You are on page 1of 5

IV The Years of Recovery (1981-82)

At the outset of 1981, the economic environment cut (Table 8).5 Largely as a result of expenditure
was characterized by relatively high unemployment, increases, the consolidated public sector deficit rose
high levels of inventories, and excess capacity. The from 3.2 percent of GNP in 1980 to 4.6 percent in
Government continued with its adjustment effort dur- 1981. Increased expenditures resulted from higher
ing 1981-82, but relaxed financial policies to counter central government spending, greater purchases of rice
the severe economic recession. Economic conditions by the Grain Management Fund to replenish stocks
improved significantly during this period as output used after the 1980 crop failure, and extraordinarily
rose by an annual average of about 6 percent, while large capital outlays in telecommunications.
the rate of inflation fell gradually to below 5 percent Expenditure policy focused initially on increasing
and the current account deficit to below 4 percent of the tempo of public spending on rural projects so as
GNP. Nevertheless, the adjustment process was by to cushion the loss in agricultural incomes. Outlays
no means completed by the end of 1982. The economy for low-income housing and social overhead capital
still operated well below full capacity and the external also were increased, partly to repair typhoon damage.
financing requirements remained large—a particularly Thus, the structure of expenditure shifted toward
serious problem in light of the emerging international public capital formation and housing, and much of the
debt crisis. fiscal stimulus was provided through net lending op-
erations. Several temporary tax changes reinforced
these expenditure measures. Income taxes for low-
Policies income workers were cut and special excise duties for
selected consumer durables were reduced. A tempo-
The adjustment program for 1981-82 was designed rary investment tax credit was extended, as was the
to restore economic growth, while reducing domestic scheme to encourage additional investment by certain
inflation and the external imbalance. This program smaller firms. The larger overall deficit in 1981 resulted
continued to be supported with a stand-by arrangement in significant increases in both foreign and domestic
with the Fund (March 1981-February 1982) and a financing. The ratio of domestic financing to GNP rose
structural adjustment loan from the World Bank. The from 2.3 percent in 1980 to 3.4 percent in 1981, largely
authorities adopted a more stimulative financial policy reflecting an increase in bank financing (Table 7).
to revive the economy. The public sector deficit rose With the strengthening of the economy in 1982, fiscal
to over 4 percent of GNP, while domestic credit policy was reined in so as to help correct the external
expansion slowed only moderately despite a sharp imbalance and improve the price performance. Faced
decline in inflation. Exchange rate policy was managed with large shortfalls in revenues, central government
flexibly, although the real effective exchange rate expenditure was cut to a level below the budgetary
appreciated somewhat and contributed to a weakening target—a step which was instrumental in reducing the
of exports. The Government's structural policies fo- public sector deficit to 4.3 percent of GNP.6 Expend-
cused on the public investment program, tax reform,
and trade liberalization. 5
The stance and impulse of fiscal policy have been measured on
the basis of public sector revenues and expenditures, but very
similar qualitative results are obtained on the basis of central
government expenditures and revenues.
Fiscal Policy 6
The removal of the Korea Telecommunications Authority (KTA)
from the public sector accounts in January 1982 also contributed to
the improvement in the public sector position. In 1981, telecom-
Fiscal policy was used to stimulate aggregate demand munications operations accounted for 0.6 percentage point of the
public sector deficit of 5 percent of GNP. The 1982 public sector
in 1981. The budgetary impulse became expansionary deficit was 4.6 percent of GNP, of which 0.5 percentage point
as public sector expenditures were raised and taxes represented net lending to the KTA. Therefore, of the 0.4 percentage

10

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution


Policies

iture restraint held central government outlays roughly Table 4. Korea: Selected Monetary Aggregates,
unchanged as a proportion of GNP (22.5 percent). The
1982
tax to GNP ratio increased marginally as a result of
the positive effects of a new education surtax and the (Percentage change)1
underlying high elasticity of the tax system. The ratio March June September December
of domesticfinancingto GNP declined from 3.4 percent
Domestic
in 1981 to 3 percent in 1982. Within domestic financing, credit 21.0 31.6 30.0 18.1
bank financing was limited to 0.6 percent of GNP in Broad money 27.5 41.0 38.3 4.2
1982—compared with 2 percent in 1981—while non- Reserve
bankfinancingrose by 1 percentage point to 2.4 percent money 2 -1.2 2.9 45.4 -5.8
of GNP. The ratio of foreign financing to GNP in- Quarterly change at seasonally adjusted annual rates.
creased slightly to 1.3 percent in 1982. Adjusted for increase in reserve requirements.

Monetary Policy of funds from nonbank financial markets. As a result,


the ratio of bank deposits to currency rose by 11
percent in May 1982. Lending activities in nonbank
The objective of monetary policy in 1981 was to markets were curtailed, creating severe liquidity prob-
support economic growth while securing a reduction lems for enterprises that depended heavily on these
in inflation and further external adjustment. Monetary sources of finance.
policy accommodated increased bank borrowing by To offset the contraction in nonbank lending and to
the public sector, which was associated with the avoid a generalized financial crisis, the Bank of Korea
stimulative stance of fiscal policy. Nevertheless, over- permitted a rapid expansion of bank credit and sup-
all credit was sufficiently tight to help bring about a ported this expansion by sharply increasing reserve
further reduction in domestically generated inflation money. During the period May-September 1982, do-
and a decline in the current account deficit. The growth mestic credit expanded at an annual rate of 30 percent
of domestic credit decelerated from 41 percent in 1980 (seasonally adjusted); and reserve money grew at an
to 31 percent in 1981. Credit to the public sector annual rate of 48 percent (adjusted for seasonal factors
accounted for 19 percent of the overall increase in and a change in reserve requirements). As the turmoil
domestic credit, compared with 8 percent in 1980. in financial markets subsided in the fourth quarter of
With a substantial decline in net foreign assets, the 1982, expansion of domestic credit slowed to an annual
growth of broad money slowed from 27 percent to 25 rate of 18 percent (Table 4).
percent. However, as the rate of inflation fell sharply, Reflecting the less expansionary fiscal policy in 1982,
the real stock of broad money rose by 12 percent in credit to the public sector accounted for only 8 percent
1981, compared with a decline of 6 percent in 1980. of the total increase in domestic credit, compared with
The income velocity of money, which had risen in 19 percent in 1981. The reduced borrowing require-
1980 following three years of steady decline, fell ments of the public sector in 1982 considerably eased
slightly in 1981 in line with the deceleration in the rate the burden of reserve money management. In 1982,
of inflation. (The close association between the be- about 50 percent of the credit needs of the public
havior of velocity and the real yield on deposits in sector was satisfied by the Bank of Korea in 1982,
Korea is shown in Chart 4.) compared with about 85 percent in 1981. Credit to the
Monetary conditions in 1982 were dominated by a private sector in 1982 grew at virtually the same rate
financial scandal in the unorganized money market as in 1981 (about 25 percent). The growth of broad
(the curb market) in May, which forced two large money also accelerated in the second and third quar-
corporations into default and threatened other firms ters, but slowed to 4 percent (annual rate) in the fourth
with insolvency. Dishonored checks rose sharply; their quarter because of the sharp slowdown in the growth
value during May reached almost 8 percent of demand of net domestic assets, the large balance of payments
deposits. Confidence in nonbank financial intermedi- deficit, and some reflow of funds to nonbank financial
aries was shaken and the public withdrew large amounts markets. For 1982 alone, broad money rose by 27
percent—slightly faster than the average rate of ex-
pansion for the period 1980-81. Income velocity of
point reduction in the public sector deficit to GNP in 1982, only 0.1 broad money fell by about 11 percent (compared with
percentage point was due to telecommunications operations (i.e.,
the deficit without telecommunications was reduced from 4.4 percent an average annual decline of about 3 percent during
of GNP in 1981 to 4.1 percent in 1982). 1978-81), reflecting the increase in bank deposits after

11

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution


IV • THE YEARS OF RECOVERY

the curb market incident,7 higher real interest rates, Table 5. Korea: Velocity of Money, 1978-82
and lower inflationary expectations (Table 5).
(Percentage change)
Bank interest rates, which are under government
control, were reduced during 1981-82, but these re- Period averages 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982
ductions were held to less than the decline in inflation Nominal GNP 34.6 26.9 18.1 23.5 13.8
so that real interest rates would become positive. The Broad money 39.3 26.8 25.8 27.4 28.1
nominal interest rate on one-year time deposits was Velocity -3.4 — -6.1 -3.1 -11.1
gradually reduced from 19.5 percent in early 1981 to Sources: Korean authorities; and Fund staff estimates.
8 percent in the second half of 1982. After the sharp
drop in inflation in 1981, real interest rates turned
positive in the fourth quarter of 1981 and remained Exchange Rate Policy
positive throughout 1982, averaging about 3 percent.
Lending rates, which ranged from 12 percent to 17.5
percent in early 1981, were also reduced gradually to The authorities pursued a flexible exchange rate
a uniform rate of 10 percent in mid-1982. The adjust- policy during 1981-82 to preserve the external com-
ment of interest rates was aimed at spurring investment petitiveness of Korean producers. The effective ex-
by lowering interest costs of firms, while still main- change rate remained relatively stable as the won was
taining a positive level of real interest rates. The allowed to depreciate by about 13 percent against the
lowering of domestic interest rates was faster and U.S. dollar. However, because domestic inflation ex-
sharper than the decline in international interest rates, ceeded foreign inflation, the real effective exchange
and a differential was opened in favor of foreign assets rate appreciated by about 6 percent, contributing to
in 1982. This differential narrowed late in the year as the weak performance of exports in 1982.
foreign rates declined.
Preferential interest rates for priority sectors were Structural Policies
eliminated in 1982, but directed loans remained an
important feature of Korea's financial system. A sub-
stantial part of directed lending continued to be chan- During 1981-82, structural policies were aimed at
neled through the deposit money banks as well as the increasing the productivity and efficiency of the econ-
Korea Development Bank and other development omy. These policies encompassed public sector in-
institutions. In carrying out directed lending activity, vestment, a comprehensive tax reform, and trade
banks either use their own funds, supported by redis- liberalization. The investment program was designed
counting of eligible bills by the Bank of Korea, or act to support an increasingly urban and industrial econ-
as a conduit for government lending funds. As part of omy. An important objective of the investment plan
an effort to improve the allocation of financial re- was to reduce dependency on imported petroleum by
sources, the authorities reduced the share of directed expanding domestic coal production and constructing
loans in total loans from 20 percent in 1980 to 16 electricity-generating plants powered by coal, liquefied
percent in 1982. natural gas, and nuclear fuel. To reinforce energy
The monetary authorities, in early 1982, changed conservation, the Government passed through to do-
the instruments by which they conduct monetary mestic consumers only 30 percent of the $5 per barrel
policy. The Bank of Korea replaced direct credit reduction in world oil prices in 1982. About 40 percent
control, exercised through ceilings on individual banks, of the savings from the decline in world oil prices were
with indirect control exercised through the instruments earmarked for a special multipurpose fund to finance
of reserve requirements, open market operations, and projects primarily in the energy sector. The remainder
the rediscount mechanism. The system of preferential of the savings was absorbed by an import duty. Because
lending rates of commercial banks was eliminated in basic needs for clothing and food had been largely
June 1982, and the rediscount rates of the Bank of met, housing became the centerpiece of the Govern-
Korea were unified. In addition, to permit banks more ment's social development efforts. Housing construc-
flexibility in their lending operations, the maximum tion was promoted by a combination of financial
loan period for working funds was extended from one incentives to private investors and direct public sector
year to ten years. investment.
Significant reforms of the tax system were introduced
in 1981 as part of the overall policy of structural
7
An econometric analysis indicates that there was an upward adjustment. These reforms included an increase in the
shift in the demand for broad money following the curb market
incident. Aside from this shift, the demand function remained a
separate tax for interest and dividend income, a sim-
stable function of real income, interest rates, and expected inflation. plification of the corporate tax structure, and an ex-

12

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution


Economic Developments

tension of the value-added tax. The 1982 tax changes other hand, fell by 2 percent as a result of strong
were more sweeping and were aimed at both making conservation and oil-substitution efforts.
the system more neutral with respect to resource During 1982, external demand weakened consider-
allocation and increasing the tax effort. The new tax ably as traditional export industries—textiles, shoes,
measures changed the tax status of corporations, wood, paper—suffered under the impact of the global
modified certain deductions and tax incentives to favor recession and restrictive trade policies in the industrial
small- and medium-size firms, introduced tax credits countries, as well as some loss of external competi-
to promote development of technology, reduced the tiveness. Nevertheless, the growth of real GNP re-
number of industries that received tax advantages, and mained at about 6 percent as domestic demand con-
introduced a minimum tax on public corporations. In tinued to expand in response to stimulative financial
addition, individual income tax rates were reduced, policies. Fixed capital formation grew in real terms
and deductions for wage and salary earners and spouses (by 13 percent) for the first time since 1979. The major
were increased. The implementation of these measures factors contributing to this outcome were: (a) faster
was facilitated by the high elasticity of the taxes with growth in the nonagriculture sector; (b) a cut in
respect to GNP (about 1.2), which ensured that ade- domestic interest rates; and (c) a decline in prices of
quate revenues were available for financing the Gov- imported raw materials and oil. Also, a brisk recovery
ernment's development effort. in construction activity began in early 1982 because
With the improved economic situation during of government efforts to stimulate housing. These
1981-82, the import liberalization drive was resumed efforts included lowering the capital gains tax on
following its lapse during the previous two years. This houses, increasing the supply of housing sites, con-
drive was aimed at improving the structure of industry structing low-income housing units, and expanding
by enhancing competition, stabilizing prices by in- housing loans. Consumption continued to rise by about
creasing supplies, and facilitating trade negotiations 4 percent in real terms as an acceleration in public
with trading partners which restricted imports from consumption offset a slowdown in private consump-
Korea. At the same time, to avoid major disruptions tion. With the return of agricultural output to normal
in domestic production, selective use was made of levels, food grain imports were drastically reduced.
import tariffs. Import restrictions were lifted on a large The volume of non-oil imports rose by 6 percent, while
number of items during 1981-82, raising the ratio of the volume of oil imports declined by 1 percent,
unrestricted imports to total from 69 percent to 77 reflecting continued success of energy conservation
percent. policies.
Domestic inflation fell from a peak of 35 percent in
1980, to 13 percent in 1981, and 5 percent in 1982. The
Economic Developments principal reasons for this fall were lower inflation
Economic growth resumed in 1981, as real GNP abroad and a stable effective exchange rate. Prudent
rose by 6 percent. The recovery of agriculture and demand management, improved food supplies, wage
rapid expansion of exports dominated developments moderation, and productivity gains also contributed
in aggregate output during 1981. Following the disas- to lower inflation. Price controls were eliminated in
trous harvest of 1980, agricultural production rose by 1981 and replaced by a price monitoring system under
22 percent in 1981, returning to the 1979 level. The which selected enterprises are required to report price
volume of exports rose by 17 percent in response to increases to the Government.
both the devaluation of the won in 1980 and buoyant With the decline in inflation, the growth of nominal
foreign markets. Domestic demand revived on the wages decelerated from 23 percent in 1980, to 20
basis of an upturn in consumption and stimulative percent in 1981, and 15 percent in 1982. Real wages
financial policies, but accounted for only one third of actually fell by 1 percent in 1981, while labor produc-
the overall growth in aggregate demand. Investment tivity increased by 18 percent. The unusually large
remained weak. Fixed investment in real terms de- growth of labor productivity reflected the fact that in
clined for the second consecutive year, owing to the the initial phase of economic recovery, firms increased
still fragile business confidence, depressed profits, and production mainly by lowering excess capacity, rather
persistence of excess capacity, particularly in the than by increasing employment. The unemployment
heavy industry sector. Shipbuilding, automobiles, fer- rate declined moderately from 5.4 percent in 1980 to
tilizer, and cement industries were particularly af- 4.5 percent in 1981 because of a rapid increase in
fected. The recovery of aggregate demand and the employment in services and in agriculture. Employ-
shortage of grain supplies (arising from the crop failure ment in manufacturing, however, continued to decline
of 1980) led to an increase of 6 percent in the volume because of excess capacity. Real wages rose by 7
of non-oil imports. The volume of oil imports, on the percent in 1982, about the same as labor productivity.

13

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution


IV • THE YEARS OF RECOVERY

The unemployment rate fell slightly in 1982, reflecting form of interoffice accounts of local branches of foreign
a more rapid expansion of nonagricultural output and banks and credit lines of domestic banks with
a rise in domestic investment; manufacturing employ- foreign banks. This development reflected both re-
ment rose significantly. duced nonbank capital inflows due to lower domestic
The external position improved steadily during interest rates and limited availability of medium- and
1981-82. The current account deficit declined to long-term loans during 1982, as Korea's access to the
$4.6 billion (6.9 percent of GNP) in 1981, as the international capital market was hindered by the global
vigorous expansion of exports (20 percent) more than debt crisis. Gross international reserves rose by about
offset the increase in imports (12 percent), the contin- $0.8 billion and stood at $7.7 billion by the end of
ued growth in interest payments, and a small deteri- 1982; in terms of imports, gross reserves remained
oration in the external terms of trade. The moderate stable at around 2.9 months. The ratio of reserves to
growth of imports represented a significant adjustment short-term debt declined from 73 percent in 1980 to 58
effort in view of the exceptionally large rice imports percent in 1982.
(equivalent to 1 percent of GNP) that were necessitated
by the 1980 crop failure. In 1982, the current account
deficit was almost halved to $2.6 billion (3.7 percent
of GNP), despite stagnating exports. The main factors Situation at the End of 1982
contributing to the improvement in the current account
were a sharp decline in import prices (8 percent) and By the end of 1982, the Korean economy had made
a further slowing of the volume growth of imports. substantial headway in overcoming the economic crisis
The narrowing of the current account imbalance during of 1980. The progress in reducing the rate of inflation
1981-82 reflected a gradual decline in the ratio of gross and the current account deficit was particularly note-
domestic investment to GNP. The ratio of gross worthy. Korea's growth outcome of about 6 percent
national savings to GNP remained relatively stable. a year was satisfactory in comparison with the growth
With the gradual decline in external financing re- rates in other developing countries, but fell well below
quirements, the growth in Korea's external debt, which Korea's historical performance. The gradual weak-
had averaged about 35 percent per annum during ening of the export sector was of particular concern
1979-80, slowed to about 16 percent during 1981-82. in view of Korea's large external debt and the emerging
Nevertheless, outstanding external debt rose by close crisis in the international capital market.
to $10 billion, reaching $37 billion (52 percent of GNP) Notwithstanding the significant reduction in the
at the end of 1982; the associated debt service ratio current account deficit, Korea's borrowing during
rose from 20 percent to 21 percent. Short-term debt 1980-82 was substantial. Although Korea's debt-
rose by 15 percent per annum during 1980-82; its share servicing obligations remained consistent with its ca-
in total debt remained at around 34 percent. A large pacity to earn foreign exchange, the level of its out-
portion of the increase in short-term debt was trade- standing debt was high in an international context.
related, including such obligations as trade credit and Commercial banks became increasingly reluctant to
oil bills. Reflecting the elimination of advance deposits raise their exposure limits, mainly because of the
on deferred-payment imports, the share of trade- fallout from the financial crisis in Latin America as
related credit in total short-term debt rose from 30 well as in Asia. In this environment, the high level of
percent in 1980 to 38 percent in 1982. A significant short-term debt, particularly in relation to international
portion of the increase in short-term debt was in the reserves, became an increasing source of concern.

14

©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution

You might also like