential explanation for the decline.
most puzzling question is why it is not yet already visible in the labour Some ecological economists have long argued that the enormous
productivity statistics. But it clearly is not. growth in productivity of advanced economies was only possible at all
To get a better sense of this puzzle, it is worth looking in more depth because of the abundance of high-quality fossil energy sources
at the longer term trend in labour productivity growth in a particular (Georgescu-Roegen, 1972; Daly, 1977; Ayres, 2008; Ayres and Warr,
country for which a long time-series on labour productivity exists. The 2009). Any slowing down in the availability or quality of such sources
UK was the first country to industrialise, it typifies the structure of late- might be expected, as the Club of Rome suggested back in 1972, to
modern western economies, and may well be facing the post-growth suppress overall productivity and eventually reduce the rate of in-
challenge sooner than other OECD countries. Fig. 3 paints a remarkable dustrial output. Both the quality and the availability of resources can be
picture. Broadly speaking, trend labour productivity growth rose more captured in the concept of the energy return on energy invested
or less continually from the beginning of the century until about the (EROEI), that is the ratio of the energy delivered to the energy required
mid-1960s, aside from ups and downs related to the two world wars and to find, extract, refine and deliver that energy to the consumer (Rye and
the Great Depression. Since the mid-1960s however, with virtually no Jackson, 2018; Sers and Victor, 2018). During the early years of ex-
remission at all, the trend in labour productivity growth has been ploration, and the early years of life any particular resource, we might
falling. This fall was at best slowed down, but never entirely reversed expect the EROEI to rise, as technological efficiency improves and the
by the introduction of extraordinary new technologies such as personal dynamics of resource extraction evolve. On the other hand, we must
computing, electronic communications and the internet. also expect a countervailing tendency if the Limits hypothesis is correct.
The period between the second oil crisis and the collapse of the In other words, in the long run, we should expect the amount of energy
dotcom bubble at the turn of the millennium witnessed a kind of pla- required to extract the next marginal unit of energy to increase, as the
teau in labour productivity growth. Certainly the decline was not so fast quality of the physical resource declines. In fact it is possible to see both
during these years. But since, 9/11 labour productivity growth in the these tendencies at work, within a given geographical context over
UK has dropped precipitously. It's particularly important to recognise time.
that this decline preceded the financial crisis itself by at least a decade Fig. 5 shows the rise and fall of EROEI in oil and gas production in
and more likely by several decades. By 2016, the trend labour pro- Canada between the end of the second world war and the financial
ductivity growth rate in the UK was just 0.12%, lower than at any point crisis. It illustrates an uneven pattern of rise and fall over the time
in more than a century. period, reflecting both of the trends discussed above. Technological and
The causes of the pattern shown in Fig. 3 are by no means obvious. geological factors improved the energy efficiency of production until
Three or four possible explanations are worth considering, each of about the early 1970s, at which point there was a sharp decline as the
which has some relevance for the transition to a sustainable economy. oil crises placed an increasing demand on existing fields (with declining

Fig. 3. Labour productivity growth in the


UK 1900–2016.
Source: Author's calculations of the moving
trend (HP Filter with lamda = 100) using
data from the Bank of England millennium
dataset (BoE, 2016) and Office for National
Statistics (ONS, 2017); note that this graph
does not show the year on year variability
in labour productivity growth.

239
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

Fig. 4. Oil price ($/bbl) in current and constant prices 1966–2016.


Source: Data from the BP Statistical Review of World Energy (BP, 2017); price point: pre-1984 – Arabian Light; post-1984 – Brent Crude.

quality). The recovery between 1980 and the early 1990s probably (Poisson and Hall, 2013). A recent study from China (Feng et al., 2018)
reflects the enhanced efforts to make new discoveries in the wake of the suggests that the point-of-use EROI has fell by a half between 1987 and
crises. But it is notable that the success of this strategy in sustaining a 2012. Indeed, most EROEI studies across multiple countries show a
high EROEI was relatively short-lived. At a certain point, geological declining EROEI in the last two to three decades (Hall et al., 2014;
factors will constrain the possibility of maintaining a high EROEI. The Guilford et al., 2011).
end of the period shows another slight upturn in the EROEI associated It is fascinating of course that the peak EROEI in both these contexts
with the emergence of ‘unconventional’ oil sources, but these sources was around about the same time as the productivity peak in advanced
are themselves generally regarded as having a lower quality (lower nations, and tempting therefore to conclude that the subsequent decline
EROEI) than conventional sources (Hall et al., 2014). in labour productivity growth may have something to do with the de-
The ‘long-run’ pattern of rise and fall shown in Fig. 5 is repeated in cline in the quality of energy sources. Things may not be quite so
other geographical locations, not always so dramatically. A study for straightforward. The oil crises of the 1970s had more to do with politics
the US found that the EROEI of US oil and gas production increased than they did with underlying resource scarcity. In the years following
from around 16:1 in 1920 to around 30:1 in 1970. Subsequently, the two crises, there was a lengthy decline in oil prices which lasted
however, the EROEI declined and in 2010 was estimated to be only 10:1 right through to the end of the 1990s. By 1998, the oil price had fallen

Fig. 5. Energy Return on Energy Invested (EROEI) in Canada: 1945–2009.


Source: Data from Friese (2011).

240
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

Fig. 6. Post-tax income shares of top 10% and top 1% in the US: 1935–2015.
Source: Data from Piketty et al. (2017).

to less than $20 (in 2016 prices), lower than it had been for a quarter of certainly made it more difficult to invest in the transition to low-carbon
a century. That situation was soon to reverse, and during the early and resource efficient technology which might offset the environmental
2000's there was another steep rise towards the financial crisis peak of limits to growth. It has also contributed to some of the ‘headwinds’ that
$147 a barrel (Fig. 4). may have slowed down the pace of innovation.
This price volatility had little to do with underlying scarcity Perhaps even more important are the effects of government policy
(Baumeister and Kilian, 2016). Overall resource quality was (by defi- on the stability of the financial system. The policies pursued in since the
nition) declining even as the oil price was declining (for instance during time of the oil crises, designed to keep the growth rate going, irre-
the 1980s and 1990, and again post 2011). In reality, price is an im- spective of underlying fundamentals, were complicit in generating an
perfect indicator of the underlying quality of the physical resource. At increasing fragility in financial markets which was to have a profound
the moment, there is simply insufficient evidence to link the rise and effect not only on the economy but on the conditions of people's lives,
fall in labour productivity growth definitively to a rise and fall in re- with implications in particular for inequality.
source quality. But it remains the case, that in the long run, as resource
quality declines, there are likely to be significant implications for la- 4. The Age of Inequality
bour productivity growth. More labour rather than less may well be
needed to deliver each unit of economic output as the availability of In 2014, the French economist Thomas Piketty published his treatise
high-quality energy declines. on Capitalism in the 21st Century. It was an immediate, if unlikely,
This brings us to the third possible explanation for the decline in best-seller: a voluminous economic text book that had a global impact.
labour productivity in advanced economies, namely the changing Its fame rested on two main features. The first was the spotlight that it
structure of both demand and supply. Late modern economies are shone on rising inequality, particularly within the advanced economies.
characterised by a shift from primary and secondary manufacturing of There is now considerable evidence of reduced inequality between
material products towards the provision of services. This shift occurs nations (IMF, 2017). But within advanced nations, the situation is dif-
both in the supply structure of the economy (for a variety of reasons) ferent. Piketty and his colleagues (Piketty, 2014; Piketty et al., 2017)
and the demand structure. On the supply side, there is a tendency for have shown that the post-tax income of the richest percentiles of the US
advanced economies to export basic extraction and processing activities population received a rising share of the national income over the past
to countries with lower labour costs and lower environmental regula- half century. By 2015, the richest 10% of the population received al-
tions. On the demand side, it is possible that, once basic material needs most 40% of the national income, higher than at any time since 1945.
are satisfied, people turn more to service-based activities as the desti- The post-tax income share of the richest 1% had risen even faster than
nation for disposable income, rather than to even more material pro- that of the top 10%, and by 2015 stood at over 15% of the national
ducts. Service-based activities are generally understood to be less income, higher than at any point since 1940 (Fig. 6).
amenable to growth in labour productivity – partly because the core- The second striking feature of Piketty's bestselling work was a
value proposition in such activities relates to the time spent by human particular argument about the causes of rising inequality. Specifically,
beings in delivering the service (Jackson, 2017; Baumol, 2012). There the French economist argued that rising inequality was a direct and
are some interesting implications here for the transition to a sustainable inevitable result of the declining growth rate. There are various heur-
economy. We return to these in the concluding section. istic arguments to support this view. Certainly, there's an uncanny in-
Finally, it is possible that the financial structure of the global verse resemblance between the U-shaped curve shown in Fig. 6 and the
economy plays some role in the plight in which advanced economies in inverted U-shaped curves shown in Fig. 3 (and indeed 5). Could it be
particular appear now to find themselves. In support of growth, ad- that rising economic growth, built on increased labour productivity, is
vanced economies in particular have attempted to increase liquidity precisely what allowed society to reduce inequality through the first
through a mixture of financial innovation, low interest rates, and (more half of the 20th Century?
recently) direct monetary financing (particularly of the financial sector This was of course the idea behind what became known as ‘trickle-
itself). This has tended to stimulate speculative investment at the ex- down’ theory: the hypothesis that economic growth is the best way to
pense of productive investment in the real economy. Whether this reduce the inequality that divides society and undermines political
process has held back labour productivity growth is less clear. But it has solidarity. It was President Kennedy who popularised the idea that a

241
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

‘rising tide lifts all boats’. Wealth generation for the richest should flow countries. It is beyond the scope of this paper to discuss this dynamic in
back into society as the rich spend their income on more and more detail. But the overall effect has been, in formal terms, increasingly to
goods and services. Setting aside for the moment the environmental favour the interests of capital over labour. In less formal terms, it has
impacts of this increased throughput, the process should at least allow contributed to job insecurity, exacerbated inequality and contributed to
for income growth amongst the very poorest, who would find em- the rise of a new political populism – the disenfranchised protest of
ployment in the manufacturing sectors that provided for this increasing those left behind in the process.7
expenditure. With labour productivity rising, production costs would All of this appears to support Piketty's conclusion that rising in-
fall, allowing employers to compensate their employees with ever equality is an inevitable result of a declining growth rate. Beyond his
higher wages. With more spending power in the economy generally, empirical exploration, Piketty also attempted to put this relationship on
even the poorest sectors of society would be encouraged to spend more a theoretical footing. He showed first that capital's share of income is
into the economy. And so the virtuous cycle would continue.6 directly proportional to the rate of return on capital multiplied by the
In fact, as Piketty and his colleagues have shown (Fig. 7), in the savings rate and is inversely proportional to the growth rate. This in-
immediate post-war years, the benefits of growth did flow pre- verse proportionality on the growth rate means that, all things being
dominantly to the poorest in society. Between 1946 and 1980, the equal, as the growth rate falls, the share of income going to the owners
lowest income percentiles in the US received the highest income of capital will rise. Unless the distribution of capital is itself entirely
growth, while the highest income percentiles received the lowest in- equal (a situation which clearly does not pertain at the moment) the
come growth. The average real growth in per capita GDP during the relationship therefore presents the spectre of an ‘explosive’ rise (Krusell
period was around 2%. Average income growth in the lowest percentile and Smith, 2014) in inequality as the growth rate declines to zero.
was three times this, at 6%, while income growth in the richest per- The analysis contains a couple of critical assumptions, however. The
centile was little more than half the economy wide average (Fig. 7 – first of these concerns the behaviour of the savings rate as the growth
blue lines and markers). Not surprising then, that inequality was rate declines – Piketty implicitly assumed it would stay constant. The
broadly declining over that period. second relates to the ease with which it is possible to substitute capital
In the period since 1980, the story has been a very different one. for labour. With constant savings rate and high substitutability of ca-
Average income growth over the period was lower to start with, at only pital for labour, it's straightforward to show that Piketty was right.
1.4%, between 1980 and 2014. But the striking part of the story was the Inequality rises explosively. This world has strong resonances with the
reversal in the fortunes of the poorest and richest as beneficiaries of that kind of dystopian future that we are increasingly being told may soon
growth. The incomes of the bottom 50% of the population grew at a be upon us: a small minority of high-tech companies drive an increas-
meagre 0.6%, only half the average rate of growth of the economy as a ingly automated world with a rising capital intensity in which there is
whole, while the incomes of the richest 5% grew at 1.7% per annum, less and less need for wage labour. Demand may well stagnate, social
significantly above the average income growth (Fig. 7 – red lines and conditions will deteriorate for the majority but as long as the minority
markers). The story within the story is even more striking. Since 1980, owners of capital have sufficient sway over government to protect their
it was increasingly the super-rich who benefited from whatever growth returns, there are insufficient grounds or resources to shift track.
the economy could provide. The average growth rate of the top 0.001% These outcomes only transpire, however, under conditions which
of the population was over 6%, allowing them to increase their post-tax include a more or less constant savings rate and a high elasticity of
earnings by a factor of seven over the last three decades. The poorest substitution between capital and labour. Outside of those conditions,
5% saw their post-tax incomes fall in real terms over the same period. other outcomes are entirely possible. One such world is a future where
Shifts in labour productivity growth may have had something to do the net savings rate declines alongside the growth rate. Under condi-
with this story. Neoclassical economics assumes that wage growth fol- tions in which it is increasingly difficult to protect the rate of return on
lows labour productivity growth. If each hour of work is 2% more capital, the decline on returns is likely to disincentivise investment and
productive each year, then in theory, employers can afford to pay lower the savings rate. The outcome is that inequality is contained
workers a 2% wage increase, without facing any additional costs. But between more reasonable bounds (Jackson and Victor, 2018).
when labour productivity growth is falling or stagnant, wage growth is Varying the ease of substitution between capital and labour has an
also sluggish, so that even when GDP growth is buoyed up by fiscal or even more striking effect. With a modest protection of the right to work
monetary policy, it tends to leave workers on the whole less well off in and fewer incentives to accumulate capital (modelled through a low
the economy and to increase inequality. In fact (Fig. 8), since the 1970s, substitutability between capital and labour), inequality declines ‘natu-
as productivity growth slowed down, the rate of labour compensation rally’ in the economy, even without the impact of re-distributive policy
has been suppressed considerably below the growth in labour pro- measures such as a capital tax (Piketty, 2014) or the introduction of a
ductivity, exacerbating inequality even further. universal basic income (RSA, 2015). With the introduction of modest
Fig. 8 shows this pattern for the United States. The wage rate fol- levels of such measures, it is possible to reduce inequality substantially,
lowed labour productivity growth rather closely between the Second even as the growth rate declines towards zero (Jackson and Victor,
World War and the mid-1970s. But since that time, the two trends have 2018).
diverged significantly. Cumulative wage rate growth has fallen sub- In short, the idea that rising income inequality is an inevitable
stantially below the cumulative growth in labour productivity. Fig. 8 consequence of falling growth rates is incorrect. Under the appropriate
tells a remarkable and complex story of the decline in the relative conditions, an economy with a declining growth rate might equally be
bargaining power of workers over recent decades. This story involves headed towards lower income inequality and greater stability of em-
the emergence of new technologies, the squeezing of producer margins ployment. The choice, it turns out, lies in the underlying structure of
from higher resource prices, and a protracted pursuit of cheap labour
strategies involving a substantial off-shoring of labour to less developed
7
I'm grateful to Herman Daly for alerting me to the multiple dependencies
here. Particularly fascinating is the extent to which new technologies with
6
It is interesting to compare this view against the argument (Seidel, 2017) potentially high marginal labour productivities have contributed to the disen-
that there is a much longer term trend for elites to accumulate proportionately franchisement of labour in an economy in which the average labour pro-
more and more wealth until one of the ‘great levellers’—famine, plague, eco- ductivity is stalling. The implications of this dynamic are similar to those dis-
nomic collapse, or revolution—breaks the cycle. The wider implications lie cussed in Susskind (2017). But this evidence shows that perverse implications
beyond the scope of this paper. But I am grateful to an anonymous reviewer for can arise long before high levels of unemployment arise. Susskind's ‘im-
pointing this out to me. miseration of labour’ is a gradual and complex process.

242
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

Fig. 7. The rise and fall of the American dream. Post-tax income growth in the US by percentile 1946–2014.
Source: Data from Piketty et al. (2017).

Fig. 8. The gap between US labour compensation and productivity.


Source: Data from the Economic Policy Institute; see EPI (2014); updated data available online at: http://www.epi.org/productivity-pay-gap/.

economic relations and, in particular, in the relations between labour contributing role. Perhaps the most troubling possibility is that the
(the workforce in paid employment in the economy) and capital (the wide-spread technological advances facilitated by ready abundance of
owners of productive and financial assets). high-quality energy resources in the first seventy years of the 20th
century are no longer available to advanced economies in the 21st.
5. Confronting the Post-growth Challenge Evidence of a decline in the quality of some physical resources already
exists. Sooner or later further declines are inevitable. As they arrive,
A decade after the financial crisis, growth rates in advanced they are likely to depress labour productivity growth still further.
economies have still not returned to those experienced in the pre-crisis The critical question is how policy should respond to this not-so-
era. A long-term decline in the rate of labour productivity growth is one new reality. The conventional response has been to look for conditions
of the underlying factors contributing to this situation. Understanding – technological, fiscal, monetary – to keep growth going, whatever the
that long-term decline is clearly vital. Debt overhang, shifting patterns cost. The prevalent ‘rescue narrative’ relies on an assumption that with
of demand and the geo-politics of resource supply all play some appropriate policy incentives, new technological breakthroughs will

243
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

emerge and productivity growth will recover. Candidate ‘saviours’ in economists, was: no. Chasing growth through loose monetary policy in
this rescue narrative are various. For some (NCE 2014 2017), innova- the face of challenging underlying fundamentals had led to financial
tion will arrive from investment in the same clean, low-carbon tech- bubbles which destabilised finance and culminated in crisis.
nologies that are needed to tackle climate change and offset resource Perhaps the most pernicious impact of this period of loose monetary
depletion. For others (Ford, 2015; Avent, 2016), innovation will come policy – and indeed of the crisis itself – was the steady rise in inequality
from the emerging digital revolution: increased automation, robot- within advanced nations. There were several channels through which
isation, artificial intelligence. But to date, none of the productivity this acceleration occurred. In the first place, cheap money led to fi-
gains foreseen by these technologies have been manifest at the macro- nancial speculation. Those with access to capital could achieve sub-
economic level and this latter world could lead to the ‘immiseration’ of stantial capital gains as asset prices rose. When wealth is already un-
labour (Susskind, 2017) and levels of inequality reminiscent of the equally distributed, this tendency leads directly to higher income
worst scenarios outlined in the previous section. inequality. As income inequality increases, it leads to excessive in-
In historical perspective, it is clear that the advanced economies vestment funds, because richer households tend to have a high pro-
now stand at a distinct, and uncomfortable cross-roads. Two competing pensity to save than poorer ones. This excess of savings leads to more
theories about how to maintain growth (Keynesianism and monetarism) speculation, pushing asset prices up again and accelerating inequality
have dominated macroeconomics over the last half century. Neither is further. It is also likely to depresses growth, partly through the reduced
adequate to the challenge of resolving current conditions. Developed in spending power of poorer households and partly through the crowding
response to the Great Depression in the 1930's, John Maynard Keynes' out of investment in the real economy. Policy responses which attempt
macroeconomics saw a critical role for government in maintaining to stimulate investment by reducing the interest rate, end up making
economic stability (Keynes, 1936). If supply potential was not enough money cheaper and incentivising more speculation, fuelling a vicious
to keep growth going (as Says had argued), governments could not rely cycle of rising inequality (Credit Suisse, 2014, p34).
on households and firms simply to go on spending during the hard But this cycle of rising inequality was by no means inevitable. Nor is
times. They must play an active role in stimulating the economy to it inevitable in the future. More correct would be to argue that rising
‘kick-start’ growth again. The strategy worked, up to a point. It was instability (both social and financial) is the result of our persistent at-
exemplified in particular by Franklin D Roosevelt's ‘New Deal’ in the tempts to breathe new life into capitalism, in the face of underlying
States. fundamentals that are now beginning to point in the opposite direction.
The subsequent ‘failure’ of Keynesianism to solve the problems of Reversing the trend by raising the labour productivity growth rate
‘stagflation’ during the oil crises led to a temporary disillusionment through selective technologies is a highly uncertain strategy that may
with the idea and in the early 1980s, western governments (pre- well intensify the environmental and social problems of the 21st cen-
dominantly led by the anglo-centric nations) abandoned Keynes and tury. By privileging the interests of the owners of capital over the in-
turned instead to monetarism – the brainchild of Chicago school terests of those employed in wage labour in the economy, it may be
economist Milton Friedman. Built on a neoliberal philosophy with a possible for short time to keep a certain kind of economic growth going.
strong belief in the free market as the best regulator of human affairs, But the end result is a somewhat frightening sense that, as the Institute
monetarism had no time for fiscal stimulus (or indeed with government for Public Policy Research (IPPR, 2018) recently pointed out, when the
intervention generally) and argued instead that the route out of low next crisis hits there will be neither fiscal nor monetary room for
growth was to reduce the cost of money, so that firms would more manoeuvre.
easily invest in the productive capacity of the economy and households In short, this paper has argued that the ‘growth fetish’ which has
could fund any temporary constraints on spending through debt. These dominated western political thinking for over half a century lies at the
mechanisms for financial liquidity would free up the economy to grow heart of the problems now encountered by advanced economies. It has
again, allowing prices to fall and employment to bounce back. hindered ecological innovation, exacerbated financial instability and
At first these policies seemed to be successful. In the wake of the oil reinforced inequality. There is a case to be answered, of course, that this
crises, conditions improved. Greater liquidity spurred investment, re- strategy has continued to benefit the few. But its legitimacy as a
stored levels of consumer demand and even (arguably) stimulated in- strategy to ensure a better life for the many is severely dented.
novation in the energy sector which brought down the price of oil, for Prosperity itself is being undone by an allegiance to growth at all costs.
almost two decades. In the long run, however, things were not so Reaching beyond these potentially destructive conditions is clearly
simple. Loose monetary policy and tight fiscal policy were slowly challenging, but by no means impossible. There is an emerging (and
creating increasing fragility in financial markets. Though they fa- increasingly timely) interest in ideas around de-growth (D'Alisa et al.,
cilitated a continued reduction in public debt burdens, this only proved 2014; Kallis, 2015; Van den Bergh, 2015) and in the economics of a
possible by transferring debt to the private sector. While interest rates ‘post-growth’ society (Cassiers et al., 2017; Blewitt and Cunningham,
were low and debt burdens were not too high, this didn't seem to matter 2014; Jackson, 2009, 2017). These approaches tend to accept that be-
much. But as more and more households accumulated more and more yond a certain point, and for a variety of reasons, relentless economic
debt, the conditions for instability were accumulating. By the early growth may be neither desirable nor indeed feasible. Whether for se-
2000s, firms, banks and households had become ‘overleveraged’. The cular reasons, or from a decline in resource quality, or from the need to
policy response was to pump more and more money into the system by curtail damaging environmental impact, proponents of these ideas at-
lowering interest rates again and relaxing financial regulations even tempt to envision the social conditions (and economic implications) of a
further. All it needed was a change in the rate of defaults on ‘subprime’ world in which, for the advanced economies at least, it is necessary to
loans and the bubble would have to burst. This was the era of ‘easy ‘manage without growth’ (Victor, 2008/2018).
money’, the ‘age of irresponsibility’ as then Prime Minister Gordon Perhaps the most interesting avenue that emerges from this ex-
Brown called it, and it led inexorably to the financial crisis.8 ploration relates to the fundamental challenge which lies at the heart of
‘The question then arises,’ wrote Summers (2014, p68) ‘can we it, the decline in labour productivity growth. Amongst the potential
identify any stretch [in the last decades] during which the economy causes of such a decline lies one which carries the seeds of a new way of
grew satisfactorily under conditions that were financially sustainable?.’ thinking about the role of enterprise and work in a post-growth society.
His answer, and indeed the answer of a number of other mainstream Structural changes from primary (extractive) and secondary (manu-
facturing) towards tertiary (service) sector industries may be partially
responsible for the transition towards a lower productivity growth
8
See Jackson, 2017, Chapter 2, for a fuller discussion. See also Wolf (2014) (Nordhaus, 2006). Though often presented in conventional economics
and Turner (2015). as a problem – for instance as the source of Baumol's (2012) ‘cost

244
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

disease’ – there are certain service-based sectors which are both lighter growth Era. Polity Press, London.
(more sustainable) in material terms and contribute particular benefits Ford, M., 2015. The Rise of the Robots. Penguin, London.
Friese, J., 2011. The EROI of conventional Canadian natural gas production.
in terms of the quality of life. These human services – particularly those Sustainability 3, 2080–2104.
based around care, craft and creativity – might well provide the clue to FT, 2018. The threat of secular stagnation has not gone away. Financial Times Online at:
a lighter (more sustainable) economy capable of delivering a lasting https://www.ft.com/content/aa76e2a8-4ef2-11e8-9471-a083af05aea7.
Galbraith, J., 2014. The End of Normal: The Great Crisis and the Future of Growth. Simon
prosperity without the need for economic growth.9 & Schuster, New York.
The US writer Wendell Berry (2008) once remarked that ‘human Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas, 1972. The Entropy Law and the Economic Process. Harvard
and earthly limits, properly understood, are not confinements, but ra- University Press, Cambridge, Mass.
Gordon, Robert, 2012. Is US economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the
ther inducements… to fullness of relationship and meaning’. Nowhere six headwinds. In: NBER Working Paper 18315. National Bureau of Economic
is this observation more true than in the context of the post-growth Research. Online at, Cambridge, Mass. http://www.nber.org/papers/w18315.pdf.
challenge facing the advanced economies in the 21st Century. That Gordon, Robert, 2016. The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living
Since the Civil War. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
challenge, properly conceived, is not to pursue ever more desperate
Guilford, M., Hall, C., O'Connor, P., Cleveland, C., 2011. A new long term assessment of
policies to regain the lost footings of a fossil-fuel driven hyper-pro- energy return on investment (EROI) for US oil and gas discovery and production.
ductivity, but rather to create the conditions for an economy that works Sustainability 3, 1866–1887.
for everyone, within the constraints of a finite planet. As I have argued Hall, C., Lambert, J., Balogh, S., 2014. EROI of different fuels and the implications for
society. Energy Policy 64, 141–152.
extensively elsewhere (Jackson, 2017), that task is precise, definable, Hamilton, C., 2003. Growth Fetish. Allen and Unwin, Crows Nest NSW.
pragmatic and achievable. Hansen, Alvin, 1939. Economic progress and declining population growth. Am. Econ.
Rev. 29 (1), 1–15.
Hirsch, Fred, 1977. Social Limits to Growth. Palgrave Macmillan, London.
Acknowledgements IMF, 2017. Fostering inclusive growth. Report to the G20 leaders summit, Hamburg, July
2017. Online at. https://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/2017/062617.pdf.
An earlier draft of this paper was prepared as input for the UK IPPR, 2018.. Just about managing demand - reforming the UK's macroeconomic policy
framework. IPPR, London Online at: https://www.ippr.org/files/2018-04/
Global Strategic Trends review. I am grateful to Herman Daly, Andrew 1524760741_cej-just-about-managing-demand-march2018.pdf.
Fergusson, Linda Gessner, colleagues in CUSP and the MoD, and two Jackson, T., 2009. Prosperity Without Growth – Economics for a Finite Planet. Routledge,
anonymous reviewers for thoughtful comments on the earlier paper. I London.
Jackson, T., 2017. Prosperity Without Growth – Foundations for the Economy of T
am grateful for the continuing financial support of the Economic and Tomorrow. Routledge, London.
Social Research Council which has funded some of the research behind Jackson, T., 2018. Everything, in short, except that which makes life worthwhile. In:
this paper, in particular through CUSP (Grant No: ES/M010163/1) and Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity, Blog, 18 March 2018.
Jackson, T., Victor, P., 2018. Confronting inequality in the new normal: basic income,
a previous Professorial Fellowship (Grant no: ES/J023329/1).
factor substitution and the future of work. CUSP working paper no 11. Centre for the
Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity, Guildford. UK Online at. https://www.
References cusp.ac.uk/themes/s2/wp11/.
Jackson, T., Webster, R., 2016. Limits revisited: a review of the limits to growth debate.
Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity, Guildford Online at. http://
Autor, D., Salomons, A., 2017. Does productivity growth threaten employment: roboca- limits2growth.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2016/04/Jackson-and-Webster-2016-
lypse now? In: Paper for the European Central Bank Forum on Central Banking. Limits-Revisited.pdf.
Avent, R., 2016. The Wealth of Humans: Work and its Absence in the 21st Century. Kallis, Giorgos, 2015. The degrowth alternative, essay for the great transition initiative.
Penguin, London. Online at. http://www.greattransition.org/publication/the-degrowth-alternative.
Ayres, R., 2008. Sustainability economics: where do we stand. Ecol. Econ. 67, 281–310. Kennedy, R., 1968. Speech to the University of Kansas, March 1968. Online at. https://
Ayres, R., Warr, B., 2009. The Economic Growth Engine: How Energy and Work Drive www.jfklibrary.org/Research/Research-Aids/Ready-Reference/RFK-Speeches/
Material Prosperity. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. Remarks-of-Robert-F-Kennedy-at-the-University-of-Kansas-March-18-1968.aspx.
Bank of England, 2016. Millennium of Economic Data. Available online at. http://www. Keynes, J.M., 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Chapter 16,
bankofengland.co.uk/research/Pages/datasets/default.aspx#threecenturies. Section II. Macmillan, London, pp. 134.
Baumeister, C., Kilian, L., 2016. Forty years of oil price fluctuations: why the price of oil Krusell, P., Smith, A., 2014. Is Piketty's ‘Second Law of Capitalism’ Fundamental?
may still surprise us. J. Econ. Perspect. 30 (1), 139–160. https://doi.org/10.1257/ Working Paper (1st Version). National Bureau of Economic Research,
jep.30.1.139. Washington DC.
Baumol, W., 2012. The Cost Disease – Why Computers Get Cheaper and Health Care Layard, Richard, 2005. Happiness: Lessons From a New Science. Penguin, London.
Doesn't. Yale University Press, New Haven and London. Meadows, Dennis, Meadows, Donella, Randers, Jørgen, Behrens, William, 1972. The
Berry, W., 2008. Faustian Economics - hell hath no fury. Harpers Magazine Online at: Limits to Growth. Universe Press, New York.
https://harpers.org/archive/2008/05/faustian-economics/. Mol, A.P.J., 2001. Globalization and Environmental Reform: The Ecological
Blewitt, J., Cunningham, R., 2014. The Post-Growth Project: How the End of Economic Modernization of the Global Economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA (ISBN 0-262-
Growth Could Bring a Fairer and Happier Society. Green House, London. 13395-4).
Boulding, K., 1973. Comment to the US Congress Hearing on the Energy Reorganisation Nordhaus, W., 2006. Baumol's diseases: a macroeconomic perspective. In: NBER Working
Act of 1973. 93rd Congress. First Session: 11510:248. Paper 12218. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
BP, 2017. BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2016. BP plc, London. OECD, 2017. Hours worked (indicator). doi: 10.1787/47be1c78-en. Online at. https://
Cassiers, I., Maréchal, K., Méda, D., 2017. Post-growth Economics and Society: Exploring data.oecd.org/emp/hours-worked.htm.
the Paths of a Social and Ecological Transition. Routledge, London. ONS, 2017. Personal well-being in the UK: July 2016 to June 2017. Office for National
Coyle, D., 2014. GDP – A Brief but Affectionate History. Princeton University Press, Statistics, London Online at. https://www.ons.gov.uk/
Princeton. peoplepopulationandcommunity/wellbeing/bulletins/measuringnationalwellbeing/
D'Alisa, Giacomo, Damaria, Federico, Kallis, Giorgos (Eds.), 2014. Degrowth: A april2016tomarch2017.
Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, London. O'Neill, D., Fanning, A., Lamb, W., Steinberger, J., 2018. A good life for all within pla-
Daly, Herman, 1977. Steady State Economics. W H Freeman and Co Ltd., New York. netary boundaries. Nature Sustainability 1, 88–95.
Douthwaite, R., 1992. The Growth Illusion – How Economic Growth Has Enriched the Philipsen, D., 2015. The Little Big Number: How GDP Came to Rule the World and What
Few, Impoverished the Many and Endangered the Planet. Lilleput Press, Dublin. to Do About it. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Easterlin, Richard, 1974. Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical Piketty, T., 2014. Capital in the 21st Century. Harvard University Press. Harvard.
evidence. In: David, D., Reder, M. (Eds.), Nations and Households in Economic Piketty, T., Saez, E., Zucman, G., 2017. Distributional national accounts: methods and
Growth. Stanford University Press, Stanford. estimates for the United States data appendix. Online at. http://gabriel-zucman.eu/
EPI, 2014. Raising America's pay: why it's our central economic policy challenge. Briefing files/PSZ2018DataAppendix.pdf.
paper #378. Economic Policy Institute, Washington DC Online at. http://www.epi. Poisson, A., Hall, C., 2013. Time series EROI for Canadian oil and gas. Energies 6,
org/files/pdf/65287.pdf. 5940–5959.
Feng, J., Feng, L., Wang, J., King, C., 2018. Modeling the point of use EROI and its im- Raworth, K., 2017. Doughnut Economics - seven ways to think like a 21st Century
plications for economic growth in China. Energy 144, 232–242. economist. Penguin, London.
Fioramonti, L., 2015. The World After GDP – Politics, Business and Society in the Post- Rockström, J., Steffen, W., Noone, K., Persson, Å., Chapin, F.S., III, E.Lambin, Lenton,
T.M., Scheffer, M., Folke, C., Schellnhuber, H.J., Nykvist, B., De Wit, C.A., Hughes, T.,
van der Leeuw, S., Rodhe, H., Sörlin, S., Snyder, P.K., Costanza, R., Svedin, U.,
Falkenmark, M., Karlberg, L., Corell, R.W., Fabry, V.J., Hansen, J., Walker, B.,
9
Both Baumol and indeed Keynes before him (1936, Ch 16 Section II) have Liverman, D., Richardson, K., Crutzen, P., Foley, J., 2009. A safe operating space for
made that point that these relatively ‘inefficient’ sectors can be good for the humanity. Nature 461, 472–475. Online at: http://www.nature.com/nature/
economy – and indeed for human wellbeing (Jackson, 2017). journal/v461/n7263/full/461472a.html.

245
T. Jackson Ecological Economics 156 (2019) 236–246

RSA, 2015. Creative citizen, creative state: the principled and pragmatic case for a uni- sites/default/files/Vox_secular_stagnation.pdf, Accessed date: 17 October 2015.
versal basic income. Royal Society for the Arts, London Online at. https://www. Turner, G., 2008. A comparison of the limits to growth with 30 years of reality. Glob.
thersa.org/discover/publications-and-articles/reports/basic-income. Environ. Chang. 18, 397–411.
Rye, C., Jackson, T., 2018. A review of EROEI-dynamics energy-transition models. Energy Turner, Adair, 2015. Between Debt and the Devil. Money, Credit and Fixing Global
Policy 122, 260–272. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2018.06.041. Finance. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Seidel, W., 2017. The Great Leveller. Princeton University Press, Princeton. Van den Bergh, Jeroen, 2015. Neutral about growth: key to prosperity and sustainability.
Sers, M., Victor, P., 2018. The energy-emissions trap. Ecol. Econ. 151, 10–21. In: Paper Presented to a Conference on Wealth, Welfare and Work for Europe,
Stiglitz, J., 2009. GDP fetishism. Project syndicate. Online at. https://www.project- December 2014. OECD, Paris.
syndicate.org/commentary/gdp-fetishism. Victor, Peter, 2008/2018. Managing Without Growth – Slower by Design Not Disaster.
Storm, S., 2017. The new normal: demand, secular stagnation and the vanishing middle- Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
class. INET working paper no 55, May 2017. Online at. https://www.ineteconomics. Victor, Peter, Dolter, Brett (Eds.), 2017. Handbook on Growth and Sustainability. Edward
org/uploads/papers/WP_55-Storm-The-New-Normal.pdf. Elgar, Cheltenham.
Credit Suisse, 2014. Global Wealth Report 2014. Credit Suisse, Geneva. https:// Von Weizsäcker, E., Lovins, A., Hunter Lovins, L., 1995. Factor Four: Doubling Wealth,
publications.credit-suisse.com/tasks/render/file/?fileID=60931FDE-A2D2-F568- Halving Resource Use - The New Report to the Club of Rome. London Earthscan.
B041B58C5EA591A4. Waring, Marilyn, 1988. If Women Counted: A New Feminist Economics. Harper Collins,
Summers, Lawrence, 2014. U.S. economic prospects: secular stagnation, hysteresis, and New York.
the zero lower bound. Bus. Econ. 49 (2), 66–73. WB, 2017. World indicators database. GDP at constant 2010$. Online at. https://data.
Susskind, D., 2017. A model of technological unemployment. In: Dept of Economics worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.
Discussion Paper Series. University of Oxford, Oxford. Wolf, Martin, 2014. Strip private banks of their power to create money. In: Financial
Teulings, Coen, Baldwin, Richard, 2014. Secular stagnation: facts, causes and cures. Times, (April 25th 2014).
Centre for Economic Policy Research, London Online at. http://www.voxeu.org/

246

You might also like