You are on page 1of 17

Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

The erosion of state capacity and the European


innovation policy dilemma
A comparison of German and EU information technology policies
Edgar Grande∗
Technische Universität München, Lehrstuhl für Politische Wissenschaft, Lothstr. 17, D-80335 München, Germany

Abstract
The article analyzes the impact of the globalization of markets, technologies and companies and of the Europeanization of
public policies on state capacities in technology policy. Based on empirical examples from the field of information technology,
the article argues that technology policy has been characterized by two contradictory developments in the last two decades.
On the one hand, the concepts and strategies guiding public policies have become more and more complex, resulting in
comprehensive programs for national and European “innovation policies”. On the other hand, as a result of the economic
globalization; as well as of changes in the internal structure of the state, the state capacities to implement these ambitious
strategies successfully have been eroding. As a consequence, technology policy both on the national and on the supranational
level has been confronted with an intensifying strategic dilemma. Finally, the article discusses policy options to cope with
this strategic dilemma in innovation policy. © 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Europeanization; Globalization; Technology policy

1. Economic globalization and national The challenges which confront the nation state in
technology policy technology policy at the turn of the century are highly
ambiguous. On the one hand, since the late 1980s
For decades, the public support of scientific and a rapidly expanding number of authors has argued
technological innovations has been regarded as being that, in the process of globalization, both the impor-
one of the major functions of the modern welfare tance of technology for the public welfare of modern
state. The pursuit of “national interests” and the in- democracies and of the nation state as a promoter
ternational competition between states and between of technological advances and of industrial competi-
companies have guided the establishment and the ex- tiveness have been increasing (see, e.g. Brandin and
pansion of national research capacity, and have shaped Harrison, 1987; Porter, 1990; Stopford and Strange,
the development of modern technologies — for both 1991; Tyson, 1992; Thurow, 1992; Luttwak, 1993).
civilian and for military purposes. The globalization According to the new “logic of technology wars”,
of companies, markets and technologies, however, states are no longer competing for power over more
has significantly affected this role of the nation state territory, rather they are competing for the means to
and its capacity to act in technology policy. create wealth within their territory (cf. Stopford and
Strange, 1991, p. 1). And “technology, because it
∗ Tel.: +49-89-289-24310; fax: +49-89-289-24275. affects standards of living and wealth and because
E-mail address: grande@pol.wiso.tu-muenchen.de (E. Grande). it is the source of the superweapons of the future,

0048-7333/01/$ – see front matter © 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 0 4 8 - 7 3 3 3 ( 0 0 ) 0 0 1 6 4 - 5
906 E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

is the new area of competition. But it is not the 2. State capacity in technology policy
traditional competition of capitalism. This conflict — a neo-institutionalist approach
is more sophisticated than the competition found in
most of the existing political and economic systems. Any attempt to identify the capability of public
Only the most clever and enduring competitors will actors to reach their strategic goals in a distinct pol-
be rewarded in the arena. Those that prevail in this icy field, such as technology policy, is confronted
war will control the resources of the world; they will with the problem of finding an appropriate concept
control their Lebensraum; they will be the next global of “state capacity” which could be employed in em-
powers” (Brandin and Harrison, 1987, p. V). pirical research. This is not to say that a grand theory
On the other hand, there are frequent claims that, of “The State” is needed in the first place. As his-
due to the globalization of companies, markets and torical and comparative institutionalist research has
technologies, the very capacity of the nation state shown, “possibilities for state interventions of given
to promote and to control the creation, distribution types cannot be derived from some overall level of
and utilization of advanced technologies has been generalized capacity or ‘state strength”’ (Evans et al.,
declining (Ohmae, 1990; Camilleri and Falk, 1992; 1985b, p. 353). But state capacity is not simply the
OECD, 1992; OECD, 1999; Muldur and Petrella, sum of the state’s legal competencies and of its finan-
1994; Gerybadze et al., 1997). Most important in this cial, human and military resources either (on the var-
respect is the growing asymmetry between the limited, ious concepts of “state capacity”, see Weiss, 1998,
territorially-based scope of the state’s jurisdiction pp. 14–40). According to neo-institutionalist policy
and the global, borderless range of action of compa- analysis, policy outcomes can be interpreted as the
nies. According to the “logic of global capitalism”, composite effect of a large variety of institutional
the notion of a “national interest” has lost its signif- variables, i.e. institutions are the main explanatory
icance: “The global economy follows its own logic variable. In contrast to older concepts of institution-
and develops its own web of interest, which rarely alism, neo-institutionalist policy-analysis is guided
duplicate the historical borders between nations. As by a much broader understanding of institutions. The
a result, national interest as an economic, as opposed neo-institutionalist concept includes “both formal or-
to a political, reality has lost much of its meaning” ganizations and informal rules and procedures that
(Ohmae, 1990, p. 183) — and, one could add, states structure conduct” (Thelen and Steinmo, 1992, p. 2);
have lost most of their functions in technology policy. and, in addition, this concept goes beyond the realm of
Against this background, it is the purpose of the public actors and organizations, including private ac-
following article to give an empirical account of the tors and organizations as well. Based on this broader
development of state capacity in German and Euro- concept of institutions, neo-institutionalist policy
pean information technology. Based on a concept of research has identified a number of “institutional”
state capacity derived from neo-institutionalist pol- variables which can be instrumental in explaining
icy analysis (Section 2), the article first looks at the policy outcomes and which, in sum, can contribute to
development of national state capacity in the German a state’s capacity in a particular policy field (Zysman,
IT sector (Section 3). The results indicate that there 1983; Evans et al., 1985a; Hall, 1986; Scharpf, 1987;
has been a significant decline in national state ca- Steinmo et al., 1992; Weaver and Rockman, 1993;
pacity to influence this sector. The crucial question Mayntz and Scharpf, 1995; Hall and Taylor, 1996;
addressed in the second part of this article (Sections Weiss, 1998). Among these variables are the rules of
4 and 5) then, is whether the transfer of policies from electoral competition; the structure of party systems;
the national to the European level has compensated the organization of government and the relations
for this loss of national state capacity. Has it been among its various branches and levels; the gover-
possible to “bring the state back in” within a more nance of markets; and, the structure and organization
complex institutional architecture, thus strengthening of economic actors such as companies, business orga-
Europe in the global technology race? Or has the nizations and trade unions. Most important for the
Europeanization of technology policy reinforced the purpose of this article are the following three sets
erosion of state capacity in Europe? of variables:
E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921 907

1. Firstly, the state’s internal structure and its in his book “Governing the Economy” (Hall, 1986).
resources, e.g. the horizontal and vertical division In the perspective of empirical policy research, the
of power, and the norms, rules and habits guiding approach employed in this article combines the usual
the behavior of politicians and public officials. “top-down” approach with a “bottom-up” analysis, as
2. Secondly, the internal organization of the rele- suggested by Sabatier (1986).
vant societal sub-sectors, e.g. the governance of
markets, the organization of an industry and the
internal resources of companies. 3. The German state and the IT industry
3. Thirdly, state–society relations, i.e. the (formal
and informal) relations between the state and the
For a better understanding of some of the recent
actors and organizations in the relevant societal
problems in European technology policy, historical
sub-sectors, e.g. the inter-organizational relations
comparisons with German technology policy in the
between government departments and companies.
1970s and 1980s can be highly instructive. Both the
German state and the German research system show
In this analytical perspective, state capacity is the
some features which also characterize the institutional
product of a complex configuration of public and
architecture of European technology policy (Reger
private actor constellations with their respective inter-
and Kuhlmann, 1995). In regard to German technol-
ests, strategies and resources. First of all, the success
ogy policy, it is important to emphasize four basic
of public policies depends on the state’s capabil-
characteristics:
ity to strategically provide and allocate resources.
Without adequate institutional capacity, appropriate 1. Firstly, the German state is highly fragmented. The
policy instruments, or a certain degree of strategic organization of the national government gives its
coherence, governments would certainly not be able various branches a high degree of autonomy and,
to influence the activities of companies or research in addition, the national government has to share
laboratories. However, even the most generous and considerable powers with the federal states (Län-
well-administered public program would miss its tar- der). In technology policy, the national government
get if the companies ignore it or if they only use commands the largest budget. This is indicated, for
public money to replace internal funds which are al- example, by the distribution of public expenditures
ready available. Hence, the success of industry-related for R&D outside the universities. In 1997, 16.3 bil-
public R&D policies also depends on the structural lion DM were spent by the national government,
opportunities and restrictions the companies offer, compared to 4.8 billion DM spent by the 16 federal
i.e. their competitive environment, their strategies, states (Länder) (BMBF, 1998b, p. 374). However,
their internal organization, etc. Moreover, successful outside their own budgets, the federal states have
policies are often based on close and stable relations a number of possibilities to participate in national
between public actors and companies. Without such policy-making.
links and without the trust developed within these 2. Secondly, the German R&D system is regarded as
networks, the government lacks sufficient knowledge highly differentiated. In a comparative perspec-
about possible and necessary interventions which can tive, the most striking feature is the institutional
easily result in the exploitation of its activities through differentiation of strong public research organi-
opportunistic behavior by the companies. zations outside the university system responsible
In the perspective of a neo-institutionalist state for basic and applied research (among them the
theory, the approach outlined here is broader than Max–Planck-Society and the Fraunhofer Society)
the neo-Weberian approach as emphasized, for ex- which enjoy considerable autonomy from govern-
ample, by Theda Skocpol and others (Evans et al., ment (see Hohn and Schimank, 1990).
1985a). Rather, it builds upon Peter Katzenstein’s 3. Thirdly, despite the existence of a considerable
concept of a “policy network” as presented in number of public research organizations, industry
“Between Power and Plenty” (Katzenstein, 1978), and accounts for the major share of R&D in Germany,
the institutionalist approach advanced by Peter Hall although its share of R&D expenditures has been
908 E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

declining significantly during the 1990s — from competitiveness of every major industrial country.
64% in 1990 to 60.8% in 1996 (BMBF, 1998b, Hence, this sector has been one of the major targets
p. 6). In 1997, 61.6% of research and develop- of technology policy and one of the most desirable
ment expenditures came from industry. Applied assets in the “technology race” between advanced
research and experimental development are almost industrial countries (Arnold and Guy, 1986).
exclusively the province of industry. Germany has been no exception. An empirical anal-
4. Fourthly, the societal sub-systems involved in tech- ysis of the role of the state in the German IT sector
nology policy, namely science and the economy, (see in particular Grande and Häusler, 1994) shows
enjoy a high degree of functional autonomy from that industrial R&D activities and public R&D poli-
the state. According to the self-image of the major cies have been closely linked for a long time. Despite
actors in politics, science and industry, this auton- the public commitments to a free market economy,
omy is one of the preconditions for the efficiency every government — regardless of its ideological
of the German R&D system. This is not to say that profile — has tried to promote industrial research in
there are no networks between government and the information technology. Since the late 1960s, the state
research community or business. Empirical analy- has launched numerous programs intended to influ-
sis has shown that there is a multitude of formal ence and to stimulate companies’ R&D activities or,
and informal contacts (see Meyer-Krahmer, 1989; sometimes, to overcome their reluctance to innovate.
Grande and Häusler, 1994). However, it implies All of these programs were “obsessed” by the goal to
that the government’s scope for direct, hierarchical improve the “competitiveness” of the “national” in-
intervention is limited. dustry vis-à-vis their foreign competitors, IBM in par-
ticular. For this reason, the programs were addressed
As a consequence of this constellation, German to the small “club” of “national” companies and were
technology policy has been, for most of the time, formulated in close cooperation with the companies.
characterized by a feature which has become typi- As of 1967, when the first national program for
cal for European technology policy too. Rather than the computer industry started, until 1989, the Federal
establishing and controlling public research laborato- Research Ministry spent about 10 billion DM to pro-
ries, the state had to guide and control private R&D mote information technology (i.e. data processing,
activities without destroying the autonomy of science micro-electronics, telecommunications and industrial
and industry. This means that from the very beginning automation). More than half of this money (approx-
of a deliberate national technology policy in the early imately 5.5–6 billion DM) was given directly to the
1960s, public authorities had to employ the techniques German IT industry. Quite obviously, the German
of an “indirect management”, as analyzed by Lax and state was very active in promoting the IT industry
Sebenius (1986) in the case of industrial companies: with the aim of improving its competitiveness on the
they had to provide positive incentives for compa- domestic market and abroad. But did the state actually
nies, coordinate programs and policies, negotiate with have the capacity for successful interventions?
research organizations and with companies, etc. Of If one takes the industry’s market performance
course, the crucial questions then became: did the as an indicator for the policy’s success, the German
German state actually have the capacity to purpose- R&D programs promoting the IT industry can hardly
fully intervene into the R&D activities of industry by be regarded as being particularly successful. The
these means? Was it possible to promote the techno- number of “national” companies has been very small
logical and economic competitiveness of companies? in the past decades anyway. In micro-electronics,
The following empirical analysis is based on a sec- the domestic supply mainly came from Siemens and
tor study of the German IT industry, mainly covering AEG; in data processing, in addition to Siemens
data processing, micro-electronics and telecommu- and AEG, some smaller companies such as Nixdorf,
nications. The IT sector is highly instructive for an Kienzle and Triumph–Adler entered the market in
analysis of state capacity in technology policy since the 1970s. Because of the de facto closure of the
this sector has been regarded as being of strategic national telecommunications market, the market posi-
importance for both military power and the industrial tion of domestic telecommunications companies was
E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921 909

stronger, with Siemens being the major supplier of well as the state. As far as the state’s role was con-
the national PTT (the Deutsche Bundespost). cerned, the strategy chosen would have required at
At the end of the 1990s, Siemens is the only ma- least an effective coordination of R&D programs and
jor “German” IT company which has survived, and of public procurement, as emphasized in the literature
even Siemens has decided to sell its micro-electronics on successful technology policies (cf. Nelson, 1982;
business. Its former long-time competitor AEG was Lundvall, 1985). Such a comprehensive approach of
taken over by Daimler Benz in the early 1980s, and combining “technology push” programs and “demand
most of its IT activities were either sold or closed. pull” policies was already advocated by the German
Most of the smaller German IT companies have computer industry in the mid-1960s and the Federal
been taken over by foreign companies, for example, Research Ministry repeatedly tried to employ this ap-
Mannesmann–Kienzle by DEC and Triumph–Adler proach in its data processing programs. However, for
by Olivetti. Promising new start-ups have been ex- institutional reasons, particularly the decentralized
tremely scarce and even the most promising ones, structure of the “semi-sovereign” German state and its
like Nixdorf, have been unable to survive. bureaucracy (cf. Katzenstein, 1987), such a coordina-
Even without a comprehensive evaluation of the tion came to nothing. As a consequence, the share of
IT programs, it is obvious that German IT policy has domestic IT companies (mainly Siemens) receiving
failed to meet most of its goals most of the time. government contracts for data processing equipment
Success stories, like those of the Japanese govern- in Germany was well below the respective shares
mental programs in the 1960s and 1970s in the fields in other countries with a national computer industry
of data processing, micro-electronics and telecom- (France, Japan, the US). In the end, the technology
munications (Anchordogay, 1989; Fransman, 1990), policy strategy that emerged within this sector in the
are missing completely. This poor record could well 1970s was a plain technology push strategy with very
be taken as evidence that it is useless in principle limited success.
for the state to intervene in the economy and in the The second example comes from the field of
proper working of markets. Upon closer inspection, telecommunications. At first sight, the telecommuni-
however, it becomes obvious that the organization cations sector seemed to offer much more favorable
of the German IT industry offered opportunities for conditions for national technology policy in Germany.
purposeful and selective intervention. In principle In this sector, there was a centralized public agency,
at least, public programs could have (and have!), to the Deutsche Bundespost, which enjoyed a full-range
some extent, influenced the course and the scale of monopoly on networks, services and equipment, and
the companies’ research (for telecommunications, see close, well-established links to a small “club” of
Schnöring and Neu, 1991). However, the use of these domestic equipment suppliers. The problem in this
opportunities has been restricted by various institu- case was, that the Deutsche Bundespost, for various
tional factors both within the companies and within organizational reasons, turned out to be a rather con-
the state structure. In fact, empirical studies have servative force and in the late 1970s, was blamed
shown that very particular constellations of factors for being responsible for the declining international
were responsible for the programs’ limited success. competitiveness of the German telecommunications
Two examples may suffice to illustrate this point (for equipment industry. The close links between the
more details see Grande and Häusler, 1994). Deutsche Bundespost and the equipment industry
The first example comes from the field of data pro- were regarded as a handicap rather than an advantage.
cessing. In data processing, the German government And because of the strong institutional autonomy of
chose a highly ambitious strategy in the 1970s: to the Deutsche Bundespost from direct government in-
make a frontal attack on the market leader IBM in tervention, the Federal Research Ministry’s attempts
the market in which IBM was strongest, which at that to make the PTT more receptive to technological in-
time was the mainframe business (cf. Flamm, 1988). novations came to nothing. In this constellation, the
Such a strategy would have been very demanding Federal Research Ministry tried to loosen relations
and risky anywhere; and in the German case it soon between the PTT and the industry by offering a R&D
turned out to be too much for both the companies as program in telecommunications and by advocating the
910 E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

liberalization of the telecommunications equipment would have required an intensive “positive” coor-
market. As in data processing, the program’s success dination of governmental policies; however, in the
has been limited, partly because the major industrial German system of government — with its high au-
players, like Siemens, were reluctant to participate, tonomy for each Federal Ministry — such an effort
and partly because the PTT failed to efficiently ab- was unrealistic (Mayntz and Scharpf, 1975).
sorb the companies’ growing technology potential in In sum, we can see that German technology policy
its procurement policy. The main beneficiaries of the for the IT sector was confronted with a protracted
program were Siemens’ smaller competitors, mainly strategic dilemma: those technology policy strate-
SEL (then an ITT-subsidiary) and AEG, which were gies which were feasible within the existing insti-
later taken over by foreign competitors like Alcatel tutional structures of the German state turned out to
and Philips (and, most of AEG’s telecommunications be under-complex and, thus, inadequate to reach the
business, by Bosch). programs’ goals; however, more adequate, compre-
In both examples, it was not a lack of money or hensive policy strategies tended to be over-complex,
a lack of knowledge on behalf of the state, or the thus overstraining the institutional capability of the
companies’ unwillingness to participate in national German state. This innovation policy dilemma has
programs, which were responsible for the policy’s intensified during the 1990s as a consequence of the
disappointing results. Rather, it was a highly con- globalization of markets, companies and technolo-
tingent constellation of institutional factors in each gies on the one hand, and as a consequence of the
sector which explains most of the programs’ poor Europeanization of technology policy on the other.
performance.
In the 1980s, German technology policy for the IT
sector responded to the obvious shortcomings of its
4. The erosion of state capacity in German IT
programs not by reformulating its goals, but by refin-
policy (I): the globalization of markets, firms
ing its underlying strategy. In the face of intensifying
and technologies
international competition, the Federal Government
adopted a comprehensive innovation policy strat-
At about the same time as the German state started
egy, articulated in two national framework programs
its most ambitious attempt to support the “national” IT
for information technology, the “Regierungsbericht
industry in its intensifying competition with foreign
Informationstechnik”, effective as of 1984, and the
rivals, state capacity in technology policy had signifi-
“Zukunftskonzept Informationstechnik”, enacted in
cantly begun to decline. Meanwhile, plenty of empiri-
1989. Both programs included a broad range of ac-
cal evidence illustrates that public interventions in the
tivities and instruments distributed over a number of
companies’ R&D activities have become much more
policy fields. In addition to public R&D subsidies,
difficult, if they are still possible at all (cf. Grande and
policy fields such as competition policy, public pro-
Häusler, 1994; Gerybadze et al., 1997; Hack, 1998;
curement, standardization, data protection, education
Meyer-Krahmer, 1999; OECD, 1999). The first and
policy, the modernization of the public telecommu-
most important factor responsible for the erosion of
nications infrastructure, and the liberalization of the
the state capacity to intervene is the globalization of
national and European telecommunications markets,
technologies, markets and companies. In the case of IT
to mention only a few of the most important, would
industry — one of the industrial sectors affected most
be designed in such a way that they would contribute
— globalization has triggered various changes both in
to the international competitiveness of the German IT
the companies’ internal structures and in their external
industry. These approaches corresponded very well
relations. In the context of national technology policy,
with theoretical approaches which advocate more
three processes have been of particular importance:
comprehensive strategies in innovation policy (cf. in
particular Porter, 1990). In the German context, how- 1. Firstly, the decentralization of R&D activities:
ever, these integrated innovation policy approaches One of the major changes in business R&D has
were over-ambitious and had no chance to be real- been a reorganization of research: “Large firms are
ized. A proper implementation of these approaches pulling back from long-term projects, and instead
E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921 911

integrating R&D into product development” 30% in 1998. In 1998, Siemens occupied about
(OECD, 1999, p. 7). In the IT sector, this devel- 14,000 R&D employees abroad, dispersed over 28
opment has been particularly vivid. Already in countries and 56 locations (Weyrich, 1998).
the 1980s, IT companies had started to reorganize 3. Thirdly, the integration of R&D activities into
their R&D activities with the goals of exploit- global networks of inter-firm cooperations: Al-
ing their R&D more effectively, speeding up the though cooperation between firms has a long
development of new products, and making R&D tradition in the IT sector, the 1980s witnessed a
departments more responsive to customer needs. tremendous increase in the number of joint ven-
In practice, this means that they have cut back their tures, strategic alliances and R&D co-operations:
central R&D laboratories and integrated R&D ac- “From 1980 to 1994, the total number of science
tivities into the various product divisions. A clear and technology alliances grew at 10.8% per year,
indication of this development is the decline of and about 65% of those alliances involved two
basic research in the large German IT companies partners from different countries” (OECD, 1999,
(Siemens, Daimler, Bosch). In 1979, 8.2% of their p. 13). In the case of German IT companies, al-
overall R&D expenditures was for basic research; ready in the early 1990s, approximately 90% of the
whereas in 1987, only 4.8% was for basic research technological collaboration efforts involved a for-
(Grande and Häusler, 1994, p. 374). Meanwhile, eign partner. Siemens, for example, in 1991/1992
in some fields such as telecommunications, basic was involved in about 1400 cooperative projects;
research performed in central research facilities and there were only two German companies among
has almost disappeared. the company’s major partners.
2. Secondly, the internationalization of R&D acti-
vities: The assumption that the companies’ As a consequence of all these developments, the
R&D activities would be an “important case of target of public R&D policies has been fundamen-
non-globalization” (Patel and Pavitt, 1991) has tally changing. In contrast to the heyday of national
by and large turned out to be wrong. Recent data technology policy, when the state dealt with a small
from the OECD indicate that the R&D activities number of clearly distinct national companies, the tar-
of multinational corporations “are no longer firmly get of public policy is now an ever-changing, intricate
anchored to their home bases” (OECD, 1999, p. 8). network of “multi-domestic” corporations. This new
In the major OECD countries, foreign subsidiaries constellation raises several problems for any purpose-
already account for 12% of total industrial R&D ful political intervention into corporate R&D trying
spending (OECD, 1999, p. 8). It is true that there to create national competitive advantages. First of all,
are significant cross-national and cross-sectoral since it was the central R&D laboratories with their
variations. Whereas US and Japanese companies long-term, generic research which used to be most
still execute more than 90% of their R&D activities receptive to public R&D programs, the decentraliza-
in their home country, in smaller countries a con- tion of corporate R&D implies that the “window of
siderable share is already abroad. In the Swiss case, opportunity” for purposeful government intervention
for example, about 50% of the companies’ R&D is into the companies’ R&D activities has become much
abroad (Boutellier et al., 1996, p. 283). In the Ger- smaller. Moreover, since the distinction between
man case, the foreign subsidiaries of German com- “home” and “host” countries has been blurred, any
panies spent about 10 billion DM on R&D in 1995, “national technology policy to support specific forms
which was about 17% of the companies’ total na- of activities becomes increasingly meaningless be-
tional R&D expenditures; conversely, about 16% cause there are so many leakages — in both financial
of the industry’s R&D expenditure in Germany advantages and research results — to non-national
come from the subsidiaries of foreign companies companies” (OECD, 1991, p. 100).
(BMBF, 1998b, p. 7). In information technology, In principle, there are three strategic options for
the major “national” company, Siemens, is well technology policy to overcome these difficulties: first,
above this average. The share of its foreign R&D to adapt its strategic goals to the new constellation;
employees doubled from 15% in 1985/1986 to secondly, to develop new instruments which are better
912 E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

suited to the new constellation; and thirdly, to adapt the Franco-German Airbus have been the predominant
the institutional architecture of technology policy to mode of cooperation; in the space sector, cooperation
the new global context. took place in the framework of international orga-
In practice, technology policy has to some extent nizations such as the European Space Agency (ESA),
tried to make use of all these options: “As a reac- founded in 1975. Attempts at European cooperation
tion to the globalization of the research base, many within the Community framework in data processing
governments are experimenting with new science and (Eurodata, Unidata) and in micro-electronics, initi-
technology policy goals and new tools to reach these ated in the late 1960s and 1970s, failed completely
goals” (OECD, 1999, p. 9). German technology policy (cf. Sharp and Shearman, 1987, pp. 24–41).
has been no exception from this general trend. In the In the 1980s, however, economic and technolo-
course of the 1980s, the promotion of basic research, gical changes radically transformed the perceptions
mainly in public research organization, was given about technological and industrial competitiveness in
priority over the public support of corporate R&D. Europe and about the need for collaborative efforts
Consequently, the volume of national R&D subsidies on the European level (Peterson, 1993; Sandholtz,
to industry has been stagnating since 1981, whereas 1992; Sharp and Shearman, 1987; Peterson and Sharp,
expenditures for public research organizations have 1999). The dramatic decline of European industries
almost doubled. In the case of Siemens, the share of in strategic sectors such as micro-electronics and data
public subsidies to the company’s budget for R&D de- processing, US predominance on globalizing markets,
clined from 10% in 1980 to 2.9% in 1990 (Grande and and the rise of Japan as a technological power com-
Häusler, 1994, p. 377). In addition, new instruments bined to trigger a new “technology gap” debate, thus
to promote R&D in small and medium-sized com- creating a favorable climate for a “common European
panies, and to stimulate technology based start-ups, response”. Compared to the frustrating national efforts
have been employed — to mention only a few of the (see, e.g. Cawson et al., 1990), a common European
new programs developed in the 1980s and 1990s. The response was expected to offer several advantages.
institutional architecture of technology policy has also It would help to overcome the fragmentation of na-
been changing significantly since the early 1980s. tional resources and programs, and it would offer a
Partially, at least, as a response to the globalization common cooperation platform for the European com-
of technologies, markets and companies, new insti- panies. In brief, by transferring competencies and
tutional levels of technology policy-making above resources from the national to the supranational level,
(“Europeanization”) and below (“regionalization”) both the scope and the scale of technology policy
the nation state have been emerging. would be expanded, and the growing gap between
globalizing markets and national policies would
be bridged.
5. The erosion of state capacity in German IT Based on this rationale, the European Community
policy (II): the Europeanization of technology became a major player in technology policy in the
policy in the IT sector 1980s. With the adoption of the “First Framework
Programme” in the summer of 1983, a fundamental
Most important in this respect is the Europeani- strategic reorientation of the Community’s science
zation of technology policy, which gained new and technology policy was introduced. A new em-
momentum in the 1980s. It is true that European coop- phasis was given to activities designed to improve the
eration in technology policy was one of the earliest ex- competitiveness of European industry, and a new gen-
amples of supranational integration with the European eration of sectoral programs was initiated, targeted
Atomic Energy Community (EURATOM) founded al- at a number of high-tech industries whose competi-
ready in 1957. However, after the crisis of EURATOM tiveness was expected to be crucial for the industrial
in the mid-1960s, it rather seemed as if the European development of Europe. In the following years, the
countries would cooperate only outside the Commu- EC established a very comprehensive framework of
nity framework, if at all. In the aviation sector, bilateral programs aimed at improving the competitiveness of
agreements such as the Anglo-French Concorde and European industry.
E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921 913

In addition to research funding, the European irrelevant for the large, globally-operating companies.
Community (respectively, Union) has acquired com- A closer look reveals that these subsidies can still be
petencies in a multitude of areas, which are of impor- highly significant. For example, in the early 1990s,
tance for the regulation of technological developments 20–30% of the European IT companies’ long-term
and the improvement of industrial competitiveness. generic research was conducted within the various
When it comes to such issues as the establishment EC programs.
of guidelines for environmental protection, the reg- Despite all these programs and activities, the
ulation of genetic engineering, the liberalization of Community’s technology policy has not been partic-
the telecommunications markets or data protection, ularly successful either — if success is measured by
agreement on technical norms and standards, or the the policy’s contribution to the competitiveness of
approval of corporate mergers, the EU has become a the European IT industry (Peterson and Sharp, 1999,
crucial actor, in some areas even the most important pp. 205–207). It is true that the programs have con-
actor. And by strictly monitoring R&D funding in tributed to intensifying cooperation between European
the member states on the basis of its competencies researchers and research institutes in Europe. How-
in competition policy, the Community has, for quite ever, the European companies have failed to gain
some time now, restricted their capacity to act in the significant shares of the IT world market. At the
area of technology policy. end of the 1990s, the industry’s international market
The sector that has gained most attention in the position was still feeble. In 1995, after 10 years of
Community’s new strategy has been information massive Community support for the European IT in-
technology. ESPRIT, the Community’s new program dustry, the Commission had to concede that “over the
for the promotion of R&D in the information tech- last fifteen years its (i.e. the EUs; EG) technologi-
nology industry, prepared in the early 1980s, became cal and commercial performance in high-technology
the “flagship” of the Community’s technology policy sectors such as electronics and information technolo-
(Sandholtz, 1992; Grande and Häusler, 1994; Peterson gies has deteriorated” (European Commission, 1995,
and Sharp, 1999). Other programs based on the “ES- p. 5).
PRIT model” in telecommunications (RACE), and There are many reasons for the disappointing per-
on the use of telematics in various sectors of society formance of the Community’s IT programs. First of
(transport, medicine etc.) were swift to follow. In its all, it soon became obvious that European programs
first four “Framework Programmes”, the Community were unable to overrule the global logic of markets,
spent about 9 billion ECU on its various IT programs. companies and technologies. Initial hopes that the
In the late 1980s and the early 1990s, about 40% companies would prefer to cooperate within Europe
of the Community’s research budget was devoted and compete outside Europe turned out to be illusion-
to information technology. In the fifth “Framework ary. In the 1990s, the companies adopted complex
Programme”, which started in 1999, 24% will be strategies with a mix of national, European and global
spent in the field of information technology, i.e. 3.6 partnerships and rivalries. In micro-electronics, for
billion ECU (BMBF, 1998a, p. 25). example, ideas to establish a “European” chip factory
In the 1980s, the main target of the respective with the help of Community funding were not only at
programs were the big IT companies in the EC mem- odds with the Community’s competition policy, but
ber states (GEC, Philips, Siemens, Thompson, etc.). also with the companies’ global strategies. Siemens,
In the heyday of the ESPRIT program, the European one of the prime targets of plans like these, not only
IT companies received more than half of their pub- participated in the various national and European pro-
lic R&D subsidies from Community programs. It is grams available, but also cooperated with US (IBM,
true, however, that these subsidies were only a small Motorola) and Japanese (Toshiba) competitors in the
share of the companies’ overall R&D budget anyway. development and production of advanced semicon-
In the case of Siemens, for example, only 2% of the ductors.
company’s research is currently financed by public In addition, Community R&D programs in IT
funding. This should not be taken as an indicator, initially suffered from a considerable strategic de-
however, that public R&D subsidies have become ficiency. Programs such as ESPRIT, BRITE and
914 E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

EURAM were designed purely as “technology push” Commission in the 1990s on industrial, economic
programs. The aim of these programs was to pro- and innovation policy (European Commission, 1990,
duce a “technology push” which was expected to 1993, 1995). In its White Paper on industrial policy,
lead to a substantial improvement in the industrial for example, R&D policy (as an “accelerator”) was
competitiveness of the EC. Similar to the German IT integrated in a comprehensive framework including
programs of the 1970s and 1980s, the effectiveness competition policy, education policy, cohesion policy,
of such “technology push” programs was very lim- environmental policy, trade policy and policies for
ited. For example, the most in-depth evaluation of small and medium-sized companies (European Com-
the ESPRIT program concluded that “In particular mission, 1990). In its Green Paper on Innovation,
the industry led, technology push, approach of ES- the Commission stated: “Strengthening the capacity
PRIT, whilst demonstrably capable of producing good for innovation involves various policies: industrial
results, is not achieving the lift in European com- policy, RTD policy, education and training, tax pol-
petitiveness which is now called for” (Dekker, 1992, icy, competition policy, regional policy and policy
p. 33). on support for SMEs, environment policy, etc. Ways
By the end of the 1980s, the European Commission must, therefore, be found of identifying, preparing
began to realize the shortcomings of its technology and implementing — in a coordinated fashion — the
policy and started developing a more comprehen- necessary measures covered by these various policies”
sive innovation policy approach, similar to German (European Commission, 1995, p. 3).
technology policy a decade ago. Inspired by Michael The experiences of German IT policy in the 1980s
Porter’s seminal work on the “Competitiveness of would suggest that the major problem is not the iden-
Nations” (Porter, 1990), which was to become the tification of policies, rather, it is their coordinated
new holy book for the Commission’s technology preparation and implementation. And the crucial
policy, the Community modified its strategy in this question, in fact, is whether European policies are
policy field. The new strategy was based on the as- able to overcome the deficiencies of national poli-
sumption that the existing problems of competitive- cies in this respect. Empirical analyses of European
ness in European industry are caused not so much technology policy confirm this assumption (Grande,
by technology “gaps” or lack of funds for research, 1994, 1995). The EUs political and administrative
but rather by severe deficiencies in the diffusion and structures are to a limited extent only, able to meet the
application of generally well-known technologies demands placed on an integrated innovation policy at
and their integration into complex technical systems. the Community level. It is common knowledge that
The European Commission repeatedly emphasized the decision making process is protracted, that its re-
“that the main problem of European firms is not sults often consist of unsatisfactory compromises and
primarily the amount of their R&D expenditures, that the administrative implementation of decisions is
but rather their inadequate ability to turn their re- cumbersome.
search and technology developments into inventions However, it would be wrong to only blame the
and to turn their inventions into market shares and European Commission for these institutional deficien-
profits”. The result, as the Commission concluded, cies. The core of the institutional problems of Euro-
is “a distinct gap between Europe’s efforts in basic pean technology policy is the fact that policy must be
research and R&D investments on the one hand and developed and implemented in a multi-level frame-
the results in the area of innovation and competi- work of governance with complicated interactions
tiveness on the other” (European Commission, 1992, among national and European actors and institutions
p. 10). (Grande, 1999). In this institutional context, the repre-
This problem, called the “European paradox” sentatives of the national research administrations play
(European Commission, 1995, p. 5; see also An- a key role in the European decision-making process.
dreasen et al., 1995), was addressed in several expert Due to the unstable balance of power between the
reports to the Commission (e.g. the Ciampi report; Council, the Commission and the Parliament on the
Consultative Group on Competitiveness, 1995), and one hand, and between the EU and its member states
in various White and Green Papers presented by the on the other, these processes are usually extremely
E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921 915

complicated and correspondingly lengthy, in so far as has clearly been inadequate (Aigrain et al., 1989).
they are formalized at all. By the end of the 1990s, John Peterson and Margaret
In such an institutional framework, a high degree Sharp arrive at the disillusioning conclusion that “It
of consensus on the goals and priorities of European is difficult to see where RTD policy has been coor-
technology policy among the participants of negoti- dinated effectively with other EU policies — such
ation processes would be necessary in order to make as energy, transport, agriculture, the environment,
quick and appropriate decisions. In the previous or industry — despite the vastly increased impor-
two decades, this has not been the case. The nego- tance of science and technology in all these sectors”
tiations concerning the Community’s “Framework (Peterson and Sharp, 1999, p. 221). Inter-Commission
Programmes” and its numerous “specific” programs rivalries have been frequent, and rather than weak-
have shown that there are not only multi-faceted cul- ening, they even “appeared to be intensifying”
tural differences among the EU member states, but also (Peterson and Sharp, 1999, p. 218); and the Task
a number of fundamental conflicts of interest, be they Forces established in the mid-1990s, with the goal of
motivated by economic, regional or socio-political improving policy coordination within the Commis-
reasons (cf. Grande, 1995). As a result, programs “turn sion, have been failing. The overall result has been
out to be shopping lists of national priorities, often a fragmented assessment of problems and an incre-
with low coherence and little European value added”, mental development of programs — sometimes even
as, for example, the Davignon Panel concluded in working at cross-purposes, rather than an integrated
its 5-year assessment of the EUs “Fourth Framework policy approach.
Programme” (Davignon, 1997, p. 14). In the actual Hence, there are good reasons why recent studies
practice of funding, a complicated mix of political of European technology policy “stress the need for
selection criteria, such as the “adequate” participa- greater co-ordination of the various policies not only
tion of small and medium-sized companies, the “just” at the sectoral but also on the transnational level in
return of funds to the member states or the “adequate” order to better face the challenges of globalization.
participation of economically less-developed member Stress laid on the co-ordination of the research, in-
states, has always had to be taken into consideration novation and education policies supports the efforts
— in addition to criteria of excellence. As a result, the of the European policy in these sectors which could
programs’ strategic coherence has been rather low. find increased effectiveness if a similar approach
In addition to these political and institutional defi- were followed in the Member States” (Lundvall and
ciencies of the European policy process, the organi- Borrás, 1998, p. 3). However, there is no basis for
zation of competencies for technology policy in the the assumption that the EU is better equipped to cope
European Commission is also ill-suited to implement with the problem of horizontal and vertical policy
an integrated policy strategy. Within the Commis- coordination than was Germany with its technology
sion, competencies are highly fragmented and the policy in the 1970s and 1980s.
coordination mechanisms available are weak. The At the end of the 1990s, it seems as if Euro-
administration of the research programs is divided pean technology policy has hit the same dead-end as
among numerous offices and in the 1990s, even in in- German technology policy in the decades before.
formation technology, two Directorates General (DG This is not to deny the theoretical plausibility and the
III and DG XIII) were responsible for the respective heuristic value of an integrated innovation policy ap-
programs. The same is true for other domains vital to proach. But empirical evidence seems to indicate that
technology policy (e.g. transportation, telecommuni- the political and institutional preconditions for the co-
cations). In the past, the organization of offices was herent formulation and proper implementation of such
often governed by short-term political expediency an approach are unrealistic. As long as this coordina-
rather than sound, task-oriented planning. In such tion problem has not been solved, the Europeanization
an organizational setting, a close policy coordination of technology policy only adds to the political and
would be particularly important. However, policy co- institutional complexity of technology policy-making
ordination within the Commission in general is said without increasing the problem-solving capacity
to be weak, and in the field of technology policy, it of the state. Hence, the European policy making
916 E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

process is confronted with the same innovation policy that the deliberate strategies based on a full-scale
dilemma as that of Germany. “steering” of public policies and industrial activities
are unsuited for a highly fragmented and decentral-
ized institutional setting as exists both in Germany
6. Conclusions: towards a new paradigm in and in the EU.
European technology policy? The crucial question then, is whether or not there
are possibilities to improve the performance of EU
During the last two decades, technology policy in technology policy. In principle, there are at least three
Europe has been characterized by two developments options which provide a way out of the innovation
running in opposite directions. On the one hand, the policy dilemma outlined above without giving up the
concepts and strategies guiding public R&D policies substance of the policy’s goals. The first option would
have become more and more complex, resulting in en- be to concentrate and to centralize the institutional
compassing programs for national and European “in- setting, the second one would be to decentralize the
novation policies”. On the other hand, as a result of the policy, and the third would be to adopt a policy strategy
globalization of technologies, markets and companies, which is better suited to the institutional framework
and of changes in the internal structure of the state, of the EU.
the state’s capability to successfully implement these The first option, a stronger concentration and
ambitious strategies have been eroding. As a conse- centralization of competencies and resources in in-
quence, public R&D policy both on the national and novation policy, is the most obvious solution to the
on the supranational level has been confronted with an coordination problems within the EU. The use of
intensifying strategic dilemma: policy strategies which “hierarchy” as an organizing principle to cope with
have been feasible within the existing institutional complexity is well known in organization theory
structures turned out to be under-complex and, hence, (Simon, 1962), and in fact, this was the strategy pur-
inadequate to improve industrial competitiveness in sued in German technology policy in the 1960s and
the IT sector; however, more adequate, comprehensive 1970s. Within the national government, competencies
innovation policy strategies tended to be over-complex were concentrated within a single ministry (Stucke,
and overstrained the state’s institutional capability, in 1993), and at the same time, the importance of the
particular its capacity for horizontal and vertical policy federal states in technology policy declined. However,
coordination. the German example has also given some indica-
This has been one of the main reasons why the per- tions of the limits of such a strategy. The limits of
formance of the “competition state” (Peterson, 1993) any concentration of resources and competencies are
in Europe has been rather disappointing in the past reached as soon as the genuine competencies of other
decades. Hitherto, national and European technology major ministries are touched, for example the legal
policy has responded to the problem of policy failure competencies of the Ministry of Finance in tax pol-
by designing even more ambitious, more comprehen- icy. In addition, both in federal states like Germany
sive and better integrated programs and by tightening and in the EU, there are strict constitutional (respec-
the networks between public authorities, compa- tively, contractual) limits to a full-scale centralization
nies and research organizations even more skillfully. of resources and competencies. Hence, in practice a
The Commission’s recent proposal for a “Euro- stronger concentration and centralization of compe-
pean research area” based on a “more co-ordinated tencies in European innovation policy is not realistic.
implementation of national and European research The second option to cope with the European
programmes” is another example of such efforts innovation policy dilemma, a decentralization of tech-
(European Commission, 2000). If the argument devel- nology policy, seems to be more promising. Such a
oped in this article holds true, these efforts would be strategy, as advocated for example by Peterson and
futile. However, this does not imply that technology Sharp (1999, pp. 232–233), is supported by the experi-
policy on a supranational level is useless or that it is ences of EU activities financed by the structural funds
impossible for the EU to pursue an ambitious strategic on the regional level and, most of all, by the success
approach in this field. Rather, the argument implies of regional innovation policies in high-technology
E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921 917

industries such as IT and biotechnology (Braczyk interests of the participants in a widespread debate
et al., 1998; Braczyk et al., 1999). These examples are generated, formulated and transformed. The fi-
seem to indicate that the institutional framework of nal, composite result of these independent efforts
innovation policies on the local and regional level is may be said to be rational” (Fach and Grande, 1992,
less complex, and, moreover, that local and regional p. 17). Emergent strategies must not be confused with
governments — because of the proximity of actors a neo-liberal market model or with a laissez-faire
— are better equipped with “soft”, trust-based instru- approach. They can well very be the object of pur-
ments of political intervention. poseful political action. However, strategy forma-
Hence, there are good reasons to argue that the tion follows a different logic and employs different
most promising measures of technology policy “are instruments.
best designed and delivered at the regional or even Most important for the purpose of this article, these
subregional level of government. What are needed different approaches can be related to different organi-
from Brussels are programmes that provide a cat- zational settings. Deliberate strategies are best suited
alyst but, as with the structural funds, essentially to ideal-type hierarchies, whereas emergent strate-
promote such action at lower levels of government” gies are better suited to organizations with distributed
(Peterson and Sharp, 1999, p. 233). There is no need power or “adhocracies”. Quite obviously, the EU, with
to deny the benefits of regional innovation policies in its multi-level system of governance and its compli-
many instances, but there are some doubts that they cated mix of interests, comes closer to the latter type
actually allow to escape from the innovation policy than to the former. Against this background, the fun-
dilemma as described for national and supranational damental failure of European technology policy was
policies. First of all, at the regional and local level, that it employed a strategic approach which did not fit
there is an extreme heterogeneity of institutions which the basic characteristics of its institutional framework.
make for considerable variation in the effectiveness And this would imply that EU policy-making, if pos-
of policy implementation. For this reason, propos- sible, should employ a “grass–root model” of strategy
als advocating a decentralization and regionalization formation as suggested by Mintzberg and McHugh
of innovation policies are inevitably faced with the (1985) and some kind of emergent strategy rather than
problem how the multitude of activities on the vari- deliberate ones.
ous levels can be integrated into a coherent strategic This is not the proper place to develop such a
framework. “grass–root model” for European technology policy
The third option tries to solve the European inno- in full detail. Rather, I will outline a few basic ele-
vation policy dilemma by adopting a policy strategy ments which seem to be characteristic of an emergent
which is better suited to the EUs fragmented and de- strategy in European technology policy. The common
centralized institutional framework. The key to such rationale of all these activities would be to stimulate,
a strategy could be a distinction introduced in orga- intensify, promote and guide the self-coordination
nization theory by Mintzberg and McHugh (1985). of independent actors and organizations in order to
They distinguish between “deliberate strategies” on make European technology policy a joint effort, in-
the one hand, i.e. plans intentionally designed and im- stead of relying on purposeful policy-coordination
plemented, and what they call “emergent strategies”, by a supranational institution. Key elements of an
i.e. an “unintended order” emerging from the uncoor- emergent strategy in technology policy could be: (i)
dinated activities of individual actors or organizations forecasting; (ii) frameworking; (iii) activating and
that nevertheless can be both rational and socially mediating; and (iv) financing.
acceptable. “Strategy” in the latter case is not de-
fined with respect to intentions, but with respect to 6.1. Forecasting
realization. Whereas deliberate strategies emphasize
the implementation of pre-given goals, emergent Forecasting exercises have become an important
strategies emphasize processes and results: emergent element of any technology policy approach (Cuhls,
strategies “are the product of a process. In the course 1998). For an approach relying on the emergent
of this process, the individual or collective aims and results of uncoordinated and uncontrolled individual
918 E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

activities by companies and public research insti- have been articulated are aggregated and reconciled.
tutes, the identification of long-term problems and In national research systems, this is the function of
opportunities, and the formulation of long-term tasks intermediary institutions. In the Dutch research sys-
for research and policy-making, systematic forecast- tem, for example, “the intermediary layer is densely
ing is essential. However, in such an approach the populated, and there are many network links between
results of forecasting exercises are not interpreted as the institutions, committees, councils, programming
being “substantive” knowledge for deliberative policy bodies, etc. Horizontal co-ordination occurs easily”
making. Rather, they are used as cognitive maps and (Van der Meulen and Rip, 1998, p. 758). In the case
guidelines for open public debates. The final result of the EU, this intermediary layer is clearly under-
should not be unanimous decisions, but common vi- developed (Grande and Peschke, 1999a,b). Although
sions guiding the independent activities of politicians, there are a host of national and transnational organiza-
civil servants, researchers and citizens. tions active in European R&D policy, horizontal links
are weak and the inter-organizational networks are
6.2. Frameworking fragmented. Hence, the establishment of intermediary
institutions and the promotion of inter-organizational
In an emergent policy strategy, it is more important networks must be an important part of an emergent
to provide an appropriate institutional and organiza- policy strategy in the EU.
tional framework for (individual, organizational and
collective) learning, both in politics and in economics, 6.4. Financing
than it is to make a definite decision, once and for
all. As Lundvall and Borrás (1998, p. 35) have rightly Money matters and public research funding on
emphasized, in a context of increased market com- both a national and a supranational level must also
petition and rapid innovation, it is the capacity to be part of an emergent strategy in technology policy.
learn which is of crucial importance for companies. Rather, it is the basic philosophy of funding which
And the same holds true for policies. What makes distinguishes the different strategies. Whereas de-
a political strategy brilliant in such a context is not liberate strategies in recent years have been based
foresight and decision-making power, “but a capacity on an ever tighter coupling of basic research and
and willingness to learn, supported by a tolerant orga- socio-economic objectives, an emergent strategy em-
nization and its committed personnel” (Mintzberg and phasizes the open-ended character of basic research
McHugh, 1985, p. 194). Thus, it would be a major instead. As Barend van der Meulen and Arie Rip have
function of an emergent strategy in technology policy recently argued, “Research results need not have an
to establish the framework for a “learning” economy unambiguous link with socio-economic objectives.
and society. Their results are useful in the sense that these become
part of a knowledge reservoir, and thus, building
6.3. Activating and mediating blocks for ‘new combinations’ that are formed with
specific socio-economic objectives in mind”. And
In an emergent policy strategy, the public’s active as a consequence, “The way (research; EG) results
participation in the design and use of technical systems become part of the reservoir, and the access to the
is crucial. In such a strategy, interested citizens are not reservoir (including knowledge structuring efforts)
forced into the role of mere consumers; instead, their may well be more important than the fine-tuning of
practical experiences, imagination and creativity are research projects to socio-economic objectives” (Van
used in the development of socially acceptable new der Meulen and Rip, 1998, p. 767).
technologies. Hence, it must be an integral part of an This last aspect indicates best, that a shift to a new,
emergent strategy in technology policy to promote and emergent strategy in EU technology policy does not
cultivate democratic participation in technology policy require completely new instruments, additional resour-
making. ces or new competencies. Rather, it implies a new
This includes the organization of an efficient public paradigm, i.e. a new way of looking at problems,
mediation process, in which the different interests that of selecting policy instruments and of using them.
E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921 919

Most importantly, in an emergent strategy, solutions Boutellier, R., Kloth, B., Bodmer, C.E., 1996. Neue Organisa-
to problems grow “like weeds in the garden; they are tionsformen globaler Forschung und Entwicklung. Zeitschrift
not cultivated like tomatoes in a hothouse” (Mintzberg Führung + Organisation 65, 282–287.
Brandin, D.H., Harrison, M.A., 1987. The Technology War. A
and McHugh, 1985, p. 194). Admittedly, compared to Case for Competitiveness. Wiley, New York.
the “hothouse” approaches with their high ambitions Braczyk, H.-J., Cooke, P., Heidenreich, M. (Eds.), 1998. Regional
and their big promises as employed in EU technology Innovation Systems. UCL Press, London.
policy during the last two decades, a “gardening” app- Braczyk, H.-J., Fuchs, G., Wolf, H.-G. (Eds.), 1999. Multimedia
and Regional Economic Restructuring. Routledge, London.
roach as advocated here seems to be much more Camilleri, J.A., Falk, J., 1992. The End of Sovereignty? The Poli-
modest and much less appealing. However, it also tics of a Shrinking and Fragmenting World. Edward Elgar,
seems to be the most promising way for Europe to Aldershot.
escape the existing strategic dilemma in innovation Cawson, A., et al., 1990. Hostile Brothers: Competition and
policy. Closure in the European Electronics Industry. Clarendon Press,
Oxford.
Consultative Group on Competitiveness, 1995. Improving Euro-
pean Competitiveness. First report to the President of the
Acknowledgements Commission and the Heads of State or Government. Brussels.
Cuhls, K., 1998. Technikvorausschau in Japan. Ein Rückblick
auf 30 Jahre Delphi-Expertenbefragungen. Physica-Verlag,
This article is based on a paper prepared for the con- Heidelberg.
ference “Civilian Technology Policy in the European Davignon Panel, 1997. Five-Year Assessment of the European
Union and the United States: Recent Experiences and Community RTD Framework Programmes by an Independent
Panel Chaired by Viscount E. Davignon. Brussels.
New Directions”, Atlanta, 9–10 April 1999, sponsored Dekker Report, 1992. The Report of the Information and
by the European Union Center of the University Sys- Communications Technologies Review Board. Brussels.
tem of Georgia and the School of Public Policy of the European Commission, 1990. Industriepolitik in einem offenen
Georgia Institute of Technology. In April 2000, the und wettbewerbsorientierten Umfeld. COM (90) 556, Brussels.
author had the opportunity to present the basic ideas European Commission, 1992. Die Forschung nach Maastricht —
Bilanz und Strategie. SEK (92) 682, Brussels.
to a seminar at the Institute for Advanced Studies at European Commission, 1993. White Paper on Growth, Competi-
Vienna. The author is indebted to the participants of tiveness, Employment. The Challenges and Ways Forward into
both events for providing inspiring comments to the the 21st Century. Brussels.
first draft of this manuscript, in particular to Peter European Commission, 1995. Green Paper on Innovation. Brussels.
European Commission, 2000. Towards a European research area.
Biegelbauer, Hans Klein, Stefan Kuhlmann and Philip
Communication from the Commission. COM (2000) 6,
Shapira. Furthermore, he appreciates the assistance of Brussels.
Sarah E. Fritz in the preparation of the manuscript. Evans, P.B., Rueschemeyer, D., Skocpol T. (Eds.), 1985a. Bringing
the State Back In. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Evans, P.B., Rueschemeyer, D., Skocpol, T., 1985b. On the road
toward a more adequate understanding of the state. In: Evans,
References P.B., Rueschemeyer, D., Skocpol T. (Eds.), Bringing the State
Back In. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 347–366.
Aigrain, P., et al., 1989. The Report of the Framework Programme Fach, W., Grande, E., 1992. Emergent rationality in technological
Review Board. Brussels. policy: nuclear energy in the Federal Republic of Germany.
Minerva XXX, 14–27.
Anchordogay, M., 1989. Computers Inc.: Japan’s Challenge to
Flamm, K., 1988. Creating the Computer: Government, Industry,
IBM. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
and High Technology. Brookings, Washington, DC.
Andreasen, L.E., Coriat, B., den Hertog F., Kaplinsky, R. Fransman, M., 1990. The Market and Beyond: Cooperation and
(Eds.), 1995. Europe’s Next Step: Organizational Innovation, Competition in Information Technology Development in the
Competition and Employment. Frank Cass, London. Japanese System. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Arnold, E., Guy, K., 1986. Parallel Convergence: National Gerybadze, A., Meyer-Krahmer, F., Reger, G., 1997. Globales
Strategies in Information Technology. Pinter, London. Management von Forschung und Innovation. Schäffer-Poeschel-
BMBF (Bundesministerium für Bildung und Forschung), 1998a. Verlag, Stuttgart.
Das 5. Europäische Forschungsrahmenprogramm. Chancen für Grande, E., 1994. Vom Nationalstaat zur europäischen Politi-
die Forschung in Deutschland. BMBF, Bonn. kverflechtung. Expansion und Transformation moderner Staatli-
BMBF (Bundesministerium für Bildung, Wissenschaft, Forschung chkeit — untersucht am Beispiel der Forschungs- und Technol-
und Technologie), 1998b. Faktenbericht 1998. BMBF, Bonn. ogiepolitik. Habilitationsschrift, Universität Konstanz, Germany.
920 E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921

Grande, E., 1995. Forschungspolitik in der Politikverflechtungs- Nelson, R.R. (Ed.), 1982. Government and Technical Progress: A
Falle? institutionelle Strukturen, Konfliktdimensionen und Cross-Industry Analysis. Pergamon, New York.
Verhandlungslogiken europäischer Forschungs- und Technolo- OECD, 1991. Technology in a Changing World. OECD, Paris.
giepolitik. Politische Vierteljahresschrift 36, 460–483. OECD, 1992. Technology and the Economy: The Key Relationship.
Grande, E., 1999. Innovationspolitik im europäischen Mehrebenen- OECD, Paris.
system: zur neuen Architektur des Staatlichen. In: Grimmer, K., OECD, 1999. Globalisation of Industrial R&D: Policy Issues.
Kuhlmann, S., Meyer-Krahmer, F. (Eds.), Innovationspolitik in OECD, Paris.
globalisierten Arenen. Leske + Budrich, Opladen, pp. 87–103. Ohmae, K., 1990. The Borderless World. Power and Strategy in
Grande, E., Häusler, J., 1994. Industrieforschung und Forschung- the Interlinked Economy. Harper, New York.
spolitik. Staatliche Steuerungspotentiale in der Informations- Patel, P., Pavitt, K., 1991. Large firms in the production of the
technik. Campus, Frankfurt a. M. world’s technology: an important case of non-globalization.
Grande, E., Peschke, A., 1999a. Organizing science in Europe. Journal of International Business Studies, 1–21.
European Review 7, 295–312. Peterson, J., 1993. High technology and the competition state: an
Grande, E., Peschke, A., 1999b. Transnational cooperation and analysis of the Eureka programme. Routledge, London.
policy networks in European science policy-making. Research Peterson, J., Sharp, M., 1999. Technology Policy in the European
Policy 28, 43–61. Union. Macmillan, London.
Hack, L., 1998. Technologietransfer und Wissenstransformation. Porter, M.E., 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. Free
Zur Globalisierung der Forschungsorganisation von Siemens. Press, New York.
Westfälisches Dampfboot, Münster. Reger, G., Kuhlmann, S., 1995. Europäische Technologiepolitik in
Hall, P.A., 1986. Governing the Economy. Polity Press, Oxford. Deutschland: Bedeutung für die deutsche Forschungslandschaft.
Hall, P.A., Taylor, R.C.R., 1996. Political science and the three Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg.
new institutionalisms. Political Studies 44, 936–957.
Sabatier, P.A., 1986. Top-down and bottom-up approaches to
Hohn, H.-W., Schimank, U., 1990. Konflikte und Gleichgewichte
implementation research: a critical analysis and suggested
im Forschungssystem: Akteurkonstellationen und Entwick-
synthesis. Journal of Public Policy 6, 21–48.
lungspfade in der staatlich finanzierten außeruniversitären
Sandholtz, W., 1992. High-Tech Europe: The Politics of
Forschung. Campus, Frankfurt a. M.
International Cooperation. University of California Press,
Katzenstein, P. (Ed.), 1978. Between Power and Plenty. Foreign
Berkeley.
Economic Policy of Advanced Industrial States. University of
Scharpf, F.W., 1987. Sozialdemokratische Krisenpolitik in Europa.
Wisconsin Press, Madison, WI.
Das Modell Deutschland im Vergleich. Campus, Frankfurt
Katzenstein, P., 1987. Policy and Politics in West Germany: The
a. M.
Growth of a Semisovereign State. Temple University Press,
Schnöring, T., Neu, W., 1991. Bundesrepublik Deutschland. In:
Philadelphia.
Grupp, H., Schnöring, T. (Eds.), Forschung und Entwicklung
Lax, D.A., Sebenius, J.K., 1986. The Manager as Negotiator. Free
für die Telekommunikation: Internationaler Vergleich mit zehn
Press, New York.
Lundvall, B.-A., 1985. Product Innovation and User-Producer Ländern, Bd. II. Springer, Berlin, pp. 255–412.
Interaction. Aalborg University Press, Aalborg. Sharp, M., Shearman, C., 1987. European Technological Coope-
Lundvall, B.-A., Borrás, S., 1998. The globalising learning ration. Routledge, London.
economy: implications for innovation policy. European Simon, H., 1962. The architecture of complexity. Proceedings of
Commission, Brussels. the American Philosophical Society 106, 467–482.
Luttwak, E.N., 1993. The Endangered American Dream: How to Steinmo, S., Thelen, K., Longstreth, F. (Eds.), 1992. Structuring
Stop the United States From Becoming a Third World Country Politics. Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis.
and How to Win the Geo-Economic Struggle for Industrial Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Supremacy. Simon & Schuster, New York. Stopford, J.M., Strange, S., 1991. Rival States, Rival Markets.
Mayntz, R., Scharpf, F.W., 1975. Policy-Making in the German Competition for World Market Shares. Cambridge University
Federal Bureaucracy. Elsevier, Amsterdam. Press, Cambridge.
Mayntz, R., Scharpf, F.W. (Eds.), 1995. Gesellschaftliche Selbs- Stucke, A., 1993. Institutionalisierung der Forschungspolitik:
tregelung und politische Steuerung. Campus, Frankfurt a. M. Entstehung, Entwicklung und Steuerungsprobleme des Bundes-
Meyer-Krahmer, F., 1989. Der Einfluß staatlicher Technologie- forschungsministeriums. Campus, Frankfurt a.M.
politik auf industrielle Innovationen. Nomos, Baden-Baden. Thelen, K., Steinmo, S., 1992. Historical institutionalism in compa-
Meyer-Krahmer, F. (Ed.), 1999. Globalisation of R&D and Techno- rative politics. In: Steinmo, S., Thelen, K., Longstreth, F. (Eds.),
logy Markets. Consequences for National Innovation Policies. Structuring Politics. Historical Institutionalism in Comparative
Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg. Analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 1–32.
Mintzberg, H., McHugh, A., 1985. Strategy formation in an adho- Thurow, L., 1992. Head to Head. The Coming Economic Battle
cracy. Administrative Science Quarterly XXX, 160–197. Among Japan, Europe, and America. William Morrow, New
Muldur, U., Petrella, R. (Eds.), 1994. The European Community York.
and the Globalization of Technology and the Economy. Tyson, L., 1992. Who’s Bashing Whom? Trade Conflict in High-
Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Technology Industries. Institute for International Economics,
Luxembourg. Washington, DC.
E. Grande / Research Policy 30 (2001) 905–921 921

Van der Meulen, B., Rip, A., 1998. Mediation in the Dutch science Weyrich, C., 1998. Industrieforschung vor globalen Herausforder-
system. Research Policy 27, 757–769. ungen. In: Fricke, W. (Ed.), Innovationen in Technik, Wissen-
Weaver, R.K., Rockman, B.A. (Eds.), 1993. Do Institutions Matter? schaft und Gesellschaft. Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, Bonn,
Government Capabilities in the United States and Abroad. The pp. 55–74.
Brookings Institution, Washington, DC. Zysman, J., 1983. Governments, Markets, and Growth. Financial
Weiss, L., 1998. The Myth of the Powerless State. Governing the Systems and the Politics of Industrial Growth. Cornell
Economy in a Global Era. Polity Press, Oxford. University Press, Ithaca.

You might also like