You are on page 1of 10

American Economic Association

Price Expectations and the Phillips Curve


Author(s): Robert E. Lucas, Jr. and Leonard A. Rapping
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 3 (Jun., 1969), pp. 342-350
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1808963 .
Accessed: 01/12/2013 15:17

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Price Expectations and the
Phillips Curve
By ROBERT E. LUCAS, JR. AND LEONARD A. RAPPING*

Until recently, there have been two main approaches,as implemenitedempiricallyby


approaches to the rationalization of the these and other authors,imply a permanent
observed negative correlationbetween the and rather discouraging tradeoff between
unemployment rate and the rate of infla- inflation and unemployment. The results
tion (the Phillips curve)'. Phillips [19] and have led to two important policy conclu-
Lipsey [8] postulated a competitive adjust- sions: first, that sustained inflation is both
ment mechanism,where the rate of change necessary and sufficient to the sustained
in money wages is negatively related to maintenance of low unemployment rates;
excess supply in the labor market, with the and, second, that policies (like wage-price
latter quantity measuredby the unemploy- guideposts) which may shift the Phillips
ment rate. A second view, expressed by curve, are an important ingredient of na-
Eckstein and WVilson[3] and Perry [17] tional economicpolicy.
emphasizes a collective bargaining mecha- Recently, several authors have sought to
nism with unemployment rates and other elaborate different theories underlying the
variables(like profitrates) measuringunion Phillips curve, emphasizingthe role of ex-
bargainingpower over (or employer resis- pectations in labor markets either in addi-
tance to) increasesin money wages.2Both tion to, or in place of, the bargainingmecha-
* The authors are associate professors at Carnegie- nisms referredto above.3These approaches,
Mellon University. They wish to thank T. W. McGuire while differing considerably in detail, all
and E. Phelps who commented on an earlier draft of suggest that the inflation-unemployment
this paper. trade-offis a short run phenomenon,or that
' Throughout this paper the term Phillips curve is
used interchangeably to refer either to a price change- sustained inflation will make no contribu-
unemployment relationship or to a money wage change- tion to the permanent lowering of unem-
unemployment relationship. ployment rates. In view of the policy impli-
2 These remarks are not intended to suggest that the
references cited contain a well articulated theory of cations drawnfrom the originalapproaches,
wage-employment determination in an economy domi- as sketched above, it is clearly crucial to
nated by collective bargaining. We have been unable to attempt to discriminateempiricallybetween
find such a theory anywhere in the literature. We have,
however, attempted to construct a rationalization of what may be called the "bargainingmech-
the Phillips curve along these lines ourselves-an at- anism approach" and the "expectations
tempt which ran into two difficulties we found insur- approach"to a theory of the Phillips curve.
mountable. First, why should "money illusion" char-
acterize the outcome of collective bargaining if the The objective of this paper is to review a
individuals and employers involved are free of it? Sec- particularversion of the "expectations ap-
ond, even if one had an adequate theory of wage deter- proach" (our own), to test this version on
mination in a single, unionized sector, what implica-
tions will this theory have for aggregate wage and em- either ambiguous or irrelevant to absol-utewage determi-
ployment determination? (This later point is developed nation. For an application of a bargaining based
more fully in [91.) In part, the union impact on aggre- Phillips curve to the entire economy (as opposed to the
gate wages depends on the wage interconnections be- manufacturing sector studied in [31,and [18]) see Tella
tween the unionized sector and the rest of the economy. and Tinsley [21].
In several recent studies, McGuire and Rapping, [11], 3 We have in mind our own previous study, [91, as
[12], [13], [14] argue that most of the evidence on well as Phelps [181, Friedman [4], Meltzer [10], and
"spillovers" from uinionized to nonunionized sectors is Mortenson [15].

342

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
LUCAS AND RAPPING: THE PHILLIPS CURVE 343

United States time series for 1904-65, and wtY wt*


to use this theory as a frameworkfor isolat- WtA S
ing short and long run unemployment-
inflation trade-offs.Theory, tests, and con-
clusions are given in sections I, II, and III
respectively.
-Short-run
~{w*hed fixed}
I. An ExpectationsTheoryof
the Phillips Curve wt/Mt
In an earlierstudy4we postulated an ag- FIGURE 1
gregate labor supply function of the form:
In (Nt/Mt) the 'interpretationof all or part of measured
unemployment as an excess supply in the
(1) = iB0+ 31 Iin(Wt/Wt*) + 12 In (wg*) usual sense is precluded. We sought, then,
- 13 in (Pt*/P9), an alternativehypothesis as to what people
mean when they answer"yes"to the Census
whereNt is total man-hourssupplied,Ms is
Bureauquestion: "Areyou actively seeking
population, wt is the current real wage
work?" We hypothesized that respondents
(Wi/Pt), and wt and P* are "permanent" to this question take it to mean: "Are you
or "normal"real wages and prices respec-
seeking work at your normal wage rate?"
tively. In [91,eq. (1) is generatedby a two-
Thus we assumed that the labor force as
periodFisheriananalysis of the household's
measured by the employment survey con-
labor-leisurechoice problem,which implies
sists of employed persons plus those who
that 9, and /3 are positive, while /2 may
are searchingfor work at what they regard
have either sign. Estimates reported in [91
as their normal wage rate (or, roughly
indicate that 12 is approximatelyzero, or
equivalently, in their normal occupation).
that the long run labor supply schedule is
To define unemployment (in our sense)
approximatelyvertical. On the other hand,
more precisely, we define the normal labor
it was found that labor supply is highly
supply, N*, to be the quantity which would
responsive to changes in Wt/Wt*, the ratio
be supplied when the actual wage rate, wt,
of currentto normal wages, and to the an-
equals the anticipated normal wage, w*l,
ticipatedinflationrate, In(Pt*/Pt). Thus the
and when actual prices, Pt, equal normal
short and long run behaviorof labor supply,
prices, P* . Under these conditions, (1)
as predictedby our theory and confirmedin
becomes:
our tests, is as inidicatedin Figure 1.1
Combiningthis supplymodelwith a labor (2) In ( */Mt) -A n + /3 lit til

demand function, and assuming that labor


markets are cleared each period, one has a + (82 - 31) ItnWt- l3 (P*t/P_)
complete aggregate labor market model Subtracting(1) from (2) gives:
(once the formation of w* and P* is de-
in = 3
scribed). Completingthe model in this way, (3) (vt/lNt) In} (7ot-1/wt)

'
4Since considerable space is devoted to explaining ()+ 3 (P .1/Pt).
equation (1) in our earlier paper [9], treatment here will
be sketchy. Because In (N*lNt)-(N*-N,)IN*, the
5 An anticipated rise in the price of future goods in- left side of (3) has the dimensionsof an un-
duces, among other effects, a substitution of current employment rate, but it will differfrom the
leisure for future goods consumption-hence a decrease
in current labor supply (other prices, including the measured unemploymenitrate, Ut, for two
nominal interest rate, remaining fixed). reasons. First, teenagers and women may

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
344 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

fail to report themselves as unemployed of (8) for 1904-65, and various subperiods,
and, secondly, N* is defined in terms of a are reported.
representative household and so does not As with the other empirical Phillips
allow for the frictional component of mea- curves, (8) implies a long run as well as a
sured unemployment. Since there is reason short run inflation-unemployment trade-off,
to think that the frictional and nonfric- with the consequent promise of a permanent
tional components of total unemployment decrease in unemployment if the economy
vary together, we assume that Ut and is willing to tolerate a sustained inflation.
In (N*/Nt) are linearly related: This long run trade-off is, however, built
inmo(8) in a transparent way by the expec-
(4) Ut = go + g lin (N*t/Nt), gO, gi > 0.
tations hypotheses (6) and (7). Thus the
Combinilng (3) and (4): reason (8) offers a long run trade-off lies in
the assumption of an unreasonable stub-
Ut = go + git3l in (wt-l/wt)
borness on the part of households: if a sus-
+ g913 III (P1/f-Pt). tained inflation policy is pursued by the
It remains only to link the unobserved, government, households following (7) will
normal wages and prices to observable, continue forever to underpredict future
actual values. In our original model we prices.
assumed that both normal variables are There is no entirely satisfactory way to
adaptively calculated by households from remedy this deficiency in the theory within
actual values, with the same reaction the framework of adaptive expectations.
parameterX, O<X < 1, or that: Any forecaster predicting future prices as a
fixed function, however complicated, of
(6) In (w*X) In
i (zet) + (1- X) In (w* 1), past prices can be systematically fooled by
and: a clever opponent manipulating the actual
series at will. But since there is little reason
(7) In (P*) X In (Pt) + (1- X) In (P* ) to believe that the government systemati-
Using standard methods to reduce the cally manipulates prices, it may be worth-
system of difference equations (5)-(7) to a while to examine adaptive schemes which,
single difference equation in Ut, we obtain :6 unlike (6) and (7), permit a short run
Phillips curve without deciding the ques-
t= Xgo - g3l In (wt/wt-i) tion of the existence of a long run curve a
(8) - gp33 In (Pt/Pt_1) priori.
Focusing on the anticipation of prices
+ (1-X) L.
rather than real wages, a natural generaliza-
The reader should note that when going tion of (7) is the hypothesis that ln(Pt*) is a
from (5) to (8) the coefficients of the wage "rational distributed lag function" of past
and price terms change sign because in (6) actual values,8 or that:
and (7) we assume an "elasticity of expec-
tations" less than unity (when current of the three variables wi, Pg and wtPg (money wages)
prices or real wages rise, suppliers anticipate implies knowledge of the rate of change of the third,
an eventual return to normalcy). Since (8) (8) can be rewritten in two other ways. In particular,
one may relate unemployment to money wage changes,
relates unemployment to the inflation rate as is more conventionally done.
(ceteris paribus) it is a Phillips curve in the 8 The term "rational distributed lag function" is

broad sense.7 In the next section, estimates from Jorgenson [6], where the word "rational" applies
to the form of the generating function of the distri-
6 See note 10. buted lag. Jorgenson shows that a distributed lag has a
I Since knowledge of the rates of chanige of any two rational generating function if and only if it can be ex-

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
LUCAS AND RAPPING: THE PHILLIPS CURVE 345

In (fPt*) = boIn (Pt) + b, In (Pt-1) ward sloping short run Phillips curve is
+ + br In (Ptr)
equivalent to the condition bo< 1 (an "elas-
ticity of expectations" less than unity).
+ a, In (Pe*l) + The slope of the long run Phillips curve is
- a, In (P*L). obtained by summing the coefficients co
As in (7), we impose the condition: + - * * +Ck and dividing by one minus the
sum of the lagged unemployment terms,
(10) bo + + b + a1 + * + a, el+ * * +em.
?
For k-=0, (11) implies that there will be
so that a proportional change in all past
a long run Phillips curve if and only if there
prices would imply a change in Pt* of the
is a short run Phillips curve, both cases
same proportion.9 \We assume as well that
occurring whenever cO< . For k> 1, how-
(9) is stable.
ever, it is entirely possible that co<0 and
Equations (5), (6) and (9) form a system
simultaneously cO+ ** +Ck=0, so that
of three linear difference equations in Ut,
the slope of the long run curve is zero.
ln(P*) and ln(w*) with forcing variables
In the next section, we report estimates
in(Pt) and ln(wt), which may, using the
of the coefficients of (11) for the case k= 2,
restriction (10), be reduced to a difference
n =1, m = 2-the values which, after some
equation in Ut of the form :10
experimenting, appeared to yield the
lt = a + co0 In (Pt) + "best" results.11 Using this case as a
+ CkA Itn (Pt-k) -+ (oA Iin(Wt) maintained hypothesis, we also test the
hypotheses Co+Cl+C2=0 and do+d,= 0.
(11) + +
+d,S in (wt1n) In the testing and estimation, we assume
+ e1t7t_1 + * * - + emUt-m, that (11) is disturbed by an error term
Et, where {Et } is a sequence of independent
where Axt=xt-x_j1. The coefficient co of
identically distributed random variables
the current inflation rate in (11) is equal to
with finite variance a2 and mean 0, inde-
gfl1(bo- 1) so that the existence of a down-
pendent of contemporaneous values of
pressed in the form (9), which he calls its "final form". wt and Pt. Under these conditions, and
This usage should not be confused with "rational ex- provided (11) is stable,'2 the estimated
pectations" as defined by Muth in f16]; the two con-
cepts are unrelated.
coefficients will be consistent and asympto-
T
The formulation (9) is sufficiently general to include tically normal, and certain Chi-square
the best known expectations hypotheses. For example, tests (described in detail below) will be
to obtain (7), let bo =X and a, = 1-X.For expectations of
inflation which are adaptive on the rates of change of
approximately valid.
prices (and hence extrapolative on price levels) set
bo= 1+X) bi = -1, and a, = IA, and other ai, bj equal to II. Empirical Results.
zero. (This example also shows that one would not
wish to impose the restriction bi>O on (9)). Any con-
In this section we report tests of (8) and
vex combination of regressive (as in (7)) and extrapola- (11), on data series covering the period
tive expectations can then be formed in an obvious way. 1900-65. For the years 1900-60, the un-
10This reduction is most easily carried out by re-
writing (5), (6) and (9) in terms of current (time t)
employment series used is from Leber-
values of the variables, using the lag operator E de- gott [7, p. 512] and for 1961-65, reported
fined by Ex,=xt-1. Then to obtain (11), one multiplies census data are used [1, p. 236]. The price
both sides of (5) by [1-a,E-. . .-a8E-] [l-(1-X)E] and
substitutes from (6) and (9) to eliminate terms involving
series is the Consumer Price Index taken
wt* and P9*. Then applying (10) to the resulting expres-
sion yields (11). The parameters k, n and m of (11) are 11In terms of the parameters of (9), this case corre-
found to be k=-nax(r,s)-1, n=s, and m=s+1. Simi- sponds to r =3 and s = 1.
larly, the constants c,, di, eq are determinable functions 12 The stability of (11) follows from the assumed sta-
of bo, ... , a .... a a,,x,gi,0i and S. bility of (6) and (9).

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
346 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
TABLE 1-ESTIMATES FOR MODEL BASED oN EQUATIONS (5), (6) AND (7).a

Variable
Time Constant Aln(Pg) Aln(wg) (Ut.1) R2(Adj) DWS
Period

1904-65 2.32 -25.28 -21.72 .822 .832 1.44


(.57)*** (5.82)*** (10.18)* (.054)***

1904-29 4.04 -10.84 -29.75 .322 .370 1.67


(.95)*** (6.84) (12.21)** (.176)

1930-45 2.50 -70.80 4.19 .818 .953 2.21


(1.40) (8.73)*** (22.45) (.063)***

1946-65 4.15 -13.80 - 4.51 .249 .180 1.73


(1.37)*** (10.23) (12.74) (.208)

1930-65 4.2 -59 -41 .80 .925 1.50


from [91 (I.0)*** (8)*** (24) (.05)***

* ) ~~~~~~.025
** one tail significanceat .01
*;** ~~~~~.005
a The unemployment rate is measured as a percentage while the Aln variables are on
the order of magnitude of .01. The effect of a one percentage point increase in the rate of
inflation on the percentage unemployment rate is found by dividing the estimated
Aln(Pt) coefficients by 100. For example, for the period 1904-29 the coefficient of Aln(Pj)
is -10.84 which is interpeted to mean that when the inflation rate goes from, say, 0 per-
cent to 1 percent, the unemployment rate falls initially by about .11 percentage points.

from [1, p. 262] and [20]. Hourly com- the results that it was fortunate that we
pensation was obtained by linking the tried it.
Lucas-Rapping [9] all economy hourly In Table 1 standard errors are given
money compensation series (1929-65) to below each coefficientestimate. Each set of
the Rees [20] series for manufacturing estimates indicates a (short and long run)
(1900-29). 13 Phillips curve with a quantitatively signi-
In Table 1 we report estimates of the ficant negative slope. Thus for example,
coefficients of (8) for the period 1904-65 leaving aside the question of statistical
(line 1), for three subperiods (lines 2-4) significance, the estimated inflation term
and roughly comparable estimates for for the period 1946-65 implies an initial
1930-65 from [9] (line 5).14 The division fall in the measuredunemployment rate of
of the period into three subperiods is about .14 percentagepoints per percentage
arbitrary. We wish to separate the post- point increasein the inflation rate. Under a
war years to obtain comparability with sustained inflation, the final impact on
the many Phillips curve studies done for unemployment is .18 per percentage point
this period. In view of the folklorereferring increase in the inflation rate [.1380/(1-
to 1929 as "the end of an era," it seemed .249)]. The real wage rate has a statisti-
another natural dividing point. Whatever cally significant effect in the predicted
the reasons for this subdivision, however, direction for the entire period and for the
we think the readerwill agree after seeing 1904-29 period, but not for the latter two
periods. There is an indication of serial
13 The data used in this paper are available upon re-
correlation in each regression.l"The Chi-
quest from the authors.
14 In [91, we measured price by the GNP deflator.
S5 We refer to the stated values of the Durbin-WVat-

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
LUCAS AND RAPPING: THE PHILLIPS CURVE 347

TABLE 2-ESTIMATES FOR MODEL BASED ON EQUATIONS (5), (6) AND (9).

R2
Constant Aln(Pt) Aln(Pt-1) Aln(Pt-2) Ahl(wt) Aln(wtt-1) Ut_1 Ut-2 (Adj) DWS
Period\

1904-65 1.15 -39.16 35.36 -17.38 -11.86 26.67 1.170 - .322 .876 2.01
(.63) (6.69)*** (8.19)*** (6.84)*** (9.19) (9.52)*** (.126)*** (.123)***

1904-29 2.12 -20.09 30.32 -12.61 -34.78 - 1.32 .680 .021 .532 1.91
(1.21) (8.11)** (9.07)*** (9.11) (13.52)*** (12.92) (.227)*** (.232)

1930-45 1.98 -96.87 5.97 -24.27 18.90 11.44 .423 .374 .966 1.87
(2.08) (15.49)*** (22.13) (13.04) (22.24) (21.50) (.277) (.286)

1946-65 5.55 -12.73 -13.20 7.00 - 15.05 -10.44 .247 - .147 - .05 1.94
(3.29) (17.29) (34.20) (15.48) (22.68) (30.39) (.305) (.275)

, } one tail significance at {?

square statistic for testing the stability significance tests on the added coefficients?
of the coefficients across the three sub- Second, are the instability and serial
periods takes the value 70.9, to be com- correlation which appear in the Table 1
pared to the .005 criticalvalue (8 degreesof estimates eliminated? Third, do the esti-
freedom) of 22.0.16 Hence the hypothesis mates succeed in reconciling a downward
that the coefficients are equal in all sub- sloping short run Phillips curve with a
periods is decisively rejected. flat long run curve.
In turning to estimates for the more The estimates for the entire period, and
complicated hypothesis (11) (with k=2, to a lesser extent for the subperiods, indi-
n= 1, m= 2) reported in Table 2, we have cate clearly that the additional lagged
in mind three sets of questions. First, is inflation rates, rates of wage change, and
the additional complexity justified by unemployment rates result in a significant
improvement."7 Further, serial correlation
appears to be absent from all regressions.
son statistic. Of course, the critical values tabulated by The instability across periods is, however,
these authors in [21do not apply to stochastic difference
equations as estimated here. still present as measured by the Chi-
16 Let SSu and DF be the residual sum of squares and square statistic 64.2, to be compared to
the degrees of freedom under the maintained hypothe- the .005 critical value (16 degrees of free-
sis, let SS,, be the residual sum of squares under the null
hypothesis, and let df be the number of independent dom) of 34.3. Thus, we must discuss the
restrictions imposed by the null hypothesis. The statis- results for each period separately, rather
tic used is (DF)(SS.-SSQ/SSj2) which converges in dis- than treat the first line of Table 2 as an
tribution to a Chi-square with df degrees of freedom as
DF goes to infinity. In the subperiods, DF is as low as accurate Phillips curve for the entire
8 in some of our tests, so caveat arbiter. period. (It is fortunate that we chose
As an alternative test statistic, we conisideredthe F- arbitrarily to split the data period since
statistic based on SSn and SS.. Since the estimated
equations are stochastic difference equations, the test there is no clue in the results on the first
is also at best approximately valid and the properties line of Table 2 that the regression over the
of the latter approximation, while perhaps superior to whole period is dangerously misleading.)
the one we used, are unknown. Similar considerations
led us to use unit normal, rather than Student's tables, 17 The significance of coefficients of added variables is

to judge the significance of the estimates reported in the criterion we have uised to select the "best" of the
Tables 1 and 2. various instances of (11).

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
348 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

In the two subperiods, 1904-29 and over the first subperiod 1904-29. In this
1930-45, indicated in Table 2 there is period, the first-period impact of an in-
evidence of a short run Phillips curve: the crease in the inflation rate is a decrease in
coefficient of Aln(Pt) in each regression is unemployment, but this initial effect is
negative and significantly different from counteracted in the second year with an
zero. On the other hand, for the period effect in the opposite direction. The third
1946-65 there is no statistical evidence of a period effect is again negative. Adding the
short run Phillips curve, but this regression price change coefficients over the three
does not improve on the comparable period terms yields a negative estimate in this
results reported in Table 1. To test for case, but this sum does not differ signifi-
the existence of a long run Phillips curve cantly from zero."8Similar remarks hold for
we consider three null hypotheses. First, the wage change coefficients over the first
the hypothesis that a sustained, con- two periods.
stant percentage rate of inflation has no The results for the second period, 1930-
long run effect on unemployment is seen, 45, indicate the presence of a long run
from (11), to require that the coefficients Phillips curve. But the results for the
of all price change variables (three in the 1946-65 period are strikingly different.
regressions reported in Table 2) add to For this period there is no evidence of a
zero: we refer to this hypothesis (in Table long run relationship, a not too surprising
3, below) as Ho. The hypothesis that the result in light of the fact that the individ-
coefficients of the lagged wage changes ual coefficients are all statistically insig-
sum to zero is termed H1. Finally, let H2 nificant in this period.
be the hypothesis that both Ho and H1 are
true. III. Conclusions
The objective of this paper has been to
TABLE 3-CHI-SQUARE TESTS articulate what we have called an expecta-
tions theory of the Phillips curve, and to
Hypothesis develop and test some of its implications.
Tested IH, H1 H2
Period Our primary emphasis has been on the
possibility, strongly suggested by our
1904-65 x2 8.360*** 1.159 9.566** theory, that the Phillips curve is a short
1904-29 x2 .095 3.051 3.819 run phenomenon, in the sense that a sus-
18 To estimate the slope of the long run Phillips curve,
1930-45 x2 23.497*** .702 24.627***
one divides the sum of the price change coefficients by
1946-65 x2 .587 .279 .942 one minus the sum of the lagged unemployment co-
efficients. This estimate can be large even in cases
01 significance where its numerator does not differ significantly from
** Rejected at
Hypothesis :ReJect
Null tIypothesls zero. Thus, for example, for the period 1904-29 this
**,, f .005 level.
estimate is - 7.96 which is smaller in absolute value
than the initial effect of -20.09 (Table 2). On the other
hand, for the periods 1930-45 and 1946-65 the long
Table 3 provides Chi-square statistics run point estimates are -567.34 and -21.03 respec-
for testing these hypothesis, for the entire tively. These estimates are larger than the initial in-
period and for each subperiod, within the flation impact as estimated by the leading inflation
term in Table 2. Of course, to the extent that the
version of (11) reported in Table 2. In view lagged unemployment rates reflect the impact of
of the instability of coefficients across forces other than lagged inflation rates, we may sub-
periods, only the subperiod results appear stantially overstate the long run effect of inflation on
unemployment rates. A discussion of this and other
to be of interest. Table 3 shows that there estimation problems in models such as ours can be found
is no evidence of a long run Phillips curve in Griliches[5].

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
LUCAS AND RAPPING: THE PHILLIPS CURVE 349

tained inflation will have a temporary but Squares Regression II," Biometrika,
not a long run effect on unemployment. As 1951, 38, 159-77.
reported in the last section, our results [3] ECKSTEIN,0. AND T. WILSON,"Deter-
show (1) that our particular expectations- mination of Money Wages in American
based Phillips curve is not stable over the Industry," Quart. Jour. Econ., Aug.
1962, 76, 379-414.
three (arbitrary) subperiods of the period
[4] FRIEDMAN, M., "The Role of Monetary
1904-65, (2) that a short run Phillips Policy," Am. Econ. Rev., March 1968,
curve exists in each subperiod, although 58, 1-17.
the relationship for the most recent period, [5] GRILICHES,Z., "Distributed Lags: A
1946-65, is less statistically obvious than Survey," Econometrica, Jan. 1967, 35,
for the earlier periods, and (3) that the 16-49.
hypothesis that there is no long run Phil- [6] JORGENSON, D. W., "Rational Dis-
lips curve is accepted for the periods tributed Lag Functions," Economnetrica,
1904-29 and 1946-65, but rejected for the Jan. 1966, 34, 135-149.
period 1930-45. [7) LEBERGOTT, S., Manpower in Economitic
What is to be concluded from these Growth: The American Record Since
tests? As reported econometric models go, 1800, New York, 1964.
[8] LIPSEY, R. G., "The Relationship Be-
ours can scarcely be called successful, but
tween Unemployment and the Rate of
we think its failures are suggestive along Change of Money Wage Rates in the
several lines. First, it is clear that the exis- U.K., 1862-1957," Economica, Feb.
tence of a short run Phillips curve is con- 1960, 27, 1-31.
sistent (in practice as well as in principle) [9] LUCAS, R. E., JR. AND L. A. RAPPING,
with the absence of a long run inflation- "Real Wages, Employment and Infla-
unemployment tradeoff. Second, the ex- tion," Jour. Pol. Econ. (forthcoming).
pectations view as we have developed it [10] MELTZER, A. H., "Is Secular Inflation
appears to have promise in the sense that Likely in the U.S.," Monetary Problems
the additional explanatory variables it of the Early 1960's: Review and Approval
suggests are frequently (though by no Atlanta, 1967.
[11] McGUIRE, T. W. AND L. A. RAPPING,
means uniformly) significant. Third, and
"The Role of Market Variables and
most important, statistical Phillips curves Key Bargains in the Manufacturing
are highly unstable over time, and this Wage Determination Process," Jour.
instability is far too serious to be dismissed Pol. Econ., Oct. 1968, 78, 1015-36.
by a vacuous reference to structural [12] , "The Determination of Money

change in either 1929 or 1946. Until the Wages in American Industry: Com-
variables which are shifting these curves ment," Quart. Jour. Econ., Nov. 1967,
can be identified, and verified as important 81, 684-90.
by testing over the entire period, we see no [13] , "The Supply of Labor and
alternative to the conclusion that empiri- Manufacturing Wage Determination in
cal Phillips curves (ours included) are a the United States: An Empirical Exam-
ination," International Econ. Rev. (forth
weak foundation on which to base policy
coming).
decisions. [14] , "Interindustry Wage Change
REFERENCES Dispersion and the 'Spillover' Hypothe-
[1] Council of Economic Advisors, Eco- sis," Am. Econ. Rev., June 1966, 61,
nomic Report of the President, January 493-501.
1967, Washington 1967. [15] MORTENSON,D. T. "A Theory of Wage
[2] DURBIN, J. AND G. S. WVATSON,"Test- and Employment Dynamics," in E.
ing for Serial Correlation in Least Phelps et. al., The New Microeconomics

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
350 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

in Employment and Inflation Theory: tween Unemployment and the Rate of


Price Wage and Employment Decisions, Change of Money Wage Rates in the
forthcoming. United Kingdom, 1861-1957," Econo-
[16] MUTH, J. F., "Rational Expectations mica, Nov. 1958, 25, 283-99.
and the Theory of Price Movements," [20] REES, A., "Patterns of Wages, Prices,
Econometrica, 1961, 29, 315-35. and Productivity," in C. Myers (ed.)
[17] PERRY, G., "The Determinants of Wage Wages, Prices, Profits and Productivity,
Rate Changes," Rev. Econ. Stud., Oct. New York 1959.
1964, 31, 287-308. [21] TELLA, A. J., AND P. A. TINSLEY, "The
[18] PHELPS, E. S., "Money Wage Dynamics Labor Market and Potential Output of
and Labor Market Equilibrium," Jour. the FRB-MIT Model: a Preliminary
Pol. Econ., Aug. 1968, 76, Part II, 687- Report," (paper presented at the Win-
711. ter, 1967 meeting of the Econometric
[19] PHILLIPS, A. W., "The Relation Be- Society).

This content downloaded from 198.105.44.150 on Sun, 1 Dec 2013 15:17:22 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like