You are on page 1of 6

LAND MARKETS IN DEVELOPING AND TRANSITION

ECONOMIES: IMPACT OF LIBERALIZATION


AND IMPLICATIONS FOR FUTURE REFORM

KLAUS DEININGER

Well-functioning land markets can, in prin- ment intervention. To assess whether such in-
ciple, contribute to broad-based rural de- tervention could be justified and, if yes, what
velopment in several ways. First, where the form it might take, empirical investigation of
ownership distribution of land differs from the both the equity and efficiency implications of

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Cornell University Library on June 26, 2015


optimum operational structure, land markets land markets is needed. Providing a summary
can transfer land from less to more productive of such evidence is the goal of this paper.
producers and thus increase productivity. Sec- The next section reviews the conceptual
ond, transferable land rights make it less costly foundation of agricultural land rental and sales
for rural residents to take jobs in the nonfarm markets, highlighting the importance of tenure
economy, something that is likely to boost the security, the changes brought about by broader
off-farm sector. Third, transferability of land economic growth, and differences between
increases investment incentives because those rental and sales markets. The “Empirical
who make such an investment can enjoy the Evidence” section presents a summary of em-
benefits even if they are no longer able to per- pirical evidence from different regions regard-
sonally use the land. Finally, the ability to trans- ing the potential and pitfalls of land markets
fer land at low cost will reduce the transaction and their development over time. The section
cost of accessing credit and can, if there is effec- “Implications for Policy and Research” draws
tive demand for credit, increase credit supply. out conclusions with respect to the scope for,
Past literature has discussed the potential of and the limitations of, public land policy and
land markets and the different contractual op- avenues for future research.
tions open to participants (Sadoulet, Murgai,
and de Janvry; Hayami and Otsuka) as well as
the performance of such markets in specific re- Conceptual Foundations
gional contexts (Carter and Salgado; Rozelle
and Swinnen; Deininger 2003). For many rural Without significant economies of scale, and in
households, land is, however, not only a pro- the absence of imperfections in other markets,
duction factor but also a key asset, implying e.g., for credit, land rental markets will im-
that, over and above their impact on efficiency prove efficiency and equity. A large literature
of land use, land markets will have far-reaching has demonstrated that unmechanized agricul-
impacts on equity. In fact, concern that, in the ture generally does not exhibit economies of
presence of imperfections in other markets, scale in production, even though economies
unmitigated operation of land markets would of scale from marketing may in some cases
lead to undesirable equity outcomes, has tra- be transferred back to the production stage
ditionally provided a justification for govern- (Binswanger, Deininger, and Feder). Even at
higher levels of mechanization, there are rarely
Klaus Deininger is lead economist in the Development Research economies of scale beyond what can be man-
Group of the World Bank. The paper benefited from discussions aged by the operator’s family. The need to
with a wide range of stakeholders during workshops in Budapest, supervise hired laborers implies that owner-
Kampala, Pachuca, Phnom Penh, and Washington.
Special thanks are due to Michael Carter, Jonathan Conning, operated farms are generally more efficient
Alain de Janvry, Gershon Feder, Bruce Gardner, and William than those relying on permanent wage workers
Liefert. The views expressed are those of the author and do not
necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its Board of Executive
(Otsuka, Chuma, and Hayami).
Directors, or the countries they represent. At the same time, a number of factors,
This article was presented in a principal paper session at the including credit rationing and the scope to
AAEA annual meeting (Montreal, Quebec, July 2003). The arti-
cles in these sessions are not subjected to the journal’s standard use land as collateral to overcome informa-
refereeing process. tional imperfections that are inherent to credit
Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 85 (Number 5, 2003): 1217–1222
Copyright 2003 American Agricultural Economics Association
1218 Number 5, 2003 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

markets, may increase the purchase price of tial credit market access by different groups
land over and above the present value of of agents, all create scope for increasing the
agricultural profits. Where access to credit price of land beyond the present value of prof-
is important and land is the main collateral its from agricultural production (Carter and
available, greater credit access by large farm- Zimmerman). This will make it difficult for
ers can lead to the appearance of a positive poor but efficient producers to acquire land
relationship between farm size and produc- through the sales market (Carter and Mesbah).
tivity, possibly counteracting the supervision Second, in risky environments where small
cost advantage of small owner-operated farms landowners do not have access to credit mar-
(Kevane, Mathijs and Swinnen). kets, land sales markets will be thin, prices
Especially if rent is paid on an annual basis, can fluctuate considerably, and distress sales
rental requires limited initial outlays of capi- of land by poor but technically efficient pro-
tal, provides less scope for divergence between ducers can occur with negative equity and effi-
land prices and the productive value of the ciency impacts can occur (Kranton and Swamy;

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Cornell University Library on June 26, 2015


land, and is associated with lower transaction Bidinger et al., Cain). Finally, the fact that per-
costs than land sales. This, together with partic- unit transaction costs incurred in land markets
ipants’ ability to adapt contract terms to pre- generally decrease with the size of the land
vailing market imperfections at least to some transferred and are often further increased by
extent, implies that rental can be a flexible way transaction taxes, can result in market segmen-
to transfer land from less to more productive tation or push transactions into informality
producers, which may also provide a stepping (Carter and Zegarra).
stone for tenants to accumulate experience and
possibly make the transition to land ownership
at a later stage. Empirical Evidence
The literature has long pointed out that
rental arrangements based on fixed rather than The general conclusions discussed in the fore-
share rents are more likely to maximize pro- going section, and the importance of govern-
ductivity (Hayami and Otsuka). Poor produc- ment policies in shaping the outcomes from
ers may, however, not be offered fixed rent con- land sales markets, are supported by empiri-
tracts due to the risk of default. Where this cal evidence. In particular, secure and clearly
is the case, sharecropping has emerged as a assigned property rights provide the basis for
second-best solution. In theory, sharecropping active rental markets in many developed coun-
contracts could be associated with inefficien- tries and have also proven critical in transition
cies, which might be reduced by government economies. Rental is associated with informa-
intervention. In practice, losses associated with tional and cost advantages over government-
such contracts were found to be small and im- sponsored land reallocation in East Asia where
proving on them through government inter- there is evidence of ill-functioning credit mar-
vention proved to be difficult, if not impos- kets increasing the scope for distress sales.
sible (Shaban; Nagarajan, Quisumbing, and African cases show that, where access to land is
Otsuka). The alternatives open to potential not too unequal, broader economic growth can
tenants, in particular rural wage rates—which lead to a rapid increase in efficiency-enhancing
are in turn affected by access to infrastruc- rental transactions and at the same time illus-
ture and nonfarm economic development, do trate the importance of secure land rights for
generally have a more important impact on the development of the off-farm economy. In
the equity impact of land rental contracts Latin America, macroeconomic liberalization
(Mookherjee and Ray). had a similarly clear impact on the extent of
Although transfer of use rights through land market transactions even though this was
rental markets can go a long way to improve in many cases insufficient to overcome a legacy
productivity, only the ability to transfer owner- of unequal land distribution and access.
ship allows use of land as collateral for credit. In industrialized nations, rental markets of-
The performance of sales markets is, however, ten cover large shares of cultivated area, up to
affected by three factors. First, a number of 70% in some cases (Swinnen). In the United
variables including participants’ expectations States, the share of renters increased from 35%
regarding future price movements, macroeco- in 1950 to 43% in 1992, much of which involves
nomic instability, subsidies to agriculture, the sharecropping (Dasgupta, Knight, and Love).
ability to use land as a collateral in credit mar- Secure individual land rights allow house-
kets, and selective tax breaks and differen- holds to enter into long-term contracts that
Deininger Land Markets 1219

do not appear to be associated with reduced participation in 2001 at about 10% of house-
investment incentives; to the contrary many holds (China National Bureau of Statistics).
tenants prefer rental to land purchase given Advantages of decentralized transfers include
its lower capital requirements and greater greater flexibility, improved efficiency and eq-
flexibility (Bierlen). uity, and less scope for politically motivated in-
In most Central and Eastern European terference. Comparing the outcomes achieved
(CEE) countries, the post-communist transi- by both mechanisms confirms that decentral-
tion implied that land plots were restituted ized allocation brings greater efficiency gains
to original owners who often did not want to than administrative transfers. In view of high
be involved in farming. Rental played an im- levels of unsatisfied demand (22.4% of house-
portant role in the initial transition and, even holds indicated that at the current market rate
where secure long-term land rights are now they would be willing to rent in), this suggests
well established, remain of great importance that better rental market functioning could in-
where macroeconomic uncertainty, together crease productivity by between 7% and 12%

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Cornell University Library on June 26, 2015


with shallow financial markets continue to im- (Deininger and Jin 2002).
pede development of rural land sales markets. A similar increase in decentralized land
By contrast, well-functioning and efficiency- rental transactions is apparent from Vietnam:
enhancing land markets have been slow to while only 3.8% of rural households partici-
evolve in many countries of the Common- pated in land rental in 1992, 15.8% did so in
wealth of Independent States (CIS) where 1998. More productive households are more
land was privatized in the form of “paper likely to rent and to engage in land pur-
shares” rather than plots that can be phys- chases, illustrating that, with economic de-
ically identified and exchanged. Collective velopment and emergence of off-farm oppor-
managers’ privileged access to output or input tunities, rental markets can increase holding
markets implies that in these instances most sizes and welfare among those who, for var-
“rental” transactions consist of the transfer ious reasons, do not migrate. At the same
of land shares back to the former collective time, households that experienced unexpected
(Csaki, Feder, and Lerman). There is, how- shocks have a higher tendency to engage in dis-
ever, evidence that in situations where land has tress sales, especially if credit market access is
been physically redistributed, as in the Kyrgyz limited (Deininger and Jin 2003).
Republic, even small endowments of land can Given their more unequal land ownership
make a significant contribution to welfare and distribution, several South Asian countries
reduce the variability of consumption. More- have, in addition to efforts at redistributing
over, efficiency-enhancing markets for tem- land beyond a certain size, imposed tenancy
porary exchange of land are slowly emerging laws that combine rent ceilings with the award
(Deininger and Savastano). of semi-permanent rights to tenants in an
East Asia illustrates how government inter- attempt to improve cultivators’ welfare. Al-
vention in land markets, even if it worked well though such measures can provide short-term
earlier, may be overtaken by more decentral- advantages to sitting tenants, they are likely
ized mechanisms. In China, administrative re- to cut off the supply of land to the rental
allocations provided, until very recently, the market and reduce incentives to undertake
main mechanism to transfer land between pro- land-related investment (Basu and Emerson).
ducers. However, an increase in the demand Due to political resistance, effective imple-
for land transactions due to off-farm migra- mentation remained limited and positive ini-
tion made reliance on administrative mech- tial effects are reported for only one state,
anisms increasingly difficult, in addition to West Bengal (Banerjee, Gertler, and Ghatak;
drawing attention to possible inefficiencies as- Rawal). However, as second-generation prob-
sociated with the discrete nature of redistri- lems related to restrictions put on transferabil-
butions and the informational imperfections ity by beneficiaries of these reforms are begin-
related to the fact that village leaders of- ning to emerge, possibilities for modification of
ten lack the information (or the incentives) tenancy legislation are more widely discussed
to identify producers who are most produc- (Saxena).
tive. This is visible in some of China’s poor- Large differences in land market activity
est provinces where land rental market par- across African countries can often be directly
ticipation increased from 2.3% of producers traced to past interventions. Rental markets
in 1995 to 9.4% in 2000 (Deininger and Jin that include long-term transactions that are
2003). Recent national estimates put rental in many respects equivalent to sales, are very
1220 Number 5, 2003 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

active in West Africa, even though they remain uity. The fact that in many cases this potential is
mostly informal (Amanor and Diderutuah). not fully realized suggests that policy interven-
In East and Southern Africa, colonial policy tions to address constraints that limit the du-
had long outlawed such markets (Deininger ration or outreach of land rentals can improve
and Binswanger). Still, there is evidence that productivity and equity. Such constraints in-
market activity can increase with greater non- clude large differences in initial endowments,
farm opportunities and economic liberaliza- ill-functioning markets for other factors, high
tion. In Uganda, the share of households rent- transaction costs, and doubts about tenure se-
ing in land increased from 13% in 1992 to curity or recognition of land transfers. The ex-
36% in 1999 and there is clear evidence that, tent to which any of these factors is amenable
by transferring land to poor but more able to policy intervention varies, but finding ways
producers, greater market activity contributed to ensure tenure security and reduce the trans-
to increased equity and allocative efficiency, action costs of transferring land use rights is a
contrary to what is observed in land sales mar- key issue in most parts of the developing world.

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Cornell University Library on June 26, 2015


kets (Deininger and Mpuga). Where restric- Evidence on the impact of markets for per-
tions on rental markets remain, their removal manent transfers suggests that, as one would
could contribute to better land utilization and expect, land sales markets are less likely to
accelerate development of the economy. In improve productivity and equity and may, un-
Ethiopia, farmers who had taken nonfarm jobs der certain circumstances, reduce one or both
perceived a significantly higher risk of land loss of these objectives. Although this has often
through redistribution than those engaging in been used as a justification for imposing lim-
self-cultivation (Deininger et al.). itations on land sales, doing so will have a
In Latin America, a perception of weak number of negative side effects. Even if well
property rights and a history of land rental implemented, such restrictions have almost in-
market restrictions imply that rental markets variably ended up weakening property rights,
are often less effective in transforming a highly increasing the cost of land transfers, and driv-
unequal land ownership structure into a more ing transactions into informality. As the ben-
egalitarian operational distribution of land efits from transferring land will become more
than one might expect. Macroeconomic lib- relevant with economic development and spe-
eralization during the 1990s led to a signifi- cialization, the cost of such restrictions is likely
cant drop of land prices, and, in some cases, to increase over time. Providing other safety
better performance of land rental markets in nets may be a cheaper option to ward off dis-
much of the region. At the same time, the level tress sales and destitution than outlawing land
and amount of transactions often appear to sales, especially in view of the fact that such
lag well behind the potential and the areas restrictions need to be enforced by a bureau-
transacted remain small (Deininger, Zegarra, cracy that may itself develop into a source of
and Lavadenz). Insecure property rights and rent seeking. Thus, with very few exceptions
the possibly high costs of enforcement imply such as farm size limits in the thousands of
that virtually all land rental is short term, in hectares to limit speculative acquisition in the
many cases with close relatives where enforce- case of rapid structural change, the costs associ-
ment without recourse to formal authorities ated with such measures far outweigh possible
is possible (Barham, Carter, and Deininger). benefits; therefore there is little to recommend
Nonetheless, interventions to increase the se- such restrictions as an effective tool for policy.
curity of property rights and eliminate rental While this suggests that there is little justifi-
restrictions can have a significant impact not cation for restricting the functioning of land
only on land market activity, but also on gov- markets, it also implies that, in developing
ernance, as illustrated by the case of Mexico country situations characterized by a highly
(World Bank). unequal land ownership distribution and mul-
tiple market imperfections, land markets may
not bring about a distribution that will max-
Implications for Policy and Research imize productivity within a time frame that
would be consistent with broader social goals.
Review of an emerging empirical literature on In such cases, government programs to im-
the functioning of land markets provides evi- prove access to assets by the poor can be justi-
dence that, contrary to fears that land markets fied on equity and efficiency grounds although
would systematically disenfranchise the poor, experience illustrates that successful conduct
rental generally improves productivity and eq- of such programs is not easy. In Colombia, for
Deininger Land Markets 1221

example, land rental was still more effective “Power, Distortions, Revolt and Reform in
in transferring land to productive and land- Agricultural Land Relations.” Handbook of
poor producers than the government’s land Development Economics 3B(1995):2659–2772.
reform program (Deininger, Gonzalez, and Cain, M. “Risk and Insurance: Perspectives on
Castagnini). This suggests that where such pro- Fertility and Agrarian Change in India and
grams are to be implemented, they should Bangladesh.” Population and Development Re-
build on and complement land transfers by pri- view 7(1981):435–74.
vate agents rather than trying to substitute for Carter, M., and R. Salgado. “Land Market Liber-
them. alization and the Agrarian Question in Latin
Most research on land markets thus far has America.” A. de Janvry, J.P. Platteau, and E.
focused on outcomes at any given point in Sadoulet, eds., pp. 246–78. Land Access, Rural
time, implying that there is still considerable Poverty and Public Action. New York: Oxford
scope for exploring the impact of land market University Press, 2001.
arrangements on longer term outcomes. Re- Carter, M.R., and E. Zegarra. “Land Markets and

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Cornell University Library on June 26, 2015


search to address this issue could explore the the Persistence of Rural Poverty in Latin Amer-
interaction between land rental and sales mar- ica: Post-Liberalization Policy Options.” A.
kets and the role of land in the asset portfolio Valdes and R. Lopez, eds., pp. 451–96. Rural
of poor rural households. Better understand- Poverty in Latin America: Analystics, New Em-
ing and more specific evidence of the impact of pirical Evidence and Policy Options. New York:
land ownership and access on levels and vari- Palgrave MacMillan Press, 2000.
ability of consumption, on productive invest- Carter, M.R., and D. Mesbah. “Can Land Market
ment, and on the ability to acquire other agri- Reform Mitigate the Exclusionary Aspects of
cultural or nonagricultural assets would not Rapid Agro-Export Growth?” World Develop-
only be desirable to expand our knowledge on ment 21(1993):1085–100.
the functioning of land markets but also help Carter, M.R., and F.J. Zimmerman. “The Dynamic
provide evidence on the impacts of specific Cost and Persistence of Asset Inequality in an
assets. Agrarian Economy.” Journal of Development
Economics 63(2000):265–302.
China National Bureau of Statistics. China Year-
References book 2003: Rural Household Survey. Beijing:
Rural Survey Organization, National Bureau
Amanor, K.S., and M.K. Diderutuah. Share Con- of Statistics, 2003.
tracts in the Oil Palm and Citrus Belt of Csaki, C., G. Feder, and Z. Lerman. “Land Poli-
Ghana. London: International Institute for En- cies and Evolving Farm Structures in Transi-
vironment and Development, and Groupe de tion Countries.” World Bank. Policy Research
Recherche et d’Echange Tecnologiques, 2001. Working Paper 2794, Washington DC, 2002.
Banerjee, A., P.J. Gertler, and M. Ghatak. “Em- Dasgupta, S., T.O. Knight, and H.A. Love. “Evolu-
powerment and Efficiency: Tenancy Reform in tion of Agricultural Land Leasing Models: A
West Bengal.” Journal of Political Economy Survey of the Literature.” Review of Agricul-
110(2002):239–80. tural Economics 21(1999):148–76.
Barham, B.L., M.R. Carter, and K. Deininger. Deininger, K., and H.P. Binswanger. “Rent Seeking
“Making Land Market Liberalization Work for and the Development of Large-Scale Agricul-
the Welfare of the Rural Poor in Honduras.” ture in Kenya, South Africa, and Zimbabwe.”
Working paper, Madison, WI, University of Economic Development and Cultural Change
Wisconsin, 2003. 43(1995):493–522.
Basu, K., and P.M. Emerson. “The Economics Deininger, K., M.A. Gonzalez, and R. Castagnini.
of Tenancy Rent Control.” Economic Journal “Comparing Land Reform and Land Mar-
110(2000):939–62. kets in Colombia: Impacts on Equity and Effi-
Bidinger, P.D., T.S. Walker, B. Sarkar, A.R. Murty, ciency.” World Bank Policy Research Working
and R. Babu. “Consequences of Mid-1980s Paper, Washington DC, 2003.
Drought: Longitudinal Evidence from Mah- Deininger, K., and S. Jin. “Land Rental Markets
bubnagar.” Economic and Political Weekly as an Alternative to Government Realloca-
26(1991):105–14. tion? Equity and Efficiency Considerations
Bierlen, R. “Land Leasing and Debt on Farms: Sub- in the Chinese Land Tenure System.” World
stitutes or Complements?” Quarterly Journal Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2930,
of Business and Economics 39(2000):18–38. Washington DC, 2002.
Binswanger, H.P., K. Deininger, and G. Feder. ——. “The Impact of Property Rights on House-
1222 Number 5, 2003 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

holds’ Investment, Risk Coping, and Policy Mookherjee, D., and D. Ray. “Contractual Struc-
Preferences: Evidence from China.” Economic ture and Wealth Accumulation.” Boston Uni-
Development and Cultural Change 51(July versity, Institute for Economic Development
2003):851–82. Discussion Paper: 107, 2000.
——. “Land Sales and Rental Markets in Transi- Nagarajan, G., A.R. Quisumbing, and K. Otsuka.
tion: Evidence from Rural Vietnam.” World “Land Pawning in the Philippines: An Ex-
Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3013, ploration into the Consequences of Land
Washington DC, 2003. Reform Regulations.” Developing Economies
Deininger, K., S. Jin, B. Adenew, S. Gebre-Selassie, 29(1991):125–44.
and M. Demeke. “Market and Non-Market Otsuka, K., H. Chuma, and Y. Hayami. “Permanent
Transfers of Land in Ethiopia: Implications Labour and Land Tenancy Contracts in Agrar-
for Efficiency, Equity, and Non-Farm Develop- ian Economies: An Integrated Analysis.” Eco-
ment.” World Bank Policy Research Working nomica 60(1993):57–77.
Paper 2992, Washington DC, 2003. Rawal, V. “Agrarian Reform and Land Markets: A

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Cornell University Library on June 26, 2015


Deininger, K., and P. Mpuga. “Land Markets Study of Land Transactions in Two Villages of
in Uganda: Incidence, Impact, and Evolu- West Bengal, 1977–1995.” Economic Develop-
tion over Time.” World Bank Policy Research ment and Cultural Change 49(2001):611–29.
Working Paper, Washington DC, 2003. Rozelle, S., and J.F.M. Swinnen. “Transition and
Deininger, K., and S. Savastano. “Land Access Agriculture.” Journal of Economic Literature,
and Land Markets in the Kyrgiz Republic”. in press.
World Bank. Policy Research Working Paper, Sadoulet, E., R. Murgai, and A. de Janvry. “Ac-
Washington DC, 2003. cess to Land via Land Rental Markets.” A. de
Deininger, K., E. Zegarra, and I. Lavadenz. “De- Janvry et al., eds., pp. 196–229. Access to Land
terminants and Impacts of Rural Land Mar- Rural Poverty and Public Action. New York:
ket Activity: Evidence from Nicaragua.” World Oxford University Press, 2001.
Development 31(2003):1385–404. Saxena, N.C. Tenancy Reforms vs Open Market
Hayami, Y., and K. Otsuka. The Economics of Con- Leasing—What Would Serve the Poor Better?
tract Choice: An Agrarian Perspective. Oxford; New Delhi: Planning Commission, Govern-
New York, Toronto and Melbourne: Oxford ment of India, 2002.
University Press, Clarendon Press, 1993. Shaban, R.A. “Testing between Competing Models
Kevane, M. “Agrarian Structure and Agricultural of Sharecropping.” Journal of Political Econ-
Practice: Typology and Application to Western omy 95(1987):893–920.
Sudan.” American Journal of Agricultural Eco- Swinnen, J.F.M. “Political Reforms, Rural Crises,
nomics 78(1996):236–45. and Land Tenure: A Historic Analysis of Land
Kranton, R.E., and A.V. Swamy. “The Hazards of Leasing and Tenure Reforms in Western Eu-
Piecemeal Reform: British Civil Courts and rope.” PRG Working Paper Leuven, 2002.
the Credit Market in Colonial India.” Jour- World Bank. “Mexico—Land Policy A Decade af-
nal of Development Economics 58(1999):1– ter the Ejido Reforms.” LAC Rural Devel-
24. opment and Natural Resources Sector Unit,
Mathijs, E., and J.F.M. Swinnen. “Production Or- Washington DC, 2002.
ganization and Efficiency during Transition: ——. Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduc-
An Empirical Analysis of East German Agri- tion. Washington DC: World Bank and Oxford
culture.” Review of Economics and Statistics University Press, 2003.
83(2001):100–7.

You might also like