You are on page 1of 4

The World Bank

September

PREMnotes
2000
number 42

Economic Policy

Measuring growth in total factor


productivity
Estimating growth in total factor productivity is difficult, but it is essential for
assessing countries’ past and potential economic performance.
Gains in total factor productivity (TFP), (1) Y = A (K α H 1 – α )γ,
reflecting more efficient use of inputs, have
long been recognized as an important where A is TFP, γ measures the extent of
source of improvements in income and returns to scale, and α measures the Gains in total
welfare. Cross-country differences in income importance of physical capital in output.
levels and growth rates are mostly due to If γ = 1 (γ > 1) (γ < 1), there are constant factor productivity
differences in productivity (Klenow and (increasing) (decreasing) returns to scale.
Rodriguez-Clare 1997; Easterly and Levine By expressing equation 1 in growth rates drive gains in
2000). and rearranging the variables, TFP growth
Measuring TFP is therefore important in can be written as growth in output less a income and growth
assessing countries’ past and potential weighted average of growth in inputs:
economic performance. But it is also
difficult, for two reasons. Fairly innocuous (2) gA = gY – γ [α gK + (1 – α) gH ],
differences in assumptions can lead to very
different estimates of TFP growth. And the where gX is the growth rate of variable X.
interpretation of measured TFP growth can Given data on the growth rates of Y, K, and
be problematic when such growth reflects H and information on the parameters of
factors other than purely technical change— the production function, we can obtain
such as increasing returns to scale, markups estimates of productivity growth as the
due to imperfect competition, or gains from difference between output growth and a
sectoral reallocations. weighted average of growth in inputs. This
This note discusses some of these diffi- note considers these two ingredients and
culties using data for the Republic of Korea interprets the results.
in 1960–97 for illustration. An Excel work-
sheet is available to readers who wish to repro- The data matter
duce the exercises described here for other While real GDP growth rates are easy to
countries; see PREMnotes or the Growth obtain, measuring the growth rates of K and
Thematic Group Web site under PREMnet. H is more difficult. In most cases physical
The starting point for estimating TFP capital is measured using the perpetual
is a production function that represents inventory method, which uses an estimate
how inputs are combined to produce of the capital stock in a base year,
output. For example, suppose that GDP (Y) assumptions on depreciation, and the flow
is produced using two factors, physical of new investment. But measured growth
capital (K) and human-capital-adjusted rates of capital stock—and thus estimates
labor input (H), using a Cobb-Douglas of TFP growth—can be very sensitive to
production function: assumptions about initial stocks and

from the development economics vice presidency and pover ty reduction and economic management n e t w o r k
Table 1 Estimates of TFP growth percent a year. Such differences can have
are sensitive to assumptions about substantial effects on estimated productivity.
the production function (percent)
Input and output gro w t h
The production function matters
Average annual growth in Korea, 1960–97 With data on Y, K, and H, we now require
Y K H only information on the parameters of the
8.5 11.6 4.9 production function to estimate productivity
growth. Because these parameters are not
Sensitivity of TFP growth estimates 1
directly observable, it is common to make
Average annual TFP growth in Korea, 1960–97
α = 0.3 α = 0.4 α = 0.5 some assumptions.
γ = 1.0 1.6 0.9 0.3 For a constant returns to scale
γ = 1.2 0.2 –0.6 –1.4 production function (γ = 1), it is common
Small differences γ = 0.8 3.0 2.4 1.9 to assume values of α between 0.3 and 0.5.
Depending on the observed growth rates
Sensitivity of TFP growth estimates 2
in assumptions Average annual TFP growth in Korea, 1960–97
of physical and human capital, the value
σ = 0.8 σ = 1.0 σ = 1.2 chosen can matter a lot for estimates of TFP
can lead to big α = 0.3 3.3 1.6 –0.7 growth. The top panel of table 1 reports
average annual growth rates of Y, K, and H
differences in in Korea in 1960–97. The first row in the
depreciation rates, and it is important to middle panel shows how TFP growth rates
estimates of check the robustness of conclusions on TFP change as the value of α is increased from
growth against small changes in these 0.3 (resulting in TFP growth of 1.6 percent
TFP growth assumptions (see Pritchett 1996). a year) to 0.5 (resulting in TFP growth of
The production function also depends just 0.3 percent a year). By increasing α, we
on human-capital-adjusted labor input (H), are increasing the weight on the fastest-
which is a way of summarizing the growing factor of production in equation
contribution of “brains” (education) and 2, physical capital, resulting in lower
“brawn” (the size of the labor force) to labor estimated TFP growth.
input. One way to do this is to adjust the Estimates of TFP growth are also very
number of workers for their years of sensitive to assumptions about the degree
schooling (S) by assuming that each of scale economies. The remaining rows of
additional year raises workers’ productivity the middle panel fall with increasing returns
by a given percentage. Various estimates to scale, because some of the increase in
suggest that, defined in this way, the returns output previously attributed to productivity
to education are about 10 percent. The improvements is instead attributed to scale
number of workers is the product of the economies. In some cases the distinction
working-age population (L) and the between the two may be relevant. If, for
participation rate (P). Thus we can express: example, there are increasing returns to
scale at low levels of development, and
(3) H = L P e 0.1S decreasing returns to scale at high levels of
development, the distinction would be
How important is it to measure labor important in identifying how much of
input in this way rather than simply as measured TFP growth is likely to be
population? In many countries it can be very sustained over the long run.
important. In Korea the combined effect of So far we have assumed that the
growth in the working-age population, in parameters of the production function do
participation rates, and in average education not change over time. But they might. If,
levels increased the human-capital-adjusted for example, the production function is of
labor force by about 5 percent a year the constant elasticity of substitution (CES)
between 1960 and 1997—almost three times type with an elasticity different from 1, the
as fast as the growth in population of 1.6 weight on capital in equation 1 can change

PREMnote 42 September 2000


over time, depending on the size of the conclusion is misguided, because it ignores
elasticity of substitution and the rate at the fact that decisions to invest in physical
which K grows relative to H. This effect is and human capital are themselves likely to
shown in the bottom panel of table 1 for depend on TFP growth. A simple ratio
some plausible values of the elasticity of ignores the portion of growth in inputs
substitution between physical and human induced by productivity growth, which
capital (σ). should also be attributed to TFP growth.
Finally, it is worth noting that estimates A better way of assessing the importance
of TFP growth constructed in this way can of TFP growth is to ask the following
track output growth closely—and so may question: if output growth is above average,
not be very informative—because they how much of this additional growth can
subtract growth of measured physical and be attributed to TFP growth? One way to
human capital (which by construction are answer this question is to consider the The endogeneity of
quite smooth) from output growth (which covariance between productivity growth and
typically is not). Thus estimates of the output growth divided by the variance of factor inputs should
variation in TFP growth over time can be output growth (see Klenow and Rodriguez-
quite sensitive to the period for which they Clare 1997). Because this calculation reflects be considered when
are calculated, and the robustness of the TFP-induced increases in inputs, rather than
results to the sample period should be assuming inputs to be exogenous, it gives assessing the
checked carefully. a more accurate picture of the role of TFP
growth in the growth process. In Korea the importance of
The interpretation matters share of growth attributable to productivity
What do these estimates of TFP growth growth jumps from the naive estimate of 18 TFP growth
actually measure? At the firm level it is fairly percent to more than 80 percent. While the
straightforward to equate gA with technical second figure may be high, it illustrates the
progress. At the aggregate level it is less clear. importance of taking into account the
If resources shift from less productive to endogeneity of factor inputs when assessing
more productive firms, perhaps as a result the importance of TFP growth.
of economic reforms or if more productive
firms simply grow faster, aggregate TFP Where do we go from here?
growth may be observed even in the absence Estimated TFP growth is very sensitive to
of technical progress at the firm level. assumptions about the underlying
Although we may also be interested in parameters in the production function.
these other effects, gA measures more than Thus a natural step is to try to estimate the
just the fundamental improvements in production function directly. There are two
technology that underpin growth in the ways to do so. One is to assume that the
long run. Distinguishing between these economy in question is characterized by
different sources of TFP growth is important constant returns to scale (γ = 1) and perfect
because there are likely to be natural limits competition. Then it is possible to view the
to the gains from structural change once parameter α as 1 minus the share of wages
resources have been reallocated to the most in value added (see Young 1995 and Hsieh
efficient sectors. 1999). But in many developing countries
What can be said of TFP growth relative it seems implausible to assume constant
to output growth? It is often asserted that returns to scale and perfect competition—
TFP growth “accounts for” a certain fraction and we have already seen how sensitive
of growth. For example, given output estimates of productivity growth are to
growth of 8.2 percent in Korea in 1960–97, assumptions on constant returns to scale.
and estimated TFP growth of 1.4 percent, Moreover, reliable data on wages are often
one might think that TFP growth accounted not available for the economy as a whole.
for just 18 percent of output growth (1.4 A second approach is to try to estimate
percent divided by 8.2 percent). But this the production function econometrically—

PREMnote 42 September 2000


for example, by regressing output growth “It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized
on input growth (see Basu and Fernald Facts and Growth Models.” World Bank,
1995). While this approach does not require Washington, D.C.
assumptions of constant returns and perfect Hsieh, Chang-Tai. 1999. “Productivity
competition, the problem of inputs Growth and Factor Prices in East Asia.”
responding endogenously to TFP growth American Economic Review 89 (2): 133–38.
returns to the fore. In the econometric Klenow, Peter, and Andres Rodriguez-Clare.
approach the residual in the regression is 1997. “The Neoclassical Revival in Growth
interpreted as TFP growth. But we have Economics: Has it Gone Too Far?” NBER
already seen that the residual is correlated Macroeconomics Annual 12: 73–103.
with growth in inputs, the right-hand Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and
variables in the regression. Thus ordinary David Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the
An econometric least squares estimation will be invalid and Empirics of Economic Growth.” Quarterly
it becomes necessary to find good Journal of Economics 107: 407–37.
approach to instrumental variables—a difficult task. Pritchett, Lant. 1996. “Mind Your P’s and
But the econometric approach has its Q’s: The Cost of Public Investment Is Not
estimating the rewards. Given appropriate data and the Value of Public Capital.” Policy
instrumental variables techniques, it is Research Working Paper 1660. World
production function possible to retrieve estimates not only of Bank, Washington, D.C.
TFP growth but also of the extent of scale World Bank. 1999. “Republic of Korea:
can shed light economies and deviations from perfect Establishing a New Foundation for
competition. These can shed light on Sustained Growth.” Report 19595-KO.
on important important policy issues that are as Washington, D.C.
interesting as TFP growth. In the recent Young, Alwyn. 1995. “The Tyranny of Num-
policy issues Korea Economic Report (World Bank bers: Confronting the Statistical Realities
1999), for instance, the econometric of the East Asian Growth Experience.”
approach is used to examine questions such Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 641–80.
as the extent to which key Korean
manufacturing sectors had been exposed
to competition prior to the East Asian crisis, This note was written by Swati R. Ghosh (Senior
and whether less competition was associated Economist, PREM Unit, East Asia and Pacific
with lower productivity growth. Region) and Aart Kraay (Senior Economist,
Development Economics Research Group), draw-
Further reading ing on work done for the Korea Economic Report
Basu, Susanto, and John Fernald. 1995. “Are (World Bank 1999).
Apparent Productivity Spillovers A If you are interested in similar topics, consider
Figment of Specification Error?” Journal joining the Growth Thematic Group. Contact
of Monetary Economics 36 (1): 165–88. Sandeep Mahajan (x80287) or click on Thematic
Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2000. Groups on PREMnet.

This note series is intended to summarize good practice and key policy find-
ings on PREM-related topics. The views expressed in these notes are those of
the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the World Bank. PREM-
notes are distributed widely to Bank staff and are also available on the PREM
website (http://prem). If you are interested in writing a PREMnote, email your
idea to Sarah Nedolast. For additional copies of this PREMnote please contact
the PREM Advisory Service at x87736.

Prepared for World Bank staff

You might also like