You are on page 1of 13

Hybrid Forms of Third-Party Dispute Resolution: Theoretical Implications of

Combining Mediation and Arbitration


Author(s): William H. Ross and Donald E. Conlon
Source: The Academy of Management Review , Apr., 2000, Vol. 25, No. 2 (Apr., 2000),
pp. 416-427
Published by: Academy of Management

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/259022

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Academy of Management is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
The Academy of Management Review

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
@ Academy of Management Review
2000, Vol. 25. No. 2, 416-427.

NOTE

HYBRID FORMS OF THIRD-PARTY DISPUTE


RESOLUTION: THEORETICAL IMPLICATIONS
OF COMBINING MEDIATION AND
ARBITRATION

WILLIAM H. ROSS
University of Wisconsin at La Crosse

DONALD E. CONLON
Michigan State University

We contrast two hybrid dispute resolution procedures (arbitration-mediation and


mediation-arbitration) that involve using mediation and arbitration in different se-
quences. The former's strengths stem from lowering disputant expectations and en-
hancing cooperative behaviors during the mediation phase. The latter procedure
likely will be less costly and time consuming, enhance fairness judgments, and
produce greater compliance to arbitrated decisions. We argue that the greatest ben-
efit from arbitration-mediation is that it should encourage disputants to settle differ-
ences themselves.

The intervention of a third party-a person, dures. By hybrid we mean procedures that com-
government agency, or other institution-often bine elements of mediation and arbitration. We
can facilitate conflict resolution between disput- believe such hybrid forms hold great promise for
ing parties (Conlon & Sullivan, 1999; Kressel & managing conflicts, although such procedures
Pruitt, 1989; Purdy & Gray, 1994). For example, have been undertheorized conceptually. We an-
formal third-party procedures often are used for alyze two procedures: the well-known media-
public sector labor-management disputes, tion-arbitration procedure and the novel arbitra-
where dispute resolution system designers want tion-mediation procedure. We first briefly define
to avoid strikes. Other contexts in which third each and then identify criteria for evaluating
parties intervene include intraorganizational them. Next, we consider why disputants might
disputes; small claims business disputes; and prefer one type of hybrid procedure, and, finally,
consumer complaint disputes, such as in the using these criteria, we consider the conse-
securities industry (cf. Kressel & Pruitt, 1989; quences of choosing one type of hybrid proce-
Lewicki, Litterer, Minton, & Saunders, 1994; dure for disputant behaviors, expectations, and
Podd, 1997). Although differences exist among outcomes. Throughout this discussion, we de-
these third parties and the contexts in which velop testable research propositions. We antic-
they serve, all fulfill similar roles and, thus, are ipate that such an analysis will prove valuable
more alike than different. This reflects the "ge- both to researchers and policy makers seeking
neric view" of conflict resolution (Levinger & to design their third-party systems.
Rubin, 1994; Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993).
Our purpose here is to compare and evaluate
hybrid third-party dispute resolution proce- DISTINCTIONS BETWEEN MEDIATION AND
ARBITRATION

Our hybrid procedures reflect different combi-


We presented an earlier version of this work at the annual
nations of two well-established third-party
meeting of the Academy of Management in San Diego, Au-
gust 1998. We thank Elizabeth Wessman, Laura Jaryznski,
procedures: mediation and interest arbitration.
and the anonymous reviewers for comments on earlier ver- Mediation is a procedure whereby a third party
sions of this note. assists disputants in achieving a voluntary set-

416

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2000 Ross and Conlon 417

tlement (i.e., the mediator cannot impose a set- rate (typically 60 to 80 percent, although settle-
tlement on the disputants). Interest arbitration ment is not guaranteed) and high compliance
(or, more simply, arbitration) is a procedure rates (Hoh, 1984; Kochan, 1979; Kressel & Pruitt,
whereby a third party holds a hearing, at which 1989). Mediation also is a face-saving procedure:
time the disputants state their positions on the each side can make concessions to the other
issues, call witnesses, and offer supporting evi- without appearing weak. Finally, disputants of-
dence for their respective positions. After eval- ten see mediation procedures as fair (Karam-
uating the evidence and considering other rele- bayya & Brett, 1989; Pierce, Pruitt, & Czaja, 1993;
vant factors (e.g., legal constraints and Ross, Conlon, & Lind, 1990).
economic conditions), the third party issues a The greatest benefit of binding arbitration is
binding settlement (Elkouri, Elkouri, Goggin, & that it always produces a settlement. Moreover,
Volz, 1997). Note that in the field of industrial the threat of arbitration often motivates parties
relations, interest arbitration often is used to to settle voluntarily, because the parties give up
determine the terms of a new collective bargain- decision control once they arbitrate (Farber &
ing agreement, and it stands in contrast to griev- Katz, 1979). The procedure may produce speedy
ance arbitration, which deals with the interpre- settlements relative to other third-party proce-
tation of an existing collective bargaining dures, such as adjudication. Finally, arbitration
agreement. (We do not consider grievance arbi- allows representatives to "save face" with con-
tration in this note.) stituents, because they can blame the arbitrator
Both mediation and arbitration can be evalu- if the imposed settlement is unsatisfactory
ated according to the criteria of decision control (Marmo, 1995; Rose & Manuel, 1996).
and process control, as described by Thibaut
and Walker (1975, 1978) and elaborated upon by
COMBINING MEDIATION AND ARBITRATION
Elangovan (1995). Thibaut and Walker define
these terms as follows: Recognizing the strengths of each procedure,
some scholars have advocated the adoption of
Decision control is measured by the degree to
which any one of the participants may unilater- alternative, hybrid, third-party procedures.
ally determine the outcome of the dispute. For Clearly, we cannot discuss all possible proce-
example, when a third-party decisionmaker dural combinations here. Instead, we focus on
alone may order a resolution to be imposed, the two different hybrid procedures in which both
decisionmaker has total decision control. Control
mediation and arbitration components are uti-
over the process refers to control over the devel-
opment and selection of information that will lized fully: mediation-arbitration and arbitra-
constitute the basis for resolving the dispute. Par- tion-mediation. We focus on mediation-arbitra-
ticipants given authority to conduct an investiga- tion in part because it is the best-known hybrid
tion and to plan the presentation of evidence may procedure (Devinatz & Budd, 1997; Kagel &
be said to exercise considerable process control
Kagel, 1972). We focus on arbitration-mediation
(1978: 546).
because it involves combining the same two
Mediation and adversarial arbitration both af- third-party procedures, albeit in a different tem-
ford the disputants high process control, for dis- poral sequence.
putants have ample opportunity to present in- Mediation-arbitration (hereafter med-arb)
formation as they attempt to influence the consists of two phases: (1) mediation, followed
perceptions of the third party. However, the two by (2) arbitration, if mediation fails to secure an
procedures differ in terms of decision control. agreement by a predetermined deadline. The
Disputants have high decision control in medi- same third party serves as both mediator and
ation (they may reject any settlement suggested arbitrator (Kagel, 1976). The procedure is incre-
by the mediator) but low decision control in ar- mental: only if mediation fails to produce an
bitration (they must accept an arbitration rul- agreement does the arbitration phase occur,
ing). which culminates with the third party imposing
Both mediation and arbitration offer several a binding settlement on the parties. This tempo-
strengths. Mediation offers the possibility of dis- ral arrangement is consistent with the sugges-
covering underlying issues and promoting inte- tions of many scholars (e.g., Ury, Brett, Goldberg,
grative agreements (McEwen & Maiman, 1984; 1988), who argue that dispute resolution proce-
McGrath, 1966). It produces a high settlement dures should be arranged in a "low-to-high-cost

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
418 Academy of Management Review April

sequence" for the users (Ury et al., 1988: 62-63). findings from the decision-making literature,
Other writers also have suggested that media- where appropriate.
tion should precede arbitration (e.g., Starke &
Notz, 1981).
One relatively new hybrid procedure is arbi-
PROCEDURAL PREFERENCE
tration-mediation (hereafter arb-med). Briefly,
arb-med consists of three phases. In phase one An important first question concerns dispu-
the third party holds an arbitration hearing. At tant preferences for med-arb or arb-med. If of-
the end of this phase, the third party makes a fered a choice of procedures (e.g., a "multi-door
decision, which is placed in a sealed envelope courthouse"; see Olczak, Grosch, & Duffy, 1991),
and is not revealed to the parties. The second will disputants prefer one hybrid procedure over
phase consists of mediation. The sealed enve- another? If so, why? Such questions are impor-
lope containing the third party's decision is dis- tant for three reasons. First, if they do not prefer
played prominently during the mediation phase. a particular procedure, the parties may avoid
Only if mediation fails to produce a voluntary using it, which may have implications for dis-
agreement by a specified deadline do the par- pute resolution system functioning (e.g., staff
ties enter the third phase, called the ruling and resources may be invested in procedures
phase. Here, the third party removes the ruling that few disputants want or use). Second, the
from the envelope and reveals the binding rul- parties may behave differently when using a
ing to the disputants (Cobbledick, 1992; Sander, procedure they do not favor relative to one they
1993). To ensure that the envelope contains the prefer, affecting both processes (e.g., the amount
original ruling and not a later ruling (e.g., a of information revealed) and outcomes (whether
ruling created after the mediation phase), the a voluntary settlement is reached). Third, the
third party can ask a disputant from each side to parties' preferences may be related to justice
sign the envelope across the seal at the begin- beliefs, which, in turn, may affect compliance
ning of mediation. rates with imposed decisions; disputants may
be less likely to comply with decisions that were
reached using seemingly unfair procedures.
Building upon the Thibaut and Walker (1975,
CONTRASTING THE TWO HYBRID
1978) theory of procedure, as well as the work of
PROCEDURES
Deutsch (1973), we believe that for "interest-
What criteria should be used for evaluating based disputes" (rather than, say, disputes over
the hybrid procedures? In order to compare med- "mratters of principle"), disputants are primarily
arb and arb-med systematically, we have organ- motivated by self-interest (Pillutla & Murnighan,
ized our criteria (and our discussion) around the 1999). The consequences of this self-interest mo-
following temporal sequence. Briefly, we pro- tive for procedural preference are numerous and
pose that the parties desire to maintain control multifaceted. First, disputants seek to retain de-
over both the dispute resolution process and its cision control because it gives them veto power
outcomes. This desire affects disputants' proce- over any third-party proposal that provides un-
dural preferences and their resulting procedural acceptable outcomes (thereby protecting their
choice (if any choice is available). We also ex- self-interests). Participants generally view a
amine the consequences of using a particular procedure as fairer if they retain decision con-
hybrid procedure for disputant expectations and trol, although they may be willing to relinquish
behaviors, as well as immediate and long-term decision control if they are unable to settle the
outcomes from using the procedure. This tempo- dispute themselves (Heuer & Penrod, 1986; Lind
ral sequence is a specific application of a gen- & Tyler, 1988). This suggests a preference for
eral model offered by Pruitt and Carnevale dispute settlement during the mediation rather
(1993), and it serves as a framework to organize than arbitration phase of hybrid procedures.
our propositions in a logical fashion. Second, to the extent that process control has
As we examine preferences, expectations, and implications for favorable outcomes, disputants
behaviors, we rely heavily upon Thibault and seek to maintain process control. Research dem-
Walker's (1975) notions of process control and onstrates that disputants usually prefer such
outcome (decision) control. We also incorporate procedures as mediation, where they retain sub-

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2000 Ross and Conlon 419

stantial amounts of process control (Pierce et al., given a choice between these two hybrid proce-
1993). dures, disputants will prefer med-arb.
Third, disputants avoid situations where out-
Proposition 1: Disputants prefer using
comes cannot be determined in advance ("un-
the med-arb procedure over the arb-
certain" situations) or where the probability of
med procedure.
obtaining a favorable outcome is low ("risky"
situations; see Knight, 1921). Arbitration creates Of course, procedural designers and theorists
such a situation, where parties cannot deter- must consider factors other than disputant pref-
mine in advance which evidence will be most erence. Disputants may prefer a procedure that
compelling to the third party. To reduce such maximizes the likelihood of a favorable out-
uncertainty, each party may exaggerate its de- come, but such a procedure may not be in the
mands and reduce its level of concession mak- best interest of policy makers. For example, a
ing (a phenomenon known as the chilling effect), public sector union may be able to best achieve
hoping that the arbitrator will "split the differ- favorable outcomes through conventional arbi-
ence" and give them a modestly favorable set- tration, yet the state legislature may want a
tlement (Notz & Starke, 1987). The parties also procedure that lowers disputant expectations so
may employ impression management tech- that the parties will seek voluntary settlements.
niques (Jordan & Roloff, 1997) designed to con- Policy makers also may want to promote inte-
vince the third party of the virtue of their respec- grative agreements, which may not be likely
tive positions (Wall, 1991). with conventional arbitration.
What are the implications of these processes We next consider the implications of hybrid
for procedural preference among the two hybrid procedural design for disputant expectations
procedures? With med-arb the parties retain de- and behaviors.
cision control during the mediation phase. The
parties exercise process control by engaging in
impression management during mediation; they HOW HYBRID PROCEDURES AFFECT
also exercise process control by presenting ad- DISPUTANT EXPECTATIONS AND BEHAVIORS
ditional evidence and formal arguments during
Disputant Expectations Regarding Outcomes
any subsequent adversarial type of arbitration
hearing. It is only at the end of the process that We expect that the choice of med-arb or arb-
they relinquish decision control. Thus, with med will have important effects on disputant
med-arb the parties retain process and decision cognitions as the disputants seek favorable out-
control longer and have greater opportunity to comes. A critical determinant of whether dispu-
reduce the uncertainty associated with receiv- tants agree depends on whether their outcome
ing an arbitrator's binding decision. expectations create a positive "zone of agree-
In contrast, with arb-med the parties have ment" or "settlement range" (Walton & McKer-
only one chance to influence the third-party's sie, 1965). The zone of agreement is determined
binding decision-at the initial arbitration hear- by the disputants' respective resistance points-
ing. Thus, although the parties technically re- that is, the point beyond which each will resist
tain decision and process control throughout the making concessions. For example, suppose that
subsequent mediation phase, they must also a company is negotiating with its union, and
recognize that a binding decision has been ren- management negotiators are unwilling to pay
dered already (only not yet "served") and that employees over $9.00 an hour (their resistance
any further impression management attempts point). If employees are unwilling to work for
will be ineffectual. The early forfeiture of deci- less than $9.50 an hour (their resistance point),
sion control, thus, is salient throughout the me- there is no overlapping zone of agreement, and
diation phase of arb-med. Further, since the rul- an agreement will not occur unless one side
ing is displayed prominently in the sealed changes its resistance point.
envelope, the uncertainty of the outcomes con- We believe that the arb-med procedure is
tained in that ruling also is made more salient. more likely to change the resistance points of
Therefore, if our assumptions are correct-that the disputants, leading to a greater probability
disputants seek favorable outcomes and seek to that an overlapping zone of agreement will ex-
avoid uncertain situations-we predict that, if ist. Several arguments support this assertion.

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
420 Academy of Management Review April

First, the characteristics discussed above that offer arbitration looms largest at the last minute,
make arb-med a less preferred procedure-the when the arbitrator's award is at hand" (1981:
prominence of the "threat" of an arbitration rul- 225).
ing (in the envelope) during the mediation Extension of this logic to the arb-med proce-
phase, the reduced opportunity for outcome con- dure suggests that, having completed the arbi-
trol through impression management, and so tration hearing and knowing that a decision has
on-also work to lower disputants' outcome ex- been reached (but not yet revealed), the parties
pectations. Lower outcome expectations should should be experiencing great uncertainty. When
lead to an increased likelihood of a positive combined with the disputants' desire for out-
zone of agreement and, thus, should produce come control and lower outcome expectations
more cooperative behavior by the disputants. (as discussed above), the uncertainty over what
Second, there is evidence that disputants in types of outcomes will be received should moti-
arbitration settings overestimate their probabil- vate the disputants to reduce such uncertainty
ity of success (e.g., Neale & Bazerman, 1991), and by agreeing during the mediation phase.
the med-arb procedure does little to address this The idea that uncertainty facilitates coopera-
overconfidence. In fact, med-arb may heighten tion also is supported by findings in cognitive
overconfidence, because disputants who do not psychology. Shafir and Tversky (1992) have de-
settle in mediation can continue to direct im- scribed a one-trial prisoner's dilemma game,
pression management attempts toward the third where subjects were either aware or unaware of
party during arbitration and thereby continue to their opponent's choice to compete or cooperate.
bolster their false estimate of prevailing in ar- When subjects knew that their opponent had
bitration. In contrast, arb-med may cause dispu- made a competitive choice, only 3 percent re-
tants to actively consider the possibility of los- sponded with a cooperative choice. When sub-
ing: because a ruling already has been jects knew that their opponent had made a co-
rendered, the disputant must entertain the pos- operative choice, 16 percent responded with a
sibility that the ruling has been unfavorable. cooperative choice. But, when subjects did not
Disputants may estimate the probability of an know if their opponent had competed or cooper-
unfavorable ruling and then adjust it during me- ated, 37 percent chose to cooperate. Shafir and
diation, whenever the mediator offers positive or Tversky (1992) explain their findings in terms of
negative feedback regarding their positions. a disjunction effect, defined as follows: people
prefer choice a over choice b when X occurs;
Proposition 2: Disputants have lower they also prefer a over b when X does not occur,
outcome expectations in arb-med than
but they prefer b over a when it is uncertain
in med-arb.
whether or not X occurs (also see Tversky &
Shafir, 1992). The arb-med procedure sets up
similar dynamics for the disjunction effect. For
Behaviors During the Mediation Phase
example, if we substitute "a favorable arbitrator
Cooperation. We expect hybrid procedures to decision" for X, "compete" for a, and "cooperate"
influence cooperative behaviors differentially for b in the above description of the disjunction
during mediation. If the arb-med procedure low- effect, we have a situation where greater num-
ers outcome expectations, then it is likely that bers of disputants engage in cooperative behav-
disputants in arb-med will behave more cooper- ior when they do not know if the arbitrators'
atively with each other than they would in med- decision will favor them or not.
arb. This proposition is supported by research
Proposition 3: During the mediation
on final offer arbitration (Coleman, Jennings, &
phase, disputants will engage in more
McLaughlin, 1993; Feuille, 1975), where the arbi-
cooperative behavior in arb-med than
trator can only pick one side's proposal; the ar-
in med-arb.
bitrator is not permitted to fashion a different
settlement. Pruitt (1981) has reported that many Revealing information. An important part of
cases are resolved by the disputants after the cooperation is revealing information. The re-
arbitration hearing is held but before a decision vealing of more information is associated with a
is revealed to the parties. He suggests that "the greater probability of achieving an integrative,
uncertainty produced by the prospect of final high-quality agreement (Pruitt, 1981; Thompson,

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2000 Ross and Conlon 421

1991, 1998). Information sharing often occurs dur- Proposition 5: Disputants will respond
ing private caucuses with a mediator. Yet, dis- to mediator suggestions for settlement
putants may be reluctant to reveal information if with more concessions in arb-med
they fear that the third party might use that than in med-arb.
information when making a subsequent arbitra-
Proposition 6: Disputants will agree to
tion ruling (Fuller, 1962). This apparent loss of
specific mediator settlement propos-
outcome control through exercising process con-
als more frequently in arb-med than
trol (revealing information in mediation) is an
in med-arb.
inherent difficulty of med-arb. For example, sup-
pose that a union's bargaining position is that There is, however, one circumstance in which
workers need thirteen paid holidays. If union these propositions may not hold. If final-offer
leaders reveal to the mediator in a private cau- arbitration is used in med-arb, the parties may
cus that they will accept ten holidays, then they already be aware of the prospect of losing in
may fear that the third-party might remember arbitration. The disputants may look to the third-
this fact and rule for ten holidays if arbitration party suggestions during the mediation phase
becomes necessary. An arbitration ruling for ten as alternatives to losing in arbitration, and
holidays would confirm this fear, even if the these suggestions may hold substantial weight.
third party based this decision on other criteria. Thus, when final-offer arbitration is used, dispu-
However, if an arbitration ruling already has tants may be responsive to mediator sugges-
been made and nothing revealed during medi- tions with either procedure.
ation can influence that ruling, then there is no
incentive for withholding information during
IMMEDIATE AND LONG-TERM OUTCOMES
mediation. Thus, arb-med should increase the
probability that a disputant will reveal confi- Next, we focus on how med-arb and arb-med
dential information during private caucuses may produce different outcomes- both long and
with a mediator, or even to the other disputant. short term. We distinguish between these two
types of outcomes because it is possible that one
Proposition 4: During the mediation
hybrid procedure may promote immediate out-
phase, disputants will reveal more
comes (e.g., the parties may be more likely to
confidential information in arb-med
settle the dispute), but, if the parties feel pres-
than in med-arb.
sured to settle, then that may have implications
Receptiveness to mediator suggestions. One for long-term outcomes, such as being commit-
strength of the arb-med procedure is that the ted to abide by the agreement (see Kressel &
threat of losing in arbitration is salient to the Pruitt, 1989, for a discussion). We demonstrate
disputants, particularly if package final-offer ar- that arb-med tends to have several relative ad-
bitration is used. This awareness and fear of vantages with regard to immediate outcomes;
losing (loss aversion) should increase dispu- however, med-arb is more advantageous for
tants' motivation to settle and make them more long-term outcomes.
amenable to mediator suggestions. However, re-
search also shows that motivation to settle
Immediate Outcomes
alone does not increase the likelihood of settle-
ment-disputants need specific guidance from Settlement frequency. One goal of dispute res-
their third party (Ross, 1990). If disputants are olution systems is to encourage voluntary settle-
motivated to settle, then, when the third party ments. This means that a settlement in the me-
provides specific guidance in the form of sug- diation phase, where the parties retain decision
gested settlements, the parties are likely to control, is preferable to a settlement in the arbi-
make greater concessions to move toward the tration phase, because the parties voluntarily
suggested settlement point. The result of such have agreed to the settlement and because sat-
movement is the greater likelihood of agree- isfaction and commitment tend to be high in
ment. Researchers have observed that media- such cases (Kressel & Pruitt, 1989). We propose
tors frequently suggest settlements, so this is that arb-med will produce a greater number of
not an uncommon behavior (Baker & Ross, 1992; settlements in the mediation phase than will
Kolb, 1983). med-arb. Curry and Pecorino (1993) have noted

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
422 Academy of Management Review April

that in arbitrations over salary disputes in pro- two procedures. Arb-med has both an arbitra-
fessional baseball, the parties (who had previ- tion hearing phase and a mediation phase in
ously exhausted negotiations) submitted sealed every case. Only if the dispute is settled in me-
final-offer bids to the arbitrator. However, prior diation does the third phase, the ruling phase,
to receiving the arbitrator's decision, the parties become irrelevant. However, with med-arb nei-
frequently displayed a burst of negotiation ac- ther the arbitration hearing nor the ruling phase
tivity, since they hoped to avoid an arbitrated is held if the dispute is settled in the mediation
settlement (also see Burgess & Marburger, 1993). phase. Because a majority of cases are mediated
The frequency of negotiated settlements that oc- successfully (Kressel & Pruitt, 1989), med-arb is
cur after an arbitration hearing but prior to likely to produce faster resolutions than arb-
learning of the arbitrator's ruling suggests that med. Moreover, since many external third par-
the separation of the arbitration phase and the ties are paid a per diem amount, med-arb also is
ruling phase inherent in the arb-med procedure likely to be less costly.
should facilitate voluntary agreements. Also, if
Proposition 9: On average, disputes
the parties have lowered outcome expectations
will be resolved more quickly in the
with arb-med (as described earlier), they might
med-arb procedure than in the arb-
be motivated to avoid using arbitration-
med procedure.
particularly if final-offer arbitration is em-
ployed. Proposition 10: The med-arb procedure
will produce lower financial costs
Proposition 7: There will be more vol-
than the arb-med procedure.
untary (mediated) settlements using
arb-med than med-arb.
Long-Term Outcomes
Settlement quality. The quality or value of
settlements reached in the mediation phase Justice beliefs. There are several reasons to
should be higher with arb-med than med-arb. propose that med-arb will lead to greater long-
This idea flows from Proposition 4, which states term perceptions of procedural and distributive
that disputants reveal more confidential infor- justice. Researchers have shown that having an
mation in the mediation phase of arb-med. The opportunity to present one's case (exercising
revealing of information is associated with a process control) enhances one's beliefs about
greater probability of achieving an integrative, procedural fairness for both instrumental (out-
high-quality agreement (Thompson, 1991; Wein- come-related) and value-expressive reasons (cf.
gart, Thompson, Bazerman, & Carroll, 1990). In- Folger & Cropanzano, 1996; Lind & Tyler, 1988).
tegrative settlements, by definition, provide Such beliefs enhance the likelihood that the pro-
greater total benefit (i.e., joint benefit to both cedure will be used for future disputes. Clearly,
parties) than do nonintegrative settlements, under both procedures disputants have opportu-
whether quality is defined in terms of joint pay- nities to exercise process control. However, we
offs or Pareto efficiency or creativity (cf. Tripp & propose that, for instrumental reasons, dispu-
Sondak, 1992). If the parties share more informa- tants' perceptions of process control will be
tion, it follows then that the probability of greater with med-arb. As we discussed earlier
achieving a high-quality mediated settlement is regarding impression management, the med-
higher with the arb-med procedure. arb procedure allows disputants two opportuni-
ties to present their case prior to the arbitrator
Proposition 8: Mediated settlements
making a decision, whereas arb-med only al-
are likely to be of higher quality in
lows one such opportunity. Therefore, although
arb-med than in med-arb.
both procedures provide disputants with pro-
Speed and cost of settlement. Whereas Prop- cess control, we anticipate that disputant per-
ositions 2 through 8 support the novel arb-med ceptions of such control will be greater with
procedure, the remaining propositions bolster med-arb.
the better-known med-arb procedure. For exam- The treatment received by disputants from the
ple, med-arb can be expected to be less costly third party also may influence their procedural
and to produce, on average, faster resolutions. justice perceptions. The parties may view a third
This expectation stems from the nature of the party's request for a concession in the mediation

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2000 Ross and Conlon 423

phase of arb-med as more threatening and ag- ported that typical compliance rates are about
gressive than the identical request in the medi- 80 percent for mediation, versus only 48 percent
ation phase of med-arb. In arb-med the parties for adjudication in small claims court. Lind and
may view it as a harbinger of what will come if Tyler state, "Even when decisions are supposed
no agreement is reached. This may lead dispu- to be binding, as is the case in adjudication and
tants to perceive that they were treated with less arbitration procedures, the enforcement of the
respect and dignity in the arb-med procedure. decision can be difficult in the face of active or
Notions of respect or "standing" play a central even passive resistance" (1988: 81).
role in the interactional justice literature and in Anecdotal evidence from financial securities
recent models of procedural justice, such as the and automobile "lemon law" arbitration (e.g.,
group value model (e.g., Lind & Tyler, 1988). Gold, 1988; Podd, 1997) also highlights that non-
Distributive justice judgments also are likely compliance with arbitrator decisions occurs. In
to be greater in med-arb. Regarding outcomes the -labor-management field, noncompliance
reached in mediation, disputants in arb-med may take the form of attempting to achieve con-
may feel pressured to agree because of specific tract changes through the use of the grievance
suggestions made by the third party, amplified mechanism. For example, a union might flood
by the threat of the arbitrated decision that al- the system with frivolous grievances dealing
ready exists but is not revealed. Disputants may with one contract clause in an attempt to force
view any mediated agreement reached in arb- the other side to renegotiate that clause. Alter-
med as "coerced," with a loss of outcome control; natively, a union might turn to grievance arbi-
this violates Leventhal, Karuza, and Fry's (1980) tration. For example, one public sector teachers'
justice criterion of bias suppression. union reportedly attempted to get smaller class
Arb-med may also negatively impact the per- sizes through arbitrating grievances dealing
ceived fairness of arbitrated outcomes. Because with class size under a "safe working condi-
the outcome is determined prior to mediation, it tions" contract clause, after the union had been
is not sensitive to concessions, procedural de- unable to secure smaller classes when previ-
velopments (e.g., agreeing to refer a matter to a ously negotiating its contract (State of Califor-
special committee), or relationship changes be- nia, Department of Youth Authority and Califor-
tween the parties (e.g., agreeing to implement nia State Employees Association, 1987).
integrative "win-win" bargaining) that may We expect fewer arbitrated outcomes to occur
have occurred during the mediation phase. This in arb-med than in med-arb, but we also expect
may lead disputants to believe that the arb-med that disputant compliance may be more prob-
procedure relies on less accurate information lematic. Disputants may view the decision im-
(because the arbitrator made his or her decision posed in arb-med as not reflecting the "new
without the benefit of new information) or per- understanding" reached in the mediation phase.
haps is a procedure that violates prevailing Earlier we discussed how one key element of
standards of ethicality (for the same reason). arb-med is that the third party's ruling cannot be
Both accuracy and ethicality have been consid- updated by any new information or insight dis-
ered important fairness-enhancing criteria (Lev- covered in the mediation phase. This raises the
enthal et al., 1980). Thus, to the extent that arb- possibility that arbitrated decisions in the arb-
med violates these normative expectations of med procedure could include obvious oversights
what a procedure should be, we believe that or flaws that an arbitrated decision in med-arb
disputants will view med-arb as more procedur- could avoid. Such flawed outcomes might lead
ally and distributively fair. disputants to have a lower level of commitment
to imposed settlements in arb-med.
Proposition 11: Disputants will report
In addition, several authors have noted that
greater levels of procedural and dis-
both procedural and distributive fairness judg-
tributive justice in med-arb than in
ments are important determinants of decisions
arb-med.
to comply with third-party decisions (cf. Lind,
Compliance with arbitrated outcomes. Fi- Kulik, Ambrose, & de Vera Park, 1993; McEwen &
nally, disputants' long-term compliance with Maiman, 1984). Pruitt, McGillicuddy, Welton,
third-party-imposed outcomes is a persistent and Fry (1989) compared mediation with med-
problem. McEwen and Mciiman (1984) have re- arb in community dispute resolution centers and

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
424 Academy of Management Review April

found that when disputants believe a procedure diation phase-settlements the disputants can
is fair, they are more likely to comply with the take the credit for (e.g., a union negotiator can
ruling or agreement resulting from that proce- "sell" to his or her constituents) and will likely be
dure. As we stated earlier, the early loss of de- more committed to. Med-arb, however, typically
cision control in the arb-med procedure may vi- will be less costly and time consuming; lead to
olate disputant expectations of what a fair enhanced levels of procedural justice; and, should
procedure should be. If disputants see med-arb arbitrated decisions be imposed, lead to greater
as a fairer procedure, they should be more likely compliance with arbitrated decisions.
to comply with an arbitration ruling from med- In summary, we see that the greatest benefit
arb than from arb-med. of the arb-med procedure is that it encourages
disputants to settle their differences themselves
Proposition 12: Disputants will be
(a short-term effect), whereas the greatest bene-
more likely to comply with arbitration
fit of the med-arb procedure may be enhanced
rulings issued in med-arb than in arb-
perceptions of fair treatment and greater com-
med.
pliance with arbitral rulings (long-term effects).
The above description of relative strengths
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS: strongly suggests that policy designers and/or
A CONTINGENCY APPROACH third parties should pursue a contingency ap-
proach to procedural selection based on the spe-
Table 1 summarizes our propositions. As indi-
cific criteria, listed in Table 1, they want to max-
cated in the table, arb-med's strengths lie pri-
imize. This suggestion is similar to a
marily in its inherent motivational capacity. By
contingency approach to procedural selection
appearing to threaten to reduce each party's
offered by Elangovan (1995, 1998). Building upon
decision control, the procedure should lower dis-
the work of Thibaut and Walker (1975),
putant expectations and produce uncertainty
Elangovan has identified six decision attributes
among the disputants. These dynamics should
that influence how much process and outcome
motivate the parties to maintain decision con-
(decision) control should be granted to the dis-
trol. We predict that, in attempting to ensure
puting parties and to the third party. Briefly,
that they do not relinquish decision control, the
these attributes can be organized according to
parties will be highly motivated to settle the
the following questions:
dispute during the mediation phase and will
demonstrate a variety of cooperative behaviors
1. How important is the dispute?
in that phase. As a result, arb-med should pro- 2. How important is it to resolve the dispute
duce a greater number of settlements in the me- quickly?

TABLE 1
Listing of Effects and Which Procedure Is Likely to Produce the Effect

Relative Relative
Advantage to Advantage to
Proposition Arb-Med Med-Arb

1. Procedural preference X
2. Lower outcome expectations among disputants X
3. More cooperation between disputants in mediation phase X
4. More confidential information revealed to third party X
5. Disputants will make more concessions in mediation phase X
6. Disputants will agree to specific settlement suggestions X
made by third party in mediation phase
7. Frequency of settlements in mediation phase X
8. Mediated settlements of higher quality X
9. Speed of resolution of dispute X
10. Financial costs of procedure X
11. Perceptions of procedural and distributive justice X
12. Compliance with arbitrated outcomes X

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2000 Ross and Conlon 425

3. Does the dispute concern the application of disputes. The set of propositions offered here
existing rules, or does it concern the alter- suggests that third parties be given authority to
ation of existing rules?
determine which procedure should be used,
4. Do the parties expect frequent work-related
interaction? based on the criteria the third party wishes to
5. Would the parties be committed to a settle- maximize. Thus, if long-term procedural justice
ment imposed by a third party? and compliance are issues of great concern, the
6. Is the probability high that the parties third party may choose to implement med-arb.
would negotiate a settlement compatible
However, if the third party believes that the par-
with the larger organization or system?
ties have not been forthcoming with relevant
When med-arb and arb-med are considered in negotiating information, or if the third party
light of these attributes, the situations favoring feels that obtaining a high-quality voluntary
each procedure become clearer. First, settlement is paramount, then the third party
Elangovan suggests that third parties retain may prefer arb-med.
outcome control for important disputes. Third Obviously, in this note we have described
parties in both procedures retain outcome con- only the basics of each procedure and a few key
trol. Yet, if the potential loss of outcome control situational variables that might be relevant for
is more salient with arb-med, and disputant ac- procedural choice. Many additional situational
ceptance of third-party proposals during medi- factors might influence the effectiveness of and
ation is greater (Proposition 6), then arb-med satisfaction with each procedure. These range
should be used with "important" disputes. Sec- from the context in which the intervention oc-
ond, med-arb produces a faster settlement than curs and the power differentials between dispu-
arb-med and should be used when a quick set- tants to the "style" with which a third party
tlement is desired (Proposition 9). Third, either implements any specific procedure (e.g., Arnold
hybrid procedure is adequate for developing or & Carnevale, 1997). These factors cannot be con-
altering existing rules (e.g., labor-management sidered here (for a review of such factors, see
contracts). Fourth, if the parties have an ongoing Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993). However, this note
relationship, either procedure is satisfactory; serves as a call for researchers and policy mak-
however, med-arb may be preferred because of ers to consider these forms of hybrid third-party
its relative advantage for long-term outcomes. procedures.
For disputes where the parties do not have a
long-term relationship, arb-med may be more
satisfactory because it promotes information ex-
REFERENCES
change, concession making, and a high fre-
quency of settlements (Propositions 4, 5, and 7). Arnold, J., & Carnevale, P. J. 1997. Preferences for dispute
resolution procedures as a function of intentionality,
Fifth, if the third party imposes a settlement,
consequences, expected future interaction, and
compliance may be greater if med-arb is used
power. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 27:
(Proposition 12), suggesting that med-arb be 371-398.
chosen if compliance is a concern. Finally,
Baker, C., & Ross, W. H. 1992. Mediation control tech-
Elangovan's model suggests that if the parties niques: A test of Kolb's "Orchestrators" vs. "Dealmak-
can find a solution that is compatible with the ers" model. International Journal of Conflict Manage-
larger system's goals, the third party should use ment, 3: 319-342.

a procedure that yields more process and out- Burgess, P. L., & Marburger, D. R. 1993. Do negotiated and
come control to the parties. Such a procedure arbitrated salaries differ under final-offer arbitration?
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 46: 548-559.
heightens disputant perceptions of procedural
and distributive justice. Because med-arb ap- Cobbledick, G. 1992. Arb-Med: An alternative approach to
expediting settlement. Working paper, Harvard Program
pears to yield more control to the parties and
on Negotiation, Harvard University, Boston.
enhances justice perceptions, med-arb is pre-
ferred under these conditions (Proposition 11). Coleman, B. J., Jennings, K. M., & McLaughlin, F. S. 1993.
Convergence or divergence in final-offer arbitration in
Thus, Elangovan's contingency approach offers
professional baseball. Industrial Relations, 32: 238-247.
additional guidance as to when one hybrid pro-
Conlon, D. E., & Sullivan, D. P. 1999. Examining the actions of
cedure is preferable.
organizations in conflict: Evidence from the Delaware
It is apparent that no single procedure-even Court of Chancery. Academy of Management Journal,
a single hybrid procedure-is optimal for all 42: 319-328.

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
426 Academy of Management Review April

Curry, A. F., & Pecorino, P. 1993. The use of final offer arbi- Public-sector bargaining: 150-190. Washington, DC: BNA
tration as a screening device. Journal of Conflict Reso- Books.
lution, 37: 655-680.
Kolb, D. M. 1983. The mediators. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Deutsch, M. 1973. The resolution of conflict: Constructive and
Kressel, K., & Pruitt, D. G. 1989. Conclusion: A research per-
destructive processes. New Haven, CT: Yale University
spective on the mediation of social conflict. In K. Kressel
Press.
& D. G. Pruitt (Eds.), Mediation research: 394-435. San
Devinatz, V. G., & Budd, J. W. 1997. Third party dispute reso- Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
lution: Interest disputes. In D. Lewin & D. Mitchell (Eds.),
Levinger, G., & Rubin, J. Z. 1994. Bridges and barriers to a
The human resource management handbook: 95-135.
more general theory of conflict. Negotiation Journal, 10:
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. 201-215.
Elangovan, A. R. 1995. Managerial third-party dispute inter-
Leventhal, G. S., Karuza, J., & Fry, W. R. 1980. Beyond fair-
vention: A prescriptive model of strategy selection.
ness: A theory of allocation preferences. In G. Mikula
Academy of Management Review, 20: 800-830. (Ed.), Justice and social interaction: 167-218. New York:
Elangovan, A. R. 1998. Managerial intervention in organiza- Springer-Verlag.
tional disputes: Testing a prescriptive model of strategy
Lewicki, R., Litterer, J., Minton, J., & Saunders, D. 1994. Nego-
selection. International Journal of Conflict Management, tiation. Burr Ridge, IL: Irwin.
9: 301-335.
Lind, E. A., Kulik, C. T., Ambrose, M., & de Vera Park, M. 1993.
Elkouri, F., Elkouri, E. A., Goggin, E. P., & Volz, M. M. 1997. Individual and corporate dispute resolution: Using pro-
How arbitration works (5th ed.). Washington, DC: BNA cedural fairness as a decision heuristic. Administrative
Books. Science Quarterly, 38: 224-251.
Farber, H. S., & Katz, H. 1979. Why is there disagreement in Lind, E. A., & Tyler, T. R. 1988. The social psychology of
bargaining? American Economic Review, 77: 347-352. procedural justice. New York: Plenum.
Feuille, P. 1975. Final offer arbitration and the chilling effect. Marmo, M. 1995. The role of fact finding and interest arbitra-
Industrial Relations, 14: 302-310. tion in "selling" a settlement. Journal of Collective Ne-
Folger, R., & Cropanzano, R. 1996. Elaborating procedural gotiations in the Public Sector, 14: 77-97.
fairness: Justice becomes both simpler and more com- McEwen, C. A., & Maiman, R. J. 1984. Mediation in small
plex. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 22: claims court: Achieving compliance through consent.
435-442. Law and Society Review, 18: 11-49.
Fuller, L. 1962. Collective bargaining and the arbitrator. Pro- McGrath, J. E. 1966. A social psychological approach to the
ceedings, Fifteenth Annual Meeting, National Academy study of negotiations. In R. V. Bowers (Ed.), Studies on
of Arbitrators: 8-54. Washington, DC: Bureau of National behavior in organizations: 101-134. Athens: University of
Affairs. Georgia Press.

Gold, P. W. 1988. Massachusetts "lemon law" arbitration Neale, M. A., & Bazerman, M. H. 1991. Cognition and ration-
program: 1987 report. Dispute Resolution Journal, 43(3): ality in negotiation. New York: Free Press.
48-55.
Notz, W. W., & Starke, F. A. 1987. Arbitration and distributive
Heuer, L. B., & Penrod, S. 1986. Procedural preference as a justice: Equity or equality? Journal of Applied Psychol-
function of conflict intensity. Journal of Personality and ogy, 72: 359-365.
Social Psychology, 51: 700-710.
Olczak, P. V., Grosch, J. W., & Duffy, K. G. 1991. Toward a
Hoh, R. 1984. The effectiveness of mediation in public-sector synthesis: The art with the science of community medi-
arbitration systems: The Iowa experience. Arbitration ation. In K. G. Duffy, J. W. Grosch, & P. V. Olczak (Eds.),
Journal, 39(2): 30-40. Community mediation: A handbook for practitioners and
Jordan, J. M., & Roloff, M. E. 1997. Planning skills and nego- researchers: 329-344. New York: Guilford.

tiator goal accomplishment. Communication Research, Pierce, R. S., Pruitt, D. G., & Czaja, S. J. 1993. Complainant-
24: 31-63. respondent differences in procedural choice. Interna-
Kagel, J. 1976. Comment. In H. Anderson (Ed.), New tech- tional Journal of Conflict Management, 4: 199-222.
niques in labor dispute resolution: 185-190. Washington, Pillutla, M., & Murnighan, J. K. 1999. On fairness and justice
DC: BNA Books. in bargaining and in allocation decisions and proce-
Kagel, S., & Kagel, J. 1972. Using two new arbitration tech- dures. Working paper, Northwestern University, Evan-
niques. Monthly Labor Review, 95(11): 11-14. ston, Illinois.

Karambayya, R., & Brett, J. 1989. Managers handling dis- Podd, A. 1997. NASD discloses disciplinary measures. WaIl
putes: Third party roles and perceptions of fairness. Street Journal, January 27: B7.
Academy of Management Journal, 32: 687-704. Pruitt, D. G. 1981. Negotiation behavior. New York: Academic
Press.
Knight, F. H. 1921. Risk, uncertainty, and profit. London:
Houghton Mifflin. Pruitt, D. G., & Carnevale, P. J. 1993. Negotiation in social
Kochan, T. A. 1979. Dynamics of dispute resolution in the conflict. Pacific Grove, CA: Brooks-Cole.

public sector. In B. Aaron, J. R. Grodin, & J. L. Stern (Eds.),


Pruitt, D. G., McGillicuddy, N., Welton, G., & Fry, W. R. 1989.

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
2000 Ross and Conlon 427

Process of mediation in dispute settlement centers. In K. Thibaut, J., & Walker, L. 1975. Procedural justice: A psycho-
Kressel & D. Pruitt (Eds.), Mediation research: 368-393. logical analysis. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Asso-
San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. ciates.

Purdy, J., & Gray, B. 1994. Government agencies as mediators Thibaut, J., & Walker, L. 1978. A theory of procedure. Califor-
in public policy conflicts. International Journal of Con- nia Law Review, 66: 541-566.
flict Management, 5: 158-180.
Thompson, L. L. 1991. Information exchange in negotiation.
Rose, J. B., & Manuel, C. 1996. Attitudes toward collective Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 27: 161-179.
bargaining and compulsory arbitration. Journal of Col-
Thompson, L. L. 1998. The mind and heart of the negotiator.
lective Negotiations in the Public Sector, 25: 287-310.
Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Ross, W. H. 1990. An experimental test of motivation and
Tripp, T., & Sondak, H. 1992. An evaluation of dependent
content control on dispute mediation. Journal of Applied
variables in experimental negotiation studies: Impasse
Behavioral Science, 26: 111-118.
rates and Pareto efficiency. Organizational Behavior
Ross, W. H., Conlon, D. E., & Lind, E. A. 1990. The mediator as and Human Decision Processes, 51: 273-295.
leader: Effects of behavioral style and deadline cer-
tainty on negotiator behavior. Group and Organization Tversky, A., & Shafir, E. 1992. The disjunctive effect in choice

Studies, 15: 105-124. under uncertainty. Psychological Science, 3: 305-309.

Sander, F. E. A. 1993. The courthouse and alternative dispute Ury, W. L., Brett, J. M., & Goldberg, S. B. 1988. Getting disputes
resolution. In L. Hall (Ed.), Negotiation: Strategies for resolved: Designing systems to cut the costs of conflict.
mutual gain: 43-60. Newbury Park, CA: Sage. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

Shafir, E., & Tversky, A. 1992. Thinking through uncertainty: Wall, J. A., Jr. 1991. Impression management in negotiations.
Nonconsequential reasoning and choice. Cognitive Psy- In R. A. Gicalone & P. Rosenfeld (Eds.), Applied impres-
chology, 24: 449-474. sion management: How image-making affects manage-
rial decisions: 133-156. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Starke, F. A., & Notz, W. W. 1981. Pre- and post-intervention
efforts of conventional versus final offer arbitration. Walton, R., & McKersie, R. 1965. A behavioral theory of labor
Academy of Management Journal, 24: 832-850. negotiations: An analysis of a social interaction system.
New York: McGraw-Hill.
State of California, Department of Youth Authority and Cal-
ifornia State Employees Association. 1987. Labor Arbi- Weingart, L. R., Thompson, L. L., Bazerman, M. H., & Carroll,
tration Information System, vol. 14. Case No. 2082: 248- J. S. 1990. Tactical behaviors and negotiation outcomes.
251. Fort Washington, PA: Labor Relations Press. International Journal of Conflict Management, 1: 7-31.

William H. Ross is a professor of industrial relations at the University of Wisconsin at


La Crosse. He received his Ph.D. in industrial-organizational psychology from the
University of Illinois. His research interests include dispute resolution systems de-
sign, dispute mediation, procedural justice, and conflict management.

Donald E. Conlon is an associate professor of management at Michigan State Uni-


versity. He received his Ph.D. in organization behavior from the University of Illinois.
His research interests include third-party intervention in conflicts, justice perceptions
in a variety of contexts (e.g., downsizing, service encounters), intragroup conflict, and
organizational decision making.

This content downloaded from


116.68.97.53 on Wed, 25 Nov 2020 02:44:51 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like