You are on page 1of 11

The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

The Electricity Journal


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electr

Optimizing prices for small-scale distributed generation resources: A


review of principles and design elements
Amparo Nieto
NERA Economic Consulting, 777 South Figueroa Street, LA 90017, USA

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Article history:
Received 1 March 2016 Regulators worldwide are considering many proposals to improve pricing schemes for low-carbon
Accepted 7 March 2016 distributed electricity resources in order to achieve compensation that is fairer and better aligned with
Available online xxx the incremental benefits to the utility and society. The key concern is that under the current practice of
net metering, the expansion of renewables-based, small-scale distributed generation is at odds with the
Keywords: utility’s efforts to provide service on a reliable, efficient (least-cost) and equitable basis.
Energy ã 2016 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Tariffs
Marginal cost
Distributed generation
Solar PV
Storage

1. Introduction systems, the growth of renewables-based distributed generation


(DG)2 is increasingly at odds with the utility’s efforts to provide
The U.S. has moved a long way towards the restructuring of its service on a reliable, efficient (least-cost), and equitable basis.
energy sector. Today, the push for a cleaner environment and the In the case of solar DG, the cost of integrating residential and
subsequent expansion of renewable energy generation resources is small commercial customers’ generation systems is often social-
changing the dynamics of both wholesale and retail electricity ized among all customers. Among the integration challenges are
markets, and is demonstrating the need for further regulatory the increased ancillary services often required to balance the
reforms. The intermittent, rather unpredictable output of renew- excess output sent to the grid in real time, and the potential
able-based generation presents short term reliability challenges acceleration of upgrades to distribution facilities in certain areas to
and may dramatically affect long-term resource planning deci- handle reverse flows, which raises the cost of delivery. More
sions. At the wholesale level, new mechanisms to incentivize notably, there may be severe adverse equity impacts due to the
“flexible” generation capacity resources are being developed to implicit rate-funded subsidy mechanism employed in most states
address the sudden and potentially large fluctuations of aggregate to compensate for the output of small-scale solar or wind
generation supply in order to ensure system stability.1 At the retail generation systems. These facilities are subsidized by the practice
level, regulators are developing new pricing measures for low- of net metering, along with ratepayer-funded rebates and federal
carbon distributed electricity generation resources such as solar tax incentives. Currently, 44 states and the District of Columbia
Photovoltaics (PV) and wind, that allow for fair compensation, one have adopted formal net metering policies which typically is
that better aligns with the incremental benefits of these resources available to residential and commercial solar systems of up to 1
to the utility and society, so as to not unduly burdening other MW of demand. Under this billing practice, the distribution utility
customers. The main concern is that under the current pricing has the obligation to buy any exported generation from the

2
E-mail address: amparo.nieto@nera.com (A. Nieto). Distributed generation (DG), also known as embedded generation, is located at
1
This may include the need to acquiring ramping resources, and other or near the point of power consumption and typically meets a portion of the
dispatchable generation required to integrate high levels of variable generation customers' daily electricity needs or provides backup service to customers that
reliably. need highly reliable power.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tej.2016.03.004
1040-6190/ ã 2016 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
32 A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41

Fig. 1. Average residential load before and after PV, SMUD July 2014.

customer’s generation facility at the prevailing retail per-kWh rate, wind turbines, do not receive comparable subsidies.6 The fact that
regardless of the value of that energy to the grid.3 The cumulative customers may not be acquiring the least-cost renewable energy
excess energy delivered to the distribution grid in one month is available raises controversy as to how much renewable DG is
netted against the customer’s energy purchases from the grid the desirable.
same month, and any excess is carried over to offset consumption A number of states are now evaluating rate reforms that seek to
in the next billing cycle. In essence, the electric meter runs reduce or eliminate the subsidies to renewable DG customers
backwards when the customer system generation sends surplus provided by net metering. However, regulators are finding it very
generation to the utility grid. Because the standard rate applicable challenging to agree on a “fix” that is considered fair to all grid
to residential and small commercial customers is generally users, and does not conflict with federal or state environmental
structured as a two-part rate, with a low monthly fixed charge policy or energy conservation goals. In order to facilitate
and a flat per-kWh charge that does not change by time of day, 4 the consensus, first there needs to be a clear and widespread
tariff revenues from customers under net metering decline faster understanding of the goals of regulatory energy pricing. The goal
than the cost savings realized by the utility or distribution owner. behind a rate reform is not to hinder DG development, but to
The subsequent net revenue gap must be collected from all promote a more optimal expansion of DG that benefits all
customers in the rate class at the next general rate case to keep the customers in the long term. Next, there needs to be a detailed
utility financially whole, thus leading to cross-subsidies.5 evaluation of the distortions embedded in the utility’s existing
From its onset, the practice of net metering was known to pricing scheme for both bundled service rates and network rates,
provide a subsidy to DG, funded by regular, full-service customers. and to what extent such distortions can be mitigated given the
Installation costs for utility-scale solar PV projects and for behind available metering technology. Ensuring a system of tariffs that do
the meter residential and commercial rooftop solar have plum- a better job at signaling the costs effectively imposed on the system
meted in recent years. As the costs of solar technologies fall and the by load growth, or equivalently, the direct financial benefit to the
net metering share of the utility’s customer base expands, in some utility from load reductions, is critical to meet best practice rate
cases, exponentially, the validity of net metering as an appropriate making goals. Any subsidy aiming to foster a target amount of
tool to stimulate small-scale renewable DG has been called into distributed solar generation on account of its clean attributes is
question. Not only are there equity concerns about the intra-class more appropriately channeled outside of the retail tariff or
cross-subsidies inherent in net metering, but also concerns that unbundled distribution charges.
other clean energy resources, in particular utility-scale solar and The right tariff revisions will not only promote efficient DG
development, but will also support the development of more
optimal amounts of other “distributed energy resources” (DER)
such as residential and commercial demand response, electric
3
Under net metering, a single bi-directional meter registers the energy exported vehicles (EV), behind-the-meter energy storage such as battery
from the on-site system to the grid.
4
Rates that have an inverted kWh block structure may be particularly
suboptimal, providing a large credit to net metered usage. For example, SDG&E’s
6
residential and small solar commercial customers may receive for excess energy an A federal investment tax credit under the 2005 Energy Policy Act offers up to a
average of over 22 cents/kWh under net metering. 30% offset against all solar generator installation cost. Wind turbines receive a
5
Cross-subsidies can be determined through comparing class revenue target production tax credit. These credits are expected to be gradually phased out by
with actual tariff revenues plus avoided costs from DG. 2022.
A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41 33

systems or thermal ice storage, and microgrids. Rates that properly demand is barely reduced as compared to pre-solar demand levels.
reflect the underlying marginal costs of service will help ensure Thus, the customer contributes roughly the same to peak
that consumer decisions to install rooftop solar or wind turbines infrastructure (generation capacity and network) needs as
are based on economically efficient incentives and do not lead to compared to prior to installing solar. This is the case in winter-
uneconomic bypass7 of the utility system. peaking regions where the solar generation profile does not fit load
well, but also in summer peaking regions, where the lack of perfect
2. The case for rate restructuring alignment of solar generation with the hours of system peak
largely disqualifies solar facilities as a firm peak-shaving resource.
Revisions to retail and network tariff structures are urgently Fig. 1 illustrates this phenomenon. The solid line shows a
needed to prevent growing and potentially unsustainable intra- residential customer’s average hourly load pattern in a summer
class subsidies. There is limited value to regulatory methods that month in Sacramento Municipal District (SMUD). The solar PV
leave suboptimal rates in place, as observed in prior utilities’ production is given by the dotted line, and the dashed line shows
attempts to handle revenue erosion challenges. A mechanism the pattern of consumption that the utility sees as a result of solar
called “revenue decoupling” has been used in the past to break the system installation. The excess solar output that flows back to the
link between a utility’s revenue and the amount of energy it sells to grid, represented by the negative net energy usage in the chart,
the customer, in the context of energy efficiency and demand begins to decline in the middle to late afternoon, corresponding
response programs, and is now being proposed in some states to with SMUD system’s peak period when system generation costs
deal with net revenue losses from DG. The decoupling surcharge is and delivery costs may be at their highest. By 4 pm, most solar
meant to ensure that the utility collects its authorized fixed costs in homes generate enough power to meet their own needs, but not
between general rate cases. Thus, this mechanism removes the enough to export power back to the grid, precisely when excess
disincentive for a utility to encourage energy conservation or power would be most beneficial to the grid. The peak of customer’s
distributed generation in any given period of time. Decoupling is solar output in the summer generally takes place in the late
useful to effectively correct the short-term utility revenue gap as morning and early afternoon, which tend to be the off-peak hours
energy sales decline, but, since it does not require changing the of the utility system. This is also when solar homes send the most
basic rate structure, it does nothing to reduce the underlying cross- extra power to the grid.
subsidy problem, or to encourage the development of cost- The lack of time-differentiation means that DG customers have
effective DG. little incentive to control their consumption in the late afternoon
hours when their production is tapering off but the utility’s costs
2.1. Time-differentiation: the key starting point are still high. If solar PV output does not have a meaningful effect
on annual system peak demand, it does little to enhance system
An optimal rate aims to minimize the social deadweight loss reliability, or reduce expected annual loss of load probability
created by prices that encourage increased usage when it is more (LOLP) or shortage costs. Thus, it does not avoid transmission or
costly to serve (on-peak) and lower usage when it would be distribution network expansion, or lower the cost of energy and
cheaper to serve (off-peak). In general, many of the rate reform capacity market purchases that the utility may need to meet
proposals put before regulators to date have focused on addressing expected load growth. If small-scale solar customers were able to
the cross-subsidization issue via a “fixed vs. variable” cost split, access the wholesale market (directly or through third-party
generally assuming that all “fixed” embedded costs must be aggregators) and bid an expected profile of excess generation into
recovered through fixed charges. There is normally little consider- day-ahead or real-time markets, the value of solar to the grid at a
ation given to whether volumetric charges will provide efficient given time, net of any ancillary services, would be immediately
price signals that change with marginal cost changes throughout monetized by solar owners. Lacking that ability, retail tariffs are
the day. If not done correctly, a simplified ‘fixed-variable’ fix may left to fulfill the market value-discovery role, if only averaged by
actually introduce another type of intra-class cross-subsidies by time of day within a season and over the years the rates will be in
further undermining incentives for efficient usage patterns. effect. A retail tariff with time-differentiated charges will be more
The main culprit of the current distortions in retail energy likely to encourage more installation of solar panels with the best
residential and small commercial rates is precisely the traditional possible orientation to maximize peak period production8 and
emphasis on overly simplified structures and prices that do not provide incentives to all customers to control their peak loads.
vary by time of day. With no time of day charges, customers with a Consumers will make more efficient energy consumption and DG
higher percentage of their monthly electricity consumption in the investment decisions when the prices they face for electricity
high cost (peak) hours relative to the average customer are reflect the marginal costs of using more or less electricity at any
subsidized by those customers with a lower percentage of monthly given time. Efficient consumption patterns and levels are a
usage in the peak hours. The absence of time of day energy charges prerequisite for optimal system expansion and resource allocation,
means that capacity costs, along with energy costs, are recovered ultimately enabling lower cost of service.
uniformly across all hours of the day. In that case, a higher-than
class’ average load factor customer may subsidize customers with a 2.2. Marginal-cost based rate structures
lower load factor, even though they all may be consuming the same
amount of energy at the time of system peak. A number of alternative rate designs can be adopted to improve
The presence of renewable generation such as solar PV incentives for development of efficient DG and other DER. The final
exacerbates these intra-class problems because solar customers structure will be influenced by regulatory priorities and con-
reduce sharply their load factor upon installation of solar panels. straints in each state, but the principles should not fundamentally
The total energy that solar customers require from the utility or differ. To ensure that both utilities and consumers have the right
competitive retailer drops, while their maximum, coincident peak

8
The orientation of the solar panels makes a difference. Most solar panels point
7
Uneconomic bypass may take place if the utility’s marginal cost of serving the south since they maximize year-round solar power production, generating about
customer is lower than the per-kWh retail charge that the customer saves when 10–20% more than west-facing panels. However, west-facing panels are better
self-generating, overstating the actual avoided cost to the system. aligned with the later afternoon (system peak) hours.
34 A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41

Table 1
Cost-reflective rate structure.

Rate components

Energy charge On-peak demand charge Per-connected or contract demand charge Monthly customer charge
(c/kWh) ($/ kW)b ($/max kW) ($/mo)

Marginal cost componenta Peak Off-


Peak
Energy cost (LMP) U U
Generation capacity U
Transmission U
Distribution substation and primary U
lines
Local distribution facilities U
Customer costs U
a
A revenue reconciliation factor would be needed to meet total class' allocated costs.
b
It may be replaced with a “super-peak” per-kWh charge.

financial incentive to encourage or engage in DG or other DER, key more unbundled rate components will help address the increas-
objectives to guide ratemaking reforms should be as follows: ingly divergent load patterns of customers within the class more
effectively, and thereby minimize cross-subsidies.
(a) Rate structures should ensure that all customers see economi- With these objectives in mind, an optimal rate requires a
cally efficient price signals for usage and distributed generation multipart structure that follows the underlying structure of
investment decisions, by time of day and season. marginal cost of service, as illustrated in Table 1.
(b) Rates must provide enough revenue such that the utility can
earn a reasonable return on prudent investment over time. This 2.2.1. Local facilities charges per kW of contract capacity
means that changes in tariff revenues track as much as possible When unbundling the distribution cost, it is essential to
the on-going changes in costs of service. distinguish between the elements of the distribution infrastruc-
(c) Rates should be equitable, meaning customers are placed in the ture that are sized according to ongoing changes in a distribution
right rate class and are charged on the basis of the energy, area’s coincident peak demand (distribution substations and
capacity and customer-related costs they impose to the system. upstream primary feeders) versus the local facilities (local primary
(d) Rates should be affordable, meaning that major rate changes lines, secondary lines, and transformers), which are sized to
may need to be gradually phased in to avoid unacceptably large specifically meet the total non-coincident demands of the
bill impacts. customers served from them. Substations and upstream high-
voltage distribution feeders are designed to serve diversified loads,
Ensuring stability in rate-setting methods and transparent while the local facilities are typically sized to serve the maximum
criteria to trigger tariff adjustments is often cited as another key expected demand (the design demand) of the customers expected
ratemaking goal, since it promotes trust in the regulatory system to be connected to it over the service life of the facility.10 The
and improves price predictability. Notwithstanding this principle, typical per-kW cost of connection for a customer class will
major breakthroughs in technology such as those introduced by generally vary by service area (rural vs. urban) number of
smart meters and communications infrastructure may warrant a customers with access to natural gas for space heating versus
tariff overhaul to maximize efficiency gains and improve fairness. “all-electric” customers, and other variables such as presence of
Preserving gradualism and regulatory trust in that context may electric vehicle charging. Because the utility does not expect to
require grandfathering rates for existing DG owners, in the event expand the size of the transformer over time as the customer’s
that a change in the rate setting method will significantly reduce demand grows, all connected customers, including those with DG,
the compensation for energy exports. The specific term over which should face a fixed monthly local facilities charge levied on an
existing rates will be grandfathered should be determined on a estimate of their design demand.11 Ideally, the billing systems
case by case basis, to balance the goals of providing reasonable would include a record of each customer’s design demand (or
payback certainty for PV investors and to align the compensation contract kW). If there are no records of design demand, the billing
for solar exports with the evolving value of distributed solar to the contract demand could be set at the highest metered non-
system. coincident demand of the customer over a sufficiently long recent
For maximum efficiency in price signals applicable to all period (e.g., the past 18 months), as a proxy for the amount of load
customers, time-differentiated per-kWh charges should be set as that the distribution transformers must stand ready to withstand
close as possible to the underlying marginal unit cost in each at any given time.12 In general, if a customer’s maximum demand
period. A marginal cost analysis seeks to estimate the impact on exceeds the assumed design demand at any time, the billing
costs experienced by the utility or the unbundled default service demand should be reset at the higher level. A customer’s non-
supplier, and distribution owner, from a customer addition and coincident demand may be larger than his demand at the time of
changes in customer usage at different times of day. A marginal system peak.
cost study unbundles different components of cost of service- i.e.,
generation, transmission, ancillary services, distribution substa-
tion and trunkline feeders,9 local distribution facilities and
customer services—according to what triggers these costs by
10
customer group and voltage level. As more customers install DG, The diversity of customers’ loads is taken into account when developing the
required size of the facility but diversity may not be a large factor if there are only a
few customers connected to the transformer.
11
The type of distribution connection policy in place will determine the local
9
The trunkline feeder is the segment of the primary line from a distribution facilities costs that are to be recovered in rates as opposed to up-front.
12
substation to the point where it branches to create a primary tap line, to which If metering is not available, the standard design demands used by planners for
primary customer connects. buildings of specific sizes can be used as a proxy.
A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41 35

An important caveat regarding defining a DG customer’s design Customers should not be discouraged from using electricity
demand is that DG customers should be treated the same, for that would have more value to them than it actually costs the
reasons of equity, as non-DG customers. Using a contract demand utility to supply. There may be, however, situations where demand
charge based on the customer’s generation nameplate capacity is growth has been unusually slow, and the ample capacity margins
not appropriate. A solar DG customer’s billing demand for a local in the region or service area drive both generation capacity and
facilities charge should reflect the maximum load that the grid-related marginal costs down. In some extreme scenarios, the
customer may potentially place on the local distribution system, increase to the fixed charge needed to set usage charges at the
because the transformer needs to be sized large enough to handle lower expected marginal cost over the upcoming rate period might
the customer’s load when the DG system is not operating.13 This result in very large customer bill impacts that could drive some
requires looking at the sum of the energy delivered to the customer customers to disconnect from the grid. It is inefficient to drive
from the grid and the energy generated by the solar system that is customers off the system simply because of electricity bills that
consumed on-site. In addition, the local distribution system needs exceed marginal costs. Thus, even if increasing the fixed charge to
to absorb the excess energy produced by solar panels and unused meet the class revenue target would be optimal, there may be cases
locally. Thus, the billing determinant for local facilities charges in where it is not possible to do so completely,without keeping
rates specifically set for DG customers should take into account volumetric charges slightly above marginal costs or market-based
whether the volume of export energy from their facilities is large value.
enough to add stress to the distribution facilities, after taking into Opponents to any increase to fixed charges argue that shifting
account the share of export power absorbed by other residents cost recovery away from volumetric components of the rate harms
served from the same transformer. the state policy goal of expanding solar DG, since it will reduce the
Temporary non-coincident demand reductions due to milder- value of any net metering credits that small-scale DG systems
than-average weather conditions or installation of renewable, receive. As DG continues to expand, however, a fixed charge
intermittent self-generation do not free up space in the increase may be needed to prevent growth of inequity between
transformer on a long-term basis. A customer may be entitled to customers with on-site solar generation and other residential
a lower than the class average design demand in cases where the customers. Utilities across 18 states requested a cost recovery shift
utility has installed a circuit breaker that limits access to the grid to to fixed charges for standard residential and small commercial
that amount, or if the customer adopts an automated control rates over the last two years,in large part motivated for expected
system that enables a permanent lower maximum demand. growth of distributed solar generation.14 However, it is not efficient
to simply shift the peak demand grid-related costs to a fixed
2.2.2. Fixed (customer) charge charge, because doing so precludes customers from having control
Fixed charges should ideally be set to recover the costs that do over their electricity bill, i.e., they could not directly receive a
not change when a customer uses more or less electricity or reliability credit if they reduced their peak energy usage. Cross-
demand after connecting to the grid. These costs may include the subsidies would remain, in this case those customers using more
marginal customer-related expenses such as installing, operating than the class’ average peak demand would be subsidized by
and maintaining the meter and service drop, meter reading and customers using less than the average peak demand. Assessing the
billing activities, and the cost of maintaining customer commu- suitability of the requested fixed charge increases in standard rates
nications. They may also include a fixed monthly local distribution should be done keeping in mind the extent to which they will
facility price component, based on the average class non- correct current cross-subsidies implicit in the existing rate
coincident demand if there are relatively homogeneous customers structure. When the fixed charge is set so low that costs unrelated
within the class. In practice, many utilities have residential fixed to usage are shifted to volumetric charges, higher-than average
charges that barely recover the direct customer-related costs. In usage residential customers – which may include customers with
some states residential charges are as low as $5 per month, when in limited access to natural gas for heating – end up paying more than
fact marginal customer-related costs may be as high as $20 per their fair share of fixed costs.
month or $40 once the monthly distribution facility cost is added. Utilities’ requests for higher fixed charges to address the impact
Although marginal costs is the starting point, the fixed charge of DG are sometimes rejected on the grounds that they have a
may be adjusted to reconcile the difference between the revenue negative impact on conservation goals, since they reduce the per-
that would result from setting all rate components at the estimated kWh price signal, and/or a negative large impact on low-use
marginal unit costs and the revenue requirement established for customers’ bills, which may include low-income residential users.
the class. Reconciling the marginal-cost-based revenue gap by first However, these effects are not by themselves a reason to
adjusting the fixed charge is the right design approach because perpetuate an inefficiently low customer charge or a poor rate
fixed charge changes do not typically affect electricity usage structure. In fact, these arguments presume that existing residen-
decisions considerably. In general, keeping the volumetric charges tial rates facilitate the right conservation incentives or low-
– those that vary with energy consumption and any metered (as- income-related subsidies. In most cases this is not the case, and an
used) peak demand charges – as close as possible to marginal costs increase in customer charges actually corrects a distortion built in
is more important to ensure that customers do not have an the prior design. First, flat seasonal volumetric prices incentivize
overstated or understated incentive to conserve. The same customers to reduce usage below optimal levels in off-peak
efficiency principle applies in the context of addressing rate periods, leading to an inefficient use of the capacity that is available
reforms in the presence of renewable DG. Accommodating cost- to them, and do not encourage enough conservation in peak hours.
effective DG may require raising fixed charges to bring volumetric Excessive usage charges in the bulk of off-peak hours may also lead
charges closer to the underlying time-differentiated marginal to self-generation, or uneconomic bypass. Second, keeping fixed
costs. charges unreasonably below cost helps residential customers with
below the class average usage, but generally a share of these
customers are not low-income. Low-income customers often have
13
Large co-generation systems owned by commercial and industrial customers
are generally assessed standby rates that reflect the costs of using the distribution
14
grid as a backup. Small-scale and renewable DG facilities are normally exempt from Utilities in 12 states recently received regulatory approval to implement fixed
this rate. charge increases for all residential rates.
36 A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41

higher electricity consumption than the average customer in the the U.S. are generally not sufficiently cost-reflective. When
class and are actually disadvantaged by high variable rates. Most residential customers can opt for TOU rates, the diurnal peak
solar customers are not low-income users and in fact lower income period definitions are often too broadly defined covering eight or
users tend to disproportionally shoulder the subsidies to solar ten hours – even when system planners may predictably expect the
customers when volumetric charges are above cost. highest probability of peak and highest cost of service to occur in a
In principle, providing support to low-income citizens and particular subset of those hours. Too long peak periods dilute the
correcting for uneven social income distribution is more efficiently peak per-kWh price signal. In addition, a peak season should be set
achieved through fiscal policy, i.e., outside of the electricity tariffs. to include the core peak months, where peak load is statistically
However if electricity rates are to continue funding low-income more likely to drive system expansion, particularly in the context
programs, subsidies should specifically target qualifying low- of reducing the size of cost shifting associated with net metering
income customers. An appropriate mechanism would be through a but also for improving incentives for conservation. This again is not
fixed low-income credit directly applied on their electricity bills, so always the current practice in today’s rate making.
as not to distort price signals in the basic rates for all consumers.
2.2.4. (As-used) coincident peak demand charges
2.2.3. Super-peak per-kWh charges In some cases, peak chasing concerns may prevent implement-
Increases in load may trigger investments in transmission ing a three or four-hour “super peak” energy charge that would
infrastructure in hours when capacity is strained, generally around reflect the typical high marginal costs in the critical hours of the
the time of system peak. Meeting generation resource adequacy day, particularly if applied to all residential customers. In that case,
targets is also linked to changes in the utility’s coincident system in order to maintain a clear peak price signal, and provided that the
peak. Investments in high-voltage distribution infrastructure may right meters are in place, it may be advisable to adopt an “as-used”,
involve adding or upgrading distribution substations or trunkline on-peak demand charge that would apply to the customer’s
feeders generally driven by expectations of growth in the maximum demand as metered within a reasonable number of
substation area peak load. Thus, incremental investments or hours around system peak period. The demand charge would
peak-related procurement costs are in principle suitable for recover coincident peak-related marginal capacity costs, thereby
recovery in on-peak per-kWh charges, or peak demand charges. reducing the per-kWh charges to only reflect marginal energy costs
Time-differentiated peak kWh charges require a forecast of hourly by time of day. Demand charges that are based on customer’s
locational marginal energy prices (LMPs), time-differentiated highest demand during the peak period are important for all
regional generation capacity market prices,15 an estimate of customers but especially relevant for solar net metering customers
marginal transmission costs beyond the congestion costs that who consistently rely on energy imports on the highest cost hours
are captured by the LMPs ancillary services, and high-voltage of the day, typically the evening hours. An on-peak demand charge
distribution costs.16 Estimating marginal delivery costs require gives solar customers an incentive to reduce consumption in the
examining the utility’s planning processes and, in particular, any few hours when their solar system generation is ramping down but
investment decisions aimed to meet load growth or maintain the utility system is experiencing peak demands.
reliability over the planning horizon, as opposed to hypothetical With a properly designed on-peak demand charge, if the
plant and load additions. A long-run marginal cost estimate is customer reduces peak usage, he receives bill savings equal to the
generally not useful for purposes of setting electricity rates that estimated full avoided capacity cost. As-used peak demand charges
may be changed every few years, since they do not send that reflect the underlying marginal capacity costs will therefore
meaningful price signals to customers when current and expected ensure that decisions to invest in demand-limited devices, stagger
system conditions, including reserve margins, differ from opti- the use of domestic electric appliances, or adopt behind-the meter
mal.17 Rates based on long-run marginal costs do a poor job at energy storage are based on economically-efficient incentives, i.e.,
reflecting the ongoing cost to the utility of meeting peak load without incurring in uneconomic bypass. A caveat of coincident
growth over the upcoming planning period (or the avoided cost peak demand charges is that they assume the customer’s
associated with load reductions from demand response, energy maximum monthly on-peak demand takes place the same day
efficiency or DG over the same period). and hour that the system peaks, and that the entire monthly
When time of use (TOU) rates are not properly designed, they capacity cost responsibility lies in that hour. This limitation is a
fail to preserve intra-class cross equity or produce efficient necessary compromise in absence of “dynamic” rates that allow
conservation incentives. A peak period should ideally be designed the utility to predict the highest demand hours in the month. As
to include only the highest marginal-cost hours in the day, to with any rate design reforms, the level of the peak demand charge
promote the right conservation incentives. The annualized may need to be tempered slightly after a careful analysis of
marginal generation capacity, transmission, high-voltate distribu- distributional bill impacts. Since solar customers’ electricity
tion feeders and distribution substation costs are allocated to the consumption has a tendency to peak closer to (or at the time
hours in each daytype and month, based on each hour’s relative of) the system peak, it makes sense to set separate rates with a
probability of peak, or the relative share of loss-of-load hours peak demand charge calculated explicitly for them. While a solar
(LOLH) in the case of generation. The combination of hourly customer will rely more on the utility in cloudy days, imports are
marginal costs is the key input to define the right time-of-day and unlikely to peak early in the afternoon (outside of the core peak
seasonal periods and price differentials. However, today the few hours). This is because solar panels will still be producing energy in
examples of residential or small commercial TOU rates existing in overcast days, albeit at a lower rate than normal. In general, more
granularity in rate periods may be required if a time-differentiated
demand charge is adopted for the entire residential rate class. For
15
The marginal generation capacity cost for a utility operating in a well- example, a lower demand charge may be required for a subset of
interconnected market is a function of loads and capacity resources region-wide. the early afternoon (shoulder) hours, along with the peak demand
16
In a restructured market, estimating marginal transmission costs requires a charge, for the residential rate.
financial approach, identifying a forecast of open access transmission tariffs and the
hours that trigger a higher transmission bill from the ISO.
17
A long-run marginal cost analysis assumes the utility has sufficient time to
2.2.5. Dynamic rates
adjust all inputs to the most efficient system configuration by employing capital and As is the case for conservation, promotion of cost-effective DG is
operating cost measures to precisely match load growth. best achieved with marginal cost-based dynamic pricing. The
A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41 37

optimal dynamic rate design would be a real-time pricing (RTP) revenue requirement should involve looking at a future test year’s
rate, but RTP rates are not well accepted in the residential segment. costs and weather-normalized class hourly load profiles. Despite
Other dynamic rates only modify the kWh charge on system’s AMI, load forecasting is challenging due to the intermittent nature of
critical days and during specific critical events called by the utility, DG and the potential for errors in the expected DG penetration by
and thus may be easier to implement, particularly if coupled with area. Utility rates will never perfectly match utility cash flow and
smart programmable thermostats. These include critical peak therefore there will always be over- or under recovery of costs in a
pricing (CPP) or peak-time rebate (PTR). Any CPP or PTR critical given year. However, if the utility incorporates an estimate of future
peak rate need to include a marginal cost component for customer reaction to new rate charges or specific demand response
generation capacity, transmission, and high-voltage distribution programs when setting rates, the mismatch between revenue
in the price for those critical peak hours. While they are more collected and revenue target will be largely reduced. Cost allocations
efficient than regular TOU rates, they may not be easily adopted as will still need to be revisited at the time of a rate case and adjusted if
a mandatory residential rate. customers within the class demonstrate a change in load patterns.

3. Redefining cost of service by customer class 3.3. Choice of cost allocation method

3.1. Treating DG customers as a separate class A thorough tariff reform should include an analysis of the legacy
cost allocation methods, to determine if changes are warranted. As
A separate rate class for net metered DG customers will be a result of growing renewable DG, more attention should be paid to
necessary if the key features for reforming standard residential the specific method to classify and allocate costs to set class
rates into a multi-part, time-differentiated structure are not revenue requirements, particularly if customers with DG can be
politically acceptable. Initially a rate for net metering customers separated into a standby alone class. There are two main methods
may need to be set as revenue neutral to the otherwise applicable to allocate costs to customer classes. One is based on embedded
tariff. Hourly and sub-hourly load data from net metering costs, also referred to as “average cost” approach. The other
customers facilitated by smart meters or advanced metering approach is based on class marginal cost of service. These days,
infrastructure (AMI) will inform the cost to be allocated to the net many utilities use embedded costs to allocate revenue requirement
metering class. AMI data can improve load forecasting dramati- to customer classes, as well as to set rate levels. Other utilities use
cally, since there is no need to extrapolate results from a sample of embededd cost studies to set class revenue targets but rely on
load research profiles. As discussed, currently intermittent DG may marginal cost analysis to set the actual tariff design. Setting
not provide substantial system wide or local reliability benefits to bundled standard tariffs or network charges with volumetric
the system, but to the extent that DG customers are placed in a charges that reflect marginal costs by time of day can be done even
separate cost-reflective rate and collectively begin to change usage if class revenue targets are established based on an embedded cost
patterns in a way that reduces going-forward costs of the utility, allocation method. However, fully adhering to the goal of achieving
the residential DG class should see a corresponding reduction in its an efficient size of network system requires setting revenue targets
revenue target. That reduction should ideally match the expected as a function of classes’ marginal cost contributions relative to total
avoided costs over the period the rates are going to be in effect. This marginal cost of service. At the very least, elements of marginal
requires that network planners become adept at accounting for costs should be used in embedded cost allocation studies.
forward-looking DG and DER system impacts in general.18 A marginal cost study generally allows more granularity at the
Otherwise, a reduction in the peak demand-related cost allocator time of assessing forward-looking costs of service. For example,
for net metering customers would merely lead to a cost shift to embedded cost studies rarely differentiate local connection costs
other customer classes in the cost of service study. Likewise, versus upstream distribution costs. All distribution costs may
additional costs imposed by DG may be better tracked through a treated as being driven by system wide non-coincident demands.
separate net metering class. For generation costs, embedded cost of service studies also exhibit
The specific connection policy also matters. If the connection or limited granularity, with little time differentiation. A number of
line extension policy is not properly designed, placing DG studies classify the bulk of fixed costs of existing power plants as
customers in a separate rate class would be required to mitigate peak demand-related, even though mid and base-load power
subsidies to high interconnection costs. Rates do not need to plants were built mostly to provide energy cost savings. This
socialize any higher connection costs associated with the bi- approach favors high-load factor customers. In contrast, a marginal
directional electricity flow of DG customers when customers are cost analysis is a bottom-up approach that uses classes’ hourly load
asked to pay for any needed reinforcement costs in an up-front profiles, relies on hourly marginal unit cost data for both energy
connection fee or customer-specific separate monthly fee. and capacity related costs, thus taking into account class usage in a
broader range of hours when defining classes’ cost-responsibility.
3.2. Test year When marginal costs are used to set each class revenue
requirement, each class’ marginal cost revenue (the revenue that
A critical input to pricing is the allocation of the overall revenue would be obtained from setting all rate components equal to
requirement to the various rate categories and customer classes. marginal cost) is adjusted as necessary to create a set of tariffs that
Recognizing the impact of DG customers on utility costs going- will yield the total allowed revenue requirement. A marginal-cost
forward may require revisiting the traditional cost of service based revenue requirement allocation seeks to assign costs to
approaches. There is often no detailed examination on the methods classes in a manner that takes into account not only cost causation
to allocate cost of infrastructure and social public policies to but also customer response to price changes, to minimize
customer classes, even though they are the premise to establish the efficiency distortions that result from setting prices different from
level of non-bypassable costs. At a minimum, determining a tariff marginal costs.19 Using this approach, average rates for each

18 19
Utility load forecasts generally rely on historical trends, and to that extent they This process steems from the inverse price elasticity rule formulated by Ramsey
implicitly capture the ongoing impact of DG, but not sufficiently the impact of future pricing, which guides the appropriate relative difference between rates and
DG. marginal costs.
38 A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41

customer class are marked up (or down) with respect to marginal charges (either upfront or ongoing) may be combined with
costs in inverse proportion to the customer group’s elasticity of traditional net metering or with a fixed payment for excess solar
demand, e.g., how likely they are to react to price changes by generation. Regulators may also adopt a buy-sell arrangement that
relocating, switching to an alternative energy source, installing relies on social avoided cost compensation. There is substantial
self-generation, or acquiring more efficient electricity appliances. controversy about emerging proposals as to what costs are avoided
In practice, many states that rely on marginal costs for cost and what is the amount of net unrecovered cost that should be
allocation use an implicit assumption that each customer class has shifted back to net metering customers.
the same price elasticity and adjust each class’ marginal cost
revenues proportionally (a method known as equi-proportional 4.1. Solar access charges
marginal cost, or EPMC) to close the gap between marginal cost
revenues and total revenue requirement. Improvements to this One of the proposed mechanisms to recover the “non-
method can be made by applying different adjustments depending bypassable” costs involves preserving net metering but ensuring
on the potential for self-generation in particular customer classes. that DG customers pays the same amount for all the energy that
This is relevant in the context of DG, since customers who adopt they would have used before the installation of solar panels, except
solar panels are generally showing higher price elasticity than for the avoided costs directly achieved by the utility. The access
those who do not. charge aims to recover the “excessive compensation” the customer
receives through net metering for both reduced usage and
3.4. Environmental cost analysis exported energy. Thus the DG customer continues to pay the
normal residential rate for purchases from the utility, under a net
While there is little doubt that solar and wind DG resources metering arrangement, but also pays a solar access charge which
have a positive impact as clean energy resources, their environ- may be defined as a per-kWh surcharge, as a specific solar demand
mental benefits may not be inherently quantifiable in a traditional charge, or as a charge per kW of the involved solar system
cost-of-service study, since they do not represent a direct benefit nameplate capacity. The access charges proposed to date generally
or cost saving to the utility or load-serving entity. An environmen- assume that the utility will continue to procure the same amount
tal cost component may be implicitly captured in the marginal of generation and transmission capacity to serve that customer,
energy cost analysis, in hours when fossil fuel units that have and plan for the same amount of distribution capacity as if the solar
internalized the cost of complying with state or federally panels had not been installed; in other words, it reflects the
established CO2 emission reductions are dispatched at the margin. amount of “fixed costs” attributable to the average solar customer,
Market energy prices will fail to reflect the cost of negative effectively charging back the customer for the portion of fixed
externalities associated with conventional carbon-based genera- transmission and distribution costs, and social policy-related non-
tion resources in the absence of a CO2 cap-and trade program.20 In bypassable costs embedded in the kWh rate that would have been
that case, the only direct quantifiable environmental benefit of collected if there had been no on-site generation.
renewable-based DG exports to the grid is the market value of the Distribution grid access charges implemented this way are
renewable energy certificates (RECs), to the extent that the utility equivalent to adopting a fixed charge, assessed exclusively to net
can use the renewable energy received from the DG facility metering customers. Because the grid access charge is designed to
towards its renewable portfolio standard (RPS) requirement.21 avoid impacting the customer’s otherwise applicable tariff, only
Alternatively, the customer may be able to retain the REC, costs directly avoided by the utility are used in its calculation.
obtaining a supplemental source of funding for DG. The market Generally, the solar access charge acknowledges estimated
value of RECs may be low in states with significantly more REC- benefits (avoided costs) associated with the customer’s solar
producing resources than needed to meet the prevailing RPS. Any system output such as reduction in energy and losses. The actual
additional environmental value attributable to low-carbon DG that implementation details vary widely among the proposals put
is not currently internalized by market prices can only be forward to date. The decision to establish a cost recovery
estimated as a shadow price. Subsidies to renewable DG deemed mechanism through an ‘ad-hoc’ grid access charge is fundamen-
necessary on account on its environmental value are best provided tally different from a rate restructuring exercise, one that sets up
through a transparent mechanism outside of the standard tariff the base rate components equal to marginal costs. To estimate a
setting, such as via utility-run auctions targeting specific amounts grid access charge, the analyst generally looks at an average or
of renewable DG, so as to avoid excessive cross-subsidies. typical customer. The charge is based on the assumed solar
generation profile and a pre-defined assumption on the amount of
4. Alternatives to standard retail rate restructuring energy consumption offset by the solar output and exported to the
grid. Thus, the grid access charge may not be completely equitable,
Regulators may reject any sort of marginal cost-based demand since it is not based on each customer’s maximum demand or
charge or mandatory time-differentiation, at least until a general actual net energy volumes. Also, because the grid access charge is
rate case may take place, or due to policy, legislative, or technical set as a residual amount to recover the non-bypassable costs, the
constraints. In the meantime, other approaches may be used to customer does not face any price signal about the value of a
attempt to mitigate cross-subsidy concerns under net metering, permanent reduction in peak demand.
particularly with regard to small-scale solar PV. Ad-hoc grid access
4.2. Avoided cost-based compensation for export energy

20 If neither the required rate structure reform, nor moving


A cap-and-trade program offers opportunities for the most cost-effective
emissions reductions, if well designed. States may be a part of a cap-and-trade customers to a separate, net metering class is possible, a second
program aimed at pricing emissions, such as the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative best solution to reducing cross-subsidization to DG customers is to
(RGGI). eliminate net metering of exports and compensate excess
21
Utilities and other load-serving entities may satisfy RPS through the purchase of generation at avoided costs. The avoided-cost compensation can
third-party RECs of by procuring renewable electricity, typically at a premium over
conventional generation contracts. REC is a tradable certificate. One REC is issued
be set to reflect the time-differentiated utility’s opportunity cost,
for every 1 MWh of electricity placed on the grid and its value represents all the i.e., the expected avoided incremental energy costs adjusted by
clean energy benefits of energy generated from a renewable facility. losses, plus a component of avoided capacity costs if the solar
A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41 39

generation is paired with storage and helps offset coincident peak Moving away from full net metering and towards avoided-cost
load. The avoided unit cost may also in principle, be designed to based payments for solar energy exports is a step in the right
include an environmental avoided cost, such as the REC value. In direction and it is preferable than continuing the practice of net
cases where the distributed solar generation does not directly metering under sub-optimal rate structures. However, ideally the
qualify as an RPS resource, the export payment may still include a export price should be time-differentiated, and locational, in order
small green energy premium, to reflect the fact that the solar to ensure a fair compensation. In addition, enforcing ad hoc
generation exported to the grid offsets loads of other utility surcharges to recover an estimated average of non-bypassable
customers and hence lowers the overall retail load that needs to be costs may be problematic because it often does not involve a
served from utility-scale contracted generation resources. In some transparent and easily replicable computation and because again,
jurisdictions, utilities already provide avoided cost payments to the surcharge calculation is a function of the level of the kWh retail
commercial or industrial customers for their excess generation, charge and a predetermined assumption on the monthly energy
and they are generally limited to avoided loss-adjusted energy displaced by an average solar system, thus it is less efficient than
marginal costs. Using an export avoided-cost approach does not adopting full 'gross metering' and simply letting the customer
fully remove the cost-shifting to non-solar customers, since the receive an avoided-cost based credit for all of its solar output.
solar customer would continue benefiting from large bill savings
for the share of on-site electricity usage that is offset by self- 4.3. Value of solar, or ‘sell all, buy all’ approach
generation at a rate that exceeds the value of load reductions.
Attempts to remove net metering have taken place in California A number of states, particularly where the retail residential per-
and other states. In August 2015, the three California investor- kWh rate does not stimulate as much solar DG as compared to
owned utilities (IOUs) proposed eliminating net metering and states with higher rates, have adopted or are considering adopting
adopting a system of compensation of solar excess generation at a value of solar (VOS) rate, or sell-all, buy-all payment format.
the utility’s levelized avoided costs. The proposals differed by Under such arrangements, the compensation for DG output is
utility but they would all significantly reduce the profitability of decoupled entirely from the energy tariff. A DG customer pays the
the customer-sited solar systems, compared to their value under standard retail rate for all of its energy requirements (regardless of
existing net-metering practice. For example, Southern California whether they are met with imports from the grid or from the
Edison (SCE) proposed an export rate of $0.08/kWh, based on customer on-site generation) and sells all energy generated by the
avoided energy cost plus a $0.01 per-kWh REC premium,, along solar panel (i.e., not just the excess energy) to the utility, at a price
with a monthly grid access charge of $3 per kW of nameplate that represents the “social” avoided cost associated with that
capacity of the solar system that would recover the estimated non- generation. In essence, a VOS rate is equivalent to compensating for
avoided transmission, distribution, and social costs associated with export generation at avoided cost, along with a non-bypassable
the energy displaced by the output of a typical residential PV grid access charge, but including avoided environmental exter-
system.22 In January 2016, the California Public Utilities Commis- nalities in addition to the direct financial benefits to the utility. The
sion (CPUC) issued a decision that preserved net energy metering VOS rate is generally a flat, non-time-differentiated value, and set
and determined the parameters of a successor net energy metering higher than the average retail per-kWh rate.
rate (NEM 2.0) for all three IOUs, subject to further review in 2019. VOS agreements can emulate a long-term contract by
CPUC also ordered that net metering customers with systems less guaranteeing a levelized price for the entire output of the solar
than 1 MW in size will be charged a one time interconnection fee, panel throughout its useful life, if the payment is fixed throughout
based on the utility company’s actual costs but excluding a guaranteed period of 20–25 years, thus providing high
distribution upgrades, and non-bypassable charges ranging predictability of investment returns, or can be designed so that
between 3 and 2 cents per kWh to cover the cost of social the payment is updated annually or every few years. Austin Energy
programs such as low-income and energy efficiency subsidies, for in Texas pioneered the adoption of a VOS rate in 2012. Its levelized
all their metered imports from the grid, before netting for exports. value is recalculated annually, so as to reflect current utility costs
Finally, the CPUC decided that all residential customers will be and prevent overpayments when system costs fall. Effective Jan. 1,
moved to a mandatory TOU rate by 2019.23 NEM 2.0 customers will 2016, the VOS rate is 10.9 cents per kWh. A similar method was
have their accounts grandfathered on this successor tariff for 20 approved as optional for utilities in Minnesota, with the difference
years. By contrast, within approximately the same time frame, the that the VOS rate is fixed for 20 years once the customer registers
Nevada Public Service Commission approved the end of net for the rate. VOS is also under consideration in Maine and at several
metering in the state, moving all NV Energy's DG customers to a other jurisdictions.
separate rate with increased fixed charges and lower kWh charges The VOS gross-metering approach aims to ensure that the
effective in January 2016.24 Instead of net metering, solar utility recovers the full cost of serving the solar customer, including
customers in Nevada will be compensated at the estimated the costs of social programs that may have been allocated to the
avoided wholesale energy cost of roughly 2.6 cents per kWh for the rate class the customer belongs to. This is in principle, analogous to
excess solar power delivered to the grid, i.e., assuming no reliability the idea of paying demand response participants the market price,
or environmental value is provided by solar exports. or LMP, less the generation component of the rate. Just like the grid
access charge notion, the VOS rate intends to make customers pay
for the non-avoided share of generation capacity, transmission,
22
This grid access charge was estimated assuming non-avoidable costs were equal and distribution costs embedded in the retail rate, but using the
to 10.8 cents per kWh of energy offset by the customer solar system, assuming a actual customer usage, as opposed to the class average, to
typical solar panel system size of 6 kW.
23 determine the appropriate recovery of non-bypassable costs. Since
Before the Public Utilities Commission of the State of California, “Decision
Adopting Successor to the Net Energy Metering Tariff”. Decision 16-01-044, January the VOS is generally set higher than the retail rate the customer
28, 2016. Rulemaking 14-07-002. receives a positive value for the energy consumed on-site. A VOS
24
The fixed charge for new solar customes will increase from $12.75 per month to rate ensures that the customer benefits by exactly the value of
$17.90 a month in 2016, then will increase by $5.15/month each year until it reaches estimated avoided or marginal costs, in addition to any expected
$38.51 a month in 2020. The rate that solar customers will pay for grid-supplied
power effectively in January 2016 declines slightly from 10.8 cents per kWh in 2016
environmental benefit. In that sense, it seeks to mimic the
to 9.9 cents for Southern Nevada. Before the Public Utilities Commission of Nevada, efficiency properties of compensation that solar customers would
Modified Order February 12, 2016. Dockets No. 15-0741 and 15-0742. receive with rates that were set based on marginal costs plus an
40 A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41

adder for externalities under net metering. However, the lack of namely at peak hours, thereby transforming the way the
time-differentiation in VOS rate approaches to date means that distribution grid is planned. In New York, under the PSC’s initiative
solar customers are compensated on the basis of an average solar “Reforming the Energy Vision” (REV), the distribution utility will
generation profile and so are not entirely equitable. A VOS rate is assume the role of “Distribution System Platform” (DSP), promot-
also a second best solution to the extent that it does not correct for ing and coordinating interconnection of DERsthat may provide a
the cross-subsidies that occur among customers within a class wide array of services to the grid.
when local distribution facilities costs are recovered in per-kWh Batteries are beginning to be a cost-effective option for large
charges. commercial and industrial customers, and it is conceivable that as
The VOS components in the proposals seen or approved to date rates are structured to reflect the higher costs of service in peak
include long-term estimated cost savings in energy, some savings hours and the cost of batteries keeps declining, smaller customers
in generation capacity, transmission and distribution losses, plus will also eventually find that battery systems are cost effective.26
other potential benefits from renewable energy development. The Energy storage will particularly play a key role in the development
range varies with Maine having estimated the highest VOS to date, of renewable-based microgrids, a single controllable entity serving
at 33 cents per kWh, about two times the retail per-kWh rate level. one or multiple customers within a community embedded within
The main controversy with the VOS approach is the size of the the distribution system. Smart microgrids can deploy, in addition
environmental adder. The environmental value may be limited to to co-generation, renewable generation, thermal and electric
the avoided cost to the utility to comply with environmental storage, and advance controls that allow the system to automati-
regulations such as meeting the state RPS or the federal Clean cally disconnect from the grid and work in “islanding” mode during
Power Plan (CPP) requirements, or buying pollution emission planned or unplanned outages. Customers in a microgrid can
credits. In some cases, such as in Minnesota, the approved adjust their internal usage during normal grid conditions and sell
methodology also includes the value of additional externalities excess power to the grid when it is economic to do so, provided
created by solar such as local job creation, and avoided future that the right price signals are in place, thus adding resilience value
adverse climate change effects such as flooding.25 The use of to the grid. Even outside of a microgrid or solar community,
environmental externality values is common in benefit-cost advanced technology such as smart inverters with communication
analyses of energy efficiency and demand-side-management capabilities will allow individual DG to be a resource to the utility
(DSM) programs in integrated resource planning. They have not to maintain grid reliability as load grows, by making the
been used explicitly as part of an actual retail pricing mechanism, distributed generation available to the macrogrid to maintain
other than implicitly in “feed-in tariffs” that provide a rate of system stability or avoid curtailments. They may be directly
return high enough to attract investment in an infant industry. A dispatched by the utility or respond as expected to relieve local
VOS payment structure is still a cross-subsidy to the extent that the overloading in the distribution circuit, and may potentially do so at
externality values exceed the current utility avoided compliance a lower cost than the utility. Network prices or standby tariffs
costs, and the gap must be met by rate revenues from non-solar applicable to microgrids should be set so that the microgrid
customers. Despite its limitations, VOS compensation is neverthe- continues to pay for the use of the distribution facilities while
less a more transparent method to provide a subsidy to clean connected to the grid, to the extent that they need supplementary
energy resources than net metering, and can potentially improve energy from the grid or if they need extra transformer capacity to
with more granularity in the VOS price-setting methodology, for sell excess power.
example by distinguishing between regular solar customers and
customers with behind the meter storage. 5.2. The value of ‘D’

5. DG as a ‘non-wires’ alternative As part of this process, a strong interest has been placed in
quantifying the “distribution value” to the utility, for purposes of
5.1. The role of energy storage compensating DER resources for distribution grid services.
Providing distribution services and receiving a fair compensation
The concept of distributed energy resources that may serve as for it, in addition to any market-based revenue that they may
“non-wires” alternatives and thus partially or fully defer network receive through aggregation bids in wholesale energy and capacity
investment is gaining traction as a regulatory policy goal. The markets, may help behind-the-meter storage or microgrids be
regulator should provide opportunities for customers who may financially viable. In the past, any attempts to adopt locational
adopt storage technologies paired with their DG facility, or who tariffs have been rejected by regulators on the grounds that it
engage in automated demand response, to participate in the utility would be inequitable. The administrative burden of having
transmission and/or distribution planning process as local “non- separate rates for multiple distribution locations is likely another
wires” alternatives, i.e., in lieu of new capacity.26 This may be factor. If the unbundled distribution component in rates is based
achieved through the right combination of rate design and on a system wide average, the signal may be too low to serve as an
incentive regulatory approaches. California, New York, and other incentive for DG locational decisions. System-wide marginal cost
states are paying particular attention to both grid-connected and estimates are useful for pricing purposes when most areas of the
behind-the-meter energy storage. Distributed energy storage will system have similar reserve margins but are less likely to induce
add flexibility to the distribution grid, enabling DG customers to the right response from DERs when load growth or expansion has
store part or all of the energy generated in excess of their own been uneven across the various distribution service areas. To a
needs for their own use or for exports to the grid at a later time, large extent, a detailed marginal cost analysis by substation area
can help with this exercise. The value of DG, storage or a microgrid
is in part dependent on the current and expected level of capacity
margins in a given distribution feeder or substation. The
25
The VOS rate approved in Minnesota includes about 3 cents/kWh as an computational method should be granular enough to identify
environmental adder, based on the federal social cost of carbon ($37 per metric ton) where expansion of distribution stations or lines is needed to meet
developed by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).
26
Currently, homeowners are unlikely to save money by shifting their power
expected load growth and the level of investment, as an annualized
consumption from the grid to a battery-backed PV system, particularly one large cost per kilowatt, that local DERs can provide when offsetting the
enough to make going off-grid feasible. specific area's peak load Even if LMPs were defined at the
A. Nieto / The Electricity Journal 29 (2016) 31–41 41

distribution node level, meaning that distribution losses and committed response and availability, which is a function of the
congestion were captured by distribution nodal prices, their role deployed control systems. In the case of microgrids, the utility may
would be limited as a locational incentive to foster development of negotiate dispatchability and other operating arrangements
microgrids. The congestion costs between nodes embedded in through short-term or long-term service agreements, ideally after
those nodal prices would not necessarily or distribution planner a competitive solicitation process that spurs efficient competition
fully signal when it is efficient to invest and how much. This is between a range of non-wires alternatives and investments by
because reliability failures come at too high a cost, and the utility distribution facilities. The microgrid may receive a partial
will likely step in before the congestion costs around a distribution distribution credit if using a control mechanism that ensures no
load pocket or the risk of curtailment is high enough to incentivize more than an agreed-upon amount of energy is taken from the grid
non-wires alternatives. at critical times, effectively agreeing to reducing the standby
Initially, meeting the regulatory task of encouraging optimal service needs. or receive a direct avoided capacity cost payment if it
location of DER in the right places solely through geographically can send energy to the distribution grid in hours where the
differentiated distribution rates will be challenging. Among the transmission system has experienced an outage. Location-specific
potential obstacles are: reliability-based rebates can be provided up front, tied to expected
contribution to capacity cost savings over the next cycle of
 Distribution marginal cost estimates are typically not estimated investment. Alternatively, payments can be provided upon verified
by sub-areas of service or feeder due to the lack of detailed local load relief.
hourly substation load data. A DER in a particular area may have a
significant distribution value at a time when no other system 6. Conclusion
wide benefits are created because local distribution networks
peak at times different from the rest of the state or region where Regulators and utilities have an opportunity to promote clean
they operate.Eventually detailed data on reserve margins by small-scale distributed resources in a way that serves environ-
feeder will become available, but load forecasting at the feeder mental goals without unduly burdening non-participant custom-
level may be challenging in the initial stages. ers. Getting the right rate structure in place and improving cost
 A key element to determine proper signals in distribution rates allocation methods as the market gets ready to embrace DG will be
has to do with the actual cost study relied upon to set locational critical in ensuring that outcome. In determining a rate reform, the
rates; the cost basis used for the rate may not reflect short-term, goal should not be to pick winners and losers, but rather to adopt a
but rather a longer-term marginal cost that averages several time-of-use, marginal cost-based rate design that gives appropri-
cycles of build and then growth into the new capacity. ate and equitable price signals. Lacking the ability to optimize all
retail residential and commercial rates, a separate, cost-reflective
Even if the DG facility has adopted storage and is optimally sited rate specifically designed for solar customers may be required to
to relieve capacity constraints in specific areas of the system, the preserve best practice ratemaking goals under net metering. An
utilities might act conservatively and be reluctant to account for it alternative is to provide an avoided cost payment to compensate
in its capacity expansion plan, in order to preserve reliability, at DG customers for excess generation. This second-best approach
least until experience demonstrates the minimum amount of allows for value-based compensation but only partially mitigates
equivalent "wires service" that the DER provides under several cost shifting if the base rate structures remain suboptimal. The
contingency scenarios. Thus, in the near term, a certain amount of same principles that govern decisions on retail rates and net
redundancy in grid investments will prevail. Specific payments or metering can in principle be applied to reforms of standby rates for
rebates in exchange for grid-provided services may be necessary to larger DG, or microgrids, as well as any pricing mechanisms
provide effective incentives to DG with behind-the-meter storage intended to compensate for services provided by DER to the
capabilities, or microgrids, if standard distribution rates fail to system. Additional compensation for the positive environmental
effectively signal locational differences in costs. A contract or attributes of renewable-based DG not accounted for in market
locational rebate system with penalty enforcement mechanisms prices for energy or RECs is better handled outside of the standard
may do the job of signaling the incremental value of load reduction retail tariff system, via well designed buy-all, sell-all agreements or
in the specific area of constraint and at stimulating the use of DER feed-in tariffs. Finally, undertaking updates to cost of service
as non-wires alternatives. studies as more DG customers are added to the grid will be key in
Detailed estimates of near-term locational avoided costs, ensuring that any incremental benefits from distributed resources
including deferred investment or reduced cost of ancillary services, are captured appropriately in class revenue targets. This will be
such as reactive power resources, voltage control and other, over particularly important as customers begin to adopt behind-the-
the upcoming distribution planning cycle should be made meter storage or join smart microgrids, ultimately enabling them
transparent to all customers, to allow higher predictability of to serve as “non-wires” alternatives.
the value of D. Such cost estimates may serve to establish a cap
price for DER solicitations, or as a starting point to negotiate the Amparo Nieto is a Vice President with NERA Economic Consulting, is an economist
specializing in the electricity industry with over 20 years of experience advising
terms of contracts with DER owners that commit to serve as non- utilities, regulators and system operators on wholesale energy and capacity market
wires alternatives. The ability of a specific DER to maximize design, electricity network pricing, regulatory rate reviews, and cost modeling.
avoided costs to the utility will depend on dispatchability levels, or

You might also like