You are on page 1of 22

Article

Progress in Human Geography


34(6) 715–735
The limits of ‘neoliberal ª The Author(s) 2010
Reprints and permission:
sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav
natures’: Debating green 10.1177/0309132510376849
phg.sagepub.com
neoliberalism

Karen Bakker
University of British Columbia, Canada

Abstract
This paper presents a meta-analysis of recent critiques of geographical scholarship on ‘neoliberal natures’.
The analysis juxtaposes distinct (and at times divergent) conceptualizations of neoliberalism – as political doc-
trine, as economic project, as regulatory practice, or as process of governmentalization – and also of nature –
as primary commodity, as resource, as ecosystem service, or as socio-natural assemblage. Strategies for
developing a more systematic account of the variegation of neoliberal natures are discussed, with the goal
of provoking scholars of neoliberal natures to reflect upon their core conceptual and methodological com-
mitments, while contributing to broader debates over neoliberalism and the ‘nature of nature’.

Keywords
environment, markets, nature, neoliberalism, political ecology, political economy, resources

I Introduction geographers (for edited collections, see Heynen


et al., 2007; Mansfield, 2008a; for a recent
The past few decades have witnessed a rapid
review, see Himley, 2008). Studies have been
increase in the involvement of private corpora-
conducted of Bolivia’s water wars, carbon emis-
tions in resource ownership, biotechnological
sions trading, the commodification of pets,
innovation, and the provision of ecosystem ser-
bio-prospecting, wetland banking, international
vices. Simultaneously, markets (and market
trade in human organs, and genetically modified
proxies) have been deployed as mechanisms of
organisms, to cite just a few examples (Bakker,
environmental governance at multiple scales.
2004, 2005; Bridge, 2004; Dibden et al., 2009;
Advocates present these developments as a wel-
Goldman, 2005; Guthman, 2004, 2007; Heynen
come ‘greening’ of capitalism that will resolve
and Perkins, 2005; Heynen and Robbins, 2005;
critically urgent environmental crises, and prom-
Liverman and Vilas, 2006; McAfee, 2003;
ise a virtuous fusion of goals of economic growth,
McCarthy, 2005a, 2005b, 2005c; 2006a;
efficiency, and environmental conservation.
McCarthy and Prudham, 2004; Mansfield,
Opponents reject these developments as ‘green-
2004, 2007a; 2007b; Perreault, 2005, 2006;
washing’ of the appropriation of resources
and the environmental commons for private
profit, which will deepen socio-environmental
Corresponding author:
inequities. Department of Geography, University of British Columbia,
The ensuing debate on ‘neoliberal natures’ 1984 West Mall, Vancouver, BC V6R 2P5, Canada
has elicited sustained interest on the part of Email: bakker@geog.ubc.ca

715
716 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

Prudham, 2004, 2005, 2007; Roberts, 2008; Inevitably, some readers will disagree with
Robertson, 2004, 2007; St. Martin, 2005, 2007). my attempt at framing these approaches and the
This paper explores recent critiques of geo- associated attempt at dialogue. These disagree-
graphical scholarship on neoliberal natures ments are both legitimate and reflective, I would
(see Bakker, 2005, 2009; Braun, 2008, 2009; argue, of broader tensions across the discipline
Castree, 2006, 2008a, 2008b; Harris, 2009a, and indeed beyond. The goal of the paper is not
2009b; Himley, 2008; Littlefield et al., 2008). to resolve these tensions, but rather to engage
My goal is two-fold: to unpack conceptual with them – as a means of responding to recent
blind spots and methodological pitfalls within critiques, and exploring avenues for rethinking
this literature and to suggest constructive scholarship on neoliberal natures.
responses. In this context, the title of the paper My analysis of these critiques is structured
has a dual meaning: the limits to nature’s neo- around two interrelated challenges which they
liberalization (in the spirit of Harvey’s Limits present to scholars of neoliberal natures: the call
to Capital); and the limitations of conceptual to move ‘beyond nature’, on the one hand (sec-
frameworks deployed within the ‘neoliberal tion II); and the call to move ‘beyond neoliberal-
natures’ research agenda. ism’, on the other (section III). This framing is
This discussion is offered in a spirit of not meant to imply a rejection of these terms, nor
engaged pluralism (Barnes and Sheppard, is it intended to imply an assertion of a post-
2009). My goal is to bring three strands of geo- neoliberal transition. Rather, the term ‘beyond’
graphical scholarship on neoliberal natures into is used to signal a critical engagement with the
dialogue. Political economic approaches ontological status of both neoliberalism and
(inflected with the concerns of political ecology) nature, in order to stimulate dialogue about con-
are the foil for much of my analysis.1 I also ceptual blind spots, and associated methodologi-
invoke two other perspectives on neoliberalism cal commitments. By way of illustration, let me
and nature that are articulated within the broader reframe these critiques as a set of questions with
‘material turn’ in geography (Bakker and which (critics argue) the neoliberal natures liter-
Bridge, 2006; Jackson, 2000; Whatmore, ature has not yet grappled. Why do some types
2006): relational approaches, particularly as of neoliberalization processes occur with respect
developed within cultural geography; and an to some types of socio-natures, and not others?
analytic of environmental governance, particu- How can we account for the articulation between
larly as developed within political ecology. It local expressions of neoliberal projects and
is not my intention to shore up (crumbling) broader processes of neoliberalization? How
distinctions between subfields of geographical might our analyses account for the co-
inquiry; nor do I intend to narrowly delimit constitution (or co-production) of socio-natures
the definition of neoliberal natures. Rather, and neoliberalization processes?
as explored below, I suggest that the overlaps As the paper progressively unpacks these
between (and divergences among) these questions (and associated critiques), I develop
approaches are productive territory: for exam- the following argument: scholarship on neolib-
ple, the distinct (and at times divergent) con- eral natures would benefit from an expansive
ceptualizations of neoliberalism – as political view of socio-nature (rather than narrowly
doctrine, as economic project, as regulatory defined nature-as-resource), an incorporation
practice, or as process of governmentaliza- of non-dualistic understandings of agency, and
tion – and also of nature – as primary com- a more systematic account of the variegation
modity, as resource, as ecosystem service, of neoliberalization. This would, in turn, imply
or as socio-natural assemblage.2 reworking our definitions of neoliberalism,

716
Bakker 717

through integrating multiple dimensions of neo- overly constrained view of agency and fails to
liberalization – affective, libidinal, and cultural, confront the political subjectivity of socio-
as well as political, ecological, and economic. In natures (Braun, 2008). This is the case, I suggest,
making these arguments, my goal is to suggest because scholars of neoliberal natures often
how scholars might engage more comprehen- implicitly rely on a humanist view of the subject,
sively with the multiple entanglements between and an associated anthropocentric conception of
socio-natures and capital under neoliberal political subjectivity. Little reference is made,
modes of governance, while accounting more for example, to the range of terms (Latour’s
fully for the co-presence of the non-human – ‘hybrids,’ Swyngedouw’s ‘socio-natures’,
both animate ‘nature’ and inanimate ‘things’ – Haraway’s ‘cyborgs’) employed by scholars of
within conventional human worlds. political ecology, human ecology, and science
and technology studies (STS) to invoke the
necessity of dispensing with the humanist model
II Beyond nature? of the subject, and associated nature-society
Let me begin with a question. What is the ‘nature’ dualism so central to modern thought (Haraway,
in ‘neoliberal nature’? More precisely, which 1991; Latour, 1993; Swyngedouw, 1999). Braun
‘natures’ are the foci of our concern, and how are argues that the ‘concerted attempt among politi-
they defined? In response, let me begin by exam- cal economists to understand the ways in which
ining the framing of nature in two flagship collec- non-human nature resists its incorporation into
tions on neoliberal natures (which focus on particular political economic and spatial forms’
political economic approaches): Mansfield’s is limited by its failure to incorporate the ‘non-
Privatization: Property and the Remaking of human . . . as a constitutive element of social
Nature-society Relations (2008a); and Heynen and economic life’ (Braun, 2008: 668). His argu-
et al.’s Neoliberal Environments (2007). A scan ment suggests that it is no mere coincidence that
through these two volumes generates a list of scholars operating from a political economic
natures: agricultural foodstuffs, land, fish, gold, perspective have generally shied away from
trees, water, wetlands, wildlife (such as deer and studying bio-cultural entities, or animals: they
elk), and urban green space. These volumes raise questions of agency of the co-constitution
largely define nature as a resource, often narrowly of humans and non-humans that are difficult to
circumscribed as primary commodities. Other handle within the conceptual frameworks typi-
types of socio-natures – such as human bodies, cally employed in this literature (although for
genetically modified organisms, ecosystem ‘ser- an exception see Robbins and Luginbuhl,
vices’ of various kinds – receive scant attention 2007). The (inadvertent) consequence is a fail-
(although for two exceptions see Prudham, ure to address the full scope of environmental
2007, and Robbins and Luginbuhl, 2007). A processes and socio-natural entities subsumed
recent review of the literature (Himley, 2008) within processes of neoliberalization.
suggests that this pattern is relatively consistent: Let me give a counter-example: Nast’s work
studies in this vein have tended to focus on the on pet love under neoliberalism (Nast, 2006).
encroachment of capitalist economic relations Nast documents the commodification and spatia-
on what we conventionally delimit as ‘the envi- lization of pet–human relationships that are
ronment’ and ‘resources’, which are usually articulated with political economic processes of
(albeit implicitly) defined as non-humans. neoliberalization. She argues that these pet–
As a result, political economic approaches to human relationships are characterized by new
the study of neoliberal natures have given rise to practices, such as dog yoga (‘doga’) and the
the following critique: this research adopts an cloning of pets. These practices entail an

717
718 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

intensification of the affective ‘work’ required of often sensitive to biophysical difference, and
pets, but are also, Nast argues, a form of commo- thereby to a certain vision of nature’s agency.
dification of pet lives (and loves). These arise, After all, much scholarship in this vein has been
she argues, in response to a range of alienations influenced by Neil Smith’s (1984) seminal work
associated with post-industrial lives and places, on the production of nature and related debates
including changes in family and community over the social construction of nature. Nature’s
structures, aging, and patterns of labour mobility. agency is usually framed as a set of constraints
The post-industrial ‘isolations and narcissisms’ upon human action, and specifically as a set of
with which Nast is concerned stem from, but are limits to capital accumulation (hence the charac-
in turn enrolled in, broader socio-spatially terization of nature as ‘uncooperative’ and
uneven processes of wealth accumulation and ‘unruly’ in many studies). Nature is, in this fram-
investment. The surprising proliferation and ing, neither passive nor inert.
intensification of pet services and relationships The preceding rejoinder is true, but this misses
over the past 20 years, in other words, are part the central point, I think, of Braun’s argument,
of a dual process: the intensification of nature which focuses on the need to extend political
accumulation and hyper-commodification of adjudication to non-humans (see also Escobar,
consumption under neoliberal regimes of capital 1998). Framed in this way, the challenge is to
accumulation, which have created the affective go beyond the truism that nature is socially con-
conditions for the growth and diversification of structed to ‘theorise the manifold forms in which
the capitalized pet economy. The neoliberalism it is culturally constructed and socially produced,
of nature, from this perspective, is simultane- while fully acknowledging the biophysical basis
ously economic, social, libidinal, emotional, of its constitution’ (Escobar, 1999: 3). Accepting
material and cultural (see also Guthman, 2009; Braun’s critique, in other words, implies that
Mansfield, 2003, 2008b, 2008c). scholars of neoliberal nature should adopt a
Nast’s work is an example of the conceptual non-anthropocentric view of the agency of nature,
commitments of ‘animal geographies’, which and interrogate the status of non-humans as polit-
frame animals as co-constitutive actors in ical subjects. In this way, we might produce better
construction of human societies and economies, accounts of the interrelationships between ecolo-
while querying the boundaries between the gical processes, non-humans and humans –
human and non-human (Hinchliffe et al., 2005, whereby agency is both enabled and constrained.
2007; Philo and Wilbert, 2000; Whatmore, And we would be more sensitive to the pitfalls of
2002; Wolch and Emel, 1998). This framing of characterizations of nature as a passive backdrop
socio-natural entities as actors is notably absent to (or victim of) political economic forces. This
from the majority of the literature on neoliberal approach poses, of course, a direct challenge to
natures. Contrast, for example, Nast’s work with the modern, Western notion of distributive justice
political economic approaches: the multiple (from which non-humans are generally excluded)
dimensions of neoliberalization processes versus and the humanist model of the subject upon which
political economic questions of capital accumu- studies of neoliberal natures are conventionally
lation and labour; affective interiorization versus predicated. There is nothing novel in this insight;
biophysical limits; individual bodies versus here, I simply note that this issue is one that scho-
resources; the consumption versus the produc- lars of neoliberal natures – particularly those of a
tion of neoliberalized natures. political economic persuasion – have not yet
Of course, it is important to moderate this addressed in a sustained manner.
critique with recognition of the fact that political Where might we look for examples of such an
economic approaches to neoliberal natures are approach? Political ecology offers an example

718
Bakker 719

of what might be termed a ‘co-production’ be through engagement with scholarship on


approach, in which accounts of the ecological emotional and affectual geographies (see Pile,
(as well as economic and political) effects of nat- 2010, for a recent review).5 This literature sug-
ure’s neoliberalization are combined with docu- gests that relationships with non-humans are not
mentation of constraints imposed upon capital solely instrumental (as conventional definitions
accumulation by the biophysical characteristics of resources suggest); they are also characterized
of specific resources. Often, this entails selec- by multiple non-instrumental values and emo-
tively adopting methods and frameworks from tions. Affective connections and emotional rela-
ecological sciences and political ecology. tionships between humans and non-humans
Robbins’ account of the enrolment of grass seeds play an important role in configuring political
in the social construction (and material produc- and ethical sensibilities; and, in turn, this plays
tion) of the North American lawn is one example a role in shaping consumption desires and
of an approach which integrates knowledge resource extraction practices (Hinchliffe, 2008;
derived from the ecological sciences (Robbins, Hinchliffe et al., 2007; Lorimer, 2005).
2007). Klepeis and Vance’s (2003) account of Let me give a concrete example of how an
the environmental impacts of agricultural neoli- understanding of concepts of emotion and affect
beralization policies is an example of the inte- might contribute to research on primary com-
gration of methods from ecology. modities: the case of conflict diamonds. Easily
In pointing to these examples, I am aware accessible ‘alluvial’ diamonds (scattered in sur-
of the need for caution regarding the potential face deposits, requiring only artisanal mining
pitfalls of so-called ‘new ecology’ approaches technologies) are much more likely than Kim-
(Scoones, 1999; Zimmerer, 2000), particularly berlite diamonds (concentrated in subsurface
the easy appeal of ‘integrative research’ (for a deposits, requiring intensive technology) to
recent discussion, see Demeritt, 2009).3 To some finance armed struggles by rebel movements.
extent, these pitfalls might be addressed by The former, characterized as ‘blood diamonds’
addressing the production and social construc- by NGO campaigners, have shaped global com-
tion of scientific knowledge.4 Robertson’s anal- modity circuits as well as the tactics and out-
ysis of the role of ecological science in the comes of armed struggles around the world (Le
commodification of wetlands, via the production Billon, 2008). As Le Billon suggests, paying
of knowledge about aspects of wetlands that careful attention to the different biophysical
might be codified and rendered exchangeable characteristics of resources and their interactions
via ‘wetland banks’, is one example. Some scho- with strategies of resource extraction can teach
lars have pushed this agenda even further, us much about the mutual constitution of
through querying the practices by which analyti- resources and political economic projects. For
cal categories such as ‘ecology’ and ‘economy’ example, analyses of the pathways by which
are actively constituted through practices of sci- ‘blood diamonds’ are incorporated into global
entific inquiry (eg, Mitchell’s 2002 account of commodity chains can inform us about the
the interrelationships between human and non- causes of the unintended violence wreaked on
human actors in colonial Egypt). artisanal mining communities by ‘fair trade’
campaigns.
But the non-instrumental values attached to
1 Blood diamonds resources like diamonds are also central to an
Another way in which scholars of neoliberal nat- analysis of their enrolment in commodity chains.
ures might address the question of the co- The socio-cultural construction of desire is, for
constitution of humans and non-humans could example, at the heart of the cartelization of the

719
720 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

global diamond industry; the resulting social con- comprehensive if we expand our definition of
struction of scarcity has political economic out- what ‘counts’ as nature (not merely defined
comes (such as higher diamond prices) but instrumentally, as a resource), and if we acknowl-
cannot be explained solely in political economic edge the multiple dimensions of the relationships
terms. Desire must also be understood with refer- (not solely political and economic) between
ence to what Lorimer (2005) terms ‘nonhuman humans and non-humans. As a result, moving
charisma’: the desirability of diamonds, their beyond ‘nature’ provides suggestive insights, in
imbrication with commodified cultural tropes line with ongoing debates in geography over the
(often related to rites of passage). At the other end meaning, scope, and analytical utility of the term
of the commodity chain, in diamond-producing neoliberalism (Bakker, 2005; Larner, 2003).
areas, both hope and fear (and their manipulation) In order to develop this argument, let me turn
play a central role in minerals extraction, armed to the question of how scholarship on neoliberal
conflict, and resistance (Le Billon, 2006; Lori- natures already does move ‘beyond neoliberal-
mer, 2005). Non-governmental actors, in turn, ism’, beginning (again) with a consideration of
rely on an invocation of affect in their political economic approaches. Perhaps most
consumer-targeted campaigns to halt the con- obviously, the case study approach (a hallmark
sumption of ‘blood diamonds’. Arguably, the of this body of research) dispenses with
emotive effect of advertising slogans such as the notion of neoliberalism as an ideal-type,
‘Diamonds are a rebel’s best friend’ have been through careful specification of the specific
critically important in the dramatic changes processes at work in ‘actually-existing neoliber-
which the diamond commodity chain has under- alisms’. Moreover, this body of research moves
gone in the past decade (Le Billon, 2006). us beyond neoliberalism-as-doctrine, through
Understanding diamonds, in short, requires offering a rebuttal to proponents of ‘free market
reference not only to political economies and environmentalism’ (or ‘green neoliberalism’,
ecologies, but also to the non-instrumental values as opponents term it).6 This is accomplished
that flow between humans and non-humans through documenting the limits to nature’s
when resources are co-produced. The political neoliberalization, which arise not only because
economic transformations we assemble under the neoliberalism takes place within existing politi-
broad label of neoliberalism are enacted, in other cal economic formations with which it has an
words, upon the human and the non-human alike. antagonistic relationship, but also because of the
This requires attention to the broad range of prac- articulation of labour and accumulation strate-
tices (from the desacralization of ‘natural ele- gies with ecological processes in specific bio-
ments’ to the creation of client subjectivities) physical settings, which create barriers and
through which the neoliberalization of nature constraints to capital accumulation. A number
unfolds, and demonstrates how the concept of of studies have causally linked these limits to the
affect might extend our understanding of the process of re-regulation (or ‘roll-out neoliberali-
relationship between the humans and other zation’), offering an explanation of why the
socio-natures under neoliberalism. implementation of neoliberalization processes
is accompanied by an intensification of facilita-
tive government activity, thereby countering
III Beyond neoliberalism? widespread assumptions of the ‘retreat of the
How might the preceding discussion be articu- state’ under neoliberalism (eg, Lockie and Hig-
lated with recent debates in geography over neo- gins, 2007).
liberalism? I will make the case, below, that our In short, scholarship on neoliberal natures has
accounts of neoliberalization will be more already done a great deal to move us beyond

720
Bakker 721

hegemonic, oversimplified understandings of neoliberalization if we have not accounted for the


neoliberalism. Nonetheless, this body of commonalities and differences in patterns of
research has been the object of a compelling cri- ‘actually-existing neoliberalisms’ across differ-
tique: this literature, taken as a whole, is com- ent types of resources in different places. Having
promised of disparate, unconnected case identified these commonalities and differences,
studies (Bakker, 2005, 2009; Castree, 2005, we need to theorize their emergence in the con-
2008a, 2008b). This, in turn, inhibits the ability text of distinct neoliberal experiments. This
of geographers working on neoliberal natures implies accepting the assertion that these experi-
to ‘connect the dots’ between cases. Castree, in ments are neither entirely homogenous (and gen-
particular, argues that little work has been done erically reproduced) nor entirely heterogeneous
on identifying commonalities in drivers, pat- (and unique). Rather, local experiences of the
terns, and effects of neoliberalization processes neoliberalization of nature reflect the interplay
– such as the privileging of private property of inherited institutional lineages, policy land-
rights, market-mimicking regulatory strategies, scapes, local economic and political dynamics,
state-led market proxies, and commodification and the multiscalar dynamics of regulatory
strategies. Collectively, geographers are thus restructuring. In light of this formulation of var-
unable to account for variegation; specifically, iegation, the problem with a case study approach
they are unable to generate convincing explana- (specifically, site- and resource-specific studies
tions of the neoliberalization of nature as a his- of neoliberalization) is that it enables differentia-
torically and geographically differentiated, yet tion to be empirically documented, but foregoes
global (or at least translocal) phenomenon. an analysis of the systematic production of
This is troubling, because there is tremendous geoinstitutional differentiation, insofar as it
variation in the articulation of neoliberalism neglects to articulate local cases with translocal
with different types of socio-natures. Take, for neoliberalization processes.7 As a result, scho-
example, the case of primary commodities: lars of neoliberal nature limit their ability to
whereas neoliberalization has been widespread when, where, and why neoliberal projects are
and far-reaching in some cases (such as tropical implemented, succeed and/or fail.
foodstuffs in developing countries), it has been How might this critique be refuted? One
much more restricted in others (such as water) response is that the biophysical characteristics
(Bakker, 2005; Cashin et al., 2000; Daviron and of resources, and the socio-economic processes
Ponte, 2005; Talbot, 2004). Other cases, such as with which they are associated, vary so dramati-
oil, are relatively mixed: nationalization has cally that expedience (and analytical rigour)
remained important (although often via ‘hybrid’ demands a case study approach. Another
forms), but other dimensions of neoliberal eco- response is that the tendency to engage in
nomic strategies – a shift from state to private resource-specific case studies arises from a refu-
control of oil extraction, intensification of sal (admirable, although often implicit) to
extraction rates, and price deregulation – have engage in analytical abstractions about ‘nature’
been widely implemented (Le Billon and Cer- as a general, unitary category: biophysical dif-
vantes, 2009). ferences are so significant as to render abstrac-
Reframing this critique in terms of the concept tion impossible. These justifications are
of variegation might help clarify why this point is sometimes offered to defend the fact that the
analytically crucial (Brenner et al., 2010; Peck, majority of scholarship on neoliberal natures is
2008; Peck and Theodore, 2007). If we accept the devoted to case studies.8 But both of these justi-
claim that capitalism is variegated, this implies fications are unconvincing, in my opinion. On
that we cannot adequately explain processes of the one hand, differentiation is constitutive of

721
722 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

translocal neoliberalization processes (rather neoliberalization strategies and socio-natural


than a phenomenon that could be used to dispute categories might be queried; the categories
the existence of such processes). On the other, are not definitive, but rather descriptive and
the refusal to examine the ‘context of context’ inductive. Finally, the categorization in Table 1
amounts to myopia regarding the patterning of is overly coarse: each category might be subdi-
processes of ecological as well as political eco- vided (for example, eco-system services are usu-
nomic change (Brenner et al., 2010). If we dis- ally divided into provisioning, regulating, and
miss these rebuttals (as I think we should), supporting services); as a result, insufficient
then Castree’s critique stands. attention is given to differentiation within these
categories.
In light of these caveats, Table 2 offers one
1 Conceptualizing variegation example of a more nuanced approach to concep-
How, then, might we take Castree’s critique for- tualizing variegation, focusing on resources. Key
ward? One strategy would be to try to develop to the distinct categories drawn in this table is the
conceptual frameworks that might account for insight that private property rights are more diffi-
variegation as a dialectic between geoinstitu- cult to establish for some types of resources (such
tional differentiation and translocal (but not gen- as flow resources) than others. As a result, differ-
eric) patterns and processes. Table 1 offers one ent practices of neoliberalization are more likely
potential approach to categorizing variegation: to be applied to different kinds of socio-natures –
a descriptive typology. Here, my purpose is to because of their different biophysical characteris-
categorize the primary vectors of variegation tics, behaviours, and articulation (co-constitu-
through mapping generic neoliberalization stra- tion) of labour and consumption practices; for
tegies across a coarsely defined set of socio- example, in the case of fresh water, private
natures. The range of tactics (vertical headings) companies are more likely to engage in private-
represents an attempt at an expanded conceptua- sector participation than full-blown privatization,
lization of the dimensions of neoliberalization: which will be the preferred strategy where private
affective, relational, ecological, and economic. property rights can be well established. Different
The range of socio-natures (horizontal headings) resources are also differentially articulated with
spans a broad range of categories of socio- labour: in some cases, labour processes are more
natures – primary commodities, ecosystem ser- constrained by the biophysical characteristics of
vices, and affective bodies. Accordingly, the socio-natures (such as variability in resource
typology brings together literatures that do not stocks). To formalize this distinction, I have used
normally ‘speak’ to one another, yet which all a distinction between ‘extractive’ or ‘cultivation-
engage with different aspects of the neoliberali- based’ industries9 (Benton, 1989; Boyd et al.,
zation of socio-nature. 2001), each of which is likely to be associated
Several caveats obviously apply. Typologies with a distinct strategy of neoliberalization.
should not be interpreted as an attempt at a uni- A few caveats deserve mention here. Table 2
fied description in an overly tidy, rigid, ideal- is reflective of a certain delineation of the cate-
type format; this is certainly not my intent. Table gory of nature-as-resource, and an associated
1 captures only a small sampling of the litera- (constrained) vision of nature’s agency. More-
ture; it is not intended to be comprehensive, but over, the boundaries between categories are not
rather to provide one (and not the sole) example easily policed: for example, is water static or
of how we might categorize scholarship on the mobile as it flows through the hydrological
multifaceted patterning of the neoliberalization cycle? Finally, because resources are relational,
of socio-nature. Moreover, my classification of it is impossible to definitely assert that any one

722
Table 1. Neoliberalizing socio-natures: a descriptive typology (adapted from Bakker, 2009, in dialogue with Castree, 2008a, 2008b, 2009)
Primary commodities Affective bodies Ecosystem services
(including cultivated and (including humans, companion (including regulating and supporting functions
extracted resources) species, bio-cultural entities) such as crop pollination)

Privatization Privatization of gold resources in Guyana Whole organism patents (Prudham, 2007) Patenting biological processes (Dickenson,
(private ownership of (Bridge, 2002) Commodification of breast milk (Boyer, 2007; van Dooren, 2008)
property/private property 2010)
rights)
Marketization Water markets in Chile (Budds, 2004) Markets in human organs Carbon emissions trading (Bailey, 2007a,
(markets determine Tradeable quotas in ocean fisheries (Scheper-Hughes, 2005) 2007b)
resource allocation and (Mansfield, 2007b) Global trade in oocytes and embryos Wetland ‘banking’ (Robertson, 2004)
pricing) (private assisted reproduction services)
(Waldby and Cooper, 2008)
Market proxies Corporatization of state water supply in Workfare policies (Peck, 2001) Outsourcing of government water quality
(market-simulating South Africa (McDonald and Ruiters, 2005) monitoring to private sector (Prudham,
processes; delegation of 2004)
state functions to private
actors)
De-regulation and ‘Fair trade’ regulation of diamond sector Liberalization of trade agreements on Liberalization of trade agreements governing
re-regulation (Le Billon, 2006) bio-prospecting (Hayden, 2003; capital flows to the water sector (Brown
(liberalization, voluntarist Industry-determined agri-environmental McAfee, 2003) et al., 2008)
regulation) and food standards (Guthman, 2007; Risk-shifting of workers’ health and safety Forest Stewardship Council certification
Higgins et al., 2008) issues through individual ‘responsibili- (Eden, 2009)
zation’ policies (Gary, 2009)
Rescaling Rescaling of environmental trade agreements Communities as legitimate forest users ‘Green’ governance of ecosystem services via
governance (McCarthy, 2004) under decentralized neoliberal forest multilateral financial institutions (eg, Global
governance (McCarthy, 2006b) Environment Fund) (Goldman, 2005)
Real subsumption Biotechnological agricultural innovations Dolly the sheep and other genetically Patented technologies substituting for
(Biotechnological modes (McAfee, 2003) modified organisms (Franklin, 2007) ecosystem services (Robertson, 2004)
of production) Private IVF/assisted reproduction
services(Gupta, 2008)
Externalization Agricultural pollution costs shifted to workers Costs of social provisioning shifted to Neoliberal cost-cutting increases fresh water
(of social and and non-human socio-natures (Dibden et al., women under neoliberalism (Bakker, pollution burden in Ontario, Canada
environmental costs) 2009; Higgins et al., 2008) 2003; Sutton, 2010) (Prudham, 2004)

(continued)

723
724
Table 1 (continued)
Primary commodities Affective bodies Ecosystem services
(including cultivated and (including humans, companion (including regulating and supporting functions
extracted resources) species, bio-cultural entities) such as crop pollination)

Ecological/social fix ‘Green’ mining technologies (Warhurst and New types of pets/pet practices as the Payment for ecosystems services in Mexico
(environmental/ Bridge, 2003) internalization of social alienation for (McAfee and Shapiro, 2010)
social degradation as profit (Nast, 2006)
a source of profit)

States of exception Indigenous identities mobilized through Constrained/suspended citizenship for Eco-tourism/Recodification of existence
(reconfiguration of identity, neoliberalization of gas in Bolivia (Perreault, globalized workers (eg, caregivers) value of natural landscapes as ‘ecosystem
citizenship) 2006) (Pratt, 2004) services’ (Duffy, 2008)

Alienation Rescripting of indigenous identities with Neoliberal sexual actors (Adam, 2005) Commodification of biodiversity via intellectual
(of emotional, affective respect to neoliberal land tenure reforms Transnational sexualities and the property rights transforms indigenous
relations) and livelihoods (Bury, 2005; Valdivia, 2004) production of desire under worldviews of the sacred (Posey, 2002)
neoliberalism in China (Rofel, 2007)
Bakker 725

Table 2. Resource neoliberalization: differentiated strategies


Private property rights Clear property rights Diffuse/weak property rights
Resource type (eg, ‘static’ or ‘fixed’ resources) (eg, ‘mobile’ or ‘flow’ resources)
‘Extractive’ resources Privatization Market proxies
(eg, minerals)
(Stocks less volatile;
labour processes more predictable)

‘Cultivated’ resources Real subsumption Marketization


(eg, agriculture)
(Stocks more volatile;
labour processes less predictable)

strategy of neoliberalization will be systemati- will be able to conflate different processes under
cally preferred: the categories in Table 2 might the umbrella term neoliberalism.
easily mutate, depending on historical and geo- Second, these typologies offer a starting point
graphical context. for dialogue about comparative analysis. Specif-
With these caveats in mind, let me offer four ically, Table 1 suggests that comparative studies
reasons why this sort of typological thought- might be made of the range of neoliberalization
experiment is useful. First, these typologies dis- strategies applied to a specific type of socio-
pense with the notion of neoliberalism as an nature (a ‘vertical’ approach); and/or studies of
ideal-type, coherent, unitary category. Rather, a specific neoliberalization strategy as applied
they suggest that neoliberalization unfolds as a to a range of socio-natures (a ‘horizontal’
range of strategies, which vary depending on the approach). Both typologies remind us, though,
target (eg, property rights versus governance that comparison can not be done in a formulaic
practices) and the type of socio-nature. Not all fashion, given the broad range of strategies via
strategies of neoliberalization apply to all types which neoliberalization is enacted, and the fact
of resources: for example, real subsumption (the (as Table 2 suggests) that neoliberalization is
manipulation of biological processes – to pro- relationally defined – in this instance, in articula-
duce systematic increases in or intensification tion with the different biophysical characteristics
of biological productivity (ie, yield, turnover of resources. This rests on an assumption that
time, metabolism, photosynthetic efficiency) in processes of neoliberalization may be very dif-
the pursuit of higher rates of profit) does not ferent, and have different causes, in different
apply to abiotic resources.10 The conceptual pre- instances. But this does not foreclose the possi-
cision enabled by distinguishing between these bility of comparative analysis. Rather, the typol-
different strategies of neoliberalization might ogies are intended to build on the discussion of
enable a response to one of the major pitfalls variegation (above), through suggesting one
of this literature: scholars often use the term strategy through which we could develop more
‘neoliberalism’ (or cognate terms, such as ‘pri- systematic bases upon which to assess the degree
vatization’) in a variety of ill-defined, often con- to which cases are ‘like’ or ‘unlike’, and poten-
flated ways, often implicitly assuming that tially amenable to comparative analysis.
neoliberalism is hegemonic in effect (and, at Third, these typologies are useful as a
times, monolithic in form). Greater conceptual thought-experiment about how variegation is,
precision means that it is less likely that scholars in part, mediated through the co-constitution of

725
726 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

neoliberalization and socio-natures. Specific generally take into account the environmental
neoliberalization processes will have very dif- dimension of (re)regulation processes (with
ferent trajectories and effects when articulated notable exceptions, such as Alan Lipietz). The
with different types of socio-natures. In other 1970s was also a decade during which wide-
words, strategies of neoliberalization are modu- spread awareness emerged of the fact that an
lated by different kinds of socio-natures – not instrumentalist approach to nature as a ‘source’
only because of their different biophysical char- for resources and ‘sink’ for wastes was reaching
acteristics, but also because of their articulation (human-perceived) limits; in turn, mass environ-
with labour practices, consumption processes, mental movements emerged. The response, on
and affective relationships. the part of capital, was a shift to intensive accu-
mulation strategies: the commodification of new
types of socio-natures, and the search to convert
2 Rethinking genealogies of environmental externalities into sources of
neoliberalization profit, joined well-established strategies of ‘eco-
A fourth and final comment on the utility of logical fixes’.12 Simultaneously, the production
these typologies: they might provoke us to of neoliberal natures has become a global proj-
think more broadly about ways in which we ect, mediated by international financial organi-
define neoliberalism, and the genealogical nar- zations. Environmental governance – from
ratives we devise to justify and explain those local to global scales – has been captured by the
definitions. Let me formulate this as a question: doctrine of ‘liberal environmentalism’, which
what (if anything) is distinctive about neolib- asserts the belief in the ‘compatibility of envi-
eral natures? This question arises because of ronmental concern, economic growth, the basic
the fact that political economists have long tenets of a market economy, and a liberal inter-
recognized that capitalism is predicated upon national order’ (Bernstein, 2000). This doctrine
our metabolism of nature (eg, Benton, 1996; gradually achieved near-hegemonic status dur-
Burkett, 1999; Foster, 2000; Smith, 1984); ing the 1970s and 1980s (albeit at different paces
take, as an example, the well-recognized paral- and in distinct ways across locales), from the
lels between contemporary accounts of ‘accu- 1984 Brundtland Report (Our Common Future),
mulation by dispossession’ and historical to the Rio Environment and Development Sum-
enclosures (eg, Perelman, 2000; see also Glass- mit in 1992, and the ‘greening’ of multilateral
man, 2006; Harvey, 2003). In other words, why development banks and development policy as
talk about neoliberalism; why not just talk symbolized by the creation of the Global Envi-
about capitalism? ronment Facility in 1991 and consolidated by the
The answer hinges, in part, on the qualitative Johannesburg Summit in 2002 (Bernstein,
differences that characterize new practices of 2000). Simply put, whereas market principles
capital accumulation (eg, real subsumption) were often viewed in opposition to environmen-
brought to bear on new types of socio-natures tal protection and conservation in the mid-
(eg, biocultural entities) that have emerged over twentieth century, they had by the end of the
the past 30 years. century become reconciled with economic
Readers familiar with this literature will have growth and entrenched in mainstream environ-
in mind regulation-theoretic accounts of neoli- mental policy as emblematized in the doctrine
beralism as a political and economic project that of sustainable development (Hartwick and Peet,
rose to the fore of public policy in the 1970s as a 2003). The neoliberalization of socio-nature
(politically contested) response to the crisis of must thus be understood as, simultaneously, a
Fordism.11 These accounts do not, however, disciplinary mode of regulation, and an

726
Bakker 727

emergent regime of accumulation that redefines to resist the neoliberalization of socio-natures, a


and co-constitutes socio-natures. central theme of which has been the re-
A central irony of these processes is that they embedding of our societies and economies within
purport to present a solution to environmental lifeworlds. If the neoliberalization of nature dis-
crises which capitalism has played a role in cre- embeds the economy not just from society, but
ating. These crises are simultaneously discur- also from the socio-ecologies upon which we all
sive, social, and material. They arise from the depend, then restraining technoscience, reinvent-
social construction and political mediation of a ing capitalism, and re-imagining our world-
very real set of deteriorating environmental, views, scalar politics and scalar ontologies of
social and economic conditions, raising ques- socio-nature are urgent tasks. We might thus
tions about the limits – cognitive and material reframe the ‘double movement’ as a set of inter-
– of our models of resource exploitation and our twined struggles over the material conditions of
instrumentalist approach to nature and to the reproduction (in its broadest sense) as well as
reproduction of bodily life. There is nothing par- production.
ticularly new, of course, about fears of environ- Reframing the ‘double movement’ in this way
mental threats. But the modern notion of is predicated upon what some might view as a
environmental crisis derives its potency, in part, heterodox conceptualization of neoliberalism,
from the discursive mediation of popular percep- and an equally heterodox genealogical account
tions of ‘global’ threats – albeit locally mediated of the emergence of ‘green neoliberalism’. I
and experienced – that have come to the fore in would argue that this is necessary if we are to
both policy and public discourse over the twen- produce comprehensive accounts of the neoli-
tieth century (Guha, 2000). beralization of socio-natures, broadly defined.
Framed in this way, the debate over neoliberal Again, the discussion above is not intended to
natures takes on a qualitatively new dimension in be definitive, but rather suggestive of the path-
which psychological and political struggles over ways that we might explore with this goal in
‘ecological fixes’ play an important role (Bakker, mind.
2004). In Beck’s formulation, this is character-
ized as the negotiation of the risks posed by envi-
ronmental ‘bads’ (rather than goods), spurred by IV Reflections
the fear of their effects which comes to dominate In making these arguments, let me emphasize
collective politics and individual psyches in that I am not suggesting that we should abandon
industrialized societies (Beck, 1992). The threat the concepts of neoliberalism and nature, nor
posed by capitalist modernity is not merely to dilute them to the point where they are all-
an existing social order, but rather a deeply exis- inclusive, and thus analytically unhelpful.
tential threat to the basis of life itself. In making Rather, my suggestions are aimed at stimulating
the connection between psyche and society, dialogue on better strategies for confronting the
Beck’s notion of the ‘risk society’ suggests a conceptual polysemism of both ‘neoliberalism’
broad interpretation of Polanyi’s concept of the and ‘natures’. These arguments are made with
‘double movement’ – in which capitalism oscil- the intention of provoking scholars of neoliberal
lates between dis-embedding and re-embedding natures to reflect upon their core conceptual and
economic activity from society (Polanyi, 1944). methodological commitments, while contribut-
In other words, the neoliberalization of nature ing to broader debates over neoliberalism and
threatens to alienate and dis-embed ‘nature’ from the ‘nature of nature’.
the socio-natural relations by which it is consti- Let me briefly recapitulate. I have suggested
tuted. The result has been a series of struggles above that we might search for a more expansive

727
728 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

understanding of neoliberal natures as the out- in the environmental realm – are not always uni-
come of cultural, social, and psychological – as formly negative for all actors. Accepting that
well as political, economic, ecological – struggles neoliberalization is variegated suggests the pos-
over our understandings of and relationships sibility that outcomes may be positive as well as
between socio-natures, both human and negative in specific geo-historical contexts. In
non-human. An expanded understanding of what other words, reregulation of the environment
‘counts’ as nature (beyond a narrow view of under neoliberalism produces a shift in the
nature-as-resource) implies a reformulation of ‘costs’ and ‘benefits’, and their allocation
how we trace genealogies of neoliberalism, as between different users – with some aspects of
both a multiscalar disciplinary regime and a proj- what we conventionally classify as ‘the environ-
ect of accumulation, wherein the disciplining of ment’ appearing to gain (while others lose) in the
socio-natural actors is articulated with translocal encounter (Bakker, 2005; Harris, 2009a). This
processes, yet refracted through local conditions. has a further implication for the study of resis-
This implies, in turn, an engagement with the tance, insofar as the ambiguous implications of
multiple dimensions of neoliberalization – as a neoliberalism for the environment are reflected
cultural formation and as ecological process, as in the fractures between different fractions of
well as a set of political and economic processes environmental movements. For example, main-
and governing practices (Kingfisher and stream environmental NGOs such as the World
Maskovsky, 2008; Ong, 2007). In doing so, the Resources Institute are openly supportive of
co-constitution of socio-natures and neoliberali- ‘market environmentalism’ (and of the techno-
zation becomes a central problematic. A more scientific innovations which fuel it), whereas
nuanced view of the agency of nature (together ‘deep ecology’-inspired environmental groups
with an expanded account of the variety of nat- (such as Earth First!) also tend to be anti-
ures subject to neoliberalization) would broaden capitalist (and sometimes anti-technology) in
and deepen our accounts, while enabling greater orientation.
conceptual precision regarding effects and viable My framing of the political ambivalence of
alternatives. This, in turn, suggests an expanded ‘green neoliberalism’ contrasts with much of the
understanding both of neoliberalism (cultural, literature on resistance to the neoliberalization
psychological, libidinal, as well as economic and of nature within geography, which tends to focus
ecological) and the socio-natures with which it is on anti-capitalist, alter-globalization move-
articulated. The typologies (presented as Tables 1 ments. Subtler questions of identity, and the
and 2) were intended to suggest one strategy for divergent views on markets within environmen-
engaging in dialogue about variegation, but were tal organizations and environmental movements
not intended to reify categories via which varie- more generally, are rarely systematically
gation is expressed. addressed (for an exception, see Harris, 2010).
Potential pitfalls to these suggestions were In short, the conceptual commitments sketched
discussed above. Here, let me point to potential out in this paper might be useful in working
opportunities. Take, for example, the issue of the through critical accounts of alternatives and
effects of neoliberalization processes on socio- resistance to neoliberalization.
natures. In much of the literature, the effects of The work of analysing resistance should, to put
neoliberalization processes are assumed to be it simply, take into account this messiness rather
necessarily (and often solely) negative. But care- than glossing over it. Let me point to one promis-
ful attention to the problematic of variegation ing approach that stems from recent work in
suggests a different, more ambivalent view- Gramscian political ecology. A focus on struggles
point: the impacts of neoliberalism – particularly over the co-constitution of resources and social

728
Bakker 729

relations enables the identification of counter- in turn deepen our contributions to what Neil
hegemonic forms of (re)production allied with Smith terms a ‘new political theory of nature’,
alternative concepts of nature-society relations leading to more fruitful engagement with post-
(see Ekers and Loftus, 2008; Holifield, 2009; neoliberalism – not as an assertion of a putative
Karriem, 2009; Wainwright and Mercer, 2009). political economic transition (of whose existence
I would argue that these sorts of approaches are we should, in my opinion, be sceptical – cf. Peck
necessary if scholars of neoliberal nature want et al., 2010), but rather as a thought-experiment
to engage seriously with questions of resistance, fully attentive to emergent political, cultural,
not only as ‘discursive erasure threatened by neo- socio-economic, and socio-natural forms, and
liberal theory’ (Gibson-Graham, 2008: 620), or as better equipped to anticipate and explore alterna-
struggle – on the part of both humans and non- tives to neoliberal imaginaries.
humans – to enrolment in specific practices which
we term ‘neoliberal’, but also as creative engage- Acknowledgements
ment with processes of neoliberalization in which Noel Castree, Kathryn Furlong, Leila Harris, Becky
socio-natures reshape and reframe – in positive as Mansfield, Philippe Le Billon, Hana Boye, and seven
well as negative ways – the conditions of their anonymous reviewers provided helpful comments.
own reproduction. The usual disclaimers apply.
Let me close with some comments directed at
sceptics. On the one hand, some might argue that Notes
those of a political economic persuasion can 1. This focus is not intended as a covert attempt at coloniz-
deploy their own versions of relational ing the concept of ‘neoliberal natures’; rather, it is an
approaches without adopting concepts or termi- explicit attempt to situate the positionality of my
nology from cognate subdisciplines. Others might critique.
resist the codification implicit in the typological 2. Space constraints do not permit more than an allusion
thought-experiment I have presented, and reject to related work by scholars in anthropology, political
science, and sociology, including Arun Agrawal,
the call to articulate analyses of political and eco-
Michael Goldman, Tania Li, and Timothy Mitchell.
nomic processes with accounts of assemblages of
3. There is an obvious parallel here with debates about the
socio-natures. This paper has positioned itself in degree to which political ecologists should use meth-
opposition to these views, in the spirit of ‘engaged ods derived from the ecological sciences (Walker,
pluralism’ (Barnes and Sheppard, 2009). Let me 2005). Attempts to reconcile the concerns of anthro-
offer three justifications for this. First, I have pology and ecosystems ecology in the 1970s covered
argued that dialogue can generate useful insights: much of the same ground (Abel and Stepp, 2003;
for example, those of a political economic persua- Biersack, 1999; Kottak, 1999; Little, 1999).
sion have much to learn from considering the 4. It is beyond the scope of this paper to deal with the
degree to which a commitment (whether implicit potential contributions of science and technology
or not) to a humanist view of the subject leads to a studies or actor-network theory to this particular point.
constrained research focus on resources as See Callon (1998); Latour (1993); Murdoch (2001).
5. The terms emotion and affect are not interchangeable,
primary commodities, excluding other types of
and definitions vary in the literature. So let me offer a
socio-natures. Second, I have argued that grap-
simple definition of affect: an unconscious relational
pling seriously – and simultaneously – with capacity of radical openness to other bodies, experi-
relational ontologies and the problematic of varie- enced by humans and non-humans alike (Anderson,
gated capitalisms might allow scholars of neolib- 2006; McCormack, 2003). Affect is, in this definition,
eral natures to develop a more comprehensive distinct from and prior to the conscious experience of
account of the multifaceted articulation of neoli- an emotion (although debate exists as to whether
beralization with socio-natures. Third, this might affect is pre- or post-cognitive).

729
730 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

6. ‘Free market environmentalism’ may be defined as a the extraction of nature ‘as is’, and in the latter case the
mode of resource regulation that promises a virtuous intensification of biological productivity involving
fusion of economic growth, efficiency, and environ- commodities amenable to manipulation via biotech-
mental conservation (eg, Anderson and Leal, 2001). nological innovations with the goal of increased profit
Proponents argue that, through establishing private via higher yields, improved disease resistance, and
property rights, employing markets as allocation more rapid maturation rates (Boyd et al., 2001).
mechanisms, and incorporating environmental extern- 11. See Harvey (2005) for a more detailed discussion. Key
alities through pricing, environmental goods will be moments in the emergence of neoliberalism as a doc-
more efficiently allocated, thereby simultaneously trine (and political practice) include: the Latin Ameri-
addressing concerns over environmental degradation can experiment with authoritarian market reform;
and inefficient use of resources. In short, markets will structural adjustment in developing countries in
be deployed as the solution rather than the cause of response to the debt crisis; and so-called ‘shock therapy’
environmental problems. in former Soviet states.
7. In using the term ‘translocal’, I am not implying an 12. The terms ‘extensive’ and ‘intensive’ are distinct from
assumption of convergence, or of some missing ‘mas- those used in regulationist analyses. In the latter
ter narrative’, but rather of a set of common patterns, approach, ‘extensive’ accumulation has a spatial
origins, and drivers, which are mediated through his- dimension, referring to the pre-Fordist strategies of
torically and geographically specific contexts. mass exploitation, conjoined with the exploration,
8. A third response might point to the prevalent emphasis conquest and consolidation of overseas sources of raw
within the discipline of geography on case study-based materials and outlets for produced goods. The regula-
approaches, and inductive theorization, as discussed in tionist term ‘intensive’ refers to a (Fordist) regime of
the exchange between Castree (2008a, 2008b, 2009) and accumulation that is characterized by a set of strate-
Bakker (2009). Contrast this with the research agenda gies focused on the intensification of production,
that emerged in political science around Elinor linked with real rising buying capacity, creating a ‘vir-
Ostrom’s conceptualization of common-pool resources tuous’ upward spiral of growth. The analogy here
in the 1980s (Ostrom, 1990). would be that nature is first produced extensively, and
9. Of course, this distinction is not fixed, but is rather subsequently capitalized intensively.
the contingent outcome of resource management
practices (groundwater, for example, may be
‘extracted’ or ‘cultivated’, depending on the balance References
between extraction and renewal rates). Similarly, Abel T and Stepp JR (2003) A new ecosystems ecology for
Bunker (1989) distinguishes between ‘extractive anthropology. Conservation Ecology 7(3): 12.
industries’ (eg, mining) and ‘transformative indus- Adam B (2005) Constructing the neoliberal sexual actor:
tries’ (eg, manufacturing) (see also Barham et al., Responsibility and care of the self in the discourse of
1994). Benton (1989) offers another categorization, barebackers. Culture, Health and Sexuality 7(4): 333–
which distinguishes between nature-based (ie, pri- 346.
mary commodity) production and industrial produc- Anderson B (2006) Becoming and being hopeful: Towards
tion (ie, manufacturing). These framings may be a theory of affect. Environment and Planning D: Soci-
read as a critique of the focus of mainstream political ety and Space 24(5): 733–752.
economy on labour as a transformative process Anderson T and Leal D (2001) Free Market Environment-
(rather than an adaptive process); the mainstream alism. New York: Palgrave.
approach overlooks the fact that the biophysical char- Bailey I (2007a) Neoliberalism, climate governance and
acteristics of ‘natural resources’ shape appropriation the scalar politics of EU emissions trading. Area
process and affect profit rates. But see Burkett’s 39(4): 431–442.
(1999) critiques of Benton’s analysis, in particular his Bailey I (2007b) Market environmentalism, new environ-
resuscitation of a nature/society dualism. mental policy instruments, and climate policy in the
10. Boyd et al. (2001) distinguish between the ‘formal’ United Kingdom and Germany. Annals of the Associa-
and ‘real’ subsumption of nature; in the former case tion of American Geographers 97(3): 530–550.

730
Bakker 731

Bakker I (2003) Neo-liberal governance and the reprivati- Brenner N, Peck J, and Theodore N (2010) Variegated neo-
zation of social reproduction: Social provisioning and liberalization: geographies, modalities, pathways. Glo-
shifting gender orders. In: Bakker I and Gill S (eds) bal Networks 10(2): 1–41.
Power, Production and Social Reproduction. London: Bridge G (2002) Grounding globalization: The prospects
Macmillan-Palgrave, 66–82. and perils of linking economic processes of globalization
Bakker K (2004) An Uncooperative Commodity: Privatiz- to environmental outcomes. Economic Geography 78(3):
ing water in England and Wales. Oxford: Oxford 361–386.
University Press. Bridge G (2004) Mapping the bonanza: Geographies of
Bakker K (2005) Neoliberalizing nature? Market mining investment in an era of neoliberal reform. The
environmentalism in water supply in England and Professional Geographer 56(3): 406–421.
Wales. Annals of the Association of American Geogra- Brown E, Cloke J, and Ali M (2008) GATS and develop-
phers 95(3): 542–565. ment: The case of the water sector. Progress in Devel-
Bakker K (2009) Neoliberal nature, ecological fixes, and opment Studies 8(1): 1–5.
the pitfalls of comparative research. Environment and Budds J (2004) Power, nature and neoliberalism: The
Planning A 41: 1781–1787. political ecology of water in Chile. Singapore Journal
Bakker K and Bridge G (2006) Material worlds? Resource of Tropical Geography 25: 322–342.
geographies and the ‘matter of nature’. Progress in Bunker S (1989) Staples, links, and poles in the construc-
Human Geography 30: 1–23. tion of regional development theory. Sociology Forum
Barnes T and Sheppard E (2009) ‘Nothing includes every- 4(4): 589–610.
thing’: Towards an engaged pluralism in Anglophone Burkett P (1999) Marx and Nature: A Red-Green Perspec-
economic geography. Progress in Human Geography tive. New York: St Martin’s Press.
33: 1–22. Bury J (2005) Mining mountains: Neoliberalism, land
Barnett C (2005) The consolations of ‘neoliberalism’. tenure, livelihoods, and the new Peruvian mining
Geoforum 36(1): 7–12. industry in Cajamarca. Environment and Planning
Beck U (1992) Risk Society: Towards a New Modernity. A 37: 221–23.
London: SAGE. Callon M (ed.) (1998) The Laws of the Markets. London:
Benton T (1989) Marxism and Natural Limits: An Ecolo- Blackwell.
gical Critique and Reconstruction. In: Benton T (ed.) Cashin P, Liang H, and McDermott T (2000) How persis-
The Greening of Marxism. New York: Guilford Press, tent are shocks to world commodity prices? IMF Staff
157–183. Papers 47(2): 177–217.
Benton T (1996) The Greening of Marxism. New York: Castree N (2005) The epistemology of particulars: Human
Guilford Press. geography, case studies, and ‘context’. Geoforum 36:
Bernstein S (2000) The Compromise of Liberal Environ- 541–544.
mentalism. New York: Columbia University Press. Castree N (2006) From neoliberalism to neoliberalization:
Biersack A (1999) Introduction: From the ‘new ecology’ to Consolations, confusions, and necessary illusions.
the new ecologies. American Anthropologist 101: 5–18. Environment and Planning A 38(1): 1–6.
Boyd W, Prudham S, and Schurman R (2001) Industrial Castree N (2008a) Neoliberalising nature: The logics of
dynamics and the problem of nature. Society and Natu- deregulation and reregulation. Environment and Plan-
ral Resources 14: 555–570. ning A 40: 131–152.
Boyer K (2010) Of care and commodities: Breast milk and Castree N (2008b) Neoliberalising nature: Processes,
the new politics of mobile biosubstances. Progress in effects, and evaluations. Environment and Planning
Human Geography 34(1): 5–20. A 40: 153–173.
Braun B (2008) Environmental issues: Inventive life. Castree N (2009) Researching neoliberal environmental
Progress in Human Geography 32: 667–679. governance: A reply to Karen Bakker. Environment
Braun B (2009) Nature. In: Castree N, Demeritt D, and Planning A 41: 1788–1794.
Liverman D, and Rhoads B (eds) A Companion Daviron B and Ponte S (2005) The Coffee Paradox: Global
to Environmental Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, Markets, Commodity Trade, and the Elusive Promise of
19–36. Development. London: Zed Books.

731
732 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

Demeritt D (2009) Geography and the promise of integra- Guthman J (2004) Agrarian Dreams: The Paradox of
tive environmental research. Geoforum 40(2): 127– Organic Farming in California. Berkeley, CA: Univer-
129. sity of California Press.
Dibden J, Potter C, and Cocklin C (2009) Contesting the Guthman J (2007) The Polanyian way? Voluntary food
neoliberal project for agriculture: Productivist and multi- labels as neoliberal governance. Antipode 39(3):
functional trajectories in the European Union and Austra- 456–478.
lia. Journal of Rural Studies 25(3): 299–308. Guthman J (2009) Teaching the politics of obesity: insights
Dickenson D (2007) Property in the Body: Feminist Per- Insights into neoliberal embodiment and contemporary
spectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. biopolitics. Antipode 41(5): 1110–1133.
Duffy R (2008) Neoliberalising nature: Global networks Haraway D (1991) Simians, Cyborgs and Women: The
and ecotourism development in Madagascar. Journal Reinvention of Nature. London, Routledge.
of Sustainable Tourism 16(3): 327–344. Harris L (2009a) Gender and emergent water governance:
Eden S (2009) The work of environmental governance net- Comparative overview of neoliberalized natures and
works: Traceability, credibility and certification by the gender dimensions of privatization, devolution and
Forest Stewardship Council. Geoforum 40(3): 383–394. marketization. Gender, Place and Culture 16(4):
Ekers M and Loftus A (2008) The power of water: Devel- 387–408.
oping dialogues between Foucault and Gramsci. Envi- Harris L (2009b) A review of Heynen N, McCarthy J,
ronment and Planning D: Society and Space 26(4): Prudham WS and Robbins P (eds) Neoliberal Environ-
698–718. ments: False Promises and Unnatural Consequences.
Escobar A (1998) Whose knowledge, whose nature? Biodi- Annals of the Association of American Geographers
versity, conservation, and the political ecology of social 99(1): 209–213.
movements. Journal of Political Ecology 5: 53–82. Harris L (2010) Neo(liberal) citizens of Europe: politics,
Escobar A (1999) After nature. Steps to an antiessentialist scales, and visibilities of environmental citizenship
political ecology. Current Anthropology 40(1): 1–30. in contemporary Turkey. Citizenship Studies:
Foster JB (2000) Marx’s Ecology: Materialism and forthcoming.
Nature. New York: Monthly Review Press. Hartwick, E and Peet R (2003) Neoliberalism and nature:
Franklin S (2007) Dolly Mixtures: The Remaking of Gen- The case of the WTO. Annals of the AAPPS 590:
ealogy. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. 188–211.
Gary G (2009) The responsibilization strategy of health Harvey D (2003) The New Imperialism. Oxford: Oxford
and safety: Neo-liberalism and the reconfiguration of University Press.
individual responsibility for risk. British Journal of Harvey D (2005) A Brief History of Neoliberalism. Oxford:
Criminology 49: 326–342. Oxford University Press.
Gibson-Graham JK (2008) Diverse economies: Performa- Hayden C (2003) When Nature Goes Public: The Making
tive practices for ‘other worlds’. Progress in Human and Unmaking of Bioprospecting in Mexico. Princeton,
Geography 32(5): 613–632. NJ: Princeton University Press.
Glassman J (2006) Primitive accumulation, accumulation Heynen N and Robbins P (2005) The neoliberalization of
by dispossession, accumulation by ‘extra-economic’ nature: Governance, privatization, enclosure and valua-
means. Progress in Human Geography 30(5): 608– tion. Capitalism, Nature, Socialism 16(1): 5–8.
625. Heynen N, McCarthy J, Prudham WS, and Robbins P (eds)
Goldman M (2005) Imperial Nature: The World Bank and (2007) Neoliberal Environments: False Promises and
Struggles for Social Justice in the Age of Globalization. Unnatural Consequences. New York: Routledge.
New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Higgins V, Dibden J, and Cocklin C (2008) Neoliberalism
Guha R (2000) Environmentalism: A Global History. New and natural resource management: Agri-environmental
York: Longman. standards and the governing of farming practices,
Gupta J (2008) Embodied subjects and fragmented objects: Geoforum 39(5):1776–1785.
Women’s bodies, assisted reproduction technologies Himley M (2008) Geographies of environmental
and the right to self-determination. Journal of Bioethi- governance: The nexus of nature and neoliberalism.
cal Inquiry 5(4): 239–249. Geography Compass 2(2): 433–451.

732
Bakker 733

Hinchliffe S (2008) Reconstituting nature conservation: Little PE (1999) Environments and environmentalisms in
Towards a careful political ecology. Geoforum 39(1): anthropological research: Facing a new millennium.
88–97. Annual Review of Anthropology 28: 253–284.
Hinchliffe S, Kearnes M, Degen M, and Whatmore S Littlefield C, Mahlstedt A, Popp A, and Trautmann N
(2005) Urban wild things: A cosmopolitical experi- (2008) A review of Heynen N, McCarthy K,
ment. Environment and Planning D: Society and Prudham WS and Robbins P (eds) Neoliberal Envir-
Space 23: 643–658. onments: False Promises and Unnatural Conse-
Hinchliffe S, Kearnes M, Degen M, and Whatmore S quences. Environment and Planning A 40:
(2007) Ecologies and economies of action – sustain- 2028–2030.
ability, calculations and other things. Environment and Liverman D and Vilas S (2006) Neoliberalism and the
Planning A 39(2): 260–282. environment in Latin America. Annual Review of Envi-
Holifield R (2009) How to speak for aquifers and people at ronment and Resources 31: 327–363.
the same time? Environmental justice and counter- Lockie S and Higgins V (2007) Roll-out neoliberalism and
network formation at a hazardous waste site. Geoforum hybrid practices of regulation in Australian agri-
40(3): 363–372. environmental governance. Journal of Rural Studies
Jackson P (2000) Rematerialising social and cultural geo- 23(1): 1–11.
graphy. Social and Cultural Geography 1: 9–14. Lorimer H (2005) Cultural geography: The busyness of
Karriem A (2009) The rise and transformation of the being ‘more-than-representational’. Progress in
Brazilian landless movement into a counter-hegemonic Human Geography 29: 83–94.
political actor: A Gramscian analysis. Geoforum 40(3): McAfee K (2003) Neoliberalism on the molecular scale:
316–325. Economic and genetic reductionism in biotechnology
Kingfisher C and Maskovsky J (2008) The limits of neoli- battles. Geoforum 34: 203–219.
beralism. Critique of Anthropology 28: 115–126. McAfee K and Shapiro E (2010) Payment for ecosystem
Klepeis P and Vance C (2003) Neoliberal policy and services in Mexico: Nature, neoliberalism, social
deforestation in southeastern Mexico: An assessment movements and the state. Annals of the Association of
of the PROCAMPO Program. Economic Geography American Geographers, forthcoming.
79: 221–240. McCarthy J (2004) Privatizing conditions of production:
Kottak CP (1999) The new ecological anthropology. Trade agreements as neoliberal environmental govern-
American Anthropologist 101: 23–35. ance. Geoforum 35(3): 327–41.
Larner W (2003) ‘Neoliberalism?’ Environment and Plan- McCarthy J (2005a) Commons as counterhegemonic proj-
ning D: Society and Space 21(5): 509–512. ect. Capitalism, Nature, Socialism 16(1): 9–24.
Latour B (1993) We Have Never Been Modern. McCarthy J (2005b) Scale, sovereignty, and strategy
Cambridge, MA; Harvard University Press. in environmental governance. Antipode 37(4):
Latour B (1998) To modernise or ecologise? That is the 731–753.
question. In: Braun B and Castree N (eds) Remaking McCarthy J (2005c) Devolution in the woods: Community
Reality: Nature at the Millennium. London: Routle- forestry as hybrid neoliberalism. Environment and
dge, 221–242. Planning A 37(6): 995–1014.
Latour B (2004) Politics of Nature. Cambridge, MA: McCarthy J (2006a) Neoliberalism and the politics of
Harvard University Press. alternatives: Community forestry in British Columbia
Le Billon P (2006) Fatal transactions: Conflict diamonds and the United States. Annals of the Association of
and the (anti)terrorist consumer. Antipode 38(4): American Geographers 96(1): 84–104.
778–801. McCarthy J (2006b) Rural geography: Alternative rural
Le Billon P (2008) Diamond wars? Conflict diamonds and economies – the search for alterity in forests, fisheries,
geographies of resource wars. Annals of the Association food, and fair trade. Progress in Human Geography.
of American Geographers 98(2): 345–372. 30(6): 803–811.
Le Billon P and Cervantes A (2009) Oil prices, scarcity and McCarthy J and Prudham S (2004) Neoliberal natures
geographies of war. Annals of the Association of Amer- and the nature of neoliberalism. Geoforum 35:
ican Geographers 99(5): 836–844. 275–283.

733
734 Progress in Human Geography 34(6)

McCormack DP (2003) An event of geographical ethics in Peck J, Theodore N, and Brenner N (2010) Postneoliber-
spaces of affect. Transactions of the Institute of British alism and its malcontents. Antipode 41(6): 1236–
Geographers 28(4), 488–507. 1258.
McDonald D and Ruiters G (2005) The Age of Commodity: Perelman M (2000) The Invention of Capitalism: Classi-
Water Privatization in Southern Africa. London: cal Political Economy and the Secret History of Pri-
Earthscan. mitive Accumulation. Durham, NC: Duke University
Mansfield B (2003) From catfish to organic fish: Making Press.
distinctions about nature as cultural economic practice. Perreault T (2005) State restructuring and the scale politics
Geoforum 34(3): 329–342. of rural water governance in Bolivia. Environment and
Mansfield B (2004) Neoliberalism in the oceans: Planning A 37: 263–284.
‘Rationalization’, property rights, and the commons Perreault T (2006) From the Guerra del Agua to the
question. Geoforum 35: 313–326. Guerra del Gas: Resource governance, neoliberalism and
Mansfield B (2007a) Privatization: Property and the popular protest in Bolivia. Antipode 38(1): 150–172.
remaking of nature–society relations. Antipode 39(3): Philo C and Wilbert C (2000) Animal Spaces, Beastly
393–405. Places: New Geographies of Human-Animal Relations.
Mansfield B (2007b) Property, markets, and dispossession: London: Routledge.
The Western Alaska Community Development Quota Pile S (2010) Emotions and affect in recent human geogra-
as neoliberalism, social justice, both, and neither. Anti- phy. Transactions of the Institute of British Geogra-
pode 39(3): 479–499. phers 35(1): 5–20.
Mansfield B (ed.) (2008a) Privatization: Property and the Polanyi K (1944) The Great Transformation: The Political
Remaking of Nature-Society Relations. Oxford: and Economic Origins of Our Time. New York: Farrar
Blackwell. and Reinhart.
Mansfield B (2008b) The social nature of natural child- Posey D (2002) Commodification of the sacred through
birth. Social Science and Medicine 66: 1084–1094. intellectual property rights. Journal of Ethnopharma-
Mansfield B (2008c) Health as a nature-society question. cology 83(1–2): 3–12.
Environment and Planning A 40: 1015–1019. Pratt G (2004) Working Feminism. Philadelphia, PA: Tem-
Mitchell T (2002) Rule of Experts: Egypt, Techno-Politics, ple University Press.
Modernity. Berkeley, CA: University of California Prudham S (2004) Poisoning the well: Neoliberalism and
Press. the contamination of municipal water in Walkerton,
Mitchell T (2008) Rethinking economy. Geoforum 39: Ontario. Geoforum 35: 343–359.
1116–1121. Prudham S (2005) Knock On Wood: Nature as Commodity
Murdoch J (2001) Ecologising sociology: Actor-network in Douglas-fir Country. New York: Routledge.
theory, co-construction and the problem of human Prudham S (2007) The fictions of autonomous inven-
exemptionalism. Sociology 35: 111–133. tion: Accumulation by dispossession, commodifica-
Nast H (2006) Loving . . . whatever: Alienation, neoliber- tion and life patents in Canada. Antipode 39(3):
alism and pet-love in the twenty-first century. Acme 406–428.
5(2): 300–327. Robbins P (2007) Lawn People: How Grasses, Weeds, and
Ong A (2007) Neoliberalism as a mobile technology Chemicals Make Us Who We Are. Philadelphia, PA:
Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers Temple University Press.
32(1): 3–8. Robbins P and Luginbuhl A (2007) The last enclosure:
Ostrom E (1990) Governing the Commons: The Evolution Resisting privatization of wildlife in the western United
of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: States. In: Heynen NJ, McCarthy WS, Prudham S, and
Cambridge University Press. Robbins P (eds) Neoliberal Environments: False
Peck J (2001) Workfare States. New York: Guilford Press. Promises and Unnatural Consequences. Abingdon:
Peck J (2008) Remaking laissez-faire. Progress in Human Routledge, 25–37.
Geography 32(1): 3–43. Roberts A (2008) Privatizing social reproduction: The pri-
Peck J and Theodore N (2007) Variegated capitalism. mitive accumulation of water in an era of neoliberal-
Progress in Human Geography 31(6): 731–772. ism. Antipode 40(4): 535–560.

734
Bakker 735

Robertson M (2004) The neoliberalization of ecosystem Valdivia G (2004) On indigeneity, change, and representa-
services: Wetland mitigation banking and problems in tion in the northeastern Ecuadorian Amazon. Environ-
environmental governance. Geoforum 35: 361–373. ment and Planning A 37: 285–303.
Robertson M (2007) Discovering price in all the wrong van Dooren T (2008) Inventing seed: The nature(s) of
places: The work of commodity definition and price intellectual property in plants. Environment and
under neoliberal environmental policy. Antipode Planning D: Society and Space 26(4): 676–697.
39(3): 500–526. Wainwright J and Mercer K (2009) The dilemma of
Rofel K (2007) Desiring China: Experiments in Neoliber- decontamination: A Gramscian analysis of the Mexi-
alism, Sexuality, and Public Culture (Perverse Moder- can transgenic maize dispute. Geoforum 40(3): 345–
nities). Durham, NC: Duke University Press. 354.
St. Martin K (2005) Disrupting enclosure in New Waldby C and Cooper M (2008) The biopolitics of repro-
England fisheries. Capitalism, Nature, Socialism duction. Australian Feminist Studies 23: 55–73.
16(1): 63–80. Walker P (2005) Political ecology: Where is the ecol-
St. Martin K (2007) The difference that class makes: Neo- ogy? Progress in Human Geography 29(1): 73–82.
liberalization and non-capitalism in the fishing industry Warhurst A and Bridge G (2003) Economic Liberalisa-
of New England. Antipode 39(3): 527–549. tion, Innovation, and Technology Transfer: Opportu-
Scheper-Hughes N (2005) The last commodity: Post- nities for cleaner production in copper mining and
Human Ethics and the global trade in ‘fresh’ organs. processing. In: Brundenius C (ed.) Technological
In: Ong A and S Collier (eds) Global Assemblages: Change and the Environmental Imperative: The
Technology, Politics and Ethics as Anthropological Challenge to the Copper Industry. Cheltenham:
Problems. Oxford: Blackwell, 145–168. Edward Elgar, 11–43.
Scoones I (1999) New ecology and the social sciences: Whatmore S (2002) Hybrid Geographies: Natures,
What prospects for a fruitful engagement? Annual Cultures, Spaces. London: SAGE.
Review of Anthropology 28: 479–507. Whatmore S (2006) Materialist returns: Practising cultural
Smith N (1984) Uneven Development. Oxford: Blackwell. geographies in and for a more-than-human world.
Sutton B (2010) Bodies in Crisis: Culture, Violence, and Cultural Geographies 13(4): 600–610.
Women’s Resistance in Neoliberal Argentina. Toronto: Wolch J and Emel J (1998) Animal Geographies: Place,
Rutgers University Press. Politics, and Identity in the Nature-Culture Border-
Swyngedouw E (1999) Modernity and hybridity: Nature, lands. London: Verso.
regeneracionismo, and the production of the Spanish Yeung H (2005) Rethinking relational economic geogra-
waterscape, 1890–1930. Annals of the Association of phy. Progress in Human Geography 30(1): 37–51.
American Geographers 89(3): 443–465. Zimmerer KS (2000) The reworking of conservation
Talbot J (2004) Grounds for Agreement: The Political geographies: Nonequilibrium landscapes and nature–
Economy of the Coffee Commodity Chain. Oxford: society hybrids. Annals of the Association of American
Rowman and Littlefield. Geographers 90(2): 356–336.

735
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

You might also like