You are on page 1of 16

International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

International Review of Law & Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/irle

Resolution of corporate insolvency during COVID-19 pandemic. Evidence


from France ]]
]]]]]]
]]


Nicolae Stef a, , Jean-Joachim Bissieux b
a
CEREN EA 7477, Burgundy School of Business, Université Bourgogne Franche-Comté, Department of Accounting, Finance & Law, Dijon, France
b
Maître Jean-Joachim BISSIEUX Mandataire Judiciaire, 2B avenue de Marbotte Immeuble "Marbotte Plaza", BP 57970, 21079 Dijon, France

a r t i cl e i nfo a bstr ac t

Article history: We investigate how the lockdown enforcement by French authorities is associated with the resolution of
Received 3 September 2021 corporate insolvency. In this sense, we make a distinction between four legal procedures, namely the
Received in revised form 30 January 2022 amicable liquidation (out-of-court exit), the judicial liquidation (court-driven exit), the restructuring pro­
Accepted 1 March 2022
cedure available to non-defaulted firms, and the restructuring procedure available to defaulted firms. Using
Available online 3 March 2022
a sample of 3488 non-listed and non-financial French firms, our estimates yield three major findings. First,
the likelihood of judicial liquidation increased after the lifting of the quarantines compared to the pre-
JEL Classification:
G33 H12 pandemic period. Second, the non-defaulted firms had a higher likelihood to reorganize in court during the
second lockdown. Third, the lifting of the first lockdown led to a decrease in the probability of restructuring
Keywords: the assets of defaulted firms. Although the main objective of the lockdown was to limit spread of the virus,
Covid-19 its enforcement has not encouraged the use of the out-of-court exit path.
Lockdown © 2022 The Author(s). Published by Elsevier Inc.
Bankruptcy CC_BY_4.0
Reorganization
Liquidation
Firm

1. Introduction Surprisingly, bankruptcies appeared to slow down in some


countries during the lockdown period. According to the United
High levels of COVID-19 infection obliged local authorities across Kingdom’s (UK) Insolvency Service, the daily number of compulsory
the world to impose social distancing and quarantine measures. As liquidations decreased by 80% in May 2020 compared with the
firms were temporarily confronted with low or nonexistent demand, prelockdown period of March 2020. Additionally, 944 cases of cor­
the risk of mass bankruptcies overshadowed entire economies. porate insolvencies were reported in May 2020 in England and
Demmou et al.’s (2021) analysis on OECD (Organisation for Wales, which was 30% less than those in the same month of the
Economic Co-operation and Development) countries indicated a previous year. The American Bankruptcy Institute also confirms an
decline in firms’ profits ranging from 40% to 50% as a result of the average decrease of 25.1% in business filings for the period from
COVID-19 shock. Most notably, it was predicted that an expected April 2020 to June 2020 compared with those during the same
percentage of 7–9% of viable firms would be subject to financial period in 2019. The first lockdown was enforced in France from
distress with a negative book value on equity, whereas around one- March 17, 2020, to May 10, 2020, during which French business in­
third of firms would be unable to cover interest expenses (Demmou solvencies decreased by 63% in April 2020 compared with those in
et al., 2021). In the context of a not only a 15% drop in the volume of February 2020, while the average decrease over the year was 19.1%
goods and services traded but also an estimated decrease of 3.3% of for April 2020 (Banque de France). How were such reductions pos­
the global gross domestic product, the insurance company Euler sible? Following the explanations of the UK’s Insolvency Service,
Hermes predicted a strong global wave of bankruptcies due to the bankruptcy institutions were forced to reduce capacity to establish
pandemic in May 2020 with an expected rise of bankruptcies by 25% new work conditions to safeguard their employees’ health.
in United States and 19% in Europe. Moreover, documents provided by British insolvency practitioners
suffered from long delays. Federal courts in the United States and
French commercial courts were temporarily closed to the general

Corresponding author. public, and their activities were managed through online services.
E-mail addresses: nicolae.stef@bsb-education.com (N. Stef), On a different note, Castelliano et al. (2021) emphasized that the
jeanjoachim.bissieux@etudebissieux.com (J.-J. Bissieux).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irle.2022.106063
0144-8188/© 2022 The Author(s). Published by Elsevier Inc.
CC_BY_4.0
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

pandemic also affected the labor courts leading to a considerable 2. Resolution of corporate insolvency and the pandemic crisis
decrease in the clearance rate and an increase in court backlogs.
Despite these impediments, some firms still managed to leave the 2.1. Insolvency framework of France
market during the lockdown and post-lockdown periods, as the
accumulation of debt and decreases in liquidity led to a rise in im­ French bankruptcy code includes an array of procedures aimed at
mediate liabilities and decrease in available assets, raising the pay­ addressing corporate financial failure.1 The use of an insolvency
ment default risk. proceeding depends on the capacity of the debtor (firm) to honor its
Some studies have also raised the potential issue of increased financial obligations. A firm that is unable to meet its commitments
bankruptcies that could be caused by the health crisis (Carletti et al., within a period of 45 days is considered to be in suspension of
2020; Demary, 2021; Didier et al., 2021; Liu et al., 2021). Battiston payment. Consequently, the debtor can settle the creditors’ claims
et al. (2007) asserted that a bankruptcy boom is favored by long through one of the two procedures, namely, judicial liquidation or
delayed payments (trade credits) and additional costs generated by the redressement judiciaire (judicial restructuring) procedure. The
failures in supply. Similarly, Jacobson and Von Schedvin (2015) ar­ path of judicial liquidation is pronounced by the Commercial Court
gued that trade debtor failures increase the bankruptcy risk of trade or Judicial Court, depending on the location of business activity.
creditors, leading to an avalanche of corporate failures. Such ele­ Initiating this procedure requires not only the firm’s payment de­
ments can be found in the context of COVID-19. Hence, effectively fault but also the impossibility to restore the financial health of the
addressing corporate insolvency during the pandemic periods is a business through a restructuring procedure. A bankruptcy practi­
question of considerable importance in bankruptcy literature. Our tioner is appointed by the competent court to terminate the firm’s
study aims to answer that question by shedding light on how lock­ activity by selling its assets to settle the creditors’ claims. The closing
down measures correlate with firms’ institutional path to the re­ of judicial liquidation is pronounced by the court when liabilities are
solution of insolvency. In this sense, we investigate the French no longer due, the creditors’ claims are fully satisfied, or the con­
insolvency framework that provides multiple legal procedures, such tinuation of the procedure is prevented by a lack of assets.
as amicable liquidation (out-of-court exit); judicial liquidation Conversely, the redressement judiciaire procedure is a re­
(court-driven exit), a reorganization procedure for non-defaulted structuring tool, including three main objectives, which are the
firms (sauvegarde); and a restructuring procedure for firms in pay­ debtors’ survival, preservation of employment, and creditors’ re­
ment default (redressement judiciaire). Using a sample of 3488 imbursement. When the procedure is triggered, the debtor is subject
nonfinancial firms, we examine the consequences of the two quar­ to an observation period, which cannot exceed 18 months, during
antines enforced by French public authorities in 2020 on the firms’ which the debtor and administrator appointed by the court must
likelihood to engage in one of these institutional paths. identify solutions for achieving the three main objectives. According
Corporate failure is driven by various factors ranging from fi­ to Blazy et al. (2013), the observation period grants a stay of claims,
nancial features (Lennox, 1999) to subcontracting relationships (Doi, during which managers can maintain their positions with the help of
1999), business maturity (Pérez et al., 2004), macroeconomic in­ the administrator. If the firm’s restructuring is doomed to fail, the
stability (Bhattacharjee et al., 2009), debt cost (Bottazzi et al., 2011), court can convert the redressement judiciaire procedure into a judi­
founders’ experience (DeTienne and Cardon, 2012), directors’ in­ cial liquidation.
dependence (Hsu and Wu, 2014), firm-specific uncertainty (Byrne The French bankruptcy code also provides procedures to firms
et al., 2016), new firm formation (Stef and Jabeur, 2018; Jabeur et al., that are not confronted with a default of payment. In this sense,
2021), difficulty of firing (Stef, 2018), legal form (Iwasaki and Kim, some bankruptcy codes can rely upon different liquidation proce­
2020), legal reform (Bose et al., 2021), and institutional quality (Stef, dures. For instance, the insolvency code of the UK provides three
2021). A detailed typology of the causes of bankruptcy was initially types of procedures, including compulsory liquidation, the creditors’
developed by Blazy et al. (2013), proposing seven types of default voluntary liquidation, and members’ voluntary liquidation (Blazy
causes, including strategy, production, finance, management, out­ et al., 2013). The first two procedures can be enforced when a debtor
lets, accident, and external environment. Their analysis demon­ is unable to fully repay debts, while the last procedure can be trig­
strated that the major causes of corporate bankruptcy in France and gered when shareholders holding sufficient assets are willing to
the UK are primarily poor quality products, high price strategy, and/ dissolve their own firms to cover the creditors’ claims. Similarly, the
or disappearance of customers (outlets). In the case of legal re­ French bankruptcy system relies on a liquidation procedure known
structuring, external environment appeared to be the second most as amicable liquidation. The procedure results from a voluntary
frequent cause of firms defaulting. Similarly, Blazy and Stef (2020) decision made by the owners (shareholders), who must vote for the
reported the impact of external environment as one of the principal early dissolution of the company at an extraordinary general
causes of bankruptcy in Hungary, Poland, and Romania. In their in­ meeting. It can be triggered as long as the interests of a firm’s
vestigation, causes related to the external environment included creditors are not harmed. Therefore, the assets’ values must cover
exchange rate fluctuations, increase in competition, or credit crunch the liabilities so that creditors are fully reimbursed at the end of the
periods, as well as events of force majeure (e.g., war, political crisis, or procedure. After establishing an inventory, the liquidator, who is
natural catastrophe). A new component of firms’ external environ­ appointed by the owners, proceeds to sell the assets and then dis­
ment is the global spread of COVID-19. In this framework, our study charge the debts. The primary objective is not to pay off creditors but
will address the relevance of public health lockdown measures as to put an end to a firm’s operations by releasing its residual assets.
determinants of firms’ failure for the first time. This procedure can be a tool for restructuring companies, as the
We organized the remainder of our study into the following four remaining assets can be reinvested, reallocated to new activities, or
sections. Section 2 provides an overview of France-specific institu­ redistributed to the partners; however, if the proceeds from selling a
tional paths to insolvency resolution (subsection 2.1), presents the firm’s assets are not sufficient to cover the liabilities and creditors
specificities of the French lockdown, discusses the incentives for are unwilling to accept a lower reimbursement, a firm must follow
firms to leave the market during the pandemic crisis (subsection the path of a court-driven exit (Ponikvar et al., 2018).
2.2), and examines the attractiveness of these paths for (non)de­
faulted firms confronted with the COVID-19 pandemic (subsection
2.3). Data and the empirical analysis are presented in Sections 3 and
4, respectively. The final section highlights and discusses the major 1
The legal framework of bankruptcy procedures is covered by book No. 6 of the
results of our study. French commercial code.

2
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

incentives to file for a liquidation procedure. According to the French


commercial code, a cessation of payments must be declared to the
court within a period of 45 days that will decide the settlement
procedure of a firm’s debt. In the context of COVID-19, a new order
was enacted by the French government that (1) granted the right to
file for bankruptcy only to debtors, (2) permitted an assessment of
the cessation based on firm’s financial health as reported on March
Fig. 1. Institutional paths to resolution of inslovency. 12, 2020—just four days before the first lockdown start date, and (3)
encouraged the use of preventive bankruptcy procedures by firms
facing payment cessation after March 12.4 Hence, the new govern­
Nevertheless, firms that are not subject to payment suspension mental order provided debtors the opportunity to decide when to
but to financial difficulties can initiate a restructuring procedure exit during the periods of lockdown and post-lockdown. In this new
known as sauvegarde procedure.2 As in the case of redressement ju­ context, firms that engaged in judicial liquidation procedures were
diciaire, the procedure aims to restore the firm’s financial health and probably businesses with extremely low chances of financial re­
preserve employment; however, the maximum length of the ob­ covery; however, it can also be speculated that lockdown established
servation period is 12 months and the manager that retains their a context that encouraged debt renegotiation, leading to the out-of-
position must propose a restructuring plan. The financial measures court exit or reorganization path. Our research seeks to explore this
included in the plan must be accepted by the creditors through framework for the first time in bankruptcy literature by examining
voting. If the firm’s cessation of payment occurs during the execu­ the association between lockdown enforcement and the likelihood
tion of the plan, the court can convert the sauvegarde procedure into of triggering a bankruptcy procedure.
either a judicial liquidation or redressement judiciaire procedure.
Fig. 1 presents an overview of a firm’s institutional path to in­
2.2.2. Global strategies to face the pandemic crisis
solvency resolution.
One of the most severe consequences of the COVID-19 pandemic
was the imposition of lockdowns, representing a public health
2.2. Failure risk and the COVID-19 pandemic strategy aimed at hampering the virus spread. During lockdowns,
individuals are subject to self-isolation and travel restrictions, while
2.2.1. Specificities of the French lockdown firms are forced to temporarily close. Such an environment limits
Following the rise of COVID-19 infections at the beginning of consumption, as individuals tend to pursue their basic needs, i.e.,
2020, the French government enforced its first lockdown on March food and health, to the detriment of other secondary needs.
17, 2020, which lasted until May 5, 2020. Unfortunately, lifting the Consequently, firms need to react and adapt to the new market
first lockdown did not inhibit the spread of the virus, leading to a conditions emerging from the viral contagion. In this sense, Wenzel
second lockdown from October 30, 2020, to December 14, 2020. et al. (2020) identified four potential strategic responses of firms to
Those two lockdowns imposed two major restrictions. First, in­ the current crisis, namely, retrenchment by managing reductions in
dividuals were obliged to follow social distancing rules that limited costs and assets, persevering with measures to maintain business
movement outside of their homes. Exceptions to these rules were activities, innovating based on strategic renewal, and exit through
applied for those seeking to go to work, to a medical appointment, to the discontinuation of operational activities. Failures in the first
purchase goods of basic necessity, to walk near their homes for an three responses can lead to a firm’s dissolution. Moreover, failure
hour, or to attend a judicial summon. Second, businesses that were risk might increase during a longer period of lockdown, which
not essential to the functioning of the national economy were forced completely inhibits a firm’s sales as customers are confronted with
to temporarily close. The only entities that remained opened were self-isolation. In this sense, Carletti et al. (2020) examined the po­
food shops, essential public institutions, banks, pharmacies, and gas tential financial impact of lockdown duration using a sample of
stations. 80,972 Italian firms. Not surprisingly, their empirical analysis fore­
These restrictions placed strong pressure on firms’ capacity to casted that a three-month lockdown would lead to an aggregate
remunerate employees and to honor fiscal obligations. yearly drop in profits, amounting to 10% of the national GDP and to
Consequently, the French government decided to provide some the financial distress of 17% of the sample firms.
public support to the private sector.3 First, firms subject to financial According to Kraus et al. (2020), the strategic responses of family
difficulties had the option to defer the payment of social contribu­ firms to the COVID-19 crisis were triggered by the following two
tions and direct taxes. Second, a public program of state guaranteed main motivations: safeguarding liquidity and improving the firm’s
loans, aimed to strengthen the liquidity of firms, was launched at the long-term survival. The second motivation can be accomplished if
beginning of the first lockdown. This device allowed all firms, except the firm remains on the market; therefore, owners’ key motivation
for real estate and financial firms, to benefit from a state-guaranteed seems to be maintaining a degree of liquidity that can allow for the
loan amounting to 3 months of 2019 turnover, or two years of payroll coverage of their fixed costs at the least. In this sense, Didier et al.
for innovative or young firms. These loans did not require a re­ (2021) suggested the term hibernation to describe the use of a bare
imbursement in the first year. Third, firms confronted with a re­ minimum amount of cash by firms facing social distancing measures
duction in activity could apply for a program addressing long-term and pandemic lockdown. Such cash should be used to adjust op­
partial activity that granted an allowance to employees for their erational activities and freeze a firm’s relationship with stake­
nonworking hours. holders. However, the hibernation period may depend on liquidities
In the context of the pandemic, a short-term bankruptcy reform that a firm was holding prior to the enforcement of a national
was also adopted by the French authorities, which impacted owners’ quarantine.
Some evidence of COVID-19′s impact on liquidity was presented
by De Vito and Gómez (2020). Using a sample of 14,245 listed firms
2
The French law also proposes two procedures to negotiate the debt in a con­
fidential and amicable manner under the guidance of a trustee appointed by the
4
Commercial Court, i.e., the conciliation procedure and mandat ad hoc procedure. According to the order number 2020–341 of March 27, 2020, these provisions
3
We identified these public measures from press releases provided by the French remained in force until August 24, 2020. A more detailed analysis of this govern­
Ministry of Finance Economics and Revival. mental order is provided by Lemercier and Mercier (2020).

3
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

from 26 countries, their empirical analysis indicates that a drop in McKnight (2017) noted that natural disasters open business oppor­
sales by 50% and 75% for firms with partial flexibility would lead to tunities that can encourage entrepreneurs to create value. Never­
an average increase of short-term liabilities ranging from 216.01% to theless, amicable liquidation requires that the firm is not confronted
779.26%, respectively. Moreover, a larger contraction in demand with a payment default and that all creditors are satisfied with the
would render 10% of firms illiquid within 6 months. Miyakawa et al. amount of their reimbursement. The achievement of these two
(2021) examined the exit rate of Japanese firms under several as­ conditions seems to be hampered by the liquidity crisis induced by
sumptions. First, firm exits potentially increased by 20% compared COVID-19. Nonfinancial businesses largely drew funds from bank
with the pre-pandemic period, assuming that the temporary re­ credit lines, anticipating disruptions in cash flow and an extreme
duction in sales was anticipated by firms. Second, the increase in exit deterioration of funding conditions (Li et al., 2020). Guerini et al.
rates amounts to almost 110% if sales reduction fully impacted firms’ (2020) suggested that the lockdown enforcement produced an un­
expectations for future sales. As pointed out by Famiglietti and precedented increase in the share of illiquid firms, from 3.8% to al­
Leibovici (2020), the virus spread harmed firms’ revenues and most 10%, based on a sample of about one million French
tightened access to external finance; hence, firms with high levels of nonfinancial companies. Therefore, the pandemic crisis is con­
cash or fluid access to funding should more easily cover large ex­ jectured to have reduced firms’ capacity to settle their debts in full in
penditures related to wages and overhead costs. Famiglietti and order to pursue the path of amicable liquidation, favoring the use of
Leibovici (2020) also argue that firms with less liquidity and more the court-driven exit. A higher likelihood of judicial liquidation is ex­
debt are more prone to bankruptcy given the inability to meet short- pected during the pandemic periods, captured either by the lockdown or
term financial obligations and limited access to external finance. post-lockdown periods.
Overall, the pandemic crisis has put pressure on firms’ capacity to However, Brown (1989) argued that a set of mutually advanta­
use internal resources and attract additional funds. Such behavior is geous reorganization plans are available to firms facing financial
primarily explained by the drop in demand due to the state of distress. The prospect of business reorganization should be more
quarantine and firms’ operational functioning in the stage of hi­ attractive to stakeholders when the liquidation of assets generates
bernation. Following Famiglietti and Leibovici (2020), the exit path high losses and creditors can receive a low degree of reimbursement.
as a response to COVID-19 outbreak should have been followed by In the context of the pandemic, lockdowns imposed a temporary
firms holding less liquidity and/or more debt prior to lockdown shutdown of business activities and restrictions on consumers’ be­
enforcement. In the context of the COVID-19 pandemic, Amankwah- havior. Didier (2021) suggested that firms’ survival could be favored
Amoah et al. (2021) argued that business failure is more likely for by hibernation, characterized as the adjustment of operational ac­
firms that lack the capacity to quickly alter their business model in tivities to a reduced capacity. Because firms depend on key re­
favor of a new routine that facilitates adaptation to the practice of lationships with some stakeholders (employees, customers, local
social distancing and adherence to governments’ new directives. authorities, and creditors), business survival also requires that all of
Moreover, their study asserts that the risk of corporate failure is these stakeholders share the burden of the firm’s reduced activity
likely to increase as authorities cannot rely upon the best practices until the pandemic is overcome. Similarly, Stef (2015) showed that a
to guide policy interventions during the pandemic. If such failure is firm’s survival is favored by plans that share the costs of re­
imminent, the question of which institutional path a firm should organization between the debtor and creditors.
follow arises. In this situation, why should reorganization be an attractive legal
path during the pandemic? The French restructuring procedures
2.3. How can insolvency be resolved in a pandemic? (sauvegarde and redressement judiciaire) can be useful mechanisms
to support a firm’s hibernation, during which the debtor, along with
As the French government temporarily granted debtors the ex­ the creditors and bankruptcy administrator, can identify efficient
clusive right to trigger judicial liquidation during the pandemic, a solutions to adapt business operations to the new environment.
relevant question is which insolvency resolution path is suitable for According to Le and Phi (2021), a hibernation strategy that includes
firms facing financial difficulties. White (1980) noted that the con­ the minimization of operations and a reduction in salaries should be
tinuation of business activity should be encouraged when the pre­ followed by a recovery phase addressing business innovation and
sent value of future earnings resulting from a firm’s survival is policies aimed at recovering customers. However, the consensus
higher than the liquidation value of assets. However, the COVID-19 needed for reorganization can be hampered by conflicts between
crisis left firms with very limited cash reserves and induced severe unsecured creditors and well-secured creditors (Bergström et al.,
losses to shareholders that would act as residual claimants of a firm’s 2002). A collateral value closer to the value of the claim can en­
assets in case of bankruptcy (Liu et al., 2021). Moreover, Altig et al. courage some creditors to oppose the firm’s reorganization. Such
(2020) argued that the COVID-19 crisis led to massive uncertainty conflicts are overcome by the French bankruptcy code because
across multiple considerations, such as the duration of social dis­ creditors only vote for the approval of the restructuring plan, while
tancing, changes in consumer spending patterns, the speed of eco­ the relevant court can enforce the plan or a modified version of the
nomic recovery, travel restrictions, and the impact on business plan, even when creditors initially reject the plan (Blazy and
formation. Hence, the pandemic is assumed to have diminished the Chopard, 2012). Thus, the content of the plan must convince only the
value of future earnings, biasing the path of a financially distressed judge for a firm to legally restructure its activities. Overall, a higher
firm toward potential liquidation. likelihood of firms’ restructuring through sauvegarde or redressement
In the landscape of French law, amicable liquidation is an exit judiciaire procedures can be expected during the pandemic periods.
path subject to the shareholders’ discretion, whereas initiating ju­ Firms have also benefited from public measures adopted by the
dicial liquidation addresses the debtor’s legal obligation, resulting French government during the pandemic, including addressing the
from a severe shortage of assets. In the shadow of the pandemic deferment of social contributions, state-guaranteed loans, and wage
crisis, the use of amicable liquidation can allow the formation of new compensations due to activity reductions. According to the OECD
firms, as existing managers and partners may be able to allocate the (2021), countries that relied more on financial subsidies and tem­
liquidation surplus generated by the procedure to an activity that porary changes than insolvency procedures were able to reduce the
they plan to conduct in the postcrisis period. Linnenluecke and use of bankruptcy at national levels. As argued by Cros et al. (2020),

4
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

the public measures adopted by the French state can explain the the national weights would lead to the use of 65 firms instead of
slowdown of bankruptcy filings by small- and medium-sized en­ 224 firms.
terprises, which decreased by 29% by mid-November 2020 com­ Fig. 2 presents the distribution of our sample according to four
pared with those in 2019. By providing financial protection to firms major pandemic periods that were enforced by French public au­
and employees, the public policies might have diminished the at­ thorities, namely, the period of the first lockdown (First Lockdown),
tractiveness of bankruptcy procedures that are recognized to have a the period between the first and second lockdown (First Post-lock­
higher degree of debtor friendliness (Blazy et al., 2018). Moreover, down), the period of the second lockdown (Second Lockdown), and
policy intervention that encourages firms’ survival, rather than op­ the period after the second lockdown (Second Post-lockdown).7 Al­
erational restructuring may lead to business hibernation (Didier most 20.2% of sample firms were liquidated during the period be­
et al., 2021). Hence, the use of bankruptcy procedures (restructuring or tween the two lockdowns, which accounts for nearly six months.
liquidation) is expected to be negatively impacted by the pandemic Among the periods studied, about 39% of corporate restructuring
periods. occurred during that period. The lifting of the lockdown implied not
only the cessation of travel restrictions for individuals but also the
reopening of the French commercial courts in charge of adminis­
3. Data and variables tering bankruptcy procedures.
We have constructed two sets of data. The first set of accounting
We have used the DIANE database of Bureau van Dijk to identify variables includes those that were reported one year prior to the
nonfinancial French firms that were subject to a legal procedure initiation of the procedure dealing with firms’ performance (EBITDA/
between January 1, 2019, and March 31, 2021. In this database, we TA and ROA), financial needs (LEV and WC/TA), level of capital (TA and
have identified 4334 firms that were voluntarily dissolved through Equities), and liquidity (CR and QR). The second set captures firms’
an amicable liquidation, 6401 firms that were liquidated in court, features, such as age (AGE), partnership legal form (Legal Form), and
395 firms that triggered a sauvegarde procedure, and 1030 firms that activity sector type (Industry, Trade, Transport, or Restaurant).
followed a redressement judiciaire procedure.5 The final sample is Additionally, we also included the 2019 level of investment ex­
composed of 3448 firms that reported balance sheets and financial penditures per capita at a regional level (Invest) as a proxy of local
income statements one year prior to the commencement of bank­ development. Detailed definitions of our variables are presented in
ruptcy proceedings. For firms that engaged on a bankruptcy path Table 1.
between January 1, 2020, and March 31, 2021, we used the financial Average and median values of our variables are presented in
data available for 2019, while the financial data available for 2018 Table 2 for each subsample of firms facing amicable liquidation
was used for the other firms. It should be noted that our sampling (column 1), judicial liquidation (column 2), the sauvegarde proce­
approach has two major limitations. First, our empirical analysis dure (column 3), and the redressement judiciaire procedure (column
relies only on firms that triggered a bankruptcy procedure, and thus, 4). Several observations can be drawn from the summary statistics.
excluded healthy firms that maintained their operations. Second, First, firms that engaged in an out-of-court debt settlement were
firms with missing accounting data were not included in our final associated with a low operational or economic performance (EBITDA/
sample; however, the lack of financial data can be associated with a TA and ROA) and a high degree of indebtedness (LEV). Additionally,
sign of financial distress. Additionally, we restricted our bankruptcy firms that settled debts in court through judicial liquidation, on
analysis on the primary forms of firms’ default resolutions without average, had the lowest equity value (Equity), implying less financial
considering insolvency procedures that resulted from the conversion involvement from owners. Second, firms that were able to trigger a
of other procedures. sauvegarde procedure were, on average, the largest firms in our
Overall, we kept 29.33% of the amicable liquidation sample sample (TA) and were also associated with high values of owners’
composed of 4334 firms, 23.09% of the judicial liquidation sample investment (Equity); however, firms subject to a redressement judi­
based on 6401 firms, 56.71% of the sauvegarde sample composed of ciaire procedure, on average, present low degrees of liquidity (CR and
395 firms, and 46.12% of the redressement judiciaire sample, which QR). The procedure of redressement judiciaire was designed for firms
included 1030 firms. Nevertheless, Blazy and Stef (2020) re­ in payment default, which generally occurs when firms lack li­
commended that the sampling method must be close to actual quidity. Third, the subsample of out-of-court exits includes firms
distribution at the national level. According to Altares D&B, the that have, on average, less experience (AGE), are primarily non­
number of judicial liquidations represented 67.6% of the total partnership firms (Legal Form), and operate in the industry and trade
number of court-driven procedures in 2019 and 72.5% in 2020, the sectors. Fourth, t-tests for differences in means between the sub­
redressement judiciaire procedures represented 30.5% in 2019 and samples suggest that the four subsamples statistically differ in terms
25% in 2020, and the sauvegarde procedures accounted for 1.9% in of indebtedness degree (LEV), firm’s size (TA), and liquidity (CR
2019 and 2.6% in 2020.6 In our sample, the distribution of judicial and QR).
liquidation procedures is 59.8% of the total number of court-driven
procedures in 2019 and 71.5% in 2020, whereas the redressement
4. Empirical analysis
judiciaire procedure represents 29.6% in 2019 and 17.9% in 2020.
Overall, the distribution of court-driven procedures is close to the
4.1. Multinomial probit approach
distribution of procedures at national level, with the exception of the
sauvegarde procedure that has a large weight (10.6% in 2019 and
According to Cheng and Long (2007), the most commonly used
10.5% in 2020). However, we have decided to keep all of the ob­
econometric model to examine discrete choice data is the multi­
servations for the sauvegarde procedure because the application of
nomial logit model. However, this approach relies on the assumption
of independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA), assuming that the
choice between two alternatives is not affected by the features of
5 other available alternatives. The multinomial logit model is
We have manually identified the firms that triggered a sauvegarde procedure or
redressement judiciaire procedure using www.societe.com and www.procedur­
ecollective.fr based on the French Official Bulletin of Civil and Commercial
7
Announcements. The bulletin is a public journal of legal announcements of all the acts The first lockdown covers the period from March 17, 2020, to May 5, 2020,
registered in the Trade and Companies Register of France. whereas the second lockdown was the period from October 30, 2020, to December
6
Data on the annual number of amicable liquidations are not available for France. 14, 2020.

5
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

ī
īī
ī

Fig. 2. Sample distribution.

Table 1
Variables.

Procedure Variable equal to 0 if the firm was subject to an amicable liquidation, 1 to a judicial liquidation, 2 to a sauvegarde procedure and 3 to a
redressement judiciaire procedure.
First Lockdown Dummy variable equal to 1 if the bankruptcy procedure was triggered during the first lockdown of 2020 and 0 otherwise.
First Post-Lockdown Dummy variable equal to 1 if the bankruptcy procedure was triggered between the first lockdown and the second lockdown of 2020 and 0
otherwise.
Second Lockdown Dummy variable equal to 1 if the bankruptcy procedure was triggered during the second lockdown of 2020 and 0 otherwise.
Second Post-Lockdown Dummy variable equal to 1 if the bankruptcy procedure was triggered after the second lockdown of 2020 and 0 otherwise.
EBITDA/TA Earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization as a percentage of total assets.
LEV Ratio between the value of total debts and the value of total assets.
TA Value of total assets.
CR Ratio between current assets and current liabilities.
ROA Ratio between the net income and the value of total assets.
WC/TA Ratio between the working capital and the value of total assets.
Equity Value of firm’s equity.
QR Current assets less inventories divided by current liabilities.
Age Age of firm measured in years.
Legal Form Dummy variable that identifies partnership firms.
Industry Dummy variable that identifies industrial firms.
Trade Dummy variable that identifies firms operating in the trade sector.
Transport Dummy variable that identifies transport firms.
Restaurant Dummy variable that identifies firms with restaurant activities.
Invest Investment expenditures per capita at regional level.

Notes: Our financial variables were extracted from the DIANE database of Bureau van Dijk while Invest from the INSEE (French Institute of Statistics and Economic Studies).

inappropriate when this assumption is violated (Powers and Xie, Pandemic is a vector composed of First Lockdown, First Post-lockdown,
2008). The Hausman and McFadden (1984) test and Small and Hsiao Second Lockdown, and Second Post-lockdown; Accounting is the vector
(1985) test confirm that the IIA assumption is rejected for our data of accounting variables lagged one year prior to the opening of the
set. Referencing Bowen and Wiersema (2004), the multinomial procedure (EBITDA/TA, LEV, and a logarithm of TA and CR),8 whereas
probit model (MPM) can be used in this case because it does not Features is the vector of additional explanatory variables (logarithm
impose the IIA assumption, allowing the errors across different al­ of Age, Legal Form, Industry, Trade, Transport, Restaurant, and a
ternatives to be correlated. A similar solution was also applied by logarithm of Invest).9
other studies, examining firms’ exit routes, such as Ponikvar et al. One concern regarding our empirical framework is that a pre vs.
(2018) and Peljhan et al. (2020). As our main goal is to investigate post analysis does not account for inherent trends in outcomes.10
how the enforcement of lockdowns relates to the likelihood of an Our analysis would have benefited from a control group of firms not
institutional path, we use the following MPM: subject to lockdown or the pandemic crisis; however, as both

Prob (Procedurei = j) = Γ (α0 + α1 Pandemici + α2 Accountingi + α3


Featuresi + ξi) (1) 8
The vector of accounting variables relies on variables that were found to have an
explanatory power for firms’ exit paths, such as voluntary dissolution or involuntary
where i is the firm’s index and Γ is the multinomial probit function; liquidation (Irfan et al., 2018; Jabeur and Fahmi, 2018; Ponikvar et al., 2018; Stef and
Procedure is the dependent variable that equals 0 if the firm was Zenou, 2021).
9
The multinomial logit approach provides similar results to the multinomial probit
subject to an amicable liquidation, 1 for a judicial liquidation, 2 for a
model (results available upon request).
sauvegarde procedure, and 3 for a redressement judiciaire procedure. 10
We are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing out this issue.

6
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux

Table 2
Summary statistics. Average and median values per subsample.

Subsamples

Variables Amicable Liquidation (1.) Judicial Liquidation (2.) Sauvegarde (3.) Redressement (4.) 1. vs 2. t-test 1. vs 3. t-test 1. vs 4. t-test 2. vs 3. t-test 2. vs 4. t-test 3. vs 4. t-test

A. Pandemic periods
First Lockdown 0.043 (.) 0.051 (.) 0.058 (.) 0.051 (.) 0.358 0.329 0.517 0.646 0.985 0.680
First Post-Lockdown 0.202 (.) 0.297 (.) 0.214 (.) 0.156 (.) 0.000 *** 0.679 0.028 ** 0.010 ** 0.000 *** 0.057 *
Second Lockdown 0.070 (.) 0.073 (.) 0.147 (.) 0.078 (.) 0.758 0.000 *** 0.572 0.000 *** 0.727 0.004 ***
Second Post-Lockdown 0.103 (.) 0.150 (.) 0.121 (.) 0.114 (.) 0.000 *** 0.433 0.522 0.242 0.047 ** 0.792
B. Accounting variables
EBITDA/TA − 0.241 (0.070) 0.044 (0.004) − 0.021 (0.000) − 0.104 (−0.017) 0.052 * 0.539 0.578 0.559 0.057 * 0.005 ***
LEV 9.445 (3.277) 0.679 (0.218) 0.941 (0.845) 1.200 (0.958) 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.111 0.000 *** 0.001 ***
TA (K€) 742.418 (273.4) 3240.32 (740.4) 9413.6 (1831.2) 2895.14 (878.4) 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.582 0.000 ***
CR 3.969 (1.624) 1.413 (1.087) 1.934 (1.123) 1.118 (0.927) 0.000 *** 0.001 *** 0.000 *** 0.012 ** 0.015 ** 0.000 ***
ROA − 0.661 (0.019) 0.108 (0.003) − 0.091 (−0.017) − 0.246 (−0.066) 0.000 *** 0.123 0.095 * 0.080 * 0.000 *** 0.003 ***
WC/TA 0.397 (0.108) 0.077 (0.000) − 0.011 (0.045) − 0.220 (−0.080) 0.148 0.467 0.110 0.289 0.000 *** 0.000 ***
Equity (K€) 740.828 (166.1) 358.214 (101.5) 2770.84 (404.5) 851.710 (208.9) 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.548 0.000 *** 0.001 *** 0.005 ***

7
QR 1.140 (0.947) 3.669 (1.161) 1.584 (0.879) 0.860 (0.696) 0.000 *** 0.009 *** 0.001 *** 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.001 ***
C. Firm’s features
Age 13.327 (9) 15.990 (11) 16.545 (11) 16.589 (13) 0.000 *** 0.001 *** 0.000 *** 0.597 0.429 0.970
Legal Form 0.329 (.) 0.468 (.) 0.531 (.) 0.465 (.) 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.078 * 0.911 0.104
Industry 0.228 (.) 0.418 (.) 0.246 (.) 0.360 (.) 0.000 *** 0.570 0.000 *** 0.000 *** 0.025 ** 0.003 ***
Trade 0.359 (.) 0.225 (.) 0.295 (.) 0.234 (.) 0.000 *** 0.064 * 0.000 *** 0.021 ** 0.682 0.084 *
Transport 0.026 (.) 0.074 (.) 0.031 (.) 0.046 (.) 0.000 *** 0.652 0.030 ** 0.017 ** 0.034 ** 0.352
Restaurant 0.118 (.) 0.055 (.) 0.094 (.) 0.095 (.) 0.000 *** 0.279 0.157 0.022 ** 0.002 *** 0.967
Invest (€) 159.795 (156) 160.054 (156) 168.290 (156) 170.459 (153) 0.896 0.038 ** 0.003 0.058 * 0.004 *** 0.779
Number of firms: 1271 1478 224 475

Notes: Average values of the variables are reported for each subsample of firms dealing with the amicable liquidation (column 1), the judicial liquidation (column 2), the sauvegarde procedure (column 3) and the redressement judiciaire
procedure (column 4). Median values are included in the brackets. p-values of the t-tests for difference in means between the subsamples are reported in the last columns. * implies a difference in means that is significant at the 10% level,
** at the 5% level and *** at the 1% level.
International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Table 3
French bankruptcy procedures and pandemic periods.

Lag = 1 year Lag = 2 years

Variable Amicable Judicial Sauvegarde (3) Redressement (4) Amicable Judicial Sauvegarde (7) Redressement
Liquidation (1) Liquidation (2) Liquidation (5) Liquidation (6) (8)

First Lockdown − 0.021 0.045 − 0.003 − 0.022 − 0.067 0.083 * 0.009 − 0.025
(0.046) (0.042) (0.014) (0.020) (0.045) (0.046) (0.019) (0.026)
First Post-Lockdown − 0.093 0.168 *** − 0.013 − 0.062 *** − 0.094 *** 0.186 *** − 0.015 − 0.077 ***
(0.027) (0.025) (0.008) (0.011) (0.025) (0.025) (0.009) (0.013)
Second Lockdown − 0.049 0.026 0.044 ** − 0.020 − 0.033 0.004 0.048 ** − 0.018
(0.039) (0.035) (0.019) (0.017) (0.041) (0.040) (0.020) (0.022)
Second Post-Lockdown − 0.103 *** 0.128 *** − 0.001 − 0.024 * − 0.100 *** 0.150 *** − 0.007 − 0.042 **
(0.033) (0.031) (0.011) (0.014) (0.030) (0.031) (0.012) (0.016)
EBITDA/TA lag 0.016 − 0.002 − 0.002 − 0.012 * 0.026 ** − 0.009 − 0.005 *** − 0.012 ***
(0.011) (0.010) (0.002) (0.007) (0.011) (0.012) (0.001) (0.003)
LEV lag 0.067 *** − 0.055 *** − 0.005 *** − 0.007 ** 0.049 *** − 0.024 ** − 0.008 *** − 0.018 ***
(0.015) (0.014) (0.001) (0.002) (0.009) (0.013) (0.002) (0.003)
Logarithm (TA lag) − 0.292 *** 0.125 *** 0.083 *** 0.084 *** − 0.253 *** 0.112 *** 0.073 *** 0.068 ***
(0.027) (0.026) (0.009) (0.013) (0.025) (0.023) (0.009) (0.013)
CR lag 0.049 *** − 0.012 0.002 − 0.039 *** 0.044 *** − 0.029 *** 0.001 − 0.017 **
(0.009) (0.009) (0.018) (0.005) (0.010) (0.012) (0.003) (0.007)
Logarithm (Age lag) 0.084 *** − 0.076 *** − 0.017 ** 0.009 0.044 * − 0.027 − 0.015 * − 0.002
(0.025) (0.022) (0.008) (0.012) (0.026) (0.024) (0.009) (0.015)
Legal Form − 0.072 *** 0.055 *** 0.004 0.013 − 0.093 *** 0.061 *** 0.010 0.022
(0.021) (0.019) (0.007) (0.011) (0.022) (0.021) (0.009) (0.014)
Industry − 0.107 *** 0.131 *** − 0.025 *** 0.000 − 0.111 *** 0.144 *** − 0.030 *** − 0.004
(0.028) (0.025) (0.008) (0.013) (0.028) (0.027) (0.009) (0.017)
Trade 0.064 ** − 0.044 * − 0.002 − 0.017 0.080 *** − 0.047 * − 0.006 − 0.027
(0.029) (0.026) (0.009) (0.014) (0.030) (0.028) (0.010) (0.017)
Transport − 0.219 *** 0.252 *** − 0.022 * − 0.011 − 0.194 *** 0.235 *** − 0.027 ** − 0.014
(0.048) (0.046) (0.012) (0.023) (0.044) (0.047) (0.013) (0.030)
Restaurant 0.082 ** − 0.113 *** 0.021 0.009 0.077 * − 0.122 *** 0.026 0.019
(0.038) (0.033) (0.018) (0.021) (0.042) (0.038) (0.021) (0.027)
Logarithm (Invest) − 0.027 − 0.056 0.024 0.058 − 0.133 0.032 0.027 0.074
(0.092) (0.082) (0.035) (0.049) (0.114) (0.108) (0.041) (0.063)
Observations 3488 2899
Wald chi-square 745.59 *** 616.20 ***
Log pseudolikelihood − 3121.4 − 2912.4
Maximum VIF 1.57 1.58
Prediction rate (%) 66.03% 59.68%

Notes: Marginal effects at the mean were estimated using a multinomial probit regression with robust standard errors. The dependent variable is a dummy variable that is equal to
0 if the firm was subject to an amicable liquidation, 1 to a judicial liquidation, 2 to a sauvegarde procedure and 3 to a redressement judiciaire procedure. The prediction rate (%)
represents the percentage of correctly predicted observations. Delta-method standard errors are included in the brackets. * implies a significant coefficient at the 10% level, ** at 5%
level, and *** at the 1% level. Detailed definitions of the variables are presented in Table 1.

lockdowns were enforced over the entire population of French firms, follow a voluntary exit more often than a court-driven exit. Conse­
the assessment of our research question can only rely on a com­ quently, we should expect firms holding more liquidity (CR) and pre­
parison with the pre-pandemic period. This is why we considered a viously operating with high levels of performance (EBITDA/TA) to have
large pre-pandemic subsample covering the period from January 1, a higher likelihood of amicable liquidation or the sauvegarde proce­
2019, to March 16, 2020. Additionally, Karlson et al. (2012) demon­ dure. Although a high level of debt (LEV) can be associated with more
strated that the size of the estimated coefficients depends on the financial interests that can weaken reimbursement capacity, firms’ size
other explanatory variables included in an econometric specifica­ can relate to the institutional path in two ways. More assets can imply
tion. In this sense, Wulff (2015) noted that a positive (negative) higher stakeholder dependence, as captured in an extensive network
coefficient does not necessarily correspond to an increase (decrease) of partners and creditors (Balcaen et al., 2011). Therefore, a voluntary
in the probability of a certain outcome, whereas the nonlinear re­ liquidation decision can be complex and a firm’s negotiations with
lationship between an explanatory variable and that probability can creditors can be long. A court-driven procedure (judicial liquidation,
even change sign of the coefficient. Consequently, Wulff (2015) ar­ sauvegarde procedure, and redressement judiciaire procedure) can be
gues that the interpretation of the results should rely on the mar­ triggered by firms because of the high costs required by the co­
ginal effects and predicted probabilities. Given that the sign of the ordination of creditors (Bruche, 2011). In contrast, valuable assets can
coefficient cannot be used to assess the relationship between the be easily converted into cash, allowing large firms to prevent credit
dependent variable and pandemic periods, our interpretation will default and embark on an amicable liquidation rather than on a court-
follow Wulff’s (2015) recommendations. driven procedure.
In Table 3, we present the marginal effects at the mean for our
4.2. Estimates four procedures when the accounting variables and Age lag by one
year (columns 1–4) and two years (columns 5–8).11 Our results
An amicable liquidation or the sauvegarde procedure can be trig­ suggest that the probability of a judicial liquidation (column 2)
gered by firms that are not in default of payment so that the creditors’
claims can be settled in full. According to Harada (2007), the prob­
ability of economic-forced exit is high for firms with loans from fi­ 11
We used the command margins in STATA 14.2 to compute the marginal effects. In
nancial institutions and declining sales. Similarly, Balcaen et al. (2012) the case of dummy variables, margins calculate the discrete first difference from the
demonstrated that firms with less debt and high levels of cash tend to base category.

8
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Fig. 3. Monthly averages of predicted probabilities. Estimates based on the first econometric specification.

increased, on average, by 16.8% in the first post-lockdown period and likelihood of liquidating assets in court (columns 2 and 6) and a low
by 12.8% in the second post-lockdown period, compared with the likelihood of an out-of-court exit (columns 1 and 5). Table 3 also
period prior to the first lockdown. These effect sizes are larger when offers some insights regarding the consistency of our regressions.
we consider the two-year lag specification, ranging from 18.6% to First, no severe multicollinearity was detected, as the maximum
15%. Surprisingly, the probability of triggering a redressement judi­ variance inflation factor is below 10. Second, the proportion of cor­
ciaire procedure after the first lockdown was, on average, 6.2% lower rectly predicted cases is higher than 65% only for the econometric
(column 4) than the probability of triggering a similar procedure specification based on the one-year lag. Third, the Wald test con­
prior to the pandemic crisis. The new environment that emerged, firms that at least one coefficient is statistically different than zero.
based on travel restrictions and social distancing, following the first We next graph the predicted probabilities of MPM by type of
lockdown harmed the capacity of defaulted firms to reorganize their institutional path.13 This approach allows us to better understand
activities in court. In contrast, non-defaulted firms had, on average, the changes in these predicted probabilities following the two
more chances to restructure their operations through a sauvegarde lockdowns. Fig. 3 shows the evolution of the monthly averages of
procedure during the second lockdown (columns 3 and 7). These predicted probabilities that were estimated in columns 1–4 of
firms likely took advantage of the lockdown context to negotiate Table 3. The strongest evidence that confirms the previous findings
with creditors and identify solutions with the court administrator to primarily relates to the three court-driven procedures. In the case of
facilitate the firm’s adaptation to the new environment. judicial liquidation, the average predicted probability increased from
In terms of control variables, the likelihood of amicable liquida­ 36.5% prior to the pandemic crisis to 55% during the first post-
tion was high for firms with high levels of debt (LEV) and liquidity lockdown period and slightly lowered to 51.7% during the second
(CR). Holding an asset value (logarithm (TA)) higher by 1% in the year post-lockdown period. This finding is also strengthened by the es­
previous to commencement of a bankruptcy procedure increased timates in Appendix A that shows the coefficients using the multi­
the probability of a court-driven procedure by 5.4% for judicial li­ nomial probit approach by considering the group of firms subject to
quidation (column 2) and 3.6% for the sauvegarde procedure (column judicial liquidation as the comparison group. Additionally, the
3) and the redressement judiciaire procedure (column 4).12 The latter average likelihood of a sauvegarde procedure reached the highest
result suggests that large firms had a high likelihood of legally re­ value of 12% during the second lockdown. It is also notable that the
structuring operations. Given that such firms must manage high largest drop in the likelihood of the redressement judiciaire procedure
stakeholder dependence (Balcaen et al., 2011), out-of-court nego­ occurred during the period between the two lockdowns. This result
tiations with a large cohort of partners and creditors may fail. Ad­ was also confirmed in column 4 of Table 3.
ditionally, on average, industrial and transport firms had a high

12 13
Effect sizes were calculated by multiplying the coefficients with the base 10 For a given firm, MPM predicts a probability for each of the four institutional
logarithm of 1.01. paths. The sum of the four predicted probabilities is equal to 1.

9
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Table 4
French bankruptcy procedures and pandemic periods. Alternative accounting variables.

Lag = 1 year Lag = 2 years

Variable Amicable Judicial Sauvegarde (3) Redressement (4) Amicable Judicial Sauvegarde (7) Redressement
Liquidation (1) Liquidation (2) Liquidation (5) Liquidation (6) (8)

First Lockdown − 0.097 ** 0.080 * 0.010 0.006 − 0.078 * 0.045 0.046 − 0.013
(0.042) (0.048) (0.021) (0.023) (0.043) (0.051) (0.030) (0.032)
First Post-Lockdown − 0.137 *** 0.190 *** − 0.022 ** − 0.030 *** − 0.111 *** 0.178 *** − 0.013 − 0.054 ***
(0.024) (0.025) (0.011) (0.010) (0.024) (0.028) (0.012) (0.016)
Second Lockdown − 0.087 ** 0.041 0.037 0.009 − 0.052 − 0.011 0.059 ** 0.003
(0.037) (0.044) (0.023) (0.018) (0.037) (0.044) (0.027) (0.028)
Second Post-Lockdown − 0.158 *** 0.147 *** 0.009 0.002 − 0.124 *** 0.161 *** − 0.010 − 0.027
(0.027) (0.032) (0.016) (0.014) (0.029) (0.033) (0.015) (0.021)
ROA lag 0.001 0.004 − 0.003 * − 0.002 0.031 *** − 0.008 − 0.008 ** − 0.015 **
(0.006) (0.006) (0.002) (0.002) (0.011) (0.010) (0.003) (0.010)
WC/TA lag 0.010 *** − 0.006 * − 0.002 *** − 0.001 ** 0.023 *** − 0.010 * − 0.006 *** − 0.008 ***
(0.004) (0.003) (0.001) (0.001) (0.007) (0.005) (0.001) (0.002)
Logarithm (Equity lag) 0.132 *** − 0.233 *** 0.062 *** 0.039 *** 0.111 *** − 0.238 *** 0.064 *** 0.064 ***
(0.017) (0.018) (0.007) (0.007) (0.016) (0.019) (0.008) (0.011)
QR lag − 0.031 ** 0.053 *** 0.003 − 0.025 *** − 0.058 *** 0.068 *** 0.005 − 0.014
(0.012) (0.012) (0.003) (0.004) (0.007) (0.010) (0.004) (0.015)
Logarithm (Age lag) − 0.119 *** 0.083 *** 0.017 0.019 ** − 0.095 *** 0.068 *** 0.009 0.019
(0.023) (0.024) (0.010) (0.010) (0.024) (0.026) (0.012) (0.016)
Legal Form − 0.156 *** 0.114 *** 0.024 ** 0.019 ** − 0.153 *** 0.100 *** 0.022 ** 0.031 **
(0.020) (0.021) (0.010) (0.009) (0.021) (0.023) (0.010) (0.015)
Industry − 0.198 *** 0.208 *** − 0.024 ** 0.013 − 0.183 *** 0.194 *** − 0.031 *** 0.020
(0.025) (0.027) (0.011) (0.012) (0.025) (0.029) (0.012) (0.019)
Trade 0.035 − 0.023 − 0.011 − 0.002 0.038 − 0.009 − 0.012 − 0.017
(0.028) (0.030) (0.012) (0.012) (0.029) (0.032) (0.013) (0.020)
Transport − 0.244 *** 0.303 *** − 0.039 *** − 0.021 − 0.208 *** 0.304 *** − 0.051 *** − 0.046
(0.034) (0.040) (0.013) (0.020) (0.035) (0.045) (0.011) (0.031)
Restaurant 0.134 *** − 0.149 *** 0.005 0.010 0.136 *** − 0.121 ** − 0.006 − 0.010
(0.044) (0.044) (0.022) (0.021) (0.049) (0.014) (0.023) (0.033)
Logarithm (Invest) 0.076 − 0.124 0.034 0.014 − 0.044 0.011 − 0.021 0.053
(0.091) (0.101) (0.053) (0.048) (0.092) (0.102) (0.057) (0.077)
Observations 2487 2237
Wald chi-square 513.25 *** 490.83 ***
Log pseudolikelihood − 2396.2 − 2295.0
Maximum VIF 1.60 1.60
Prediction rate (%) 60.07% 57.58%

Notes: Marginal effects at the mean were estimated using a multinomial probit regression with robust standard errors. The dependent variable is a dummy variable that is equal to
0 if the firm was subject to an amicable liquidation, 1 to a judicial liquidation, 2 to a sauvegarde procedure and 3 to a redressement judiciaire procedure. The prediction rate (%)
represents the percentage of correctly predicted observations. Delta-method standard errors are included in the brackets. * implies a significant coefficient at the 10% level, ** at 5%
level, and *** at the 1% level. Detailed definitions of the variables are presented in Table 1.

4.3. Robustness check presented in Appendix B, which considers the estimated coefficients
of this robustness check. Owners can benefit from the residual value
Following Stef and Zenou (2021), we assess the robustness of our of assets if one of the voluntary liquidation or reorganization pro­
findings using an alternative set of accounting variables composed of cedures is triggered. According to Carletti et al. (2020), the pandemic
ROA, WC/TA, the logarithm of Equity,14 and QR.15 Estimates are pre­ crisis not only drained the level of liquidity but also eroded the
sented in Table 4. Surprisingly, the likelihood of an amicable liqui­ equity capital of firms severely impacted by the lockdown enforce­
dation decreased by 9.7% during the first lockdown, 13.7% after the ment and reported high leverage and a small size prior to the crisis.
first lockdown, 8.7% during the second lockdown, and 15.8% after the Large investments encouraged owners to settle all firms’ claims
second lockdown (column 1). However, these marginal effects are outside of court or to restructure business activities. Interestingly,
estimated using only 71.3% of the initial sample. The other results the marginal effects of QR seem to provide an opposite sign for the
regarding court-driven procedures are robust compared with the two liquidation procedures compared with the marginal effects of CR
previous findings. Table 4 shows that the effect sizes are large for from Table 3. The major difference between the two liquidity ratios
First Post-lockdown and Second Post-lockdown, mainly in the case of is that QR includes only current assets that can be converted into
judicial liquidation. An average increase in the likelihood of court- cash in less than three months. When the value of a firm’s inventory
driven exits, ranging from 14.7% to 19%, should have been expected is excluded from the liquidity measure, the likelihood of judicial li­
in the post-quarantine periods. quidation is subject to an average increase of 5.3%, while the like­
Moreover, firms with a high level of equity were associated with lihood of amicable liquidation is subject to an average decrease of
a high probability of voluntary liquidation (columns 1 and 5) or 3.1%, following a 1% increase in QR. Hence, the value of firms’ in­
reorganization (columns 3, 4, 7, and 8). Similar findings are also ventory can have a significant influence in the arbitration between
the two liquidation procedures.
We complete the robustness test with a graphical analysis based
on the monthly averages of the predicted probabilities from columns
14
We treated the negative values of Equity as equal to 0 in the log-transformed 1–4 of Table 4. Fig. 4 reveals opposing patterns for amicable and
function.
15
Table 7 in Appendix C reports an additional robustness test by including regional
judicial liquidation. The average likelihood of amicable liquidation
effects in the econometric specification of Eq. (1). The previous findings remain progressively decreased from 43.9% (before the first lockdown) to
robust. 29.7% (after the second lockdown), whereas the average likelihood of

10
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Fig. 4. Monthly averages of predicted probabilities. Estimates based on the second econometric specification.

judicial liquidation increased to 56.3%, mainly during the first post- Although the main objective of the lockdown was to limit the
lockdown period. On a different note, the likelihood of firms’ re­ spread of the virus, its enforcement has not provided strong in­
structuring severely decreased during the period between the two centives to exit through an out-of-court procedure such as the
lockdowns, during which the average likelihood of a sauvegarde amicable liquidation. As a matter of fact, our estimates report an
procedure was 4.5% and that of a redressement judiciaire procedure expected average increase in the likelihood of court-driven exit
was 6.6%. ranging from 12.8% to 19% points during the post-lockdown periods.
Bernstein et al. (2019) argued that a firm’s liquidation driven by the
court can lead to an inefficient allocation of assets in the presence of
5. Concluding remarks local market frictions. Considering that the pandemic produced li­
quidity shortcomings, finding a potential user for firms’ assets may
This study investigates how the lockdown enforcement by French require high search costs that can increase the bankruptcy costs and
authorities is associated with the resolution of corporate insolvency. limit the creditors’ debt recovery. Therefore, the use of the amicable
In this sense, we make a distinction between four legal procedures, liquidation should be encouraged during and after the pandemic
namely the amicable liquidation (out-of-court exit), the judicial li­ crisis because it can accelerate the allocation of assets to more
quidation (court-driven exit), the restructuring procedure of sauve­ successful entrepreneurs. Moreover, longer bankruptcy delays can
garde available to non-defaulted firms, and the restructuring prevent financially distressed firms from exiting and, also, the for­
procedure of redressement judiciaire available to defaulted firms. mation of new firms (Melcarne and Ramello, 2020). Hence, the
Using a sample of 3488 non-listed French firms, our estimates yield pressure on the insolvency courts may be diminished through the
three major findings. First, the likelihood of judicial liquidation in­ promotion of the out-of-court exit.
creased after the lifting of the quarantines compared to the pre- Nevertheless, the judicial liquidation can represent a solution
pandemic period. Second, the non-defaulted firms had a higher to the exit of firms severely affected by the COVID-19 crisis, called
likelihood to reorganize in court during the second lockdown. Third, “zombie” companies. Demary (2021) employed the concept of
the lifting of the first lockdown led to a decrease in the probability of “zombification” to describe firms that survive without having the
restructuring the assets of defaulted firms. pressure to restructure their activities to stay in the market. Such

11
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

“zombification” can be supported by government’s rescues mea­ of nonviable firms and liquidation of viable firms (Fisher and Martel,
sures or even debt deleveraging that can disempower the man­ 2004; Laitinen, 2011; Stef, 2017). The use of a court-driven re­
agers and reduce their incentives to maintain the firm’s organization should be encouraged during and after the pandemic
competitiveness. Not surprisingly, the COVID-19 crisis led to an crisis, as it can allow preservation of both asset value and em­
average 37% drop in judicial liquidations on French territory in ployment.
2020 compared to 2019 due to the massive support from the State However, it should be noted that our findings are based on short-
to private companies through a system of financial aid (solidarity term results that considered only the two French lockdowns that
fund and loan guaranteed by the State). If the creditors’ right to were enforced in 2020. A long-term empirical approach that in­
trigger the debtor’s liquidation is restricted, one may expect more tegrates additional observation years and other potential lockdown
“zombification” among firms facing financial difficulties. Philippon periods would be suitable to comprehensively investigate the re­
(2021) pointed out that a laissez-faire public approach can lead to lationship between the pandemic crisis and firms’ failure. An ana­
excessive liquidation while the efficient reallocation of assets can lysis regarding insolvency resolution during the pandemic periods
be hampered by an indiscriminate bailout of firms. Hence, public can also be further expanded to different legal systems, such as the
measures aimed to restore the financial health of firms affected by common law system, which is mainly recognized for its creditor-
the pandemic must limit the incentives of non-viable firms to friendly orientation that opposes the debtor-friendly orientation
continue their operations. associated with the civil law systems. Understanding the con­
Based on our findings, firms in default of payment had difficulty sequences of the arbitration between the protection of creditors’
engaging in restructuring, mainly during the first post-lockdown interest and employment preservation (firm survival) is of major
period. However, court-driven reorganization procedures can offer importance for legislators seeking to accelerate the recovery of the
useful mechanisms to preserve the value of assets, particularly national economy in the post-pandemic context.
during a pandemic. According to James (2016), firms can strategi­
cally file for a restructuring procedure not only to preserve more CRediT authorship contribution statement
asset value for business stakeholders but also to stem the decline in
performance through measures aimed at overcoming others’ com­ Nicolae Stef: Formal analysis, Methodology, Writing – original
petitive advantages. Conflicts of interests between creditors and draft, Writing – review & editing, Funding acquisition, Visualization
other stakeholders can be mitigated by preserving the firm’s value. Jean-Joachim Bissieux: Conceptualization, Resources.
Using a legal index based on a scale from 0% (no protection) to 100%
(high level of protection), Blazy et al. (2018) revealed that the re­ Acknowledgments
dressement judiciaire procedure can provide a high degree of asset
protection (82%), close to the protection provided by judicial liqui­ The authors acknowledge support from the Bourgogne-Franche-
dation (91%). Additionally, restructuring seems to be less costly for Comté Regional Council (Project COVID-ENT). We are also grateful to
shareholders and creditors. If the commercial courts can diminish Antoine Jolly and two anonymous referees for their insightful com­
the risk of filtering failure, this could lead to increased restructuring ments.

Appendix A

See Table 5.

12
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Table 5
Multinomial probit approach. French bankruptcy procedures and pandemic periods.

Lag = 1 year Lag = 2 years


Variable Amicable Liquidation (1) Sauvegarde (2) Redressement (3) Amicable Liquidation (4) Sauvegarde (5) Redressement (6)

First Lockdown − 0.133 − 0.129 − 0.244 − 0.302 * − 0.061 − 0.287


(0.163) (0.205) (0.184) (0.176) (0.211) (0.194)
First Post-Lockdown − 0.515 *** − 0.520 *** − 0.798 *** − 0.553 *** − 0.524 *** − 0.790 ***
(0.094) (0.124) (0.103) (0.095) (0.132) (0.108)
Second Lockdown − 0.146 0.346 ** − 0.188 − 0.080 0.389 ** − 0.096
(0.137) (0.161) (0.153) (0.158) (0.170) (0.159)
Second Post-Lockdown − 0.453 *** − 0.278 * − 0.419 *** − 0.499 *** − 0.360 ** − 0.509 ***
(0.120) (0.156) (0.124) (0.119) (0.162) (0.128)
EBITDA/TA lag 0.032 − 0.020 − 0.074 0.071 − 0.039 − 0.043
(0.040) (0.032) (0.054) (0.045) (0.033) (0.034)
LEV lag 0.241 *** 0.057 0.075 * 0.150 *** − 0.037 − 0.045
(0.061) (0.043) (0.043) (0.037) (0.031) (0.030)
Logarithm (TA lag) − 0.799 *** 0.744 *** 0.265 *** − 0.746 *** 0.563 *** 0.121
(0.101) (0.088) (0.076) (0.095) (0.103) (0.078)
CR lag 0.113 *** 0.041 − 0.216 *** 0.151 *** 0.070 − 0.028
(0.035) (0.032) (0.051) (0.041) (0.044) (0.050)
Logarithm (Age lag) 0.317 *** − 0.038 0.223 ** 0.145 − 0.113 0.042
(0.089) (0.114) (0.093) (0.095) (0.116) (0.098)
Legal Form − 0.250 *** − 0.075 − 0.036 − 0.317 *** − 0.014 − 0.012
(0.077) (0.100) (0.082) (0.082) (0.103) (0.087)
Industry − 0.472 *** − 0.601 *** − 0.276 *** − 0.516 *** − 0.625 *** − 0.301 ***
(0.103) (0.125) (0.103) (0.106) (0.131) (0.109)
Trade 0.211 ** 0.066 − 0.014 0.256 ** 0.022 − 0.042
(0.105) (0.130) (0.113) (0.109) (0.136) (0.118)
Transport − 0.933 *** − 0.800 *** − 0.544 *** − 0.905 *** − 0.794 *** − 0.483 **
(0.192) (0.248) (0.188) (0.204) (0.268) (0.205)
Restaurant 0.418 *** 0.501 *** 0.336 ** 0.417 *** 0.508 ** 0.355 **
(0.140) (0.191) (0.160) (0.157) (0.205) (0.175)
Logarithm (Invest) 0.074 0.417 0.492 − 0.341 0.230 0.302
(0.325) (0.479) (0.376) (0.425) (0.515) (0.413)
Intercept 1.161 − 4.281 *** − 2.364 *** 2.380 ** − 3.088 *** − 1.321
(0.777) (1.100) (0.859) (0.942) (1.192) (0.929)
Observations 3488 2899
Wald chi-square 745.59 *** 616.20 ***
Log pseudolikelihood − 3121.4 − 2912.4
Maximum VIF 1.57 1.58
Prediction rate (%) 66.03% 59.68%

Notes: Coefficients were estimated using a multinomial probit regression with robust standard errors. The dependent variable is a dummy variable that is equal to 0 if the firm was
subject to an amicable liquidation, 1 to a judicial liquidation, 2 to a sauvegarde procedure and 3 to a redressement judiciaire procedure. The group of firms that were subject to a
judicial liquidation is the comparison group. The prediction rate (%) represents the percentage of correctly predicted observations. Delta-method standard errors are included in
the brackets. * implies a significant coefficient at the 10% level, ** at 5% level, and *** at the 1% level. Detailed definitions of the variables are presented in Table 1.

Appendix B

See Table 6.

13
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Table 6
Multinomial probit approach. Alternative accounting variables.

Lag = 1 year Lag = 2 years


Variable Amicable Liquidation (1) Sauvegarde (2) Redressement (3) Amicable Liquidation (4) Sauvegarde (5) Redressement (6)

First Lockdown − 0.367 ** − 0.038 − 0.077 − 0.281 0.267 − 0.143


(0.179) (0.230) (0.230) (0.190) (0.233) (0.221)
First Post-Lockdown − 0.642 *** − 0.578 *** − 0.632 *** − 0.590 *** − 0.452 *** − 0.604 ***
(0.098) (0.149) (0.130) (0.106) (0.153) (0.125)
Second Lockdown − 0.276 * 0.240 0.010 − 0.106 0.453 ** 0.044
(0.153) (0.194) (0.183) (0.163) (0.199) (0.181)
Second Post-Lockdown − 0.640 *** − 0.151 − 0.223 − 0.604 *** − 0.381 ** − 0.419 ***
(0.123) (0.171) (0.148) (0.130) (0.191) (0.148)
ROA lag − 0.006 − 0.042 * − 0.026 0.087 ** − 0.063 − 0.062
(0.023) (0.022) (0.019) (0.042) (0.041) (0.038)
WC/TA lag 0.032 ** − 0.013 * − 0.001 0.073 *** − 0.034 ** − 0.019
(0.014) (0.007) (0.006) (0.024) (0.014) (0.013)
Logarithm (Equity lag) 0.693 *** 1.043 *** 0.776 *** 0.696 *** 1.052 *** 0.755 ***
(0.066) (0.095) (0.076) (0.067) (0.105) (0.074)
QR lag − 0.159 *** − 0.069 ** − 0.323 *** − 0.260 *** − 0.077 ** − 0.194 ***
(0.047) (0.030) (0.064) (0.031) (0.039) (0.060)
Logarithm (Age lag) − 0.402 *** 0.030 0.039 − 0.350 *** − 0.041 − 0.033
(0.089) (0.124) (0.109) (0.096) (0.135) (0.108)
Legal Form − 0.547 *** 0.040 − 0.023 − 0.554 *** 0.024 − 0.026
(0.081) (0.110) (0.099) (0.088) (0.114) (0.097)
Industry − 0.820 *** − 0.616 *** − 0.235 * − 0.809 *** − 0.667 *** − 0.252 **
(0.105) (0.145) (0.131) (0.111) (0.149) (0.125)
Trade 0.116 − 0.075 0.019 0.104 − 0.107 − 0.072
(0.109) (0.151) (0.140) (0.115) (0.155) (0.136)
Transport − 1.218 *** − 1.082 *** − 0.711 ** − 1.156 *** − 1.347 *** − 0.759 ***
(0.207) (0.329) (0.281) (0.212) (0.346) (0.257)
Restaurant 0.548 *** 0.332 0.375 * 0.526 *** 0.183 0.192
(0.165) (0.246) (0.216) (0.184) (0.275) (0.228)
Logarithm (Invest) 0.382 0.564 0.355 − 0.120 − 0.220 0.238
(0.350) (0.633) (0.522) (0.356) (0.630) (0.484)
Intercept − 1.035 − 4.468 *** − 2.830 ** 0.072 − 2.612 * − 2.300 **
(0.771) (1.413) (1.162) (0.790) (1.426) (1.066)
Observations 2487 2237
Wald chi-square 513.25 *** 490.83 ***
Log pseudolikelihood − 2396.2 − 2295.0
Maximum VIF 1.60 1.60
Prediction rate (%) 60.07% 57.58%

Notes: Coefficients were estimated using a multinomial probit regression with robust standard errors. The dependent variable is a dummy variable that is equal to 0 if the firm was
subject to an amicable liquidation, 1 to a judicial liquidation, 2 to a sauvegarde procedure and 3 to a redressement judiciaire procedure. The group of firms that were subject to a
judicial liquidation is the comparison group. The prediction rate (%) represents the percentage of correctly predicted observations. Delta-method standard errors are included in
the brackets. * implies a significant coefficient at the 10% level, ** at 5% level, and *** at the 1% level. Detailed definitions of the variables are presented in Table 1.

Appendix C

See Table 7.

14
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Table 7
French bankruptcy procedures and pandemic periods. Regional effects.

Lag = 1 year Lag = 2 years

Variable Amicable Judicial Sauvegarde (3) Redressement (4) Amicable Judicial Sauvegarde (7) Redressement
Liquidation (1) Liquidation (2) Liquidation (5) Liquidation (6) (8)

First Lockdown − 0.022 0.046 − 0.000 − 0.023 − 0.068 0.087 * 0.011 − 0.031
(0.046) (0.042) (0.015) (0.020) (0.046) (0.046) (0.019) (0.025)
First Post-Lockdown − 0.091 0.163 *** − 0.011 − 0.060 *** − 0.093 *** 0.182 *** − 0.013 − 0.075 ***
(0.027) (0.025) (0.008) (0.011) (0.025) (0.025) (0.009) (0.013)
Second Lockdown − 0.054 0.023 0.048 ** − 0.016 − 0.037 − 0.005 0.053 *** − 0.010
(0.039) (0.035) (0.019) (0.018) (0.041) (0.040) (0.013) (0.023)
Second Post-Lockdown − 0.102 *** 0.124 *** − 0.001 − 0.022 − 0.099 *** 0.145 *** − 0.006 − 0.040 **
(0.033) (0.031) (0.011) (0.014) (0.030) (0.031) (0.012) (0.017)
EBITDA/TA lag 0.016 − 0.002 − 0.002 − 0.012 * 0.027 *** − 0.010 − 0.005 *** − 0.012 ***
(0.011) (0.010) (0.002) (0.007) (0.010) (0.011) (0.001) (0.003)
LEV lag 0.067 *** − 0.056 *** − 0.005 *** − 0.007 ** 0.049 *** − 0.025 *** − 0.007 *** − 0.018 ***
(0.015) (0.014) (0.001) (0.002) (0.009) (0.009) (0.002) (0.003)
Logarithm (TA lag) − 0.296 *** 0.128 *** 0.084 *** 0.085 *** − 0.255 *** 0.111 *** 0.074 *** 0.070 ***
(0.027) (0.026) (0.009) (0.012) (0.026) (0.023) (0.009) (0.013)
CR lag 0.048 *** − 0.012 0.002 − 0.037 *** 0.045 *** − 0.029 ** 0.001 − 0.017 **
(0.010) (0.009) (0.002) (0.006) (0.010) (0.012) (0.003) (0.007)
Logarithm (Age lag) 0.081 *** − 0.077 *** − 0.016 * 0.012 0.039 − 0.027 − 0.014 0.002
(0.025) (0.022) (0.009) (0.012) (0.026) (0.025) (0.009) (0.015)
Legal Form − 0.074 *** 0.053 *** 0.005 0.016 − 0.095 *** 0.059 *** 0.012 0.024 *
(0.022) (0.020) (0.007) (0.011) (0.022) (0.021) (0.008) (0.014)
Industry − 0.107 *** 0.141 *** − 0.028 *** − 0.005 − 0.109 *** 0.154 *** − 0.035 *** − 0.011
(0.028) (0.025) (0.008) (0.013) (0.028) (0.028) (0.009) (0.016)
Trade 0.063 ** − 0.037 − 0.004 − 0.021 0.083 *** − 0.041 − 0.009 − 0.033 **
(0.029) (0.027) (0.009) (0.013) (0.030) (0.029) (0.010) (0.017)
Transport − 0.221 *** 0.258 *** − 0.022 ** − 0.015 − 0.193 *** 0.241 *** − 0.028 ** − 0.020
(0.048) (0.046) (0.011) (0.022) (0.044) (0.047) (0.013) (0.029)
Restaurant 0.073 * − 0.108 *** 0.019 0.016 0.070 * − 0.122 *** 0.024 0.028
(0.038) (0.033) (0.017) (0.021) (0.042) (0.038) (0.020) (0.029)
Logarithm (Invest) − 0.001 − 0.428 * 0.108 0.321 *** − 0.704 0.018 0.155 0.530
(0.270) (0.234) (0.071) (0.102) (0.419) (0.343) (0.088) (0.143)
Observations 3488 2899
Wald chi-square 827.67 *** 659.26 ***
Log pseudolikelihood − 3078.1 − 2869.3
Maximum VIF 5.73 5.81
Prediction rate (%) 66.15% 60.02%
Regional effects Yes Yes

Notes: Marginal effects at the mean were estimated using a multinomial probit regression with robust standard errors and regional effects. The dependent variable is a dummy
variable that is equal to 0 if the firm was subject to an amicable liquidation, 1 to a judicial liquidation, 2 to a sauvegarde procedure and 3 to a redressement judiciaire procedure. The
prediction rate (%) represents the percentage of correctly predicted observations. Delta-method standard errors are included in the brackets. * implies a significant coefficient at
the 10% level, ** at 5% level, and *** at the 1% level. Detailed definitions of the variables are presented in Table 1.

References Blazy, R., Chopard, B., Nigam, N., 2013. Building legal indexes to explain recovery rates:
an analysis of the French and English bankruptcy codes. J. Banking Financ. 37 (6),
1936–1959.
Altig, D., Baker, S., Barrero, J.M., Bloom, N., Bunn, P., Chen, S., Thwaites, G., 2020. Blazy, R., Stef, N., 2020. Bankruptcy procedures in the post-transition economies. Eur.
Economic uncertainty before and during the COVID-19 pandemic. J.Public Econ. J. Law Econ. 50, 7–64.
191, 104274. Bose, U., Filomeni, S., Mallick, S., 2021. Does bankruptcy law improve the fate of
Amankwah-Amoah, J., Khan, Z., Wood, G., 2021. COVID-19 and business failures: the distressed firms? The role of credit channels. J. Corp. Financ. 68, 101836.
paradoxes of experience, scale, and scope for theory and practice. Eur. Manag. J. 39 Bottazzi, G., Grazzi, M., Secchi, A., Tamagni, F., 2011. Financial and economic de­
(2), 179–184. terminants of firm default. J. Evol. Econ. 21 (3), 373–406.
Balcaen, S., Manigart, S., Ooghe, H., 2011. From distress to exit: determinants of the Bowen, H.P., Wiersema, M.F., 2004. Modeling Limited Dependent Variables: Methods
time to exit. J. Evolut. Econ. 21 (3), 407–446. and Guidelines for Researchers in Strategic Management. Emerald Group
Balcaen, S., Manigart, S., Buyze, J., Ooghe, H., 2012. Firm exit after distress: differ­ Publishing Limited.
entiating between bankruptcy, voluntary liquidation and M&A. Small Bus. Econ. Brown, D.T., 1989. Claimholder incentive conflicts in reorganization: the role of
39 (4), 949–975. bankruptcy law. Rev. Financial Stud. 2 (1), 109–123.
Battiston, S., Gatti, D.D., Gallegati, M., Greenwald, B., Stiglitz, J.E., 2007. Credit chains Bruche, M., 2011. Creditor coordination, liquidation timing, and debt valuation. J.
and bankruptcy propagation in production networks. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 31 (6), Financ. Quant. Anal. 1407–1436.
2061–2084. Byrne, J.P., Spaliara, M.E., Tsoukas, S., 2016. Firm survival, uncertainty, and financial
Bergström, C., Eisenberg, T., Sundgren, S., 2002. Secured debt and the likelihood of frictions: is there a financial uncertainty accelerator? Econ. Inquiry 54 (1),
reorganization. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 21 (4), 359–372. 375–390.
Bernstein, S., Colonnelli, E., Iverson, B., 2019. Asset allocation in bankruptcy. J. Financ. Carletti, E., Oliviero, T., Pagano, M., Pelizzon, L., Subrahmanyam, M.G., 2020. The
74 (1), 5–53. COVID-19 shock and equity shortfall: firm-level evidence from Italy. Rev. Corp.
Bhattacharjee, A., Higson, C., Holly, S., Kattuman, P., 2009. Macroeconomic instability Finance Stud. 9 (3), 534–568.
and business exit: Determinants of failures and acquisitions of UK firms. Castelliano, C., Grajzl, P., Watanabe, E., 2021. How has the Covid19 pandemic impacted
Economica 76 (301), 108–131. the courts of law? Evidence from Brazil. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 66, 105989.
Blazy, R., Boughanmi, A., Chopard, B., Letaief, A., 2018. Analyse économique du droit de Cheng, S., Long, J.S., 2007. Testing for IIA in the multinomial logit model. Sociol.
la faillite: les dix fonctions des procédures collectives. Rev. D′économie Financ. 1, Methods Res. 35 (4), 583–600.
117–160. Cros, M., Epaulard, A., Martin, P., 2020. Les défaillances d′entreprises dans la crise
Blazy, R., Chopard, B., 2012. (Un) secured debt and the likelihood of court-supervised Covid-19: zombification ou mise en hibernation?. Point de vue, France Stratégie/
reorganization. Eur. J. Law Econ. 34 (1), 45–61. CAE, December.

15
N. Stef and J.-J. Bissieux International Review of Law & Economics 70 (2022) 106063

Didier, T., Huneeus, F., Larrain, M., Schmukler, S.L., 2021. Financing firms in hiberna­ Le, D., Phi, G., 2021. Strategic responses of the hotel sector to COVID-19: toward a
tion during the COVID-19 pandemic. J. Financ. Stab. 53, 100837. refined pandemic crisis management framework. Int. J. Hosp. Manag. 94, 102808.
Doi, N., 1999. The determinants of firm exit in Japanese manufacturing industries. Lemercier, K., & Mercier, F. (2020). Coronavirus: présentation de l′ordonnance sur les
Small Bus. Econ. 13 (4), 331–337. difficultés des entreprises. Dalloz Actualité, April 1, 2020.
Demary, M. (2021). Will COVID-19 cause insolvencies, zombification or debt de­ Lennox, C., 1999. Identifying failing companies: a re-evaluation of the logit, probit and
leveraging? (No. 3/2021). IW-Kurzbericht. DA approaches. J. Econ. Bus. 51 (4), 347–364.
DeTienne, D.R., Cardon, M.S., 2012. Impact of founder experience on exit intentions. Li, L., Strahan, P.E., Zhang, S., 2020. Banks as lenders of first resort: evidence from the
Small Business Econ. 38 (4), 351–374. COVID-19 crisis. Rev. Corp. Finance Stud. 9 (3), 472–500.
De Vito, A., Gómez, J.P., 2020. Estimating the COVID-19 cash crunch: global evidence Linnenluecke, M.K., McKnight, B., 2017. Community resilience to natural disasters: the
and policy. J. Account. Public Policy 39 (2), 106741. role of disaster entrepreneurship. J. Enterp. Commun. People Places Glob. Econ. 11
Demmou, L., Calligaris, S., Franco, G., Dlugosch, D., McGowan, M.A., Sakha, S. (2021). (1), 166–185.
Insolvency and debt overhang following the COVID-19 outbreak: Assessment of Liu, Y., Qiu, B., Wang, T., 2021. Debt rollover risk, credit default swap spread and stock
risks and policy responses. returns: evidence from the COVID-19 crisis. J. Financ. Stab. 53, 100855.
Didier, T., Huneeus, F., Larrain, M., Schmukler, S.L., 2021. Financing firms in hiberna­ Melcarne, A., Ramello, G.B., 2020. Bankruptcy delay and firms’ dynamics. Small Bus.
tion during the COVID-19 pandemic. J. Finan. Stab. 53, 100837. Econ. 54 (2), 405–419.
Famiglietti, M., Leibovici, F., 2020. Covid-19’s shock on firms’ liquidity and bankruptcy: Miyakawa, D., Oikawa, K., Ueda, K., 2021. Firm exit during the covid-19 pandemic:
evidence from the great recession. Econ. Synop. 7, 1–2. evidence from japan. J. Jpn. Int. Econ. 59, 101118.
Fisher, T.C., Martel, J., 2004. Empirical estimates of filtering failure in court‐supervised OECD, 2021. Business dynamism during the COVID-19 pandemic: which policies for
reorganization. J. Emp. Legal Stud. 1 (1), 143–164. an inclusive recovery? OECD policy responses to coronavirus (COVID-19).
Guerini, M., Nesta, L., Ragot, X., Schiavo, S., 2020. Firm liquidity and solvency under the Peljhan, D., Zajc Kejžar, K., Ponikvar, N., 2020. Ownership structure and firm exit
Covid-19 lockdown in France. OFCE policy Brief 76. routes. Appl. Econ. 52 (15), 1671–1686.
Harada, N., 2007. Which firms exit and why? An analysis of small firm exits in Japan. Pérez, S.E., Llopis, A.S., Llopis, J.A.S., 2004. The determinants of survival of Spanish
Small Bus. Econ. 29 (4), 401–414. manufacturing firms. Rev.f Ind. Org. 25 (3), 251–273.
Hausman, J., McFadden, D., 1984. Specification tests for the multinomial logit model. Philippon, T., 2021. Efficient programs to support businesses during and after lock­
Econ. J. Econ. Soc. 1219–1240. downs. The Review of Corporate Finance Studies. 10 (1), 188–203.
Hsu, H.H., Wu, C.Y.H., 2014. Board composition, grey directors and corporate failure in Ponikvar, N., Kejžar, K.Z., Peljhan, D., 2018. The role of financial constraints for alter­
the UK. Br. Account. Rev. 46 (3), 215–227. native firm exit modes. Small Bus. Econ. 51 (1), 85–103.
Irfan, M., Saha, S., Singh, S.K., 2018. A random effects multinomial logit model for the Powers, D., Xie, Y., 2008. Statistical Methods for Categorical Data Analysis. Emerald
determinants of exit modes. J. Econ. Stud. Group Publishing.
Iwasaki, I., Kim, B.Y., 2020. Legal forms, organizational architecture, and firm failure: a Small, K.A., Hsiao, C., 1985. Multinomial logit specification tests. Int. Econ. Rev.
large survival analysis of Russian corporations. Eur. J. Law Econ. 49 (2), 227–275. 619–627.
Jabeur, S.B., Fahmi, Y., 2018. Forecasting financial distress for French firms: a com­ Stef, N., 2015. Cost sharing and bankruptcy law orientation. Res. Law Econ. 27,
parative study. Empir. Econ. 54 (3), 1173–1186. 181–207.
Jabeur, S.B., Mefteh-Wali, S., Carmona, P., 2021. The impact of institutional and macro­ Stef, N., 2017. Voting rules in bankruptcy law. Rev. Law Econ. 13 (1), 20140063.
economic conditions on aggregate business bankruptcy. Struct. Ch. Econ. Dyn. Stef, N., 2018. Bankruptcy and the difficulty of firing. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 54, 85–94.
Jacobson, T., Von Schedvin, E., 2015. Trade credit and the propagation of corporate Stef, N., 2021. Institutions and corporate financial distress in Central and Eastern
failure: an empirical analysis. Econometrica 83 (4), 1315–1371. Europe. Eur. J. Law Econ. 52 (1), 57–87.
James, S.D., 2016. Strategic bankruptcy: A stakeholder management perspective. J. Stef, N., Jabeur, S.B., 2018. The Bankruptcy prediction power of new entrants. Int. J.
Bus. Res. 69 (2), 492–499. Econ. Bus. 25 (3), 421–440.
Karlson, K.B., Holm, A., Breen, R., 2012. Comparing regression coefficients between Stef, N., Zenou, E., 2021. Management-to-staff ratio and a firm’s exit. J. Bus. Res. 125,
same-sample nested models using logit and probit: A new method. Sociol. 252–260.
Methodol. 42 (1), 286–313. Wenzel, M., Stanske, S., Lieberman, M.B., 2020. Strategic responses to crisis. Strateg.
Kraus, S., Clauss, T., Breier, M., Gast, J., Zardini, A., Tiberius, V., 2020. The economics of Manag. J.
COVID-19: initial empirical evidence on how family firms in five European White, M.J., 1980. Public policy toward bankruptcy: me-first and other priority rules.
countries cope with the corona crisis. Int. J. Entrep. Behav. Res. Bell J. Econ. 550–564.
Laitinen, E.K., 2011. Assessing viability of Finnish reorganization and bankruptcy Wulff, J.N., 2015. Interpreting results from the multinomial logit model: demonstrated
firms. Eur. J. Law Econ. 31 (2), 167–198. by foreign market entry. Org. Res. Methods 18 (2), 300–325.

16

You might also like