You are on page 1of 68

Tax Avoidance vs.

Tax Aggressiveness:
A Unifying Conceptual Framework

Gerrit Lietz
University of Münster
gerrit.lietz@wiwi.uni-muenster.de

Working Paper
Current draft: 12/2013

Abstract

I develop a unifying conceptual framework of corporate tax planning. The framework accommodates con-
structs frequently studied in empirical tax accounting research, i.e. tax avoidance, tax aggressiveness, tax
sheltering, and tax evasion, by relating them to the seminal notion of effective tax planning presented in
Scholes and Wolfson [1992]. Most importantly, literature knows no universal approach to the constructs of
tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]). In search of a useful reference point
to delimit non-aggressive from aggressive tax avoidance, I put a particular focus on the more-likely-than-
not probability of a tax transaction being legally sustainable upon potential audit (Lisowsky, Robinson, and
Schmidt [2013]). I further provide an overview of commonly used and recently suggested empirical
measures of the underlying constructs and discuss their context-sensitive strengths and weaknesses. Finally,
I arrange the measures along the lines of the proposed conceptual framework in an attempt to provide guid-
ance as to which proxy most adequately reflects which conceptual construct. Although a demanding task,
the promotion of a sound theoretical understanding and careful empirical handling of the relevant tax con-
structs should enrich the discussion and foster consistent inferences.

Keywords: Tax avoidance; tax aggressiveness; corporate tax planning; conceptual framework.
JEL Classification: H20; H25; H26; M41

I thank Bradford Hepfer, Adrian Kubata, Sven Nolte, John Robinson, Tim Wagener, Christoph Watrin, Ryan Wilson, and
brown bag seminar participants at the Münster Institute of Accounting and Taxation for their comments and suggestions.

Electronic copy
Electronic copy available
available at:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828
1. Introduction

Empirical tax research in accounting knows no uniform definition of frequently investigated con-

structs, such as “tax avoidance” or “tax aggressiveness” (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010], Dunbar,

Higgins, Phillips, and Plesko [2010]). Some consider these terms to describe essentially the same con-

struct and hence use them interchangeably.1 However, others interpret “avoidance” to have a different

meaning than “aggressiveness”, and consequently prefer one expression over the other, sometimes

further depending on the specific research context (e.g., Balakrishnan, Blouin, and Guay [2012]). Be-

yond that, tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness are both related to tax sheltering, which itself is sub-

ject to extensive research and ongoing public debates (e.g. Weisbach [2002a], Wilson [2009],

Lisowsky et al. [2013], U.S. Department of Treasury [1999]). Finally, some may be able to clearly

distinguish between the constructs of tax sheltering and tax evasion, while yet others may perceive

sheltering and evasion to be rather similar in that they share a criminal or fraudulent connotation.

In this study, I develop and illustrate a conceptual framework that strives to promote a shared under-

standing about commonly investigated constructs of corporate tax planning. This framework is unify-

ing in putting constructs with a focus on explicit income tax reductions in perspective with the funda-

mental Scholes-Wolfson theme of global effective tax planning, which advocates the consideration of

“all parties”, “all taxes”, and “all costs” (Scholes and Wolfson [1992]).2 The goal is to comprehensive-

ly discuss and best possibly delimit the explicit tax planning constructs that continue to be investigated

in a large and growing body of empirical research (see Shackelford and Shevlin [2001], Hanlon and

Heitzman [2010], and Lietz [2013] for reviews). A thorough conceptual framework further provides a

basis for an orderly assessment of the various empirical proxies, which have been developed to opera-

tionalize the discussed constructs. In sum, an advanced conceptual understanding may provide oppor-

tunity for greater consistency in future research and improve inferences made from corporate data.

Given the plurality of possible perceptions of explicit tax planning constructs, a conceptual framework

must be capable of accommodating existing constructs, but also leave room to include perceptions that

1
E.g. Chen et al. [2010], Huseynov and Klamm [2012], or Katz et al. [2013]. Further, some may prefer to use
alternative terms such as “tax management” (e.g. Minnick and Noga [2010]) to describe essentially what is
more commonly referred to as general “tax avoidance” (as e.g. proposed in Dyreng et al. [2008] and Hanlon
and Heitzman [2010]).
2
The seminal textbook is currently available in its 4th edition, Scholes et al. [2009].

Electronic copy
Electronic copy available
available at:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828
may yet emerge in the future. A comprehensible classification of explicit tax planning manifestations

should also be accompanied by a clear use of terminology. However, simply “agreeing” on one single

term (e.g. just “tax avoidance” or just “tax aggressiveness”) for in fact a wide and diverse range of

explicit tax actions may not always proof useful. A simplified, yet no longer differentiated use of ter-

minology can complicate the study of related, but still different notions of explicit tax planning. Some-

times it appears rewarding to study constructs individually and/or in their own particular contexts in

order to reach flawless conclusions and consistent implications.

With a view to ongoing political debates circulating around noncompliant corporate tax behavior and a

growing public perception of corporate tax “unfairness”, it appears particularly advisable to raise con-

cerns about the undifferentiated use of tax planning terminology. Accusations of corporate tax misbe-

havior have gained momentum in the light of the recent financial crisis, tight economic budgets, close-

to-zero corporate effective tax rates, and the revelation of large-scale offshore tax haven use.3 Unfor-

tunately, public and political concerns with regards to corporate tax savings are often ambiguously

stated in that they do not clearly enough differentiate between potentially “unfavorable” tax avoidance,

particularly “aggressive” types of tax avoidance (e.g. the use of tax shelters?), and most likely criminal

forms of tax evasion. In order to promote a more target-oriented debate, especially with a view to the

general desire to improve the “fairness” – a construct which itself is already difficult to handle –4 of

the tax system, all involved parties may eventually benefit from a more careful handling of relevant

tax constructs. An imprecise use and recitation of different tax planning constructs can increase the

risk that opinion-forming institutions, and regulators themselves, mistakenly convey the impression

that any sort of tax planning directed at a relative reduction of explicit taxes (i.e. “avoidance”) is inevi-

tably illegal or has to have at least a connotation of moral doubt. While this might be true for some
3
On June 15, 2013, the international consortium of investigative journalists (ICIJ) published online its latest
version of an “offshore leaks database”, containing ownership information about companies established in
ten offshore jurisdictions including the British Virgin Islands, the Cook Islands and Singapore, covering
nearly 30 years up to 2010, see http://offshoreleaks.icij.org/. For an example of the (rather herculean) task of
estimating the amount of global wealth shifted offshore and the tax loss associated with offshore structuring,
see Henry [2012].
4
“Fairness, to most people, requires that equally situated taxpayers pay equal taxes (“horizontal equity”) and
that better-off taxpayers pay more tax (“vertical equity”). Although these objectives seem clear enough, fair-
ness is very much in the eye of the beholder. There is little agreement over how to judge whether two taxpay-
ers are equally situated.” (Minarik [2008], p. 489). Apart from (given) degrees of horizontal and vertical eq-
uity within an established tax system, “fairness” also means that all taxes owed are rigorously collected: "[…]
you have to collect the taxes that are owed. That is only fair to companies and people who play by the rules
and it's vital for developing economies too." (Mr. David Cameron, WSJ Europe, June 18, 2013).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


constructs, in particular tax evasion, which is conducted with a clear and criminal intent to defraud,

this might not be the case for others. Different tax constructs may vary considerably in terms of the

assumed legal sustainability and tax system favorability of underlying tax transactions. One should

objectively take into account that many observable tax avoidance schemes are not only legal according

to the letter of the law, but their use might oftentimes actually turn out to be socially desirable, once all

implicit consequences and nontax costs are fully incorporated.5

Surely, if relevant actors and institutions in charge would arrive at a more consistent understanding of

underlying constructs and terminology, more target-oriented reforms and correctives of unwanted tax

behavior could be accomplished. The standpoint assumed here is that an adequate approach to this

topic is to acknowledge that each of the more widely-cited tax constructs on their own have valid rea-

sons to be separately circumscribed and investigated. Thus, an important feature of the conceptual

framework proposed here is that the key constructs, namely corporate effective tax planning, tax

avoidance, tax aggressiveness, tax sheltering and tax evasion, all have individual features and thus

usually do not reflect the exact same set of tax-motivated activities. The conceptual constructs can to

some extent overlap but should not be understood as completely identical; not least to be justified in

their parallel existence. Terminology-wise it follows that related terms should not simply be used in-

terchangeably, but rather carefully taking into account the individual research setting and question.

As this study’s focus is on the conceptual constructs underlying empirical tax accounting research, a

consequential challenge is to discuss the choice of adequate empirical proxies that best possibly opera-

tionalize the investigated construct. Many empirical measures, mostly based on publicly available

financial statement data, have been developed in prior literature.6 In addition, research consistently

develops new or refined ways to approximate corporate tax behavior. Thus, building on the conceptual

discussion, the second part of this paper is devoted to the assessment of empirical measures of explicit

corporate tax planning. I finally arrange and discuss the major empirical measures along the dimen-

sions of the conceptual framework to suggest guidance which construct they likely capture. I conclude

with suggestions for consistent future research.

5
Tax systems are frequently designed to achieve social goals (e.g. encourage economic growth, finance public
projects, redistribute wealth and property) by granting tax-favored treatment to a number of business activi-
ties (e.g. R&D activities, agricultural production, foreign export activities, charitable and educational activi-
ties etc.); see Scholes et al. [2009] (p. 4).
6
See Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] for an earlier overview.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


2. Unifying Conceptual Framework of Corporate Tax Planning

Figure 1 illustrates the unifying conceptual framework of corporate tax planning. The relevant tax

constructs discussed in the following are depicted in the top half, namely tax planning in the Scholes-

Wolfson sense, tax avoidance, tax aggressiveness, tax sheltering, and tax evasion. Apart from the gen-

eral notion of effective tax planning, all constructs of explicit tax planning are further arranged along

the dimensions of legality and compliance. These dimensions represent the presumable degree of law-

fulness and perceived compliance of the tax actions likely captured by the individual tax constructs.

The legality dimension ranges from perfectly legal, over increasingly “grey-scaled”, to clearly illegal

with an intent to defraud. The dimension of compliance stretches from strict compliance, over poten-

tially tax system unfavorable noncompliance, to apparent noncompliance.

The bottom of Figure 1 provides some tangible examples for tax actions, which may be subsumed

under the corresponding constructs, e.g. the investing in tax-favored assets, choosing a specific depre-

ciation method, opting to defer taxable revenue to future assessment periods, classifying certain trans-

actions as “tax exempt”, shifting income between different tax jurisdictions (e.g. tax havens), engaging

in tax-relevant transfer pricing, or setting up particular tax shelter structures.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Tax Planning
explicit and implicit („all parties, all taxes, all costs“)
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828

Tax Avoidance
explicit income tax reduction

Constructs of Tax Aggressiveness


interest:

“more likely than not“


chance of a tax-related
transaction being upheld Tax Evasion
under audit >50%

Legality:
or other specified clearly illegal;
perfectly legal Reference Point
“grey-scaled“ activities with intent to defraud

Compliance:
strict apparent
potentially tax system – “unfavorable“ noncompliance
compliance noncompliance

E.g. investment
E.g. characterization of income (i.e. deferred revenue);
in tax-favored
classification of a transaction as tax exempt; shift in
bonds; choice of
income between jurisdictions (i.e. transfer pricing); Tax Sheltering
depreciation
decision to file (multi-state) tax return; etc.
method

Figure 1: Unifying Conceptual Framework of Corporate Tax Planning

5
The approach to arrange tax-reducing activities according to their perceived degree of legality is in

line with prior literature. Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] (p. 137) describe a “continuum” of tax avoid-

ance, ranging from perfectly legal tax avoidance (e.g. investment in tax-exempt municipal bonds) to

such actions that can be described as “pushing the envelope of tax law”. Similarly, Lisowsky et al.

[2013] consider such tax transactions to range further toward the right end of the continuum, for which

there is weaker legal support, i.e. where the goal is more likely to create tax benefits that have “no

economic corollary” (Chirelstein and Zelenak [2005], p. 1939).7

Below the legality dimension, Figure 1 depicts the potential degree of tax system compliance.8 As a

closely related dimension, compliance can generally be understood in a legal sense, too.9 However,

compliance from the tax system perspective is here interpreted more broadly, stressing the occasional

mismatch between the letter of a rule and the actual spirit of the rule. While the literal application of

many tax-related actions may well be legal on paper, those actions might still be unfavorable to the tax

system and could be perceived as uncooperative towards the collective (Wenzel [2002a]).10 In the

context of the here proposed conceptual framework, this implies that not only more obvious acts of tax

evasion but also such tax avoidance that draws on (tentatively) legal means might still be considered

non-compliant in a social sense. Although not always easy to handle, the compliance dimension may

still help to motivate a more nuanced assessment of corporate tax behavior.11

7
Lisowsky et al. [2013] associate tax reserves with shelter activity and “overlay the tax avoidance continuum
with the FIN 48 recognition and measurement process to illustrate that the UTB account balance should be
informative of tax sheltering.” (p. 9).
8
As such, the compliance-degree of underlying tax behavior is not intended to serve as the primary dimension
to define or delimit the relevant tax avoidance constructs. It is rather intended to stimulate a more differenti-
ated dealing with the subject of (and empirical findings on) corporate tax planning.
9
Lawrence H. Summers of the U.S. Treasury has characterized corporate tax avoidance as “what may be the
most serious compliance issue threatening the American tax system today.” (see U.S. Department of
Treasury [2000] press release from February 29, 2000).
10
Moreover, Wenzel [2002b] (p. 630) states that “[…], when taxpayers try to find loopholes with the intention
to pay less tax, their actions, even if technically legal, may be against the spirit of the law and in this sense
considered noncompliant.” (with further reference to James et al. [2001]).
11
Admittedly, while it is clearly a noble goal to differentiate between more or less “desirable” tax avoidance, it
appears at the same time just as hard for research as for anyone else to reasonably gauge or objectively meas-
ure a consensus “favorable” degree of noncompliance. Nevertheless, when going far afield drawing political
implications from empirical findings, it should be kept in mind that not only tax evasion, but also tax avoid-
ance and tax aggressiveness may well be worth debatable with regards to their overall favorability.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


2.1. Tax Planning

The underlying concept to which all other tax constructs within the unifying conceptual framework

relate is that of corporate tax planning (see top in Figure 1). Tax planning, as it is understood through-

out the following, is based on the seminal global planning approach to taxes and business strategy

proposed in Scholes et al. [2009]. In accordance with the so-called Scholes-Wolfson framework12,

effective tax planning

 considers the tax positions of all parties to a contract (multilateral approach),


 considers all taxes, both explicit and implicit, and
 acknowledges the relevance of all costs, both tax and nontax costs13

in the corporate decision making process aimed at the maximization of after-tax returns. From taking

into account the three general themes “all parties”, “all taxes”, and “all costs” it follows that mere tax

minimization strategies are not necessarily desirable. Besides changes in explicit taxes affecting after-

tax returns, implicit taxes (e.g. reduced pre-tax rates of returns for tax-favored investments) and other

nontax costs (e.g. agency costs, transaction costs, financial reporting costs) may considerably decide

over the net effectiveness of corporate tax planning (or tax policy making, vice versa). The role and

assertiveness of tax authorities and other relevant stakeholders frequently co-determines the optimal

tax strategy and its potential outcome. Regardless of empirical difficulties to measure and quantify

nontax costs, it is important to emphasize that after-tax profitability of businesses frequently cannot be

maximized without affecting other stakeholders’ goals. Tax planning always requires an integral con-

sideration and trade-off of all explicit and implicit taxes as well as nontax costs.

At this point, the subordinate constructs within the framework, i.e. tax avoidance, tax aggressiveness,

and tax evasion differ from the overarching construct of tax planning (see Figure 1). These constructs

specifically relate to the “all taxes” bucket of effective tax planning, more precisely that of explicit

taxes. They share the common purpose of reducing the explicit corporate tax burden.

12
Also referred to as the “SWEMS framework”. On the occasion of the recently held February 2013 ATA
Doctoral Consortium, Shevlin [2013] stressed the prevailing usefulness of the Scholes-Wolfson framework in
examining and understanding cross-sectional variation in firms propensity to engage in more or less tax
avoidance, pointing out that “no paper really challenges the framework” (pp. 4, 7).
13
See Scholes et al. [2009] (p. 3).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


2.2. Tax Avoidance

Tax avoidance within the here presented framework is broadly defined as the reduction of a firm’s

explicit taxes in any manner. This approach is in line with the definition assumed by Dyreng et al.

[2008] and Hanlon and Heitzman [2010], who point out that this definition does not differentiate be-

tween tax-favored real activities, tax planning that is explicitly undertaken to avoid tax payments,

and/or tax benefits expected from lobbying. Further, the construct of tax avoidance does not distin-

guish between clearly legal, legally doubtful or “grey-scaled”, illegal, and in fact fraudulent tax prac-

tices (Dyreng et al. [2008]).14 This broad definition appears adequate for research questions that ad-

dress the overall extent to which firms manage an explicit reduction of tax liabilities or cash tax out-

flows. Research would principally prefer to gauge the “global” (i.e. combined explicit and implicit)

effects of corporate tax planning, but is often faced with substantial difficulties in empirically estimat-

ing all implicit taxes associated with tax avoidance. This circumstance frequently leads to the omission

of implicit taxes in the employed empirical measures (Scholes et al. [2009], p. 147),15 which is im-

portant to bear in mind when evaluating firms’ true “effective” tax burdens and when assessing the

distributions of tax burdens across taxpayers.

Hence, if one is interested in a firm’s general ability to reduce its explicit tax burden, without further

characterizing the specific nature of activities that are employed to realize the tax savings, the here

suggested construct of interest is tax avoidance (see Figure 1). Tax aggressiveness, tax sheltering, and

tax evasion can be subsumed under the construct of general tax avoidance, given that all of these con-

structs are likewise aimed at a reduction of a firms’ explicit tax payments or liabilities. While these

constructs do differ in the perceived degree of legal sustainability of the transactions they represent,

they all describe the explicit avoidance of taxes.

It follows that the construct of tax avoidance may include aggressive, potentially even evasive types of

explicit tax planning. At the same time, there agreeably exist numerous tax actions that are by no intui-

tion “aggressive”, but still lead to a considerable reduction of explicit taxes. These non-aggressive tax

avoidance actions are represented by the overhanging left end of tax avoidance in Figure 1. For many

14
Put differently, tax avoidance captures all certain and uncertain (sustainable and unsustainable) tax positions
that may or may not be legally challenged (Lisowsky et al. [2013]).
15
E.g. the long-run cash effective tax rate, that is defined as the sum of cash taxes paid over ten years divided
by the sum of pretax book income over those same ten years (Dyreng et al. [2008]); see also Section 4.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


straightforward types of tax avoidance there is no reason to doubt their lawfulness. Firms that restrict

their tax avoidance to a combination of perfectly legal activities, e.g. investing in tax-favored munici-

pal bonds or opting for the tax-optimal depreciation method offered by the legislator, should fall under

the category of non-aggressive tax avoidance. With regards to similarly tax-motivated actions it ap-

pears unsuitable to speak of tax aggressiveness, given that the taxpayer’s main intention is to make

sure not to pay more taxes than is actually demanded of him; both in accordance with the letter of the

law and likely also with the spirit of the law. Presumably, government and regulators pursue specific

socially desired objectives by the formal exemption of certain asset types from taxation or by incorpo-

rating tax-favorable depreciation options into the law. Thus, from the global standpoint of efficient tax

planning (incorporating “all parties”, “all costs”, “all taxes”), a certain degree of explicit tax avoidance

is in fact “desirable” from a global standpoint. This should be true at least to the extent to which

courts,16 regulators and others see nothing unduly about straightforward legal tax avoidance. To label

and treat any possible avoidance behavior as “aggressive” would not only miss any additional merit.

More problematically, it would unnecessarily harbor the risk of signaling misleading connotations

about corporate tax behavior for which there actually exists wider public acceptance.

2.3. Tax Aggressiveness

Tax aggressiveness (as depicted in Figure 1) is understood to be situated at the next lower aggregation

level of tax avoidance. It refers to a further delimited scope of tax avoidance actions that are particu-

larly “aggressive”, a feature that calls for further specification. The outlined conceptual framework

generally suggests that the weaker the legal support of a firm’s tax position, the more reasonable it is

to consider this tax position aggressive.17 In a similar way, the degree of tax system favorable compli-

16
A quote that is regularly cited to underline that there is nothing generally immoral about paying as low
amounts of taxes as possible within the legal boundaries is that of Judge Learned Hand, dating back to 1935:
“Anyone may arrange his affairs so that his taxes shall be as low as possible; he is not bound to choose that
pattern which best pays the treasury. There is not even a patriotic duty to increase one's taxes. Over and over
again the Courts have said that there is nothing sinister in so arranging affairs as to keep taxes as low as pos-
sible. Everyone does it, rich and poor alike and all do right, for nobody owes any public duty to pay more
than the law demands.” (Judge Learned Hand in the case of Gregory v. Helvering 69 F.2d 809, 810 [2d Cir.
1934], aff’d, 293 U.S. 465, 55 S. Ct. 266, 79 L.Ed. 596 [1935]).
17
See also Frischmann et al. [2008], who define tax aggressiveness as the act of “engaging in significant tax
positions with relatively weak supporting facts”. Lisowsky [2010] relatedly places tax aggressiveness close
to the right end of a range of avoidance activities stretching from legitimate tax planning to engagement in
abusive tax sheltering.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


ance should generally decrease the more aggressive a firm plans its taxes. The great challenge lies in

the attempt to objectively define a cut-off point at which the underlying tax avoidance actions are to a

critical level legally challengeable in order for the construct of interest to be appropriately labeled tax

aggressiveness. Hence, it is expressly acknowledged that this cut-off point generally lies in the eye of

the beholder. Nonetheless, the framework developed here explicitly suggests a “more-likely-than-not”

(MLTN) – threshold of a tax-related transaction being upheld under potential audit as a particularly

useful reference point to make a distinction between non-aggressive and aggressive types of tax avoid-

ance (see Figure 1).18 Firms that structure their tax positions in ways that hypothetically bear the >50

% risk of not being sustained upon the potential examination by the IRS (or any other institution) are

here and in the following considered to be tax “aggressive”. Notwithstanding the given difficulties in

assessing the “true” probability of tax positions being more or less likely to be eventually sustainable,

the proposed MLTN reference point has the advantage that it is clearly linked to the well acknowl-

edged assessment dimension of legality.19

2.4. Tax Sheltering

A considerable share of the empirical tax avoidance literature deals with the important construct of

corporate tax sheltering (e.g. Wilson [2009], Lisowsky [2010]). Tax shelter engagement is sometimes

closely linked, or may even coincide with the actual evasion of taxes. According to Lisowsky et al.

[2013] (p. 8), tax sheltering can be considered as the “most extreme subset of tax aggressiveness […]

which tests the bounds of legality”. Notice, however, that the here proposed framework does not view

tax sheltering as yet another sub-construct of explicit corporate tax planning (such as tax avoidance

and tax aggressiveness; see top of Figure 1). Rather, tax sheltering is generally considered a specific

category of explicit tax planning actions, e.g. involving the use of special legal vehicles, offshore tax

haven involvement, etc. (see bottom of Figure 1). As sheltering frequently lacks a considerable busi-

18
In a contemporary paper, Lisowsky et al. [2013] similarly use a MLTN threshold to differentiate between
general tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness, albeit their particular study’s setting is focused on accounting
for UTBs under FIN 48 and its predictive ability to proxy for tax shelter participation.
19
As the target-oriented differentiation between tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness is one of the crucial ele-
ments, i.e. both a major benefit and a considerable challenge, of this study, Section 3 is further devoted to the
critical discussion of the MLTN reference point. In the pursuit of a well-rounded analysis, other examples of
potential reference points (implicitly) assumed in the literature will also be referred to, appropriately recog-
nizing that perceptions and preferences in this regard justifiably vary among researchers.

10

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


ness purpose and often depends on the use of legal loopholes, it is here assumed to usually – but not

necessarily – reflect tax aggressiveness.

Other common definitions of tax sheltering likewise underscore the here depicted conceptual under-

standing and stress the particular aggressive character of sheltering. Definitions usually refer to the

tax-motivated misstatement of economic income with the goal to reduce explicit taxes (e.g. Bankman

[2004]). This is usually done in a fashion inconsistent with any purposive reading of the relevant regu-

lation (McGill and Outslay [2004], p. 743, see also Bankman [1994]). The U.S. Congress [1999] de-

scribes tax shelters as arrangements aimed at the avoidance of taxes by generating economic benefits

without incurring economic loss or risk. The American Institute of Certified Public Accountants fur-

ther defines abusive tax shelters as having “no business purpose other than tax avoidance, unless they

are consistent with the intent of applicable tax laws.”20 The U.S. Department of Treasury [1999] notes

that corporate tax shelters may take many different forms, making it difficult to find a universal defini-

tion of tax sheltering. Nonetheless, tax shelters share a number of common features, e.g. the “lack of

economic substance, inconsistent financial and accounting treatment, presence of tax-indifferent par-

ties, complexity, […], promotion or marketing, confidentiality, high transaction costs, and risk reduc-

tion arrangements” (U.S. Department of Treasury [1999], p. 12). In relation to the suggested MLTN

reference point for the construct of tax aggressiveness, it is assumed that tax shelter activity would be

relatively challenging to sustain under audit, and/or may more often than other transactions turn out to

be prohibited and penalized after the fact.21

Moreover, with a view to the compliance dimension of the conceptual framework, tax shelter engage-

ment is perceived to be largely unfavorable to the tax system as a whole, both in the eyes of policy

makers and the general public. Thus, the conceptual construct of tax sheltering is considered to be a

manifestation of more aggressive types of tax-motivated actions. Notice however that sheltering does

not necessarily have to be illegal,22 nor does it necessarily have to be conducted with the sole aim of

20
AICPA [2003] (p.1).
21
A feature that, at least by a selected few and to a limited extent, can in some cases be observed empirically,
e.g. drawing on mandatory private disclosures of tax shelter participation as made to the Internal Revenue
Service’s Office of Tax Shelter Analysis, see Lisowsky et al. [2013] or other confidential tax shelter and tax
return data (e.g. Wilson [2009], Lisowsky [2010]).
22
As illustrated by the dashed box around tax sheltering on the bottom of Figure 1.

11

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


evading taxes.23 In fact, many shelter structures are in probably designed on the premises that they

have some, although hard to maintain, legal justification.24 In other words, tax shelter firms that “test

the bounds of legality” (see reference to Lisowsky et al. [2013] above) do not always actually cross

them. Finally, even those types of tax shelters, which are in fact impermissible (e.g. because they do

not exhibit a formally required “economic substance” or a “business purpose”), do not necessarily fall

under the category of tax evasion (right end in Figure 1), which is further discussed in the following.

2.5. Tax Evasion

A fundamental feature of tax evasion is its clear unlawfulness (see e.g. Holmes [1916], Slemrod and

Yitzhaki [2002]).25 However, in order to differ from (illegal) tax aggressiveness, tax evasion further

requires an affirmative action that constitutes the attempted evasion of a tax. It is committed willfully

with the deliberate intent to defraud.26 Acknowledging the difficulties in drawing the dividing line

between legal and illegal cases to begin with,27 this conceptual framework nonetheless requires these

additional criteria in the definition of tax evasion. This approach is beneficial in so far, as it follows

established jurisdiction:

According to a 2004 U.S. Supreme Court case, tax evasion connotes the integration of three elements:

(1) the end to be achieved, i.e., the payment of less than that known by the taxpayer to be legally due,

or the non-payment of tax when it is shown that a tax is due, (2) an accompanying state of mind which

is described as being "evil," in "bad faith," "willful," or "deliberate and not accidental", and (3) a

23
Further, tax sheltering - just as any other sub-construct of explicit tax avoidance - still needs to be evaluated
under the “all parties-all costs-all taxes” view of global tax planning.
24
Bankman [2004] (p. 9) describes a tax shelter as a transaction that is “(1) marketed and tax-motivated, (2)
succeeds under at least one literal reading of the governing statute or regulation, (3) misstates economic in-
come, and (4) in doing so reduces the tax on capital, (5) in a manner inconsistent with any purposive or inten-
tionalist reading of the statute or regulation.”
25
See right end of Figure 1.
26
Compare e.g. Sansone vs. United States [1965], 380 U.S. 343 par. 16: “The elements of §7201 are will-
fullness; the existence of a tax deficiency; and an affirmative act constituting an evasion or attempted evasion
of the tax”; referring to §7201 “Attempt to evade or defeat taxes” in 26 U.S.C (Subtitle F Chapter 75 Sub-
chapter A).
27
Notice however that (formal) legality alone is not always understood consistently. For example, it lies in the
eye of the beholder if the legality of a tax shelter only depends on the letter of the law or if a substance over
form perspective should be assumed that also takes into account underlying legal doctrines and intentions of
the lawmaker, see e.g. Kersting [2008].

12

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


course of action or failure of action which is unlawful.28 As such, tax sheltering may constitute tax

evasion if it is illegal and conducted in an affirmative act with the willful attempt to defraud. In turn,

the mere absence of a business purpose in a transaction cannot be sufficient to qualify tax shelter ac-

tivity as tax evasion.

Further in line with this understanding, the Joint Committee on Taxation of the U.S. Congress [1999]

describes a tax shelter as an aggressive arrangement that is designed principally to avoid or evade

federal income taxes. Thus, if it is possible to identify and investigate tax shelter activity that is clearly

illegal, it would be appropriate to consider the construct under investigation to be tax evasion, as long

as a clear intent to defraud on the side of the taxpayer is further assumed. Empirically, however, such

behavior is hard to detect. Some studies are able to identify tax transactions with a degree of legality

that may at least be considered questionable, by drawing on court dockets or confidential tax return

data (Wilson [2009], Lisowsky [2010]).29 Precisely, and in line with the here proposed conceptual

understanding, these studies refer to tax aggressiveness and at no point state to directly investigate the

construct of tax evasion.

With a view not only to the tax shelter literature but also to the corresponding public interest in tax

sheltering and tax evasion, the intention here is to underscore the need to clearly explain and delimit

the actual construct under investigation before drawing analogies with other evidence or in order to

reject or support common claims. To arrive at good results, institutions contributing to the tax policy

debate should not brush aside this challenge of carefully distinguishing between (oftentimes perfectly

legal) tax avoidance, more doubtful tax aggressiveness, frequently questionable tax sheltering, and

clearly abusive, in fact criminal shades of tax evasion.30 In their ongoing “fight against tax evasion”,31

28
Further, the court states that tax avoidance “should be used by the taxpayer in good faith and at arm’s
length”, whereas tax evasion “is a scheme used outside of those lawful means and when availed of, it usually
subjects the taxpayer to further or additional civil or criminal liabilities.”, see court decision in the case of
Commisioner of Internal Revenue vs. The Estate of Benigno P. Toda [2004], G.R. No. 147188, September
14, 2004 with further reference to Vitug and Acosta [2000] and deLeon [1988].
29
With a view to court rulings, some of the observed firms likely decided not to settle but instead go to court,
where some eventually win their case (i.e. sustain their position in the aftermath).
30
Accordingly, the AICPA recently pointed out: “Crucial to the debate is the difficulty of clearly distinguishing
between transactions that are abusive and transactions that are aggressive and legitimate. At the same time, it
must be recognized that taxpayers have a legitimate interest in arranging their affairs so that they pay no
more than the taxes they owe.” (AICPA [2011], p. 12, par. 2).
31
E.g. G8 Leaders [2013]; G20 Leaders [2008]; U.S. Department of Treasury [2013]; Council of the European
Union [2013].

13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


policy makers and regulators may first and foremost have an interest to focus on such aggressive tax

actions that without doubt could be identified as fraudulent and criminal. Such actions could be se-

verely sanctioned, also in order to deter other firms from engaging in clearly tax system unfavorable

tax planning. Also in a social justice sense, measures to combat tax aggressiveness should especially

target such forms of illegal tax aggressiveness that are clearly designed to defraud the state of its tax

funds. In these veins it appears target-oriented to further differentiate (possibly illegal) tax aggressive-

ness and/or tax sheltering from the construct of fraudulent tax evasion. Nonetheless, when it comes to

safeguard or even increase corporate tax revenues on larger scales, it might be more purposeful to step

up efforts to curtail tax aggressiveness (or tax avoidance) more generally.

3. Non-Aggressive Tax Avoidance vs. Tax Aggressiveness

3.1. Requiring the Use of Reference Points

Next to tax avoidance, tax aggressiveness is the construct most frequently investigated in empirical tax

accounting research.32 Throughout the literature, tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness are often per-

ceived to capture different scopes of explicit tax planning activities. Alternatively, some might simply

use terms and constructs synonymously. A possible reason for the interchangeable use of the two

terms or the identification of only one single relevant construct of explicit tax avoidance, respectively,

may be that some conceive it to be possible and/or beneficial to narrow down on one single consistent

concept of explicit tax planning. However, the problem is that in order for a single construct to be

universally accepted and generally applicable in terms of capturing every relevant type of tax-

motivated action, it would be necessary to adopt a very broad definition of explicit tax planning. In

case of individual research settings and questions that do however not desire to address the general

spectrum of explicit tax-reducing actions, but rather want to focus on a particularly aggressive, e.g.

grey-scaled or morally doubtful, subset of tax avoidance, more precisely delimited constructs may in

fact prove useful.

32
By way of illustration, a straightforward online search using the Google Scholar engine as a starting point
provides 176,000 (22,600; 43,600; 91,900) results of research papers and related documentation that contain
the term “tax avoidance” (“tax aggressiveness”; “tax sheltering”; “tax evasion”). Narrowing down the search
to abstracts and working papers which are available and circulated on the social science research network
(SSRN) provides 517 (42; 32; 682) results for “tax avoidance” (“tax aggressiveness”, “tax sheltering”, “tax
evasion”), accordingly. [Search results as of July 10, 2013; see scholar.google.com and papers.ssrn.com].

14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


It seems beneficial not to discard a separate construct of tax aggressiveness next to (non-aggressive)

tax avoidance in favor of one single, oftentimes too wide to consistently interpret construct of explicit

tax planning. In fact, the conceptual separation of tax avoidance from tax aggressiveness allows to

identify firms that exhibit high levels of tax aggressive (e.g. because they engage in legally risky

transactions), but at the same time realize low levels of overall tax avoidance (e.g. reflected by rela-

tively high effective tax rates). It appears reasonable, that in some circumstances firms may get en-

gaged in some risky tax transactions such as particular tax shelters, but apart from that are unable to

substantially lower the amounts of taxes paid. In other words, a conceptual differentiation may in fact

allow identifying firms that are aggressive, but in fact unsuccessful, tax avoiders.

However, the perception of what actually constitutes tax aggressiveness may vary depending on indi-

vidual preferences or a particular research setting. Of course it is not mandatory to agree on one uni-

versally accepted reference point for aggressive tax planning, but it appears rewarding to at least re-

duce the impending ambiguousness and risk of misleading interpretations to a minimum. In order to

produce more consistent evidence, any individually adopted reference point of tax aggressiveness

should be comprehensibly explained. Consequently, and a bit more technical, the understanding in this

framework with regards to the necessary differentiation between tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness

can be illustrated as follows:

15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828

Figure 2: Delimiting Non-aggressive Tax Avoidance and Tax Aggressiveness

16
As depicted in Figure 2, the construct of tax avoidance – as opposed to tax aggressiveness – does not

refer to any reference point other than the hypothetical tax liability (or payment) that would result

from a state of “zero explicit tax-planning”. At exactly this juncture, the construct of tax aggressive-

ness differs from tax avoidance: With regards to the individual research question, tax aggressiveness

needs a well specified and explicitly articulated criterion (reference point, RP), at which general

avoidance turns into aggressive behavior in the eye of the beholder. This may be a benchmark-tax

strategy, a particular level of planning effort or “success”, etc. For at least as long as there is no single

universally accepted reference point, studies need to be very specific about what in particular charac-

terizes the relevant subset of tax aggressive actions within their particular research setting. Put differ-

ently, it requires clarification why a study is in fact a tax aggressiveness study and not a “general” tax

avoidance study.

Drawing on a finance context, possible definitions of the term aggressive include “an approach to in-

vesting that seeks above-average returns by taking above-average risks”33 and “concentrating on

growth and high yields, rather than long-term security”.34 These definitions elucidate that an action in

order to be labeled “aggressive” requires a certain reference points. Speaking in terms of the above

examples, clarification would be required with regards to what is actually meant by “above-average

risks”, “high yields”, or “particularly willing”. Transferred to the field of taxation, aggressive firms

could be characterized as particularly willing to engage in tax transactions that might eventually be

overthrown by the IRS or earn disapproval by other regulators.35 Just as different people have different

ideas of “risk”, a universally accepted definition of “tax aggressiveness” based on clearly specified

characteristics is hard to obtain. In fact, some might consider it more serviceable to define tax aggres-

siveness using reference points that vary depending on a given research context. Thus, while the con-

ceptual framework developed in this study stresses the likely usefulness of the MLTN probability of a

tax position being sustainable upon potential audit, i.e. the weak or strong legal support of a tax-

motivated activitiy, there clearly are valid alternative reference points.

33
See The Free Dictionary by Farlex (2013), www.thefreedictionary.com/aggressiveness.
34
See The Oxford English Dictionary (2013), http://www.oed.com/view/Entry/3952#eid8581615.
35
“[…] intuitively, aggressiveness is thought of as pushing the envelope of tax law” (Hanlon and Heitzman
[2010], p. 137).

17

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


3.2. MLTN Probability of a Tax Position being Legally Sustainable

The here developed conceptual framework suggests a > 50 % probability of a tax position being sus-

tainable under (hypothetical) audit as the preferred reference point of non-aggressive tax avoidance. In

turn, a tax position which is equally or less likely to be legally sustainable is considered aggressive

(See Fig. 1).36

Arguably, there are several advantages of using a MLTN threshold as the adequate reference point to

delimit non-aggressive from aggressive explicit tax planning. First, the central benefit of a MLTN

reference point is its close connection to the legal dimension of the conceptual framework. A particu-

lar focus on the assessment of the legal sustainability (and thus, uncertainty) surrounding a tax position

corresponds well with the frequently advocated notion to classify relevant tax constructs according to

the alleged degree of legality of underlying tax actions (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010], Rego and

Wilson [2012], Lisowsky et al. [2013]). Second, drawing on a MLTN criterion can be well-motivated

as it has clearly garnered broad acceptance in different tax-related regulatory contexts. Notwithstand-

ing the fact that the MLTN-concept is not identical across all contexts in which it is already applied,

involved researchers, practitioners, and the U.S. standard setter should to a notable degree be familiar

with the general notion of “MLTN”. Since 2006, FASB Interpretation No. 48 “Accounting for Uncer-

tainty in Income Taxes “ (FIN 48)37, which has been extensively discussed throughout research and

the business community, mandates specific rules for the recognition, measurement, and disclosure of

uncertain tax positions. In a two-step approach, firms have to (1) accrue those tax positions that are

more likely than not to yield tax benefits, i.e. will likely be sustained upon examination (recognition

step), and (2) have to estimate the likely outcomes of recognized positions using scenario analyses and

assigned probabilities (measurement step). If a tax position does not meet the MLTN recognition

threshold, no tax benefit is recognized in the financial statements. Otherwise, a tax reserve (UTB)

36
Alternatively (e.g. from a tax return preparer’s point of view), one could think of aggressive tax avoidance,
which is more or equally likely not to be legally sustainable (right side of the MLTN reference point), as par-
ticularly “risky” positions with regards to their potential outcome under audit. Accordingly, “risky tax avoid-
ance” could be a synonym for “tax aggressiveness” (e.g. Rego and Wilson [2012], p. 776).
37
FIN 48 is the interpretation of ASC 740, formerly known as FAS 109 “Accounting for Income Taxes”. In
2009, FASB has reorganized its accounting standards codification system FASB [2009]. Since then, FIN 48
(FAS 109) is officially codified as ASC 740-10 (ASC 740). However, consistent with still common practice
in the literature, this study continues to refer to the interpretation as “FIN 48”.

18

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


representing the difference between the recognizable tax benefit and the position reported on the tax

return is accrued.38

In a recent study, Lisowsky et al. [2013] explicitly draw on the FIN 48’s MLTN standard in order to

conceptually frame their particular research setting that investigates tax disclosures and unrecognized

tax benefits (UTBs). Hence, Lisowsky et al. [2013] provide a related example for how a MLTN stand-

ard can be employed as a useful reference point for tax aggressiveness. The authors consider UTB tax

positions to be tax aggressive depending on whether the taxpayer believes that it is more likely than

not that the tax position would be sustained in court based on its technical merits.39 Slightly differing

from the here suggested conceptual understanding, the authors understand the break-point between tax

avoidance and tax aggressiveness to be located somewhere to the left of the actual MLTN threshold.

In other words, tax positions might also be subsumable under the concept of tax aggressiveness if

chances of legal sustainability are in fact somewhat greater than 50 %. While the idea behind this ap-

proach is reasonable in so far, as tax positions evaluated to be only slightly more likely than not to be

sustainable (e.g. 51 % instead of 50%) are conceptually probably not much less “aggressive” than tax

positions that are just below the MLTN threshold (e.g. 49 %) of being sustainable. However, given

that any explicitly and percentage-wise quantified MLTN recognition threshold (both in practice and

in theory) is to a large extent discretionary anyhow, it is here assumed – at least for the benefit of a

clearly stated reference point – that the critical threshold is in fact a >50 % chance. Notice that the

MLTN-concept in the context of this study and conceptual framework is understood in general terms,

i.e. with no necessary or required reference to FIN 48 or UTBs.40

Another usage of the MLTN standard is incorporated in the U.S. Department of Treasury Circular 230

rules, which govern the practice of lawyers, CPAs and other practitioners before the IRS.41 Depending

38
Hence, the tax reserve should reflect the degree of uncertainty inherent in a self-assessed tax position, sug-
gesting UTBs (or changes thereof) may be an appropriate proxy for tax avoidance. This possibility is dis-
cussed in Section 4.2.d.
39
According to FIN 48, par. 6; see Lisowsky et al. [2013] (p. 9).
40
The MLTN test is understood to be (fictitiously) applicable to any type of tax avoidance behavior. Underly-
ing tax actions at no point need to be subject to any actual audit under any specific standard or regulation by
any particular institution (e.g. IRS).
41
U.S. Department of Treasury [2011], Circular No. 230, Rev. 8-2011, (p. 26), §10.35 (b) (4) (i): “Written
advice is a reliance opinion if the advice concludes at a confidence level of at least more likely than not a
greater than 50 % likelihood that one or more significant Federal tax issues would be resolved in the taxpay-
er’s favor.”

19

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


on further specified circumstances, Circular 230 demands that written tax advice that may be relied

upon by a taxpayer for penalty protection lives up to a MLTN standard. Further, and very closely re-

lated to the here discussed constructs of tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness, the Public Company

Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB) in 2006 adopted the MLTN standard in its Rule 3522 “Tax

Transactions”. Pursuant to this rule, public accounting firms are prohibited from providing non-audit

service to an audit client that involves marketing, planning, or opining in the favor of an “aggressive

tax position transaction [...] that was initially recommended, directly or indirectly, by the registered

public accounting firm and a significant purpose of which is tax avoidance, unless the proposed tax

treatment is at least more likely than not to be allowable under applicable tax laws.”42

In a related vein, another MLTN usage was introduced in revisions to Internal Revenue Code Section

6694 under the Small Business and Work Opportunity Tax Act of 2007. The goal of this revision was

to increase the preparer standard for tax return positions, requiring that a position that is not adequate-

ly disclosed must meet a MLTN criterion for the preparer to avoid penalty.43 Further, this MLTN pen-

alty standard applies in assessing whether a taxpayer is subject to penalty for tax positions that fall

under tax shelter rules. Such shelter positions, that in turn are generally defined to involve “significant

tax planning”, must also satisfy the MLTN criteria as for the taxpayer to avoid penalty assessment.

Third, while especially FIN 48 and its interpretation-specific MLTN standard have received excessive

attention, it should be highlighted that MLTN standards have garnered global acceptance and are in-

corporated into numerous regulations across jurisdictions. In addition to the FASB, the International

Accounting Standards Board (IASB) has readily incorporated the MLTN concept into pivotal account-

ing standards. Similarly to FIN 48, International Accounting Standard 12 “Income Taxes” (IAS 12)

requires the realization of tax benefits to be “probable” in order for tax assets to be recognized. While

there may have been differing interpretations of “probable” and “more-likely-than-not” when IAS 12

was first established, standard setters and practitioners today largely agree that the MLTN threshold is

relevant in assessing uncertain tax positions and with respect to other accounting contexts.44

42
Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB) [2006] ( p. 59), Rule 3522 (b) [Effective pursuant to
SEC Release No. 34-53677, File No. PCAOB-2006-01 (April 19,2006)].
43
For further details see e.g. PwC [2008] (p. 2).
44
See e.g. the appendices of IAS 37, IFRS 3, and IFRS 5 explicitly define “probable” as “more likely than not”.
According to IAS 37 par. 14, an entity must recognize a provision if, and only if, a present obligation has

20

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


In sum, for over almost a decade, MLTN standards have been actively promoted, many times ex-

plained to a broad audience, and frequently applied in many contexts. Taken together, the generally

observable efforts to improve objectivity and transparency in tax accounting by increasingly relying

on MLTN criteria speak in favor of employing a MLTN-based assessment as a useful reference point

of tax aggressiveness, which might actually be capable of broader consensus. Acknowledging that

MLTN standards are gaining momentum in accounting regimes even outside the U.S., the (increasing-

ly international) research community, regulators, and involved institutions should benefit from a con-

sistent use of a MLTN reference point to distinguish between tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness.

While the MLTN assessment of tax actions from a legal sustainability standpoint is here proposed as a

possible reference point that has the potential to foster more consistent future research, it is expressly

stated that this is not the only reasonable reference point for corporate tax aggressiveness. The next

section will thus attempt to further evaluate the differences between the MLTN reference point and

existing approaches to delimit tax aggressiveness and demonstrate to what extent the MLTN approach

is capable of capturing activities that are considered “aggressive” in contemporaneous research.

3.3. MLTN in Relation to other Possible Reference Points

As indicated earlier, the reference point for tax aggressiveness could rest in a number of other possible

tax transaction characteristics. Alternatively, one could also establish a certain “minimum level” of tax

avoidance, which is likely to be only accomplishable by those firms that draw on aggressive tax

avoidance, without further specifying those actions. Examples for the former could be specifically

identified tax schemes, e.g. certain tax shelter structures, which may reasonably differ in their aggres-

siveness from rather benign types of tax avoidance, a closer defined tax risk associated with an under-

lying set of tax positions, or some impending negative consequences that may only be entailed in par-

ticularly aggressive transactions (e.g. specific IRS penalties). Examples for the latter could be the re-

quirement of an above mean level of tax avoidance (e.g. using industry/size-benchmarked effective tax

arisen as a result of a past event, the payment is probable (“more likely than not”), and the amount can be es-
timated reliably. Even though footnote 1 to par. 23 of IAS 37 states that “the interpretation of ‘probable’ in
that specific standard as ‘more likely than not’ does not necessarily apply in other standards”, there appears
to be broad agreement among practitioners (see e.g. Ernst&Young [2012], PwC [2011], PwC [2009]) and in
the literature (see e.g. Küting and Zwirner [2005], p. 1554, Pellens et al. [2006], p. 197) that the more-likely-
than-not approach should also apply in the context of accounting for deferred tax assets under IAS 12.

21

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


rates),45 the orientation towards a best-competitor’s tax expense or unrecognized tax benefit position,

or the use of propensity-matched book-tax differences as a proxy for tax aggressiveness.

Another way to distinguish aggressive from generally avoidant behavior would be to define tax ag-

gressiveness as a generally socially irresponsible behavior (e.g. Erle [2008]). However, when com-

pared to the above described reference points, it likely turns out to be even more subjective and prone

to conflicting interpretations to determine what is socially responsible or in fact desirable.46 Accord-

ingly, the potential social irresponsibility associated with a tax position appears hardly capable of serv-

ing as a useful reference point for tax aggressiveness in most settings. Besides, it would likely turn out

to be difficult to measure and quantify social responsibility in empirical tests.47

To further illustrate the MLTN probability of a tax position being sustainable upon potential audit in

relation to other possible reference points, three alternative concepts of tax aggressiveness found in

contemporary empirical tax avoidance research will be discussed in the following (Lisowsky [2010],

Armstrong, Blouin, and Larcker [2012b], and Balakrishnan et al. [2012]). The goal is to (a) demon-

strate at which point other (more context-specifically developed) definitions of tax aggressiveness may

not capture the scope of activities that are considered “aggressive” within the here proposed frame-

work, and (b) further illustrate how the suggested MLTN reference for tax aggressiveness would be

transferable to the aggressive scopes of tax avoidance identified in the selected studies.

a. First-Order Importance of Reducing a Firm’s Tax Burden

In his study on the empirical modeling of corporate tax shelter use, Lisowsky [2010] briefly discusses

the demand for a broadly accepted definition of corporate tax aggressiveness. He similarly identifies

the challenge that in fact tax aggressiveness “is a matter of judgment, degree, and scope”, and propos-

es to define tax aggressiveness as behavior in which the reduction of the corporate tax burden is of

“first-order importance” (= reference point). Subordinately, any non-tax effects are considered “sec-

45
As e.g. suggested in Balakrishnan et al. [2012] and further discussed in the following.
46
Just as it is disproportionately harder to define “non-favorable” or “non-cooperative” tax behavior than more
or less legal activities.
47
To clarify, this does not mean that there is generally no particular research setting in which social irresponsi-
bility may well serve as the crucial characteristic of the subset of tax avoidance activities under investigation.
As long as the perception of social irresponsibility is clearly defined and adequately depicted, it may still turn
out to be an appropriate reference point in the given context of a particular study or research objective.

22

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


ond-order”, or marginal. By way of example, Lisowsky [2010] considers tax benefits from deprecia-

tion or stock options as being of second-order importance to the first-order capital allocation and/or

managerial incentive alignment effects. Consequently, he considers such tax benefits as “benign”

forms of tax avoidance – and not as tax aggressiveness.

While it seems comprehensible to label many tax shelter activities “aggressive”, especially with a ref-

erence to the frequently predominant purpose of avoiding taxes, it is less clear why a tax position that

exists for second-order important reasons can categorically not be aggressive. For example, assume a

firm invests in a specific asset, solely basing this decision on its operational needs (i.e. “first-order

importance” is not tax). Assume further that there is uncertainty with regards to whether or not this

investment might actually qualify for a tax-favored treatment, e.g. in form of being granted a tax-

favorable depreciation or even a tax-exempt status for the expected returns. Even though the tax treat-

ment of this asset is clearly of “second-order importance” to management, it seems reasonable that the

tax department could either assume a more “compliant” position (e.g. opt for a standard depreciation

method and record all realized returns from the investment in its tax return), or a more “aggressive”

tax position (e.g. opt for a more tax-favorable treatment which applicability is not guaranteed and not

declare any returns provided by this investment). The use of the proposed MLTN reference point for

tax aggressiveness (which is also suggested in Lisowsky et al. [2013]) would be capable of subsuming

both tax sheltering (as intended by Lisowsky [2010]) and “second-order important” – but still aggres-

sive – tax positions under the construct of tax aggressiveness.

b. Tax-Related vs. Tax-Driven Tasks of Tax Directors

Armstrong et al. [2012b] investigate the type of tax planning referred to in tax directors’ compensation

contracts and whether the contractual incentives are associated with levels of tax aggressiveness. In

this specific context, it is assumed that responsible tax directors play three different roles. First and

foremost, they ensure general tax compliance. Second, they also act as an advisor in cases of strategic

investment decisions. Third, directors may be explicitly charged with actively pursuing tax planning

opportunities, i.e. invest in projects where the net present value is exclusively driven by tax benefits.

Armstrong et al. [2012b] consider only activities falling under the third category (= their individual

reference point) to be tax aggressive.

23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Similar to the earlier approach followed in Lisowsky [2010], the definition of Armstrong et al. [2012b]

may not be easily transferable to other contexts, as it probably does not capture all tax activities many

people would actually consider tax aggressive. For instance, it appears conceivable that a manager

advises strategic investment decisions (first role, not the third role) that are aggressive in that they

involve considerable risk taking with regards to the specific tax position associated with this invest-

ment. Even though the net present value of the investment may under no circumstance be primarily

driven by the expected tax benefits,48 management can still seek an aggressive tax treatment (involving

tax highly uncertain tax positions) of this investment.

c. Uncommonly Low Tax Burden: Industry- and Size Benchmark

In a contemporary working paper, Balakrishnan et al. [2012] ask whether tax aggressiveness reduces

the financial reporting transparency of a firm. Just as “transparency” is a broader construct that is like-

ly to be affected by various shades of corporate activities, the authors opt for a broader definition of

tax aggressiveness, respectively. In their given research context, Balakrishnan et al. [2012] define ag-

gressive firms as such that pay unusually low amounts of taxes given their particular industry and size.

Hence, the understanding of tax aggressiveness in Balakrishnan et al. [2012] “does not rely on or cap-

ture any specific tax planning technique”.

While this conceptual definition of tax aggressiveness avoids the limitation (in this specific research

context) of capturing only specific tax transactions, e.g. certain tax shelters, it does not involve any

assessment of either the legal sustainability of a transaction or any alternative feature of the underlying

tax activities.49 With a view to the large number of potential determinants of cross-sectional (and with-

in-industry) variation in corporate tax avoidance, it is not instantly intuitive why two firms with simi-

lar average industry-/size- adjusted ETRs would necessarily act equally “(non-)aggressive”. The au-

thors themselves recognize that firms of comparable size within the same industry may still have very

48
Implying that the Lisowsky [2010] definition would probably consider this investment as being of “second-
order importance” to tax planning and likewise not subsume it under tax aggressiveness.
49
Which is of course a technical advantage in the empirical research design/measurement, but rather circum-
vents the challenge of conceptually differentiating the nature of underlying transactions that characterize
them as either aggressive or non-aggressive.

24

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


different tax avoidance options available (Balakrishnan et al. [2012], p. 5).50 However, if one does not

focus on the more or less aggressive nature of tax avoidance actions, the framework proposed here

would rather refer to tax avoidance51 and still agree with the use of ETR-based measures to proxy for

aggregate levels of not closer characterized explicit tax planning.52 In sum, the intention here is by no

means to criticize the innovative approach taken in Balakrishnan et al. [2012]. Rather, the goal is to

demonstrate the functioning of the here developed conceptual understanding by transferring it to the

context of contemporary research examples.

d. Tax Risk

In their definition of tax aggressiveness, a number of papers have further incorporated the notion of

tax risk, which firms are exposed to during or after their tax planning decisions. For example,

Gallemore and Labro [2013] argue that two firms with equally low ETRs may ceteris paribus be faced

with different tax risks, i.e. due to differences in the internal information quality. If a firm’s tax risk is

high, Gallemore and Labro [2013] (p. 12) consider this firm to be more tax aggressive than the firm

with an equally low, but otherwise less risky tax position. In a similar vein, Frischmann et al. [2008],

Mills, Robinson, and Sansing [2010], or Rego and Wilson [2012] consider tax planning (more precise-

ly, tax reporting) to be aggressive if it involves certain risks, e.g. a higher uncertainty on their UTB tax

positions under FIN 48. This concept of “risky tax avoidance” (Rego and Wilson [2012], p. 776; see

also Hanlon, Maydew, and Saavedra [2013]) is very much in line with the here proposed MLTN refer-

ence point of tax aggressiveness if one assumes that the “risk” involved in a tax position is largely

attributed to the more or less probable legal sustainability upon (hypothetical) audit.

Overall, the above discussion about other potential reference points of tax aggressiveness indicates

that a MLTN criterion with a focus on the potential legal sustainability of a tax position could well be

50
Even if the tax opportunities of “comparable” firms were in fact similar, it would still be required to assume
that the same quintile of total assets as well as 48 industries defined by Fama and French [1997] are sufficient
to adequately classify generally very large and geographically as well as functionally diversified multination-
als in adequate “size”- and “industry”-bins.
51
With its levels being industry-/size benchmark being well intuitive and also useful.
52
With specific respect to the here proposed MLTN reference point for tax aggressiveness, it appears unlikely
that those firms that are more successful in avoiding taxes than their peer firms necessarily need to rely on
legally less sustainable tax positions.

25

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


transferable to various actual research settings and would likely be capable to capture activities others

would also agree to treat as tax aggressive.

4. Empirical Measures of Corporate Tax Avoidance

4.1. Obtaining Corporate Tax Data

In empirical tax research, the reliable measurement of corporate tax avoidance and its related con-

structs naturally is a key issue (Dunbar et al. [2010]). Accordingly, the number of existing proxies for

tax avoidance, tax aggressiveness, and tax sheltering is large.53 In most settings, it would probably be

preferable to directly study a firms’ “true” tax liabilities or tax positions as reported to the authorities.

However, since the actual taxable income and due tax payments are stated in confidential tax returns,

they are mostly unobservable to researchers.54 For this reason, most empirical measures are inferred

from publically available financial statement data and employ estimates of taxable income or tax pay-

ments (Manzon and Plesko [2002]).55

Publically Disclosed Financial Statement Data

As research progresses, a growing variety of financial statement-based measures is being employed

and further developed. These measures can broadly be divided into the following categories: GAAP-

or cash-based (long-run) effective tax rates (ETRs), variants of total, permanent, or temporary book-

53
There really is no direct empirical “measure” of tax evasion, probably because evasion is characterized by its
fraudulent illegality, which is determined only after the fact (when it actually becomes observable). At best, it
can be proxied for such particularly aggressive tax actions which can be reasonably assumed to be frequent-
ly, but not necessarily, also used for evasive purposes. Put differently, the best way to “proxy” for evasion
would be to proxy for aggressiveness. Moreover, at least from the perspective of tax avoidance research, the
need for a specific tax evasion measure appears questionable, as tax evasion should not be a significant driver
of variation in overall tax avoidance among larger publically traded firms.
54
Exceptions include Altshuler and Auerbach [1990], Boynton et al. [1992], Collins and Shackelford [1995],
Collins and Shackelford [1998], Cordes and Sheffrin [1981], Cordes and Sheffrin [1983], Lyon [1997], Lyon
and Silverstein [1995], Mills [1998], Mills et al. [1998], Omer et al. [2000], Plesko [1994], Plesko [2000],
Lisowsky [2009, 2010].
55
A standard procedure of estimating taxable income from financial statements is to gross-up the income
statement’s current tax expense (FAS No. 109) by the statutory tax rate (Omer et al. [1991], Omer et al.
[1993], Gupta and Newberry [1997], Manzon and Plesko [2002]). Studies usually draw on large public com-
pany databases, e.g. Compustat North America, which conveniently provides “data standardized according to
financial statement presentation and specific data item definitions assuring […] consistent, comparable data
with which to analyze companies and industries.” (Standard & Poor's [2013], p. 2).

26

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


tax differences (BTDs), residuals from regression models that estimate the discretionary portion of the

above measures to single out tax-motivated behavior, and unrecognized tax benefits (UTBs) recorded

under FIN 48.

Understandably, the estimation of taxable income from financial statements is problematic. This is

mainly for three reasons.56 First, there are items that may lead to an over- or understatement of the

reported current tax expense relative to the actual tax liability of a firm, e.g. certain stock option de-

ductions, valuation allowances, or tax contingency reserves (e.g. Plesko [2003]). Second, even assum-

ing that the current tax expense from the income statement is an adequate proxy for the actual tax lia-

bility, the grossing-up of the tax expense may still yield biased estimates of the actual taxable income.

This might be the case where tax credits exist, such as R&D- or foreign tax credits. With regards to

loss firms, the tax expense may be truncated at zero or relevant information on possible tax refunds

may be missing.57 Third, the group of firms consolidated for book purposes might not coincide with

the group of firms consolidated for tax purposes (e.g. Mills, Newberry, and Trautman [2002], Plesko

[2003]).58 Consequently, “[t]he tax expense on the income statement cannot be expected to reflect the

taxes of entities that are not included on that income statement.” (Hanlon [2003], p. 845)

Ultimately, most of the problems that arise when computing tax estimates from GAAP financial

statements are rooted in the predominant objective of GAAP reporting, which is to provide decision-

useful information about the firm’s economic performance to investors – and not the general disclo-

sure of tax information.59 Taxes, from this point of view, are mainly relevant insofar as they affect

56
See e.g. Hanlon [2003] and Plesko [2003].
57
Moreover, the use of the U.S. statutory tax rate to gross-up the total tax expense of a multinational firm
sourcing its income across many different tax jurisdictions likely produces measurement error.
58
Under FAS No. 94, firms are required to file consolidated financial statements for all operations in which the
ultimate owner has at least a 50 % interest. For tax accounting purposes (IRC §§ 1501, 1504), consolidation
is only (voluntarily) permitted if there is a minimum ownership of at least 80 %; see Manzon and Plesko
[2002].
59
FASB [1978] states in SFAC 1 that financial accounting serves the purpose to provide decision-useful infor-
mation to investors and creditors. In SFAC 2, FASB [1980] names “relevance” and “reliability” as the main
qualitative characteristics that make accounting information useful. Correspondingly, the IASB [2001] states
in its framework that “[…] further harmonisation can best be pursued by focusing on financial statements
that are prepared for the purpose of providing information that is useful in making economic decisions”
(preface) and that “while all of the information needs of these users cannot be met by financial statements,
there are needs which are common to all users. As investors are providers of risk capital to the entity, the
provision of financial statements that meet their needs will also meet most of the needs of other users that fi-
nancial statements can satisfy.” (par. 10).

27

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


GAAP net earnings and the balance sheet, notwithstanding conceivable reasons why outside investors

would actually want to know taxable income. For instance, investors may care about taxable income

because it may serve as a useful benchmark for reported earnings or to learn about a firm’s success in

avoiding taxes (Lenter, Shackelford, and Slemrod [2003], Hanlon, LaPlante, and Shevlin [2005]).

Nevertheless, drawing on available financial statement data often turns out to be not just the only

available, but in fact quite a reasonable solution. For instance, Plesko [2000] compares public financial

statement numbers with confidential tax return numbers and finds a significant positive correlation

between the actual tax liability (before tax credits) and the reported current federal tax expense. In a

related approach, Lisowsky [2009] is able to investigate a multi-period matched tax return-financial

statement data set and develops a model to infer the tax return liabilities of U.S. firms from publicly

obtainable financial statement data. He finds that SFAS No. 109 related disclosures, i.e. current tax

expense, tax benefits from stock options, current-year tax cushion accruals, consolidation BTDs, and

R&D, are informative in inferring actual tax (while intra-period tax allocation is not).

The addressed problems regarding the use of financial statements to infer a firm’s tax status are further

put into perspective if one considers the potential limitations of alternative data sources, in particular

actual tax return data. First, different consolidation scopes for book and tax purposes would make it

difficult to merge any one tax return with any one set of financial statements (see Mills and Plesko

[2003]). This is especially unhelpful if research is interested in comparing the accounting earnings

with the taxable income of the same set of entities. Second, studies often focus on large multinational

groups that may exhibit substantial tax-relevant activities outside the U.S. that may not be included in

U.S. tax returns. Third, if the goal is to learn about the market’s perception of corporate tax avoidance,

e.g. the information content of firms’ taxable income conveyed to investors, it is only consistent to use

information that is also actually available to the market, i.e. information other than tax return data

(Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]).

Not uncommonly, existing measures are adjusted or “refined” within the context of particular studies.

A prominent example can be found in Dyreng et al. [2008] who investigate firms’ overall ability to

sustainably avoid taxes. The study introduces the “long-run” Cash ETR, which proxies firms’ tax lia-

bility over ten consecutive years, drawing on the item “cash taxes paid”. Further, empirical measures

may be adjusted as the individual and/or common understanding of the underlying tax construct

28

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


changes, e.g. when literature defines tax aggressiveness is in novel ways. Recent examples include

proposals to adjust corporate ETRs for the industry median or to benchmark ETRs based on firm-size

and industry (Brown and Drake [2012], Balakrishnan et al. [2012]). Alternatively, the development of

novel proxies can be motivated by the use of previously overlooked and hitherto unavailable data. A

measure for tax avoidance, in particular (risky) tax aggressiveness, that has only recently been intro-

duced is the level of (or changes in) firms’ unrecognized tax benefits (UTBs), accounted for under

FIN 48 since 2006 (e.g. Lisowsky et al. [2013]). Yet others have access to tax return data (Mills

[1998]) or use confidential survey information to proxy for tax avoidance (e.g. Mills et al. [1998]).60

Identification of Tax-Motivated Transactions

Another way to approximate a company’s tax avoidance status it to directly detect specific transac-

tions, e.g. shelter structures, which are employed with the primary purpose to reduce the corporate tax

burden. For instance, shelter firms can be identified from court records or the financial press (e.g.

Graham and Tucker [2006], Wilson [2009]), or based on shelter information directly reported to the

IRS (Lisowsky [2010], Lisowsky et al. [2013]).61 This approach is beneficial as it allows for the proper

identification of intentional transaction-based tax aggressiveness, which can create unique research

settings. On the downside, information on firms’ actual tax shelter information is frequently limited

and only available for a small number of firms. To alleviate this issue, although advising caution with

regards to the generalizability of findings, studies have developed helpful predictive models that esti-

mate the likelihood of firms being involved in tax sheltering, based on their actually observable fun-

damental firm characteristics (see e.g. Wilson [2009] and Lisowsky [2010]). Similarly focusing on

observable, likely tax-driven transactions, Dyreng and Lindsey [2009] identify U.S. multinational

groups’ foreign operations located in tax havens and show a significant association with a group’s

ETR, making “tax haven presence” another potential way to gauge corporate tax avoidance behavior.

All of the above approaches to proxy for tax avoidance and/or tax aggressiveness based either directly

on financial statement data or on observations of tax largely tax-motivated transactions, are discussed

in more detail throughout the following.

60
Mills et al. [1998] use survey data from Slemrod and Blumenthal [1993] on 365 U.S. firms’ tax-related ex-
penditures.
61
Lisowsky et al. [2013], for a sample of U.S. firms, have access to “reportable transactions” as disclosed in
Form 8886 under IRC Code §6011 to the IRS’ office of tax shelters (OTSA).

29

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


4.2. Choosing between Measures

Empirical measures reflecting corporate tax avoidance should be selected with care as strong empirical

research designs demand for target-oriented operational definitions of theoretical constructs (Libby,

Bloomfield, and Nelson [2002]).62 Valid results and solid conclusions depend on a thorough compre-

hension of empirical measures’ definitions, strengths and limitations (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]).63

As theoretical constructs of tax avoidance differ, different proxies should also be evaluated with re-

gards to their potential capability of capturing respective constructs of explicit tax planning. While

some measures may better capture the aggressive end of the spectrum, others might be useful to better

reflect variation in howsoever achieved explicit tax reductions (“broad measures” of tax avoidance).

Moreover, measures generally capable of carving out particular scopes of tax avoidance (e.g. aggres-

siveness), may still suffer bias. For instance, measures may to some extent pick up earnings manage-

ment rather than tax planning incentives. Another evaluation criterion is that of conforming versus

non-conforming tax planning. To the extent firms save taxes by concomitantly managing their book

and taxable income downwards, most non-conforming measures, such as ETRs and BTDs, will not

reflect this type of behavior.64 This can create concerns if sample firms are faced with relatively weak

financial accounting constraints (e.g. private firms). In this case, firms may be more willing to engage

in conforming types of tax avoidance because they perceive their GAAP figures in general, and GAAP

ETR in particular, to be of relatively low relevance to both their internal and external stakeholders

(Cloyd, Pratt, and Stock [1996]).

Depending on a measure’s particular definition, e.g. regarding the numerator and/or denominator of an

ETR, or the permanent or temporary character of a BTD, derived results may differ and it is important

to understand why or why not this might be the case.65 Further, while some proxies may be readily

computable for large firm samples, others impose specific data requirements that may restrict the sam-

62
For further illustration see the “predictive validity framework” (and the so-called “Libby-Boxes”), developed
in Libby [1981], Runkel and McGrath [1972], Libby et al. [2002].
63
Dunbar et al. [2010] perform extensive correlation analyses on nine tax avoidance measures and come to
conclude that the fundamental properties of the most frequently used measures “are not only different from
each other, but that each possesses a distinct, and varied, pattern of behavior:”
64
Accordingly, non-conforming proxies do generally not capture tax avoidance resulting from changes in lev-
erage, i.e. will not reflect the tax benefits of interest deductibility (Bernard [1984]).
65
Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]; Dechow et al. [2010] on the appropriate choice of earnings quality proxies.

30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


ple size or the periods covered. Some accounting-based measures rely on figures that are reported

under specific U.S. GAAP rules (e.g. UTBs as recorded under FIN 48) which makes them not easily

transferable to other, e.g. European corporate settings.66 Similarly, the usability of some metrics may

be restricted to firms with certain legal or organizational structures. For example, reporting require-

ments, and hence data availability, may vary according to the legal form of a firm.

To further illustrate that the use of particular measures is context-sensitive, the remaining section aims

to further explain the advantages and caveats of commonly applied measures. First, the definitions of

the various measures (and variations thereof) are discussed. Table 1 provides detailed definitions of 21

currently available tax avoidance measures. The key differences, advantages, and limitations, as well

as data requirements are systematically evaluated. In a second step, based on this initial assessment

and discussions in prior literature, the attempt is made to best possibly arrange each individual proxy

along the lines of the proposed unifying conceptual framework of tax planning (Section 5).

66
Another example is the information on “cash taxes paid” necessary to compute basic cash effective tax rates.
While this item is generally on Compustat for U.S. listed firms, it is not available (at least not in machine-
readable form) for most European-based firms.

31

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Table 1: Summary of Corporate Tax Avoidance Measures
Table 1 defines and describes empirical proxies of corporate tax avoidance. It complements the overview in Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] (p. 140), who summarize 11 of the following 21 measure variants.
References to original sources or examples in literature applying the measures are also provided. (Continued on next page).

Measure Definition Description Reference(s)

Worldwide total income tax expense Effective tax rate (ETR) derived from financial statement information, reflecting the Tax footnotes to U.S. GAAP
GAAP ETR
Worldwide total pre tax accounting income total tax expense (TXT) per dollar of pre-tax book income (PI) in year t. financial statements
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828

Worldwide current income tax expense Current tax expense (TXC) per dollar of pre-tax book income (PI) in year t, (un-
Porcano [1986],
Current GAAP ETR )adjusted e.g. for minority interests; extraordinary items. Alternative specifications
Worldwide total pre tax accounting income scale with operating cash flows.
Zimmerman [1983]

ETR Differential Statutory ETR GAAP ETR The difference between the statutory ETR and the firm's GAAP ETR in year t. Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]

Worldwide cash taxes paid Cash taxes paid (TXPD) per dollar of pre-tax book income (PI) in year t, (un- E.g. Dyreng et al. [2008],
Cash ETR
Adjusted worldwide total pre tax accounting income )adjusted e.g. for minority interests; extraordinary items. Chen et al. [2010]

∑ Worldwide cash taxes paid Sum of cash taxes paid (TXPD) over n years divided by the sum of pre-tax earnings
Long‐run Cash ETR Dyreng et al. [2008]
∑ Adjusted worldwide total pre tax accounting income (PI) over n years (less special items (SPI)).

∑ Worldwide cash taxes paid


Cash tax ratio Ratio of cash taxes paid to cash flows from operations in year t. Dyreng, Hanlon, and Maydew [2008, 2010]
∑ Pre tax operating cash flow before interest and taxes

Long run CASH ETR , industrymedian Long run CASH ETR , ,


Cash ETR_3_INDi,p where: Three-year average cash ETR adjusted for the industry median; p indicating one of
Brown and Drake [2012]
∑ cashtaxpaid twelve rolling three-year periods within the sample time frame.
LRCASHETR ,
∑ pretaxincome specialitems

Firms’ mean industry size Cash (or GAAP) ETR less firms’ Cash (GAAP) ETR, where Cash
TA_Cash ETR;
(GAAP) ETR is the sum of current tax expense (cash taxes paid) over years t, t-1 and t-2, divided by Average three-year GAAP ETR (or Cash-ETR), adjusted based on industry and size. Balakrishnan et al. [2012]
TA_GAAP ETR
the sum of pre-tax income over years t, t-1 and t-2.

Current GAAP ETR equals current (i.e. total less deferred) tax expense over five
Current ∑ Worldwide current income tax expense years (t-4 to year t) divided by the sum of pre-tax book income calculated over the Ayers, Jiang, and LaPlante [2009],
GAAP ETR_5 ∑ Worldwide total pre tax accounting income same period; high tax planners defined as firms ranked in the lowest 20% of Current Harrington and Smith [2012]
GAAP ETR for each two-digit SIC industry and year.

Composite measure: 5-year GAAP- and Cash ETRs are ranked into deciles per year.
CTA See description. An average rank across the two measures is calculated and standardized between Shevlin, Urcan, and Vasvari [2013]
zero and one.

32
The total difference between book and taxable income. Computed as the difference
Pre‐tax book income – U.S. CTE Foreign CTE / U.S. STR ‐ NOLt ‐ NOLt‐1
between book income (PI) less minority interest (MII) and an estimate of taxable
E.g. Mills et al. [1998]
income. Taxable income is estimated by grossing up the sum of federal tax expense
Total BTD Temporary BTD Permanent BTD
(TXFED) and foreign tax expense (TXFO) by the statutory rate and then subtracting

the change in the net operating loss (TCLF) from year t-1 to year 1. BTD is scaled by

BTD beginning of the year total assets (AT).


Definition in Manzon and Plesko 2002 :
Measure estimates amount of variation between book and taxable income explained
US domestic income – U.S.CTE/U.S. STR – state income taxes – other income taxes – equity in by different tax and accounting rules and economic factors.
Manzon and Plesko [2002]
earnings
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828

Permanent book-tax differences computed as the difference between total book-tax


Permanent BTD
Total BTD ‐ Temporary BTD differences (BTD) and temporary book-tax differences. According to Shevlin [2002] Shevlin [2002]
PermBTD
(p. 439) “the ideal tax shelter would give rise to permanent differences”.

Hanlon [2005],
Temporary BTD Deferred tax expense ‐ Statutory tax rate Computed by grossing up deferred tax expense (DTE) by the statutory rate (STR).
Blaylock, Shevlin, and Wilson [2012]

A measure of unexplained, "abnormal" total book-tax differences. Desai and


Discretionary total BTD Residual from Desai and Dharmapala [2006, 2009],
Dharmapala [2006, 2009] use the residuals from regression of the Manzon and
DD_BTD BTDit ß1TACCit μi εit Chyz, Leung, Li, and Rui [2013]
Plesko [2002] version of BTD on total accruals.

Error term from the following regression: The unexplained portion of the ETR differential (=GAAP ETR minus statutory tax
ETR differential x Pre‐tax book income a b x Controls e rate).
DTAX Frank, Lynch, and Rego [2009]
Residual obtained from: DTAX is the residual obtained from estimating the equation to the left by GICS code
PERMDIFFit α0 α1INTANGit α2UNCONit α3MIit α4CSTEit α5ΔNOLit α6LAGPERMit εit and fiscal year, where all variables, including the intercept, are scaled by beginning
of the year total assets (AT).

DTAX measure modified by including the Oler, Shevlin, and Wilson [2007] measure
Modified DTAX Equation as above plus log of foreign assets as additional control. Armstrong, Blouin, Jagolinzer, and Larcker [2012a]
of foreign assets to control for multinational operations.

Residuals from the following regression:


Excess GAAP ETR; GAAP ETR , or Cash ETR , α β ∗ LogTA , β ∗ Levearge , β ∗ DivDummy , β ∗ PB , Abnormal ETRs not explained by financial and firm- specific characteristics;
Huseynov and Klamm [2012]
Excess Cash ETR β ∗ INSTOWN , β ROA , β ∗ CapExp , ε , residuals from an equation that regresses ETR measures on firm specific variables.

Tax liability accrued for taxes not yet paid on uncertain positions.

Can be predicted (Pred_UTB) at the end of year t. Calculated based on the estimated E.g. Rego and Wilson [2012],
UTB Unrecognized tax benefit, i.e. amount of tax reserves disclosed under FIN 48. coefficients from the following prediction model: Lisowsky et al. [2013]
UTB α α PT_ROA α SIZE α FOR_SALE α R&D α LEV α DISC_ACCR
α SG&A α MTB α SALES_GR

Graham and Tucker [2006]


(Shelter Active Dummy; TSP),
Tax shelter activity Firms identified via court records, news from the financial press, or confidential tax
Indicator variable set equal to one for firms engaged in tax shelters. Wilson [2009] (SHELTER),
TSP, SHELTER, RT data (e.g. reportable transactions to the OTSA).
Lisowsky [2010, 2013] (RT),
Lanis and Richardson [2011]

Estimated probability that a firm engages in a tax shelter, derived from a tax shelter
Wilson [2009],
Prob_SHELTER Probability that a firm engages in a tax shelter. utilization model's main parameter estimates. Prob_SHELTER cannot identify the
Lisowsky [2010] (TSS)
dollar size of tax shelter benefits.

The number of material operations in tax haven locations


HAVEN Tax haven involvement identified based on Exhibit 21 data (10-K). Dyreng and Lindsey [2009]
disclosed in Exhibit 21 of the current year 10‐K.

33
a. Variants of Effective Tax Rates

Effective tax rates (ETRs) relate a company’s tax burden to its ability to pay taxes and are used to

indicate the relative tax burden across firms (Rego [2003]). ETR-based measures are generally calcu-

lated by dividing some estimate of a firm’s tax liability (numerator) by a measure of pretax profits or

cash flows (denominator). In order to fully understand possible inferences across different ETR

measures it is vital to know what the different numerators and denominators capture and what type of

explicit tax avoidance they do not reflect (see Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]). Most apparently, differ-

ent ETR variants vary in terms of what they include as the relevant tax liability in the numerator.

Some GAAP-based ETRs include the total, i.e. the current plus the deferred tax expense, whereas al-

ternative definitions merely use the current tax expense. Alternatively, ETRs can be calculated using

cash taxes paid in the numerator instead (Cash ETRs).67 With respect to the relevant time horizon,

ETRs can either be computed on an annual basis or cumulated over multiple years (long-run ETRs).

GAAP- and Cash ETRs

The GAAP ETR is defined as total income tax expense divided by pre-tax accounting income (see

Table 1). As the total tax expense in the numerator represents the sum of current plus deferred tax

expense, the GAAP ETR is not affected by any tax strategies that defer the expense of taxes (e.g. dif-

ferent depreciation patterns for book and tax purposes). Alternatively, the GAAP ETR can be defined

to only include the current tax expense in the numerator (Current GAAP ETR), in which case defer-

ral strategies would be reflected. Thus, the GAAP ETR is the rate that impacts accounting, whereas the

Current GAAP ETR may only impact accounting earnings if the item that affects the Current GAAP

ETR is not a temporary difference (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]).

As indicated more generally in Section 4.1, drawing on financial statement data to derive expensed

taxes bears the risk of over- or understating the estimated tax expense relative to the taxes actually

paid.68 This may be the case with respect to accounting items such as large tax deductions for stock

67
Cash taxes paid of U.S. firms can be found in the financial statements as a supplemental disclosure within the
statement of cash flows or in the notes. “Cash tax paid” is data item 317 in Compustat.
68
See e.g. Hanlon [2003] and Plesko [2003].

34

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


options, 69 valuation allowances, or tax contingency reserves (“tax cushions”)70 accounted for under

FAS No. 109. Another way to gauge a firm’s tax avoidance status involving the GAAP ETRs is to

calculate its ETR Differential. This measure is defined as the difference between a jurisdiction’s stat-

utory tax rate and the firm’s GAAP ETR. The lower a firm’s realized GAAP ETR is compared to the

generally applicable tax rate, the more tax avoidance it likely conducts. Obviously, if using the same

(e.g. U.S.) statutory tax rate across all firms within a given sample, comparing GAAP ETRs directly

would yield similar results (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]).

The Cash ETR is defined as cash income taxes paid over a firm’s pretax book income. As opposed to

GAAP ETRs, Cash-based ETRs do not impact accounting earnings and are not affected by changes in

accounting accruals. They do however reflect deferral strategies. If estimated on an annual basis, the

Cash ETR’s numerator and denominator might not match if the cash taxes paid include taxes paid on

different period’s earnings (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]).71 An advantage of using cash taxes in the

numerator is that tax benefits are taken into account notwithstanding their income sheet treatment, e.g.

the tax consequences of employee stock options. Moreover, Cash ETRs (unlike GAAP ETRs) remain

unaffected by changes in valuation allowances or tax reserves (Dyreng et al. [2008]).

The tax expense (cash taxes paid) in the nominator of a GAAP ETR (Cash ETR) in most studies repre-

sents the worldwide tax expense (worldwide cash taxes paid), i.e. the estimated tax liability is not lim-

ited to federal taxes but includes all local, state, and foreign taxes.72 This is important in order to avoid

a mismatch between the numerator and the denominator, in particular in cases of large multinational

69
See Hanlon and Shevlin [2002] for further details on the research implications of accounting for tax benefits
of employee stock options. Evidence further suggests that management manipulates earnings through these
accounts (Gleason and Mills [2002], Miller and Skinner [1998], Schrand and Wong [2003], Dhaliwal et al.
[2004]).
70
See Cazier et al. [2009] for further discussion of tax reserves.
71
Another (general) source of mismatch between the numerator and the denominator of an ETR could be “ex-
traordinary items”71 (Gallemore and Labro [2013]). Such items are not reflected in the denominator of the
ETR, as they are reported below pretax income (i.e. presented separately in the income statement). This is
problematic if firms pay at least some taxes on these items, which would lead to an increase in the numerator
while leaving the denominator unaffected. To control for this effect, Gallemore and Labro [2013] include ex-
traordinary items (scaled by average total assets) as an explanatory variable in their cross-sectional regression
of information environment quality on the Cash ETR. They predict and find a positive effect.
72
For further variations of GAAP ETR definitions that “can be selected along three dimensions: tax, income,
and sample.”, see Omer et al. [1993], with further reference to Stickney and McGee [1982], Zimmerman
[1983], and Shevlin [1987].

35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


firms that conduct business – and potentially pay taxes – across multiple jurisdictions.73 More general-

ly, available financial statement information allows only for the computation of worldwide tax rates on

worldwide income, federal tax rates on domestic income, or foreign tax rates on foreign income. In

other words, “this simple [effective tax rate] calculation can only capture information as fine as the

numerator or denominator” (Dyreng and Lindsey [2009], p. 1285).74

With further respect to the denominator, GAAP- and Cash ETRs both use pretax GAAP earnings and

thus can only capture non-conforming tax avoidance. That is, ETR measures only reflect tax avoid-

ance activities that create a deviation between book and taxable income.75 In turn, ETRs do not reflect

any conforming tax strategies that avoid explicit taxes by reporting both lower GAAP earnings and

lower taxable income. For example, ETRs will generally not reflect the tax benefits of changes in lev-

erage or interest deductibility (Bernard [1984]).76 This can be especially relevant if investigated firms

are private (not public) firms. Private firms are commonly assumed to engage in more conforming tax

planning than public firms because private firms face lower financial reporting costs (see Cloyd et al.

[1996], Hanlon, Mills, and Slemrod [2007]). In sum, particularly with a view to studies focusing on

private firms, results need to be interpreted with care when using common tax avoidance proxies.

73
An alternative approach can be found in Desai and Dharmapala [2009], who prefer using firms’ reported
current federal tax expense only, since this procedure avoids problems of inferring the applicable foreign tax
rates. Alternatively, the authors include a control variable approximating foreign activity in their regression
analysis (see. Desai and Dharmapala [2009], pp. 39-40).
74
For the case of large multinationals, in order to better depict how foreign operations actually affect world-
wide, federal, and foreign tax rates of U.S. groups, Dyreng and Lindsey [2009] hence develop a specific re-
gression framework. This allows capturing the variation in estimated tax expense measures associated with
income sourced in various locations.
75
Examples for book-tax non-conforming tax avoidance include the straightforward use of R&D development
tax credits, the relocation of operations to low-tax countries, the shift of income from high- to low-tax loca-
tions, the engagement in synthetic lease transactions, or the use of off-balance sheet entities to create deduc-
tions or losses that reduce the consolidated taxable income (see Badertscher et al. [2011] , p. 14, Fn. 12).
76
Further examples for conforming tax avoidance are the acceleration of R&D- as well as advertising expendi-
tures, the deferral of revenue recognition to future periods (“real transaction management”), or the selling of
assets to generate one-time gains or losses that similarly affect book and taxable income (“one-time transac-
tion management”), see Badertscher et al. [2011] (p. 19), Klassen [1997].

36

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Long-Run ETRs

Dyreng et al. [2008] suggest the Long-run Cash ETR defined as the sum of cash taxes paid over ten

years divided by the sum of pre-tax earnings (less special items77) over those same ten years. The au-

thors point out the long-run nature of the measure as a main benefit as it alleviates the year-to-year

volatility in annual ETRs and more closely depicts firms’ actual explicit tax costs over time.78 Further,

any long-run ETR should have the ability to capture potential reversals of accounting accruals and

should thus be less affected by accrual management, e.g. compared to annual ETRs.79 However, as the

denominator of the long-run Cash ETR is also a measure of GAAP pretax income, concerns may per-

sist that upward earnings management (with no corresponding effect on taxes paid) biases the ETR

downward (e.g. Badertscher et al. [2011]). This concern is somewhat mitigated in the case of long-run

measures, because firms that succeed in permanently managing their pretax book-income upward

without having to pay additional taxes, can still be considered tax avoiders (Hanlon and Heitzman

[2010]). In their investigation exploring the effects of top executives on tax avoidance, Dyreng,

Hanlon, and Maydew [2010] alternatively use cash flows from operations in the denominator of their

long-run ETR (Cash tax ratio).80 This allows to better control for executives’ earnings management

incentives possibly affecting the pre-tax earnings in common ETRs’ denominators.81 In addition, the

Cash tax ratio is interesting as it allows for the measurement of some conforming tax avoidance, at

least as long as the underlying tax strategy is accrual-based.82

In sum, as Dyreng et al.’s [2008] original research objective is to gauge the extent to which some U.S.

companies are able to avoid cash taxes (a) sustainably over time, and (b) by any available means, the

use of long-run cash-based ETR measures or variants thereof appears intuitive. However, the long-run

cash ETR was developed in the particular context of one study and does not necessarily need to be

77
It has become common practice to subtract special items as they are sometimes large, thus introducing con-
siderable volatility (especially in annual) ETRs, see Dyreng et al. [2008], with further reference to
Burgstahler et al. [2002]. Dechow and Ge [2006] provide evidence that investors might misunderstand the
transitory nature of special items.
78
One obvious “downside” of long-run measures is that there are usually fewer available firms.
79
Studies have argued that earnings management most likely occurs through exercising discretion in determin-
ing accruals, e.g. Healy [1985].
80
Dyreng et al. [2008] originally developed this measure as an alternative specification in their 2008 paper.
81
Although the interpretation of this ratio becomes somewhat less intuitive (Dyreng et al. [2010], p. 1177).
82
As it otherwise would again reduce both the denominator (operative cash flows) and the numerator (taxable
income; taxes paid), see Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] (p. 141, Fn. 49).

37

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


(nor was it ever intended to be) the superior tax avoidance measure in every other research setting.

Even though (variants of) long-run Cash ETRs are probably the most frequently applied measures

throughout literature,83 research designs still need to be sensitive to the circumstance that for specific

questions there may be other, maybe more suitable measures available.

Besides varying the relevant time frame, another way to adjust long-run ETR measures is to bench-

mark the ratio against the industry median or based on firms relative size. Brown and Drake [2012] (p.

13) calculate firms’ three-year average cash ETR adjusted for the industry84 median cash ETR (Cash

ETR_3_INDi,p), with p indicating one of twelve rolling three-year periods within the sample’s time

span. In line with Dyreng et al. [2008], the notion behind using a three-year horizon is to reduce statis-

tical noise. The idea behind benchmarking the ratio against the respective industry’s mean is to ac-

count for the possibility that tax avoidance opportunities may be correlated with industry membership,

although results in Dyreng et al. [2008] demonstrate that there is also considerable within-industry

variation of corporate tax planning. Balakrishnan et al. [2012] define tax aggressive firms as the ones

that pay unusually amounts of taxes relative to their industry and size (TA_Cash ETR). Hence, this

study additionally benchmarks the three-year Cash ETR (and GAAP ETR alternatively) against a

firm’s size in the attempt to thoroughly single out the above “normal”85 level of explicit tax planning.

Alternatively, although less common, long-run ETRs can also be calculated using Current GAAP

ETRs. For example, Ayers et al. [2009] cumulate current effective tax rates over five consecutive

years (Current GAAP ETR_5) and treat firms ranked in the lowest 20 percent of Current GAAP

ETR_5 for each two-digit SIC industry and year as high tax-avoiding firms. The five-year accumula-

tion is intended to offset some of the potential over- and understatement of the (actual) tax liability.

Moreover, since the study’s particular focus is on taxes due in the current period, deferred tax expens-

es representing future tax effects from current transactions are excluded from the definition. Being

aware of GAAP-based ETRs’ own limitations, the study draws on Cash ETRs in alternative specifica-

tions; a procedure common to many studies investigating the determinants and consequences of tax

avoidance in order to thoroughly address research design limitations.

83
Although often using alternative time horizons, e.g. three or five years instead of ten. Notice that cash taxes
paid over shorter time periods become less meaningful as they include payments to (and refunds from) the
IRS and other authorities pertaining to tax disputes that began many years ago (see e.g. Dyreng et al. [2010]).
84
Industries are classified according to Barth et al. [1998].
85
Balakrishnan et al. [2012] p. 10. Industries in this study are classified based on Fama and French [1997].

38

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Another recent approach to the ETR-based measurement of tax avoidance can be found in Shevlin et

al. [2013], who combine firms’ five-year cumulative GAAP- and Cash ETR into a single measure, the

so-called composite tax avoidance measure (CTA).86 The idea is to reduce error and noise effects

entailed in the GAAP- and Cash ETR. To obtain the CTA measure, both the GAAP- and the Cash

ETRs are ranked into deciles in every observed year. Then an average rank across both measures is

calculated and standardized to range between zero (high tax avoidance) and one (low tax avoidance).87

b. Variants of Book-Tax Differences

The total, i.e. the permanent plus the temporary, book-tax difference (BTD) is an estimate of the dif-

ference between a firm’s reported pretax book income and its estimated taxable income.88 Such a re-

porting gap may generally result from the fact that firms follow separate sets of rules for tax and fi-

nancial accounting, each pursuing different objectives.89 Assuming a high degree of conformity be-

tween financial and tax accounting rules, firms likely face a fundamental trade-off when making fi-

nancial and tax reporting decisions. This is because a generally desired increase of financial reporting

income may inevitably come at higher tax costs, whereas the attempt to report a lower income to the

tax authorities would have to coincide with a lower income reported to shareholders (i.e. financial

reporting costs).90 Nonetheless, studies have documented a significant increase in BTDs during the

1990s,91 indicating that firms may in fact not always have to trade off their financial and tax reporting

choices. Instead, firms appear to have opportunities to manage their book income upwards (to report a

86
An application example being the observation in Shevlin et al. [2013] that a drop in the CTA measure from
the 90th percentile to the 10th percentile of its sample distribution is paralleled by a decrease in cash flows
(scaled by total assets) by 0.7 % (the sample’s average cash flow ratio being 11 %), (p. 6).
87
See Shevlin et al. [2013] (p. 18) and Panel A of Table 2 (p. 47).
88
The total BTD can be decomposed into a temporary and a permanent part (see Table 1). As tax avoidance
activities that generate temporary differences lead to a lower current tax expense, they also lead to a corre-
sponding increase in the deferred tax expense. Thus, the total BTD would largely remain unaffected by tem-
porary tax strategies. By contrast, the temporary BTD (defined as the deferred tax expense grossed up by the
statutory tax rate) would capture such reverting tax strategies. Accordingly, the permanent BTD is defined as
the total BTD minus the temporary BTD.
89
See Manzon and Plesko [2002] (pp. 178-184) for a thorough discussion. See also Section 4 of this study.
90
See Shackelford and Shevlin [2001] for a survey of literature investigating this trade-off.
91
See e.g. Manzon and Plesko [2002] (p. 186) for a graphic illustration of the increase in BTDs.

39

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


strong economic performance), while at the same time managing their taxable income downwards (to

reduce their tax burden).92

Research generally adopts the view that firms’ tax and financial accounting choices are fairly inde-

pendent.93 Following this view, it appears intuitive that BTDs should provide some information about

corporate tax avoidance behavior.94 Nevertheless, BTDs conceptually do not necessarily reflect tax

avoidance, especially if the over-reporting of book income (“earnings management”) is the primary

cause of a BTD.95 As valid tax outcomes are much harder to derive than e.g. earnings quality charac-

teristics, the great challenge for tax research is to accurately document the tax-related part of a BTD

(Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]). Moreover, the existence of firm-specific characteristics independent of

aggressive tax or book reporting may further complicate the use of BTDs as a proxy for tax aggres-

siveness (Wilson [2009]).

While caution is thus advisable,96 there is nevertheless considerable evidence indicating that large

positive BTDs might serve as a useful signal of tax avoidance. Considering that both financial and tax

income are ultimately based on the same underlying economic transactions,97 tax authorities might

view large gaps between the book income and the taxable income as a sign of potential tax aggres-

siveness and step up their investigative efforts (Cloyd [1995], Cloyd et al. [1996], Badertscher,

92
This incentive to reduce taxable income is also present in loss firms, as losses provide firms with tax benefits
through the use of carrybacks and carryforwards (Maydew [1997]).
93
See e.g. Cloyd [1995], Cummins et al. [1995], Kasanen et al. [1996], Mills [1998], Phillips [2003], Frank et
al. [2009].
94
As Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] (p. 141, Fn. 50) point out, BTD-measures are closely related to ETR mea-
sures, as BTD measures subtract one measure of income from the other and ETR measures relate some esti-
mate of a tax liability to a measure of income. Obviously, the fundamental caveats to the approach of infer-
ring taxable income from financial statements (Hanlon [2003]) also carry over to the estimates of BTDs.
95
In this case, the book income may be significantly increased within the scope of managerial discretion, while
leaving the taxable income rather unaffected. Prior studies provide compelling evidence that (aggressive) fi-
nancial reporting practices in parts contribute to the existence of BTDs and that firms with large temporary
BTDs exhibit less persistent (i.e. lower quality) GAAP earnings (Hanlon [2005], Lev and Nissim [2004]).
96
E.g. Manzon and Plesko [2002], Hanlon and Shevlin [2005], Mills et al. [2002].
97
Further considering that not only GAAP standards but also IRC Section 446 (a) demands that tax accounting
methods “clearly reflect income”.

40

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Phillips, Pincus, and Olhoft [2009]).98 Thoroughly outlining this argumentation, Mills [1998] predicts

and finds that firms with larger BTDs face greater proposed IRS audit adjustments.99

Desai [2003] investigates the above mentioned increase in BTDs during the 1990s and posits that the

divergence of book and tax income is not assignable to common financial accounting drivers (e.g.

depreciation), but rather to increased tax shelter activity. Moreover, Desai and Dharmapala [2009]

perform a validation check of BTDs as a valid measure of tax sheltering. Following Graham and

Tucker [2006], the authors compile a set of firms allegedly involved in shelter activity in a particular

year. Using a logit model (indicator variable set to 1 for alleged tax shelter firm-years), they estimate

the relationship between tax sheltering and BTDs, controlling for various firm characteristics.100 All

else constant, the BTD tends to be larger in firm-years of alleged sheltering (Desai and Dharmapala

[2009], Table 2, p. 540-41). Heltzer [2009] transfers the Basu [1997] measure of accounting conserva-

tism to the taxation context, suggesting that while firms with large positive total BTDs exhibit finan-

cial-reporting conservatism similar to that of other firms, they do appear to engage in more “conserva-

tive” tax reporting (which, in a tax context, seems interpretable as being more aggressive).

Tax sheltering, an aggressive means to avoid taxes, is often considered to create permanent (rather

than temporary) BTDs, which makes Permanent BTDs particularly attractive to the tax planning cor-

poration and potentially useful as a measure to gauge tax aggressiveness. Based on court records and

press articles, Wilson [2009] identifies a sample of firms accused of tax sheltering and develops a pre-

dictive model of the type of firms that are likely involved in tax sheltering. Estimated coefficients

from logistic regressions and marginal changes in the probability of employing a tax shelter indicate

that a 1 % increase in BTDs leads to a 2.78 % increase in the probability a firm is involved in tax shel-

tering. These findings imply that large BTDs may well serve as a signal of aggressive tax reporting.

98
In a similar notion, but with a focus on the earnings quality dimension, large BTDs have been found to lead
to greater scrutiny from external auditors (Hanlon et al. [2012]) and are likely interpreted as “negative infor-
mation” by credit rating agencies (Ayers et al. [2010]).
99
Next to total BTDs, Mills [1998] uses the difference between the federal tax expense for book less the tax as
declared to the IRS as an alternative BTD measure. Third, she uses the deferred tax expense (temporary
BTDs).
100
The idea to infer tax shelter behavior from financial statements originally stems from the U.S. Department of
Treasury [1999], who noted that “one hallmark of corporate tax shelters is a reduction in taxable income with
no concomitant reduction in book income.” (pp. ii and 3) and that a major feature of tax shelters was the “in-
consistent financial accounting and tax treatment […]” (p. v), see also McGill and Outslay [2004] (p. 743).

41

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


In another recent paper, Blaylock et al. [2012] extend prior research on the ability of Temporary

BTDs to provide information on earning quality (Hanlon [2005]). Their work contributes to current

research by suggesting novel methods for partitioning firms according to the source of their large

BTDs. The results provided in Blaylock et al. [2012] suggest that in cases where large positive tempo-

rary BTDs are predominantly driven by tax avoidance (earnings management), earnings and accruals

persistence is higher (lower), compared to other firms with large positive BTDs.

In sum, acknowledging the competing explanations for BTDs, evidence suggests that BTDs may cap-

ture a notable portion of tax avoidance. In particular, studies repeatedly highlight a significant associa-

tion between rather tax aggressive actions, i.e. tax sheltering, and large BTDs. However, as an im-

portant limitation, studies name their (often small) samples including those firms who engage in tax

actions that draw the particular attention of tax authorities, or firms that are actually “caught” with

inappropriate tax sheltering by the IRS.101 Thus, there is a potential selection bias and results may not

easily be generalizable. Also, findings might not simply be transferable to newer or further advanced

types of tax sheltering that have not yet been present at the time of a study (Wilson [2009], p. 993).

Lastly, just like ETR-based measures, BTDs obviously only reflect non-conforming tax avoidance,

which makes them impractical to use when comparing tax avoidance behavior across firms that attach

varying degrees of importance on their financial accounting earnings.

c. Discretionary and Abnormal Measure Partitions

In the manner of the Jones [1991] model, which proxies a firm’s engagement in earnings management

by estimating the discretionary part of accounting accruals, the literature suggests ways to isolate the

discretionary part of a BTD that most likely reflects tax avoidance (DD_BTD). Using the residuals

from panel data regressions of firms’ total BTDs102 on total accruals,103 Desai and Dharmapala [2006,

2009] aim to carve out the portion of the BTD that is attributable to tax planning, i.e. which is not

101
If the IRS or other tax authorities look for large BTDs to identify corporate tax aggressiveness, then what
many studies – at least to some extent –capture is the tax authority’s perception or model of tax aggressive-
ness (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010], p. 141).
102
Defined according to Manzon and Plesko [2002], see Table 1 above for details.
103
In alternative specifications (following e.g. Healy [1985], Dechow et al. [1995]), BTDs are regressed on
abnormal accruals in order to quantify the extent to which earnings management is the driver of the book-tax
gap, see Desai and Dharmapala [2006], Section 5).

42

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


explained by earnings management.104 In the context of their study, the authors use this “abnormal”

part of discretionary BTDs as their measure for tax avoidance, or more precisely, tax sheltering.

Frank et al. [2009] investigate the relation between aggressive tax reporting and aggressive financial

reporting. The authors consider firms to be tax aggressive if they exhibit high discretionary permanent

BTDs (rather than total or temporary BTDs) that are likely related to tax planning. The study’s meas-

ure of tax aggressiveness is obtained by regressing permanent differences (PERMDIFF)105 on nondis-

cretionary items unrelated to explicit tax planning.106 The residual from this regression, the unex-

plained discretionary portion of permanent BTDs, is their measure of tax aggressiveness (DTAX).

Frank et al. [2009] (p. 471) support their decision to base the measure on permanent differences with

two main reasons. First, temporary BTDs have been found to capture pre-tax accrual management

(e.g. Phillips, Pincus, and Rego [2003]), hence tax avoidance measures that include temporary or total

BTDs may be spuriously correlated with proxies for financial reporting aggressiveness.107 Second,

(largely anecdotal) evidence on the common nature of aggressive tax shelters suggests that tax shelter-

ing rather generates permanent, as opposed to temporary, BTDs.108 Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] as-

sume a skeptical view with regards to the latter argument, pointing out that “shelters” come in many

different forms, some of them just as well generating temporary BTDs, or even no BTD at all.109

104
As the authors point out themselves, the fact that this measure is estimated in form of a residual makes it
impractical to be quantified in dollar amounts or to measure aggregated tax sheltering across firms and/or
whole economies (as the residual sums to zero for firm i over all years, see Desai and Dharmapala [2006], p.
160).
105
Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] stress that the denotation “PERMDIFF” is rather unfortunate, given that this
measure as it is defined actually captures more than permanent BTDs. In fact, PERMDIFF captures anything
that affects GAAP ETRs (e.g. also tax credits, foreign operations being subjected to different tax rates, earn-
ings designated as permanently reinvested), and can alternatively be thought “[…] the difference between the
effective and statutory tax rates multiplied by pre-tax accounting income” (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010], p.
142). DTAX then would be the portion of this ETR differential under management’s control (e.g. by engag-
ing in shelters).
106
These items include goodwill, intangible assets, minority interest, current state tax expense, change in tax
loss carryforwards, and prior period’s permanent BTD (by year and two-digit SIC industry).
107
Tax avoidance actions that generate permanent tax benefits increase net income, but do not affect pre-tax
discretionary accruals.
108
Frank et al. [2009] (p. 472) refer to Weisbach [2002b], Shevlin [2002], Wilson [2009], Graham and Tucker
[2006] and the U.S. Department of Treasury [1999].
109
Descriptions of different types of tax shelters can be found in Wilson [2009] (Appendix, p. 995), Hanlon and
Slemrod [2009] (Appendix A, p. 139), Desai [2009] (p. 172, on Enron’s “project steel”), and U.S.
Department of Treasury [1999].

43

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


A slightly modified version of the DTAX measure (Modified DTAX) can be found in Armstrong et

al. [2012a]. The definition is generally equal to that in Frank et al. [2009] (see Table 1), however, the

variables regressed on PERDMIFF to obtain the error term representing the discretionary portion of

tax-motivated permanent differences further include foreign assets as a control (as measured in Oler et

al. [2007]). The goal is to control for the presence of “ordinary” multinational operations that may

result in ETR differentials but do not necessarily make a firm a particular tax aggressive firm

(Armstrong et al. [2012a], p. 14, Fn. 9). Huseynov and Klamm [2012] alternatively estimate the ab-

normal part of a firm’s GAAP ETRs (Excess GAAP ETR), and Cash ETR respectively. Similar to the

approach taken in Frank et al. [2009], GAAP or Cash ETRs are regressed on firm fundamentals, such

as total assets, leverage, institutional ownership, return on assets, and capital expenditures, in order to

obtain a residual ETR component reflecting discretionary tax avoidance actions.

Overall, in order to get some sense of the extent to which firms (intentionally) engage in tax avoid-

ance, the approach to infer tax-related discretionary portions of BTDs or ETRs appears conceptually

helpful. However, as is the case with the Jones [1991] model and modified versions thereof (e.g.

Dechow and Dichev [2002]), a model’s power greatly depends on its ability to accurately separate the

relevant “abnormal” part from the total effect.110 In this regard, a model is only as good as the proxies

included to single out the known (or rather believed to be known) determinants of non-discretionary

behavior. Closely related to this issue, it requires implicit assumptions as to which BTD-affecting ac-

tions are primarily tax driven (i.e. “intentional” tax avoidance), and which actions may only be of sec-

ond-order importance (i.e. a “byproduct” of earnings management) and should thus rather be captured

in the non-tax driven controls than in the regressions’ residuals (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]).

d. Unrecognized Tax Benefits

In 2006, FASB issued FIN 48 “Accounting for Uncertainty in Income Taxes” (ASC 740-10) with the

intention to reduce the diversity in practice related to the reporting of tax reserves.111 Under FIN 48,

110
For example, original Jones-type models sometimes explain as little as 10 % of the variation in accruals
Dechow et al. [2010] and are likely to be severely misspecified if they fail to adequately control for firm per-
formance (Kothari et al. [2005]) or firm growth (McNichols [2000], Collins et al. [2012]), which to a great
extent determine over what should be considered the “normal” level of accruals.
111
Prior to FIN 48, under SFAS 109 and SFAS 105, tax contingency reporting did not follow a uniform ap-
proach (alternatives included the “loss contingency-”, “best estimate-”, and “tax advantaged-” approach, see

44

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


publicly traded firms are required to disclose their unrecognized tax benefits (UTB), which represent

an income tax reserve for future tax contingencies. Accordingly, UTBs are also referred to as “tax

reserves” or “tax contingencies” (e.g. Cazier, Rego, Tian, and Wilson [2011]).112

Under FIN 48, all uncertain tax positions must be evaluated in a two-step recognition and measure-

ment approach. This approach requires a firm to determine whether its tax position meets the more-

likely-than-not (MLTN) probability of being legally sustainable upon audit on its tax return, based

solely on its technical merits. In cases where the MLTN threshold is not satisfied, no tax benefit will

be recorded. For tax positions meeting or beating the MLTN threshold, the recordable tax benefit is

the largest amount of benefit that is cumulatively greater than 50% likely to be realized. The remain-

ing difference between the tax benefits as reported on the tax return and the benefits that passed the

two-step recognition and measurement procedure is recorded as an increase in the tax reserve.113

This approach to accounting for uncertain tax positions immediately suggests that the FIN 48 tax re-

serve should at least reflect some scope of uncertainty inherent in a (self-assessed) tax position and

hence also some extent of tax-related managerial discretion.114 Following this notion, Frischmann et al.

[2008] consider tax reporting to be aggressive if it involves certain risks. Adopting this concept of

e.g. Dunbar et al. [2007]), and relevant information was usually not disclosed. Gleason and Mills [2002] in-
vestigate the diversity in tax reserve disclosure practice prior to FIN 48 and find it to be partly related to
firms’ inconsistent interpretation of the materiality threshold. For an early post-implementation review of ac-
ademic research dealing with FIN 48 see Blouin and Robinson [2011]. FIN 48 applies to annual periods after
December 15, 2006 (December 15, 2008 for private firms).
112
UTB data can be obtained from tax footnote disclosures. Based on that information, UTBs can also be esti-
mated (PRED_UTB) using a predictive model that draws on other firm characteristics (see e.g. Rego and
Wilson [2012]).
113
See Dunbar et al. [2007] (pp. 3-5) for an illustrative example, Robinson and Schmidt [2013] (appendix A) for
an overview of the specific disclosure items required under par. 20 and 21 of FIN 48. In addition, from 2010
onwards, firms are required to report their uncertain tax positions (UTP), ranked in terms of largest to small-
est. For further discussion on this “Schedule UTP” see Coder [2010], Dellinger [2010], Sapirie [2010].
114
This notion also lead auditors and their clients to heavily criticize FIN 48, fearing the new regulation would
“provide a roadmap for the tax authority that may undercut the firm’s bargaining power in the associated tax
disputes” (Spatt [2007], see also survey responses in Graham et al. [2012]). However, while investors gener-
ally appear to incorporate portions of UTBs in their valuation considerations (e.g. Robinson and Schmidt
[2013], Koester [2011], Song and Tucker [2008]), there is only little evidence that investors may have antici-
pated any incremental costs supposedly associated with the introduction of FIN 48 (Frischmann et al.
[2008]). Lisowsky et al. [2013] provide descriptive statistics on reportable transaction participation, suggest-
ing that reporting aggressiveness decreased some years prior to FIN 48, possibly in response to other regula-
tory events (e.g. the Sarbanes-Oxley Act; SOX). Blouin and Robinson [2011] (p. 33) further summarize:
“[…] it appears that the IRS views the FIN 48 disclosure as not particularly helpful in audit selection because
it often aggregates a variety of tax positions as well as across several jurisdictions.”

45

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


“risky tax avoidance” constituting tax aggressiveness (Rego and Wilson [2012], p. 776), the amount of

UTBs accrued under FIN 48 may serve as a reasonable measure of tax avoidance, if not tax aggres-

siveness (see also DeWaegenaere, Sansing, and Wielhouwer [2010], who provide theoretical analyses

of UTBs being adequate proxies for tax aggressiveness).

However, the question to what extent observable tax reserves in fact approximate tax avoidance may

be difficult to answer. Problematic is the “dual nature” of the UTB account (Hanlon and Heitzman

[2010], p. 143). As illustrated above, the uncertainty taken on in a tax position underlying UTBs

should provide insights into firms’ tax avoidance behavior. However, because the accrual of a tax re-

serve eventually affects book net income, UTBs can also be useful instrument to engage in earnings

management.115 Hence, managers may have to trade off their aggressive tax and financial reporting

incentives when deciding on whether or not to record a tax reserve. If managers essentially pursue

their financial reporting goals, some risky uncertain tax positions may not be reflected by changes in

UTBs, while other observable changes in UTBs may in fact not always reflect tax avoidance, but earn-

ings management instead.116

Empirical studies so far suggest that UTBs capture at least some scope of tax avoidance, albeit the

“true bias” caused by aggressive financial reporting remains largely unclear. There is however some

considerable evidence that implies UTBs may at least serve as useful proxies for tax sheltering.

Lisowsky [2010] finds a positive relation between the estimated tax reserve and reportable transac-

tions disclosed to the IRS. Under the awareness that financial reporting incentives may considerably

affect FIN 48 reserves, Lisowsky et al. [2013] seek to further validate the use of tax reserve accruals to

signal aggressive tax positions. They estimate logistic regressions of reportable transaction use on the

FIN 48 tax reserve (UTB). The results suggest a significant positive association between tax shelter

115
Studies find that managers likely exercise discretion over tax reserves to achieve financial reporting goals
(Dhaliwal et al. [2004], DeSimone et al. [2011]). With regards to the post-FIN 48 regime, early evidence
suggests that UTBs are used to smooth earnings (e.g. Blouin and Tuna [2007], Gupta et al. [2012]). Auditor-
provided tax services may also play an important role in the (discretionary) determination of UTBs (Gleason
and Mills [2011]).
116
Apart from the here discussed studies, research investigating the cross-sectional determinants of UTBs to
learn more about whether FIN 48 yields valuable information related to the nature and degree of corporate
tax avoidance is still scarce (see Alexander et al. [2009], Campbell [2010], Cazier et al. [2009] for some re-
cent work in progress).

46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


participation and the tax reserve, indicating that UTBs may be a reliable proxy for predicting tax shel-

ters.117

e. Tax Shelter Participation

An alternative approach to classify firms as tax avoiders is to directly check for their actual engage-

ment in specific tax avoidance actions, namely tax sheltering.118 Empirical studies have detected Tax

shelter activity from the financial press, tax court records, or reportable transactions to the IRS or

other (tax) authorities.119

Based on court records and financial news stories, Graham and Tucker [2006] investigate a sample of

44 tax shelter participators between 1975 and 2000 and show that these firms have larger interest de-

ductions (approximately 9 %) and lower debt ratios (8 %) than comparable non-sheltering firms. Add-

ing further observations to the Graham and Tucker [2006] sample, Wilson [2009] investigates the fi-

nancial reporting effects of tax shelter involvement and develops a predictive model based on his sam-

ple of tax shelter firms (Prob_SHELTER).120 The model identifies specific firm-characteristics that

likely result from tax shelter participation (e.g. large BTDs) and are associated with the type of firm

likely engaged in tax sheltering (e.g. firm size). Lisowsky [2010] also seeks to infer tax shelter usage

from financial statements, employing confidential information on reportable transactions to the office

of tax shelter analysis (OTSA). The IRS data allows for the examination of 64 tax shelter firms (267

tax shelter observations) reported between 2000 and 2004. Results suggest that reportable transactions

are a valid proxy for publicly disclosed, i.e. litigated, tax shelters (see Graham and Tucker [2006]).

Lisowsky’s [2010] extended predictive model of tax sheltering identifies a positive relation between

shelter utilization and the presence of subsidiaries located in tax havens, foreign-source income, book-

117
In addition, with regards to the Lisowsky [2010] shelter detection model, the predictive ability of the tax
shelter score (TSS, indicating the probability of a firm engaging in tax shelters) turns out significant using
both the logged UTB and the Lisowsky [2010] variables as well as using logged UTB alone (as a summary
proxy) for tax shelter use.
118
Keep in mind that “tax sheltering” is not an individual construct of explicit tax planning, but rather a catego-
ry of explicit tax planning activities, commonly assumed to reflect rather aggressive types of tax avoidance.
119
A comparable approach to identify tax shelter engagement for an Australian firm sample is also employed in
Lanis and Richardson [2011].
120
Hanlon and Slemrod [2009] also identify tax shelter firms and relate sheltering news to stock price reactions.
In a recent working paper, Gallemore et al. [2012] combine the samples of Graham and Tucker [2006],
Wilson [2009], and Hanlon and Slemrod [2009] to obtain the largest sample of publicly identified tax shelter
firms to date (see Lietz [2013] for a detailed review).

47

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


tax differences, litigation losses, use of promoters, profitability, and size (Lisowsky [2010], p.

1695).121 In addition, the study provides a metric called TaxShelterScore, which represents the esti-

mated probability that a corporation engages in sheltering activities (see Table 1 for calculation de-

tails).

The apparent advantage of investigating a sample of actual tax shelter firms is to identify intentional

tax aggressiveness at a transaction level (Hanlon and Heitzman [2010]). Hence, if the objective is to

learn something about the tax behavior implications or typical characteristics of firms that actually

engage in sheltering, this is a valid proxy as it straightforwardly covers a particularly relevant scope of

firms. Conversely, if the desire is to gauge the “overall” level of explicit tax avoidance, tax shelter

engagement is probably an inappropriate proxy, given that shelters describe a limited scope of transac-

tions, next to a range of other possible tax avoidance activities. Thus, tax shelter firms are not neces-

sarily the ones that avoid the most taxes, also because the choice to engage in a tax shelter is most

likely an endogenous one. On the one hand, firms that cannot reduce their explicit tax burden in other

ways might use tax sheltering as the “ultima ratio” to avoid taxes. Firms that do have other means

available, on the other hand, may not need to (additionally) engage in sheltering (Hanlon and

Heitzman [2010], p. 143).

Moreover, as previously indicated in the discussion on BTD-measures, there are important selection

considerations with regards to shelter samples. Tax shelter firms, in order to be identifiable, are firms

that were actually “caught”, that is formally charged, filed suit, or revealed themselves by reporting

their tax shelter involvement to the IRS (e.g. Graham and Tucker [2006], Lisowsky et al. [2013]). To

that extent, the characteristics of the observable sample firms may not be representative of shelter

firms in general.

f. Tax Haven Presence

In the context of multinational firms, Dyreng and Lindsey [2009] show that the presence of operations

in tax haven jurisdictions (HAVEN) is significantly associated with a group’s effective tax rate. More

precisely, the authors find that U.S. firms with affiliates in at least one tax haven country display a

121
Moreover, the model yields a negative relation between tax shelter usage and leverage, which is consistent
with the findings in Graham and Tucker [2006].

48

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


worldwide ETR on pretax income that is approximately 1.5 percentage points lower than that of firms

with no tax haven operations.122 The study defines tax havens as material operations (disclosed in ex-

hibit 21 of form 10-K) in particular low-tax countries, e.g. Bahamas, Cayman Islands, Liechtenstein,

or Malta. Altogether, the study identifies 53 tax haven countries, considering a country a tax haven if it

can be identified as a haven according to at least three of four sources quoted at

http://www.globalpolicy.org (as of 03/04/2008).123 The authors themselves note that as this definition

of tax havens is static, measurement error is introduced to the extent that countries evolve into (de-

volve out) of tax haven status going forward (Dyreng and Lindsey [2009], p. 1297).

Since some affiliation of a large multinational firm to a tax haven jurisdiction is likely not very repre-

sentative of its overall efforts to engage in tax avoidance, tax haven presence is rather employed as an

alternative proxy next to other common measures124 or as a useful control variable when tax avoidance

is investigated in a global setting. For instance, Atwood, Drake, Myers, and Myers [2012] in a recent

study investigate home country tax system characteristics. The study finds that required book-tax con-

formity, worldwide or territorial tax system, and the perceived enforcement quality are related to cor-

porate tax avoidance across jurisdictions, after controlling for various firm-specific and cross-country

factors. One of these factors is the presence of tax haven operations. Interestingly, the inclusion of tax

haven presence allows the authors to infer that a change of home-country tax system features not only

affects managements’ tax avoidance through accruals management, but also through specific tax-

motivated transactions, e.g. tax havens or tax shelters (see Atwood et al. [2012], p. 1853).

122
Dyreng and Lindsey [2009] (pp. 1286-1287).
123
The three sources are the OECD, the U.S. Stop Tax Havens Abuse Act, the IMF, and the Tax Research Or-
ganization, see Dyreng and Lindsey [2009] (pp. 1297-1298, and table 2).
124
E.g. Balakrishnan et al. [2012] or Higgins et al. [2013] use tax haven presence as alternative tax aggressive-
ness proxies in their investigations.

49

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


5. Arranging the Measures within the Unifying Conceptual Framework

In the following, the most commonly used empirical measures of tax avoidance are arranged along the

lines of the proposed unifying conceptual framework of corporate tax planning. Admittedly, given that

the delineation of underlying theoretical constructs itself is ultimately a matter of judgment, and fur-

ther bearing in mind the limitations and unresolved issues surrounding the common empirical proxies,

this clearly is a demanding task.125 Still, this procedure may yield useful illustrative guidance indicat-

ing which of the empirical measures most likely capture which particular scope of explicit tax plan-

ning, e.g. tax avoidance, tax aggressiveness, or tax sheltering. Figure 3 illustrates the relevant concep-

tual constructs, complemented by the most commonly employed measures of tax avoidance.

The proxies placed along the the framework are (variants of) the GAAP- and cash ETR (GAAP ETR,

Cash ETR), book-tax differences (BTD), the discretionary portion of BTDs (DD_BTD, see Desai and

Dharmapala [2006]), permanent BTDs (PermBTD), the discretionary portion of “permanent” BTDs

(DTAX, Frank et al. [2009]), (changes of) unrecognized tax benefits (UTB), probabilities for tax shel-

ter engagement derived from predictive models (Prob_Shelter, Wilson [2009]; TSS, Lisowsky [2010]),

and actual tax shelter activity (TSP, Graham and Tucker [2006]; SHELTER, Wilson [2009]; RT,

Lisowsky [2010]).126

125
For this reason, and also for reasons of clarity, particular subforms of common measures (e.g. ETR differen-
tial or CTA as a variation of general ETR measures; see Table 1) are not further included in the discussion
(arrangement) of empirical measures along the lines of the conceptual framework (see Figure 3).
126
As discussed in Section 4.2.f., tax haven presence as opposed to active tax shelter participation, does not give
much indication of the overall tax avoidance status of a corporate group, but rather useful as an additional
control variable in studies of multinational groups’ tax behavior.

50

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Tax Planning
explicit and implicit („all parties, all taxes, all costs“)

Tax Avoidance
explicit income tax reduction

GAAP ETR
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828

Measures Cash ETR


arranged Tax Aggressiveness
according to
the scope of
BTD
tax avoidance
DD BTD
they largely
PermBTD
capture DTAX
UTB
Prob_SHELTER
“more likely than not“ TSP, SHELTER, RT
chance of a tax-related
transaction being upheld Tax Evasion
under audit >50%,

Legality:
or other specified clearly illegal;
perfectly legal Reference Point “grey-scaled“ activities with intent to defraud

Tax Sheltering

GAAP ETR (Variants of) GAAP effective tax rate(s), e.g. total tax expense devided by pretax financial income (e.g. Stickney and McGee 1982).

Cash ETR (Variants of) cash effective tax rate(s), e.g. cash taxes paid over n years divided by pretax financial income over same n years (Dyreng, Hanlon, and Maydew 2008).

BTD Book-tax-differences: total difference between financial and estimated taxable income (e.g. Desai 2003).

DD_BTD Discretionary book-tax difference: portion of BTD unexplained by earnings management (Desai and Dharmapala 2006).

PermBTD Permanent BTDs: a subset of BTDs that reflect a reduction of the firm‘s tax liability while increasing net financial income.

DTAX Discretionary permanent differences: portion of Perm_BTDs unexplained by legitimate tax positions (Frank, Lynch, and Rego 2009).

UTB Unrecognized tax benefits (e.g. Rego and Wilson 2012, Lisowsky 2013).

Prob_SHELTER Prob_S (predicted probability of a firm engaging in a tax shelter (Wilson 2009), Tax Shelter Score (TSS) (Lisowsky 2010, 2013).
Actual tax shelter activity, identified e.g. based on tax court records and news articles (e.g. tax shelter participation (TSP), Graham and Tucker 2006; SHELTER, Wilson
TSP, SHELTER, RT 2009), or via reportable transactions disclosed to OTSA (RT, Lisowsky 2010, 2013).

Figure 3: Empirical Measures within the Unifying Conceptual Framework of Tax Planning

51
The purpose of placing the individual measures along the continuum of tax avoidance is to illustrate

their aptness to capture individual constructs of explicit tax planning and to provide illustrative guid-

ance as to their usefulness depending on the specific research question. Proxies placed toward the left

end of the continuum, i.e. GAAP ETR and Cash ETR, can be reasonably assumed to reflect the

“broader” range of tax avoidance, i.e. tax avoidance including both the non-aggressive and the aggres-

sive portion of activities.127 By contrast, measures that are located further toward the right are better

suitable to proxy for aggressive tax avoidance. In line with the conceptual understanding, each indi-

vidual measure graphically extends to the right (as indicated by the grey bars in Figure 3), as any

measure captures (i.e. is likewise affected by) relatively more aggressive types of tax planning.128

In turn, measures located further right may to some extent also be affected by activities usually under-

lying constructs further to the left. For instance, BTDs likely also reflect perfectly legal tax positions

(e.g. differences in book and tax depreciations; Lisowsky et al. [2013]). Similarly, tax shelter activity

may also impact ETRs. However, the fact that tax shelter activity may have an impact on other

measures does not impair its ability to identify firms that intentionally engage in particular aggressive

tax planning.129 By contrast, one cannot clearly identify the extent to which non-aggressive actions

obscure the BTD’s power to proxy for more aggressive tax avoidance (e.g. Phillips et al. [2003]),

which implies a placement further to the left (e.g. in relation to RT or SHELTER.) Nonetheless, and as

discussed earlier, shelters are frequently assumed to lead to permanent BTDs, and BTDs have also

been shown to be correlated with IRS audit adjustments. This suggests a placement further to the right,

e.g. when compared to ETRs. Since the purpose of the DD_BTD (DTAX) measure is to extract the

discretionary part of the BTD (Perm_BTD) associated with aggressive tax avoidance, it is placed to

the right of BTD (Perm_BTD); although only slightly, taking into account the limitations of regres-

sion-based partitions (see Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] and above).

Measures like DTAX or UTB are likely to primarily reflect aggressive types of tax planning as they

incorporate the notions of “abnormal” or discretionary tax avoidance and the risk associated with a

less sustainable tax position. The Frank et al. [2009] measure of adjusted permanent BTDs, DTAX,

127
That is, ETRs capture explicit tax planning activities “that have both certain and uncertain outcomes with tax
authorities” (see Katz et al. [2013], p. 14, with reference to a three-year Cash ETR employed in their study).
128
The bars stretching all the way to the right end of the spectrum thus also illustrates that any empirical measure
is potentially affected by explicit tax reductions that result from evasive (fraudulent) illegal tax actions.
129
This places tax shelter activity (and shelter probabilities) to the aggressive end of the spectrum.

52

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


tends more toward the aggressive end of the conceptual framework (e.g. Blaylock et al. [2012]). It has

further been shown to be significantly associated with SHELTER involvement (e.g. Wilson [2009],

Dunbar et al. [2010]). Similarly, Balakrishnan et al. [2012] (pp. 9-10) posit that shelter probabilities

and DTAX likely correlate with aggressive types of tax avoidance but also point out that neither re-

flects the “full array of tax planning activities”.

Alternatively, FIN 48 straightforwardly asks management to assess the legal sustainability of any un-

certain tax position when accounting for tax reserves, implying that UTBs should be well reflective of

aggressive types of tax avoidance (Frischmann et al. [2008], DeWaegenaere et al. [2010]).130 Howev-

er, given that UTBs are likely to not only reflect the uncertainty in a firm’s tax position, but also earn-

ings management incentives (tax reserve accrual management), this measure is likely inappropriate to

proxy for broader scopes of tax avoidance.131 Additional analyses provided in Lisowsky et al. [2013]

support this placement of UTBs among the other measures of explicit tax planning. The authors run

supplementary analyses on the FIN 48 tax reserve’s ability to reflect tax shelter activity and further

include common tax avoidance measures (ETR, Cash ETR, BTD, permanent BTD, and DTAX) in

their regression of reportable transaction use (i.e. tax shelter activity) on UTBs.132 Results indicate that

none of the tax avoidance measures provide information about firms’ tax shelter engagement except

for the UTB.133 This test might imply that the tax reserve may be the strongest available proxy for tax

sheltering when compared to other existing metrics, while it is not a well suited proxy for broader

constructs, such as (non-aggressive) tax avoidance. Notice however, that the above approaches arrange

measures relative to tax sheltering, which may well be assumed to reflect individual aggressive tax

actions, but may not necessarily be representative of the overall level of tax avoidance (and thus also

aggressiveness).134

130
According to Frischmann et al. [2008] (p. 263), “UTBs provide an excellent measure of a firm’s tax aggres-
siveness because they represent management’s beliefs about the tax positions most likely to be challenged.”
131
“[…] the tax contingency or UTB is not a clean measure of tax avoidance by any stretch”, Hanlon and
Heitzman [2010] (p. 143).
132
See Lisowsky et al. [2013], eq. (1b) and Panel B of Table 4.
133
The authors conduct several robustness tests, e.g. including the other measures while excluding the UTB (test
of multicollinearity), including each measure one at a time (with/without UTB), or adjusting the BTD to
eliminate the change in UTB. Results remain unchanged, see Lisowsky et al. [2013], Fn. 38.
134
Hanlon and Heitzman [2010] (p. 143) to conclude that “studies that correlate a measure of tax avoidance with
tax shelter use may or may not be establishing support for the validity of their tax avoidance measure.”

53

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


In a contemporary working paper, Hutchens and Rego [2012] provide preliminary evidence indicating

that larger tax reserves are related to higher costs of capital. The authors start from the premise that tax

avoidance should increase after-tax cash flows and thus have a positive impact on shareholder wealth.

As UTBs likely reflect much uncertainty (i.e. risk) with respect to firms’ tax positions, shareholders

may demand higher returns from risky tax positions.135 However, when drawing on a variety of alter-

native measures of tax avoidance, Hutchens and Rego [2012] no longer find a positive association. For

lower Cash ETRs the relation with cost of capital is actually negative. As an explanation, the authors

point to the circumstance that general tax avoidance measures, e.g. Cash ETRs, likely do not capture

firms’ risk exposure. Hence, early stage findings in Hutchens and Rego [2012] would largely support

the here presented arrangement of measures along the lines of the proposed conceptual framework.

In sum, measures that predominantly capture the aggressive end of tax avoidance may be unsuitable

depending on the research question. Studies “that are indifferent to the legality of the tax avoidance”

(Blaylock et al. [2012], p. 103) should opt for rather broad measures (e.g. long-run Cash ETR), e.g. to

partition their sample in tax avoiders vs. non-tax avoiders.136 In this case, a “traditional” ETR may not

reflect temporary differences, and tax shelter activity could be too narrow to classify firms (e.g. ac-

cording to the likely source of their BTDs). Thus, “long-term Cash ETRs are appropriate for their ob-

jective” (Frank et al. [2009], Fn. 3), but not appropriate for studies that examine tax aggressiveness.137

If a study strives to provide policy recommendations with respect to questions such as “how to curb

aggressive forms of tax avoidance?”, “how to identify firms involved in unfavorable tax sheltering?”,

or “how to efficiently combat tax evasion?”, proxies situated toward the right hand side appear more

appropriate. However, with regards to the latter question, it needs to be stressed that none of the exist-

ing measures directly identifies, or is explicitly designed to proxy for, clearly criminal types of tax

aggressiveness (i.e. tax evasion). Although most empirical measures should pick up at least some of

135
Largely consistent with the findings presented in Wilson [2009].
136
Frequently firms in the lowest decile of long-run cash ETRs are classified as tax avoiders (e.g. Ayers et al.
[2009], Hanlon et al. [2012], Blaylock et al. [2012]).
137
Another way to question the suitability of ETRs to delimit tax aggressive subsamples can be derived from
Gallemore and Labro [2013], who incorporate the notion of tax risk assumed by firms during their tax plan-
ning decisions in the definition of tax aggressiveness (which would here be considered a less likely sustaina-
ble tax position, i.e. a move towards or eventually across the MLTN reference point). The authors argue that
two firms with equally low ETRs may ceteris paribus face different tax risks (in this case due to differences
in the internal information quality). If a firm’s tax risk is high, Gallemore and Labro [2013] (p. 12) consider
this firm to be more tax aggressive than the firm with an equally low, but otherwise less risky, tax position.

54

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


the tax reductions achieved through illegal and fraudulent means, even identified tax shelters by no

means have to be illegal,138 nor are they necessarily evasive.

6. Concluding Remarks

“All parties”, “all taxes”, “all costs” are the three dimensions of the Scholes et al. [2009] paradigm of

efficient tax planning. In order to maximize after-tax returns, firms need to consider all explicit, im-

plicit, and nontax costs and consequences of their tax decisions. In the light of this approach, tax

avoidance and its related concepts can be characterized by their focus on the reduction of explicit tax-

es. Tax avoidance, tax aggressiveness, tax sheltering, and tax evasion all relate to the “all taxes” buck-

et of the Scholes-Wolfson theme, and a growing body of tax research continues to study the determi-

nants and consequences of firms’ varying levels of explicit tax burden, be it in more or less aggressive

ways, e.g. drawing on tax shelters or any other thinkable tax-motivated transaction.139

The unifying framework of corporate tax planning developed in this study provides readers with an

advanced conceptual understanding of theoretical constructs and researchers who are new to this area

with a comprehensive starting point. The framework raises awareness for the challenges associated

with a careful handling of underlying theoretical concepts and their adequate empirical operationaliza-

tion. Firms generally have a large array of instruments and options available to reduce their explicit

tax burden. As a lot of these tax actions are quite straightforward and largely legal, others are legally

doubtful, harder to sustain upon (hypothetical) audit or even evasive. Research has a reasonable inter-

est to make inferences with respect to all of these subsets of explicit tax planning. While a consistent

classification of the relevant constructs (and their related proxies) would theoretically be desirable, this

goal is practically hard to realize. All the more it is important to put considerable efforts into under-

standing both the conceptual and the empirical challenges present in this field of research. This study

138
Lisowsky et al. [2013] (p. 8) point out that “tax aggressiveness, or even tax sheltering, does not imply illegal-
ity. Such a determination occurs in a court of law and relatively few tax shelter cases are litigated.” Hence,
findings based on research designs that employ tax aggressiveness proxies may not necessarily tell us much
about the level firms are engaged in fraudulent tax evasion.
139
Ever more studies investigate how various stakeholders (the “all parties” dimension) might incentivize or
discourage firms to engage in more or less tax avoidance, which nontax costs (the “all cost” dimension) are
potentially associated with tax avoidance, and within which settings implicit taxes (the “all taxes” dimension)
may play an important role.

55

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


strives to make a contribution in this matter while clearly acknowledging that there are legitimate al-

ternative perceptions and approaches to this matter.

Under the unifying conceptual framework of corporate tax planning developed in the context of this

particular study, future research and public debate may benefit from considering the following points:

 It should only be referred to the construct of tax aggressiveness only if one specifically deals

with a specific scope of general tax avoidance which is further characterized as to what makes it

“aggressive” when compared to non-aggressive tax avoidance. In turn, tax avoidance could be

deliberately defined as not further differentiating between tax actions, as long as they are aimed at

the reduction of explicit taxes. If the intention is to gauge and investigate the overall extent of tax-

reducing efforts, it would be target-oriented to refer to general tax avoidance. Consequentially, in

the interest of diverse but conceptually consistent research, tax avoidance and tax aggressiveness

should not simply be used interchangeably.

 It follows that studies may benefit from an explicitly stated reference point that serves as a defin-

ing benchmark for tax aggressiveness, as opposed to non-aggressive avoidance. In particular with

a view to the mounting research, the standpoint assumed here is that all involved parties, be it re-

searchers, firms, or policymakers, would clearly benefit if they agreed on one explicit, compre-

hensible, and consistent reference point to distinguish tax avoidance from tax aggressiveness.

This study prefers the more-likely-than-not probability of a tax position being legally sustainable,

but expressly acknowledges the existence of other potential reference points.

 Once a study has identified its relevant underlying conceptual construct, suitable empirical

measures need to be carefully selected. Given the plurality of operationalizations that exist in the

literature, sometimes strenuous efforts need to be put into fully understanding and incorporating

the benefits and limitations attached to the various available proxies.

In sum, it may proof beneficial to agree on a broader conceptual consensus with regards to underlying

concepts and terminology where possible. In cases where uniform definitions and/or perceptions of

relevant constructs are impossible to reach or, more importantly, could eventually compromise ad-

vances in research, a thorough conceptual discussion should still sensitize all interested parties to bet-

ter understand and interpret the diversity in empirical tax accounting research.

56

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


References

AICPA, 2011. American Insitute of Certified Public Accountants, Interpretation No. 1-1 (“Reporting and Disclosure
Standards”) and Interpretation No. 1-2 (“Tax Planning”) of Statement on Standards for Tax Services No. 1, Tax
Return Positions (October 20).

AICPA, 2003. File No. S7-49-02, Proposed Rule: Strengthening the Commission's Requirements Regarding Auditor
Independence.

Alexander, Raquel, Mike Ettredge, Mary Stone, and Lili Sun, 2009. Assessing Uncertain Tax Benefit Aggressiveness.
Working Paper, Washington and Lee University, University of Kansas, University of Alabama, University of North
Texas.

Altshuler, Rosanne, and Alan Auerbach, 1990. The Significance of Tax Law Asymmetries: An Empirical Investigation, The
Quarterly Journal of Eocnomics 105 (1): 61-86.

Armstrong, Christopher, Jennifer Blouin, Alan Jagolinzer, and David Larcker, 2012a. Governance, Incentives, and Tax
Avoidance. Working Paper, University of Pennsylvania, University of Colorado, Stanford University.

Armstrong, Christopher, Jennifer Blouin, and David Larcker, 2012b. The incentives for tax planning, Journal of Accounting
and Economics 53 (1-2): 391-411.

Atwood, T.J., Michael Drake, James Myers, and Linda Myers, 2012. Home Country Tax System Characteristics and
Corporate Tax Avoidance: International Evidence, The Accounting Review 87 (6): 1831-1860.

Ayers, Benjamin, John Jiang, and Stacie LaPlante, 2009. Taxable income as a performance measure: The effects of tax
planning and earnings quality, Contemporary Accounting Research 26 (1): 15-54.

Ayers, Benjamin, Stacie Laplante, and Sean McGuire, 2010. Credit Ratings and Taxes: The Effect of Book-Tax Differences
on Rating Changes, Contemporary Accounting Research 27 (2): 359-402.

Badertscher, Brad, Sharon Katz, and Sonja Olhoft Rego, 2011. The Impact of Private Equity Ownership on Portfolio Firms´
Corporate Tax Planning. Working Paper, University of Notre Dame, Columbia University, University of Iowa.

Badertscher, Brad, John Phillips, Morton Pincus, and Sonja Olhoft, 2009. Earnings Management Strategies and the Trade-Off
between Tax Benefits and Detection Risk: to Conform or Not to Conform?, The Accounting Review 84 (1): 63-97.

Balakrishnan, Karthik, Jennifer Blouin, and Wayne Guay, 2012. Does Tax Aggressiveness Reduce Corporate Transparency?
Working Paper, University of Pennsylvania.

Bankman, Joseph, 1994. The structure of Silicon Valley start-ups, UCLA Law Review 41 (Rev. 1737): 1737-1768.

Bankman, Joseph, 2004. The Tax Shelter Battle, in: HENRY AARON/JOEL SLEMROD, The Crises in Tax Administration,
Washington D.C., 9-28.

Barth, Mary, Wiliam Beaver, and Wayne Landsman, 1998. Relative valuation roles of equity book value and net income as a
function of financial health, Journal of Accounting and Economics 25 (1): 1-34.

Basu, Sudipta, 1997. The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings, Journal of Accounting and
Economics 24 (1): 2-37.

57

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Bernard, Victor, 1984. A Comment On: "Effective Corporate Tax Rates", Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 3 (1): 75-
78.

Blaylock, Bradley, Terry Shevlin, and Ryan Wilson, 2012. Tax Avoidance, Large Positive Temporary Book-Tax Differences,
and Earnings Persistence, The Accounting Review 87 (1): 91-120.

Blouin, Jennifer, and Leslie Robinson, 2011. Academic research on FIN 48: What have we learned? - Prepared for the
Financial Accounting Foundations' Post-Implementation Review of Financial Accounting Standards Board
Interpretation No. 48. Working Paper, University of Pennsylvania, Dartmouth College.

Blouin, Jennifer, and Irem Tuna, 2007. Tax Contingencies: Cushioning the blow to earnings? Working Paper, University of
Pennsylvania.

Boynton, Charles, Paul Dobbins, and George Plesko, 1992. Earnings Management and the Corporate Alternative Minimum
Tax, Journal of Accounting Research 30 (Supplement): 131-153.

Brown, Jennifer, and Katharine Drake, 2012. Network ties among low-tax firms. Working Paper, Arizona State University.

Burgstahler, David, James Jiambalvo, and Terry Shevlin, 2002. Do Stock Prices Fully Reflect the Implications of Special
Items for Future Earnings?, Journal of Accounting Research 40 (3): 585-612.

Campbell, Linda, 2010. FIN 48 and micro-cap firms. Working Paper, Texas State University - San Marcos.

Cazier, Richard, Sonja Rego, Xiaoli Tian, and Ryan Wilson, 2011. Did FIN 48 Limit the Use of Tax Reserves as a Tool for
Earnings Management? Working Paper, Texas Christian University, Indiana University, University of Minnesota,
University of Oregon.

Cazier, Richard, Sonja Rego, Xiaoli Tian, and Ryan Wilson, 2009. Early Evidence on the Determinants of Unrecognized Tax
Benefits. Working Paper, Texas Christian University, Indiana University, University of Minnesota, University of
Oregon.

Chen, Shuping, Xia Chen, Qiang Cheng, and Terry Shevlin, 2010. Are family firms more tax aggressive than non-family
firms?, Journal of Financial Economics 95 (1): 41-61.

Chirelstein, Marvin, and Lawrence Zelenak, 2005. Tax Shelters and the Search for a Silver Bullet, Columbia Law Review 105
(6): 1939-1966.

Chyz, James, Winnie Siu Ching Leung, Oliver Zhen Li, and Oliver Meng Rui, 2013. Labor unions and tax aggressiveness,
Journal of Financial Economics 108 (3): 675-698.

Cloyd, Bryan, 1995. The Effects of Financial Accounting Conformity on Recommendations of Tax Preparers, Journal of the
American Taxation Association 17 (2): 50-70.

Cloyd, Bryan, Jamie Pratt, and Toby Stock, 1996. The Use of Financial Accounting Choice to Support Aggressive Tax
Positions: Public and Private Firms, Journal of Accounting Research 34 (1): 23-43.

Coder, Jeremiah, 2010. Wilins discusses need for uncertain tax position reporting, Tax Notes 126 (March 8): 1188-1191.

58

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Collins, Daniel, Raunaq Pungaliya, and Anand Vijh, 2012. The Effects of Firm Growth and Model Specification Choices on
Tests of Earnings Management in Quarterly Settings. Working Paper, University of Iowa, Sungkyunkwan University.

Collins, Julie, and Douglas Shackelford, 1995. Corporate Domicile and Average Effective Tax Rates: The Cases of Canada,
Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States, International Tax and Public Finance 2 (1): 55-83.

Collins, Julie, and Douglas Shackelford, 1998. Global organizations and taxes: An analysis of the dividend, interest, royalty,
and management fee payments between U.S. multinationals' foreign affiliates, Journal of Accounting and Economics
24 (2): 151-173.

Commisioner of Internal Revenue vs. The Estate of Benigno P. Toda, Jr., 2004. Decision, September 14, 2004, G.R. No.
147188, September 14, 2004.

Cordes, Joseph, and Steven Sheffrin, 1983. Estimating the Tax Advantage of Corporate Debt, The Journal of Finance 38 (1):
95-105.

Cordes, Joseph, and Steven Sheffrin, 1981. Taxation and the Sectoral Allocation of Capital in the U.S., National Tax Journal
52 (1): 419-432.

Council of the European Union, 2013. Council agrees measures to combat VAT fraud, Press Release June 21.

Cummins, Jason, Trevor Harris, and Kevin Hassett, 1995. International Accounting, Asymmetric Information, and Firm
Investment, in: MARTIN FELDSTEIN et al., Taxing Multinational Corporations, University of Chicago Press, Chicago,
95-102.

Dechow, Patricia, and Ilia Dichev, 2002. The Quality of Accruals and Earnings: The Role of Accrual Estimation Errors, The
Accounting Review 77 (Supplement): 35-99.

Dechow, Patricia, and Weili Ge, 2006. The persistence of earnings and cash flows and the role of special items: Implications
for the accrual anomaly, Review of Accounting Studies 11 (2-3): 253-296.

Dechow, Patricia, Weili Ge, and Catherine Schrand, 2010. Understanding Earnings Quality: A review of the proxies, their
determinants and their consequences, Journal of Accounting and Economics 50 (2-3): 344-401.

Dechow, Patricia, Richard Sloan, and Amy Sweeney, 1995. Detecting Earnings Management, The Accounting Review 70 (2):
193-225.

deLeon, Hector, 1988. The fundamentals of taxation, Rex Book, Manila.

Dellinger, Kip, 2010. The IRS FIN 48 disclosure initiative: Two worlds., Tax Notes 127 (April): 199-201.

Desai, Mihir, 2003. The Divergence between Book and Tax Income, in: JAMES M. POTERBA, Tax Policy and the Economy,
MIT Press, Cambridge, 169-206.

Desai, Mihir, 2009. Earnings Management, Corporate Tax Shelters, and Book-Tax Alignment, National Tax Journal 62 (1):
169-186.

Desai, Mihir, and Dhammika Dharmapala, 2009. Corporate Tax Avoidance and Firm Value, Review of Economics and
Statistics 91 (3): 537-546.

59

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Desai, Mihir, and Dhammika Dharmapala, 2006. Corporate Tax Avoidance and high-powered Incentives, Journal of
Financial Economics 79 (1): 145-179.

DeSimone, Lisa, John Robinson, and Bridget Stomberg, 2011. Distilling the reserve for uncertain tax positions: The
revealing case of Black Liquor. Working Paper, Stanford University, University of Texas at Austin.

DeWaegenaere, Anja, Richard Sansing, and Jacco Wielhouwer, 2010. Financial accounting measures of tax reporting
aggressiveness. Working Paper, University of Tilburg.

Dhaliwal, Dan, Cristi Gleason, and Lilian Mills, 2004. Last-Chance Earnings Management: Using the Tax Expense to Meet
Analysts' Forecasts, Contemporary Accounting Research 21 (2): 431-459.

Dunbar, Amy, Danielle Higgins, John Phillips, and George Plesko, 2010. What do measures of tax aggressiveness measure?,
Proceedings of the National Tax Association Annual Conference on Taxation, 18-26.

Dunbar, Amy, Linda Kolbasovsky, and John Phillips, 2007. FIN 48 Adoption Disclosures, Financial Reporting Watch
(October 24): -.

Dyreng, Scott, Michelle Hanlon, and Edward Maydew, 2010. The Effects of Executives on Corporate Tax Avoidance, The
Accounting Review 85 (4): 1163-1189.

Dyreng, Scott, Michelle Hanlon, and Edward Maydew, 2008. Long-run corporate tax avoidance, The Accounting Review 83
(1): 61-82.

Dyreng, Scott, and Bradley Lindsey, 2009. Using Financial Accounting Data to Examine the Effect of Foreign Operations
Located in Tax Havens and Other Countries on U.S. Multinational Firms’ Tax Rates, Journal of Accounting Research
47 (5): 1283-1316.

Erle, Bernd, 2008. Tax Risk Management and Board Responsibility, in: WOLFGANG SCHÖN, Tax and Corporate Governance,
Part 3, Springer, 205-220.

Ernst&Young, 2012. US GAAP versus IFRS - The Basics, Available online:


http://www.ey.com/UL/en/AccountingLink/Publications-library-US-GAAP-vs--IFRS--The-Basics. Last accessed:
09/23/2013.

Fama, Eugene, and Kenneth French, 1997. Industry costs of equity, Journal of Financial Economics 43 (2): 153-193.

FASB, 2009. FASB Accounting Standards Codification System Launches Today, News Release 07/01/2009.

FASB, 1978. Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts 1, Objectives of Financial Reporting by Business Enterprises.

FASB, 1980. Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts 2, Qualitative Characteristics of Accounting Information.

Frank, Mary, Luann Lynch, and Sonja Olhoft Rego, 2009. Tax Reporting Aggressiveness and its Relation to Aggressive
Financial Reporting, The Accounting Review 84 (2): 467-496.

Frischmann, Peter, Terry Shevlin, and Ryan Wilson, 2008. Economic consequences of increasing the conformity in
accounting for uncertain tax benefits, Journal of Accounting and Economics 46 (2-3): 261-278.

60

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


G8 Leaders, 2013. G8 Lough Erne summit, Enniskillen, Northern Ireland, Communique to the 2013 summit.

G20 Leaders, 2008. G20 Washington summit Declaration on financial markets and the world economy (15 November 2008).

Gallemore, John, and Eva Labro, 2013. The Importance of the Internal Information Environment for Tax Avoidance.
Working Paper, University of North Carolina.

Gallemore, John, Edward L. Maydew, and Jacob R. Thornock, 2012. The Reputational Costs of Tax Avoidance and the
Under-Sheltering Puzzle. Working Paper, University of North Carolina, University of Washington.

Gleason, Cristi, and Lillian Mills, 2011. Do Auditor-Provided Tax Services Improve the Estimate of Tax Reserves?,
Contemporary Accounting Research 28 (5): 1484-1509.

Gleason, Cristi, and Lillian Mills, 2002. Materiality and Contingent Tax Liability Reporting, The Accounting Review 77 (2):
317-342.

Graham, John, Michelle Hanlon, Terry Shevlin, and Nemit Shroff, 2012. Incentives for Tax Planning and Avoidance:
Evidence from the field. Working Paper, Duke University, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, University of
California-Irvine.

Graham, John, and Alan Tucker, 2006. Tax shelters and corporate debt policy, Journal of Financial Economics 81 (3): 563-
594.

Gupta, Sanjay, Rick Laux, and Dan Lynch, 2012. Do Firms Use Tax Reserves to Meet Earnings Targets? Evidence from the
Pre- and Post-FIN 48 Periods. Working Paper, Michigan State University, Pennsylvania State University.

Gupta, Sanjay, and Kaye Newberry, 1997. Determinants of the variability in corporate effective tax rates: Evidence from
longitudinal data, Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 16 (1): 1-34.

Hanlon, Michelle, 2005. The persistence and pricing of earnings, accruals, and cash flows when firms have large book-tax
difference, The Accounting Review 80 (1): 137-166.

Hanlon, Michelle, 2003. What Can We Infer about a Firm's Taxable Income from Its Financial Statements?, National Tax
Journal 56 (4): 831-863.

Hanlon, Michelle, and Shane Heitzman, 2010. A review of tax research, Journal of Accounting and Economics 50 (2-3): 127-
178.

Hanlon, Michelle, Gopal Krishnan, and Lillian Mills, 2012. Audit Fees and Book-Tax Differences, Journal of the American
Taxation Association 34 (1): 55-86.

Hanlon, Michelle, Stacey LaPlante, and Terry Shevlin, 2005. Evidence for the possible information loss of conforming book
income and taxable income, Journal of Law and Economics 48 (2): 407-442.

Hanlon, Michelle, Edward Maydew, and Daniel Saavedra, 2013. Tax Risk and Corporate Cash Holdings. Working Paper,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, University of North Carolina.

61

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Hanlon, Michelle, Lillian Mills, and Joel Slemrod, 2007. An Empirical Examination of Corporate Tax Noncompliance, in:
ALAN AUERBACH et al., Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century, Cambridge University Press, New York,
Chapter 5.

Hanlon, Michelle, and Terry Shevlin, 2002. The Accounting for the Tax Benefits of Employee Stock Options and
Implications for Research, Accounting Horizons 16 (1): 1-16.

Hanlon, Michelle, and Terry Shevlin, 2005. Book-tax conformity for coporate income: an introduction to the issues., Tax
Policy and the Economy (NBER) 19 (1): 101-134.

Hanlon, Michelle, and Joel Slemrod, 2009. What does tax aggressiveness signal? Evidence from stock price reactions to
news about tax shelter involvement, Journal of Public Economics 93 (1-2): 126-141.

Harrington, Christine, and Walter Smith, 2012. Tax avoidance and corporate capital structure, Journal of Finance and
Accountancy 11 (October): 1948-3015.

Healy, Paul, 1985. The Effect of Bonus Schemes on Accounting Decisions, Journal of Accounting and Economics 7 (1): 85-
107.

Heltzer, Wendy, 2009. Conservatism and Book-Tax Differences, Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 24 (3): 469-
504.

Henry, James, 2012. The Price of Offshore Revisited, Tax Justice Network Paper Series. Available online:
http://www.taxjustice.net/cms/upload/pdf/Price_of_Offshore_Revisited_120722.pdf. Last accessed: 09/22/2013.

Higgins, Dannielle, Thomas Omer, and John Phillips, 2013. Working Paper, University of Connecticut, Texas A&M
University.

Holmes, Oliver, 1916. Bullen v. Wisconsin, (240): 630.

Huseynov, Fariz, and Bonnie Klamm, 2012. Tax Avoidance, tax management and corporate social responsibility, Journal of
Corporate Finance 18 (4): 804-827.

Hutchens, Michelle, and Sonja Rego, 2012. Tax Risk and Cost of Equity Capital. Working Paper, Indiana University.

IASB, 2001. Framework for the Preparation and Presentation of Financial Statements, London.

James, Simon, John Hasseldine, Peggy Hite, and Marika Toumi, 2001. Developing a tax compliance strategy for revenue
services, Bulletin for International Fiscal Documentation 55 (4): 158-164.

Jones, Jennifer, 1991. Earnings Management During Important Relief Investigations, Journal of Accounting Research 29 (2):
193-228.

Kasanen, Eero, Juha Kinnunen, and Jyrki Niskanen, 1996. Dividend-based earnings management: Empirical Evidence from
Finland, Journal of Accounting and Economics 22 (1-3): 283-312.

Katz, Sharon, Urooj Khan, and Andrew Schmidt, 2013. Tax Avoidance and Future Profitability. Working Paper, Columbia
Business School, North Carolina State University.

62

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Kersting, Christian, 2008. Report on the Discussion, 1st Presenation by Reuven S. Avi-Yonah and Comment by Pekka
Timonen (Chair: Wolfgang Schön), in: WOLFGANG SCHÖN, Tax and Corporate Governance, Part 3, Springer, 221-
224.

Klassen, Kenneth, 1997. The impact of inside ownership concentration on the tradeoff between financial and tax reporting,
The Accounting Review 72 (3): 455-474.

Koester, Allison, 2011. Investor valuation of tax avoidance through uncertain tax positions. Working Paper, Georgetown
University.

Kothari, S P, Andrew Leone, and Charles Wasley, 2005. Performance matched discretionary accrual measures, Journal of
Accounting and Economics 39 (1): 163-197.

Küting, Karlheinz, and Christian Zwirner, 2005. Zunehmende Bedeutung und Indikationsfunktion latenter Steuern in der
Unternehmenspraxis, Betriebs-Berater (28): 1553-1562.

Lanis, Roman, and Grant Richardson, 2011. The effect of board of director composition on corporate tax aggressiveness,
Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 30 (1): 50-70.

Lenter, David, Douglas Shackelford, and Joel Slemrod, 2003. Public Disclosure of Corporate Tax Return Information:
Accounting, Economic, and Legal Perspectives, National Tax Journal 56 (4): 803-830.

Lev, Baruch, and Doron Nissim, 2004. Tax income, future earnings and equity values, The Accounting Review 74 (4): 1039-
1074.

Libby, Robert, 1981. Accounting and human information processing: theory and applications, Prentice Hall, Englewood
Cliffs.

Libby, Robert, Robert Bloomfield, and Mark Nelson, 2002. Experimental research in financial accounting, Accounting,
Organizations and Society 27 (8): 775-810.

Lietz, Gerrit, 2013. Determinants and Consequences of Corporate Tax Avoidance. Working Paper, University of Münster.

Lisowsky, Petro, 2009. Inferring U.S. tax liability from financial statement information, Journal of the American Taxation
Association 31 (1): 29-63.

Lisowsky, Petro, 2010. Seeking Shelter: Empirically Modeling Tax Shelters Using Financial Statement Information, The
Accounting Review 85 (5): 1693-1720.

Lisowsky, Petro, Leslie Robinson, and Andrew Schmidt, 2013. Do Publicly Disclosed Tax Reserves Tell us About Privately
Disclosed Tax Shelter Activity?, Journal of Accounting Research 51 (3): 583-629.

Lyon, Andrew, 1997. Cracking the Code: Making Sense of the Corporate Alternative Minimum Tax, Brookings Institution,
Washington D.C.

Lyon, Andrew, and Gerald Silverstein, 1995. The Alternative Minimum Tax and the behavior of multinational corporations,
in: MARTIN FELDSTEIN et al., The Effects of Taxation on Multinational Corporations, University of Chicago Press,
Chicago, 153-177.

63

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Manzon, Gil, and George Plesko, 2002. The Relation between Financial and Tax Reporting Measures of Income, Tax Law
Review 55 (1): 175-214.

Maydew, Edward, 1997. Tax-induced earnings management by firms with net operating losses, Journal of Accounting
Research 35 (1): 83-96.

McGill, Gary, and Edmund Outslay, 2004. Lost in Translation: Detecting Tax Shelter Activity in Financial Statements,
National Tax Journal 57 (3): 739-756.

McNichols, Maureen, 2000. Research design issues in earnings management studies, Journal of Accounting and Public
Policy 19 (4-5): 313-345.

Miller, Gregory, and Douglas Skinner, 1998. Determinants of the Valuation Allowance for Deferred Tax Assets under SFAS
No. 109, The Accounting Review 73 (2): 213-233.

Mills, Lillian, 1998. Book-Tax Differences and Internal Revenue Service Adjustments, Journal of Accounting Research 36
(2): 343-356.

Mills, Lillian, Merle Erickson, and Edward Maydew, 1998. Investments in Tax Planning, Journal of the American Taxation
Association 20 (1): 1-20.

Mills, Lillian, Kaye Newberry, and William Trautman, 2002. Trends in Book-Tax Income and Balance Sheet Differences,
Tax Notes 96 (Special Report): 1109-1124.

Mills, Lillian, and George Plesko, 2003. Bridging the Reporting Gap: A Proposal for More Informative Reconciling of Book
and Tax Income, National Tax Journal 56 (4): 865-893.

Mills, Lillian, Leslie A. Robinson, and Richard C. Sansing, 2010. FIN 48 and Tax Compliance, The Accounting Review 85
(5): 1721-1742.

Minarik, Joseph, 2008. Taxation, in: DAVID HENDERSON, The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics, Liberty Fund Inc.,
Indianapolis, 489-490.

Minnick, Kristina, and Tracy Noga, 2010. Do corporate governance characteristics influence tax management?, Journal of
Corporate Finance 16 (5): 703-718.

Oler, Mitchell, Terry Shevlin, and Ryan Wilson, 2007. Examining Investor Expectations Concerning Tax Savings on the
Repatriations of Foreign Earnings under the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004, Journal of the American Taxation
Association 29 (2): 25-55.

Omer, Thomas, Karen Molloy, and David Ziebart, 1993. An Investigation of the Firm Size-Effective Tax Rate Relation in the
1980s, Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 7 (1): 167-182.

Omer, Thomas, Karen Molloy, and David Ziebart, 1991. Measurement of Effective Corporate Tax Rates Using Financial
Statement Information, Journal of the American Taxation Association 13 (1): 57-72.

Omer, Thomas, George Plesko, and Marjorie Shelley, 2000. The Influence of Tax Costs on Organizational Choice in the
Natural Resource Industry, Journal of the American Taxation Association 22 (1): 38-55.

64

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Pellens, Bernhard, Rolf Füllbier, and Joachim Gassen, 2006. Internationale Rechnungslegung - IFRS 1 bis 7, IAS 1 bis 41 -
IFRIC-Interpretationen - Standardentwürfe, 6 Ed., Schäffer-Poeschel, Stuttgart.

Phillips, John, 2003. Corporate Tax-Planning Effectiveness: The Role of Compensation-Based Incentives, The Accounting
Review 78 (3): 847-874.

Phillips, John, Morton Pincus, and Sonja Olhoft Rego, 2003. Earnings Management: New Evidence Based on Deferred Tax
Expense, The Accounting Review 78 (2): 491-521.

Plesko, George, 2000. Book-tax differences and the measurement of corporate income, Proceedings of the National Tax
Association 92nd Annual Conference on Taxation in Washington D.C., 171-176.

Plesko, George, 1994. Corporate Taxation and the financial characteristics of firms, Public Finance Quarterly 22 (3): 311-
334.

Plesko, George, 2003. An evaluation of alternative measures of corporate tax rates, Journal of Accounting and Economics 35
(2): 201-226.

Porcano, Thomas, 1986. Corporate Tax Rates: Progressive, Proportional, or Regressive, Journal of the American Taxation
Association 7 (2): 17-31.

Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB), 2006. Bylaws and Rules - Section 3: Professional Standards, 1-15.

PwC, 2011. Income Tax Accounting - A comparative look between US GAAP and IFRS, Available online:
http://www.pwc.com/en_US/us/cfodirect/assets/pdf/insight/5190.pdf. Last accessed: 09/23/2013.

PwC, 2008. More likely than not - A comparison of FIN 48 and the tax penalty standard, Available online:
http://www.pwc.com/en_us/us/tax-compliance-services/assets/fin_48_tax_penalty_standard.pdf. Last accessed:
09/23/2013.

PwC, 2009. Similarities and differences - A comparison of "full IFRS" and IFRS for SMEs, Available online:
http://www.pwc.com/gx/en/ifrs-reporting/pdf/Sims_diffs_IFRS_SMEs.pdf. Last accessed: 09/23/213.

Rego, Sonja Olhoft, 2003. Tax-Avoidance Activities of U.S. Multinational Corporations, Contemporary Accounting
Research 20 (4): 805-833.

Rego, Sonja Olhoft, and Ryan Wilson, 2012. Equity Risk Incentives and Corporate Tax Aggressiveness, Journal of
Accounting Research 50 (3): 775-810.

Robinson, Leslie, and Andrew Schmidt, 2013. Firm and investor responses to uncertain tax benefit disclosure requirements.
Working Paper, Dartmouth College, North Carolina State University.

Runkel, Philip, and Joseph McGrath, 1972. Research on Human Behavior - A Systematic Guide to Method, Reinhart and
Winston Inc., New York.

Sansone vs. United States, 1965. 380 U.S. 343, 85 S.Ct. 1004, 13 L.Ed.2d 882 from March 29.

Sapirie, Marie, 2010. UTP regime continues to be refined, officials say., Tax Notes 129 (December): 1298-1299.

65

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


Scholes, Myron, and Mark Wolfson, 1992. Taxes and Business Strategy: A Planning Approach, 1 Ed., Prentice-Hall Inc.,
Upper Saddle River, NJ.

Scholes, Myron, Mark Wolfson, Merle Erickson, Edward Maydew, and Terry Shevlin, 2009. Taxes and Business Strategy: A
Planning Approach, 4 Ed., Prentice-Hall Inc., Upper Saddle River, NJ.

Schrand, Catherine, and Franco Wong, 2003. Earnings Management Using the Valuation Allowance for Deferred Tax Assets
under SFAS No. 109, Contemporary Accounting Research 20 (3): 579-611.

Shackelford, Douglas, and Terry Shevlin, 2001. Empirical tax research in accounting, Journal of Accounting and Economics
31 (1-3): 321-387.

Shevlin, Terry, 2013. Back to the Basics: Why the Scholes-Wolfson Paradym still Matters Presentation at the at the February
2013 ATA Doctoral Consortium, 1-11.

Shevlin, Terry, 2002. Symposium on corporate tax shelters, Part II: Commentary: Corporate tax shelters and book-tax
differences., New York University Tax Review 55 (Spring): Rev. 427.

Shevlin, Terry, 1987. Taxes and Off-Balance-Sheet Financing: Research and Development Limited Partnerships, The
Accounting Review 52 (3): 480-509.

Shevlin, Terry, Oktay Urcan, and Florin Vasvari, 2013. Corporate Tax Avoidance and Public Debt Costs. Working Paper,
University of California-Irvine, London Business School.

Slemrod, Joel, and Marsha Blumenthal, 1993. The compliance costs of big business, The Tax Foundation, Washington D.C.

Slemrod, Joel, and Shlomo Yitzhaki, 2002. Tax Avoidance, Evasion, and Administration, in: ALAN AUERBACH/MARTIN
FELDSTEIN, Handbook of Public Economics, Elsevier Science B.V., Amsterdam, Chapter 22.

Song, Wei-Ling, and Alan Tucker, 2008. Corporate Tax Reserves, Firm Value, and Leverage. Working Paper, Louisiana
State University, Pace University New York.

Spatt, Chester, 2007. The economics of FIN 48: Accounting uncertainty in income taxes, Speech by SEC Staff (March 8).

Standard & Poor's, 2013. Compustat - Continuing to Set the Standard, Available online:
http://www.compustat.com/WorkArea/DownloadAsset.aspx?id=4308. Last accessed: 09/23/2013.

Stickney, Clyde, and Victor McGee, 1982. Effective Corporate Tax Rates - The Effect of Size, Capital Intensity, Levarage,
and other factors, Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 1 (2): 125-152.

U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, 1999. Study of Present-Law Penalty and Interest Provisions as Required by
Section 3801 of the Internal Revenue Service Restructuring and Reform Act of 1998 (Inlcuding Provisions Relating
to Corporate Tax Shelters), JCS 3-99, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington D.C.

U.S. Department of Treasury, 1999. The Problem of Corporate Tax Shelters: Discussion, Analysis and Legislative Proposals,
1-165.

U.S. Department of Treasury, 2011. Regulations Governing Practice before the Internal Revenue Service., Title 31: Code of
Federal Regulations, Subtitle A, Part 10 (published June 3 2011), 1-48.

66

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828


U.S. Department of Treasury, 2000. Tackling the Growth of Corporate Tax Shelters, Press Release February 28.

U.S. Department of Treasury, 2013. Treasury Engaging with More than 80 Countries to Combat Offshore Tax Evasion and
Improve Global Tax Compliance, Press Release July 12.

Vitug, Jose, and Ernesto Acosta, 2000. Tax Law and Jurisprudence 44, 2 Ed., Rex Book Store, Quezon City.

Weisbach, David, 2002a. Ten truths about tax shelters, Tax Law Review 55 (Rev. 215): 215-253.

Weisbach, David, 2002b. Thinking outside the boxes: A response to Professor Schlunk, Texas Law Review 80 (4): 893-911.

Wenzel, Michael, 2002a. An Analysis of Norm Processes in Tax Compliance. Working Paper, Australian National
University.

Wenzel, Michael, 2002b. The Impact of Outcome Orientation and Justice Concerns and Tax Complicance: The Role of
Taxpayers' Identity, Journal of Applied Psychology 87 (4): 629-645.

Wilson, Ryan, 2009. An Examination of Corporate Tax Shelter Participants, The Accounting Review 84 (3): 969-999.

Zimmerman, Jerold, 1983. Taxes and firm size, Journal of Accounting and Economics 5 (1): 119-149.

67

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2363828

You might also like