You are on page 1of 12

2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 147

doi: 10.1093/heapol/czh018 Health Policy and Planning 19(3),


HEALTH POLICY AND PLANNING; 19(3): 147–158 © Oxford University Press, 2004; all rights reserved.

The role of community-based health insurance within the


health care financing system: a framework for analysis
SARA BENNETT
Abt Associates, Bethesda, MD, USA and Health Policy Unit, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine,
London, UK

There is increasing advocacy for community-based health insurance (CBHI) schemes as part of a broader
solution to health care financing problems in low-income countries, but to date there is very limited under-
standing of how CBHI schemes interact with other elements of a health care financing system. This paper
aims to set out a preliminary conceptual framework for understanding such interactions, and highlights the

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


kind of research questions raised by such a framework. A basic conceptual map of a CBHI scheme is devel-
oped, and extensions added to this map that incorporate (1) effects upon non-members of schemes, (2)
government subsidies to providers, (3) government subsidies to schemes, and (4) issues raised by the exist-
ence of multiple risk-pooling schemes in a particular context. The utility of a broader approach to analyz-
ing/assessing CBHI schemes is illustrated through examination of two policy issues, namely (1) coordination
of CBHI risk pools and government risk pools, and (2) equity implications of CBHI schemes and the role of
government subsidies in such schemes. It is concluded that there is a strong need for empirical work to
explore how CBHI schemes and the broader health care financing system interact, and that even if individual
schemes achieve their own objectives (in terms of equity, efficiency etc.), this does not necessarily imply that
such objectives will be achieved at the system level.

Key words: community-based health insurance, equity, risk pooling

Introduction government or private for-profit company, that provides risk


pooling to cover all or part of the costs of health care
‘The objectives of policy relate to the entire population services.3 There is increasing advocacy for CBHI schemes as
and thus the overall health care system: insurance part of a system-wide solution to improving access for health
‘schemes’ should be assessed in terms of how the care services. CBHI schemes appear particularly appropriate
schemes contribute to the system-wide insurance objec- for providing insurance coverage to persons with limited
tive1 . . . policies that can improve the financial sustain- protection from other sources, such as those who are not
ability of individual insurance schemes can, at the same engaged in formal sector employment. They also seem
time, detract from the efficiency and sustainability with particularly relevant to low-income countries where govern-
which the insurance objective of the entire health care ment revenue is limited and there is currently extensive
system is pursued.’ (Kutzin 2001) reliance upon out-of-pocket payment. For example, the
report of the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health
While there is substantial force to the logic of the argument states: ‘The Commission recommends that out-of-pocket
presented in the quotation above, to date much of the expenditures by poor communities should increasingly be
research on community-based health insurance (CBHI) has channeled into “community financing” schemes to help cover
focused upon individual CBHI schemes themselves and the the costs of community-based health delivery’ (WHO 2001:
extent to which particular schemes are equitable, sustainable 60).
or efficient (e.g. Diop et al. 1995; Jakab and Krishnan 2001;
Schneider and Diop 2002). To date, there has not been a clear National governments are increasingly recognizing that
and comprehensive exposition of the nature of the inter- CBHI schemes can be part of a national financing strategy:
actions between CBHI schemes and the broader health care Ghana is in the process of developing a health financing
financing system. For example, a recent review of 258 policy that will, most likely, give a key role to CBHI schemes,
community-based health financing schemes2 asserts the need and Tanzania has already done so. However, even where
for analysts to adopt a societal view in evaluating the impact CBHI schemes are not explicitly viewed to be part of govern-
of CBHI schemes, but found that: ‘Almost all studies are ment financing policy, in most cases they implicitly interact
focused on the scheme and the scheme members with only with government financing policy. While CBHI schemes still
marginal or no analysis of the impact of the scheme in the tend to cover a small proportion of a nation’s population, in
population at large and the possible effects of the schemes some countries this picture is changing – and changing fast.
beyond their members’ (ILO 2002a: 46). In Ghana, it is now estimated that there are 157 Mutual
Health Organizations (MHOs) (one particular form of CBHI
A broad working definition of a CBHI scheme is any scheme scheme), up from just four 2 years ago (personal communi-
managed and operated by an organization, other than a cation, Chris Atim).
2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 148

148 Sara Bennett

The purpose of this paper is to provide a conceptual frame- Africa (Atim et al. 1998). The diversity of CBHI schemes
work for analyzing how CBHI schemes interact with other means that different schemes will contribute to the overall
components of the health care financing system in terms of financing system in different ways.
financial flows (revenue collection, pooling, purchasing) and
the related issues of population coverage and benefit It is only recently that governments in developing countries
packages. The focus is upon what are frequently incidental, have begun to articulate the role they see CBHI schemes
unplanned interactions between CBHI and other financing playing within the bigger health-financing picture. Of the
schemes; other papers have addressed how governments may schemes listed in Table 1, the Community Health Fund in
explicitly attempt to influence the behaviour of CBHI Tanzania and the Health Card Scheme in Thailand are both
schemes through a variety of mechanisms (Ranson and schemes that their governments helped to develop and shape.
Bennett 2002). Given the fact that, to date, virtually no Yet even in these cases, there has not always been an attempt
studies have discussed CBHI schemes from a system-wide to explore thoroughly the nature of interaction between
perspective, this paper is not designed to present lessons, but various forms of risk pooling. For example, in Tanzania it has
rather to highlight the types of questions that need to be simply been stated that the Community Health Fund will
addressed, and begin to illustrate an organizing framework cover rural communities while complementary employer-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


for addressing them. mandated insurance funds will cover urban-based workers
and civil servants (Ministry of Health, Tanzania undated).
A conceptual framework for examining interactions between
CBHI schemes and other aspects of the health care financing For schemes such as SEWA and Nkoranza, where there has
system is important both to guide research in this area and been no attempt to ensure complementary roles between
to help governments identify some of the key policy issues government financing systems and the scheme, the role that
faced as CBHI schemes become an increasingly common the CBHI scheme plays in practice varies with the scheme
feature of health financing environments. In order to explore population coverage and the socio-economic/demographic
the implications of interactions between CBHI schemes and profile of members. If schemes had a clear understanding of
the rest of the health care financing system, this paper: their intended role with respect to the broader health care
system, then various mechanisms could be employed to influ-
• Sets out a series of conceptual maps that illustrate how ence who enrolled. For example, how schemes set their
CBHI schemes may relate to the broader health care premiums, define their benefit packages, market their
financing system; services, etc., will affect enrollment patterns. But in most
• Uses the maps to explore how CBHI schemes may (or may cases, neither schemes nor government have thought clearly
not) contribute to national policy objectives, and how about this or communicated about it; consequently, actual
different features of CBHI schemes, and government population coverage is somewhat ad hoc, and the relation-
policy may interact to affect achievement of policy objec- ship between the CBHI scheme and the broader system is
tives. frequently incidental rather than planned. A conceptual
framework is required to help policymakers understand and
As this paper is largely conceptual in nature, it does not draw analyze how CBHI schemes interact with the broader health
heavily upon empirical data. However, throughout the text, care financing system.
references are made, for illustrative purposes, to four
different CBHI schemes. Table 1 summarizes key features of
the four CBHI schemes discussed here. These schemes were Scheme objectives versus government objectives
not selected because they were thought to be representative In principle (or in theoretical terms), the primary purpose of
of the population of CBHI schemes, but because they are any insurance scheme is to share risk between individuals and
relatively well documented, and because they illustrate hence extend financial protection to members of the scheme
different ways in which schemes can interact with govern- (Mills 1983). In practice, different stakeholders in a risk-
ment financing systems. Of the four schemes discussed, two pooling scheme may have different perspectives on the
are from Asia and two from Africa. Relatively few Latin objectives of a scheme, and stakeholder objectives will also
American CBHI schemes appear to exist. Information about vary according to the type of CBHI scheme.5 This section is
the schemes was collected through literature review and concerned with how government (or social) objectives for
supplemented by contacts with analysts who have researched CBHI schemes may differ from the objectives of key stake-
the individual schemes.4 holders in specific schemes (namely scheme managers and
scheme members).
From the table, the diversity of CBHI schemes is evident:
schemes differ markedly in terms of their ownership struc- Table 2 identifies three types of criteria (equity, financial
tures, funding flows, benefit package composition, and sustainability/revenue raising and efficiency) that are
membership. Scheme objectives and origins are also diverse. commonly used to assess health care financing systems, and
For example, some schemes (such as Nkoranza in Ghana) identifies how precise objectives across these dimensions will
were initiated by private non-profit providers seeking vary according to whether a scheme-level or government
initially to secure their revenue base; others (such as SEWA (social) -level perspective is adopted.6
in India) grew from micro-credit schemes that added health
insurance activities to protect their members; still others In many cases, there is not a clear alignment (and sometimes
sprung from the traditional ‘mutuelle’ movement in West there is even conflict) between scheme-specific objectives
2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 149

The role of CBHI 149

Table 1. Background and context on CBHI schemes used to illustrate alternative modes of interaction between schemes and government

Scheme and location Nature of ownership Providers and Benefit package Sources
relationship with
providers

SEWA, Ahmedabad, India Women-owned Private for-profit, private Predominantly primary Ranson (2002)
micro-credit agency non-profit or public care. Some hospital ILO (2002b)
providers. Bills paid benefits with cap on
by member who then total benefits.
seeks reimbursement
from the scheme.
Nkoranza, Ghana Initially the mission St Theresa’s mission Hospital services Atim and Madjiguene
hospital in Nkoranza hospital (that initiated (2000)
district, more recently the scheme). Hospital
ownership and bills scheme directly

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


management has been on a fee-for-service
transferred to the local basis.
community.
Community Health Fund, Government/District Government, private Predominantly primary Chee and Smith (2002)
Tanzania Health teams for-profit and private care with some Shirima (1996)
non-profit health care hospital benefits. Ministry of Health,
facilities in principle. Tanzania (undated)
In practice no or few
for-profit providers
participate.
Direct budgetary
subvention to
providers.
Health Card Scheme, Thailand Government Government health care
facilities.
Funding allocations Both primary and Supachutikul (1996)
to providers secondary care. Pannurunothai et al.
proportional to use. (2000)

Table 2. Scheme objectives versus government (or social) objectives

Objective Scheme level perspective Government-level perspective

Equity – Poorer members of society join schemes – Equitable access to (a basic package
– Equitable access to benefits by members of) services throughout the population
under the scheme – Progressive distribution of government
– Premiums are progressive subsidies

Financial sustainability/revenue raising – Scheme revenues outweigh expenditures – Adequate total resources mobilized
– Adequate enrollment levels to ensure an acceptable level of care

Efficiency – Reasonable administrative costs to – Reasonable administrative costs for system as


scheme a whole
– Purchase of appropriate services – Appropriate service mix in system
as a whole

and social ones. For example, reasonable administrative costs There is also tension between the different objectives
at the scheme level may be achieved, but administrative costs identified in Table 2. Government and individual schemes
at the system level may be exacerbated by the challenges may place different emphasis on different objectives. For
inherent to regulating multiple insurers. Similarly, while individual schemes, ensuring sustainability is likely to be a
promoting sustainability is an obvious objective at the dominant objective: without sustained operations no other
scheme level, it is not clear that, in and of itself, this should objectives can be achieved. Yet mechanisms to promote indi-
be a government policy objective. For example, individual vidual scheme sustainability can conflict substantively with
scheme sustainability may be achieved through dumping equity concerns. Exclusion of high-risk individuals from
severe or chronic cases into the public health care system, or scheme membership will affect the sickest and probably most
through reliance upon government subsidies – both of which vulnerable members of the population. Increasing premium
may potentially detract from the overall sustainability of the levels will discourage the poor from joining. Placing limi-
broader health care system. tations on a benefit package will most likely reduce the level
2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 150

150 Sara Bennett

of effective protection provided against financial risk. While risk protection may be limited. Furthermore, many CBHI
this will affect all income groups, it may have the most severe schemes involve some form of co-payment for services within
consequences for the poorest. the benefit package, and this will also affect the extent of risk
protection.
Health policy analysts have been significantly more opti-
mistic about the potential for CBHI schemes in low-income Even for those services covered entirely within the benefit
countries compared with for-profit private insurers (Carrin package, there are multiple questions about how individual
1987). The non-profit nature of CBHI schemes appears to CBHI schemes for these services interact with the broader
have led to the assumption that the objectives of CBHI health care financing system:
schemes are more closely aligned with government objec-
tives. While there may be some truth to this, CBHI schemes (1) What happens to people who are not members of the
must be driven by similar imperatives to for-profit schemes scheme? Do they pay user fees? Are they excluded from
in order to ensure their sustainability. So while in principle it care?
may be anticipated that there is considerable alignment (2) Do health care providers receive additional financial
between government health care financing goals and CBHI support? For example, do they receive government

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


scheme goals, in practice (1) individual schemes by necessity subsidy in one form or another? How does this differ
may have to focus more on sustainability issues than equity between public and private providers?
issues, and (2) even if individual CBHI schemes share (3) Does the CBHI scheme receive additional financial
government goals, this does not necessarily mean that their support? For example, are there government subsidies
overall system-wide impact contributes to government goals. paid directly to the fund? Do donors support the oper-
The question of the extent to which pursuance of individual ating costs of the fund?
scheme goals contributes to government goals is clearly (4) How are the above issues affected when there are
context specific and needs to be empirically examined rather multiple risk-pooling schemes? How equitable is govern-
than assumed. ment support to these schemes, and what if any tensions
arise between the multiple risk pools?
The basic model
These four sets of questions drive the extensions to the basic
Figure 1 illustrates the most basic (limited) model of CBHI model discussed in the following section. For ease of presen-
schemes. It shows that households enrolled in the scheme pay tation these extensions to the basic model do not address
premiums into the CBHI fund. In turn, the scheme pays services outside the package or co-payment issues for
health care providers for services, and in return, these services covered by CBHI schemes, however some of these
providers offer health care services to scheme members. issues are returned to in the penultimate section.

This limited model considers only what happens within the


CBHI scheme. Of course, no CBHI scheme can offer a
Extending the basic model
benefit package that is truly comprehensive; thus, certain
services will always be provided outside of the benefit
Payments by non-members – no government subsidy
package and paid for by other means (such as by private out-
of-pocket payments or by government). The effective degree The most basic extension to the model is to consider the
of risk protection offered by an individual CBHI scheme will position of non-members of the scheme (see Figure 2). It is
depend upon the extent to which the benefit package offered rare that CBHI schemes achieve universal coverage of their
covers a comprehensive package of services, particularly target population. Accordingly, there are non-members who
higher cost services. If certain commonly used, high cost will also need to seek health care services. The evidence
services are omitted from the benefit package, then effective available (largely anecdotal) suggests that it is primarily the
rural middle-class that joins such schemes (Bennett et al.
1998; ILO 2002a).
Services
Patients/ Hospitals In most instances, non-members are not excluded from
provided
scheme members service use but must pay a separate fee (normally to the
Primary care health care provider) to use services. By implication,
providers providers fully recover their costs through a combination of
insurance payments and user fees. This model is common
Premiums paid amongst schemes that utilize unsubsidized private providers,
Provider payment who are also used by non-members. For members of the
SEWA scheme using private for-profit providers, the model
would look similar to Figure 2. In most countries, public
facilities receive some sort of government subsidy and in
CBHI scheme
many Sub-Saharan African contexts, non-profit private
providers also receive some form of government subsidy
(Gilson et al. 1994). Accordingly, schemes such as Nkoranza
Figure 1. The basic model: how CBHI schemes operate in Ghana do not, strictly speaking, fall into this model.
2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 151

The role of CBHI 151

cross-subsidy between scheme members and non-


members, or vice versa?
Fees paid by non-members
Non-members Payments by non-members and government subsidy to
providers
Services
Scheme members provided Hospitals Figure 3 shows the next extension to the basic model. Not
only are there non-members who must pay something to
Primary care
access care, but government also provides a subsidy to health
providers
care providers. This scenario is very widely prevalent in Sub-
Saharan Africa where, in effect, many CBHI schemes are risk
Premiums paid
Provider payment pooling only for the cost-sharing element of what are
primarily government-funded health care services. Many
Sub-Saharan African systems (particularly those in East and
Southern Africa) have moved from fully government-funded

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


CBHI scheme public health care systems to a national system of cost sharing
through user fees, and even to (on a limited scale) risk
pooling through CBHI for the cost-sharing element. To date,
Figure 2. Extension 1: contributions from non-members, no governments have not necessarily stepped back to consider
government subsidy whether the resulting pattern of subsidies is optimal. Govern-
ment subsidies are not only received by public health care
This amendment to the basic model gives rise to a set of facilities. In many Sub-Saharan African countries (such as
empirical questions: Ghana, Kenya, Malawi, Tanzania and Zambia) governments
provide subsidies to private non-profit (mission) facilities
(Gilson et al. 1994). In general, private for-profit providers
Population coverage
receive close to no subsidy from government at all.
• What proportion of the target population join the scheme?
• How do members’ and non-members’ profiles differ? The map of financial flows illustrated in Figure 3 is very close
to what occurs in the Nkoranza scheme in Ghana; however,
the Nkoranza scheme does not offer insurance for primary
Financial flows (pooling and purchasing)
care or outpatient services. St. Theresa’s hospital, the
• If supply is limited, what happens to the distribution of primary provider under the scheme, does however receive
services between members and non-members? certain subsidies (such as staff salaries) from the government
• What proportion of a particular provider’s revenue comes of Ghana. In Nkoranza, the CBHI scheme essentially
from user fees versus payments from the CBHI? What, if provides a mechanism for the population to pool risks for the
any, implications does this have for the CBHI’s ability to user fees associated with government-subsidized care at the
influence provider behaviour? hospital.
• Do amounts paid for similar services for members and
non-members differ? How does this affect the quality and This addition to the model also gives rise to a separate set of
quantity of services provided to each? Is there questions:

Fees paid
Non-members

Services
Patients/ Hospitals
provided
scheme members
Primary care
providers

Premiums paid
Provider payment

CBHI scheme
Government

Figure 3. Extension 2: contributions from non-members and government subsidy to providers


2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 152

152 Sara Bennett

Population coverage subsidies to the fund is based on equity. Government subsi-


dizes the cost of social health insurance (targeted at formal
• What is the impact of the scheme on the capture of govern-
sector workers): tri-partite contributions to the Social
ment subsidies? Does the scheme enhance access for
Security Scheme are made by employer, employee and
members who are then better able to access government
government. Therefore, it was argued to be inequitable for
subsidies?
government not to subsidize premiums for informal sector
workers (a generally less affluent group) who chose to enroll
Financial flows (pooling and purchasing) in the Health Card Scheme. In Tanzania, the government
matching grant was introduced when it was realized that esti-
• Where does the primary risk pooling occur within the
mated premium costs would be too high for the average
system (on the part of government or on the part of the
household to enroll.8 Matching grants were seen as a way to
CBHI scheme) and how does this vary according to
reduce premiums, therefore increasing enrollment (Shirima
delivery level?
1996). Besides making scheme membership more affordable,
• What is the relative magnitude of the different financial
subsidies may be used to offset risk differences between
flows (CBHI, government, out-of-pocket payments) to the
schemes or compensate for regional income inequities

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


provider? How does this vary between different levels of
(Busse 2002). However, in practice these other rationales for
the health care system?
government subsidy to schemes have not been observed in
developing countries.
Benefit package
Many existing CBHI schemes have received some external
• How do the different benefit packages covered by CBHI donor support. Sometimes this has supported technical
and government relate? To what extent is there potential assistance to the scheme, or has covered certain operating
for cost shifting? costs (such as the printing of insurance cards), and on some
occasions this has been used to ‘bail out’ failing schemes. In
Government subsidies direct to the scheme most cases, donor contributions to schemes constitute one-
off investments (unlike government subsidies), but nonethe-
The third extension to the basic model (Figure 4) shows, in less donor contributions raise many of the same issues as
addition to the features mentioned above, direct government government subsidies that are presented below.
subsidy to the CBHI fund.7 This type of arrangement does
not appear particularly common at the moment, but does This further amendment raises additional questions, for
occur in a number of countries. For example, in the Health example:
Card Scheme in Thailand, the government now makes
matching contributions to the premiums paid by households
Population coverage
to the scheme. Similarly, the Tanzanian government matches
contributions made by households to the Community Health • Are subsidies to the scheme used to extend population
Fund. coverage to poorer groups, or do they constitute a general
subsidy to the scheme which might simply enhance benefits
In Thailand, the rationale for government to provide direct for members?

Fees paid
Non-members

Services
Patients/ Hospitals
provided
scheme members
Primary care
providers

Premiums paid
Provider payment

CBHI scheme
Government
Government
subsidies to
scheme

Figure 4. Extension 3: adding government subsides to the scheme


2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 153

The role of CBHI 153

Financial flows (pooling and purchasing) consequences of multiple risk pools in developing country
contexts. Thailand, where in addition to the Health Card
• How does the magnitude of government subsidies to the
Scheme there is a variety of other schemes covering different
scheme compare with government subsidies to providers
parts of the population, is perhaps an exception to this, with
and with revenues from premiums?
growing evidence about equity implications and cost shifting
on the part of the provider. Cost shifting arises due to the fact
Benefit package that different insurance schemes are likely to provide
• Are subsidies to the scheme used to extend and to help different benefits and modes of payment, and therefore there
purchase services that individuals might be unwilling to are incentives for health care providers to play one insurance
pay for (e.g. health education, public health services)? scheme against another in order to increase revenues
(Sullivan 2001). This may simply take the form of subsidiz-
ing care for members of one type of scheme by over-charging
Multiple risk-pooling schemes
another scheme (this is a common practice for public hospi-
The fourth and final extension to the basic model concerns tals in Thailand treating patients under the low income
the situation where there are multiple risk-pooling schemes scheme (Supachutikul 1996)). In some instances, one patient

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


present in the same country. This situation is depicted in may be covered by more than one scheme and this may
Figure 5. This Figure depicts the case where there are create incentives for providers to re-classify patients or their
multiple CBHI schemes; however, the other risk pools could condition. For example, there is evidence from Thailand of
be social health insurance schemes or government financing health care providers reclassifying illnesses and injuries as
of services. ‘work related’ so that they can be covered under the
Workmen’s Compensation Fund (that pays providers on a
In practice, the implications of multiple risk pools will fee-for-service basis) rather than the Social Security Scheme
depend considerably on the extent to which there is clear (that pays providers on a capitation basis) (Varophan 1992).
market segmentation between them, and the extent to which
behaviour of CBHI schemes is regulated. In Tanzania, Other common consequences of the existence of multiple
multiple risk pools already exist, with the Community Health risk-pooling schemes are evident from industrialized country
Fund operating in parallel with a social security scheme, and literature. For example, schemes may try to cream skim,
with different Community Health Funds in different districts. dumping higher risk patients into other risk pools. Govern-
However, there is fairly clear market segmentation between ment mechanisms to address this problem include mandating
these risk pools, and limited or no competition. In Ghana acceptance of all enrollees, restricting choice of insurer,
there is a burgeoning number of CBHI schemes, and pending development of high-risk pools (targeted specifically at high-
government legislation would further complicate the risk individuals and generally heavily government subsi-
scenario by requiring the establishment of district-level dized), and risk equalization or adjustment approaches
CBHI schemes. If this goes ahead as envisaged, then (Soderlund and Khosa 1997). None of these mechanisms are
competition between schemes is likely to occur, and many of without problems in terms of restricting consumer choice, the
the questions raised below would seem very pertinent. complexity of their informational requirements or in terms
of enforcement. For example, mandating acceptance of all
Overall, there is very little empirical evidence about the who present to enroll appears straightforward, but there are

Fees paid
Non-members

Services
Member Hospitals
provided
households
Primary care
providers

Premiums paid
Provider payment

Government
CBHI schemes
Government
subsidies to
scheme

Figure 5. Extension 4: multiple risk pooling schemes


2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 154

154 Sara Bennett

concerns that schemes can still cream skim through adjust- two key policy areas: how the combination of risk pools
ments in benefit packages, premiums or bureaucratic extends financial risk protection and issues of equity.
requirements that deter higher risk people from enrolling.
The mechanisms listed have been experimented with mainly
Financial risk protection: coordinating risk pools
in the context of high-income countries (and to a limited
degree in middle-income countries). It would seem that in Standard insurance theory suggests that insurance schemes
most low-income country contexts, their implementation is should focus upon unpredictable, low risk, high cost events –
even more problematic due to limited government capacity. in practice however, CBHI schemes cover a bewildering
variety of benefit packages, as evidenced by the benefit
There has also been substantial discussion in the United packages of the schemes referred to in this paper. A system-
States of how multiple, fragmented risk pools limit purchas- wide approach to understanding CBHI would suggest that
ing power and strengthen the relative power of providers vis even if there is no formal coordination between CBHI and
à vis insurers (Reinhardt 1990). There is great diversity in the government financing system, individuals will seek out
developing countries in terms of risk pool size in CBHI and prefer CBHI schemes that offer complementary risk
schemes (ILO 2002a); however, there is limited understand- protection to that provided by government. There are three

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


ing of the impact of multiple risk pools upon purchasing or key variables determining what constitutes ‘complementary’
financial sustainability, or how the mix of payment systems risk protection: the extent of co-payment (user fees) for
used by such schemes affects outcomes. government-subsidized services, the extent of the benefits
package or essential package provide by government, and
The issues identified above are likely to arise when there are user perceptions of relative quality of care in public and
multiple competing risk pools. If there is geographically private sectors. Figure 6 illustrates the first two of these
based market segmentation of risk pools (as with the various dimensions.
district-level Community Health Funds in Tanzania) then the
problems are likely to be less severe. It should be recognized, Frequently, governments offer a range of health services at
however, that in any situation where CBHI schemes co-exist subsidized prices. This range of services is sometimes
with significant government subsidies to providers, then referred to as the ‘essential package’. Although many
there are de facto at least two risk pools. governments used to offer a basic package of services free to
the population (i.e. fully subsidized), during the past two
The type of questions that arise with this latest modification decades in Sub-Saharan Africa there has been increasingly
to the basic model include: widespread adoption of supplementary user fees. Accord-
ingly, government risk pooling in many Sub-Saharan African
countries, including Tanzania and Ghana, is now limited to
Population coverage
the shaded area (A) in Figure 6.9 In such contexts, CBHI risk
• Are there distinct profiles for members joining different pools may cover the co-payment element (B) or services
types of schemes? To what extent to the different schemes outside the essential package (C) or some combination of
serve segmented markets (e.g. markets segmented by these. In environments where government subsidies are low
geographical area or type of employment) versus compet- and user fees are high compared with household incomes,
ing for members? there may be demand for a focus upon B.

The nature of demand for CBHI schemes is likely to vary


Financial flows (pooling and purchasing)
within a country depending upon the supply environment
• Do government subsidies to different risk-pooling schemes and local income levels. In urban areas where access to non-
vary, and if so how? Do differences in government subsi- essential services (either through private providers or higher
dies to different schemes enhance or detract from equity? level government facilities) is greater, demand for additional
• How fundamentally different are the premiums and insurance coverage is more likely to focus on services outside
payment mechanisms, and what incentives do these differ- the essential package (area C). In poor areas, communities
ences create for patients and providers? will find user fees relatively less affordable and therefore
seek CBHI schemes that focus more upon quadrant B.
Benefit packages
In India, the SEWA scheme complements government health
• How do benefit packages vary between schemes? Do care financing in a different way. The government of India
different schemes essentially provide the same benefit (together with state governments) offers an extensive
package or are benefit packages complementary (so that package of services, with (at least in principle) zero co-
people might join more than one scheme)? payment. In practice, however, the quality of these services
is widely perceived to be low (and informal charges are wide-
spread). Benefits under the SEWA scheme cover most
Understanding the implications of more complex
primary care services, but allow members to seek private
models of CBHI for policy objectives
sector care (where quality of care is frequently perceived to
The questions presented above raise a substantial number of be better) (ILO 2002b; Ranson 2002). SEWA also provides
policy issues for government. It is not possible to explore all some coverage of hospital services, but caps on the benefit
of these implications here. Instead, this section focuses upon package mean that more severe cases are thrown back into
2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 155

The role of CBHI 155

Source of funds
Government funded User fee

Essential
package
A B

Outside of

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


C
essential package

Services

Figure 6. Coordinating government risk pools and CBHI risk pools

the government risk pool where they are entitled to free based upon the extent to which poor members of the
hospital care (albeit of low quality). community do join. While getting the poor to join CBHI
schemes seems likely to promote their access to basic
This discussion suggests that in any context where govern- services, it is not clear that this is the best strategy through
ment-financed services are an important source of care, which to promote the progressive distribution of subsidies,
demand for risk protection through CBHI schemes will be and it is also a matter of concern as to what happens to the
significantly influenced by government’s own funding poor who do not join.
patterns, and CBHI schemes will need to adjust to reflect
changing government financing policies. For example, one of In order to be able to explore the equity implications of
the stimuli to recent discussions of reinsurance in Ghana has existing CBHI schemes, we need to understand more about
been government plans to devolve teaching hospitals and what happens to non-members and, more broadly, the effec-
require them to become more financially autonomous tiveness of government targeting strategies. For example, the
(reducing the essential package). Conversely, how govern- Thai Health Card scheme explicitly targets the rural middle-
ment develops policy towards CBHI schemes may depend class (Supachutikul 1996). The government operates a
somewhat on what type of risks the schemes are covering. parallel system of programmes to provide free health care
For example, government subsidies to CBHI schemes may services for the elderly, school children and the poorest
better target the poor if they focus upon CBHI schemes that households. In this context, high membership amongst very
risk pool for area B (co-payments) rather than area C poor households in CBHI schemes would be counter to
(services outside the package). equity goals. In most contexts where there are CBHI
schemes however, it is unlikely that there are other social
This discussion of coordinating risk pools also has impli- safety nets that guarantee access for those who do not join
cations for the recent discussion regarding reinsurance of the scheme.
CBHI schemes (Dror 2002). Where schemes focus upon co-
payment for the essential package (B), reinsurance is It is possible that non-members might actually be made
unlikely to be necessary, as most services within this package worse off by a CBHI scheme than before. This might occur
face predictable demand and are low cost. Schemes that in a number of ways:
focus upon area C are much more likely to require reinsur-
ance. • Establishment of the scheme may be associated with
an increase in prices for health care for non-members
(as was the case in the Community Health Fund in
Equity implications
Tanzania);
Table 2 hypothesized that core equity objectives for govern- • In a context of restricted supply, access for non-members
ment were (1) to create equitable access to a basic package to providers may be adversely affected as members may
of health care services, and (2) to promote the progressive receive preferential access;
distribution of government subsidies. Some prior studies (e.g. • Faced with differential reimbursement/payment rates,
Jakab and Krishnan 2001) have made an implicit assumption providers may reduce the quality of care provided to non-
that it is desirable for poorer people to join CBHI schemes, members (depending on the incentives inherent in the
and indeed have measured the ‘equity’ of CBHI schemes reimbursement schedule);
2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 156

156 Sara Bennett

• Government may redirect its budget from direct support important not only in contexts where government intends to
to public health care services to support to CBHI schemes, contribute to or in some way interact with CBHI schemes;
leading to lower quality care for non-members at govern- the implications of CBHI and broader health care system
ment providers; interaction need to be better understood in virtually all
• If a large proportion of the middle class join CBHI type contexts. While there is a growing body of evidence about the
schemes then, in the medium term, pressure upon govern- impact of individual schemes, there is virtually no infor-
ment to maintain public funding for health care services mation about the role that CBHI schemes can and do play in
may be reduced. terms of the broader health care financing system. The paper
has tried to illustrate how, even if an individual CBHI scheme
Again, whether or not these effects occur is an empirical appears to be achieving its own goals in terms of equity,
question, which future analyses of CBHI schemes really need efficiency and financial sustainability, it is far from certain
to address. that the scheme is contributing to social objectives across
these dimensions. Given the lack of evidence and under-
The complex flows of government subsidies to CBHI standing about how CBHI schemes contribute to overarch-
schemes described in the previous section further complicate ing health financing/health system goals, recent advocacy for

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


the analysis. Clearly if CBHI scheme members are much increasing prepayment via CBHI schemes is probably best
better able to access a service heavily subsidized by govern- understood in terms of abhorrence for the most apparent
ment, then it means that they are more likely to capture the alternative, i.e. high levels of out-of-pocket user fees.
government subsidies flowing to providers than non-
members. Similarly, if large parts of the population cannot The frameworks set out here point to a substantial agenda
afford to join a CBHI scheme, even with government subsi- for research. At the most basic level, far greater empirical
dies to the scheme, then those who can will capture the subsi- evidence is required about how CBHI schemes do indeed
dies. In the Community Health Fund in the Hanang district interact with the broader health care financing system: the
of Tanzania, scheme membership remained very low (less models described here need to be populated with data. The
than 5% of the district population) and those who did join frameworks presented also suggest a number of other
the scheme benefitted from two sets of government subsidies: priority areas for policy-oriented research, including:
(1) those provided directly to providers and (2) subsidies
provided directly to the Fund (Chee and Smith 2002). • What types of risk pooling is government best positioned
to provide vis à vis CBHI-type schemes? While there has
For both types of government subsidies the precise rules been theoretical discussion of the types of services govern-
regarding use of subsidies are also important in terms of ment should subsidize (see Hammer 1997), this question
understanding equity impacts. Government subsidies to has not been examined with a specific eye to how CBHI
either the health care provider or the CBHI scheme could be and government risk pools may complement each other.
specifically targeted at providing services for the poor, and Basic cross-scheme data on how CBHI benefit packages
specifically those who cannot afford to purchase membership and population coverage vary with government financing
of the CBHI scheme. It seems rare, in practice, that this is the patterns would help inform this discussion.
case. Subsidies to providers tend to reflect historical patterns • How should government target subsidies in contexts with
rather than anything else. In most cases providers appear CBHI schemes? In supporting the development of CBHI
under no compulsion to use such subsidies for services for the schemes, government must think carefully about how to
poor, but simply absorb them into their general operating make best use of scarce government resources. As the
budget. It would seem that in order to benefit the poor, much conceptual maps demonstrate, there are multiple financing
more targeted approaches are required. roles that government could play with respect to CBHI
schemes, but at this point there is little clarity about what
While it appears likely that CBHI schemes will change the sorts of subsidy are most desirable in which contexts.
allocation of government resources, the acceptability of the • How do CBHI schemes affect non-members? Social policy
outcomes is unclear. For example, in contexts where the regarding CBHI schemes may be particularly affected by
urban middle-class generally captures subsidies, subsidies to the degree to which such schemes improve or detract from
rural CBHI schemes, even if they are not targeted to the very the situation for non-members. More information is
poor, may represent an improvement in terms of equity. needed about the effects of schemes upon non-members.
Similarly, societies may perceive it to be acceptable for CBHI
schemes to improve the position of scheme members if the While the need for further research to enhance our under-
position of non-members is not adversely affected as a conse- standing of how CBHI schemes link to system-wide goals
quence, but if CBHI schemes actually make non-members, seems relatively uncontroversial, it is less clear how success-
and potentially poorer community members, worse off, then ful efforts to better integrate or regulate CBHI schemes will
this is unlikely to be acceptable. be. Some CBHI analysts anticipate an evolutionary path for
CBHI schemes, whereby they gradually become more regi-
mented and integrated into a comprehensive social safety net
Conclusions
structure (Carrin et al. 1999; Arhin-Tengkorang 2001). This
This paper has argued that analysts and policymakers possible evolutionary path reflects what has occurred in
contemplating CBHI schemes need to move away from a Korea and Thailand (Peabody et al. 1995; Supachutikul
scheme-specific perspective to a system-wide one. This is 1996). While development of a regulatory framework could
2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 157

The role of CBHI 157

bring CBHI goals into greater alignment with government six countries. Technical Report No. 19. Bethesda, MD: Partner-
goals, in practice, in many of the contexts where CBHI ships for Health Reform (PHR).
schemes now thrive there is rather limited trust in govern- Bennett S, Creese A, Monasch R. 1998. Health insurance schemes
for people outside formal sector employment. ARA Paper No.
ment and limited government capacity to regulate. In such
16. Geneva: World Health Organization (WHO), Division of
contexts, scheme proponents have an understandable Analysis, Research and Assessment.
concern that government intervention may be a death knell. Busse R. 2002. The role of health insurance subsidies in achieving
Given these tensions it will prove difficult to achieve a proper pro-poor redistributional goals. In: Dror DM, Preker AS (eds).
balance between regulating schemes to achieve government Social reinsurance: a new approach to sustaining community
objectives and stifling scheme growth through heavy-handed health financing. Geneva: ILO, and Washington, DC: World
intervention. Bank.
Carrin G. 1987. Community financing of drugs in Sub-Saharan
Africa. International Journal of Health Planning and Manage-
Endnotes ment 2: 125–45.
Carrin G, De Graeve D, Deville L. 1999. Introduction to
1 The function of insurance is stated to be ‘access to care with
special issue on the economics of health insurance in low and
financial risk protection’ (Kutzin 2001). middle-income countries. Social Science and Medicine 48:

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


2 The definition of community-based health financing in the
59–64.
cited document includes both schemes with prepayment and risk Chee G, Smith K. 2002. Assessment of the Community Health Fund
pooling and those without. in Hanang District, Tanzania. Bethesda, MD: Abt Associates,
3 In East Africa in particular there are several examples of
Partners for Health Reformplus (PHRplus).
provider initiated and (largely provider) owned CBHI schemes. Diop F, Yazbeck A, Bitran R. 1995. The impact of alternative cost
While the definition given here of CBHI incorporates such schemes, recovery schemes on access and equity in Niger. Health Policy
several analyses have pointed out tensions between provider objec- and Planning 10: 223–40.
tives and usual CBHI objectives. Consequently there is increasing Dror D. 2002. Health insurance and re-insurance at the community
consensus that building CBHI schemes around providers is not the level. In: Dror DM, Preker AS (eds). Social reinsurance: a new
best design. The discussion below focuses upon CBHI schemes approach to sustaining community health financing. Geneva:
where the provider is not responsible for scheme management and ILO, and Washington, DC: World Bank.
risk pooling. Gilson L, Dave Sen P, Mohammed S, Mujinja P. 1994. The poten-
4 The author acknowledges a debt to Kent Ranson for infor-
tial of health sector non-government organizations: policy
mation about the SEWA scheme, Chris Atim for information about options. Health Policy and Planning 9: 14–24.
the Nkoranza scheme, and Grace Chee for information about the Hammer JS. 1997. Prices and protocols in public health care. The
Community Health Fund in Tanzania. Literature on the Health World Bank Economic Review 11: 409–32.
Card Scheme in Thailand was supplemented by the author’s own ILO. 2002. Extending social protection in health through community
knowledge acquired with the assistance of many Thai researchers. based health organizations: evidence and challenges. Geneva:
5 For example, for many provider-initiated schemes, the
International Labour Organization-Universitas.
primary objective (at least initially) was to raise revenue, whereas ILO. 2002b. Women organizing for social protection: The Self-
for community-owned schemes the key objective is more likely to employed Women’s Association’s Integrated Insurance Scheme,
improve access with financial protection for members. India. Geneva: International Labour Organization.
6 The three supplementary objectives identified in the table are
Jakab M, Krishnan C. 2001. Community involvement in health care
not meant to be comprehensive. For example, it has been proposed financing: a survey of the literature on the impact, strengths and
that CBHI schemes may contribute to participatory democratic weaknesses. Background Paper No. 9. Washington, DC: World
development (Schneider et al. 2001). This may be an important Bank.
supplementary objective of such schemes; however this objective Kutzin J. 2001. A descriptive framework for country-level analysis
does not raise the same concerns with respect to alignment of of health care financing arrangements. Health Policy 56:
scheme and system-wide objectives as those listed in the table. 171–204.
7 An alternative but similar approach would be to subsidize
Mills A. 1983. Economic aspects of health insurance. In: Lee K, Mills
directly those individuals joining CBHI schemes (Busse 2002). A (eds). The economics of health in developing countries.
8 Premiums were initially calculated on the basis of user fees
Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 64–88.
that would be charged for an average of two health centre visits per Ministry of Health. Undated. Community Health Fund (CHF):
person per annum. The government’s decision to subsidize this design. United Republic of Tanzania, Dar Es Salaam.
appears to reflect an implicit acknowledgement that user fees are Pannarunothai S, Srithamrongsawat S, Kongpan M, Thumvanna P.
unaffordable to the majority. 2000. Financing reforms for the Thai Health Card Scheme.
9 The actual size of shaded area (A) clearly varies substantially
Health Policy and Planning 15: 303–11.
between countries. In some cases A may be very small. Peabody JW, Lee S, Bickel SR. 1995. Health for All in the Republic
of Korea: one country’s experience with implementing
universal health care Health Policy 31: 29–42.
References Ranson K. 2002. Health insurance for the informal sector: two non-
Arhin-Tenkorang D. 2001. Health insurance for the informal sector governmental, non-profit schemes in Gujarat. PhD Thesis
in Africa: design features, risk protection and resource mobiliz- submitted to the University of London, London School of
ation. Commission on Macroeconomics and Health Working Hygiene and Tropical Medicine.
Paper Series, Working Group 3, Paper 1. Washington, DC: Ranson K, Bennett S. 2002. How can central governments help
World Bank. further social goals through microinsurance? In: Dror DM,
Atim CB, Sock M. 2000. An external evaluation of the Nkoranza Preker AS (eds). Social reinsurance: a new approach to sustain-
community financing health insurance scheme, Ghana. Techni- ing community health financing. Geneva: ILO, and Washington,
cal Report No. 50. Bethesda, MD: Partnerships for Health DC: World Bank.
Reform (PHR). Reinhardt U. 1990. The health system of the United States: lessons
Atim CB, Diop FP, Ette J et al. 1998. The contribution of mutual for other countries. Unpublished paper delivered at the Inter-
health organizations to financing, delivery, and access in health national Seminar on Health Financing and Health Insurance in
care in West and Central Africa: Summaries and case studies in Selected Countries in Asia, Bali.
2 czh018 (jr/d) 1/4/04 12:23 pm Page 158

158 Sara Bennett

Schneider P, Diop F. 2002. Impact of prepayment pilot on health care this paper and made extremely insightful and helpful comments.
utilization and financing in Rwanda: findings from final Chris Atim, Grace Chee and Kent Ranson also provided useful
household survey. Partners for Health Reformplus (PHRplus) information about particular CBHI schemes. Preparation of this
TE002. Bethesda, MD: Abt Associates. paper was supported by the Partners for Health Reformplus
Shirima RM. 1996. The Community Health Fund in Tanzania. In: (PHRplus) Project. This was made possible through support
Beattie A, Doherty J, Gilson L, Lambo E, Shaw P (eds). Papers provided by the United States Agency for International Develop-
from an EDI Health Policy Seminar held in Johannesburg, ment (USAID) under Prime Contract No. HRN-C-00–00–00019–00
South Africa, June 1996. Washington, DC: World Bank. awarded to Abt Associates, Inc. The opinions expressed herein are
Soderlund N, Khosa S. 1997. The potential role of risk equalization the author’s and do not necessarily reflect the views of Abt Associ-
mechanisms in health insurance: the case of South Africa. ates, Inc. or USAID.
Health Policy and Planning 12: 341–53.
Sullivan K. 2001. On the “efficiency” of managed care plans. Inter-
national Journal of Health Services 31: 55–65.
Supachutikul A. 1996. Situation Analysis on health insurance and Biography
future development Bangkok: Health Systems Research Insti- Sara Bennett, Ph.D., is the Senior Research Advisor for the Partners
tute. for Health Reformplus Project, a USAID-funded project operated
Varophan P. 1992. Reimbursement and appropriateness of treat-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/heapol/article/19/3/147/774121 by guest on 15 December 2021


by Abt Associates. She also holds a part-time position as lecturer on
ment under the Workmen’s Compensation Scheme. Thesis for the Health Economics and Financing Programme, London School
the degree of Master of Economics, Chulalongkorn University, of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine. Sara has a Ph.D. in health econ-
Bangkok (in Thai). omics from the London School of Economics and Political Science.
WHO. 2001. Macroeconomics and Health: Investing in health for She has previously researched and written widely on health care
economic development. Report of the Commission on Macro- financing issues, including community-based health insurance and
economics and Health. Geneva: World Health Organization. aspects of health sector reform. Sara has worked long-term in
Lesotho, Zambia, Thailand and the Republic of Georgia.
Acknowledgements Correspondence: Dr Sara Bennett, Abt Associates Inc., 4800 Mont-
The author would like to thank Joe Kutzin, Charlotte Leighton, gomery Lane, Suite 600, Bethesda, MD 20814, USA. Tel: +1 301–347
Mary Paterson and Kent Ranson, all of whom read earlier drafts of 5390, fax: +1 301–913–0562, email: sara_bennett@abtassoc.com

You might also like