You are on page 1of 580

The SAGE

Handbook of

Comparative
Politics

9781412919760-FM.indd i 3/11/2009 6:17:09 PM


9781412919760-FM.indd ii 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM
The SAGE
Handbook of

Comparative
Politics

Edited by
Todd Landman and
Neil Robinson

9781412919760-FM.indd iii 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


© Introduction and Editorial Arrangement, Todd Landman and Neil Robinson 2009

Chapters 1–28 © Sage Publications 2009

First published 2009

Apart from any fair dealing for the purposes of research


or private study, or criticism or review, as permitted under
the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act, 1988, this publication
may be reproduced, stored or transmitted in any form, or by
any means, only with the prior permission in writing of the
publishers, or in the case of reprographic reproduction, in
accordance with the terms of licences issued by the Copyright
Licensing Agency. Enquiries concerning reproduction outside
those terms should be sent to the publishers.

SAGE Publications Ltd


1 Oliver's Yard
55 City Road
London EC1Y 1SP

SAGE Publications Inc.


2455 Teller Road
Thousand Oaks, California 91320

SAGE Publications India Pvt Ltd


B 1/I 1 Mohan Cooperative Industrial Area
Mathura Road
New Delhi 110 044

SAGE Publications Asia-Pacific Pte Ltd


33 Pekin Street #02-01
Far East Square
Singapore 048763

Library of Congress Control Number: 2008930782

British Library Cataloguing in Publication data

A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library

ISBN 978-1-4129-1976-0

Typeset by CEPHA Imaging Pvt. Ltd., Bangalore, India


Printed in Great Britain by MPG Books Group, Bodmin, Cornwall
Printed on paper from sustainable resources

9781412919760-FM.indd iv 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


Contents

List of Tables and Figures viii

Acknowledgements ix

Notes on Contributors x

Introduction 1
Todd Landman and Neil Robinson

PART I METHODS AND FIELDS OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS 11

1 The Distinctiveness of Comparative Research 13


Charles C. Ragin and Claude Rubinson

2 Global Comparative Methods 35


Paul Pennings, Hans Keman, and Jan Kleinnijenhuis

3 Case Studies 50
Darren Hawkins

4 Is there a Quantitative-Qualitative Divide in Comparative


Politics? The Case of Process Tracing 67
James A. Caporaso

5 Establishing Equivalence 84
Jan W. van Deth

6 Comparative Political Sociology 101


Willfried Spohn

7 Comparative Institutional Analysis 125


Vivien A. Schmidt

8 Comparative Political Economy 144


Thomas Plümper

9781412919760-FM.indd v 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


vi CONTENTS

9 The Contribution of Area Studies 159


Stephen E. Hanson

10 Comparative Politics and International Relations 175


John M. Hobson

PART II CLASSIC ISSUES IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS 191

11 Post-Industrial Democracies: Political Economy


and Democratic Partisan Competition 193
Herbert Kitschelt

12 Government Formation 227


Wolfgang C. Müller

13 Institutional Design 246


Josep M. Colomer

14 Comparative Political Behaviour: What is being Compared? 263


Shaun Bowler

15 Changes in the Causes of Democratization through Time 278


Barbara Geddes

16 Political Culture 299


Christian Welzel

17 Revolution 319
Jack A. Goldstone

18 Social Movements 348


Vincent Boudreau and David S. Meyer

19 Corruption 362
Paul Heywood

PART III NEW AND EMERGING ISSUES IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS 379

20 Electoral Authoritarianism 381


Andreas Schedler

21 Electoral Corruption 395


Sarah Birch

22 Comparative Federalism 410


David McKay

9781412919760-FM.indd vi 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


CONTENTS vii

23 Human Rights 423


Todd Landman

24 Governance 439
Philip Keefer

25 Terrorism 463
Jennifer S. Holmes

26 Comparative Regional Integration and Regionalism 477


Fredrik Söderbaum

27 Transitional Justice 497


Paola Cesarini

28 The Globalization of Comparative Public Opinion Research 522


Pippa Norris

Index 541

9781412919760-FM.indd vii 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


List of Tables and Figures

TABLES

Table 1.1 Causal conditions and presence of Black strikebreaking 24


Table 1.2 Truth table for the presence of Black strikebreaking 24
Table 1.3 Truth table for the presence of shaming, with counterfactual conditions 27
Table 2.1 Regression analysis of factors explaining democracy 39
Table 5.1 Different types of equivalence problems and strategies 88
Table 7.1 The four new institutionalisms 138
Table 11.1 Post-industrial democracies and the next tier of countries 198
Table 11.2 Functional Division of Gross Domestic Product, 2005 217
Table 16.1 The concept of self-expression values 305
Table 27.1 Sub-types of transitional justice 500
Table 28.1 Key features of the cross-national series of surveys 523

FIGURES

Figure 7.1 Scholars’ use of the four new institutionalisms: Rational choice (RI),
historical (HI), sociological (SI), and discursive (DI) 139
Figure 16.1 The human empowerment framework 306
Figure 16.2 Self-expression values related to elite-challenging actions and
efficacious orientations 307
Figure 16.3 Self-expression values related to individual’s
definition of democracy and their demand for democracy 309
Figure 16.4 Self-expression values related to the over- and underrating of democracy 310
Figure 22.1 Forms of regional cooperation and integration of decision-making rules
costs and benefits of membership 416
Figure 23.1 The categories and dimensions of human rights 427
Figure 24.1 The evolution of corruption perceptions, Indonesia, 1995–2001 442

9781412919760-FM.indd viii 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


Acknowledgements

We would like to thank all of our contributing authors and the publisher, particularly David
Mainwaring, for their patience and perseverance in the preparation of this manuscript. It has
taken far longer to put this book together than we had hoped or planned and your forbearance
has been much appreciated.
That the book has appeared at all is in no small measure the result of help that we have
received along the way. Karen Buckley has on several occasions provided heroic assistance,
particularly as we went through the final edit. Financial assistance was provided at the start of
the project by the University of Limerick Faculty of Arts, Humanities and Social Sciences
Research Board. Tom Lodge also made a crucial intervention that helped move the process
along at a critical juncture.
On a personal note we’d like to offer the traditional thanks to our families for their toleration
of our absences and complaints about the progress of the work. Neil would like to thank Maura,
for listening to the moaning, both general and specific, and for everything else, and Sáoirse and
Mani for insisting – quite rightly – that playtime was accorded at least equal importance with
all of life’s other activities, including book editing.
Todd offers thanks to Pavlenka and Stephen Small for being great friends and a super sound-
ing board, and extends his heartfelt thanks to Melissa, Oliver, Sophia and Briony Rose (the
newest addition to the Landman clan in the UK) for proving that family life and all that goes
with it offers the best lessons for understanding the big questions in life.

9781412919760-FM.indd ix 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


Notes on Contributors

Sarah Birch is Reader in Politics at the University of Essex and Co-Editor of the British
Journal of Political Science. She is author of Elections and democratization in Ukraine
(Palgrave, 2000), Electoral systems and political transformation in post-communist Europe
(Palgrave-Macmillan, 2003), and co-author of the companion volume, Embodying democracy:
Electoral system design in post-communist Europe (Palgrave-Macmillan, 2002). Her most
recent book is Full participation: A comparative study of compulsory voting (Manchester
University Press, 2008). She has also published numerous articles on electoral systems and
electoral conduct. Her current research interests include electoral conduct and political ethics.
Vincent Boudreau is Professor of Comparative Politics at the City College of New York and
the City University of New York’s Graduate Center. Professor Boudreau writes about protest
movements, state repression and democratization in Southeast Asia, both comparatively, and
with particular focus on the Philippines. His latest book is Resisting dictatorship: Repression
and protest in Southeast Asia (Cambridge, 2004). His most recent research seeks to explain
divergent patterns of post-transition politics in Indonesia and the Philippines, and patterns of
collective violence across Southeast Asia. He also serves on the editorial board of Comparative
Politics.
Shaun Bowler is Professor of Political Science at the University of California, Riverside. His
research interests include comparative political behaviour and electoral systems. He is co-
author, along with Christopher Anderson, Andres Blais, Todd Donovan, and Ola Listhaug of
Loser’s consent (Oxford, 2005).
James A. Caporaso is Professor of Political Science in the Department of Political Science,
University of Washington. He is a former president of the International Studies Association
(1997–98), former Chair of the Executive Committee of the European Community Studies
Association (1995–97), and the editor of Comparative Political Studies. His research interests are
in global political economy, regional integration, and comparative institutional analysis. He has
published articles in the American Political Science Review, West European Politics, Journal
of Common Market Studies, International Organization, and International Studies Quarterly.
Paola Cesarini teaches in the Department of Political Science at Providence College, special-
izing in comparative politics and human rights. Previously, she worked for the World Bank, the
United Nations, and the Institute of Latin American and Iberian Studies at Columbia University.
Her primary research interests are: transitional justice, comparative democratization, and the
politics of memory. She is co-editor, with Katherine Hite, of Authoritarian legacies and democ-
racy in Latin America and Southern Europe (University of Notre Dame Press, 2004). Her work
has appeared in peer-reviewed periodicals – such as the Journal of Latin American Studies and
International Studies Review – and various edited volumes.

9781412919760-FM.indd x 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xi

Josep M. Colomer is Research Professor in Political Science at the Higher Council of


Scientific Research and affiliated professor at Barcelona-Graduate School of Economics. He is
elected member of the Academia Europaea and life member of the American Political Science
Association. Author of two dozen books, published in five languages, including Political insti-
tutions (Oxford University Press, 2001), Handbook of electoral system choice (Palgrave-
Macmillan, 2004) and Great empires, small nations (Routledge, 2007).
Jan W. van Deth is Professor of Political Science and International Comparative Social
Research at the University of Mannheim (Germany). His main research areas are political
culture (especially social capital, political engagement, and citizenship), social change, and
comparative research methods. He was Director of the Mannheim Centre for European Social
Research (MZES), convenor of the international network Citizenship, Involvement, Democracy
(CID), and Book Series Editor of the Studies in European Political Science of the European
Consortium for Political Research (ECPR). He is a Corresponding Member of the Royal
Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences (KNAW) and national coordinator of the German
team for the European Social Survey. Recent publications include Civil society and governance
in Europe. From National to international linkages (edited with William Maloney; Edward
Elgar, 2008).
Barbara Geddes has written about the breakdown in authoritarian regimes, bureaucratic
reform and corruption, political bargaining over institutional choice and change, and research
design. Her publications include Paradigms and sand castles: Theory building and research
design in comparative politics (2003), Politician’s dilemma: Building state capacity in Latin
America (1994), ‘What do we know about democratization after twenty years?’ Annual Review
of Political Science (1999) and ‘A game theoretic model of reform in Latin American democra-
cies,’ American Political Science Review (1991). Her current research focuses on politics inside
dictatorships. She teaches Latin American politics, authoritarian politics, and research design
at UCLA.
Jack A. Goldstone is Hazel Professor and Director of the Center for Global Policy at George
Mason University. He is the author of Revolution and rebellion in the early modern world
(California, 1991), and editor of The Encyclopedia of Political Revolutions (Congressional
Quarterly, 1998). He has received the Distinguished Contribution to Scholarship award of the
American Sociological Association, the Arnoldo Momigliano Prize of the Historical Society,
and fellowships from the ACLS and the MacArthur Foundation.
Stephen E. Hanson is Herbert J. Ellison Professor in the Department of Political Science and
the Director of the Ellison Center for Russian, East European, and Central Asian Studies at the
Jackson School of International Studies at the University of Washington. He is the author of
Time and revolution: Marxism and the design of Soviet institutions (University of North
Carolina Press, 1997), winner of the 1998 Wayne S. Vucinich book award from the American
Association for the Advancement of Slavic Studies. He is also a co-editor of Capitalism and
democracy in Central and Eastern Europe: Assessing the legacy of communist rule, (Cambridge
University Press, 2003), a co-author of Postcommunism and the theory of democracy (Princeton
University Press, 2001), and the author of numerous journal articles examining postcommunist
politics in comparative perspective.
Darren G. Hawkins is Professor of Political Science at Brigham Young University, where he
teaches and researches on international relations, human rights, and international organizations.
He has coedited a volume of Delegation and agency in international organizations (Cambridge
University Press) and authored International human rights and authoritarian rule in Chile

9781412919760-FM.indd xi 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


xii NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

(Nebraska University Press). He has also published a number of scholarly articles on interna-
tional human rights, international institutions, and democracy. These have appeared in
International Organization, Journal of Politics, International Studies Quarterly, Comparative
Politics, Global Governance, Review of International Studies, and other journals.
Paul M. Heywood is Sir Francis Hill Professor of European Politics at the University of
Nottingham, and Adjunct Professor at Hunan University, China, where he is also Senior
Adviser to the Anti-Corruption Research Center. He has published widely on political corrup-
tion, as well as on contemporary European politics. Amongst his recent books are Spain and
the European Union (with Carlos Closa; Palgrave, 2004) and Developments in European
politics (edited with Erik Jones, Martin Rhodes and Ulrich Sedelmeier; Palgrave, 2006). He is
currently working on issues of administrative reform and corruption risks.
John M. Hobson is Professor of Politics and International Relations at the University of
Sheffield, and is co-director of the Political Economy Research Centre and a sub-editor of
Political Studies. His main research interest lies in the critique of Eurocentrism and the recon-
struction of a non-Eurocentric account of inter-civilizational relations and globalization, past
and present. He has authored/co-authored six books to date, two of which are co-edited
volumes. His most recent books are: The eastern origins of western civilisation (CUP, 2004);
Everyday politics of the world economy (CUP, 2007; co-edited with Leonard Seabrooke). He
has published over 40 book chapters and journal articles, and is currently working on a book
that contains some of John A. Hobson’s 1930’s lectures, provisionally entitled The struggle for
the international mind.
Jennifer S. Holmes, is Associate Professor of Political Economy and Political Science at the
University of Texas at Dallas. Her major area of research is political violence, terrorism, and
political development with an emphasis on Latin America and Southern Europe. She is the
author of Terrorism and democratic stability (Manchester University Press, 2001, Transaction,
2006), Terrorism and democratic stability revisited (Manchester University Press, 2008), and
Guns, drugs, and development: Violence in Colombia (with Sheila Amin Gutiérrez de Piñeres
and Kevin Curtin, University of Texas Press, 2009). She is also the editor of New approaches
to comparative politics: Insights from political theory (Lexington Books, 2003, 2008), and co-
editor of Latin American democracy: Emerging reality or endangered species? (Routledge,
2008). Articles by Dr. Holmes have been published in Terrorism and Political Violence, Latin
American Politics & Society, Bulletin of Latin American Research, International Journal of
Social Economics, Studies in Conflict and Terrorism, International Journal of Public
Administration, and Revista de Estudios Colombianos.
Philip Keefer is Lead Research Economist in the Development Research Group of the World
Bank. The focus of his work, based on experience in countries ranging from Bangladesh, Benin,
Brazil, and the Dominican Republic to Indonesia, México, Perú and Pakistan, is the determinants
of political incentives to pursue economic development. His research, on issues such as the
impact of insecure property rights on growth; the effects of political credibility on policy; and
the sources of political credibility in democracies and autocracies, has appeared in journals rang-
ing from the Quarterly Journal of Economics to the American Review of Political Science.
Hans Keman is Professor and Chair in Comparative Political Science at the VU University
Amsterdam. He has been editor of the European Journal of Political Research and recently of
Acta Politica. He has published books and articles on Parties and Government in Parliamentary
Democracies, Democracy and Social and Economic Performance, Social Democracy and the
Welfare State, institutional theory and on Comparative Methods.

9781412919760-FM.indd xii 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xiii

Herbert Kitschelt is Professor for Comparative Politics at Duke University, North Carolina.
In recent years he has primarily worked on the comparison of parties and party systems in
advanced industrial democracies, post-communist Eastern Europe and Latin America. He is the
co-editor of Patrons, clients and policies (Cambridge University Press, 2007) and co-author
of the forthcoming Latin American party systems (Cambridge University Press, 2009). He is
currently involved in a global comparison of patterns of democratic accountability in electoral
democracies.
Jan Kleinnijenhuis is Professor of Communication Science at the VU University Amsterdam
since 1998. His research interests include agenda building and agenda setting processes in
which both old and new media play their role, as well as methods for content analysis and panel
survey analysis to chart these processes in great detail. He has published on these subjects in
journals such as Political Analysis, the British Journal of Political Science, Journal of
Communication, and the Harvard International Journal of Press/Politics. Together with
Paul Pennings and Hans Keman he wrote Doing research in Political Science: An introduction
to comparative methods and statistics (Sage, 1999/2006).
Todd Landman is Reader in the Department of Government and Director of the Centre for
Democratic Governance at the University of Essex. He is author of Studying human rights
(Routledge, 2006), Protecting human rights (Georgetown, 2005), and Issues and methods in
comparative politics (Routledge, 2000, 2003, 2008); co-author of Measuring human rights
(Routledge, 2009), Governing Latin America (Polity, 2003), and Citizenship rights and social
movements (Oxford, 1997, 2000); and editor of Human rights, Volumes I–IV (Sage, 2009). He
has published articles in International Studies Quarterly, The British Journal of Political
Science, Human Rights Quarterly, Democratization, The British Journal of Politics and
International Relations, and Political Studies.
David McKay is Professor of Government at the University of Essex. He is the author of
Federalism and European Union (Oxford, 1999) and Designing Europe: Comparative lessons
from the federal experience (Oxford, 2001) which won the W.J.M. Mackenzie prize for the best
book published in political science, 2001. His research includes work on the sustainability of
federal systems and in particular the links between institutional arrangements and the spatial
dimension to political conflict including the political economy of European monetary union.
David S. Meyer is Professor of Sociology, Political Science, and Planning, Policy and Design
at the University of California, Irvine. He has published numerous articles on social movements
and social change, and is author or coeditor of six books, most recently, The politics of protest:
Social movements in America (Oxford University Press). He is most interested in the connec-
tions among institutional politics, public policy, and social movements, particularly in regard
to issues of war and peace.
Wolfgang C. Müller is Professor in Political Science, University of Mannheim and former
Director of the Mannheim Centre for European Social Research (MZES). His recent book
publications include Policy, office, or votes? How political parties in Western Europe make
hard decisions (co-edited with Kaare Strøm; Cambridge University Press, 1999), Coalition
governments in Western Europe (co-edited with Kaare Strøm; Oxford University Press, 2000),
Delegation and accountability in parliamentary democracies (co-edited with Kaare Strøm and
Torbjörn Bergman; Oxford University Press, 2003), Political parties and electoral change
(co-edited with Peter Mair and Fritz Plasser; Sage, 2004), and Cabinets and coalition bargain-
ing: The democratic life cycle in Western Europe (co-edited with Kaare Strøm and Torbjörn
Bergman; Oxford University Press, 2008). His research interests include political representation,

9781412919760-FM.indd xiii 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


xiv NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

delegation relationships, government coalitions, political parties, and political institutions in


Europe.
Pippa Norris is the McGuire Lecturer in Comparative Politics at the John F. Kennedy School
of Government, Harvard University. She has also served as Director of the Democratic
Governance Group at UNDP in New York. Her work compares democracy, elections and public
opinion, political communications, and gender politics in many countries worldwide. A well-
known public speaker and prize-winning author, she has published almost three-dozen books.
This includes a series of volumes for Cambridge University Press: A virtuous circle (2000,
winner of the 2006 Doris A. Graber award), Digital divide (2001), Democratic phoenix (2002)
and Rising tide (with Ronald Inglehart, 2003), Electoral engineering (2004), Sacred and
secular (with Ronald Inglehart, 2004, winner of the Virginia Hodgkinson prize), Radical right
(2005), and Driving democracy: Do power-sharing institutions work? (2008), Her most recent
books are Cultural convergence? Cosmopolitan communications and national diversity (with
Ronald Inglehart, CUP, 2009), and an edited volume, Guardians of the public interest:
Strengthening the news media, democratic governance and human development (The World
Bank, 2009).
Paul Pennings is Associate Professor of Political Science at the VU University Amsterdam. His
research and teaching interests are in the fields of Comparative (European) Politics and
Comparative Methods and Statistics. He has publised widely in peer-reviewed academic jour-
nals in political science, such as Acta Politica, Electoral Studies, European Journal of Political
Research, European Union Politics, Party Politics, Political Studies and Sociological Methods
and Research. His recent publications include Doing research in Political Science.
An introduction to comparative methods and Statistics (with Hans Keman and Jan Kleinnijenhuis
Sage, 2nd edition, 2006) and (with Christine Arnold) ‘Is Constitutional Politics like Politics
“At Home”? The Case of the EU Constitution’, Political Studies 56 (4): 789–806, which was a
finalist for the Harrison Prize for the best article published in Political Studies in 2008.
Thomas Plümper is Professor of Government at the University of Essex and Director of the
Essex Summer School in Social Science Data Analysis. He also holds affiliations with the Max
Planck Institute of Economics in Jena, the Institute for International Integration Studies, Dublin
and the Peace Research Institute in Oslo. He published articles in the American Journal of
Political Science, International Organization, Political Analysis, Annals of the Association of
American Geographers, World Development, European Journal of Political Research, the
British Journal of Political Science, Journal of Conflict Resolution, and International Studies
Quarterly.
Charles C. Ragin holds a joint appointment as Professor of Sociology and Political Science at
the University of Arizona. His substantive interests include such topics as the welfare state,
ethnic political mobilization, and international political economy. However, for the past two
decades his work has focused primarily on broad issues in methodology, especially the chal-
lenge of bringing some of the logic and spirit of small-N case-oriented research to the study of
medium-sized and large Ns. His most recent books are Redesigning social inquiry: Fuzzy sets
and beyond (University of Chicago Press, 2008) and Configurational comparative methods:
Qualitative comparative analysis and related techniques (co-edited with Benoit Rihoux; Sage
Publications, 2008).
Neil Robinson is Senior Lecturer in the Department of Politics and Public Administration at
the University of Limerick, Ireland. He is the author of Ideology and the collapse of the Soviet
system. A critical history of Soviet ideological discourse (Elgar, 1995), Post-communist politics

9781412919760-FM.indd xiv 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS xv

(with Karen Henderson, Prentice Hall, 1997), and Russia: a state of uncertainty (Routledge,
2002), and editor of Institutions and political change in Russia (Macmillan, 2000), Reforging
the weakest link: global political economy and post-Soviet change in Russia, Ukraine and
Belarus (Ashgate, 2004), and State-building. Theory and practice (with Aidan Hehir, Routledge,
2007). He has published in Soviet Studies, European Journal of Political Research, The Journal
of Communist Studies and Transitional Politics, Review of International Political Economy,
Communist and Post-Communist Studies and other journals.
Claude Rubinson is a Ph.D. candidate in the Department of Sociology at the University of
Arizona. His interests include globalization and comparative political-economy; art, technol-
ogy, and culture; social stratification; and research methodology. He uses case-oriented, com-
parative research methods to study the relationship between political-economic decline and
cultural expression. His dissertation examines the changing aesthetics and ideologies of the
Arts and Crafts movement, which arose with the decline of British hegemony. In addition to
his work on comparative methodology, he has also published work on multi-valued logic and
logical ambiguity in ACM’s /SIGMOD Record/.
Andreas Schedler is Professor of Political Science at the Centro de Investigación y Docencia
Económicas (CIDE) in Mexico City. His recent publications include Electoral authoritarianism:
The dynamics of unfree competition (Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2006), “The Mexican Standoff:
The Mobilization of Distrust,” Journal of Democracy (January, 2007), “Democrats with
Adjectives: Linking Direct and Indirect Measures of Democratic Support” (with Rodolfo
Sarsfield), European Journal of Political Research (August, 2007), and “The Contingent Power
of Authoritarian Elections,” Democratization by elections? A new mode of transition, ed.
Staffan I. Lindberg (Johns Hopkins University Press, 2009). His ongoing comparative research
focuses on the internal dynamics of electoral authoritarian regimes worldwide.
Vivien A. Schmidt is Jean Monnet Professor of European Integration and Director of the
Center for International Relations at Boston University, and Visiting Professor at Sciences Po,
Paris. She has written widely in the areas of European political economy, institutions and
democracy, as well as political theory. Recent publications include Democracy in Europe
(Oxford, 2006), The futures of European capitalism (Oxford, 2002), Welfare and work in the
open economy (2 volumes co-edited with F.W. Scharpf, Oxford, 2000), and “Discursive
Institutionalism: The Explanatory Power of Ideas and Discourse” Annual Review of Political
Science (2008).
Fredrik Söderbaum is Associate Professor of Peace and Development Research at the School
of Global Studies, University of Gothenburg, and Senior Associate Research Fellow at the
United Nations University-Comparative Regional Integration Studies (UNU-CRIS), Bruges,
Belgium. His latest books include EU and the global South (co-edited with Patrik Stålgren,
Lynne Rienner, 2009, forthcoming); Afro-regions: The dynamics of cross-border micro-
regionalism in Africa (co-edited with Ian Taylor, Nordic Africa Institute, 2008), The EU as a
global player: The politics of interregionalism (co-edited with Luk van Langenhove, Routledge,
2006), The political economy of regionalism: The case of Southern Africa (Palgrave Macmillan,
2004), Theories of New Regionalism (co-edited with Tim Shaw, Palgrave Macmillan, 2003).
Willfried Spohn is Adjunct Professor in sociology at FU Berlin. He was director of an EU
research project ‘Representations of Europe and the Nation in current and prospective member
states – elites, media and civil society’ at the European University Viadrina, Frankfurt-Odra.
His recent publications are (with Steven Hanson): Can Europe work? Germany and the recon-
struction of postcommunist societies, Seattle, 1995; ‘History and the Social Sciences,’

9781412919760-FM.indd xv 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


xvi NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS

International Encyclopedia of the Social and Behaviorial Sciences, London, 2001; (with
Anna Triandafyllidou): Europeanization, national identities and migration, (2002), and
‘Multiple Modernity, Nationalism and Religion - A Global Perspective,’ in: U. Schuerkens
(ed.), Global forces and local life – Worlds, (2003).
Christian Welzel is Professor of Political Science at Jacobs University Bremen and Vice-
President of the World Values Survey Association. He is also affiliated faculty and a regular
visitor of the Center for the Study of Democracy at UC Irvine. His research focuses on the
themes of democratization, modernization, human development, as well as human values and
cultural change. Christian Welzel has published more than 80 scholarly articles and chapters.
His most recent book (with Ronald Inglehart) is Modernaization, cultural change and
democracy: The human development sequence (New York: Cambridge University Press).

9781412919760-FM.indd xvi 3/11/2009 6:17:10 PM


Introduction
Todd Landman and Neil Robinson

Comparative politics has firmly established politics research. There are three main jour-
itself as a significant, vibrant, and definitive nals dedicated to comparative politics, includ-
tradition and field of inquiry in the discipline ing World Politics, Comparative Politics, and
of political science. The field, at least as far as Comparative Political Studies, while other
research and postgraduate teaching are con- top-rated journals in the field, such as the
cerned, has moved well beyond its early American Journal of Political Science, Journal
‘public law’ phase of comparative institution- of Politics, British Journal of Political Science,
alism and its more parochial labelling as ‘any- International Studies Quarterly, Government
thing that studies countries outside the United and Opposition, Journal of Conflict Resolution,
States’ (see, e.g. Valenzuela, 1988; Landman, and Journal of Peace Research have a signifi-
2000, 2003, 2008). It is now one that is at the cant and frequent number of articles that can
centre of debates on normative and empirical broadly be classified as comparative.
theory (Lichbach and Zuckerman, 1997), In many ways, the field of comparative
quantitative and qualitative methodology politics has been defined by what it does,
(King et al., 1994; Brady and Collier, 2004; namely, providing explanation and under-
Gerring, 2007), and the ability for political standing of important social and political
science scholarship to have practical relevance phenomena through the comparison of simi-
to practitioners and policy makers across a larities and differences across different units,
range of significant issues areas in the contem- where such units are typically, but not
porary world (e.g. Flyvbjerg, 2001; Schram exclusively, nation states. The methodological
and Caterino, 2006). The American Political core of comparative politics draws on J. S.
Science Review (and now Perspectives on Mill’s (1843/1961) methods of ‘difference’
Politics) has long had a special section devoted and ‘agreement’, and allows for some form
to book reviews in comparative politics, the of ‘control’ to be introduced in ways that
specialized section of the American Political approximate the experimental or quasi-
Science Association on Comparative Politics experimental conditions found in the natural
has over 1,500 members and is the largest of sciences (see Faure, 1994; Mahoney and
the Association’s sections, and major political Goertz, 2004; Goertz, 2005). In short, to com-
science research meetings such as the European pare is to control. Alongside the methodologi-
Consortium for Political Research’s annual cal identity of comparative politics, some have
workshops are often dominated by comparative argued that the field has its own distinctive

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:1 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


2 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

theoretical traditions (e.g. Chilcote, 1994), but comparative and single-country analysis.
today comparative politics is characterized This challenge suggests that all comparative
more through the development of rational, analysis broadly occupies a continuum that
structural, and cultural theories (see Lichbach trades the number of observations off against
and Zuckerman, 1997) that are tested using the strength of the inferences that are drawn
some form of comparative method. Evidence (see Landman, 2000, 2003, 2008). For King
is collected and analyzed in systematic fash- et al. (1994), the inferences drawn from
ion to yield substantive inferences that typi- small-N comparative analysis and single-
cally go beyond the confines of the case or country studies could be strengthened only
cases that have been compared. through raising observations, which is
From the early comparisons until now, achieved through analyzing individual level
comparative method has advanced consider- data within studies that compare few coun-
ably, which is a function of greater attention tries, or adding countries and time to the
to questions of case selection, the logic of analysis such that variables are given room
inference and raising the number of observa- to vary and comparative studies avoid inde-
tions, data availability, and enhanced compu- terminate research designs. Despite the
ter technology, among others. These new achievements of the classic comparativists,
themes and developments are raised repeat- King et al. (1994) were able to show that
edly across the chapters of this volume. many studies still suffered from selection
Classic ‘first generation’ comparativists such bias and that many of the findings from the
as Gabriel Almond, Robert Dahl, Barrington existing literature could be called into ques-
Moore, Seymour Martin Lipset, Samuel tion on this basis (see also Geddes, 2003).
Huntington, Arend Lijphart, Giovanni Sartori, Since the publication of Designing Social
Ted Gurr, Theda Skocpol, Adam Przeworski, Inquiry, there have been many new volumes
and Henry Teune achieved so much in setting that respond to, challenge, and modify the
the research agenda of the field across a main arguments laid out by King et al. (1994).
range of seminal topics such as democracy, A special symposium on the book appeared in
political violence, political development, the American Political Science Review in which
social revolution, institutional design, and qualitative scholars responded to the challenge.
many others, while at the same time develop- Book-length responses and clarifications most
ing strategies for comparison that were atten- notably include Mahoney and Rueschemeyer’s
tive to variation in the outcomes that were to (2003) Comparative historical analysis in the
be explained, as well as rules of inquiry that social sciences, Brady and Collier’s (2004)
addressed questions of concept development, Rethinking social inquiry, George and Bennet’s
conceptual stretching, case selection (at least (2005) Case studies and theory development
partially), and theory-building. These schol- in the social sciences, and Gerring’s (2007)
ars generally saw a methodological division Case study research. Stronger challenges to
in the field between those engaged in large-N the position adopted in Designing social
cross national quantitative analysis on the inquiry came in the form of Bent Flyvjberg’s
one hand, and those engaged in either small-N (2001) Making social science matter and
comparative analysis or single-country case Schram and Caterino’s (2006) Making political
studies on the other (Lijphart, 1971).1 This science matter, which attempt to rescue the
division has persisted to some degree in the substantive role for social (and political) sci-
field but was significantly challenged through ence in studying questions and providing
the publication of Designing social inquiry answers to problems in ways that have greater
(King et al., 1994), which argued that meaning and understanding for the world at
the same logic of inference that applies to large and to avoid the overly scientific and
large-N statistical analysis (on individual or ‘technicist’ element that had begun to dominate
aggregate data) should apply to small-N the profession.

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:2 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


INTRODUCTION 3

These various developments in the field topic, and tried to look toward future devel-
have shown that now, more than ever before, opments within the field of comparative poli-
scholars are concerned with how to carry out tics. The volume should, we hope, provide a
the best research on the most pertinent topics primer on how to ‘do’ or ‘think’ about com-
in ways that provide answers to significant parative politics, and on what the relationship
questions that are supported by the best avail- of comparative politics research might be to
able evidence that is analyzed in the most other areas of political study, and to show the
systematic fashion. The fault lines between many ways in which the field has responded
different types of practitioners have not been and is responding to new events and chal-
closed through the development of any uni- lenges in the political world. The extent to
fied political methodology for comparative which the book can do this will depend, to a
politics. Rather, there has been considerable large degree, on how it is used. Books such
dialogue across the ‘separate tables’ (Almond, as this are generally used selectively, that is,
1990) within the field that recognizes the dif- the reader dips in the book to read a chapter
ferent ways in which comparative method or two on issues that they have to research,
matters for studying significant social and and the rest of the volume goes unread. Such
political phenomena; Comparativists may instrumental reading has its place but we
often work at separate tables but they do so in would encourage any reader using the book
the same places; they work together, as in this way to be a bit less instrumental and
Stepan (2001: 2) put it, in ‘invisible colleges’. to follow themes between chapters and in
Today, comparativists engage in the quantita- particular, to follow points made about
tive comparison of many countries, qualita- method and approach from the chapters on
tive and quantitative comparison of few substantive research themes to the chapters
countries and qualitative and quantitative in Part I of the book on method and the fields
analysis conducted in single countries. These of comparative politics and vice versa. Ideally
comparisons typically use the nation state and a reader should work their way through all of
annual observation as the basic unit of analy- Part I of the book as well as looking at any of
sis, but many studies compare individual level the later chapters on research themes.
data across and within countries, and analysis However since that might be too much for
of sub-national units, such as states within the researcher in a hurry we have sought to
federal systems have provided new avenues assist reading between the chapters of this
to raise observations within single country book by providing brief summaries of the
studies. chapters in Part I and by pointing to some
The Sage Handbook of Comparative (but by no means all) of the connections that
Politics has been organized in ways that exist to later chapters in the course of those
address these larger developments in the field summaries. It is unusual to just summarize
by bringing together leading academics in some chapters of a book rather than all of
comparative politics from across many dif- them. But a handbook is not an edited work
ferent approaches and many different sub- where a number of authors seek to explore an
stantive topics. The volume is organized in issue from a number of different perspectives
three parts. Part I looks at methods and the and the editors draw out the common lessons
fields of comparative politics; Part II details of their authors’ work in an introduction.
research achievements and developments in A handbook presents a much wider selection
some of the classic themes of comparative of topics and approaches and thus any sum-
politics research; Part III looks at emerging mary of the whole would be little more than
research themes and issues. Throughout an extended contents page for the most
the chapters, the authors have summarized part. Many of the substantive issues addressed
developments within their particular area of in Parts II and III of this volume do not
interest, discussed challenges relating to the relate to one another directly except through

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:3 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


4 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

comparative method; the best way of having problems are contextualized by reference to
these chapters talk to one another is thus to other research traditions in political science,
relate them where possible to the method most notably area studies and the study of
chapters in Part I. This is particularly impor- international relations, the two fields that
tant because all areas of comparative politics most clearly, explicitly, and sometimes acri-
research, as is apparent in the chapters in moniously (all sides being guilty) cut across
Parts II and III are undergoing change. There comparative political research. Appreciating
are many reasons for this. Partly change is methodological problems and the place of
driven by intellectual developments within comparative research in any substantive
the broad comparative politics research com- research area, whether it be a classic theme
munity. Works like King et al. (1994) and the such as the study of revolution (here covered
responses to it listed above are one sign of by Jack Goldstone) or a new area such as tran-
this, but there has also been considerable sitional justice or human rights (see the chap-
development of approaches driven by the ters by Paola Cesarini and Todd Landman),
clash of contrasting theories within compara- requires that we work and think – and there-
tive politics (for example in comparative fore read – back and forth between method,
political sociology and comparative institu- theory and data much more rigorously, widely
tional analysis, as the chapters included here and consistently than might have been the
by Willfried Spohn and Vivien Schmidt case in the past. This is perhaps particularly
show). Equally, change is being driven by important in newer areas of study where
inter-related changes in global politics and there may be a dearth of work or data that can
political systems across the globe, not least settle conceptual problems inductively, where
the spread – no matter that it is uneven and there are issues about what is being studied
frequently unfinished – of democracy. These (is the topic one that is actually fit to be stud-
changes are generating new research themes, ied comparatively or is it an international
such as electoral authoritarianism and cor- relations issue?), and where there are policy
ruption (see the chapters by Andreas Schedler imperatives to provide an answer to a research
and Sarah Birch in this volume), or allowing problem quickly. One or more of these issues
them to be studied in a more properly com- pertains at least to the comparative study of
parative fashion for the first time. They are terrorism and processes of regionalization as
providing new research data on subjects such is demonstrated in the chapters by Holmes
as government formation from a wider range and Söderbaum.
of cases (see the chapter by Wolfgang It is thus important for readers to try and
Müller), or public opinion (see the chapter by work between the methodological and theo-
Pippa Norris), or pose questions about how retical points raised in Part I and the ideas
lessons learnt from longstanding research about research themes presented in Parts II
themes, such as inquiry in to democratiza- and III so that issues of change identified in
tion, political economy, and democratic these latter parts of the handbook can be
partisan competition, social movements, or addressed rigorously. There is no consistent
corruption (see the chapters by Barbara answer to how to do comparative research in
Geddes, Herbert Kitschelt, Vincent Boudreau Part I of this book, rather the chapters within
and David Meyer, and Paul Heywood) can it discuss the status of comparative politics,
be exported beyond the boundaries of conceptual specification, large-N versus
their original sets of cases. These changes small-N, and case study methods to highlight
and the new themes and possibilities for the nature of the classic trade-off between
research that they raise can only be made ‘reliability (which improves with the increase
sense of through engagement with the of cases) and validity (which is hampered by
methodological issues that comparative a large number of cases)’, as Paul Pennings,
political analysis raises and when research Hans Keman and Jan Kleinnijenhuis put it

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:4 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


INTRODUCTION 5

in their chapter, and what needs to be done or general overview of the issues that case study
thought about to work around the trade-off. work raises, its use in generating and assess-
In the first chapter, Charles Ragin and Claude ing generalizable hypotheses, the issues that
Rubinson argue for the distinctiveness of different forms of case study, such as coun-
comparative politics as a bridge between terfactual and congruence analysis, and proc-
large-N and case study work and for its for- ess tracing, raise, and the relationship of case
malization as a method using qualitative studies to different deterministic and proba-
comparative analysis (QCA). This argument bilistic theories. Caporaso focuses specifi-
follows Ragin’s earlier work (Ragin, 1987; cally on the benefits of process tracing and
1994; 2000) and the effort therein to specify the issues raised by that. Process tracing
how traditional methodological core of com- seeks to see if an observed phenomena can
parative politics, Mill’s methods of ‘differ- be related to a hypothesized cause by a series
ence’ and ‘agreement’, can be augmented to of intervening variables. Caporaso distin-
deal with problems of multiple causes for the guishes the analytical devices and techniques
same phenomenon across a range of cases. necessary to distinguish types of process
Formalization using Ragin’s QCA method is a tracing and their relationship to other
means of dealing rigorously with what he and forms of explanation based on quantitive
Rubinson call a ‘moderate number of cases method or cross-case comparison. The care
(usually around five to fifty)’, whilst still taken in Hawkins’ and Caporaso’s chapters
being sensitive to the details of each case. to distinguish the different logics at work in
Formalization of comparative method as case study research should be contrasted
suggested by Ragin and Rubinson deals with with the discussions and comparisons of
many of the methodological issues associ- different case studies in the later chapters of
ated with smallish (but not really small) N the book.
research. However, what if there are a large-N Finally, the discussion of general method-
of cases or if there are only a very, very few ological issues is rounded off in Jan van
N, or if cases need to be worked up singly for Deth’s chapter, which puts all of the issues
some reason? The chapters by Paul Pennings, raised above into perspective by reviewing
Hans Keman and Jan Kleinnijenhuis, James how we establish the ground of comparison
Caporaso, and Darren Hawkins look at these by ascertaining equivalence. van Deth sur-
issues. Pennings et al. give a practical exam- veys the various forms of bias that can hinder
ple of how conceptualization is important the establishment of equivalence and strate-
and underpins large-N comparison. The gies that can be deployed to deal with them.
example that they use to demonstrate the van Deth’s chapter highlights the observation
importance of conceptualization and how it made above that to compare is to control. It
influences findings in large-N research also confirms the general conclusion of the
should be read in conjunction with Geddes preceding chapters, namely that no matter
chapter in Part II on the causes of democrati- what the particular theoretical basis of
zation (and vice versa), since Geddes also enquiry or the technique of analysis to be
raises the question of comparability of used conceptual development and specifica-
democratizing systems over time and issues tion is always the first order priority in com-
of what needs to be conceptualized to insure parative analysis.
comparability and robust conclusions about The other chapters in Part I introduce broad
democratization. The next two chapters by areas of comparative political analysis and
Hawkins and Caporaso deal with problems relate comparison to area studies and interna-
of case study research and its relationship to tional relations. We start with Willfried
small- and large-N research. Broadly, both Spohn’s chapter on comparative political soci-
see qualitative methods as complementary to ology since the development of comparative
quantitative methods. Hawkins provides a political sociology mirrors the development

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:5 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


6 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

of comparative politics more generally. have developed in the wake of the moderni-
Spohn’s chapter therefore sets the scene for zation paradigm, and how the struggle with
the next two chapters on comparative institu- that paradigm continues as elements of it
tional analysis and comparative political reasserted themselves after the collapse of
economy. This is because the crises of the communism in the late 1980s and under the
first major paradigm of comparative politics, cover of ideas about the globalization as
modernization, from the 1960s onwards led homogenization.
to the diversification of comparative political The next two chapters spin off from these
sociology research on the one hand, and on themes. Vivien Schmidt examines develop-
the other created the impetus for the develop- ments in comparative institutional analysis.
ment of comparative institutional analysis This has been one of the most productive
and comparative political economy.2 These areas of comparative research, particularly of
crises were both intellectual, as it was recog- small-N research, over the last decade thanks
nized that the paradigm was failing to account to the emergence of new institutionalism.
for variation in the development experience, With Schmidt’s chapter we begin to see the
and ‘real-world’ political, as the template of tension – sometimes productive, sometimes
western industrial democracy, and the moderni- conflictive, and occasionally both – between
zation experience that went with it, was rejected rational, structural, and cultural theories since
in large parts of the globe. The modernization the mainstream varieties of new institutional-
paradigm’s structural-functionalism, Spohn ism are underpinned by rational, structural/
argues, had allowed the incorporation of the historical, or cultural/ideational assumptions.
political (government, ideology and idea- Schmidt posits that the three mainstream
tional factors, social and political movements new institutionalist positions are in dialogue
and parties, policy, etc.) in an overarching with each other since they, and the scholars
framework of social evolution. The collapse working with them, can be placed on a
of the modernization paradigm as a hegem- continuum, and argues for a fourth form of
onic approach to comparative political soci- new institutionalism,discursive institutional-
ology (and hence too much of comparative ism. Scholars working from this theoretical
politics generally) encouraged developments position, she argues, draw on the other forms
within comparative political sociology and of institutionalism and can see themselves as
beyond it. Research in comparative political loyal to a tradition, but are joined together by
sociology became more diverse as other tra- their efforts at explaining change by demon-
ditions that spoke to social evolution, such as strating the causal influence of ideas. Thomas
Marxism and neo-Marxism, reasserted them- Plümper’s chapter provides further discus-
selves, and as new paradigms developed, such sion of the rational choice version of new
as post-colonialism and post-modernism, that institutionalism and places it in the context
challenged the positivistic assumptions of all of the general development of comparative
grand theoretical narratives about human political economy. This, as Plümper notes is
development. At the same time, the weaken- different to other fields of comparative polit-
ing of the modernization paradigm enabled ical inquiry in that it is ‘programmatic’. By
the assertion of the autonomy of politics, programmatic Plümper means that compara-
which helped to reinvigorate institutional tive political economy is concerned to
analysis and encouraged the use of more develop interdisciplinary research, drawing
individualistic research methodologies and as it does on insights and methods from eco-
theories, which helped the development and nomics to try to formulate general theories
spread of political economy approaches. of political phenomena. Political economy
Spohn concentrates on developments within might also be termed programmatic in the
comparative political sociology to show sense that this methodological approach and
how rational, structural, and cultural theories aspiration to develop general theories of

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:6 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


INTRODUCTION 7

politics has developed as a research pro- for understanding any society, and some of the
gramme to cover an ever wider number of claims to superiority of comparative politics
research topics. Plümper outlines how this researchers based on the assertion that com-
has happened, starting with voting and the parison is scientific. The development of area
behaviour of politicians as vote maximizers studies and comparative politics, Hanson
and interest group behaviour. These areas of shows, has in fact often been complementary
research laid the foundations for the expan- despite the fiery rhetoric across the ‘divide’,
sion of political economy approaches in to and many of the charges against area studies
new areas: institutional analysis, the macr- are fairly flimsy: area studies have been theo-
oeconomic consequences of elections and retically diverse, rather than politically con-
electoral systems, and constitutional political strained by funders, and has lead to
economy (the study of how institutional generalization as often as not in political sci-
design influences decision making and ence, if not in other disciplinary sections (such
the distribution of decision making powers). as history) of the broader area studies com-
Plümper gives an overview of each of these munity. Hanson does find some merit with the
areas of research, plus the emerging area criticism that the definition of area can fre-
of the comparative study of open economies. quently be unthinking (a point also raised for
More detail on these areas, and some discus- the study of regionalization in Söderbaum’s
sion of alternative approaches to them can chapter), arbitrary and indefensible from the
be found in some of the chapters that point of view of comparative politics. But the
follow, in particular those by Kitschelt (on alternatives, comparing by regimes across
political economy and democratic partisan the globe rather than within regions for exam-
competition in postindustrial democracies), ple, means defining categories, such as regimes
Müller (on government formation), Colomer better and more consistently (see also Geddes’
(on institutional design), Bowler (on com- chapter on democratization). Finally, there are
parative political behaviour), McKay (on reasons to keep to traditional area boundaries
federalism), and Keefer (on governance and in some cases because they do share many
growth). commonalities and can therefore be made to
Part I ends with two chapters on areas that fit with comparative politics methods.
overlap with comparative political analysis, Hobson defines the gap between interna-
area studies and international relations. Despite tional relations (IR) and comparative politics
this overlap, the relationship between these and seeks to correct misunderstandings on
areas and comparative politics has, as John both sides. International relations scholars do
Hobson puts it at the start of his chapter on not recognize comparative politics research
international relations and comparative poli- as being about international relations because
tics, been ‘highly complex, fraught and prob- international relations is not interested in
lematic’. Some would say that this is an variations in states and treats the interna-
understatement. The relationship of compara- tional as an independent variable. The dif-
tive politics to area studies in particular has ferences between international relations
bordered on open warfare on a number of and comparative politics crystallized for
occasions as Stephen Hanson’s chapter on the Hobson with the rise of neorealism in inter-
relationship between comparative politics and national relations and its efforts at develop-
area studies shows. Hanson, however, plots a ing parsimonious explanation based on a
sensible course between the excessive cultur- structural theory of international anarchy.
alism of some parts of the area studies com- This theoretical perspective meant that
munity, which argue that there is no point to comparative politics and international
comparison since the context of local relations were forced apart since comparative
particularities and immersion in language, politics recognized the domestic realm
culture and custom are absolute preconditions and views states as diverse whilst IR

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:7 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


8 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

‘accords exclusive ontological weighting to and parts, see, Daalder, 1997; Lichbach and
the international system and views states as Zuckerman, 1997; Mair, 1996; Peters, 1998: 1–27;
Ragin, 1987: 1–18. The chapter by Spohn in this
functionally similar units’ with their functions volume also provides a detailed history of one major
defined by their competition in a continuous area of comparative politics, comparative political
anarchic system. There is, Hobson notes, sociology, and many of the others recount the main
comparison within international relations theoretical and conceptual developments in sub-
(between different time periods for example), strands of comparative politics.
2. For other arguments about how the various
and recognition that domestic factors can crises of the modernization paradigm moved com-
influence state’s responses to international parative political analysis forward see Mair, 1996 and
phenomena, but this has thus far only served Geddes, 2003: 6–17.
to highlight the outsider status of comparison
within IR because these comparisons are used
to attack the IR mainstream. The net result is
that both sides of the divide IR/comparative REFERENCES
politics divide often oversimplify certain
aspects of the international in their studies, Almond, G. (1990) A discipline divided. Schools
oversimplification that could be resolved by and sects in political science, Newbury Park,
importing categories from the other or having CA: Sage.
a better awareness of the theoretical and Brady, H.E. and Collier, D. (eds) (2004)
Rethinking social inquiry: Diverse tools,
methodological positions that the other con-
shared standards. Lanham, MD: Rowman
tains. As with Hawkins and Caporaso’s chap-
and Littlefield.
ters, Hanson and Hobson’s chapters should be Chilcote, R. (1994) Theories of comparative
contrasted with the discussions and compari- politics (2nd edition). Boulder, CO: Westview
sons of different within region studies and Press.
treatments of the international in the later Daalder, H. (ed.) (1997) Comparative European
chapters of the book. politics. The story of a profession. London:
Collectively Part I of this handbook shows Pinter.
that there is currently a thorough and ongo- Faure, A. (1994) ‘Some methodological prob-
ing restatement of what comparative politics lems in comparative politics’, Journal of
consists of and what it can do. The descrip- Theoretical Politics, 6 (3): 307–22.
Flyvbjerg, B. (2001) Making social science
tions of research developments in classic and
matter. Cambridge: Cambridge University
emerging areas of comparative politics
Press.
research in Parts II and III when taken Geddes, B. (2003) Paradigms and sand castles.
together with his restatement of the nature Theory building and research design in com-
and possibilities of comparative research parative politics. Ann Arbor: University of
open up great opportunities for future Michigan Press.
research. We hope that this collection is of George, A.L. and Bennett, A. (2005) Case stud-
great value to you as a scholar, who knows ies and theory development in the social
that the most solid forms of knowledge are sciences. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
built on the systematic comparison of simi- Gerring, J. (2007) Case study research: Principles
larities and differences that you observe. and practices. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Goertz, G. (2005) Social science concepts: A
user’s guide. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
NOTES University Press.
King, G., Keohane, R.O., and Verba, S.
1. Obviously, we are simplifying the history of (1994) Designing social inquiry:
comparative politics somewhat but the general point Scientific inference in qualitative
being made stands. For more detailed histories of the research. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
field, and alternative categorizations of its concerns Press.

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:8 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


INTRODUCTION 9

Landman, T. (2000) Issues and methods in science. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
comparative politics. London: Routledge. pp. 309–35.
Landman, T. (2003) Issues and Methods in Mill, J.S. (1843/1961) A system of logic,
comparative politics (2nd. edition). London: ratiocinative and inductive: being a con-
Routledge. nected view of the principles of evidence and
Landman, T. (2008) Issues and methods in the methods of scientific investigation,
comparative politics (3rd. edition). London: London: Longman.
Routledge. Peters, B.G. (1998) Comparative politics. Theory
Lichbach, M.I. and Zuckerman, A.S. (1997) and methods. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
‘Research traditions and theory in compara- Ragin, C.C. (1987) The comparative method.
tive politics: an introduction’, in Lichbach, Moving beyond qualitative and quantitative
M.I. and Zuckerman, A.S. (eds). Comparative strategies. Berkeley: University of California
politics. Rationality, culture, and structure. Press.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Ragin, C.C. (1994) Constructing social research.
pp. 3–16. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press.
Lijphart, A. (1971) ‘Comparative politics and Ragin, C.C. (2000) Fuzzy-set social science.
the comparative method’, American Political Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Science Review, 65 (3): 682–93. Schram, S.F. and Caterino, B. (eds) (2006)
Mahoney, J. and Goertz, G. (2004) ‘The possi- Making political science matter. New York:
bility principle: Choosing negative cases in New York University Press.
comparative research’, American Political Stepan, A. (2001) Arguing comparative
Science Review, 98 (4): 653–69. politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mahoney, J. and Rueschemeyer, D. (eds) (2003) Valenzuela, A. (1988) ‘Political science and
Comparative historical analysis in the social the study of Latin America’, in Mitchell, C.
sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University (ed.) Changing perspective in Latin
Press. American studies. Insights from six disci-
Mair, P. (1996) ‘Comparative politics: an over- plines. Stanford: Stanford University Press,
view’, in Goodin, R. and Klingemann, H-D. pp. 63–86.
(eds) A new handbook of political

9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:9 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM


9781412919760_Intro.indd Sec1:10 3/11/2009 3:07:21 PM
PART I

Methods and Fields of


Comparative Politics

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 1 3/11/2009 3:16:12 PM


9781412919760_Chap01.indd 2 3/11/2009 3:16:13 PM
1
The Distinctiveness of
Comparative Research
Charles C. Ragin and Claude Rubinson

INTRODUCTION engage in the development, testing, and


revision of theory – traditionally the province
Social research is inherently comparative of case-oriented research, as well as
(Lieberson, 1985). Researchers compare the hypothesis testing and theory adjudication –
relative effects of variables across cases; they usually seen as the province of variable-
compare cases directly with one another; oriented research. But the greatest strengths
and they compare empirical cases with of comparative methodology arise from its
counterfactual cases. But the comparative distinctiveness. Fundamentally set theoretic
method – sometimes referred to as ‘small- in nature, comparative methods presuppose
N comparison’ – constitutes a distinctive particular epistemological and theoretical
approach to understanding social phenom- perspectives (Ragin, 1987; 2000; Rubinson
ena. Frequently, comparative methods are and Ragin, 2007). Although social research-
portrayed as a ‘bridge’ between qualitative, ers conventionally conceive of social reality
case-oriented research and quantitative, in terms of tendencies and probabilities,
variable-oriented research. This interpreta- social scientific theory – like comparative
tion is certainly valid. By embracing aspects research – is predominately set theoretic in
of both qualitative and quantitative methods, nature. Frequently, however, even compara-
comparative methods can circumvent some tive researchers do not recognize the set theo-
of the limitations of both approaches. But retic character of their work.
comparative research is not merely a bridge, In the second part of this chapter, we expli-
for it has many distinctive features and cate the set theoretic nature of a number of
strengths. classic comparative studies. We identify and
We begin this chapter by reviewing the illustrate three types of set theoretic relation-
conventional view of comparative methods ships and discuss how they form the basis of
as simultaneously qualitative and quantita- three forms of comparative analysis: descrip-
tive. The moderate number of cases employed tive, constitutive, and causal. Next, we discuss
by comparative researchers allows them to the case-oriented nature of social research.

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 3 3/11/2009 3:16:13 PM


14 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

The set theoretic orientation of comparative and enhance statistical power (Cohen, 1988).
research invokes a case-oriented perspective: Faced with hundreds or thousands of cases,
sets are composed of elements (cases) and however, it is impossible for researchers to
comparative research is the analysis of how know the details of each case. As the cases
cases in one set relate to cases in another set. become obscured and retreat to the background,
We then discuss the issue of causal complex- variables advance to the fore. Large-N analysis,
ity. Comparative methods are especially well- then, tends to focus on variables and their
suited for the study of how combinations of relationships.
causal conditions produce particular out- The fundamental goal of variable-oriented
comes. The study of necessary and sufficient research is the production of descriptive
conditions – a prominent concern among or explanatory inferences (Brady, 2004).
comparativists – is but one aspect of compara- Descriptive inferences are produced by gen-
tive causal analysis. eralizing from patterns found within samples
We conclude our discussion of comparative (King et al., 1994). All else being equal, the
research by examining its formal methods. larger a sample, the greater the researcher’s
Reviewing two contemporary applications of confidence in generalizing to a wider popu-
comparative methodology, we illustrate the lation. Explanatory inferences are produced
construction and analysis of truth tables. Truth through hypothesis testing (King et al., 1994).
tables form the foundation of comparative Hypothesis testing requires a well-specified
analysis; whether explicitly or implicitly, theory of the relationships among variables,
most comparative researchers construct truth which may be confirmed or refuted by com-
tables. We demonstrate how Mill’s (1875) paring the theory’s predictions against
methods of agreement and difference as well evidence. Again, all else being equal, the
as Ragin’s Qualitative Comparative Analysis larger the sample, the greater the researcher’s
(QCA) – the two dominant implementations confidence that a relationship found in a
of formal comparative methods – make use sample does, in fact, exist in the wider popu-
of them. QCA builds upon and extends lation. As both benefit from a large number of
Mill’s methods, as we demonstrate through observations, the affinity between variable-
analyses of causal complexity and counter- oriented research and quantitative methods is
factual cases. mutually reinforcing.
Case-oriented research and qualitative
methods, by contrast, are most useful when
applied to a small number of cases. Because
COMPARATIVE METHODS qualitative techniques leverage the research-
AS A BRIDGE er’s in-depth knowledge of cases, every addi-
tional case requires researchers to further
In describing the methodological landscape divide their attention. Examination of details
of the social sciences, it is conventional to highlights the distinctiveness of each case.
distinguish between quantitative, variable- While imposing limits on generalization and
oriented analysis and qualitative, case- thereby hindering hypothesis testing, this
oriented analysis (Ragin, 1987). There is, of focus facilitates theory development (George
course, no inherent reason that variable- and Bennett, 2005). In-depth case knowledge
oriented analysis must be quantitative and makes it easier to see which case aspects are
case-oriented analysis, qualitative (Rubinson relevant to the question at hand and how
and Ragin, 2007). Still, there is a natural these aspects fit together. This understanding
affinity, which is a consequence of the way in may be used to construct new theory or
which the number of cases influences the revise existing theory, thus generating new
research process. Quantitative techniques hypotheses for future testing.
require a large number of cases – the more, This is not to say that case-oriented research-
the better – so as to meet model assumptions ers cannot engage in hypothesis testing;

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 4 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 15

indeed, popular examples of case-oriented researchers begin their research armed with a
research include ‘crucial,’ ‘most-likely,’ and well-specified theoretical model and hypoth-
‘least-likely’ case studies that test whether a eses regarding how change in one variable
theory operates as predicted (Eckstein, 1992). affects changes in others. In contrast to these
In general, however, researchers who want to two extremes, comparativists typically begin
develop new theory tend to use qualitative, their research with a rough idea of the con-
case-oriented techniques to examine cepts, variables, and cases that are likely to
small-Ns, while those who want to test be relevant to their research question. Because
theory tend to apply quantitative, variable- comparative researchers typically study a
oriented methods to large-Ns (Ragin, 1994). moderate number of cases, it is not feasible
A consequence of this bifurcation is that to use a purely exploratory approach and
social research is characterized by a large conduct an open-ended, in-depth examina-
number of studies that examine either tion of every case. At the same time, conven-
small-Ns or large-Ns, but relatively few stud- tional hypothesis testing fails due to the
ies that examine a moderate number of cases limited degrees of freedom available. Instead,
(Ragin, 2000: 25). comparative researchers seek to answer their
Comparative research can bridge the divide research questions by examining the fit
between qualitative, case-oriented research between concepts and cases, ideas and evi-
and quantitative, variable-oriented research. dence. The notion of ‘fit’ is key. For com-
Like case-oriented methods, comparative parativists, a good theory is a middle-range
methods maintain the integrity of cases; like theory that fits the evidence well (Mjoset and
variable-oriented methods, comparative meth- Clausen, 2007). Such a theory will identify
ods examine patterns of relationships among which variables are relevant to the question
variables. Comparative methods, then, may be at hand, explain how these variables are
used for both theory development and hypoth- related to one another, and, specify the con-
esis testing. With a moderate number of cases texts under which they operate.
(usually around 5–50), it becomes possible to Through investigation of the fit between
examine cross-case patterns while still attend- theory and data, comparativists discover
ing to the details of each case. areas for adjustment and improvement.
In comparative research, theory develop- Ultimately, the resulting theory must be
ment and hypothesis testing interact in two judged on its own merits. Does the theory
ways. First, comparative methods may be provide a compelling explanation of the
used to develop, test, and revise a particular observed cases? Does it explain unobserved
theory. Second, comparative methods may or previously anomalous cases? Does it pro-
be used to adjudicate between competing duce observable implications and novel
theories. insights? Is it falsifiable? There is always a
trade-off between specificity and generality,
and theories vary in their explanatory scope.
Developing, testing, and Very specific theories may not generalize
beyond the observed cases; very general
revising theory
ones may not add anything new to our under-
Comparative methods encourage a reciprocal standing. Ultimately, whether any particular
relationship between theory development and theory is successful depends upon striking
theory testing. In a strictly qualitative case- the proper balance between specificity
oriented study, researchers enter the field and generality for the research question at
armed only with sensitizing concepts, which hand. The advantage of using comparative
they use to help them construct new theory as methods to develop, test, and revise theory is
they try to make sense of their cases. In a that they make these choices, considerations,
purely quantitative variable-oriented study, and decisions explicit.

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 5 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


16 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

considered relevant or not – as the ‘possi-


Adjudicating between theories
bility principle.’
A popular use of quantitative methods is to Given an initial set of cases, the researcher
adjudicate between competing theoretical first examines scope conditions in order to
perspectives. Given two or more theories that exclude cases to which the theory does not
purport to explain the same phenomenon, apply. The researcher then applies the possi-
researchers identify the variables specified bility principle in order to restrict the sample
by each theory and estimate a series of to relevant cases. Mahoney and Goertz (2004)
models using the same dataset. By examin- operationalize the possibility principle as a
ing measures of statistical significance, rule of exclusion and a rule of inclusion. The
explained variation, and model fit, research- exclusion rule, which takes priority over the
ers can determine which theory best explains inclusion rule, directs the researcher to
the outcome of interest. develop a list of ‘robust eliminatory varia-
Comparative methods may be applied to bles’ which predict the absence of the out-
this purpose as well. While the process tends come. Cases are excluded as irrelevant ‘if
to differ, the logic is the same. As the goal of their value on any eliminatory independent
hypothesis testing is the generation of explan- variable predicts the nonoccurrence of the
atory inferences (see above), the construction outcome of interest’ (Mahoney and Goertz,
of the set of relevant cases is crucial. Because 2004: 658). The inclusion rule states that
comparativists study fewer cases than quanti- ‘[cases are relevant if their value on at least
tative researchers, they typically devote much one independent variable is positively related
more attention to the task of delineating the to the outcome of interest’ (Mahoney and
set of relevant cases and then constructing Goertz, 2004: 657). We regard this threshold
their datasets. Of particular concern are as a preliminary guideline and recommend
scope and possibility conditions. Scope con- that researchers use their theoretical and sub-
ditions specify the conditions under which a stantive knowledge when specifying inclu-
theory is relevant (Cohen, 1989). Cases that sion thresholds.
do not meet a theory’s scope conditions are The proper application of scope condi-
considered irrelevant, regardless of whether tions and the possibility principle to a popu-
they exhibit the outcome of interest. Skocpol lation will produce a theoretically and
(1979), for example, limits her theory of the substantively relevant sample of both posi-
causes of social revolutions to countries tive and negative cases. If the resulting
without a recent history of colonial domina- sample is too large for comparative analy-
tion and thereby excludes the cases of Mexico sis, then researchers should select repre-
and Vietnam. Possibility conditions specify sentative cases that maximize the diversity
the conditions under which an outcome is of cases on relevant causal conditions. To
possible (Goertz, 2005; Mahoney and Goertz, adjudicate among competing theories, the
2004). For example, there are many (in fact, comparative researcher examines each case
infinite) cases of the non-occurrence of social to see if the relationships between causal
revolutions. When the outcome of interest is conditions and outcomes hold as predicted
clearly impossible, the case is irrelevant for by each theory. Theories are evaluated
the theory at hand. Irrelevant cases should be according to how well they predict both the
excluded from the data set because their presence and absence of the outcome. Like
inclusion does not benefit hypothesis testing conventional quantitative adjudication tech-
and, indeed, may hinder it (Braumoeller and niques, comparative techniques of adjudica-
Goertz, 2002; Clarke, 2002; Mahoney tion can indicate opportunities for theory
and Goertz, 2004). Mahoney and Goertz refinement by exposing the ways in which
(2004) codify the specification of possibility different theories complement one another
conditions – that is, whether cases are and might be combined.

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 6 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 17

Example: Berg-Schlosser and de Meur’s were subjected to the same historical events.
(1994) ‘Conditions of Democracy’ That some emerged as democratic and others
Social scientists have a longstanding interest as authoritarian suggests that each country
in the rise and evolution of democracy and possessed the potential for democratic break-
have developed a wide array of theoretical down. Expanding the sample beyond the
explanations for its emergence, persistence, small handful normally examined in com-
and breakdown. Observing that there have parative research provides a test of the gener-
been few attempts to adjudicate among these alizability of the theories: ‘all of the major
theories, Berg-Schlosser and de Meur (1994) “breakdown” cases with their specific pat-
test eight of the most prominent models pre- terns and the major “survivors,” including
dicting the success or failure of democratiza- some of the smaller countries which often
tion: Dahl (1971, 1989), Hermens (1941), tend to be overlooked, are considered’ (Berg-
Linz (1978), Lipset (1981), Luebbert (1987), Schlosser and de Meur, 1994: 254). At the
Moore (1966), Sani and Sartori (1983), and same time, the moderate sample size permits
Vanhanen (1984). Berg-Schlosser and de Berg-Schlosser and de Meur to interrogate
Meur (1994) construct their dataset by draw- the individual cases when seeking to make
ing from the inter-war period in Europe, sense of results. Indeed, to this end, the
emphasizing the similarities among the cases: researchers exclude certain countries from
For a study of the chances and failures of democ- the sample: ‘cases like Denmark and Norway
racy in a comparative perspective, the interwar have not been included because they were
period in Europe provides a unique setting, since found to add relatively little variation over
the cases to be considered share many common and above the conditions and relevant factors
socioeconomic and political-cultural characteris-
for a case like Sweden’ (Berg-Schlosser and
tics. Their history is relatively well researched and
well documented. The time period under consid- de Meur, 1994: 254). In contrast to conven-
eration is clearly demarcated by common events, tional quantitative methods, the inclusion of
the two world wars which significantly altered additional cases in comparative research is of
both the internal and external political landscapes no benefit unless they serve to better repre-
and set them apart from earlier and later develop-
sent the combinations of conditions present
ments. All cases can initially be designated as par-
liamentary democracies, some of them relatively in the population: Berg-Schlosser and de
well established, others more recent, and some Meur’s 1994 sample is representative not of
existing more in form than in substance. They Western European countries during the inter-
were subsequently affected by a common external war period per se but, rather, of the types of
stimulus, the world economic crisis of the late
countries that existed in Western Europe at
1920s and early 1930s. Some parliamentary
regimes survived, while others yielded to authori- that time.
tarian rule and, in particular, fascism. Prevailing For each theoretical model, Berg-Schlosser
assumptions concerning modernization and and de Meur (1994) examine whether the
progress, whether liberal or Marxist, were severely countries in their sample conform to the
shattered (1994: 253).
model’s predictions of democratic survival
The theories under investigation were versus breakdown. A model is confirmed
developed primarily through the examination when it correctly predicts the survival or
of Western European countries, and it is not breakdown of democracy. The attention to
clear that they should also apply to non- individual cases permits the researchers to
Western societies. In order to satisfy scope identify cases that partially support or contra-
conditions, Berg-Schlosser and de Meur dict a model’s hypothesis as well. Comparing
(1994), therefore, restrict their sample to 16 the successes and failures of each theory,
Western European countries. The limited time Berg-Schlosser and de Meur find the strong-
period seeks to satisfy possibility conditions. est support for, first, structural models that
All of the countries in the sample entered the emphasize socioeconomic conditions and,
period as parliamentary democracies and second, agency models that emphasize the

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 7 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


18 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

actions of individual actors. Institutional and our observations in a contingent manner:


meso-level models are only weakly sup- ‘Given certain conditions, a given effect is
ported. Complex models incorporating nine likely to occur.’ In this view, social reality is
or more independent variables were more inherently random and all social processes
likely to produce mixed results, a conse- embody a stochastic component that cannot,
quence of the diversity present among cases. even in principle, be identified, much less
Applying QCA (Ragin, 1987) to simplify modeled (Goldthorpe, 2000: chapter 7). The
their results, Berg-Schlosser and de Meur most formal versions of this approach are
(1994: 276) find the most parsimonious solu- found in probabilistic models – such as
tions to emphasize ‘basic factors like demo- regression analysis – that produce precise
cratic legitimacy and the political role of the predictions of the likely effect of one variable
military (as with Dahl) together with some upon another. In contrast to the tendential
actor-related aspects like interventions by conception of social reality, comparative
members of the upper class (for Linz)’. methods see the social world in terms of sets
Perhaps the most significant finding, how- and set theoretic relations, especially those
ever, is that the emphasis on historically that are consistent with arguments of causal
important cases such as Great Britain, necessity or sufficiency. This view motivates
Germany, Italy, and Spain has, in fact, hin- a search for invariant or at least highly con-
dered understanding of democratic persist- sistent connections between causal condi-
ence and breakdown: tions and outcomes.
But it can also be seen that countries like Finland,
Czechoslovakia, Greece, and even France are
hardly in line with the expectations of any of the Set theory in comparative research
theorists and in several instances provide direct
counterfactual examples. This result points to the Although the tendential view of reality domi-
often rather limited perspective in theory building nates social scientific discourse, most social
of some of these authors as far [as] geographical
scientific theory invokes a set theoretic notion
distribution and historical depth are concerned
(Berg-Schlosser and de Meur, 1994: 276). of reality. For example, when researchers
observe that ‘religious fundamentalists are
Bridging the worlds of case-oriented and politically conservative’ they are arguing that
variable-oriented analysis, comparative religious fundamentalists form a rough subset
methods make it possible for Berg-Schlosser of the set of political conservatives. Another
and de Meur to adjudicate among competing example: Esping-Andersen (1990) proposes a
theories, examine relations among explana- set theoretic model of the nation-state. Liberal,
tory variables, and identify cases that contra- corporatist, and social democratic countries
dict specific theories. are each a subset of the welfare capitalist
countries; together, they constitute a complete
set: The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism.
Capitalist countries are not necessarily wel-
THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF THE fare states, however. Esping-Andersen uses
COMPARATIVE METHOD the term ‘welfare’ as a modifier, indicating
that welfare states are a subset of capitalist
The greatest strengths of the comparative countries. And capitalist countries are, in turn,
method arise from its distinctiveness, not a subset of all countries.
from its facility for bridging variable-
oriented and case-oriented analysis. Social Types of set theoretic connections
researchers traditionally conceive of social The existence of a set theoretic relationship
reality in terms of tendencies and probabilis- indicates that some type of connection may link
tic relationships. That is, we generally frame distinct phenomena. This connection can take

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 8 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 19

one of three basic forms: descriptive, constitu- would have nothing like the same significance,
tive, or causal. Consider, for illustration, the above all for the social structure and all the specific
problems of the modern Occident connected with
opening observation that motivates Weber’s it. Exact calculation – the basis of everything
investigation of The Protestant ethic and the else – is only possible on a basis of free labour
spirit of capitalism: ‘the fact that business lead- (1958: 22).
ers and owners of capital, as well as the higher
grades of skilled labour, and even more the Weber’s model of capitalism, then, is a
higher technically and commercially trained combination of six essential conditions. Such
personnel of modern enterprises are over- a model is constitutive: the elements of the
whelmingly Protestant’ (1958: 35). The puzzle model are closely intertwined and together
that motivates Weber’s analysis is explaining constitute rational capitalism. For example,
the fact that people in these occupations consti- double-entry accounting ‘is also found in the
tuted a rough subset of the set of Protestants. Far East, the Near East, and in antiquity’
His observation is not simply that there is an (Weber, 1958: 22) but contributes to ‘the
‘association’ between two variables, but that a continual pursuit of profit’ only when com-
specific connection – between certain occupa- bined with free labor.
tions and Protestantism – is remarkably con- Whenever a set-theoretic connection is
sistent (they are ‘overwhelmingly’ Protestant). interpreted as evidence that something is an
He goes on to query: ‘[W]hy were the districts ‘essential’ component, aspect, or part of
of highest economic development at the same another, it may be viewed as constitutive.
time particularly favourable to a revolution in Whether a set-theoretic relation is seen as
the Church?’ (Weber, 1958: 36). Weber notes, evidence of a constitutive versus a causal
in effect, that these highly developed districts connection is a matter of interpretation. For
constitute a subset of those opposed to the example, some might interpret the fact that
Catholic Church – that again there is a remark- the advanced industrial societies are uni-
ably consistent, almost uniform, connection. As formly democratic as evidence that ‘eco-
first presented by Weber, these two set theoretic nomic development is causally sufficient for
connections are primarily descriptive in nature democratic government.’ Others, however,
because he says nothing about why these con- might avoid making a causal argument and
nections exist. interpret this same connection as evidence
Weber’s goal in The Protestant ethic is to that having a democratic government is an
unravel the puzzle of the set-theoretic connec- essential part of being an advanced industrial
tions between capitalism and Protestantism. society. The key distinction is in how the
Defining the spirit of capitalism as the method- connection is understood and interpreted.
ical, continuous pursuit of profit, Weber begins Constitutive analysis is central to what
by elucidating the relevant characteristics of Ragin (1992) has referred to as the process of
modern capitalism: rational calculation, entre- ‘casing.’ Researchers engage in casing when-
preneurs, credit markets, the separation of ever they attempt to delineate the conceptual
work and home, and double-entry accounting boundaries of a case or set of cases.
(Weber, 1958: 17–22).1 Each of these condi- Researchers often engage in casing as they
tions, however, has existed before and, there- attempt to identify conceptually the observa-
fore, cannot be solely responsible for capitalist tions included in their analyses. In The
exchange. It is only with the rise of the labor Protestant ethic, Weber’s primary concern is
market – ‘the rational capitalistic organization the casing of rational capitalism. He
of (formally) free labour’ (Weber, 1958: 21) – asks, ‘What is rational capitalism? How is it
that these conditions take on a modern, capi- different from other economic systems?’
talistic character: Casing seeks to answer the questions, ‘If
For without the rational capitalistic organization of I see it, how will I know?’ ‘What are its
labour, all this, so far as it was possible at all, essential elements?’

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 9 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


20 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

An important aspect of casing is that it one set is connected to membership in


identifies the theoretically salient character- another. Weber does this by linking Luther’s
istics of the case. That capitalism involves conception of the calling to the spirit of capi-
exchange for gain is not salient because talism. By describing how the sense of call-
exchange for gain exists everywhere, at all ing combined with a worldly asceticism led
times (Weber, 1958: 17). Exchange for gain Protestants to embrace capitalist production
may be central to rational capitalism but, and exchange, Weber details how member-
theoretically, it is not decisive. The separa- ship in one set (people possessing the
tion of work and home, however, has much Protestant ethic) connects to membership in
greater theoretical salience. Although the another (people possessing the spirit of capi-
‘spatial separation of places of work from talism). Note that Weber does not claim that
those of residence exists elsewhere’ (Weber, all Protestants embraced capitalism, nor does
1958: 22), it is only under conditions of he claim that all those who embraced capital-
capitalism that this separation forces workers ism were Protestant. That is, Weber does not
to seek their livelihood on the labor market: argue for the existence of a perfect subset
‘The tendency everywhere else was for relationship at the individual level but rather
acquisitive enterprises to arise as parts of a an affinity between the two. The two rough
royal or manorial household (of the oikos), subset relations described at the outset of this
which is, as Rodbertus has perceived, with discussion are evidence of this affinity.
all its superficial similarity, a fundamentally
different, even opposite, development’ Set theory and within-case analysis
(Weber, 1958: 22, emphasis in original). Social researchers use the term ‘case study’ in
Thus, constitutive analysis seeks to identify a variety of ways (Ragin and Becker, 1992).
the interconnected components of a type of Frequently, comparative research is subsumed
case – its essential features. It produces a under the term (e.g., Gerring, 2007: chapter 2).
litmus test for membership in the set of cases However, we find it useful to distinguish
under observation. An observation is excluded between within-case analysis (i.e., single
if it lacks any of the essential features or dis- case studies) and cross-case analysis (i.e.,
plays any feature that is prohibited. comparative studies) as each of these forms
Having outlined the characteristics of of analysis entails distinct research meth-
modern capitalism, Weber observes that ods. Within-case analysis focuses on singular
modern capitalism first took root in Protestant- cases. Many researchers feel that because
dominated regions. That is to say, the set of single-case studies lack a comparative ele-
regions where modern capitalism arose are a ment, they are not ‘real research.’ We disagree.
subset of the set of Protestant countries. To Case studies are particularly useful in inter-
establish a causal connection, Weber seeks to preting culturally or historically significant
link the rise of Protestantism with the rise of phenomenon (Ragin, 1994). Case studies of
modern capitalism: events such as the storming of the Bastille
(Sewell, 1996), the funeral of Abraham
Montesquieu says (Esprit des Lois, Book XX,
Lincoln (Schwartz, 1991), and the rise of the
chap.7) of the English that they ‘had progressed
the farthest of all peoples of the world in three English working class (Thompson, 1966) are
important things: in piety, in commerce, and in valuable because they apply social science
freedom’. Is it not possible that their commercial theory and concepts to the study of the causes
superiority and their adaptation to free political and consequences of important moments of
institutions are connected in some way with that
historical transformation or qualitative
record of piety which Montesquieu ascribes to
them? (1958: 45) change.
Moreover, case studies are not necessarily
To establish causality, researchers must spec- non-comparative. There is a crucial distinc-
ify the mechanism by which membership in tion between the unit of analysis and the unit

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 10 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 21

of observation (Denton, 2007). Unfortunately, three routes to modernity; that is, his three
social researchers often use the term ‘case’ to sets of modernizing revolutions. The set of
refer to both. As King et al. (1994) point out, bourgeois revolutions culminating in democ-
a single case study may involve many obser- racy include the cases of the French
vations. Thompson (1966), for example, uses Revolution and the English and American
a variety of methods to examine and synthe- civil wars. The set of conservative revolu-
size data from a variety of sources in order to tions culminating in fascism include the
explain the emergence of English working cases of Japan’s Meiji Restoration and
class consciousness. Today it is fashionable Bismarck’s unification of Germany. Finally,
to refer to such research as ‘triangulated’ or the set of peasant revolutions culminating in
‘multi-method’ (Brewer and Hunter, 2006; communism include the Russian and Chinese
Reinharz, 1992), but case study researchers revolutions. In turn, these three sets of revo-
have always leveraged a variety of data lutions constitute a subset of what might be
sources and analytic techniques in order to termed ‘modernizing revolutions.’
confirm their findings and make sense of Hobsbawm (1967) observes that ‘[t]he
their cases. As cases exist in space and across author of a comparative analysis does not
time, implicit – if not explicit – comparisons compete with the specialists; he exploits
are inevitable. Thompson’s study covers 50 them and may have to question them.’
years and spans the whole of the country. (p. 821) Within-case and comparative studies
He invites comparison of the English workers are complementary. The set theoretic nature
by including separate chapters on field labor- of comparative research requires the conduct
ers, artisans, and weavers. Likewise, his exam- of within-case analysis, as sets are all about
ination of worker responses compares various cases – the elements contained within sets –
forms of resistance, protest, and working-class and the characterization of cases in terms of
radicalism. By the conclusion of the text, set memberships.
Thompson has reviewed the cultural and
structural transformations between 1780
and 1832 that gave rise to class conscious-
ness among English workers. Thompson’s Causal complexity in
project may be understood as a comparison
comparative research
between the working class of 1780, a class
an sich, and the working class of 1832, a class Conventionally, researchers do not present
für sich. their causal arguments in terms of set rela-
Finally, within-case analysis is an essential tions but, rather, in terms of how causes
component of good cross-case, comparative come together to produce outcomes. Moore
research. It is for this reason that some (1966), for example, speaks of ‘three routes
researchers subsume comparative research to the modern world,’ and Skocpol (1979)
under the moniker of ‘case study.’ Good discusses social revolutions as the product of
cross-case comparison necessarily involves state breakdowns and peasant revolts. Neither
the investigation of individual cases on their author makes their sets explicit, and fre-
own terms. Indeed, a common method of quently it takes some effort to discern the set
presenting comparative research is exempli- relations. However, close analysis of most
fied by Barrington Moore, Jr. (1966) in comparative work reveals a conjunctural
Social Origins of Dictatorship and understanding of causation. In essence,
Democracy. Moore spends the bulk of the causal conjunctures involve intersections of
text reviewing the individual cases (that is, conditions, which in turn can be understood
conducting within-case analysis) and offers as set intersections.
systematic comparative analysis at the con- Moore (1966), for example, identifies five
clusion. It is here that Moore constructs his conditions for the development of democracy.

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 11 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


22 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

1. The development of a balance to avoid too strong The study of necessity and sufficiency is a
a crown or too independent a landed aristocracy. longstanding interest of comparative research-
2. A turn toward an appropriate form of commercial ers (Goertz and Starr, 2003). A cause is nec-
agriculture. essary when the set of cases exhibiting the
3. The weakening of the landed aristocracy.
cause (e.g., state breakdown) includes the
4. The prevention of an aristocratic-bourgeois coali-
tion against the peasants and workers.
entire set of cases exhibiting the outcome
5. A revolutionary break with the past. (pp. (e.g., social revolution), The presence of state
430–31). breakdown is a necessary condition for the
occurrence of social revolution. A cause is
Each of these items involves a process of sufficient when the set of cases exhibiting the
transformation: ‘development,’ ‘turn,’ ‘weak- outcome (e.g., social revolution) includes the
ening,’ ‘prevention,’ ‘break.’ When these entire set of cases exhibiting the cause or,
processes are found together, they constitute more commonly, a combination of causes
a ‘bourgeois revolution’ which is one form of (e.g., the combination of state breakdown
‘modernizing revolutions.’ However, Moore’s and peasant revolt). The combined presence
unit of observation is not the modernizing of state breakdown and peasant revolt is a
revolution – that is his unit of analysis – but, sufficient condition for the occurrence of
rather, individual countries. Countries that social revolution.
experienced the combination of these proc- Complex conditions of necessity and
esses, such as England, France, and the sufficiency can combine to form what
United States, are found in the set of coun- Ragin (1987) calls ‘multiple conjunctural
tries that experienced bourgeois revolutions. causation.’ Multiple conjunctural causation
Countries that did not experience each of exists when a single causal condition is nei-
these processes, such as India which lacked a ther necessary nor sufficient to produce
revolutionary break with the past, are not the outcome on its own but, rather, only in
found in the set of countries that experienced combination with other causal conditions.
bourgeois revolutions. Moreover, India is not Re-examining Gamson’s (1990) social pro-
found among the set of countries that experi- test data, for example, Ragin (1989) finds
enced modernizing revolutions of any form that challenging groups (social movement
(bourgeois, conservative, or peasant), which organizations) secure new advantages for
according to Moore explains its long-term their constituents if they satisfy any one
stagnation (Moore, 1966: chapter 6). of the following combinations of causal
Skocpol’s subtitle – A Comparative Analysis conditions.
of France, Russia, and China – immediately
reveals countries as her units of observation. 1. No bureaucratic organization, middle or mixed
Searching for necessary and sufficient condi- strata constituents, no help from outsiders, and
tions of social revolution, Skocpol uncovers acceptance by antagonists.
2. Middle or mixed strata constituents, non-dis-
important subset relations. First, countries that
placement goals, and help from outsiders.
experience social revolution are a subset of
3. Bureaucratic organization, lower strata constitu-
countries that experience state breakdown or ents, non-displacement goals, and acceptance by
peasant revolt. Second, countries that experi- antagonists.
ence state breakdown combined with peasant 4. Non-displacement goals, help from outsiders, and
revolt are a subset of countries that experience acceptance by antagonists (pp. 392–93).
social revolution. The first relationship – in
which the outcome is a subset of the cause – While any one of these combinations of
identifies a relationship consistent with neces- conditions will result in the challenging
sity; the second relationship – in which the group securing new advantages, there is no
cause is a subset of the outcome – identifies one individual cause common to all combina-
that is consistent with sufficiency. tions. Mackie (1974) refers to such causes as

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 12 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 23

INUS causes because each is an Insufficient occurred. Cities in the analysis have the following
(not sufficient by itself) but Necessary com- characteristics in common: the population was
over 25,000, the steel industry was an important
ponent of a causal combination that is, itself, employer, black workers were a significant part of
Unnecessary (due to multiple paths) but the steel workforce, and the recruitment efforts of
Sufficient to bring about the outcome. the national committee reached each location
during the organizing drive. We selected cases
from Foster’s (1920) account of the organizing
drive and include only those locations that actually
participated in the strike. The final group of 16
METHODS OF COMPARATIVE cases ranges in size from single-industry towns to
ANALYSIS major multi-industry cities. (1995: 1497–8)

Comparative analysis can be formalized By conducting a case study of each city in


through the construction of truth tables, which the sample, Brown and Boswell produce the
show the connections between different com- data set shown in Table 1.1.4 ‘Recent black
binations of conditions and an outcome migration’ is an indicator of whether the city
(Ragin, 1987, 2000). Although conventional has recently experienced a large increase in
datasets may be used in their construction, the its population of young, single, black males.
columns of a truth table do not represent vari- A city is considered to have a weak steel-
ables, per se, nor do the rows represent cases. workers union (‘Weak union’) if the union
Rather, the columns of a truth table represent had previously suffered a failed strike against
sets and the rows represent relationships US Steel (the primary target of the 1919 steel
among sets, specifically, all logically possible strike). ‘Political repression’ exists when
intersections among the relevant sets. These local governments align themselves with
intersections may be understood as represent- capital rather than labor.
ing logically possible combinations of causal These three causal conditions were not the
conditions. Comparative research is the study only conditions that Brown and Boswell
of the connections between combinations of (1995) examined. Their initial truth table
conditions and outcomes. Whether implicitly included only two conditions, ‘Recent black
or explicitly, comparative researchers con- migration’ and ‘Weak Union.’ However, this
struct truth tables when they examine how configuration created a ‘contradiction’
causal conditions relate to specific outcomes. (Ragin, 1987: 113–18): five cities – Buffalo,
To illustrate the construction of a truth Chicago, Gary, Johnstown, and Cleveland –
table, we review Brown and Boswell’s (1995) all experienced recent black migration and a
analysis of how split labor markets affected history of strong unions; however, the first
interracial strikebreaking and solidarity during four cities exhibited black strikebreaking
the 1919 steel strike. After conducting case while Cleveland did not. Contradictions indi-
studies of 16 northern cities,2 Brown and cate an inadequately specified model (Ragin,
Boswell (1995) use comparative methods 1987) because identical conditions should
(specifically, crisp-set QCA) to identify three lead to similar outcomes. To resolve contra-
causal conditions that explain four forms of dictions, comparative researchers reexamine
interracial strikebreaking.3 To simplify our both their theory and their cases. It may be
discussion, we review just one of their out- that an error was made in the process of
comes: the presence of black strikebreaking casing and that the contradictory case(s) does
in the face of white worker solidarity. not properly belong to the population under
Brown and Boswell (1995) begin their investigation. More commonly, the researcher
analysis by constructing a sample of cities uncovers an additional causal condition that
that participated in the strike: explains the contradictory result. In the
Our unit of analysis is the steel-producing com- analysis at hand, Brown and Boswell
munities where relevant variation in race relations (1995) considered three variables that they

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 13 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


24 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Table 1.1 Causal conditions and presence of black strikebreaking


(from Brown and Boswell, 1995, Table 5)
City Recent Black Weak Political Black
migration union repression strikebreaking
Bethlehem No Yes Yes No
Buffalo Yes No Yes Yes
Chicago Yes No Yes Yes
Cleveland Yes No No No
Decatur No No Yes No
East Chicago Yes Yes Yes Yes
Gary Yes No Yes Yes
Johnstown Yes No Yes Yes
Joliet No Yes Yes No
McKeesport No Yes Yes No
Milwaukee No Yes Yes No
New Castle No Yes Yes No
Pittsburgh Yes Yes Yes Yes
Reading No Yes Yes No
Wheeling No No No No
Youngstown Yes Yes Yes Yes

suspected might affect the connection Brown and Boswell (1995) find that all but
between black migration and strong unions, one of the possible combinations is repre-
on the one hand, and black strikebreaking, on sented by at least one city; of those, two
the other: city size, whether the city was combinations are associated with the emer-
dominated by US Steel or Bethlehem Steel, gence of black strikebreaking. The causal
and local government repression. The addi- combination that is not represented in the
tion of the third condition, local government sample is referred to as a ‘remainder’ (Ragin
repression, yielded a truth table free of con- et al., 2006b) and is identified by marking the
tradictions and also was confirmed as caus- outcome with a dash (–). Remainders are
ally relevant in their case studies. common because social phenomena are
A truth table consists of one row per logi-
cally possible combination of conditions. A Table 1.2 Truth table for the presence of
truth table, then, has 2k rows, where k equals black strikebreaking, derived from
the number of causal conditions. As the Brown and Boswell (1995: 1505, Table 5)
number of causal conditions increases, and M U R Y Cases
the size of the truth table grows exponen- 1 1 1 1 1 East Chicago, Pittsburgh,
tially, analysis become increasingly complex. Youngstown
Software packages such as fsQCA (Ragin 2 1 1 0 –
et al., 2006a) can help to manage this com- 3 1 0 1 1 Buffalo, Chicago, Gary,
plexity; nevertheless, most practitioners exam- Johnstown
4 1 0 0 0 Cleveland
ine between five and ten causal conditions. To
5 0 1 1 0 Bethlehem, Joliet,
construct the truth table, the researcher refers McKeesport,
to the previously specified dataset and records New Castle, Reading
which combinations of causal conditions are 6 0 1 0 0 Milwaukee
associated with the presence of the outcome 7 0 0 1 0 Decatur
and which are associated with its absence.5 8 0 0 0 0 Wheeling
Brown and Boswell’s (1995) final truth table Note: M = recent black migration, U = weak union,
is presented in Table 1.2. R = political repression, Y = black strikebreaking

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 14 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 25

characterized by limited diversity (Ragin, The researcher first applies the method of
1987: 104–13, 2000). That is, many of the agreement to the positive cases exhibiting the
logically possible combinations of causal outcome. Upon identifying a causal condi-
conditions simply do not exist in reality. (We tion (or causal combination) associated with
address the issue of limited diversity, espe- the outcome, the researcher examines the
cially its relation to counterfactual analysis, negative cases to see if the absence of
in greater detail below). the outcome is associated with the absence of
the cause. Referring again to Brown and
Boswell’s (1995) truth table (Table 1.2), the
Mill’s methods of agreement method of difference reconfirms the initial
conclusion that black strikebreaking is a
and difference
product of recent black migration and politi-
The classic techniques of comparative meth- cal repression. Of the five configurations that
odology are those proposed by Mill (1875). exhibit the absence of strikebreaking, none
The simplest of all comparative logics, the exhibits the presence of both recent black
method of agreement is also the most likely migration and political repression.
to lead to faulty conclusions. The logic As the indirect method of difference com-
behind the method of agreement holds that prises two applications of the method of
any given outcome will, inevitably, have a agreement, the same two limitations apply to
single cause. By examining a sample of cases both methods. The first – the threat of an
exhibiting the same outcome, a researcher omitted variable – is common to all compara-
seeks to identify the single cause that all tive research methods and, indeed, all social
cases have in common. Ragin (1987: 36) research methods. Researchers may draw the
extends this logic to encompass combina- wrong conclusion when important causes are
tions of conditions, arguing that the success- omitted. If the identified causal condition is,
ful identification of a shared combination of itself, caused by an antecedent condition, the
causally relevant conditions would also sat- researcher’s explanation will be incomplete.
isfy the method of agreement. Applying the Spurious relationships raise a similar type of
method of agreement to Brown and Boswell’s issue. If both the identified causal condition
(1995) truth table (Table 1.2), reveals that all and the outcome are caused by an omitted
instances of black strikebreaking occurred in third condition, the researcher may identify
cities characterized by recent black migra- the wrong condition as causing the outcome.
tion and political repression. According to In this latter situation, one hopes that the
Mill’s method of agreement, then, the error will be uncovered as the researcher
research will conclude that the combined examines his or her cases and when attempt-
presence of recent black migration and polit- ing to elucidate how the condition causes the
ical repression caused black strikebreaking. outcome. The second and more significant
The process by which the cause produces the limitation of the method of agreement is that
outcome remains to be explained. In the it is incapable of addressing multiple con-
absence of a well-specified theory, such junctural causation. As Mill (1875), himself,
explanations are generally best developed emphasized, when an outcome has more than
through the application of within-case meth- one cause, the method of agreement will not
ods such as process tracing. be able to identify any of them:
Mill’s indirect method of difference – That some one antecedent is the cause of a given
what Ragin (1987: 39) refers to as ‘a double effect because all other antecedents have been
application of the method of agreement’ – found capable of being eliminated, is a just infer-
ence only if the effect can have but one cause. If it
leverages negative cases (that is, cases that admits of several, nothing is more natural than
do not exhibit the outcome) in order to that each of these should separately admit of
strengthen the researcher’s conclusions. being eliminated. (1875: 474–5)

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 15 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


26 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Qualitative Comparative Analysis Truth table reduction


The analysis of multiple conjunctural causa-
Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA, see tion involves a process known as ‘truth
Ragin, 1987, 2000) builds upon Mill’s meth- table reduction’ or ‘Boolean minimization.’
ods in two fundamental ways. Most signifi- A reduced or simplified truth table results in
cantly, QCA permits the analysis of multiple a Boolean equation that expresses the various
conjunctural causation, addressing the great- causal combinations that are associated with
est limitation of Mill’s methods. Moreover, the presence of the outcome. Ragin (1987)
by employing counterfactual analysis, QCA details the complete minimization process;
permits a more nuanced analysis of the rela- here, we provide only an overview.6 The basic
tionship between causal conditions and the process of Boolean minimization is derived
presence and absence of outcomes. from the proposition that invariant, or close to
Rooted in set theory, QCA uses set invariant, connections exist between explana-
algebra – also known as Boolean algebra – to tory conditions and outcomes. Each row of
analyze causal configurations. Boolean alge- the truth table represents a logically possible
bra provides operations for analyzing and combination of causal conditions. For each
manipulating sets. The most useful of these combination that is associated with the
operations for comparative research are dis- presence of the outcome, the truth table
cussed in Ragin (2000: 171–80) and include reduction process seeks to eliminate logi-
set union (logical or, represented as addition) cally redundant terms. In Table 1.2, the first
and set intersection (logical and, represented and third configurations are represented by
as multiplication). Truth table configurations the equations:
are represented as Boolean equations in
s
which an uppercase letter represents the MUR Y
presence of a condition while a lowercase
letter represents its absence. In Boolean s
MuR Y
notation, Row 1 of Table 1.2 is represen-
ted as: When a pair of equations is identical
except for a single causal condition, the dis-
s
M⋅U⋅R Y tinguishing term may be considered
irrelevant and can be eliminated. The mini-
which indicates that ‘The presence of black mization of these two equations, therefore,
migration in combination with a weak union produces:
and political repression is sufficient for black
s
strikebreaking.’ Just as with linear algebra, a MR Y
shortened notation may be used for multipli-
cative terms, and the above equation also which is the same result as was obtained
may be represented as: through the application of Mill’s method of
agreement: the presence of recent black
s migration and political repression resulted in
MUR Y
black strikebreaking. QCA’s methods are a
superset of Mill’s methods.
Row 5, which is read as ‘The absence of
A more complex example is provided by
recent black migration in combination with a
Stokke’s (2007) analysis of ‘shaming’ as an
weak union and political repression is suffi-
attempt to secure compliance with interna-
cient for the absence of black strikebreaking,’
tional fishing agreements. Shaming involves
is represented as:
an attempt to change a party’s behavior by
s
exposing their violations to others (in this
mUR y case, the international community). Having

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 16 3/11/2009 3:16:14 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 27

conducted a series of case studies of shaming 4. Inconvenience (I): The inconvenience to the target
attempts, Stokke (2007) identifies five causal of the behavioral change that the shamers seek
conditions that affect whether shaming to elicit.
attempts are successful. 5. Reverberation (R): Domestic-level political costs
if shamers scandalize the target as a culprit.
(p. 503)
1. Advice (A): Whether the shamers can substantiate
Having conducted his case studies and
their criticism by reference to explicit advice by
identified his causal conditions, Stokke
the regime’s scientific body.
2. Commitment (C): Whether the target behavior (2007) produces a truth table which we have
violates explicit commitments. reproduced as Table 1.3.7 With five causal
3. Shadow of the future (S): The target’s perceived conditions, the corresponding truth table has
need to strike future deals and whether ignor- 32 logically possible combinations. The
ing the criticism will jeopardize such beneficial ten cases are distributed among eight con-
arrangements. figurations, resulting in 24 remainders (two

Table 1.3 Truth table for the presence of shaming, with counterfactual
conditions (based on Stokke, 2007, Table 1)
A C S I R Y Cases
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Compliance
2 1 1 1 1 0 0 EC unilat. 1
3 1 1 1 0 1 –
4 1 1 1 0 0 1 EC unilat. 2
5 1 1 0 1 1 –
6 1 1 0 1 0 –
7 1 1 0 0 1 –
8 1 1 0 0 0 –
9 1 0 1 1 1 1 Overfishing
10 1 0 1 1 0 –
11 1 0 1 0 1 –
12 1 0 1 0 0 –
13 1 0 0 1 1 0 Mesh-size 2
14 1 0 0 1 0 0 Mesh-size 1
15 1 0 0 0 1 –
16 1 0 0 0 0 1 Krill report, Krill cap2
17 0 1 1 1 1 –
18 0 1 1 1 0 –
19 0 1 1 0 1 –
20 0 1 1 0 0 –
21 0 1 0 1 1 –
22 0 1 0 1 0 –
23 0 1 0 0 1 –
24 0 1 0 0 0 –
25 0 0 1 1 1 –
26 0 0 1 1 0 –
27 0 0 1 0 1 –
28 0 0 1 0 0 –
29 0 0 0 1 1 –
30 0 0 0 1 0 0 Loophole, Krill cap 1
31 0 0 0 0 1 –
32 0 0 0 0 0 –
Note: A = advice, C = commitment, S = shadow of the future, I = inconvenience, R = reverberation

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 17 3/11/2009 3:16:15 PM


28 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

configurations, Acsir and acsIr, characterize of determining the cause of successful


two cases each). shaming.
Half of the represented configurations are
examples of successful shaming: Complexity, parsimony, and
s counterfactual analysis
ACSIR Y In developing explanations of social life, in
s ‘telling about society’ (Becker, 1986), social
ACSir Y researchers seek to balance complexity and
s parsimony. The avoidance of crude, vulgar
AcSIR Y accounts demands that researchers recognize
s the possibility of multiple conjunctural cau-
Acsir Y sation, that there may exist a variety of expla-
nations, across cases, for the same outcome.
As the first and third equations differ only Indeed, Mill (1875) observes that, in the
with regard to the presence of commitment, social world, multiple conjunctural causation
that causal condition may be eliminated from is not the exception but the rule:
those configurations. The resulting mini- Now, in the case of political phenomena, the sup-
mized Boolean equation: position of unity of cause is not only wide of the
truth, but at an immeasurable distance from it.
s
ASIR + ACSir + Acsir Y The causes of every social phenomenon which we
are particularly interested about, security, wealth,
freedom, good government, public virtue, general
states that there are three combinations of intelligence, or their opposites, are infinitely
conditions that result in successful attempts numerous, especially the external or remote
at shaming. Observe that this solution is far causes, which alone are, for the most part, acces-
more complex and nuanced than that pro- sible to direct observation. No one cause suffices
of itself to produce any of these phenomena.
duced by Mill’s method of agreement.
(1875: 475)
The method of agreement would identify
only condition A (the presence of explicit And yet an explanation that is too particular,
advice from the scientific community) too qualified, can be as unsatisfying as one
as common to all events of successful sham- that is too general.
ing. The method of agreement, therefore, This tension between particularization and gener-
produces: alization – between literal and abstract representa-
tion – comes with the territory, I think, when
s you’re transmitting vicarious experience. A simple
A Y
chronicle of details, however graphic, locks you
into a particular time and place. You move beyond
This equation is too simplistic a solution to it by abstracting, but abstracting is an artificial
be convincing: surely the process of success- exercise, involving an oversimplification of com-
fully shaming a regime is more complicated plex realities (Gaddis, 2002: 14).
than simply having the support of the scien- This tension is particularly acute in compara-
tific community. And, indeed, application of tive research which studies both similarity
Mill’s indirect method of difference confirms and difference (Ragin, 1994). To establish set
this assertion. An examination of Table 1.3 membership and identify explicit relations
rejects the hypothesis that it is exclusively among sets, comparative researchers must
the scientific community that determines maintain the integrity and distinctiveness of
whether attempts at shaming will be success- their cases while demonstrating what they do
ful. Configurations 2, 13, and 14 are all and do not have in common. The more that a
instances of unsuccessful shaming over the researcher emphasizes the particular circum-
objections of the scientific community. stances and experiences of a case, the more
In this instance, Mill’s methods are incapable that a researcher restricts their scope and

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 18 3/11/2009 3:16:15 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 29

possibility conditions, the less portable the counterfactual existed?’ Instead of running a
argument becomes. thought experiment, however, the comparative
Counterfactual analysis provides a means by researcher need only include the remainder in
which comparativists can balance particularity the analysis. Whether to incorporate a particu-
and generality. Exploring how the hypothetical lar counterfactual case is a determination that
presence or absence of a causal condition must be made upon the basis of substantive
would affect the outcome under investigation, and theoretical knowledge (Ragin and Sonnett,
counterfactual analysis is predominantly asso- 2004). Two criteria must be evaluated. Is the
ciated with case-oriented research. In fact, all counterfactual case plausible? And, if so, is it
social research involves counterfactual analysis reasonable to think that it would produce the
in some way (Lieberson, 1985) but case- outcome in question? Depending upon how it
oriented researchers tend to make their counter- affects the set relations within the truth table,
factual theorizing explicit (Fearon, 1991). In the inclusion of remainders may result in a
comparative research, counterfactual cases Boolean equation that is more parsimonious,
form the basis of thought experiments through more complex, or the equivalent of the origi-
which researchers assess a theory’s plausibility nal solution. Researchers must use their sub-
(Weber, 1905). stantive and theoretical knowledge to evaluate
Counterfactual analysis is particularly the feasibility of any solution resulting from
useful as a theory development tool the inclusion of counterfactuals.
(McKeown, 2004). Recognizing the com- Software packages such as fsQCA (Ragin
plexity of the social world, researchers tend et al., 2006a) simplify the process of con-
to be conservative when constructing theo- ducting counterfactual analysis. For example,
ries. Preferring to claim too little rather than by incorporating all remainders that produce
too much, social researchers are more likely a simpler result, fsQCA can be used to iden-
to make errors of omission rather than com- tify the most parsimonious solution possible
mission. Counterfactual analysis provides a for any truth table. Applying this procedure
means by which to test the implications of a to Stokke’s truth table (Table 1.3) produces a
theory (McKeown, 2004) and thereby assess dramatically simpler solution:
the viability of more parsimonious variants.
For any given analysis a researcher may con- s
i + SR Y
struct a variety of counterfactual cases.
Frequently, just a single causal condition is which indicates that shaming will be success-
altered; more complex analyses examine a ful when (a) it is not inconvenient for the
range of hypothetical conditions. targets of the shaming to change their behav-
Truth tables permit a systematic approach ior or (b) when future considerations and
to counterfactual analysis, one which encom- present political costs are high.
passes both simple and complex counterfactu- This solution and the previous solution of
als. As previously discussed, the social world the same truth table can be considered two
is characterized by limited diversity. In truth endpoints on a continuum that runs from
tables, limited diversity manifests itself as complexity to parsimony. Observe that the
‘remainders’ – the logically possible configu- complex solution (Acsir + ACSir + ASIR) is
rations of causal conditions that lack empirical a subset of the parsimonious solution (i +
instances. Representing ‘events that did not SR). Cases of shaming that involve the
happen’ (Lieberson, 1985: 45), remainders absence of inconvenience to the target – that
serve as counterfactual cases in comparative is, members of set i include members of sets
research (Ragin and Sonnett, 2004). Acsir and ACSir. Likewise, cases of shaming
Counterfactual analysis using remainders that invoke a shadow of the future and rever-
is straightforward: the researcher asks berations – members of set SR – include
‘How would my conclusions change if the members of set ASIR. The presence of this

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 19 3/11/2009 3:16:15 PM


30 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

subset relationship indicates that it is possi- intermediate solutions using counterfactual


ble to select counterfactual cases to produce analysis.8 The researcher can then adjudicate
intermediate solutions, between the parsimo- among the various solutions, selecting that
nious and the complex. one that best balances specificity and gener-
One way to derive an intermediate solution alizability given the current state of theory
is to use the technique described in Ragin and and what is known about the cases.
Sonnett (2004). Examining the term ASIR,
Ragin and Sonnett (2004) observe that ‘Causal
conditions S and R cannot be removed because
they appear in the corresponding parsimoni- CONCLUSION
ous term (SR) at the other end of the contin-
uum’ (p.16). To remove S or R would violate Comparative research is frequently seen as a
the subset relationship and, therefore, the only bridge connecting the worlds of qualitative,
candidates for removal are A and I. To discern case-oriented research and quantitative, vari-
whether either of these conditions may be able-oriented research. Focusing on a moder-
removed, the researcher must rely upon theo- ate number of cases, comparativists are able
retical and substantive knowledge. The fact to engage in both theory development (usu-
that the support of the regime’s scientific advi- ally the province of qualitative researchers)
sory board is the only condition present in all and hypothesis testing (usually the province
cases of successful shaming suggests that it of quantitative researchers). While compara-
may be a necessary condition and should be tive research can certainly be seen as a
retained. However, it does not make sense bridge, its greatest strengths arise from its
that shaming would be more likely to be suc- distinctiveness. In common with the bulk of
cessful when it is inconvenient (I) for a target social science theorizing, comparative meth-
to change its behavior than when it is conven- ods are fundamentally set theoretic.
ient (i). The causal condition I, therefore, may In contrast to conventional variable-
be dropped to produce the causal combina- oriented researchers, comparativists do not
tion ASR. seek mere associations but, rather, seek to
The same logic applies to the sets Acsir establish explicit connections among social
and ACSir. Conditions i, S, and R cannot be phenomena, conceived in set-theoretic terms.
removed because it would violate the subset To do this, comparativists maintain the integ-
relationship. Nor should conditions A, C, and rity of cases so as to identify sets that share
S be removed as each should contribute to members. Set relationships take three basic
the success of shaming. Removing condi- forms. A descriptive set relation articulates
tions c, s, and r produces the terms Ai and connections among sets but stops short of
ACSi. As the latter causal combination is a explanation. A constitutive set relation iden-
subset of the former, it may be removed, tifies essential aspects or components of
leaving Ai. The reduced terms, ASR and Ai, wholes and may be used to constitute theo-
yield the intermediate Boolean equation: retically based populations (e.g., the set of
modernizing revolutions). A causal set rela-
s
Ai + ΑSR Y tion goes beyond establishing an empirical
connection and details the causal mecha-
which is a superset of the complex solution nisms that explain how and why membership
(Acsir + ACSir + ASIR) and a subset of the in one set (the cause) is empirically linked to
parsimonious solution (i + SR). membership in another (the outcome). Causal
As long as the subset principle – that set relations often address conditions of
more complex solutions must be a subset of necessity and/or sufficiency, with a special
more parsimonious solutions – is maintained, concern for causal heterogeneity and INUS
researchers can produce a series of such causation (Mackie, 1974).

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 20 3/11/2009 3:16:16 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 31

The core of causal analysis in comparative


research is the truth table, just as the core of NOTES
variable-oriented causal research is the linear
additive regression equation. These are funda- 1. We recognize that Weber also postulated more
mentally different ways of understanding the complex models of capitalism. See, for example,
social world. The configurational perspective Collins (1980), Giddens (1958), and Weber (1920).
Here, we restrict our discussion to Weber’s model
of comparative research emphasizes the search as presented in The Protestant Ethic for illustrative
for highly consistent relationships linking purposes.
combinations of causes to outcomes. The truth 2. The cities that Brown and Boswell (1995)
table models these relationships. Considering include in the analysis are: Bethlehem, Buffalo,
that comparativists typically trace their line- Chicago, Cleveland, Decatur, East Chicago, Gary,
Johnstown, Joliet, McKeesport, Milwaukee, New
age to the likes of Durkheim and Weber, the Castle, Pittsburg, Reading, Wheeling, and
introduction of truth table analysis to com- Youngstown.
parative research is relatively recent (Ragin, 3. The four outcomes that Brown and Boswell
1987). We have argued, however, that most (1995) examine are: (1) black strikebreaking (whites
comparative analysis involves truth tables, support union), (2) white strikebreaking (blacks sup-
port union), (3) biracial strikebreaking (low overall
either explicitly or implicitly. Contemporary compliance with union), and (4) biracial labor coali-
methodological developments – specifically, tion (high overall compliance with union).
the formalization of the comparative method as 4. Brown and Boswell (1995) do not actually
Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) – present this dataset in their article. Rather, it is
aim to improve comparative research by derived from the truth table that they present as
Table 5 on page 1505. We are able to derive the
making explicit its assumptions, algorithms, original dataset from the truth table only because the
and techniques. This formalization has allowed researchers include a column listing which cities cor-
the development of software packages to respond to which causal configurations. This is one
facilitate technical aspects of comparative reason that we strongly recommend that compara-
analysis, which in turn frees researchers to tive researchers explicitly identify which cases corre-
spond to which truth table configurations. (The
concentrate on their most important task: primary reason being so that cases remain in the
getting to know their cases (Rubinson and foreground of the analysis.)
Ragin, 2007). 5. Based upon substantive and theoretical knowl-
If there is a downside to this formalization edge, the researcher may specify a threshold indicat-
and the associated development of software ing the outcome’s presence. For example, in a large
dataset the researcher may specify that the outcome
packages for comparative analysis, it is the must be present in at least three (or five or ten) cases
fear – as others have speculated (Shalev, to be recognized whereas in a small dataset the
2007) – that lowering the bar to entry will researcher may specify a minimum threshold of one
encourage the rote application of compara- case. Threshold specification relies upon the research-
tive methods. In fact, we expect the opposite. er’s in-depth knowledge of the population. For the
present discussion, we rely upon Brown and Boswell
Truth table analysis simultaneously elimi- (1995) threshold of one case, which is reasonable for
nates the most banal analytic tasks while an N of 16 cases. For additional discussion of thresh-
permitting a more sophisticated analysis of old specifications, see Ragin (2005) and von Eye
more cases in more depth. The investigation (1990).
of necessary and sufficient conditions, causal 6. Specifically, we omit a discussion of prime impli-
cant minimization (see Ragin, 1987: 95–8). Prime
complexity, and counterfactuals all become implicant minimization does not apply to the exam-
increasingly feasible through the application ples we review and does not affect our results.
of QCA, which directly implements the set 7. There is an inconsistency in Stokke’s (2007:
theoretic logic of comparative analysis. 507) reported truth table: rows 4 and 8 share the
Comparative research can, indeed, be done same configuration of causal conditions and out-
comes. Our Table 1.3 reflects this correction.
with or without formal techniques; however, 8. The software package fsQCA (Ragin et al.,
it is best done with an appreciation of its 2006a) includes procedures to facilitate such
distinctiveness. analyses.

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 21 3/11/2009 3:16:16 PM


32 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

REFERENCES Esping-Andersen, G. (1990) The three worlds


of welfare capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Becker, H.S. (1986) ‘Telling about society’, in University Press.
H.S. Becker (ed.) Doing things together: Fearon, J.D. (1991) ‘Counterfactuals and
Selected papers. Evanston, IL: Northwestern hypothesis testing in political science’, World
University Press, pp. 121–36. Politics, 43 (2): 169–95.
Berg-Schlosser, D. and de Meur, G. (1994) Foster, W.Z. (1920) The great steel strike and
‘Conditions of democracy in interwar Europe: its lessons. New York: Huebsch.
A Boolean test of major hypotheses’, Gaddis, J.L. (2002) The landscape of history:
Comparative Politics, 26 (3): 253–79. How historians map the past. Oxford: Oxford
Brady, H.E. (2004) ‘Doing good and doing University Press.
better: How far does the quantitative tem- Gamson, W. (1990) The strategy of social pro-
plate get us?’, in H. Brady and D. Collier test. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
(eds), Rethinking social inquiry: Diverse tools, George, A.L. and Bennett, A. (2005) Case stud-
shared standards. Lanham, MD: Rowman ies and theory development in the social
and Littlefield, pp. 53–67. sciences. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Braumoeller, B.F. and Goertz, G. (2002) ‘Watching Gerring, J. (2007) Case study research: Principles
your posterior: Comment on Seawright’, and practices. New York: Cambridge
Political Analysis, 10 (2): 198–203. University Press.
Brewer, J. and Hunter, A. (2006) Foundations Giddens, A. (1958) ‘Introduction’, in M. Weber
of multimethod research: Synthesizing styles. (ed.), The Protestant ethic and the spirit of
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. capitalism. New Jersey: Prentice Hall,
Brown, C. and Boswell, T. (1995) ‘Strikebreaking pp. 1–12.
or solidarity in the great steel strike of 1919: Goertz, G. (2005) Social science concepts: A
A split labor market, game-theoretic, and user’s guide. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
QCA analysis’, American Journal of Sociology, University Press.
100 (6): 1479–519. Goertz, G. and Starr, H. (eds) (2003) Necessary
Clarke, K.A. (2002) ‘The Reverend and the conditions: Theory, methodology, and appli-
ravens: Comment on Seawright’, Political cations. Lanham, MD: Rowman and
Analysis, 10 (2): 194–7. Littlefield.
Cohen, B.P. (1989) Developing sociological Goldthorpe, J.H. (2000) On sociology:
knowledge: Theory and method. Chicago: Numbers, narratives, and the integration of
Nelson-Hall. research and theory. Oxford: Oxford
Cohen, J. (1988) Statistical power analysis University Press.
for the behavioral sciences. New York: Hermens, F.A. (1941) Democracy of anarchy?
Lawrence Erlbaum. A study of proportional representation. Notre
Collins, R. (1980) ‘Weber’s last theory of capital- Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame.
ism: A systematization’, American Sociological Hobsbawm, E.J. (1967) ‘Review of Social origins
Review, 45 (6): 925–42. of dictatorship and democracy’, American
Dahl, R.A. (1971) Polyarchy: Participation and Sociological Review, 32 (5): 821–2.
opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University King, G., Keohane, R. and Verba, S. (1994)
Press. Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference
Dahl, R.A. (1989) Democracy and its critics. in qualitative research. Princeton, NJ:
New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Princeton University Press.
Denton, T. (2007) ‘Unit of observation in cross- Lieberson, S. (1985) Making it count: The
cultural research: Implications for sampling improvement of social research and theory.
and aggregated data analysis’, Cross-Cultural Berkeley: University of California Press.
Research, 41 (3): 3–31. Linz, J.J. (1978) Crisis, breakdown, and reequili-
Eckstein, H. (1992) ‘Case study and theory in bration. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins
political science’, in Regarding politics: Essays University Press.
on political theory, stability, and change. Lipset, S.M. (1981) Political man: The social
Berkeley: University of California Press, bases of politics. Baltimore, MD: Johns
pp. 117–73. Hopkins University Press.

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 22 3/11/2009 3:16:16 PM


THE DISTINCTIVENESS OF COMPARATIVE RESEARCH 33

Luebbert, G.M. (1987) ‘Social foundations of [computer software]. Tucson, Az: Department
political order in interwar Europe’, World of Sociology, University of Arizona.
Politics, 39 (4): 449–78. Ragin, C.C., Rubinson, C., Schaefer, D.,
Mackie, J.L. (1974) The cement of the universe: Anderson, S., Williams, E. and Geisel, H.
A study of causation. Oxford: Clarendon. (2006b) User’s guide to fuzzy-set/qualitative
Mahoney, J. and Goertz, G. (2004) ‘The possi- comparative analysis [computer manual].
bility principle: Choosing negative cases in Tucson, AZ: Department of Sociology,
comparative research’, American Political University of Arizona.
Science Review, 98 (4): 653–69. Ragin, C.C. and Sonnett, J. (2004) ‘Between
McKeown, T.J. (2004) ‘Case studies and the limits complexity and parsimony: Limited diversity,
of the quantitative worldview’, in H.E. Brady counterfactual cases, and comparative analy-
and D. Collier (eds), Rethinking social inquiry: sis’, in S. Kropp and M. Minkenberg
Diverse tools, shared standards. Lanham, MD: (eds), Vergleichen in der politikwissenschaft.
Rowman and Littlefield, pp. 139–67. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für
Mill, J.S. (1875) A system of logic, ratiocinative Sozialwissenschaften.
and inductive: Being a connected view of the Reinharz, S. (1992) Feminist methods in social
principles of evidence and the methods of research. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
scientific investigation, Vol. 2. London: Rubinson, C. and Ragin, C.C. (2007) ‘New
Longmans, Green, Reader, and Dyer. methods for comparative research?’, in
Mjoset, L. and Clausen, T.H. (eds) (2007) L. Mjoset and T. H. Clausen (eds), Capitalisms
Capitalisms compared, Oxford: Elsevier. compared. Oxford: Elsevier, pp. 373–89.
Moore, B., Jr. (1966) Social origins of dictator- Sani, G. and Sartori, G. (1983) ‘Polarization,
ship and democracy: Lord and peasant in the Fragmentation and Competition in Western
making of the modern world. Boston, MA: Democracies’, in Hans Daalder and Peter
Beacon Press. Mair (eds), Western European party systems:
Ragin, C.C. (1987) The comparative method: Continuity and change. London: Sage.
Moving beyond qualitative and Quantitative Schwartz, B. (1991) ‘Mourning and the making
Strategies. Berkeley, CA: University of of a sacred symbol: Durkheim and the Lincoln
California Press. assassination’, Social Forces, 70 (2): 343–64.
Ragin, C.C. (1989) ‘The logic of the compara- Sewell, W.H., Jr. (1996) ‘Historical events as
tive method and the algebra of logic’, transformation of structures: Inventing revo-
Journal of Quantitative Anthropology, 1 (2): lution at the Bastille’, Theory and Society,
373–98. 25 (6): 841–81.
Ragin, C.C. (1992) ‘“Casing” and the process Shalev, M. (2007) ‘Rejoinder: Affirming limits
of social inquiry’, in C.C. Ragin and H.S. and defending alternatives to multiple
Becker (eds), What is a case? Exploring the regression’, in L. Mjoset and T.H. Clausen
foundations of social inquiry. Cambridge: (eds), Capitalisms compared. Oxford: Elsevier,
Cambridge University Press, pp. 217–26. pp. 391–409.
Ragin, C.C. (1994) Constructing social research. Skocpol, T. (1979) States and social revolu-
Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. tions: A comparative analysis of France,
Ragin, C.C. (2000) Fuzzy-set social science. Russia, and China. Cambridge: Cambridge
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. University Press.
Ragin, C.C. (2005, April) From fuzzy sets Stokke, O.S. (2007) ‘Qualitative comparative
to crisp truth tables (COMPASS working analysis, shaming, and international regime
Paper 2004: 28) Retrieved January 21, 2008, effectiveness’, Journal of Business Research,
from http://www.compasss.org/Raginfztt_ 60 (5): 501–11.
April05.pdf. Stoll, R.R. (1979) Set theory and logic. New
Ragin, C.C. and Becker, H. S. (eds) (1992) York: Dover.
What is a case? Exploring the foundations of Thompson, E.P. (1966) The making of the
social inquiry. Cambridge: Cambridge English working class. New York: Vintage
University Press. Books.
Ragin, C.C., Drass, K.A. and Davey, S. (2006a) Vanhanen, T. (1984) The emergence of democ-
Fuzzy-set/qualitative comparative analysis 2.0 racy: A comparative study of 119 states,

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 23 3/11/2009 3:16:16 PM


34 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

1850–1979. Helsinki: Societas Scientiarum methodology of the social sciences. Glencoe,


Fennica. IL: The Free Press, pp. 164–88.
von Eye, A. (1990) Introduction to configural Weber, M. (1920) ‘The origin of modern capi-
frequency analysis: The search for types and talism’, in R. Collins (ed.) Four sociological
antitypes in cross-classifications. New York: traditions: Selected readings. Oxford: Oxford
Cambridge University Press. University Press, pp. 36–57.
Weber, M. (1905) ‘Objective possibility and Weber, M. (1958) The Protestant ethic and the
adequate causation in historical explana- spirit of capitalism. New Jersey: Prentice
tion’, in E.A. Shils and H.A. Finch (eds), The Hall.

9781412919760_Chap01.indd 24 3/11/2009 3:16:16 PM


2
Global Comparative
Methods
Paul Pennings, Hans Keman and Jan Kleinnijenhuis

INTRODUCTION by focusing on quantitative research, in par-


ticular time series analysis and the use of
Comparative research is generally defined pooled cross-section time series data sets.
either at the level of systems (often national), Global comparative methods enable us to
or as a process by assessing politics over compare many countries by using abstract
time (often yearly). Both descriptions are concepts that can travel in order to discover
generally considered to differentiate the com- universal factors that account for the phe-
parative approach from other approaches nomenon to be explained. These types of
within social science such as rational choice. analyses are often characterized by a trade-
In line with this definition of comparative off between the level of abstraction and the
research, this chapter focuses on comparative scope (or number) of countries so that they
studies in which the nation-state is the unit of have per definition both strengths and weak-
analysis and countries are researched at one nesses attached to them.
point in time or over time. The focus on quantitative analysis might
Both time and space are important dimen- give the impression that theory is not consid-
sions in most research designs. Depending ered to be important for comparative research.
on the units of variation and the causal rela- But the contrary is true. Theory, considered
tionship under review, inter-temporal and/or as a set of plausible research answers to a
cross-sectional variation will define the type research question, always precedes compara-
of cases that are needed to organize the com- tive research. Often it consists of a number of
parative data. This chapter discusses the causal relations that are to be confirmed by
strengths and weaknesses of two types of means of empirical evidence, which refute or
comparative research designs whose logic is confirm the tenability of the proposed rela-
closely related to the dimensions of time and/ tions. Without theory or by using flawed
or space: synchronic cross-sectional com- theory, quantitative comparative research
parisons and diachronic (pooled) cross-time becomes meaningless and cannot lead to
comparisons. We make an important restriction valid results and insights.

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 1 3/11/2009 3:24:52 PM


36 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

The restriction to quantitative methods l polyarchy – indicating the positive conditions


does not imply that these provide better for the population to participate in national
means for a comparative study of social reality decision-making.
than qualitative methods. Neither of these
approaches is better suited for comparative The combination of both variables presents
research by themselves: all depends on how the degree of ‘democraticness’ in a society
they are used given the research question and from a comparative perspective. Keman’s
the research design. The discussion will focus study is based on 172 countries in the world
on methodological problems associated with (40% non-democracies; 10% old democra-
this form of analysis and makes explicit which cies; 50% recent (established after 1945) or
problems and pitfalls need to be taken into new (after 1988) democracies). The starting
account in order to arrive at valid results. point is the well-known conceptualization of
The discussion is divided into two main democracy by Dahl as polyarchal democracy,
parts. The first part focuses on the measure- being a political system with the six institu-
ment of democracy and democratization on a tions listed below (Dahl, 1984, 1998).
global scale using a synchronic large-N
design. This theme is among the most promi- 1. Universal suffrage and the right to run for public
nent examples of global research. The second office.
part is explanatory and examines factors that 2. Free and fairly conducted elections.
account for democratization, such as eco- 3. Availability and observance of the right to free
nomic development. In this part the emphasis speech and protection to do so.
4. The existence and free access to alternative (and
is diachronic analysis within a large-N design
often competing) information (not controlled by
by taking time into account. government).
5. The undisputed right to form and to join relatively
autonomous organizations, in particular political
CONCEPTS AND MEASUREMENT parties (and crucially: parties in opposition).
OF DEMOCRACY AND 6. The responsiveness of government (and parties)
DEMOCRATIZATION: SYNCHRONIC to voters and accountability of government (and
ANALYSIS WITHIN A LARGE-N parties) to election outcomes and parliament.
DESIGN
It is this combined set of institutions that
Doing research on many countries confronts distinguishes polyarchic regimes from other
us with the problem of conceptualization. A regime types. The coming about of these
classic example from comparative politics is institutions can then be seen as the process
the research on democracy and democratiza- towards democratization. The persistance of
tion. The concept of democracy may seem the whole set is the hallmark of an estab-
unproblematic, but it is highly complex and lished democracy (see also Keman, 2002;
multi-dimensional which means it is not self- Schmidt, 2000: 393–5).
evident how to apply this concept within a Among many comparativists Tatu
large-N design. Below, various ways of con- Vanhanen can be counted as a prime example
ceptualizing, measuring and transforming who has attempted to describe and analyze
democracy into a valid and reliable cross- the process of democratization (Vanhanen,
national variable are explored. We adopt 1990, 1997, 2003). His index of polyarchy is
Keman’s (2002) view on democracy which based on two measures representing ‘partici-
distinguishes two dimensions: pation’ and ‘competition’ that together form
an Index of Democratization (ID). The degree
l pluralism – representing the possibilities of of legal competition (in a democracy there
organizing as a group on the societal level free will be at least two equal groups which are
from the state; and free to compete for power) is operationalized

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 2 3/11/2009 3:24:52 PM


GLOBAL COMPARATIVE METHODS 37

as 100 minus the percentage of the votes won First of all, it appears that the dissimilar
by the largest party (a high score indicates a conceptualizations and operationalizations
high degree of competition). The degree of lead to different results. The number of non-
participation is operationalized as the number democratic countries is proportionally twice
of voters as a percentage of the total popula- as high according to Coppedge and Reinicke
tion (a high score indicates a high degree of than that found by Jagger and Gurr (the dif-
participation). From his analysis it appears ference is 30 cases). Yet, Keman has found
that on average the countries score higher that the differences are less if one controls
today than in the 1980s (1980 = 8.96; 1990 = the results for regime types such as the ones
13.9) on the Index of Democratization. developed by Alvarez et al. (1996):
Indeed, the world has changed towards more Presidentialism, parliamentarism, dictator-
democratization and now contains a growing ships and autocracies. It should be noted that
number of countries that have taken the road on the level of individual cases the differ-
to greater polyarchy. ences are – again – not large, but certain
Coppedge and Reinicke (1990) have devel- cases appear to be odd or even out of place
oped a scale that examines the available insti- (partly due to fact that the data used are more
tutions that promote a pluralist organization of often than not supplied by public authorities
society. In addition to examining the require- or derived from constitutional documents).
ments for free and fair elections, they have Contrary to the indicators and scales dis-
developed indicators to measure the degree of cussed here, there is also research that focuses
freedom of organization, of speech and infor- explicitly on the execution of individual
mation and of access to government sources of rights not interfered with by the state (and its
information. This operationalization is quite agencies). An example is the Freedom House
close to Dahl’s idea of polyarchy. Coppedge index of political and civil rights (Freedom
and Reinicke measure the extent to which House, 2007) which has been established
groups in society can organize themselves and since 1972. This scale runs from 1 to 7,
are capable of conducting a viable opposition. where a low value implies actual availability
As Schmidt (2000: 402) rightly observes, this and observation for these rights. Taken
kind of operationalization tends to ignore the together these two scales provide informa-
formal institutions (i.e., Rule of Law) that tion on the extent to which a nation is not
restrict the powers of government and the only formally democratic, but can also be
state. To some extent this defect has been considered as truly liberal democratic in
solved by Jaggers and Gurr (1995), who within practice and therefore, as close as can be to
the research programme ‘Polity III’, have col- Dahl’s polyarchy. Studies that apply this
lected data across most nation-states on: scale show that the prevalence and observ-
ance of political and civil rights do make a
l those institutions that facilitate and promote difference. What is striking is the marked dif-
political choice by citizens; ference between parliamentarism and presi-
l the availability of basic civil and political rights dentialism in this respect. The latter regime
for all citizens; and type consistently shows a worse record in
l the existence of constitutional requirements that observing civil and political rights, notwith-
limit the executive powers. standing its rule of law (Riggs, 1998).
Are these scales satisfactory as truly com-
Jaggers and Gurr have developed a scale that parative variables? According to Bollen
enables them not only to differentiate between and Paxton (2000) this is not the case, mainly
‘autocracy’ and ‘democracy’, but also the due to the (ab)use of ‘subjective’ measures
level of democracy available. What do these (such as, for instance, those of Coppedge
cross-national variables tell us about the level and Reinicke and of the Freedom
of democratization? House). Subjective measures often contain

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 3 3/11/2009 3:24:52 PM


38 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

judge-specific errors that may produce number of associations with the other varia-
reliable (whilst measured consistently and bles that can be seen as explaining the cross-
dependably), but not valid ratings of democ- national variation in democraticness as well
racy due to bias that comes from the inclu- as possibly accounting for certain societal
sion of extraneous factors. A combination by performances. We shall employ the ‘variable
means of grouped panel rating on the basis of oriented’ approach for a global universe of
judges with diverse orientations or experi- discourse because this type of analysis with a
ences could reduce this bias (Bollen and high number of cases and few variables is
Paxton, 2000: 79). In Keman’s approach crucial for the development of a ‘middle-
objective measures are combined with sub- range’ theory regarding the democraticness
jective ones. To this end he collected a of political systems (see Lane and Ersson,
number of scales and indexes that have been 1999).
developed both subjectively and objectively Surveying the literature on explaining
and grouped these variables as being produc- democracy as a system and its development
tive for creating pluralistic conditions or (i.e., the process) the following answers have
promoting polyarchic institutions (see Bollen, been offered.
1993; Bollen and Paxton, 2000; Keman
2002; Schmidt, 2000). By ex ante dividing l Economic development and socio-economic
the measures into more pluralistic and pol- circumstances influence both its development
yarchic the validity of the variables in use is and working (e.g., Berg-Schlosser and de Meur,
improved. A statistical procedure to combine 1996).
variables on pluralism and polyarchy is factor l Modernization of society and the extension
analysis that can be used to merge several of public welfare are conducive to (further)
variables into one or two that indicate the democratization of the national state (e.g., Dahl,
1998).
extent of democracy and degree of democatic-
l Institutionalization of democracy as a regime in
ness across the world. Of the 127 nations that relation to its viability which over time enhances
have positive scores on both dimensions – the level of democraticness (e.g., Diamond and
pluralism and polyarchy – about one-third Plattner, 1994).
(N = 43) of the countries included can be l Organized political action in terms of participa-
considered – according to this operationali- tion and opposition, which ‘makes democracy
zation – as genuinely democratic (i.e., the work’ (in whatever fashion or way) is an impor-
score is >1.0). This is a relatively high tant and often neglected facet of democratic
number of countries. The ‘older’ and the politics (e.g., Norris, 1999).
‘richer’ the countries are the stronger their
democraticness appears to be. In addition, To what extent do these factors account for
the parliamentary types of democracy score the cross-national variation regarding the
consistently higher than any other type of extent of pluralism and polyarchy? Table 2.1
regime, including presidentialism. Finally, reports four regression models incorporating
Latin-American countries do fare better than explanatory variables for occurrence and
postcommunist ones. This supports the idea viability of democracy. The four models are
that ‘ageing’ is an important factor in devel- all, but for two factors, statistically signifi-
oping higher levels of democraticness. cant (the rate of urbanization and the size of
the public sector appear irrelevant in this
context) and thus all lend support to the
Doing causal analysis in large-N answer as to why democracies are dependent
on certain factors to develop and remain
designs: Synchronic designs
viable as democracies. Most of the results are
In this section we shall employ these three unsurprising and underwrite extant knowl-
indexes of democracy to (re)consider a edge (Landman, 2003). Yet, it is also clear

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 4 3/11/2009 3:24:52 PM


GLOBAL COMPARATIVE METHODS 39

Table 2.1 Regression analysis of factors explaining democracy


Independent variables Dependent variables
Pluralism Polyarchy
Economics α −14.1 −25.8
GNP per Capita β 0.45 (3.95) 0.42 (3.91)
Government β 0.12* (1.08) 0.25 (2.33)
expenditures per
Capita
R2 25.5% 33.1%
Society α −17.7 −18.6
Urbanization β −0.12* (−1.13*) 0.07* (0.70)
Human β 0.66 (6.49) 0.56 (5.64)
Development
Index
R2 32.4% 36.9%
Institutions α −7.3 −7.2
Presidentialism β 0.34 (4.48) 0.34 (4.51)
Parliamentarism β 0.74 (10.49) 0.73 (9.76)
R2 40.3% 39.3%
Politics α −16.5 −19.44
Electoral turnout β 0.35 (3.37) 0.38 (3.84)
Central government β 0.19 (1.81) 0.24 (2.39)
expenditures
R2 16.8% 22.9%
Note: OLS procedure has been employed; number of cases is 82 and 110; t-values are in parentheses; insignifcant
results are flagged*. Source: Keman, 2002 (adapted).

that none of the models is superior to the economic wealth certainly can help to foster
others: neither in terms of explained democracy and is more often than not associ-
variance (adjusted R2), nor in the magnitude ated with higher level of democraticness, but
of influence. is not the driving force as many political sci-
The first model, depicting the working of entists and economists in the period directly
the market as well as the state, demonstrates after the World War II claimed (Castles,
that the ‘wealth of a nation’ is certainly an 1998).
incentive for democratization. However, this The same can be said of the societal forces
is not the case for the size of the public (the second model). Although much of the
sector. Yet, at the same time it is also clear literature claims that the composition of soci-
that this is an insufficient condition per se. ety and its consequences for inter-class
There are many outliers that prove the con- rivalry are important for understanding the
trary. For example, many non-democratic process of democratization as well as the
nations have also considerable levels of stability of a democratic regime, this hypoth-
public expenditure. Likewise, a number of esis is not supported by our analysis. From
states with aggregated economic riches spring our analysis it appears that urbanization –
to mind that are close to dictatorship or used as a proxy for modernization – is unre-
autocracy (e.g., some of the Arabian coun- lated to the indicators for democracy.
tries). In short, we hold the view that Hence, it is either an invalid proxy indicator

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 5 3/11/2009 3:24:52 PM


40 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

or the modernization thesis is not valid. We weakly supported, and – as was the case with
think both explanations are plausible (and economics and society – we can only repeat
this is supported in much of the literature; our observation that, although there is a rela-
see: Landman, 2003; Rueschemeyer et al., tionship, it is not convincing and cannot be
1992). considered as a major factor for democratiza-
Conversely, the quality of life as expressed tion and democraticness as such (Keman,
by the Human Development Index (http://hdr. 2002).
undp.org/) is an important asset for develop- In summary: the cross-national analysis of
ing and sustaining democracy. Yet, again as factors promoting pluralism and polyarchy
with economic factors, we can only go along demonstrates (ceteris paribus) that favoura-
with this claim as far as it implies a necessary ble economic conditions and high(er) levels
condition; but – judging by an explained vari- of human development are incentives for
ance of approximately 36.8% – it is an insuf- achieving higher levels of democraticness.
ficient condition for improving the level of However, like political factors, they are not
democraticness of a nation. In addition, it crucial per se, nor functional under all cir-
should be noted that both explanations – the cumstances. It appears rather that the inter-
economy and society – tend to become func- play of these factors benefits further
tional ones. If so, and we think this is correct, democratization and may well enhance the
the causality of the argument is weak if not level of democraticness of a nation. Hence
absent. Rather we would go along with those there is not a definitive set of factors,
who advocate a more ‘case oriented’ approach conditions or prerequisites (although their
that enables researchers to disentangle the absence may certainly harm the level of
subtle variations within a society and to democraticness attained!) that allows for a
develop ‘path dependent’ explanations (e.g., successful development and extension of
Putnam, 1993). democracy.
The third model concerns the impact on
the level of democraticness of the organiza-
tion of the democratic polity. Too often the
institutional fabric of democracy has been TIME SERIES ANALYSIS
considered as the end-result of democratiza-
tion. We think this view is biased if not Until now we have discussed synchronic
wrong because institutions are not static, but research designs. By introducing the element
are continuously modified by actors. The of time one can analyze more cases and study
coming about of a democracy, whether it is developments over time. In doing so, the
‘old’ (and now established, as in the OECD- problem of ‘too many variables and too few
world) or ‘new’ (hence recently established, cases’ becomes less, but it also introduces a
as in Central and Eastern Europe), the strug- new problem, namely that the cases are not
gle for more democracy is mainly fought out independent. This problem may invoke a
over institutions which explains why they are large number of statistical complications of
not constants (in the long run). which the most important ones are discussed
The last model reported in Table 2.1 con- below. The discussion and examples are
cerns the active use of designated powers by derived from Pennings et al. (2006).
the people and by the state. On the one hand, Time series analysis is discussed here only
we examined the use of the ballot box, and on in the sense of ordinary regression analysis
the other hand, we scrutinized the idea that with points or periods in time as the units of
central government is strongly associated with analysis. The dependent variable yt is meas-
democraticness: a democratic state will be ured at point t. Since it takes some time
conducive to greater state intervention (by before effects come into place, the independ-
popular demand). Both contentions are only ent variables in time series analysis are often

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 6 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


GLOBAL COMPARATIVE METHODS 41

measured in earlier points in time than the then it is misleading to think of the consecu-
dependent variable. Time series regression tive time points as independent observations.
analysis is a powerful tool for causal analy- Autocorrelation implies that the number of
sis, since the timely order of a cause and its independent observations is smaller than the
consequence can be expressed with a time number of time points. Whereas the compu-
lag between the independent variables and tation of standard errors of regression esti-
the dependent variable. A time lag is the dif- mates in ordinary least squares (OLS) is
ference k between a time t in a series and a based on the available number of time points,
time t−k in the same or another series. Often this computation should be based – less
this means that the current Y-values are due optimistically – on the (unknown) number of
to changes in X in the previous period. The independent observations. In the presence of
introduction of this time element is an impor- autocorrelation OLS estimates of regression
tant added value compared to the cross- coefficients in non-autoregressive models
sectional analysis that we discussed before. are inefficient, although still unbiased.
The availability of time series data allows Autocorrelation in autoregressive models
one to construct an autoregressive model. In makes things even worse. Estimates will not
an autoregressive process the current value only be inefficient but also biased.
depends on one or more of the (usually A straightforward diagnostic of first-order
immediately) preceding values. The basic serial correlation would be the correlation
idea of an autoregressive model is that the coefficient rt, t−1 between residuals in succes-
current state of affairs yt is dependent prima- sive points in time. The Durbin-Watson sta-
rily on the state of affairs in the immediate tistic DW is based on this serial correlation
past (yt−1), although external influences coefficient between residuals. It is roughly
(effects of xt and zt) and random shocks (εt) equal to 2 − 2rt, t−1; it thus takes values
together with an autonomous trend (b0) may between 0 and 4 rather than between –1 and
sum up to a change. The resulting R2 from an +1. Since DW is roughly equal to 2 − 2 rt, t−1;
autoregressive model is not to be compared it thus takes values between 0 and 4 rather
with the R2 in an ‘ordinary’ model. Especially than between −1 and +1. DW = 2 corresponds
when almost nothing changes as compared to with r = 0, DW = 0 with r = +1, and DW = 4
the previous point in time the R2 of an autore- with r = −1. DW-values in the neighbourhood
gressive model will be high, since a lack of of 2 indicate the absence of autocorrelation.
changes (due to slowness of social changes Values near 0 indicate the presence of auto-
and rigidities in social structures) will result correlation: it is likely that a deviation from
by definition in a close correspondence the regression line at time t will be followed
between yt and yt−1. This contradicts the at time t + 1 by a deviation in the same direc-
intuitive meaning of ‘explained variance’ of tion. If errors are positively correlated, as
many social scientists. they usually are, standard errors are underes-
Autocorrelation is defined as serial corre- timated and the R2 and t-values have an
lation between residuals. It occurs when the upward bias so that they present an overly
residuals in a given time period carry over optimistic view about the accuracy of the
into a later time period. First-order serial coefficients. This bias makes us reject the
correlation is correlation between immedi- null hypothesis of no relationship far more
ately successive points in time (between often than we should. Values of DW between
observations at time points t and t−1), for 2 and 4 indicate an oscillating pattern: if the
example, when an overestimate in one year is actual value at time t is higher than one
likely to lead to an overestimate in the next would expect on the basis of the regression
year. False predictions for one point in time equation, then it is likely that the actual value
will result in false predictions for the next at time t + 1 is lower than one would expect
points in time. If autocorrelation is present, on the basis of the regression equation.

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 7 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


42 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Negatively correlated errors (DW = 4) are asso- period). This intuitive solution is flawed,
ciated with overestimated standard errors. however. Meaningful variation within the
Durbin-Watson-values are computed by aggregated time spans is easily ignored.
most statistical packages, but usually it is still Moreover the periodization is often arbitrary,
necessary to consult a table with DW-values because each variable tends to have its own
to find out whether a specific DW-value periodicity, its own rhythm of change. Here
indicates autocorrelation, no autocorrelation, we will stick to solutions which retain all
or doubt given a specific number of time data points in the regression equation.
points as units of analysis and a given number Let us first consider a non-autoregressive
of independent variables. Regrettably the DW- model which exhibits autocorrelation accord-
tables have a region of doubt, depending on ing the DW-test (DW far lower than 2). This
the number of independent variables and the indicates that the process being studied remains
number of observations, in which it is unde- by and large in the same state as in the previous
cided from a statistical point of view whether point in time. It may still be possible to explain
autocorrelation is present or not. changes, however. To explain changes relative
The Durbin-Watson test (DW-test) applies to the status quo either a simple first-order-
to non-autoregressive time series regression difference regression model or a more advanced
models, but should not be applied to autore- autoregressive model should be used.
gressive models. To indicate whether auto- In the first-order-difference model the
correlation in the residuals from an dependent variable is the change Dyt = yt −
autoregressive equation is absent, one should yt−1 in Y (the zero-order-dependent variable)
not use the ordinary Durbin-Watson-test, but as compared to the previous point in time.
for example the Durbin’s h-test. If the usual Regardless of the previous level yt−1 of the
5% criterion is used, the assumption that dependent variable Dyt will become zero
serial autocorrelation is absent is tenable whenever yt = yt−1. The difference model Dyt =
when h < 1.645. If Durbin’s h-test indicates b0 + b2 xt−1 + b3 zt−1 + εt is equivalent to a
that autocorrelation is present in an autore- model yt = b0 + b1 yt−1 + b2 xt−1 + b3 zt−1 + εt
gressive regression equation estimated with with yt as the dependent and the lagged
OLS, then the OLS conclusion should be that dependent variable yt−1 as an independent
should not have been used. One must resort variable with b1 constrained to 1. In a first-
to generalized least squares estimation pro- order-difference model the motion of an
cedures which are implemented in most sta- object is the dependent variable, whereas in a
tistical packages. OLS estimates of regression zero-order model the position of an object is
coefficients can be used in autoregressive the dependent variable.
models, however, when Durbin’s h-test indi- In an autoregressive model yt = b0 + b1 yt−1 +
cates the absence of autocorrelation. b2 xt + b3 zt + εt the regression coefficient for
An often used, rather intuitive solution to the lagged dependent variable yt−1 is not con-
obtain independent observations would be to strained to 1, but empirically estimated. The
diminish the number of time points in the autoregression coefficient b1 gives informa-
regression analysis, for example by aggregat- tion about what exactly is being influenced
ing quarterly data to yearly data, or by aggre- by the remaining independent variables. An
gating yearly data to five years data, or by estimate of b1 = 0 is equivalent to an ordinary
aggregating all time points before and after regression model with yt as the dependent
important historical events (e.g., World War II, variable. An estimate of b1 = 1 is equivalent
the 1973 oil crisis, the 1989 velvet revolu- to the first-order-difference model. Empirical
tion). Two procedures may be used: simply estimates of b1 will often result in between 0
pick out one time point per period or smooth and 1. An estimate of b1=1/2 would indicate
the data within each time period (for example that the remaining independent variables in
by computing average values for each time the model have an influence on yt – 1/2 yt−1.

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 8 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


GLOBAL COMPARATIVE METHODS 43

To compare a non-autoregressive model The regression models based on the original


(b1 = 0), a first difference model (b1 = 1) and variables typically suffer from the autocor-
an autoregressive model (say, with b1 = 1/2) relation defect. Difference models and/or
it is helpful to think of the ‘shocks’ required autoregressive models will usually cure the
from the remaining independent variables to autocorrelation disease, but difference models
keep y at an extreme high (or low) level. In a and autoregressive are usually not robust. At
first-order-difference model a continuation least three origins of this lack of robustness
of the shocks which brought about today’s can be mentioned.
level of yt is superfluous to preserve the Autoregressive models will usually leave
status quo. For this reason a first-order- only a small portion of the variance in the
difference model is also known as the random dependent variable unexplained. Exogenous
walk (RW) which is the most well-known influences are hard to verify when the remain-
non-stationary process. This process resem- ing unexplained variance is small, especially
bles a walker who time and again takes a step when measurement errors are present. A
so as to keep a tail wind from the independ- second reason why autoregressive models
ent variables, regardless of where he came and difference models often fail to retrieve
from or where he wants to go. He will stay the obvious is their fixation on short term
where he is when it is dead calm. In a non- changes. Long term shocks in exogenous
autoregressive model our walker will return variables which have already influenced
home immediately once there is not a breath the lagged dependent variable will not be
of wind. This property of non-autoregressive attributed to exogenous variables but to the
model is known as regression towards the endogenous lagged dependent variable. In
mean, which means that without continued the last decades error correction models or
external shocks the mean will be restored. An co-integration models have been developed
autoregressive model with an autoregressive to account for long-term effects of exogenous
parameter of 0.5 resembles a walker who variables, without introducing autocorrela-
returns half way home when the wind drops. tion once more. These models will be left
The solution for autocorrelation in an autore- aside here.
gressive regression equation (as indicated by The third, and most important reason, is
Durbin’s h) or in a first-order-difference simply the limited number of time points.
model (as indicated by the ordinary DW-test) Data on 25 consecutive years is almost noth-
is subject to debate, both from a theoretical ing, especially when autocorrelation is
as from a statistical point of view. One solu- present. Twenty-five years may shrink to five
tion would be to develop a second-order- ‘independent’ years when most years are
difference model, which has as the dependent almost perfect copies of their predecessors.
variable the rate of the change of the Data on short time series cursed with auto-
change of the original dependent variable. correlation are compatible with many sim-
A second-order model from physics would be plistic rivalling theories, but they are simply
a model with the acceleration of an object – insufficient to estimate the parameters of any
rather than its position (zero-order) or its complex theory.
motion (first-order) – as the dependent
variable.
Time series data are a perfect means to Pooled time series analysis
assess causality because of their timely order
and therefore might be superior to cross- One way out of this difficulty in time series
sectional models. However, this is only the analysis is to test elaborated theories for many
case when they are handled properly given time series simultaneously, which brings us to
a large number of statistical complica- pooled time series analysis. The advantage of
tions that are likely to impact on the results. time series analysis is its ability to assess the

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 9 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


44 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

time dependency of causal relationships. Often analyses, especially in aggregate data.


the data available do mount up to short time Heteroscedasticity will usually arise because
series only (e.g., 40 points in time or even the appropriate models for the various cross-
less). More often than not various plausible sections will not be precisely identical.
models will account for the data on such a Therefore, a model to explain all cross-sec-
short time series. One way out is to increase tions will usually do better for some than for
the quantity of the data used for testing. others, which amounts to unequal variances of
Pooled time series analysis (or panel anal- the residuals for the cross-sections. In our
ysis) combines time series for several cross- example on expenditures heteroscedasticity
sections. The data are stacked by cross-section means the following. The tendencies which
and time points. A classical example is a led to higher public expenditures in the
pooled time series database of 828 units seventies manifested themselves in all
stacked by 18 OECD countries over 46 years capitalist countries. Nevertheless, the precise
(1960–2006). Instead of studying the effects effect of an increasing percentage of elderly
of various variables on public expenditures in on public expenditures may depend on polity
each country through time, these effects may variables such as the electoral system, and on
be studied for a number of countries simulta- policy and legislation with respect to health
neously. Instead of testing a time series care technology, health care insurances and
model for one country using time series data, pensions for the elderly. If one model is tested
or testing a cross-sectional model for all for all cross-sections at all time points, then
countries at one point in time, a pooled time heteroscedasticity comes in since the residuals
series model is tested for all countries through for ‘extreme’ countries will be large as
time. Much more refined tests of theories compared to the residuals for mainstream
will become possible, since the available countries.
units of analysis increase from T (number of The combination of autocorrelation and
time points) to NT (number of cross-sections heteroscedasticity in sample data may result
times number of time points). Pooled time in extremely inefficient, although unbiased,
series analysis captures not only variation estimates of the true population parameters.
that emerges through time, but variation The diagnosis of autocorrelation and hetero-
across different cross-sections as well. Note scedasticity in pooled time series analysis is
that not all global methods are necessarily fairly straightforward, although statistical
highly complex. Most available studies can software packages are usually not ideally
be situated between the advanced statistical suited for its implementation. The degree of
analysis of Przeworksi et al. (2000) on the heteroscedasticity due to pooling is to be
relationship between democracy and devel- obtained by examining the residual variances
opment (1950–1990) and the more descrip- of the pooled model per cross-section. A
tive approach of Lane and Ersson (2002) who sequence plot of the residuals for the various
study the size of government in all countries cross-sections will give a first visual impres-
on the basis of aggregated data. sion. Ideally the average of the residuals
Regrettably pooled time series analysis also within each cross-section should be equal to
has a serious drawback. Since pooled time zero. If an inspection of the sequence plot
series analysis is still time series analysis, the suggests that the mean residual varies from
problem of autocorrelation must still be dealt cross-section to cross-section then the con-
with. But in addition to autocorrelation per clusion should be that crucial variables that
cross-section heteroscedasticity between explain the differences between cross-
cross-sections comes in. Heteroscedasticity is sections (regardless of the precise time point
the unequal distribu-tion or variance of the being looked at) are still lacking.
error term which invalidates significance tests. A simple diagnostic test on the robustness
It is a common problem in cross-sectional of the pooled model is to run the same model

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 10 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


GLOBAL COMPARATIVE METHODS 45

on its residuals for each cross-section through The solutions to the problems raised by
time and on its residuals for each time unit pooled time series analysis might be divided
over cross-sections. If the same model holds in two groups. The first group of solutions is
for all cross-sections and all time points, then directed at the improvement of the models to
the pooled model will not be able to explain fit pooled time series data. The second group
its own residuals split up by cross-section of solutions is directed at the development of
and time unit. Thus, for a regression model statistical estimation procedures to improve
tested on 80 units stacked by 8 cross-sections on OLS deficiencies when a combination of
over 10 years, 8 + 10 = 18 regressions should autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity is
be performed on the residuals from the present.
pooled model. The model should not be able Let us start with model improvements to
to explain significant proportions of the vari- get rid of heteroscedasticity between cross-
ance within its own residuals in more than sections. When the mean of the residuals for
5% of the cases. Thus, the pooled model one or more specific cross-sections is un-
from our example should not be able to pro- equal to zero, then one should add variables
duce significant regression estimates within to the model so as to explain these cross-
its own residuals in more than four time units sectional differences better. A non-theoretical
or cross-sections. If the model is able to model to get rid of heteroscedasticity between
explain additional variance in its own residu- cross-sections completely would be to add
als for a large number of time units or cross- one dummy variable to the model for each
sections (more than 4 in our example) then cross-section, except one. This model is
the suspicion should be that the original called the least squares dummy variable
model does not hold for all cross-sections (LSDV) model in the jargon of pooled time
and time units equally well. series analysis. The LSDV-model accounts
A proper diagnosis of autocorrelation in for different Y levels by estimating different
pooled time series analysis is cumbersome, intercepts for each cross-section. A more
because of its statistical relatedness with advanced variant would be to assume that
cross-sectional heteroscedasticity. If there is each cross-section has a randomly distributed
cross-sectional heteroscedasticity there will intercept associated with it (the random coef-
be autocorrelation almost by definition: if the ficients model). We would advise against
predictions for the complete cross-section these non-theoretical solutions, since a-theo-
are wrong, then the mispredictions for each retical dummies and random intercepts that
of its successive time points will be serially are added to a regression model will usually
correlated. Model improvements to reduce be collinear with some variables of theoreti-
the cross-sectional heteroscedasticity will cal interest. The explanatory power of the
therefore usually also diminish autocorrela- variables of theoretical interest will easily get
tion. The formulas of the Durbin-Watson obscured. It is far better to include a few
statistic and Durbin’s h allow for a computa- variables which account for the major differ-
tion over time series for several cross- ences between the cross-sections, than to
sections. One technical warning is probably include every separate cross-section (except
not superfluous: the lag of the first time point one) as a dummy-variable. The LSDV model
for a specific cross-section is missing (and and the random coefficients model should
not equal to the last time point for the preced- only be used when the available theory gives
ing cross-section in the data file). It is a pit- no cues at all with respect to differences
fall to rely on autocorrelation diagnostics per between processes in the cross-sections being
time series. Precisely because the separate studied.
time series in pooled time series analysis are To get rid of serial autocorrelation the same
too short, Durbin-Watson-tests per cross- model ramifications (first-order-difference
section produce chaotic results. model, autoregressive model) should be

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 11 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


46 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

considered as in ordinary time series analysis. Troeger, 2007). In addition, both the size and
A rather different question is which estimation the sign of the estimates may strongly depend
technique should be used when autocorrelation on the exclusion of particular countries.
and heteroscedasticity have not been banned From this overview of the problems and
completely. How should we deal with the fact pitfalls of pooled analysis follows that purely
that OLS estimates will be inefficient and there- cross-sectional analyses are still necessary and
fore usually underestimate the standard errors useful since they are not disturbed by the prob-
of the regression estimates? Econometricians lems inherent in time series. They can be used
have proposed various estimation techniques to validate the results of pooled time series
for this purpose. The most widely applied is the analysis. If an analysis includes institutional
Parks-Kmenta method, a specimen of the gen- and political variables that hardly vary over
eralized least squares (GLS) family of estima- time, there is not much use for pooling repeated
tion techniques (White, 1994: 245–54). These observations over time, unless efficient estima-
estimation techniques guarantee that the esti- tion techniques can be utilised (Plümper and
mates asymptotically hit the mark. They are Troeger, 2007). Pooling data is especially
unbiased when sample sizes draw near infinity. useful if an effect is assumed to be equal across
Recently Beck and Katz (1995) have shown space and time or when the research focuses
that the Parks-Kmenta estimation technique on short term effects. When these conditions
produces quite chaotic results when time series are not fulfilled, statistical problems are likely
are as short as in comparative political science to make the results meaningless.
(usually less then 50 years per cross-section). We end our discussion with the same
Katz and Beck showed also that OLS estimates example as in a previous section on syn-
of regression coefficients are more robust chronic analysis, but we now introduce the
than Parks-Kmenta estimates when sample element of time. Burkhart and Lewis-Beck
sizes are small. Katz and Beck have developed (1994) have analysed the economic factors
a formula to compute panel corrected standard that may boost democratization. Their data
errors (PCSEs) which encompass autocorrela- set is an adapted and extended version of the
tion and heteroscedasticity in the computation Freedom House democracy indicators.
of the standard errors of the OLS-regression Burkhart and Lewis-Beck added to this data
estimates. dummies for the position of countries (c =
The use of panel data has become quite core, m = semiperiphery, p = periphery).
common in quantitative comparative research. They also employ the energy consumption
Unfortunately this is accompanied by a per capita (logged) as an economic develop-
number of problems and pitfalls. These are ment measure (that correlates 0.9 with gross
discussed by Kittel and Winner (2005) and national product per capita). Burkhart and
Plümper et al. (2005) in their critique on the Lewis-Beck test the ‘economic development
study of Garrett and Mitchell (2001) on the thesis’ with the following model:
relationship between total government
expenditure and the partisan composition of Dt = a + bDt−1 + cEt + d(M × Et)
government as well as economic internation- + e(P × Et) + u
alization. In their discussion on PCSE they
where
argue that autoregressive models with panel
corrected standard errors should not be used Dt is the democracy index at time t ;
as a universal remedy for problems in panel Dt−1 is the democracy index from the year
data analysis. If the assumption on the error before;
terms are not tested before PCSEs are calcu- Et is energy consumption per capita (logged to
lated and/or problems with non-stationary the base 10) at time t ; and
data are not recognized, the conclusions will (M × Et) is the dummy variable for semiperiphery
always be highly problematic (Plümper and status multiplied by Et.

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 12 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


GLOBAL COMPARATIVE METHODS 47

The Burkhart and Lewis-Beck’s model is an welfare but also, and more importantly, at the
autoregressive model having the lagged distribution of a wider range of power
dependent variable at the right hand side of resources. Vanhanen’s conceptualization and
the equation (like in Yt = Yt−1 + Xt). This type operationalization of the index of power
of modelling is not without complications as resources indeed results in a much higher
it may well boost the R2 and Beta-weight. explained variance of 0.71.
Dt−1 acts to control for omitted independent This example shows us that a high
variables: as the other forces acting on explained variance is only to be trusted when
democracy are uncertain, they will be essen- both the theoretical and statistical specifica-
tially summarized in the democratic per- tions of the model are correct. The diachronic
formance of the nation during its previous Burkhart and Lewis-Beck model is far more
year. Their estimation procedure is GLS- complicated than our synchronic replication.
ARMA which avoids first-order autocorrela- But by reducing its complexity and by com-
tion and cross-sectional heteroscedasticity. paring its results with other research out-
Their model throws up a pseudo-R2 of 0.71 comes, it becomes clear what the weaknesses
and the b-scores are 2.49 (for Et), −1.33 (for of this model are. In that sense we can con-
M × Et) and −1.54 (for P × Et). Their conclu- clude that, although diachronic methods are
sion is that economic development matters more advanced, they cannot replace syn-
most for nations in the core, it still matters, but chronic methods.
about half as much, in the semi-periphery.
For nations in the periphery, the economic
effect is just a bit less. Taken together, eco-
nomic factors, both international and domes- CONCLUSION
tic, appear decisive in shaping a nation’s
democratic future. Global comparative methods are potentially
In order to show the complications of this capable to incorporate many countries and
type of diachronic analysis, we will replicate extensive time series in the analysis. The
the analysis synchronically, using OLS strengths and weaknesses are closely related
regression on a 1988 cross-section. The to those of quantitative methods in general.
results of our analysis match with that of Their main strength is that the scope of com-
Burkhart and Lewis-Beck, be it that our esti- parison is widened across time and space.
mates indicate moderate effects. This out- This opens up new possibilities for strong
come confirms our suspicion that the inferences and theory-building and the iden-
autoregressive model might not throw up a tification of deviant cases. Their main weak-
reliable R2, namely an adjusted R2 of 0.36 ness is that they may easily lead up to
(compared to 0.71 in the original analysis). misleading results due to their complexity. In
A theoretical, instead of statistical, explana- addition, global methods are often applied in
tion of the moderate performance of the a case-blind manner by focusing on the inter-
Burkhart and Lewis-Beck model is provided relationships between the variables which are
by Vanhanen (1990). He proposed an alterna- included in the statistical models.
tive for the socio-economic hypothesis of These pitfalls or weaknesses do not make
democratization, by hypothesizing that ‘global methods’ worse or better equipped
democratization takes place under conditions for comparative studies than other approaches
in which power resources have become so in social science since their usefulness for
widely distributed that no group is any longer comparative research depends on how
able to suppress its competitors or to main- they are applied. Anyone applying ‘global
tain its hegemony (Vanhanen, 1990: 66). The methods’ should be aware of the methodo-
main difference with Burkhart and Lewis-Beck logical trade-offs which are involved in doing
is that Vanhanen not only looks at the level of this type of research. In particular, there is a

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 13 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


48 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

trade-off between reliability (which improves Burkhart, R.E. and Lewis-Beck, M.S. (1994)
with the increase of cases) and validity ‘Comparative democracy: The economic
(which is hampered by a large number of development thesis’, American Political
cases). Science Review, 88 (4): 903–10.
During the last 20 years several new tech- Castles, F.G. (1998) Comparative public policy.
Patterns of post-war transformation.
niques have been introduced which enable
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
the statistical analysis on data relating to
Coppedge, M. and Reinicke, W.H. (1990)
many countries and time points that are inte- ‘Measuring polyarchy’, Studies in Comparative
grated into a single pooled data set (also International Development, 25 (1): 51–72.
referred to as panel data). The main problem Dahl, R.A. (1984) ‘Polyarchy, pluralism, and
with panel analysis is the lack of robustness, scale’, Scandinavian Political Studies, 7 (4):
since the estimates are highly dependent on 225–40.
the model specification. For this reason it is Dahl, R.A. (1998) On democracy. New Haven,
often necessary to compare the results of CT: Yale University.
panel analysis with those of cross-sectional Diamond, L. and Plattner, M.F. (eds) (1994)
analysis in order to determine whether they Nationalism, ethnic conflict, and democracy.
Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University
point into the same direction. This brings us
Press.
to the conclusion that, although pooled time
Freedom House (2007) Freedom in the World
series analysis is often seen as a methodo- 2006. The Annual Survey of Political Rights
logical advancement compared to cross-sec- and Civic Liberties. Retrieved June 6, 2007,
tional regression analysis, it does not make from www.freedomhouse.org
the latter useless. In addition, cross-sectional Garrett, G. and Mitchell, D. (2001)
analysis is still to be preferred to panel analy- ‘Globalization, government spending and
sis if the variables vary little over time, as is taxation in the OECD’, European Journal of
often the case with institutional variables. Political Research, 39 (2): 145–77.
Jaggers, K. and Gurr, T.R. (1995) ‘Tracking
democracy’s third wave with the Polity III data’,
Journal of Peace Research, 32 (4): 469–82.
REFERENCES Keman, H. (ed.) (2002) Comparative demo-
cratic politics. A guide to contemporary
Alvarez, M., Cheibub, J. A., Limongi, F. and theory and research. London: Sage.
Przeworski, A. (1996) Classifying political Kittel, B. and Winner, H. (2005) ‘How reliable is
regimes. Unpublished manuscript. University pooled analysis in political economy? The
of Chicago. globalization-welfare state nexus revisited’,
Beck, N. and Katz, J. (1995) ‘What to do – and European Journal of Political Research,
not to do – with time-series cross-section 44 (2): 269–93.
data in comparative politics’, American Landman, T. (2003) Issues and methods in
Political Science Review, 89 (3): 634–47. comparative politics. An introduction (2nd
Berg-Schlosser, D. and de Meur, G. (1996) edition) Oxford: Oxford University Press.
‘Conditions of authoritarianism, fascism, and Lane, J.E. and Ersson, S. (1999) Politics and
democracy in interwar Europe: Systematic society in Western Europe. London: Sage.
matching and contrasting of cases for “small Lane, J.E. and Ersson, S. (2002) Government
N” analysis’, Comparative Political Studies, and the economy. A global perspective.
29 (4): 423–68. London: Continuum.
Bollen, K.A. (1993) ‘Liberal democracy: validity Norris, P. (ed.) (1999) Critical citizens: Global
and method factors in cross-national meas- support for democratic government. New
ures’, American Journal of Political Science, York: Oxford University Press.
37 (4): 1207–30. Pennings, P., Keman, H. and Kleinnijenhuis, J.
Bollen, K.A. and Paxton, P. (2000) ‘Subjective (2006) Doing research in political science.
measures of liberal democracy’, Comparative An introduction to comparative methods
Political Studies, 33 (1): 58–86. and statistics. London: Sage.

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 14 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


GLOBAL COMPARATIVE METHODS 49

Plümper, T. and Troeger, V. (2007) ‘Efficient and legitimacy’, International Political Science
estimation of time-invariant and rarely Review, 18 (3): 253–78.
changing variables in finite sample panel Rueschemeyer, D., Huber, E. and Stephens,
analyses with unit fixed effects’, Political J.D. (1992) Capitalist development and
Analysis, 15 (2): 124–39. democracy. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Plümper, T., Troeger, V. E. and Manow, P. Schmidt, M.G. (2000) Demokratietheorien (3rd
(2005) ‘Panel data analysis in comparative edition) Opladen: Leske and Budrich.
politics: Linking method to theory’, European Vanhanen, T. (1990) The process of democrati-
Journal of Political Research, 44 (2): 327–54. zation. A comparative study of 147 states,
Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M.E., Cheibub, J.A. 1980–1988. New York: Crane Russak.
and Limongi, F. (2000) Democracy and devel- Vanhanen, T. (1997) Prospects of democracy:
opment. Political institutions and well-being A study of 172 countries. London:
in the world, 1950–1990. Cambridge: Routledge.
Cambridge University Press. Vanhanen, T. (2003) Democratization. A com-
Putnam, R.D. (1993) Making democracy work: parative analysis of 170 countries. London:
Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton, Routledge.
NJ: Princeton University Press. White, L.G. (1994) Political analysis: Technique
Riggs, F.W. (1998) ‘Presidentialism vs. parliamen- and practice. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
tarism: Implications for representativeness

9781412919760_Chap02.indd 15 3/11/2009 3:24:53 PM


3
Case Studies
Darren Hawkins

INTRODUCTION debate best practices and relative advantages


of different methods and to use the term
A case study is among the oldest and most ‘case study’ in confusing ways, especially in
widely used methods available to compara- informal conversation. Some of the largest
tive scholars. While many concepts in wide- disagreements concern whether case studies,
spread usage come to mean different things and especially process tracing techniques,
to different people and even lose meaning involve fundamentally different forms of
and coherence, scholarly understandings of scientific processes and inference than quan-
the nature, purpose, strengths, and weak- titative methods. This debate has large conse-
nesses of a case study have actually experi- quences for how scholars conceptualize and
enced relative convergence over the past carry out case studies.
decade. Scholars who utilize different meth- Unlike some debates in political science,
ods also tend to agree on the importance of however, this discussion has generated more
methodological pluralism, arguing that while light than heat and has been unusually pro-
case studies can stand on their own, they can ductive. In this chapter, I argue that important
also complement, improve, check, and differences do indeed exist between case
deepen other methods, especially large-N study and quantitative methods, or more spe-
quantitative studies. Much of the scholarly cifically, between process tracing and corre-
dialogue on methods has also converged on lational methods. These differences concern
the view that case studies should adhere to the extent to which underlying observations
rigorous scientific standards similar to those are independent of each other and the extent
that govern quantitative analysis, thereby to which temporal sequencing is used to
discarding interpretivist or postmodern rela- identify causation. Case studies embrace and
tivist positions on case studies (Brady and utilize the spatial and especially temporal
Collier, 2004; George and Bennett, 2005; connections between observations while
Gerring, 2004; King et al., 1994). quantitative methods assume the independ-
This is not to say that case study practice ence of observations, often viewing connec-
or quality is uniform or that no conceptual tions among observations and temporal
confusion exists. Indeed, scholars continue to sequencing as problems to be solved

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 1 3/11/2009 3:26:37 PM


CASE STUDIES 51

(e.g., when scholars insert autoregressive action, social activism, rebellion, class,
terms as a problem-solving procedure with- social values, and material interests and
out a substantive interest in those terms). hence should be relevant to a wide array of
Whether these differences require fundamen- scholars.
tally different scientific logics is a much
murkier question that may not ultimately
prove productive.
What is clear is that case studies offer par- PROMINENCE, DEFINITIONS,
ticular advantages to scholars that are fre- AND SCOPE
quently complementary to the advantages
from large-N quantitative research. These Discussion of case study methods has
include depth of analysis, construct validity, increased substantially in recent years, with a
the identification of causal mechanisms, number of important books and articles pub-
asymmetric theoretical arguments (related to lished, as evidenced by the bibliography for
necessary and sufficient conditions), and this chapter. This discussion has increased at
theory generation. Once those advantages are the same time as, or a little after, a decline in
understood, scholars can design their research the actual use of case studies in articles pub-
to improve their methodological choices, lished in many top journals. First glancing at
produce more insightful analyses, and reach the related sub-discipline of international
more defensible conclusions. Without such relations, a study of top journals in the field
progress, case studies may become relatively found that case studies and qualitative stud-
undervalued and under-utilized, a deve- ies lacking an explicit methodology (which
lopment that some fear has already come many would also label case studies) fell
to pass. steadily from 1980–2000 with a commensu-
This chapter consists of three parts. It first rate rise in quantitative methods and a small
examines the definitions and scope of case rise in cross-method studies (Sprinz and
studies as well as their prominence in the Wolinski-Nahmias, 2004: 5–8). In fact, a
comparative literature. The second elaborates causal relationship between the two seems
three key case study techniques: counterfac- likely. As case studies have been squeezed
tual analysis, congruence analysis, and proc- out of journals and threatened by increas-
ess tracing, with an emphasis on this last ingly sophisticated quantitative methods,
technique. The third explores the trade-offs scholars trained in and committed to qualita-
inherent in case study analysis along a series tive case methods have fought back by
of dimensions. In the spirit of case study becoming more self-conscious about their
methods, I illustrate many abstract points methodologies and engaging in debates with
throughout this essay by referring to Elisabeth their quantitative colleagues. These efforts
Jean Wood’s book (2003), Insurgent have been institutionalized through a qualita-
Collective Action and Civil War in El tive methods section of the American Political
Salvador. To clarify my selection procedure, Science Association, annual workshops, and
the book is one of only two single case study similar efforts.
books to win the best book award from Similar data on the use of case study meth-
the Comparative Politics section of the ods over time in comparative politics are
American Political Science Association more difficult to find, but some scattered
from 1993–2005 (the remainder are all evidence suggests that the pattern is similar
comparative case studies and the other case to that of international relations. Munck and
study award winner on imperial Japan is Snyder (2007) conducted the most compre-
much farther from my substantive expertise). hensive survey of methods used in compara-
Wood’s book deals with classic questions of tive research, but did not examine trends over
comparative politics involving collective time and restricted their analysis to three

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 2 3/11/2009 3:26:37 PM


52 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

top-ranked comparative politics journals, there is also a remarkably strong level of


Comparative Politics, Comparative Political agreement that methodological pluralism can
Studies, and World Politics, thereby ignoring and should be valued. Brady, Collier, and
comparative politics research published else- Seawright (2004), among King et al.’s most
where. They found 63% of the articles in well-known, energetic and persistent critics,
those journals (using sample years from 1989 have argued that ‘scholars should carefully
to 2004) were mainly qualitative, a category evaluate the strengths and weaknesses of
that suggests some type of case study (Munck these diverse [methodological] tools. … This
and Snyder, 2007: 13). Mahoney’s (2007a: eclectic approach is the most promising
33) critique of this study examined the three avenue for productive decisions about
leading general journals in political science, research design’ (pp. 19–20). Of equal impor-
American Journal of Political Science, tance, they argue that this methodological
Journal of Politics, and American Political eclecticism should take place under an
Science Review, finding that only 8% of the umbrella of ‘shared standards for the applica-
comparative politics research published there tion of these tools’ (p. 19). The debate, in
was qualitative. Perhaps more importantly, other words, is not a relativistic one in which
Mahoney reported that from 2001–2005, all points of view are equally valued and no
only 40% of the articles in Comparative grounds for discrimination are tolerated.
Political Studies were qualitative, and that King et al.’s critics go to great lengths to
about half of the comparative articles in articulate rigorous methodological standards
World Politics in recent years have been that utilize sound logic and careful nuances.
qualitative, suggesting a trend to quantitative The main thrust for the critics is that King
analysis. Once again, as the proportion of et al. treat qualitative research as derivative
articles in top journals utilizing case studies of the logic governing quantitative research.
has declined, the scholarly conversation on The critics argue, in contrast, that qualitative
case study methods has ramped up. research is often quite distinctive and gov-
Unfortunately, no studies examining case erned by a separate, though equally rigorous
study methods in books or other types of logic (George and Bennett, 2005: 10–16;
(geographically or topically bounded) jour- McKeown, 1999).
nals have appeared. Moreover, both King et al., and their critics
The contemporary scholarly conversation largely agree that quantitative and qualitative
on qualitative case study methods began in work are complementary and often improve
earnest with the publication of King et al.’s each other when used jointly. King et al. argued
Designing Social Inquiry in 1994. A variety (in a follow-up article to their book) that ‘much
of scholars immediately engaged and chal- of the best social science research can combine
lenged the work and some then spent the next quantitative and qualitative data, precisely
several years formulating more systematic because there is no contradiction between the
responses. Whether conceptualized as direct fundamental processes of inference involved in
responses or not, most subsequent qualitative each’ (King et al., 2004: 183). While many crit-
methods pieces have at least addressed King ics argue that the inferential processes underly-
et al.’s arguments and some engage those ing case study and statistical work are different,
arguments at considerable length. The most they tend to agree that the two methods are
prominent examples are the book-length fundamentally complementary. Tarrow (2004)
treatments in 2004 by Brady and Collier offered six different bridges or ways of putting
(who most often write as Collier, Brady and them together. Collier et al. (2004a) discussed
Seawright) and in 2005 by George and case study and statistical research in terms of
Bennett. trade-offs, a useful metaphor employed by a
While scholars quarrel about a wide vari- number of scholars and invoked in this
ety of arguments put forward in King et al., chapter.

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 3 3/11/2009 3:26:37 PM


CASE STUDIES 53

As a result of this conversation, basic defi- definitions. In Yin’s (1990) book on case
nitions of case studies have become more study methods for the well-known Sage
precise and delimited in recent years. One methods series, he defined a case study in
fairly typical definition is offered by Gerring negative fashion by arguing that it was
(2004: 342): ‘An intensive study of a single almost any qualitative method that did not
unit for the purpose of understanding a larger involve experiments, surveys, histories, and
class of (similar) units.’ Units, in turn, refer to analyses of archival information. Yet this
‘spatially bounded phenomenon – e.g., a definition confuses different methodological
nation-state, revolution, political party, elec- techniques with overall methodological pur-
tion, or person – observed at a single point in pose and design implicit in the definition
time or over some delimited period of time.’ endorsed here. In fact, historical and archival
Seawright and Collier (2004: 275) suggest research or quantitative surveys can form an
much the same thing when they say that a case important part of a case study.
study is a ‘research design focused on one In a different vein, Eckstein’s (1975: 85)
(N = 1) or a few cases’ where cases are defined classic article on case studies defines a case
as ‘the units of analysis of a given study.’ as a ‘phenomenon for which we report and
Similar definitions can be found in Sprinz and interpret only a single measure on any perti-
Wolinsky-Nahmias (2004) and in George and nent variable’. If Wood had used this defini-
Bennett (2005). Since comparative cases are tion, she would have been able to report only
taken up elsewhere in this volume, this chapter on a single measure of the underlying varia-
focuses on the single case study. By way of bles of interest. The key dependent variable
example to illustrate Gerring’s various levels for Wood consists of the level of peasant sup-
at which the unit of analysis might be situated, port for guerrillas, but this varied by area of
a case study might concern the examination of the country and over time in the 1980s. It
El Salvador during the period of Civil War, the would be far too restrictive to report a single
Christian Democratic Party, the military, the value for this variable and it would not be
resistance movement known as the Frente helpful to label each locality and time period
Farabundo Martí para La Liberación Nacional a discrete case, thereby creating thousands of
(Farabundo Martí Front for National cases within a time span of several years. In
Liberation, or FMLN), the October 1979 fact, Eckstein’s definition calls into question
coup, social inequality, or Roberto whether a single ‘case study’ could actually
d’Aubuisson, the death squad director. The exist in any context because it seems likely
nature of the unit to be studied is the choice of that all case studies involve some kind of
the researcher, as informed by theory and pre- variation along some important dimension.
vious studies. Wood’s (2003: 2, 17) unit of Rather, it is more productive to think of a
analysis is the ‘powerful insurgent movement’ case study as the study of a particular tempo-
that formed in El Salvador in the 1980s, with rally and spatially bound unit (whose scope
a particular focus on ‘insurgent campesinos’ can vary substantially depending on the
or peasants who actively supported the insur- research question), which can itself be
gency by providing information and supplies decomposed into more discrete periods of
but were not themselves combatants. The time, subunits and variables (Gerring, 2004:
question motivating the selection of this unit 342). The nature of a particular unit, time
of analysis is a classic one in comparative period and variable depends on the scholar’s
politics: Given the high risks and uncertain choices and objectives. For Wood, the El
outcomes of collective action, how and why Salvadoran civil war constitutes a spatially
do collective movements develop? and temporally delimited unit that can
While at first glance these definitions may be broken down further. Temporally, scholars
seem overly expansive or painfully obvious, could examine each month or some
they are not at all in comparison with prior other discrete time period within the war.

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 4 3/11/2009 3:26:37 PM


54 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Spatially, scholars can examine different in the rows and variables in the columns, an
actors, processes, or geographical areas observation consists of the set of measures of
within El Salvador. These are sometimes each variable found for a given unit along its
referred to as ‘within-case’ variations. At row. King et al. (1994) utilized this definition
each of those points in time and space, many of observation and repeatedly argued that
variables can be observed. In her study, increasing the number of observations is one
Wood interviewed approximately 200 peas- of the most important measures that qualita-
ants, many repeatedly, from 1987 to 1996 in tive scholars could take to produce better
two different areas of the country. research. Increasing the number of observa-
While this definition of a case study defined tions makes it easier to identify patterns and
as a unit is fairly elastic, it is not infinitely so. to sort out which variables change in pre-
When choosing a given case, the researcher is dicted directions and which do not. They
essentially asserting that the various compo- help solve the many variables, small-N prob-
nents of that case interact with each other in lem that plagues case study research.
important ways and that the internal cohesion As Collier et al. (2004b: 252) have pointed
of the moving parts within the case is greater out, however, the application of this advice to
than the cohesion between that case and other a case study can create confusion because
examples of a similar phenomenon. In Wood’s observations can also refer to a single piece
book, the social movement supporting the guer- of information (rather than a group of obser-
rillas ebbed and flowed across space and time, vations about a set of variables for one unit).
yet can be treated as a cohesive whole because Moreover, that piece of information may not
these internal dynamics fed off and responded pertain to any of the existing variables for
to each other more than they responded to, for which the scholar already has data or it might
example, the ebb and flow of Peru’s guerrilla be a fairly unique piece of information that
movement in the 1980s. Wood (2003: 171–2, cannot be replicated for other units and thus
189–90) argues, for example, that the success- cannot be included in a traditional matrix
ful establishment of peasant land cooperatives dataset.
in one area produced similar efforts in nearby Hence, the term ‘observation’ can mean
areas – though by way of critique, Wood does two different things, which necessarily com-
not provide interview evidence that peasants plicate King et al.’s seemingly straightfor-
were learning from or inspired by nearby ward advice to increase the number of
examples. This notion of moving parts within a observations. The first general strategy, most
comparatively cohesive unit marks a funda- consistent with King et al. (1994: 219–28), is
mental distinction with Eckstein’s (1975) clas- to add observations in one of three ways:
sic definition, which focuses on a much more
discrete observation of a particular unit at a (a) observe additional units similar to the unit under
study or subdivide the unit under study into more
particular point in time; for example, an indi-
discrete units or periods of time, or both;
vidual peasant in the year 1990. Eckstein’s (b) identify additional observable implications of
conceptualization is more consistent with the the theory by identifying other hypotheses that
concept of a case advanced by King et al. account for variation in the dependent variables
‘Observations’ is also a term that seems within the same unit; or
straightforward but can become rather (c) combine a and b.
complicated. In quantitative analysis, an
observation is often conceptualized as a These strategies are generally familiar to quan-
single measure on each of a number of differ- titative analysts who might, for example, break
ent variables pertaining to a particular unit at years down into months in order to increase
a particular point in time (and is thus similar observations and obtain greater variation. They
to Eckstein’s definition of a ‘case’). In a tra- are also generally well-known and practiced in
ditional quantitative matrix dataset with units case studies. Where scholars retain the same

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 5 3/11/2009 3:26:37 PM


CASE STUDIES 55

unit of analysis and break it into smaller parts, in the face of oppression and violence. As one
this is often labeled ‘within-case analysis.’ peasant put it, ‘There were so many deaths of
Wood utilizes this strategy by disaggregat- cooperative promoters – half a battalion of dead
ing the El Salvador civil war into different for the simple crime of lending help to the
areas, smaller time periods and 200 individu- cooperatives. But I would say that this ‘crime’
als, though she does not formalize it as a has been, simply, my accomplishment’ (Wood,
quantitative analyst would by creating actual 2003: 204). Peasants who did not join the
rows and columns of data. She then identifies insurgency, on the other hand, spoke only of
informal correlations, or their absence, loss and never of pride as in this passage: ‘We
among the variables. For example, when have suffered and we continue suffering. We
assessing the issue of whether social class can’t hold either side responsible; it is the
contributed to collective action, Wood reports system of war that has brought us these losses’
that support for the guerrillas occurred in (Wood, 2003: 212). It is important to note that
areas where land was distributed more widely correlational and generative inferences are not
as well as in areas where it was held by very mutually exclusive. Wood finds correlational
few and that insurgent peasants were drawn patterns where those who joined the collective
from all walks of life and classes (Wood, action nearly always mentioned pride, dignity,
2003: 198–9). The lack of correlation, per- and the virtue of standing up for something. Yet
ceived intuitively, leads her to conclude that it is the fact that these interviews shed light on
social class was not an important factor in the motives, on how and why some peasants trans-
emergence of collective action. Recent schol- lated poverty and oppression into collective
arship stressing the complementarity of action that makes them valuable causal-process
methods suggests that Wood could have uti- observations.
lized statistical analyses to investigate these
correlations more rigorously.
The second strategy for increasing observa-
tions, advocated by Collier et al., is to treat CASE STUDY TECHNIQUES
‘causal-process’ observations differently from
‘data-set’ observations. A causal-process Just as quantitative researchers have a variety
observation refers to any information that of techniques at their disposal, so do case
‘provides information about context or mech- study scholars. Those techniques may be
anism and contributes to a different kind of grouped into three main categories: counter-
leverage in causal inference’ (Collier et al., factual analysis, congruence analysis, and
2004: 252). The leverage used by quantitative process tracing (Bennett, 2004: 22–6).
scholars is that of correlation. The leverage Counterfactual analysis typically seeks to
used in causal process observations, in con- test the proposition that A was necessary for
trast, is ‘generative’ or ‘ontic’; that is, it offers Y to occur by asking what would happen if A
direct information about how causes generate were not present (Fearon, 1991; Tetlock and
effects by focusing on the connection between Belkin, 1996). Because it is relatively simple
the two (McKeown, 1999: 171–2; also see the to imagine a different outcome in the absence
discussion below on process tracing). of any A, thereby confirming its importance,
To illustrate, Wood’s most important causal- scholars have articulated some important
process observations came from her detailed checks on counterfactual reasoning. Tetlock
interviews in which peasants offered reasons and Belkin (1996: 18) identify six:
for acting as they did. The interviews
suggested that most peasants did not fight due 1. clearly specified and circumscribed antecedents
to class consciousness, material benefits or pre- and consequents;
existing social networks, but rather because 2. consistent causal logic that links antecedents and
they wanted to express their dignity and pride consequents;

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 6 3/11/2009 3:26:37 PM


56 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

3. alterations to as few historical facts as possible; All forms of congruence analysis also face
4. articulating principles that are consistent with similar problems. Similar to quantitative
existing theory; analysis, they focus on correlation between
5. articulating principles that are consistent with variables and so care should be used in
existing statistical generalizations; and
making causal inferences. Correlational pat-
6. the identification of testable implications in the
case under study or a related case.
terns between independent and dependent
variables might be spurious or might seem
For many, this final check is crucial because more prominent than they are because other
it involves non-counterfactual data. A useful relevant variables have been omitted from the
example relates to speculation about the pattern-matching effort. The units and time
causes of the extinction of dinosaurs, where periods selected for observation might be
the counterfactual is that a large asteroid biased in some way, producing a stronger or
impacted the earth 65 million years ago weaker sense of correlation than would exist
(Tetlock and Belkin, 1996: 10). This counter- if more observations were added. Because
factual is particularly amenable to empirical congruence analysis has so much in common
investigation because scientists have been with statistical regression analysis and is
able to draw a number of related observable subject to many of the same problems and
implications about its impact and find evi- pitfalls, Collier et al. (2004c: 94) even refer
dence for those implications. to it as ‘intuitive regression.’ As mentioned,
Congruence analysis refers to the basic Wood relied on such intuitive patterns in
idea that the presence and strength of assessing the strength of key variables
independent and dependent variables should (see pp. 227–8 for one example); in some of
be correlated (Van Evera, 1997: 56–63). those cases, quantitative methods would have
Scholars utilize theories to make predictions been feasible and increased the transparency
about the nature of that correlation and then of her reasoning and confidence in her
observe the presence and strength of inde- results.
pendent and dependent variables to deter- Perhaps an even larger problem is that for
mine the extent to which the theoretical probabilistic rather than deterministic theo-
predictions seem to hold. This fundamental ries, correlations offer uncertain insights. If
idea lies at the heart of some of the most A is likely to produce Y, and A is present
well-known and venerable methodological while Y is absent, the argument cannot be
discussions in social science and compara- infirmed since the relationship is only prob-
tive politics: Mill’s (1875) ‘method of agree- able. Repeated observations can give more
ment’ and ‘method of difference,’ Przeworski confidence in the results (if A is present and
and Tenue’s (1970) ‘least similar cases’ Y absent in ten different observations, we
and ‘most similar cases,’ George’s (1979) have stronger evidence against the proposi-
‘structured focused case comparisons’ and tion), but the number of observations required
Ragin’s (1987) ‘qualitative comparative anal- to produce high levels of confidence may
ysis.’ While George and Bennett (2005: also require quantitative analysis. Congruence
151–92) go to great lengths to demonstrate analysis can produce, on the other hand,
differences between their ‘congruence more definitive results for deterministic theo-
method’ and these other congruence ries, such as those that invoke the language of
analyses, their similarities are more striking necessary and sufficient conditions. Where A
than their differences. All are based on is posited as a necessary condition to produce
the same underlying logic of identifying Y, for example, and A is absent while Y is
correlational patterns in the presence present, we can with this single observation
and strength of independent and dependent infirm the argument that A is a necessary
variables. condition. Many scholars, however, are

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 7 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


CASE STUDIES 57

understandably reluctant to utilize determin- 2005: 176–8). Causality can be identified with
istic theories in the social sciences (see dis- greater certainty because of the time sequenc-
cussion below). A related problem is that ing inherent in process tracing that unravels
different independent variables can produce the ways in which one small event triggers
similar results, a process known as equifinal- another and how the chain of events results in
ity. Where several different paths can pro- the overall whole.
duce the same result, the number of Process tracing ‘focuses on whether the
observations needed to identify such correla- intervening variables between a hypothesized
tions will increase substantially. To see if A cause and observed effect move as predicted
or B or C produce Y, scholars would need to by theories under investigation’ (Bennett,
observe A without B or C, B without C or A, 2004: 22). Similar techniques are also labeled
and so forth. ‘within-case analysis’ (Mahoney, 2007b: 131)
While problems undoubtedly exist with ‘causal process observations’ (Collier et al.,
congruence procedures, they still mark an 2004b: 252–8). In essence, the investigator
important and useful method in almost any asks: What chain of events should we observe
case study (George and Bennet, 2005: 181– if this casual mechanism is correct? Different
185; King et al., 1994: 206). Some variables causal logics should suggest different paths
can be discounted while others gain more from the independent to the dependent varia-
credibility. The absence of A in the presence ble. Those paths should have different observ-
of Y does not rule out the theoretical proposi- able implications that can be broken down
tion that A is likely to produce Y, but it does into relatively discrete moments of time appli-
mean that A does not produce Y in that case. cable to different actors and processes. George
Hence, this can lead to the identification of and Bennett (2005) describe the nature of
new variables that are also likely to produce process tracing in the following terms:
Y and it can lead to ideas about the condi- Process tracing is an indispensable tool for theory
tions under which A produces Y. If A is testing and theory development not only because
widely perceived to be an important variable it generates numerous observations within a case,
and the case is significant, it can cast some but because these observations must be linked in
doubt on A’s importance. Because it offers particular ways to constitute an explanation of the
case. It is the very lack of independence among
initial insights into how the independent these observations that makes them a powerful
variables map onto the dependent variable, tool for inference. … Process-tracing is fundamen-
congruence analysis is almost always helpful tally different from methods based on covariance
and productive. At the same time, it is less or comparisons across cases. In using theories to
useful for identifying causal mechanisms. develop explanations of cases through process-
tracing, all the intervening steps in a case must
As a result, a wide variety of scholars be as predicted by a hypothesis … or else that
endorse process tracing as the third key tech- hypothesis must be amended – perhaps trivially or
nique, and perhaps the most important, in case perhaps fundamentally – to explain the case. It is
study research. For King et al., process tracing not sufficient that a hypothesis be consistent with
is simply a way of increasing the number of a statistically significant number of intervening
steps. (p. 207)
observations by redefining the unit of analysis
to a lower level of aggregation. For critics, this Process tracing holds out two great prom-
is precisely the point where King et al. go ises to researchers: it can distinguish between
astray. In the critics’ view, process tracing is a spurious correlations and cause and effect,
fundamentally different technique that requires and it can identify which of many possible
different kinds of observations and that allows causal mechanisms is the most likely or the
scholars to go beyond correlation and to iden- most important. The possibility of establish-
tify causation with greater certainty (Collier ing strong evidence for causation leads many
et al., 2004b: 252–8; George and Bennett, scholars to remark on the complementarity

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 8 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


58 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

between process tracing and statistical meth- some probably responded to the wind and the
ods, which address issues of causal process chain reaction by standing more resolutely in
either not at all or only with great difficulty place while others eagerly joined in the proc-
(Collier et al., 2004b, 255; George and ess, with the result that there were several
Bennett, 2005: 207–8, 224). Ideally, statisti- chain reactions that stopped and started at
cal methods can establish patterns of covaria- various places in the longer chain.
tion while process tracing can identify the All of this is ‘documentable’ using process
causal mechanisms that demonstrate the link- tracing (hence, its advantage), but the notion
ages underlying these patterns. that a single hypothesis will be consistent with
The most easily accessible illustration of the multitude of observed behavior seems less
process tracing is that of falling dominoes in realistic. In the end, we have improved our
a chain (George and Bennett, 2005: 206–7). analysis because we now know that the fall of
Where quantitative approaches might exam- the first domino did not in fact cause the fall
ine the first domino and last domino in a of the last, but the cause of the last’s fall
chain and observe that they were both upright remains a mix of different causal processes
at time t1, and then that they both fell in the focused on the wind, the chain reaction, and
same direction at t2 and t3, process tracing the last domino’s weak-willed reaction to
requires that scholars document the fall of external forces. The point is not that process
the intermediate dominoes. The observable tracing is useless. Rather, the point is that iso-
implication is that an intermediate domino lating causal mechanisms is very difficult,
was struck by the one ahead of it and in even with process tracing methods. Wood
turn struck the one behind it at some (2003) grapples with these sorts of issues in
point between the fall of the first and the fall her study (see pp. 208–12 for one example).
of the last. Some affected by government violence
At least two problems arise. The first is that responded by supporting the rebels while
process tracing may reveal a variety of causal others withdrew into themselves. Some who
mechanisms at work, perhaps simultaneously, believed in social justice supported the rebels
and it is difficult or impossible to sort them while others argued violence was not justified.
all out, even at close range. Requiring all of Wood aptly and honestly summed up the evi-
the intervening steps to be consistent with the dence: ‘Those who did not support the insur-
hypothesis (as George and Bennett do in the gency were a heterogenous group, yet some
above quote, emphasis in the original) could patterns are evident’ (p. 212). One such pat-
be a recipe for frustration in the social sci- tern is that government violence generally
ences where people often operate with mixed increased peasant action except in areas where
motives, behavior often cannot be observed government forces were particularly strong.
but must be reconstructed, random events This sort of interactive effect is the product of
intervene, or various factors combine in unex- careful process tracing, but Wood’s broader
pected ways. In the social sciences, we would difficulty in identifying patterns may illustrate
rarely be able to capture the dominoes on the inherent limitations in social science
camera but rather have to interview them later research.
and deal with all of the psychological phe- The second problem is meshing this proc-
nomena and effects of human agency that the ess tracing with the observed correla-
social world encompasses. Some would tions (Beck, 2006). If a causal mechanism is
undoubtedly claim they wanted to fall while identified in one case, is it generalizable to
others would say they were forced to do so. other cases? For many social phenomena,
The wind was probably gusting while the there may of course be multiple paths toward
dominoes were falling, creating doubts about the outcome in question (equifinality). Not
the relative importance of the chain reaction only do different combinations of variables
versus the wind. And, exercising their agency, stimulate the same outcome, but the same

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 9 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


CASE STUDIES 59

cause may produce the same effect through as searches for generalizable causal laws:
different causal pathways. Understanding gen- Why do individuals engage in collective
eral cause-effect relationships thus requires a action? Why does democracy arise? Why
back-and-forth process between identifying does poverty persist?
causal mechanisms and identifying correla- These are certainly important questions;
tions among variables. A given correlation is perhaps so important they can sometimes blind
likely to be consistent, in theory, with a variety scholars to the pursuit of other important and
of causal mechanisms. Process tracing that perhaps more tractable questions. Such ques-
identifies a particular causal mechanism in a tions might include: How unified or fractured is
given case should then suggest new correla- the anti-globalization movement and how is it
tions to explore quantitatively. evolving? What is the current quality of democ-
racy in Mexico? How bad is poverty in Britain;
is it worse some places than others and has it
changed at all over recent years? These sorts of
TRADE-OFFS questions often have clearer policy relevance:
international trading rules might become more
One important trend among scholars is to con- responsive to their critics; problems in Mexico
sciously consider the trade-offs involved in the might be identified and addressed; and future
choice of any given methodology. Case studies recruits to the ranks of terrorism might be
provide several benefits but also incur some deterred. Scholars should at least consider the
important costs. Generally speaking, case stud- possibility that the quest for broad causal state-
ies are, in abstraction, better at depth (rather ments may get in the way of worthy and valu-
than breadth) of arguments, internal, and con- able case-specific information. Again, since
struct validity (rather than generalizability), both seem necessary the language of ‘trade-off’
causal mechanisms (rather than causal effects), seems quite applicable.
deterministic (rather than probabilistic) argu-
ments, and the generation of new theories
(rather than theory-testing) (Gerring, 2004: Construct validity versus
346–52). Not all scholars would agree with this
generalizability
list, of course, but many recent qualitative stud-
ies have endorsed a subset of these costs and Relatedly, the second trade-off involves con-
benefits (Bennett, 2004: 34–45; Collier et al., struct validity versus generalizability.
2004a: 195–227), and thus the list identifies Construct validity refers to the ability to
various possible trade-offs rather than a consen- measure the theoretical concepts that schol-
sus of opinion. Each of these trade-offs is con- ars intend to measure. The difficulty is that
sidered in turn, an organizational device that I scholars frequently wish to measure abstract
borrow from Gerring (2004). concepts whose meaning and practice can
vary substantially across different cultural
and historical contexts. As Bennett (2004)
summarized the issue:
Depth versus breadth
This requires detailed consideration of contextual
As Gerring (2004, p. 348) put it, ‘Research variables, which is extremely difficult to carry out in
designs invariably face a choice between statistical studies but common in case studies.
knowing more about less and knowing less Whereas statistical studies run the risk of ‘concep-
about more.’ While this is an intuitive and tual stretching’ if they lump together dissimilar
cases to get a higher sample size (Sartori 1970),
widely accepted claim, it is worth consider-
case studies move in the opposite direction, refining
ing the normative dimensions of this trade- concepts with a higher level of validity but doing so
off for a moment. Many of the classical at the cost of producing generalizations applicable
questions of political science are often framed only over a smaller number of cases. (p. 34)

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 10 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


60 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

The generalizability problems with case studies at all? One relatively simple response
studies are well-known. Geddes (1990) and is that some phenomena are rare enough that
Achen and Snidal (1989) are often credited they cannot be subjected to statistical meth-
with first bringing sustained attention to the ods, with social revolutions as an oft-cited
problem of drawing theoretical inferences example (Gerring, 2004: 351; Skocpol,
from single cases. King et al. (1994: 149) are 1979). Even when events are not so rare, they
well-known for their advice to minimize may be normatively important because of
selection bias by selecting cases so that vari- their large effects on others or their status as
ation is achieved on the explanatory variables important reference points in policy debates.
while allowing the possibility of variation in The Spanish transition to democracy, for
the dependent variable (where the selection example, is but one of dozens of democratic
should ideally be blind). Geddes examined transitions since 1974, but received enormous
three prominent causal arguments for broad attention because of its smooth, peaceful
and important phenomena in comparative nature, and the model it provided for Latin
politics: economic growth, revolution, and American countries in the 1980s (Colomer,
inflation. In each case, she showed how 1991). Similarly, democratic transitions in
answers about the causes of these phenom- large, important countries like Mexico, Brazil,
ena would vary widely depending on which and Argentina attracted numerous case studies
countries and time periods the analyst exam- justified on normative grounds that it is simply
ined. In most cases, the factors thought to worth knowing in some detail how their tens
create the outcomes in question also existed of millions of citizens accomplished such
in cases where the outcomes did not occur, desirable outcomes with wide-ranging impli-
leading her to articulate the oft-repeated cations for them and for numerous other
wisdom that scholars should not select cases people and states.
by examining just one outcome on the These responses answer the generalizabil-
dependent variable. ity challenge by focusing on the importance
For Geddes (1990: 54–8), however, these of the cases at hand. Other responses meet
selection problems went even deeper than the challenge in a head-on fashion. Numerous
attempting to confirm causal connections. scholars have pointed out that selecting cases
Unwarranted assumptions about generaliza- on the dependent variable is helpful if the
bility also infected efforts to create new theo- theory in question posits necessary causes. If
ries, one of the strengths of case study causes are necessary for an outcome, then
analysis (see below). In her view, moderniza- selecting only positive outcomes provides
tion and dependency theory – the classic the most demanding way for telling analysts
paradigms of comparative politics in devel- if those causes are in fact always present
oping countries – both arose from selective (Dion, 1998; Harvey, 2003; Ragin, 2000).
readings of readily available case study evi- Alternatively, if identifying causal mecha-
dence. If so, there is little mystery about why nisms that produce the outcomes in question
both paradigms wound up in the discard pile is the goal of the research (see discussion in
after too much inconvenient evidence accu- next section), then it is a viable strategy to
mulated around them. Their history is cer- select the dependent variable and examine
tainly a useful reminder to comparativists to the process by which the desired outcomes
be careful about generalizing too much from occurred. Such cases could then generate
specific cases, even in the name of develop- new hypotheses that could be tested on a
ing new theory. wider range of cases (see discussion of
Case study scholars have developed a large theory generation below).
supply of responses to these generalizability Case study scholars have long defended
issues and the related question of case selection procedures by invoking the notion of
selection (Collier et al., 2004c). If generaliza- a ‘crucial case’ (Eckstein, 1975), though recent
bility is such a problem, why engage in case research calls that argument into question

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 11 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


CASE STUDIES 61

(Gerring, 2007). A crucial case is one that is average effect of various causes on the out-
most (least) likely to produce the outcome in come, taking all other effects into account
question on a range of criteria but fails to do so (Mahoney and Goertz, 2006: 230) As Gerring
(and does so). Where these unexpected out- points out, multiple cases, and statistical
comes occur, runs the typical argument, schol- methods are required to estimate these causal
ars can have higher levels of confidence in their weights.
results (Hawkins, 2001). The difficulty, Gerring
Assuming that the causal relationship is probabilis-
argues (2007: 236), is that few social science tic in nature … the researcher must examine sev-
theories make ‘risky’ predictions about out- eral instances of this phenomenon to gauge the
comes that are subject to being falsified by a average causal effect of X on Y and the random
single case. Most theories are probabilistic; are element of that variation. The calculation of a
causal effect presumes the investigation of cross-
thought to be true only under certain (often
unit variation precisely because, for a probabilistic
underspecified) conditions; identify interaction cause, one cannot assume that the behavior of
effects that can alter the outcomes; and/or posit one unit will be indicative of the behavior of other
a variety of causal mechanisms by which the units. Units may behave differently. Thus, the
outcomes may occur. Hence, a predicted out- example of a single unit, even if subjected to iter-
ated testing, is not a good way to estimate casual
come that does not occur may simply be the
effects and is certainly inadequate to the task of
result of chance or may be the result of an estimating probabilities. (2004: 348)
underspecified, unclear theory. In this view, the
more precise the theory (the riskier its predic- Calculating average causal weights is
tions), the more it can be subjected to a ‘crucial impossible in case studies, though it is some-
case’ logic. times possible to obtain an ordinal ranking of
As an alternative to the crucial case, the importance of various causes. Rather,
Gerring (2007: 238–46) suggests a ‘pathway case studies focus on careful explication of
case’ approach in which the general correla- causal mechanisms in particular cases, or in
tional patterns between causes and outcomes delimited sets of cases. In particular, case
are known, but the causal pathway or mecha- study researchers often set out to identify
nisms are unknown. In these circumstances, the multiple pathways or combinations of
researchers can select cases in which the factors that produce the outcome of interest
cause (established in correlational statistical (Mahoney and Goertz, 2006: 232). They are
studies) and effect are both present and other often interested in equifinality, or the variety
established causes are either missing or of paths that can produce similar outcomes.
present in lower quantities. In other words, Mackie (1980: 62) refers to these factors as
the case is one in which the hypothesized INUS conditions – ‘insufficient but nonredun-
cause should be exerting a large influence on dant part of an unnecessary but sufficient’
the outcome. In such a case, scholars can combination of conditions. While this formu-
more clearly identify the causal mechanisms lation at first appears unwieldy, it appears upon
that lead from cause to effect (see next sec- reflection to capture the tenor of much case
tion). While generalizability would still be an study research and could actually be quite help-
issue, it is less of a concern because correla- ful in organizing and presenting conclusions.
tional studies establish the existence of a Mahoney and Goertz (2006: 232) point out,
relationship between the cause and effect. ‘Research findings with INUS causes can
often be formally expressed through Boolean
equations such as Y= (A AND B AND C) OR
Causal mechanisms versus (C AND D AND E).’ In this abstraction, all
of the factors from A to E are INUS condi-
causal effects
tions. They are insufficient on their own yet
Quantitative researchers are often interested an important part of the explanation (non-
in estimating the causal effects of independ- redundant). When combined together with
ent variables; that is, in calculating the each other in particular ways, they jointly

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 12 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


62 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

become unnecessary (because multiple causal arguments, with determinism taking the form
paths are available) but sufficient conditions to of necessary and/or sufficient conditions
explain the outcome. This detailing of differ- (Dion, 1998; Gerring, 2004: 349). Although
ent causal pathways or mechanisms is a clear there are no clear measures of how many
strength of qualitative research that makes it a case studies employ these concepts, Goertz
valuable complement to quantitative methods (2003: 76–94) demonstrated that the practice
(Ragin, 1987; 2000). is at least not terribly rare by compiling a
Wood’s book may have been strengthened sample of 150 necessary condition hypothe-
by a greater effort to incorporate this sort of ses in the social sciences. The underlying
analysis. Rather than identifying the different logic is straightforward: in necessary condi-
ways in which the underlying factors combine tions, an outcome Y cannot occur without the
into causal pathways, she tends to treat the presence of X; and in sufficient conditions
factors in isolation from each other. The main the presence of X ensures the presence of Y.
variable of peasant values is not an important Yet a large debate has erupted over whether
part of the analysis until late in the book necessary and sufficient conditions are in fact
(p. 226) and its interaction with other factors deterministic. The wording and logic appear
is only briefly discussed (pp. 237–40). That to be inherently deterministic, or more pre-
discussion refers to local state violence and cisely, invariant – because multiple sufficient
proximity of insurgent forces as necessary fac- conditions might exist (equifinality) and
tors for rebellion, but the evidence for that hence the notion of ‘determinism’ is mislead-
claim is lacking. If instead of seeking to show ing. Still, on its face, a condition that is nec-
how some factors were more important than essary for an outcome or that ensures a
others, Wood had first sought to identify and particular outcome appears to suggest a
sort out the multiplicity of causal pathways, her worldview inconsistent with probabilistic
analysis may have offered even more insights. views of political outcomes.
Once several causal pathways have been The difficulty is that many proponents of
charted through varying combinations of under- necessary and sufficient conditions seem
lying factors, scholars might even begin to unwilling to defend the proposition that the
analyze the relative importance (causal weights) social world is invariant (Braumoeller and
of those individual factors. If C is found in 90% Goertz, 2000; Dion, 1998; Mahoney and
of the causal pathways, for example, it could be Goertz, 2006). They argue, common-sensi-
considered a more important influence on the cally, that we all inhabit a probabilistic
outcome than the other factors. In emphasizing world. Efforts to square the circle by making
the values of peasants and the meanings they deterministic theories work in a probabilistic
ascribed to their actions, Wood (2003: 231–41) world, however, have run into a variety of
essentially utilized an intuitive form of this problems. One of the most obvious is the
INUS/Boolean analysis. Her claim that those semantic illogic of the claims, as in this
values constitute the most significant part of the example from Dion (1998, p. 136): ‘deter-
explanation would be strengthened by demon- ministic necessary conditions are perfectly
strating that they are present in most of the compatible with a probabilistic world.’ He
causal pathways, each of which combines mul- explains that even if condition X occurs, this
tiple factors. does not determine whether Y will occur.
While true by definition, this claim glosses
over the fact that the relationship is still
Deterministic versus probabilistic invariant with respect to Y, which cannot
exist without X. Braumoeller and Goertz
arguments
(2000) have argued that invariant claims can
Case studies have often been associated be evaluated by using evidence probabilisti-
with deterministic rather than probabilistic cally. In their view, counter-examples (where Y

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 13 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


CASE STUDIES 63

is present without X) may be due to some causal mechanisms in a particular case can
kind of error in measurement or conceptuali- easily be turned into a probabilistic argument
zation, and the likelihood that negative cases for multiple cases. Mainwaring and Pérez-
are errors can be evaluated using statistical Liñán (2005: 21–5) do precisely that when
probability. This approach, like that of Dion, surveying much of the qualitative literature
preserves the invariant nature of the underly- on Latin American democratization and
ing theoretical relationship between X and Y drawing probability-oriented hypotheses
and by using observed frequencies to assess from it.
the likelihood that they are invariant. Moreover, case studies can be used to pro-
The difficulty is that these arguments do vide systematic evidence for probabilistic
not completely square the circle. They intro- arguments by utilizing within-case analysis.
duce some element of probability, but the This is precisely what Wood achieves in her
underlying hypothesized relationship remains account of insurgent collective action in El
essentially invariant. Case study scholars Salvador. She found that peasants who joined
thus still face an unpalatable option between the rebellion were far more likely to refer to
accepting the invariant nature of necessary deeply held values of participation, defiance,
and sufficient claims or abandoning the logic and pleasure in agency (Wood, 2003:
altogether. Clark et al. (2006) have offered 229–36). The correlation between values and
one potential way out of the conundrum by participation was not invariant, and Wood
dropping the notion of necessary and suffi- repeatedly refers to ‘many’ (rather than all)
cient conditions for that of asymmetrical who felt this way. Hence, these values
causes and conditions. A condition is were neither necessary nor sufficient, but
asymmetrical, in their view, if it exhibits rela- they did constitute ‘principal reasons’ (Wood,
tively small levels of variance in the associ- 2003: 18) for engaging in collective action.
ated outcomes: If Y is present, X is nearly In short, qualitative research and common
always present. Necessary conditions are thus arguments associated with them are
‘near-necessary’ and the entire problematic quite compatible with probabilistic views
language is abandoned in favor of asymmetry. of political outcomes and can be used
This approach is more clearly probabilistic; to both generate and test probabilistic
the logic asserts that the presence of Y dra- arguments.
matically increases the probability that X is
also present, but does not guarantee it.
A related issue concerns the relationship Theory generation versus
between qualitative methods and asymmetri-
theory testing
cal (necessary and sufficient) theories.
Mahoney and Goertz (2006: 232–4) draw a Case study methods can be rich sources of
fairly sharp line between qualitative and new theoretical propositions and insights
quantitative conceptions of causation, argu- (Van Evera, 1997: 21–7). Uncovering the
ing that the former deals with the logic of causal mechanism in one particular case can
necessary and sufficient conditions while the lead scholars to develop new ideas about how
latter deals with the logic of probability. Yet other cases might work. Mahoney (2007b)
further examination suggests the pairing notes three particular techniques that can be
between approaches and logics is not so used to generate new hypotheses. The first is
clear. While qualitative research certainly the exploration of deviant case studies, or
seems better suited to dealing with asym- cases where outcomes do not conform to
metrical hypotheses, Clark et al. (2006) have theoretical expectations (Eckstein, 1975;
developed a quantitative method for dealing Lijphart, 1971). The second involves careful
with these kinds of arguments. On the flip involvement in the details of the cases to
side, any argument identifying sufficient identify overlooked patterns that crop up in

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 14 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


64 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

interviews, archival records, and the like. The of the evidence is an integral part of produc-
third consists of particular attention to the ing that explanation. For this reason, case
temporal dimension of the phenomena studies are quite frequently inductive in
to identify turning points or the conjunction nature.
of different factors. None of these theory-
generating mechanisms is likely to be uti-
lized in quantitative research unless scholars
are involved in gathering and coding their CONCLUSION
own data, a procedural step that has much in
common with case study analyses. The close Scholars have engaged in a sophisticated and
relationship between case studies and theory productive debate about case study methods
generation is brought into striking relief by that has produced a wealth of insights. Case
Munck and Snyder (2007: 13), who found studies are widely viewed as useful comple-
that 80% of the articles in their study com- ments to large-N statistical methods with
bined qualitative methods and inductive particular strengths in depth of analysis, con-
theorizing. struct validity, the identification of causal
While few would contest the claim that mechanisms, asymmetric theoretical argu-
case studies are useful for generating new ments (related to necessary and sufficient
theoretical insights, the ability to test theories conditions), and theory generation. While
using case studies is much debated. One case studies seem to possess these ‘natural’
potential impediment to using case studies in strengths and trade-offs undoubtedly exist, it
theory testing is data mining, or using the is also important not to overstate case study
same data to both generate and test hypothe- limitations. Case studies can also be useful in
ses. While case study practitioners could of causal inference, probabilistic theories, and
course use data from one case to generate theory testing. Some of the most important
hypotheses that are examined in other cases advances in case study methods involve
and thereby avoid the problem, the amount of insights into appropriate case selection, proc-
time and effort put into a case study and the ess tracing and causal-process observations,
need to publish results often means that data and the role of necessary and sufficient con-
are used to both generate and test (or, per- ditions. Whether scholarly research will
haps more often, ‘illustrate’) theories. As incorporate all of these ‘lessons learned’
Mahoney (2007a: 37) points out, however, remains an open question, but case study
data mining is not unique to case study meth- methodologists have certainly done much to
ods. Quantitative researchers can also (and carefully consider the uses of case studies
perhaps routinely do) look for patterns in the and to make available the necessary analyti-
data, generate hypotheses to fit those pat- cal tools and procedures.
terns, and then ‘test’ them on the same data
set. Mahoney and Goertz (2006) argue that
such data mining is far more harmful in
quantitative analyses because the goal is to
estimate the average effects of independent ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
variables and such effects can change dra-
matically through changes in model specifi- I would like to thank Kirk Hawkins, Jay
cation that occur through data mining. In Goodliffe, Kelly Patterson, and participants
case study research, on the other hand, the in the research seminar in Brigham Young
goal often consists of explaining outcomes in University’s political science department for
particular cases. Hence, a careful examination their insights and comments on this piece.

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 15 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


CASE STUDIES 65

(eds), Rethinking Social Inquiry: Diverse


REFERENCES Tools, Shared Standards. New York:
Cambridge University Press, pp. 229–66.
Achen, C.H. and Snidal, D. (1989) ‘Rational Colomer, J.M. (1991) ‘Transitions by agree-
deterrence theory and comparative case ment: Modeling the Spanish way’,
studies’, World Politics, 41 (2): 143–69. American Political Science Review, 85 (4):
Beck, N. (2006) Is causal-process observation 1293–302.
an oxymoron? Political Analysis, 14 (3): Dion, D. (1998) ‘Evidence and inference in the
347–52. comparative case study’, Comparative
Bennett, A. (2004) ‘Case study methods: Politics, 30 (January): 127–45.
Design, use, and comparative advantages’, Eckstein, H. (1975) ‘Case study and theory in
in D.F. Sprinz and Y. Wolinsky-Nahmias political science’, in F.I. Greenstein and
(eds), Models, numbers and cases: Methods N.W. Polsby (eds), Handbook of Political
for studying international relations. Ann Science: Strategies of Inquiry. Reading, MA:
Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. Addison-Wesley.
19–55. Fearon, J. (1991) ‘Counterfactuals and hypoth-
Brady, H.E. and Collier, D. (2004) Rethinking esis testing in political science’, World Politics,
social inquiry: Diverse tools, shared 43 (2): 169–95.
standards. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Geddes, B. (1990) ‘How the cases you choose
Littlefield. affect the answers you get: Selection bias in
Brady, H.E., Collier, D., and Seawright, J. comparative politics’, Political Analysis, 2:
(2004) ‘Refocusing the discussion of meth- 131–50.
odology’, in H.E. Brady and D. Collier (eds), George, A. (1979) ‘Case study and theory
Rethinking social inquiry: Diverse tools, development: The method of structured,
shared standards. Lanham, MD: Rowman focused comparison’, in P. Gordon (ed.),
and Littlefield, pp. 3–20. Diplomacy: New approaches in history,
Braumoeller, B.F. and Goertz, G. (2000) ‘The theory and policy. New York: Free Press,
methodology of necessary conditions’, pp. 43–68.
American Journal of Political Science, 44 (4): George, A. and Bennett, A. (2005) Case Study
844–58. and Theory Development in the Social
Clark, W.R, Gilligan, M.J., and Golder, M. Sciences. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
(2006) ‘A simple multivariate test for asym- George, A. and McKeown, T. J. (1985) ‘Case
metric hypotheses’, Political Analysis, 14 (3): studies and theories of organizational deci-
311–31. sion making’, in R.F. Coulam and R.A. Smith
Collier, D., Brady, H.E., and Seawright, J. (eds), Advances in information processing in
(2004a) ‘Critiques, responses, and trade- organizations. Greenwich, CT: Jai Press,
offs: Drawing together the debate’, in H.E. pp. 21–58.
Brady and D. Collier (eds), Rethinking Social Gerring, J. (2004) ‘What is a case study and
Inquiry: Diverse Tools, Shared Standards. what is it good for?’, American Political
New York: Cambridge University Press, Science Review, 98 (2): 341–54.
pp. 195–228. Gerring, J. (2007) ‘Is there a (viable) crucial-
Collier, D., Brady, H.E., and Seawright, J. case method?’, Comparative Political Studies,
(2004b) ‘Sources of leverage in causal infer- 40 (3): 231–53.
ence: Toward an alternative view of method- Goertz, G. (2003) ‘The substantive importance of
ology’, in H.E. Brady and D. Collier (eds), necessary conditions hypotheses’, in G. Goertz
Rethinking Social Inquiry: Diverse Tools, and H. Starr (eds), Necessary Conditions:
Shared Standards. New York: Cambridge Theory, Methodology and Applications. New
University Press, pp. 229–66. York: Rowman and Littlefield, pp. 65–94.
Collier, D., Mahoney, J., and Seawright, J. Harvey, F.P. (2003) ‘Practicing coercion:
(2004c) ‘Claiming too much: Warnings about Revisiting successes and failures using
selection bias’, in H.E. Brady and D. Collier Boolean logic and comparative methods’, in

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 16 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


66 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

G. Goertz and H. Starr (eds), Necessary Munck, G. and Snyder, R. (2007) ‘Debating the
Conditions: Theory, Methodology, and direction of comparative politics: An analysis
Applications. New York: Rowman and of leading journals’, Comparative Political
Littlefield. Studies, 40 (1): 5–31.
Hawkins, D. (2001) ‘Democratization theory Przeworski, A. and Tenue, H. (1970) The logic of
and nontransitions: Insights from Cuba’, comparative social inquiry. New York: Wiley.
Comparative Politics, 33 (4): 441–61. Ragin, C.C. (1987) The comparative method:
King, G., Keohane, R., and Verba, S. (1994) Moving beyond qualitative and quantitative
Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference strategies. Berkeley: University of California
in qualitative research. Princeton, NJ: Press.
Princeton University Press. Ragin, C.C. (2000) Fuzzy-set social science.
King, G., Keohane, R., and Verba, S. (2004) Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
‘The importance of research design’, in H.E. Sartori, G. (1970) ‘Concept misformation in
Brady and D. Collier (eds), Rethinking social comparative politics’, American Political
inquiry: Diverse tools, shared standards. Science Review, 64 (4): 1033–53.
Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, pp. Seawright, J. and Collier, D. (2004) ‘Glossary’,
181–92. in H.E. Brady and D. Collier (eds.), Rethinking
Lijphart, A. (1971) ‘Comparative politics and social inquiry: Diverse tools, shared stand-
the comparative method’, American Political ards. New York: Cambridge University Press,
Science Review, 65: 682–93. pp. 273–313.
Mackie, J.L. (1980) The cement of the universe: Skocpol, T. (1979) States and social revolu-
A study of causation. Oxford: Oxford tions: A comparative analysis of France,
University Press. Russia, and China. New York: Cambridge
Mahoney, J. (2007a) ‘Debating the state of University Press.
comparative politics: Views from qualitative Sprinz, D.F., and Wolinsky-Nahmias, Y. (2004)
research’, Comparative Political Studies, 40 ‘Introduction: Methdology in international
(2): 32–38. relations research’, in D.F. Sprinz and
Mahoney, J. (2007b) ‘Qualitative methodology Y. Wolinsky-Nahmias (eds) Models, numbers
and comparative politics’, Comparative and cases: Methods for studying interna-
Political Studies, 40 (1): 122–44. tional relations. Ann Arbor: University of
Mahoney, J. and Goertz, G. (2006) ‘A tale of Michigan Press, pp. 1–16.
two cultures: Contrasting quantitative and Tarrow, S. (2004) ‘Bridging the quantitative-
qualitative research’, Political Analysis, 14 qualitative divide’, in H.E. Brady and
(3): 227–49. D. Collier (eds), Rethinking social
Mainwaring, S. and Pérez-Liñán, A. (2005) inquiry: Diverse tools, shared standards.
‘Latin American democratization since 1978: Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield,
Democratic transitions, breakdowns, and pp. 171–80.
erosions’, in F. Hagopian and S.P. Mainwaring Tetlock, P.E. and Belkin, A. (1996) ‘Counterfactual
(eds), The third wave of democratization in thought experiments in world politics:
Latin America: Advances and setbacks. logical, methodological, and psychological
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, perspectives’, in P. E. Tetlock and A. Belkin
pp. 14–59. (eds), Counterfactual thought experiments
McKeown, T. (1999) ‘Case studies and the in world politics: Logical, methodological,
statistical worldview: Review of King, and psychological perspectives. Princeton,
Keohane, and Verba’s Designing social NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 1–38.
inquiry: Scientific inference in qualitative Van Evera, S. (1997) Guide to methods for
research’, International Organization, 53 (1): students of political science. Ithaca, NY:
161–90. Cornell University Press.
Mill, J.S. (1875) A system of logic, ratiocinative Wood, E.J. (2003) Insurgent collective action
and inductive: Being a connected view and civil war in El Salvador. New York:
of the principles of evidence and the Cambridge University Press.
methods of scientific investigation, Vol. 2. Yin, R.K. (1990) Case study research: Design
London: Longmans, Green, Reader, and and methods. Newbury Park, CA: Sage
Dyer. Publications.

9781412919760_Chap03.indd 17 3/11/2009 3:26:38 PM


4
Is there a Quantitative-
Qualitative Divide in
Comparative Politics?
The Case of Process Tracing
James A. Caporaso

MEANINGS OF QUALITATIVE AND


Quality as the property itself
QUANTITATIVE
Quantity as variation in degree of that qual-
The discipline of political science is said to be ity. This is the most basic distinction of
divided between those who pursue a qualita- qualitative and quantitative. A quality is the
tive approach and those who study politics property itself, such as democracy, aliena-
quantitatively. As Pierson (2007) has shown, tion, or integration while a quantity refers to
this division is uneven across sub-fields, with measurable variation in that property. So
American politics the most quantitative and ‘democracy’ is qualitatively different from
international relations the least. Comparative ‘party government’ but perhaps different in
politics has a history in which knowledge of degree (in quantity in other words) from
particular countries, their cultures, institu- authoritarianism. Some qualities do not vary.
tions, and behavior, are thought of as very They exist only as types, for example, preg-
important components of research, whether as nancy, sovereignty (some say you are sover-
context for more detailed empirical generali- eign or not), and party affiliation (Democrat
zations, or as objects of study themselves. As or Republican), though not party loyalty.
such, comparative politics has had to grapple Most qualities do vary, so that one can say
with the qualitative/quantitative issue in a par- there is more or less alienation, more or less
ticularly intensified fashion. Yet, without a democracy, more or less party fragmentation
clear idea of what is meant by the qualitative/ and so on. I do not think that it is a major
quantitative distinction, it is impossible to claim of qualitative analysis that most political
know what is at stake. Below is a brief inven- science properties do not vary and therefore
tory of meanings of this term. do not, at bottom, have a quantitative aspect.

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:1 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


68 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Even when qualitative analysis is called for, (historical, cultural, sociological, class) and
as in Ragin’s (2000) analysis based on meanings, and to be able to reconstruct the
Boolean algebra, there is a practical recogni- symbols and worldviews so that it becomes
tion that the qualitative categories are often comprehensible that others act as they do.
truncated versions of underlying continua. If Herbert Gans’ Urban Villager (1982), Ann
one accepts this reasoning, it is a logical mis- Cornelisen’s Women of the Shadows (1976)
take to treat qualitative and quantitative as and Paul Willis’ Learning to Labor (1981),
alternatives to one another. They are mutu- are representative of this category of work.
ally implicated categories.

Qualitative as case study


Qualitative analysis is analysis
Sometimes scholars in comparative politics
that is verbal
use the term ‘qualitative’ to refer to detailed
It relies on words, imagery, and ordinary lan- studies of single cases, where a case can be a
guage, or a modified (jargon) extension of country, region, political party, peasant move-
ordinary language. It is opposed to numerical ment, land tenure system, and so forth. Often
analysis where numbers carry the message, such studies are contrasted with large-N statis-
even if the numbers are themselves represent- tical work. While this use of qualitative can be
ative of concepts in a theory. Qualitative useful, case studies are often statistical and
analysis in this sense could use a rich reper- rely on extensive use of within-case observa-
toire associated with ordinary language, tions to provide variation and the basis for
including metaphor, analogy, relationships, generalization. If many studies are not for-
sequences, stories (narratives, about which mally cross-country, informally most of them
more later), ambiguity, irony, and so on. While are. Scholars are constantly asking ‘what is
this usage of qualitative is central to how this an instance of?’ and ‘how does this com-
many think of the qualitative-quantitative pare to other cases I am not studying?’
divide, we should note that it is not congruent
with the distinction made above. In short, one
can easily use ordinary language to express
quantitative relationships and numbers to rep- CLAIMS OF QUALITATIVE RESEARCH
resent qualities. ‘The more I ignore him, the
more he tries to engage me in conversation’. In this chapter, by qualitative I mean an
Think of the underlying quantitative nature of approach which relies on verbal reasoning
this statement in contrast to ‘code Republicans and representation, limits itself to a single
as 0 and Democrats as 1’, where the numbers case (though this can be relaxed), and
indicate membership or non-membership. attempts to understand within-system rela-
tionships either through comparisons over
time, across sub-system units, or by the nest-
Qualitative analysis as interpretive ing of intra-systemic relationships within the
overall political and social system.1
or hermeneutic
Given this definition of qualitative, what
The term ‘qualitative’ can refer to a style of are some of its claims? I discern four claims
research, one that aims at understanding about the distinctive strengths of the qualita-
rather than explanation and prediction. tive approach of which I will address only
Qualitative becomes an aspect of an approach one. First, deviant case analysis: qualitative
rather than a property of a concept. The goal researchers argue that they are well equipped
is to place oneself in the position of the other to deal with cases that do not conform to
person, in order to understand the context a general pattern, whether that pattern is

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:2 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


IS THERE A QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DIVIDE IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS? 69

produced by statistical analysis or simply by philosophy of science as a third-party arbiter.


theoretical expectation. Deviant case analysis The most one can do is to point out the impli-
turns out to be a particular expression of the cations of the approaches and look for places
broader problem of causal heterogeneity. where their logics converge or diverge.
Large-N researchers frequently address devi-
ant cases by statistical methods which attempt
to reduce the distance between outliers and
the regression line. Qualitative researchers QUALITATIVE ANALYSIS AND
argue that the problem is best approached CAUSAL MECHANISMS
through attempts to reduce heterogeneity of
cases. A homogenous population will have In this section, I will restate the claim that
less confusion between independent and qualitative analysis is superior in terms of its
dependent variables. Second, the qualitative ability to demonstrate causal relations. Since
approach is better equipped to discover new this claim runs counter to the standard view
concepts and to elaborate these concepts in a of causality, I will briefly describe the latter.
theoretically fruitful way (Coppedge, 1999). The qualitative approach has a formidable
Its typical strengths are present more in the foe to address; one that finds its philosophic
context of discovery rather than the context roots in Hume and that has been updated by
of verification. Third, qualitative research, modern technologies associated with time
because of its ties to categorical logic, is series analysis and recursive structures. For
better equipped to uncover the combinatorial convenience, I refer to the standard view as
logic of causality underlying many relation- the Simon-Blalock model of causality.
ships central to comparative politics After stating the claims of qualitative analy-
(Mahoney, 2001; Ragin, 1987, 2000). And sis regarding causality, I attempt three things.
fourth, the qualitative approach is said to be First, I elaborate the causal model relying on a
more adept at uncovering causal mecha- mechanistic account. In so doing, I set out the
nisms, in contrast to the quantitative approach elementary logic of mechanistic thinking and
which relies on identifying controlled covari- show why, according to its adherents, it con-
ance structures to elucidate causality. stitutes a different and superior way of think-
All four claims are important and raise ing of causality. Second, I compare one variant
complex issues that are clearly too complex (the theoretical narrative) of this account of
for a single chapter to manage. I will focus on causality to the standard Simon-Blalock view
only the last of these four claims, the dispute and argue that there is no necessary incompat-
about causality. The basic dispute revolves ibility between both accounts. Indeed, the two
around the exact meaning of a causal relation approaches seem to require one another for a
and which of two approaches provides the full understanding of causality (Seawright,
more satisfying account. The two approaches 2005). Third, I consider a second variant and
are the covariance model of causality drawing reach a conclusion that is not so accommodat-
first upon Hume (1748/1955) and later refined ing. Recasting the logic of the mechanistic
in the Simon-Blalock (Simon, 1957a, b; account into one called the historical narrative
Blalock, 1961) model and second, the qualita- leads to a way of thinking about temporal
tive model which provides a mechanistic processes that cannot be assimilated into the
account of the process that characterizes a standard model.
causal relation. Both approaches provide a
definition of a causal relation, suggest appro-
priate methods to study these relations, and The main claim
are supported by distinctive philosophies of
science. It is therefore difficult, if not impos- The main claim of the qualitative approach is
sible, to resolve the dispute by using a neutral that quantitative research, based on large-Ns,

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:3 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


70 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

is very good at identifying statistical associa- causal mechanism and show how this mecha-
tions and covariance structures, but not so nism is connected to outcomes. If this claim
good at uncovering specific causal mecha- is true, there is a considerable gap between
nisms.2 While these associations fit well with the qualitative and quantitative approaches to
the Humean idea of causality as constant causal explanation.
conjunction (or succession of events), they Reliance on mechanisms has a longstand-
do not provide for a critical component of ing tradition in post-Humean philosophy of
causal arguments, namely a mechanism science and is increasingly the favored stance
(Bunge, 1997; Elster, 1998; Hedstrom and among practicing social scientists and phi-
Swedberg, 1998). In its strongest form, the losophers of science. Harré (1972), for exam-
claim is that qualitative research is best ple, argues that the two great metaphysical
equipped to make causal inferences because theories of causality are the generative theory
it is well suited to discover mechanisms. and the succession theory.
Since discovering causal mechanisms In the generative theory the cause is supposed to
requires a close-up qualitative examination have the power to generate the effect and is con-
of processes that can only be imperfectly nected to it. In the succession theory a cause is just
glimpsed from the large-N vantage point, what usually comes before the event or state, and
extended analysis of single cases (process which comes to be called its cause because we
have acquired a psychological propensity to expect
tracing in the most popular version) offers that kind of effect after the cause. (p. 116)
the best opportunity to study mechanisms.
Causality, mechanisms, single cases, and In case there is any doubt as to which view is
process tracing are linked in this approach. preferred, Harré observes:
At first glance, this claim to grasp causal- For the believer in generative causality the exist-
ity through direct examination of the mecha- ence of the statistics is but the first step in a long
nisms seems to be based on a naïve process of investigation which ends only when the
empiricism. One of the legacies of Hume was nature of the things involved has been found out
the banishment of necessary forcings and all and the reasons for the statistics thus elicited.
Science follows the generative rather than the
mechanisms that claim to have such powers
successionist theory of causality (p. 118).3
in favor of a strict empiricist view of causal-
ity that relies on associations among observ- In the rest of this section, I link mecha-
able events. Necessary relations, causal nisms to the methodology of process tracing
forcings, and generative relations are not and show that this method can go in two
observed. True, as we learn early in graduate quite different directions. The first version of
school, correlation does not mean causation, process tracing is decidedly explanatory and
and as should be added, ‘at least not by cannot avoid covariance. Each successive
itself’. Nevertheless, demonstration of a con- link in the extended causal chain rests, if only
nection between X and Y would seem to be implicitly, on another covariance structure.
the first-cut requirement on which additional The second version of the process-tracing
causal investigation rests. In this sense, evi- methodology is more idiosyncratic. It rests
dence of association establishes candidacy on the discovery of a chain of events, rather
for causal status. than a distribution of values of variables, that
To qualitative analysts, extended discus- leads to certain outcomes. While these two
sion of causality as covariance is beside the approaches share some features – the obser-
point. Qualitative researchers argue that mere vations in both are temporally ordered, steps
correlations, even when embedded within a in the sequence of events link background
theory that has asymmetric (recursive) prop- conditions with outcomes – there are many
erties with controls for confounding varia- important differences too. However, since the
bles, still falls short in terms of causal theory. idea of mechanism plays such a big role in
To demonstrate causality, one must uncover a what follows, I briefly discuss this concept.

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:4 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


IS THERE A QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DIVIDE IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS? 71

The idea of mechanism has become very complementing it (Gerring, 2005, 2006).
popular in modern social research and phi- I call it the theoretical narrative. The second
losophy of science (see Bunge, 1997 and model, which relies on specific events of a
Hedstrom and Swedberg, 1998, for general non-theoretical sort, is more particular and
discussions of the role of this concept in leads to the historical narrative.
social research and philosophy of science).
The term has been used in quite different (a) Mechanism and covariance,
ways, sometimes to refer to observables and the theoretical narrative
sometimes to unobservables, at times to The qualitative approach argues that a focus
events that have a general theoretical status on single cases and the isolation of mecha-
as opposed to specific events that have no nisms is the best way to go in order to under-
general counterpart. Sometimes the use of stand causality. Sometimes, it is implied that
mechanism is limited to the micro level the exploration of a causal mechanism is suf-
while macro theory is deprived of the term ficient, on its own, to prove a causal relation-
while others (e.g., Boudon, 1998) see mecha- ship. That is, the relationship between X and
nisms as potentially operating at any level. Y can be proven through the identification of
I bypass these controversies to define a mecha- a causal pathway stretching from X to Y. The
nism as an intervening factor4 that occurs relationship can be diagrammed as follows:
between some background variable and an
outcome. Mechanisms seek to connect back- X1 → X2 → X3 → X4 → Y
ground factors (often structural) with a defi-
nite but more remote outcome. If a series of The argument is that the above account is
mechanisms is linked together in some kind superior to one based on the demonstration
of temporal order, we can refer to that struc- of the covariation of X1 and Y. The specifica-
ture as a causal pathway or process. Several tion of mechanisms (X2, X3, and X4) fills in
different causal pathways might exist, link- the temporal and spatial gaps between X1
ing background conditions to outcomes, in and Y and increases our confidence that this
which case we can speak of equifinality. is how the causal process works. A statistical
The device of mechanism is useful for correlation between X1 and Y might group
giving coherence to temporally extended together instances where X1 was followed by
causal chains, especially where any particu- these three intervening variables with
lar link may not be crucial in bringing about instances where no such succession of events
the outcome. In this sense, a mechanism occurred. A coefficient could then rest on an
cannot be exogenous or the point of depar- unidentified mixture of different causal proc-
ture of a causal chain just as it cannot be the esses: some where the above process holds,
final outcome. A mechanism is by definition some where no relationship at all exists, and
intermediate. It provides the connective tissue some where X1 does ‘lead to’ Y but via a dif-
that links temporally ordered events. Indeed, ferent causal path, that is, with different
its function is to give coherence to these con- intervening factors. Because the process
nections and to provide this temporal order. approach gives us a purer view of the causal
If the connections are made rigorously, a process that does not rely on mixing hetero-
causal process can be the result. If mecha- geneous causal relations, it is preferred to the
nisms do not refer to variables but instead covariance view.
refer to particular events and actors without While elaboration of intervening mecha-
theoretical status, the result can be a historical nisms may be desirable, a nagging question
narrative or simply a story. I will illustrate the still remains. Is the identification of the proc-
two types of processes below. The first proc- ess leading from X1 to Y ipso facto evidence
ess model is fully compatible with the covari- of causality? Sometimes advocates of the
ance view of causality and can be seen as qualitative mechanistic view of causality

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:5 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


72 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

treat this as a non-problem, as if the analyst causality. If a mechanism is a link in a causal


directly grasps the causal connection by chain, it can only be shown to be a valid link
direct intuition. Once the intervening mecha- to the extent that it is non-spurious. Repeated
nisms have been delineated, the causal associations between X and Y (covariance)
relation has been demonstrated and episte- as well as the elimination of third variables
mological inquiry can cease. This seems as common causes are required to demon-
unsatisfying and in need of further examina- strate the relationship. Seen in this light, a
tion. How can we be certain that a causal mechanism does not have a distinct ontologi-
relation has been demonstrated? If David cal status compared to a variable and there-
Hume (and Alexander George) (George and fore mechanisms do not have special
Bennett, 2005) watch someone flip a light dispensation from the task of explaining
switch, followed by light, which one has wit- covariation between X and Y.
nessed a causal relation? Presumably, Hume To understand this better, let us pursue the
would be satisfied by the before-after rela- logic of the mechanistic approach. Suppose
tionship so long as it proved stable (a con- we observe a relationship between X and Y.
stant conjunction) while George might be The accuracy of our measures is not at issue.
bewildered by the magic involved in the join- We are sure that X and Y occurred. How
ing of these two events, since no intervening could we know that X in fact had causal force
mechanisms were provided. George would in bringing about Y? What basis would we
have to press for a more detailed account, have for knowing that the joint occurrence of
perhaps even learning something about X and Y was not utterly contingent, that is,
electricity. that they co-occurred completely by chance?
I accept the proposition that the more we Further, even if the relationship was not due
know about the land in between, the more to chance (which we could not know with
confident we can be about a causal relation. only one observation), how would we know
Yet the critical question, perhaps obscured by that the relationship was not spurious? In any
the light switch example, is this: how do we snapshot or pairing of temporally adjacent
know that the intervening factors identified events, there is an impossibly large number
are the ones that truly cause the outcome? It of other events that also fit the co-occurrence
is a legitimate question because the qualita- of X and Y. How do we know one of these
tive view claims to focus on generative rela- events (or several in conjunction) is not the
tions, that is, those where the identified true cause? We don’t. In order to establish
factors produce the outcomes. This is a some basis for the causal inference, we
decidedly anti-Humean position (consciously would have to repeatedly observe the tempo-
so) but this is precisely where the qualitative ral ordering of X and Y and we would have
view of causality has its distinctive appeal. to go to some lengths to rule out other causal
How do we know that the intervening factors mechanisms that might be at work. In short,
are not irrelevant or spuriously related to the this would take us back to the standards of
outcome? The constant conjunction model of stable association (covariance) and non-
causality must identify not only a stable asso- spuriousness characteristic of the quantita-
ciation between X and Y but must demon- tive approach.
strate that this pattern is non-spurious, that is, Yet, the reasons for adopting a process-
not the result of association with a third vari- based model of causality are greater than the
able. By what logic should the qualitative light switch example suggests. In that exam-
view be exempt from demonstrating non- ple, we are fairly certain that the association
spuriousness? between flipping the switch and the light
Once we have asked this question we can going on is not a spurious relation. We may
see that the mechanistic approach does not not know what happens ‘inside the wall’
provide a satisfying stand-alone account of beyond the switch (the black box in this case),

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:6 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


IS THERE A QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DIVIDE IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS? 73

but the relation is stable and when exceptions show that such inequality works through the
occur (an old light bulb, overtaxed fuse box, system by illustrating its class composition,
or faulty wiring) we can generally detect the and demonstrate how the inequality is mobi-
culprit. In cases such as this, we might think lized by political actors who manage a cam-
it fastidious rather than scientific to peer paign on this issue will have produced a more
inside the black box. Why, after all multiply convincing study.
entities against the advice of William of In this section, I have argued that one type
Occam? The answer is easily given if of qualitative model of causality, the theo-
we utilize examples more akin to the social retical narrative, joins mechanisms to the
sciences. idea of covariance essential to Humean
Take the relationship between levels of approaches to causality. It is not mechanism
inequality and public policies aiming at the versus covariance but rather mechanism and
reduction of inequality. A high level of ine- covariance. In this approach, neither mecha-
quality is a background factor (with respect nism nor covariance by itself is sufficient for
to some outcome such as political demands an adequate account of causality. Covariance
for greater equality) while the mobilization by itself may blend heterogeneous causal
of sentiment against this inequality would be processes into one set of coefficients (e.g., a
closer to the outcome. Closer yet would be correlation coefficient representing a variety
party strategy to use this inequality as a cam- of causal pathways connecting background
paign issue while a particular speech or tele- factors to outcomes). A mechanistic account
vision advertisement would be even more might identify a set of temporally related
proximally related to the outcome (e.g., an events with no underlying causal connec-
election). In turn, the election could be seen tions, in the sense that the identified relations
as an event which leads to a public policy are contingent and spurious. Subjecting
that aims to reduce inequality. The basic idea mechanisms to the covariance requirement
is clear enough. Background factors are and subjecting covariance to the mechanism
related to outcomes via extended causal requirement enriches both.
chains, series of events and intervening con-
ditions which mediate the remote and proxi- (b) Mechanisms and stories,
mal conditions. Now suppose there are two the historical narrative
different research studies. The first one shows In the theoretical narrative, I argued that
the reader an impeccable state of the art mechanism and covariance are best seen as
regression connecting macro inequality in a complementary to one another and that a
society with public policies aiming to reduce more satisfying explanation can be obtained
these inequalities. The second shows the by joining them in a unified account. In this
same beginning and ending conditions but view, mechanism and covariance are not fun-
elaborates numerous intervening conditions damentally at odds with one another. Indeed,
which connect inequality with public poli- the two ideas are worth more together than
cies. The second study would be more cred- separately. Considered as such, there is no
ible than the first because there is more barrier between qualitative and quantitative
connective tissue. While we can never be approaches. The qualitative aspect urges us
certain, we have more confidence if the main to uncover the mechanisms lying between
episodes of the intervening process are estab- variables temporally and spatially removed
lished and if the links in the chain do seam- from one another. The quantitative aspect
lessly lead to the outcome. A gross pattern of urges us to think of these mechanisms as
inequality need not lead to remedial policies variables which must be viewed as covari-
and a macro correlation between inequality ance structures in their relations with one
and public policies would be difficult to another. Neither can be disregarded without
interpret with confidence. Someone who can loss of information.

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:7 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


74 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

In this section, I present an alternate view by a Serbian nationalist, Gavrilo Princip, in


that is not nearly so conciliatory. This view the summer of 1914’, and the Soviet repre-
holds that mechanistic accounts need not rest sentative in the Security Council (Andrei
on variables at all but rather on arrays of Vyshinsky) was absent in late June 1950
events/actors/actions viewed in particularis- when the United Nations undertook collec-
tic ways. This particularity can be achieved tive security measures to respond to the
in two ways. The historical narrative can be North Korean invasion of South Korea. No
made up of terms that represent specific attempt is made to describe these events as
events which are not presented as instances elements of a more general class of events
of more general categories. What are joined (assassinations of political leaders) or to
are events that do not have broad conceptual assign them scores on some underlying
status and are not treated as variables, even continuum.
qualitative ones. The second form of particu- What is sometimes difficult for the quanti-
larity occurs when the narrative assumes the tative approach to accept is that the use of
form of a story in which rare events and con- proper names is not just for the purpose of
junctures made up of independent streams of describing, rather than explaining, an event
low probability events, influence outcomes. such as the outbreak of World War I.
This is sometimes called conjunctural his- According to some accounts (Lebow, 2000–
tory. In both cases, elements of the story 2001), the assassination of the Archduke
resist quantification, though with more force Franz Ferdinand by Gavrilo Princip was not
in the former than the latter.5 In what follows a superfluous and substitutable event in the
I focus on the former meaning of historical inevitable march toward war. Few would
narrative. deny that the assassination had consequences.
The significance of stories, or historical Rather, the argument is made that if it had not
narratives, is downplayed, even degraded, in been for the assassination in the summer of
social science. Stories have connotations of 1914, another event would surely have trig-
being ad-hoc, descriptive, and cobbled gered war. Europe was a dry forest ready to
together sequences of events designed (even burn. Any number of events could have initi-
tailored) to account for an outcome without ated the fire. Against the ‘streetcar’ view that
offering a general explanation. The critic catalysts come along often (Thompson,
argues that the narrative essentially describes 2003), one can place the view that rare and
what has happened but does not recognize unpredictable events sometimes have big
the event as an instance of a general category, consequences that would not have otherwise
thus working against accumulation and inte- occurred. If the Serbian nationalist had been
gration of knowledge. The contrast between apprehended, delayed, thrown off balance by
the theoretical and historical narrative is the policeman who tried to interfere with his
stark. On the one hand, we have abstract shot, or if the carriage holding the archduke
concepts where events must submit to the had not stopped to allow another touring car
question ‘of what is this an instance?’ The to back up because of a wrong turn (Lebow,
United States and Canada are members of a 2000–2001: 592–3), the immediate crisis and
democratic dyad. Italy is an example of a perhaps the war itself would have been
fragmented party system and Amnesty averted. To be sure, WWI had underlying
International is an international non-govern- structural causes but even structural causes
mental organization. Each of these concep- do not last forever. Striking as the counter-
tual umbrellas carries a theoretical message. factual is, if the crisis of the summer of 1914
On the other hand we have concrete events had been averted, time would have been
with proper names, and specific information bought. According to Lebow (2000–2001:
about time and place attached. ‘The Austrian 601), the window of opportunity for war was
Archduke Franz Ferdinand was assassinated probably only several years long.

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:8 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


IS THERE A QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DIVIDE IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS? 75

Without the twin assassinations at Sarajevo, significance of these events in terms of some
Europe might have remained at peace for another larger story.
several years. In even that short a time, there is
good reason to believe that many of the pressures
Once the question is formulated in this
making Austrian, German, and Russian leaders way, the major research task is to focus on
risk-prone would have abated … In Austria … the the discovery of the steps and their sequences.
death of Franz Joseph in 1916 would have brought A ‘step’ is not a value of a variable. It has no
Franz Ferdinand to the throne, and he was com- distribution and it is not necessarily treated
mitted to introducing the universal franchise into
Hungary. Internal turmoil in Austria-Hungary
as an instance of a larger distribution.7
would have made it less, not more, war-prone. It Narrative structure may go as follows: first
is possible that Europe would have evolved in very we had these conditions, which led to Y, and
different ways, and without the Great War many that served to stimulate m, n, and o (mecha-
of the horrors of the twentieth century could have nisms), which in turn led to Z. As Becker
been averted. (Lebow, 2003: 476)
puts it, the process (the connection of events
The above example suggests that specific over time) is taken to be important for the
events, narrated properly, can be interpreted result, ‘perhaps even constitutive of it’
causally. But I am getting ahead of myself (Becker, 1992: 209). So temporal ordering
since I have not discussed what narration, (sequence), conjunctures (the coming
properly construed, means. In what follows, together of independent events), and time-
I attempt to identify the historical narrative sensitive influences are all central to good
structure, provide a simple schematic to dis- story telling.
tinguish it from the theoretical narrative, and The historical narrative is deceptively sim-
make arguments as to why we might con- ilar in structure to the theoretical narrative,
sider such a narrative as explanatory in the though it has some important differences.
broad sense. In doing this, I hope to show the We can think of the theoretical narrative as
continuities as well as discontinuities between follows:
qualitative and quantitative approaches.
Let me start by acknowledging a debt to X →Y → Z
A. R. Louch’s ‘History as Narrative’ (1969)
as well as to the work of Howard Becker where X, Y, and Z refer to distributions of
more generally.6 The former is a historian time-ordered variables, which implies
and the latter a sociologist, yet both arrive at a lagged data matrix where X and Y are
similar conceptions of the logical form of a paired with later observations of Y and Z
narrative explanation. respectively.
Becker (1998) asks us to imagine that
what we ‘want to study has, not causes but a Xt1 Yt2 Zt3
history, a story, a narrative’ (pp. 60–61).
Continuing, he suggests that a narrative : : :
account, in contrast to correlational studies,
depicts the thing to be explained ‘… as : : :
something that comes about through a series
of steps.’ (p. 208). Instead of asking about the : : ::
necessary (and perhaps sufficient) conditions
for X, we ask how X came to be the way it is. Xtn Ytn +1 Ztn +2
This way of looking at things pushes us to
discover X’s history, that is, the sequences This in turn implies that r X.Y and rY.Z
and links that are part of the process that (correlation of X with Y and Y with Z). The
brought X about. What makes a narrative results of the data analysis of this matrix is
interpretation possible is the temporal and a set of coefficients (correlation coeffi-
spatial adjacency of different events and the cients, regression coefficients) describing the

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:9 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


76 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

relations between X, Y, and Z. The larger the pattern in the succession of events. All we
n (number of observations) and the smaller can say is that B followed A in this case. The
the number of coefficients, the more parsi- light switch can’t be repeatedly thrown. The
monious the theory. archduke has either been assassinated or he
Now consider the case of the historical has not. So two questions immediately arise.
narrative with intermediate mechanisms: The first is what grounds do we have for
believing that the relationship between A and
X →Y → Z B is causal and not spurious? Presumably,
there are lots of other events that might inter-
Where X, Y, and Z are specific events (not pose themselves between A and B. What
variables), which implies: standards do we use for including A in the
chain along with B and not some other event?
X → m, n, o → Y → p, q, r → Z The second concerns explanation. Do these
sequences of events qualify as explanation?
Where m, n, o and p, q, and r are intervening The first question is answered in terms of
mechanisms. The role of detailed process ‘narrative smoothness’. The second is
tracing becomes critical here with the burden answered in terms of explanatory logics out-
on the analyst to identify the factors that lie side the covering law model.
in between X, Y, and Z. Notice that covari- What basis do we have for believing that
ance (constant conjunction) is not an issue later events came about because of earlier
here because there is no distribution (so ones? Clearly this is a more demanding ques-
means, and variances, and covariances cannot tion than the descriptive one that asks if cer-
be calculated). If causality is to be estab- tain events follow or precede others. We have
lished, the steps in the process leading from already seen that one of the claims of qualita-
X to Z must be made convincingly. This in tive research is that it can identify causal
turn requires that the intervening mecha- patterns and it can do this on the basis of a
nisms must be supplied in such a way as to generative idea of causality whereby later
leave little doubt that the larger events in forms result from earlier ones. In one sense,
question are actually (non-spuriously) con- this claim is circular. It amounts to saying
nected. The historical narrative satisfies the that a chain of causality can be shown by
requirement that a series of mechanisms is observing a chain of causality. In a certain
identified which connects X to Y. sense, this is true. Belief in the causal chain
Let us carefully consider the idea of the depends to a large extent on the not so simple
historical narrative as put forth by Louch act of seeing or observing the sequence of
(1969). His basic idea is that a narrative is a events. But if this is true, it is no more circu-
way of accounting for something as the out- lar than the covering law model of explana-
growth or result of a series of prior steps. tion in which the occurrence of X is
Though Louch does not emphasize the role ‘explained’ by telling us that X occurred
of mechanism, his account is fully consistent because Y occurred and X always occurs
with it, indeed, it even depends on it. Yet it is when Y occurs. Everything interesting in the
clear in his argument that the steps in the covering law model is a part of the auxiliary
sequence are not variables. The Xs and Ys action (is this an instance of X? and is the
are actors and specific events whose actions relationship between X and Y really invari-
are told at an increasingly fine level of granu- ant?) What makes the historical narrative
larity. Louch’s narrative is clearly a version interesting is the extent to which the narrator
of the historical narrative diagrammed can give a seamless account of the sequence
above. of events leading to the outcome. In pulling
But if the connections are made in terms of this off, the idea of narrative smoothness is
specific events, it means we cannot observe a crucial (Louch, 1969).

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:10 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


IS THERE A QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DIVIDE IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS? 77

The task of the historian, according to mighty task, given this example, may be one
Louch (1969), is to lay out the thing to be reason historians are inclined to focus on
explained on a continuum, and to trace the shorter time periods. As Louch (1969) argues,
temporal process which led to the final result the task of the historian is to ‘make[s] conti-
in great detail. The gaps may be filled in by nuity visible; he [the historian] fills in the
visual observation of that which occurs gaps’ (p. 56).
between background events and the outcome. The attempt to achieve narrative smooth-
The historian Roberts (1996) speaks of the ness blurs the line between a close descrip-
necessity of microcorrelation.8 Historical tion and explanation. This is why within-case
sociology deals with broad macro forces: analysis is often favored by the qualitative
social unrest, inequality of wealth, remote- researcher. Any event that might intrude into
ness of political institutions, and class con- the process to affect the outcome is either
flict. There is much explanatory room made part of the process (endogenized in a
between these background factors, which different sense) or argued to be irrelevant.
predispose people toward mobilization, and Irrelevancy would have to be argued on
actual mobilization for a specific cause. The exactly the inverse grounds of narrative
greater the reliance on mechanisms for inter- smoothness.9 It is in this sense that the his-
mediate information, the fewer the gaps torical narrative controls irrelevant consider-
between distal and proximal terms, the ations. While this is quite different from
greater the confidence we have in the story. partial correlations and stratified research
Louch’s idea is that if we look carefully, we designs of the quantitative researcher, it fits
can literally see the process by which the in with the overall qualitative approach.
event in question comes about. A detailed Anything that cannot be shown to be part of
account in terms of mechanisms provides the a tight sequence of events, does not qualify to
semiotic glue that gives meaning to the nar- be part of the narrative.
rative. The process of carefully observing the From the standpoint of historical narrative,
chronology of events, if disciplined and fine- a small number of cases (one is the limit) is a
grained enough, is explanation. The final strength rather than a weakness, largely
result, the thing we want to explain, comes because it minimizes the problem of causal
about as a natural result of the process lead- heterogeneity. Since the case is pure (unmixed
ing up to it. with heterogeneous cases), its causes are
The task of the historian is to focus on the likely to be more homogeneous. The large-N
apparent dissimilarities in an object or proc- researcher must attempt to deal with dis-
ess, and through a form of observational jointed findings by introducing new variables
arbitrage, to show how later forms emerge and specifications, by using dummy variables
out of earlier ones. Filling in the gaps, iron- to account for group differences, by assign-
ing out the differences, and demonstrating ing time-varying parameters, or by assigning
continuity help to achieve narrative smooth- unexplained cases to an error vector (Ragin,
ness. For example, one could look at the 2000: 50). Adding cases has benefits, in
French Revolution (1789), France in 1848, terms of both internal and external validity,
the birth of the Fourth Republic in France but it makes a single satisfactory theory less
(1946), and the appearance of the Fifth likely.
Republic in 1958. Despite the many impor- To strengthen the case that narrative
tant differences, the historian would fill in smoothness gives us greater inferential lever-
the considerable gaps in such a way as to age, let me provide an example of a powerful
smooth out the differences between France in theory where narrative smoothness does not
these different periods and to show how later exist. I illustrate with a strong theory to avoid
periods were somehow extensions or modifi- the straw man charge. The Stolper-Samuelson
cations of earlier ones. That this would be a (1941) theorem, as told by Rogowski (1989),

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:11 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


78 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

predicts that exogenous shifts in international some fashion, but not necessarily because of
economic openness lead to electoral realign- explicit causal connections of the sort that X
ments. Increasing (decreasing) exposure to caused Y. However, coherence may be sup-
trade will benefit (harm) holders of relatively plied through analogies or by interpretive
abundant (scarce) factors of production and reference to a larger narrative template in the
this will lead to changes in domestic political mind of the reader or historian. The Vietnam
alignments. Such a spare story, based only on War has been debated in light of the Munich
background economic information (relative analogy, the domino ‘theory’, and the quag-
factor profiles) and its relationship to politi- mire metaphor. One could tell a story of the
cal coalitions, would not give us as much first Gulf War of 1990–1991 using nothing
inferential confidence as one in which back- but proper names and specific time-place
ground conditions were tied to the electoral information (Bush, Baker, Glaspie, Sununu,
outcomes via an elaborate specification of Hussein, the United Nations, and the Gulf
mediating mechanisms. If the theory speci- Cooperation Council). Still, the reader could
fied not only how trade affects factor incomes, very well understand these specific events in
but also how these incomes are perceived by light of a larger morality play emphasizing a
real social classes, how these objective inter- villain (Hussein), a victim (Kuwait), and a
ests are mobilized (or not) by political entre- hero or rescuer such as the United States,
preneurs, and the way in which these classes United Nations (Lakoff, 2003: 3). These sto-
are or are not organized into electoral con- ries, or narrative templates, are deeply embed-
stellations where they could make their votes ded in our memories. Thus, Alker (1987)
count, this would greatly add to the story. suggests that we take seriously ‘alternative
Indeed, one of the main goals of the Analytic scripts’, ‘plot possibilities’, and ‘context-
Narrratives book is to ‘… focus on the sensitive story grammars’ that lie behind
mechanisms that translate … macrohistorical historical processes we study (pp. 1–5).
forces into specific political outcomes.’ There are metaphors of birth, growth and
(Bates et al., 1998: 13) To the extent that the decay, of the virtuous person gone astray
gaps are filled in, the account is all the more (sin) and cleansing himself (penance, redemp-
plausible, even convincing. So there is a tion and renewal), of innocence and loss of
sense, more than intuitive, that a detailed innocence, and of humility and hubris. There
tracing of the process helps us understand the is considerable evidence that people orient
outcome. themselves to the world in terms of meta-
The second question has to do with whether phors (Lakoff and Johnson, 1980).
the historical narrative is explanatory. This is Let us take as a time-tested example the
a difficult question to answer, not least story of Ulysses and the Sirens, the subject of
because there are different models of expla- a great literary epic. One reason that this
nation. Perhaps some would argue that the theme has been so appealing across the ages
historical narrative provides description but is that it is so widely useful and evocative for
not a general law. Hence there is no explana- both theoretical and interpretive accounts.
tion. I argue that the historical narrative is This theme (of Ulysses having himself tied to
more than mere description but different the mast) has been invoked to describe the
from a general covering law in the Hempel daily pre-commitments by which the recov-
(1965) and Nagel (1961) sense. Broader sig- ering alcoholic tries to pre-commit (empty
nificance of the historical narrative is real- the liquor cabinet in the morning), the insti-
ized not by subsuming particulars under tutional devices ‘invented’ by politicians and
covering laws but through the relationship bankers to avoid inflation (place banks out-
between the particulars of the story and inter- side the line of executive and legislative
pretive frameworks, metaphor and myth authority), and the behavior of the military
(Lakoff, 2003). The story parts may cohere in commander who wants to send costly signals

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:12 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


IS THERE A QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DIVIDE IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS? 79

to the enemy (by burning bridges). The carries the connotation of limited generaliz-
Ulysses metaphor brings together a wide ability (see Boudon, 1998; Elster, 1989). The
array of examples and integrates them within particularity of such accounts is best (though
a common interpretive framework. It is by not exclusively) addressed by qualitative
the assimilation of these examples to the approaches.
master framework that the particulars acquire
significance. The tale of Ulysses is not
a causal story, though surely it could be re-
expressed as such. CONCLUSION
In this section I have attempted to expli-
cate the underlying logic of the theoretical In this chapter I have focused on the role of
and historical narratives. Both rely on time- causal process tracing in single cases within
ordered information and both attempt to the context of comparative politics. While
achieve a meaning that goes well beyond the admittedly different from cross-country com-
data at hand. In the theoretical narrative, the parisons, single cases offer ample opportuni-
introduction of mechanisms does not make ties for within-case comparison and analysis.
for challenges that are qualitatively new. I have addressed a main claim of qualitative
Mechanisms are just ‘in-between variables’. researchers, which is that the qualitative
In addition, quantitative expression is not approach is better positioned to make causal
only compatible with the theoretical narra- inferences in a single case narrative study.
tive; it goes naturally with it. Quantitative approaches are well designed to
The historical narrative is based on a dif- detect structures of covariance in large-N
ferent logic. To demonstrate causality, the studies and thus have an affinity with Humean
theoretical narrative relies on regular ties (and Simon-Blalock) models of causality,
(constant conjunction) between temporally while qualitative approaches have an affinity
adjacent but lagged observations. Extraneous with mechanistic models of causality. In
causes are eliminated through statistical con- what sense is this claim true? In what sense
trols or research design strategies. The can small N studies, even single cases using
explanatory model is one based on a fit detailed process tracing, provide a convinc-
between the particulars to be explained and a ing model of causality?
general covering law. The historical narrative In answering this question, I confronted a
relies on filling in the gaps between events prior issue about the nature of mechanism.
that are temporally removed from one another Depending on the conception of mechanism,
and achieving a narrative smoothness. It is two quite different views of causal process
the closing of the gap between background analysis are possible, leading inescapably to
conditions and outcomes, along with place- two distinct versions of within-case analysis.
ment of the story within a larger interpretive The first view of mechanism leads to the
framework that lends cogency to the theoretical narrative and relies on variables
account. and their connections. The causal process is
A focus on mechanisms involves a shift not substantially different from the Humean
away from abstract general laws with no model. What is required to demonstrate cau-
spatial-temporal parameters to the operation sality are still constant conjunction, asym-
of factors in specific social and political con- metry (temporal ordering is the most common
texts. Since narratives are by definition proc- kind), and non-spuriousness. As such, there
esses which transpire over time, these is no barrier to quantitative expression.
mechanisms will of necessity be tailored to Indeed, it is hard to see how causal infer-
limited temporal orders such as episodes ences could be supported in the absence of
(Tilly, 2001), conjunctures, and sequences quantitative expression. In the second case,
(Pierson, 2004). The term mechanism often the historical narrative, the logic is different.

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:13 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


80 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Here the terms of the narrative are either going in different directions, depending on
particular (not instances of general variables) the options given by a prior state, that is,
or a combination of general variables and more the idea of a stage or phase. As Becker
particular events. The historical narrative fol- (1998: 32–3) might put it, if A occurs (say I
lows the causal flow and can mix actions of graduate high school), then I could learn a
specific actors with statements about general trade, go into the army, or become a fly fish-
theoretical variables (Abbott, 2001: 142). ing guide in the Rockies in the following
Specific mechanisms and historical detail are years. This agentic, or case-oriented view,
filled in to supply narrative smoothness and gives us a different perspective than the vari-
coherence without much attention to the able-centered view of the world where prob-
ontological status of the connections. There ability transition matrices and Markov
are few formal models of the structure of processes might describe the life courses of
explanation outside of the Hempel (1965) or large numbers of individuals.
Nagel (1961) variety.10 Instead, practitioners Second, there is nothing inherently qualita-
of the historical narrative appeal to more tive about mechanism and mechanism-based
intuitive and everyday standards such as explanation. We have seen (or I have tried to
‘does the story make sense?’, ‘is it followa- show) that a mechanism can operate as a spe-
ble?’, and ‘can one understand how later cial kind of variable, one with an in-between
events flowed out of prior ones?’ location. As such, mechanisms can be used to
With all the talk of history, we may have to produce correlation and regression coeffi-
remind ourselves that this is a chapter about cients in the normal ways. As a result, a static,
comparative politics. Are not comparative cross-sectional account based on a large
and historical approaches usually alternatives sample can be enriched by stretching out the
to one another? My underlying assumption is time period and examining the process, that is,
that the answer to this question is no, and that the way the variables relate over time.
much of the power of small-N studies in Third, mechanism-based accounts become
comparative politics lies in teasing out the qualitative when the terms in the account are
temporal structure of single cases or small-N particular, that is, when they are proper names.
comparisons. Research in comparative poli- Since these terms do not refer to properties
tics does not imply the absence of history, which vary (increase or decrease), they cannot
especially in small-N settings. I point to the be quantified. Still, coherent stories can be told
work of Pierson (2004); Collier and Collier incorporating idiosyncratic terms and actions
(1991); Moore (1966); and Luebbert (1991) of individuals. The worth and meaning of a nar-
as examples of comparative research that is rative account is not exhausted by a descriptive
sensitive to the temporal dimension. summary of the terms in the story. The assas-
What are some of the implications of this sination of the Archduke Ferdinand by Gavrilo
analysis of the quantitative theoretical narra- Princip could be understood as the action of a
tive and the qualitative historical narrative? Serbian nationalist (agent of a frustrated nation)
First, it makes less sense to think of a dichot- or as a catalyst in a tragic play (unintended
omy between qualitative and quantitative consequences, the war no one wanted).
approaches, and more to accept a continuum Strangely absent from most accounts of World
running from the abstract language of varia- War I are references to villains, victims, and
bles to completely idiosyncratic stories which heroes. In the qualitative account, much more
have no generalizability. Variable-based depends on meaning than on correlations and
accounts are quantifiable in principle while regressions. And the semiotic glue is provided
particularistic stories are not. In the middle by the mechanisms in the story.
we can think of contingent theories, not so Fourth, and finally, there are opportunities
much as probabilistic theories but rather as where the two approaches can be comple-
situations described by the possibility of mentary. As Mahoney (2007: 132) and

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:14 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


IS THERE A QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DIVIDE IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS? 81

Sambanis (2003: 2) forcefully argue, there demonstration of the link between cause and effect
are numerous studies in which a macro is concerned. Instead of demonstrating a pattern of
covariance, the absence of feedback (no endogene-
(large-N) correlation holds, but where the ity), and the absence of symptomatic covariation due
process by which the outcome occurred is to confounding influences (perhaps a third variable
not the one specified by the theory. This causing both X and Y, with these two variables
points to a place where quantitative and showing symptomatic correlation), the attention of
qualitative approaches can be helpful to one the analyst turns toward internal relations and dis-
covery of ‘the nature of things’.
another. The quantitative approach can be 4. I use the term ‘factor’ advisedly here, since the
responsible for establishing the correlations; logical status of mechanism is controversial. If a
the qualitative process approach (either theo- mechanism is really a variable taking up a particular
retical or historical narrative) can examine position between background facts and outcomes,
the pathways to see if they conform to the then it is easy to assimilate mechanistic accounts into
the standard view of causality. The term ‘factor’ allows
theory. Perhaps a single outcome, say an us to keep the logical status of mechanism open.
advanced welfare state or a democratic peace, 5. See Braumoeller (2003) for an attempt to quan-
can be achieved via a number of different tify complex conjunctural phenomena.
causal paths. If so, a judicious mix of qualita- 6. By Becker, see especially Tricks of the Trade
tive and quantitative approaches would be (1998) and ‘Cases, causes, conjunctures, stories, and
imagery’ in Ragin and Becker, What is a Case?
best equipped to demonstrate that ‘why?’ and (1992).
‘how?’ are different questions that connect at 7. This does not mean that the terms in the his-
a higher level. torical narrative are completely idiosyncratic. I will
return to this point later.
8. The argument about microcorrelation in narra-
tive history is analogous to the posited need for
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT microfoundations in rational choice theory. In both
cases, there is a perceived gap between a back-
ground condition (macroincentives and background
I am indebted to John Gerring for several of causes) and some observable outcome. The outcome
his articles on causality and mechanism, par- is not explainable on the basis of macro data. What
ticularly Gerring (2006). I am also grateful is needed is the information that comes from the
for his ongoing conversations with me on individual and his choices or from the chain of events
that lead up to, and in a sense, cause the outcome.
these subjects. I am also grateful for a semi-
9. Narrative irrelevance would have to be estab-
nar organized by my colleague Aseem lished on the basis of the absence of smooth connec-
Prakash in which two of my colleagues – tions among events in the story. If a term in the
Margaret Levi and Susan Whiting – served as narrative overlapped with others in meaningless
critical and helpful discussants. ways, if it created sequences that did not make
sense, or if it enlarged the discontinuities rather than
minimized them, it would be difficult to justify inclu-
sion.
10. There are attempts at formal models by
NOTES Roberts (1996), especially chapter 2 ‘The Explanatory
Power of Colligation’; by Danto (1985); and by
1. While there is no logically necessary reason why Stinchcombe (1968).
verbal expression, detailed case studies and avoid-
ance of statistical relationships have to come
together, in this chapter I combine them to drama-
tize the differences between qualitative and quanti-
tative research. In practice, quite often researchers REFERENCES
combine statistical analysis with detailed analysis of
single cases.
2. For an extended treatment of this subject, and
Abbott, A. (2001) Time matters: On theory and
a careful comparison of the covariance and mecha- method. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
nismic approaches to causality, see Gerring (2006). Press.
3. This formulation would seem to remove causal- Alker, H.R., Jr. (1987) ‘Fairy tales, tragedies and
ity from the empirical realm, at least insofar as world histories’, Behaviormetrika, 21: 1–28.

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:15 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


82 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Bates, R.H., Greif, A., Levi, M., Rosenthal, J.-L. Gerring, J. (2006, May) The mechamismic
and Weingast, B. R. (1998) Analytic worldview: Unpacking the box. Manuscript
Narratives. NJ: Princeton University Press. (pp. 1–19) Boston University.
Becker, H.S. (1992) ‘Cases, causes, conjunc- Harré, R. (1972) The philosophies of science:
tures, stories, and imagery’, in C.C. Ragin An introductory survey. Oxford: Oxford
and H.S. Becker (eds), What is a Case? University Press.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Hedstrom, P. and Swedberg, R. (eds) (1998)
pp. 205–216. Social mechanisms: An analytical approach
Becker, H.S. (1998) Tricks of the trade. Chicago, to social theory. Cambridge: Cambridge
IL: University of Chicago Press. University Press.
Blalock, H.M., Jr. (1961) Causal inference in Hempel, C.G. (1965) Aspects of scientific
nonexperimental research. Chapel Hill, NC: explanation and other essays in the philoso-
University of North Carolina Press. phy of science. New York: Free Press.
Boudon, R. (1998) ‘Social mechanisms without Hume, D. (1748/1955) An inquiry concerning
black boxes’, in P. Hedstrom and R. Swedberg human understanding. USA: Liberal Arts
(eds), Social Mechanisms. Cambridge: Press.
Cambridge University Press, pp. 172–203. Lakoff, G. (2003, March 18) Metaphor and
Braumoeller, B.F. (2003) ‘Causal complexity war, again. Alter Net. Retrieved February 4,
and the study of politics’, Political Analysis, 2008, from http://www.alternet.org/
3 (3): 209–233. story/15414.
Bunge, M. (1997) ‘Mechanism and explana- Lakoff, G. and Johnson, M. (1980) Metaphors
tion’, Philosophy of the Social Sciences, we live by. IL: University of Chicago Press.
27 (4): 410–65. Lebow, R.N. (2000–2001) ‘Contingency,
Collier, R. B. and Collier, D. (1991) Shaping the catalysts, and international system change’,
political arena: Critical junctures, the labor Political Science Quarterly, 115 (4):
movement, and regime dynamics in Latin 591–616.
America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Lebow, R.N. (2003) ‘A data set named desire: a
Press. reply to William R. Thompson’, International
Coppedge, M. (1999) ‘Thickening thin con- Studies Quarterly, 47 (4): 475–478.
cepts and theories; Combining large n and Louch, A.R. (1969) ‘History as narrative’, History
small n in comparative politics’, Comparative and Theory, 8 (1): 54–70.
Politics, 31 (4): 465–476. Luebbert, G.M. (1991) Liberalism, fascism, or
Cornelisen, A. (1976) Women of the shadows. social democracy: Social classes and the
Boston: Little, Brown. political origins of regimes in interwar
Danto, A. C. (1985) Narration and knowledge. Europe. New York: Oxford University Press.
New York: Columbia University Press. Mahoney, J. (2001) ‘Beyond correlational anal-
Elster, J. (1989) Nuts and bolts for the social ysis: Recent innovations in theory and
sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University method’, Sociological Forum, 16 (3):
Press. 575–93.
Elster, J. (1998) ‘A plea for mechanisms’, in Mahoney, J. (2007) ‘Qualitative methodology
P. Hedstrom and R. Swedberg (eds), Social and comparative politics’, Comparative
mechanisms: An analytical approach to social Political Studies, 40 (2): 122–144.
theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Moore, B. (1966) Social origins of dictatorship
Press, pp. 45–73. and democracy: Lord and peasant in the
Gans, H.J. (1982) The urban villagers: Groups making of the modern world. Boston: Beacon
and class in the life of Italian–Americans. Press.
New York: Free Press. Nagel, E. (1961) The structure of science:
George, A.L., and Bennett, A. (2005) Case Problems in the logic of scientific explana-
studies and theory development in the social tion. New York: Harcourt Brace.
sciences. Cambridge: MIT Press. Pierson, P. (2004) Politics in Time. Princeton,
Gerring, J. (2005) ‘Causation: A unified frame- N.J.: Princeton University Press
work for the social sciences’, Journal of Pierson, P. (2007) ‘The costs of marginalization:
Theoretical Politics, 17 (2): 163–98. Qualitative methods in the study of American

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:16 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


IS THERE A QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DIVIDE IN COMPARATIVE POLITICS? 83

politics’, Comparative Political Studies, 40 (2): Simon, H.A. (1957b) ‘Spurious correlation: a
145–169. causal interpretation’, in Models of man,
Ragin, C.C. (1987) The comparative method. social and rational. New York: John Wiley,
Berkeley: University of California Press. pp. 37–49
Ragin, C.C. (2000) Fuzzy set social science. Stinchcombe, A.L. (1968) Constructing social
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. theories. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
Ragin, C.C., and Becker, H.S. (eds), (1992) Press.
What is a Case? Cambridge: Cambridge Stinchcombe, A.L. (1991) ‘The conditions of
University Press. fruitfulness of theorizing about mechanisms
Roberts, C. (1996) The logic of historical expla- in social science’, Philosophy of the Social
nation. College Park: Pennsylvania State Sciences, 21 (3): 367–88.
University Press. Stolper, W.F. and Samuelson, P.A. (1941)
Rogowski, R. (1989) Commerce and coalitions: ‘Protection and real wages’, Review of
How trade affects domestic political align- Economic Studies, 9 (1): 58–73.
ments. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Thompson, W.R. (2003) ‘A streetcar named
Press. Sarajevo: Catalysts, multiple causal chains,
Sambanis, N. (2003) Using case studies to and rivalry structures’, International Studies
expand the theory of civil war (Conflict Quarterly, 47 (4): 453–474.
prevention and reconstruction working Tilly, C. (1997) ‘Means and ends of compari-
papers, no. 5: 1–62) Washington, DC: Social son in macrosociology’, Comparative Social
Development Department, World Bank. Research, 16 (1): 43–53.
Seawright, J. (2005) ‘Qualitative comparative Tilly, C. (2001) ‘Mechanisms in political proc-
analysis vis-à-vis regression’, Studies in esses’, Annual Review of Political Science, 4:
Comparative International Development, 40 21–41.
(1): 3–26. Willis, P.E. (1981) Learning to labor: How work-
Simon, H.A. (1957a) ‘Causal ordering and ing class kids get working class jobs. New
identifiability’, in Models of man, social and York: Columbia University Press.
rational. New York: John Wiley, pp. 10–36.

9781412919760_Chap04.indd Sec1:17 3/11/2009 3:32:49 PM


5
Establishing Equivalence
Jan W. van Deth

INTRODUCTION intentions are misinterpreted and goals are


seldom reached.
An Austrian businessman embarrassed his With the burgeoning of comparative
French colleagues by insisting on concluding research in the last few decades, contexts
their negotiations before they went to dinner. increasingly attracted attention. Many com-
An Italian in Sweden could not find a reli- parativists started their career by studying
gious association that would provide him such topics as voting behaviour, marriage
with social support and was sent to the town patterns, or religious norms in a single con-
hall to fill out a number of forms. A French text, and their need for comparisons is usu-
politician appeared in a crisp white dress on ally based on the assumption that similar
the Chinese Wall and did not know that white phenomena can be found in other groups,
indicates grief and mourning in that part of cultures, regions, or countries. The basic
Asia. A Dutch couple decided to spend much design of comparative research is simple and
money on a ‘deftig’ meal to celebrate their straightforward. In order to reach insights not
wedding anniversary in a German sea resort attainable in single-case studies, one exam-
and were very disappointed to be served a ines either the same phenomena in different
very simple farmer’s meal. An American contexts or different phenomena in similar
fundraiser visited several European cities contexts (cf., Przeworski and Teune, 1970:
only to find out that in many languages no 31–46). For many purposes, a comparative
translation of the word ‘fundraising’ exists. approach is preferred to single-observation
This list of misunderstandings, embarrass- studies and reasoning by analogy,1 although
ments, and confusions can be easily made case studies clearly have their own merits
longer. They all share the basic pattern that and advantages (cf., Feagin et al., 1991;
specific ideas and phenomena can have dif- Rueschemeyer, 2003) and strong arguments
ferent meanings in different circumstances. have been offered for so-called ‘small-N’
Finishing negotiations before dinner, approach- analyses (cf., Ebbinghaus, 2005; Hall, 2003:
ing religious organizations, wearing white 395–8; Ragin, 2004) as well as ingenious
clothes, dining in a formal environment, or strategies for middle-of-the-road positions
looking for opportunities to collect financial (cf., McKeon, 2004; Ragin, 2000; Schneider
support is generally unproblematic – it is the and Wagemann, 2006). In comparative
particular context which makes these behav- approaches, difficult questions arise once we
iours unusual or odd. As a consequence, examine the terms ‘same phenomena’ or

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:1 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


ESTABLISHING EQUIVALENCE 85

‘similar contexts’ somewhat closer. Is a chapter approaches are emphasized that can
Swedish community agency for social caring be applied by comparativists, and that the
‘the same’ as a religious social association in epistemological complications of ‘travelling’
Italy because they perform similar tasks? Is theories are not a major concern here.
collecting financial support in a German vil-
lage ‘the same’ as ‘fundraising’ in Scotland
although the last phrase cannot even be trans-
lated into German? When then, is a phenom- TYPES OF EQUIVALENCE
enon ‘the same’ in different contexts, or is it
allowed to speak of ‘similar’ contexts?
Identity, equivalence, bias
Ironically, the very core of the compara-
tive approach – to trace differences and simi- The problem of equivalence is not restricted
larities by looking at two or more objects, or to the use of particular terms or concepts in
phenomena – seems to lead directly to a different contexts. In fact the problem is evi-
number of nasty complications. If we use dent in each type of comparative research
only culture- or nation-specific terms and irrespective of the particular field, irrespec-
concepts, it will be difficult to make any tive of the particular methodology applied
cross-cultural or cross-national comparisons and irrespective of the phase of the compara-
at all. But if we simply use identical concepts tive research process considered. It is this
for various settings, we are unlikely to obtain almost universal relevance that gives the
appropriate information about national or debate about equivalence its prominent
culture-bound phenomena. This dilemma is a status.
more restrictive formulation of the funda- Problems of equivalence in comparative
mental problem of comparative research in research become clear when we start with the
finding generalizations, whereas the ‘unique- notion of identical terms or concepts. Two
ness’ of every setting is immediately appar- things are considered to be identical when
ent and historic and idiographic factors they agree or are exactly the same in every
usually cannot be neglected. The heart of the detail or are similar in appearance. The term
problem is that in comparative research ‘... identity, however, refers to absolute same-
reality seems to demand a configurative ness or equality of two values. Ever since the
approach; generalizability seems to demand development of traditional logic in the Middle
a more analytical approach’ (Verba, 1967: Ages, the Principle of Identity (‘A = A’;
117). How then, are we to sail between the ‘Whatever is, is’) has been a cornerstone of
Scylla of losing national or cultural validity reasoning. The common version of the idea
by looking for generalizations, and the of identity states that two things are identical
Charibdis of endangering cross-cultural or when they share all their qualities: that is
cross-national comparability by focusing on when all of their properties are the same. In
specific features only? other words, two objects, or phenomena are
In this chapter the problems of establish- identical if for every class, one object belongs
ing equivalence in comparative research are to the class if, and only if, the other does.2
discussed. The next section presents a brief Leibniz used this line of reasoning to formu-
overview of several aspects of identity and late an important conclusion based on a non-
equivalence as well as an overview of several trivial version of the so-called principle of
types of equivalence and bias. The third sec- Identity of Indiscernibles (‘principium iden-
tion addresses the practical complications of titatis indiscernibilium’). If two objects differ
studying similar phenomena in different set- in some intrinsic, non-relational property,
tings and offers options for empirical research reasoned Leibniz, they must be two. The
by focusing on functional equivalence. paradoxical nature of the identity problem
This implies that in the practical part of this has been formulated by Wittgenstein

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:2 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


86 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

(1921/1963) succinctly and conclusively: important aspect is the restriction of similarity


‘Roughly speaking, to say of two things that to one or more specifically defined properties.
they are identical is nonsense, and to say of We are willing to accept conclusions about the
one thing that it is identical with itself is to say role of clearly differently financed voluntary
nothing at all’ (p. 83, emphasis in original). associations in different cities if these organiza-
Comparative research, then, must start tions manage to hold similar positions in com-
from the idea that even similar phenomena or munal networks for many decades. Likewise,
objects are never identical. The question is we are willing to assess the different purchas-
whether we can restrict the differences ing powers of local currencies if we can be sure
between two phenomena or objects to intrin- that the appearance and taste of hamburgers are
sic, non-relational properties irrelevant to the ‘identical’ in various countries. It is the similar-
goal of our research. For instance, the fact ity of relevant properties of different phenom-
that Scottish and German voluntary associa- ena or objects that lies at the centre of the idea
tions differ in the way they acquire financial of equivalence in comparative research.
resources does not have to bother us in com- Mainly based on psychological research
parative studies on the role of these organiza- Van de Vijver and Leung (1997; Harkness
tions in community politics. Another example et al., 2003: 13–15; Van de Vijver, 2003a)
concerns the field of currencies and exchange propose to stress a lack of equivalence to char-
rates. In order to see whether exchange rates acterize the problematic aspects of compari-
are ‘correct’, one can use the so-called sons in cross-cultural research. In this way, the
Hamburger Standard or Big Mac Currency. complications attached to the idea of equiva-
It is based on the idea that a Big Mac ham- lence become much clearer than by focusing
burger is made according to the same recipe on the idea itself, and, as a consequence, strat-
in some 80 countries. The purchasing-power egies to deal with non-equivalence can be
parity of the product can be computed by developed more systematically and applied
comparing its price in local currency to its more efficiently. In order to search for the
price in dollars in the US. The result is an causes of equivalence problems, the term bias
assessment of the under- or over-valuation of is introduced defined as ‘... the presence of
the local currency. This assessment is based nuisance factors that challenge the compara-
on the fact that all disturbing or irrelevant bility of scores across cultural groups’ (Van de
factors are controlled for (ingredients, weight, Vijver, 2003a: 144; cf., Van de Vijver, 1998:
production, sales conditions, etc.), while the 43). Obviously, bias and equivalence are
relevant property (local value) varies across closely related, but they are distinct concepts
nations.3 In other words, comparisons become focusing the attention on the sources of the
meaningful if one distinguishes between rel- problems of comparability on the one hand,
evant and irrelevant properties. and the problems as such on the other. In other
The search for (ir)relevant properties of dis- words: if we can locate and analyze the bias in
tinct phenomena or objects suggests a move our concepts and indicators, appropriate pro-
from the idea of identity towards that of equiva- cedures can be developed and applied to
lence. The concept of equivalence appears in establish equivalence. Since using the concept
fields as divergent as logic, informatics, phys- bias directly leads to possible causes of equiv-
ics, psychology, mathematics, electronics, alence problems, the two terms are used here.
finance, and civil and criminal law. Although
the term has specific meanings in each disci-
pline, broadly speaking we refer to the equiva- Types of bias and equivalence
lence of two objects or phenomena if they have
the same value, importance, use, function, or The concepts of equivalence and bias offer the
result. Although the etymological origin of the opportunity to depict the specific problems
term points in the direction of similarities,4 the and solutions at each phase of comparative

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:3 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


ESTABLISHING EQUIVALENCE 87

research processes. Especially in the field of the respective strategies to handle them, three
cross-cultural and cross-national survey categorizations are used here. First, equiva-
methods interest for these problems has been lence problems can be discerned on the basis
rising rapidly in the last two decades (cf., of the source of the complications. In his
Braun, 2006; Harkness, 1998; Hoffmeyer- elaboration of the different types of bias Van
Zlotnik and Harkness, 2005; Hoffmeyer- de Vijver (2003a: 145–8) proposes to distin-
Zlotnik and Wolf, 2003a; van Deth, 1998). In guish between three main sources of bias:
this area a number of large scale comparative construct bias (occurs when a construct is not
projects have been successfully carried out identical across groups), method bias (occurs
and many strategies to deal with comparabil- when methods applied are not identical
ity and validity are based on the experiences across groups), and item bias (occurs when
accumulated here.5 Yet the concepts and ter- item measures do not have the same average
minology developed in survey research can across groups). Method bias is further speci-
easily be generalized and transferred to appli- fied as sample bias, instrument bias, and
cations of other social science methods. administration bias. This classification of
Equivalence problems usually become three main possible sources of bias and the
apparent as translation problems at the outset. subdivision of the second category are used
Even seemingly straightforward translations here as a first step to distinguish equivalence
of single words provide complications due to problems and the respective strategies to
different meanings of the words in different handle them.
contexts. As mentioned, no German word A second distinction is based on the ques-
exists for the English term ‘fundraising’. tion whether the problems are dealt with in
Similarly, the term ‘Bürgerinitiative’ is advance or that procedures are developed to
closely related to, but certainly not identical handle existing information (cf. Ehling, 2003;
with, the Dutch phrase ‘inspraak’. But even if Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and Harkness, 2005). In
the translation appears to be unproblematic, case of ex-ante strategies, concepts and pro-
phrases can have very different meanings. A cedures are developed to maximize chances
German prosecutor was cited by an American that the final measures will be equivalent.
newspaper after he had called a Holocaust The precautions are considered before the
denier a ‘rat catcher’. This is a perfect trans- actual collection of data starts and can
lation of the German word ‘Rattenfänger’ include, for example, guidelines for transla-
that the prosecutor had used, but fails to tions or detailed instructions on how to con-
make clear that the accused Nazi defender struct an index. Ex-post strategies, on the
was not a specialized animal exterminator, other hand, focus on the establishment of
but somebody who misled his followers with equivalence after the data have been col-
propaganda and humbug. The English lan- lected and usually contain such strategies as,
guage depiction would be a ‘pied piper’. For for example, weighting and selecting of
identifying errors in translations, a number of cases or an increase of the level of abstrac-
procedures are available now.6 tion of the concepts used. Ex-post strategies
Although translations in comparative are typically part of secondary analyses
research are vital, we will not discuss them research strategies (cf. van Deth, 2003:
here as a separate strategy to deal with 302–3) and include corrections and selection
equivalence problems. Instead, we will of available information.
emphasize the complications of actual com- Partly overlapping with ex-ante and ex-
parative research confronted with the prob- post characterisations is the third distinction
lem of equivalence. Several proposals have between input and output harmonization (cf.
been presented to characterize equivalence Ehling, 2003; Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and
problems systematically. In order to summa- Harkness, 2005; Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and
rize the various types of these problems and Wolf, 2003b). Input harmonization requires

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:4 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


88 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

the specification of common concepts and output harmonization strategies by specify-


procedures that have to be used in each group ing, for instance, the data collection and
in similar ways. Context-specific deviations translation procedures in detail (input harmo-
from these prescriptions are only permissible nization) and urging for the use of adequate
when they are indispensable. Equivalence of measures for the level of education in each
the final measures is obtained on the basis of country (output harmonization).
the fact that common concepts and proce- The three categorizations can be combined
dures have been defined for each group from to characterize the various strategies to handle
the outset. From this characterization it is equivalence problems. The rows in Table 5.1
clear that input harmonization can only be are defined by the five distinct sources of
part of ex-ante strategies. Output harmoniza- bias as proposed by Van de Vijver and Lueng
tion focuses on the common aim to obtain (1997), whereas the columns distinguish
equivalent measures by specifying the goals between ex-ante and ex-post strategies.
to be reached and by offering the opportunity Furthermore, ex-ante strategies can be
to apply appropriate concepts and procedures divided into input and output harmonization.
for each group separately. Usually, context- In this way, a total of 15 different types of
specific deviations are required here in order bias and equivalence in comparative research
to establish equivalence. Output harmoniza- can be discerned. Ex-ante input harmoniza-
tion can be included in both ex-ante and in tion strategies all aim at establishing equiva-
ex-post strategies. Large scale international lence by defining concepts and prescribing
projects normally use a mixture of input and procedures to be implemented. For instance,

Table 5.1 Different types of equivalence problems and strategies


Ex-ante strategies Ex-post strategies
Input harmonization Output harmonization Output harmonization
Construct bias Define concepts Specify concepts Specify and correct concepts
– translation procedures – intercultural teams – reassessment/reinterpretation
– intercultural teams – ‘conceptual stretching’
Method bias Sample Define population and Specify sample Specify and correct sample
bias sample – instructions for sampling – weighting procedures
– population definition for and quotas – selection procedures
each group
Instrument Define instruments Specify instruments Specify and correct instruments
bias – concept definition – specification of dimensions, – index construction
structure, or aspects – dimensional analyses; scaling
Adminis- Define administration Specify administration rules Specify and correct
tration rules – specification of goals to be administration rules
bias – procedures for attained – weighting procedures
organization of – selection procedures
fieldwork
Item bias Define items Specify items Specify and correct items
– translation procedures – specification of indicators – psychometric scaling
– intercultural teams techniques
– linguistic analyses

Search for specific Search for common Establish common


measures: measures: measures:
Definition and rules Specification Correction

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:5 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


ESTABLISHING EQUIVALENCE 89

a clear definition of the concepts to be used orientations, or social mobility ex-ante strat-
and unambiguous rules for the translation egies have become increasingly important.
process can reduce construct bias and item Furthermore, many international projects
bias from the very beginning. In a similar such as the European Social Survey have
way, sample bias can be reduced if a detailed made high-quality data available that can be
description of the sampling procedures to be used to reassess equivalence systematically.
applied is available. Usually, ex-ante input Detailed instructions for both input and
harmonization strategies are based on the output harmonization procedures are availa-
idea of convergence: the development of a ble now (cf. Ehling, 2003; Harkness,
measure for each group according to specific 1999; Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and Wolf, 2003b;
rules will finally result in an equivalent Lynn, 2001; Van de Vijver, 2003a: 149–52).
measure for the set of groups. However, even the strict implementation of
Whereas the common characteristic of ex- all these instructions does not guarantee that
ante input harmonization strategies is that the final constructs are equivalent. Here, too,
definitions and specifications of rules are of the proof of the pudding is in the eating: that
imminent importance, ex-ante output harmo- is, equivalence can only be assessed on the
nization strategies focus on common meas- basis of empirical information. For that
ures and their conceptual specifications for reason, ex-post strategies to reduce bias and
each group from the very beginning. In this to establish equivalence will be further elabo-
approach, for instance sample bias can be rated here.7
reduced by specifying the population to be
included in the study clearly and leaving it to
experts to develop appropriate sampling pro-
cedures to reach these populations in differ- EX-POST EQUIVALENCE STRATEGIES
ent settings (cf. Häder and Gabler, 2003:
119). Another example is provided by the use Ex-post equivalence strategies can be speci-
of a common concept that is operationalized fied by looking at the main sources of poten-
in different ways for different groups by tial bias: construct bias, method bias, and
intercultural teams of researchers in order to item bias. Construct bias seems to be a dis-
reduce construct bias. tinct category here, while the border line
The final group of strategies distinguished between method bias – especially instrument
consists of ex-post output harmonization bias – and item bias is not always easy to
approaches. Here the question is irrelevant draw when dealing with ex-post approaches.
whether the information available is obtained
by using ex-ante input or ex-ante output pro-
cedures – or by using no procedure at all. Construct bias and
Ex-post strategies try to establish equiva-
construct equivalence
lence by selecting and correcting informa-
tion. For example, instrument bias (and item As every child knows, apples and pears can
bias) can be reduced by searching for a set of be easily compared if they are considered to
items that can be used to construct an appro- be specimen of ‘fruit’. In a similar way,
priate index for each group. As in the case of Catholic and Muslim practices can be com-
ex-ante output harmonization strategies, ex- pared as being particular instances of the
post strategies presume that a clear-cut speci- more general concept ‘religious behaviour’.
fication of the concept to be measured is In this way, a reinterpretation or reassess-
available. ment of available information can be used to
With the development of teams of experts establish construct equivalence: not the spe-
from several countries to study such topics cific measures or indicators (apples, Catholic
as voting behaviour, party platforms, value prayers), but the more abstract concepts

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:6 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


90 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

(fruit, religion) are equivalent. Information, ignoring specific properties and we accept
then, does not have to be similar at the opera- two constructs to be equivalent exactly
tional level as long as we succeed in construct- because these properties are ignored. As
ing measures indicating similar concepts at a mentioned, this strategy requires a high level
higher level of abstraction. Construct equiva- of auxiliary information about the systems
lence is established by eliminating features being compared in order to avoid the falla-
that are relevant for specific groups only. cies of ‘conceptual stretching’, ‘pseudo
This line of reasoning suggests a direct equivalence’, or simply shifting the problem
way of dealing with equivalence problems from one level to another. Yet it is clear that
among different groups: increase the level of the explicit neglect of specific characteristics
abstraction until group-specific differences certainly increases the opportunities for com-
become irrelevant and can be ignored. This parative research by improving construct
strategy requires extensive auxiliary informa- equivalence.
tion about the settings being compared as
well as a sophisticated way of developing
and demarcating constructs. Although the Sample bias and
intelligent use of auxiliary information is a
sample equivalence
conditio sine qua non for every type of com-
parative research and although a high level of Sample bias exists when the information
abstraction is always desirable from a theo- available is obtained from groups that differ in
retical point of view, the risks involved in relevant aspects. For instance, cross-national
increasing the level of abstraction are evi- survey research usually focuses on sampling
dent. First, we risk the fallacy so nicely pre- ‘inhabitants of age 15 and higher’. Even if
sented by Sartori (1970, 1994) that concepts the resulting samples are evidently representa-
easily can be ‘stretched’ in such a way that tive of the populations defined accordingly,
they lose virtually all of their analytical and it is not appropriate to use these samples for
heuristic power.8 If, for instance, the concept a comparison of, for instance, ‘eligible voters’
‘constitutional states’ is stretched to ‘any since voting requirements (minimum age,
state form’, we have no way of testing the citizenship, etc.) vary between countries. In a
proposition ‘constitutions obstruct tyranny’. similar way, a comparison of welfare pay-
The second risk in increasing the level of ments in various countries can be clearly
abstraction is, of course, the neglect of ‘real’ biased if the information available is restricted
differences and the establishment of ‘pseudo to statistics made available by the OECD.10
equivalence’. For example, an explanation of The OECD provides high-quality informa-
the role of ‘social associations’ in Italy and tion for the major industrial countries –
Sweden can be highly misleading if the term limiting any comparison to this specific
‘associations’ is not differentiated between group of countries. Especially, experiences
the two countries. Finally, it is clear that with multiple sampling frames in interna-
increasing the level of abstraction could tional projects have stimulated the attention
come down to nothing more than a move of for the problems of sample equivalence
the equivalence problem from one level to (cf. Lynn et al., 2004).
another. Not much is gained if we have to Ex-post strategies to deal with sample bias
assess the equivalence of the concept ‘social consist, first of all, of selection procedures. If
support’ instead of that of the stimulus ‘being the minimum age to be eligible to cast a vote
a member of an association’.9 is 18 years in one country and 21 in another,
By increasing the level of abstraction of our the non-eligible voters in each country can be
concepts irrelevant or group-specific proper- easily deleted in order to establish sample
ties are removed from our analyses. In other equivalence. Selection procedures, however,
words, we establish construct equivalence by can also include extensions of the information

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:7 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


ESTABLISHING EQUIVALENCE 91

available. Adding information about welfare equivalent if they fit in similar ways in simi-
payments in several central European coun- lar structures within each groups. This
tries and restricting the information available approach stresses the position of, or the func-
from the OECD to the European member tion of, a concept in specific structures and is
states of this organization, results in a dataset usually called functional equivalence.11
that enables a comparison of welfare state Strategies based on the idea of functional
payments across Europe and avoids the limi- equivalence are especially suitable to deal
tation of analyzing developed European with instrument bias and item bias.
countries only. An elaborate example of Functional equivalence stresses the relevance
reducing sample bias is presented by Schäfer of relationships instead of intrinsic properties of
(2006) who compares political orientations concepts. Especially in system theories as pro-
among ‘young adolescents’ in a number of posed by Luhmann (1970), relationships pro-
German youth studies – each of which using vide the core and backbone of the argument.
a different definition of the exact age group In this perspective, any comparison of systems
questioned. will be confronted by the question of identity
A second strategy to deal with sample bias and functional equivalence:
is to weight the samples in order to obtain a
Every comparison of a system presupposes a pre-
more representative image of the statistical ceding theoretical analysis of the systems involved,
populations (cf. Häder and Gabler, 2003: which clarifies its relational problem and possible
123–4). By now, weighting procedures are solutions. Under these circumstances the compari-
common practice in survey research and son yields several variants of solutions for one and
the same relational problem. In this way the
most datasets include weight coefficients to
hypothesis of its functional equivalence is verified.
correct the under- and overrepresentation of The question why single systems opt for different
specific groups. Obviously, weighting proce- variants is then converted into concrete historical
dures correct the samples for specific fea- research, which always presupposes the determi-
tures (usually groups defined according to nation of equivalences in case it should not be
limited to the detection of facts only. (Luhmann,
their level of education, sex, and age), and
1970:25)
the impact of these corrections on the rele-
vant variables remain unclear frequently. Although very critical of traditional
As these examples of selection and weight- (American) functionalism, Luhmann’s analy-
ing strategies make clear, sample bias shares ses show the opportunities for using the idea
an important characteristic with all other of functional equivalence in comparative
ex-post equivalence strategies: meaningful research. His suggestion to study the histori-
corrections can be implied only if an unam- cal development of existing systems helps us
biguous specification of the groups to be answer the question of why different systems
compared is available. opt for different solutions. These measures
do not have to belong to a common set of
measures or indicators but can be attuned to
Instrument bias, item bias, and the specific circumstances in each system.12
It is this ‘belonging’ to a specific part of a
functional equivalence
system which makes concepts equivalent in
In order to examine the equivalence of con- comparative research. This suggestion can be
cepts systematically specific ex-post proce- rephrased as a general plea to rely on inter-
dures have been developed. Many of these pretations (or hypotheses) and auxiliary
procedures rely on the idea of an indissoluble information in the course of assessing the
connection between the meaning of particu- equivalence of (different) concepts or indica-
lar concepts, on the one hand, and their rela- tors used in different settings.
tionships with other concepts, on the other. Functional equivalence refers to the
Two concepts, then, are considered to be requirement that concepts should be related

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:8 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


92 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

to other concepts in other settings in more or (and dealing with instrument bias) or in the
less the same way. It is based on the notion that form of relating different items to each other
comparability ‘... cannot be conceived as an in various settings (and dealing with item
attribute of elements but as an attribute of the bias). The concept under consideration has to
elements’ relationships to a more general point be integrated into some structure (pattern,
of reference’ (Nießen, 1982: 86, emphasis in model, network, theory), and equivalence is
original). Stated in this way, functional equiva- established by assessing the degree to which
lence has much in common with reasoning by these similar concepts have the same position
analogy. An analogy is based on the recognition or play the same role within these structures.
or suggestion of similarity between two objects In empirical-analytical approaches in com-
or two sets of objects. However, while analo- parative research, the idea of functional
gies are based on similar relationships between equivalence is operationalized as instrument
different objects (i.e., A:B therefore C:D), func- validity: that is, as the satisfactory perform-
tional equivalence refers to similar relation- ance of indicators within some theoretical
ships between similar objects in different and operational context to which they refer.
settings (i.e., A[i]:B[i] therefore A[j]:B[j]). It is From this depiction of functional equiva-
this last type of similarity between the theoreti- lence it is clear that relationships (structures)
cal or operational contexts ([i] and [j]) which are at the centre of the problem of compara-
provides clues for answering the question about bility. Apparently, by developing this strategy
which properties are considered relevant in our we return immediately to the position taken
comparisons. by Przeworski and Teune (1970): that the
The seminal work of Przeworski and Teune ultimate test of concepts and instruments is
(1966; 1970) contains a precise depiction of not to be found in a meticulous search for
the basic structure of comparative analyses identical measures, but in ‘... the similarity of
as well as a clear definition of the equiva- the structure of indicators … Equivalence is
lence concept based on the idea that infer- a matter of inference, not of direct observa-
ence should guide attempts to solve the tions’ (pp. 117–18, emphasis in original).
problems. Their concept of equivalence: Sophisticated approaches to deal with this
... does not refer to observations but only to the search for structures have become available
results of inferences made from those observa- through techniques like confirmatory factor
tions, that is, the inferred measurement state- analysis or (full) structural equation models
ments. An instrument is equivalent across systems (cf. Braun, 2006; Harkness, 1998; Hoffmeyer-
to the extent that the results provided by the
instrument reliably describe with (nearly) the same
Zlotnik and Harkness, 2005; Van de Vijver,
validity a particular phenomenon in different social 2003b; Van de Vijver and Leung, 1997:
systems. Stimulus equivalence is an important 99–106). Equivalence is certainly not to be
problem only if measurement does not involve considered an intrinsic property of some
inference. (Przeworski and Teune, 1970: 108, indicator or construct, but, as Van de Vijver
emphasis in original)
and Leung (1997) put it: ‘Equivalence should
Przeworski and Teune argue within a frame- be established and cannot be assumed’ (p.
work of classical test and measurement 144, emphasis in original). And Hoffmeyer-
theory and rely heavily on the distinction Zlotnik and Wolf (2003b) phrase the same
between direct and indirect measurement. idea even more clearly for cross-national
But ‘inference’ can also be observed when comparisons: “Functional equivalence in this
we use some directly measured indicator in a respect cannot be attained by a process of
wider theoretical setting and study its rela- ‘translation’. Instead functional equivalence
tionships with other factors. Some type of can only be attained by identifying the
inference is always required in order to overall similarities between the national con-
establish equivalence, whether in the form of cepts and national structures that relate to the
constructing an instrument with a set of items background variables of interest.” (p. 391)

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:9 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


ESTABLISHING EQUIVALENCE 93

From this repeated emphasis on inference which encompass these concepts and
in assessing the degree of instrument bias measures. If we want to reduce instrument
and equivalence, three important conclusions bias and item bias, four different strategies
can be drawn about research strategies in for constructing functional equivalence are
comparative politics. First, if we wish to available based on the question whether we
establish equivalence as the functional equiv- focus on internal or external structures, on
alence of some concept by analyzing rela- the one hand, and whether we use a common
tionships in terms of underlying patterns, we set of items or specific items for each group,
must use at least two indicators for each con- on the other (cf. van Deth, 1998: 9–14). In
cept in each setting, since the minimum all four cases the logic of the strategy is
requirement for any relationship is the exist- straightforward: the equivalence of an
ence of two objects or phenomena. It is the instrument (and its containing items) is
relationship between items which will pro- based on the consistency of its structural
vide information about the equivalence of the relationships.
concepts obtained. Second, we do not have to
restrict our analyses to inferences based on a
common set of stimuli, items, or indicators. Using a common set of indicators;
Inference can be based on different stimuli,
internal consistency
items, or indicators in various settings, and
equivalence once again becomes a question If we use a common set of items, the question
of relationships. Third, if inference is stressed, is how to assess the equivalence of an instru-
we must distinguish between internal and ment based on these items. The strategy of
external ways to infer conclusions about rela- using a common set of indicators and the cri-
tional aspects of our observations or indica- terion of internal consistency is meant to
tors. Internal consistency means that the resolve this problem by analyzing the struc-
stimuli, indicators or items used should show ture among similar items in various settings.
more or less the same structure in different Sophisticated methodological applications of
environments; external consistency means this type of strategy have been proposed
that indicators are related in the same way to by Mokken (1971: 224–53); Saris and
an element not belonging to the initial set of Münnich (1995); Saris (1997); and others (cf.
indicators. For example, the question of Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and Harkness, 2005).
whether a construct like fundraising is equiv- A traditional example of this strategy is
alent in various settings has no meaning. Rokkan’s emphasis on so-called ‘second-or-
Only if we introduce relationships between der comparisons’ and its application in
two or more items to measure the collection Almond and Verba’s (1963) work on political
of financial resources of voluntary associa- culture in five countries. In that work, nations
tions (internal consistency) or linkages are compared by emphasizing patterns
between fundraising and another concept between indicators within different countries.
(external consistency) we can try to establish Even if the cross-national validity of the indi-
equivalence. These relationships can be con- cators is questionable, the results obtained
ceptualized among a common set of stimuli from the analyses of the relationships between
or indicators, but different measures can be the indicators provide the basis for accepting
used in different settings. the equivalence of the phenomena (cf. Verba,
By focusing on functional equivalence to 1969). An identical position is taken by
deal with instrument and item bias, opportuni- Inglehart in his analyses of the rise of post-
ties for comparative research are substantially materialist value orientations in 11 countries
expanded. Concepts and measures do not have in the early 1970s. He explicitly avoids
to be similar at the operational level as long as discussions about different levels of post-
we succeed in depicting similar structures materialism between the countries and

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:10 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


94 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

focuses on comparisons within given sam- level of education appear related in a similar
ples (Inglehart, 1997: 37–8). Methodologically way to the other indicators, the functional
more sophisticated examples are the use of a equivalence of the indicator for education is
multi-trait–multi-method approach in the established (Brauns et al., 2003; Treiman,
field of cross-national research on stereotype 1975; Treiman and Terrel, 1975). This exam-
effects of the characterizations of nations ple provides a clear strategy for basing
(Hunyady and Münnich, 1995) or the cross- equivalence on the idea of structural similar-
national measurement of life satisfaction ity and the use of inference. However, it also
(Saris and Scherpenzeel, 1995). Van de Vijver shows the weakness of the approach. As
and Leung (1997: 55) point to mono-trait– Müller (1997: 130) argues, the complications
multi-method approaches involving the use of establishing equivalence are simply moved
of multiple diverse measures to capture the from the concept of education to the concepts
same construct (so called ‘triangulation’). of income and occupational status and differ-
ences in the impact of background factors
may well modify the structure in different
Using a common set of indicators; countries.14
A sophisticated variant of this strategy is a
external consistency
two-step strategy transforming instruments to
As the examples of Almond and Verba, a similar level in the first phase in order to
Inglehart, and others indicate, functional perform intra-level comparisons in the second
equivalence can be established by referring phase. An example of this strategy lies in the
to relationships between the construct con- analyses of Kuechler (1991) who suggests
sidered and one or more other concepts. In using so-called ‘contingency patterns’ in his
this strategy, a similar structure in different work on political support in Western Europe.
settings is accepted as evidence of the equiv- In order to avoid the pitfalls in a comparison
alence of the concepts. This line of reasoning of the marginal distributions of survey ques-
can be found in several areas of comparative tions (like the degree of satisfaction with
research. Gabriel (1998: 46–8) evaluated dif- democracy), he relates the developments of
ferences in the degree of national pride of these marginals to the development of macro-
West European countries by looking at the economic indicators like inflation and unem-
correlations with other indicators of attach- ployment rates in different countries. In this
ment to the political system.13 In order to way, he is able to test several ideas about the
deal with both longitudinal and cross- relationships between the state of the economy
sectional comparisons, Clausen (1967) intro- and the level of mass support without relying
duced the method of ‘differential correlations’ on the assumption that the instrument applied
for establishing the equivalence of measures has the same meaning in different countries.
of voting behaviour in different sessions of In other words, the macro-economic indica-
the American Congress. tors serve as external points of reference to
The complications of analyses involving establish the equivalence of the instruments
levels of education illustrate an example used in the questionnaires.
from another area of comparative research.
Since national educational systems are very
different, a straightforward cross-national Using a non-common set of
comparison of levels of education is highly
indicators; internal consistency
problematic. An attempt to resolve these
problems uses directly-related concepts like The use of internal consistency as the central
income, occupational status, or social mobil- criterion for equivalence among a set of non-
ity and labour market chances as ‘criterion common indicators is illustrated by looking
variables’. If nation-specific measures of the at two applications of a method proposed by

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:11 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


ESTABLISHING EQUIVALENCE 95

Przeworski and Teune (1966). The so-called resulted in consistent predictions, the authors
Identity-Equivalence Method relies explicitly concluded that different questions were
on the idea that constraint among items or measuring the same dimensions (pp. 91, 93).
indicators does not imply using the same set More recently interesting proposals have
of stimuli or items in each setting. The been developed to rely more heavily on his-
method starts with the search for a core set of torical and qualitative information for com-
identical stimuli or items which provide an parative research. Locke and Thelen (1998)
anchor for evaluating the constraints of each point at the relevance of ‘national institu-
measurement instrument. The next step is to tional arrangements’ for any cross-national
add culture- or nation-specific indicators or comparison of conflicts between labour and
items in order to reduce instrument bias in a management. They suggest a strategy called
specific context. Finally, the instruments are ‘contextualized comparison’ which ‘…
applied in each setting and comparisons are self-consciously seeks to address the issue
based on the results obtained with these dis- of equivalence by searching for analytically
tinct instruments.15 equivalent phenomena – even if expressed
An example of this strategy is the con- in substantively different terms – across dif-
struction of equivalent measures for the con- ferent contexts’ (Locke and Thelen, 1998:
cept ‘political participation’. The level of 11). The various contributions presented
political participation can be measured in in the publication edited by Mahoney
several countries by constructing nation- and Rueschemeyer (2003) can be seen as
specific instruments (van Deth, 1986). On examples of this strategy of ‘contextualized
the basis of the ‘identity-equivalence method’, comparison’.
a common structure emerges in eight West
European countries. This set appears to be a
cumulative, one-dimensional scale in each
country. The next step is the search for CONCLUSION
nation-specific additions to the common
scale and the construction of non-identical, Establishing equivalence is one of the nasti-
equivalent measures. est problems facing comparativists. On the
The strategy of relying on the structure one hand, specific features of each group,
between different sets of stimuli in different culture, or nation have to be taken into
settings as a means of establishing equiva- account, because they establish the objects
lence avoids ‘conceptual stretching’ as well and phenomena that lead to the research
as moving the problem of equivalence from interests and curiosity in the first place. On
one area to another. In this way, a fruitful the other hand, meaningful comparisons can
strategy is obtained to deal with instrument only be carried out if the objects or phenom-
bias and item bias in comparative research. ena have at least one feature in common.
Phrased in this way, it is clear that establish-
ing equivalence is at the very heart of each
Using a non-common set of comparison. Although especially survey
researchers increasingly pay attention to this
indicators; external consistency
problem, the simplistic idea that identity
It is hard to find empirical examples of strat- would imply equivalence still seems to be
egies based on a non-common set of indica- widely spread.
tors and the criterion of external consistency. Several strategies are available to deal
In a study of role conflict, Ehrlich et al. with equivalence problems. The idea to start
(1962) collected data from two distinct popu- with a distinction between the sources of
lations and from the fact that different stimuli non-equivalence (bias) and actual attempts
showed a high degree of association and to establish equivalence proved to be very

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:12 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


96 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

helpful to systemize various approaches Establishing equivalence is, first of all,


available. Bias can be located in the con- a theoretical and conceptual problem. In
structs, methods, or items applied. The rap- other words: vague and ambivalent concepts
idly increasing recommendations to avoid require careful theoretical reconsiderations
equivalence problems (ex-ante strategies) from the outset; not the application of sophis-
have already resulted in a number of high- ticated procedures to establish equivalence.
quality datasets available for comparative
research. Scholars developing comparative
research can rely on the experiences col-
lected in other projects and follow the recom- ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
mendations presented.16 Furthermore,
important constructs, such as the level of Parts of this overview are based on an earlier
education have been standardized and made publication on the same topic (van Deth,
comparable by international groups of 1998).
experts. This work has been expanded to
include many other demographic and socio-
economic ‘background’ variables (cf.
Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and Wolf, 2003a). NOTES
The depiction of distinct types of bias appears
to be very helpful for a discussion about the 1. This does not deny, of course, the specific value
of single-observation studies or the opportunities for
various ex-post strategies to deal with equiva-
combining case studies in a comparative design. The
lence problems. Attempts to increase the level obligatory quotation here, however, is taken from
of abstraction can be very helpful to improve Durkheim (1937/1981): ‘La sociologie comparée
the equivalence of our constructs, but run the n’est pas une branche particulière de la sociologie;
risk of ‘conceptual stretching’ and the accom- c’est la sociologie même, en tant qu’elle cesse d’être
purement descriptive et aspire à rendre compte des
panying loss of analytical power. Sample bias
faits’ (p. 137).
can be reduced by selecting or expanding the 2. This statement becomes a tautology when the
cases selected, or by applying weighting proce- property of ‘being identical with an object’ is allowed
dures. Many authors have suggested procedures to be a property of that very same object. Proof of
to deal with instrument bias and item bias by this trivial version is given by Honderich (1995: 391).
See for a different approach Lowe (1989).
relying on the idea of functional equivalence. In
3. The Big Mac index was introduced by The
these approaches structural relationships among Economist and is published every year since 1986
the items considered (internal consistency), or (cf., www.economist.com/markets/Bigmac/Index.
between the items and some other measures cfm). Obviously, other ‘identical’ products like a pair
(external consistency) are used to construct of Levi 501 jeans or a bottle of Coca-Cola can per-
form the same function in comparisons of the pur-
instrument equivalence.
chasing power of currencies.
None of the procedures suggested for deal- 4. The word equivalence is a combination of the
ing with equivalence problems can be recom- Latin words ‘aequus’ (equal) and ‘valere’ (to be
mended in general or can be praised as the strong; to be worth). See for an extensive overview
‘best’ procedure. Establishing equivalence in of the use of this concept Johnson (1998) who
presents a list of no less than 52 (!) different types of
comparative research requires a careful loca-
equivalence – ranging from ‘Calibration Equivalence’
tion of the sources of bias as well as an atten- to ‘Vocabulary Equivalence’ – mentioned in the lit-
tive exploration of the opportunities to reduce erature.
this bias without losing crucial information 5. Examples are the International Social Survey
about the phenomena to be studied. Any Programme (ISSP) or the European Social Survey
(ESS). See van Deth (2003: 305, 309) for an overview
equivalence procedure, however, can only be
of these projects and their web site addresses or the
implemented successfully if an unambiguous contributions presented by Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and
specification of the concept to be compared Wolf (2003b); Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and Harkness
is available. (2005).

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:13 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


ESTABLISHING EQUIVALENCE 97

6. See Osgood (1967) for an early example of testing hypotheses or causal interpretations, on the
evaluating linguistic differences on the basis of cross- other. As Jackman (1985) states, ‘... to identify and
national consistency or Van de Vijver and Leung measure a variable is not to assume that it influences
(1997: 35–51) for a list of guidelines for translation a second variable. Indeed, any such assumption
and adaptation of instruments in comparative research. would beg the question’ (p. 171). For this distinction,
Harkness (2003) presents overviews of linguistic prob- see also the concept ‘structural equivalence’ dis-
lems in cross-cultural survey research and available cussed by Esser (1996: 433–4).
procedures to deal with these complications. 15. A formal definition of this procedure is pre-
7. Ehling’s (2003) remark that ‘Ex-post output sented by Przeworski and Teune (1966: 557). See
harmonisation is associated in general with the Westle (1998) for a more extensive discussion and
greatest quality losses in terms of international com- application of their approach.
parability, since subsequent adjustment of the data is 16. See for instance documentation of the
frequently only possible within certain limits’ (p. 28), European Social Survey (www.europeansocialsurvey.
clearly underestimates the opportunities to deal with org) or the ‘rules’ summarized by Hoffmeyer-
bias systematically as explained in the next section Zlotnik and Wolf (2003b: 404–5); Harkness (1999);
below. See for an impressive application of exactly or Lynn (2001).
this strategy to the field of gender-specific concepts:
Braun (2006).
8. In a discussion of the opportunities to reach
comparability by increasing the level of abstraction of
the concept ‘democracy’ Collier and Levitsky (1997)
show the advantages and limitations of this
REFERENCES
approach.
9. The ‘general tension between easy operational- Almond, G.A. and Verba, S. (1963) The civic
izability and comparative adequacy’ is discussed by culture. Political attitudes and democracy in
Smelser (1973; cf., Van de Vijver and Leung, 1997), five nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
but the most elegant presentation of the problem is University Press.
clearly Sartori’s ‘Ladder of Abstraction’ that can be Arter, D. (2006) ‘Conclusion. Questioning the
climbed and descended in actual research (1970: ‘mezey question’: An interrogatory frame-
1041). For an application of this idea to coups d’état
work for the comparative study of legisla-
in Africa, see O’Kane (1993).
10. See for access to these data: www.oecd.org/
tures’, The Journal of Legislative Studies, 12
statsportal. (3–4): 462–82.
11. For this reason the term ‘structural equiva- Braun, M. (2006) Funktionale äquivalenz in
lence’ is used as a synonym for ‘functional equiva- interkulturell vergleichenden umfragen.
lence’ (Van de Vijver, 2003a: 153). Mythos und Realität. Mannheim: ZUMA.
12. For a similar line of reasoning based on clear Brauns, H., Scherer, S., and Steinmann, S.
functionalist notions, see the analyses presented by (2003) ‘The CASMIN educational classifica-
Patterson and Wahlke (1972) and Arter (2006) in the tion in international comparative research’,
field of legislative behaviour or the proposals of in J.H.P. Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and C. Wolf
Helms (1995) to study political parties.
(eds), Advances in cross-national compari-
13. This example once again shows that the line
between strategies using external and internal con-
son. A European working book for demo-
sistency among a common set of indicators is not graphic and socio-economic variables. New
always very clear. If Gabriel had started with the aim York: Kluwer/Plenum, pp. 221–44.
of measuring the construct ‘attachment to the politi- Clausen, A.R. (1967) ‘Measurement identity in
cal system’ and had used his two questions as differ- the longitudinal analysis of legislative voting’,
ent indicators of this construct, his approach would American Political Science Review, 64 (4):
have been an example of a mono-trait–multi-method 1020–35.
strategy as indicated by Van de Vijver and Lueng Collier, D. and Levitsky, S. (1997) ‘Democracy
(1997: 55). with adjectives. Conceptual innovation in
14. In addition, Müller (1997: 130) states that the
comparative research’, World Politics, 49 (3):
argument becomes circular if we want to explain
income and status on the basis of education if the
430–51.
relationships between these indicators are already Durkheim, E. (1937/1981) Les règles de la
used to establish equivalence. Although the implicit méthode sociologique. Paris: Presses
warning is important, this criticism seems to be Universitaires de France.
based on a confusion of the phases of concept Ebbinghaus, B. (2005) ‘When less is more:
formation and measurement, on the one hand, and selection problems in large-N and small-N

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:14 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


98 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

cross-national comparisons’, International Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik, J.H.P. and Harkness, J.A.


Sociology, 20 (2): 133–52. (2005) ‘Methodological aspects in cross-na-
Ehling, M. (2003) ‘Harmonising data in official tional research: Foreword’, in J.H.P.
statistics’, in J. H. P. Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and J.A. Harkness (eds),
C. Wolf (eds), Advances in cross–national Methodological aspects in cross-national
comparison. A European working book for research. Mannheim, Germany: ZUMA. 11,
demographic and socio–economic variables. pp. 5–10.
New York: Kluwer/Plenum, pp. 17–31. Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik, J.H.P. and Wolf, C. (eds)
Ehrlich, H.J., Rinehart, J.W. and Howell, J.C. (2003a) Advances in cross-national compari-
(1962) ‘The study of role conflict: Explorations son. A European working book for demo-
in methodology’, Sociometry, 25 (1): 85–97. graphic and socio-economic variables. New
Esser, H. (1996) Soziologie. Allgemeine York: Kluwer/Plenum.
Grundlagen. Frankfurt a. M: Campus. Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik, J.H.P. and Wolf, C. (2003b)
Feagin, J.R., Orum, A.M., and Sjoberg, G. ‘Comparing demographic and socio-
(1991) A case for the case study. Chapel Hill, economic variables across nations’, in J.H.P.
NC: University of North Carolina Press. Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik and C. Wolf (eds),
Gabriel, O.W. (1998) ‘Fragen an einen europä- Advances in cross-national comparison. A
ischen vergleich’, in R. Köcher and J. Schild European working book for demographic
(eds), Wertewandel in Deutschland und and socio-economic variables. New York:
Frankreich. Nationale Unterschiede und Kluwer/Plenum, pp. 389–406.
europäische Gemeinsamkeiten. Opladen: Honderich, T. (1995) The Oxford companion to
Leske & Budrich, pp. 29–51. philosophy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Häder, S. and Gabler, S. (2003) ‘Sampling and Hunyady, G. and Münnich, Á. (1995) ‘A
estimation’, in J.A. Harkness, F.J.R. Van de modified true score MTMM model for ana-
Vijver and P.Ph. Mohler (eds), Cross-cultural lysing stereotype effects of characteriza-
survey methods. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, pp. tions of nations’, in W.E. Saris and
117–42. Á. Münnich (eds), The multitrait-multimethod
Hall, P.A. (2003) ‘Aligning ontology and meth- approach to evaluate measurement instru-
odology in comparative research’, in ments. Budapest: Eötvös University Press,
J. Mahoney and D. Rueschemeyer (eds), pp. 173–84.
Comparative historical analysis in the social Inglehart, R. (1977) The silent revolution.
sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Changing values and political styles among
Press, pp. 373–404. Western publics. Princeton: Princeton
Harkness, J.A. (ed.) (1998) Cross-cultural survey University Press.
equivalence Mannheim: ZUMA. Jackman, R.W. (1985) ‘Cross-national statisti-
Harkness, J.A. (1999) ‘In pursuit of quality: Issues cal research and the study of comparative
for cross-national survey research’, Social politics’, American Journal of Political Science,
Research Methodology, 2 (2): 125–40. 29 (1), 161–82.
Harkness, J.A. (2003) ‘Questionnaire transla- Johnson, T.P. (1998) ‘Approaches to equiva-
tion’, in J.A. Harkness, F.J.R. Van de Vijver lence in cross-cultural and cross-national
and P. Ph. Mohler (eds), Cross-cultural survey survey research’, in J.A. Harkness (ed), Cross-
methods. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, pp. 35–56. cultural survey equivalence. Mannheim:
Harkness, J.A., Mohler, P. Ph. and Van de ZUMA, pp. 1–40.
Vijver, F.J.R. (2003) ‘Comparative research’, Kuechler, M. (1991) ‘The dynamics of mass
in J.A. Harkness, F.J.R. Van de Vijver and political support in Western Europe:
P. Ph. Mohler (eds), Cross-cultural Methodological problems and preliminary
survey methods. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, pp. findings’, in K. Reif and R. Inglehart (eds),
3–16. Eurobarometer: The dynamics of European
Helms, L. (1995) ‘Parteiensysteme als system- public opinion. Houndmills, Basingstoke:
struktur. Zur methodisch-analytisch kon- Macmillan, pp. 275–93.
zeption der funktional vergleichenden Locke, R. and Thelen, K. (1998) ‘Problems of
parteiensystemanalyse’, Zeitschrift für equivalence in comparative politics: Apples
Parlamentsfragen, 26 (4): 642–57. and oranges, again’, APSA–CP: Newsletter

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:15 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


ESTABLISHING EQUIVALENCE 99

of the APSA Organized Section in Patterson, S.C. and Wahlke, J.C. (1972) ‘Trends
Comparative Politics, 9 (1): 9–12. and prospects in legislative behavior research’,
Lowe, E.J. (1989) ‘What is a criterion of iden- in S.C. Patterson and J.C. Wahlke (eds),
tity?’, The Philosophical Quarterly, 39 (154): Comparative legislative behavior: Frontiers of
1–21. research. New York: Wiley, pp. 289–303.
Luhmann, N. (1970) Soziologische aufklärung. Przeworski, A. and Teune, H. (1966) ‘Equivalence
Aufsätze zur theorie sozialer systeme. in cross-national research’, Public Opinion
Opladen: Westdeutscher verlag. Quarterly, 30 (4): 551–68.
Lynn, P. (2001) Developing quality standards Przeworski, A. and Teune, H. (1970) The logic
for cross-national survey research: Five of comparative social inquiry. New York:
approaches (ISER Paper 2001–21) Essex, UK. Wiley.
Working papers of the Institute for Social Ragin, C.C. (2000) Fuzzy-set social science.
and Economic Research. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Lynn, P., Häder, S., Gabler, S., and Laaksonen, S. Ragin, C.C. (2004) ‘Turning the tables: How
(2004) Methods for achieving equivalence case-oriented research challenges variable-
of samples in cross–national surveys: The oriented research’, in H.E. Brady and
European social survey experience. (ISER D. Collier (eds), Rethinking social inquiry.
Paper 2004–09) Essex, UK: Working Papers Diverse tools, shared standards. Lanham,
of the Institute for Social and Economic MD: Rowman and Littlefield, pp. 123–38.
Research. Rueschemeyer, D. (2003) ‘Can one or a few
Mahoney, J. and Rueschemeyer, D. (eds) (2003) cases yield theoretical gains?’, in J. Mahoney
Comparative historical analysis in the social and D. Rueschemeyer (eds), Comparative
sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University historical analysis in the social sciences.
Press. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
McKeon, T.J. (2004) ‘Case studies and the pp. 305–36.
limits of the quantitative worldview’, in H.E. Saris, W.E. (1997) ‘Comparability across mode
Brady and D. Collier (eds), Rethinking social and country’, in W.E. Saris and M. Kaase
inquiry. Diverse tools, shared standards. (eds), Eurobarometer. Measurement instru-
Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, ments for opinions in Europe. Mannheim:
pp. 139–67. ZUMA, pp. 125–39.
Mokken, R.J. (1971) A theory and procedure of Saris, W.E. and Münnich, Á. (eds) (1995) The
scale analyis. With applications in political multitrait-multimethod approach to evaluate
research. The Hague: Mouton. measurement instruments. Budapest: Eötvös
Müller, W. (1997) ‘Vergleichende sozialstruk- University Press.
turforschung’, in D. Berg-Schlosser and Saris, W.E. and Scherpenzeel, A. (1995)
F. Müller-Rommel (eds), Vergleichende ‘Correction for measurement error in life
politikwissenschaft. Ein einführendes studi- satisfaction research’, in W.E. Saris and
enhandbuch (3rd edition). Opladen: Leske & Á. Münnich (eds), The multitrait-multimethod
Budrich, pp. 121–41. approach to evaluate measurement instru-
Nießen, M. (1982) ‘Qualitative aspects in cross- ments. Budapest: Eötvös University Press,
national comparative research and the prob- pp. 243–67.
lem of functional equivalence’, in M. Nießen Sartori, G. (1970) ‘Concept misformation in
and J. Peschar (eds), International comparative comparative politics’, American Political
research. Problems of theory, methodology Science Review, 64 (4): 1033–53.
and organisation in Eastern and Western Sartori, G. (1994) ‘Compare why and how.
Europe. Oxford: Pergamon Press, pp. 83–104. Comparing, miscomparing and the compar-
O’Kane, R.H.T. (1993) ‘The ladder of abstrac- ative method’, in M. Dogan and A. Kazancigil
tion. The purpose of comparison and the (eds), Comparing nations. Concepts, strate-
practice of comparing African coups d’etat’, gies, substance. Oxford: Blackwell,
Journal of Theoretical Politics, 5 (2): 169–93. pp. 13–34.
Osgood, C.E. (1967) ‘On the strategy of cross- Schäfer, J. (2006) Sozialkapital und politische
national research into subjective culture’, Orientierungen von jugendlichen in
Social Science Information, 6 (1): 5–37. Deutschland. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag.

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:16 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


100 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Schneider, C.Q. and Wagemann, C. (2006) Vijver and P. Ph. Mohler (eds), Cross-cultural
‘Reducing complexity in qualitative analyses survey methods. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley,
(QCA): Remote and proximate factors pp. 207–33.
and the consolidation of democracy’, Van de Vijver, F.J.R. and Leung, K. (1997)
European Journal of Political Science, 45 (5): Methods and data analysis for cross-cultural
751–86. research. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Smelser, N.J. (1973) ‘The methodology of com- van Deth, J.W. (1986) ‘A note on measuring
parative analysis’, in D.P. Warwick and political participation in comparative
S. Osherson (eds), Comparative research research’, Quality and Quantity, 20 (2–3):
methods. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 261–72.
pp. 42–86. van Deth, J.W. (ed.) (1998) Comparative poli-
Treiman, D.J. (1975) ‘Problems of concept and tics. The problem of equivalence. London:
measurement in the comparative study of Routledge.
occupational mobility’, Social Science van Deth, J.W. (2003) ‘Using published survey
Research, 4 (3), 183–230. data’, in J.A. Harkness, F.J.R. Van de Vijver,
Treiman, D.J. and Terrel, K. (1975) ‘Status and P. Ph. Mohler. (eds), Cross-cultural survey
attainment in the United States and Great methods. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, pp. 291–309.
Britain’, American Journal of Sociology, 81 Verba, S. (1967) ‘Some dilemmas in comparative
(3), 568–83. research’, World Politics, 20 (1): 111–27.
Van de Vijver, F.J.R. (1998) ‘Towards a theory Verba, S. (1969) ‘The uses of survey research in
of bias and equivalence’, in J.A. Harkness the study of comparative politics: Issues and
(ed.), Cross-cultural survey equivalence. strategies’, in S. Rokkan, S. Verba, J. Viet and
Mannheim: ZUMA, pp. 41–65. E. Almasy (eds), Comparative survey analysis.
Van de Vijver, F.J.R. (2003a) ‘Bias and equiva- The Hague: Mouton, pp. 56–105.
lence: Cross-cultural perspectives’, in J.A. Westle, B. (1998) ‘Tolerance’, in J.W. van Deth
Harkness, F.J.R. Van de Vijver and P. Ph. (ed), Comparative politics. The problem of
Mohler. (eds), Cross-cultural survey meth- equivalence. London: Routledge, pp. 20–60.
ods. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, pp. 143–55. Wittgenstein, L. (1921/1963) Tractatus logico-
Van de Vijver, F.J.R. (2003b) ‘Bias and substan- philosophicus. Logisch-philosophische
tive analyses’, in J.A. Harkness, F.J.R. Van de abhandlung. Frankfurt a. M: Suhrkamp.

9781412919760_Chap05.indd Sec1:17 3/11/2009 3:38:07 PM


6
Comparative Political Sociology
Willfried Spohn

THE CHANGING CONTOURS comparative political sociology differs to


OF COMPARATIVE POLITICAL some extent to those used in comparative
SOCIOLOGY politics and sociology. However, because
political science and comparative politics are
Sociology and political science have a com- also involved in the investigation of relation-
plex relationship and against the backdrop of ships between the political and social spheres,
the two disciplines political sociology can be there is a considerable overlap between com-
defined as an interdisciplinary field of inquiry parative political sociology and comparative
developed by both sociologists and political politics (Landman, 2003).
scientists to study the interrelations and inter- Modern political sociology only emerged
actions between the socio-cultural life-world as a distinct field of specialization after
and the political sphere: between society and World War II, building on the different intel-
state, between social and political institu- lectual and academic traditions of political
tions, groups and behaviour. Political sociol- science and sociology that had developed in
ogy in short, looks at ‘the social bases of the first half of the twentieth century, and
politics’ (see inter alia, Braungart and combining European and American legacies
Braungart, 2000; Janoski et al., 2004; (Bendix, 1973; Eckstein, 1971; Eisenstadt,
Kimmerling, 1996; Lipset, 1959; Nash, 2000; 1971). A common theoretical background
Orum, 1983, 1996).1 Comparative political for the interdisciplinary development of
sociology relates to those parts of political political sociology was the modernization
sociology that use explicitly a comparative paradigm. This integrated classical sociologi-
methodology and related comparative meth- cal traditions and in its structural-functional
ods. Whereas comparative politics concen- version provided a way of integrating the
trates on the comparative analysis and political into a multi-dimensional framework
explanation of political phenomena, compara- of socio-political evolution (Knöbl, 2001;
tive political sociology as an interdisciplinary Kumar, 2000; Tipps, 1973). This also allowed
field of inquiry combines comparative politics it to integrate the specific aspects of
and comparative sociology, focusing on socio- traditional political science: government,
cultural phenomena and their interconnections political institutions, public law and related
with the political sphere. As a consequence, political behaviour (Almond and Bingham,
the range of comparative methods used in 1966; Apter, 1965; Dahl, 1971; Easton, 1953).

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 1 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


102 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

The modernization paradigm was accompa- variables to cultural-scientific approaches


nied by a fast-growing field of comparative concerned with cultural meaning and cogni-
research that extended classical European- tive construction in their impacts on the social
American comparisons to the decolonizing, and political spheres. These counter-trends
newly developing states in the non-Western also questioned the predominant variable-
world (Lerner, 1965; Weiner, 1966). As a oriented quantitative methods used in com-
result, political sociology became essentially parative political macro-sociology and
defined by comparative political moderniza- resulted in the development of case-oriented
tion research on the globally varying forma- qualitative and interpretive comparative
tion of modern political systems as a crucial methods. Though comparative political
part of societal modernization processes. macro-sociology with its theoretical focus on
The modernization paradigm grounded political modernization and methodological
comparative political sociology in a macro- orientation to quantitative methods has
sociological Western-centric evolutionist remained the defining core of political sociol-
framework. This served not only as a value- ogy, there emerged a strong tendency towards
free analytical frame of reference but also as the search for the micro-sociological founda-
a self-legitimising ideology of the Western, tion of politics and case-oriented comparisons.
and particularly US-American, developmen- On the social-scientific side, historical-
tal models. Increasingly this has been ques- sociological approaches focused on the
tioned by critical counter-trends in political micro-sociological foundations of political
sociology (Latham, 1997; Yack, 1997). A processes (Skocpol, 1984; Tilly, 1984); insti-
first counter-trend questioning the main- tutionalist approaches tried to specify the
stream affirmative positivism was developed institutional environments of politics
by conflict theory on the basis of renewed (Mahoney and Rueschemeyer, 2003); and
forms of critical theory orienting political rational-choice approaches analysed the
sociology to issues of political power and rational action orientation involved in political
social inequality (Coser, 1967). Second, in a individual and collective action (Kiser and
renewal of Marxist traditions, neo-Marxism Hechter, 1998). On the cultural-scientific side,
developed a critical analysis of political the post-modernist and post-structuralist
power and its foundation in capitalist devel- ‘cultural turn’ renewed a hermeneutic-
opment and class conflict (Bottomore, 1979). interpretive and cultural-historical tradition
A third counter-trend evolved in the form of in sociology and political science, and hence
post-modernist and post-structural perspec- also in political sociology (Adams et al.,
tives based on the ‘cultural turn’ that ques- 2005); this was often radicalized by con-
tioned not only the Western-centric structivist epistemological perspectives
modernization paradigm but also the econo- that directed research to the deconstruction
mism of most neo-Marxist approaches and of cultural archaeologies or frames of
hence the positivistic mode of comparative political power, institutions and actions
political macro-sociology (Nash, 2001). (Nash, 2000).
Finally, a fourth counter-trend has extended These traditional and counter currents
the post-modernist-cultural orientation to continue to shape the present state of com-
the non-Western world in the form of post- parative political sociology. The liberal-capi-
colonial studies (Chaturvedi, 2000). These talist modernization paradigm in the form of
counter-trends have been accompanied by a transition and transformation research
general movement from social-scientific experienced a conspicuous revival with the
approaches seeking causal explanation breakdown of communism as an alternative
through the identification of invariant laws form of modernization as well as an ideo-
or regularities between social and political logy (Grancelli, 1995). Once again, renewed

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 2 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 103

macro-modernization analysis in political


sociology has been contested in two direc- COMPARATIVE MACRO-SOCIOLOGY
tions. On the one hand, the comparative- OF POLITICS: POLITICAL
civilizational approach argues for a multiple MODERNIZATION AND
modernities perspective because of the per- SOCIAL CHANGE
sistence of many different forms of modern
societies (Eisenstadt, 2002). This has been Modern political sociology as the systematic
augmented by the intensification of globali- study of the relationships between the politi-
zation and the trend towards examining the cal and social spheres emerged with the
impact of various globalization processes on experience of the social and political changes
national and international politics that it has in Western Europe and the Americas in the
produced (Held et al., 1999; Robertson, late-eighteenth and early-nineteenth centu-
1992; Scholte, 2002). On the other hand, ries. Although the roots of political sociology
critical alternatives to the liberal-capitalist can be traced back to Greek philosophy and
modernization paradigm in the form of neo- its impact on medieval, early modern and
Marxism, post-modernism and post-colonial- enlightenment political thought, emerging
ism remain, and are complemented by modern political sociology as a combination
micro-sociological perspectives calling for of political science and sociology wanted to
the comparative analysis of the sociological understand the formation of modern absolut-
foundations of multiple modernities and ist nation-states, how political revolutions
globalization. produced change, and the impact of the
The resulting current epistemological, the- social changes created by the industrial revo-
oretical, methodological and analytical plu- lution on politics (Eisenstadt, 1963, 1971).
ralism in comparative political sociology Whereas early political science concentrated
demarcates the space of comparative meth- more on political governance and public law
odology and research involved. On the social- (Eckstein, 1971), early political sociology
scientific pole of this methodological space, focused more on the socio-economic changes
the comparative enterprise in political sociol- related to capitalist development, industriali-
ogy continues through the application of zation and social structure and their impact
large-scale, global quantitative variable- on the political realm (Kumar, 2005). Early
oriented research methods and through com- political sociology was on the one hand
parative qualitative, case-oriented research macro-sociological, in that it studied macro-
on the micro-foundations of politics and trends in political and social evolution, and
political processes. On the cultural-scientific on the other hand explicitly or implicitly
pole of this methodological space, compara- comparative in contrasting Western European
tive qualitative, case-oriented methods com- and North American processes of political
bine with interpretive and deconstructive and socio-economic modernization to each
research orientations, often in tension with other and to Eastern or Oriental experiences.
quantitative, variable-oriented approaches At the same time, the founding fathers of
and seldom complementing them (Ragin, comparative political sociology – among
1987). In the following, I will outline the whom we can count Charles Montesquieu
changing contours of comparative political and Alexis de Tocqueville in France; Adam
sociology in its different currents and waves, Smith and John Stuart Mill in Great Britain;
concentrating on exemplary compara- and Karl Marx and Lorenz von Stein in
tive studies, and summarizing the resulting Germany – reflected both their particular
pluralistic – though compartmentalized – intellectual traditions of philosophical and
space of comparative methodology in com- political thought as well as the specific social
parative political sociology. and political experiences of their countries.

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 3 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


104 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

On these foundations, the classical phase of The different national traditions of


comparative political sociology started with European political sociology came together
the institutionalization of sociology as a spe- only with the synthesis of American and
cific academic discipline at European univer- European sociology, enabled by the forced
sities in the late-nineteenth and early-twentieth emigration of many of its representatives, in
centuries. It was connected with new political post-World War II American sociology.
experiences such as the formation of new Structural-functional system theory and the
nation-states in Italy and Germany, the impor- related modernization paradigm developed
tance of nationalism and democratization, as by Talcott Parsons, Edward Shils and others
well as the rise of communism and fascism played a central role (Alexander, 1994;
after World War I. In this context, the tradi- Knöbl, 2001; Zapf, 1971). Societal develop-
tional evolutionist and optimistic approaches ment was conceptualized according to basic
of the founding fathers became contested by social-evolutionary processes such as social
more ambiguous and pessimistic perspectives differentiation and individualization, capital-
and at the same time new topics became rele- ist industrialization and social stratification,
vant. French sociology founded by Emile nation-state formation and democratization,
Durkheim and Maurice Halbwachs (Lukes, as well as value generalization and seculari-
1972) emphasized social integration, national zation. This multi-dimensional bundle com-
consciousness or conscience collective as the prised the major evolutionary processes from
basis and cement of national politics (Aron, traditional to modern society and simultane-
1967; Duverger, 1972). German political soci- ously claimed the functional co-evolution of
ology, in close contact with Austria and devel- these processes. Within this frame of refer-
oped particularly by Ferdinand Tönnies, ence, the realm of politics was seen as
Ludwig Gumplowicz, Max Weber, Werner one sub-system of the social system, and
Sombart, Otto Hintze, Robert Michels and political modernization as one functional
Karl Mannheim (for an overview see component of overall societal modernization.
Mommsen and Osterhammel, 1987), concen- Characteristically, modern American society
trated on topics such as nation, ethnicity and and polity formed the telos of these evolu-
nationalism; state bureaucracy and state agen- tionary processes and accordingly served as a
cies, democratization, political parties and comparative model not only for the recon-
charismatic political leaders Nedelmann 1997. struction of European societies but also for
Italian political sociology by Gaetano Mosca the many post-colonial societies in the non-
and Vilfredo Pareto and particularly influ- European world (inter alia Black, 1966;
enced by Weber and Michels focused on the Finkle and Gable, 1966; Geertz, 1963; Lerner,
role of political elites (Linz, 2006). In con- 1965; Parsons, 1977; Shils, 1977).
trast, British and American scholars such as Guided by this universal framework, a
Henry Maine, Thomas Marshall, Harold rapidly expanding field of comparative
Lasswell and Harold Laski were rather con- research on modernization and particularly
cerned with the political development of con- political modernization developed. One cor-
stitutional democracy, political parties and nerstone of systematic-comparative analysis
political/social pressure groups in Britain and of components of political modernization
the US (Eckstein, 1971). Whatever the topical such as social communication, bureaucracy,
emphasis, all these approaches in political education, national culture and political cul-
sociology remained comparative macro- ture were the influential ‘Studies in Political
sociological, contrasting the tendencies of Development’ organized by the Committee
the modern political realm with the on Comparative Politics of the Social Science
European traditional order and with the non- Research Council (Almond and Verba 1963;
European world, as well as with some attempts Binder et al., 1971; Grew, 1978; LaPalombara,
to compare the individual countries with each 1963; Pye and Verba, 1965; Weiner, 1966;
other. also Deutsch, 1953). Another cornerstone

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 4 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 105

was Seymour Martin Lipset’s democratiza- particular, Samuel Huntington (1968/2003)


tion thesis and Stein Rokkan’s social cleav- pointed out that political modernization was
age thesis. Lipset’s (1959) democratization not necessarily promoted by economic mod-
thesis, originally formulated in his Political ernization, but was also influenced by the
Man, stated that democracy as a political interconnection of state stability and democ-
system with constitutional government, citi- ratization, a linkage that was particularly in
zens’ rights and free elections goes generally jeopardy in new post-colonial states. Third,
hand in hand with economic development, the tendency for macro-sociological research
the formation of a middle class, the rise of cum quantitative research methods was ques-
cultural education and social welfare and a tioned by in-depth historical-comparative
resulting pluralist political culture (Bollen, research that highlighted the path-dependent
1980; Lipset, 1984; Marks and Lipset, 1998). specific causal configurations of dimensions
The social cleavage thesis developed by and factors of political modernization.
Stein Rokkan (Lipset and Rokkan, 1967) For instance, Barrington Moore (1966)
tried to explain the post-World War II voter highlighted the crucial importance of pre-
alignment patterns in Western Europe as a industrial landlords and peasants for the
result of varying cleavage structures evolving different types of capitalist-democratic, con-
between state and church, aristocracy and servative-fascist and communist-autocratic
bourgeoisie as well as bourgeoisie and work- paths of modernization; Reinhard Bendix
ing class during the course of political mod- (1977) focused on the historically varying
ernization (Rokkan et al., 1999). Whereas legitimacy pattern of political power related
Lipset particularly focused on American to different concepts of nationhood and citi-
exceptionalism in contrast to Western Europe, zenship; and Charles Tilly (1975) empha-
Rokkan concentrated more on the varieties of sized the historical contingency of the
political modernization in Western Europe; formation of nation-states in Europe.
but both also initiated broadly comparative These refinements and revisions of compara-
research on political modernization in the tive research on political modernization also
new states in the non-Western regions of had consequences for the comparative meth-
Asia, Africa and Latin America. A current ods used. The predominant search for gen-
summary of this continuing research agenda, eral or functional laws between a few
although there have been some revisions of independent and dependent variables across
the original modernization framework, can a large number of cases pursued in macro-
be seen in many volumes on democracy in sociological, quantitative cross-national com-
Western and non-Western states (Diamond, parative research on political modernization
1999; Diamond and Plattner, 2002; Lipset, became contested and complemented by
1998). comparative research methods that concen-
The refinement and revision of the original trated more on causal configurations in a few
modernization framework as it related par- cases on the basis of qualitative-historical
ticularly to the evolutionary, functional and research. The resulting methodological space
macro-sociological premises of comparative for comparative analysis was summarized by
political modernization research had three Tilly (1984) who distinguished generalising
major aspects.2 First, modernization was comparisons with many variables and cases,
questioned as an evolutionary progressive individualizing comparisons with few varia-
process and instead seen as fragile and full of bles and cases, encompassing comparisons
contradictions and breakdowns (Eisenstadt, with cases and variables embedded in a
1966). Second, modernization was ques- larger system, and variation-finding compari-
tioned as a functionally interdependent mul- sons with a systematic search for varying
tidimensional process and instead causal relations of variables in few, well
conceptualized as two distinct dimensions of researched cases; or in a more qualitative
economic and political modernization. In direction by Theda Skocpol (1984) who

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 5 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


106 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

emphasized model-theoretical, causal and only of modernization theory but also of neo-
interpretive comparative methods. Marxism. And post-colonial approaches,
which are often married with post-modernism,
criticized the Euro-centrism not only
of modernization theory but also of neo-
CRITICAL ALTERNATIVES: Marxism from the perspective of the post-
CONFLICT THEORY, NEO-MARXISM, colonial world.
POST-PODERNISM AND Broadly, the critical countermovement
POST-COLONIALISM against the mainstream modernization para-
digm in political sociology started with the
The modernization paradigm and the related perception of the negative features of advanced
comparative research on political moderniza- liberal-capitalist societies and was accompa-
tion represented not only an analytical frame- nied by a renewal of critical-theoretical
work for comparative investigation but also, currents within classical sociology. An influ-
in a sense, an ideological base for American ential strand was the critical analysis of the
foreign policy. At its core, much of political political and social power structures of
modernization theory and research took for Western societies as developed, for instance,
granted that the American model of modern in C. Wright Mills (1956, 1963) and George
society, its capitalism, social structure and W. Domhoff’s (1967, 2001) investigation of
democracy, was the highest stage of socio- the American power elite and replicated by
political evolution. This went hand in hand John Scott (1991) in the United Kingdom,
with a missionary democratic orientation to Raymond Aron (1950) in France, and Ralf
the development of the Third World, a strong Dahrendorf’s (1965) and W. Zapf’s (1965)
anti-communist sentiment against the Second studies of German elites. Characteristically,
World and a conservative-affirmative attitude the core concept of power was less seen in its
regarding the existing democratic regimes in positive aspects of national sovereignty,
the First World (Latham, 1997; Yack, 1997). responsible government and rational author-
As a consequence, the modernization para- ity and more in its negative aspects of hierar-
digm became the target of a variety of critical chical power structures, limited democratic
countermoves against and within the Western participation, and social inequality. A second
model of modernity in search of more democ- strand of this renewal of critical-theoretical
racy that were particularly fuelled by the currents in sociology developed a variety of
political and cultural revolt of 1968 in most critical concepts with the purpose to expand
Western, and some non-Western, societies. the democratic spaces in Western societies.
These critical countermoves against the pre- Particularly important were the concepts of
dominant modernization paradigm revolved participatory democracy, social protest and
around four main currents that have had a social movements, industrial democracy,
lasting impact on political sociology and welfare state, civil society and public sphere.
related comparative research. Conflict theo- Here, of lasting influence were Jürgen
ries based on traditions of critical theory Habermas’s (1989) study of the transforma-
challenged the affirmative functions of mod- tion of the public sphere in Germany, Pierre
ernization theory vis-à-vis Western moder- Bourdieu’s (1984, 1987) concepts of social,
nity. More specifically within this critical political and cultural capital, Marshall’s
tradition, neo-Marxism renewed and devel- (1964) category of citizenship, and the con-
oped Marxist political economy as a key to cept of civil society re-imported from East-
understanding power structures in Western Central Europe (Keane, 1988). Related to
and between Western and non-Western socie- this critical orientation was the general criti-
ties. Post-modernist approaches emerged as a cism of the static, functional and evolutionist
critical move against the grand narratives not premises of the modernization paradigm

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 6 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 107

and the inverse emphasis on the tensions, phenomenon (Anderson, 1991). Both mod-
contradictions, conflicts and social change at ernization and neo-Marxist theories shared a
the centre of political sociology. This was Eurocentric tendency to structuralism, func-
connected to a general renewal of critical tionalism and evolutionism, and were fixated
theory in political sociology, reinvigorating on economic development, social-structure
the critical-reflexive potential of classical and class-based power politics. Against this,
sociology, Marxism and psychoanalysis for post-modernism emphazised, on the one
the study of modern societies and politics hand, new structural developments and phe-
(Bottomore, 1979). nomena of Western/global capitalism, such
A second critical countermove against as post-industrialism, post-Fordism, new
comparative political modernization research communication technologies, consumer cul-
can be classified as neo-Marxism. Though ture, new social movements, feminism and
neo-Marxism shared the general motivations multiculturalism and a related cultural plu-
and orientations of critical theory in many ralism that had a crucial impact on post-
respects, it was oriented more specifically to modern attitudes, political culture (for a
the Marxist legacy of political-economic cultural-scientific interpretation, see Kumar,
analysis rather than to the Marxist philo- 2005), and new patterns of political party
sophical heritage (Bottomore, 1979). At the formation (for a political-scientific explana-
core of neo-Marxist analysis was the rela- tion see Inglehardt, 1990; 2006). On the
tionship between the economic structure of other, post-modernism went hand in hand
capitalism and the capitalist state (Giddens, with the emergence of new collective actors
1973; Offe, 1972; Poulantzas, 1973); the in the social and political spheres, particu-
impact of class structures and interrelations larly feminist and ecological orientations in
on political power (Miliband, 1977; Therborn, the context of the many new social move-
1978); and following Antonio Gramsci ments that shifted the analytical attention
(1971) the changing forms of the state and from structures to culture and agency (Archer,
functioning of capitalist hegemony (Laclau 2000; Lister, 2002; Squire, 2004). In parallel,
and Mouffe, 2001). Neo-Marxism was pri- there developed new post-modernist theories
marily oriented to the social inequalities, and methodologies that criticised the grand
social conflicts and political power structures narratives of modernization theory and neo-
in advanced Western capitalism, though it Marxism and shifted to the ‘micro-physics’ and
was limited – like modernization theory cultural-epistemological construction of
and comparative political modernization power (Foucault, 1972; Nash, 2000). Against
research – by its inbuilt Euro-centrism, econ- this background, a post-modern political
omism, and evolutionism. In the long run, sociology emerged that focused particularly
more influential for comparative political on the deconstruction of the power relations
sociology were the more historical-compara- built into state structures and agencies in
tive approaches to state formation and class relation to various social and political actors
conflicts in the transition from feudalism to and movements under the post-modern con-
capitalism (Anderson, 1979) as well as the dition (Owen, 2000).
origins and development of the modern world The fourth countermove against compara-
system concentrating on the changing global tive modernization research represents a par-
economic hierarchy between core, semi- allel post-modern development in the
peripheries and peripheries (Chase-Dunn, relationship between the advanced capitalist
1991; Wallerstein, 1999). countries and the post-colonial Third World.
The third countermove against comparative Primarily developed by non-Western intel-
modernization research developed against lectuals in contact with the Western academia,
the limits of the neo-Marxist alternative post-colonialism reflected the post-modernist
and thus can be seen also as a post-Marxist disenchantment not only with modernization

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 7 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


108 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

theory but also with neo-Marxism. Parti- similarities. As a result, post-colonial studies
cularly influential was Edward Said’s in political sociology were also mostly inter-
Orientalism (1979) and the following post- ested in qualitative-deconstructive work rather
colonial and subaltern studies redirecting the than systematic comparisons between the
structural power analysis of the Third World various types of post-colonial political regimes
towards the cultural construction of colonial and societies. Nevertheless, the main effect of
and post-colonial societies, and from elites to these various critical alternatives on compara-
the lower, oppressed and silenced classes, tive political sociology was to strengthen
groups and individuals (Chaturvedi, 2000; qualitative case-oriented against quantitative
Conrad and Randeria, 2002). Since post- variables-oriented methods of comparison
colonial and subaltern studies were primarily (Adams et al., 2005).
developed in literary criticism, comparative
literature, anthropology and ethnography,
there is also a hitherto unresolved tension,
but also emerging debate on their relation to COMPARATIVE MICRO-
a political sociology of post-colonial socie- FOUNDATIONS OF POLITICS:
ties (Bartolovich and Lazarus, 2001). Here, SOCIAL-SCIENTIFIC AND CULTURAL-
in contradistinction to the political moderni- CONSTRUCTIVIST APPROACHES
zation approaches in the sociology of devel-
opment (So, 1990), three currents developed: The common denominator of the various
the political economy of the Third World critical counter-currents against the predomi-
(Hoogvelt, 1997; McMichael, 2004; Menzel, nant modernization paradigm and related
2000); the political analysis of the third- comparative research in political moderniza-
world state (e.g., Bayart, 1993; Kamrava, tion has been a broad critique of its Eurocentric
2002); and the analysis of political culture universalistic, evolutionary and normative
(Comaroff and Comaroff, 1991; Cooper, premises. The major impacts on comparative
2003; Ferguson, 2006). political sociology have been the questioning
These four counter-currents against the of the self-explanatory validity of macro-
predominant political modernization para- structural causal correlations; the movement
digm also had important consequences for the from structure to agency and culture; the
use of comparative methods. Generally speak- shift from researching system stability to
ing, the critique of liberal-capitalist modernity conflict and change; as well as the movement
profoundly weakened the systematic compar- from an affirmative normative attitude to a
ative study of processes of political moderni- more pluralistic value orientation in politics.
zation and promoted critical, but rarely However, it would be misleading to state that
comparative, research. The only exception the critical countermoves brought the
was neo-Marxism, where the historical- predominance of the comparative macro-
sociological move to compare political-social sociology of politics to an end. Rather, the
configurations with qualitative case-oriented comparative macro-sociology of politics has
methods remained influential. But critical lost its original capability of defining the
theory and conflict theory were generally sub-discipline of political sociology, being
more interested in the re-examination of indi- forced to revise the structural-functionalist
vidual cases and only rarely and in a few cases assumptions of modernization theory by inte-
engaged in systematic comparative research. grating many components of the critical
Even more so, post-modern approaches gener- counter-currents. These critical counter-
ally discouraged systematic comparative currents, however, did not converge in a
work, since the individualized, decentred, common counter-paradigm. Instead, they devel-
fragmented and chaotic world these approaches oped and institutionalized in various currents,
depicted emphasized differences but not thus pluralizing but also compartmentalizing

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 8 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 109

the interdisciplinary enterprise of political (Goldstone, 1991; McDaniel, 1989, 1991);


sociology. At the same time, the common and of social classes, social movements,
effect of the critical revisions has been a gen- social protest and political mobilization
eral movement towards the search for the (e.g., Katznelson and Zolberg, 1986; Moore,
micro-foundations of politics. This search 1981; Tilly, 1978; Thompson, 1963).
has developed in two principled directions of The comparative methods used in these his-
social-scientific and cultural-constructivist torical orientations in political sociology are
approaches, thereby increasingly making either constellative-causal (analysing causal
complex the macro-micro research agenda connections and regularities in political-
and strategies in comparative political social macro-configurations) or variation-
sociology. finding (identifying varying meso- and
A first redirection of the comparative micro-causal mechanisms of political proc-
macro-sociology of politics motivated by the esses) in the social-scientific direction; and
critique of the structural-functional and evolu- qualitative-interpretive (understanding and
tionary modernization framework developed comparing different kinds of meaning and
as a corollary to the rise of historical sociol- action orientations) or deconstructive
ogy. Instead of taking the unfolding self- (analysing and comparing hidden cognitive
propelling causality of social and political structures) in a cultural-scientific direction
modernization macro-processes for granted, a (Ragin, 1987; Sewell, 2005; Skocpol, 1984;
general methodological thrust became directed Tilly, 1984).
towards the historicization and contextualiza- The second redirection of the macro-
tion of the macro-process of political mod- sociology of politics has concerned the ana-
ernization, focusing on particular trajectories lytical differentiation of the macro-unity of
and sequences of political modernization. Of the state. With the aim of ‘bringing the state
special influence here was Moore’s Social back in’ (Evans et al., 1985) – a demand
Origins (1966), which provided an in-depth against liberal-utilitarian and neo-Marxist
analysis of four different trajectories of orientations alike – political-sociological
political modernization and their specific analysis turned to the social basis of specific
class constellations. He was followed in a state functions, agencies and actors. In the
similar vein by Skocpol’s States and Social social-scientific direction, particularly influ-
Revolutions (1979), Anderson’s Passages from ential has been the comparative analysis of
Antiquity to Feudalism (1979) and Lineages social policy (Charrad, 2001; de Swaan,
of the Absolutist State (1980). This approach 1998; Esping-Anderson, 1990; Orloff, 1993;
was further developed by Michael Mann’s Skocpol, 1992; Weir et al., 1988), but also
Sources of Social Power (1986/ 1993; see other state domains, such as economic policy
Hall and Schroeder, 2006), and Dietrich (Carruthers, 2005), administration (Kiser and
Rueschemeyer, Evelyn Huber-Stephen and Kane, 2001), police (Knöbl, 1998) and mili-
John Stephen’s Democracy and Capitalist tary (Tilly, 1990) were of interest. In the
Development (1992). At the same time, there cultural and constructivist orientation, there
developed more specialized topics of research have been investigations of the cultural
that looked comparatively at particular his- frameworks of the state (Steinmetz, 1999);
torical phases and topical dimensions of the impact of religion on state-formation and
political modernization, particularly in the political culture (Bellah, 1981; Gorski, 2003;
historical sociology of the state (e.g., Zaret, 1985); the relationships between state,
Ertmann, 1997; Evans et al., 1985 or Poggi, nation and nationalism (Giddens, 1985;
1978, 2001); of nations and nationalism (e.g., Greenfeld, 1993); nationalism and religion
Anderson, 1983; Bendix, 1977; Gellner, (Casanova, 1994; Spohn, 2003); nationalism
1983; Marx, 1998; Smith, 1986, 2001); and language (Laitin, 1992); ethnicity and
the historical sociology of revolutions citizenship (Brubaker, 1992; Joppke, 1999;

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 9 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


110 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Soysal, 1994), or power and legitimacy 1996; Thelen, 1999; see also Chapter 6 of this
(Chirot, 1996). volume).
The third trend in comparative political
sociology has attempted to analyze the com- The fourth trend in comparative political
plex intermediary space between the political sociology is connected to these different
realm and society in terms of civil society kinds of institutionalism, but has gone even
and public sphere, or meso-level social and further in the direction of individual and col-
political institutions (Bryant and Hall, 1994; lective agency and related forms of a renewed
Rueschemeyer and Rueschemeyer 1998). In methodological individualism. On the social-
addition to the classical topics of political scientific side, the rational choice approach
society such as political parties and pressure became increasingly influential in compara-
groups, interest has focused on the political tive political sociology. Here, the big catego-
impact of business associations or trade ries of socio-political analysis such as state,
unions, the political role of city or regional bureaucracy, nation and nationalism are stra-
governments; and the various forms of new tegically explained by reference to rational
social movements such as women’s, environ- choices of actors in specific institutional con-
mental, anti-nuclear or civil rights movements texts. Examples of this rational choice
in their cultural repertoires, organizational approach in political sociology are Michael
structure and mobilization patterns (Rucht, Hechter’s Internal Colonialism (1975) or
1990); also important here is the analysis of Margaret Levi’s Of Rule and Revenue (1988).
social capital and its impact on politics and The comparative method used here attempts
political culture (Putnam, 1993). In a cultural to establish general law-like causal state-
and constructivist direction increasing atten- ments about action choice patterns. Another
tion has been focused on social institutions micro-sociological approach represents the
such as prisons or asylums, which were ana- idea of social mechanism that tries to explain
lyzed as part of the ‘micro-physics’ of power context-specific political processes by refer-
(Foucault, 1972; Nash, 2001). Culture, lan- ence to general causal interaction or network
guage, discourse and identity of collective patterns. This approach has been developed
actors have also been investigated, particu- generally by Hedström and Swedberg (1998)
larly, following Thompson (1963), class lan- and used by McAdams et al. (2003, also
guages and identities (e.g., Sewell, 2005) or Tarrow and Tilly, 2007) regarding different
following Bourdieu (1977) cultural capital issues of political contention. The compara-
and discourse patterns (e.g., Wuthnow, 1989). tive method used here tries to identify and
More recently, the media as a medium and an explain variations of political processes. On
actor alike in the public sphere has increas- the cultural-constructivist side, there is a
ingly become a focus (Schudson and Waisbrod, revival of Max Weber’s recourse to action
2004). Connected to the analysis of these orientations and corresponding ideal-types as
various institutions as meso-level foundations components of political institutions and
of politics different kinds of institutionalist behaviour and the related hermeneutic
approaches developed: method of Verstehen and interpretive types of
comparisons (Matthes, 1992). Sometimes
(a) a historical institutionalism oriented to the insti- overlapping with hermeneutic-interpretive
tutional frameworks of path-dependent develop-
approaches, but often based on a construc-
ments;
tivist epistemology, cultural-constructivist
(b) a rational choice institutionalism concentrating
on the interplay of institutional frameworks and approaches attempt to understand the micro-
rational choices of actors; and physics of political power by deconstructing
(c) a cultural institutionalism that concentrated on the epistemological and cultural frameworks
the institutionalized cultural frames or the cul- of political actors. Important examples here
tural construction of institutions (Hall and Taylor, are in particular in the area of post-colonial

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 10 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 111

studies (e.g., Comaroff and Comaroff, 1991; breakdown of communism as a system as well
Cooper, 2003; or Ferguson, 2006). This as a political ideology. This caesura was fol-
deconstructivist method, however, is prima- lowed by attempts to catch-up to Western
rily oriented to uncover the cultural frames of modernity through political transition and
individual and collective behaviour and social transformation processes in the post-
seldom used for systematic comparisons. communist Second World, but with repercus-
In comparison to variable-oriented com- sions also for socialist and communist states
parative methods in cross-cultural political and movements in the non-Western Third
modernization research, the trend in political World. As a corollary to this there has been a
sociology to examine the micro-foundations decisive renewal of comparative political mac-
of politics clearly advances qualitative, con- ro-sociology in the form of transition and
text-bound case-oriented methods of com- transformation research on the foundations of
parison. In social-scientific approaches there a revised modernization framework or neo-
is continuity towards generalizing compari- modernization analysis (Bönker et al., 2002).
sons. But with the search for context-bound At the same time, with the diversification of
or case-specific causality, the thrust of com- modernization processes in Western and non-
parative analysis favours case study-oriented Western societies, there has developed also a
comparisons, be it in the form of model- new multiple modernities perspective that has
theoretical, configurational-causal, or varia- criticized the modernist premise of a converg-
tion-finding analysis (Ragin, 1997; Skocpol, ing Westernization of the world and instead
1984; Tilly, 1984). In cultural-constructivist analyzed the dynamics of a variety of different
approaches, even if there is a methodological modernities (Eisenstadt, 2002; Spohn, 2001;
continuum from configurational-causal and Therborn, 1995). In addition to these two
interpretive methods, comparative methods macro-sociological approaches, a third macro-
are mostly oriented to qualitative, interpre- sociological direction has developed around
tive, individualizing and contrasting methods the new area of transnational comparative
in order to understand cultural specificities political sociology looking particularly to the
(Matthes, 1992). As a result, the generalizing process of European integration and enlarge-
orientations in comparative political sociol- ment (Bach, 2000; Wallace and Wallace,
ogy are weakened in favour of individualiz- 2004) as well as the overarching processes of
ing methods of comparison. globalization and its impacts on national poli-
tics (Albrow, 1996; Held, 2005; Held et al.,
1999; Lechner and Boli, 2001; Scholte,
2002).
THE RENEWED COMPARATIVE
The renewal of a revised modernization
MACRO-SOCIOLOGY OF POLITICS: approach has been particularly connected to
NEO-MODERNIZATION ANALYSIS, transition and transformation research on
MULTIPLE MODERNITIES, post-communist countries. Where explicitly
EUROPEANIZATION AND stated, this research has been based on a neo-
GLOBALIZATION modernization analysis that emphasizes not
only objective structures, institutions and
The main counter trend to a macro-sociology functions but also the subjective modernizing
of politics based on a revised modernization action orientations directing the transition
paradigm and complemented by neo-Marxist and transformation of post-communist socie-
macro-approaches was thus a move to a meso- ties and polities (Alexander, 1994; Tiryakian,
and micro-sociology of politics (Adams et al., 1995). Transition research concentrated on
2005; Mahoney and Rueschemeyer, 2003). the various transition paths from authoritar-
In turn, this trend became reversed with a ian, post-totalitarian or totalitarian rule
new instance of macro-political change: the to democratic-constitutional regimes, their

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 11 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


112 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

consolidation, fragility or reversal to authori- religions, related political and cultural pro-
tarianism (Bremmer and Tarras, 1997; Dawisha grammes of modernity and crystallizing in
and Parrot, 1997; Linz and Stepan, 1996). It multiple modernities and paths of moderniza-
has explicitly compared not only the various tion. Of particular importance here are the
post-communist experiences in East-Central different kinds of world religions and
Europe, South-Eastern Europe, Russia and the different ways and strengths of transcendental
Commonwealth of Independent States with orientations that generate tensions and contra-
each other, but also compared them to the dictions between pragmatic and fundamental-
earlier transitions from authoritarian to demo- ist forms of politics or paradoxes of democracy
cratic rule in Southern Europe and South (Eisenstadt, 1999a, 1999b). This research pro-
America as constitutive parts of the third wave gramme has been realized in several studies on
of democratization (Huntington, 1991; Linz Europe (Eisenstadt, 1987; Sachsenmaier and
and Stepan, 1996). Transformation research Riedel, 2002), North and South America
has also looked at the socio-economic proc- (Roniger and Waisman, 2002; Whitehead,
esses of emerging capitalist market economies 2005), Judaism and Israel (Eisenstadt, 1992),
in the form of the shock therapies, privatiza- India and Japan (Dornbos and Kaviraj, 1997;
tion strategies and other economic policies, Eisenstadt, 1996), but opens also approaches to
their relation to the political transition proc- Russia, China, the Islamic civilisation, North
esses as well as their variations (Grancelli, and sub-Saharian Africa (Eisenstadt, 1989).
1995). In a similar direction, the political soci- A third form of comparative political
ology of third-world countries, divided macro-sociology looks at the intensification
between modernization research and world- of transnational and global forces following
system or dependence approaches and con- the collapse or transformation of the com-
fronted with the widespread weakening of munist second world. Against the back-
socialist or communist developmental strate- ground of the formation of the EU and its
gies moved to a neo-modernist mode of trans- enlargement to the East an important field of
formation and transition research (So, 1990). comparative-transnational studies in political
Although the neo-modernist renewal of sociology has become the analysis of the
political macro-sociology used a more open Europeanization of national societies (Bach,
theoretical framework and produced a rapidly 2000; Beichelt et al., 2006; Graziano and
growing comparative research (Andrain and Vink, 2007). Historically, the study of
Apter, 1995; Plattner, 2003; Vanhannen, 1997), European integration was a subject in politi-
it once again was questioned by the many cal science and its sub-discipline of interna-
cases which did not follow prescribed tional relations concentrating primarily on
Western paths to capitalism and democracy the macro-unit of the state in order to explain
and instead preserved the communist frame- the formation and dynamics of a transna-
work or moved in authoritarian or totalitarian tional institutional order (Loth and Wessels,
directions (Centeno and Lopez-Alves, 2001). 2001). After the reunification of Europe fol-
Against this background, the multiple moder- lowing the collapse of Soviet communism,
nities perspective in the tradition of compara- the foundation of the EU after Maastricht in
tive political macro-sociology has been 1992 and the developing eastern enlarge-
developed, particularly by Shmuel Eisenstadt ment, and as a consequence the increasing
and his collaborators, and become increas- impact of the enlarging European integration
ingly influential (Arnason et al., 2005; process on individual societies, sociology,
Arjomand and Tiryakian, 2004; Arnason, and particularly political sociology, brought
2003; Eisenstadt, 2002). In a nut-shell, this in perspectives from below on the social and
approach assumes that there are differing cultural bases of European integration and
kinds and dynamics of world civilisations enlargement. In contrast to political science
on the bases of core institutions and core approaches that concentrate primarily on the

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 12 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 113

political, legal and institutional impacts on contemporary-synchronic direction compar-


European societies, the political sociology of ing structural and cultural variations in the
Europe has looked at the impacts of European multiple forms of globalization in global-
integration particularly on national econo- national and global-local links (Berger and
mies, social policies, public spheres and civil Huntington, 2002; Haynes, 1998; Robertson,
societies (Eder and Giesen, 2002; Lehmbruch 1992). At the same time, there is an increas-
and Scharpf, 2000; Marginson and Sisson, ing tendency not only to concentrate on the
2006). In its comparative orientation, it impact of globalization on Western, but also
concentrates on the varying forms of on non-Western politics and societies
Europeanization not only on old member- (Hoogvelt, 1997; McMichael, 2004; Menzel,
states but combines with post-communist 2000). As well, the issues analyzed take up
transformation research to examine the new the whole range of dimensions and compo-
and prospective member-states (e.g., Eder nents of macro- and micro-analysis in com-
and Spohn, 2005; Grabbe, 2006; Ichijo and parative political sociology (e.g. Huber and
Spohn, 2005; Katzenstein and Byrnes, 2004; Stephens, 2001; Janoski and Wang, 2004;
Spohn and Triandafyllidou, 2003). Weiss, 2005, 2007).
Finally, a growing field of political macro- The renaissance of neo-modernization
sociological research looks increasingly political macro-sociology has thus gone hand
beyond Europe to the impact of globalization in hand with a re-emphasis of variable-
and the emerging world order on nation-states oriented, survey-based and multivariate com-
and the transformation of the interrelation- parative methods (Barnes and Simon, 1998;
ships between the national political sphere and Inglehardt, 2006). At the same time, this
national society, economy and culture. come-back of macro-sociology of politics
Globalization has three general meanings: cum quantitative methods has not been able
to dominate the overall trends in comparative
l the growing interconnection of the world by political sociology. Rather, it combined in
transnational economic, social and cultural, par- different ways with comparative research
ticularly communicative forces; methods more appropriate for the analysis of
l the growing dominance of transnational spaces
individual cases. Accordingly, qualitative
over national societies; the formation of a world
order; and
case-oriented, comparative-historical as well
l a related cognitive dimension of a growing as interpretive-comparative methods have
global consciousness or globality (Held et al., remained in place, either as distinct modes of
1999; Lechner and Boli, 2002; Martinelli, 2005; comparison or in combination with quanti-
Robertson, 1992; Scholte, 2002; Waters, 1995). tative variable-oriented comparative meth-
ods (Abbott, 2001; Ragin, 1997, 2000;
Whereas political science approaches con- Rueschemeyer, 2003).
centrate on the interrelation between global
political and legal institutions and nation-
states and national politics, the political soci-
ology of globalization looks at the economic, CONCLUSION: THE SPACE OF
social and cultural global forces and their COMPARATIVE METHODOLOGY
impact on the nation-state and national polit- IN POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY
ical order (Fobden and Hobson, 2002).
Comparative political sociology then has Political sociology can be characterized as an
two main foci in analysing globalization: a inter-disciplinary research field between
historical-diachronic orientation comparing political science and sociology, moving from
differing degrees of globalization in relation the synthesis of classical foundations in the
to nation-state societies (Mann, 1997; form of macro-sociological political mod-
Osterhammel and Petersson, 2003); and a ernization research through the challenges of

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 13 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


114 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

critical alternatives to political meso- and comparisons in this tradition refer particu-
micro-sociological approaches and to larly to four aspects:
renewed macro-approaches in the form of
neo-modernization analysis, the multiple 1. nation-state societies as units for comparisons;
modernities perspective and transnational/ 2. the relations between components or variables
global orientations. This inter-disciplinary within different national contexts;
development of political sociology where it 3. national configurations of components; and
involved comparison included a widening 4. national configurations within the global system.
and pluralizing of comparative methodology,
encompassing social-scientific generalizing The emergence of critical alternatives
to cultural-scientific individualizing methods against the structural-functional moderniza-
of comparison on macro-, meso- and micro- tion paradigm, however, has been accom-
levels of political-sociological analysis. This panied by a general tendency towards
final section attempts to summarize the wid- qualitative-comparative orientations and
ening, pluralizing, but also compartmental- sometimes even further to a reproduction of
izing, space of comparative methodology and a historicist position of the uniqueness, and
methods in political sociology and concludes thus incomparability, of human experiences.
with a plea for a more energetic intra- and Critical theory and conflict theory were more
inter-disciplinary methodological coopera- interested in reflecting and analysing the
tion in comparative political-sociological contradictory and conflictive nature of
research. Western modernity rather than developing a
Political sociology – like sociology more systematic orientation in comparative
generally – from its classical phase onwards, research on these conflicts and contradic-
has oscillated between generalizing nomoth- tions. Also neo-Marxist approaches, by con-
etic and individualizing idiographic research tinuing the social-scientific mode of analysis,
orientations (Chilcote, 1994; Collier, 1991; were more interested in investigating the
Collins, 1968; Goldstone, 1997; Smelser, contradictory nature of modern capitalism,
1976; Vallier, 1971; Spohn, 1998, 2001). In a class structure and political power rather than
parallel, comparative methodology has been applying a rigorous comparative methodol-
characterized by tensions between social- ogy. Post-modernism and post-colonialism
scientific positions attempting like John as part of the ‘cultural turn’ in the social sci-
Stuart Mill (1872) or Emile Durkheim (1982) ences, sociology and also political sociology
to establish through comparative methods renewed cultural-critical analysis and often
general causal laws, on the one hand, and, on historicist positions on the uniqueness and
the other, cultural-scientific positions insist- authenticity of decentred, fragmented and
ing, like German historicism, on the unique- individualized ‘worlds’. In various ways,
ness of the human condition allowing only therefore, critical alternatives against main-
for comprehension through individualizing stream comparative political macro-sociol-
contrasts, as well as few attempts to mediate ogy also implied a move away from
like Max Weber in his Wissenschaftslehre macro-sociological, cross-cultural and quan-
(1951) between both positions (Hall, 1999; titative methods towards qualitative, herme-
Ragin, 1987). With the crystallization of neutic and deconstructive ones.
modern political sociology in the framework Against this background of critical moves
of the modernization paradigm, however, the against modernist political macro-sociology,
predominating mode became a generalizing comparative political sociology increas-
comparative methodology using particularly ingly looked to the analysis of the micro-
quantitative multivariate statistical techniques foundation of politics. This trend towards
(Dogan and Pelassy, 1984; Przeworksi and context-specific, time/space-bound or grounded
Teune, 1970). As Kohn (1989) summarizes, comparisons continued in social-scientific

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 14 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 115

as well as cultural-scientific modes of analy- developing global system require new meth-
sis. On the social-scientific side, there devel- ods of relational comparisons, starting from
oped particularly three types of causal the premise of entangled rather than inde-
analysis. pendent units of analysis (Kaelble and
Schwierer, 2003). Regarding the analysis of
1. The comparative macro-analysis of specific path- general patterns of globalization, generaliz-
dependent configurations (in contrast to the ing, data-based, multivariate comparisons are
application of theoretical models or interpretive generally used, but the analysis of different
analysis, see Skocpol, 1984, also Rueschemeyer forms of globalizations or ‘glocalizations’
et al., 1992: 12–39);
(interconnecting the global and the local)
2. Comparisons of the social mechanisms of politi-
cal processes that sought variation (in contrast
require again context-bound, variation-
to generalizing, individualizing or encompassing finding or cultural comparative methods
comparisons, eg., Tilly, 1984); and (cf., Landman, 2003).
3. General models of rational choices as basis of The complex space of comparative method-
social actions in institutional contexts. ology in political sociology is thus character-
ized by an increasing methodical pluralism,
On the cultural-scientific side, there can be but at the same time there is also, under the
distinguished individualising comparisons pressures of academic specialization, a ten-
between a few cases (Skocpol, 1984); con- dency towards intra- and interdisciplinary
trasting deconstructive comparisons of dif- compartmentalisation and segmentation. The
ferent cultural institutions, symbolic systems, challenging task therefore is to combine more
meaning structures or discourses (Sewell, strategically than often done the different
1998; 2005); as well as intercultural or tran- comparative methods on the levels of episte-
scultural comparisons of mutual communica- mologies, theoretical approaches, research
tion, perception, definition of self and the strategies and research agendas. This would
other and understanding (Matthes, 1992). A particularly require to link comparisons of
few attempts have been also made to com- socio-political macro-configurations with
bine quantitative and qualitative methods of comparisons of institutional meso-settings as
comparative inquiry, particularly Charles well as micro-levels of individual and collec-
Ragin (1987, 2000) or Andrew Abbott (2001), tive action; to bring together social-scientific
but these have been rarely applied in actual quantitative and cultural-scientific case-
political-sociological studies. oriented comparisons; to make systematic use
The renewal of political macro-sociology of historical comparative analyses; and to con-
has meant continued comparative research centrate, under the conditions of an increas-
characterized by the use of quantitative mul- ingly globalizing world, on the varying
tivariate methods in cross-cultural compari- entanglements between the global, the national
sons (Dogan and Pelassy, 1984). The scope and the local. A crucial academic precondition
of international comparisons has decisively for attacking this task would be to enhance
expanded with the third wave of democrati- considerably intra-, inter-disciplinary and
zation and related transition and transforma- trans-disciplinary cooperation in political
tion research. At the same time, the renewal sociology and its reference disciplines of soci-
of political macro-sociology has included ology and political science (Hall, 1999).
also cultural-constructive approaches, such
as the multiple modernities perspective, thus
requiring configurative, cultural and individual- NOTES
ising comparative methods on the macro-level,
particularly in the form of inter-civilizational 1. There is no generally agreed definition of politi-
comparisons. In addition, the intensifying cal sociology; it changes with the contours of this
globalization processes in the context of a interdisciplinary undertaking in the context of its

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 15 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


116 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

changing subject. On the one hand, the meaning of Almond, G. and Bingham Powell G. (1966)
the ‘social’ creates problems: in many definitions it is Comparative politics: a developmental
identical with society, but with the questioning of approach. Boston: Little, Brown.
the boundaries of the nation-state by transnational Almond, G. and Verba, S. (1963) The civic cul-
and global processes, it is seen as complex social
ture. Political attitudes and democracy in five
network not necessarily coextensive with national
boundaries (e.g., Braungart and Braungart, 2000:
nations. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
197). Moreover, the concentration on the social basis Anderson, B. (1983) Imagined communities.
of politics often implies the exclusion of the ‘cul- London: Verso.
tural’. On the other, the meaning of ‘politics’ deline- Anderson, P. (1979) Passages from antiquity to
ates the political to state, governmental and political feudalism. London: Verso.
institutions instead of taking also into account the Anderson, P. (1980) Lineages of the absolutist
pervasive role of power relations through the whole state. London: Verso.
socio-political space. As well, it tends to abstract Anderson, P. (1991) The origins of postmod-
from the cultural frames and components of the ernism. London: Verso.
political and power (cf., Nash, 2000: 1ff., calling for
Andrain, C.F. and Apter, D.E. (1995) Political
a new political sociology).
2. In contrast to Francis Fukuyama (2006) in his
protest and social change. Analyzing politics.
preface to the new edition of Samuel Huntington London: Macmillan.
(1968, 2003), I hold the view that the self-critical Apter, D. (1965) The politics of modernization.
revision of modernization theory by giving up the Chicago: The Chicago University Press.
structural-functionalist and evolutionary framework Archer, M. (2000) Being human: The problem
does not mean the end of modernization theory as of agency. Cambridge: Cambridge University
such. Rather, the basic categories of modernization Press.
remain in place, now conceived of as analytical tools Arjomand, S. and Tiryakian, E. (2004) Rethinking
in search for causal explanations; as a set of norma- civilizational analysis. Leiden: Brill.
tive-ideal-typical orientations instead of universal real
Arnason, J. (2003) Civilizations in dispute:
types of socio-political evolution; and as political
developments based on agency and culture rather
Historical questions and theoretical ques-
than objective processes of structural evolution tions. Leiden: Brill
(Tiryakian, 1990). In this sense, mainstream Arnason, J., Eisenstadt, S. and Wittrock, B.
modernization theory has moved from structural- (2005) Axial age civilizations and world
functional system theory of socio-political evolution history. Leiden: Brill.
to a historical-contextual and agency based analytical Aron, R. (1950) ‘Social Structure and the Ruling
framework. At the same time, this revisionism does Class’, British Journal of Sociology, 1(1) 1–16
not prevent the predominant mainstream projection and 1(2)126–143.
of Western modernity to the political development in Aron, R. (1967) Eighteen lectures on industrial
European history as well as non-Western societies.
society. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.
Bach, M. (ed.) (2000) Europäisierung nationaler
gesellschaften. Opladen: Westdeutscher
Verlag.
REFERENCES Barnes, S.H. and Simon, J. (eds) (1998) The
postcommunist citizen. Budapest: Erasmus
Abbott, A. (2001) Time matters: On theory and Foundation.
method. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Bartolovich, C. and Lazarus, N. (eds) (2002)
Adams, J., Clemens, E. and Orloff, A. (eds) Marxism, modernity and postcolonial stud-
(2005) Remaking modernity. Politics, history, ies. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
and sociology. Durham, London: Duke Press.
University Press. Bayart, J.-F. (1993) The state in Africa. Oxford:
Albrow, M. (1996) The global age. CA: Stanford Oxford University Press.
University Press. Beichelt, T., Chotuj, B., Rowe, G. and Wagner,
Alexander, J. (1994) ‘Modern, anti, post, and H.-J. (2006) Europastudien. Eine Einführung,
neo: How social theories tried to understand Wiesbaden: Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.
the ‘new world’ of ‘our time’’, Zeitschrift für Bellah, R. (1981) Varieties of civil religion.
Soziologie, 23 (1): 165–97. New York.

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 16 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 117

Bendix, R. (ed.) (1973) State and society. A sociology (2nd edition). Princeton, NJ:
reader in comparative political sociology. Princeton University Press, pp. 355–78.
Berkeley: University of California Press. Casanova, J. (1994) Public religions in the
Bendix, R. (1977) Nation-building and citizen- modern world. Chicago: Chicago University
ship. Berkeley: University of California Press. Press.
Bendix, R. (1978) Kings and people. Berkeley: Centeno, M. and Alves–Lopez, J. (2001) The
University of California Press. other mirror. Grand theory in the lens of
Bendix, R. and Lipset, S.M. (1967) ‘The field of Latin–America. NJ: Princeton University
political sociology’, in L. Coser (ed.), Political Press.
sociology. New York: Harper and Row, Charrad, M. (2001) States and women’s rights:
pp. 9–47. The making of postcolonial Tunisia, Algeria,
Berger, P. and Huntington, S. (2002) and Morocco. Berkeley: University of
Globalizations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton California Press.
University Press. Chase-Dunn, C. (1991) Global formations.
Binder, L., Coleman, J. S., LaPalombara, J., Pye, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University
L.W., Verba, S. and Weiner, M. (eds) (1971) Press.
Crises and sequences in political develop- Chaturvedi, V. (ed.) (2000) Mapping subaltern
ment. NJ: Princeton University Press. studies and the postcolonial. London: Verso.
Black, C. (1966) Dynamics of modernization. Chilcote, R. (1994) Theories of comparative
New York: Harper & Row. politics (2nd ed.) Boulder, CO: Westview
Bollen, K.A. (1980) ‘Issues in the comparative Press.
measurement of political democracy’, Chirot, D. (1996) Modern tyrants. Berkeley:
American Sociological Review, 45 (2): University of California Press.
370–90. Collier, D. (1991) ‘The comparative method:
Bönker, F., Müller, K. and Pickel, A. (eds) Two decades of change’, in D. Rustow and
(2002) Postcommunist transformation in the K. Erickson (eds.), Comparative political
social sciences. Lanham, RI: Roweman & dynamics. New York: HarperCollins.
Littlefield. Collins, R. (1968) ‘A comparative approach to
Bottomore, T. (1979) Political sociology. New political sociology’, in R. Bendix (ed.), State
York: Harper and Row. and Society. Berkeley: University of California
Bourdieu, P. (1984) Distinction: A social cri- Press.
tique of the judgement of taste. Trans. R. Comaroff, J. and Comaroff, J. (1991) Of revela-
Nice. London: Routledge. tion and revolution. Chicago: Chicago
Bourdieu, P. (1987) Outline of a theory of prac- University Press.
tice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Conrad, S. and Randeria, S. (eds) (2002) Jenseits
Braungart, R.G. and Braungart, M.M. (2000) des eurozentrismus. Postkoloniale per-
‘International political sociology’, Current spektiven in den geschichts - und kulturwis-
Sociology, 50 (2): 197–217. senschaften. Frankfurt/M.: Campus.
Bremmer, I. and Taras, R. (Eds.) (1997) New Cooper, F. (2003) Colonialism in question.
states, new politics: Building the post–soviet Theory, knowledge, history. Berkeley:
nations. New York: Cambridge University University of California Press.
Press. Coser, L.A. (ed.) (1967) Political sociology. New
Brubaker, R. (1992) Citizenship and nation- York: Harper & Row.
hood in France and Germany. Cambridge, Dahl, R.A. (1971) Polyarchy: Participation and
MA: Harvard University Press. opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Bryant, C. and Hall, J.A. (eds) (1994) Civil soci- Press.
ety. Theoretical, historical and comparative Dahrendorf, R. (1965) Gesellschaft und freiheit
perspectives. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge in deutschland. München: Piper.
University Press. Dawisha, K. and Parrot, B. (eds) (1997)
Carruthers, B.G. (2005) ‘The sociology of The consolidation of democracy in east–
money and credit’, in N. Smelser and R. central Europe. MA: Cambridge University
Swedberg (eds), The handbook of economic Press.

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 17 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


118 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

De Swaan, A. (1988) In care of the state: sociology. A reader. New York: Basic Books,
Health care, education and welfare in Europe pp. 3–23.
and the USA, Cambridge: Polity Press. Eisenstadt, S.N. (ed.) (1971) Political sociology.
Deutsch, K. (1966) Nationalism and social com- A reader. New York: Basic Books.
munication. An inquiry in the foundations of Eisenstadt, S.N. (1987) The European civiliza-
nationality. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. tion in comparative perspective. Oslo:
(Original work published 1953). Scandinavian University Press.
Diamond, L. (1999) Developing democracy. Eisenstadt, S.N. (ed.) (1989) Patterns of mod-
Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University ernization (2 vols.) Leiden: Brill.
Press. Eisenstadt, S.N. (1992) Jewish civilization. The
Diamond, L. and Plattner, M. (2002) Democracy Jewish historical experience in comparative
after communism. Baltimore, MD: The John perspective. New York: State University of
Hopkins University Press. New York Press.
Diamond, L., Linz, J. and Lipset, S.M. (1995) Eisenstadt, S.N. (1996) The Japanese civiliza-
Politics in developing countries: comparing tion. A Comparative View. Chicago: Chicago
experiences with democracy. Boulder, CO: University Press.
Rienner Publishers. Eisenstadt, S.N. (1999a) Paradoxes of democ-
Dogan, M. and Pelassy, D. (1984) How to com- racy. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins
pare nations: Strategies in comparative poli- University Press.
tics. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House. Eisenstadt, S.N. (1999b) Fundamentalism,
Domhoff, G.W. (1967) Who rules America? sectarianism and revolution: The Jacobin
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Dimension of Modernity. Cambridge:
Domhoff, G.W. (2001) Who rules America? Cambridge University Press.
Power and politics. Boston: McGraw-Hill. Eisenstadt, S.N. (ed.) (2002) Multiple moderni-
Dornbos, M. and Kaviraj, S. (eds) (1997) ties. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.
Dynamics of state formation. India and Eisenstadt, S.N. and Rokkan, S. (eds) (1973)
Europe. New York: Sage. Building states and nations. Beverly Hills:
Durkheim, E. (1982) The rules of sociological Sage.
method. New York: The Free Press. Eisenstadt, S.N., Roniger, L. and Seligman, A.
Duverger, M. (1972) The study of politics. (1987) Centre formation, protest movements
London: Nelson. and class structure in Europe and the United
Easton, D. (1953) The political system: An States. Leiden: Brill.
inquiry into the state of political science. Ertmann, T. (1997) Birth of the Leviathan.
New York: A. Knopf. Building states and regimes in early modern
Eckstein, H. (1971) A perspective on compara- Europe. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge
tive politics, past and present. In H. Eckstein, University Press.
H. and D. Apter (eds), Comparative politics. A Esping-Andersson, G. (1990) Three worlds of
reader. New York: The Free Press, pp. 1–33. welfare capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Eder, K. and Giesen, B. (2002) European citi- University Press.
zenship. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Evans, P., Rueschemeyer, D. and Skocpol, T.
Eder, K. and Spohn, W. (2005) European iden- (1985) Bringing the state back in. Cambridge,
tity and collective memory. The effects of UK: Cambridge University Press
integration and enlargement. Aldershot: Ferguson, J. (2006) Global shadows. Africa in
Ashgate. the neo-liberal world order. Durham, NC:
Eisenstadt, S.N. (1963) Political systems of Duke University Press.
empire. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Finkle, J. and Gable, R. (eds.) (1966) Political
Publisher. development and social change. New York:
Eisenstadt, S.N. (1966) Modernization. Protest John Wiley.
and change. Englewood, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Fobden, S. and Hobson, J.M. (2002) Histo-
Eisenstadt, S.N. (1971) ‘General introduction: rical sociology and international rela-
The scope and development of political soci- tions. Cambridge: Cambridge University
ology’, in S.N. Eisenstadt (ed.), Political Press.

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 18 3/11/2009 3:41:19 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 119

Foucault, M. (1972) The archaeology of knowl- Hall, J.R. (1999) Cultures of inquiry. From
edge. London: Tavistock. epistemology to discourse in sociohistorical
Fukuyama, F. (2006) ‘Foreword’, in S.P. research. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Huntington, Political Order in Changing Press.
Societies. Yale: Yale University Press. Hall, P. and Taylor, R. (1996) ‘Political science
Geertz, C. (1963) Old societies and new states. and the three institutionalisms’, Political
The quest for modernity in Asia and Africa. Studies, 44 (3): 936–57.
London: Free Press. Haynes, J. (1998) Religion in global politics.
Gellner, E. (1983) Nations and nationalism. New York: Longman.
London: Verso. Haynes, J. (2005) Comparative politics in a glo-
Giddens, A. (1973) The class structure of the balizing world. Oxford: Polity Press.
advanced societies. London: Hutchinson. Hechter, M. (1975) Internal colonialism. The
Giddens, A. (1985) Nation-state and violence. Celtic fringe in British national development,
Berkeley: University of California Press. 1536–1966. London: Routledge.
Goldstone, J. (1991) Revolution and rebellion in Hedström, P. and Swedberg, R. (eds) (1998)
the early modern world. Berkeley: University Social mechanism: An analytical approach to
of California Press. social theory. New York: Cambridge
Goldstone, J. (1997) ‘Methodological issues in University Press.
comparative macro-sociology’, Comparative Held, D. (2005) Democracy and the global
Social Research, 16: 107–20. order. Cambridge, UK: Polity.
Gorski, P. (2003) The disciplinary revolution. Held, D., McGrew, A., Goldblatt, D. and
Calvinism, confessionalism and the growth Perraton, J. (1999) Global transformations:
of state power in early modern Europe. Politics, economics and culture. Oxford:
Chicago: Chicago University Press. Polity Press.
Grabbe, H. (2006) The EU’s transformative Hoogvelt, A. (1997) Globalization and the
power. Europeanization through condition- postcolonial world. London: McMillan.
ality in Central and Eastern Europe. Palgrave, Huber, E. and Stephens, J. (2001) Development
Macmillan. and crisis of the welfare state. Parties and
Gramsci, A. (1971) Selections from prison policies in global markets. Chicago, IL:
notebooks. London: Lawrence and Wishart. University of Chicago Press.
Grancelli. B. (ed.) (1995) Social change and Huntington, S.P. (1968/2003) Political order in
modernization. Lessons from eastern Europe. changing societies. New Haven: Yale
Berlin: Gruyter. University Press.
Graziano, P. and Vink, M. (eds) (2007) Huntington, S.P. (1991) The third wave:
Europeanization: New research agendas. Democratization in the late twentieth century.
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press.
Greenfield, L. (1993) Nationalism. Five roads to Huntington, S.P. (1996) The clash of civilizations.
modernity. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
University Press. Ichijo, A. and Spohn, W. (Eds.) (2005) Entangled
Grew, R. (1978) Crisis of political development identities. Europe and the nation. Aldershot:
in Europe and the United States. Princeton, Ashgate.
NJ: Princeton University Press. Inglehardt, R. (1990) Culture shift in advanced
Habermas, J. (1989) The structural transforma- industrial society. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
tion of the public sphere. An inquiry into a University Press.
category of bourgeois society. Cambridge, Inglehardt, R. (1997) Modernization and post-
MA: MIT Press. modernization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Hall, J.A. (1986) International orders. Oxford: University Press.
Polity Press. Inglehardt, R. (2006) Modernization, postmod-
Hall, J.A. and Schroeder, R. (Eds.) (2006) An ernization and democracy. Cambridge, UK:
anatomy of power. The social theory of Cambridge University Press.
Michael Mann. Cambridge: Cambridge Janoski, T., Alford, R., Hicks, A. and Schwartz, M.
University Press. (Eds.) (2004) The handbook of political

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 19 3/11/2009 3:41:20 PM


120 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

sociology. States, civil society and globaliza- Kohn, M. (ed) (1989) Cross-national research in
tion. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University sociology. Newbury Press.
Press. Kumar, K. (2000) ‘Industrialization and mod-
Janoski, T. and Wang, F. (2004) ‘The politics of ernization’, in M. Waters (ed.), Modernity.
immigration and national integration’, in T. Critical concepts. London: Routledge.
Janoski, R.R. Alford, A.M. Hicks, and M.A. Kumar, K. (2005) From post-industrial to post-
Schwartz (eds), The handbook of political modern society. London: Routledge.
sociology. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge Laclau, E. and Mouffe, C. (2001) Hegemony
University Press, pp. 630–54. and socialist strategy. Towards a radical
Joppke, C. (1999) Immigration and the nation– democratic politics (2nd edition) London:
state, the United States, Germany and Great Verso.
Britain. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Laitin, D. (1992) Language repertoires and
Kaelble, H. and Schwierer, J. (eds) (2003) state construction in Africa. Cambridge:
Transfer und vergleich. Komparatistik in den Cambridge University Press.
sozial-, geschichts – und kulturwissenschaf- Landman, T. (2003) Issues and methods in
ten. Frankfurt/M: Campus. comparative politics. An introduction (2nd
Kamrava, M. (1993) Politics and society in the edition) London: Routledge.
third world. London: Routledge. LaPalombara, J. (ed.) (1963) Bureaucracy and
Katzenstein, P. and Byrnes, T. (eds) (2004) political development. Princeton, NJ:
Religion in an expanding Europe. Cambridge: Princeton University Press.
Cambridge University Press. Latham, M. (1997) Modernization as ideology.
Katznelson, I. and Zolberg, A. (eds) (1986) American social science and ‘nation–build-
Working-class formation. Princeton, NJ: ing’ in the Kennedy era. Duke, NC: University
Princeton University Press. of North Carolina Press.
Keane, J. (ed.) (1988) Civil society and the Lazarus, N. (2001) ‘Unsystematic fingers at the
state: New European Perspectives. London: conditions of the times: “Afropop” and the
Verso. paradoxes of imperialism’, in G. Castle (ed.),
Keane, J. (1998) Civil society. Cambridge: Polity Postcolonial Discourses. Oxford, Blackwell,
Press. pp. 232–50.
Kimmerling, B. (ed.) (1996) Trend report: Lechner, F. and Boli, J. (2001) Globalization. A
Political sociology at the crossroads?, Current reader. London: Sage.
Sociology, 44 (3), 152–76. Lehmbruch, G. and Scharpf, F. (2000)
Kiser, E. and Hechter, M. (1998) ‘The debate Europäische sozialpolitik. Frankfurt/M:
on historical sociology, rational choice and Suhrkamp.
its critics’, American Journal of Sociology, Lerner, D. (1965) The passing of traditional
104: 785–816. society. Modernizing the Middle East. New
Kiser, E. and Kane, J. (2001) ‘Revolution and York: Freedom.
State Structure: The Bureaucratization of Tax Levi, M. (1988) Of rule and revenue. Berkley,
Administration in Early Modern England and CA: University of California Press.
France’, American Journal of Sociology, 107 Linz, J. (2006) Robert Michels, political sociol-
(1): 183–22. ogy, and the future of democracy. New
Knöbl, W. (1998) Polizei und herrschaft im Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publisher.
modernisierungsprozess. Staatsbildung und Linz, J. and Stepan, A. (1996) Problems of
innere sicherheit in Deutschland, England transition and consolidation of demo-
und Amerika, 1770–1914. Frankfurt/M.: cracy. Southern Europe, South America
Campus. and postcommunist Eastern Europe.
Knöbl, W. (2001) Spielräume der modernisie- Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University
rung. Das ende der eindeutigkeit. Weilerswist: Press.
Vielbrück. Lipset, S.M. (1959) Political man: The social
Knoke, D., Pappi, U., Broadbent, J. and bases of politics. Garden City, NY:
Tsujinaka, M. (1996) Comparing policy net- Doubleday.
works. New York: Cambridge University Lipset, S.M. (1984) ‘Social conflict, legitimacy
Press. and democracy’, in W. Connolly (ed.),

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 20 3/11/2009 3:41:20 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 121

Legitimacy and the state. New York: New McDaniel, T. (1989) Autocracy, modernization
York University Press, pp. 88–103. and revolution in Russia. Princeton, NJ:
Lipset, S.M. (1994) ‘The social requisites of Princeton University Press.
democracy revisited’, American Sociological McDaniel, T. (1991) Autocracy, modernization
Review, 59 (1): 1–22. and revolution in Russia and Iran. Princeton,
Lipset, S.M. (ed.) (1998) Democracy in Europe NJ: Princeton University Press.
and the Americas. Washington, DC: McMichael, P. (2004) Development and social
Congressional Quarterly. change (3rd edition) Thousand Oaks, CA:
Lipset, S.M. and Rokkan, S. (1967) Party Pine Forge.
systems and voter alignments: Cross– Menzel, U. (2000) Globalisierung und frag-
national perspectives. New York: Free mentierung. Frankfurt/M: Suhrkamp.
Press. Meyer, J., Boli, J., Thomas, G. and Ramirez, F.
Lister, R. (2002) ‘Citizenship and gender’, in (1997) ‘World society and the nation-
K. Nash and A. Scott (eds), The Blackwell state’, American Journal of Sociology, 103:
companion to political sociology. Cambridge, 144–81.
UK: Blackwell, pp. 323–32. Miliband, R. (1977) Marxism and politics.
Loth, W. and Wessels, W. (eds) (2001) Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Theorien europäischer integration. Opladen: Mill, J. S. (1872) On Liberty. Boston: James R.
Westdeutscher Verlag. Osgood.
Lukes. S. (1972) Emile Durkheim: His life and Mills, C. W. (1956) The power elite. New York:
work. New York: Harper & Row. Oxford University Press.
Mahoney, J. and Rueschemeyer, D. (2003) Mommsen, W. and Osterhammel, J. (1987)
Historical analysis in the social sciences. Max Weber and his contemporaries. London:
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hyman.
Mann, M. (1986/1993) The sources of social Moore, B. (1966) Social Origins of Dictatorship
power (2 vols.) Cambridge. MA: Cambridge and Democracy. Lord and peasant in the
University Press. making of the modern world. Boston: Beacon
Mann M. (1997) ‘Has globalization ended Press.
the rise and rise of the nation-state?’, Review Moore, B. (1981) Social injustice. The social
of International Political Economy, 4 (3): bases of obedience and revolt. Cambridge,
472–96. MA: Cambridge University Press.
Marginson, P. and Sisson, K. (2006) European Nash, K. (2000) Contemporary political sociol-
integration and industrial relations. Multi- ogy. Globalization, politics and power.
level governance in the making. New York: Oxford: Blackwell.
Palgrave. Nash, K. (2001) ‘The cultural turn in social
Marks, G. and Lipset, S. (1998) Reexamining theory: towards a theory of cultural politics’,
democracy. Newbury Park, CA: Sage. Sociology, 35 (1): 77–92.
Marshall, T. (1964) Class, citizenship and social Nash, K. and Scott, A. (2004) The Blackwell
development. Garden City, NY: Doubleday. companion to political sociology. Oxford:
Martinelli, A. (2005) Global modernization. Blackwell.
Rethinking the project of modernity. London: Nedelmann, B. (1997) ‘Between national social-
Sage. ism and real socialism: Political sociology in
Marx, A. (1998) Making race and nation. A the federal republic of Germany’, Current
comparison of Brazil. South Africa and the Sociology, 45: 157–86.
United States. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge Offe, C. (1972) Strukturprobleme des kapitalis-
University Press. tischen Staates; Aufsätze zur politischen
Matthes, J. (1992) ‘The operation called verste- Soziologie. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.
hen’, in J. Matthes (ed.), Zwischen den kultu- Offe, C. and Keane, J. (1984) Contradictions of
ren? Göttingen: Vandenhoek & Ruprecht. the welfare state. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
pp. 75–99. Orloff, A. (1993) The politics of pensions: A
McAdam, D., Tarrow, S. and Tilly, C. (2003) comparative analysis of Britain, Canada and
‘Dynamics of contention’, Social Movement the United States, 1880s–1940. Madison:
Studies, 2 (1), 99–102. The University of Wisconsin Press.

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 21 3/11/2009 3:41:20 PM


122 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Orum, A.M. (1983) ‘Political sociology’, in Rucht, D. (1990) Modernisierung und soziale
N. Smelser (ed.), Handbook of sociology. bewegung, Deutschland, Frankreich und
Newbury Park: Sage. USA Im Vergleich. Frankfurt/M: Campus.
Orum, A.M. (1996) ‘Almost a half century of Rueschemeyer, D. (2003) ‘Comparative histori-
political sociology: Trends in the United cal analysis and knowledge accumulation
States’, Current Sociology, 44: 132–51. in the social sciences’, in J. Mahoney and
Osterhammel, J. and Petersson, N. (2003) History D. Rueschemeyer (eds), Comparative histori-
of globalization. Dimension, processes, cal analysis in the social sciences. Cambridge:
epochs. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Cambridge University Press, pp. 3–39.
Press. Rueschemeyer, D., Huber-Stephens, E. and
Owen, D. (2000) ‘Postmodern political sociol- Stephens, J. (1992) Democracy and capitalist
ogy’, in K. Nash and A. Scott (eds), The development. Chicago: Chicago University
Blackwell companion to political sociology. Press.
Oxford: Cambridge University Press, Rueschemeyer, D. and Rueschemeyer, M. (eds)
pp. 71–81. (1998) Participation and democracy East and
Parsons, T. (1977) Societies. Evolutionary and West. Comparisons and Interpretations.
comparative perspectives. Englewood Cliffs, Amonk, NY: Sharpe.
NJ: Prentice Hall. Sachsenmeyer. D. and Riedel, J. (eds) (2002)
Poggi, G. (1978) The development of the Reflections on multiple modernities,
modern state: A sociological introduction. European,Chinese and other interpretations.
Stanford: Stanford University Press. Brill: Leiden.
Poggi, G. (1990) The state: Its nature, develop- Said, E. (1979) Orientalism. New York: Vintage.
ment and prospect. Stanford, CA: Stanford Scholte, J-A. (2000) Globalization. A critical
California Press. introduction. New York: Palgrave
Poggi, G. (2001) Forms of power. Malden, MA: Scholte, J-A. (2002) Governing global finance.
Polity Press. Coventry: University of Warwick.
Poulantzas, N. (1973) Political power and social Schudson, M. and Waisbrod, S. (2004) ‘Toward
classes. London: Verso. a political sociology of the new Media’, in
Przeworski, A. and Teune, H. (1970) The Logic T. Janoski, R.R. Alford, A.M. Hicks, and M.A.
of comparative social inquiry. New York: Schwartz (eds), The Handbook of political
Wiley-Interscience. sociology. Cambridge: Polity, pp. 350–365.
Putnam, R. (1993) Making democracy work: Schwinn, T. (ed.) (2006) Vielfalt und
Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton, einheit der moderne. Wiesbaden: Verlag für
NJ: Princeton University Press. Sozialwissenschaften.
Pye, L. and Verba, S. (1965) Political culture Scott, J. (1991) Who Rules Britain? Cambridge:
and political development. Princeton, NJ: Polity
Princeton University Press. Sewell, W. (1998) ‘Are cultural history and com-
Ragin, C. (1987) The comparative method. parative method compatible?’, in W. Spohn
Moving beyond qualitative and quantitative (ed.), Kulturanalyse und vergleichende
strategies. Berkeley, CA: University of forschung. Comparativ 8 (1): 89–93.
California Press. Sewell, W. (2005) Logics of history. Social
Ragin, C. (2000) Fuzzy-set social science. theory and social transformation. Chicago:
Chicago: Chicago University Press. Chicago University Press.
Robertson, R. (1992) Globalization. Social theory Shils, E. (1977) Center and periphery. Essays in
and global culture. London: Routledge. macro-sociology. Chicago: Chicago University
Rokkan, S., Flora, P., Kuhnle, S. and Urwin, Press.
D.W. (Eds) (1999) State formation, nation- Skocpol, T. (1979) States and social revolu-
building and mass politics in Europe: The tions. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
theory of Stein Rokkan. Oxford, UK: Oxford Press.
University Press. Skocpol, T. (ed.) (1984) Vision and method in
Roniger, L. and Waisman, C. (eds) (2002) historical sociology. Cambridge: Cambridge
Globality and multiple modernities. North University Press.
and Latin America in comparative perspec- Skocpol, T. (1992) Protecting soldiers and
tive. Brighton, UK: Sussex Academic Press. mothers: The political origins of social policy

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 22 3/11/2009 3:41:20 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY 123

in the United States. MA: Belknap Press of Thompson, E.P. (1963) The making of the
Harvard University Press. English working class. Harmondsworth:
Smelser, N. (1976) Comparative methods in the Penguin.
social sciences. Englewood Cliffs Tilly, C. (1968) The vendée. Cambridge, MA:
Smith, A. (1986) Ethnic origins of nations. Harvard University Press.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Tilly, C. (ed.) (1975) The formation of national
Smith, A. (2001) Nationalism. Oxford: Oxford states in Western Europe. Princeton, NJ:
University Press. Princeton University Press.
So, A. (1990) Social change and development. Tilly, C. (1978) From mobilization to revolution.
Modernization, dependency and world- Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
system theories. London: Sage. Tilly, C. (1984) Big structures, large processes,
Soysal, Y. (1994) Limits of Citizenship. Migrants huge comparisons. New York: Russell Sage
and post-national membership in Europe. Foundation.
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Tilly, C. (1990) Coercion, capital and European
Spohn, W. (1998) ‘Cultural analysis and com- states, AD 990–1990. Oxford: Blackwell.
parison in historical sociology’, in W. Spohn Tipps, D. (1973) ‘Modernization theory and the
(ed.), Kulturanalyse und vergleichende forsc- comparative study of societies: A critical per-
hung. Comparativ, pp. 94–120. spective’, Comparative Studies in Society and
Spohn, W. (2001) ‘History and the social sci- History, 15 (2): 199–226.
ences’, in L. Baltes and N. Smelser (eds), Tiryakian, E. (1990) ‘Modernization. Exhumetur
International encyclopaedia of the social and in pace. Rethinking macro-sociology in
behavioral sciences (vol. X) London: Elsivier, the 1990s’, International Sociology, 6 (2):
pp. 6829–35. 165–80.
Spohn, W. (2003) ‘Nationalismus und religion Tiryakian, E.A. (1995) ‘Collective effervescence,
in West- und Osteuropa. Ein historisch-sozio- social change and charisma: Durkheim,
logischer ansatz’, in M. Minkenberg and Weber and 1989’, International Sociology:
U. Willems (eds), Politik und religion, Journal of the International Sociological
Politische Vierteljahresschrift 33. Association, 10 (3): 269.
Spohn, W. and Triandafyllidou, A. (2003) Vallier, I. (ed.) (1971) Comparative methods in
Europeanization, national identities and sociology. Berkeley, CA: University of
migration. Changes in boundary construc- California Press.
tions between Western and Eastern Europe. Vanhanen, T. (1997) Prospects of democracy: A
London: Routledge. study of 172 countries. London: Routledge.
Squire, J. (2004) ‘Feminism and democracy’, in Wallace, H. and Wallace, W. (2004) Policy-
K. Nash and A. Scott (eds), The Blackwell making in the European Union. Oxford:
companion to political sociology. Cambridge, Oxford University Press.
UK: Blackwell, pp. 366–74. Wallerstein, I. (1999) The essential Wallerstein.
Steinmetz, G. (ed.) (1999) State/culture: State Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
formation after the cultural turn. Ithaca, NY: Waters, M. (1995) Globalization. London:
Cornell University Press. Routledge.
Stompka, P. (1994) The sociology of social Weber, M. (1951) The methodology of the
change. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. social sciences. New York: Free Press.
Tarrow, S. and Tilly, C. (2007) Contentious Wiener, A. and Diez, T. (2004) European integra-
politics. Boulder, CO: Paradigm. tion theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Thelen, K. (1999) ‘Historical institutionalism in Weiner, M. (1966) Modernization. The dynam-
comparative politics’, Annual Review of ics of growth. New York: Basic Books.
Political Science, 2: 369–404. Weir, M., Orloff, A.S. and Skocpol, T. (1988)
Therborn, G. (1978) What does the ruling class The politics of social policy in the United
do when it rules? State apparatuses and States. Studies from the project on the fed-
state power under feudalism, capitalism and eral social role. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
socialism. London: New Left Books. University Press.
Therborn, G. (1995) European modernity and Weiss, L. (2005) States in the global economy.
beyond. The trajectory of European societies, Bringing domestic institutions back in.
1945–2000. London: Sage. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 23 3/11/2009 3:41:20 PM


124 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Weiss, L. (2007) The myth of the powerless social and political thought. Notre Dame:
state. Hong Kong: UP Publications. Indiana University Press.
Whitehead, L. (2005) Latin America. A new Zapf, W. (1965) Wandlungen der deutschen
interpretation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton eliten. München: Piper.
University Press. Zapf, W. (1971) Die theorien der modernisie-
Wuthnow, R. (1989) Communities of discourse: rung, Köln: Athenäum.
Ideology and social structure in the reforma- Zaret, D. (1985) The heavenly contract: Ideology
tion, enlightenment and European socialism. and organisation in pre–revolutionary puri-
Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press. tanism. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Yack, B. (1997) The fetishism of modernities:
Epochal self-consciousness in contemporary

9781412919760_Chap06.indd 24 3/11/2009 3:41:20 PM


7
Comparative Institutional
Analysis
Vivien A. Schmidt 1

INTRODUCTION ‘old institutionalism’ prevalent until the early


1950s, which studied the formal institutions
In recent years, the ‘new institutionalism’ has of government, than in countering the
become central to the methodological debates behaviorism that had subsequently largely
in political science. What political scientists eclipsed the old institutionalism with the
mean by new institutionalism, however, study of political behavior (on this history,
beyond the basic tenet that political institu- see Somit and Tanenhaus, 1982; see also
tions are key to the study of political action, Schmidt, 2005). ‘New institutionalism’ was a
is often very different. There are, in fact, a response to the absence of institutional anal-
variety of ‘new institutionalisms’ which focus ysis in political science, and maintained the
on different objects of study, with different importance of considering collective action
logics of explanation, and with very different as collective – through composite or institu-
ways of conceptualizing not just institutions tional actors – as opposed to reducing politi-
but also interests, causes, norms, and ideas. cal action to its methodological individualist
Such differing institutionalisms also deal parts. The theoretical core uniting the very
with the question of institutional change in disparate kinds of institutionalisms that
very different ways. It is only very recently, emerged rejected the proposition that observ-
moreover, that scholars within the different able behavior was the basic datum of number
institutionalisms have made serious attempts of different, readily identifiable approaches,
to bridge these differences, mainly on the divided along continua ranging from univer-
borderline between approaches. salistic to particularistic generalizations,
‘New institutionalism’ began in the late from positivism to constructivism, and from
1970s and early 1980s with the desire of static to more dynamic explanations of polit-
a wide range of scholars to bring institu- ical action.
tions back into the explanation of political From the one ‘new institutionalism’ origi-
action. It was less focused on rejecting the nally defined in the mid 1980s by James March

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 1 3/11/2009 3:43:33 PM


126 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

and Johan Olsen (1984) and the three ‘new


institutionalisms’ elaborated in the mid 1990s RATIONAL CHOICE
by Peter Hall and Rosemary Taylor (1996), we INSTITUTIONALISM
can now identify four main new institutionalist
approaches: the three older ‘new institutional- Rational choice institutionalism emerged
isms’ – rational choice, historical, and socio- from the need to bring institutions back in as
logical institutionalism – plus a fourth newer a way of explaining outcomes that could not
‘new institutionalism’ – discursive institutional- be explained by universal theories of rational
ism. Rational choice institutionalism focuses action without reference to their institutional
on rational actors who pursue their preferences context. This began with those interested in
following a ‘logic of calculation’ within politi- American congressional behavior who found
cal institutions, defined as structures of incen- that conventional rational choice analyses
tives. Historical institutionalism instead details which predicted instability in congressional
the development of political institutions, decision-making due to uncertainties result-
described as regularized patterns and routine ing from the multiplicity of individual pref-
practices, which are the (often unintended) erences and issues (e.g., Riker, 1980) could
outcomes of purposeful choices and histori- not explain the unexpected stability of out-
cally unique initial conditions in a ‘logic of comes. They found the answer in the institu-
path-dependence.’ Sociological institutionalism tional context, in particular, in congressional
sees political institutions as socially constituted rules of procedure that lowered the transac-
and culturally framed, with political agents tion costs of making deals (Shepsle, 1986;
acting according to a ‘logic of appropriateness’ Weingast and Marshall, 1988).
that follows from culturally-specific rules and Their main object of inquiry, however, was
norms. Finally, discursive institutionalism con- not the institutional context itself but rather
siders the ideas and discourse that actors use to the nature of rational action within such insti-
devise, deliberate, and/or legitimize political tutions. For their methods of explaining such
action in institutional context – whether seen as action, moreover, rational choice institution-
incentive structures, regularized practices, or alists owe much to the ‘new economics of
social constructions – according to a ‘logic of organization’ focused on property rights,
communication.’ rent-seeking, and transaction costs with
This chapter analyzes each of the four ‘new regard to the operation and development of
institutionalisms’ in turn in terms of their basic institutions (Moe, 1984; Weingast and
characteristics, their epistemological and onto- Marshall, 1988; Williamson, 1975). Thus,
logical presuppositions, their approaches to they posit rational actors with fixed prefer-
institutional change, and their benefits and ences who calculate strategically to maxi-
drawbacks. In addition, it considers the ways mize those preferences and who, in the
in which these different approaches have in absence of institutions that promote comple-
recent years sought to bridge their differences, mentary behavior through coordination, con-
in particular in the growing dialogues between front collective action problems. Such
rational choice and historical institutionalism collective action problems include the ‘pris-
on the one hand, historical and sociological oners’ dilemma’ and the ‘tragedy of the com-
institutionalism on the other. Importantly, mons,’ where individual actors’ choices can
however, it also shows that the recent turn to only lead to sub-optimal solutions (Elster and
ideas and discourse which is in large part Hylland, 1986; Hardin, 1982; Ostrom, 1990).
responsible for the rise of discursive institu- And they have been elaborated through a
tionalism has roots in all three other institu- variety of theoretical approaches. These
tionalist traditions, and represents a natural include principal agent theories about
progression in these three traditions. how ‘principals’ in national governments

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 2 3/11/2009 3:43:33 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 127

maintain control or gain compliance from the l994). Because rational choice institutionalist
‘agents’ to which they delegate power, explanation works at such a high level of
whether in the US (e.g., Cox and McCubbins, abstraction, it offers a very ‘thin’ definition
1993; McCubbins and Sullivan, 1987) or in of rationality in which individuals qua indi-
the European Union (Pollack, 1997); and viduals are not considered. Moreover, because
theories about delegation in international it has a rather simplistic understanding of
organizations (Martin, 2000) or about the human motivation as interest-based, it misses
collective decision-making traps of suprana- out on the subtleties of human reasons for
tional regional organizations, such as the action (see Mansbridge, 1990).
European Union (Scharpf, 1999). Moreover, The rational choice institutionalist approach
they may explore game-theoretic approaches also has difficulty explaining institutional
to democratic transitions (Przeworski, 1991) change over time, given its assumptions
or offer ‘analytic narratives’ of individual about fixed preferences and its focus on equi-
historical events (Bates et al., 1998). librium conditions (see Blyth, 1997; Green
Rational choice institutionalism focuses and Shapiro, 1994). In addition to being
on the interests and motivations behind static, it can be highly functionalist, because
rational actors’ behavior within given institu- it tends to explain the origins of an institution
tional settings. Its deductive approach to largely in terms of its effects; highly inten-
explanation makes it good at capturing the tionalist, because it assumes that rational
range of reasons actors would normally have actors not only perceive the effects of the
for any action, at identifying the institutional institutions that affect them but can also
incentive structures, at predicting likely out- create and control them; and highly voluntar-
comes, and at bringing out anomalies or ist because they see institutional creation as a
actions that are unexpected given the general quasi-contractual process rather than affected
theory. However, it has difficulty explaining by asymmetries of power (see Bates, 1988;
any anomalies that depart radically from Hall and Taylor, 1996: 952).
interest-motivated action. And problems with Moreover, rational choice institutionalists’
over-generalization abound where the push is emphasis on the self-interested nature of
toward universalistic generalizations human motivation, especially where it is
(Scharpf, l997). Only an approach like ‘actor- assumed to be economic self-interest, is
centered institutionalism’ has largely man- value-laden, and can appear economically
aged to avoid this problem, by developing deterministic. Its normativity results from its
‘bounded generalizations’ about the out- assumptions that political action is motivated
comes of actors’ institutionally-constituted by instrumental rationality alone and that a
strategic interactions through the identifica- utilitarian calculus serves as the universal
tion of subsets of cases in which variance in arbiter of justice (e.g., Elster and Hylland,
policy outcomes can be explained by vari- 1986: 22 – see the critique by Immergut,
ances in the same set of factor constellations 1998: 14). Moreover, rational choice institu-
(i.e., problems, policy legacies, actors’ tionalists generally tend to see institutions in
attributes, and institutional interactions) a positive light (Moe, 2003: 3), and rarely
(Scharpf, 1997). But however ‘bounded’ the question the institutional rules within which
generalizations, rational choice institutional- rational actors seek to maximize their utility,
ism’s very deductiveness, along with its theo- either in terms of the justness of the institu-
retical generality that starts from universal tional rules, the exercise of institutional
claims about rationality, make it difficult if power (see Immergut, 1998: 13), or even
not impossible for it to explain any one indi- in terms of efficiency (e.g., North, 1990).
vidual’s reasons for action or any particular A notable exception is Margaret Levi’s
set of real political events (Green and Shapiro, (1989) Marxian rationalist analysis of the

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 3 3/11/2009 3:43:33 PM


128 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

‘predatory’ state with regard to tax collec- et al., 1992; Thelen, 1999). Path-dependency
tion. But mostly, institutions are assumed to itself ensures that rationality in the strict
be good things that create greater stability for rational choice sense is present only insofar as
rational actors’ utility maximization. institutions are the intended consequences of
actors’ choices. But this is often not the case,
given the unintended consequences of inten-
tional action and the unpredictability of inter-
HISTORICAL INSTITUTIONALISM vening events. As a result, the institutional
structures of the historical institutionalists are
Historical institutionalism has been much not as efficient as they appear to rational
more focused than rational choice institution- choice institutionalists.
alism on the actual institutions, or ‘macro- Moreover, historical institutionalism tends
structures,’ in which political action occurs. to be less universalistic in its generalizations
It began in the late-1970s and early- to mid- than rational choice institutionalism while
1980s by ‘bringing the state back in’ (Evans interests are contextual rather than universally
et al., 1985; Skocpol, 1979; Katzenstein, defined (Thelen, 1999; Zysman, 1994). The
1978), with a focus on how the state struc- result is less general, more ‘mid-range’ theory,
tured action and on how state capacity and which tends to focus on changes in a limited
policy legacies structured outcomes. Very number of countries unified in space and/or
quickly, however, historical institutionalists time or on a specific kind of phenomenon that
began to disaggregate the state into its com- occurs in or affects a range of countries at one
ponent institutional parts (see Blyth and time or across time (Thelen, 1999). But
Vargwese, 1999). Their studies included although more particular in its generalizations,
accounts of how structural constraints implicit the ‘new’ historical institutionalism rarely stays
in France and Britain’s socio-economic at the level of the ‘mere story-telling’ of which
organization affected their political economic it is sometimes accused by rational choice
development (Hall, 1986); of how small institutionalists. Noticeably absent is the focus
European states’ combination of economic on ‘great men’ or ‘great moments’ characteris-
openness with strong welfare states could be tic of more traditional historical approaches in
explained by historically-developed, corpo- the old institutionalism. In fact, the macro-
ratist institutional structures (Katzenstein, historical approach prevalent in most accounts
1985); and of how past welfare state policies tends to emphasize structures and processes
set the conditions for future policies in a much more than the events out of which they
comparison of the US and Britain (Pierson, are constructed, let alone the individuals whose
1994). actions and interests spurred those events.
Institutions, for the historical institutional- Here, too, then, there are no individual actors
ist, are understood not as rationalist structures as such. What is more, any ‘micro-foundational
of incentives but rather as sets of regularized logic’ related to strategic action and rationalist
practices with rule-like qualities that structure calculation is generally missing. Instead, his-
action and outcomes (see Hall and Thelen, torical institutionalist explanation tends to
2006). Historical institutionalists, moreover, follow the logic of path-dependency.
are primarily concerned with sequences in In the logic of path dependency, develop-
development, timing of events, and phases of ment begins with ‘configurative’ moments
political change. They examine not just the (e.g., Collier and Collier, 1991), ‘punctuated
asymmetries of power related to the operation equilibrium’ (Krasner, 1988), or critical junc-
and development of institutions but also the tures which ‘set into motion institutional
path-dependencies and unintended conse- patterns or event chains (with) deterministic
quences that result from such historical devel- properties’ (Mahoney, 2000: 507). Path
opment (Hall and Taylor, 1996: 938; Steinmo dependence is a self-reinforcing sequence of

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 4 3/11/2009 3:43:33 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 129

events which, through positive feedback or Rosemary Taylor (1996: 940–41) term either
self-reinforcing mechanisms, ensure increas- a ‘calculus’ approach – which puts the his-
ing returns that, if lasting over a very long torical institutionalists closer to the rational
time, make for a ‘deep equilibrium’ which is choice institutionalists, albeit still with a pri-
highly resistant to change (Pierson, 2000, macy to historical structures that shape
2004). But as a result, historical institutional- actors’ interests – or a ‘culture’ approach –
ism can appear historically deterministic or which puts them closer to the sociological
even mechanistic given the focus on conti- institutionalists, although here historical
nuities and the assumption that change comes structures add to norms to give meaning to
only in bursts, with stasis in between. actors’ interests and worldview.
A corrective to this problem can be found Examples abound in particular on the
in the work of Kathleen Thelen (2002, 2004) combination of historical institutionalism
and Wolfgang Streeck (Streeck and Thelen, with rational choice institutionalism. Ellen
2005), who theorize about the process Immergut’s (1992) comparative study of
of incremental change. They argue that the healthcare reform explains cross-national
(many) evolutionary changes over time may differences in physicians’ calculations of
be as if not more transformative than the their interests in terms of the way in which
(rarer) revolutionary moments, and they governing structures – as veto-points – affect
therefore replace path dependence with vari- their expectations of future success in limit-
ous processes of path renewal, revision, or ing (or not) reform efforts. Thelen’s (2004)
replacement. They show that institutional study of institutional change in skills regimes
evolution results from certain mechanisms of in Britain, Germany, Japan and the United
change such as ‘displacement’ when actors States turns to rationalist accounts of ongo-
‘defect’ from one set of institutions to another; ing political negotiation focusing on political
‘layering’ in which institutions are amended coalitions and political conflicts to explain
or added to by reformers; ‘drift,’ in which change through layering and conversion.
institutions increasingly fail to do what had Peter Hall in a collaborative project with
been intended as a result of deliberate neglect; David Soskice (2001) embedded a rationalist
‘conversion’ in which institutions are reinter- analysis of firm-centered coordination in a
preted or redirected to new goals, functions, historical institutionalist analysis of the
or purposes; ‘exhaustion’ in which institu- binary division of capitalism into liberal
tions are depleted, and break down (Streeck market economies (e.g., Britain) and coordi-
and Thelen, 2005; Thelen, 2002, 2004). But nated market economies (e.g., Germany), in
although this approach effectively put the seeking micro-foundations for historical
history back into historical institutionalism, institutionalism. Paul Pierson (2004), finally,
by detailing the full panoply of changes that in his study of the dimension of time in
may occur, and by abandoning historical political analysis has used historical institu-
determinism in favor of historical indetermi- tionalism to provide a temporal dimension to
nacy, it mainly describes institutional change. rational choice institutionalism.
It does not explain it. How change is insti- The main question for historical institu-
gated remains unclear, and cannot be ade- tionalists who seek to combine their
quately explained without adding elements approaches with rational choice institutional-
from other analytic approaches (for a fuller ism in an effort to provide micro-foundations
discussion, see Schmidt, 2006b). is how to reconcile historically evolving
The main problem for the historical insti- institutional rules and shifting actor
tutionalists, given their emphasis on struc- preferences with rationalist expectations of
tures, is how to account for human agency. fixed preferences and stable institutions.
For this, historical institutionalists mostly Most often, where the rationalist elements
turn to analyses that add what Peter Hall and in any given analysis become predominant,

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 5 3/11/2009 3:43:33 PM


130 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

historical development gives way to rational- different, primarily rationalist, language (e.g.,
ist logics of coordinated games and systemic Pierson, 2004).
equilibria. Thus, for example, one of the
main criticisms of Hall and Soskice’s account
of the varieties of capitalism is that its
emphasis on complementarity and positive SOCIOLOGICAL INSTITUTIONALISM
feed-back effects from coordination makes
for an explanation which is largely static, Sociological institutionalism, much like his-
overly functionalist and path-dependent, and torical institutionalism, began in the late
unable to account for change (see Crouch, 1970s, mainly in the sociological sub-field of
2005; Morgan et al., 2005; Schmidt, 2002a; organizational theory. Sociological institu-
Chapter 3). By the same token, where the tionalists rejected rationalist assumptions
historical institutionalist is predominant, as about the rationality and efficiency of organi-
in Streeck and Thelen’s (2005) emphasis on zations in particular, to focus instead on the
incremental change, the rationalist elements forms and procedures of organizational life
remain rather thin. This is because where stemming from culturally-specific practices.
macro institutions change all the time, it Although sociological institutionalism has its
becomes difficult to theorize how they struc- origins in the writings of organizational theo-
ture individual actors’ incentives. Moreover, rists (e.g., Meyer and Rowan, 1977; DiMaggio
if some individual actors accept the institu- and Powell, 1991), in political science, the
tions while others are seeking to redirect or seminal work is by James March and Johan
reinterpret them, then actors’ preferences are Olsen (1989), who argued that cultural as
differentially affected by the institutions, and well as historical structures matter, and who
it is impossible a priori to know which ones. have therefore been claimed as often by his-
Rational choice institutionalist theorizing torical institutionalists as by sociological
within the context of incrementalist historical institutionalists. Sociological institutionalist
institutionalism is therefore difficult if not analyses that are particularly significant for
impossible, and we are left only with empiri- political scientists include Frank Dobbin’s
cal investigation of actors’ motivations, (1994) study of nineteenth century railways
their interests, and their ideas within macro- policy, where reasonably similar policies
institutional context (see Schmidt, 2006b). were ‘concealed’ as state actions in the
Although the problems of integrating his- United States but ‘revealed’ as state actions
torical institutionalism and rational choice in France; Neil Fligstein’s (1990) account of
institutionalism are great, research at the bor- the transformation of corporate control as
ders of these two institutionalisms remains resulting from change not just in economic
arguably the most vibrant in political science environments but also in corporate leaders’
today. Rational choice institutionalists them- perceptual lenses; and Yasemin Soysal’s
selves have sought to bridge the gap as well, (1994) contrast of immigration policy in
as evident from the increasing numbers of Europe and America, which showed the
collaborative volumes bringing together top importance of distinctive ‘incorporation
rationalist and historical institutionalist regimes’ for absorbing immigrants based on
scholars (e.g., Katznelson and Weingast, differing models of citizenship. The field of
2005). The main problem with regard to inte- international relations, when not rationalist,
grating approaches is that historical institu- has been particularly affected by sociological
tionalist analyses that take on rational institutionalism (see Finnemore, 1996),
institutionalist elements tend to get taken although it goes under the rubric of ‘con-
over by them, largely because the very structivism.’ Most notable has been Peter
process of translation from historical to ration- Katzenstein’s (1996) edited volume which
alist terms leads many to end up speaking a focuses on how interests develop from state

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 6 3/11/2009 3:43:33 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 131

identities, with norms acting as collective anomalous because they do not fit generally
expectations about the proper behavior for a expected interest-motivations – get lost.
given identity, and with state identities struc- Because such explanations are arrived at
turing national perceptions of defense and inductively rather than deductively, they can
security issues. lend insight into individuals’ reasons for
Institutions, for the sociological institution- action in ways that rational choice institu-
alist, are cast neither as rationalist incentive tionalism cannot, whether they fit the norm
structures nor path-dependent macro- or depart from it. Moreover, because such
structures but rather as the norms, cognitive explanations account contextually for indi-
frames, and meaning systems that guide viduals’ reasons for action, sociological insti-
human action as well as the cultural scripts tutionalism is better able to explain the
and schema diffused through organizational events out of which historical institutional
environments, serving symbolic and ceremo- explanations are constructed. And because
nial purposes rather than just utilitarian ones. sociological institutional explanations
Rationality, moreover, is socially constructed emphasize the role that collective processes
and culturally and historically contingent. It of interpretation and legitimacy play in the
is defined by cultural institutions which set creation and development of institutions,
the limits of the imagination, create shared they can account for the inefficiencies in
understandings and norms that frame actions, institutions that rational choice institutional-
establish basic preferences, shape identity, ism cannot (Meyer and Rowan, 1977; see
and influence interests. Moreover, such insti- discussion in Hall and Taylor, 1996: 953).
tutions constitute the setting within which By the same token, however, because socio-
purposive, goal-oriented action is deemed logical institutionalism makes no universalistic
acceptable according to a ‘logic of appropri- claims about rationality and is generally focused
ateness’ (see March and Olsen, 1989; Meyer on explanation within rather than across cul-
and Rowan, 1977; DiMaggio and Powell, tures, it risks an implicit relativism which leads
1991; see also Campbell, 2004). one to question whether sociological institu-
Sociological institutionalism is thus in tionalism allows for any cross-national gener-
direct contradiction to rationalists’ views of alizations at all. In fact, generalizations are
human behavior as following a ‘logic of cal- possible here too, by invoking similarities as
culation’ which is prior to institutions, by well as differences in cultural norms and identi-
which individuals may be affected but not ties, much in the way of historical institutional-
defined. Instead, it assumes that norms, iden- ism with country-specific institutional structures
tities, and culture constitute interests, and are and processes. The resulting explanation, how-
therefore endogenous because they are ever, involves a lower level of generality and
embedded in culture, as opposed to exoge- less parsimonious, ‘thicker description’ than in
nous (see Ruggie, 1998; Wendt, 1987). As a historical institutionalism, let alone rational
result of the cultural embeddedness of ration- choice institutionalism.
ality, however, sociological institutionalism Finally, rather than appearing either eco-
is sometimes accused by rational choice nomically or historically deterministic, socio-
institutionalists of not allowing for general logical institutionalism can appear culturally
enough explanations, with the ‘cultural deterministic where it emphasizes the cul-
knowledge’ it provides useful mainly as pre- tural routines and rituals to the exclusion of
liminary to rational choice universalization. individual action which breaks out of the
But when the objects of sociological institu- cultural norm, that is, rule-creating action as
tionalism are subsumed under rational choice opposed to rule-following action. Moreover,
explanation, often the very essence of socio- its emphasis on macro-patterns may make it
logical institutionalism – the norms, rules, appear like ‘action without agents’ (Hall
and reasons which are culturally unique or and Taylor, 1996: 954) or, worse, structures

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 7 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


132 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

without agents (see the critique by Checkel, institutionalism (Hay, 2006), and economic
1998: 335). And like the rational choice constructivism (Abdelal et al., in press). But
approach, it too can be too static or equilibrium- these other terms tend to highlight primarily
focused, and unable to account for change the substantive content of ideas in discourse,
over time – although where it adds a histori- whereas our term also encompasses the inter-
cal perspective, it can also show how norms active processes that serve to generate those
are institutionalized, as in the case of the ideas and communicate them to the public.
police and military in postwar Japan and The ‘institutionalism’ in the term, moreover,
Germany (Katzenstein, 1996) or how state suggests that this is not only about the com-
identities can change and pull interests along munication of ideas or ‘text’ but also about
with them, as in the case of anti-militarism in the institutional context in which and through
Germany and Japan (Berger, 1998). which ideas are communicated.
While the boundaries between rational Discursive institutionalism tends to offer
choice and sociological institutionalism tend an analysis of political reality which, although
to be clearly demarcated, the boundaries very different from the other three new insti-
between historical and sociological institu- tutionalisms, nonetheless builds on the others
tionalism have never been, especially since in a complementary manner. Institutions –
historical institutionalists who did not turn whether understood in ‘new institutionalist’
for agency to the strategic action of rational terms as socially constituted, historically
choice institutionalism turned instead to the evolving, or interest-based rules of interac-
cultural norms and ideas of sociological tion that represent incentives, opportunities,
institutionalism. In recent years, however, the and/or constraints for individual and collec-
boundaries between rational choice and soci- tive actors – frame the discourse, serving to
ological institutionalism have also been sof- define repertoires of more or less acceptable
tening, as increasing numbers of scholars (and expectable) ideas and discursive inter-
have been seeking to engage a dialogue actions (see Schmidt, 2002a: Chapter 5).
between the approaches (e.g., Jupille et al., However, discursive institutionalism also
2003). For the moment, though, the gap offers a framework within which to theorize
remains quite large, with the greatest advances about how and when ideas in discursive
mainly by rational choice institutionalists interactions may enable actors to overcome
who have used the results of sociological constraints that explanations in terms of
institutionalist studies for rationalist pur- rational behavior and interests, historical
poses, as in the ‘analytic narratives’ approach rules and regularities, and/or cultural norms
of Robert Bates and colleagues (Bates et al., and frames present as overwhelming impedi-
1998). ments to action. Discursive institutionalism
itself has its sources in the turn to ideas of
scholars immersed in the other three new
institutionalisms, who looked to ideas as a
DISCURSIVE INSTITUTIONALISM way to enable them to explain the dynamics
of institutional change within their own pre-
Discursive institutionalism is the term we ferred institutionalism. But while for some,
will use for the fourth and newest of the ‘new turning to ideas meant staying within the
institutionalisms’ (see Campbell and initial constructs of their own institutionalist
Pederson, 2001; Kjaer and Pederson, 2001; approach, others moved beyond, into discur-
Schmidt, 2002a: Chapter 5; Schmidt, 2008; sive institutionalism, and a primary concern
Schmidt and Radaelli, 2004) – although with ideas and how they are communicated
other terms abound, such as ideational through discourse (for a fuller account see
institutionalism (Hay, 2001), constructivist Schmidt, 2008).

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 8 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 133

Rational choice institutionalism ‘social traps.’ Instead, institutions are better


and the turn to ideas understood as the carriers of ideas or ‘collec-
tive memories,’ which make them objects of
Among rational choice institutionalists, the trust or mistrust and changeable over time
foray into the realm of ideas has remained as actors’ ideas and discourse about them
rather circumscribed. For the most part, ideas change in tandem with changes in their per-
have been cast as mechanisms for choosing formance (Rothstein, 2005: Chapters 1 and 7).
among interests, behaving like switches (or Moreover, if one sees ideas as constitutive of
‘road maps’) that funnel interests down spe- interests, then, as Paul Sabatier demonstrates,
cific policy directions, serving as filters, the dynamics of policymaking can be better
focal points, or lenses that provide policy- cast in terms of the advocacy coalitions that
makers with strategies (see also Bates et al., are differentiable not just in terms of cognitive
1998; Goldstein and Keohane, 1993; ideas – meaning perceptions of objective
Weingast, 1995). Douglass North (1990) interests – but also in their normative ideas –
went farther, by casting ideas as ‘shared meaning perceptions of which interests are
mental modes.’ But if this is the case, then appropriately pursued (Sabatier and Jenkins-
there is nothing to stop ideas from having an Smith, 1993).
effect on the content of interests, and not just Discursive institutionalists who follow in
on the order of interests – which would make the rational choice institutionalist tradition
it impossible for rationalists to continue to do not ignore the material interests, eco-
maintain the artificial separation of ‘objec- nomic in particular, which are at the basis of
tive’ interests from ‘subjective’ ideas about much of the institutional incentive structures
interests, that is, beliefs and desires (see cri- in the rational choice institutionalist litera-
tique in Blyth, 2003: 696–7; also Blyth, ture. But they separate analytically the very
2002: Chapter 2). What is more, taking ideas concept of material interests into material
seriously would force rational choice institu- reality and interests. Whereas they posit
tionalists to abandon a whole range of interests as constituted by ideas and dis-
assumptions, in particular, about fixed pref- course, such that interests cannot be sepa-
erences and neutral institutional incentive rated from ideas about interests, they see
structures, that make for the parsimony of the material reality mostly as separate from
approach and everything that follows from it, interests, and best understood as the setting
including the ability to mathematically model within which or in response to which agents
games rational actors play as opposed to conceive of their interests. Thus, they prob-
those ‘real actors play’ (see Rothstein, 2005: lematize the rationalists’ whole notion of
Chapter 1; Scharpf, 1997). This helps explain ‘objective’ material interests by theorizing
why most rational choice institutionalists interests as subjective responses to material
quickly abandoned the pursuit of ideas. conditions (see Blyth, 2002 and discussion in
For the relatively few rational choice insti- Hay, 2006). Moreover, although they would
tutionalists who nonetheless persisted, and not deny that a certain range of responses to
thereby flipped over into discursive institu- material realities can be expected, given what
tionalism, some of the most knotty problems we know about human rationality (and irra-
could be addressed, such as assumptions tionality), they do deny the validity of rational
about institutions as inherently good (or bad) choice institutionalists’ extrapolation of pre-
and actors as instrumental. If one takes ideas dictions about rational actors’ ‘objective’ and
seriously, as Bo Rothstein argues, institutions fixed preferences from such expected
need no longer be treated as neutral struc- responses. Instead, discursive institutional-
tures of incentives or (worse) the immutable ists take the actual responses to material real-
products of ‘culture’ that lead to inescapable ity as their subject of inquiry.

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 9 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


134 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Historical institutionalism learning process that led to a neo-liberal con-


sensus on European Monetary Union follow-
and the turn to ideas
ing the German exemplar; Craig Parsons’
In the historical institutionalist tradition, the (2003) detailed history of the ways in which
move into ideas has been more significant. French ideas about constructing EU institu-
Here, the question is really where the tipping tions became institutionalized; and my own
point is between historical institutionalists elaboration of the ideas and discourse that
who continue to see institutions as constitu- help explain the different dynamics of change
tive of ideas and those who might better be in the three (rather than just two) varieties of
called discursive institutionalists within a capitalism of Britain, Germany, and France
historical institutionalist tradition because (Schmidt, 2002a: Chapters 5 and 6).
they see ideas as constitutive of institutions For discursive institutionalists in the his-
even if shaped by them. Interestingly enough, torical institutionalist tradition, then, while
even in the book that gave historical institu- the macro-structures and regularized prac-
tionalism its name (Steinmo et al., 1992), the tices that are the subject of historical institu-
few chapters that were focused on ideas – tionalist analysis are significant for shaping
those of Peter Hall, Desmond King, and ideas, ideas can also serve to reshape the
Margaret Weir – take us beyond historical macro-structures and regularized practices.
institutionalism. But whereas Peter Hall’s This suggests another avenue for historical
(1989) earlier edited volume on the adoption institutionalists who seek to go beyond
of Keynesianism ideas remained largely his- description to explanation of ‘what happens.’
torical institutionalist because historical Instead of turning to rational choice or socio-
structures come prior to ideas, influencing logical institutionalism for human agency,
their adoptability, his later article (Hall, both of which are still quite static, as we have
1993) on the introduction of monetarist ideas already seen, they could turn to discursive
in Thatcher’s Britain crossed the line to dis- institutionalism to help explain the
cursive institutionalism, since ideas are cen- dynamics of institutional change, with ideas
tral to change and constitutive of new and discourse providing another kind of
institutions. Desmond King (1999) in his micro-foundational logic to institutional
book on illiberal social policy in Britain and development.
the US makes this move quite explicit through
the focus on the role of ideas and knowledge
in the making of policy, although historical Sociological institutionalism
institutionalism remains in the emphasis on and the turn to ideas
how institutional arrangements facilitated
British reform efforts and hindered US ones. In the sociological institutionalist tradition,
What defines work that is clearly discur- one cannot talk about a move into ideas as
sive institutionalist within the historical insti- such, since ideas have always been at the basis
tutionalist tradition is the focus on ideas as of the approach – as norms, cognitive frames,
explanatory of change, often with a demon- and meaning systems. However, there is also a
stration that such ideas do not fit predictable tipping point here, On the one side are those
‘rationalist’ interests, are underdetermined ‘constructivist’ scholars who see ideas more as
by structural factors, and/or represent a break static ideational structures, as norms and iden-
with historical paths. Examples include Sheri tities constituted by culture, and who therefore
Berman’s (1998) historical contrast between remain largely sociological institutionalist as
the German Social Democrat capitulation per the earlier definition. These include con-
before Nazism and the Swedish Social structivists like Peter Katzenstein and his
Democrats’ success in reinventing socialism; colleagues who show how interests deve-
Kate McNamara’s (1998) account of the loped from state identities structure national

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 10 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 135

perceptions of defense and security issues practices but also as a resource used by entre-
(Katzenstein, 1996). On the other side are preneurial actors to produce and legitimate
those constructivists who more clearly fit those ideas. Their approaches can be divided
under the rubric of discursive institutionalism. into those focused on the ‘coordinative’ dis-
These are the constructivists who, in addition course among policy actors and those more
to putting ideas into cultural context, also put interested in the ‘communicative’ discourse
them into their ‘meaning’ context (e.g., Hay, between political actors and the public (see
2006; Kjaer and Pederson, 2001). They tend Schmidt, 2002: Chapter 5).
to present ideas as more dynamic, that is, as In the coordinative sphere, discursive insti-
norms, frames, and narratives that not only tutionalists tend to emphasize primarily the
establish how actors conceptualize the world individuals and groups at the center of policy
but also enable them to reconceptualize the construction who generate the ideas that
world, serving as a resource to promote form the bases for collective action and iden-
change through ‘structuration’ (Wendt, 1987: tity. Some of these scholars focus on the
359–60), through the diffusion of international loosely connected individuals united by a
norms in developing countries (e.g., common set of ideas in ‘epistemic communi-
Finnemore, 1996), through the reconstruction ties’ in the international arena (Haas, 1992).
of state identities and ideas about European Others target more closely connected indi-
integration (Risse, 2001), through the dis- viduals united by the attempt to put those
semination of neo-liberal ideas in Britain ideas into action through ‘advocacy coali-
(Hay, 2001) or through the continuity and tions’ in localized policy contexts (Sabatier
changes in ideas and values in the politics of and Jenkins-Smith, l993) or through ‘advo-
welfare state adjustment (Schmidt, 2000). cacy networks’ of activists in international
Constructivist discursive institutionalists, politics (Keck and Sikkink, 1998). Yet others
in short, add a focus on values, culture, and single out the individuals who, as ‘entrepre-
norms to the emphasis on the construction of neurs’ (Finnemore and Sikkink, 1998;
interests of the more ‘positivist’ discursive Fligstein and Mara-Drita, 1996) or ‘media-
institutionalists of the rationalist or historical tors’ (Jobert, 1992; Muller, 1995) draw on
institutionalist traditions. But importantly, and articulate the ideas of discursive com-
the ideas in discourse do not only reflect munities and coalitions in particular policy
cultural norms; the discourse through which domains in domestic or international arenas.
they are conveyed, if persuasive, can also In the communicative sphere, discursive
serve to reframe such norms and recreate institutionalists emphasize the use of ideas in
new cultural mores. the mass process of public persuasion in the
political sphere. Some of these scholars focus
on electoral politics and mass opinion (Mutz
Discursive interactions et al., l996), when politicians translate the
ideas developed by policy elites into the
Most of the discursive institutionalists just political platforms that are put to the test
discussed tend to deal mainly with ideas, through voting and elections; others are more
leaving the interactive processes of discourse concerned with the ‘communicative action’
implicit as they discuss the ideas generated, (Habermas, l996) that frames national politi-
accepted, and legitimized by the various cal understandings; yet others, focus on the
actors. Some scholars, however, have gone more specific deliberations in the ‘policy
farther to formalize the interactive processes forums’ of informed publics (Rein and Schön,
of idea generation, acceptance, and legitimi- l991) about the on-going policy initiatives of
zation, and to clarify how they are structured. governments. Exemplary of this is David
They tend to see discourse not only as a Art’s (2006) investigation of the elite-led
set of ideas bringing new rules, values, and public debates about the Nazi past in Germany

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 11 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


136 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

and Austria in the 1980s that engendered very constraints derived from the three newer
different political cultures and partisan poli- institutionalisms are included – whether
tics by the 1990s, and highly contrasting rationalist interests, historical paths, or cul-
results with regard to the rise of the far right. tural norms. The appearance of voluntarism
In all of these approaches, the empirical is especially problematic for scholars who
analysis of institutions and the process of focus only on ideas, where ‘text’ appears
institutional change is very different from without context, occasionally in postmodern-
that found in rationalist, historical, or socio- ist approaches. But even where the context is
logical institutionalism, since it is focused on considered, other problems may arise.
who talks to whom about what when how In discursive approaches that follow in the
and why, in order to show how ideas are gen- sociological institutionalist tradition, there is
erated, debated, adopted, and changed as always the danger that social construction
policymakers, political leaders, and the public goes too far, and that material interests
are persuaded, or not, of the cognitive neces- qua material interests are ignored in favor
sity and normative appropriateness of ideas. of seeing everything as socially con
Institutional context clearly also matters here, structed within a given culture (see the cri-
affecting where who talks to whom about tique of Sikkink, 1991, by Jacobsen, 1995).
what. For example, in ‘simple’ polities (or This leads one to question whether there is
single-actor constellations) where governing anything ‘out there’ at all, mutually recogniz-
activity tends to be channeled through a able across cultures. But while discursive
single authority, mainly the executive – approaches in the sociological institutionalist
countries like Britain and France – the com- tradition may suffer from too much construc-
municative discourse to the general public tivism, those in the rational choice or histori-
tends to be much more elaborate than the cal institutionalist tradition may suffer from
coordinative discourse among policy actors, too much positivism, with political action
since without it governments face sanctions assumed to be motivated by instrumental
ranging from interest group protest to loss of rationality alone, such that cognitive ideas
public confidence and loss of elections. By about interests over-determine the choice
contrast, in ‘compound’ polities where gov- of ideas, crowding out the normative
erning activity tends to be dispersed among values which also color any conceptualiza-
multiple authorities – countries like Germany tion of interest.
and Italy – the coordinative discourse among But all discursive institutionalist
policy actors tends to be much more elabo- approaches, whether positivist or construc-
rate than the communicative discourse to the tivist, may also be overly deterministic with
public, since it is crucial for reaching agree- regard to the role of ideas, seeing the influ-
ment on policy among the many actors ence of ideas everywhere in the way that
involved (see Schmidt, 2002a, 2006a). rational choice institutionalists see instru-
mental rationality everywhere or sociological
institutionalists, cultural rationality. Most
The limits of discursive importantly, ‘stuff happens’. As the histori-
cal institutionalists remind us, processes of
institutionalism
change are often unconscious – as people
Discursive institutionalism, in short, explains may act without any clear sense of what they
the dynamics of change (but also continuity) are doing, creating new practices as a result
through ideas and discursive interactions. As of ‘bricolage’ and destroying old ones as a
such, it largely avoids the static determinism result of ‘drift’ (Thelen, 2004; Streeck and
of the other three ‘new institutionalisms’. By Thelen, 2005; see also Campbell, 2004:
the same token, however, it risks appearing 69–74). But even when there is conscious
highly voluntaristic unless the structural action, when people do have ideas about

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 12 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 137

what they are doing, what they do most often from other variables, to identify it as the
has unintended consequences, not only in an independent variable. But instead of ignoring
historical institutionalist sense because the discourse because of the difficulties, because
outcomes may be unanticipated but also in a it may not be the cause, it is much better to
discursive institutionalist sense because ideas ask when is discourse a cause, that is, when
may be reinterpreted or misunderstood. does discourse serve to reconceptualize inter-
Thus, the big question for discursive insti- ests, to chart new institutional paths, and to
tutionalism in explaining change, once reframe cultural norms. But for this, more
we have established that ideas and discourse work needs to be done on establishing what
do matter and how they matter, is: When do general criteria to use in evaluating what
ideas and discourse matter, that is, when do represents ‘good’ ideas in a discourse (but
they exert a causal influence? And when see Schmidt and Radaelli, 2004) and in
don’t they? establishing when discourse is ‘transforma-
Establishing causality with regard to ideas tive,’ and when not.
and discourse can be problematic. The very Even in the absence of general criteria of
question itself may seem inappropriate to evaluation, empirical investigations have gone
constructivist discursive institutionalists who a long way to demonstrate how and when
see causal logics of explanation as operating ideas and discourse have been transformative.
in a different domain from a constructiv- This has been done through process-
ist logic of interpretation (e.g., Bevir and tracing of ideas held by different actors that
Rhodes, 2003; Wendt, 1999). Other construc- led to different policy choices (Berman,
tivists, however, argue that bracketing off 1998); through matched pairs of country
questions of causality and explanation from cases where everything is controlled for
those of meaning and interpretation is unnec- except the discourse to show the impact of
essary (see Hay, 2004: 145). In fact, whether discourse on welfare adjustment (see
constructivist or positivist, most discursive Schmidt, 2002b); through speeches and
institutionalists see their main explanatory debates of political elites that then lead to
task as that of demonstrating the causal influ- political action (Dobbin, 1994); through
ence of ideas and discourse (e.g., Blyth, opinion polls and surveys to measure the
2003; Hay, 2001; Parsons, 2003; Schmidt, impact of the communicative discourse
2002a: Chapters 5 and 6). (Koopmans, 2004); through interviews and
Discourse, just as any other factor, some- network analysis to gauge the significance of
times matters, sometimes does not in the the coordinative discourse, and more.
explanation of change. The question is when Institutional context also needs to be taken
does it matter, say, by redefining interests as into consideration, however. For example, in
opposed to merely reflecting them in ration- ‘simple’ polities (or ‘single-actor’ systems)
alist calculations, by reshaping historical where the communicative discourse is most
paths as opposed to being shaped by them, or elaborate, the causal influence of discourse is
by recreating cultural norms as opposed to most likely to be ascertainable in the
reifying them (see Schmidt, 2002a: 250–6). responses of the general public over time, as
And when are other factors more significant, discovered through protests and election
say, where the creation of new institutional results, opinion polls, and surveys. By con-
paths or cultural norms may be better cap- trast, in ‘compound’ polities (or ‘multi-actor’
tured by historical or sociological institution- systems) in which the coordinative discourse
alist analysis, because actors don’t have any is most elaborate, the causal influence is
clear idea about what they are doing when more likely to be seen in whether or not there
they are doing it. Part of the reason many is any agreed policy, with empirical investi-
political scientists avoid explanations related gation focused on interviews and reports of
to discourse is that it is difficult to separate it policy actors (Schmidt, 2002a).

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 13 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


138 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

CONCLUSION institutionalism, they are constitutive of inter-


ests, history, and culture in discursive institu-
Thus, the four new institutionalisms – rational tionalism. Moreover, scholars have increasingly
choice, historical, sociological, and discursive been exploring commonalities along the bor-
institutionalism – differ greatly from one ders of their approaches. The most significant
another (see Table 7.1). Each has a different such exploration has been that between the
object of explanation – whether rational behav- older new institutionalisms and the newest,
ior and interests, historical rules and regulari- discursive institutionalism.
ties, cultural norms and frames, or ideas and To get a sense of how all of this fits
discourse; a different logic of explana- together in a very general way, I present a
tion – whether calculation, path-dependency, chart that situates scholars’ work cited above
appropriateness, or communication; different within each of the four institutionalisms
emphases on continuity or change – whether on while arraying the four institutionalisms
continuity through fixed preferences, through along a horizontal continuum from positiv-
path dependency, or through cultural norms, ism to constructivism and from interests to
or on change through ideas and discursive culture, with history in between, and along a
interactions. And they also have different vertical continuum from static to dynamic,
problems of explanation: economic determin- with culture, history, and interests at the
ism for rational choice institutionalism; static end, ideas and discourse at the dynamic
historical determinism for historical institu- end (see Figure 7.1). I put historical institu-
tionalism; cultural determinism or relativism tionalism between rational choice and socio-
for sociological institutionalism; and idea- logical institutionalism, mainly because
tional determinism or relativism for discursive rational choice and sociological institutional-
institutionalism. Adding confusion to all of ism are largely incompatible, whereas his-
this is that concepts may be shared across torical institutionalism can go either to the
institutionalisms, although they have different positivist or the constructivist side when it
uses and functions in the different institution- adds agency. I put discursive institutionalism
alisms. Interest is a concept that has currency underneath all three because, although it is
across institutionalisms, even though distinctive, it can rest upon the insights of
only rational choice institutionalism gives it any one of the three and because scholars
priority over institutions. Ideas also appear often see themselves as continuing to fit in
across institutionalisms, but whereas they one or another of the traditions even as they
come second to interests in rational choice fit best in discursive institutionalism.
institutionalism, to history in historical insti- But although discursive institutionalism
tutionalism, and to culture in sociological thus appears at the bottom of the explanatory

Table 7.1 The four new institutionalisms


Rational choice Historical Sociological Discursive
institutionalism institutionalism institutionalism institutionalism
Object of Rational behavior Historical rules and Cultural norms and Ideas and discourse
explanation and interests regularities frames
Logic of Calculation Path-dependency Appropriateness Communication
explanation
Ability to Static continuity Static continuity Static continuity Dynamic change and
explain change through fixed through path through cultural continuity through
preferences, dependence (except norms, ideational ideas and discursive
stable institutions where incremental frames interaction
change)
Problems of Economic Historical Cultural determinism Ideational determinism
explanation determinism determinism or relativism or relativism

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 14 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 139

Positivism Constructivism

interests history
culture
RI HI SI
…..Skocpol …. …Powell/Dimaggio.. static

Shepsle ……Krasner….
Williams …..Katzenstein 1985….. …Dobbin….
McCubbins/ ….Hall 1986… ….Soysal…
Sullivan …. Hall 2001….
…...Pierson….
Martin ..….Scharpf… …March/Olson…
….Schmidt 2002a ch 3,4…
……Thelen…. …Fligstein….

Goldstein/Keohane
….Weingast.. ...Katzenstein 1996…
..…Hall 1989…
ideas …Hall 1993…
norms
Rothstein …McNamara… …Wendt…
……… Berman … ….Risse….
… Blyth …
…..Haas…. ….Muller/Jobert…
….Sabatier….
……..Hay……

discourse ….Schmidt 2000, 2002a ch 5,6; 2006...


discourse DI
Figure 7.1 Scholars’ use of the four new institutionalisms: Rational choice (RI), Historical
(HI), Sociological (SI), and Discursive (DI)

hierarchy in this figure, lending new insights ideas about rationalist interests and cultural
into the reconceptualization of rationalist norms or the frozen landscapes of macro-
interests, the reshaping of historical paths, and structures and routinized actions prior to our
the reframing of cultural norms, it would be a investigation into the dynamics of change. But
mistake to therefore think of it as something what this in fact illustrates is that rather than
that is secondary to the other three new insti- speaking of explanatory hierarchies, we do
tutionalisms, to be dismissed as not ‘parsimo- best to see each of the four new institutional-
nious’ enough or too micro-foundational (as isms as eminently worthwhile methodological
would dyed-in-the-wool rational choice insti- approaches in their own right, as all engaged
tutionalists) or not a distinctive institutional- in the theoretically and empirically worth-
ism of its own (Campbell, 2004). Rather, it is while enterprise of explaining different parts
better to see it as in a natural progression from of political reality. And most important for
the three older new institutionalisms, or as ensuring future progress in political science,
progress over them. As such, we could flip the therefore, would be to continue to explore
hierarchy over, to present the other three new commonalities at the boundaries of the vari-
institutionalisms as background knowledge to ous approaches, in an effort to build as com-
the discursive institutionalist approach, pro- plete a picture of politics, economics, and
viding useful insights into the crystallized society as we can.

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 15 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


140 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

NOTE Campbell, J.L. and Pedersen, O. (2001) The rise


of neoliberalism and institutional analysis.
1. For an earlier discussion of institutionalism, with Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
a focus on the state, see Schmidt (2005). For a much Checkel, J. (1998) ‘The constructivist turn in
fuller discussion of ‘discursive institutionalism,’ see international relations theory’, World Politics,
Schmidt, 2008. 50 (2): 324–48.
Collier, D. and Collier, R. (1991) Shaping the
political arena. Princeton: Princeton University
Press.
Cox, G. and McCubbins, M. (1993) Legislative
REFERENCES Leviathan: Party Government in the
House, Berkeley: University of California
Abdelal, R., Blyth, M., and Parsons, C. (in press) Press.
The case for economic constructivism. Crouch, C. (2005) Capitalist diversity and
Art, D. (2006) The politics of the Nazi past in change: Recombinant governance and insti-
Germany and Austria. New York: Cambridge tutional entrepreneurs. Oxford: New York:
University Press. Oxford University Press.
Bates, R. (1988) ‘Contra contractarianism: Some DiMaggio, P.J. and Powell, W.W. (1991)
reflections on the new institutionalism’, ‘Introduction’, in W.W. Powell and P.J.
Politics and Society, 16 (2–3): 387–401. DiMaggio (eds), The new institutionalism in
Bates, R., Greif, A., Levi, M., Rosenthal, J.-L. organizational analysis. Chicago: University
and Weingast, B. (1998) Analytic narratives. of Chicago Press, pp. 1–38.
Princeton: Princeton University Press. Dobbin, F. (1994) Forging industrial policy.
Berger, T.U. (1998) Cultures of antimilitarism: Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
National security in Germany and Japan. Elster, J. and Hylland, A. (eds) (1986)
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Foundations of social choice theory.
Berman, S. (1998) The social democratic Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
moment: Ideas and politics in the making of Evans, P., Rueschemeyer, D. and Skocpol, T.
interwar Europe. Cambridge: Harvard (1985) Bringing the state back in. New York:
University Press. Cambridge University Press.
Bevir, M. and Rhodes, R.A.W. (2003) Finnemore, M. (1996) ‘Norms, culture, and
Interpreting British governance. London: world politics: Insights from sociology’s insti-
Routledge. tutionalism’, International Organization, 50
Blyth, M.M. (1997) ‘“Any more bright ideas?” (2): 325–47.
The ideational turn in comparative political Finnemore, M. and Sikkink, K. (1998)
economy’, Comparative Politics, 29 (2): ‘International norm dynamics and political
229–50. change’, International Organization, 52 (2):
Blyth, M.M. (2002) Great transformations: 887–917.
Economic ideas and institutional change in Fligstein, N. (1990) The transformation of cor-
the twentieth century. New York: Cambridge porate control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press. University Press.
Blyth, M.M. (2003) ‘Structures do not come Fligstein, N. and Mara-Drita, I. (1996) ‘How to
with an instruction sheet: Interests, ideas, make a market: Reflections on the attempt
and progress in political science’, Perspectives to create a single market in the European
on Politics, 1 (4): 695–706. Union’, American Journal of Sociology, 102
Blyth, M.M. and Vargwese, R. (1999) ‘The state (1): 1–32.
of the discipline in American political Goldstein, J. and Keohane, R. (1993) Ideas and
science: Be careful what you wish for?’, foreign policy: Beliefs, institutions and
British Journal of Politics and International political change. Ithaca: Cornell University
Relations, 1 (3): 345–65. Press.
Campbell, J.L. (2004) Institutional change and Green, D. and Shapiro, I. (1994) The patholo-
globalization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton gies of rational choice. New Haven: Yale
University Press. University Press.

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 16 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 141

Haas, P.M. (1992) ‘Introduction: Epistemic com- Jacobsen, J.K. (1995) ‘Much ado about ideas:
munities and international policy coordination’, The cognitive factor in economic policy’,
International Organization, 46 (1): 1–35. World Politics, 47 (2): 283–310.
Habermas, J. (1996) Between facts and norms: Jobert, B. (1992) ‘Représentations sociales,
Contributions to a discourse theory. London: controverses et débats dans la conduite des
Polity Press. politiques publiques’, Revue Française de
Hall, P. (1986) Governing the economy: The Science Politique, 42 (2): 219–34.
politics of state intervention in Britain and Jupille, J., Caporaso, J.A. and Checkel, J.T. (eds)
France. New York: Oxford University Press. (2003) ‘Integrating institutions: Rationalism,
Hall, P. (1989) ‘Conclusion’, in P.A. Hall (ed.), constructivism, and the study of the European
The political power of economic ideas: Union’, Comparative Political Studies, 36
Keynesianism across nations. Princeton, NJ: (1–2): 1–2.
Princeton University Press, pp. 361–91. Katzenstein, P.J. (ed.) (1978) Between power
Hall, P. (1993) ‘Policy paradigms, social learn- and plenty. Madison: University of Wisconsin
ing and the state: The case of economic Press.
policy-making in Britain’, Comparative Katzenstein, P. (1985) Small States in World
Politics, 25 (3): 275–96. Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe Ithaca,
Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (2001) ‘Introduction’, in N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
P.A. Hall and D. Soskice (eds), Varieties of Katzenstein, P.J. (ed.) (l996) The culture of
capitalism: The institutional foundations of national security: Norms and identity in
comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford world politics. New York: Columbia University
University Press, pp. 1–71. Press.
Hall, P. and Taylor, R. (1996) ‘Political science Katznelson, I. and Weingast, B.R. (eds) (2005)
and the three new institutionalisms’, Political Preferences and situations: Points of inter-
Studies, 44 (4): 952–73. section between historical and rational
Hall, P. and Thelen, K. (2006) Varieties of choice institutionalism. New York: Russell
Capitalism and Institutional Change, Sage Foundation.
European Politics and Society Newsletter Keck, M.E. and Sikkink, K. (1998) Activists
(Spring). beyond borders: Advocacy networks in inter-
Hardin, R. (1982) Collective action. Baltimore, national politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
MD: Johns Hopkins. Press.
Hay, C. (2001) ‘The “crisis” of Keynesianism King, D. (1999) In the name of liberalism:
and the rise of neoliberalism in Britain: An Illiberal social policy in the United States and
ideational institutionalist approach’, in J.L. Britain. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Campbell and O. Pedersen (eds), The rise of Kjaer, P. and Pederson, O. (2001) ‘Translating
neoliberalism and institutional analysis. Liberalization: Neoliberalism in the Danish
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, Negotiated Economy’, in J. L. Campbell and
pp.193–218. O. Pedersen (eds), The Rise of Neoliberalism
Hay, C. (2004) ‘Taking ideas seriously in explan- and Institutional Analysis. Princeton: Princeton
atory political analysis’, British Journal University Press, pp. 191–248.
of Politics and International Relations, 6 (2): Koopmans, R. (2004) The Transformation of
142–9. Political Mobilisation and Communication
Hay, C. (2006) ‘Constructivist institutionalism’, in European Public Spheres. 5th Fifth
in R. A. W. Rhodes, S. Binder, and B. Rockman Framework Programme of the European
(eds), The Oxford handbook of political insti- Commission. http://europub.wz–berlin.de
tutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press, Krasner, S. (1988) ‘Sovereignty: An institutional
pp. 56–74. perspective’, Comparative Political Studies,
Immergut, E. (1992) Health politics: Interests 21 (1): 66–94.
and institutions in Western Europe. New Levi, M. (1989) Of rule and revenue. Berkeley,
York: Cambridge University Press. CA: University of California Press.
Immergut, E. (1998) ‘The theoretical core of Mahoney, J. (2000) ‘Path Dependence in
the new institutionalism’, Politics and Society, Historical Sociology’, Theory and Society, 29:
26 (1): 5–34. 507–48.

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 17 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


142 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Mansbridge, J. (ed.) (1990) Beyond self- Pierson, P. (2004) Politics in time: History, insti-
interest. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. tutions, and social analysis. Princeton, NJ:
March, J.G. and Olsen, J.P. (1984) ‘The new Princeton University Press.
institutionalism: Organisation factors in polit- Pollack, M. (1997) ‘Delegation, agency, and
ical life’, American Political Science Review, agenda setting in the European Community’,
78 (3): 734–49. International Organization, 51 (1): 99–134.
March, J.G. and Olsen, J.P. (1989) Rediscovering Przeworski, A. (1991) Democracy and the
institutions: The organizational basis of poli- market. Cambridge: Cambridge University
tics. New York: Free Press. Press.
Martin, L. (2000) Democratic commitments. Rein, M. and Schön, D.A. (1991) ‘Frame-reflective
Princeton: Princeton University Press. policy discourse’, in P. Wagner, C.H. Weiss,
McCubbins, M. and Sullivan, T. (eds) (1987) B. Wittrock and H. Wollmann (eds), Social sci-
Congress: Structure and Policy. New York: ences, modern states, national experiences,
Cambridge University Press, 1987. and theoretical crossroads. Cambridge:
McNamara, K. (1998) The currency of ideas: Cambridge University Press, 262–89.
Monetary politics in the European Union. Riker, W. (1980) ‘Implications from the disequi-
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. librium of majority rule for the study of insti-
Meyer, J.W. and Rowan, B. (1977) tutions’, American Political Science Review,
‘Institutionalized organizations: Formal struc- 75: 432–47.
ture as myth and ceremony’, American Risse, T. (2001) ‘Who are we? A Europeanization
Journal of Sociology, 83 (2): 340–63. of national identities?’, in M. Green Cowles,
Moe, T. (1984) ‘The new economics of organi- J. Caporaso, and T. Risse (eds), Transforming
zation’, American Journal of Political Science, Europeanization and domestic change.
28 (4): 739–77. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Moe, T. (2003, April) Power and political insti- Rothstein, B. (2005) Social Traps and the
tutions. Paper presented at conference on Problem of Trust. Cambridge University
Crafting and Operating Institutions, Yale Press, Cambridge.
University, New Haven, CT. Ruggie, J. (1998) ‘What makes the world hang
Morgan, G., Whitley, R., and Moen, E. together? Neo-utilitarianism and the social
(eds) (2005) Changing capitalisms? constructivist challenge’, International
Internationalization, institutional change, Organization, 52 (4): 855–85.
and systems of economic organization. New Sabatier, P. and Jenkins-Smith, H.C. (eds)
York, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (1993) Policy change and learning: An advo-
Muller, P. (1995) ‘Les politiques publiques cacy coalition approach. Boulder, CO:
comme construction d’un rapport au monde’, Westview.
in A. Faure, G. Pollet and P. Warin (eds), La Scharpf, F.W. (1997) Games real actors play.
construction du sens dans les politiques Actor-centered institutionalism in policy
publiques: Débats autour de la notion de research. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
référentiel. Paris: L’Harmattan. Scharpf, F.W. (1999) Governing in Europe.
Mutz, D.C., Sniderman, P.M., and Brody, R.A. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
(1996) Political Persuasion and Attitude Schmidt, V.A. (2000) ‘Values and discourse in
Change. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan the politics of adjustment’, in F.W. Scharpf
Press. and V.A. Schmidt (eds), Welfare and work in
North, D.C. (1990) Institutions, institutional the open economy: Vol 1. From vulnerability
change, and economic performance. to competitiveness. Oxford: Oxford University
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Press, 229–310.
Ostrum, E. (1990) Governing the commons. Schmidt, V.A. (2002a) The futures of European
New York: Cambridge. capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Parsons, Craig (2003) A Certain Idea of Europe. Schmidt, V.A. (2002b) ‘Does discourse matter in
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. the politics of welfare state adjustment?’,
Pierson, P. (1994) Dismantling the welfare Comparative Political Studies, 35 (2): 168–93.
state? Cambridge: Cambridge University Schmidt, V.A. (2005) ‘Institutionalism and the
Press. state’, in C. Hay, D. Marsh and M. Lister

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 18 3/11/2009 3:43:34 PM


COMPARATIVE INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS 143

(eds), The state: Theories and issues. Thelen, K. (1999) ‘Historical institutionalism in
Basingstoke: Palgrave. comparative politics’, in The Annual Review
Schmidt, V.A. (2006a) Democracy in Europe. of Political Science. Palo Alto: Annual Reviews
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Inc., pp. 369–404.
Schmidt, V.A. (2006b, August) Bringing the Thelen, K. (2002) ‘How Institutions Evolve:
state back into the varieties of capitalism Insights from Comparative-Historical
and discourse into the explanation of Analysis’, in J. Mahoney and D. Rueschemeyer
institutional change. Paper prepared for (eds.), Comparative Historical Analysis in the
presentation for the Annual Meetings of the Social Sciences. New York: Cambridge
American Political Science Association, University Press.
Philadelphia, PA. Thelen, K. (2004) How institutions evolve:
Schmidt, V.A. (2008) “Discursive Institutionalism: The political economy of skills in
The Explanatory Power of Ideas and Germany, Britain, the United States, and
Discourse,” Annual Review of Political Science. Japan. New York: Cambridge University
11: 303–26. Press.
Schmidt, V.A. and Radaelli, C. (2004) ‘Conceptual Weingast, B. (1995) ‘A rational choice perspec-
and methodological issues in policy change in tive on the role of ideas: Shared belief sys-
Europe’, West European Politics, 27 (4): 1–28. tems, state sovereignty, and international
Shepsle, K. (1986) ‘Institutional equilibrium cooperation’, Politics and Society, 23 (4):
and equilibrium institutions’, in H.F. 449–64.
Weisburg (ed.), Political science: The science Weingast, B. and Marshall, W. (1988) ‘The
of politics. New York: Agathon, pp. 51–82. industrial organization of Congress’, Journal
Skocpol, T. (1979) States and revolutions. New of Political Economy, 96 (1): 132–63.
York: Cambridge University Press. Wendt, A. (1987) ‘The agent-structure prob-
Somit, A. and Tanenhaus, J. (1982) The devel- lem in international relations theory’,
opment of American political science from International Organization, 41 (3): 335–70.
Burgess to behavioralism. New York: Wendt, A. (1999) Social theory of international
Irvington. relations theory. Cambridge: Cambridge
Soysal, Y. (1994) Limits of citizenship. Chicago: University Press.
University of Chicago Press. Williamson, O. (1975) Markets and hierarchies.
Steinmo, S., Thelen, K., and Longstreh, F. (eds) New York: Free Press.
(1992) Structuring Politics: Historical Zysman, J. (l994) ‘How institutions create his-
Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, torically rooted trajectories of growth’,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3 (1):
Streeck, W. and Thelen, K. (eds) (2005) Beyond 243–83.
Continuity. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

9781412919760_Chap07.indd 19 3/11/2009 3:43:35 PM


8
Comparative Political Economy
Thomas Plümper

INTRODUCTION median-voter theorem (Downs, 1957), the


logic of collective action (Olson, 1965), and
In many research areas interdisciplinary the tragedy of the commons (Hardin, 1968).
research constitutes the rule rather than the Even less commonly known ideas such as
exception. In the social sciences, one research log-rolling (Buchanan and Tullock, 1962),
area exists in which interdisciplinary research political institutions and veto-players
is programmatic: political economy. Over the (Tsebelis, 1995), and the political business
last three decades, political economy has cycle (Hibbs, 1977; Tufte, 1975) are increas-
been one of the fastest growing approaches ingly commonplace on the syllabi of post-
in the social sciences. Political economic graduate courses in political economy.
reasoning has infiltrated virtually all disci- Second, political economists provided
plines and fields of research across the social path-breaking insights into the interaction
sciences. Theories first formulated by politi- between corporations and governments. The
cal economists have improved our under- theory of ‘special interest politics’ (Grossman
standing of social interactions and social and Helpman, 2001) explains why opportun-
order, political behavior and choice and even istic governments, which are solely inter-
market mechanisms in general. ested in their political survival, implement
In comparative politics, political econo- policies that deviate from the interest of the
mists have participated in three major theo- median voter. Clearly, the interaction between
retical developments: First, they helped various types of actors is mediated by the
establish an analytical perspective to politics institutional setting in which political deci-
in which uncovering regularities, patterns sions are being made. Policies in autocracies
and causal mechanisms stand are of primary tend to differ from policies in democracies,
interest rather than person, single events or government spending is usually higher in
unique political orders. The functioning of countries with proportional electoral systems
institutions, the interplay between institu- than in countries with majoritarian electoral
tions and actors, and the interdependencies systems, and presidential democracies are
between different, perhaps seemingly more likely to become autocracies than par-
unrelated political institutions attracted liamentary democracies – to mention just a
the most attention. By now, almost all stu- few predictions of political economic
dents of political science learn about the models.

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 1 3/11/2009 3:44:31 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 145

Third and more recently, political econo- how this class structure simultaneously deter-
mists are at the forefront of explaining how mines the organization of both the economy
government decisions are altered by the and the state. In a Marxian perspective, eco-
increase in global economic integration. Due nomics, political science, and sociology all
to these models, comparative politics stands deal with the same logic. As a consequence,
at the brink of relaxing the assumption that economic, political and social phenomena
policies in one country are independent of may well be analyzed by the same approach.
policies in other countries. Rapidly moving on through history, the
This review discusses the contribution of early 20th century marked the decisive
political economy to comparative politics. In break-up of the social sciences into a variety
particular, I discuss the institutional and the of subdisciplines. To gain legitimacy, propo-
comparative turns in political economy and nents of various subdisciplines were con-
the more recent development toward an cerned about becoming distinguishable from
‘open economy’ political economy – one in what had been called ‘Staatswissenschaft’ in
which policy choices of government partly Germany – and political economy in the
depends on policies in other countries. I will Anglo-Saxon countries. Yet, the postwar
also argue here that the institutional turn period witnessed a slow re-appearance of
fuelled a subsequent comparative turn in political economic approaches. By then, most
political economy. Since institutions do not political economists treated ‘states and mar-
change much over time, a comparative per- kets’ as equally important and partly inde-
spective helps in identifying institutional pendent systems. Charles Lindblom, for
influences on political behavior as well as on example, discusses politics as a struggle over
social and economic outcomes. authority (Lindblom, 1977: 17f.) and markets
as institutions which distribute scarce means
in the absence of political authority. In
this perspective, the state and the market
WHAT IS POLITICAL ECONOMY become equally relevant principles according
AND WHAT DO POLITICAL to which resources are distributed within a
ECONOMISTS DO? society.
All these distinct perspectives have their
Broadly speaking, political economists deal own shortcomings: Smith’s perspective
with market failure, suboptimal political out- appears too narrow, Marx’ framework fails to
comes and trade-offs between various politi- explain the huge differences across ‘capital-
cal goals – among many other issues. ist societies’, and Lindblom’s approach has a
Covering a diverse range of problems, the few blind spots as modern societies are not
various different meanings the umbrella term only about the distribution of authority but
‘political economy’ has had during its long also about non-hierarchical relations and
history hardly comes as a surprise. Perhaps about efficient production. We nevertheless
beginning with Adam Smith’s Wealth of still find elements of all three broad perspec-
Nations some authors define political econ- tives in modern political economy. Many
omy simply as the analysis of how, why, and political economists explain governments’
with what consequences governments inter- intervention into markets by the necessity to
vene in markets. constrain market forces, others explain how
Writing almost a century later, Karl Marx individuals differ and how these differences
further broadened the concept to also include affect and bias political decisions. For exam-
the ‘production’ of political, economic and ple, some interests find it easier to organize,
social order. In Critique of Political Economy some organizations are more influential and
and in Das Kapital Marx perceives the class better organized than others, and more
structure as exogenously given and discusses powerful interest groups have (this borders a

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 2 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


146 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

tautology) a larger influence on political common dilemmas, and principal/agent


decisions than less well organized interests problems are frequently studied phenomena
and unorganized interests. in this area of political economy. Second,
True, these dichotomies are partly mis- political economists study political failure.
leading and largely simplifying. Governments As Allen Drazen (2000: 7) has put it, politi-
do not just interfere into market policies; cal economy ‘begins with the observation
they also guarantee the proper functioning of that actual policies are often quite different
markets by guaranteeing ownership rights from optimal policies.’ Third and finally,
and by securing contracts. Moreover, a free- political economists explore political trade-
market economic order is consistent with offs. Here, the trade-off between the efficient
varying levels of political participation of organization of markets and approximately
workers and with different degrees of politi- equal outcomes of market processes (the
cal intervention into ‘free markets’. And efficiency-equality trade-off) may be the
finally, neither does the market exist free of most famous but hardly the sole trade-off.
authority, nor does the state always use its
monopoly of power.
Due to this messy interaction between
politics and markets, the state and the econ- INGREDIENTS FROM THE POLITICAL
omy, and politics and economics, recent ECONOMISTS’ COOKBOOK
attempts to define the nature of the beast
political economy gave up a clear dominant The aforementioned definitions hardly
dichotomy. Most recent authors define politi- explain why political economy became
cal economy by describing what political important for theoretical and empirical
economists do. Weingast and Wittman advancements in comparative politics. To
(2006) state: understand the influence of political econ-
omy, we have to dig deeper and look into the
Political economy is the methodology of econom-
ics applied to the analysis of political behavior and political economists’ ‘cookbook’. Only this
institutions. As such, it is not a single, unified perspective allows us to observe the signifi-
framework, but a family of approaches. Because cance of political economy for establish-
institutions are no longer ignored, but instead are ing an analytical perspective in political
often the subject matter of investigations, this science.2
approach incorporates many of the issues of con-
cern to political sociologists. Because political
behavior and institutions are themselves a subject
of study, politics also becomes the subject of Opportunistic and ideological
political economy. All of this is tied together by a
set of methodologies, typically associated with parties and politicians
economics, but now part and parcel of political
science itself. (pp. 3–4)1 Modern political economy has its roots in a
discussion of how voters vote and whether
According to Weingast and Wittman, what partisan or opportunistic models explain
political economists do defines the nature political outcomes best. Partisan models
and boundaries of political economy, but assume that parties have a political platform
what about the current work of political which varies relatively little over time and
economists? Without trying to be exhaustive, which makes parties easily distinguishable
I would like to give three answers: First, from each other (Bartels, 2000; Wittman,
political economists analyze political 1977). In contrast, opportunistic models sup-
responses to market failure. The provision pose that (all) parties seek maximizing votes
(or underprovision) of public goods, cooper- or the probability of being in power (Alesina,
ation (and the lack thereof) in the face of 1989; Alesina et al., 1997). If winning

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 3 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 147

elections is the only goal of politicians, then


Voters
they do not have an ideology. They will sup-
port the policy proposal that maximizes their At first glance, how voters vote seems to be a
political support. simple question. Anthony Downs (1957), one
Both set of assumptions seem not entirely of the founding fathers of modern political
unrealistic, but the truth certainly lies some- economy, suggested that voters develop
where in the middle. Even ideological parties rational expectations about their utility from
make concessions if they gain cabinet seats different parties being in power and then vote
in return. Parties cannot afford to have strict for the party that maximizes their utility: ‘To
ideologies if they have to compete with ignore the future when deciding how to vote
purely opportunistic parties. In turn, even (…) would obviously be irrational, since the
opportunistic parties may have ideological purpose of voting is to select a future govern-
positions in some policy dimension, espe- ment.’ (p. 40) This conception of voting
cially since the political market does not behavior translates nicely into a spatial voting
immediately punish strong and unpopular theory: each voter knows his or her individ-
views on a relatively unimportant policy. Yet, ual preferences and the position of the parties
researchers do not have to formulate compli- in all relevant policy dimensions (often, the
cated models and assume a weighted func- number of relevant policy dimensions equals
tion which includes both ideology and 1 by assumption) and vote for the party clos-
opportunism. Rather, the choice of the model est to their own position. In other words, if
often depends on the analytical intention. voters minimize the distance between their
Some researchers perceive opportunistic position and the government’s position, they
models as having a peculiar feature – a fea- maximize their utility.3
ture which sometimes turned them into vig- While Downs provides a convincing
orous critics of these models: if parties are answer, an equally plausible argument was
purely opportunistic then there seems no formulated by V.O. Key, who stressed the
space for stable and diverse partisan prefer- element of punishment. Voters can only force
ences. Again, the Downsian median-voter governments to implement ‘good’ policies,
theorem seems to predict this outcome. In when they punish a poor performance of the
fact, however, opportunistic models predict incumbent. He writes:
convergence only in the case of a two-party
The patterns of flow of the major streams of shift-
system without entry, without ideology- ing voters graphically reflect the electorate in its
driven party members, without uncertainty great, and perhaps principal, role as an appraiser
about the position of the voters and so on of past events, past performance, and past actions.
(Adams, 1999; Plümper and Martin, 2007). It judges retrospectively; it commands prospec-
If more than two parties populate the politi- tively only insofar as it expresses either approval or
disapproval of what has happened before. (Key,
cal system and the parliament, party posi- 1966: 61)
tions do not converge. Thus, ‘polarized’ party
systems and differences in partisan platforms Yet, the past performance of a government
can be consistent with the assumption of does not necessarily predict future perform-
purely opportunistic models. ances. The influence of government’s activi-
Over the last decades, political economists ties on the business cycle seems to be moderate
have learned not to consider opportunistic at best: Not even the most skilled government
and partisan models as mutually exclusive. can isolate their country from the effects of an
They use both types of models as flexible, exogenous shock such as an oil crisis. One has
equally possible tools. The variety of assump- to keep in mind, however, that Key does not
tions allows researchers to develop flexible necessarily assume fair4 or fully informed
albeit parsimonious models. retrospective voters. His retrospective voters

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 4 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


148 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

just evaluate past performance of governments process, the incentive for individuals with
and generalize from their appraisal – whether moderate interests to get organized increases.
fair or unfair, justified or unjustified, whether In other words, the presence of interest
correct or incorrect. groups trying to pull policies in their favored
Both prospective and retrospective voting direction provides an incentive for others to
assumptions contain an element of truth to establish a competing group which prevents
them. Yet, while both arguments can in prin- this from happening. If all individuals had
ciple easily be unified, political economists the same influence on interest groups and if
are interested in parsimonious models and all contributed the same amount of resources
rarely make models more complicated than to interest groups, then a situation in which
necessary. Accordingly, political economists no interest group exists and a situation in
prefer to use pure assumption than a combi- which all individuals have joined interest
nation of positions. groups would lead to the same policy out-
come. However, since membership in inter-
est groups is costly, the average level of
welfare for each individual is lower in a soci-
Interest groups
ety where interest groups must spring up to
Interest groups provide the perhaps most compete with one another than one in which
important reason why political outcomes voters did not have to organize.
deviate from the preferences held by the However, this result does not necessarily
median vote. In fact, most political econo- hold. Political economists also investigate
mists believe that interest groups are founded how interest groups influence the govern-
with the intention to shift policies away from ment, and this research casts doubt on too
the median voter’s preference. In a world ‘lobby-sceptical’ approaches such as Olson’s
without interest-groups, the median voter theory of the ‘rise and decline of nations’
gets what she wants. With well-organized (Olson, 1982). Interest groups have an ability
and influential interest groups, however, to provide four not mutually exclusive instru-
the outcome of the political decision- ments: First, they can buy policies by giving
making process deviates from the prefer- resources to parties. Second, they can share
ences of the median voter (Grossman and private information with the government.
Helpman, 2001). Third, they can try to change the preferences
Mancur Olson in his seminal book on col- of voters by providing the public with infor-
lective action convincingly argued that not mation, and finally they can buy time from
all interests are equally likely to organize politicians and direct their attention to a par-
(Olson, 1965). In his view, small groups will ticular problem.
find it easier to overcome the collective The sheer existence of influential interest
action problem associated with establishing groups does not necessarily reduce the aggre-
an interest representation. The same holds gate welfare of their country, even though
true for groups which find it easier to observe information asymmetries between interest
and punish free-riding behavior. groups and the government exist. When
If these assumptions hold true, the median interest groups endow the public and the
voter and individuals with preferences close government with valuable information –
to the median voter’s preference are least information which helps the government to
likely to join an interest group. Quite the improve policies – the aggregate welfare
contrary, bearing the costs of interest groups effect of interest groups may even be posi-
pays off for individuals with relatively tive. This holds even if interest groups do not
radical preferences in important policy dimen- spread information because its members
sions. However, once radical interest groups could lose from the potentially induced policy
gain influence on the policy formation changes.

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 5 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 149

Lessons learned: The role of economists. Though research on corporatist


assumptions in modern bargaining structures in advanced capitalist
societies became more central in the 1970s
political economy
(Schmitter and Lehmbruch, 1979), it almost
Political economy brought an analytical per- took another ten years until political econo-
spective into political science. Political econo- mists begun to explore the impact of political
mists did not seek to ‘explain’ particular political institutions more thoroughly. Research on
events – they tried to formulate general theories central bank independence (Cukierman,
of political phenomena. The analytical perspec- 1992; Grilli et al., 1991), wage bargaining
tive requires simplifying assumptions. structures (Calmfors and Driffill, 1988;
But how much abstraction provides the most Przeworski and Wallerstein, 1982), and elec-
promising research strategy? The answer is: it toral systems (Besley and Case, 1995) more
depends. Neither abstract nor complex theories or less simultaneously opened political econ-
are per se more valuable. First, researchers have omy to rigorous research on political institu-
to keep the purpose of their theories in mind. tions. Of course, political economists also
And holding the purpose of the theory constant, became increasingly influenced by develop-
they have to find the optimal ratio between ments in mainstream comparative politics,
abstraction and explanatory power. If more where the institutional turn (March and
complicated assumptions lead to a more realis- Olson, 1984) preceded the institutional turn
tic theory, but the explanatory power does not in political economy by at least 10 years.
increase, then the simpler theory is superior Nevertheless, political economists found
despite its less realistic assumptions. If, how- their niche within the emerging institutional
ever, a further simplification of a theory leads to paradigm.
a severe decline in explanatory power, research- Due to space constraints, this section can
ers should prefer the more complex theory. If only survey a small faction of the results of two
one theory is more complex and explains a decades of institutional political economic
certain phenomenon better than a second theory, research. Before I do so, however, let me first
both have their value. explain how political economists make a con-
Over the last decades, political economists ceptual distinction between institutions and
have learned the principle of parsimony. actors. Though such a distinction cannot always
Competing simplifying assumptions are no be made easily, the political economic perspec-
longer a matter of intense debates and either- tive is admirably clear: Actors are defined by
ors. The debates of the 1960s and 1970s their independent utility functions and by
centered on the correct set of assumptions choices. Institutions are typically modeled as
might rumble on – but different point of incentive or constraint in the choice set. Thus,
views nowadays rarely lead to heated contro- researchers may model institutions either as
versies. Over the last decades, political econ- actors or as political constraint. For example,
omists have learned their lessons: different political economists can model independent
and seemingly competing assumptions enrich central banks as institutions, which constrain
the political economy toolbox. government decisions, or as actors which have
independent utility functions and act strategi-
cally (Ferejohn and Weingast, 1992a; 1992b).

THE INSTITUTIONAL AND


COMPARATIVE TURNS IN
Macroeconomic consequences
POLITICAL ECONOMY
of elections
Political institutions have only fairly recently If parties are (partly) interested in winning
been given central attention by political elections and if governments have (some)

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 6 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


150 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

political autonomy, then governments will consumption and investment – the unem-
misuse political power to win elections and ployment rate declines. Once the economic
to stay in power. As many political econo- subjects correct their expectations, however,
mists have shown (Hibbs, 1987; Tufte, 1978), the stimulating effect evaporates. Yet, the
incumbents benefit from favorable economic interest rate cut increases the inflation rate
conditions. Creating favorable conditions leading an election inducted short-term stim-
thus seems to be a viable strategy for win- ulus package to have long term adverse eco-
ning elections. nomic consequences.
In the 1970s, the Philips curve suggested Therefore, contrary to the assumptions of
governments could easily create an increas- early political economists, governments are
ing demand for labor by reducing the interest not likely to misuse monetary policy for elec-
rate, increasing money supply, and by rising toral purposes. This does not mean, however,
government deficit spending. This being true, that governments never and under no circum-
an incumbent could create a political busi- stance manipulate the economy. As Robert
ness cycle with lower unemployment rates Franzese repeatedly has argued, not all gov-
before and higher unemployment rates after ernments actually need to fuel the economy.
elections which fosters its electoral chances If unemployment is already low and eco-
(Nordhaus, 1975). A reduction in the interest nomic growth high, a further interest cut
rate before the election reduces the price of would not only look inappropriate, its effect
money and thus stimulates consumption and would also be likely to be small. Likewise,
investment, and in consequence the unem- the incumbent may not need the help of a
ployment rate declines. Similarly, a deficit- politically induced business boom in compe-
financed increase in government spending tition with a weak challenger (Franzese,
allows the government to provide benefits to 2002; Franzese and Long Jusko, 2006).
potentially pivotal voters. Hence, if used cor- The mixed empirical results for the politi-
rectly both policies should significantly cal business cycle theory do not come as a
increase the incumbent’s chances of getting surprise. By ignoring what Franzese and
reelected (Hibbs, 1977; Nordhaus, 1975; Long Jusko have dubbed ‘context condition-
Tufte, 1978). ality’, the empirical analyses suffer from
In practice, however, this theory has some severe specification errors. As they have con-
serious flaws. First, cheap money has, at cluded: ‘The empirical evidence surveyed
best, a fairly short effect. As economic sub- here clearly supports models of political-
jects learn that the increase in demand origi- economic cycles that are context conditional’
nates in unsustainable government policies, (Franzese and Long Jusko, 2006: 560).
they adjust their expectations to the prospect Many ‘context conditions’ are indeed insti-
of rising interest rates and cut down con- tutional influences. Trivially enough, inde-
sumption and investment despite the low pendent central banks provide an effective
interest rates. If the economic subjects fully obstacle for the opportunistic use of mone-
anticipate the attempt of the government to tary policies. Less obvious, but almost equally
manipulate the state of the economy, both the effective, a fixed exchange-rate regime
inflation rate and the unemployment rate reduces monetary policy autonomy of gov-
remain about constant (assuming a closed ernments even without independent central
economy). In the worst case, the economic banks. Since monetary policy must be used
subjects initially respond to the decline in to stabilize the exchange-rate, the political
interest rates but overshoot in their adjust- room for manipulating the business cycle
ment to learning that governments manipu- declines, but it does not diminish. Rather, the
lated the interest rates for electoral purposes. government’s room for maneuverability
As a consequence, the reduction in the depends on the country’s current exchange-
interest rate causes a short term increase in rate to the base currency, the parity, the bands

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 7 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 151

within which the exchange-rate may move The political consequences of electoral
without intervention, and the elasticity of the systems can be significant and important.
exchange-rate to changes in the interest-rate Even at a first glance it becomes obvious that
differential. the number of parties actually entering into
After 30 years of research into the political parliament crucially depends on the electoral
business cycle, political economists have a system. Majoritarian systems typically lead
much improved understanding of the mutual to 2-party or 3-party systems. In proportional
dependencies of policies and institutions. In systems the number of represented parties
addition, the political business cycle litera- tends to be much larger. For example, 12 par-
ture not only brought the political economic ties entered into the Polish Sejm after the
approach closer to mainstream political sci- 1991 elections and up to 17 parties frag-
ence, the political business cycle also consti- mented the Italian parliament in the 1970s,
tuted the first political economic research when parties only had to win 300,000 votes
agenda, on which political scientists worked (instead of plus 60,000 votes in one of 27
alongside economists. The unhealthy divi- electoral regions) for one parliament seat.
sion of labor had collapsed and has since As a consequence, a single party is not
then not been re-established. very likely to win a stable majority in propor-
tional systems, while single party govern-
ments dominate majoritarian systems. Hence,
Macroeconomic consequences coalition governments, minority governments
and oversized coalitions are by far more fre-
of electoral systems
quent in proportional systems.
Variation across electoral systems offers one Both the number of parties and the exist-
of the most compelling explanations for ence of coalition governments affect the
observed heterogeneities within the group of behavior of parties and eventually policies.
democracies. Electoral systems vary in many For example, the larger the number of par-
respects, but much of the explanatory power ties, the more parties spread out in the policy
of electoral system results from the seem- space. In two-party systems, parties formu-
ingly simple distinction between majoritar- late positions relatively close to the median-
ian and proportional electoral systems. voter’s preferences. In multiparty systems,
In proportional systems, each party is parties spread out over the entire policy
awarded with a share of the total number of space. As a result, the average distance
parliamentary seats which by-and-large between voters and their nearest party
resembles its vote shares. Small deviations declines, but the party close to the voter may
from this rule result from additional institu- be small and not very influential. Proportional
tional features such as Germany’s 5 per cent systems thus bring about radical parties,
hurdle, which bans parties below a vote share which at times win seats in the parliament
of 5 per cent from parliament. As a result, (Lijphart, 1994a, 1994b). In majoritarian
parties which win more than 5 per cent and systems, radical parties have little chance of
make it into parliament get a slightly larger winning parliamentary seats. The British
seat share than vote share. National Party, for example, has not won a
Majoritarian systems split the electorate up single seat in the British parliament to date.
into different districts. Each district represents The tendency toward radical parties
a defined number of seats in parliament. These in proportional systems is moderated by
seat(s) are won by the party which attracts the the formation of coalition governments.
simple or a qualified majority of the votes in Relatively moderate parties not only tend
the district. Majoritarian systems have a rela- to win more seats than radical parties,
tively low correlation between seat shares and but they also do not like to share political
vote shares. responsibilities with radical parties. In many

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 8 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


152 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

countries, a consensus between moderate par- to the institutional character of presidency.’


ties ensures that radical parties are not allowed (Cameron, 2006: 253). This shift in perspec-
to join a coalition – a strategy which aims at tive has advanced political scientists under-
reducing radical parties to mere protest par- standing of presidential systems.
ties. But these mediating forces do not fully In parliamentary systems, the members of
remove the political differences between parliament elect the chief executive, while in
majoritarian and proportional systems. presidential systems the voters elect the presi-
Another important difference between dent directly. As a consequence, the executive
majoritarian and proportional systems results in presidential systems enjoys greater inde-
from the higher importance of parties in pro- pendence from the members of parliament
portional systems. In majoritarian systems, and therefore also from the parties. In most
the political career of each member of the cases, the president also has more competen-
parliament depends foremost on his constitu- cies in presidential systems. She appoints the
ency. Candidates that do not win their district prime minister and may also dissolve the gov-
do not make it into the parliament. In propor- ernment (for a broader discussion, see Lijphart,
tional systems, the parties typically rank their 1994a, 1994b; Sartori, 1997).
candidates before the elections. In this case, In comparison, the parliament elects the
the candidate’s expected utility depends on prime minister in parliamentary systems.
his position on the party-list, which gives Often, the largest party of the ruling coalition
party leaders a strategic instrument with nominates the prime minister. Given this
which they can influence the position of constellation, conflict of interest between the
members of parliament. executive and the legislative is rare.
In subsequent research, political econo- Presidential systems, to the contrary,
mists build on these institutional differences often lead to the emergence of divided
to explain why policies vary. Persson and government – a situation which occurs when
Tabellini (2003; 2004), for example, find that the president belongs to another party than
government spending is higher under propor- the majority of the parliament. In these cases
tional rules. Majoritarian elections concen- and in other cases in which the president’s
trate power, which ‘tends to favor the wealthy’ policy preference differs from the policy
(Persson and Tabellini, 2006: 733). In major- preference of the parliament’s majority, the
itarian systems, radical parties are not only president and the parliament interact strategi-
unlikely to win parliamentary seats, the cally (Cameron, 2000).
influence of lobbies also tends to be higher as The political economic discussion of the
the electorate is less influential and power strategic logic of presidentialism draws from
more concentrated. the Romer-Rosenthal model (Romer and
Rosenthal, 1978). This model assumes that the
legislative majority proposes a bill and the
Constitutional political economy 1: president can accept or reject the proposal.
If he rejects, the status quo remains in
Presidentialism
effect. In this type of model, the agenda-
Before public choice and political economy setters make an assumption on the preference
influenced the discussion of political institu- of the veto actor and maximize their utility by
tions in political science, scholarly work on taking the veto-player’s position as a constraint
presidential systems dominantly dealt with into consideration. The veto player will never
the personality of the presidents. The politi- use his veto unless the agenda-setter miscalcu-
cal economy approach to presidentialism lates his policy preferences. Yet, the two actors
‘shifted the analytical focus from the person- may find themselves in a war of attrition-like
ality or psychology of individual presidents situation in which many pareto-efficient

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 9 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 153

compromises exist. In such a situation, deci- Constitutional political economy 2:


sions are typically delayed because both actors
Federalism and bicameralism
seek to maximize their individual utility.
Usually the actor for whom the strategic delay In Germany, the classical example for a fed-
costs less or who has more resources wins the eral and bicameral country, unified govern-
‘war of attrition’ (Cameron, 2000). ment with one party dominating both
Recent variants of the Romer-Rosenthal chambers (the Bundestag where the popula-
model treat the game between the legislature tion is represented and Bundesrat where the
and the president as a sequence of connected Länder are represented) to create unified
decisions. These ‘sequential veto bargaining’ government is rare. Thus, many researchers
(Groseclose and McCarty, 2001) models analyzing divided government in bicameral
assume imperfect information on both sides systems compare them utilizing the same
and are strategically complex. For example, framework used to study divided govern-
the president can veto even pareto-efficient ments in presidential systems. In this per-
initial proposals to extract further conces- spective, the majority in the upper house
sions from the parliament. However, the strategically interacts with the majority in the
parliament may prefer not to suggest an lower house (Cutrone and McCarty, 2006;
updated version of the bill to the president, in Tsebelis and Money, 1997).
order to get more goodwill for other propos- However, federalism is more than bicam-
als from the president. In other words, a eralism and divided government. First, fed-
sequential game does not need to be more eral political systems typically use the
realistic than single shot games, they all add subsidiarity principle to distribute political
an important meta-level to the analysis. In responsibilities across the various political
sequential bargaining, the legislature and the levels. The European Union, which whole-
president fight for dominance over the legis- heartedly supports the principle of subsidi-
lative process rather than for single bills and arity (presumably because the EU believes
concessions. subsidiarity increases its political responsi-
Some authors add a pre-stage to the bar- bility), claims:
gaining game, in which president and legisla- The subsidiarity principle is intended to ensure that
ture signal their preferences or even send a decisions are taken as closely as possible to the
veto threat to the other actor. These models citizen and that constant checks are made as tow-
have large empirical significance for the hether action at Community level is justified in the
United States (but unknown significance in light of the possibilitiesavailable at national,
regional or local level. (Europa Glossary, n.d.)
other presidential systems). As Cameron
(2000) shows, in the US post-war history, In practice, however, the subsidiarity prin-
presidents almost never vetoed a bill without ciple often leads to conflicts and deadlock
signaling that they intended to do so and the between overlapping jurisdictions and into a
legislature has almost always responded by ‘joint decision trap’ (Scharpf, 1988). Thus,
making concessions. Taking all these into federal systems reduce the autonomy of gov-
consideration, the direct election of the pres- ernments on each level unless responsibili-
ident gives her more political autonomy than ties are clearly defined and fully divided
prime ministers typically have. As a conse- between the various levels of government. If
quence, Linz claims, the stakes of the presi- political responsibilities overlap, political
dential system rise, leading to political authorities find themselves in a veto bargain-
polarization and antagonisms and ulti- ing game which, at best, delays decisions
mately making presidential systems more and, at worst, render a change of the status
prone to becoming authoritarian systems quo impossible unless a pareto-efficient solu-
(Linz, 1993). tion exists.

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 10 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


154 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Under certain conditions federal systems With the institutionalist turn in the late
lead to regulatory competition. Without 1980s political economists begun to use
obstacles to the mobility of goods, services, larger samples. Yet, this shift to comparative
capital and labor, but with different jurisdic- research designs was not caused by methodo-
tions within one country, competition for logical concerns but by the lack of sufficient
mobile capital and jobs becomes likely. This institutional variation over time in single
situation may cause a downward spiral of countries. For instance, constitutions in post-
regulations and taxation as jurisdictions aim war OECD countries are very stable and
at attracting as much of the mobile factors as durable. Switzerland maintains many of the
possible. As the burgeoning literature on same institutions and rules put into place in
fiscal federalism has demonstrated, federal- the late 13th century and the US has had a
ism may lead to lower overall government presidential system since the late 1700s.
spending if the horizontally disintegrated Electoral rules, central bank autonomy, or
political units (the states) assume authority federalism – to mention just a few – do not
over the tax rates. However, federalism likely change often even in relatively long time-
leads to a higher overall level of taxation if series datasets. Single case studies and time
the central government maintains the right to series analyses simply do not find enough
set taxes or if states coordinate their tax rates variation for reliable estimates and infer-
effectively. ences. The lower the variation over time
becomes, the more cases are needed for a
reliable analysis. The institutional turn has
Toward a comparative shifted the political scientists’ research inter-
ests from merely describing institutions to a
political economy
more sophisticated analysis of the causes and
For early political economists, the United consequences of institutions.
States provided the only relevant test case. As a consequence, the 1990s saw a steep
Political economy has not entirely overcome increase in comparative research designs in
an unfortunate degree of US-centrism. The political science. Interestingly, many of the
discussion of political institutions in the early comparative studies were conducted by
‘Oxford Handbook of Political Economy’ non-American scholars who had studied or
focuses almost exclusively on the US politi- worked in American political science depart-
cal system and a US style of institutions. But ments. These scholars brought a fresh com-
is the USA a well-chosen case? The odds are parative perspective to the systematic study
that it is not if researchers are interested in of political institutions, and they saw very
generalization across space. In many respects, early on the need for broadening the perspec-
the USA resembles an outlier: the country is tive to make political systems which do not
too large, too powerful, culturally too diverse, look much like the US system analyzable
too rich, has only two parties that regularly within the same standard framework.
compete and consistently win elections at the At the same time, quantitative approaches
federal and state level, and the subtle system to analyzing empirical evidence became the
of checks and balances remains unique. dominating methodology at least in American
Moreover, American interest groups are far political science. True, European political
too powerful and parties too weak, the coun- science lagged behind, but during the last
try fights far too many wars, has too much decade European political science began to
influence on international organizations and converge toward the American standard.
they in turn have little influence on the Again, political economy can be found at the
American government. In short, the USA forefront of these developments. Perhaps
looks like one of the least likely cases for better trained than mainstream political
generalizations and valid inferences. scientists (the influence of economics!),

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 11 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 155

political economists found it easier to employ countries (Franzese and Hays, 2006, 2007),
more sophisticated methods for analyz- adjust their monetary policy if the Federal
ing politics and policies in comparative Reserve Bank or the European Central Bank
perspective. changes its main interest rate (Plümper and
Finally, one also should not underestimate Troeger, 2006a, 2006b), and so on. Hence, it
the importance of new methodologies and seems fair to argue policy choices are increas-
better datasets. Since countries are often ingly influenced by policy choices in other
fairly heterogeneous, a simple quantitative countries. If this is the case, than a large
cross sectional analysis likely suffers from share of recent empirical studies in compara-
omitted variable bias. In the 1990s, research- tive politics and comparative political
ers learned to deal with some forms of omit- economy are likely to suffer from omitted
ted variable bias when they moved to panel variable bias.
designs, which allowed them to control for Of course, theories on policy spill-over
time-invariant unit heterogeneity (Beck and between countries can at least be traced back
Katz, 1995; Plümper and Troeger, 2007). to the globalization literature (Garrett, 1995,
1998). However, the globalization literature
lacked a consistent technique for analyzing
policy spill-overs. If one country’s regulation
PERHAPS NOT A CONCLUSION, partly depends on other countries’ regula-
BUT ‘THE NEXT BIG THING’: tions, then the other country’s regulation is
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY also not be independent of the first country’s
OF OPEN ECONOMIES regulation. This constellation leads to a
severe endogeneity problem. The endogene-
This chapter discussed the contribution of ity problem can be solved, but appropriate
political economy to comparative politics. techniques are not easy to use and their prop-
I have shown that political economy which erties have been known for only a short time.
was at the core of the development of an If, however, spatial lags are ignored, than
analytical perspective to political science regression analyses likely overestimate the
and also contributed to (though rather effects of domestic influences (Franzese and
delayed) the institutional turn in comparative Hays, 2006, 2007). Accordingly, political
politics. Keeping this influential past in economists have to re-examine some old and
mind, we may ask: Where does comparative well-established empirical findings in the
political economy go from here? light of new theories of policy diffusion
Though, of course, the future remains (Simmons and Elkins, 2004) and employ on
open, it seems fair to say that the next big newly developed spatial models with sub-
thing will be the analysis of spatial effects in stantive lags (Beck et al., 2006; Franzese and
economic policy decisions. As yet, compara- Hays, 2006, 2007).
tive political economists have implicitly or
explicitly assumed that economic policies are
the consequences of a domestic game, in
which the government takes its own prefer- NOTES
ences, the interests of voters and interest
groups, domestic political institutions and 1. This definition sounds remarkably similar to the
the state of the economy into consideration. editorial statement of Public Choice, a journal loosely
This already complex picture overlooks the associated with the Public Choice society: ‘Public
Choice deals with the intersection between econom-
fact that policies are not necessarily
ics and political science. It started when economists
independent of policies in other coun- and political scientists became interested in the appli-
tries. Governments respond to changes in cation of essentially economic methods to problems
active labor market policies in neighboring normally dealt with by political scientists. It has

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 12 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


156 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

retained strong traces of economic methodology, choices. Evidence from gubernatorial term
but new and fruitful techniques have been devel- limits’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110
oped which are not recognizable by economists.’ (3): 769–98.
Retrieved February 18, 2008 from http://www. Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G. (1962) The
thelockeinstitute.org/publicchoice.html
calculus of consent. Logical foundations of
2. Stephen Hanson’s contribution to this volume
tells the same story of the analytical turn from a dif-
constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor:
ferent perspective, when he explains how scholars University of Michigan Press.
working on area studies developed an interest in Calmfors, L. and Driffill, J. (1988) ‘Centralization
generalizations. of wage bargaining’, Economic Policy, 6 (1):
3. Over the last 50 years, the Downsian model has 14–61.
been modified to more closely resemble reality and Cameron, C.M. (2000) Veto bargaining.
to make better predictions of electoral outcomes. For Presidents and the politics of negative
example, according to probabilistic models (Adams, power. Cambridge: Cambridge University
1999; Ordeshook, 1986) voters do not know the Press.
position of parties perfectly (or parties do not know
Cameron, C.M. (2006) ‘The political economy
the distribution of voter preferences perfectly). Other
authors have argued that voters are ‘biased’ toward
of US presidency’, in B. Weingast and D.
a certain party and underestimate the distance Wittman (eds), The Oxford handbook of
between their preferences and the party’s position political economy. Oxford: Oxford University
while perhaps over estimating their ideological dis- Press. pp. 241–55.
tance to other parties (Converse, 1976). Converse, P.E. (1976) The dynamics of party
4. ‘Fair’ here means that voters hold candidates support. Cohort–analyzing party identifica-
responsible for policy outcomes that the government tion. Beverly Hills: Sage.
could actually influence. Accordingly, an exogenous Cukierman, A. (1992) ‘Measuring the inde-
shock should not influence vote choices, but how the pendence of central banks and its effect on
government deals with this shock should.
policy outcomes’, World Bank Economic
Review, 6 (3): 353–98.
Cutrone, M. and McCarty, N. (2006) ‘Does
bicameralism matter?’, in B. Weingast and
REFERENCES D. Wittman (eds.), The Oxford handbook of
political economy. Oxford: Oxford University
Adams, J. (1999) ‘Policy divergence in multi- Press. pp. 180–95.
candidate probabilistic spatial voting’, Public Downs, A. (1957) An economic theory of
Choice, 100 (1–2): 103–22. democracy. New York: Harper & Row.
Alesina, A. (1989) ‘Politics and business cycles Drazen, A. (2000) Political economy in macr-
in industrial democracies’, Economic Policy, oeconomics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
4 (8): 55–98. University Press.
Alesina, A., Roubini, N. and Cohen, G.D. Europa Glossary (n.d.) Subsidiarity. Retrieved
(1997) Political cycles and the macroecon- February 18, 2008 from http://europa.eu/
omy. Cambridge: MIT Press. scadplus/glossary/subsidiarity_en.htm
Bartels, L. (2000) ‘Partisanship and voting Ferejohn, J. and Weingast, B. (1992a) ‘Limitation
behavior, 1952–1996’, American Journal of of statutes. Strategic statutory interpreta-
Political Science, 44 (1): 35–50. tion’, Georgetown Law Journal, 80 (3):
Beck, N. and Katz, J. (1995) ‘What to do (and 565–82.
not to do) with time-series cross-section Ferejohn, J. and Weingast, B. (1992b) ‘A posi-
data’, American Political Science Review, 89 tive theory of statutory interpretation’,
(3): 634–47. International Review of Law and Economics,
Beck, N., Gleditsch, K. and Beardsley, K. (2006) 12 (3): 263–79.
‘Space is more than geography. Using spatial Franzese, R.J. (2002) ‘Electoral and partisan
econometrics in the study of political econ- cycles in economic policies and outcomes’,
omy’, International Studies Quarterly, 50 (1): Annual Reviews of Political Science, 5:
27–44. 369–421.
Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995) ‘Does electoral Franzese, R.J. and Hays, J.C. (2006) ‘Strategic
accountability affect economic-policy Interaction among EU Governments in Active

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 13 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL ECONOMY 157

Labor Market Policy-making’, European March, J.G. and Olson, J.P. (1984) ‘The new
Union Politics, 7 (2): 167–89. institutionalism. Organizational factors in
Franzese, R.J. and Hays, J.C. (2007) ‘Spatial political life’, American Political Science
econometric models of cross-sectional inter- Review, 78 (2): 734–49.
dependence in political science panel and Nordhaus, W. (1975) ‘The political business
time-series-cross-section data. Political cycle’, Review of Economic Studies, 42 (2):
Analysis, 15 (2): 140–64. 160–90.
Franzese, R.J. and Long Jusko, K. (2006) Olson, M. (1965) The logic of collective action:
‘Political-economic cycles’, in B. Weingast Public goods and the theory of groups.
and D. Wittman (eds), The Oxford handbook Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
of political economy. Oxford: Oxford Olson, M. (1982) The rise and decline of
University Press. pp. 554–64. nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Garrett, G. (1995) ‘Capital mobility, trade, and Ordeshook, P.C. (1986) Game theory and politi-
the domestic politics of economic policy’, cal theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University
International Organization, 49, 657–87. Press.
Garrett, G. (1998) Partisan politics in the global Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2003) Economic
economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT
Press. Press.
Grilli, V., Masciandaro, D. and Tabellini, G. Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2004) ‘Constitutions
(1991) ‘Political and monetary institutions and economic policy’, Journal of Economic
and public finance’, Economic Policy, 13 Perspectives, 18 (1): 75–98.
(12): 342–92. Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2006) ‘Electoral
Groseclose, T. and McCarty, N. (2001) ‘The systems and economic policy’, in B. Weingast
politics of blame. Bargaining before an audi- and D. Wittman (eds), The Oxford handbook
ence’, American Journal of Political Science, of political economy. Oxford: Oxford
45 (1): 100–19. University Press. pp. 723–38.
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (2001) Special- Plümper, T. and Martin, C.W. (2007) Multiparty
interest politics. Cambridge: MIT Press. competition. A computational model with
Hardin, G. (1968) ‘The tragedy of the com- abstention and memory. Unpublished manu-
mons’, Science, 162 (3859): 1243–8. script, University of Essex, UK.
Hibbs, D. (1977) ‘Political parties and macr- Plümper, T. and Troeger, V.E. (2006a)
oeconomic policy’, American Political Science ‘Monetary policy autonomy in European
Review, 71 (4): 261–75. non-Euro countries, 1980–2005’, European
Hibbs, D. (1987) The political economy of Union Politics, 7 (2): 213–34.
industrial democracies. Cambridge: Harvard Plümper, T. and Troeger, V.E. (2006b) Fear of
University Press. floating and the external effects of currency
Key, V.O. (1966) The responsible electorate. unions (IIIS discussion papers no. 181), Trinity
Rationality in presidential voting 1930–1966. College, Dublin.
New York: Vintage. Plümper, T. and Troeger, V.E. (2007) ‘Efficient
Lijphart, A. (1994a) ‘Democracies: Forms, per- estimation of time invariant and rarely chang-
formance and constitutional engineering’, ing variables in finite sample panel analysis
European Journal of Political Research, 25 with unit fixed effects’, Political Analysis,
(1): 1–17. 15 (2): 124–39.
Lijphart, A. (1994b) Electoral systems and party Przeworski, A. and Wallerstein, M. (1982)
systems. A study of 27 democracies, 1945– ‘Structural dependence of the state on capital’,
1990. Oxford: Oxford University Press. American Political Science Review, 82 (2):
Lindblom, C. (1977) Politics and markets. The 11–29.
world’s political economic systems. New Romer, T. and Rosenthal, H. (1978) ‘Political
York: Basic Books. Resource Allocation, controlled agendas,
Linz, J. (1993) ‘Presidentialism, multipartism, and the status quo’, Public Choice, 33 (4):
and democracy. The difficult combination’, 27–44.
Comparative Political Studies, 26 (2): Sartori, G. (1997) Comparative Constitutional
198–228. engineering. An inquiry into structures,

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 14 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


158 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

incentives, and outcomes. New York: New multipartyism’, British Journal of Political
York University Press. Science, 25 (3): 289–325.
Scharpf, F.W. (1988) ‘The joint-decision trap. Tsebelis, G. and Money, J. (1997) Bicameralism.
Lessons from German federalism and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
European integration’, Public Administration, Tufte, E. (1975) ‘Determinants of the outcomes
66 (3): 239–78. if midterm congressional elections’, American
Schmitter, P.C. and Lehmbruch, G. (eds) (1979) Political Science Review, 69 (3): 812–26.
Trends toward corporatist intermediation. Tufte, E. (1978) Political control of the econ-
Beverly Hills: Sage. omy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Simmons, B.A. and Elkins, Z. (2004) ‘The glo- Weingast, B. and Wittman, D. (2006) ‘The
balization of liberalization. Policy diffussion reach of political economy’, in B. Weingast
in the international political economy’, and D. Wittman (eds), Oxford handbook of
American Political Science Review, 98 (1): political economy. Oxford: Oxford University
171–89. Press. pp. 3–25.
Tsebelis, G. (1995) ‘Decision-making in Wittman, D. (1977) ‘Candidates with policy
political systems. Veto players in presidential- preferences: A dynamic model’, Journal of
ism, parliamentarism, bicameralism and Economic Theory, 14 (1): 180–9.

9781412919760_Chap08.indd 15 3/11/2009 3:44:32 PM


9
The Contribution of
Area Studies
Stephen E. Hanson

INTRODUCTION operate independently of departmental con-


straints. Bates does concede the continuing
The role of ‘area studies’ in the comparative relevance of the work of area specialists, but
politics subfield of political science has been only insofar as they continue to ‘record the
the subject of a prolonged and often acrimo- data from which political inferences [might]
nious debate. On one hand, advocates of a be drawn by social scientists residing in
more deductive approach to social science political science departments’ (Bates, 1996).
inference have railed against area specialists Some supporters of Bates’ position even sug-
for their presumed hostility to both generaliz- gested that this proposed division of labor
able theory and quantitative methodology. As could become an international one, since ‘the
Robert Bates warned in 1996 in his initial area expertise of natives working in their
‘Letter from the President’ in the American own countries is likely to be deeper and
Political Science Association (APSA) richer than what those of us working in the
Comparative Politics Newsletter: US can generate anyway,’ while more theo-
retically sophisticated and methodologically
Within the academy, the consensus has formed
rigorous scholars in the US might increas-
that area studies has failed to generate scientific
knowledge. Many see area specialists as having ingly focus on ‘non-specific, increasingly
defected from the social sciences to the camp of abstract “theory”’ (Golden, 1998: 6).
the humanists … They tend to lag behind others in On the other hand, defenders of area studies
terms of their knowledge of statistics, their com- have insisted that political analysis should
mitment to theory, and their familiarity with
always be grounded in a thorough knowledge
mathematical approaches to the study of politics.
(Bates, 1996) of regional context, without which, in their
view, a deeper understanding of the dynamics
Area studies centers, Bates argues, thus rep- of political order and political change is impos-
resent something of an institutional ‘problem sible. Attacks on area studies, according to this
for political science,’ given their ability to camp, reflect the ascendance of narrowly eco-
attract sufficient outside funding and admin- nomic approaches to politics that reflect a paro-
istrative support to allow area specialists to chial misunderstanding of human motivation.

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:1 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


160 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Thus Chalmers Johnson excoriates Bates for signify scientific rigor, would now be changed
assuming that ‘rational choice theory contains a to ‘analytical’; the word ‘institutional’ would
unique capacity to transcend culture and reduce now be claimed by the champions of deduc-
all human behavior to a few individual motiva- tive theory – the same speech could be deliv-
tional uniformities’ (Johnson, 2001: 60). As for ered again today, over three decades later,
Bates’ and Golden’s idea that area specialists practically verbatim.
might play a useful role as purveyors of This is quite remarkable, given that Ward’s
regional data useful for more general theoreti- speech emphasized that this fruitless debate
cal analysis, Johnson replies acidly: ‘One prob- had already been raging in the discipline for
lem with this proposed division of labor is that many decades, and that some way to transcend
these social scientists do not produce beautiful it should therefore be urgently sought. Indeed,
objects but junk and real area specialists have a Ward began his presentation by quoting Jasper
much better record of producing theory Shannon’s 1950 presidential address to the
than their self-proclaimed theoretical rivals’ Southern Political Science Association, which
(Johnson, 2001: 62). detailed with ironic humor how, in the history
Given the invidious tenor of this debate, one of political science since the era of Woodrow
might think that the crisis over the role of area Wilson, initial optimism about the discovery of
studies in the comparative politics subfield was ‘laws of politics as clear and definite as those of
truly unprecedented. Certainly, the immediate physics’ – knowledge of which would enable
professional stakes involved are very high, the spread of good institutions across the
affecting everything from the priorities of pri- world – had gradually given way in the face of
vate and public funding agencies to future the twin disasters of the Great Depression and
standards for tenure decisions. Not surprisingly, World War II to increasing skepticism about the
the struggle between area specialists and deduc- possibility of arriving at a single neutral science
tive generalists has frequently devolved into a of politics (Shannon, quoted in Ward, 1975:
zero-sum struggle between warring camps. 24–26). Historians of the political science dis-
When one steps back to examine the entire cipline confirm the broad outlines of Shannon’s
history of the interaction between area studies account. The ‘first behavioral revolution’ of the
and the political science discipline, however, 1920s, led by figures like Charles Merriam,
one quickly discovers that the basic contours called for a higher level of scientific rigor
of this debate are very old indeed. Note, for through the use of modern methods such as
example, the characterization of the area stud- public opinion surveys, psychological experi-
ies controversy contained in the 1973 APSA ments, and economic approaches to history
Presidential Address of prominent Japan spe- (Farr and Seidelman, 1993). By the 1930s,
cialist Robert E. Ward of Stanford University: however, optimism about this ‘rationalist’
Many behavioralists allege that something called
approach to social science had largely broken
the ‘Area Approach’ lacks rigor and scientific down as a result of attacks by émigré scholars
potentiality. It is viewed as descriptive and relativ- fleeing totalitarian rule such as Hannah Arendt,
istic, often historical or institutional rather than Leo Strauss, and Eric Voegelin – who, in their
behavioral in focus, and normally idiosyncratic in own way, provided a continental European
terms of its findings. In current professional par-
lance these are not terms of praise.
‘area studies’ perspective on the prevailing
A few so-called ‘area types’ respond with coun- orthodoxies of American political science
tercharges of cultural illiteracy, gross ethno- (Gunnell, 1993).
centrism, uncritical scientism, and scornful Thus, with some slight thematic and stylistic
characterizations of those members of the opposi- variations, the political science debate about the
tion who venture abroad as ‘itinerant methodolo-
gists’ or worse. (Ward, 1975: 27)
contribution of area studies has raged in much
the same form for nearly a century now. Under
With only a few minor terminological such circumstances, one might ask what pur-
updates – the word ‘behavioral,’ which used to pose is served by writing yet another essay on

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:2 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


THE CONTRIBUTION OF AREA STUDIES 161

the topic! It is my contention here, however, deductive theory and defenders of regional
that the puzzling longevity of the area studies expertise alike – might promote a more toler-
controversy itself provides an important clue as ant and fruitful interrelationship between the
to its nature and possible resolution. Specifically, two camps.
I argue that the area studies debate reflects a
deeper confusion among political scientists of
all stripes about how to combine deductive and
inductive reasoning in social research. To tran- STEREOTYPES ABOUT AREA STUDIES
scend this debate will require scholarly agree-
ment on some difficult and fundamental Before we can assess the contribution of area
questions about how to develop scientifically studies to the subfield of comparative poli-
fruitful typologies of regime type – agreement tics, we need to understand precisely how
that is highly unlikely in the absence of mutual ‘area studies’ as a distinct approach to the
intellectual respect between self-professed analysis of world politics emerged in the first
area specialists and comparative politics place. In this respect, several common criti-
generalists. cisms of the area studies approach appear to
The chapter will be organized as follows. rest on faulty historical premises.
I will begin by showing how a careful exam- Thus, one common criticism of area stud-
ination of the long history of the area studies ies is that its particular orientations and
controversy helps to invalidate several choice of material were directly influenced
common stereotypes about area studies in the by the Cold War priorities of the United
political science discipline: first, they are not States government – in particular, the global
merely a product of Cold War policy con- struggle against communism (Cohen, 1985;
cerns; second, they are unlikely to disappear Farish, 2005). Advocates of this viewpoint
as a result of increasing political and eco- point out that the initial push to expand area
nomic globalization; and finally, they are studies training in the postwar era by the
more frequently the source of new general Rockefeller, Ford, and Carnegie Foundations
theory than an obstacle to it. I will then turn focused primarily on Russia and East Asia –
to a critique of area studies that has substan- the early sites of conflict between the United
tially greater merit: namely, that the conven- States and its communist adversaries. The
tional definitions of world ‘areas’ are arbitrary National Defense Education Act of 1958,
in ways that inhibit, rather than promote, which initiated the Title VI National Resource
theoretical cumulation. While there is some Centers of the Department of Education that
truth to this claim, I argue that rival ‘theoreti- provide the basic infrastructure for area stud-
cal’ categorizations of regime types are at least ies training in most major US universities to
as arbitrary. Indeed, as I show in the subse- this day, was launched as a direct response to
quent section, the typical geographic divisions the Soviet launch of the sputnik satellite the
utilized in contemporary area studies pro- year before.1 Many leading area specialists in
grams do tend to highlight many important political science departments spent time in
structural, institutional, and cultural variables the US military during World War II, and
that are shared among countries within vari- many more lent their expertise to various
ous world regions. Hence area studies tend to government security agencies, including the
sensitize political scientists to the limited Central Intelligence Agency and the
scope conditions of supposedly ‘universal’ Department of Defense, throughout the Cold
models and theories developed in the context War period (Lambert et al., 1984: 2–10).
of a single world region such as North America. Surely the dominant role of Cold War con-
I conclude by showing how heightened aware- cerns among area studies funders must have
ness of the deeper theoretical complexities of hindered the search for objective scientific
the area studies controversy – by advocates of knowledge among area specialists?

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:3 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


162 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Of course, the connection between the stable democracy and peace, and ‘unilateral-
funding of area studies programs and the ists’ skeptical of the relevance of Wilsonian
strategic priorities of the US government ideals to non-Western contexts (Knock, 1992;
cannot be denied.2 However, the further argu- Thorsen, 1998).3 Nor does the presumed pro-
ment that US and private funding of area American foreign policy bias of area studies
studies centers undermined their scholarly appear to hold after the collapse of the Soviet
objectivity assumes that the divide between Union – as any reader of Chalmers Johnson’s
political science generalists and area studies recent works on US foreign policy can attest
practitioners overlaps substantially with an (Johnson, 2000).
ideological divide between critics and defend- Even if the accusation that area specialists
ers of US foreign policy. Closer examination were unduly affected by Cold War priorities
of the issue calls such an assumption into seems unwarranted, however, many analysts
question. From Herman Kahn to Steven would insist that the mission of area studies
Krasner, social scientists explicitly oriented has nevertheless become anachronistic in the
toward general theorizing have been just as post-Cold War context. Thus one of the most
likely to be engaged in the formulation of US common critiques of area studies research
foreign policy as have prominent area spe- since 1991 has been the argument that it fails
cialists. Among the latter, too, one finds any to take into account new social, technologi-
number of critics of US policymaking, rang- cal, and cultural trends in an era of increasing
ing from the neo-Marxist Barrington Moore ‘globalization’ (Prewitt, 1996). From this
(who began his career as a Soviet specialist) point of view, area studies must be reinvented
to reformist liberals like Albert Hirschman to account for the rise in influence of non-
(who made his name as a Latin Americanist). state actors ranging from democratic advo-
Even within the area specialization most cacy groups to terrorist cells; the erosion of
closely connected to Cold War concerns – state boundaries as a result of cross-border
Sovietology itself – there is no discernable trade, migration, epidemics, and media; and
ideological pattern linking an area studies the invention of new international communi-
orientation to support of US policy. Indeed, cation technologies such as the Internet and
after the collapse of the Soviet Union, one the cellular phone. Indeed, precisely these
could find both conservatives like Frances sorts of concerns led both the Ford Foundation
Fukuyama and leftists like Jerry Hough criti- and the Social Science Research Council –
cizing Sovietologists for their failure to apply historically both key funders of area studies
general political science theory to the programs – to cut their support for ‘tradi-
USSR – and, on the other hand, both con- tional’ region-based research in the 1990s
servatives like Martin Malia and leftists like (Ford Foundation, 1999; Prewitt, 1996).
Stephen Cohen blaming Sovietology for its If this second line of critique is correct, we
overreliance on abstract social science should expect to find that area specialists
models (Fukuyama, 1993; Hough, 1997; prior to 1991 paid little attention in their
Malia, 1993; Cohen, 1999). Finally, if the research to social influences that flow across
argument that area studies was dominated by formal political jurisdictions, to social move-
inveterate Cold Warriors fails to hold for the ments below the level of the nation-state, or
Cold War era itself, it fails completely to to the impact of modern technology on social
explain why there was an ‘area studies’ con- interaction. Again, however, even a cursory
troversy concerning American foreign policy familiarity with the work of leading area
long before World War II – between propo- specialists throughout the twentieth century
nents of Wilsonian universalism, based on makes such claims impossible to sustain.
Woodrow Wilson’s deeply held convictions To begin with, area studies as a whole has
about the possibility of expert political sci- arguably been more, not less, attuned to
ence knowledge of the principles ensuring international influences on national politics

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:4 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


THE CONTRIBUTION OF AREA STUDIES 163

than advocates of quantitative political sci- challenges and opportunities now highlighted
ence approaches, who have often of necessity in more recent paeans to the ‘unprecedented’
taken the nation-state as the basic unit of impact of globalization (Friedman, 1999,
analysis in large-N multi-country databases. 2005).
Indeed, the earliest area specialists in Western This brings us to the third, and by far most
academia were scholars of ancient religions widespread, stereotype about area studies
and their long-term cultural effects on ‘civili- research: that it has historically been carried
zations’; for them, mere national boundaries out primarily by scholars resistant to general
were seen as artificial modern divisions that theoretical concepts and innovative method-
would fail to reroute the deeper allegiances ologies. Taking into account the entire his-
uniting, say, the Muslim, Western Christian, tory of the area studies controversy, however,
Orthodox, or Confucian ‘worlds’ (Lambert, forces us to re-evaluate this accusation as
2001). Area specialists working within the well. Specifically, while it is true that the
paradigm of modernization theory, too, original area specialists of the pre-World War
hardly took the nation-state for granted; II era were primarily humanists interested in
rather, they took it upon themselves to explain topics such as philology, theology, and devel-
precisely why this form of political organiza- opment of ‘ancient civilizations’ – a tradition
tion had emerged out of earlier, more paro- now pejoratively labeled ‘Orientalism’ (Said,
chial forms of political allegiance (Gellner, 1978) – one is hard pressed to find repre-
1983; E. Weber, 1976). Others, such as the sentatives of this approach in the compara-
Western Europeanist Ernst Haas, examined tive politics subfield in any major political
how the nation-state itself might be tran- science department over the past five decades
scended through the emergence of suprana- or so.4 Indeed, in the immediate post-war
tional systems of interest and loyalty in period, area studies within the American uni-
specific regional contexts (Haas, 1958, 1964). versity system was utterly transformed by its
Nor did area specialists ever tend to neglect close association with Parsonian structural-
the influence of what today would be called functionalism and other variants of moderni-
‘non-state actors’ – as is clear from an exam- zation theory into an integral part of social
ination of classic works on the peasant vil- science theory-building. Given the wide-
lage and peasant rebellion in Mexico, China, spread acceptance of modernization theory’s
and Malaysia (Foster, 1965; Johnson, 1962; parsing of the ‘necessary’ stages of social
Scott, 1985) or on revolutionary movements evolution from agricultural ‘traditional soci-
and ideologies in France and Russia (Sewell, ety’ based on communalism and personal
1980; Tucker, 1969). As for the impact of loyalties to industrial ‘modern society’ based
technology, this was always one of the cen- on individualism and impersonal procedural-
tral variables in area studies research, which ism, it became possible to conceive of area
tended to take for granted the importance of studies as an arena for scientific investigation
increasing urbanization, industrialization, of the specific manifestations of ‘universal’
education, and access to media for under- social processes (Parsons, 1951; Rostow,
standing social change in various regions of 1960). Parsons himself articulated such a
the world (Apter, 1955, 1963; Lerner, 1958; goal for area studies explicitly as early as
Lowenthal, 1970). Indeed, the typical finding 1948, claiming that just as the study of the
from this body of work was that technologi- human body required collaboration among
cal change generally tends to disrupt tradi- sciences as diverse as ‘anatomy, physiology,
tional communities and identities, to facilitate biochemistry, bacteriology, and even psy-
the emergence of modern forms of individu- chology and some of the social sciences,’ the
alism, and to enable new possibilities for study of world regions would provide ‘a con-
collective action among previously marginal- crete focus for the disciplines of the social
ized groups – precisely the sorts of social sciences and related fields of the humanities

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:5 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


164 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

and natural sciences’ (quoted in Mitchell, ranging from neo-Marxism – as in the case of
2004: 86). Barrington Moore, whose first books ana-
From the 1950s on, it is hard to find lyzed the impact of modernization on the
respected comparativists arguing that their Soviet dictatorship (Moore, 1950, 1954) – to
countries of specialization are simply ‘unique’ rational choice theory, as in the case of David
and thus not amenable to comparative theo- Laitin, whose first book dealt with the effects
rizing. Instead, the goal of most area special- of language policy in the single case of post-
ists working in the broad modernization independence Somalia (Laitin, 1977).
theory tradition was to chart the specific By the end of the 1980s, modernization
ways in which local ‘traditional cultures’ in theory had fully lost its erstwhile hegemony
their region had interacted with the inescap- in the political science discipline, and rational
able forces of urbanization, industrialization, choice theory was quickly emerging as the
education, and the spread of mass media to most influential new approach to compara-
produce either successful, stalled, or failed tive politics research. As older modernization
political modernization and economic devel- theorists retired and younger scholars trained
opment. From this perspective, too, it is not in rational choice modeling entered the field
surprising that many social scientists who during the 1990s, then, the idea that one
began as specialists on the effects of mod- could build a ‘general theory’ by examining
ernization in a particular region or country global patterns of political culture fell out of
later began to engage in more explicit com- favor – and many distinguished scholars who
parative theorizing – as in the cases of Daniel had built their careers pursuing this goal
Lerner, David Apter, Barrington Moore, were implicitly recast as traditional ‘area
Lucian Pye, Robert Putnam, and countless specialists.’ In the 1970s, for example, the
other leading comparativists of the period. prominent modernization theorist Harry
It was only when modernization theory Eckstein firmly declared himself to be a
began to lose its hegemonic position in the skeptic about ‘area studies approaches,’ argu-
1970s and 1980s that studies of ‘political ing that ‘the ultimate (perhaps only) task of
culture’ began to be widely seen as atheoreti- comparative politics is to find general solu-
cal, rather than theory-driven. Erstwhile stu- tions of general problems that cut across both
dents of Parsons himself, such as Clifford geographic areas and periods of history’
Geertz, became increasingly skeptical of (Eckstein, 1975: 200). Yet two decades later,
their mentor’s claims that human social evo- two prominent defenders of area studies
lution followed a single universal pattern, could cite the very same Eckstein as some-
leading them to distance themselves from the one who ‘developed a powerful theory about
project of ‘general social science theory.’ how authority relations in the family influ-
Indeed, Geertz’s essay on ‘thick description,’ ence forms of democracy, based on an inten-
which is probably the work most widely sive study of Norway’ – demonstrating the
cited by critics interested in demonstrating scientific value of the single-country studies
the resistance of area studies to general (Hall and Tarrow, 2001: 100)! Thus we see
theory, hardly represented the mainstream that much of the contemporary debate about
area studies viewpoint; rather, it was written whether area studies are ‘theoretical’ enough
in rebellion against the overly-deductive is, on a deeper level, a struggle over the
forms of ‘cultural theorizing’ that had been validity of rival theoretical paradigms.
dominant in the social sciences for most of The myth that area specialists on the
Geertz’s early career (Geertz, 1973).5 At the whole resist generalizable theory likely per-
same time, the search for a new overarching sists for three reasons. First, area studies may
theoretical paradigm began, and this pro- suffer from ‘guilt by association’ with
pelled several prominent former area special- the Orientalist scholarship of the pre-World
ists to convert to ascendant approaches War II period, which truly did insist on the

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:6 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


THE CONTRIBUTION OF AREA STUDIES 165

uniqueness of non-Western ‘civilizations’ – outmoded Cold War priorities, an insufficient


although those who see such ideas as the core appreciation of social influences that cross
of area studies research are by now at least a existing political jurisdictions, or a simple
half-century out of date. Second, since area lack of theoretical imagination. Now that we
studies programs are typically broadly inter- have stripped away prejudices along all these
disciplinary, it is relatively easy to find histo- lines, however, we are in a position to con-
rians, anthropologists, and specialists in the front the problem of defining ‘areas’ directly
humanities who do object to generalizable and theoretically. Simply put: does organiz-
theory in the social sciences – but this tells us ing comparative politics research in distinct
nothing about the intellectual orientations of regional clusters make any scientific sense?
the political scientists associated with such If not, then even the most dispassio-
programs, who, ironically, are frequently nate, dynamic, and theoretically innova-
seen by their more humanities-oriented col- tive area studies research is built on a faulty
leagues as being overly deductive in their foundation.
analytic approaches. Third, and perhaps most Ironically, it was Harry Eckstein himself
importantly, changing political science para- who initially put this theoretical challenge to
digms have shifted our understandings of area studies most clearly. Area studies pro-
what counts as truly ‘theoretical,’ making it grams, he noted, might have been formed for
appear that area studies work explicitly ori- any one of four reasons: to fill voids in our
ented toward testing hypotheses derived from factual knowledge about various parts of the
older theories lacked any theoretical orienta- world; to provide ‘rubrics for interdiscipli-
tion at all. In fact, from the 1950s until con- nary collaboration’ among scholars with sim-
temporary times, area specialists have ilar linguistic and historical knowledge; to
continuously been very much in the center of highlight distinctive problems that arise with
debates about comparative politics theory. particular urgency in particular regions; or
because ‘the societies and polities of different
regions constitute distinctive types’ (Eckstein,
1975: 202, emphasis in original). Eckstein
WHAT IS AN ‘AREA’? argues that only the last of these four reasons
can justify the maintenance of separate area
We have seen that critiques of area studies as studies programs for political science research
driven by Cold War concerns, as irrelevant in in the long term, from a purely scientific
an era of globalization, or as inimical to gen- point of view. Once sufficient empirical
eralizable theory – however, persistent and knowledge about the various polities and
pervasive – are fundamentally without merit. societies of the world is gathered, and the
There is, however, a fourth common criticism causes of urgent political problems in various
of area studies approaches that is rather more regions isolated, only an assumption of typo-
difficult to discard: namely, that the typical logical commonality at some level can justify
definitions of ‘areas’ utilized to demarcate principles of case selection that usually gen-
the area studies programs at major US uni- erate comparisons within a particular ‘area
versities are arbitrary, and are therefore likely studies’ region (say, India with Pakistan)
to hinder scientific progress on topics requir- rather than comparisons that ignore such
ing conceptualization and research that tran- regional designations (say, India with Brazil).
scends regional borders. Indeed, one finds Eckstein’s own conclusion was that the most
this complaint about area studies included in up-to-date research on regime types showed
nearly all of the critical literature examined no real justification for distinguishing
above – even though authors differ as to the study of ‘Africa,’ ‘South Asia,’ ‘South-
whether the arbitrariness of defini- east Asia,’ ‘East Asia,’ and so on. At best,
tions of the ‘areas’ in area studies reflects only three ‘clusters’ of regimes – European,

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:7 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


166 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

‘Afro-Asian,’ and Latin American – might be In the absence of such scientific consensus,
justified empirically, based on a comprehen- however, the case for abandoning area stud-
sive survey of their typical patterns of state ies becomes much less clear cut – and this is
authority (Gurr, 1974). Ironically, Eckstein a point generally missed by critics of area
noted, ‘West Europe,’ which was one of the studies research. Indeed, given the lack of a
last parts of the world to be organized as a widely-accepted theory of regime evolution
separate ‘area studies’ region in American in the field, we cannot in principle develop
academia, is actually one of the few geo- any clear-cut tests of whether particular poli-
graphic zones that might actually merit des- ties ‘belong together’ in a single regional
ignation as a ‘area’ from a scientific point of grouping or not – since only such a theory
view (Eckstein, 1975). would allow us to identify precisely those
Eckstein’s point is a powerful one. Clearly, empirical factors that might be decisive for
there is an unavoidable element of arbitrari- arriving at a scientific judgment in this
ness in grouping world polities and societies respect. If so, then any provisional ‘theoreti-
in distinct regional clusters. While perhaps cal’ categorization of regimes may ultimately
world geography seems at first glance to jus- turn out to be just as arbitrary as ‘traditional’
tify the separate study of, say, ‘Africa’ or area studies divides – if not more so.
‘Latin America’ – although even in these Note, for instance, that the tests of regional
cases one finds sharp intraregional divisions commonality developed by Eckstein and Gurr
such as those between Mediterranean North depend directly on the theoretical notion that
Africa and the sub-Saharan countries, or ‘structures of political authority’ (understood
between Spanish-speaking and Portuguese- in Eckstein’s sense as built around five key
speaking South America – one is hard pressed dimensions: modes of recruitment, constraints
to find purely geographic reasons for distin- on decision-making, levels of participation,
guishing among the ‘Middle East,’ ‘South intensity of regulation, and complexity) are
Asia,’ ‘Southeast Asia,’ and ‘East Asia.’ the central defining feature of all political sys-
Indeed, certain geographical zones that tems (Eckstein and Gurr, 1975; Gurr, 1974). If
appear to be ‘regions’ in one historical period one rejects this theoretical approach – as
can suddenly lose their apparent cohesive- would most political scientists today – their
ness in another. Thus it is not intuitively subsequent grouping of world polities into
obvious why, for example, Tajikistan and European, Latin American, and ‘Afro-Asian’
Slovenia should still be grouped in the same clusters based on indicators of authority struc-
‘postcommunist’ regional category, now that tures no longer has any theoretical or empiri-
the Soviet bloc has disintegrated (Rupnik, cal justification. Indeed, choosing another
1999). In the face of such difficulties, does it theoretical criterion to generate an empirical
not make more sense to discard the notion categorization of regime types must necessar-
of coherent ‘areas’ in world politics ily generate an entirely different set of ‘world
altogether – perhaps searching instead for regions.’ Perhaps such alternative theoretical
ways to categorize countries that do not approaches might reveal distinct differences
depend on the use of ‘proper nouns’ at all among African, Middle Eastern, and Asian
(Przeworksi and Teune, 1970)? ‘clusters’ of countries after all – in which case,
If political scientists already possessed a defenders of traditional ‘area studies’ centers
consensual typology of political regimes as would turn out to have been on the right track,
well as a widely accepted general theory of while supporters of ‘grand theory’ might inad-
how such regimes develop, rise, and fall, such vertently have missed crucial regional varia-
a line of criticism would, I think, be devastat- bles affecting the fate of global political
ing. Scientific consensus of this sort might, in development.
principle, render the study of arbitrarily- Critics of the arbitrariness of area stud-
defined ‘world regions’ quite anachronistic. ies programs might reply to this point by

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:8 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


THE CONTRIBUTION OF AREA STUDIES 167

suggesting that even if many grand theories studies programs actually tend to capture
of regime-types fail, there is at least a chance quite well the effects of three causal factors
that some general theoretical approach to that are attracting greater attention among
regime evolution may eventually succeed. theorists of comparative political and institu-
Sticking with established regional groupings tional change. First, such programs implicitly
of countries, in contrast, cannot possibly gen- accept the importance of ‘legacies of the
erate any grand theory. Thus it is still scien- past’ for structuring contemporary political
tifically preferable to reject area studies and social issues. Second, the regional group-
approaches a priori. ings of traditional area studies programs do a
This argument, however, assumes that the reasonably good job of capturing the effects
degree of scientific arbitrariness in the group- of institutional and social diffusion among
ings of countries typical of traditional area neighboring regimes. Third, area studies
studies programs approaches 100 per cent: scholars are generally well suited to take into
that is, were we to possess a scientific con- account the causal effects of powerful inter-
sensus about the general reasons for the pretations of the world – ideological, reli-
emergence, maintenance, and disappearance gious, and cultural – that can shape regional
of political regimes, we would find zero the- development in ways often poorly predicted
oretical justification for any of the groupings by structural and institutional factors alone.
of countries we find in such programs at I will deal with each of these points in turn.
present. If we hypothesize that existing area If there is one obvious reason for the per-
studies groupings are only arbitrary to a sistence over time of traditional area studies
degree, however – in other words, that there boundaries among ‘African Studies,’ ‘Middle
might turn out to be some justification for East Studies,’ ‘South Asian Studies,’ and so
traditional area studies boundaries, even after on, it is a shared conviction among area spe-
the development of a consensual grand theory cialists concerning the crucial importance of
of regime change – the case for tossing aside history. This is true in myriad ways. To begin
area studies research entirely in favor of with, most fundamentally, the vast majority
newly-developed theoretical categorizations of contemporary area studies programs are
is substantially weakened. The scientific defined in large part by the history of expan-
decision to embrace or to break with area sion of one or more empires covering much
studies should ultimately turn, therefore, on of the territory they examine. Thus it is not
one’s assessment of just how arbitrary the much of an exaggeration to describe contem-
various boundaries of regional studies pro- porary ‘Middle East Studies’ as analyzing the
grams in Western academia actually are, rela- territory of the former Ottoman and Persian
tive to one’s confidence in the ability of new Empires; ‘East Asian Studies’ as examining
grand theories to categorize polities in more the territory of the Chinese and Japanese
scientifically fruitful ways. Empires; and ‘Latin American Studies’ as
covering the territory of the Spanish and
Portuguese Empires. The ‘former Soviet
region’ is, of course, the most clear-cut case
INSTITUTIONAL LEGACIES, of all in this respect. Other traditionally-
DIFFUSION, AND VERSTEHEN defined world areas, such as Africa, South
Asia, and Southeast Asia, are more notable
In fact, based on our current state of knowl- for the great diversity of empires that occu-
edge, there are actually many good social pied their territories in different historical
scientific reasons to embrace many of the eras. Yet even in these cases, the direct
traditional area studies groupings now insti- impacts of foreign conquests by various
tutionalized on campuses throughout North northern peoples are still at the core of
America and Europe. In particular, area regional self-definition. Of course, most area

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:9 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


168 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

specialists would also insist that their regional versa – in ways that are clearly not as sig-
programs are justified even more directly by nificant or salient for nations far from the
their coverage of distinct linguistic, religious, Asian-Pacific region. Similarly, the prospect
and cultural contexts. Yet shared languages of accession to the European Union alike had
and belief systems in different parts of the a profound impact on the political and eco-
contemporary world, too, can ultimately be nomic institutions of the countries of Eastern
traced to the history of regime change in and Central Europe; the acquis communau-
ancient times. taire cannot be said to have had such a dra-
As contemporary political scientists probe matic impact on political change in Brazil or
more deeply into the causal effects of struc- Argentina (Ekiert and Hanson, 2003;
tural and institutional legacies inherited from Vachudova, 2005). True, area studies pro-
the past, the designation of various regional grams may sometimes overemphasize the
studies programs to cover geographical interactions among polities within traditional
zones shaped profoundly by similar experi- regional borders at the expense of examina-
ences of colonial conquest seems to make tion of the influence of neighboring states
increasingly good sense. That the legacies located in ‘different’ regions; thus the influ-
of imperial law, bureaucracy, modes of socio- ence of Russia on Japan, or of China on post-
economic organization, and official cultures Soviet Central Asia, sometimes receives short
might have profound effects on the options shrift in area studies research. Yet even in
available to contemporary state builders is, of these cases, area studies specialists may
course, no surprise for analysts in the histori- intuitively grasp social limits on cross-border
cal institutionalist school of comparative influences in ways that general theorists of
politics (Evans et al., 1985; Mahoney and ‘globalization’ miss. The social and political
Rueschemeyer, 2003; Skocpol, 1979; Steinmo impact of South Asia on the Central Asia
et al., 1992). More recently, however, com- states since 1991, for example, has arguably
parativists from the rational choice tradition been rather marginal compared to that of the
have also begun to investigate the causal longstanding imperial hegemon in the region,
sequences that lead from previous institu- Russia – contrary to the assertions of journal-
tional arrangements bequeathed by past istic accounts about the potential for ‘radical
regimes to contemporary incentives structur- Islam’ to spread north from Afghanistan
ing individual decisionmaking – leading (Rashid, 2002).
some to conclude that a reconciliation Again, the typical intuitions of area spe-
between historical institutionalism and cialists about the impact and limits of diffu-
rational choice institutionalism may soon be sion across regional borders are backed up by
in the offing (Bates et al., 1998; Thelen, new theories and methodologies about the
1999; see also Chapter 6 of this volume). If mechanisms of institutional diffusion in
so, general comparative theorists of both international politics. Of course, theorists of
persuasions may soon develop a renewed economic development have long highlighted
interest in area studies work on postimperial the ways in which proximity to the developed
development and postcolonial state building capitalist ‘core’ provides structural advan-
(Wilkinson, submitted). tages largely unavailable to countries in the
A second reason why area studies special- underdeveloped ‘periphery’ (Evans, 1979;
ists tend to group themselves in distinct Wallerstein, 1974). Even those who reject
research communities that accept traditional dependency theory, however, increasingly
regional boundaries is their often implicit accept that geography plays a key role in the
understanding that the countries they study global political economy. We now know,
tend greatly to influence each other. What more clearly than ever before, just how
happens in Japan, after all, clearly shapes important geographic ‘neighbor effects’
what happens in South Korea – and vice can be for successful democratization and

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:10 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


THE CONTRIBUTION OF AREA STUDIES 169

marketization: in a nutshell, being surrounded and cultural marginalization since the fall of
by impoverished autocracies makes liberal the Ottoman Empire makes credible a com-
capitalism extremely difficult, while border- prehensive theory of global redemption
ing the European Union in the 1990s nearly through Islamic jihad against the West
guaranteed democracy and wealth (Collier, (Musallam, 2005).
2007; Gallup et al., 1999; Kopstein and As with the impacts of historical legacies
Reilly, 2000). And where states break down and geographic diffusion, these traditional
entirely, non-state networks operating in concerns of ‘area studies’ are largely in tune
neighboring states may become the principal with cutting edge approaches in the political
conduits of both resources and ideas to science discipline. On one hand, historical
would-be revolutionary elites – as we are institutionalists are increasingly interested in
now discovering in post-invasion Iraq. charting how the impact of ‘ideas’ may sys-
This brings us to the third reason why area tematically affect the later course of institu-
studies programs tend to maintain their tradi- tional development among countries in a
tional boundaries: namely, despite all of the given region (Berman, 1998; Blyth, 2002;
trends toward cultural globalization over the Hanson, 1997). On the other hand, rational
past two centuries, powerful new ideas about choice theorists are actively seeking to incor-
politics must always initially be expressed in porate the role of ‘culture’ – understood as
some local idiom. Interpretative understand- shared belief systems – into formal models of
ing of such ideas – what Max Weber called strategic interaction, and thus accounting for
the verstehen approach – requires a fair divergent paths of political and economic
degree of contextual knowledge of particular change among neighboring peoples in other-
languages and cultures (M. Weber, 1978). wise comparable environments (Greif, 2006).
Language groupings alone thus provide one Of course, even Bates (1996) admits that area
clear rationale for traditional area studies studies specialists have a strategic advantage
programs, since notwithstanding the enor- over deductive theorists concerning the issue
mous linguistic diversity of all world regions, of verstehen. As contemporary political sci-
there are still major languages in each region ence theory illustrates just how much can
that are widely shared among elites – and turn on the cultural meanings attached to
new political ideas formulated in these lan- particular modes of conduct in different parts
guages therefore tend to diffuse quickly of the world, however, that strategic advan-
along the lines of dominant linguistic com- tage may well begin to count for a great
munities. Thus fluency in Chinese, Japanese, deal more than advocates of deductive theory
or Korean is crucial for East Asianists but not in the political science discipline initially
for Africanists; fluency in Swahili is a big recognized.
advantage for a specialist on East Africa but Thus we see that the traditional divisions
not for a South Asianist. Beyond these obvi- among major area studies programs, while
ous linguistic reasons for grouping major obviously arbitrary in the sense that their
world regions, however, is a more subtle cul- initial organization does not reflect any clear
tural one: namely, that shared historical lega- theoretical principle, nevertheless can be
cies and geographic experiences make justified in ways that are remarkably consist-
particular forms of communication more sym- ent with emerging theories and methodolo-
bolically meaningful in some regions than gies in contemporary comparative politics.
others. To understand the political power of Area studies specialists tend to group together
ideas like those of Sayyid Qutb in the contem- polities and societies that have common his-
porary Middle East, for example, one needs torical origins in imperial conquest and post-
not only fluency in Arabic, but also enough colonial liberation, that geographically
historical knowledge to see how the common occupy the same zones of the world economy
Muslim Arab experience of geopolitical and are in a position to influence each other

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:11 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


170 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

profoundly through institutional diffusion, in much the same form for many decades
and that have enough linguistic and cultural now is the lack of intellectual respect shown
commonality to generate distinctive shared by partisans on both sides, which tends to
responses to new political ideas. Given what perpetuate longstanding stereotypes of the
we are learning about the importance of past ‘enemy.’
regime legacies, geographical proximity, and More specifically, despite the reasonably
cultural interpretations for the course of insti- large degree of overlap between the criteria
tutional development in human history, these for defining ‘areas’ in most area studies pro-
rough-and-ready principles for the training grams and the factors now increasingly
of future comparativists utilized in most area thought to be vital for explaining patterns of
studies programs may actually serve the institutional evolution in time and space,
comparative politics subfield rather well. At there is clearly still some truth to the claim
a minimum, discarding the hard-won exper- that traditional area studies boundaries are
tise in regional histories, patterns of eco- defined in ways that are theoretically and
nomic interaction, languages and cultures empirically arbitrary. Even if we accept the
that has been built up in area studies pro- importance of past legacies of Soviet rule for
grams over the past several decades in favor structuring post-Soviet politics and societies,
of newly-proposed theoretical categoriza- does the impact of Leninism still justify
tions of regimes seems like a very risky bet. grouping Tajikistan and Slovenia in the same
typological category – two decades after the
collapse of communism in East-Central
Europe? Or does the divide between the
CONCLUSION European Union and post-Soviet ‘Eurasia’
now provide a more logical point of depar-
The thrust of this chapter has been to provide ture for comparative political analysis?
a defense of the contribution of area studies Similarly, is there really any theoretical
to comparative politics. As we have seen, reason to study Australia and Burma as
most of the common critiques of area studies common members of ‘Southeast Asia’? Or
are based on incorrect and/or outdated under- should we study Australia and New Zealand
standings of work in this tradition. And even as ‘former British settler states’ and thus as
the strongest theoretical critique of area stud- decisively different from other postcolonial
ies research – that it is built around regional settings in that region? Concerning such
groupings of countries that are in some basic questions, ‘the facts’ will never speak for
sense arbitrary – can be countered by noting themselves. Only deductive theory, in the
cutting-edge theoretical breakthroughs in end, can provide clear conceptual criteria for
comparative politics that re-emphasize the deciding which comparisons will be fruitful
importance of history, geography, and culture for examining particular social scientific
for explaining institutional change. hypotheses.
Returning to the vituperative debate with Seen in this light, knowledge of current
which this chapter began: does this mean that trends in deductive, general social science
Johnson is right and Bates is wrong? Not theory can play a crucial intellectual role for
entirely. As we have seen, the issues involved specialists in area studies, provoking them
in judging the contribution of area studies constantly to reexamine their understandings
from a social scientific point of view are of the ‘regions’ on which they claim exper-
extremely complex, and neither side in this tise, and undermining implicitly static char-
longstanding debate has the right to dismiss acterizations of the nature of regional politics,
the contributions of the other out of hand. economics, and cultures. In some cases,
Indeed, one reason that the debate between longstanding institutional divisions among
area specialists and their critics has continued different area studies centers on American

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:12 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


THE CONTRIBUTION OF AREA STUDIES 171

campuses might even be fruitfully rethought 5. One might also point out that Geertz was an
in light of critiques developed by more gen- anthropologist, rather than a political scientist; hence
it hardly makes sense to cite his work as an example
eral theories of political and social change. of ‘area studies’ methodology in the latter discipline.
On the other hand, purely deductive analysis,
unaccompanied by inductive research into
the distinct empirical patterns of human
interaction typical of particular parts of the
world, will frequently be blind to the ways in REFERENCES
which existing historical legacies and geo-
Apter, D.E. (1955) The gold coast in transition.
graphical diffusion generate the ‘scope con-
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
ditions’ that limit the generalizability of most
Apter, D.E. (1963) Ghana in transition. New
(if not all) political science theories (Hanson York: Atheneum.
and Kopstein, 2005). Indeed, a strong train- Baker, J.A. (III.), Hamilton, L.H., et al. (2006)
ing in area studies tends to arm political sci- The Iraq study group report. New York:
entists with precisely the tools they need to Vintage Books; Washington, D.C., United
see just where ‘universal’ theories of human States Institute of Peace.
behavior break down when applied outside Bates, R.H. (1996, Winter) ‘Letter from the
the social contexts in which they were first president: Area studies and the discipline’,
developed. Thus, an open-minded and mutu- Newsletter of the APSA Comparative Politics
ally respectful dialogue between scholars Section, 7 (1): 1.
Bates, R., Greif, A., Levi, M., Rosenthal, J.-L.,
with a preference for deductive models and
and Weingast, B. (1998) Analytic narratives.
highly abstract theories, and those who prefer
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
to chart the mechanisms of political and Berman, S. (1998) The social democratic
social change that are distinct to parti- moment: Ideas and politics in the making of
cular world areas, might greatly advance interwar Europe. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
our collective understanding of the human University Press.
condition. Blyth, M. (2002) Great transformations:
Economic ideas and institutional change in
the twentieth century. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Cohen, S. (1985) Rethinking the soviet experi-
NOTES ence: Politics and history since 1917. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
1. Similar developments took place in Western Cohen, S. (1999) ‘Russian studies without
Europe. For example, African, Asian and Soviet area
Russia’, Post-Soviet Affairs, 15 (1): 37–55.
studies centres were set up in the UK in the 1960s as
Collier, P. (2007) The bottom billion: Why the
a response to geopolitical developments and inspired
by the 1958 US act (Hayter, 1975). poorest countries are failing and what can
2. Indeed, in an era when the world’s sole super- be done about it. Oxford: Oxford University
power could find only six fluent speakers of Arabic Press.
to hire for work in the US Embassy in post-invasion Eckstein, H. (1975) ‘A critique of area studies
Iraq, one might argue for much greater support from a west European perspective’, in L.W.
for and utilization of area studies expertise in Pye (ed.), Political science and area studies:
the formulation of U.S. foreign policy (Baker et al., Rivals or partners? Bloomington: Indiana
2006: 92). University Press, pp. 199–217.
3. Note, for example, Theodore Roosevelt’s cri-
Eckstein, H. and Gurr, T.R. (1975) Patterns of
tique of Wilson’s proposals for the League of Nations
authority: A structural basis for comparative
as requiring the United States to declare war ‘every
time a Jugoslav wishes to slap a Czechoslav in the inquiry. New York: Wiley.
face.’ (Quoted in Ruggie, 1997). Ekiert, G. and Hanson, S.E. (2003) ‘Time,
4. Perhaps the only prominent exception is Samuel space, and institutional change in central
Huntington (1996) – who, ironically, is certainly not and eastern Europe’, in G. Ekiert and S.E.
known in the field as an ‘area specialist.’ Hanson (eds), Capitalism and democracy in

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:13 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


172 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

central and eastern Europe: Assessing trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University


the legacy of communist rule. Press.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Gunnell, J.G. (1993) ‘American political science,
pp. 15–48. liberalism, and the invention of political
Evans, P.B. (1979) Dependent development: theory’, in J. Farr and R. Seidelman (eds),
The alliance of multinational, state, and local Discipline and history: Political science in the
capital in Brazil. Princeton, NJ: Princeton United States. Ann Arbor: University of
University Press. Michigan Press, pp.179–97.
Evans, P.B., Rueschemeyer, D. and Skocpol, T. Gurr, T.R. (1974) ‘Persistence and change in
(eds) (1985) Bringing the state back in. political systems, 1800–1971’, American
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Political Science Review, 68 (4): 1478–81.
Farish, M. (2005) ‘Archiving areas: The Haas, E.B. (1958) The uniting of Europe:
ethnogeographic board and the second Political, social, and economic forces, 1950–
world war’, Annals of the Associ- 1957. Stanford, CA: Stanford University
ation of American Geographers, 95: Press.
663–79. Haas, E.B. (1964) Beyond the nation–
Farr, J. and Seidelman, R. (Eds.) (1993) Discipline state: Functionalism and international organi-
and history: Political science in the United zation. Stanford, CA: Stanford University
States. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Press. Hall, P.A. and Tarrow, S. (2001) ‘Globalization
Ford Foundation (1999) Crossing borders: and area studies: When is too broad too
Revitalizing area studies. New York: Ford narrow?’, in P. O’Meara, H.D. Mehlinger and
Foundation. R. Ma Newman (eds), Changing perspectives
Foster, G.M. (1965) ‘Peasant society and the on international education (2nd edition).
image of limited good’, American Bloomington: Indiana University Press, pp.
Anthropologist, 67 (2): 293–315. 96–100.
Friedman, T.L. (1999) The lexus and the olive Hanson, S.E. (1997) Time and revolution:
tree. New York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux. Marxism and the design of soviet institu-
Friedman, T.L. (2005) The world is flat: A brief tions. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina
history of the twenty-first century. New Press.
York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux. Hanson, S.E. and Kopstein, J.S. (2005) ‘Regime
Fukuyama, F. (1993) ‘The modernizing impera- type and diffusion in comparative politics
tive: The USSR as an ordinary country’, methodology’, Canadian Journal of Political
National Interest, 31: 10–18. Science, 38 (March), 69–99.
Gallup, J.L., Sachs, J.D. and Mellinger A.D. Hayter, W. (1975) ‘The Hayter report and
(1999) ‘Geography and Economic Develop- after’, Oxford Review of Education, 1:
ment’, International Regional Science Review, 169–72.
22 (2): 179–232. Hough, J.F. (1997) Democratization and revo-
Geertz, C. (1973) ‘Thick description: Toward an lution in the USSR. Washington, DC:
interpretive theory of culture’, in The inter- Brookings.
pretations of cultures: Selected essays. New Huntington, S.P. (1996) The clash of civiliza-
York: Basic Books, pp. 3–30. tions and the remaking of world order. New
Gellner, E. (1983) Nations and nationalism. York: Simon and Schuster.
Oxford: Blackwell. Johnson, C. (2001) ‘Preconception vs. observa-
Golden, M. (1998, Summer) ‘Is there an inter- tion, or the contributions of rational choice
national division of labor in contemporary theory and area studies to contemporary
political science: Editor’s introduction’, political science’, in P. O’Meara, H.D. Mehlinger
Newsletter of the APSA Comparative Politics and R. Ma Newman (eds), Changing per-
Section, 9 (2): 6. spectives on international education.
Greif, A. (2006) Institutions and the path to the Bloomington: Indiana University Press, pp.
modern economy: Lessons from medieval 58–66.

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:14 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


THE CONTRIBUTION OF AREA STUDIES 173

Johnson, C. (2000) Blowback: The costs and soviet dictatorship. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
consequences of American empire. New University Press.
York: Metropolitan Books. Musallam, A. (2005) From secularism to jihad:
Johnson, C. (1962) Peasant nationalism and Sayyid Qutb and the foundations of radical
communist power: The emergence of Islamism. Westport, CT: Praeger.
revolutionary China, 1937–1945. Stanford, Parsons, T. (1951) The social system. Glencoe,
CA: Stanford University Press. IL: Free Press.
Knock, T.J. (1992) To end all wars: Woodrow Prewitt, K. (1996) ‘Presidential items’, Items, 50
Wilson and the quest for a new world order. (1); 15–18.
New York: Oxford University Press. Przeworski, A. and Teune, H. (1970) The logic
Kopstein, J. and Reilly, D. (2000) ‘Geographic of comparative social inquiry. New York:
diffusion and the transformation of the post- Wiley-Interscience.
communist world’, World Politics, 53 Rashid, A. (2002) Jihad: The rise of militant
(October): 1–37. Islam in Central Asia. New Haven: Yale
Laitin, D.D. (1977) Politics, language, and University Press.
thought: The Somali experience. Chicago: Rostow, W.W. (1960) The stages of
University of Chicago Press. economic growth: A non–communist mani-
Lambert, R.D., Barber, E.G., Merrill, M.B., festo. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Jorden, E., and Twarog, L.I. (1984) Beyond Press.
growth: The next stage in language and area Ruggie, J.G. (1997) ‘The past as prologue?:
studies. Washington DC: Association of Interests, identity, and American foreign
American Universities. policy’, International Security, 21 (4):
Lambert, R.D. (2001) ‘Domains and issues in 89–125.
international studies’, in P. O’Meara, H.D. Rupnik, J. (1999) ‘The postcommunist divide’,
Mehlinger and R. Ma Newman (eds), Journal of Democracy, 10: 57–62.
Changing perspectives on international edu- Said, E.W. (1978) Orientalism. New York:
cation. Bloomington: Indiana University Vintage Books.
Press, pp. 30–48. Scott, J.C. (1985) Weapons of the weak:
Lerner, D. (1958) The passing of traditional Everyday forms of peasant resistance. New
society: Modernizing the Middle East. Haven: Yale University Press.
Glencoe, IL: Free Press. Sewell, W. (1980) Work and revolution in
Lowenthal, R. (1970) ‘Development v. utopia in France: The language of labor from the old
communist policy’, in C. Johnson (ed.), regime through 1848. Cambridge: Cambridge
Change in communist systems. Stanford: University Press.
Stanford University Press, pp. 33–116. Skocpol, T. (1979) States and social revolu-
Mahoney, J. and Rueschemeyer, D. (eds) (2003) tions. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Comparative historical analysis in the social Press.
sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Steinmo, S., Thelen, K. and Longstreth, F. (eds)
Press. (1992) Structuring politics: Historical institu-
Malia, M. (1993) ‘A fatal logic’, National tionalism in comparative analysis. Cambridge:
Interest, 31: 80–90. Cambridge University Press.
Mitchell, T. (2004) ‘The Middle East in the past Thelen, K. (1999) ‘Historical institutionalism in
and future of social science’, in D. Szanton comparative politics’, Annual Review of
(ed.) The politics of knowledge: Area studies Political Science, 2: 369–404.
and the disciplines. Berkeley: University of Thorsen, N. (1998) The political thought of
California Press, pp. 74–118. Woodrow Wilson, 1875–1910. Princeton,
Moore, B. (1950) Soviet politics: The dilemma NJ: Princeton University Press.
of power. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Tucker, R.C. (1969) The Marxian revolutionary
Press. idea. New York: Norton.
Moore, B. (1954) Terror and progress USSR: Vachudova, M.A. (2005) Europe undivided:
Some sources of change and stability in the Democracy, leverage, and integration

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:15 3/11/2009 3:48:24 PM


174 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

after communism. Cambridge: Cambridge Weber, E.J. (1976) Peasants into Frenchmen:
University Press. The modernization of rural France, 1870–
Wallerstein, I. (1974) ‘The rise and future 1914. Stanford, CA: Stanford University
demise of the world capitalist system: Press.
Concepts for comparative analysis’, Weber, M. (1978) Economy and society: An
Comparative Studies in Society and History, outline of interpretive sociology. Berkeley:
16 (4): 387–415. University of California Press.
Ward, R.E. (1975) ‘Culture and the compara- Wilkinson, S.I. (submitted) Colonization, insti-
tive study of politics’, in L.W. Pye (ed.), tutions and conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge
Political science and area studies: Rivals or University Press.
partners? Bloomington: Indiana University
Press, pp. 23–47.

9781412919760_Chap09.indd Sec1:16 3/11/2009 3:48:25 PM


10
Comparative Politics and
International Relations
John M. Hobson

INTRODUCTION receiving end of such a dismissal, even


though I had begun teaching and working in
The relationship between the disciplines of IR. I began in my PhD by developing a com-
International Relations (IR) and Compara- parative historical-sociological perspective
tive Politics (CP) – as well as Comparative on the shift from free trade to tariff protec-
Political Economy (CPE) and Comparative tionism in Europe in the late nineteenth
Sociology (CS) – despite a prima facie or century. The dissertation was essentially a
intuitive appearance of natural or inherent critique of Marxist and liberal conceptions of
overlap, turns out to be highly complex, trade policy and sought not just to theorize
fraught and problematic. For given that CP the role of the international as it impacted
scholars often assume that they work broadly upon different states, but simultaneously
within IR, it is naturally perplexing to be told reveal how the domestic realm impacted on
by many IR scholars that their disciplines the international (thereby fundamentally
share very little in common: that ‘CP is not breaking down the ‘great divide’ between the
IR’. It is indeed perplexing, of course, two realms). At the time I assumed that my
because so many CP scholars frame their comparative historical-sociological perspec-
analyses within an international context. One tive overlapped with IR and that, in effect, I
need only think of scholars such as Theda had already paid the high start-up costs that
Skocpol (1979) or Michael Mann (1993) would ease my transition from a sociology
who not only factor in the role of the interna- doctoral student to a lecturer in IR. But
tional into their theories but go yet further by having joined a politics department in order
seeking to break down what Ian Clark (1999) to do just this (at La Trobe University,
usefully calls the ‘great divide’ between the- Melbourne in 1992), I quickly learned how
ories of the international and national realms. little I really knew about IR and how my
How could such comparative scholarship be work up to that point did not fit well within
characterized as ‘not IR’? the discipline. Having battled through my
I know just how perplexing, if not bewil- initial bewilderment, and not infrequent bouts
dering, this can be for I was once on the of perplexing difficulties over a considerable

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:1 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


176 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

period of time, I then prepared the disserta-


tion for publication by adding in a critique of THE PROBLEMATIQUE OF IR:
neorealism and, in the process, completely OR, WHY ‘COMPARATIVE
recast the argument to provide a comparative POLITICS IS NOT IR’
historical-sociology not simply of trade
policy but of IR more generally (Hobson, It helps to begin by highlighting the point
1997). Even so, it was not until I wrote my that for many CP/CPE or CS analyses the key
book The State and International Relations methodological approach deployed examines
(Hobson, 2000) that I came to fully under- how international forces or pressures are
stand why IR scholars dismiss CP as ‘not responded to in a variety of ways across
IR’. Accordingly, I seek in the first section to national societies. Thus, for example, Peter
relay my own learning experience under- Gourevitch’s book, Politics in Hard Times,
taken between 1992 and 2000 so as to pro- examines how various states responded dif-
vide a potted, ‘pain-free’ explanation for ferently to international economic recession
those CP scholars who experience bewilder- in the late-nineteenth century (Gourevitch,
ment or puzzlement in the face of this dis- 1986). Specifically, he opens up the ‘black
missal. And this will simultaneously provide box’ to reveal how domestic actor prefer-
an introduction to the problematique and ences came to shape national trade policy.
study of IR. Similarly, Theda Skocpol’s States and Social
However, while I now fully appreciate Revolutions argues that various states fared
why IR dismisses CP as ‘not IR’, I do not differently under the challenges posed by the
accept its wholesale rejection within an IR geopolitical inter-state system (Skocpol,
context, as I believe that ignoring compara- 1979). Thus revolutions occurred in France
tive insight limits the study of IR. The irony (1789), Russia (1917) and China (1949)
is that the two disciplines should be ‘bedfel- because the respective states were unable to
lows’, working together to explore the many overcome domestic fetters to the enhance-
issues and problems that confront the world ment of its fiscal-military capacity. By con-
today. And so what should be a fruitful dia- trast, the Prussian and Meiji Japanese states
logue between like-minded scholars has were able to overcome domestic fetters and
degenerated into a dialogue of the deaf, were accordingly able to remain militarily
which, I argue, comes to the detriment of competitive, thereby avoiding the fate of
both disciplines. The issue then becomes, social revolution. Many other examples
therefore, how we can resolve this problem could, of course, be marshalled here – for
so as to render the two disciplines commen- example, Gerschenkron’s analysis of late
surable in the first instance so that we may industrialisation (Gerschenkron, 1962), or
then consider how each can benefit through Tilly’s and Mann’s analysis of state forma-
mutual dialogue (which will be considered in tion (Tilly, 1990; Mann, 1993). But this is
the conclusion). And finally, the second sec- sufficient to establish the key point at stake
tion acts as a bridge between the first section here: that the comparative methodology is
and the conclusion, relaying how compara- one that holds the international realm con-
tive analysis has been conducted within IR. stant and examines how domestic forces –
Above all, outlining the problematique usually state-society relations – differ across
and study of IR conducted in the first national states and lead to different out-
two sections is a vital pre-requisite for pro- comes on the ground. That is, uniform
moting bicultural or bi-disciplinary under- international pressures are refracted in differ-
standing so that a productive dialogue can ent ways at the national level owing to
be developed in order to enhance both specific constellations of domestic forces.
disciplines. This is, to borrow Gourevitch’s well-known

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:2 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 177

phrase, a ‘second-image reversed’ approach in contradistinction to classical realism.


(Gourevitch, 1978). And ultimately this boils Significantly, while earlier classical realists –
down to the point that varying state-society E.H. Carr (1939) and especially Hans
relations are treated as the independent Morgenthau (1948/1978) – had become
variable. famous in the discipline because they sought
IR can be differentiated from CP in two to lay out a ‘science’ of international politics,
immediate ways. First, and most obviously, Waltz took this enterprise one step further.
IR is interested primarily in explaining occur- And he did so in large part by constructing a
rences within the international, rather than great divide between the national and inter-
the domestic, realm. Second, and more national realms on the one hand and banish-
importantly, for mainstream IR the interna- ing comparative analysis from the study of
tional is treated as the independent variable IR on the other. But to understand this, it is
such that national variations are ignored (ie., worth providing the background context that
state-society relations are black-boxed). How underpins these various moves that culmi-
and why has this particular spatial ontology nated in the placing of the present goalposts
emerged as the defining aspect of mainstream between which the gatekeeper of ‘legitimate
IR? In answering this question I shall delve IR’ stands on guard.
into a sociology of knowledge through relat- While it would be wrong to assume that IR
ing the construction of contemporary IR, the as a discipline began after 1919 as most IR
sub-text of which is that the present defini- scholars problematically assume (Schmidt,
tion of the discipline is highly contingent and 1998), it has nevertheless become a trope that
problematic. And this in turn fits into my IR, conceived as a separate ‘scientific’ disci-
argument made in the conclusion where I pline within the social sciences, had to await
suggest that the discipline can and should, I the arrival of Carr and Morgenthau around the
believe, be reconstructed so as to allow for time of World War II. IR is, perhaps more than
inter-disciplinary dialogical learning. any other discipline, defined by a certain inse-
As I personally entered the discipline of IR curity. It is assumed by most IR scholars (not-
I came to realize that the key that unlocks its withstanding Schmidt’s pioneering insights)
door is the ‘W-word’ – Waltz. In 1979 that it began later than most other disciplines.
Kenneth Waltz published his seminal text, The insecurity emerged as a function of the
Theory of International Politics (Waltz, perception that IR was a derivative late-comer
1979). In the present context, there are two discipline that comprised an awkward amal-
inter-related achievements that marked the gam of a variety of different disciplines and,
book. First, it brought neorealism onto the IR therefore, had no autonomous integrity.
agenda in no uncertain terms. Second, it was Crucially, it has been the quest for such exclu-
important because it sought to redefine or sive disciplinary integrity that has obsessed IR
reconstruct the discipline of IR in highly theorists in the latter half of the last century – an
exclusive or parsimonious ways that entailed obsession that is probably unique to IR. And it
banishing CP and comparative insight from is this obsession that gave Carr and Morgenthau
that which constitutes ‘legitimate IR their privileged status within the discipline.
research’. And here it is vital to realize that However, as we shall see shortly, this was gov-
Waltz’s 1979 book is the foundationalist text erned by a fundamental irony. Indeed, the
for all of modern IR; so much so that inti- whole process of constructing the discipline is
mate familiarity with it probably marks the replete with ironies. And I shall spend a good
litmus test for whether someone is conver- deal of time considering these ironies because
sant with modern IR – a test that my CP they point up the manufactured process through
readership might want to apply to itself. which the discipline has been defined in its
Waltz’s approach was defined as ‘neo-realist’ present exclusionary form.

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:3 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


178 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Both Carr’s and Morgenthau’s prominent students still taught that the key to Morgenthau
status emerged through their calling for a lies in the first chapter and its six principles
‘science of International Politics’ (IP) that of political realism (so that students very
would at last deliver to IR its disciplinary rarely read beyond the first chapter). Yet
autonomous integrity. The key contribution more surprising is that even in the first chap-
here lies with the first chapter of Morgenthau’s ter there is a hint of an alternative formula-
seminal text, Politics Among Nations tion that is outlined in his third principle
(Morgenthau, 1948/1978). There he set out which asserts that
the ‘six principles of political realism’ that the contemporary connection between interest
served to lay the foundations for this ‘science and the nation state is a product of history, and is
of IP’. Moreover, the book’s ‘legitimacy’ was therefore bound to disappear in the course of his-
enhanced further because it provided a kind tory. Nothing in the realist position militates
against the assumption that the present division of
of manual or handbook for American states-
the political world into nation states will be
men in their pursuit of great power politics replaced by larger units of a quite different charac-
after 1947 (Hoffmann, 1977; Smith, 2000). ter, more in keeping with the technical
The key principles here are the second and potentialities and the moral requirements of
sixth, which effectively assert that the sphere the contemporary world. (Morgenthau, 1948/
1978: 10)
of politics must be separated out from all
others, whether these be economic, legalistic, And the following 32 chapters lay out a rela-
moralist, social, etc. Moreover, his argument tively complex ‘comparative historical’
was that for foreign policy to be effective approach to the study and analysis of IR that
statesmen must ignore domestic social in effect extrapolates on the third principle
forces completely. Furthermore, his approach (see Hobson, 2000: 47–55; Griffiths, 1992).
advanced a positivism that transcends time In short, it is as if the vast majority of the
and space. This was realized in his famous book elaborates on the third principle which,
claims that ‘the struggle for power [between in contrast to the other five, rejects a positivist/
states] is universal in time and space’ scientific epistemology. And it is the desire
(Morgenthau, 1948/1978: 36), and that ‘all his- of IR scholars to preserve a constructed view
tory shows that nations active in international of IR as having its own autonomous and sci-
politics are continuously preparing for, entific (positivist) integrity that, I believe,
actually involved in, or recovering from accounts for why this alternative reading has
organized violence in the form of war’ gone largely unnoticed. That is, this alterna-
(Morgenthau, 1948/1978: 42). All in all, tive comparative historical sociological read-
then, in this conventional reading of ing has gone largely unnoticed because it
Morgenthau we can see the (tentative) ori- would disturb the preferred construction of
gins of the claim that the international realm the discipline that has been embraced by
must be analytically separated out from the mainstream, positivist IR scholars and gate-
domestic, that international politics must be keepers in the last three decades.
separated out from all non-political factors, Nevertheless, a yet more profound irony
and that the processes that govern interna- quickly emerges for it was Kenneth Waltz in
tional politics are universal in time and his 1979 book who forcefully took issue with
space. classical realism. And in considering this
And yet the deep irony here lies in the critique, so we necessarily move closer to
point that the following 32 chapters in many understanding how and why the break or
ways contradicted these positivistic and divide between IR and CP has occurred. As
spatial-ontological claims for which he had signalled earlier, Waltz’s major task was to
become famous. Perhaps more surprising redefine the discipline in ways that funda-
still is that there has been very little recogni- mentally separated it out from all others in
tion of this point among IR scholars, with the social sciences. And here he took to task

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:4 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 179

the classical realism of Carr and especially realm – what he terms the anarchic interna-
Morgenthau in order to achieve this objec- tional political structure – an ontological
tive. Hic criticism was simple but powerful. primacy such that it is deemed to be entirely
He claimed that classical realism was not autonomous of influences emanating from
after all a scientific theory of IP because, the domestic-national realm.
despite all popular perceptions to the con- Crucially, it was this Waltzian conception
trary, it failed to separate the international that led to a rapid narrowing of the disci-
ontologically from the domestic. Carr and pline’s mainstream boundaries (though this
Morgenthau erred, he argued, because they process had begun under the influence of
had in fact ‘merely’ created a ‘theory of for- behaviourism in the 1960s). Indeed, Waltz’s
eign policy’ rather than a proper, positivistic theory sought explicitly to banish the study
theory of the international. That is, they had of CP or equally Comparative Sociology/
looked at the domestic origins of foreign Economics from the definition of that which
policy – something that rendered their theo- constitutes ‘legitimate IR enquiry’ (eg.,
ries more commensurate with comparative Waltz, 1979: 43–9). Above all, his central
analysis rather than IR. And in the process analytical focus upon which he constructed
yet another irony emerges. For to fully his own theory, rested on the assumption that
understand Waltz’s disciplinary and theoreti- the key aspect that governs the international
cal move here requires us to entirely rethink realm is ‘continuity’. By continuity he means
the conventional positivistic reading of Carr that the international realm has always
and Morgenthau (as alluded to above and to remained the same: that international politics
which I shall return more fully in the second has always comprised conflict between polit-
section). But while it is certainly true that a ical units, whether these be empires, city-
minority of scholars have reinterpreted Carr states or nation-states (Waltz, 1979: 66). To
and Morgenthau in ways that in effect take explain this uniformity of international out-
Waltz’s claim much further (eg., Griffiths, comes, Waltz established four major points,
1992; Hobson, 2000: 45–61; Howe, 1994), all of which sought to banish comparative
it is telling that students for the most part political/economic/sociological enquiry from
are still taught that classical realism devel- the mainstream IR research agenda.
oped a ‘science of IP’ that echoes much First, conceiving international anarchy
of what Waltz (1979) stands for (eg., (defined as the absence of a higher authority
Burchill, 1996). above states) as an autonomous structure,
It helps to contextualize all this within ensures that states have no choice but to
Waltz’s three-fold typology of theories of adapt or conform to the structuralist logic of
international conflict that was systematically anarchic competition. Accordingly, the poli-
laid out in his equally famous book, Man, the tics of ‘agency’ drops out (and is thereby
State, and War (Waltz, 1959). There he consigned or banished to the discipline of
labelled those theories that locate the causes CP). Second, Waltz posits a strict dividing
of international conflict in the nature of indi- line between the autonomous or self-consti-
viduals as ‘first image’ conceptions. ‘Second tuting international realm and the residual
image’ theories focus on state-society rela- national/domestic realm, in order to retain
tions that exist at the national, domestic level. the ontological primacy of international anar-
By contrast, ‘third image’ theories locate the chy (again banishing the analysis of domestic
causes of international conflict at the interna- politics to Comparative Politics/Political
tional level. Beaming forward to 1979, Waltz Economy/Sociology). Third, he insists on the
returned to this conception and argued that omission of social process and identity –
a ‘scientific theory’ of IR/IP could only again so as to preserve the centrality of the
be achieved by developing a third image structural/materialist logic of anarchy, as is
approach, which grants the international consistent with his positivist, asociological

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:5 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


180 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

and ahistorical epistemology – thereby, once And by each specializing in a particular all
more banishing CP/CPE/CS from view. individuals become interdependent since the
And fourth, as noted above, he dismisses lecturer relies on the butcher, the baker or the
the study of international change by arguing chef for his meals. Crucially, this interde-
that the international realm is and always has pendence/specialization nexus only becomes
been marked by a dismaying persistence of possible because the problem of security
recurring events. Indeed, according to one has been solved by the presence of a hierar-
prominent IR scholar, Waltz’s theory con- chy (ie., a state) that stands above the indi-
tains only a reproductive rather than a trans- viduals. And the ordering principle that
formationist logic (Ruggie, 1986). And it instructs individuals to specialize means that
does so because by conforming to the com- the domestic system is characterized by
petitive logic of anarchy, so states unin- ‘unlike units’ (since they all perform differ-
tentionally reproduce the structure of ent functions or tasks).
international anarchy. Thus as states are By contrast, precisely because the interna-
required to emulate the leading powers and, tional system is anarchic given that there is
above all, to engage in balance of power no higher authority that can guarantee secu-
politics in order to ensure individual survival rity among states, so states (as the units) are
(thereby conforming to the ‘logic of anar- necessarily insecure and must conform to a
chy’), so it becomes impossible for any one different ordering principle: that of ‘self-
state to take over the system and transform help’. That is, each state must be self-
the anarchic multi-state system into an impe- sufficient and must not rely on others for its
rial hierarchy. But to understand this vital reproduction. Thus independence rather than
aspect of the argument we need to delve interdependence ensues so that states become
more deeply. ‘like units’ (ie., they become undifferentiated
Waltz argued that there are two types of in that they are functionally alike). That is,
political structure – domestic and interna- states are socialized entirely by an exogenous
tional – with each being defined by various variable as they conform to the competitive
levels or tiers. The first tier is the ‘ordering logic of international anarchy. And so it is
principle’; the second tier is the ‘character of here where we move to the final piece of the
the units’; and the third tier is the ‘distribu- jigsaw. The crux is that only in the interna-
tion of capabilities’. For the purposes of this tional political structure does the second tier
discussion it is only the first two tiers that (the nature or characteristics of the units)
require consideration. At the domestic level, ‘drop out’; that is, ‘the second [tier] is not
political structures are hierarchical, whereas needed in defining [the] international politi-
the international political structure is anar- cal structure, because so long as anarchy
chic. The critical point is that in the domestic endures, states remain like units’ (Waltz,
political structure the ‘second tier’ (the char- 1979: 93, 101). Why then does the second
acter of the units) stays in, whereas at the tier drop out of the definition of the interna-
international level the second tier ‘drops out’. tional political structure?
Understanding why this difference emerges, There are two main reasons why the char-
which he explains in Chapter 5, takes us to acter of the units must not be allowed to enter
the very heart of the issue that is at stake into the definition of the international struc-
here. In the domestic system, which entails a ture. First, the internal properties of states –
hierarchic political structure, the first tier social, economic, political, ideational – are
(‘ordering principle’) requires that the units always changing. Moreover, their properties
‘specialize’. That is, the units (individuals) vary (eg., some are democratic others author-
‘specialize’ in that activity in which each itarian, some are capitalist others communist,
does best. Some become lecturers, others some are Christian others Islamic). It is this
butchers, others bakers and others chefs, etc. reason in particular why states cannot enter

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:6 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 181

into defining the international precisely been the determined quest for scientific cer-
because the international political structure tainty, and a celebration of positivism which
never changes – it always remains anarchic. views ‘legitimate international relations
Put differently, if we allowed ever-changing enquiry’ as defined only by the acquisition of
states an ontological primitivism, then the objective knowledge, that prompted Waltz
international would appear to be changing all and others to find in international politics
the time; something that would offend the ‘law-like patterns’ of recurrence and continu-
very basis of Waltz’s ‘continuity’ assump- ity. As noted above, by definition such a
tion. Second, although the properties of linear pattern could not be revealed through a
states do indeed change over time, neverthe- comparative analysis of any sort precisely
less states are a by-product of the interna- because this entails treating states as onto-
tional system rather than vice versa. And logically important on the one hand and
paradoxically, while their properties vary functionally differentiated on the other. And
their primary function becomes uniform – to to reiterate the most important point: such
maintain security against other states in a law-like patterns of international recurrence
hostile, anarchic world. It is this homogene- and continuity could not be revealed were we
ity of function that leads onto the famous to treat states (or the national realm) as ever-
‘billiard ball metaphor’. States are likened to changing, unlike units that shape the interna-
billiard balls not simply because they con- tional structure because this would necessarily
stantly clash, but because billiard balls are lead to a picture of constant international
solid such that their internal functional change. This is why for Waltz, states must be
properties do not vary. And it is this assump- black boxed and held constant. And in noting
tion of functional homogeneity that leads this, so we arrive at the terminus of our quest
Waltz to characterize states as ‘like-units’. not simply as to why CP is ‘not IR’ but why
Accordingly, because they are all product CP must not be IR.
and not at all productive they cannot play a All this, however, is not without various
causal role in shaping and determining the ironies, which are useful to consider so as to
international political structure. For these reveal the arbitrary ‘construction’ of an
two reasons then, the second tier drops out of autonomous IR that stands separate to CP
the analysis or causal determination of the and other comparative disciplines. First, in
international system. his 1959 book Waltz argued in the final chap-
The upshot of this is that the international ter that an adequate account of IR had to
and national realms necessarily become onto- combine insights from each of the three
logically separated out, such that the former image theorists of international conflict
is enshrined with ontological primacy/ (Waltz, 1959: Chap. 8). And second, he
primitivism. Accordingly, this manoeuvre wrote a somewhat lesser-known book in the
means that CP and IR are necessarily divor- intervening period, Foreign Policy and
ced from each other precisely because CP Democratic Politics (Waltz, 1967), where he
grants ontological weighting to the domestic argued that the nature of domestic politics is
realm and views states as unlike units, vital to understanding the foreign policies of
whereas mainstream IR accords exclusive states. But by 1979 Waltz had turned his back
ontological weighting to the international on these potentially inclusive-disciplinary
system and views states as functionally simi- insights to embrace a highly parsimonious
lar units. and narrow conception of legitimate IR theo-
Crucially, Waltzian neorealism has proba- retical enquiry. Does this contradict his ear-
bly done most to mark out the borders of the lier position? Answering this takes us to the
discipline so as to explicitly exclude and very heart of his exclusionary conception of
marginalize CP from that which constitutes legitimate IR enquiry. For where he and the
‘real international relations’. Indeed it has classical realists had ‘gone wrong’, he now

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:7 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


182 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

insisted, was in developing a ‘theory of for- discipline became, at least in its leading fig-
eign policy’ (Waltz, 1979: 63–4, 121–3), ures, a reinforcement of the systemic modal-
which requires all manner of domestic and ity of IR (eg., Finnemore, 1996; Wendt,
comparative political insight. So by 1979 his 1999). Moreover, while in recent years the
central claim was that a ‘theory of foreign English School of IR – building on inter alia
policy’ might well tell us about how different the work of Hedley Bull (1977) – has wit-
states respond differently in the international nessed a resurgence, it nevertheless produces
system, but a scientific theory of interna- an approach which black-boxes the state and
tional politics is necessarily uninterested in state-society relations, thereby once more
such complexities or particularities. Rather, a reinforcing the present identity of IR (eg.,
scientific theory of IP is concerned to explain Dunne, 1998; Wheeler, 2000).
only a ‘small number of big and important Thus by the late-1980s, to many IR schol-
things’ (Waltz, 1979: Chap. 1, 70–2, 121–3; ars the new construction of a narrowly defined
1986: 329, 344–5). And this entails revealing discipline unconcerned with comparative
the law-like tendencies of the international insight appeared as entirely natural. But by
system, which define or govern the essential revisiting the genealogy of the discipline, we
and common strategies that all states will can now see that the present positioning of
necessarily undertake regardless of their the discipline’s boundaries is not natural but
domestic characteristics or properties. All in the product of an extremely recent intellec-
all, then, a scientific (international) systemic tual construction. This is important to estab-
theory eschews the complexities that com- lish as a prerequisite for the argument of the
parative insight necessarily entails. Conclusion below. Still, it is instructive to
Still, what sealed the centrality of interna- note that not all IR scholars ignore compara-
tional systemic analysis (as opposed to com- tive insight. But perhaps the greatest signifi-
parative analysis) in defining that which cance of this lies in the point that their
constitutes ‘legitimate IR’ was the publica- analyses constitute in effect a radical chal-
tion of Robert Keohane’s seminal book, After lenge to the present construction of the disci-
Hegemony (Keohane, 1984). By accepting pline. How then has this been affected?
Waltz’s systemic structuralist premise while
simultaneously moving away from his earlier
work on global interdependence (Keohane
and Nye, 1977), domestic and comparative COMPARATIVE INTERNATIONAL
politics were effectively dismissed from his RELATIONS: A NON-SEQUITUR?
purview. Moreover, Keohane’s book was
crucial because it was this that set up the I suggest that at least two broad comparative
neoliberal institutionalist research agenda, analytical variants can be discerned in the IR
which soon played a central role in the main- literature. My aim here is to provide a sketch
stream American IR agenda. And given that of these approaches before considering in the
in the US – the ‘home of IR’ (Crawford and Conclusion how we might begin the task of
Jarvis, 2001; Hoffmann, 1977; Smith, reconciling CP and IR so that both disci-
2000) – the mainstream IR research agenda plines might be reconstructed in mutually
was defined by the neorealist-neoliberal beneficial ways. But before we proceed here
debate during the 1980s and 1990s, so the it needs to be asked, in the light of the argu-
divorce of CP from IR, or the decree nisi, ment of the previous section, whether a com-
became finalized. parative IR is a non-sequitur. There are two
This is reflected by the way in which con- responses. First, what makes the following
structivist IR has been inserted into the disci- analyses part of the IR field is ultimately the
pline. Thus what could have seen a point that they are all seeking to explain
fundamental challenge to the identity of the developments or changes in the international

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:8 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 183

system (as opposed to CP/CPE/CS analyses 1948/1978: 253). Accordingly, the extant
which ultimately seek to explain develop- restraint of states was replaced by a crusad-
ments or changes at the domestic/national ing ‘nationalistic universalism’ in which
level). And second, many of these analyses democratic national states looked to impose
seek to provide – often explicitly – a chal- their own ethics on all other countries through
lenge to mainstream ‘systemic’ approaches. war. This, he argued, was responsible for the
era of total war that characterized the first
half of the twentieth century (the war of all
The comparative-sociological against all).
Thus in fundamental contrast to Waltz,
method in IR
Morgenthau prioritized the study of interna-
It is possible for analytical purposes to dis- tional change, which is explained by trans-
cern two sub-sets within this variant; one that formations within the units through the
makes historical comparisons between inter- extension of citizenship rights. No less sig-
national systems or regions across time and nificantly, this schema is very similar to that
one that compares them within one temporal produced by E.H. Carr, not in his famous
context. I shall take each in turn. As indicated 1939 book but in two lesser-known volumes,
earlier, one of the ironies here lies in the The New Society (Carr, 1951) and Nationalism
point that while conventionally regarded as and After (Carr, 1945). Indeed the essential
proponents of a positivistic, exclusive IR, argument is almost identical, with the main
Carr and Morgenthau in fact developed difference comprising in the point that Carr
a theory of IR that was based on a compara- singles out four historical epochs rather
tive historical sociological analysis. Here than two (for a full discussion see Hobson,
the essential mode of comparison is not 2000: 55–61).
between states in a similar time period but Importantly, this kind of comparative-
between international systems in different historical research is returning to IR, not sur-
historical epochs. In Politics Among Nations, prisingly as a means to challenge mainstream,
Morgenthau differentiated two key historical and especially neorealist, positivist analysis.
epochs, which he labelled the ‘aristocratic Indeed since the end of the Cold War main-
international’ and ‘nationalistic universal- stream (Waltzian) neorealism has come under
ism’. The former epoch that existed between sustained attack from a range of sociological
approximately 1648 and the nineteenth cen- approaches, some of which deploy a compar-
tury was characterized by relative peace and ative-historical sociological methodology
cooperation between states. It was so because (for a full discussion see Hobson, 2002). One
rulers had a high institutional autonomy from of the more easily identifiable versions in
the masses and were able to pursue inter- terms of CP understanding can be found in
state policies that were based on feudal the recent work of Chris Reus-Smit in his
norms of politeness and honour. However, book, The Moral Purpose of the State (Reus-
the rise of democratic nation-states in the Smit, 1999). He develops a constructivist
nineteenth century witnessed a fundamental comparative historical sociology by compar-
change or transformation in the international ing three regional international systems in
system. Now states became embedded within world history – specifically the Ancient
their societies, such that the mass of citizens Greek city-state system, the medieval Italian
exercised an influence in foreign policy. In city-state system and the modern sovereign
the process the moral boundary contracted state system. His principal focus is to reveal
from the international to the national level. how each system was governed by different
Thus international aristocratic morality international/regional institutional frame-
was replaced by a nationalistic ethic of works, with each being differentiated by
‘Right or wrong – my country’ (Morgenthau, the unique normative environments that

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:9 3/11/2009 3:50:51 PM


184 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

characterized the relevant constituent units. their external sovereignty. Paradoxically, this
Through such a comparative historical socio- opens up a domestic space for such states to
logical framework he is able to reveal why implement repressive domestic policies.
multilateralism has become a unique prop- Their security dilemma leads to intra-state
erty of the modern sovereign state system. wars (derived from their inability to secure
A more well-known example is found in domestic order and legitimacy). By contrast,
the pioneering article by John Ruggie in postmodern states, while having solved their
which he challenged neorealism’s ontology external security challenge, face other exter-
by revealing how the European feudal ‘heter- nal challenges connected with globalization
onomous’ system differed fundamentally and the democratic deficit problem. And, of
from its modern Westphalian successor course, modern states face the traditional
(Ruggie, 1986). And it is noteworthy that security dilemma. More generally, this type
others have produced a range of comparative of comparative approach is receiving consid-
historical-sociological analyses that reveal erable attention within IR as regionalism is
differences in international systems through increasingly viewed as a major feature of the
time (eg., Buzan and Little, 2000), usually as contemporary global system.
a function of different state-society relations,
whether these be based on class forces (eg.,
Rosenberg, 1994), or purely normative fac- Comparative politics/
tors (eg., Hall, 1999), or an amalgam of
economics in IR
materialist and non-materialist social forces
(cf. Buzan and Little, 2000; Ruggie, 1986). The second major variant of comparative
The second sub-set of this variant com- analysis conducted within IR has perhaps the
pares regions in the same temporal context, most in common with traditional CP/CPE/
usually that of the present. One instructive CS. This approach opens up the black box of
example here is found in Georg Sørenson’s state-society relations and examines the ways
book, Changes in Statehood (Sørenson, in which national variations impact on the
2001). Sørenson seeks to break down the inter-state system/international economy and
great divide between CP and IR where the sometimes vice versa. One such example lies
national-domestic and international realms in my own work that was set out in The
become co-constitutive. Crucially he argues Wealth of States (Hobson, 1997). As noted
that domestic structures can resist interna- earlier, my task here was to provide a com-
tional pressures towards homogenization and, parative historical sociology of international
in contrast to Waltz, argues that the world is change, using the transition from free trade
characterized by the presence of states as to protectionism in late-nineteenth century
unlike units. He specifies the existence of Europe as a case study. The central claim lies
three forms of state – the modern state (which in the point that international trade regime
conforms to the Weberian definition and is change is significantly informed by the nature
found in large parts of Asia); the postcolonial of internal relations within European states.
state (which does not have a monopoly of the The principal states chosen were Russia,
means of violence as found in Africa); and Germany and Britain where the ‘most differ-
the postmodern state (where there are multi- ent’ comparative method is deployed. Thus
level layers of governance, found especially unitary democratic Britain is compared with
in the EU). Most importantly, he argues that federal authoritarian Germany and unitary
each region undergoes specific domestic and autocratic Russia.
international security dilemmas (Sørenson, The argument begins by noting that the
2001, Chapters 7–9). Thus, postcolonial states shift to protectionism was significantly
enjoy limited external threat owing to the dependent upon the fiscal choices of states
structure of international law, which supports given that tariffs are (regressive) indirect taxes.

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:10 3/11/2009 3:50:52 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 185

As states faced fiscal crisis after 1870, given external economic and non-economic chal-
the escalation of the costs of war at the same lenges (cf. Keohane and Milner, 1996;
time that international recession reduced the Katzenstein, 1996; Risse-Kappen, 1995).
tax take, so governments looked for new And interestingly, these complement the
sources of tax revenues. The key claim is that analyses of various prominent comparativist
where states were disembedded from the scholars (eg., Garrett, 1998; Gourevitch,
mass of the population (which meant that 1986; Weiss, 1998, 2003).
they suffered from low governing capacity),
so they resorted to regressive indirect taxes
and therefore chose to shift to tariff protec-
tionism (as in Germany and Russia). But in CONCLUSION: RECONCILING
addition, a state’s level of institutional cen- CP AND IR FOR THEIR
tralization was a further important variable, MUTUAL BENEFIT
with federal states relying on indirect taxes
(and hence protectionism) while unitary The upshot of the previous section is that
states had greater capacity to resort to pro- comparative analysis is certainly re-emerging
gressive income taxation. Thus the more within IR, which in turn might appear to
robust unitary British state, which was also contradict the argument of the first section.
more embedded within the newly enfran- But we can resolve this potential confusion
chised masses, chose to enhance progressive by pointing out that the majority of those IR
income taxes in order to pay for new spend- scholars who deploy comparative insight do
ing prerogatives, thereby avoiding the so in order to challenge the present main-
shift back to protectionism. The British stream identity of the discipline (even if this
example is also significant because it is sometimes only implicit). And this in turn
pre-empted the later shift to an international implies that comparative insight still occu-
free trade regime after 1945 as first world pies an outsider position within the disci-
states developed more deeply embedded pline. But while such extra-disciplinary
relations with their societies. Hence national insight has, paradoxically, produced much
trade policy responses and changes in inter- richer analyses of IR, I think it highly
national trade regimes were based on specific unlikely that the growing cumulative weight
configurations of domestic state-society of such comparative analyses will spontane-
relations as they responded to external ously tip the scales away from the disci-
and domestic challenges. No less impor- pline’s current international systemic identity
tantly, while the international system con- at some point in the future. For this thrust
strained states in certain ways, it was also a will remain stymied until the discipline’s
‘resource pool’ into which states dipped in identity is explicitly reconstructed so as to
order to push through various domestic become more inclusive. But by the same
changes. Accordingly, The Wealth of States token, I do not believe that IR should simply
simultaneously deploys a ‘second image’ import CP as it is presently constructed
(inside-out) and ‘second image-reversed’ because the latter also suffers various prob-
(outside-in) approach. lems that can be resolved by a more open and
Finally, while other IR scholars have pro- constructive engagement with IR.
duced comparative studies that examine the Most generally, I want to argue that CP
domestic origins of international change (eg., and IR, as they are presently constructed,
Seabrooke, 2006), others have invoked a both suffer major blind spots that limit their
comparative domestic institutional approach utility. The essential limitations are summed
that reveals how different nexuses of state- up by their propensity to lop-sided analysis.
society relations lead to different policy out- Thus while CP/CPE/CS black boxes the
comes, in response to globalization and other international or holds it constant so that the

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:11 3/11/2009 3:50:52 PM


186 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

domestic realm is invested with ontological but rather to point to some of the problems
primacy, mainstream IR suffers the inverse that each discipline necessarily faces by
problem, investing the international with ignoring the other.
ontological primacy and treating the national- Perhaps the most poignant example here
domestic level as an analytical residual. The can be found in neo-Weberian comparative
implication of this is of course that both sociological analyses. The irony is that while
sides of the great divide need to develop neo-Weberian analyses claim to ‘bring the
thick analyses of the international/global state back in’ (eg., Evans et al., 1985; Skocpol,
and domestic realms that focus on their co- 1979; Tilly, 1990), their analyses in effect
constitutive relations if these disciplines end up by ‘kicking the state back out’
are to progress beyond their present con- (Hobson, 2000: 174–91). This is because
fines. But this is easier said than done, they (unwittingly) deploy a neorealist analy-
and would in any case be resisted by their sis of the international. And as was noted in
respective gatekeepers, largely on the grounds the first section of this chapter, such a con-
that it would supposedly expand almost infi- ception of international structure inevitably
nitely the boundaries of each discipline, renders obsolete a thick conception of the
thereby rendering them so unwieldy that they state that has agency in the international
would be impossible to teach to students. system. In the work of Skocpol and Tilly,
Noteworthy too would be Waltz’s response: ultimately domestic factors are envisaged as
that it would serve merely to replace ‘theory’ intervening variables given that they are sali-
with ‘thick description’. As he put it, ‘Elegant ent only to the extent that they enable or
[ie., parsimonious] definitions of [interna- prevent a state from conforming to the pri-
tional political] structure enable one to fash- mary logic of international anarchy/geopo-
ion an explanatory system having only a few litical competition. Put simply, in bringing
variables. If we add more variables, the the international geopolitical structure back
explanatory system becomes more compli- in, they unwittingly kick the state back out as
cated … [such that] theoretical acuity gives an independent variable. But the deepest
way to rich and dense description’ (Waltz, irony here is that in deploying a neorealist
1986: 330). Clearly then there is a great deal conception of the international, neo-
of ground-clearing that needs to be under- Weberian historical sociologists end up by
taken before we can begin the task of creat- producing an asociological and ahistorical
ing a dialogical community between IR and analysis (Hobden, 1998; Hobson, 2000:
CP scholars. Chap. 6; Hobson, 2006). Critically, therefore,
And yet for all this a profound irony had these prominent scholars been conver-
emerges here. For one of the significant sant with IR theory these perplexing contra-
points that Waltz made in the well-known dictions could have been avoided. And so it
response to his critics was that: ‘[s]omeone is a particular irony that it is historical soci-
may one day fashion a unified theory of ologists working within IR who have revealed
internal and external politics … [Nevertheless] this problem. Accordingly, neo-Weberians
students of international politics will do well can ignore this extra-disciplinary IR insight
to concentrate on separate theories of internal only at their peril.
and external politics until someone figures Inter-relatedly, when comparative scholars
out a way to unite them’ (Waltz, 1986: 340). think of the international, they usually do so
I suggest that the time has surely come to along implicitly neorealist lines. That is, they
develop such an ‘integrationist theory’, which assume that the international realm is in
effectively links up the domestic and interna- effect a geopolitical realm of competing or
tional realms without reducing or collapsing warring states. But this is merely one con-
one to the other. My aim here is not to begin ception of the international. Constructivist,
this task in the limited space that remains, English School and various liberal approaches

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:12 3/11/2009 3:50:52 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 187

all treat the international realm as imbued IR literature on globalization. And such a
with social properties of one sort or another structuralist ontology leads on to an ahistori-
that can promote cooperation between states. cal and asociological approach in which the
Paradoxically, therefore, it is to IR scholars issue of change becomes obscured. Thus
that we must often look in order to gain a opening IR up to CP/CPE and comparative
proper sociological understanding of the historical sociology can paradoxically yield a
international. Still, the key point is that as the much richer or thicker conception of the
analysis of globalization increasingly embeds international or global systems as socially
itself in many of the disciplines across the complex and immanent orders of social
social sciences, so comparative scholars can change. In short, therefore, opening up both
ignore IR theory only at their peril. disciplines to mutual dialogue is vital to pro-
But by the same token, the systemic focus moting the study and research of CP/CPE/CS
of IR precludes various factors that could and IR, the success of which will be meas-
enable a much richer analysis of the interna- ured by the extent to which the ‘great disci-
tional or global realms. Thus in ignoring plinary divide’ becomes reconstructed as a
state-society and social relations so the whole two-way permeable boundary.
issue of social agency is often lost.
Accordingly, this promotes a structuralist or
elitist, top-down conception of the world,
which provides no space or voice for more REFERENCES
everyday actors especially, though not exclu-
sively, at the sub-national level, whether Bull, H. (1977) The anarchical society. London:
these be class-based, gender-based or ethnic- Macmillan.
based (see Hobson and Seabrooke, 2007). Burchill, S. (1996) ‘Realism and neorealism’, in
One of the costs here is that we end up with S. Burchill and A. Linklater (eds), Theories of
a highly limited, if not parochial, Eurocentric international relations. London: Macmillan.
conception of the international system which Buzan, B. and Little, R. (2000) International
is shaped and governed by American hegem- systems in world history. Oxford: Oxford
ony, Western-based international institutions, University Press.
or globalization as Western capitalism writ Campbell, D. (1992) Writing security.
large. And the paradox here is that this Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Carr, E.H. (1939) The twenty years’ crisis
Eurocentric trap is one that many critical
1919–1939. London: Macmillan.
theories of IR fall into as much as do the Carr, E.H. (1945) Nationalism and after.
more mainstream approaches (Hobson, London: Macmillan.
2007). Of course, this is not to say that CP/ Carr, E.H. (1951) The new society. London:
CS necessarily escapes such a trap. But it is Macmillan.
to say that the typical top-down approaches Clark, I. (1999) Globalization and international
found in IR can be challenged by more com- relations theory. Oxford: Oxford University
paratively sensitive analyses that are able to Press.
point to bottom-up social forces that Crawford, R.A. and Jarvis, D.S.L. (eds) (2001)
are expressive of non-elite interests and International relations – still an American
identities in both the West and the East social science? NY: SUNY Press.
Dunne, T.J. (1998) Inventing international soci-
(Hobson, 2004).
ety. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
More generally, though, without a thick Evans, P.B., Reuschemeyer, D. and Skocpol, T.
conception of state-society and social rela- (eds.) (1985) Bringing the state back in.
tions, IR remains caught within a systemic Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
international/global reductionist ontology Finnemore, M. (1996) National interests in
that often banishes the possibility of social international society. Ithaca: Cornell
politics, as is apparent within so much of the University Press.

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:13 3/11/2009 3:50:52 PM


188 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Garrett, G. (1998) Partisan politics in the global Hoffmann, S. (1977) ‘An American social sci-
economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University ence: international relations’, Daedalus, 106
Press. (3): 41–60.
Gerschenkron, A. (1962) Economic backward- Howe, P. (1994) ‘The utopian theory of E.H.
ness in historical perspective. Cambridge, Carr’, Review of International Studies, 20 (3):
MA: Harvard University Press. 277–97.
Gourevitch, P.A. (1978) ‘The second image Katzenstein, P.J. (1996) Cultural norms and
reversed: the international sources of domes- national security. Ithaca: Cornell University
tic politics’, International Organization, 32 Press.
(4): 281–313. Keohane, R.O. (1984) After hegemony.
Gourevitch, P.A. (1986) Politics in hard times. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Keohane, R.O. and Milner, H. (eds.) (1996)
Griffiths, M. (1992) Realism, idealism and inter- Internationalization and domestic politics.
national relations. London: Routledge. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hall, R.B. (1999) National collective identity. Keohane, R.O. and Nye, J.S. (1977) Power and
New York: Columbia University Press. interdependence. Boston: Little, Brown.
Hobden, S. (1998) International relations and Mann, M. (1993) The sources of social power
historical sociology. London: Routledge. (Vol. 2) Cambridge: Cambridge University
Hobson, J.M. (1997) The wealth of Press.
states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Morgenthau, H. (1948/1978) Politics among
Press. nations. New York: Alfred Knopf.
Hobson, J.M. (2000) The state and interna- Reus-Smit, C. (1999) The moral purpose of the
tional relations. Cambridge: Cambridge state. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
University Press. Risse-Kappen, T. (ed.) (1995) Bringing transna-
Hobson, J.M. (2002) ‘What’s at stake in tional relations back in. Cambridge:
bringing historical sociology back into interna- Cambridge University Press.
tional relations? Transcending ‘chronofetish- Rosenberg, J. (1994) The empire of civil society.
ism’ and ‘tempocentrism’ in international London: Verso.
relations’, in S. Hobden and J.M. Hobson Ruggie, J.G. (1986) ‘Continuity and transfor-
(eds), Historical sociology of international mation in the world polity: Toward a neore-
relations. Cambridge: Cambridge University alist synthesis’, in R.O. Keohane (ed.),
Press, pp. 3–41. Neorealism and its critics. New York:
Hobson, J.M. (2004) The eastern origins of west- Columbia University Press, pp. 131–57.
ern civilisation. Cambridge: Cambridge Schmidt, B.C. (1998) The political discourse of
University Press. anarchy. New York: SUNY Press.
Hobson, J. M. (2006) ‘Mann, the state and war’, Seabrooke, L. (2006) The social sources of
in J.A. Hall and R. Schroeder (eds), An anat- financial power. Ithaca: Cornell University
omy of power. Cambridge: Cambridge Press.
University Press, pp. 150–66. Skocpol, T. (1979) States and social revolu-
Hobson, J.M. (2007) ‘Is critical theory always tions. Cambridge: Cambridge University
for the white west and for western imperial- Press.
ism? Beyond Westphalian, towards a Smith, S. (2000) ‘The discipline of international
post-racist, critical international relations’, relations: Still an American social science?’,
Review of International Studies, 33 (SI): British Journal of Politics and International
91–116. Relations, 2 (3): 374–402.
Hobson, J.M. and Seabrooke, L. (eds) Sørenson, G. (2001) Changes in statehood.
(2007) Everyday politics of the world econ- Basingstoke: Macmillan.
omy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Tilly, C. (1990) Coercion, capital and European
Press. states, AD 990–1990. Oxford: Blackwell.

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:14 3/11/2009 3:50:52 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 189

Waltz, K.N. (1959) Man, the state, and war. Weiss, L. (1998) The myth of the powerless
New York: Columbia University Press. state. Cambridge: Polity.
Waltz, K.N. (1967) Foreign policy and demo- Weiss, L. (ed.) (2003) States in the global
cratic politics. Boston: Little, Brown. economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Waltz, K.N. (1979) Theory of international Press.
politics. New York: McGraw Hill. Wendt, A. (1999) Social theory of international
Waltz, K.N. (1986) ‘Reflections on Theory politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University
of international politics: A response to my Press.
critics’, in R.O. Keohane (ed.), Neorealism Wheeler, N.J. (2000) Saving strangers. Oxford:
and its critics. New York: Columbia University Oxford University Press.
Press, pp. 322–45.

9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:15 3/11/2009 3:50:52 PM


9781412919760_Chap10.indd Sec1:16 3/11/2009 3:50:52 PM
PART II

Classic Issues in
Comparative Politics

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:02:04 PM


9781412919760_Chap11.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:02:04 PM
11
Post-Industrial Democracies:
Political Economy and
Democratic Partisan
Competition
Herbert Kitschelt

INTRODUCTION decision-making between national and sub-


national governments. Second, a huge number
There is no other region of the world that has of studies have examined political participa-
attracted as much systematic theory-guided tion and electoral behavior, as well as the
comparative research in political science as strategic conduct of organized intermediaries
today’s set of affluent, post-industrial, politi- that bring about collective action and bundle
cally, and economically stable democracies political preferences – social movements,
(abbreviated: PI-democracies). Except Japan, interest associations and political parties (cf.
all of them are Western European or deriva- Kitschelt and Rehm, 2007). Third, compara-
tively European as British settler democra- tive politics has tried to account for the out-
cies. Internationally, after World War II, this puts and outcomes of the political process,
group of countries, crystallized around a net- that is, the authoritative allocation of benefits
work of military alliances with the United and costs through ‘policies’ and the conse-
States as its hub, was the main antagonist of quences of such policies for citizens’ quality
the communist bloc. of life. This research most prominently fea-
Comparative political science has pursued tures the field of ‘comparative political econ-
primarily four broad subjects of research with omy’ that has devoted itself to two major
regard to PI-democracies. First, a great deal of questions: How do democratic political insti-
attention has been devoted to their democratic tutions and processes affect the macro-
institutions, especially their electoral systems, economic performance of democratic polities
the relationship between legislative represen- (growth, unemployment, inflation, balance
tation and executive power, and the centrali- of accounts)? And to what extent do democra-
zation, or decentralization of authoritative cies protect citizens from the risks that wage

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:02:04 PM


194 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

earners run in the capitalist market place and (semi-)authoritarian regimes elsewhere
(unemployment, illness, old age) and correct around the globe. PI-democracies are a highly
the spontaneous market-based in-equality of restricted set of the worlds’ polities sharing
incomes through public policy (taxes, trans- social, economic, political and cultural traits
fers, public services)? Fourth, with the increas- that vary across the full global set of coun-
ing policy integration of the European Union tries. As a consequence, causal mechanisms
particularly since the Single European Act of identified to account for political-economic
1986, the Maastricht Treaty of 1992, the intro- variance among PI-democracies may be irrel-
duction of the Euro, and the expansion of the evant for an account of political-economic
EU to 27 members, research has focused on variance between such democracies and all
the multi-level governance of democratic poli- the rest of non-PI-democracies and authori-
ties that cede some decision-making authority, tarian regimes. The second section turns to
particularly in the realm of market-regulatory the explanation of macro-economic policy-
policies (competition, product standards, non- making among PI-democracies. My focus is
discrimination, environmental and safety reg- on two closely intertwined performance indi-
ulations, etc.), to the supra-national, regional cators, economic growth and employment,
level. with some glances at inflation. In the third
As a result of research on democratic insti- section, I give an overview of theories of the
tutions, processes of interest mobilization, and welfare state and how they account for differ-
policy formation, comparativists have tried to ent patterns, changes, and new challenges of
identify coherent ‘types’ of PI-democracies, social policy in PI-democracies.
each characterized by distinct institutions,
processes and policy results. The best-known
proposal is that of Arend Lijphart (1999)
who distinguishes majoritarian and consen- THE GROUP OF POST-INDUSTRIAL
sual democracies (see also Powell, 2000). DEMOCRACIES
This distinction empirically overlaps to a large
extent with the political-economic distinction All current PI-democracies embarked on
between ‘liberal market economies’ (LME) the transition from agrarian to capitalist indus-
and ‘coordinated market economies’ (CME) trial market economies in the nineteenth cen-
proposed by David Soskice (1999). Beyond tury. With some major exceptions (Austria,
the comparative-static analysis of polity types, Germany, Italy, Japan, and, for very different
scholars have also devoted a great deal of reasons, colonial Ireland), in the late nine-
research to the dynamic change of such types teenth century these countries were more or
of democratic polities and political economies less inclusive competitive oligarchies with
over time. How do polities respond to the restricted suffrage (property/ethnic restric-
‘shocks’ of technological innovation, demo- tions and/or no women’s suffrage until 1918
graphic change, as well as increasing incorpo- and 1945, respectively), but open and intensely
ration of national polities in the global competitive contestation of legislative and
economic and political-military system? executive office, a fairly firm entrenchment of
In this overview I focus on the political civic and political rights, and a robust entrench-
economics of PI-democracies and bring in ment of the rule of law. In the four ‘axis
political institutions, democratic processes of powers’ Austria, Germany, Italy, and Japan,
interest articulation and aggregation, and the onset of industrialization was supported by
multi-level governance only in as much as an authoritarian state, although also here capi-
they affect political economic arrangements talist economies resulted, albeit of a non-
and outcomes in PI-democracies. In the first competitive, trust- and association-based kind.
section, I identify basic attributes that set PI This model was partially broken up only in the
democracies apart from non-PI democracies aftermath of World War II, once totalitarian

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:02:04 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 195

rulers in these countries were defeated. structure and institutions the configuration of
Nevertheless, the types of capitalism prevail- which is unique to PI-democracies:
ing in these four countries continued to diverge
from market liberal arrangements. l They all have agricultural employment below
5 per cent of the labor force and agricultural value
In the post-World War II reconstruction
added to GDP of less than 3 per cent. This applies
era, all of today’s PI-democracies entered even to important agricultural exporters such as
what Seymour Martin Lipset (1961) termed Australia, the Netherlands, or the United States.
the ‘democratic class compromise.’ They l More than 65 per cent of all gainfully employed
built mixed economies that pacified the class are in services, with the major growth areas
struggle and endowed governments with being social services (particularly health and edu-
considerable leverage in manipulating the cation), financial services and private personal
market economies for a variety of short-term services, at the expense of conventional clerical
and long-term political objectives (win elec- and sales-distributive services that are progres-
tions by demonstrating economic compe- sively displaced by machinery and information
tence, entrench partisan support of electoral technology.
l The proportion of jobs in the occupational struc-
constituencies by providing them with club
ture that require sophisticated skills and long-
goods through policy legislation, etc.). The term training has increased dramatically, as
emergence of the ‘mixed’ economy with simple task structures are taken over by compu-
durable democracy coincided with an un- terized machinery. The bulk of the entire wealth
precedented period of prolonged econo- stock of PI-democracies is therefore in human
mic growth between 1949 and 1973 when capital, while only small amounts are in fixed
the first world oil crisis disrupted econo- capital investments, let alone land and natural
mic stability. Since that time, capitalist resources that dominate the picture in poorer
PI-democracies have experienced less spec- non-PI-polities (cf. World Bank, 2005).
tacular, but still quite respectable, though l PI democracies are by far the greatest investors
more volatile, economic growth rates when in tertiary higher education (between 1 and 3 per
cent of GDP) and in research and development
measured by standards of long-term histori-
(1.0–4.6 per cent of GDP).
cal and global averages for the region. They
l All of the PI-countries are affluent. They have
achieved about 2 per cent/per capita growth a purchasing power parity (PPP) corrected per
in the 1980s, slightly less in the 1990s and capita gross national income (GNI)1 of at least
again a touch less since 2000. $ 25,000 in 2005.
While PI-democracies economically fared l Average gross capital formation in PI-democracies
worse after 1973 than in previous decades, tends to be somewhat lower than in the rest of
the variance and volatility of their perform- the world, particularly lower than in South and
ance pales compared to that of the less afflu- Southeast Asia. The average is in the vicinity of
ent polities, whether democratic or not. Some 20 per cent of GDP, with lows near 16 per cent in
of them, particularly in South and South-east the United States (followed by Britain with 17.0
per cent and Germany with 17.2 per cent) and
Asia, performed spectacularly and are on
highs at 25 per cent (Australia, followed by Japan
their way to join the tier of affluent countries at 24 per cent) in 2005, compared to greater
in the first quarter of the twenty-first century. global variance, reaching from 39 per cent in
Others, particularly in Sub-Saharan Africa China and 30 per cent in India to only 10 per cent
and Latin America, have done badly and in Côte d’Ivoire and 12 per cent in Bosnia.
delivered negative or just marginal economic
growth over the past thirty years. By global All PI-democracies are currently caught
standards, growth rates in PI-democracies up in a demographic transition in which life
have been neither exceptionally high nor expectancy is gradually rising while fertility
exceptionally low, and the same applies to rate has fallen below replacement (albeit to a
inflation and unemployment. Among other varying extent, see below). Because of the
things, this may be due to the economic rapid rise in the number of retirees, the share

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:02:04 PM


196 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

of the working age population is falling, even and therefore articulate programmatic alter-
though the proportion of children is falling natives within a more or less narrow range.
as well. Parties disperse over one, two or at most
In terms of basic political-economic insti- three dimensions of programmatic politics
tutions, PI-democracies offer relatively cheap (cf. Benoit and Laver, 2007; Kitschelt, 1994;
and expedient facilities to enforce contracts, Kriesi et al., 2006; Warwick, 2002), and the
protect investors’ rights, open or close a busi- major parties may line up on a left-right
ness and register property, and conduct busi- super dimension that combines positions on
ness across national borders (cf. World Bank, the policy dimensions in predictable fashion.
2006a). They provide an exceptional quality Parties disagree over the extent to which gov-
of the rule of law, governmental effective- ernments regulate the economy and redistrib-
ness, and impartial administration with little ute resources in favor of the worse off
propensity to corruption (World Bank Global (‘redistribution’). A second dimension con-
Governance Indicators, 2004). They top the cerns the extent to which citizens and parties
ranks of economic (market) freedom and endorse a socio-culturally libertarian concep-
global competitiveness in business leaders’ tion of individual freedom to choose life
perceptions (World Economic Forum, 2006). styles and participate in collective decision
Also economic policy-making has features making or a more authoritarian view of
that set PI-democracies apart from all other immutable collectively binding compliance
countries. PI-countries have budget and with norms and cultural standards as well as
external account balances that typically vary deference to higher political authorities. This
between moderate deficits and balanced dimension is also often associated with posi-
budget, but rarely approach public debts trig- tions on immigration and multiculturalism in
gering fiscal crisis (yet consider Belgium and society, with the more authoritarian view
Italy in the 1980s and 1990s and Japan since rejecting immigrants and insisting on cul-
2000). Nevertheless, social policy expendi- tural norms embraced by the indigenous
ture, and public expenditure more generally, population. Sometimes a third separate
are very high by global standards (35–55 per dimension concerns ecology/environmental
cent of GDP), based on an exceptional capac- protection and societal decentralization.
ity to tax the domestic economies. In practice, among the larger parties, and at
Finally, in terms of politics, PI-democracies least at the elite level of political leaders who
are looking back on political regime stability communicate their parties’ issue profile to the
for at least 30 years. They have institutional- mass media, there is a fairly high, though not
ized full civic and political freedoms and have perfect, association between positions taken
developed dense associational networks and a on these dimensions. The ‘left’ tends to be in
diverse landscape of mass media. Political favor of redistribution, libertarian conceptions
parties mostly compete on broad policy of life style, immigration and multicultural-
appeals rather than on narrow geographically ism, as well as priority for ecology and soci-
targeted benefits to specific individuals and etal decentralization. The ‘right’ calls for
groups contingent upon their vote preference acceptance of market allocation and market-
(‘clientelism’). Nevertheless, clientelistic poli- based inequality in the economic sphere,
tics eroded in several countries only after endorses more authoritarian views of collec-
momentous political-economic difficulties in tive culture and national collective identity,
the public or publically regulated and subsi- and subordinates ecological protection to eco-
dized sectors in the 1990s (cf. Kitschelt, nomic performance. Party systems then run
2007a). from a ‘new’ left crystallized around left-
Just about all electorally attractive parties socialist and ecology parties, via social demo-
support liberal democracy and basic economic crats as center-left, Christian/confessional
institutions of capitalist market economies parties as center-right, liberal parties with

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:02:04 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 197

distinct market liberal, yet often also mildly declined in most PI-democracies and citizens
socio-culturally liberal positions to radical have in greater numbers joined interest groups
right parties that emphasize exclusionary and and became mobilized around social move-
authoritarian socio-cultural conceptions, yet ments that keep parties at arms-length. A dif-
tacitly or explicitly also support a range of ferentiation of vehicles of political preference
market liberal views on economic policy.2 mobilization over parties, interest groups and
In PI-democracies, political conflict, and social movements has taken place (cf.
competition certainly cannot be reduced to Kitschelt, 2003).
economic-distributive conflict. Yet at the same As empirical referents for the cohort of
time, prophecies that economic conflict would PI-democracies, consider Table 11.1, listing
wither away in favor of controversies over all countries on earth with a per capita
quality of life (cf. Inglehart, 1997) have been income of more than US $10,000 in purchas-
empirically disproved. The critical issue is to ing power parity (PPP) in 2005, as listed in
illuminate how economic and socio-political the World Bank’s 2007 development report.3
governance issues are intertwined in party They are ranked from 1 through 45, with no
appeals and popular preference distributions ranks assigned to a couple of very small
and underlying economic market positions of countries (Iceland, Luxembourg) and two
the actors. In post-industrial society the elec- entrepôt cities that are difficult to compare to
toral constituency with the on average most large territorial countries (Hong Kong and
‘leftist’ policy and partisan preferences, both Singapore).4 Membership in the PI-democracy
in the economic-distributive as well as the cohort is dependent on:
socio-cultural sense, are no longer blue collar
manual workers, regardless of skill level, but 1. per capita gross national income (> $25,000 in
the category of socio-cultural professionals 2005 at purchasing power parity);
2. share of employment in services above 65 per
employed by not-for-profit social service
cent, as opposed to extractive industries (agricul-
organizations and symbol producing culture ture, mining) and manufacturing; and
and media companies (Kitschelt and Rehm, 3. a persistence of stable democracy for at least
2005, 2006). 30 years before 2005 (i.e., since 1975).
Overall, in PI-democracies there is a broad
consensus around the merits of democracy in The first column in the table shows countries
principle, but at the same time citizens voice a that meet all three criteria. Those in italic are
generally high, though variable, level of mis- countries that are usually included in cross-
trust in existing democratic institutions and national macro-economic studies of contem-
politicians who govern them. It is often people porary capitalist democracies. Among
inclined to be politically active and fully sup- countries that meet at least two PI-criteria,
portive of democracy in principle who embrace Norway and Ireland, the most recent arrival
the most critical positions vis-à-vis the empir- in the tier of the most affluent polities, most
ical performance of democracy in their own clearly belong to the PI group. The same can
country (Dalton, 2004). This mistrust in par- be said also for New Zealand, a British settler
ties and politicians goes together with a pro- democracy with very old political institu-
pensity to seek participatory involvement tions. More arguably, Greece and Portugal,
outside parties in social movements and inter- both countries that had authoritarian rulers
est groups independent of partisan divides. In until 1974, may be included in the group of
the first half of the twentieth century powerful PI-democracies. In the most inclusive deline-
political parties were often closely aligned ation of PI-democracies, then, we would
with subordinated interest groups and move- find 22 countries in this group, not counting
ment organizations and encapsulated them Iceland and Luxembourg because of size.
through broad membership overlap. Since the All other countries in Table 11.1 fail to meet
1960s and 1970s, mass party membership has at least two criteria to count as PI-democracies.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:02:04 PM


198 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Table 11.1 Post-industrial democracies and the next tier of countries


Country meets all Country meets two Country meets one Country meets none Excluded polities
three criteria* criteria* criterion* of the criteria* (entrepots, small
countries)
1. United States (41.9 K; 2. Norway (40.5 K; 28. Hungary (16.9 K; 20. United Arab Luxembourg (65.4
77% S) 59% S) 65% S) Emirates (24.1 K; K; n.d.)
3. Switzerland (37.1 K; 4. Ireland (34.7 K; 29. Slovakia ( 15.8 K; n.d.) Iceland (34.7 K;
n.d. S) 56% S) 67% S) 21. Kuwait (24.0 K; n.d.)
5. Denmark (33.6 K; 22. Greece (23.6 K; 30. Estonia (15.4 K; 47% S) Hong Kong
73% S) 70% S) n.d.) 24. Slovenia (22.2 K; (34.7K; 90% S)
6. Austria (33.1 K; 23. New Zealand 35. Latvia (13.5 K; 62% S) Singapore (29.7 K;
67% S) (23.1 K; n.d. S) 73% S) 25. Rep. Korea (21.9 K; 66% S)
7. United Kingdom 27. Portugal 37. Trinidad and 55% S) Cyprus (22.2 K;
(32.7 K; 73% S) (19.7 K; 70%) Tobago (13.2 K; 26. Czech Rep. (20.1 K; n.d. S)
8. Belgium (32.6 K; n.d.) 58% S) Malta (19.0 K;
73% S) 39. Mauritius (12.4 K; 31. Saudi Arabia n.d. S)
9. Netherlands (32.5 K; n.d.) (14.7 K; 37% S)
72% S) 40. South Africa 32. Oman (14.7 K;
10. Canada (32.2 K; n.d.) (12.1 K; 66% S) 42% S)
11. Sweden (31.4 K; 43. Botswana 33. Lithuania (14.3 K;
69% S) (10.3 K; n.d.) 63% S)
12. Japan (31.4 K; 68% S) 45. Mexico (10.0 K; 34. Argentina (13.9 K;
13. Finland (31.2 K; 70% S) 54% S)
66% S) 36. Poland (13.5 K;
14. Australia (30.6 K; 65% S)
71% S) 38. Croatia (12.8 K;
15. France (30.5 K; 76%) 64%)
16. Germany (29.3 K; 41. Chile (11.5 K;
70% S) 48% S)
17. Italy (28.8 K; 70% S) 42. Russia (10.6 K;
18. Spain (25.9 K; 67% S) 56% S)
19. Israel (25.3 K; n.d.) 44. Malaysia (10.3 K;
40% S)
*Criteria: (1) GNI per capita > $25 K at PPP in 2005; (2) service sector >65% value added in GDP; (3) democracy older
than 30 years; only countries with more than one million inhabitants scored (except Luxembourg, Iceland).

All except the entrepôt city states of Hong among closely clustered observations. In the
Kong and Singapore tend to be too poor to early twenty-first century there is, indeed, a
qualify. Moreover, most, but not all of them, real gulf in affluence and institutions between
have service sectors falling below 65 per cent a top tier of more than 20 democracies and
of employment (exceptions are Slovakia, the rest of the world in both economic and
Latvia, South Africa and Mexico). Most coun- political-democratic regards. This gulf would
tries between US $10,000 and US $25,000 per come into even starker relief, were we to
capita GNI do not even meet a single criterion present a broader set of indicators including
to qualify them as PI-democracies. On average, questions of governance and rule of law or of
the 23 countries in that income class have a per global economic competitiveness. In the two
capita GNP of not even one half of the average major sections of this article, however, I will
prevailing in the lead group of 22 PI-democracies focus on the dynamics of macro-economic
(US $31,000/per capita at PPP in 2005 in the policy-making and performance, as well as
lead group compared to US $15,300) in the the development of welfare states, both policy
trailing group. areas in which PI-democracies created unique
The delineation of the set of PI-democracies and globally unparalleled institutions and
is thus not akin to drawing an arbitrary line policies.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:02:04 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 199

MACRO-POLITICAL ECONOMY: financial institutions to counteract volatility in


EXPLAINING ECONOMIC market behavior. Whereas much of the schol-
PERFORMANCE arship following Shonfield over the next
twenty years focused on industrial relations,
The political-economic analysis of PI- Shonfield had the foresight to emphasize the
capitalism may trace back its origins to corporate governance and organization of pri-
Marxist and non-Marxist theorists of ‘organ- vate business itself as a component of capital-
ized capitalism’ in the interwar period, ist economies that varies systematically across
advancing the idea that the self-organization national political contexts.
of capital in trusts and industrial groups, in After Shonfield, macro-political economy
combination with state intervention, would of economic performance in the 1970s focused
create productive economic systems that on employment and inflation exploring two
counterbalance the tendency of market econ- major lines of reasoning, one centered on
omies to evolve in cycles with violent up and interest group mobilization and the other on
downswings. The boldest and simultaneously party governance. With regard to the former,
most pessimistic statement of this perspec- scholars established a relationship between
tive was probably Schumpeter’s (1950) the organization of economic interest groups
Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. and economic performance. Schmitter’s
Whereas theorists of organized capitalism (1974; 1981) distinction between pluralist and
focused on common changes in the interac- corporatist interest intermediation was most
tion between markets and politics, contem- influential. Whereas in pluralism multiple
porary political economy really began to take competing associations represent the same
off with a work that focused on the institu- functional interests, in corporatism each eco-
tional and procedural differences within the nomic interest is represented by a single group
group of affluent capitalist democracies. and officially partakes in authoritative deci-
The fountain of insight at the origin of the sion-making under the leadership of a single
research field is without doubt Andrew monopoly association. Corporatism facilitates
Shonfield’s Modern Capitalism (1965). Here, the achievement of inter-elite consensus
a business economist for the center-left among other reasons because the associational
Guardian tried to account for the astounding leaders can quell internal protest by radical
success of post-World War II capitalism when dissenters, respectively exclude them from the
compared to the interwar period, particularly organization without having to fear that such
the achievement of full employment and sus- challengers could form their own alternative
tained, accelerated technological innovation associations. Over the decades, scholars have
(Shonfield, 1965: 63). He argues that there are developed multiple measures of corporatism
common trends in all OECD countries toward (cf. Kenworthy, 2001; Siaroff, 1999). In all of
mixed economies involving some element of them, the critical ingredients are (1) centrali-
political-organizational ‘planning’ that cor- zation of associational representation and
rects and displaces spontaneous market con- industrial bargaining above the firm level, all
tracting. The main point, however, is that the way up to the national level; and (2)
different countries achieve this common result monopoly representation of functional inter-
in very different, yet causally equivalent ests by a single associational entity. Whereas
ways. What the French achieved by indica- this conceptualization homes in on structural
tive planning through allocation of capital properties of political mobilization, some have
and industrial reorganization of enterprises advocated a more behavioral conception of
by governments, the Americans and British corporatism, placing (3) a consensus-oriented
did through macro-economic fiscal policies, predisposition of the bargaining parties repre-
whereas the Germans resorted to the self- senting different functional interests at the
organization of industrial businesses and center of analysis.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


200 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

In the late 1970s and 1980s, a wealth of incentives of vote- and office-seeking politi-
studies showed that corporatist political cians to manipulate the economy through
economies have enjoyed particular advan- political resource allocation in order to advance
tages. Hibbs (1976, 1977) found that central- their electoral objectives. In the short-run, par-
ized labor unions engage in fewer strikes, as ties incumbent in executive office may boost
business and labor can anticipate and evade fiscal expenditure and run deficits before elec-
the costs of industrial action. Cameron (1978; tions to boost earnings power and dispose
1984) shows that it is particularly trade-open, voters favorably to the governing party, as the
smaller democratic polities where corporatist costs of fiscal profligacy translate into higher
interest intermediation prevails and improves inflation only after the elections (cf. Alt and
economic performance. In such polities, both Crystal, 1983: Chapter 5; Nordhaus, 1975;
inflation and unemployment tend to be lower Tufte, 1978). As voters anticipate political busi-
than elsewhere, thus defying the Keynesian ness cycles, however, parties are no longer
idea of an inflation/unemployment trade-off. capable of partisan cycles before elections, but
In a similar vein, for small European demo- are rather likely to deliver partisan-biased fiscal
cracies Katzenstein (1985) analyzed the and monetary policies, with left incumbents
origins and virtues of different modes of cor- boosting spending, after electoral victories (cf.
poratism that boosted the countries’ capacity Alesina and Rosenthal, 1995). Nevertheless,
to adapt to new economic challenges. Among politicians may not think of voters as particu-
economists speaking to political science, the larly far-sighted and therefore engage in both
most influential political economy contribu- pre- and post-election budget cycles (Franzese,
tion was probably Olson’s (1982) thesis that 2002). The critique of the original business
a proliferation of special interest groups pro- cycle literature is consistent with partisan
motes rent-seeking and reduces economic models of long-run government policy that
growth, as the provision of group advantages assert the ideological impact of left (social
leads to an undersupply of collective goods, democratic) and right (conservative, market-
unless this proliferation is counteracted by liberal) governments on the size of the public
the authority of encompassing interest organ- sector and the propensity of different govern-
izations (‘corporatism’) that internalize the ments to prioritize fights against inflation or
externalities of special group advantages and unemployment (cf. Hibbs, 1977, 1987).
prioritize collective goods provision. In the When it comes to fiscal deficits that boost
more technical economics literature on indus- public debts and ultimately inflation, how-
trial relations and wage bargaining, this argu- ever, a rather different partisan logic may
ment was further elaborated in an influential prevail. Multi-party coalition governments
article by Calmfors and Driffill (1988). deliver more deficits, as each coalition part-
Economic outcomes are good (low inflation, ner is preoccupied with negotiating tangible
low nominal wage increases) where interest advantages for its own constituency, thus
groups are too weak to affect market pricing discounting the externalities detrimental
or where business and unions are organized effects of losing the collective externalities of
in a highly centralized fashion. Economic large budget deficits out of sight (cf. Alesina
outcomes are worse, where intermediate and Perotti, 1995; qualified also Franzese,
organizational capacity and centralization of 2002: chapter 3). No single coalition partner
unions makes them pursue advantages in can incorporate these externalities in its bar-
individual firms or industries that accelerate gaining strategy and not pay an electoral
inflation. penalty. Recent research has shown that
Parallel to the interest group literature, a budget restraint is delivered by powerful
second line of reasoning in comparative politi- finance ministers in single-party or small-N
cal economy focused on party competition and coalition governments or by ex-ante com-
partisan governance of the economy. Key is the pacts among the coalition partners in large-N

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 201

coalition governments where no party is classical low profitability crisis. A fiscal


willing to cede too much authority to macroeconomic stimulus was bound to make
the finance minister (Hallerberg, 2004; things only worse (Scharpf, 1991: 36).
Hallerberg et al., 2009). Large-N coalitions Scharpf then draws on observations that an
without compacts, however, are likely to independent central bank, put in charge of
generate large deficits and inflation. The monetary stability and not controlled by par-
original claim, however, that left-wing parti- tisan government, may operate as a check on
san governments or greater ideological diver- the actions of governments and industrial
sity within governing coalitions produce relations partners. Such central banks are
higher deficits, has been by and large set wont to raise real interest rates, if govern-
aside (cf. Franzese, 2002: chapter 3; ments and industrial relations partners engage
Hallerberg et al., 2009).5 in ‘irresponsible’ wage increases. Knowing
Since the mid-1980s, a series of papers by the Central Bank’s independence and pro-
Lange and Garrett (1985) and the ensuing pensity to punish inflationary policies, politi-
research (see especially Alvarez et al., 1991 cal actors opt for fiscal and wage restraint in
and Garrett, 1998) then attempted to combine anticipation of monetary sanctions. Thus,
the logics of interest group bargaining with social democratic governments can count on
that of partisan governance by highlighting union cooperation not only because of organ-
the interdependence of interest group (union) izational and ideological links between labor
strategies of wage bargaining and government movements and left parties, but also because
strategies of fiscal policy-making. This inter- of the anticipation that a strong central bank
action yields two favorable equilibria with is ready to sanction fiscal profligacy in gov-
low inflation, low unemployment, and robust ernment spending and industrial relations
growth. The first is where conservative, bargaining.
market-liberal partisan government imposes A synthesis of theoretical insights in the
fiscal restraint and weak, decentralized labor fields of partisan fiscal policy, industrial rela-
unions are incapable of boosting nominal tions wage bargaining, and central bank-led
wages. The second presupposes strong cen- monetary policy has been most systemati-
tralized labor unions that exercise wage cally achieved in Torben Iversen’s Contested
restraint in exchange for a left government Economic Institutions (1999). As a special
delivering fiscal expansion to maintain or twist of his argument, powerful central banks
restore full employment. Scharpf (1991), are beneficial to price stability and employ-
however, pointed out at least two flaws of ment particularly under conditions of secto-
this model. First, labor unions have no incen- rally centralized industrial relations systems,
tive to cooperate with social democratic yet not in nationally centralized systems. In
governments, as social democrats could not the latter, centralized labor unions can main-
retaliate against unions as a core element of tain all-encompassing unity only by favoring
their electoral support base. Second, under unskilled workers and thus promoting pro-
conditions of a ‘classical’ economic crisis, gressive wage compression. As this strategy
driven by low profits and lack of incentives is detrimental to skill investment, employers
to invest, fiscal government expansion is pay skilled workers more than union wages,
unlikely to stimulate the economy. The fis- thus triggering ‘wage drift’ and inflation.
cally expansionary left government strategy Central banks would fight such drift, but
worked only in the 1970s during a ‘Keynesian’ therewith undercut employment.
crisis, when the oil shock drained consumer Empirically, Iversen finds support for the
purchasing power out of the Western econo- expected pattern, but there are reasons to ques-
mies so that public deficit spending could tion the mechanism driving his theoretical
fill the hole. This strategy no longer worked argument. If diverse labor union groups under
in the 1980s when firms suffered from a the umbrella of a single national bargaining

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


202 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

unit anticipate that a strong central bank will Garrett’s (1998) work for the 1980s and early
react to policies of wage compression and 1990s showed that international embedded-
wage drift with tight monetary policy causing ness of an economy has only a limited influ-
a loss of employment, wouldn’t they seek a ence on the extent to which domestic industrial
different wage compact allowing for more relations systems and governments achieve
wage inequality that would eliminate wage favorable macro-economic outcomes. Yet at
drift? Building on the same empirical observa- the same time, his investigation also shows
tions as Iversen, Franzese (2002: Chapter 4, that institutions (wage bargaining arrange-
especially pp. 243–45) offers a different ration- ments, central bank autonomy) have only
ale and interpretation of the reasons that make preciously limited capacity to affect macro-
central bank autonomy trigger higher unem- economic performance altogether.
ployment in nationally centralized industrial Two more recent extensions of the macro-
relations systems. This result occurs, depend- political economic literature are worth report-
ing on whether private or public sector unions ing in this overview. The first pushes the scope
dominate the national union federation. Where of analysis, the second the depth of causal
private sector unions are dominant, they bar- analysis. Isabela Mares (2004, 2006) has
gain in anticipation of the central bank’s capac- recently observed that the most advanced com-
ity to punish excessive wage deals and wage parative political economy literature, repre-
drift. But where centralized unions are domi- sented by Iversen (1999), explains cross-national
nated by public sector unions whose members’ divergence of unemployment and inflation
employment is not endangered by high real until the 1990s, but cannot account for rising
interest rates and losses of their companies’ unemployment over time in countries such as
international competitiveness, the centraliza- Germany and other corporatist economies,
tion of industrial relations may lead to job where the theory would predict good economic
losses in the private sector, when central banks performance. She argues that governments
punish undisciplined wage bargaining. could induce unions to comply with wage
Franzese not only proposes a sectoral disag- restraint in the past by offering additional social
gregation of union power, but also makes a policy benefits for wage earners. More recently,
move from a closed to an open economy however, increasing shares of social policy
model. A systematic treatment of international benefits have gone to working age permanent
openness constitutes the next stage of macro- labor market outsiders (homemakers, the struc-
political economic analysis.6 Theoretically this turally unemployed, early retirees) so that
brings in complications that prevent the emer- unions have lost the incentive to moderate wage
gence of unique equilibria, induced by institu- demands, with the consequence of rising unem-
tional arrangements only. Instead, assuming ployment. Hence, ‘the process of welfare state
open economies makes possible a whole range maturation gradually undermines the political
of equilibria, contingent upon the nature and exchange among trade unions and governments
extent of international exposure (Soskice, based on wage restraint in exchange for social
2000). If prices are no longer set by local policy expansion.’ (Mares, 2004: 115). While
wages, but also by wages and monetary poli- her model is logically consistent, Mares pro-
cies elsewhere, even under conditions of wage vides only a weak test of her argument, regress-
restraint no full employment equilibrium may ing unemployment on a range of variables that
occur. Lower wages may restore an industry’s includes effective tax rates and transfers to
international competitiveness, but they also labor market outsiders (ages 18–64).
drain domestic demand, domestic wage But both the concept as well as the empirical
bargaining may be unable to restore full measure of outsider benefits are hazardous:
employment, in addition to accelerating domes- When is someone a permanent outsider, rather
tic inflation to world levels. Empirically, than a temporary drop-out of labor markets and

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 203

thus not potentially a member of the union 3. employee skill formation; and
constituency? And how does Mares arrive at 4. technological innovation.
the very high estimate of expenses for labor
market outsiders?7 Moreover, is the large Soskice distinguishes between two clusters
number of labor market outsiders, particularly of institutional conditions that structure the
early retirees, just an exogenous constraint on environment and internal organization of
wage bargaining imposed by the ‘mature’ wel- the firm he terms ‘coordinated market econo-
fare state or is it itself a consequence of certain mies’ (CMEs) and ‘competitive/liberal
wage bargaining systems, where unions insist market economies’ (LMEs).
on sticky wage contracts and high wages, even CMEs have firms with concentrated owner-
at the loss of jobs, so long as unemployment of ship structures (family ownership or few large
older workers can be financially buffered and individual or corporate equity holders, often
concealed by pensioning them off into quite involving cross-ownership and bank owner-
generous early retirement deals? The real expla- ship) with active owners who supervize com-
nation of high unemployment and low job crea- pany management. This is often paired with a
tion, then, would lead entirely out of the realm financing of firms through internal funds and
of wage bargaining. It may have more to do bank debt rather than bonds or dispersed equity
with labor market inflexibility due to high job ownership held by individuals and institutional
protection and short weekly work time in con- investors. The quality of a company and its
tinental Europe, the (semi-)corporatist coun- worth as a trading partner for upstream and
tries that saw low job creation and rising downstream business is assessed based on pri-
unemployment in the 1990s where the conven- vate, ‘insider’ information, generated through
tional political economy literature would have informal networks of communication, rela-
expected continued good performance. Mares tional banking, and important industry-wide
study asks pertinent questions, but her answer associations that provide membership services.
may be only one of several that deserve close Company management is recruited from its
examination. internal labor force cultivated by a prolonged
The second extension of the comparative process of intra-organizational socialization
political economy literature turns away from and specific skill upgrading. There is neither a
pure macro-aggregates, such as factors of pro- market for companies (hostile takeovers) nor
duction and economic sectors, and instead a market for managers. This structure of corpo-
considers how firms and employees respond to rate governance and interfirm cooperation
economic incentives. It seeks to provide the nurtures ‘patient’ capital in which principals
actions of market participants as micro-founda- are interested in the long-run performance of
tions to the macro-political economy of corpo- company management, not short-term profit
ratism and monetary authority. Moreover, it objectives. This also makes firms more inclined
seeks to go beyond the focus on wage earners to opt for a system of labor market gover-
as key actors and also examine the decisions nance in which long-term wage contracts pre-
firms make when calibrating their production vail. This increases unions’ receptivity to
function. Based on this bottom-up analysis, wage moderation and to participate in a ‘stake-
it distinguishes different ‘varieties of capital- holder’ structure of corporate governance,
ism’ (VoC) (Hall and Soskice, 2001; Soskice, alongside the company’s equity owners. Long-
1999) that consist of clustered, complementary term capital and wage relations thus feed into
sets of institutions configured around firm-level a consensus-oriented system of industrial
decision-making in at least four realms: relations where wage earners are willing to
embrace wage moderation in exchange for long-
1. corporate governance and financing; term job security and an incremental improve-
2. industrial relations and wage contracting; ment of earnings (e.g., through seniority).

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


204 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Employers, in turn, are willing to negotiate a background in business administration,


with powerful centralized labor unions and accounting, or law. Publicly traded compa-
incorporate employees’ and union representa- nies that report quarterly earnings results are
tives into company management (works coun- not wont to honor long-term wage relations
cils or co-determination). and – with some exceptions – prefer a flexi-
Because in CME capitalism capital is ble labor force the size of which can be
patient and oriented to long-term profit goals, adjusted to demand. Therefore firms and
firms can credibly commit to long-term wage employees invest little in specific skills perti-
contracts. Such contracts reduce work force nent to the business or the industry and
turnover. Durability of employment rela- instead focus on general skills wage earners
tions, in turn, make it attractive to firms to can deploy in different companies. General
invest in the specific human capital of skill formation and high labor mobility result-
employees that improves company perform- ing from short-term contracts are also inhos-
ance, whether at the beginning of employ- pitable to centralized wage bargaining,
ment relations (vocational training) or later employees’ representation on company
through continuous retraining and upgrading boards and job security. Industrial relations
of skills. Corporate governance, skill forma- systems tend to be decentralized, with unions
tion, and labor relations shape a specific style playing only a minor role.
of technological innovation. It is concen- In LMEs, innovation takes place not only
trated in large firms, as venture capital is in large corporations, but to a substantial
difficult to raise in underdeveloped public extent also in small start-up companies
equity capital markets and relationship bank- founded by entrepreneurs emerging from the
ing based on established reputations contin- non-profit sector of universities and research
ues to prevail. Large firms favor incremental laboratories and raising capital initially
product and process innovations that can be through venture capitalist funds and later
brought online with the gradual reskilling through equity offerings. Such research is
and upskilling of their labor force, often after focused on revolutionary product innovations
collaborative research with other firms in the and successful particularly in areas where
same industry. For those firms, it is unimpor- innovation is the main challenge, while pro-
tant in the product cycle of an innovation to duction and after-sale service are easily
be first, but to be a solid second or third that arranged or irrelevant. Examples may be
can produce the new widget more reliably, parts of the IT and the biotechnology indus-
efficiently, with marginally improved fea- tries, but also design, fashion, music and film
tures, and great after-sale service. production and a broad array of financial and
Liberal market economies, by contrast, personal services all of which thrive under
rely on public, transparent capital markets LME arrangements. This stands in contrast
where firms raise equity capital through to manufacturing industries for consumer
stock offerings and bond issues. Ownership durables or investment goods (heavy machin-
structures tend to be dispersed, giving senior ery, turnkey production plants, etc.) whose
management extraordinary control over firms production challenges predispose them to
with large numbers of passive owners, even work better where CME institutions are
though corporate law imposes more ‘anti- prevalent.
director’ rules on companies to respect the PI-polities that feature institutionally dif-
rights and participation of minority owners. ferent varieties of capitalism therefore spe-
There are both markets for firms and senior cialize in industries and companies where
managers who are often recruited from out- their institutions give them a competitive
side the firm. Rather than production engi- advantage. Where global companies organize
neers who worked their way into management complex production chains, they place bits
(in CMEs), corporate leaders in LMEs have and pieces in polities that have comparative

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 205

institutional advantages for coping with the origin of many industrial innovations? And
specific production challenge posed by that are hierarchical arrangements not sometimes
link in the chain. The co-existence of differ- prominent enough to shape a polity’s capital-
ent varieties of CME and LME capitalism, ist economy (its ‘variety’ of capitalism) or at
therefore, is compatible with globalization of least to introduce critical heterogeneities in
production, as long as there are multiple its variety that need to be conceptually
institutional equilibria to achieve compara- accommodated? One might think of the role
tive advantage. Worst off are countries that of state funded research and development in
cannot take advantage of the complementari- the LME political economy of the United
ties between different institutional compo- States with its wide array of public or non-
nents in each type, such as corporate profit funding agencies for innovation in bio-
governance, industrial relations, human skill and information technologies, aerospace and
formation and technological innovation. Such energy production, often linked to the military-
‘incoherent’ arrangements thus are expected industrial complex. Also ‘mixed’ varieties of
to translate into weak macro-economic per- capitalism such as France and to a lesser
formance. Hall and Gingerich (2004) find in extent Italy have had powerful cores of state-
a cross-national study of economic growth owned or state–nurtured companies at the
that indeed ‘pure’ incarnations of varieties of heart of political-economic development
capitalism deliver better economic growth. strategies (consider Airbus). LME and CME
The varieties of capitalism approach con- arrangements do not exhaust the range of
stitutes a definite advance over macro- institutional forms deployed to promote eco-
economic political economy models that do nomic production and growth.
not flesh out the micro-economic relations Second, in theoretical-explanatory terms,
between employers and wage earners or the the varieties of capitalism literature has a
relations among firms and between firms and functionalist ring. If complementarities are
financial markets. But there are also formida- arrangements in which the benefits obtained
ble conceptual, theoretical and empirical from each component are improved by the
challenges this intellectual framework is presence of the other components, are these
beginning to face. interfaces brought about by intentional
In conceptual terms, are two varieties of design, by evolutionary selection, or by unin-
capitalism enough? There are the usual com- tended actions that accidentally created high
plaints that the postulate of national patterns yield production functions in specific histori-
hides variance at the level of sectors or firms cal circumstances only? The origins of dif-
(Allen, 2004), but even if we admit that the ferent capitalisms appear to have to do a
country (polity) level of institutions influ- great deal with the extent to which European
ences trajectories of economic growth and polities and their colonial settler spinoffs
performance (employment, inflation), there dismantled guilds in the early nineteenth
may be problems with a binary division century and the timing of the first wave of
between LME and CME. For one thing, the industrialization (cf. Crouch, 1993). Where
divisions may not be fine enough to capture guilds were only incompletely removed and
differential economic performance rates. where industrialization took off compara-
Thus, the Scandinavian variety of CME is tively late in the second half or last quarter
substantially different in institutional terms of the nineteenth century during a time
from continental European CMEs and it also when very heavy fixed capital investments
exhibits a different performance profile. For fuelled the growth of the lead industries
another thing, in addition to market contract- (heavy industry, railroads, later chemical
ing (LME) and horizontal relational contract- and electromechanical engineering indus-
ing (CME), is there not hierarchical planning tries), market actors built economic insti-
within firms and initiated by states at the tutions around CME-type arrangements.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


206 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

More research is needed on the origins and accurate, however, is open to debate and
trajectories of different capitalist varieties. requires a great deal of research. For now,
The account of varieties of capitalism, as Iversen and Soskice have made an interesting,
initially presented, is entirely divorced from provocative proposal to construct a link between
a consideration of politics in terms of parties production systems and democratic politics.
and political conflict (Pontusson, 2005a). We Third, it is questionable whether coherent
are dealing with a micro-logic of interaction models of capitalism perform better than mixed
between firms, wage earners, and customers. models, and whether different coherent models
Institutional frameworks provided by the have equivalent performance. Both of these
state, and the political actors that bring about propositions can be always true, always wrong,
such institutions either do not matter or are or true at times contingent upon certain bound-
seen as executors of a logic of economic ary conditions (e.g., technological innovation
comparative institutional advantage. Most frontiers). Empirically, the performance postu-
recently Iversen and Soskice (2006a, 2006b) lates in the VoC literature are controversial. The
have tried to remedy the political lacunae in VoC theorists’ claim that good economic per-
the varieties of capitalism literature by argu- formance can be achieved by functionally
ing that historically varieties of capitalism equivalent, yet different institutions is most
shaped party system alignments which, in plausible for the era from about 1950 to 1990,
turn, affected the electoral strength and but not before and unlikely thereafter. Starting
opportunities for left parties to dominate in the 1990s, some of the continental CME
governments and affect production and wel- systems, above all Germany, have performed
fare systems. CME capitalism promotes badly in terms of growth and employment. If
systems of proportional representation in anything, a branching of different subtypes of
countries, where remnants of the guild system CMEs has taken place, with the small
precipitated differences of interest between Scandinavian branch doing well economically
companies employing workers with lesser or and the bigger continental European branch
greater skill specificity, a line of conflict performing weakly over extended periods of
cross-cutting the class divide and thus trans- time. In a reanalysis of Hall and Gingerich’s
lating into party system fragmentation that (2004) study of economic growth with data
eventually induced strategic politicians in a covering OECD countries until the beginning
variety of parties to opt for a replacement of of the new millennium, Kenworthy (2006)
plurality electoral systems. The presence of could not find a growth advantage to countries
proportional representation, in turn, makes having a ‘pure’ rather than a ‘mixed’ variety of
center-left governments more likely, as lower capitalism. The other ‘congruence’ hypothesis
thresholds of legislative representation facili- that precedes and stimulated the VoC literature
tates party system fragmentation. By sup- has run into similar empirical difficulties. Lange
porting centrist parties and depriving and Garrett’s (1985) proposition that left (right)
socialists of outright electoral majorities, wing governments when paired with central-
this, in turn, enables voters to force office- ized (decentralized) industrial relations sys-
seeking socialist parties into coalition agree- tems, perform better than ‘incongruent’
ments with non-socialist parties in order to alignments (left governments + decentralized
reduce the risk that a left government could industrial relations, and right governments +
engineer a dramatic reversal of the political- centralized industrial relations), appears to hold
economic status quo. Center-left govern- PI-democracies up to the 1980s, but hardly
ments, finally, reinforce CME institutional after the early 1980s (Scruggs, 2001).
arrangements. Whether or not this theoreti- Many of the productivity advantages of
cally elegant account of the emergence CME capitalism may have eroded in the
of party systems, electoral systems, and 1990s and beyond, as the lead econo-
political economic outcomes is historically mic growth sectors involve technologies and

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 207

contractual relations that are difficult to derive benefits proportional to contributions


accommodate in a CME world. Innovative and risks covered. No one knows who will
industries thrive where there are flexible, benefit from the insurance more than others.
open and transparent capital markets and Ex post, the distribution of payouts is un-
where labor contracts are short-term, permit- equal, as some contributors received benefits
ting the frequent reconfiguration of the wage under the terms of the contract while others
force. It is therefore not surprising that previ- did not. Hedging does create winners and
ously pure incarnations of CME capitalism losers, but only ex post, behind a veil of ex-
are fraying at the margins. This applies par- ante ignorance. Public, compulsory insur-
ticularly to corporate governance, where both ance, such as pension plans, can be based on
the ‘pure’ CME capitalism in Germany (Beyer a pure principle of hedging and social protec-
and Höpner, 2003) as well as the ‘mixed’ tion, without redistribution, just as any pri-
CME capitalism in France (Goyer, 2006) has vate insurance. ‘Redistributive’ social policy,
undergone momentous change toward a lib- by contrast, involves both ex ante knowledge
eral corporate governance model. And the and ex post realization of benefit allocations
relative success of the Scandinavian econo- that require some to pay more than others per
mies since the mid-1990s may have more to unit of benefit. Examples are compulsory
do with their excellent general educational health insurance plans that offer exactly the
systems that produce a versatile, flexible work same coverage to all members, even if contri-
force than their asset-specific vocational edu- butions are set differentially by income. The
cation. More generally, technological change same redistributive impact occurs, if social
has reduced the promise of vocational educa- services (e.g., childcare) or unemployment
tion as an avenue to successful occupational benefits are paid out of general tax revenue
careers in all but a very limited set of manu- that has been collected based on earnings and
facturing industries. It is the lack of emphasis capital assets.
on higher general education that contributes to In a highly stylized way, we can distin-
the economic crisis of continental European guish three ‘types’ of welfare states that
CMEs where governments spend little on the closely follow Gøsta Esping-Andersen’s
tertiary educational sector and private univer- (1990) famous tripartition, but use the lan-
sities are marginal. guage of social protection (risk hedging) and
redistribution. First, there are residual ‘lib-
eral’ welfare states that limit redistribution
and leave most insurance protection to market
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF participants. Public programs provide protec-
WELFARE STATES: SOCIAL tion and some redistribution for a residual
PROTECTION AND group of ‘needy’ citizens who cannot take
REDISTRIBUTION advantage of insurance markets. Examples
are minimum income support and welfare,
The notion ‘welfare state’ encompasses public health benefits to the poor, and unem-
authoritative policies enacted to ‘hedge’ wage ployment benefits covered out of general
earners and their dependents from the risks taxes poor recipients of social benefits may
of losing their market income and to ‘redis- have never paid. Second, there are ‘conserva-
tribute’ income from those with higher market tive’ or Christian Democratic welfare states
incomes to those with low or no market that organize comprehensive, universalistic
incomes. Social protection and redistribution and compulsory social protection, but contri-
are analytically distinct activities. Hedging butions are more or less proportional to ben-
takes place when people contribute to an efits thus limiting the redistributive effect of
insurance pool and premiums are based on social policy. This third ‘social democratic’
actuarial risks. Ex ante, everyone expects to type of universalistic welfare state both

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


208 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

hedges all citizens against market risks, but of future labor market participants, as opposed
its universalistic coverage schemes with flat to social policies that are primarily ‘social
benefits and services also redistributes a sub- consumption’ expenditures benefiting those
stantial amount of income to the advantage who are outside labor markets or have left
of the worst-off. them for good (pensions, much of health care,
In substantive policy terms, the historical some means-tested income maintenance pro-
core of social protection and redistribution grams). Knowing the ‘type’ of welfare state
concern (1) old age insurance; (2) health and (residual, conservative, social democratic)
accident insurance; and (3) unemployment does not help us much to predict the ‘age bias’
insurance. Whereas better paid wage earners of the welfare state, conceived as its relative
could hedge against risks of old age and ill- emphasis on social investment or social con-
ness through private and voluntary insurance sumption programs (Lynch, 2006).
(typically in unions and non-profit ‘friendly There are at least four grey areas that make
societies’) before government programs it difficult to delineate the welfare state. First,
stepped in, in the realm of unemployment are private, but legally compulsory insurance
insurance problems of adverse selection programs, common in Switzerland, part of
(only those facing high risk to become unem- the welfare state or not? Functionally, such
ployed will voluntarily insure themselves) programs operate in a fashion very similar to
and moral hazard (people covered by insur- some publicly run insurance programs and
ance may perform badly in their jobs and therefore should be included in the welfare
willfully become unemployed) made this state. Second, are publicly funded social
liability strictly a matter of public coverage. policies whose administration and imple-
Since World War II, the core programs have mentation has been delegated to quasi-
dramatically increased in generosity and cov- private, non-profit institutions part of the
erage. Moreover, social policy got involved welfare state? Consider Australia, where a
in a range of additional activities such as wide array of benefits was part of national
(1) support for raising children (financial wage bargaining agreements, but not admin-
transfers and public childcare); (2) provision istered by governmental agencies. Third,
of low-income housing; and (3) a variety of legislation to make it difficult for employers
new means-tested measures to maintain to hire and fire workers (security of the wage
incomes of the poor and disabled not covered contract, labor market ‘rigidity’) certainly
by other programs. constitutes a form of governmental social
Public education, as the public effort to turn protection and in some ways even of redistri-
citizens into competent participants in labor bution, if consumers keep paying for work-
markets and politics, may be considered part ers’ wages who would have been made
of the ‘hedging’ and ‘redistributive’ role of the redundant, had it not been for labor laws
welfare state. But whereas high-quality public preventing employers from laying them off.
primary and secondary education redistribute Fourth, and most importantly, does it make
mostly toward the less well-off, public univer- sense to focus on the welfare state, as the
sity funding redistributes toward the affluent government-initiated programs enabling
whose offspring is more likely to take advan- people to hedge against market risk and
tage of tertiary education. Active labor market imposing a redistributive scheme on them, or
policy that provides retraining to those unem- is it more accurate to focus on the broader
ployed whose skills have become obsolete, by category of ‘welfare regimes’ that include
contrast, delivers redistribution toward low- non-governmental communal (family) and
income households. Together with parts of associational institutions achieving social
health care services and family support for protection and redistribution? Especially the
children, education constitutes a category of feminist critique of the welfare state literature
public ‘social investments’ in the human capital has pointed to the intimate linkage between

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 18 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 209

women’s unpaid labor in the family and social With regard to redistribution, the best
networks, on the one hand, and public provi- starting point is the by now famous Meltzer
sions, on the other (cf. Sainsbury, 1999; also and Richards (1981) hypothesis that since the
Esping-Andersen, 1999). The absence of less well-off are more numerous than the
public social investment and consumption well-off (i.e., the median voter earns less
payments (e.g., for child care, elder care, than the mean voter), in democracies there
unemployment payment for young labor will always be demand for redistribution, and
market participants) keeps women bound to that demand will be more intense, where
the home. Where a large portion of women are inequality is starker. Because democracies
still homemakers, social policy makers may require a larger share of the population to
not offer public services that would supplant pass a winning policy than authoritarian gov-
those delivered already in the family. ernments, democracies are likely to produce
Why have today’s PI-countries historically more redistributive social policies than
developed different kinds of welfare states authoritarian regimes.8 But the extent to
since the late nineteenth century? How do which this is true depends on the ability of
they now cope with the new challenges the poor to overcome collective action prob-
facing the welfare state, particularly chang- lems and organize effectively to press for
ing labor markets, the demographic revolu- their interests. Moreover, with increasing
tion involving low birthrates and a growing income the propensity to buy insurance
share of retirees in the population? Whereas increases so that moderately affluent people
the retrospective research question primarily may embrace social policy, provided it is not
focuses on the causes of social protection and targeted to non-labor market participants
redistribution, the forward-looking analysis (Moene and Wallerstein, 2001, 2003). In as
of ways to cope with new challenges focuses much as insurance and redistributive mecha-
on trade-off between social investment and nisms are intertwined, even under conditions
social consumption. of relatively low inequality support for some
Why have governments been involved in risk kinds of redistributive policies may therefore
hedging and redistribution at all? With regard to be widespread.
risk hedging (social protection), some liabili- At least four different arguments explain
ties are uninsurable in markets because of the historical trajectory of welfare states in
adverse selection and moral hazard. In addition contemporary PI-democracies. The first,
to unemployment insurance, this applies to sometimes named ‘logic of industrialism,’ a
family services and health care to a considera- derivate of modernization theory, postulates
ble extent. In other instances, the non-provision that welfare states grow with increasing soci-
of compulsory public insurance policies would etal aggregate affluence. The transition to
yield collective externalities (destitution, industrial and then PI-societies reduces the
crime), that reduce everyone’s quality of life. role of the family as a social protective and
Weakness of will may make people shun vol- human capital forming institution, along with
untary insurance against future risk and rather traditional voluntary associations, such as
consume resources that would have to be sacri- churches. Public policy is burdened with the
ficed for social protection. Myopic current task of filling the void. Development also
selves ‘free ride’ on the well-being of their comes with a continuous increase in life
future selves and produce externalities also for expectancy that expands the population of
others. Finally, for physical and/or mental rea- retirees and their social insurance needs
sons, some individuals cannot effectively par- (retirement, health care). Indeed, in global
ticipate in a market society. Here humanitarian comparison, affluence and demographics
motivations, as well as concerns about exter- may be the most powerful factors that account
nalities generated by a poverty sector, may lead for cross-national differences in scope and
to the adoption of public policy. social policy effort, as Wilensky (1975)

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 19 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


210 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

showed long ago. But when we probe into associations. In some polities, associations
finer social policy distinctions among (such as churches) and parties with a socio-
PI-democracies today, economic develop- cultural cross-class appeal, based on religion
ment drops out as a causal engine of social and/or national identity attracted support from
policy variance. In a similar vein, a second different classes. In order to compete with the
theory which postulates that it is democrati- socialist movement, cross-class parties adopted
zation, i.e., political regime form that boosts the social protectionist agenda without endors-
social policy, may explain variance among ing far-reaching redistribution.
welfare states in global comparison, but not The balance of power among associations
among already democratic PI-countries. and parties organizing different classes or
More promise to explain welfare state differ- cross-class coalitions then determines social
ences among PI-democracies is an argument policy outcomes, mediated by institutional
that builds on social class mobilization rules of democratic political decision-making.
through unions and parties (‘power resource Where a simple majority in unicameral legis-
theory,’ PRT). It has been challenged recently latures with parliamentary government
by an argument that Iversen calls ‘welfare decided on policy, social policy innovations
production regime theory,’ WPRT). It sees could be adopted most speedily. The pres-
social policies as the result of a positive-sum ence of additional decision-making arenas –
game in which workers and employers agree such as a second chamber of parliament, an
on policies that meet their respective prefer- independently elected presidency, federal
ences, even though they maintain some con- decision-making, a constitutional court with
flicting distributive interests. Both PRT and rights to review the constitutionality of legis-
WPRT go a considerable way to account for lation, and plebiscitarian policy approval –
different past trajectories of welfare states in tended to slow down social policy legislation,
contemporary PI-democracies. But they are wherever interests defeated in one arena of
both relatively uninformative, when employed decision making could reemerge as veto
to explain how PI-democracies respond to players in another arena.10
new challenges that force them to address the Wage earners come closest to realizing
trade-off between social investment and their social protectionist and redistributive
social consumption as priorities of social objectives under conditions of social corpo-
policy making. ratism, where large portions of the work
According to PRT, it is the mobilization of force are organized in centralized unions that
wage laborers in unions and employers’ asso- bargain with corresponding employers asso-
ciations and the crystallization of redistribu- ciations, and/or where unified left party rep-
tive struggles around political parties that resentation voices their interests in legislatures
determines the shape of the welfare state. and governments, while confronting a frag-
Because it is impossible here to render the mented, internally divided non-socialist party
subtleties of this research program, I will con- camp (e.g., Castles, 1978). Corporatism and
fine myself to a stylized account that is not left party hegemony are not identical, but
identical with any one of the major statements moderately strongly related (Hicks, 1999).
of this perspective.9 The critical engine to Workers might initially demand means-
build welfare states is the mobilization of the tested social policy programs bestowing health
industrial working class through socialist labor care, pension and unemployment benefits just
unions and socialist parties all of which call on them, as the most vulnerable wage earners
for social protection and redistribution in in society, but excluding white collar profes-
favor of their constituencies. But these claims sionals and all self-employed. Socialist politi-
do not go unopposed. Business developed its cians, however, realized in the 1940s and
own associations and employed its resources thereafter that they could entice at least some
to strengthen anti-welfare state parties and non-socialist parties and their supporters in

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 20 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 211

the salariat and small business to back a redistributive social policies could be adopted
broad-based welfare state consensus, if social- only during major general crises, such as the
ists agreed to encompassing, universalistic Great Depression (US Social Security Act) or
benefits schemes that also covered non- the immediate aftermath of World War II
working class claimants (cf. Baldwin, 1990). (British National Health Service). Family ben-
By doing so, socialist politicians put social efits remained marginal in liberal-residual
policy gains onto much firmer political foot- welfare states and the equalization of women’s
ing, while still achieving a substantial amount economic opportunities meant the removal of
of social protection and even some redistribu- barriers to labor market entry more than the
tion in favor of their own constituency. extension of public child care facilities.
Universalistic social policy schemes ena- In countries where Catholic confessional
bled left governments to go beyond narrow or ecumenical (‘Christian Democratic’) reli-
industrial working class interests in search of gious parties or nationalist parties (such as
securing median voter support. In the last third the French Gaullists) became politically
of the twentieth century, in universalistic dominant in the 1950s and 1960s, legislators
social democratic welfare states a whole range developed conservative welfare states with
of social policy innovations evidences the encompassing social protection, but limited
same strategy of political incorporation. By redistribution, held back by the fragmenta-
expanding family and child care benefits as tion of insurance systems along occupational,
well as women’s labor market opportunities, geographic, and even ideological lines. At
especially through public service employ- the same time, the doctrine of ‘subsidiarity’
ment, social democrats reinforced their cross- and reverence for traditional gender-roles in
class appeal. Such policies were nevertheless the family made politicians stay away from
consistent with redistributive objectives, as or go slow on social policies that would have
they made services available in a universalistic enabled women to leave home and hearth and
fashion even to very poor beneficiaries who give them access to higher education, child-
had not paid taxes that financed such services. care, gender-neutral pay, etc. An exception is
A similar dual logic of social protection and France with its long-standing pro-natalist
marginal redistribution applies to educational policies. Exercising restraint in terms of pro-
reform, and even to the expansion of higher moting economic redistribution and empha-
education. Although it most benefits the sizing subsidiarity rather than government
middle and upper income professions and activism with regard to the family, as a core
business whose offspring enjoys the greatest institution of human capital formation, con-
chances to attend university, social democrats servative welfare states also have neglected
pushed it with the idea that broad-based public educational reform and expansion of high-
university education would also give access to quality higher education after a brief burst in
working class youths, in addition to drawing the 1960s and 1970s.
non-working class voters to support the party. PRT theories of social policy reform emerg-
In contrast to countries with labor corporat- ing from class-based political party competi-
ism and strong leftist parties, countries with a tion have a great deal of plausibility, but also
powerful united non-socialist right and a encounter a number of anomalies. While
weaker, only intermittently governing labor countries with strong left or even cross-class
party produced a rather different welfare state. parties in government undoubtedly deliver
Here liberal residual welfare states emerged more redistribution than countries dominated
with very modest universalistic flat-rate ben- by market-liberal conservatives (cf. Bradley
efits, complemented by narrow, targeted, and et al., 2003; Kenworthy, 2004; Pontusson,
means-tested programs for the poor. In the 2005b), this redistribution takes place within
Anglo-Saxon polities, where this partisan con- the class of wage earners – from higher earn-
figuration prevailed, broad universalistic and ers to lower earners and from those active in

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 21 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


212 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

the labor force to retirees – rather than from economies (Kenworthy, 2004: Chapter 4),
capitalists to workers (cf. Cusak and high payroll taxes, high unemployment ben-
Beramendi, 2006; Kato, 2003; Timmons, efits, and extensive employment regulation
2005). Larger welfare states are typically create rigid labor markets that have discour-
financed through payroll taxes on labor and aged employment growth (Kenworthy, 2004:
indirect taxes on consumption all of which are Chapter 5). This, in turn, contributes to a new
proportional and even sometimes regressive insider/outsider divide in which social policy
and to a much lesser extent by progressive pushed by left parties protects those who are
taxes on income and capital gains (cf. in labor markets, but does not benefit the
Beramendi and Rueda, 2007). neediest people without capacity to obtain
Even if political parties represent socio- work (Rueda, 2005). Whereas at least activ-
economic classes with different redistributive ism in educational and training policies coun-
desires, the logic of partisan competition and teracts the exclusionary quality in social
government policy-making is not identical democratic welfare states, conservative wel-
with a politics of class conflict and redistri- fare states lack such counterweight and create
bution. As I suggested above in what may be a particularly severe insider/outsider divide.
already my own ‘amendment’ to PRT theory, A recent alternative to PRT is the new
social democrats may embrace universalistic ‘welfare production regime’ theory (WPRT)
cross-class benefits packages for reasons of a advanced by Torben Iversen in a number of
class-transcending logic of electoral office- publications and closely associated with the
seeking in order to attract support by the ‘varieties of capitalism’ theory.11 Similar to
median voter and beyond. And one should PRT, the new theory accounts for social
add here: For the same reason, they will policy outcomes in terms of preferences over
structure tax schemes for such reforms that social protection and redistribution held by
widely dissipate tax burdens rather than factors of production (wage earners and
‘fleece the rich.’ This sometimes may entice capital owners) in a polity, not by conditions
employers to agree with unions on social and interests specific to firms or sectors.
reform strategies (cf. Swenson, 2002). Unlike PRT, WPRT argues that employers
A second anomaly of PRT is that social agree to social policies that are in their own
policy conflict often did not unfold along interest to boost the productive deployment
class, but sectoral lines, with sectors charac- of the factors of production in their firms.
terized by differential risk profiles, foreign Where exactly employers’ interests overlap
trade exposure, and organizational capabilities with those of workers in social protection
(small versus large firms). A whole phalanx of and even redistribution, as long as it is con-
historical studies has demonstrated how acci- fined to redistribution among wage earners,
dent, unemployment or retirement insurance depends on whether the prevailing produc-
schemes have emerged from such cross-class tion regime is of the CME or LME type.
alignments, with compromises between con- Coordinated market economies (CME) rely
flicting positions often crafted by pragmatic, on skill formation that is ‘specific’ to indus-
office-seeking politicians in both socialist or tries or firms. For employees it is risky to
conservative parties (cf. Baldwin, 1990; invest in such skills, as no alternative employ-
Swenson, 1989; Mares, 2003). ment outside the firm or industry in which
A third problem of PRT is not so much a they currently work would allow them to
failure of causal analysis, but a lack of capac- amortize their skill investment. What makes
ity to see the limitations of social policy suc- wage earners shoulder such risk? If skill spe-
cess in social democratic or conservative cificity limits employment options to a single
welfare states. While redistribution among economic sector, generous unemployment
wage earners does not directly slow down insurance with high wage replacement rates
economic growth in contemporary capitalist over a long period of time may encourage

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 22 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 213

workers to invest in risky skills by compensat- Women are relatively less concerned about
ing them for the extra effort it would take to income-maintaining social protection and less
find a new job, were they to lose the existing supportive of left parties in LMEs, where they
one (Iversen, 2005: 41–5). If skill-specificity can (re)enter labor markets easily because of
limits employment to a single firm, workers the prevalence of general skills. As a conse-
would make such risky investments only if quence of differential labor market opportuni-
they enjoy high job protection. ties, in CMEs marriages tend to allocate a
Hence, one would surmise that countries greater share of housework to women and dis-
which already have an array of institutions courage divorce, as women have less promis-
that promote CME production – such as ing prospects to find gainful employment.
encompassing, unified labor unions, strong WPRT, based on the postulate of comple-
business associations and networks, and mentarity between social policy and produc-
incremental technological innovation config- tion regimes, is highly suggestive as a
ured around large companies and networks theoretical account of different levels of
among companies – witness energetic efforts unemployment insurance and job protection,
by employers and workers to craft social although only detailed process tracing could
policies that encourage investment in specific determine, whether the hypothesized constel-
skills. And, indeed, Iversen (2005: 53–8) lations of interests indeed brought about the
can demonstrate empirically that CME coun- resulting policies of social protection or
tries with strong vocational (i.e. specific skill) whether other political forces were at work.
training have much higher levels of job pro- It is more difficult, however, to argue that the
tection and/or more generous unemployment generosity and distributive schemes of health
insurance schemes. In cross-national com- care and pension insurance – the two finan-
parison, CME economies such as Austria, cially biggest components of modern welfare
Belgium, Germany and Sweden score high on states – or policies to support families caus-
both job security and unemployment insur- ally and functionally depend on production
ance, whereas the Anglo-Saxon LMEs score regimes. How would a more generous pen-
low on both. Japan and Italy have strong job sion plan or more comprehensive public
protection (with ‘life time’ employment) and health insurance provide incentives to invest
Denmark, Switzerland, and the Netherlands in specific skills? Conversely, should not a
have generous unemployment insurance, but rather restrictive, occupationally specific and
low job protection, to enable flexible medi- non-redistributive health and pension scheme
um-sized companies to adjust their labor give wage earners the greatest incentive to
force without great transaction costs. invest in specific skills, provided such jobs
Interestingly, at the individual level of public come with life time employment or generous
opinion, Iversen (2005: Chapter 3) finds that unemployment benefits proportional to pre-
citizens with asset-specific skills have a greater vious wage earnings and with ongoing health
propensity to support social spending on coverage? Universal health and pension plans
income maintenance and social policy. As a that redistribute toward the least skilled work-
further implication of the theory, Iversen and ers, but exist for example in Scandinavian
Rosenbluth (2006) can show that women are CMEs as well as to a lesser extent in some
much more in favor of social policy and left continental CMEs, certainly are not function-
parties, when they are employed in countries ally complementary to the acquisition of
where demand is strong for specific skills. specific skills.
Because prevailing cultural practices of child WPRT invites us to make the leap of faith
rearing force women to leave the labor force and to surmise that skill-specific workers,
intermittently, in CMEs they have thus great once sensitized to their particular labor
difficulties in maintaining specific skills market vulnerabilities, endorse not only job
and reentering labor markets successfully. security and unemployment insurance, but

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 23 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


214 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

social protection and redistribution in gen- may explain substantial aspects of past social
eral. But the generalization to other insur- policy, although each has its own limitations,
ance programs (health, pensions) or but that both theories earmark non-liberal
need-based subsidies (family benefits) does welfare states and production regimes as
not follow from the production regime argu- equilibria compatible with robust economic
ment. Moreover, it is unclear why a desire for growth and employment that appear to vanish
insurance (social protection) would also in the early twenty-first century because of
imply a desire for redistribution on the part new exogenous parameters (technology,
of skill-specific workers, at least not when in demographics, global competition). Does
comes to health care and pension benefits.12 this imply that only the market liberal option
It is one thing to endorse insurance with ex of residual welfare states with low unem-
post redistributive consequences and quite ployment insurance and job protection
another to call for social programs that ex- remains viable? Or are there driving forces of
ante redistribute benefits across social cate- social policy not emphasized in both theories
gories. Because insurance is not the same that allow us to reach different conclusions?
thing as redistribution and because redistri- In order to provide a tentative and somewhat
bution is not functionally required by CMEs, speculative answer to this question, let us
WPRT theory cannot explain the distinction briefly review the challenges and patterns of
between less redistributive continental and social policy reform that have emerged in
the more redistributive Scandinavian welfare PI-democracies.
states both of which have CME production The first challenge is that of technology,
regimes. The partisan-based argument of especially the penetration of information tech-
PRT may be more convincing in this regard, nologies (IT) as ‘general purpose’ technology
even though it misses that employers some- into all spheres of production and service
times consented to universalistic social secu- delivery. Recent econometric work once again
rity systems (cf. Swenson, 2002), especially confirms that IT technology probably has had
if they were funded out of wages by payroll the biggest impact on wages and jobs, particu-
taxes. larly for unskilled workers (IMF, 2007:
Just as with PRT theory, WPRT theory Chapter 5). The penetration of IT may pro-
may also retrospectively explain social policy mote the progressive obsolescence of specific
arrangements that are now manifestly becom- skills in manufacturing, with many of the
ing fetters on economic growth and job remaining jobs requiring a high quality scien-
creations. In the case of WPRT theory, new tific education. At the same time, the changing
challenges of technology, demographics and demand for occupational skills makes rigid
globalization may render the equilibrium labor markets with high job protection inhos-
unviable that matches labor markets based on pitable to investment and economic growth.
specific skills to generous, encompassing While there is some disagreement on the pre-
welfare states. As employment in manufac- cise calibration of the causes that bring about
turing sectors has dramatically shrunk over low employment growth, there is no one who
the past thirty years in all PI-democracies, would claim that CME regimes have an
the bulk of new job creation comes from advantage over LME countries. Nevertheless
general low-skill or general high-skill service labor market rigidities may not doom CME
employment (cf. Iversen, 2005: 67–75). To institutions in the short or medium run. The
stimulate employment in these sectors, there good news for CMEs is that the changing
may be no way around ‘selective deregula- demographics of PI-democracies with small
tion’ and/or government employment in the age cohorts entering labor markets and large
future (Iversen, 2005: 272–4). baby boomer cohorts exiting might render
We come to the surprising interim result unemployment irrelevant even in the presence
that both the PRT and the WPRT theories of rigid labor markets. Add on to this the

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 24 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 215

boom in Asian demand for capital goods, a labor market rigidities. It is not the skill-
sector in which CME countries have a huge specificity of the Scandinavian labor force
institutional advantage, and job creation may that boosts the region’s growth, but the
be less of a problem than labor scarcity, par- investment in general skill higher education.
ticularly for high-skill professions. Continental CME economies that have not
The new technological challenges in PI invested much in higher education and that
democracies, however, call for a continuous still rely to a considerable extent on tradition-
upgrading of education to deliver the skill ally skill-specific training trajectories, have
profile demanded by changing labor markets. performed much worse in terms of economic
It is currently not clear which institutional growth and job creation, a result particularly
arrangements are most conducive to deliver- visible in France, Germany, and Italy. Not by
ing a profile of qualifications congruent with a accident, it is in such countries that reform of
post-industrial economy and there is next to higher education has become a key political
no comparative research on the political econ- issue, although it is unclear whether politics
omy of human capital investments (but see can deliver. Improved higher education would
Iversen and Stephens, 2008). In LME residual financially require that the beneficiaries,
welfare states, low public investment in edu- mostly middle class offspring, pay for reforms
cation, complemented by private educational through higher tuition, or that governments
investments by the upper middle class, gener- could extract more taxes to pay for such serv-
ates a skill and qualification profile that may ices, both prospects likely to provoke intense
restrain economic growth and international opposition. Overall, when it comes to the
competitiveness. The weak performance of challenge of technology and education, con-
most LMEs in comparative literacy and school tinental European CMEs appear to be least
achievement tests suggests that a solid broad prepared, whereas LMEs and Scandinavian
middle of well-trained general-skill profes- CMEs each have strengths and weaknesses.
sionals is missing. The economic competitive- The second challenge is the demographic
ness of LMEs may depend increasingly on transition due to declining fertility and
global ‘skimming’ of foreign high-skill stu- increasing life expectancy. It reduces the
dents having received superior primary and population share that works and finances
secondary education elsewhere on earth, but social security and health care programs.
then being lured to PI-economies by access to Again we witness a divide that sets LMEs
outstanding tertiary educational facilities and with residual welfare states and Scandinavian
access to high-paying jobs thereafter. CME universalistic welfare states apart from
As explained above, an office-seeking continental CMEs with conservative welfare
electoral logic embraced by strong Social states. Whereas fertility rates in Anglo-Saxon
Democratic parties vying for the median LMEs have hovered slightly below the
voter and government control may induce replacement rate of 2.1 (US: 2.0; Australia:
party strategists to win marginal voter groups 1.8; UK: 1.7; Canada: 1.5), continental
by providing collective goods or club goods European CMEs have seen very low birth
that actually do not primarily benefit the rates (1.3 or 1.4 in Austria, Germany and
working class. Higher education reform and Italy), with the recent exception of France
expansion is a case in point. Scandinavian (1.9). Scandinavia claims an intermediate
CMEs now spend more on their public uni- position (between 1.6 in Sweden and 1.8 in
versity systems than any other set of coun- Denmark and Finland), as do Belgium and
tries on earth.13 As their economic growth the Netherlands (1.7) with welfare states that
performance since the mid-1990s suggests, combine conservative continental and uni-
high-quality tertiary education may facilitate versalistic redistributive features.
expansion into entirely new industries and In LMEs relatively cheap private child-
avert unemployment, even in the face of care services as well as possibly the fear of

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 25 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


216 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

poverty in old age without support by chil- standards of PI-democracies economic open-
dren may encourage families to have more ness appears to have induced expenditure
children, whereas in Scandinavian CMEs retrenchment (cf. Swank, 2003). With regard
and France the availability of public child to labor mobility, there is some evidence that
care lowers the burden of child rearing. In immigration reduces public spending on
contrast, in continental Europe the high cost social policy (cf. Soroka et al., 2006). Causal
of private services and the absence of public mechanisms bringing about this result, how-
child care depress fertility (cf. Esping- ever, are not entirely obvious (indirect influ-
Andersen, 1999, 2002). Economists would ence of radical right parties?), as there is
add the generosity of public pension schemes little statistical association between rates of
as another fertility-depressing constraint immigration at the national level, mobiliza-
because it makes people less likely to treat tion of xenophobic political parties, and
children as an investment in their own future public policy.
(Boldrin et al., 2005). The challenges of technology, demograph-
Add on to this that continental European ics, and globalization call less for a reduction
social security systems have been exclusively in social expenditure than a recalibration that
financed by pay-go public pension plans, in targets different groups and provides incen-
which current pensions for retirees are paid tives for different social behavior.14 Social
directly out of current receipts in payroll tax, protection and redistribution primarily fund
whereas LME residual welfare states, as well ‘social consumption’ (pensions, health care,
as CME Scandinavia, and the Netherlands income support), even though the WPRT
have strong complementary capitalized, approach points out that minor expenses of
funded public, or private pension plans. the welfare state – such as unemployment
Hence the emerging fiscal crisis of social insurance and job protection – can some-
protection induced by demographics tends to times be considered a component of ‘social
be much more intense in the continental investment,’ insofar as they encourage spe-
CMEs than elsewhere. Once again, it is not cific skill acquisition. With traditional spe-
divergence from market-liberalism in gen- cific skills becoming obsolete in many places,
eral, but the specific institutional architecture however, the targets of social investment in
of continental European CMEs with con- PI-democracies, regardless of whether they
servative welfare states that generates major have LME or CME institutions, has moved
economically detrimental incentives. on to broad investments in general skills
The differential attention to education also (higher education) and larger cohorts of
affects the capacity of PI-democracies to competent labor market entrants (higher fer-
cope with the third challenge, that of globali- tility rates and more immigrants, if properly
zation of production, capital flows and labor. trained to participate in PI economies).
There is clear evidence that the globalization Taken together, these efforts may cope with
of trade and capital has contributed to a technological innovation, demography, and
reduction of low-skilled employees’ wage globalization.
levels, though its effect is probably less pro- In order to mobilize resources for new
nounced than that of technological innova- social investments, however, private capital
tion (IMF, 2007). Nevertheless, there is little investment, public social consumption, or
evidence that countries with rapid increases private consumption must be cut. The former
in globalization also are compelled to would imply higher taxes on capital income,
cut social expenditure to make the price of something difficult to achieve in a world of
labor more competitive. Ironically, only in open capital markets and probably detrimen-
the least well-funded, liberal-residual wel- tal to economic growth prospects. This leaves
fare states with already low payroll taxes by the alternatives of doing nothing, cutting

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 26 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 217

private consumption (higher taxes on con- Table 11.2 gives an overview of invest-
sumption and/or wages) and/or reducing ment, private consumption and public con-
public consumption (‘welfare state retrench- sumption as shares of GDP in PI-democracies,
ment’) in the hope that some of the funds plus the share of net foreign trade balance,
made available to private consumers actually disaggregated by country groups: LMEs with
end up in social investment (private schools residual welfare states, CMEs with universal-
and universities, for example). istic/redistributive welfare states (Scandinavia,

Table 11.2 Functional Division of the Gross Domestic Product 2005 (in percent of GDP)
Country groups Capital Private Public Total domestic Net balance of
investment consumtion consumtion allocation exports minus
imports
1. ANGLO-SAXON COUNTRIES
Australia 25.0 61.4 18.2 104.4 −4.4
Canada 19.3 55.9 19.3 94.5 +4.3
New Zealand 24.0 58.7 17.8 100.5 −0.5
United Kingdom 17.0 65.1 21.3 103.4 −3.3
United States 16.4 70.1 18.6 105.1 −5.1
Unweighted average, 20.5 62.2 19.0 101.5 −1.5
group 1
2. SCANDINAVIA
Denmark 20.0 47.9 26.5 94.4 +5.0
Finland 18.5 52.4 22.3 93.6 +6.6
Norway 19.0 44.8 22.0 85.8 +14.2
Sweden 17.7 47.8 26.9 92.4 +7.6
Unweighted average 18.8 48.2 24.4 91.4 +8.6
group 2
3. LOW COUNTRIES
Belgium 16.7 54.0 22.7 93.4 +3.0
Netherlands 19.7 49.4 23.5 92.6 +7.2
Unweighted average 18.2 51.7 23.1 93.1 +6.9
group 3
4. CONTINENTAL EUROPE GROUP
Austria 21.2 55.8 17.8 94.8 +5.2
France 19.5 55.3 24.2 99.0 +0.5
Germany 17.2 59.2 18.6 95.0 +4.9
Italy 19.5 59.8 19.7 100.0 0.0
Switzerland 20.1 60.5 11.9 92.6 +7.4
Unweighted average 19.5 58.1 18.4 96.0 +4.0
group 4
Japan 23.9 56.5 17.6 98.0 +1.9
RESIDUAL GROUP: LATE CATCH-UP
Greece 25.8 66.8 16.4 109.0 −8.9
Ireland 25.1 45.4 14.4 84.9 +15.1
Israel 17.7 59.2 28.6 105.5 −5.3
Portugal 23.0 64.1 20.7 107.8 −7.8
Spain 28.3 57.7 17.8 103.8 −3.8
SOURCE: Calculated from OECD, Quarterly National Accounts.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 27 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


218 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

and as marginal cases Belgium and the expenditures and making room for social
Netherlands), CMEs with continental social investment. The factual question of whether
protectionist welfare states, and a residual or not PI-democracies have reduced social
group of latecomers to the PI-democracy consumption over the past decades depends
group or outliers (Israel with low private on the measures employed. As a share of
investment and high public consumption, in GDP, social expenditure has stayed high or
part due to military expenses). The OECD’s even slowly increased over the past decade
category of ‘final public consumption’ should just about anywhere in the OECD. But grow-
not be confused with the contrast between ing numbers of claimants, whether as unem-
social consumption and social investment ployed or pensioners, may conceal the at
proposed here. In the OECD categorization, times substantial entitlement cutbacks
‘public consumption’ includes all social serv- per claimant (cf. Allan and Scruggs, 2004;
ices, including public educational expendi- Korpi and Palme, 2003; Pontusson, 2005:
ture and child care that I have termed here Chapter 8). Several different arguments have
‘social investment.’ been made to account for the timing, size and
Interestingly, the share of GDP devoted to program structure of these cutbacks, but
investments is about the same in all LMEs it may be too early to judge the relative
and CMEs, regardless of overall size of the importance of each.
public sector and tax rates. Some countries First, there are theories that hold responsi-
with low tax rates have also very low invest- ble objective economic exigencies for the
ment rates (United States!). Higher invest- decline of social expenditure. While Huber
ments in human capital show up either in and Stephens (2001) subscribe to a partisan
high public sector consumption (Scandinavia theory of welfare state expansion, they argue
and Low Countries), or in high private con- that recent cuts cannot be accounted for in
sumption (LME countries with residual wel- partisan terms, but result from increasing
fare states, private educational and family claims made on social programs by unem-
services). The continental European CMEs, ployment. PRT has no prospective applica-
by contrast, have neither very high private bility. A similar exigencies based argument
consumption nor high public consumption. could be teased out of Iversen’s (2005) work.
In order to stimulate human capital generat- Social expenditure declines when the occu-
ing expenditure, resources would have to pational structure changes such that specific
be diverted from private consumption to pri- skills become less relevant, rendering high
vate investment (e.g., private child care unemployment payments and job protection
and private universities) or public investment less productive. Similarly, picking up on
(tuition for public universities, higher Iversen and Cusak (2000), one might also
taxes on consumption and/or wage income), surmise that as the speed of change in the
each implying a highly unpopular reduction occupational structure, particularly the loss
of private final consumption.15 Add onto this of jobs requiring specific skills, declines with
that the demographic transition increases the shrinking share of manufacturing in over-
pressures to spend on social consumption, all employment, social policy expenditures,
and the intensity of the ongoing distributive as a way to compensate losers in the labor
conflict between private and social consump- market, will contract as well. WPRT, how-
tion, on one side, and social investment, on ever, has not yet developed or tested an
the other, comes into sharp relief. explicit theory of welfare state retrenchment
Let us address here only the question of in PI-democracies.
the extent to which PI-democracies have Second, some research sees partisan poli-
begun to reign in on social and/or private tics consistent with PRT at work in the
consumption as a step toward recalibrating political retrenchment process (Allen and

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 28 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 219

Scruggs, 2004; Korpi and Palme, 2003; state. Here they risk losing large blocs of
Pontusson, 2005). This research is based on a voters to the opposition in elections after
careful analysis of changes in entitlement painful social policy reforms, as voters see
levels in social insurance schemes (unem- their social-protectionist demands better
ployment payments, sickness pay), based on represented with an opposition party.
standardized need profiles of claimants (say, Thus, in party systems where social demo-
a single wage earner in a family with two crats encounter strong, market-liberal con-
under-age children). Consistent with PRT, servative parties or alliances of parties waiting
such entitlement levels appear to have fallen to replace a center-left government – e.g. in
most in liberal-residual welfare states. Scandinavia, Belgium, or the Netherlands –
A different measure of social policy left parties in government are more likely to
retrenchment would not look at current pay- embrace social policy retrenchment, particu-
outs and benefit levels, but at fundamental larly when they can conceal reductions of
changes in the operation of social insurance. entitlements behind complicated long-term
Most important here is the partial transition incremental changes of contribution and ben-
from a ‘pay-go’ pension system that ploughs efits schemes. Conversely, center-left gov-
current payroll tax receipts into current pen- ernments dare less reform, where the main
sions to a partially capitalized insurance that opposition is not a market-liberal party, as in
makes the magnitude of a contributor’s pen- continental Europe with very weak market-
sion dependent on that individual’s choice of liberal parties, particularly in France,
funds and levels of contribution to a person- Germany, and Italy. The electoral costs of
alized pension savings account. Fundamental retrenchment reform may be too high for
structural reform of national pension systems either center-left or center-right governments.
may not be the exclusive reserve of market Where in such competitive configurations
liberal conservative governing parties. governing parties risk painful social policy
Governments led by social democratic or reform anyway, they face heavy electoral
labor parties may be willing to embrace such losses subsequently, as long as some com-
long-term reforms, but also sometimes short- petitors can credibly preserve its reputation
term benefits reductions contingent upon the as a stalwart of the welfare state.
configuration of party competition. Third, a further line of reasoning about
Left party governments may go ahead and welfare state retrenchment rejects both a par-
reduce public social protection and income tisan politics-based account of retrenchment
maintenance, where their major competitors as well as an argument concerning objective
have a reputation of being more fiercely social and economic circumstances.
committed to financial retrenchment of the According to Pierson’s (2001) ‘new politics’
welfare state. When compared to their parti- thesis, many welfare state programs have
san competitors, social democrats then created so broad a favorable electoral con-
present themselves as the “lesser evil” from stituency that politicians, regardless of parti-
the vantage point of all those who defend the san stripes, can engage in cutbacks only if
status quo of generous pension systems that they somehow can avoid the blame for the
become unsustainable, when compared to reform. Hence, politicians can usually make
their partisan competitors (cf. Green- cuts in universalistic, encompassing social
Pedersen, 2002; Kitschelt, 2001; Schludi, insurance programs only through all-party
2005). In polities with strong cross-class coalitions or if the program is caught up in an
Christian Democratic parties or nationalist acute fiscal crisis.
parties, like the Gaullists in France, however, An interesting idea directly speaking to
social democrats are not the only party with the social consumption/social investment
a reputation of having expanded the welfare trade-off has recently been made by Silja

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 29 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


220 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Häusermann (2007). Based on continental With regard to varieties of capitalism, over


European polities with Bismarckian paygo the past decade coordinated market econo-
pension plans, she argues that issue linkage mies have witnessed the beginnings of pro-
and logrolling can help reform. Retrenchment found change in their practices of corporate
proposals have more promise to be imple- governance, industrial relations, guarantees
mented, if they counterbalance social con- for job security, systems of skill formation,
sumption at least in part by stimulating social and technological innovation. In that process,
investments. In the realm of pensions, parties they have adopted elements of LME arrange-
could offer higher pension entitlements for ments to overcome rigid labor markets, low
times spent by women staying outside labor profitability, and weak innovativeness (few
markets in order to raise small children in new technology start-ups). This does not
exchange for cutbacks of the standard pen- imply, however, that LME type arrangements
sions earned after a lifetime of payroll contri- ‘win’ the competition of institutional models.
butions as a wage earner. LMEs have generated a whole range of growth
Continental European CMEs face not only inhibiting features of their own, such as
the greatest urgency to change their welfare corporate governance scandals, perverse
states due to low investments in general effects of managerial compensation, the cost
education that exacerbate the problems of and inefficiency of private health care systems
technological innovation and globalization as such that even in America a bipartisan consen-
well as due to the extent of demographic sus appears to emerge that holds universalistic
transformation. They also have the least polit- compulsory coverage to be indispensable, and
ical capacity to engineer unpopular reforms, a weak primary and secondary education
as they are lacking powerful market-liberal system for which LME countries compensate
parties. Both on the side of problem pressure by encouraging the immigration of highly
as well as problem-solving abilities, continen- skilled professionals attracted by an intensely
tal European CMEs trail behind LMEs with competitive tertiary education system. Also
liberal-residual welfare states and CMEs with the sharp rise in inequality and poverty in
universalistic-redistributive welfare states. LMEs places a considerable population share
at risk of permanently losing the capacity to
function competently in the market economy
and polity of PI-democracies.
CONCLUSION The ideal types whose institutional fea-
tures were postulated to create efficiency-
What are future prospects of research on the enhancing complementarities empirically
comparative macro-political economy and give way to mixed arrangements or hybridi-
welfare state development of post-industrial zation. And where reality still approximates a
democracies? It appears that the basic cate- pure type, such arrangements do not deliver
gories organizing institutional differences distinct economic payoffs (cf. Kenworthy,
between national economies – whether in 2006). New challenges become prominent
terms of ‘varieties of capitalism’ or ‘worlds with which neither the market liberal variety
of welfare states’ – are in the process of of capitalism with residual welfare states nor
becoming inadequate to capture the empiri- the coordinated market economies with con-
cal realities of political economic changes in servative or social democratic welfare states
individual PI-democracies and the global can fully cope. This concerns the political
political economy. This may also reduce their economy of (higher) education and the social
value as causal mechanisms to account for consequences of demographic change. Both
cross-national variance in economic growth are intertwined insofar as they place a new
or patterns of inequality. distributive question on the agenda, one

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 30 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 221

between social investments in current and and authoritarian radical right parties typically also on
future labor market participants and social the pro-market liberal right, except on trade. At the
mass level, the parties combine constituencies with
consumption by past or soon retiring labor somewhat different propensities on distributive poli-
market participants. tics around authoritarian and xenophobic appeals. In a
The new priorities reveal lacunae in the highly simplistic way, radical right parties in Western
comparative study of production systems and Europe that have been electorally on the ascent in a
welfare states that need to be addressed in number of countries (such as Austria, Belgium,
Denmark, France, Italy, Norway, and Switzerland)
future research. Two of such lacunae appear to have drawn over-proportionally on working class
me to be particularly important. The first con- voters with authoritarian and xenophobic appeals and
cerns the comparative political-economic anal- centrist to center-right economic-distributive propen-
ysis of education systems and particularly sities, but they also tap small business strata with vig-
institutions of higher education, including their orous anti-tax and anti-welfare inclinations. On the
controversy about the association between market
interface with technological innovation pur- liberal and xenophobic-authoritarian appeals on the
sued by market entities. Little systematic com- radical right, see Mudde (2007) arguing against and
parative research has addressed the causes of Kitschelt (2007a) arguing in favor.
differential education systems nor the forces 3. In other words, the cut-off is slightly above the
that hasten or resist reform. The second con- world’s weighted average GNI per capita in 2005,
$9,400 at PPP.
cerns the empirical comparative study of tax 4. Counting these cities as countries would be
systems and their consequences for efficient equivalent to counting New York, London, Paris, or
resource allocation and distribution. Economics Los Angeles as separate countries. Each of their per
has been better at identifying normative crite- capita GDP is higher than Luxembourg’s, and that of
ria of efficient tax systems than empirically Luxembourg, as a city state, is already substantially
greater than that of Hong Kong or Singapore.
studying the diversity of such systems. In com- 5. The exception is Iversen and Wren (1998) who
parative political economy, most of the varie- argue that full employment and low wage inequality
ties of capitalism as well as the worlds of require very high public employment implying high
welfare state literatures have just about ignored budget deficits. One might argue, however, that
systems of taxation, except with regard to cor- high payroll and consumption taxes may close these
loopholes, yet displace the problem to low private
porate taxation, a source of government reve- sector job formation and investment.
nue that pales in all PI-democracies when 6. Curiously, Franzese’s (2002: Chapter 4) other-
compared to the flow of resources furnished by wise technically much more sophisticated treatment
income, payroll, and consumption taxes. Tax than Garrett’s completely brackets international vari-
systems, however, play critical roles in shaping ables, with the exception of the sectoral composition
of the economy.
incentives for citizens’ and firms’ market strat- 7. Mares (2006): ‘I divide the number of persons
egies (and thus ultimately economic growth) aged between 18 and 65 who are neither employed
as well as for social protection and inequality. nor unemployed to the working age population, and
As political economy begins to ponder the I multiply the resulting number by the level of expen-
reconfiguration of systems of production and ditures on unemployment benefits’ (pp. 69–70).
8. On the importance of regime and suffrage, see
welfare states, it may be critical to incorporate recently Lindert (2004).
close analysis of taxation and education. 9. The main contributors to this train of thinking
are Castles (1978), Esping-Andersen (1990), Hicks
(1999), Huber and Stephens (2001), Korpi (1983;
2006), and Stephens (1979).
10. On institutional modifications of the PRT argu-
NOTES ment, see especially Huber et al. (1993).
11. I am drawing on Estevez et al. (2001), Iversen
1. Gross domestic product (GDP) plus net receipts (2005: Chapters 1–4), Iversen and Rosenbluth (2006)
of primary income from foreign sources (World Bank and Iversen and Soskice (2001, 2006).
2006b: 300). 12. Unemployment insurance may be the excep-
2. This claim is controversial in the literature on the tion to that rule. If unskilled workers have a higher
radical right, but academic experts rate anti-immigrant risk of becoming unemployed than skill-specific

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 31 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


222 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

workers and accumulate more days in unemploy- Baldwin, P. (1990) The politics of social solidar-
ment per year per unskilled worker, but all workers ity. Class bases of the European welfare
pay the same insurance premiums and draw benefits state 1875–1975. Cambridge: Cambridge
according to the same schedule, risk pooling will University Press.
redistribute resources in favor of unskilled workers.
Benoit, K. and Laver, M. (2007) Party policy in
13. According to OECD statistics, in 2001, LME
countries spent between 0.9 per cent/GDP (UK, US)
modern democracies. London: Routledge.
and 1.5 per cent/GDP (Canada) on public higher Beramendi, P. and Rueda, D. (2007) ‘Social
education, while all four Scandinavian countries democracy constrained: Indirect taxation in
dedicated about 1.5 per cent/GDP to that purpose. industrialized democracies’, British Journal of
The continental European CMEs spent only between Political Science, 37 (4): 619–41.
0.7 per cent/GDP (Italy) and 1.1 per cent/GDP Beyer, J. and Höpner, M. (2003) ‘Corporate
(Austria) on higher education. But unlike the LMEs, governance and the disintegration of organ-
they did not supplement this expenditure with gener- ized capitalism in the 1990s’, West European
ous private investment, bringing the US total to no Politics, 26 (4): 179–98.
less then 2.7 per cent of GDP and that of other LME
Boldrin, M., De Nardi, M., and Jones, L.E.
countries to 2.5 (Canada), 1.5 (Australia) and 1.1
(Britain), (see OECD, 2006).
(2005) Fertility and social security. (National
14. For an interesting analysis of recalibration in Bureau of Economic Research working
social policy, see Häussermann (2007). paper, no. 11146).
15. Of course, continental Europeans could try to Bradley, D., Huber, E., Moller, S., Nielsen, F.,
reduce their export surplus and consume more of and Stephens, J. D. (2003) ‘Distribution and
what they produce. A large trade deficit is clearly one redistribution in post-industrial democra-
major reason why U.S. consumption is exorbitantly cies’, World Politics, 55 (2): 193–229.
high as share of GDP. But Scandinavia has an even Calmfors, L. and Driffill, J. (1988) ‘Coordination
higher export surplus than continental Europe and of wage bargaining’, Economic Policy, 6 (1):
still manages to devote more to social investment
14–61.
and restrict private consumption.
Cameron, D. (1978) ‘The expansion of the
public economy: A comparative analysis’,
American Political Science Review, 72 (4):
REFERENCES 1243–61.
Cameron, D. (1984) ‘Social democracy, corpo-
Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1995) ‘Fiscal expan- ratism, labor quiescence, and the represen-
sions and adjustments in OECD countries’, tation of economic interest in advanced
Economic Policy, 10: 207–48. capitalist society’, in J. H. Goldthorpe (ed.),
Alesina, A. and Rosenthal, H. (1995) Partisan Order and conflict in contemporary capital-
politics, divided government, and the econ- ism. Studies in the political economy of
omy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Western European nations. Oxford: Oxford
Press. University Press, pp. 143–78.
Allan, J.P. and Scruggs, L. (2004) ‘Political Castles, F.G. (1978) The social democratic
Partisanship and Welfare State Reform image of society. London: Routledge.
in Advanced Industrial Societies,’ American Castles, F.G. (2002) The future of the welfare
Journal of Political Science, 48 (3): state. crisis myths and crisis realities. Oxford:
496–512. Oxford University Press.
Allen, M. (2004) ‘The varieties of capitalism Crouch, C. (1993) Industrial relations and
paradigm: Not enough variety?’, Socio- European state traditions. Oxford: Oxford
Economic Review, 2 (1): 87–108. University Press.
Alt, J.E. and Crystal, K.A. (1983) Political eco- Cusack, T.R. and Beramendi, P. (2006) ‘Taxing
nomics. Berkeley: University of California work’, European Journal of Political Research,
Press. 45 (1): 43–73.
Alvarez, R.M., Garrett, G. and Lange, P. (1991) Dalton, R.J. (2004) Democratic challenges.
‘Government partisanship, labor organization, Democratic choices. The erosion of political
and macroeconomic performance’, American support in advanced industrial democracies.
Political Science Review, 85 (2): 541–56. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 32 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 223

Esping-Andersen, G. (1990) The three worlds woods to EMU. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
of welfare. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Press. Häusermann, S. (2007) Modernization in hard
Esping-Andersen, G. (1999) Social foundations times. Post-industrial pension politics in
of post-industrial economies. Oxford: Oxford France, Germany and Switzerland.
University Press. (Dissertation, Department of Political Science,
Esping-Andersen, G. (2002) Why we need a University of Zurich).
new welfare state. Oxford: Oxford University Hibbs, D. (1976) ‘Industrial conflict in advanced
Press. industrial societies’, American Political
Estevez, M., Iversen, T., and Soskice, D. (2001) Science Review, 70 (4): 1033–58.
‘Social protection and the formation of skills: Hibbs, D. (1977) ‘Political parties and macroeco-
a reinterpretation of the welfare state’, in nomic policy’, American Political Science
P. Hall and D. Soskice (eds), Varieties of Review, 71 (4): 1467–87.
Capitalism. The institutional foundations of Hibbs, D.A. (1987) The international political
comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford economy of industrial democracies.
University Press, pp. 145–83. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Flora, P. and Heidenheimer, A. (eds) (1981) Hicks, A. (1999) Social democracy and welfare
The development of welfare states in Europe capitalism. A century of income security
and America. New Brunswick: Transaction politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Books. Huber, E., Ragin, C., and Stephens, J.D.
Franzese, R. (2002) Macro-economic policies in (1993) ‘Social Democracy, Christian
developed democracies. Cambridge: Democracy, constitutional structure, and the
Cambridge University Press. welfare state’, American Journal of
Garrett, G. (1998) Partisan politics and the Sociology, 99 (3): 711–49.
global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge Huber, E. and Stephens, J.D. (2001)
University Press. Development and crisis of the welfare state.
Goyer, M. (2006) ‘The transformation of corpo- Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
rate governance in France’, in P. D. Culpepper, IMF (2007) World economic outlook. Spillovers
P. A. Hall and B. Palier (eds), Changing France. and cycles in the global economy.
The politics that markets make. New York: Washington, D.C.
Palgrave MacMillan, pp. 80–104. Inglehart, R. (1997) Modernization and post-
Hall, P.A. and Gingerich, D.W. (2004) modernization: Cultural, economic, and
Varieties of capitalism and institutional com- political change in 43 societies. Princeton,
plementarities in the macroeconomy. An NJ: Princeton University Press.
empirical analysis (MPI Cologne Discussion Iversen, T. (1999) Contested economic institu-
Paper 04/5). tions. The politics of macroeconomics
Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (eds) (2001) Varieties and wage bargaining in advanced democra-
of capitalism. The institutional foundations cies. Cambridge: Cambridge University
of comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford Press.
University Press. Iversen, T. (2005) Capitalism, democracy and
Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001) ‘An introduc- welfare. Cambridge: Cambridge University
tion to varieties of capitalism’, in P.A. Hall Press.
and D. Soskice (eds), Varieties of capitalism, Iversen, T. and Cusak T.R. (2000) ‘The Causes of
the institutional foundations of comparative welfare State Expansion: Deindustrialization
advantage. Oxford, Oxford University Press, or Globalization?’ World Politics, 52 (3):
pp. 1–70. 313–49.
Hallerberg, M. (2004) Domestic budgets in a Iversen, T. and Rosenbluth, F. (2006) ‘The
United Europe. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University political economy of gender: Explaining
Press. cross-national variation in the gender
Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R., and von Hagen, J. division of labor and the gender voting gap’,
(2009) Domestic budgets in a United Europe. American Journal of Political Science, 50 (1):
Fiscal governance from the end of Bretton 1–19.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 33 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


224 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2006a) ‘New macr- Kitschelt, H. (2007b) ‘Growth and persistence of
oeconomics and political science’, Annual the radical right in post-industrial democra-
Review of Political Science, 9: 425–53. cies. Advances and challenges in comparative
Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2006b) ‘Electoral research’, West European Politics, 30 (5):
institutions and the politics of coalitions: 1176–207.
Why some democracies redistribute more Kitschelt, H. and Rehm, P. (2005) Family,
than others’, American Political Science and politics. Foundations of electoral
Review, 100 (2): 165–82. partisan alignments in post-industrial democ-
Iversen, T. and Stephens, J. (2008) ‘Partisan racies. Paper prepared for delivery at
Politics, the Welfare State, and the Three the 2005 Annual Meeting of the
Worlds of Human Capital Formation’, American Political Science Association,
Comparative Political Studies, 41 (4–5): Washington, DC.
600–37. Kitschelt, H. and Rehm, P. (2006) ‘New Social
Iversen, T. and Wren, A. (1998) ‘Equality, Risks and Political Preferences’, in K.
employment, and budgetary restraint: The Armingeon and G. Bonoli (eds) The
trilemma of the service economy’, World Politics of Post-Industrial Welfare States.
Politics, 50: 507–46. Adapting postwar social policies to
Kato, J. (2003) Regressive taxation and the new social risks. London: Routledge,
welfare state. New York: Cambridge pp. 52–82.
University Press. Kitschelt, H. and Rehm, P. (2007) ‘Political par-
Katzenstein, P. (1985) Small states in world ticipation’, in D. Caramani (ed.), Comparative
markets. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Press. Korpi, W. (1983) The democratic class struggle.
Kenworthy, L. (2001) ‘Wage-setting measures: London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
A survey and assessment’, World Politics, 54 Korpi, W. (2006) ‘Power resources and employ-
(1): 57–98. er–centered approaches in explanations of
Kenworthy, L. (2004) Egalitarian capitalism. welfare states and varieties of capitalism.
jobs, incomes, and growth in affluent coun- Protagonists, consenters, and antagonists’,
tries. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. World Politics, 58 (2): 167–206.
Kenworthy, L. (2006) ‘Institutional coherence Korpi, W. and Joakim P. (2003) ‘New Politics
and macro-economic performance’, and Class Politics in the Context of Austerity
Socioeconomic Review, 4 (1): 69–91. and Globalization. Welfare State Regress in
Kitschelt, H. (1994) Rationale Verfassungswahl?: 18 Countries’, 1975–1995. American Political
Zum Design von Regierungssystemen Science Review, 97 (3): 425–46.
in neuen Konkurrenzdemokratien; Kriesi, H., Grande, E., Lachat, R., Dolezal, M.,
Antrittsvorlesung, 2. Mai 1994, Department Bornschier, S., and Frey, T. (2006)
of Political Science, Duke University, ‘Globalization and the transformation of the
North Carolina und Humboldt-Universität national political space: Six European coun-
zu Berlin, Philosophische Fakultät III, tries compared’, European Journal of Political
Institut für Politikwissenschaft. Berlin: Research, 45: 921–56.
Humboldt–Univ. Lange, P. and Garrett, G. (1985) ‘The politics of
Kitschelt, H. (2003) ‘Landscapes of political growth. strategic interaction and economic
interest intermediation. Social movements, performance in the advanced industrial
interest groups, and parties in the early democracies, 1974–1980’, Journal of Politics,
twenty-first century’, in P. Ibarra, (ed.), Social 47 (3): 792–827.
movements and democracy. Basingstoke: Lijphart, A. (1999) Patterns of democracy:
Palgrave MacMillan, pp. 81–104. Government formation and performance in
Kitschelt, H. (2007a) ‘Party systems’, in C. Boix thirty-six countries. New Haven: Yale
and S. Stokes (eds), Handbook of compara- University Press.
tive politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, Lindert, P.H. (2004) Growing public. social
pp. 522–54. spending and economic growth since the

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 34 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


POST-INDUSTRIAL DEMOCRACIES 225

eighteenth century (Vol. 1, The Story) Powell, G.B. (2000) Elections as instruments
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. of democracy. New Haven: Yale University
Lipset, S.M. (1961) Party systems and the rep- Press.
resentation of social groups. Berkeley: Rueda, D. (2005) ‘Insider-outsider politics in
University of California. industrialized democracies: The challenge to
Lynch, J. (2006) Age in the welfare state. The social democratic parties’, American Political
origins of social spending on pensioners, Science Review, 99 (1): 61–74.
workers, and children. Cambridge: Sainsbury, D. (1999) ‘Gender policy regimes,
Cambridge University Press. and politic’, in D. Sainsbury (ed.), Gender
Mares, I. (2003) The politics of social risk. and welfare states regimes. Oxford: Oxford
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. University Press.
Mares, I. (2004) ‘Wage bargaining in the pres- Scharpf, F. (1991) Crisis and choice in European
ence of social services and transfers’, World social democracy. Ithaca, New York: Cornell
Politics, 57 (1): 99–142. University Press.
Mares, I. (2006) Taxation, wage bargaining, Schludi, M. (2005) The Reform of Bismarckian
and unemployment. Cambridge: Cambridge Pension Systems. A Comparison of Pension
University Press. Politics in Austria, France, Germany, Italy and
Meltzer, A.H. and Richards, S.F. (1981) Sweden. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University
‘A rational theory of the size of govern- Press.
ment’, Journal of Political Economy, 89 (5): Schmitter, P. (1974) ‘Still the century of corpo-
914–27. ratism?’, Review of Politics, 36: 85–131.
Moene, K.O. and Wallerstein, M. (2001) Schmitter, P. (1981) ‘Interest intermediation
‘Inequality, social insurance and redistribu- and regime governability in contemporary
tion’, American Political Science Review, 95 Western Europe and North America’, in
(4): 859–74. S. Berger (ed.), Organizing interests in
Moene, K.O. and Wallerstein, M. (2003) Western Europe. Pluralism, corporatism, and
‘Earnings Inequality and Welfare Spending: the transformation of politics. Cambridge:
A disaggregated analysis’, World Politics, 55 Cambridge University Press, pp. 287–330.
(4): 485–516. Schumpeter, J. (1950) Capitalism, socialism, and
Mudde, C. (2007) Populist radical right parties democracy. New York: Harper.
in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Scruggs, L. (2001) ‘The politics of growth revis-
Press. ited’, Journal of Politics, 63 (1): 120–40.
Nordhaus, W. (1975) ‘The political business Shonfield, A. (1965) Modern capitalism. Oxford:
cycle’, Review of Economic Studies, 42 (2): Oxford University Press.
169–90. Siaroff, A. (1999) ‘Corporatism in 24 industrial
OECD (2001) Literacy in the information age. democracies: Meaning and measurement’,
Paris. European Journal of Political Research, 36
OECD (2004) Learning for tomorrow’s world. (2): 175–205.
First results of PISA 2003. Paris. Soroka, S., Banting, K., and Jonston, R. (2006)
OECD (2006) Education policy analysis. Focus ‘Immigration and redistribution in the global
on higher education. Paris. era’, in P. Bardhan, S. Bowles and M.
Olson, M.J. (1982) The rise and decline of Wallerstein, (eds), Globalization and Egalitarian
nations. New Haven: Yale University Press. Redistribution. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Pontusson, J. (2005a) ‘Varieties and common- University Press, pp. 261–88.
alities of Capitalism’, in D. Coates (ed.), Soskice, D. (1999) ‘Divergent Production
Varieties of capitalism, varieties of Regimes. Coordinated and uncoordinated
approaches. New York: Palgrave-Macmillan, market economies in the 1980s and 1990s’,
pp. 163–88. in H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks and J.D.
Pontusson, J. (2005b) Inequality and prosper- Stephens (eds), Continuity and change in
ity. Social Europe vs. liberal America. Ithaca, contemporary capitalism. New York:
NY: Cornell University Press. Cambridge University Press, pp. 101–34.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 35 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


226 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Soskice, D. (2000) ‘Macroeconomic analysis Warwick, P.V. (2002) ‘Toward a common


and the political economy of unemploy- dimensionality in West European policy
ment’, in T. Iversen et al. (eds) Unions, spaces’, Party Politics, 8 (1): 101–22.
employers and central banks. Cambridge: Wilensky, H. (1975) The welfare state
Cambridge University Press, pp. 38–74. and equality: The roots of public expendi-
Stephens, J. (1979) The transition for capitalism ture. Berkeley, CA: University of California
to socialism. London: MacMillan. Press.
Swank, D. (2003) Global capital, political insti- World Bank (2005) Where is the Wealth of
tutions, and policy change in developed Nations? Measuring capital for the 21st cen-
welfare states. Cambridge: Cambridge tury. Washington DC, The World Bank.
University Press. World Bank (2006a) World development
Swenson, P. (1989) Fair shares. Unions, pay, report. Development and the next genera-
and politics in Sweden and West Germany. tion. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. World Bank (2006b) Doing business in 2007.
Swenson, P. (2002) Capitalists against markets: How to reform. Washington, DC: World
The making of labor markets and welfare Bank.
states in the United States and Sweden. World Bank Global Governance Indicators (2004)
Oxford: Oxford University Press. World Bank Global Governance Indicators
Timmons, J. (2005) ‘The fiscal contract: States, (n.d.) Retrieved February 22, 2008, from refe-
taxes, and public services’, World Politics, 57 http://info.worldbank.org/governance/
(4): 530–68. wgi2007/faq.htmpaper
Tufte, E. (1978) Political control of the econ- World Economic Forum (2006) The global com-
omy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University petitiveness report 2006–07. New York:
Press. Palgrave Macmillan.

9781412919760_Chap11.indd 36 3/11/2009 4:02:05 PM


12
Government Formation
Wolfgang C. Müller

INTRODUCTION present chapter concentrates on parliamen-


tary democracies. Certainly cabinet forma-
According to Schumpeter’s (1942) ‘realistic’ tion in parliamentary regimes with a two-party
theory of democracy, competition for govern- system often resembles government forma-
ment office is at the heart of modern democ- tion in presidential regimes with a Congress
racy. Because governments are the central majority of the president’s party. The leader
actors in most political systems politically of the winning party assumes a role similar to
ambitious individuals aim at government office that of the president. Yet, unlike the presi-
and government participation is also a central dent, the prime minister remains dependent
goal for most political parties. In democracies on their party for survival in office. And they
such competition for government office ulti- may be constrained by intra-party rules, for
mately is tied to elections. Either the people instance a commitment to confine the choice
elect the government directly or their elected of the government team to the party’s shadow
agents do so, or the government is appointed by cabinet, as is the case in the British Labour
the head of state but responsible to a parliament Party when coming to government from
resulting from general elections. In the first opposition. If anything, over time the simi-
case – in presidential systems – only the chief larities between presidential and parliamen-
executive (and possible a vice-president as part tary systems with regard to the powers of the
of a ‘package’) is directly elected. Government chief executive in government formation
formation is nevertheless an interesting process seem to have increased, even in multi-party
that is worthwhile studying as appointments systems (Poguntke and Webb, 2005). While
can indicate a more or less partisan policy and interestingly, not much research has focused
can indicate the relative weight of the various on the politics of cabinet appointments. This
tendencies in the president’s party. Presidential chapter, therefore, will focus on the more
regimes in multi-party systems may even structural features of government composi-
require building multi-party cabinets, though tion: government type and the various types
this is only one of the options available to of coalitions. The relationship between elec-
presidents (Amorim, 2006; Cheibub et al., tions and government formation is not straight-
2004; Cox and Morgenstern, 2006). forward. While most parties commanding a
Notwithstanding the relevance of govern- parliamentary majority form single-party
ment formation in presidential regimes the governments this is not universally the case.

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:06:17 PM


228 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Likewise, the outcome of government forma- of mathematical equations. Empirical work is


tion in minority situations is not always much wider in its scope. Ideally, it includes all
majority-based coalition government. And variables that potentially help explain the vari-
elections in many cases do not determine the ance in coalition formation. We should thus
government’s party composition. Rather they expect a more complete account of coalition
provide the initial endowment of politicians formations from well-crafted empirical studies
with bargaining power.1 This allows for flex- than from those that aim at testing specific
ibility, but potentially also weakens political theories. Thus, if we are interested in account-
accountability. ing for the factors that explain government
There is a long history of writing about formations in, for instance, post-war Western
organizing government as either based on sin- Europe, a specific country, or any specific
gle-party majorities or coalitions. Although situation, empirical accounts will provide us
some of the early comparative studies including with a richer explanation: a greater amount of
those of A. Lawrence Lowell and James Bryce, explained variance in quantitative studies, or a
were not shy of making generalizations for more plausible account of individual cases of
instance about the instability of coalition gov- cabinet formation. Yet, the explanation is fitted
ernment (see Dodd, 1976: 6–10), the scientific to the cases and is often theoretically under-
study of the phenomena of interest in this chap- specified. It is not so clear what we have gained
ter is closely tied to the invention of game in terms of understanding government forma-
theory. The first game-theoretic treatments of tion in different continents, countries, periods,
government formation plus the behavioural or situations.
revolution in the social sciences have inspired The second dimension relates to the number
empirical work that is completely different of cases employed in empirical work: one, a
from earlier considerations of government. It is few, or many. This dimension is one of the
this research tradition, often labelled ‘coalition organizing principles of this volume and with
studies’ (despite the fact that it is also con- regard to coalition formation can be translated
cerned with non-coalition outcomes), that is at into the archetypical case study of individual
the heart of the present chapter. episodes of government formation, the country
Research on government formation in parlia- study covering all such episodes in a given
mentary democracies can be classified along period, and the quantitative comparative study
two dimensions. The first dimension distin- of government formations maximizing both
guishes theoretical and empirical work. The countries and formation situations. Certainly a
former aims at developing theoretical argu- few studies place themselves somewhere in-
ments that help us to understand government between these categories, for instance by study-
formation. Such studies theorize on the effects ing several episodes in different countries
factors such as actor preferences, their endow- (Jungar, 2000).
ment with resources, institutions, and random In this chapter, I will review these traditions
events have on government formation. Empirical in two main sections: one for the work that is
work aims at describing and explaining govern- first and foremost of a theoretical nature and
ment formation in real-world situations. This is the second for studies that place a premium on
not to say that empirical studies are not based providing the best account of the real world of
on theory and that theoretical work is com- coalition politics. Thus, the next section
pletely separated from confrontation with the presents and discusses the theoretical advances
real world. While we can see the divide between in understanding coalition formation. The
theoretical and empirical studies as a contin- subsequent one discusses how cross-national
uum, in practice the focus of most studies quantitative studies, country studies, and case
allows them to be placed clearly on one side. studies of individual government formations
Theoretical work typically highlights a limited have contributed to our understanding of gov-
number of variables, but specifies the theoreti- ernment formation and how these approaches
cal propositions very clearly, often in the form can help making further progress. A brief

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 229

conclusion, highlighting particular promising parliament), and the remaining backbenchers


avenues for future research, follows.2 being rewarded otherwise (e.g., by government
resources that help them get re-elected).
However, early empirical tests of coalition the-
ories based on office-seeking political parties
COALITION THEORIES have found their predictive power disap-
pointing. Browne’s (1970) empirical test
showed that the Riker-Gamson theory only
Office-seeking and its limits
predicted eight per cent of the coalitions actu-
Theorists start from more or less plausible ally formed in 13 Western European coun-
assumptions that are rooted in credible tries (1945–1970). Two other office-seeking
beliefs about human predispositions, such as theories did better. Von Neumann and
greed, or – more nobly expressed – utility Morgenstern’s (1953) ‘minimal winning’
maximization. While the main body of litera- theory, predicting the formation of coalitions
ture focuses on ‘structural’ factors (resources, that would no longer win if any of its members
preferences, institutions) alternative appro- (i.e., parties) left, was supported in 50.4 per
aches focus on various dimensions of the cent of the actually formed coalitions.
formation process (Adrian and Press, 1968; Leiserson’s (1966) ‘bargaining proposition’
Grofman, 1982). All the first generation of theory, predicting the coalition with the mini-
coalition theorists additionally needed were mum number of parties, was correct in 37.8 per
minimal assumptions about a stylized world cent of the government formations. Yet, these
of politics. According to Riker’s path-breaking theories often predict not a single government
study The Theory of Political Coalitions but a set of equally likely outcomes. Once
(1962) the world of government formation is a Browne calculated the theories’ probability for
zero-sum game, governed by majority rule, correct predictions, ‘minimum number of par-
with all actors having perfect information. ties’ (‘bargaining proposition’) was the best
Consequently, the theory predicts ‘minimum theory, followed by ‘minimal winning’, with
winning’ governments. That is single-party ‘minimum winning’ last. While all three theo-
cabinets whenever a single party masters the ries did better than random, most observers
‘winning’ criterion, or, in minority situations were not satisfied with probabilities for correct
(i.e., when no single party commands a major- predictions in 12 per cent of the cases (for the
ity), the majority coalition that has fewer ‘minimum number of parties’ theory) or less.
parliamentary seats than any alternative Yet perhaps the problem is less in the predictive
winning coalition.3 Without claiming to derive power of these theories than in the originally
his predictions from game theory, Gamson inflated expectations. A theory that does 17
(1961) had already theorized the formation of times better than chance while requiring only a
the ‘cheapest winning coalition’, a concept minimum amount of information – the dis-
equivalent to Riker’s ‘minimum winning’ trbution of seats among parties – can defini-
solution. tively count as scientific progress. As Laver and
The underlying zero-sum assumption in Schofield (1990: 97) put it, it is a different
Riker’s work is that the pay-offs from govern- matter that ‘it does not tell us everything that
ment participation (i.e., cabinet offices) are we would like to know about the process of
fixed and so have to be shared among the coalition formation’. Multivariate tests of coali-
smallest number of players (in this case MPs), tion theories generally have confirmed that
allowing a bigger share for each of them. office-seeking assumptions have considerable
Political parties in this theory are implicitly explanatory power (Franklin and Mackie, 1984;
treated as coalitions of MPs. We can think of Martin and Stevenson, 2001; Mitchell and
the frontbenchers taking over government Nyblade, 2008; Warwick, 1996).
office, some of the backbenchers moving to Yet, the fact remains that office-seeking is
the frontbench (taking leadership positions in not the whole story. Perhaps it is intuitive to

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


230 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

mention that such theories can neither acc- to random level (because of the increase in
ount for the occurrence of minority govern- the number of predicted outcomes).
ments nor oversized cabinets. In the former Another possible reason for deviation at least
case the opposition parties would unneces- from the minimum winning outcome is payoff
sarily leave office perks to the government sensitivity. A few seats more may not really
parties and in the latter case government matter with regard to payoff distribution among
spoils would be divided among too many the coalition’s members. The question then is
parties or among parties comprising too how big the difference between alternative
many greedy MPs (resulting in disappoint- majorities must be to make a difference in prac-
ingly small shares for the individual politi- tice. Moreover, office payoffs are not really
cians). In practice, both types of governments fixed (zero-sum) in practice: cabinets can be
exist and they are not infrequent. Several increased or decreased in size, as can the
studies have shown that oversized cabinets number of parliamentary committees (and
(i.e., cabinets containing more parties than hence committee chairs), and government
necessary for a bare majority) are about as resources can also be increased by borrowing.
frequent as minimal or minimum winning Adding cabinet posts may decrease their value
ones (e.g., Lijphart, 1999: 98). And the work but as with all position goods the question is
of Kaare Strøm (1984, 1990a) has powerfully when exactly the devaluation sets in. Is one
brought to the discipline’s attention that cabinet position out of 15 indeed worth more
minority cabinets are not rare exceptions. than one out of 18 and if yes, is the decrease in
Nor do they typically indicate political crises. the value of individual positions proportional to
Indeed, it is possible to explain their occur- the increase in their number? And although
rence as the outcome of rational party strate- public borrowing may have detrimental long-
gies. Empirical accounts show that roughly a term consequences on the availability of gov-
third of all cabinets are of minority status ernment resources, the short-term constraints
(Müller and Strøm, 2000; Strøm, 1990a). on such a strategy may be soft, allowing for the
Early coalition theorists have recognized considerable expansion of government funds.
that their size-based predictions do conflict Indeed, as Verzichelli (2008) shows, an increase
with at least some observed behaviour. Riker in the number of cabinet parties often leads to
himself resorted to introducing incomplete an increase in the number of portfolios.
information about the actual size of the coali- The literature provides several other fac-
tion as explanation for such deviations (1962: tors that can explain why office-seeking par-
48, see also 78). In order to secure winning, ties form coalitions deviating from the
actors resort to forming coalitions that com- expected minimum or minimal outcomes
mand ‘working majorities’, that is coalitions (see de Swaan, 1973: 81–7): the requirement
with a safety net of a few extra seats (Riker of qualified majorities, the distribution of
and Ordeshook, 1973). If correct, this idea societal power deviating from that of parlia-
could also explain the formation of minority mentary power, transaction costs (Adrian and
governments, as parties may recognize that Press, 1968), the strategy of sharing the costs
they can win with less than a majority. Yet it of governing among a larger group of actors,
seems impossible to identify ‘working major- or the strategy of avoiding the costs of gov-
ity’ requirements a priori. Browne’s (1970: ernment (Mershon, 2002; Müller and Strøm,
29–30) test of Riker’s theory in a revised 2000; Strøm, 1990b), the existence of anti-
form, considering majority coalitions with up system parties, and situations where democ-
to 55 per cent of the seats as ‘minimum win- racy is under threat (Budge and Herman,
ning’, indicated that while improving the 1978; Budge and Keman, 1990: 44; von
prediction rate of actual coalitions to 16.8 per Beyme, 1983). Most of these explanations
cent, it did so at the price of reducing the typically have an ad hoc character. Integrating
probability to predict the coalition correctly them in theory-building and, perhaps even

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 231

more so, measurement constitute challenges. providing empirical data for the cross-
Budge and Herman (1978) have undertaken national measurement of party policy posi-
the most systematic early attempt at formu- tions than Ian Budge (see Budge et al., 2001;
lating an ‘empirically relevant’ theory of Budge et al., 1987; Klingemann et al., 2006).
coalition formation including such factors. And it is this version of coalition theory to
They theorize that a number of hierarchically which we turn next.
ordered criteria (threat to system survival,
absolute single-party majority, existence of
anti-system parties, etc.) can explain govern- Policy-seeking and associated
ment formation. In their empirical applica-
problems
tion they claim to explain 85 per cent of
post-war governments in 12 democracies. Coalition theories based on policy-seeking
Typically, this theory is also very efficient in political parties constitute the main alterna-
predicting a single outcome only. This tive to the office-seeking assumption of early
research cumulates in Budge and Keman coalition theories. While some early theories
(1990), a work that aims to also explain port- included policy motivations as an add-on to
folio allocation, party policy influence, and the parties’ office-seeking motivation
the causes for government termination. (Axelrod, 1970; Leiserson, 1966), it was
Michael Laver (1995) has criticised this Abram de Swaan (1973) who formulated the
‘semi-deductive’ approach (Budge and first pure policy-seeking coalition theory
Keman, 1990: 3) by stressing the inherent (Laver and Schofield, 1990: 97–103). In his
danger of circular reasoning: On the one words: ‘Coalitions emerge from the interac-
hand a threat to democracy and the saliency tion among actors, each of which strives to
of socialist–bourgeois differences are theo- bring about and join a coalition that he
rized to exercise influence on government expects to adopt a policy which is as close as
formation, on the other hand actual govern- possible to his own most preferred policy’
ment formations are likely to influence (de Swaan, 1973: 82).
whether a threat to democracy is considered Departing from exclusively office-seeking
real and how salient the socialist–bourgeois parties means taking issue with the constant-
differences are. And while Budge and Keman sum assumption in early coalition theory.
(1990) claim that their theory explains more This assumption makes the formation of a
than 80 per cent of past government forma- government akin to a bank robbery. In this
tions in 20 democracies, Laver highlights business the individual shares are handed out
that it clearly failed with regard to three pre- once the money is counted. What the partners
dictions the authors themselves singled out to in this wealth-creating operation do thereaf-
illustrate the prognostic capacity of their ter, does not affect the individual payoffs of
approach. Indeed, Budge and Keman’s (1990: the others (unless delivering them to the
190) predictions that the pentapartito in Italy police). Although some taxpayers will be at
will continue to the end of the 1990s, that the ease with this analogy, it is not exactly what
Dutch Christian Democratic Appeal will is at the heart of many government forma-
continue to dictate the composition of tions. Rather, to a large extent the rewards
government coalitions and that the Irish from government office still need to be pro-
Fianna Fàil will continue to avoid coali- duced. In this perspective government policy
tions have not faired particularly well. Yet, is the driving force behind government for-
perhaps making these predictions in the first mation. And once the focus shifts to govern-
place was overstretching what the approach ment outputs, the coalition’s ability to agree
can deliver. The work of Budge and Keman on policies becomes central. Such agreement
(1990) of course is no office-seeking requires that the government parties share
approach. Indeed, no one has done more for policy preferences, or, at least, have policy

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


232 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

preferences that are compatible (i.e., do not Another body of literature assumes com-
conflict). Government formation hence is a plex motivations, that is, the co-existence of
positive-sum game and the gains from gov- different goals such as policy and office
ernment participation increase the more the (Budge and Laver, 1986; Laver and Schofield,
government parties agree on the policies they 1990), or a combination of either or both of
want to pursue. The analogy to government these goals with the parties’ electoral con-
formation hence is not a bank robbery but the cerns (Lupia and Strøm, 1995; Müller and
founding of a business firm, with the payoffs Strøm, 1999; Schofield, 1993, 1995;
resulting from conducting regular business Schofield and Sened, 2006; Sened, 1996;
over some time. Strøm, 1990a, 1990b). Under favourable cir-
Why, then, are political parties considered cumstances politicians may be able to achieve
policy-seekers? Real-world politicians with their multiple goals simultaneously. Under
serious chances for public office are typically less favourable circumstances, they may have
recruited from party activists. Party activists, to abandon one or more goals to achieve
in turn, are those who are primarily moti- another. In most situations, however, politi-
vated by ideological incentives and typically cians will aim for some mix of political
hold more extreme policy positions than ‘rewards’. Rather than prioritizing one goal
party voters (save activists in pure patronage over all others (i.e., displaying lexicographic
parties). This relationship is covered in May’s preferences) they will make decisions about
law (see May, 1973) and in economic theo- what a gain in office positions is worth in
ries of party organization. Although politi- terms of policy concessions, and vice versa.
cians may become less radical and trustful in Policy and office are party goals that are
ideologically derived quick-fix solutions on typically at stake in government formation
their way up the career ladder due to contacts situations. Yet, such negotiations also occur
with other elites and experience, some of in the shadow of future elections, and past
their initial motivation is likely to remain. elections provide cues as to how the voters
Moreover, typically career politicians need will react to party moves. Hence, party lead-
the approval of their rank-and-file for re- ers try to anticipate whether their actions will
nomination as candidates for public office be rewarded or punished by the voters. The
and hence need to please them (Luebbert, empirical record suggests that most parties
1986). At the same time, politicians know are punished for being in government (Narud
that voters normally do not care about them and Valen, 2008). Thus, leaders taking their
having well-paid and otherwise attractive party to government are either ready to suffer
jobs but about the policy outputs of govern- some electoral losses as a price for govern-
ment. As Laver (1997) argues, ‘even politi- ment office, or they are overly optimistic that
cians who personally have no interest their skills will help them avoid this fate.
whatsoever in the policy packages they pro- Indeed, some parties maintain or even
mote for purely entrepreneurial reasons do increase their electoral base while in govern-
have some incentive to honour such promises ment. Of course, electoral results are also
when they have the opportunity to do so’ influenced by other factors that can neither
(p. 136). And politicians have an incentive to be anticipated nor influenced by serving in
implement these packages, ‘almost as if they government. Knowing that the future is
really do care about them, when they become uncertain, party leaders may go for immedi-
incumbents’ (Laver, 1997: 136). The emerg- ate rewards (Lupia and Strøm, 2008).
ing consensus in coalition studies thus is that While the introduction of policy as a driv-
policy is indeed important, either because ing force of coalition formation has made the
politicians genuinely care or because they are basic assumptions of coalition theory more
aware that the voters will sanction them if realistic, it also has added considerable theo-
they do not live up to their promises. retical and empirical challenges. If we were

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 233

able to locate each party’s policy preferences cover the smallest policy range of all poten-
precisely on some metric, and if we leave tial ‘connected winning’ coalitions (Axelrod,
aside other party goals, it is only in the one- 1970). In de Swaan’s (1973) terms, this is
dimensional policy space that we can predict almost identical with the ‘closed minimal
the outcome of government formation proc- range’ theory. According to de Swaan (1985:
esses precisely. Once we move to two or 249), who satisfied himself with ordinal
more relevant policy dimensions, a weight- policy scales, the ‘closed minimal winning’
ing problem emerges. If, for instance, eco- (or ‘minimal connected winning’) theory is
nomic and foreign policy issues divide the the best one. It did not perform so well, how-
parties, how do they weigh in? And, to make ever, in the eight-country study of Laver and
things more complicated, the answers may Budge (1992).
differ from party to party and over time. Most recently, Warwick (2000, 2006) has
Assuming that all policy dimensions are introduced the idea that political parties work
equally important to all parties does not with distinct policy thresholds. They are will-
really help, as we then face a situation in ing to engage in coalitions only until their
which coalition formation becomes unpre- ‘policy horizon’ is reached, that is the point
dictable (and coalitions unstable) once a where the policy costs from making conces-
minimum of three dimensions are involved sions to the coalition partners become too
(McKelvey, 1979). large. As Warwick (2006: 175) puts it, the
Notwithstanding these difficulties, coali- paradox of the policy horizon hypothesis is
tion theorists have formulated a number of that it ‘is so simple to state and yet so diffi-
specific policy-based theories of government cult to test’. Indeed, his test using party
formation. In one dimensional policy space manifesto data to derive both the party and
the powerful median voter theorem (Black, the government positions seems to involve a
1958) leads us to expect the median party in good dose of circularity. To be sure, Warwick
parliament to play a dominant role (de Swaan, (2006) also draws on an expert survey and
1973; Laver and Schofield, 1990: 110–3). If simulations and marshals evidence ‘that is
political parties were motivated by policy consistent with the existence of horizons’.
exclusively the median party could form a For the time being, however, we are left with
minority cabinet and still be a ‘policy dicta- a plausible hypothesis and enough support-
tor’ (Budge and Laver, 1993: 501). A more ing evidence that suggests that further inves-
realistic assumption is that median parties tigation may be worth the effort. Yet, even in
play a crucial role in government formation. the best of all worlds, policy horizons will
This means that they will typically partici- only help us understand which coalitions are
pate in government and do well with regard unfeasible and not which ones will be
to portfolio allocation and government policy. formed.
The assumption of a special role of the Finally, Laver and Shepsle (1990, 1996)
median party is indeed supported by all have theorized that institutional constraints
empirical analyses (see, e.g., Laver and force political parties to consider their coali-
Schofield, 1990; Martin and Stevenson, tion options as an ‘all or nothing’ choice of
2001; Mitchell and Nyblade, 2008; Müller government policy in each policy dimension.
and Strøm, 2000; Warwick, 1996; for a simi- This means that cabinet parties will get
lar concept see van Roozendaal, 1990). 100 per cent of their policy preferences in the
A number of theories are based on the idea domain of the government portfolios occu-
that coalition building aims at minimizing pied by their leaders but at the price of con-
the policy distance between the government ceding the same to their coalition partners
parties. One prominent case is the ‘minimal with regard to the other domains. This theory
connected winning’ coalition that is com- will also be discussed below. Here it is suf-
posed of adjacent parties that collectively ficient to say that a thorough cross-national

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


234 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

test is still beyond the means available to coalition research expert surveys involve the
empirical coalition researchers. Although danger of circular reasoning: when actual
portfolio allocation theory certainly contains coalition behaviour influences the perception
a kernel of truth, the overwhelming tenor is of party distances then these results cannot be
that the underlying assumption of ‘coalitions used for predicting coalition behaviour
that cannot coalesce’ (Dunleavy with Bastow, (Budge, 2000). These are just a few of the
2001) is too radical and does not meet the problems associated with the two most impor-
experience of coalition governance in Western tant methods employed in the generation of
Europe (see the contributions of country party positions (see Laver, 2001 and Marks,
experts in Laver and Shepsle, 1994; Müller 2007 for a fuller discussion). Of course, the
and Strøm, 2000). solution is not to abandon these methods, but
Notwithstanding the differences between to improve on their practice, combine them,
the specific policy-based coalition theories and check their results with other evidence
and the precise dependent variable, multi- where it is available (e.g., political elites sur-
variate tests generally show that policy veys). And while we have better data now
outperforms office (size) in explaining gov- than the pioneers of policy-based coalition
ernment formation (Franklin and Mackie, theory, we should be aware that our measures
1984; Martin and Stevenson, 2001). of party policy positions are approximations
Finally, unlike size-based theories, the test- only, and at times very rough ones.
ing of coalition theories based on policy pref-
erences involves considerable measurement
problems. In recent years the comparative Non-cooperative game theory
literature has employed party documents, in
and institutions
particular electoral manifestos (Laver and
Budge, 1992), and expert surveys (Benoit and Coalition theory started out as a branch of
Laver, 2006; Laver and Hunt, 1992; Warwick, cooperative game theory. In a cooperative game
2006). Both methods are certainly better than the inherent logic is to create the coalition that
the party family and literature extraction provides the biggest reward for its members
approaches that were characteristic of early collectively. For that purpose they communi-
attempts to place political parties on policy cate and can make agreements that are binding
scales. Yet, both have their own pitfalls. On and enforceable (i.e., a non-specified third
the practical side, the identification, location, power is assumed to enforce the deal on its
and coding of relevant party documents partners). Most important coalition studies dis-
requires country knowledge and language cussed above employ cooperative game theory.
skills. In practice, the most similar docu- Yet, cooperative game theory has largely given
ments, the parties’ electoral manifestos, vary way to non-cooperative game theory. Rather
considerable in comprehensiveness. Much of than assuming that actors cooperate in the pro-
the party placements depends on the coding duction of the maximum total payoff, non-
scheme and the actual coding, and concerns cooperative game theory focuses on the
have been raised over both issues (Laver, strategies of individual actors and the pay-
2001; Benoit and Laver, 2007). Expert sur- offs they receive. A coalition thus forms
veys delegate the ‘coding decisions’ to the when it provides the best outcome each of its
experts who fill in the questionnaires and thus partners can achieve individually, acting
replace the explicit and traceable choices that unilaterally. Agreements between the players
characterize content analysis by undocu- are not considered enforceable a priori.
mented processes in the brains of the respond- Rather the enforcement mechanism itself is
ents. While sufficient numbers of respondents part of the game (Morrow, 1994: 75–6;
allow the calculation of statistical error Ritzberger, 2002: 7–8). What is enforceable in
terms, the fact remains that in the context of coalition formations strongly depends on the

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 235

institutions regulating the government taking political science, Norman Schofield (1993:
office. Consequently, analyses employing non- 13). One of the consequences of great model-
cooperative game theory explicitly model the ling complexity is that thus far only games in
impact of institutions. Coalition formation stud- systems with three parties have been mod-
ies in this tradition are explicit about the conse- elled which often do not constitute the most
quences of, for instance, recognition rules (the thrilling environment for coalition theory.
choice of formateur), the sequence in which Second, ‘predictions from such institution-
parties assume this role, the existence of inves- ally rich models tend to be highly sensitive to
titure votes, and government accountability to the institutional detail’ (Austen-Smith, 1996:
second chambers (Austen-Smith and Banks, 235). This has two consequences: (a) small
1988; Baron, 1991, 1993; Diermeier et al., changes in the model often have large conse-
2003; 2006). Actors base their strategies on the quences for predictions; and (b) small devia-
calculation of the reversion outcome (i.e., what tions of real institutions from those assumed
will happen if a bargain fails). In the words of in the model often render the model irrele-
Baron (1991), ‘whether a bargain will be struck vant for the empirical case. For these reasons
depends on the expectations that all parties it is problematic to generalize the results
have about what will happen if they fail to derived from such models beyond their pre-
reach an agreement on the present attempt’ cise specification. Third, some of the common
(p. 139). Several of the studies cited here do not assumptions in these theories are at odds
just focus on the legislative game at govern- with the reality of coalition politics, for
ment formation stage but also integrate elec- instance that the players in this game have
toral politics, while Baron (1998) extends his full and perfect information (e.g., Austen-
analysis to the life-time of coalitions in an infi- Smith and Banks, 1988; Baron, 1991, 1993;
nitely repeated game. Baron and Diermeier, 2001). Fourth, progress
While the bulk of the formal coalition lit- in game-theoretic modelling has remained
erature considers coalition formation as a relatively divorced from empirical research.
legislative bargaining game, Laver and This is partly due to the fact that many game-
Shepsle (1990; 1996) build their approach on theoretic models require empirical data that
the insight that government coalitions are very is hard (if not impossible) to provide.
distinct from legislative voting alliances.4 Moreover, many game theorists fail to con-
They assume that cabinet ministers have front their models with empirical data. The
monopolistic control over their portfolios. work of Daniel Diermeier and colleagues is a
Hence, as noted above, the policy in each notable exception to this rule (see Diermeier
policy domain will fully represent the ideal and Merlo, 2004; Diermeier et al., 2003;
policy of the minister’s party. While in legis- 2006).
lative bargaining there is an infinite number All this is not to say that formal modelling
of policy points, in the portfolio allocation of government formation should be aban-
approach of Laver and Shepsle the number of doned. On the contrary, this approach has
possible policy points is reduced to those great potential and it would be wrong to
represented by the parties in the game. overlook the impressive progress coalition
And rational parties, of course, chose the theories based on non-cooperative game
government that allows them to maximize theory have made in the few years since this
their gains. tradition was established. Yet, because of the
Coalition theories based on non-cooperative limitations of even the most sophisticated
game theory have the virtue that the theory is non-cooperative game theoretic models our
very precisely formulated. This precision is understanding of coalition formation has
not free of costs, however. First, such theo- greatly benefited from empirical studies of
ries tend to be ‘very complicated’, to quote institutional factors in government formation
one of the foremost formal theorists in without explicit game-theoretic foundations.

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


236 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Examples constitute the work of Torbjörn (including Israel). Warwick (1996: 478) drew
Bergman (1993) on cabinet formation rules on 310 cabinets in 16 post-war West European
and ‘negative’ versus ‘positive’ parliamen- democracies and Mitchell and Nyblade
tarism, and Strøm, Budge, and Laver’s (1994) (2008) worked with data from 424 cabinets
seminal article on (mostly institutional) con- in 17 post-war West European democracies
straints on government formation. More (including systems that have no experience
recently, the impact of second chambers on with coalition government). Volden and
government formation has been empirically Carrubba (2004) used annual data to increase
scrutinized (Druckman et al., 2005; Druckman the number of cases. The breakdown of
and Thies, 2002). The most comprehensive Communism in Eastern Europe has greatly
survey of the relevance of institutional fac- increased the number of stable parliamentary
tors in coalition politics can be found in democracies and hence the number of cases
Strøm et al. (2003, 2008). relevant to coalition formation studies. As
yet, this potential has hardly been used.
Studying government formation, however,
is no straightforward task as several depend-
EMPIRICAL RESEARCH ON ent variables can be at the centre stage.
COALITION FORMATION Government type is the most basic choice.
We can distinguish cabinets based on politi-
cal parties and non-partisan ones, majority
Quantitative comparative studies
and minority cabinets, single-party govern-
The dominant line in empirical coalition ments and coalitions, and various types of
studies assembles cross-national datasets and coalitions (minimal winning and surplus,
employs increasingly sophisticated inference etc.) (Mitchell and Nyblade, 2008). Cabinet
statistics. All specific empirical results that composition in many cases is a more demand-
were referred to in the preceding section ing dependent variable, as it requires predict-
emerged from this research tradition. The ing the precise party composition of
relevant studies differ in their relative government (Martin and Stevenson, 2001).
emphasis on testing coalition theory and Finally, the analysis can settle with predict-
explaining the outcome of government for- ing the cabinet membership of individual
mations. Typically, authors who conduct parties. Warwick (1996) aims at identifying
empirical analysis to test their own theory both successful formateur parties and mere
put a premium on the former. cabinet membership. Another line of research
Quantitative studies aim at maximizing the focuses on the formation process, in particu-
number of roughly comparable observations lar its duration and the number of formation
in order to control for as many factors as pos- attempts (De Winter and Dumont, 2008;
sible. The number of stable parliamentary Diermeier and van Roozendaal, 1998; Golder,
democracies and years of observation were 2006; Martin and Vanberg, 2003).
relatively small when the first studies were Without doubt the quantitative cross-
conducted in the 1970s. Browne (1970) had national study of coalition formation displays
to satisfy himself with 125 coalitions in 13 virtues any academic discipline is search-
countries while Taylor and Laver (1973) were ing for: steady progress and cumulation, thus
confined to data from 132 coalitions in 12 each generation could build on the achieve-
countries. More recent researchers have ben- ments of the previous ones rather than starting
efited from the ceaseless march of time that anew. At the same time it is clear that a con-
has multiplied the number of formation situa- siderable agenda still lies ahead. And, indeed,
tions. Thus, Martin and Stevenson (2001: 34) impatient observers see ‘major shortcomings’
could base their study on 220 coalition bar- (De Winter and Dumont, 2006: 180). As De
gaining situations in 14 post-war democracies Winter and Dumont (2006) put it, ‘existing

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 237

theories do not predict and therefore suffi- explanation thus requires country-knowledge
ciently explain a significant proportion of and in-depth studies. The more peculiar an
cabinet compositions formed in the real outcome is, the greater the advantage of such
world’ (p. 180). These authors are not at ease studies (Gerring, 2006).
with the best result – Martin and Stevenson Quantitative coalition studies, regardless of
(2001) predicting close to half of the real- their independent variable, indeed have regu-
world coalitions correctly – because ‘this is larly identified substantial country effects.
done by lumping together two dozen variables According to Franklin and Mackie (1984), size
drawn from three main schools’, with the and ideology perform very differently across
consequence of lacking ‘parsimony and inter- countries in predicting coalition formation.
nal consistency’. While this judgement may Estimating their regressions separately for each
be too harsh, it makes clear that quantitative of three groups of countries, these authors
comparative studies have their limits and almost doubled the explained variance.
should be supplemented with studies from Similarly, Grofman (1989) concluded that some
other traditions. of the best-supported results in coalition
research do not apply within most countries,
but stem from the composition of the cross-
national samples (with countries being repre-
Single country studies
sented by substantially different numbers of
Single country studies constitute the second cabinets). Proper explanations should work
major genre of the coalition literature.5 In the both between and within countries. From the
first comprehensive attempt at country-specific high country-sensitivity of such results Michael
analysis of coalition politics – coalition forma- Laver, writing in the mid-1980s, arrived at a
tions, the distribution of portfolios, and the end radical conclusion: ‘at this stage in our under-
of coalition cabinets – Browne and Dreijmanis standing of the coalitional process, to conduct
(1982) explain that it was motivated by the gap anything other than a country-specific analysis
between game theoretical and cross-national of the phenomena involved is to do great vio-
empirical studies of coalitions, with the lence to reality’ (Laver, 1986: 33).
‘repeated failure’ of the latter ‘to provide con- For all these reasons single-country stud-
vincing support for the derived implications of ies have remained important in coalition
formal coalition theories’ (p. 356). In providing research. They make at least four important
single-country studies they aimed at adding ‘a contributions to the development of coalition
‘flesh and blood’ dimension to coalition stud- research. First, country studies with a uni-
ies’ (p. 1). In the Conclusion, Browne (1982) form format are an important means for
claims ‘what is needed is to orient theoretical generating data that can also be employed in
work more directly towards the contexts in comparative analyses. For one thing there are
which they are applied’ (p. 356). This tradition practical reasons that suggest such a strategy,
of research thus aims at a configurative under- as no single researcher can ever hope to
standing of coalition politics. The underlying master the complexities of coming to grips
assumption is that history, the specific configu- with national sources as a team of country
ration of political institutions (rather than indi- specialists (see Strøm et al., 2008).
vidual institutional features), and perhaps the Data rarely speaks for itself. Therefore, it is
personalities of key actors are crucial for a full often equally important that country specialists
explanation of coalition politics. While many of interpret the data and employ it in configurative
these factors can be coded and quantified, little analysis, drawing on all kinds of other informa-
but important differences (e.g., in institu- tion (that may exist for no other country). Such
tional rules) and their great number makes country-specific analysis has proved useful
the translation of ‘country’ into analytical even in the case of a very standardized overall
categories a hopeless task. A configurative research design, such as the Comparative

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


238 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Manifesto Project’s inquiry into the world governance mechanisms that is detailed in
of coalition politics (Laver and Budge, Müller and Strøm (2000) and used in com-
1992). While it is not possible to translate parative analysis in Strøm, et al. (2008) repre-
all the insights from in-depth country analysis sents the collective experience of country
into variables employed in comparative quanti- specialists who spent some time on identify-
tative studies, the country studies remain a ing and defining the relevant mechanisms.
treasure trove for understanding ‘anomalies’
and outliers in cross-national analysis. This is
the second contribution of country studies Case studies
towards the development of the coalition
studies field. Case studies of specific government forma-
Third, identifying outliers and forces that tions push the idea of an intensive research
are behind such placement in a comparative design one step further. Episodes of govern-
mapping can serve the refinement of the initial ment formation are often crucial pathways in
theoretical argument. Interesting cases are the life of a nation and for that reason merit
countries that routinely appoint non-minimal close study. Yet, to be useful for coalition
and non-minimum cabinets – such as Austria theory, such studies need to be theoretically
and Italy (Mershon, 2002; Müller, 2000; informed and they should be explicit about
Pridham, 1988) – and countries that tend to their contribution towards evaluating and,
have minority cabinets – such as the perhaps, refining, theoretical claims. A case
Scandinavian countries (Strøm, 1986). Another study, of course, is confined to what typically
way country studies can contribute to the is just one data point (observation) in quanti-
refinement of theory is checking their underly- tative coalition studies. The genuine con-
ing assumptions. Laver and Shepsle’s portfolio tribution it can make is providing a
allocation theory, for instance, was first pre- mechanism-based explanation of the case.
sented in a radical version (1990). These Quantitative studies typically are ‘black-box
authors then assembled a group of country explanations’ in the sense that the link
specialists who discussed the plausibility of between explanans and explanandum is theo-
their major assumption – that of ministers as retically stated and proven by (statistically
policy dictators within their portfolio – on the controlled) co-variation (Hedström and
basis of all evidence available for the respec- Swedberg, 1998). Good case studies can
tive country (see the country chapters in Laver show whether the theorized mechanism
and Shepsle, 1994). While Laver and Shepsle indeed works. In other words, it can check
(1996) in their final version of the portfolio whether the theorized ‘intermediary process’
allocation theory tended to give more weight by which a causal relationship links inputs
to the country evidence that supported their and outputs indeed takes place and, if not,
theorizing, they made good use of the country what an alternative mechanism may be (cf.
experts’ input in somewhat deradicalizing Gerring, 2005, 2007). To achieve that case
their claim. For instance, the minister as studies must typically draw on primary data
‘policy dictator’ (1990: 888) has given way to such as interviews with key actors, position
a more nuanced treatment (1996: 30–33). papers, letters exchanged in negotiations, and
The fourth vital contribution of country perhaps minutes of inter- or intra-party meet-
studies lies in their role in pushing forward the ings. Such sources do not always exist, if
research agenda. Often novel ideas emerge they exist it requires skill to locate them, and
from the close scrutiny of individual cases. even then access often is hard to achieve.
The relevance of the institutional rules of gov- To be sure, even the best qualitative research
ernment formation, for instance, emerged may never be able to identify the most inner
from the study of the Swedish case (Bergman, motivations of individuals. Yet, resource-rich
1993, 1995). And the full menu of coalition and well-executed case studies can move us

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 239

sufficiently close to understanding the true primary sources are often not interested in and
causal mechanisms at work in government knowledgeable of general theories, and vice
formation situations. versa. Another reason is that the incentives in
Such accounts can also take the form of the publication and citation business are at odds
analytical narratives, which by employing with the production of case studies. Yet, all
game-theoretic models marry the narrative those capable of producing such studies should
account with ‘parsimony, refinement, and (in remind themselves that even a study of what
the sense used by mathematicians) elegance’ might be considered a ‘non-event’ – a failed
(Bates et al., 1998: 11). As Bates (2007) attempt to unseat a government in a small
argues, game-theoretic modelling itself country – can be published in the discipline’s
‘should be shaped by the understandings most prestigious journal when it is masterly
achieved through fieldwork and by the materi- done (Strøm, 1994).
als mobilized in thick descriptions’ (p. 175). While case studies can fulfil these tasks
Thus, on the one hand game-theoretic model- standing alone, it is perhaps most rewarding
ling can only benefit from ‘intimate knowl- to include them in a ‘nested’ research design
edge of the key players and the strategic (Lieberman, 2005), meaning that the analysis
environment that they inhabit’ (p. 175). In the moves back and forth between quantitative
terms of Bates (2007) such knowledge pro- and case analysis. Bäck and Dumont (2007)
vides a ‘bullshit meter’, that allows the ana- have produced the first such analysis in coali-
lyst to distinguish arguments ‘that offer tion research.
traction from those that are merely clever’
(p. 174). On the other hand, carefully exe-
cuted case studies can serve as tests of game-
theoretic models by exposing the mechanisms CONCLUSION
at work in decision-making processes. Case
studies are an excellent tool to check argu- This chapter has reviewed the literature of
ments about the sequence of moves (Büthe, government formation in systems that are
2002), signalling, and the relevance of nested parliamentary and multi-party. In such
games (Tsebelis, 1990). systems elections typically result in minor-
The rich potential of case study research has ity situations. Then inter-party bargaining
not yet been fully used in coalition studies. decides on government formation and often,
Hardly anything has been published in interna- though not invariably, the outcome is coali-
tional journals and only two efforts have been tion government. Among social science
made to assemble relevant case studies for research fields, the study of government coa-
some analytic purpose. The studies in Müller lition is certainly a showpiece. Since the
and Strøm (1999) focus on cases involving beginning of political science research into
trade-offs of party goals and hence force politi- that subject in the early 1960s important and
cal parties to chose. While the relevant cases steady progress has been made. This chapter
here are overwhelmingly, but not exclusively, has also shown that this progress results from
government formations, the case studies assem- the interplay of game-theoretic work, quanti-
bled by Andeweg et al. (2009) focus on com- tative comparative analyses, and single-coun-
plex government formation processes, that is try studies. Yet, the review has demonstrated
processes that are characterized by long dura- that we still have to travel quite a distance to
tion and/or failed attempts. Interesting as these make the state of the art truly satisfying. In
studies are, they represent no more than a the remainder of this chapter, I will suggest a
beginning. There are plausible reasons for this few avenues that seem particularly promising
underdevelopment of a potentially very fruitful for a better understanding of government
angle of coalition research. One is that those formation. These relate to extensions of the
scholars who are most familiar with the relevant scope of analyses, improvements of research

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


240 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

methods, and innovations in terms of new or Finally, what novel perspectives should be
refined research questions. taken up in research on government forma-
As noted above, coalition research has tion? It is the very nature of true innovation
been constrained by the fact that government that it is more difficult to foreshadow than it
formations are not that numerous. While the is to make extensions and improvements. Yet,
situation has improved though the ceaseless there are two analytical perspectives that
march of time, the third wave of democrati- have been around as ideas and desiderata for
zation has provided a huge and as yet hardly a long time but which may now be attracting
used range of new democracies to which serious efforts to translate them into rigorous
coalition research should be extended. These theorizing and empirical research. One is the
systems would not only increase the N of insight that coalition formation ought to be
coalition studies but also add historical, insti- understood dynamically (Laver, 1974, 1986).
tutional, and behavioural variance that can be Rather than treating each government forma-
fruitfully exploited in statistical analysis. tion as an isolated event, it should be viewed
Bringing in new cases, of course, also raises as part of two cycles. One is the ‘big’ cycle
the demand for country studies for all the that connects one government with its pred-
reasons given above. ecessor and successor (cf. Franklin and
Throughout its history coalition research Mackie, 1983). The other one is the ‘smaller’
was good at adopting and at times encourag- cycle that connects the various stages coali-
ing improvements in methods and data. As tions go through – formation, governance,
noted above, coalition studies – as all other and termination. These phenomena are typi-
research fields working with party positions cally researched in mutual isolation rather
data – must rely on data that is less precise than understood in their mutual causality.
than we ideally would want to. While the This is the perspective advanced in Strøm
method that would merit redoing the huge et al. (2008), but much remains to be done.
amount of work that has gone into the CMP Another long-term critique of coalition
data is yet to emerge, attempts at developing research is its exclusive focus on inter-party
such measures and first applying them to relations. While this choice can be defended
small samples clearly should be encouraged. (see Laver and Schofield, 1990, Chapter 2), it
Government formation constitutes a natural does considerable violence to reality (see
testing ground for alternative preference Luebbert, 1986; Müller and Strøm, 1999).
measures. Another issue is the choice of Renewed interest in the role of intra-party
research strategy. As noted above, the poten- politics in coalitions (Giannetti and Benoit,
tial of case study research currently is under- 2008) may indicate that what is ahead of us
used in the discipline’s attempts at is the nested analysis of intra- and inter-party
understanding government formation. Yet, politics in government formation (and prob-
the passing of time since the inception of ably even more so at other stages of the coali-
coalition studies not only provides new cases tion life cycle).
but also opens the gates of archives. We can
expose those government formations to close
scrutiny based on primary sources that per- NOTES
haps have influenced the reasoning of early
coalition theorists and that have figured in 1. The initial endowment normally is equated with
quantitative analysis since ever. It would be the ‘mechanical’ bargaining power of parties – as
measured by voting power indices. Alternatively, we
a pity, if political science would leave this
could think about ‘directional’ bargaining power of
opportunity to professional historians, who parties, resulting from their belonging to the winners
are unlikely to ask the questions relevant to or losers of the elections (see Mattila and Raunio,
coalition theory. 2004).

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 241

2. Other surveys of coalition studies, not always


Bäck, H. and Dumont, P. (2007) ‘Combining
confined to government formation, include
Bandyopadhyay and Chatterjee (2006), De Winter
large-n and small-n strategies: The way
and Dumont (2006), Diermeier (2006), Laver (1998), forward in coalition research’, West European
Laver and Schofield (1990), Strøm et al. (2008), Politics, 30 (3): 467–501.
Strøm and Nyblade (2007). Bandyopadhyay, S. and Chatterjee, K. (2006)
3. Volden and Carrubba (2004: 521) interpret ‘Coalition theory and its applications:
Riker’s ‘minimum winning’ criterion as meaning the A survey’, Economic Journal, 116 (509):
minimum number of parties. To the best of my F136–F155.
knowledge this is the only interpretation of Riker’s Baron, D.P. (1991) ‘A spatial bargaining theory
size principle; ‘coalitions just as large as they [the of government formation in a parliamentary
participants] believe will ensure winning and no
system’, American Political Science Review,
larger’ (Riker, 1962: 47) as referring to parties rather
than parliamentary seats. After all, parliamentary
85 (1): 137–64.
seats are the decisive resource for winning in govern- Baron, D.P. (1993) ‘Government formation and
ment formation games. Nevertheless, the number of endogenous parties’, American Political
parties in a coalition is a powerful predictor that was Science Review, 87 (1): 33–47.
introduced by Leiserson (1966: 313; 1968: 775). Baron, D.P. (1998) ‘Comparative dynamics of
4. Austen-Smith and Banks (1990) have devel- parliamentary governments’, American
oped a model that builds on essentially the same Political Science Review, 92 (3): 593–609.
basic idea. Baron, D.P. and Diermeier, D. (2001) ‘Elections,
5. The volumes of Bogdanor (1983), Browne and governments, and parliaments in propor-
Dreijmanis (1982), Groennings et al. (1970), Laver
tional representation systems’, Quarterly
and Budge (1992), Laver and Shepsle (1994), Müller
and Strøm (2000) and Pridham (1986), contain more
Journal of Economics, 116 (3): 933–67.
or less standardized country studies. Bates, R.H. (2007) ‘From case studies to social
science: A strategy for political research’, in
C. Boix and S. C. Stokes (eds), The Oxford
handbook of comparative politics. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, pp. 172–85.
REFERENCES Bates, R.H., Greif, A., Levi, M., Rosenthal, J.-L.,
and Weingast, B.R. (1998) Analytical narra-
Adrian, C.R. and Press, C. (1968) ‘Decision tives. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
costs in coalition formation’, American Press.
Political Science Review, 62 (2): 556–63. Benoit, K. and Laver, M. (2006) Party policy in
Amorim Neto, O. (2006) ‘The presidential cal- modern democracies. London: Routlege.
culus: Executive policy making and cabinet Benoit, K. and Laver, M. (2007) ‘Estimating
formation in the Americas’, Comparative party policy positions: Comparing expert
Political Studies, 39 (4): 415–40. surveys and hand-coded content analysis’,
Andeweg, R.B., De Winter, L., and Dumont, P. Electoral Studies, 26 (1): 90–107.
(eds) (2009) Puzzles of government forma- Bergman, T. (1993) ‘Formation rules and minor-
tion. London: Routledge. ity governments’, European Journal of
Austen-Smith, D. (1996) ‘Refinements of the Political Research, 23 (1): 55–66.
heart’, in N. Schofield (ed.), Collective deci- Bergman, T. (1995) Constitutional rules and
sion-making: Social choice and political party goals in coalition formation. Umeå:
economy. Boston, MA: Kluwer, pp. 221–36. Umeå University.
Austen-Smith, D. and Banks, J. (1988) ‘Elections, Black, D. (1958) The theory of committees and
coalitions and legislative outcomes’, American elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Political Science Review, 82 (2): 405–22. Press.
Austen-Smith, D. and Banks, J. (1990) ‘Stable Bogdanor, V. (ed.) (1983) Coalition government
governments and the allocation of policy in Western Europe. London: Heineman.
portfolios’, American Political Science Review, Browne, E.C. (1970) Coalition theories: A logical
84 (3): 891–906. and empirical critique. Beverly Hills: Sage.
Axelrod, R. (1970) Conflict of interest. Chicago: Browne, E.C. (1982) ‘Conclusion: considerations
Markham. on the construction of a theory of cabinet

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


242 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

coalition behavior’, in Browne, E.C. Browne, de Swaan, A. (1985) ‘Coalition theory


and J. Dreijmanis, (eds) Government coali- and multi-party systems’, in H.A.M. Wilke
tions in Western democracies. New York: (ed.), Coalition formation. Amsterdam:
Longman, pp. 335–57. North-Holland, 229–60.
Browne, E.C. and Dreijmanis, J. (eds) (1982) De Winter, L. and Dumont, P. (2006) ‘Parties
Government coalitions in Western democra- into government: Still many puzzler’, in R.S.
cies. New York: Longman. Katz and W. Crotty (eds), Handbook of party
Budge, I. (2000) ‘Expert judgements of party politics. London: Sage, pp. 175–88.
policy positions: Uses and limitations in De Winter, L. and Dumont, P. (2008) ‘Uncertainty
political research’, European Journal of and complexity in cabinet formation’, in
Political Research, 37 (1): 103–13. K. Strøm, W.C. Müller, and T. Bergman (eds),
Budge, I. and Herman, V. (1978) ‘Coalitions Cabinets and coalition bargaining: The demo-
and government formation: An empirically cratic life cycle in Western Europe. Oxford:
relevant theory’, British Journal of Political Oxford University Press, pp. 123–57.
Science, 8 (4): 459–77. Diermeier, D. (2006) ‘Coalition government’, in
Budge, I. and Keman, H. (1990) Parties and B.R. Weingast and D.A. Wittman (eds), The
democracy: Coalition formation and govern- Oxford handbook of political economy.
ment functioning in twenty states. Oxford: Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 162–79.
Oxford University Press. Diermeier, D. and Merlo, A. (2004) 'An empri-
Budge, I., Klingemann, H.-D., Volkens, A., cal investigation of coalition bargaining pro-
Bara, J., and Tannenbaum, E. (2001) Mapping cedures', Journal of Public Economics, 88
policy preferences. Estimates for parties, (4–5): 783–97.
electors, and governments 1945–1998. Diermeier, D., Merlo, A., and Eraslan, H. (2002)
Oxford: Oxford University Press. ‘Coalition government and comparative con-
Budge, I. and Laver, M. (1986) ‘Office seeking stitutional design’, European Economic
and policy pursuit in coalition theory’, Legislative Review, 46 (4–5): 893–907.
Studies Quarterly, 11 (4): 485–506. Diermeier, D., Merlo, A., and Eraslan, H. (2003)
Budge, I. and Laver, M. (1993) ‘The policy basis of ‘A structural model of government forma-
government coalitions: A comparative investi- tion’, Econometrica, 71 (1): 27–70.
gation’, British Journal of Political Science, 23 Diermeier, D., Merlo, A., and Eraslan, H. (2006)
(4): 499–519. ‘The effects of constitutions on coalition
Budge, I., Robertson, D., and Hearl, D. (1987) governments in parliamentary democracies’,
Ideology, strategy, and party change: Spatial in R.C. Congleton and B. Swedenborg
analyses of post-war election programmes in (eds), Democratic constitutional design and
19 democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge public policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
University Press. pp.133–61.
Büthe, T. (2002) ‘Taking temporality serious: Diermeier, D. and van Roozendaal, P. (1998)
Modeling history and the use of narratives as ‘The duration of cabinet formation processes
evidence’, American Political Science Review, in Western multi-party democracies’, British
96 (3): 481–93. Journal of Political Science, 28 (4): 609–26.
Cheibub, J.A., Przeworski, A., and Saiegh, Dodd, L.C. (1976) Coalitions in parliamentary
S. (2004) ‘Government coalitions under government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
parliamentarism and presidentialism’, University Press.
British Journal of Political Science, 34: Druckman, J.N., Martin, L., and Thies, M.
565–87. (2005) ‘Influence without confidence: upper
Cox, G.W. and Morgensten, C. (2002) ‘Epilogue: chambers and government formation’,
Latin America's reactive assemblies and proac- Legislative Studies Quarterly, 30 (4):
tive presidents', in C. Morgenstern, and 529–48.
N. Benito, (eds) Legislative politics in Latin Druckman, J.N. and Thies, M.F. (2002) ‘The
America. Cambridge: Cambridge University importance of concurrence: The impact of
Press, pp. 446–68. bicameralism on government formation and
de Swaan, A. (1973) Coalition theories and duration’, American Journal of Political
cabinet formations. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Science, 46 (4): 760–71.

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 243

Dunleavy, P. with Bastow, S. (2001) ‘Modelling Klingemann, H.-D., Volkens, A., Bara, J., Budge, I.,
coalitions that cannot coalesce: A critique of and McDonald, M.D. (2006) Mapping policy
the Laver-Shepsle approach’, West European preferences II. Oxford: Oxford University
Politics, 24 (1): 1–26. Press.
Franklin, M.N. and Mackie, T.T. (1983) Laver, M. (1974) ‘Dynamic factors in govern-
‘Familiarity and inertia in the formation of ment coalition formation’, European Journal
governing coalitions in parliamentary democ- of Political Research, 2 (3): 259–70.
racies’, British Journal of Political Science, 13 Laver, M. (1986) ‘Between theoretical elegance
(3): 275–98. and political reality: Deductive models and
Franklin, M.N. and Mackie, T.T. (1984) cabinet coalitions in Europe’, in G. Pridham
‘Reassessing the importance of size and (ed.), Coalition behaviour in theory and prac-
ideology for the formation of government tice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
coalitions in parliamentary democracies’, pp. 32–44.
American Journal of Political Science, 28 (4): Laver, M. (1995) ‘Review of Ian Budge and
671–92. Hans Keman, Parties and democracy:
Gamson, W.A. (1961) ‘A theory of coalition Coalition formation and government func-
formation’, American Sociological Review, tioning in twenty states’, Party Politics, 1 (2):
26: 373–82. 290–93.
Gerring, J. (2005) ‘Causation: A unified frame- Laver, M. (1997) Private desires, political action.
work for the social sciences’, Journal of London: Sage.
Theoretical Politics, 17 (2): 163–98. Laver, M. (1998) ‘Models of government for-
Gerring, J. (2006) ‘Single-outcome studies’, mation’, Annual Review of Political Science,
International Sociology, 21 (5): 707–34. 1: 1–25.
Gerring, J. (2007) ‘The case study: What it Laver, M. (ed.) (2001) Estimating the policy
is and what it does’, in C. Boix and S.C. positions of political actors. London:
Stokes (eds), The Oxford handbook of com- Routledge.
parative politics. Oxford: Oxford University Laver, M. and Budge, I. (eds) (1992) Party
Press, pp. 90–122. policy and coalition government. London:
Giannetti, D. and Benoit, K. (eds) (2008) Intra- Macmillan.
party politics and coalition governments in Laver, M. and Hunt, B.W. (1992) Policy and
parliamentary democracies. London: party competition. New York, NY:
Routledge. Routledge.
Golder, S.N. (2006) The logic of pre-electoral Laver, M. and Schofield, N. (1990) Multiparty
coalition formation. Columbus, OH: Ohio government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
State University Press. Laver, M. and Shepsle, K.A. (1990) ‘Coalitions
Groennings, S., Kelley, E.W., and Leiserson, M. and cabinet government’, American Political
(Eds.) (1970) The study of coalition Science Review, 84 (3): 873–90.
behavior. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Laver, M. and Shepsle, K.A. (eds) (1994) Cabinet
Winston. ministers and parliamentary government.
Grofman, B. (1982) ‘A dynamic model of pro- Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
tocoalition formation in ideological n-space’, Laver, M. and Shepsle, K.A. (1996) Making and
Behavioral Science, 27 (1): 77–90. breaking governments: Cabinets and legisla-
Grofman, B. (1989) ‘The comparative analysis tures in parliamentary democracies.
of coalition formation and duration: distin- Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
guishing between-country and within- Leiserson, M. (1966) Coalitions in politics: A
country effects’, British Journal of Political theoretical and empirical study. (Ph.D. dis-
Science, 19 (2): 291–302. sertation, Yale University).
Hedström, P. and Swedberg, R. (eds) (1998) Leiserson, M. (1968) ‘Factions and coalitions in
Social mechanisms. Cambridge: Cambridge one-party Japan: An interpretation based on
University Press. the theory of games’, American Political
Jungar, A.-C. (2000) Surplus majority govern- Science Review, 62 (1): 70–87.
ment. A comparative study of Italy and Lieberman, E.S. (2005) ‘Nested analysis as a
Finland. Uppsala: Uppsla Universitet. mixed-method strategy for comparative

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


244 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

research’, American Political Science Review, Müller, W.C. (2000) ‘Austria: Tight coalitions
99: 435–52. and stable government’, Iin W.C. Müller and
Lijphart, A. (1999) Patterns of democracy. New K. Strøm (eds), Coalition governments in
Haven, CN: Yale University Press. Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University
Luebbert, G.M. (1986) Comparative democ- Press, pp. 86–125.
racy. Policymaking and governing coalitions Müller, W.C. and Strøm, K. (eds) (1999)
in Europe and Israel. New York: Columbia Policy, office, or votes? How political
University Press. parties in Western Europe make hard deci-
Lupia, A. and Strøm, K. (1995) ‘Coalition termi- sions. Cambridge: Cambridge University
nation and the strategic timing of parlimen- Press.
tary elections’, American Political Science Müller, W.C. and Strøm, K. (eds) (2000)
Review, 89 (3): 648–65. Coalition governments in Western Europe.
Lupia, A. and Strøm, K. (2008) ‘Bargaining, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
transaction costs, and coalition governance’, Narud, H.M. and Valen, H. (2008) ‘Coalition
in K. Strøm, W. C. Müller and T. Bergman membership and electoral performance in
(eds), Cabinets and coalition bargaining: The Western Europe’, in K. Strøm, W.C. Müller
democratic life cycle in Western Europe. and T. Bergmann (eds), Cabinets and coali-
Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 51–83. tion bargaining. The democratic life cycle in
Marks, G. (ed.) (2007) ‘Special symposium: Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University
Comparing measures of party positioning: Press, pp. 369–402.
Expert, manifesto, and survey data’, Electoral Poguntke, T. and Webb, P. (eds) (2005) The
Studies, 26 (1). presidentialization of politics. Oxford: Oxford
Martin, L.W. and Stevenson, R.T. (2001) University Press.
‘Government formation in parliamentary Pridham, G. (ed.) (1986) Coalition behaviour in
democracies’, American Journal of Political theory and practice: An inductive model for
Science, 45 (1): 33–50. Western Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge
Martin, L.W. and Vanberg, G. (2003) ‘Wasting University Press.
time? The impact of ideology and size on Pridham, G. (1988) Political parties and coali-
delay in coalition formation’, British Journal tional behaviour in Italy. London: Routledge.
of Political Science, 33 (2): 323–44. Riker, W.H. (1962) The theory of political
Mattila, M. and Raunio, T. (2004) ‘Does win- coalitions. New Haven, CN: Yale University
ning pay? Electoral success and government Press.
formation in 15 west European countries’, Riker, W.H. and Ordeshook, P.C. (1973) An
European Journal of Political Research, 43 introduction to positive political theory.
(2): 263–85. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
May, J.D. (1973) ‘Opinion structure of political Ritzberger, K. (2002) Foundations of non-
parties: The special law of curvilinear dispar- cooperative game theory. Oxford: Oxford
ity’, Political Studies, 21 (2): 135–51. University Press.
McKelvey, R.D. (1979) ‘General conditions for Schofield, N. (1993) ‘Political competition
global intransitives in formal voting models’, in multiparty coalition governments’, European
Econometrica, 47 (5): 1085–111. Journal of Political Research, 23 (1): 1–33.
Mershon, C. (2002) The costs of coalition. Schofield, N. (1995) ‘Coalition politics: A formal
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. model and empirical analysis’, Journal of
Mitchell, P.L. and Nyblade, B. (2008) Theoretical Politics, 7 (3): 245–81.
‘Government formation and cabinet type in Schofield, N. and Sened, I. (2006) Multiparty
parliamentary democracies’, in K. Strøm, W. democracy. Elections and legislative politics.
C. Müller, and T. Bergman (eds), Cabinets Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
and coalition bargaining: The democratic life Schumpeter, J.A. (1942) Capitalism, socialism
cycle in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford and democracy. New York: Harper &
University Press, pp. 782–802. Brothers.
Morrow, J.D. (1994) Game theory for political Sened, I. (1996) ‘A model of coalition forma-
scientists. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University tion: Theory and evidence’, Journal of Politics,
Press. 58 (2): 350–72.

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 18 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


GOVERNMENT FORMATION 245

Strøm, K. (1984) ‘Minority governments in Journal of Political Research, 1 (3):


parliamentary democracies: The rationality of 205–48.
nonwinning cabinet solutions’, Comparative Tsebelis, G. (1990) Nested games: Rational
Political Studies, 17 (2): 199–227. choice in comparative politics. Berkeley:
Strøm, K. (1986) ‘Deferred gratification and University of California Press.
minority governments in Scandinavia’, van Roozendaal, P. (1990) ‘Centre parties and
Legislative Studies Quarterly, 11 (4): 583–605. coalition cabinet formation: A game theo-
Strøm, K. (1990a) Minority government retic approach’, European Journal of Political
and majority rule. Cambridge: Cambridge Research, 18 (3): 324–48.
University Press. Verzichelli, L. (2008) ‘Portfolio allocation’, in
Strøm, K (1990b) ‘A behavioral theory of com- K. Strøm, W.C. Müller, and T. Bergman (eds),
petitive political parties’, American Journal of Cabinets and coalition bargaining: The dem-
Political Science, 34 (2): 565–98. ocratic life cycle in Western Europe. Oxford:
Strøm, K. (1994) ‘The Presthus debacle: Oxford University Press, pp. 237–67.
Intraparty politics and bargaining failure in Volden, C. and Carrubba, C.J. (2004) ‘The
Norway’, American Political Science Review, formation of oversized coalitions in parlia-
88 (1): 112–27. mentary democracies’, American Journal of
Strøm, K., Budge, I. and Laver, M.J. (1994) Political Science, 43 (3): 521–37.
‘Constraints on cabinet formation in parlia- von Beyme, K. (1983) ‘Governments, parlia-
mentary democracies’, American Journal of ments and the structure of power in political
Political Science, 38 (2): 303–35. parties’, in H. Daalder and P. Mair (eds),
Strøm, K., Müller, W.C. and Bergman, T. (eds) Western European party systems. London:
(2003) Delegation and accountability in par- Sage, pp. 341–67.
liamentary democracies. Oxford: Oxford von Neumann, J. and Morgenstern, O. (1953)
University Press. Theory of games and economic behavior.
Strøm, K., Müller, W.C. and Bergman, T. (eds) Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
(2008) Cabinets and coalition bargaining: The Warwick, P.V. (1996) ‘Coalition government
democratic life cycle in Western Europe. membership in west European parliamentary
Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 782–802. democracies’, British Journal of Political
Strøm, K. and Nyblade, B. (2007) ‘Coalition Science, 26 (4): 471–99.
theory and government formation’, in Warwick, P.V. (2000) ‘Policy horizons in west
C. Boix and S.C. Stokes (eds), The Oxford European parliamentary systems’, European
handbook of comparative politics. Oxford: Journal of Political Research, 38 (1): 37–61.
Oxford University Press. Warwick, P.V. (2006) Policy horizons and
Taylor, M. and Laver, M. (1973) ‘Government parliamentary government. Basingstoke:
coalitions in Western Europe’, European Palgrave Macmillan.

9781412919760_Chap12.indd 19 3/11/2009 4:06:18 PM


13
Institutional Design
Josep M. Colomer

INTRODUCTION
basically involves choices on voting and
Institutional design is the choice of rules for electoral rules. Many years ago, David Hume
collective decision-making. At the moment advised institutional designers with these
of designing institutions, two main questions words:
have to be addressed: who is entitled to par-
In contriving any system of government, and fixing
ticipate? and how will decisions be made? the several checks and controls of the constitution,
The first question points to the design of the every man ought to be supposed a knave, and to
community. Collective decisions can be have no other end, in all his actions, but private
enforceable if people within some bounda- interest. By this interest we must govern him and,
by means of it, make him cooperate to public
ries think or accept they share enough with
good, notwithstanding his insatiable avarice and
the others to abide by the outcomes, even if ambition. (Hume, 1741 [1994])
they find themselves to be losers or in a
minority on some issues, or if the costs of not In this chapter, we will prove that the assump-
complying are too high. The Western tion that people seek their own interest not
European model of nation-state building has only in making private or public policy deci-
been too often taken as the only reference sions, but also when choosing the institu-
and interesting path for building a political tional rules for making those decisions, is
community. Political science is still very broadly shared and analytically fruitful.
state-centered. However, recent and current Institutional designers, while tending to
developments, in both Europe and the rest of deploy their ‘ambition’, often aim at putting
the world, demand for a more diversified levers of rule at their easy disposal in order to
menu, as we will discuss in the following concentrate, rather than check power.
pages. The second question – how decisions However, an efficient institutional design –
are made – implies at least to major issues: that is, one making rulers ‘cooperate to
what can be decided on each occasion, which public good’, in Hume’s terms – can result
refers to how decision powers are divided from circumstances in which no actor has
among different bodies or branches of gov- sufficient influence to impose its own project
ernment, and how people’s preferences are and diverse ambitions counterweight each
transformed into collective outcomes, which other. Not surprisingly, this is a relatively

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN 247

frequent situation in a complex world, which Decline and failure of the


may explain why major institutional choices
sovereign state
are increasingly made in favour of formulas
able to produce power-sharing and to satisfy About a generation ago, a claim was made to
broad groups of people, which is just another ‘bring the state back in’ the social sciences,
way to refer to ‘public good’. as in Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschmeyer and
The following review shows that, in the cur- Theda Skocpol (1985) and, especially,
rent world, the number of small, sufficiently Skocpol (1985). This claim was initially
homogeneous communities to make consen- addressed to correct ‘too society-centered’
sual and enforceable collective decisions is ways of explaining politics and governmen-
increasing; the number of democracies is also tal processes that had prevailed during a
increasing; institutional choices tend to favour previous period starting in the 1950s and
division of powers rather than concentration in 1960s. Bringing the ‘state’ back in brought
a single body or party; and electoral rules are about much more attention to formal rules
increasingly chosen to permit multiple parties and institutions, governmental activities, and
to participate and share government. As actors’ the impact of authorities on societal proc-
self-interested behavior leads to broadly effi- esses, including economic interests and social
cient and satisfactory institutional choices, it movements. New knowledge and science
seems that a kind of ‘invisible hand’ in the have indeed developed from that impulse and
field can be identified – actually in a not very the subsequent turn in methodological
dissimilar way as a pattern of unintended con- approaches.
sequences for private decisions was also iden- However, in a number of further scholarly
tified by Adam Smith, in truth David Hume’s studies, the ‘state’ was conceived not only as
favourite disciple. an institutional and organizational structure
The chapter is divided in two parts. In the for different actor’s strategies and decisions,
first, the problems of building a community but as a unitary actor, especially in the field
are addressed with the help of the categories of international or transnational relations.
of ‘state’, ‘nation’ and ‘empire’. In the second The ‘explanatory centrality’ given to the state
part, we review the state of the art regard- as a potent and autonomous actor somehow
ing the choice of institutional rules for divi- neglected the role of both larger and smaller
sion of powers and elections. A few remarks political units, especially as the scale of poli-
conclude. tics has been changing during the most recent
period.
The promoters of the newly ‘state-centered’
approach remarked that it derived in part from
COMMUNITY-BUILDING analytical developments and problems in pre-
vious ‘society-centered’ approaches, since the
The design of institutions may involve the explanation of many societal processes
building of a large nation-state under the required to ascertain the impact of the political
modern West European model. But it may system and the state itself. Analogously, the
entail the building of other types of community, development of studies directly or indirectly
such as ‘empires’ or ‘cities’, as very large and inspired on the assumption of state centrality
small communities, respectively, were called in has contributed to pay attention to alternative
classical studies in the field. After having lost political units with an impact on states. In
the ‘state’ and brought it back in, a more diver- recent times scholars of the state have realized
sified categorization of polities or structures of that the state cannot be taken for granted; its
governments is opening its way in recent very existence is problematic; processes of
political studies. state-building and nation-building show that

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


248 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

there are different degrees of ‘statehood’ or the metropolis – in many cases, a failure
‘stateness’; there are strong and weak states, indeed. Often the very idea of ‘state’ was
as well as numerous failed ‘states’; and the frustrated since the new political units
future of the national state in the current world achieved neither internal monopoly nor exter-
is questioned by new issues of scale, space nal sovereignty.
and territoriality. There are several accounts of failed states
‘State’ is in fact a category that has become in the current world. The World Bank holds a
decreasingly able to account for many poli- permanently revised list of ‘fragile states’,
ties in the current world. Apparently, the cur- called LICUS (for ‘low income countries
rent world is organized in almost 200 ‘states’. under stress’), to be given priority, but in
But only a relatively limited number of these most cases impotent foreign aid. There are
political units can be considered to be suc- between 30 and 40 of these countries, includ-
cessful ‘states’ in a strict sense of the word. ing ‘collapsed or failing states’, others in
Sovereign states succeeded in Europe within permanent internal conflict, encompassing
a historical period that began about 300 years all together between five and ten per cent of
ago and is today essentially finished. In fact the world’s population. In another compa-
the Western European model of state has rable report, Britain’s Department for
either not been applied or has mostly failed International Development has named 46
elsewhere in the world. Now, as a conse- ‘fragile states’ of concern (Cabinet Office,
quence of the creation, successive enlarge- 2005). Other periodical reports on fragile
ments and strengthening of the European or failed states are produced by the OECD,
Union, the validity of the traditional Western the CIA (2000), and Fund for Peace and
European model of sovereign nation-state Foreign Policy (2005). The failure of state-
has weakened further because it is in decline hood as an explanation for social disorder
even in the original experience. and economic stagnation is not, however,
Elsewhere, the Western European model of very frequent and, when used, it is typically
the sovereign state has been much less suc- within a teleological framework by which
cessful. The US was created from the begin- state-building is presented as the only possi-
ning, rather than as a nation-state, as a ble model for non-European countries (as in
‘compound republic’ formed by previously Fukuyama, 2004).
existing units retaining their constituent
powers, as elaborated, among others, by
Vincent Ostrom (1987). In Asia, a few very Small is democratic
large, overpopulated empires have also
escaped from the project of statization: China, In recent worldwide developments, classical
the compound India-Pakistan-Bangladesh, as state-building under the Western European
well as Indonesia and Japan, have maintained model has been largely replaced with a prolif-
certain traditional imperial characteristics of eration of small countries, most of which do
internal complexity, not adopting the homog- not brandish some essential elements of ‘sov-
enizing features typical of modern European ereignty’. While there were only about 50
states. independent countries in the world at the
Unlike in either North America or Asia, beginning of the twentieth century, there are
attempts to replicate the typical European about 200 members of the United Nations in
‘state’ form of government were made in the early twenty-first century. They include
Hispanic America, Africa and the Middle about 70 mini-states with a population between
East as a consequence of the colonial expan- one and ten million inhabitants and 40 micro-
sion of European states and the further inde- states with less than one million inhabitants
pendence of their colonies. The experience (among them most members of the European
has been much less successful than it was in Union). In addition, there are more than

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN 249

500 non-state political units with governments have relatively harmonious interests, shared
and legislative powers located within a couple values and a common culture, which may
of dozen vast federations or decentralized make it easier to identify priority public goods
‘empires’. There are also about 20 ‘territories’ and make collective decisions that are gener-
formally linked but physically non-contiguous ally acceptable. Finally, small communities
to some large empire or state and in fact quite are more likely to generate loyalty; people will
independent, and about 15 other territories de tend to comply with collective rules and deci-
facto seceded from recognized states. Helpful sions, while leaders may be more responsive
data are provided by Kristian S. Gleditsch and regarding their own decisions and activity.
Michael D. Ward (2007) and by the Correlates Looking at the question from the other side,
of War project at the University of Michigan. the disadvantages large unitary states have in
A good collection of cases of states in process establishing a democracy able to satisfy the
of separation can be found in Bahcheli preferences of a large majority of its citizens
et al. (2004). are not difficult to identify. Within a large
The increase in the number of independent political unit, different interests, values and
countries and the corresponding decrease in opinions are likely to exist among the citizens.
their size, as well as the concurrent decen- A collective decision made on a set of differ-
tralization of large states and empires, have ent policy issues in bloc is likely to produce a
accompanied the recent spread of democracy high number of losers. Local majorities may
in the world. Contrary to some conventional become state-wide minorities and see their
knowledge, democracy does not require sov- preferences rejected from binding collective
ereign statehood. It can be argued that some decisions. In large and heterogeneous com-
lively forms of ‘democracy’ in the sense of munities, there is likely to be a group of abso-
open elections and control of rulers by broad lute winners, whose endurance may induce
layers of citizens existed in old small commu- the losers either to resist the enforceability of
nities, cities, nations and republics not invested collective decisions, not comply with them,
with the attribute of sovereignty, long before rebel, secede or emigrate. In the extreme, dic-
the notion of state was even invented. Likewise, tatorships are more likely to emerge and tri-
there are also nowadays several hundred dem- umph in very large political units or in highly
ocratic, but non-sovereign local and regional heterogeneous ones.
governments within large states or empires. The correlation between small size and
As discussed in the seminal work by Robert democracy is empirically consistent, since the
A. Dahl and Edward R. Tufte (1973), small creation of increasingly numerous, smaller
communities can be more appropriate than countries has accompanied the spread of demo-
large and populous territories for democratic cratic regimes. At the beginning of the twenty-
forms of self-government. Their advantages first century, there is democracy in all recognized
can be found in each of the three stages of the micro-countries with less than 300,000 inhab-
decision process: deliberation, aggregation, itants, in more than two thirds of those with
and enforcement. In a small community, less than one million inhabitants (including
people have more opportunities to gain knowl- the former group), and in more than one half of
edge for collective decisions by direct obser- all small countries with less than 10 million
vation and experience; thanks to territorial inhabitants (including the two former groups),
proximity, people can also deal more directly while only one third of large countries with
with political leaders; the latter can easily gain more than 10 million inhabitants enjoy demo-
information about people’s demands and cratic regimes (specifically, there is democracy
expectations by direct communication. Since in 59 of the 112 smaller countries, but in only
a small community tends, in general, to be 30 of the 86 larger countries). In other words,
relatively homogeneous in terms of both eco- the number of small democracies is twice the
nomic and ethnic variables, people may also number of large democracies.

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


250 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

The rates of success in democratization are Empire-wide political and institutional


even higher for small communities within processes indeed disappeared from the field
large federations. Nowadays, of all the large of academic political studies after the Second
countries in the world with more than 10 mil- World War. A search in the American Political
lion inhabitants, those with a federal structure Science Review (APSR) since its foundation
are democratic in almost three-fourths of the gives the following results. In the first period,
cases, while in large centralized and unitary from 1903–1949, as many as seven articles
states, democracy only exists in one-fourth of and 74 books reviewed included the words
the cases (specifically, there is democracy in ‘empire’ or ‘imperial’ in the title. Most of
13 of 18 large federal countries, but in only 17 them dealt with the ‘problems and possibili-
of 68 large centralized states). ties’ (as titled in one of the reviews) of the
British empire, followed by the German
empire, as well as the American, Chinese,
Japanese and Ottoman empires. Articles and
Bringing the empire back in
books approached such suggestive subjects
The increase in the number of viable small as empire’s unity, nationalism, federalism,
democratic governments seems to rely upon government and politics, political system,
membership to very large areas of ‘imperial’ governance, constitution and laws, legislative
size, which provide public goods such as jurisdiction, administrative system, civil
defense, security, trade agreements, common service or civil code – that is, the same kind
currencies, and communication networks. of subjects that can be studied under the
Precisely because they do not have to pay the alternative framework of ‘state’.
heavy burdens of classical statehood and sover- In contrast, not a single piece of work pub-
eignty, including a costly army and a single lished in the APSR between 1950–1967
currency, small countries in an open interna- included the words ‘empire’ or ‘imperial’ in
tional environment can benefit from their inter- the title. This suggests that ‘society-centered’
nal homogeneity and inclination to democracy. approaches which were prevalent during that
Within efficient, internally varied vast empires, period, at the same time that they neglected
small nations are now viable and, at the same the study of states also forgot the study of
time, better fit than large, heterogeneous states empires. Since 1968, the words ‘empire’ or
for democratic self-government. ‘imperial’ reappear, although only in 40 book
A few vast empires do exist in the current reviews, not in the titles of full-fledged arti-
world, including democratic and market- cles. Most of the reviews in this period focus
oriented empires, such as the USA, the on history of past colonial empires, while
European Union, India and Japan, as well as only eight address imperial relations in the
China and Russia, just to mention the most current world (mainly regarding American
prominent ones. An ‘empire’ can be conceived foreign affairs).
as a very large size polity with a government A new source of interest in the concept of
formed by multiple institutional levels and empire can be derived, however, from state-
overlapping jurisdictions. In this sense, centered studies in state-building and nation-
‘empire’ is an alternative formula to ‘state’, building. Two generations of political scientists
which can also be dictatorial or democratic or ago, some fundamental discussion was col-
something in between, but is founded on fixed lected by S.N. Eisendstadt and Stein Rokkan
boundaries, external sovereignty and the aim (1973). As they were embedded in the ‘mod-
of internal homogenization. Empires typically ernization’ paradigm, the editors acknowl-
encompass a high number of small political edged they had not been capable of ‘developing
units, including states, but also regions, cities a general theoretical structure for comparisons
and other communities, with different institu- across all regions of the world’, but remarked
tional formulas across the territory. on ‘the uniqueness of the Western experience

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN 251

of state formation and nation-building’ and its government in the world that goes beyond the
inappropriateness for the ‘Third World’. last 200 years (Finer, 1997). Finer states at the
Specifically for Africa, for instance, ‘nation- very first page of his impressive, indispensa-
building in the European style was a luxury ble and irregular three volume study that his
when not a catastrophe’. ‘concern is with states’. However, he immedi-
Somehow following or paralleling this ately acknowledges that most ‘pre-modern’
intuition, a number of historians have identi- polities did not fulfill the basic characteristics
fied spatial and temporal limits for the valid- of ‘state’, namely the notion of territorial
ity of the concept of ‘state’: basically Western sovereignty (and far less that of ‘a self-
Europe and a few of its colonies since mid- consciousness of nationality’). Actually in his
seventeenth century to late twentieth century. own ‘conceptual prologue’, Finer goes to pro-
A masterful survey of the modern states in vide a three-fold typology of structures of
this perspective is given, for example, by government based on the distinction between
Martin L. Van Creveld (1999). Other enlight- city, state and empire. In his extensive survey,
ening studies on the formation of early states the category of city-republics includes a
include William Doyle (1978), Charles Tilly number of cases in Mesopotamia, the poleis of
(1975), Hendrik Spruyt (1994) and Philip Greece, and medieval Europe. The ‘formation
Bobbitt (2002). The importance of initial of the “modern European state”’, in turn,
violence, force and coercion in building a ‘starts effectively with, and is built around, the
state has been particularly highlighted by erection of known frontiers … States were the
social historian Charles Tilly, who went so product either of aggregation from small ter-
far as to present both war-making and state- ritorial units or of the disaggregation of large
making as forms of ‘organized crime’ (Tilly, territorial units’, according to Finer (1997: 9,
1985). In the academic headquarters of polit- 35). But it can also be argued that, in the cur-
ical science more strictly defined, the role of rent world, the states themselves are suffering
violence and coercion in the formation of processes of both disaggregation into small
states has also been stressed by Margaret polities (along the revived tradition of city-
Levi (1988, 1997) and Robert H. Bates republics) and aggregation into large territo-
(2001). Bertrand Badie and Pierre Birnbaum rial units of imperial size.
(1983) remarked that the state is but one pos- In fact, most of Finer’s work deals with
sible institutional formula in complex socie- empires, using regularly and explicitly the
ties in the modern world. The failure of the word. Specifically his analysis includes Assyria,
state model beyond Europe was subsequently ‘the first empire in our modern sense’; Persia,
analyzed also by Bertrand Badie (1992). ‘the first secular-minded empire’; China, in fact
a series of ‘multi-state empires’; Rome, which
ruled through ‘imperial agents’ like the provin-
States, nations, and empires cial governors; the Byzantine empire; the Arab
empire of the Caliphate; the Ottoman empire;
A few works dealing more directly with and the Indian empires. Finer’s work provides,
political and governmental processes in thus, highly valuable material for political sci-
empires can also be mentioned. Specifically, ence analysis of polities or structures of govern-
‘the concept of empire’ and its potential in the ment through history, although his initial
analysis of long-term historical periods was emphasis on ‘states’ is dismissed by his own
discussed in an excellent book co-authored by substantive analysis of really existing govern-
an outstanding selection of historians and ments. Other interesting suggestion for further
political scientists at the initiative of Maurice work from Finer’s materials can be found in
Duverger (1980a). George E. Von der Muhll (2003).
More recently, Samuel E. Finer provided Regarding current configurations, the
the only political science-oriented history of European Union has also been analyzed as an

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


252 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

‘empire’ or at least as an empire under con- so that the imperial form of government
struction. The European Union is indeed a includes increasingly higher proportions of
very large political unit (the third in popula- the world’s population. Virtually none of the
tion in the current world), it has expanded territories of the currently existing states in
continuously outward without previously the world has been alien or outside some
established territorial limits, it is organized large modern empire. Among the very few
diversely across the territory and has multiple, exceptions are Thailand (which emerged
overlapping institutional levels of governance. from the old kingdom of Siam without
The point that the European Union may not be Western colonization) and Israel (which was
‘unique’, ‘exceptional’ or ‘unprecedented’, as created from scratch in 1948). But a world’s
frequently asserted in certain journalistic lit- single-government is not foreseeable from
erature and political speech, was addressed, historical developments. If the tendency
for instance, by Caporaso et al. (1997). For a toward increasingly larger sizes of empire, as
social scientist this only means that we are not measured by territory, is extrapolated, we
using a sufficiently broad analytical concept find only a 50 per cent probability of a single
capable of including this case among those world empire by a date placed between 2200
with common relevant characteristics, such as and 3800 (depending on the author making
that of ‘empire’. A comparison between the the calculation). If the extrapolation is based
processes of constitutional building of the on the proportion of the world’s population
European Union and of the US was sketched within the largest empire, that expectation
by Richard Bellamy (2005). The war motives should be deferred to nothing less than the
in building large empires like the European year 4300.
one were remarked by William H. Riker A relevant implication of all this discussion
(1987, 1996). The vision of the European is that, contrary to a still common assumption
Union as a new kind of empire was suggested inspiring the US and other great empires’ for-
by Robert Cooper (2003). Europe ‘as an eign policy, especially regarding the Arab
empire’ has been elaborated in parallel works region and the Middle East, democracy does
by Jan Zielonka (2006) and Josep M. Colomer not require nation-state building. In ethnically
(2006, 2007a). highly heterogeneous countries, federal-type
In the long-term there has been an ever- structures and the establishment of large-size
continuing historical trend toward larger areas of free trade and military and security
empires. The size and evolution of empires cooperation, can work rather well. Even more:
have been studied in four illuminating articles if sovereign units were strengthened in isola-
by Rein Taagepera (1978a, 1978b, 1979, tion from each other, a higher degree of state-
1997), which are partly based on data in Colin ness could, paradoxically, jeopardize the
McEvedy and Richard Jones (1978). According chances of freedom and democracy, since it
to these data, there is no evidence of empires might revive or foster inter-state rivalries and
larger than 10,000 km2 much before 3000 BC. mutually hostile relations.
The largest ancient empires, in Egypt and
Mesopotamia, with about one million km2,
were still tiny compared to the present ones.
The largest ones at the beginning of our era, in THE CHOICE OF INSTITUTIONS
China and Rome, were already much larger,
with about five million km2. But modern Within established communities, the design-
empires, including Russia and the colonial ers of institutions will aim at anticipating
empires of Spain and Britain, have encom- collective decisions on government and
passed double-digit millions of km2. policy. Two types of decisions on institutions
Another historical trend is toward an are reviewed in the following. First, those to
increasing number of simultaneous empires, regulate the division of powers among the

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN 253

various branches of government, and second, officers and control of administrative agen-
those to define the relationships between cies, congressional impeachment of the pres-
these and the public, which in democracy are ident, and judicial revision of legislation.
based on elections (Colomer, 2001b). Recent analyses have formally shown how
these counter-weighting mechanisms play in
favor of power sharing between institutions
Division of powers and as equivalent devices to super-majority
rules for decision-making. The obstacles
In the old legalistic approach to institutional introduced by the numerous institutional
design, democratic regimes were basically checks may stabilize socially inefficient
distinguished as ‘parliamentary’ or ‘presi- status-quo policies, but they also guarantee
dential’ depending on the relations between that the most important decisions are made
the legislative and the executive, as shown, by broad majorities able to prevent the impo-
for example, in the compilation by Arend sition of a small or minority group’s will.
Lijphart (1992). In parliamentary regimes With similar analytical insight but a different
there is fusion of powers between the parlia- evaluation, other analyses have remarked that
ment’s political majority and the cabinet. But separate elections and divided governments
by the early twentieth century, the develop- create a ‘dual legitimacy’ prone to ‘dead-
ment of political parties was usually inter- lock’, that is, legislative paralysis and inter-
preted as a force eroding the central role of institutional conflict. A seminal contribution,
the parliament, up to the point to label the based on a formal model for the United
British model rather than ‘parliamentary’, a States constitution, showed how the interac-
‘cabinet’ regime. However, it has more tion of separate institutional bodies is likely
recently been remarked that the growth of to produce stable policy outcomes, as by
party was instrumental to reduce the influ- Thomas Hammond and Gary Miller (1987).
ence of the monarch but not necessarily that Further discussion includes contributions by
of the parliament. With the reduction of the Fred Riggs (1988), Juan J. Linz (1990a, b),
monarch to a figurehead, the prime minister William H. Riker (1992), Kenneth Krehbiel
has indeed become the new one-person rele- (1996, 1998), Robert A. Dahl (2002), José A.
vant figure, but the position of the cabinet has Cheibub and Fernando Limongi (2002),
weakened. In contrast, the role of parliament Josep M. Colomer (2005b).
has survived, and even, in a modest way, A variant of political regime with separate
thrived. At least regarding Britain, despite elections for the presidency and the assembly,
long-standing concerns regarding the balance better called ‘presidentialism’, was estab-
of power, ‘parliament has always remained lished in almost all republics in Latin America
the primary institution of the polity’, accord- since the mid- or late- nineteenth century.
ing to Matthew Flinders (2002; see also Some founding constitution-makers in these
Bogdanor, 2003). countries claimed to be imitating the US con-
In the so-called ‘presidential’ regime, orig- stitution, but, in contrast to the preventions
inated with the 1787 constitution of the US, against one-person’s expedient decisions
there are separate elections for the assembly introduced in the US, some of them looked
and the presidency and a complex system of farther back to the absolutist monarchies pre-
‘checks and balances’ or mutual controls ceding division of powers and mixed regimes
between institutions. They include term and aimed at having ‘elected kings with
limits for the president, limited presidential the name of presidents’ (in Simón Bolívar’s
veto of congressional legislation, senate rules words). The distinction between US-style
permitting a qualified minority to block deci- checks-and-balances, unified government in
sions, senatorial ratification of presidential presidential regimes, and the more concen-
appointments, congressional appointment of trated formula of ‘presidentialism’ can be

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


254 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

referred to Madison, Jefferson, and Hamilton, model would produce an alternation between
respectively, according to James Burns presidential and parliamentary phases,
(1965). respectively favoring the president and the
Presidential dominance has been attempted prime minister as dominant figure. The first
in Latin American countries through the presi- phase of the alternation was indeed con-
dent’s veto power over legislation and his con- firmed with presidents enjoying a compact
trol of the army, which also exist in the US, party majority in the assembly. In these situ-
supplemented with long presidential terms and ations, ‘the president can become more pow-
re-elections, unconstrained powers to appoint erful than in the classical presidential
and remove members of cabinet and other regimes’, as well as more powerful than the
high officers, legislative initiative, capacity to British-style prime minister because he accu-
dictate legislative decrees, fiscal and adminis- mulates the latter’s powers plus those of the
trative authority, discretionary emergency monarch.
powers, suspension of constitutional guaran- The second, parliamentary phase was, in
tees, and, in formally federal countries, the contrast, not confirmed, since, even if the
right to intervene in state affairs. The other side president faces a prime minister, a cabinet
of this same coin is weak congresses, which are and an assembly majority with a different
not usually given control over the cabinet and political orientation, he usually retains sig-
are frequently constrained by short session nificant powers, including the dissolution of
periods and lack of resources. Recent discus- the assembly, as well as partial vetoes over
sion includes Matthew S. Shugart and John M. legislation and executive appointments,
Carey (1992), Juan J. Linz and Arturo Valenzuela among others, depending on specific rules in
(1994), Scott Morgenstern and Benito Nacif each country. This makes the president cer-
(2002). Actually the Latin American model of tainly more powerful than any monarch or
presidential dominance has gained the lowest republican president in a parliamentary
reputation among scholars and has been pro- regime, as acknowledged by Duverger him-
posed to be replaced with all the other regime self (1986, 1996, 1998). The French call this
types, including semi-parliamentarism by ‘cohabitation’. There can, thus, be indeed
Carlos S. Nino (1992), Westminster features by two ‘phases’, depending on whether the
Scott Mainwairing and Matthew S. Shugart president’s party has a majority in the assem-
(1997), US-style checks and balances by Bruce bly and can appoint the primer minister or
Ackerman (2000), and multiparty parliamen- not; however, the two phases are not properly
tarism by Josep M. Colomer and Gabriel L. presidential and parliamentary, but they
Negretto (2005). rather produce an even higher concentration
Another variant, usually called ‘semi-presi- of power than in a presidential regime and a
dential’ regime, but also ‘semi-parliamentary’, dual executive, respectively. See also discus-
‘premier-presidential’ or ‘dual-executive’, was sion in Bahro et al. (1998), Giovanni Sartori
consistently shaped with the 1958 constitution (1994), Robert Elgie (1999).
of France. With this formula, the presidency
and the assembly are elected separately, like in
a checks-and-balances regime, but it is the
Political regime performances
assembly that appoints and can dismiss a
prime minister, like in a parliamentary regime. The introduction of a second dimension, the
The president and the prime minister share the electoral system, makes the problems for
executive powers in a ‘governmental diarchy’, institutional design of democratic regimes
as early stated by Maurice Duverger (1965, more complex. In particular, within parlia-
1970, 1978, 1980b). mentary regimes one can choose either
At the beginning of the French experience, majoritarian electoral rules, which typically
Duverger speculated that this constitutional imply that a single party will be able to win

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN 255

an assembly majority and appoint the prime be associated to higher frequency of ethnic
minister, or proportional representation rules, and civil wars than presidential regimes,
which correspond to multi-party systems while parliamentary regimes with propor-
and coalition cabinets. Presidential regimes tional representation are the most peaceful
and their variants, in contrast, are less affected ones (Reynal-Querol, 2002). Updated calcu-
by the electoral system dimension since at lations show that of all attempts to establish
least one of the systems, the one for the elec- a democratic regime in countries with more
tion of the president, must be majoritarian than one million inhabitants since the nine-
and produce a single absolute winner. teenth century, those having initially adopted
Different institutional choices have been the British model of parliamentarism with
linked to different rates of success in attempts majoritarian electoral rule have survived only
of democratization and in the duration of in 37 per cent of the cases, while the rate of
democratic regimes. In order to understand success for presidential and semi-presidential
some results, it may be convenient to think regimes is 54 per cent (with high variance in
again about the stylized assumption that stra- duration), and for parliamentarism with pro-
tegic choices of different institutional formu- portional representation, of 72 per cent
las tend to be driven by actors’ relative (Colomer, 1995, 2001a, 2007b).
bargaining strength, electoral expectations,
and attitudes to risk. It is logical to expect
that citizens and political leaders will tend to
Electoral rules
support those formulas producing satisfac-
tory results for themselves and reject those Electoral system design requires major
making them permanently excluded and choices between indirect elections, direct
defeated. As a consequence, institutional elections by majority rule, mixed systems,
formulas producing widely distributed satis- and proportional representation. Regarding
factory outcomes can be more able to develop the strategies of political parties to design
endogenous support and endure. Widely rep- electoral systems, in general the ‘Micro-
resentative and effective political outcomes mega rule’ applies: the large prefer the small
can feed social support for the corresponding and the small prefer the large (‘Micro-mega’
institutions, while exclusionary, biased, arbi- is the title of Voltaire’s tale in which dwarfs
trary, or ineffective outcomes might foster and giants dialogue). Specifically, dominant
citizens’ and leaders’ rejection of the institu- and large parties prefer single-member dis-
tions producing such results. tricts with majoritarian rules able to exclude
Generally, constitutional democracies others from competition, while multiple
favoring power-sharing and inclusiveness small parties prefer large districts with pro-
should, thus, be able to obtain higher endog- portional representation rules able to include
enous support and have greater longevity them. Thus, political configurations in which
than those favoring the concentration of there is a single dominant party or two rather
power. Empirical accounts show that demo- balanced parties tend to produce choices in
cratic regimes are the most peaceful ones, favor of rather restrictive or exclusionary
while semi-democratic or transitional regimes electoral systems, such as those based on the
are most prone to conflict, even more than majority principle, while pluralistic settings
exclusionary dictatorships (basically because with multiple parties tend to favor choices in
the latter increase the costs of rebellion). favor of more inclusive electoral formulas,
Among democracies, parliamentary regimes such as those using rules of proportional rep-
are more resilient to crises and more able to resentation.
endure than presidential ones (Stepan and Maurice Duverger (1951) already noted that
Skach, 1993). But parliamentary regimes ‘the first effect of proportionality is to main-
with majoritarian electoral systems appear to tain an already existing multiplicity … On the

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


256 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

whole, proportional representation maintains systems, and to proportional representation


virtually without change the party system exist- (Colomer, 2004; see also Blais and Massicotte,
ing at the time of its adoption’, although he did 1997; Lijphart, 1994).
not elaborate. Precisely in a book review of Existing parties tend, thus, to choose elec-
Duverger, John G. Grumm remarked: toral systems able to crystallize or consolidate
the generally-held conclusions regarding the causal the previously existing party configurations
relationships between electoral systems and party and systems. Only in large countries with
systems might well be revised. … it may be more large assemblies, limited voters’ participation,
accurate to conclude that proportional representa- and successful coordination in two large par-
tion is a result rather than a cause of the party
ties, single-member districts and plurality rule
system in a given country (Grumm, 1958: 375).
remain stable as an equilibrium institutional
Seymour M. Lipset and Stein Rokkan also formula. In the US, in particular, in spite of
suggested that electoral systems should be being a very large and heterogeneous country,
treated as the result of institutional choices each representative is elected by the rather
by political actors: ‘In most cases it makes homogeneous population of a small territory
little sense to treat electoral systems as inde- in a way that the two main nation-wide parties
pendent variables. The party strategists will become large-tents or umbrellas of varied
generally have decisive influence on elec- representation.
toral legislation and opt for the system of Since the nineteenth century, we can count
aggregation most likely to consolidate their 82 major changes of assembly electoral
position’ (Lipset and Rokkan, 1967). More system in 41 countries with more than one
recently, analytical models, surveys, and dis- million inhabitants. In consistency with the
cussion on electoral system design and choice discussion above, we observe that more than
have been provided by Arend Lijphart and 80 per cent of these changes have been in the
Bernard Grofman (1988), Carles Boix (1999), direction toward more inclusive formulas.
Josep M. Colomer (2004), Pippa Norris Specifically, indirect assembly elections
(2004), Michael Gallagher and Paul Mitchell decreased and virtually disappeared in the
(2005), and Kenneth Benoit (2007). early twentieth century. Majority rule, which
It seems reasonable to assume that, under was the basic formula in the few democratic
restrictive formulas such as majority rule, countries existing in the late nineteenth and
political actors facing the effects of their own early twentieth centuries, was replaced in its
failure at coordinating themselves into a appeal by proportional representation, espe-
small number of candidacies and the emer- cially after the First World War. This trend
gence of new issues and new contenders for has intensified in recent processes of democ-
seats and offices, may shift to prefer electoral ratization. Mixed systems have spread widely
institutions able to reduce the risks of com- in the most recent period, mostly as a result
peting by giving all participants higher of changes from non-democratic regimes or
opportunities to obtain or share power. When plurality rule. Nowadays, most democratic
there are only a few parties, they can be satis- countries with more than one million inhabit-
fied with majoritarian electoral systems, but ants use electoral systems with proportional
when the number and the size of new parties representation rules.
increase, the incumbent parties may begin to Likewise, we can count 28 major changes
fear the risk of becoming absolute losers and of presidential electoral rules in 14 countries,
try to shift to more inclusive electoral formu- mostly moving from electoral college to
las. Electoral system changes indeed tend to simple plurality rule and to second-round for-
move overwhelmingly in favor of increas- mulas based on qualified-plurality or absolute
ingly inclusive, less risky formulas: from majority rules, the latter permitting multiparty
indirect to direct elections, from unanimity to competition at the first round. This trend is
majority rules, and from the latter to mixed stronger during present democratic periods.

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN 257

More specifically, it has been proven that designers in Estonia are likely to choose mul-
while dominant and large parties are likely to timember districts, typically associated to
choose simple plurality rule, small parties are proportional representation rules.
likely to choose variants of majority rule with In separate work, I myself hypothesized
second round runoff, a system which permits that electoral systems based on single-member
broader participation and coalition formation districts and majority rule would be estab-
in support of the two leading candidates. This lished and maintained when the effective
hypothesis has been supported by a statistical number of parties lies between one and four,
analysis of the determinants of electoral choice that is, when a single party may have or expect
in 49 cases of major and minor constitutional to have an absolute majority. Beyond four
changes in Latin American countries by effective parties, the parties may want to
Gabriel L. Negretto (2006). change the electoral system to introduce mul-
timember electoral districts with proportional
representation rules. The hypothesis was sup-
Large (small) assemblies, ported with empirical data for 70 countries
showing that only when the number of effec-
small (large) districts
tive parties increases to four, the probability
An example of how the analysis of inter- of an electoral system change in favor of pro-
institutional relations and institutional portional representation rises above half
choices can be operationalized for quantita- (Colomer, 2005a).
tively measurable variables and further There is, thus, a great coincidence between
empirical test is the following. Rein Taagepera the results of both the deductive and the
(2001, 2007), by deductive reasoning, has inductive analyses just reported. The stylized
presented a formula between basic elements approach focusing just on a few clearly
of the electoral system, the district magni- defined, well measurable variables makes us
tude, M, the number of seats or size of the realize that the pressures from multiparty
assembly, S, and the number of parliamen- systems to adopt inclusive electoral rules
tary parties, P, by which: P = (MS)1/4. His work differently in countries of different
initial intention was to explain the number of sizes. In large countries, a large assembly,
parties as derived from the electoral system. whose number of seats is positively corre-
But his own formula also permits to analyze lated to the country’s population, can be
the relation the other way round, that is, the elected in small, single-member districts. In
electoral system as derived from the number small countries, by contrast, the size of the
of parties. More clearly, it is: M = P4/S. assembly is small and, as a consequence, the
In a previous work, Rein Taagepera and development of multiple parties favors more
Mathhew S. Shugart had established that the strongly the adoption of inclusive, large mul-
size of the assembly, S, depends on the size timember districts with rules of proportional
of the country in terms of population, C, representation. Thus we tend to see large
approaching S = C 1/3 (Taagepera and Shugart, assemblies with small districts, and small
1989). Now we can see in the above formula assemblies with large districts.
that the larger the country, and hence the This may seem counter-intuitive, since
larger the assembly, S, the smaller the apparently small countries should have more
expected district magnitude, M. Very large ‘simple’ party configurations and less prob-
countries, precisely because they have large lems to identify a majority winner, so that they
assemblies, can stay associated to small sin- could work by simple electoral systems such as
gle-member districts. With similar number of those with single-member districts and major-
parties, the institutional designers in India, ity rule in acceptable ways (actually this tends
for example, are likely to choose single- to happen in very small and micro-countries
member districts, while the institutional with only a few hundred thousand inhabitants

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


258 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

in which no more than two parties emerge). If analyzed in several of the studies previously
the relation between variables is clearly estab- cited, and has widely spread among new
lished and measured, we can have an answer to democracies during the last decades.
the intriguing question of why large countries,
including the US and other former British
colonies, in spite of the fact that large size is
typically associated to high heterogeneity, keep CONCLUSION
single-member districts and have not adopted
proportional representation. It is not unfounded to assume that the design
A relevant implication for institutional of political institutions is usually driven by
design is that if the size of the assembly is politicians’ and would-be rulers’ ambition, the
rather stable and depends on the country’s pursuit of power, and calculations, estimates or
size, for a small country with a small assem- expectations about the likely consequences of
bly, just a few parties are necessary to pro- different institutional formulas to favor design-
duce a change of electoral system in favor of ers’ self-interest. However, as we have seen in
proportional representation. In contrast, for a the previous pages, the outcomes of such
large country and a large assembly, many endeavors tend to be relatively favorable to
parties would be necessary to produce such a formulas restricting the opportunities for high
result, as discussed for the UK, after some concentration of power and permitting broad
failed attempts to reform the electoral rules, satisfaction of people’s preferences and
by Patrick Dunleavy (2005). demands. Specifically, institutional choices
In the long-term, as we have seen in the during the last decades tend to produce small
first part of this chapter, both the number of countries, more democracies, division of
countries and the number of democracies in powers, and electoral rules favoring multiparty
the world are increasing, leading to an over- representation. In spite of, or precisely through
all decrease in the size of the democratic actors’ self-interested behavior, institutional
countries. The size of democratic assemblies choices seem to be guided by an ‘invisible
also decreases, since it is positively corre- hand’ favouring relatively acceptable solutions.
lated to the country’s population. As the Of course, all of this is based on long-term
number of parties increases within each tendencies and positively tested with only
democracy, more and more countries tend, average values for large numbers of cases. For
thus, to adopt electoral systems with propor- single-case analyses, several possible situa-
tional representation rules. tions faced by self-interested political actors
In large countries and empires, such as can be identified. If the distribution of power
Australia, Canada, France, India, the UK, and in a community is such that one single group
the US, a large assembly can be sufficiently is institutionally dominant and expects
inclusive, even if it is elected in small, single- to be secure winner with the existing institu-
member districts, due to territorial variety of the tional rules, these will not likely be changed
representatives. In small countries, by contrast, – institutional stability can be expected. In
the size of the assembly is small and, as a con- contrast, situations more prone to institutional
sequence, the enlargement of voting rights, the change include those in which there is high
broadening of the public agenda and develop- uncertainty regarding the different groups’
ment of multiple parties favors more strongly relative strength and those in which new
the adoption of more inclusive, large multi- groups are emerging and gaining increasing
member districts with proportional representa- support among voters. For anticipated losers
tion rules. Indeed, proportional representation or threatened winners, institutional change
began to be adopted for parliamentary elections can be a rational strategy if the expected
in a few relatively small Western European advantages of alternative formulas balance the
countries in the early twentieth-century, as risks of keeping playing by the existing rules.

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN 259

We should take into account that many spe- Badie, B. and Birnbaum, P. (1983) The sociol-
cific decisions and reforms are embedded in ogy of the state. Chicago: The University of
larger sets of institutional choices. Most promi- Chicago Press.
nently, the introduction of universal suffrage Bahcheli, T., Bartmann, B., and Srebrnik, H.
and processes of democratization have been, (eds) (2004) De facto states. The quest for
already since the late nineteenth century and in sovereignty. London and New York:
further waves through the twentieth century, Routledge.
paramount occasions for incumbent rulers and Bahro, H., Bayerlein, B. and Veser, E. (1998)
challenging opposition groups to decrease the ‘Duverger’s concept: Semi-presidential gov-
ernment revisited’, European Journal of
global costs of changing political institutions
Political Research, 34: 201–24.
and deal with innovative rules and formulas. In Bates, R.H. (2001) Prosperity and violence: The
general, self-interested actors may try to enlarge political economy of development. New
the opportunities to compete for power posi- York: W. W. Norton.
tions by creating multiple institutional levels Bellamy, R. (Ed.) (2005) ‘Symposium: A united
submitted to elections, such as the separation of states of Europe? (with Alberta Sbragia,
the presidency from the assembly, the embodi- Sergio Fabbrini, Glyn Morgan, Paul Magnette
ment of regional governments or the creation of and Justine Lacroix)’, European Political
newly independent units. Science, 4 (2): 175–8.
But institutional decisions may entail some Benoit, K. (2007) ‘Electoral laws as political
trade-offs between different levels and sets of consequences: Explaining the origins and
change of electoral institutions’, Annual
rules. As we have seen, federalism or territo-
Review of Political Science, 10: 363–90.
rial representation in large countries and Blais, A. and Massicotte, L. (1997) ‘Electoral
empires with diverse population may work as formulas: A macroscopic perspective’,
a substitute for proportional representation by European Journal of Political Research, 32:
giving different homogeneous, territorially- 107–29.
based groups opportunities to enter institu- Bobbitt, P. (2002) The shield of achilles. War,
tions and, thus, preventing a major electoral peace, and the course of history. New York:
reform. As another example, the introduction Alfred Knopf.
of direct presidential election may open a new Bogdanor, V. (ed.) (2003) The British constitu-
opportunity for electoral contest, but it may tion in the twentieth century. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
also constrain the degree of multipartism in
Boix, C. (1999) ‘Setting the rules of the game:
the assembly because it is always submitted to
the choice of electoral systems in advanced
majority rule and thus fosters polarization. democracies’, American Political Science
Specific analyses of institutional design proc- Review, 93: 609–24.
esses need, thus, to place the question in the Cabinet Office (2005) Investing in prevention:
context of the global relationship of forces An international strategy to manage risks of
among the relevant political actors and take instability and improve crisis response.
into account the exchanges in which they can London: Prime Minister’s Strategy Unit.
enter on parallel settings for multiple choices. Available: http://www.cabinetoffice.gov.uk/
strategy/work_areas/countries_at_risk.aspx
Burns, J. (1965) Presidential government.
Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Caporaso, J., Marks, G., Moravcsik, A., and
REFERENCES Pollack, M. (1997) ‘Does the European Union
represent an N of 1?’, European Community
Ackerman, B. (2000) ‘The new separation of Studies Association Review, 10 (3): 1–5.
powers’, Harvard Law Review, 113: 633–729. Cheibub, J.A. and Limongi, F. (2002) ‘Modes
Badie, B. (1992) L’état importé. Essai sur l’occi- of government formation and the survival of
dentalisation de l’ordre politique. Paris: presidential regimes’, Annual Review of
Fayard. Political Science, 5: 151–75.

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


260 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

CIA (2000) State failure task force reports Duverger, M. (1955/1970) Institutions politi-
(Daniel C. Esty, Jack A. Goldstone, Ted ques et droit constitutionnel (11th ed.) Paris:
Robert Gurr et al.), Phase III Findings. Presses Universitaires de France.
Directorate of Intelligence. Duverger, M. (1978) Échec au roi. Paris: Albin
Colomer, J.M. (2001a) Political institutions. Michel.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Duverger, M. (ed.) (1980a) Le concept d’em-
Colomer, J.M. (ed.) (2001b) ‘The strategy of pire. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
institutional change’, Journal of Theoretical Duverger, M. (1980a) ‘A new political system
Politics, 13: 235–48. model: Semi-presidential government’,
Colomer, J.M. (ed.) (2004) Handbook of elec- European Journal of Political Research, 8 (2):
toral system choice. New York: Palgrave– 168–83.
Macmillan. Duverger, M. (ed.) (1986) Les régimes semi–
Colomer, J.M. (2005a) ‘It’s the parties that présidentiels. Paris: Presses Universitaires de
choose electoral systems (or Duverger’s laws France.
upside down)’, Political Studies, 53 (1): Duverger, M. (1996) Le système politique fran-
1–21. çais (21st edition). Paris: Presses Universitaires
Colomer, J.M. (2005b) ‘Policy making in divided de France.
government’, Public Choice, 37: 1. Duverger, M. (1998) La constitution de la
Colomer, J.M. (2006) Grans imperis, petites France. Presses Universitaires de France.
nacions, Barcelona: Proa; (Spanish trans. Eisendstadt, S.N. and Rokkan, S. (eds.) (1973)
Grandes imperios, pequeñas naciones. Building states and nations (2 vols). Beverly
Barcelona: Anagrama) Hills-London: Sage.
Colomer, J.M. (2007a) Great empires, small Elgie, R. (ed.) (1999) Semi-presidentialism in
nations. The uncertain future of the sover- Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
eign state. London: Routledge. Evans, P.B., Rueschmeyer, D. and Skocpol, T.
Colomer, J.M. (2007b) Instituciones políticas (eds) (1985) Bringing the state back in.
(2nd edition) Barcelona: Ariel. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Colomer, J.M. and Negretto, G.L. (2005) ‘Can Finer, S.E. (1997) The history of government
presidentialism work like parliamentarism?’, from the earliest times (3 vols) Oxford:
Government and Opposition, 40 (1): 60–89. Oxford University Press.
Cooper, R. (2003) The breaking of nations. Flinders, M. (2002) ‘Shifting the balance?
Order and chaos in the twenty-first century. Parliament, the executive and the British
New York: Atlantic Monthly Press. constitution’, Political Studies, 50 (1):
Correlates of War project (n. d.) University of 23–42.
Michigan. Retrieved February 28, 2008, from Fukuyama, F. (2004) State-building: Governance
www.correlatesofwar.org. and world order in the 21st century. Ithaca,
Dahl, R.A. (2002) How democratic is the NY: Cornell University Press.
American constitution? New Haven: Yale Fund for Peace and Foreign Policy (2005) The
University Press. failed states index. Foreign Policy, July–
Dahl, R.A. and Tufte, E.R. (1973) Size and August.
democracy. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Gallagher, M. and Mitchell, P. (eds.) (2005) The
Press. politics of electoral systems. Oxford: Oxford
Doyle, W. (1978) The old European order University Press.
1660–1800. Oxford-New York: Oxford Gleditsch, K.S. and Ward, M.D. (2007)
University Press. Expanded war data. Retrieved February 28,
Dunleavy, P. (2005) ‘Facing up to multi-party 2008, from http://privatewww.essex.ac.
politics: How partisan dealignment and PR uk/~ksg/expwar.html
voting have fundamentally changed Britain’s Grumm, J.G. (1958) ‘Theories of electoral
party systems’, Parliamentary Affairs, 58: systems’, Midwest Journal of Political
503–32. Science, 2 (4): 357–76.
Duverger, M. (1951) Les parties politiques. Hammond, T. and Miller, G. (1987) ‘The core
Paris: Seuil (English trans. Political Parties. of the constitution’, American Political
New York: Wiley, 1954). Science Review, 81: 1155–74.

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:09:16 PM


INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN 261

Hume, D. (1741/1994) ‘Of the independence OECD The Fragile States Group. Retrieved
of parliament’, in K. Haakonssen (ed.), February 27, 2008, from www.oecd.org/
Political essays. Cambridge: Cambridge dac/fragilestates.
University Press, pp. 24–7. Ostrom, V. (1987) The political theory of a
Krehbiel, K. (1996) ‘Institutional and partisan compound republic: Designing the American
sources of gridlock: A theory of divided and experiment. Lincoln: University of Nebraska
unified government’, Journal of Theoretical Press.
Politics, 8: 7–40. Reynal-Querol, M. (2002) ‘Ethnicity, political
Krehbiel, K. (1998) Pivotal politics. Chicago: systems and civil wars’, Journal of Conflict
University of Chicago Press. Resolution, 46 (1): 29–54.
Levi, M. (1988) Of rule and revenue. Berkeley: Riggs, F. (1988) ‘The survival of presidentialism
University of California Press. in America’, International Political Science
Levi, M. (1997) Consent, dissent and patriot- Review, 9 (4): 247– 78.
ism. New York: Cambridge University Press. Riker, W.H. (1987) The development of
Lijphart, A. (Ed.) (1992) Parliamentary versus American federalism. Boston: Kluwer.
presidential government. Oxford: Oxford Riker, W.H. (1992) ‘The Justification of
University Press. Bicameralism’, International Political Science
Lijphart, A. (1994) Electoral systems and party Review, 13 (1): 101–16.
systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Riker, W.H. (1996) ‘European federalism: The
Lijphart, A. and Grofman, B. (Eds.) (1988) lessons of past experience’, in J.J. Hesse and
Choosing an electoral system. New York: V. Wright (eds), Federalizing Europe? The
Praeger. costs, benefits, and preconditions of federal
Linz, J.J. (1990a) ‘The perils of presidentialism’, political systems. Oxford: Oxford University
Journal of Democracy, 1 (1): 51–69. Press, pp. 9–24.
Linz, J.J. (1990b) ‘The virtues of parliamen- Rokkan, S. and Urwin, D.W. (eds.) (1983)
tarism’, Journal of Democracy, 1 (2): 84–91. Economy, territory, identity: Politics of West
Linz, J.J. and Valenzuela, A. (eds.) (1994) European peripheries. London: Sage.
The failure of presidential democracy. Sartori, G. (1994) Comparative constitutional
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University engineering. London: Macmillan.
Press. Shugart, M.S. and Carey, J.M. (1992) Presidents
Lipset, S.M. and Rokkan, S. (eds.) (1967) Party and assemblies. Cambridge: Cambridge
systems and voter alignments: Cross-national University Press.
perspectives. London: Collier–Macmillan– Skocpol, T. (1985) ‘Bringing the state back in:
Free Press. Strategies of analysis in current research’, in
Mainwaring, S. and Shugart, M.S. (eds.) P.B. Evans, D. Rueschmeyer and T. Skocpol
(1997) Presidentialism and democracy in (eds), Bringing the state back in. New York:
Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge Cambridge University Press, pp. 3–37.
University Press. Spruyt, H. (1994) The sovereign state and its
McEvedy, C. and Jones, R. (eds.) (1978) Atlas competitors. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
of world population history. Harmondsworth: University Press.
Penguin. Stepan, A. and Skach, C. (1993) ‘Constitutional
Morgenstern, S. and Nacif, B. (eds.) (2002) frameworks and democratic consolidation:
Legislative politics in Latin America. Parliamentarianism versus presidentialism’,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. World Politics, 46 (1): 1–22.
Negretto, G.L. (2006) ‘Choosing how to Taagepera, R. (1978a) ‘Size and duration of
choose presidents’, Journal of Politics, 68: empires: Systematics of size’, Social Science
421–33. Research, 7: 108–27.
Nino, C. (1992) El presidencialismo puesto a Taagepera, R. (1978b) ‘Size and duration of
prueba. Madrid: Centro de Estudios empires: Growth-decline curves, 3000 to
Constitucionales. 600 BC’, Social Science Research, 7:
Norris, P. (2004) Electoral engineering: Voting 180–96.
rules and political behavior. Cambridge: Taagepera, R. (1979) ‘Size and duration
Cambridge University Press. of empires: Growth-decline curves, 600 BC

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:09:17 PM


262 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

to 600 AD’, Social Science History, 3 (4): Tilly, C. (1985) ‘War making and state
115–38. making as organized crime’, in P.B.
Taagepera, R. (1997) ‘Expansion and contraction Evans, D. Rueschmeyer and T. Skocpol
patterns of large polities: Context for Russia’, (eds), Bringing the state back in.
International Studies Quarterly, 41: 475–504. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp.
Taagepera, R. (2001) ‘Party size baselines 169–87.
imposed by institutional constraints’, Journal Van Creveld, M.L. (1999). The rise and decline
of Theoretical Politics, 13 (4): 331–54. of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge
Taagepera, R. (2007) Predicting party sizes: The University Press.
logic of simple electoral systems. Oxford: Von der Muhll, G.E. (2003) ‘Ancient empires,
Oxford University Press. modern states, and the study of govern-
Taagepera, R. and Shugart, M.S. (1989) Seats ment’, Annual Review of Political Science, 6:
and votes. New Haven: Yale University Press. 345–76.
Tilly, C. (ed.) (1975) The formation of national Zielonka, J. (2006) Europe as empire: the
states in Western Europe. Princeton, NJ: nature of the enlarged European Union.
Princeton University Press. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

9781412919760_Chap13.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:09:17 PM


14
Comparative Political Behaviour:
What is being Compared?
Shaun Bowler

INTRODUCTION from within a broader theoretical perspec-


tive. What has helped this shift in perspective
The literature on electoral studies and elec- is a combination of a growth in the number
toral behaviour is vast, and growing. Any of democratic states (i.e., cases) coupled with
review of the literature must therefore neces- the development of large scale cross national
sarily be limited, and this chapter is no excep- data collection efforts. These two trends have
tion in picking out only a few elements from provided the basis for the comparative study
that vast literature. In what follows we are of mass behaviour and allowed the literature
concerned not so much with the specific part to move from making inferences about how a
of political behaviour being modelled so much particular case differs from or is similar to
as the implications and limitations of the kinds US experience and to being talking about
of comparisons being made. That is, there are comparative political behaviour.
a large number of studies of political behav- In what follows we distinguish between two
iour – of turnout or of vote choice and so on broad approaches within this overarching
but in this chapter the focus is not just on the category of comparative political behaviour.
kinds of political behaviour under view but One approach focuses on similarities of social
also the kinds of comparisons being made. trends across nations, the other on cross-
For a considerable period the intellectual national institutional comparison and the con-
history of electoral studies was driven by sequent differences between nations. Both of
American experience and examples. While these approaches have helped to make great
there are important intellectual strands that strides in the development of a comparative
still derive from American theoretical devel- approach to political behaviour, but each of
opment – the intellectual shift has been away them has a series of strengths and weaknesses
from seeing the electoral world through an that are tied to the kinds of comparisons they
American lens as we begin to see American make and the kinds of theoretical claims
experience as one of a class of problems which interest them.

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


264 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

could be treated more or less as if it were an


THE ‘FIRST’ GENERATION: THE
interval scale. The mapping of this psycho-
TWIN BUILDING BLOCKS OF A logical model to a single left-right policy
MODEL OF VOTE CHOICE – PARTY dimension was an added bonus. In party sys-
IDENTIFICATION AND ECONOMIC tems that were dominated by two large parties
VOTING this did not present too many problems. Where
politics was defined by a predominantly two-
With relatively few exceptions initial attempts party system such a model was acceptable.
at electoral studies outside the US were built The examples of Britain in the 1960s and
around a series of national election studies and 1970s, Germany in the 1970s and, for a while
were developed in light of insights taken from at least, Canada outside of Quebec in the same
the American context and typically by American period all seemed to have elements that made
researchers. Thus much of the very early work them ripe for analysis using American centred
on voting and voting behaviour considered vote models. There were some difficulties but since
choice as a major object of study and examined these only concerned minor parties or rela-
the role of party identification, leader assess- tively small fractions of the political system
ments and issue positions as drivers of vote they could be sidestepped. But genuinely
choice. Party identification was – as in the multi-party systems would seem to inherently
American context – a central focus and discus- challenge the idea of a single dimension. In
sions of its antecedents and/or its stability the 1980s the German party system began to
occupied considerable attention. Gradually, fol- change in new ways. Where, for example,
lowing developments in the US literature, the should one place ‘weakly identifying’ German
set of topics and questions addressed broad- Greens on the party identification scale – to
ened and work began to examine the impact the ‘left’ of the SPD or to the right of them?
of economic factors on vote choice in which These problems became even more pressing
incumbent performance on key economic indi- in nations such as the Netherlands or Italy
cators was seen to drive vote choice over and with many viable parties. Party identification
above party identification. could either be seen to be represented by one
In general this strand of work saw a series measure per party or require at least two
of high-quality studies of individual coun- dimensions – one measuring intensity and
tries and the development of national elec- another reflecting the ‘left-right’ policy posi-
tion studies in the mould of the American tion. Regardless of challenges to a ‘single
National Election Study and conducted for dimension’ of politics posed by debates over
example in Britain, Canada and Germany. post-materialism (see below), the concept of
But the multi-party nature of politics out- party identification seemed to have to be
side the US limited the applicability of models treated as multi-dimensional outside the US.
derived in the American two party setting. At Multi-partyism poses a similar challenge
the very least, American models could not be to the simple but extremely powerful argu-
applied ‘off the shelf’. For example, in models ment of retrospective voting.1 The retrospec-
of party identification it became common- tion involved voters judging the performance
place to represent party identification on a of the incumbent on economic issues and, if
single continuum ranging from strongly iden- that performance was seen to be lacking the
tifying leftists via weakly identifying leftists voter would cast a vote for the challenger. A
through to weakly identifying rightists and standard approach was to use aggregate data
on to strongly identifying rightists. One of to model the popularity function of an incum-
the major advantages of this measurement bent party, prime minister or president: vote
approach was that it meant that, as a variable, shares and/or popularity would go up when
partisanship could be represented by a single economic times were good and down when
dimension and, further, that this dimension economic times were bad.

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL BEHAVIOUR: WHAT IS BEING COMPARED? 265

Again, multi-partyism necessarily implies provided by one or the other of the twin pil-
that the simple version of the argument needs lars of voting studies – party identification or
to be revised: in a three party system with issue-voting based on economic indicators of
one party in power the voter still has to some kind.
choose which party to vote for; in a four or These kinds of studies took us a great way
five party system and coalition government along the road to understanding representa-
the voter also has to decide whether all part- tive democracy in various nations around the
ners to the government are to be voted world. But the comparisons were limited by
against or whether one coalition member the use of the US as a benchmark. That is, the
may nevertheless be worthwhile. Thus, while framing of research questions was implicitly
it is possible within say a popularity function in terms of how well or poorly the US model
approach to quite readily see a prime minis- worked rather than an attempt to fold US
ter’s popularity dip in response to economic experience into a more general model of
downturns it can be harder to predict which voter behaviour. That is findings were often
party will pick up votes in consequence. couched in terms such as ‘by contrast to
Certainly the problems posed by multi- American experience, the experience of
partyism for the two-party (‘American’) country X shows …’. Glimpses of a more
model are not insurmountable. For example, sustained and more forcefully comparative
more sophisticated estimation techniques approach to voting behaviour could be seen
(multi-nomial logit/probit) can handle the in two influential sets of studies: one set of
question of the impact of multi-partyism in a studies concerned ‘political culture’ and the
choice framework (e.g., Alvarez and Nagler, second concerned voter turnout. We will
1998). But the point here is simply that while address the political culture literature in more
the early theoretical running of comparative detail below. For the moment we will con-
electoral studies was made by American sider the literature on turnout.
models they could not be applied wholesale While models of partisanship or of eco-
and ‘off the shelf’ into other experiences. nomic voting took as their main objects of
This point mattered because the ‘compara- inquiry who the voter would choose – either to
tive’ part of comparative political behaviour identify with or to vote for – models of turnout
often meant a series of case studies and pair- took an even more basic question as its start-
wise comparisons with the US typically ing point: would the voter cast a ballot at all?
being the benchmark country of comparison. Work in this area took an expressly compara-
More ambitious work examined data from tive approach – whether comparing across US
across several different countries, but the over- states or across nations – to include institu-
arching theoretical models remained the famil- tional factors in the analysis. For example,
iar ones of partisanship, economics and – variations in electoral rules were seen as a
to some extent – the social underpinnings of major driver in variations in the motivations of
both those factors. For example, one strand voters to turnout (e.g., Blais and Dobryzynska,
of work considered the class basis of parti- 1998; Franklin, 2004; Jackman, 1987).
sanship and whether it was withering or not. Unsurprisingly, compulsory voting is an
A related strand considered class differences important determinant of turnout. More sur-
in the kinds of economic factors of interest prisingly, perhaps, proportionality of the elec-
in which, say, working class voters being toral system was also seen as a major positive
more concerned with unemployment force in prompting people to go out to vote.
than inflation while the more job secure This literature thus began to locate individual
middle class voters were more concerned behaviours within a context defined by institu-
with inflation than unemployment. Even tions. But the expressly comparative approach
in these more sociological flavoured stu- of these turnout studies was largely restricted
dies intellectual anchors would be typically to explaining the one variable – turnout.

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


266 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

A SECOND GENERATION OF STUDIES: examine democratization it also brought about


NEW DATA TO ADDRESS OLD AND an increase in the number of cases that scholars
NEW ISSUES could examine.3 It also helped generate a series
of studies on democratization that were
Beginning in the 1990s, however, a number of expressly comparative and allowed scholars to
developments meant a step forward in the range assess the relative impacts of, for example,
of topics and theoretical approaches that could economic factors on support for democracy as
be addressed from within a genuinely compara- opposed to more political or value laden factors
tive framework. One important step was the (e.g., Duch, 1995; Evans and Whitefield, 1995;
gradual cumulation of cross-national data col- Rose et al., 1998). This was only possible
lections. A series of major data collection because surveys were fielded across these new
projects meant the collection of data across a democratic nations more or less in ‘real time’ as
number of countries at the same time. One democratization unfolded.
prominent example is the Euro-barometer series Cross-national work of this kind raises issues
of public opinion polls which are conducted at of translation across languages that are them-
the same time across all EU member states. selves worth further study and affect our ability
Other examples include the World values sur- to conduct cross-national work sensibly (Blais
veys, the Latinobarometer and the CSES effort et al., 2001; Sinnott 1998). But the availability
to co-ordinate across national election surveys.2 of properly conducted opinion polls which
It is difficult to imagine now, but the early asked the same questions of citizens in may dif-
post-WWII studies were conducted in an era ferent states and often at the same time meant
when public opinion polling was relatively new that the literature as a whole could begin to
and, since it relied on face-to-face interviews, address more comparative questions of interest.
very labour intensive. Extensive public opinion Furthermore, these surveys allowed researchers
polling in the early years was therefore restricted to go beyond the simple behavioural compari-
to a few, richer, states (Britain, Canada, son of variation in turnout to examine affective
Australia) and ones of particular concern for and cognitive underpinnings of mass behaviour
historical reasons (Germany). But it meant that across a newer and wider range of cases than
in some senses the study of opinion was – to before in an explicitly comparative approach.
borrow a term – ‘frozen’ by historical circum- These more explicitly comparative approaches
stance. The only new democracies from 1945 can be loosely categorized into two broad
to 1989 were essentially the cases of Germany, groups. The first of these can be loosely termed
India, Italy and Japan. If these countries were as ones that are interested in ‘socio-cultural’
not surveyed at the time of democratic forma- approaches to citizen politics and in particular
tion it became extremely difficult to draw firm the use of political culture as an explanation.
conclusions about democratic values and The second, newer group, is more institutional
democratization in retrospect. For example, in outlook and much less interested in cultural
even if one interviewed the elderly in 1980 it explanations. We examine each in turn.
would be difficult to draw conclusions about
what went on in the 1950s in those nations for
obvious reasons of memory and memory-loss.
It seemed that the chance to study the demo- SOCIO-CULTURAL APPROACHES
cratic moment had gone. By 1989, however, TO THE STUDY OF COMPARATIVE
when a new set of countries became democra- MASS BEHAVIOUR: SIMILARITIES
cies, researchers were ready with a range of ACROSS NATIONS
survey tools to examine the transitions in
Eastern Europe and elsewhere brought about Above we noted that many of the early elec-
by the fall of the Berlin wall. Not only did the toral studies were largely pair-wise compari-
fall of the wall bring about a second chance to sons in which one country was compared to

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL BEHAVIOUR: WHAT IS BEING COMPARED? 267

another – usually the US. A major exception One of these research programmes has been
to the single country case study approach in to cast an understanding of politics in genera-
the early years of electoral studies was tional terms. In a series of works Inglehart
Almond and Verba’s study of civic culture advanced the argument that different genera-
(1963). This was one of the first systematic tions come with different political outlooks
and sustained attempts to move beyond a (Inglehart, 1977, 1990). In casual conversa-
single country study to establish a compara- tion one might, as a passing generalization,
tive framework for the study of public opin- refer to the ‘Depression era baby’ or ‘boom-
ion and attitudes. The study was of five ers’ as a short-hand for a group of people of a
countries – Britain, the US, Germany, Italy certain age. For Inglehart such generational
and Mexico – and it sought to establish a markers often come with a meaningful pack-
‘culture’ or way of doing politics in those age of political attitudes and predispositions.
nations. Among the conclusions of the study This is a more subtle analysis than one in
was that Britain and the US had a ‘partici- which shifting trends in demographics are
pant’ culture in which citizens were engaged identified and their consequences teased out.
in democracy and, hence, supportive of it. To be sure, the changing class composition of
This kind of culture contrasted with that of the societies have electoral fortunes of parties: as
‘subject’ political culture of Mexico in which the blue collar working class shrank over the
citizens did not expect to take part in politics twentieth century so, too, did the ‘natural’
and consequently helped non-democratic constituency of traditional socialist parties
forms of government persist (Almond and (see for example, Franklin et al., 1992 for an
Verba, 1963). excellent extended discussion of these kinds
Since its publication the study has come in of trends). Inglehart’s argument, however,
for sustained criticism. But the study remains is not that the composition of the electorate
a landmark in conceptualizing democracy at changes in terms of who is a member –
the mass level and attempted to do so within a although that does play its part – so much as
comparative framework. Nevertheless, doubts that what the electorate wants changes.
remain about a cultural approach to mass The big change, for Inglehart, is the shift
behaviour. Perhaps the most straightforward to a new politics of ‘post-materialism’ driven
criticism is the observation that the attitudes of by the accumulation of material wealth and
voters could be a product of the political resources.4 There have been more elaborate
system, rather than a cause and so cultural examples of what is meant by the term post-
arguments often muddle cause and effect. In materialism since then but the original survey
addition the ‘political culture’ argument of instrument (question) gives a straightforward
Almond and Verba was subject to a series of means of understanding the difference in
criticisms that apply to attempts to apply attitudes being identified:
labels to nations, that is, that they are impre-
If you had to choose among the following things,
cise in defining the mechanisms at work, they which are the two that seem the most desirable to
are definitionally blurred and often assign a you?
level of homogeneity to nationalities that is, at
best, over-stated and, at worst, inconsistent l Maintaining order in the nation.
with the main thesis. l Giving people more say in important political
Two subsequent research programmes have decisions.
sought to address some of these criticism by l Fighting rising prices.
seeking to be more specific about the mecha- l Protecting freedom of speech.
nisms at work and, also, by being more spe-
cific about the behaviours that are affected and Affirmative responses to options 2 and 4 in
so have breathed new life into the idea of civic that list are taken as signs of post-materialism.
culture. Inglehart anticipated that younger, more

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


268 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

affluent, voters who no longer experience (Dalton, 2004, 2007). That is, voters develop
worries over economic scarcity should be higher expectations of government and of
more ready to support those two responses. politics and seek more avenues for participa-
He further expected that these responses tion. Thus newer generations of citizens are
should become more and more prevalent at the same time less trusting of government
over time. and traditional means of participation but are
Unfortunately, those expectations were often more participatory in general (see
not quite borne out. While significant por- Dalton, 2007). While clearly related to the
tions of the electorate can be said to be ‘post- arguments of post-materialism this approach
materialist’ they do not seem to have produced is more specific both in its object of explana-
a wholly new way of conducting politics. tion (trust in government) and also in identi-
‘Materialist’ concerns persist in a number of fying some of the mechanisms at work to
ways, either the responses to these survey produce the trends.
questions are seen to fluctuate in response to Another, but ultimately somewhat less suc-
economic circumstances that suggests that cessful, way in which cultural explanations
attitudes may not be so much a cultural shift have been revived is through a series of argu-
more a short-term response to circumstances ments about ‘social capital’ which comprises
(see for example, Duch and Taylor, 1993 and the second of the research programmes that
subsequent debate). More worryingly still, essentially modernize and update the socio-
the share of post-materialists seems not to cultural arguments typified by Almond and
have grown very much despite a genera- Verba. These social capital arguments have a
tion of economic prosperity (and the genera- long intellectual history but in the modern
tional replacement of older ‘materialist’ period became highly influential due to the
voters by younger post-materialist ones): work of Robert Putnam (Putnam, 2000;
‘post-materialists’ do not seem to have Putnam et al., 1993). Putnam’s is a much more
become the dominant cultural or generational specific version of a cultural argument than
force. the ones seen in earlier work of Almond and
One area in which identifying generational Verba but very much in the same theme: indi-
shifts has had more success than others has viduals who engage in social groups, sports
been in discussing the changing attitudes groups, civic associations, choirs and the like
towards government and governing. The are expected to be much more participatory
1990s saw a wave of concern about declining and, also, have a set of values that aid demo-
regard for politics and politicians. When one cratic governance. An even more specific ver-
looked at the time series of public sentiment sion of this argument is found in Verba et al.
on trust in government or satisfaction with (1995) who argue that engagement in social
democracy the trends seemed in a secular organizations builds specific skill sets of
trend downwards in the post-war period. In organizational ability among individuals. That
and of themselves these trends worried many is, learning how to manage a mailing list for a
as an erosion of regard for democratic gov- child’s soccer team is little different from
ernance. In the work of Norris and Dalton we managing a mailing list for a candidate or
see painted – in very broad-brush terms – a lobby group and, hence, in building organiza-
generational model of what drives trust in tional skills informal social organizations such
government grounded in careful analysis of as children’s soccer teams or charities also
cross-national data series. Both authors build the human capital that makes democratic
develop broadly similar themes to document participation easier. To some extent, we could
the rise of what Norris calls the ‘critical citi- see the effect of the lack of social capital in the
zen’ (Norris, 1999). Dalton’s approach, for immediate post-wall period in Eastern Europe.
example, is carefully grounded in a social- While the scope for democratic action
psychological model of cognitive resources expanded very quickly ordinary citizens were

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL BEHAVIOUR: WHAT IS BEING COMPARED? 269

unaccustomed to such freedom after a genera- drawn depend in part on the implicit compari-
tion (or more) of one party rule. It is not clear son being made.
that people did at first understand the limits of The growing series of opinion data and the
democratic practice. If they went on a protest growing number of democratic countries
march could they shout slogans? Were they have, over time, provided the means by
allowed to wave banners? Could they chal- which scholars can begin to understand social
lenge any onlookers verbally? People did not changes and democratic politics. Early work
know how to behave.5 on cultural or socio-cultural trends have been
The literature on social capital has taken re-cast and re-worked into more concrete and
full advantage of the range of cross-national more focused examples of ‘cultural’ under-
survey evidence now available, most notably pinnings to politics both in terms of becom-
in the work of van Deth and Hooghe, to ing more specific about the objects of interest
examine the implications of the argument (the set of dependent variables) and also the
beyond a single country or, even, a small set mechanisms that produce the changes (the
of groups. Despite, and in some instances independent variables). Nevertheless, and
because of, the considerable body of work on despite the successes, these literatures do
this topic it has not been widely influential as have some limitations. At the risk of some
an intellectual project (see Newton, 2001 and generalization, by focusing on generational
van Deth, 2003 for a thorough conceptual trends in attitudes and widely shared sets of
assessment: Hooghe and Stolle, 2003 for a values or opinions these analyses typically
cross-national application). Some of van see democratic politics as being caused by or
Deth’s work, for example, in part confirms brought about by social change.
some of Weber’s conjectures to the effect that In a sense, this is a theme that has remained
heavy social engagement can lead to political within socio-cultural approaches since the
disengagement (van Deth, 2000). Other work days of Almond and Verba. Democratic insti-
notes that even groups that are hostile to tutions – while not exactly a ‘black box’ –
democratic values invest heavily in various tend not to be dealt with in any sustained
bonding kinds of social capital. Indeed, it way. There are, of course, exceptions to that
may be precisely these sorts of groups – statement but in general socio-cultural
extremist, revolutionary and possibly even approaches tend to assume the trends should
violent – who invest most heavily in building be seen across institutional environments and
social capital among their members. While not to develop detailed discussion of the
the literature on social capital is extensive, kinds of institutions that may be brought
and discussions of it tap very readily into about by cultural change. The socio-cultural
popular discussions of ‘what’s wrong with approach seeks similar trends across many
society today?’ the evidence in support of the nations and so resembles a ‘most different’
effects of social capital is more equivocal and systems research design. This approach is of
less certain than many proponents would course important if the goal is to identify and
care to admit. trace similar trends across different countries
One of the concerns about over time com- but it does give short shrift to differences
parisons of course is the time period taken as a between countries; differences which persist
starting point. For example, if one of the con- even if one accepts that the time trends are
cerns is that regard for democracy has declined similar and driven by similar processes.
since the 1960s one might wonder what would Socio-cultural approaches also invest voters
happen if the 1930s were chosen as the start with a great deal of agency. That is, at least
point since that period saw widespread support in the sense that voters in their aggregate
for both fascism and communism among voters have agency because political consequences
across the democratic world – including the US follow on from changes in the electorate or
and Britain.6 Again, then, the conclusions being changes among voters. What voters do or how

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


270 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

electorates change shape political institutions Wlezien (1997) and Bingham Powell (2000)
and the process of democracy but the institu- who take as a central concern the accounta-
tions do not, in turn, shape voters. It is not, bility of governments, a key feature of demo-
however, entirely clear that voters do have cratic governance and one that is closely tied
such agency. Nor is it clear that the causal to the literature on economics and voting.
arrow flows from citizens to institutions but While that literature assumed the institu-
not vice versa. Buried within socio-cultural tional context of a two party (US) system
approaches, then, is an implied argument on subsequent scholars began to model those
the limitations of democratic institutions. At a assumptions more explicitly.
very general level variation in institutional One key underpinning to the idea of
form simply does not seem to matter very accountability is that voters be able to iden-
much; what matters in this literature are gen- tify the government responsible for policy
eral trends at the level of citizens. A more action. In fact, in democratic politics, voters
recent literature has developed a very different have to be able to hold governments account-
understanding of comparative electoral stud- able for their actions in systematic ways. For
ies by seeking to embed studies of voting representative democracy to work voters
behaviour within its institutional context. In need to be able to ‘throw the rascals out’ of
doing so they have developed a different set of office and put the competent people into
research concerns from those that underpin office. But it is much easier for voters to
socio-cultural approaches. identify who is responsible for the conduct of
policy in some systems than in others. In
particular, voters find it far easier to hold
single party governments accountable than to
THE ‘DECISION DEPENDENCE’ assign responsibility for actions in coalition
OF VOTING: AN INSTITUTIONAL systems. In this way, the literature tying
APPROACH TO CROSS-NATIONAL shifts in economic variables to government
VARIATION popularity can be made richer. It is not
simply that economic factors inform voter
In focusing on the institutional context of assessments, but how they manage those
voters, vote choice and voter behaviour it is assessments and indeed whether they can act
not only possible to begin to build a more upon them depends on institutional context.
general model of voter behaviour it is also Powell’s (2000) work goes a step further
possible to begin to understand some of the to consider the ways in which governments
more fundamental mechanisms of represent- are not just accountable but also representa-
ative democracy. That is, there is a strong tive. In doing so, he can begin to make com-
component of ‘decision dependence’ when it parisons across systems about important
comes to understanding voters; both their normative concepts. Powell compares the
decisions and decision making processes are left-right (policy) positions of voters to the
dependent upon the institutional context in left-right positions of governments arguing
which they are embedded. that the closer the government position is to
It thus becomes not just possible but also the position of the median voter then the
necessary to examine the ‘decision depend- closer the government is to being representa-
ence’ of voters when we begin to frame ques- tive. On average, coalition governments are
tions of interest in terms of cross-national closer to the median voter than are single
variation in political institutions rather than party governments. In which case, coalition
cross-national similarity in social processes. governments may be more representative
Important examples of work in this area kinds of governments even as they may be
have been a series of books and papers by less accountable, thus revealing an underly-
Chris Anderson (2000, 2007) Anderson and ing trade-off in the nature of representative

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL BEHAVIOUR: WHAT IS BEING COMPARED? 271

democracy – at least so far as parliamentary using these data is a look at the prevalence of
democracy is concerned. tactical or strategic voting. In principle all
There are a series of questions one could electoral systems should see some form of
raise about this general approach – and espe- strategic voting (see Shiveley, 2005). Most
cially in relation to the topic of representation. famously, perhaps, is the tactical voting that
For example while the median voter is an underlies (and is caused by) the bias against
important figure in rational choice theory it is smaller parties in first past the post systems.
less clear that they are well suited to normative But by comparing across systems it is possi-
evaluations of democracy. Furthermore even ble to examine which electoral systems
assuming that a single left/right scale is appro- encourage or allow more strategic voting
priate to use across all polities, there may be than others (see also Gschwend, 2007).
problems in matching this across governments Similarly it is possible to examine the moti-
and mass publics. Powell (2000) himself is vations of voters across different systems: do
very careful to try a series of measures in look- voters weigh the personal characteristics of
ing for the gap between median voter and gov- candidates more heavily in some systems
ernment position, but while public opinion than others? We know, for example, that
surveys are extremely useful at establishing some electoral systems provide incentives
where voters may fall on a left right scale find- for candidates to seek a personal vote (Carey
ing a properly commensurable scale for where and Shugart, 1995; Farrell and Scully, 2007)
governments fall is much harder if – as is often but is it the case voters depend more heavily
the case – the voters are not asked to place the on assessments of individual candidate
government on the same scale. One solution attributes to arrive at a decision in some sys-
used is to rely on expert surveys of party place- tems than others? More generally still, the
ments which, as Powell is careful to demon- model of vote decision making with its vari-
strate, do provide consistent measures.7 ous components of partisanship, issue and
Nevertheless, what the work of Powell and candidate assessment, may have varying
others does is to follow along a similar path weights across different electoral systems.
to the literature on turnout: it advances a Thus the model of individual vote choice can
theory of individual political action that is be informed by institutional context that is
embedded within a theory of institutions – more or less permissive of tactical concerns
and seeks to test it. Furthermore, the range of and that values or discounts certain kinds of
opinions and attitudes that are assessed by information.
these cross-national surveys opens up the A similar set of institutional questions
possibility to test more or less any kind of tying institutions to attitudes can relate to at
model of voter choice, voter behaviour or least some of the questions studied from
opinion formation with regard to institutional within a socio-cultural framework. Take, for
and political variations. instance, the example of an understanding of
Perhaps the most sustained example of this satisfaction with or trust in democracy.
approach comes in the Comparative Study of Leaving aside the question of trends over
Electoral Systems project. In this project time and whether the trends are shared or
members of national election survey teams not, persistent differences in levels of trust
agree to ask a common set of questions and exist across nations. These differences may
the data from these surveys are made availa- be rooted in different institutional arrange-
ble. In addition a number of questions about ments. Shiveley (2005), for example, notes
the nation’s political institutions are also col- that satisfaction with democracy may vary
lected and made available.8 with the decentralization and concentration
This combination allows the marrying of political power. Alienation from govern-
of individual and institutional level variables ment may be determined by the ‘nationaliza-
in a number of ways. One example of work tion’ of politics. As more decisions are made

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


272 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

at the national level – and fewer at the local often overshadows the sub-national dimen-
level – then politics may seem more remote sion. There are several reasons for a greater
from citizens and, hence, less trustworthy. appreciation for sub-national studies. Cross-
Mistrust of government may reflect a sense national comparisons can still invite criticism
of perceived distance from government – in from a cultural perspective: if people are also
which case decentralization of power may embedded in cultural ‘institutions’ that are
help re-engage citizens. Evidence consistent not appropriately measured then the models
with this argument comes from the literature (of turnout, trust or accountability) will be
on ‘second order’ elections in which voter under-specified and may provide omitted
turnout is, in part, driven by how consequen- variable bias. Within-country comparisons
tial the election is to voters (Marsh, 1998; should reduce the number of omissions while
Percival et al., 2007; Reif and Schmitt, 1980). at the same time allowing a focus on institu-
If elections simply do not matter very much to tional effects.
voters – if not very much is at stake – voters Furthermore, if the election of interest is a
will not turn out and vote. Again, then, the national level general election then these are –
kinds of voter decision-making we see – over more or less by definition – atypical: they are
turnout and affect towards the political proc- high profile, high spending, and high stakes
ess – are shaped in fundamental ways by the elections. US Presidential elections, for exam-
type of decision they are asked to make at ple, are probably the most studied elections,
election time. yet they are the least typical elections. The
Even after the election we may see conse- more usual kind of elections are local ones –
quences of the kinds of decisions voters are low information and low-engagement elec-
asked to make in terms of how citizens feel tions. The comparison across regions or
about the government in power. Anderson political units within a single country, then,
and Guillory (1997) and Anderson et al. should provide scope for work on whether
(2005) also address how different institu- institutions do, in fact, make a difference (see
tional arrangements shape satisfaction e.g., Hoffmann-Martinot et al., 1996).
with democracy. Politics – and elections in Second, the study of the institutional bases
particular – sort citizens into ‘winners’ and of mass behaviour and public opinion has
‘losers’ but different political systems make helped generate over-confidence in our abil-
the loss and the sense of loss greater than ity to bring about changes in voter opinions
others. So, for example, single party ‘winner and behaviours. Take, for example, this state-
take all’ systems make citizens from the ‘out’ ment made by IDEA (Institute for Democracy
parties feel a greater sense of loss than multi- and Electoral Assistance – http://idea.int/
party coalition systems that build broad bases elections/index.cfm) – an international think
of support. tank on electoral design:
The institutional approach thus considers The choice of electoral system is one of the most
a different set of questions than the socio- important institutional decisions for any democ-
cultural approach. It has also developed a racy. Electoral systems define and structure the
rules of the political game; they help determine
series of successes in understanding how and
who is elected, how a campaign is fought, the role
why elections vary across nations. As the of political parties, and most importantly, who
research programme on the institutional governs. Furthermore, the choice of an electoral
effects is worked out, however, several issues system can help to ‘engineer’ specific outcomes,
remain to be worked on. such as to encourage cooperation and accommo-
dation in a divided society. (IDEA, 2008)
First, while the focus to date is often on
cross-national comparison there is a great This is a fairly typical kind of statement in
deal of value to making comparisons across part because the tie between electoral sys-
sub-national units – states, provinces or even tems and electoral behaviour appears to be
cities. But the emphasis on national politics both clear-cut and well understood. But it is

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL BEHAVIOUR: WHAT IS BEING COMPARED? 273

far from clear how precisely we can engineer consider. While it is true that political parties
outcomes. Much of our confidence in the may be seen as organizations rather than
ability to engineer outcomes comes from the institutions one would think that – even as
results of cross-sectional models – but it is organizations – their actions are likely to
not always clear that we have established have as much impact on election outcomes as
appropriate causal relations. There are very less formal associations and organizations
few examples of being able to track changes that build social capital. Yet political parties
among the public in light of institutional and their actions are often absent from
changes. New Zealand may be one of the few models looking at political behaviour in this
cases for which we have the data available to institutional sense.
track these kinds of concerns.9 Similarly, some institutional effects really
Our over-confidence in our ability to engi- compare not just one institution to another but
neer is related, in part, to a third issue: there is bundles of institutions to other bundles of
a need for greater theoretical work on institu- institutions. For example the distinction
tions and their effects. Certainly, some work on between consensus and majoritarian democra-
socio-cultural patterns does not seem to be ter- cies is due to Lijphart, who has formed a
ribly theoretically sophisticated either. In fact in major conceptualization of democratic institu-
some instances early work on social trends tions taken up by the literature to date (e.g.,
seems to involve identifying trends in data post Lijphart 1984, 1994). It is hard to understate
hoc. By contrast to such work the institutional Lijphart’s contribution in ‘bringing institu-
approach seems to be much more theoretically tions’ back in to the comparative study of
driven. Nevertheless, there is some scope for representative democracy. Yet his categories
greater theoretical development within the are not simply one institution but bundles of
institutional approach. While the guiding institutions – some of which are related to
impulse is to examine mass behaviour embed- each other in obvious ways (coalition govern-
ded within the context of institutions the theo- ments and PR for example), but other aspects
ries of institutions we examine often involve of which are not (central bank independence
very large-scale differences. Much of the work and federalism). Furthermore, these categories
on electoral systems in the vein of Duverger’s seem not so much to be theories in themselves
Law considers different effects of ‘first past the as inductively arrived at ideal types (grounded
post’ and list PR systems. These differences in the contrast between British/New Zealand
seem to be real and persistent. But these two experience on the one hand and Dutch experi-
electoral systems are very different from each ence on the other) that operate in different
other; ranged in-between these two extreme ways. To be sure, there are consequences and
points are a series of electoral systems that may hypotheses that can be drawn from his models.
or may not have such stark effects. Our confi- And the influence of his work in many differ-
dence seems to be a product more of our under- ent areas shows just how important his catego-
standing of the more extreme examples of rization has been. Nevertheless, the differences
electoral systems rather than the range he discusses are broad ranging and broad
of ground in between. A better understanding brush. It is not entirely clear which institu-
of institutions might help better ground our tional arrangement within a given bundle is
confidence in our ability to engineer.10 the most important one, or whether its effects
Relatedly, it is not always clear that the are contingent on or interactive with the
literature shares a common definition of what effects of other institutions. The comparison
constitutes an institution. The de facto choice across bundles of institutions, then, can still
of institutions included in analysis often leave a degree of uncertainty about what is
seems to gravitate towards the formal and doing the work.
constitutional rather than the less formal, but In part because institutional approaches
this need not be the only kind of institution to are sometimes somewhat under-theorized

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


274 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

beyond the general belief that we should see CONCLUSION


institutional effects it might, therefore, be
worth exercising more caution about our col- As we noted at the outset, any review of such
lective capacity to engineer before investing a vast literature as that on electoral studies
too heavily in an institutional approach. After cannot pretend to be encyclopaedic. In this
all, if only large-scale differences in institu- review large sections of the literature have
tional arrangements make a difference to simply been put to one side in order to focus
mass behaviours and attitudes then perhaps more on the kinds of comparisons that are
there is only limited scope for institutional being made by different kinds of work in
arguments? comparative electoral studies.
Finally, experimental methods have What we have termed a socio-cultural
remained relatively under-utilized to date but approach is often genuinely comparative in
would seem especially appropriate to use to scope. But the framing of these studies is
explore institutional arguments. The ability such that the work is often aimed more at
to conduct comparative work has been sup- identifying similarities across nations than in
ported by the range of available survey data exploring differences between them. This
and the range of statistical tools available to seems to be especially the case when it
analyze those data. For example, hierarchical comes to identifying whether political insti-
or multi-level models now mean there is a tutions have an effect, and if so how. By
way to appropriately combine ‘country level’ contrast the institutional approach suggests
institutional factors and individual level data. that political institutions are seen to have a
But experimental methods have a great deal of great deal of impact over the way that citi-
promise to allow scholars to focus on the zens feel and act within representative
micro-mechanisms of opinion and attitude for- democracy. It is an approach that emphasizes
mation across different institutional contexts. the differences and de-emphasizes similari-
Heaney and Hanson (2006) note the contribu- ties, and it is this approach that seems to be
tions of the Chicago based scholars Gosnell, the more vigorous one at present as the con-
Merriam and others in the 1920s and 1930s in sequence of an institutional perspective are
using experimental techniques. The advent of worked out.
large scale public opinion polls seemed to have This chapter has, then, identified two broad
pushed aside this kind of experimental work categories of work within the literature on
until their re-popularization in the American comparative electoral studies that have differ-
context (e.g., Druckman, 2004; Gerber and ent theoretical and substantive concerns that
Green, 2000: Lupia and McCubbins, 1998). are tied, in part, to the kinds of comparisons
Some work outside the US setting has been they make. The growing sophistication of sta-
conducted using experiments. Bochel and tistical and experimental tools and the ever-
Denver (1971) for example is a fore-runner growing collection of data means that the
of the Gerber and Green experiments on capacity to make meaningful comparisons is
inducing voter turnout from the British case, better now than at any previous time. To the
while other experimental work has proved extent there are limitations in the kinds of
especially valuable in developing societies comparisons that may be drawn they seem to
where survey work may be difficult to con- be based in theoretical constraints rather than
duct (e.g., Duch and Palmer, 2004; practical ones such as data availability. In
Wantchekon, 2003; Whitt and Wilson, 2007). many ways the theoretical impetus given by
The scope for more work of this kind seems ideas on social capital and on an institutional
especially promising. As with other tech- process have either run their course or, at least
niques, however, the value of the results in the case of institutional studies, are gradu-
depends on strong theory. ally being worked out. One other possible

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL BEHAVIOUR: WHAT IS BEING COMPARED? 275

source of new theoretical energy may be for 4. Ingelhart’s work also marks a major conceptual
more empirically minded scholars to reengage improvement over some socio-cultural approaches in
that he does develop an explicit theory and a set of
with normative political theory. Many of the predictions; some socio-cultural approaches that are
earliest studies of voting were often heavily content to describe demographic patterns after the
influenced by normative concerns over the event.
ideal citizen grounded in the work of theorists 5. The ‘skill set’ argument is not something to take
such as John Stuart Mill (Berelson, 1952). on board without questioning. Some of the skills being
discussed would not seem to require too steep a learn-
To some extent the work of Dalton and ing curve and – hence – not require a long apprentice-
others has already begun the process of re- ship in non-profits or other informal groups. Similarly, it
engagement with newer normative concerns is not clear what makes someone volunteer as an
such as those over deliberation and revised organizer in an informal group to begin with. Perhaps
definitions of citizenship. Similarly, current these skills are just markers for socio-economic status,
for example, being a stay-at-home parent or grandpar-
concerns about the relationship between ent who used to work in an office with PCs.
Islam and democracy will give an impetus to 6. See, for example, footage of the Cable Street
inter and intra national comparisons concern- Riots in London in 1936 http://www.youtube.com/
ing the relationship between religious values watch?v=-AQDOjQGZuA. Similarly, some of the dis-
and democracy. Even so, it may be an appro- cussion of social capital seems to suggest that things
have become ‘worse’ in a social capital sense from
priate point to attempt a more systematic some idealized ‘good old days’ in which people got
re-engagement. along with their neighbours and volunteered a lot
more. Given that the ‘good old days’ of the 1950s
and 1960s were also associated with high levels of
racism, sexism and homophobia coupled with lower
NOTES levels of education, wealth and home ownership one
could be forgiven for wondering whether the good
old days were really that good.
1. A major impetus for this attention to economic
7. More vigorous critiques of some aspects of the
factors came from outside the voting studies litera-
Lijphart-Powell conjectures and a flavour of some of
ture itself and more from the late 1970s and early
the debates may be found in Pinto-Duchinksy (1999).
1980s literature on the political business cycle, that
8. There is an extensive web presence of the CSES
is, the argument that governments manipulated
project see http://www.cses.org/resources/results/
macro-economic levers for electoral advantage.
results.htm
While issue positions had been a big part of voting
9. Saideman et al. (2002) are an exception – they
studies the heavy emphasis on economics and the
use a pooled time series analysis to look at ethnic
subsequent debates over ‘retrospective’ versus ‘pro-
conflict and electoral institutions.
spective’ and ‘pocket book’ versus ‘socio-tropic’
10. Newer theoretical work on institutions – for
voting did not occur until after the political business
example Tsebelis’ work on veto players – may help
cycle literature.
address some of these issues. Tsebelis’ argument, for
2. As something of an aside we should note that
example, can easily be seen as a way to ground at
in recent years, too, data collection for some single
least some studies of comparative electoral behav-
country cases have surpassed, and often far sur-
iour such as those relating to accountability or effi-
passed, the example of the American National
cacy (Tsebelis, 2002).
Election Study in terms of the kinds of questions that
may be investigated. The Australian, British, Canadian
and New Zealand election studies have especially
well-developed ‘value-added’ components compared
to their American counter-parts. These national sur- REFERENCES
veys may include candidate surveys, rolling cross-
sections, media analysis or combinations. The data
Almond, G. and Verba, S. (1963) The civic cul-
are also readily available.
3. The main effects of the post 1989 changes, ture: Political attitudes and democracy in five
however, remain the dramatic improvements in the nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
lives and well-being of millions of people as well as a Press.
series of traumas suffered by large numbers of Alvarez, R.M. and Nagler, J. (1998) ‘When
people in the transitions. politics and models collide: Estimating

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


276 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

models of multiparty elections’, American communist regimes’, The Journal of Politics,


Journal of Political Science, 42: 55–96. 57: 121–58.
Anderson, C.J. (2000) ‘Economic voting and Duch, R.M. and Palmer, H. (2004) ‘It’s not
political context: A comparative perspective’, whether you win or lose, but how you play the
Electoral Studies, 19 (2–3): 151–70. game: self-interest, social justice, and mass
Anderson, C.J. (2007) ‘The end of economic attitudes toward market transition’, American
voting? Contingency dilemmas and the limits Political Science Review, 98: 437–52.
of democratic accountability’, Annual Review Duch, R.M. and Taylor, M. (1993) ‘Post-
of Political Science, 10: 271–96. materialism and the economic condition’,
Anderson, C.J. and Guillory, C.A. (1997) American Journal of Political Science, 37:
‘Political institutions and satisfaction with 747–78.
democracy: A cross-national analysis of con- Evans, G. and Whitefield, S. (1995) ‘The politics
sensus and majoritarian systems’, American and economics of democratic commitment:
Political Science Review, 91: 66–81. Support for democracy in transition socie-
Anderson, C.J. and Wlezien, C. (1997) ‘The ties’, British Journal of Political Science, 25:
economics of politics in comparative per- 485–514.
spective revisited’, Political Behavior, 19 (1): Farrell, D. and Scully, R. (2007) Representing
1–6. Europe’s citizens: Electoral institutions and
Anderson, C.J., Blais, A., Bowler, S., Donovan, T., the failure of parliamentary representation.
and Listhaug, O. (2005). Losers’ consent: Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Elections and democratic legitimacy. Oxford: Franklin, M.N. (2004) Voter turnout and the
Oxford University Press. dynamics of electoral competition in estab-
Berelson, B. (1952) ‘Democratic theory and lished democracies since 1945. Cambridge:
public opinion’, The Public Opinion Quarterly, Cambridge University Press.
16: 313–30. Franklin, M., Mackie, T., and Valen, H. (1992)
Blais, A. and Dobrzynska, A. (1998) ‘Turnout in Electoral change: Responses to evolving
electoral democracies’, European Journal of social and attitudinal structures in Western
Political Research, 33 (2): 239–62. nations. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Blais, A., Gidengil, E., Nadeau, R., and Nevitte, Press.
N. (2001) ‘Measuring party identification: Gerber, A.S. and Green, D.P. (2000) ‘The
Britain, Canada, and the United States’, effects of canvassing, telephone calls, and
Political Behavior, 23: 5–22. direct mail on voter turnout: A field experi-
Bochel J.M. and Denver, D.T. (1971) ment’, The American Political Science Review,
‘Canvassing, turnout and party support: An 94: 653–63.
experiment’, British Journal of Political Gschwend, T. (2007) ‘Ticket-splitting and stra-
Science, 1: 257–69. tegic voting under mixed electoral rules:
Carey, J. and Shugart, M.S. (1995) ‘Incentives Evidence from Germany’, European Journal
to cultivate a personal vote’, Electoral Studies, of Political Research, 46: 1–23.
14: 417–39. Heaney, M.T. and Hansen, J.M. (2006) ‘Building
Dalton, R.J. (2004). Democratic challenges, the Chicago School’, American Political
democratic choices: The erosion in political Science Review, 100: 589–96.
support in advanced industrial democracies. Hoffham-Martinot, V., Rallings, C., and
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Thrasher, M. (1996) ‘Comparing local elec-
Dalton, R.J. (2007) The good citizen: How a toral turnout in Great Britain and France:
younger generation is reshaping American More similarities than differences?’, European
politics. Washington DC: Congressional Journal of Political Research, 30: 241–57.
Quarterly Press. Hooghe, M. and Stolle, D. (2003) Generating
Druckman, J. (2004) ‘Political preference for- social capital. London: Palgrave.
mation: Competition, deliberation, and the IDEA (2008). Electoral system design. Retrieved
(ir)relevance of framing effects’, American February 27, 2008, from http://www.idea.
Political Science Review, 98: 671–86. int/esd/
Duch, R.M. (1995) ‘Economic chaos and the Ingelhart, R. (1977) The silent revolution.
fragility of democratic transition in former Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


COMPARATIVE POLITICAL BEHAVIOUR: WHAT IS BEING COMPARED? 277

Ingelhart, R. (1990) Culture shift in advanced Putnam, R. (2000) Bowling alone: The collapse
industrial society. Princeton, NJ: Princeton and revival of American community. New
University Press. York: Simon and Schuster.
Jackman, R.W. (1987) ‘Political institutions and Reif, K. and Schmitt, H.H. (1980) ‘Nine second-
voter turnout in the industrial democracies’, order national elections: A conceptual frame-
The American Political Science Review, 81: work for the analysis of European election
405–23. results’, European Journal of Political
Karp, J.A. and Banducci, S.A. (2008) ‘Political Research, 8: 3–44.
efficacy and participation in twenty seven Rose, R., Mishler, W., and Haerpfer, C. (1998)
democracies: How electoral systems shape Democracy and its Alternatives:
political behavior’, British Journal of Political Understanding post-communist societies.
Science, 38 (2): 311–34. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hokins Press.
Lijphart, A. (1984) Democracies: Patterns of Saideman, S.M., Lanoue, D., Campenni, M.,
majoritarian and consensus government in and Stanton, S. (2002) ‘Democratization,
twenty-one countries. New Haven: Yale political institutions, and ethnic conflict: A
University Press. pooled, cross-sectional time series analysis
Lijphart, A. (1994) Electoral systems and party from 1985–1998’, Comparative Political
systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Studies, 35: 103–29.
Lijphart, A. (1999) Patterns of democracy: Shiveley, W.P. (2005) ‘Democratic Design: The
Government forms and performance in Comparative Study of Electoral Systems
thirty-six countries. New Haven: Yale Project’, Public Opinion Pros. Retrieved
University Press. March 26, 2008, from http://www.
Lupia, A. and McCubbins, M.D. (1998) The publicopinionpros.com/from_field/2005/oct/
democratic dilemma: Can citizens learn what shively.asp
they need to know? New York: Cambridge Sinnott, R. (1998) ‘Party attachment in Europe:
University Press. Methodological critique and substantive
Marsh, M. (1998) ‘Testing the second-order implications’, British Journal of Political
election model after four European elec- Science, 28: 627–50.
tions’, British Journal of Political Science, 28: Tsebelis, G. (2002) Veto players: How political
591–607. institutions work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Newton, K. (2001) ‘Trust, social capital, civil University Press.
society, and democracy’, International van Deth, J. (2000) ‘Interesting but irrelevant:
Political Science Review, 22 (2): 201–14. Social capital and the saliency of politics’,
Norris, P. (ed.) (1999) Critical citizens: Global Western Europe European Journal of Political
support for democratic government. Oxford: Research, 37 (2): 115–47.
Oxford University Press. van Deth, J. (2003) ‘Measuring social capital:
Percival, G., Currin-Percival, M., Bowler, S., and orthodoxies and continuing controversies’,
van der Kolk, H. (2007) ‘Taxing, spending, and International Journal of Social Research
voting: voter turnout rates in statewide elec- Methodology, 6: 79–89.
tions in comparative perspective’, State and Verba, S., Lehman Schlozman, K., and Brady,
Local Government Review, 39 (3): 131–43. H.E. (1995) Voice and equality: Civic volun-
Pinto-Duschinsky, M. (1999) ‘A reply to the tarism in American politics. Cambridge, MA:
critics’, Representation, 36 (2): 148–55. Harvard University Press.
Powell, Bingham G. (2000) Elections as instru- Wantchekon, L. (2003) ‘Clientelism and
ments of democracy: Majoritarian and pro- voting behavior: Evidence from a field
portional visions. New Haven, CT: Yale experiment in Benin’, World Politics, 55:
University Press. 399–422.
Putnam, R., Leonardi, R., and Nannetti, R. Whitt, S. and Wilson, R. (2007) ‘The dictator
(1993) Making democracy work: Civic tradi- game, fairness and ethnicity in postwar
tions in modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Bosnia’, American Journal of Political Science,
University Press. 51: 655–68.

9781412919760_Chap14.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:12:46 PM


15
Changes in the Causes of
Democratization through Time
Barbara Geddes

INTRODUCTION authoritarian government that marks the start-


ing point of the transition, and characteristics
What do we now know about the causes of of the international political economy at the
democratization that we did not know nearly time of the transition. Since different kinds of
50 years ago when Seymour Martin Lipset autocracy dependent on different kinds of
(1959) wrote his famous article linking devel- economic systems have clustered in time and
opment with democracy? The answer is: sur- space (Gleditsch and Ward, 2006), and the
prisingly little. Indeed, some of the things we international political economy has also
thought we knew decades ago have been chal- changed over time, the causes of early transi-
lenged by recent research. Very fine minds tions tend to differ from later ones. If these
have worked on explaining democratization. observations are correct, they suggest the need
They have used multiple methodological tools, for explanations of democratization that take
including in-depth case studies, small-N these differences into account. In this chapter,
research designs comparing events in several I suggest several such arguments. I also sug-
countries, large-N statistical tests using sophis- gest ways to interpret a number of empirical
ticated specifications and newly available data findings about the causes of democratization
sets, economic models, and game theory. And that makes sense of apparent inconsistencies.
yet, we have accumulated only a small store of The chapter proceeds as follows. The next
knowledge about which most scholars agree. section summarizes the current state of
Instead, serious, carefully done research chal- research on democratization in three parts:
lenges nearly all theories and findings, and empirical findings; measurement issues; and
they remain contested. theoretical models. The following one articu-
In this chapter, I suggest that one of the lates in greater detail the starting characteris-
main reasons for the inability of careful tics that I believe systematically affect the
researchers to arrive at consensus about the democratization process. It also summarizes
causes of democratization is that causes differ evidence supporting and challenging these
systematically depending on features of interpretations. Finally, it discusses the use-
the economy of the old regime, the kind of fulness of various theoretical arguments for

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 279

explaining particular trajectories of democra- longer period of time, Gleditsch and Choung
tization. The last section suggests a future (2004) and Pevehouse (2002) also found no
research agenda and some new ways of test- relationship between development and tran-
ing arguments about democratization. sitions to democracy after controlling for
characteristics of countries’ neighbors.
Other analysts, however, challenge these
arguments. In a very careful reanalysis that
THINGS WE USED TO KNOW BUT extends the time period back to 1850, Boix
NOW AREN’T SO SURE ABOUT and Stokes (2003) show that development
does contribute to democratic transitions,
As Lipset (1959) showed, more developed though the average effect for the whole
countries are more likely to be democratic period is small relative to the effect of devel-
than the less developed. The correlation opment on maintaining democracy. Boix and
between democracy and development has Stokes (2003) show that when the data set is
been demonstrated repeatedly in the ensuing divided by time periods, however, economic
decades in increasingly sophisticated large-N development is an extremely important pre-
studies (Barro, 1999; Bollen and Jackman, dictor of transition prior to 1950, but has only
1985; Burkhart and Lewis-Beck, 1994; a small (though statistically significant) effect
Gasiorworski, 1995; Przeworski et al., 2000). in the post-1950 period. In short, we still
Lipset’s (1959) argument that various conse- know that democracy is correlated with
quences of economic development cause development, but the causal reasons for the
democracy provoked controversy from the correlation remain contested.
beginning, however, and that controversy Several other empirical associations have
continues. During the first ten or so years of also achieved the status of stylized facts,
what Samuel Huntington (1991) labeled the though all have also been challenged. Multiple
Third Wave of democratization, as the last studies show that oil wealth is associated with
West European holdouts and most of the autocratic government (Barro, 1999; Fish,
more developed countries of Latin America1 2002; Ross, 2001). Countries with large
joined the democratic club, the argument that Muslim populations are less likely to be
development causes democratization seemed democratic (Fish, 2002). As with the relation-
confirmed, especially when the collapse of ship between development and democracy,
the Soviet Union brought most of the rest of controversy continues about whether these are
the ‘misplaced’ countries into the club causal relationships or correlations explained
(Diamond et al., 1988). At about the same by something else. Among those who believe
time as the Soviet collapse, however, a large relationships are causal, there are disagree-
number of poor, less developed countries in ments about the processes through which the
Africa, South Asia, and Latin America causes produce the outcome.
democratized, raising new doubts. Many Middle East experts explain the cor-
In seeming confirmation of these doubts, relation between oil wealth and dictatorship
the very sophisticated large-N study by as a consequence of the ability of ‘rentier
Przeworski and colleagues (2000) claims states’ to use revenues derived from the sale
forcefully that development has no effect on of natural resources to distribute subsidies to
democratization. Instead, they argue, it is the large parts of the population and thus to
tendency of democratic governments in maintain popular compliance with authori-
poorer countries to break down that leads to tarian government (Anderson, 1987; Crystal,
the correlation, not the greater likelihood that 1995). In a parallel argument, Dunning
dictatorships in more developed countries (2006) claims that oil rents can in some cir-
will democratize. Using a different measure cumstances be used to sustain democracy,
of democracy and a data set covering a much though Karl has claimed the opposite (1997).

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


280 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

In contrast to the various arguments about the the analyst wants to use a measure to estab-
effects of oil on regime type, Herb (2005) lish the universe within which to test an
shows that when a measure of development argument expected to hold only in one
that excludes the effect of oil is used in place kind of regime, a dichotomous measure is
of GDP per capita in statistical analyses, oil required.
rich countries fit the same patterns as other These measurement differences are one of
countries. Development, as Herb measures it, the sources of contending claims about the
has a strong positive effect on changes in causes of democratization, as analysts some-
democracy scores, whereas rent dependence, times produce different results depending on
measured separately, has no effect. In short, whether they have measured ‘democratiza-
he challenges the existence of a relationship tion’ as incremental steps toward democracy
between oil wealth and regime type, as well (using polychotomous measures) or as com-
as the rentier state argument per se. pleted transitions (using categorical or
Some observers have explained the corre- dichotomized measures). For example,
lation between adherence to Islam and autoc- Epstein et al. (2006) show that using a tri-
racy as caused by an affinity between Muslim chotomous measure of democracy instead of
doctrine or the attitudes of believers and the dichotomous indicator Przeworski et al.
authoritarianism, but public opinion research (2000) used changes their results; develop-
done in countries with substantial Muslim ment does appear to cause democratization.
populations shows that individual Muslims Development seems to affect movement into
support democratic values (Sarkissian, 2006; and out of their intermediate category, which
Tessler, 2002). Fish (2002) suggests that might be labeled mild authoritarianism,
Muslim countries tend to be authoritarian not but not transitions from full dictatorship to
for the reasons usually mentioned but because full democracy. Since the word democratiza-
of the suppression of women’s rights. tion can mean either steps toward the
democratic endpoint or completed transition,
neither measure is obviously right or wrong,
but claims to have identified causes of
DISAGREEMENTS ABOUT democratization without specifying which
MEASUREMENT meaning is captured by the measure used
contribute to the plethora of claims and
The waters have been further muddied by counterclaims.
disagreements about the appropriate meas- Democratization can take place either in
urement of democracy. The main disagree- incremental steps or in a rapid leap from
ment is over whether dichotomous categorical harsh dictatorship to fully competitive
or polychotomous2 measures are ‘better’ democracy. Since incremental steps in one
(Alvarez et al., 1996; Elkins, 2000). The direction can be followed by steps in the
answer to this question need not detain us: other, however, we cannot assume that reduc-
which is ‘better’ depends on what question tions in repression or other changes that are
the analyst seeks to answer. In studies of reflected in incremental differences in democ-
democratization, in which the measure is racy scales will lead to completed regime
generally used as the dependent variable, if transitions – though they may. At the same
the analyst seeks to explain incremental time, citizens’ lives can be much affected by
movement toward democracy, then a poly- these incremental changes, and there is cer-
chotomous ordinal scale is better.3 If the tainly reason to explain them. Referring
dependent variable to be explained is com- to incremental changes on democracy
pleted transitions, then a categorical or scales as democratization, however, causes
dichotomized measure is useful. Likewise, if confusion.

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 281

to the need to explain the correlation. In


WHAT CAUSES THE CORRELATION 1999, Barro noted: ‘Given the strength of the
BETWEEN DEVELOPMENT AND Lipset/Aristotle hypothesis as an empirical
DEMOCRACY? regularity, it is surprising that convincing
theoretical models of the relation do not
Moving beyond empirical correlations to exist. Thus development of such a theory is a
explain why the correlations exist requires priority for future research’ (S182). That has
tests of arguments about the causal processes changed. Several scholars have proposed
that have been suggested. Economic develop- plausible deductive arguments that identify
ment is correlated with many other trends, and underlying causes of democratization. They
one or more of those may be the causal mech- model interactions between elites, who want
anism that accounts for the relationship to monopolize power, and citizens, who want
between development and democracy. Lipset to influence policy and therefore demand to
(1959) and other modernization theorists sug- share power. The advantage of explicit deduc-
gested that increasing education, equality, tive models of the democratization process,
urbanization, experience working in factories, besides clarity, is that they usually have many
and the weakening of traditional loyalties to implications that can be tested against real-
tribe and village – all correlates of economic world experience. The next section discusses
development – would lead to more tolerant recent models of the process of democratiza-
and participatory attitudes among citizens, tion and the evidence supporting them.
who would then demand a say in government.
Many of these arguments have been tested. A
correlation between education, especially
primary education, and democracy is well MODELS OF DEMOCRATIZATION AS
established (Barro, 1999). The results on STRATEGIC INTERACTIONS BETWEEN
urbanization are mixed. Working in factories ELITES AND CITIZENS
contributes to more democratic attitudes
(Inkeles and Smith, 1974). These studies test Models of the interactions between ruling
the implications of arguments linking indi- elites and others that may lead to democratiza-
vidual traits to demand for democracy. They tion can be divided into two categories depend-
do not consider the interests that might oppose ing on their basic assumptions about who the
democratization (since the arguments they relevant actors are and what their goals are.
seek to test did not). They seem to assume that Some models assume that the most important
if citizens want democracy, they can achieve division within society is between rich and
it, without giving much attention to the possi- poor, and that the rich form and maintain dic-
ble reluctance of elites to give up power. tatorships in order to protect their assets. They
Scholars influenced by Marx expect the also assume, as do many other economic
middle class – which tends to grow as the models of politics, that the key policy decision
economy develops – to be the carrier of that determines redistribution is the level of
the demand for democracy: ‘no bourgeoisie, taxation on domestic capital. It is assumed that
no democracy.’4 Zak and Feng (2003) have the median voter, who is poor, prefers high
modeled a process through which this rela- taxes in order to redistribute wealth. The more
tionship might unfold. Though Zak and Feng unequal the income distribution, the poorer
do not test their model, Barro (1999) shows a the median voter and thus the more confisca-
relationship between the income share of the tory the tax rate is expected to be in a democ-
middle class and democracy. racy. (The median voter in these models has
The development of theoretical models never met ‘Homer.’5) Autocratic elites only
of democratization is an alternative response democratize because of the threat of violence

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


282 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

or revolution. In these models political leaders they fear it less because the median voter’s tax
are perfect agents of societal interests; they do preferences will then be less confiscatory.
not maximize their own revenue distinct from Elites are willing to cede some power rather
the revenue of the elite group they represent. than risk revolution when they expect democ-
An alternative conception of autocracy racy to lead only to moderate redistribution.
assumes that the most important division in Boix (2003) also argues that capital mobil-
society is between the rulers (sometimes sim- ity, which, like income equality, tends to rise
plified to a single dictator) and the ruled. with development, contributes to democrati-
They assume that rulers maximize their own zation. When capital is mobile, it can flee in
income from tax revenue at the expense of response to high taxes. Knowing that, demo-
both rich and poor ruled. Rulers thus set cratic governments are expected to refrain
taxes at the highest rate that does not deter from heavy taxation; so elites need not fear
economic effort by citizens. In these models, democracy. Thus elites’ interests can be pro-
rulers offer increments of democracy when tected by either a relatively equal income
doing so can increase the credibility of their distribution or capital mobility. Where capi-
promises to provide public goods and other tal mobility is low and income unequal, how-
policies that will increase economic growth ever, elites should be unwilling to negotiate
and thus benefit both rulers and ruled (Escribà democratization.
Folch, 2003; North and Weingast, 1989; Boix’s book (2003) is a seminal contribution
Weingast, 1997). Alternatively, rulers may to the literature on democratization because it
offer democratic institutions as a means of provides plausible micro-foundations for the
directly increasing revenues (Bates and Lien, observed correlation between development and
1985; Levi, 1988; Rogowski, 1998). In these democracy. The analysis covers nineteenth and
models, the ruled care about growth and the early twentieth century democratizations as
share of their own production they are well as more recent ones, and it includes a seri-
allowed to keep. Taxation is not seen as a ous effort to test the argument. Nearly all other
means to redistribute to the poor, but rather quantitative studies of democratization have
as a means of enriching rulers. Rulers become looked only at the post-World War II period
rich by ruling; they do not rule because they because of data limitations. Boix has made a
were rich before achieving power. They cling huge effort to overcome those limitations. His
to power in order to continue collecting rev- study has not resolved all debates, however,
enue from the productive population under because the empirical support for the argument
their control, not to protect themselves from is somewhat ambiguous. Although he finds that
redistribution. The main constraint on rulers’ income inequality has a substantial effect on
pursuit of wealth is the threat of capital flight the likelihood of democratization in a data set
or reduction in economic effort. that covers 1950–1990, some of the other evi-
dence either fails to confirm expectations or can
be interpreted in more than one way. In short,
Rich rulers versus poor ruled although Boix’s argument is plausible and
attractively simple, empirical support for it is
Boix (2003), Acemoglu and Robinson (2001, modest.
2005), and Zak and Feng (2003) argue that Furthermore, it does not take into account
democratization is more likely when income the capacity of rulers to limit capital mobility,
distribution – which tends to even out as coun- especially capital outflows. It treats capital
tries reach high levels of development – is mobility as exogenous, but governments in
more equal. Boix and Acemoglu/Robinson fact have substantial capacity to regulate capi-
argue that elites fear redistribution, which they tal outflows (Wong, 2007). If elites are more
expect to result from democratization. But likely to acquiesce in democratization if
when income distribution is relatively equal, they can protect themselves by sending their

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 283

capital abroad, then why would dictators not empirical tests so we cannot assess their fit
limit capital outflows in order to prevent elite with the real world.
defections? The Boix argument fits well with Models linking democratization to ine-
the stylized facts of West European democra- quality seem highly plausible, but the empir-
tization, however, and redistributive changes ical investigation of the relationship between
followed democratization there, as the argu- regime type and income inequality does not
ment would predict (Lindert, 1994). Further support their basic assumptions nor does
tests of this argument deserve to be important empirical investigation of the relationship
items on the democratization research agenda. between democracy and redistribution out-
Acemoglu and Robinson’s (2001) argu- side Europe. If these arguments were correct,
ment begins with many of the same basic we would expect to find the remaining dicta-
assumptions about the way the world works. It torships in the world more unequal on aver-
also gives a central role in resistance to age than democracies, but there is little
democratization to elites’ fear of redistribution evidence that the current set of recalcitrant
when the starting income distribution is une- dictatorships is made up of countries with
qual. They limit the threat of revolution to especially unequal income distributions
periods of recession, however, which compli- (Bollen and Jackman, 1985). In fact, in the
cates predictions. In this argument, when the post-World War II period, longer lived dicta-
rich are threatened by revolution (which only torships (excluding monarchies) have more
occurs during recession), they can grant redis- equal income distributions than brief ones.
tribution without changing the political system, Przeworski et al. (2000) find a positive rela-
grant democracy as a way of making the com- tionship between only one of three measures
mitment to redistribution credible, or repress. of inequality and transitions to democracy.
Redistribution without regime change is not They find a stronger relationship between
credible to the poor because they know that inequality in democracies and democratic
they cannot maintain the threat of revolution breakdown, which might explain any rela-
after the recession is over. According to tionship that exists between democracy and
Acemoglu and Robinson, democratization is a equality (if one does exist), but does not sup-
more credible commitment to maintaining port the idea that equality makes democrati-
redistribution over a longer time period. (Why zation more likely.
the poor should accept democratization as cred- The models also assume that the main rea-
ible when the model – conforming to reality – sons elites fear democracy and ordinary citi-
allows the rich to stage coups if they are zens want it is that they expect it to lead to
dissatisfied by the later tax rate is unclear.) redistribution. Lindert (1994) has shown that
In contrast to the Boix argument, Acemoglu the expected redistribution occurred in Western
and Robinson expect income inequality to Europe after the first steps toward democrati-
lead to unstable regime changes, not contin- zation were taken, but Mulligan et al. (2004)
ued authoritarianism. One of the attractive show that contemporary democracies do not
features of the Acemoglu and Robinson model on average redistribute more than dictator-
is that it explains repeated transitions between ships.6 We should not be surprised by this
democracy and dictatorship, a phenomenon result. Income distribution varied greatly
that has characterized some parts of the devel- among late twentieth century dictatorships.
oping world since the middle of the twentieth Many, both communist and non-communist,
century. The model seems to be a plausible expropriated traditional elites and redistrib-
simplification of events in much of Latin uted income and opportunities through land
America and in a few other developing coun- reform, much increased public education,
tries. Acemoglu and Robinson (2005) provide and industrialization policies that led to the
some suggestive evidence to support their movement of large numbers of people out of
arguments, but do not carry out systematic agriculture and into factories. It is hard to

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


284 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

imagine that ruling elites in these kinds of In some versions of this approach, societal
authoritarian regimes would be motivated by elites or holders of private capital can do
fear of greater redistribution. They would most to destabilize the regime if they are dis-
fear loss of their own power and wealth, but satisfied. Consequently, they are the ones
not via redistributive taxation. Income equal- most likely to be accommodated when the
ity would not reassure them because their ruler offers an institutionalized form of par-
power and wealth are tied to holding office, ticipation in return for their cooperation.
not to ownership of private resources pro- Rulers may offer representative institutions
tected by stable property rights. as a credible commitment to supply desired
Thus, neither of these models fit many of public goods (Escribà Folch, 2003; Levi,
the struggles over democratization in ex- 1988; North and Weingast, 1989) or simply
communist and developing countries, where in exchange for wealth holders’ contingent
fear of redistributive taxation is not a plausi- consent to the taxation of mobile capital
ble reason for resistance to democratization (Bates and Lien, 1985). As in the Boix (2003)
since substantial portions of productive assets argument, democratization becomes more
were state or foreign owned for much of the likely as capital becomes more mobile, but
late twentieth century. State elites who con- the reason for the relationship is different.
trol a large portion of productive assets may The more mobile capital, according to Bates
certainly fear loss of power since their access and Lien (1985), the harder it is to tax with-
to wealth depends on control of the state, but out contingent consent, and thus the more
they will not suffer less dispossession with a likely the ruler will offer representative insti-
more equal income distribution. tutions as a way of obtaining consent.
Rogowski (1998) suggests a more general
form of this logic in which citizens’ ability to
Revenue maximizing rulers versus move away increases the likelihood that
rulers will offer them representative institu-
politically powerless citizens
tions or good government in order to induce
In this approach to the study of democratiza- them, along with their productive capacity, to
tion, which owes much to seminal articles by remain within the ruler’s territory.7 Thus
North and Weingast (1989) and Olson (1993), these models explain the first small steps
rulers maximize their own individual revenue toward democratization from absolutist
via taxation, and citizens prefer low taxes and monarchy.
share a desire for productivity-enhancing Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003) suggest a
policies and public goods, regardless of their more complicated general framework that
income. In this image of politics, taxes redis- extends these models to cover more contem-
tribute wealth from citizens to rulers, not from porary transitions. Their model includes: a
rich to poor. Rulers may want revenue in order ruler supported by a winning coalition; a
to pursue wars, to buy support in order to stay ‘selectorate,’ meaning those citizens who
in power, to pay for repression, or for personal have some influence on who can join the
consumption; their reason does not affect the winning coalition; and residents who play no
logic of the argument. Rulers are motivated by role in selecting rulers. Rulers maximize per-
their desire for revenue to offer public goods sonal revenue via taxation constrained by the
that increase productivity and to impose a tax need to provide private and public goods in
rate that does not reduce investment or effort. order to maintain the support of the winning
Citizens demand regime change if they are coalition. If members of the ruling coalition
taxed too heavily or dissatisfied with current defect because they are dissatisfied with their
leaders’ provision of public goods and eco- share, the ruler loses office. Citizens outside
nomic performance. the winning coalition benefit only from the

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 285

public goods provided when the winning of citizens can challenge rulers, but does not
coalition is too large to be maintained by lead to democratization. This image is consist-
private goods alone. ent with the many real world elite-led democra-
Residents and members of the selectorate tizations, but offers no insight into the transitions
may hold demonstrations or join rebellions to of the late twentieth century in which reluctant
challenge rulers who tax them too heavily or elites were pushed into democratization by
provide insufficient public goods, but rulers popular upheaval.
in this model always respond with repres-
sion. If revolutionary challengers win despite
repression, the new rulers face the same
incentives that other rulers have to narrow the INTERNATIONAL INFLUENCES
winning coalition and keep resources for ON DEMOCRATIZATION
themselves. In other words, revolutions and
popular uprisings in this model do not Although models of democratization and
threaten redistribution or lead to democracy. most large-N empirical investigations have
Instead, they lead to a seizure of power by a focused on domestic causes, many observers
new leader and winning coalition, who maxi- of late twentieth century transitions have
mize their own wealth at the expense of those emphasized the importance of international
they exclude. One of the most useful and influences, especially the diffusion of demo-
empirically realistic points made by Bueno cratic ideas and pressure from international
de Mesquita et al. (2003) is that participation financial institutions (e.g., Bratton and van
in a coup, uprising, or revolution does not de Walle, 1997; Dunning, 2004; Whitehead,
guarantee the participant an improved share 1996). If international forces have a major
of power or wealth after the fall of the old effect on democratization, and especially if
regime because those who lead such move- there is an interaction between international
ments have incentives to renege on earlier and domestic factors, their exclusion from
promises after they win. statistical tests may explain some of the lim-
Thus democracy cannot arise as a response ited and contradictory results obtained in
to popular uprising in this model. This result these tests.
is reasonably consistent with reality. International factors have begun to be
Rebellions and revolutions rarely lead to included in empirical investigations.
democracy; instead, they lead to new dicta- Gasiorworski (1995), Gleditsch and Ward
torships, some of which are redistributive. (2006) and Gleditsch and Choung (2004)
Democratization, in the Bueno de Mesquita show that the proportion of democratic neigh-
et al. (2003) model, arises when the members bors increases the likelihood of transitions to
of the winning coalition can improve their democracy in the countries they surround,
own welfare by expanding the coalition’s lending some support to the diffusion argu-
size. This model, like those described above, ment. Pevehouse (2002) shows that member-
portrays democratization as elite led. In the ship in regional international organizations in
Bueno de Mesquita et al. model, however, which most other members are democratic
winning coalition elites are motivated simply increases the likelihood of democratization.
by wanting to improve their own welfare Since membership in democratic regional
relative to that of the ruler. They are not organizations is likely to be correlated with
responding either to a challenge from the having democratic neighbors, however, we
excluded or the threat of capital strike. cannot be sure whether organizations have
In these models, democracy is given by an independent effect beyond the effect of
leaders or other elites, not demanded or taken living in a ‘good’ neighborhood. Bueno de
by ordinary citizens. The political mobilization Mesquita and Siverson (1995), and Bueno de

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


286 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Mesquita et al. (1992) show that war affects large-N studies differ from each other
the survival of both political leaders and depending on specification, time period
regimes. Gleditsch and Choung (2004) show included, and cases used. Such varying
that wars increase the likelihood of transition results should be expected if single statistical
from one authoritarian government to another, models are being imposed on a set of dispa-
but neither Gleditsch and Choung (2004) nor rate processes without efforts to model how
Pevehouse (2002) shows strong evidence that the processes might differ over time or in dif-
war in the neighborhood decrease the likeli- ferent kinds of transitions. If quite different
hood of democratization. Marinov (2005) processes, involving different actors with dif-
shows that although sanctions are effective at ferent interests, can lead to democracy, more
bringing down democratic leaders, they have than one theory is needed. If we are trying to
little effect on the survival of dictators and use the same simple statistical model, verbal
therefore, we can infer, little effect on author- argument, or game theoretic model to explain
itarian breakdown.8 These findings suggest multiple disparate processes, we should not
that international influences should be be surprised if only the most basic features
included in explanations of democratization, can be clearly identified or if studies that
especially post-World War II since interna- focus on different regions, time periods, or
tional influences – both economic and politi- samples produce different answers, since dif-
cal – have probably become more pronounced ferent processes predominate in different
over time. time periods and regions.9
Many of the difficulties in theorizing the
process of democratization stem from the
under-theorized residual-category status of
HOW DEMOCRATIZATION authoritarianism, which has led to the usually
HAS CHANGED implicit assumption that characteristics of
the old regime have no effect on transitions.10
In this section, I describe ways that authori- If instead we classify democratization proc-
tarian government and the context within esses in terms of a few basic characteristics
which it exists have changed during the last of the autocracy and setting prior to democ-
two centuries in order to identify changes in ratization, we can then see that a number of
the causes of democratization. Autocracies the arguments currently contending for
vary in terms of the most basic characteris- preeminence fit one of the processes but not
tics of leaders and the organizations through all of them. Others are more useful for
which they cooperate with each other, the explaining democratizations that began at
economies from which they draw sustenance, other starting points.
the distribution of ability to influence politi- In the following sections, I discuss three
cal outcomes within the citizenry, and the issues that affect autocratic elites and other
international forces that buffet them. These political actors as they make choices that
differences, as I show below, affect the likeli- may or may not lead to democratization: the
hood of transition and how it occurs. extent of state ownership and intervention in
Nevertheless, we lump these disparate proc- the economy; changes in the international
esses of regime change together for explana- economy and geopolitical world that alter the
tion because the end state for all is democratic costs and benefits of autocrats’ domestic eco-
government. nomic and political strategies; and differ-
Assuming that there is one explanation of ences in autocratic institutions that affect
democratization despite these differences both their vulnerability to challenges and the
may be the reason that scholars continue to costs of leaving office, which in turn influ-
disagree about its causes. The findings of ences their willingness to negotiate.

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 287

Market economy versus state had strong incentives to seize the assets of
private wealth holders who might have
ownership and regulation
become sources of opposition, and many of
In countries with predominately market them did. In communist countries, of course,
economies, dictatorships have usually served governments owned all large firms and
the interests of the rich, consistent with the important resources, but nearly all develop-
Boix (2003) and Acemoglu and Robinson ing countries began pursuing state interven-
(2001, 2005) arguments. The relationship is tionist development strategies in the
endogenous, however. Dictatorships with mid-twentieth century. Oil and other key
other goals have used expropriation, state natural resources were either state-owned or
investment, and extensive intervention in the foreign-owned and heavily taxed in virtually
economy to reduce both the predominance of all. In countries endowed with natural
market forces and the political influence resources, government revenues came prima-
of wealthy interests. The most common form rily from either the export of state-owned
of autocracy in market-dominated economies resources or taxes on foreign-owned ones.
has been oligarchy, with or without monar- These revenues could be used to reward sup-
chy, though military governments have also porters, and additional intervention in mar-
arisen in these contexts. Though levels of kets created many more opportunities for
state ownership and regulation are deter- trading benefits for support.
mined by governments, oligarchies, as repre- State ownership makes possible both the
sentatives of the owners of private wealth, accumulation of wealth by political leaders
have no incentive to expropriate and and also the distribution of benefits to sup-
thus usually maintain private ownership. porters, and in some cases ordinary citizens,
Historically, such regimes tended to fade without high taxation of private wealth.
away as economies developed. This may Rulers who have acquired wealth through
have occurred through the kinds of processes access to state resources, in contrast to those
identified by Lipset and other modernization who hold political power because they own
theorists; as more citizens became educated, private wealth, have to fear losing most of
joined the middle class, and went to work in their assets if they are deposed, regardless of
factories, they demanded the vote, and in the income distribution or other factors that
many countries of Latin America and Western might affect future taxation.
Europe, eventually got it. The process may As long as the state interventionist devel-
also have been aided by the mechanisms opment strategy remained feasible, these
identified by Boix and Acemoglu/Robinson. regimes were not challenged by develop-
Elites may have been more willing to extend ment. In fact, those that provided good long-
the franchise where income distribution was term economic performance have been
more equal and capital more mobile. remarkably stable (cf. Przeworski et al.,
In the period from the end of World War II 2000). Some of these regimes increased
until about 1980, however, most authoritar- equality through the expropriation of tradi-
ian regimes governed countries in which tional elites, land reform, the spread of edu-
increasingly important parts of the economy cation, and rapid industrialization, which
were state-owned. In fact, dictatorships car- made it possible for many poor rural workers
ried out much of the expropriation and state to obtain better paying factory jobs. Others,
investment that resulted in these high levels however, worsened income distribution; they
of state ownership. Such strategies helped left traditional unequal land-owning patterns
them consolidate political power. Dictators intact, and urban bias inherent in import-
who rose to power via the military or leader- substitution industrialization strategies
ship of a nationalist or revolutionary party increased the wealth gap between rural and

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


288 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

urban areas (Bates, 1981). Citizens who empirical support for the idea that the causes
became better educated, got jobs in factories, of democratization might differ depending
or moved into the middle class were not for- on levels of state ownership of the economy
mally excluded from politics in these regimes, comes from the very careful Boix and Stokes
however; most of them held regular universal (2003) study showing a strong relationship
suffrage elections. In many, upward mobility between development and democratization
was available to the talented, who were co- before 1950 and a very weak relationship
opted into dominant parties. Thus, educated, from 1950 to 1990. The Przeworski et al.
ambitious citizens who might have led the study (2000), based on a sample drawn
demand for democratization according to entirely from the period of heavy state inter-
modernization theory were often accommo- vention, shows almost no effect of develop-
dated by mid-twentieth century autocracies. ment on democratization. Although the
The loss of the ability to intervene profit- evidence on the effects of income inequality
ably in their economies, rather than factors is not conclusive, in my judgment the bulk of
linked to development, challenged autocra- it suggests that less equal income distribu-
cies reliant on state ownership and other tions did not hinder democratization during
forms of state intervention. As they were the second half of the twentieth century.
forced by changes in the international econ- Capital outflows in the very late twentieth
omy to reduce regulation, end subsidies, and and early twenty-first centuries seem to have
sell state-owned assets, they lost the ability to no effect on the likelihood of democratiza-
continue delivering benefits to their support- tion, as would be expected if dictators regu-
ers, whether elite or mass. To the extent that late capital outflows (Wong, 2007).
these economic reforms gave ruling elites
the opportunity to transform state assets into
private property – as for example, during International influences
the economic reforms in Hungary before the
collapse of communism – elites feared the International forces have always influenced
loss of office less since their wealth was domestic politics through trade, international
secured. They were thus more willing to go prices, diffusion, and conquest. Big changes
along with democratization. Fears of losing in both the international economy and world
office may also be allayed by enforceable politics occurred in the late twentieth cen-
bargains not to prosecute for corruption and tury, and there are theoretical reasons to
human rights abuses (i.e., amnesties, allow- think these changes influenced democratiza-
ing outgoing rulers to take their ill-gotten tions. Globalization increased the weight of
gains into friendly exile) or institutional bar- international economic forces on national
gains that give them a good chance of return- decision making. Changes in the interna-
ing to office in competitive elections in the tional economy following the debt crisis of
future. the 1980s undermined the survival strategies
Most transitions from oligarchic rule to of a number of autocratic governments.
democracy in market-dominated economies Several geopolitical changes have also
occurred during the nineteenth and first half affected the likelihood of democratization.
of the twentieth centuries. Most transitions in Although it is rarely mentioned in studies of
the second half of the twentieth century democratization, during the nineteenth and
involved autocracies that intervened heavily early twentieth centuries, authoritarianism
in their economies, owned significant pro- was maintained in large parts of the world
ductive assets, and regulated capital outflows. through conquest. Empirical studies of democ-
A number of the empirical disagreements ratization exclude these areas because colonial
described above make sense if we take these possessions are not included in standard
differences into account. The strongest data sets, but many decolonizations resulted in

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 289

democratic government (often brief). The developing countries at low but variable interest
Cold War contributed to the maintenance of rates. With interest rates so low, most develop-
dictatorships, and its end seems to have con- ing countries borrowed heavily so that by the
tributed both to democratization and to transi- late 1970s, borrowing covered the need for
tions to milder forms of authoritarianism. capital inflows in most countries. When, in
response to the second oil price shock in 1979,
northern policy makers raised the interest rates
Changes in the international to which developing country debt was linked,
debt repayment became unmanageable. When
economy
Mexico declared itself unable to meet its debt
During the period of state interventionist obligations in 1982, the lending bubble burst.
development strategies, governments’ control Both lenders and investors fled developing
over economic assets provided the resources countries.
that held coalitions supporting autocracy Without these inflows, the state interven-
together. State ownership provided jobs for tionist economic strategy caused hyperinfla-
party cadres. Ruling families and their close tion and recession. Many governments
allies became rich from the creation of resisted economic reform because rulers
monopolies, subsidies, privileged access to understood the political difficulties it would
restricted imports, and other regulatory inter- create, but failure to change caused economic
ventions. In a strategy reminiscent of Henry crises, which also challenges regime sur-
VIII’s treatment of the monasteries, the vival. Crisis and the neoliberal reforms
expropriation of traditional and foreign undertaken in response to it reduced dicta-
wealth holders made possible the use of these tors’ ability to continue buying support and
resources to create new elites beholden to the thus contributed to the fall of many of them,
dictatorship. The debt crisis undermined this as erstwhile supporters deserted them and
political strategy because it challenged the ordinary citizens mobilized against them.
economic strategy upon which it depended. When foreign lending dried up, develop-
To understand how the debt crisis forced ing country governments faced intense eco-
changes in the state interventionist develop- nomic pressure to adopt policies conducive
ment strategy, we need to think about how the to attracting private investment. Prior to the
strategy worked in practice. State intervention- debt crisis, governments had a choice between
ist development strategies typically included relying primarily on state investment or pri-
high tariffs to protect domestically produced vate investment. Those that chose state
goods from foreign competition; overvalued investment did not have to offer credible
exchange rates to shift resources from the commitments to provide public goods, pre-
export sector (agriculture and minerals) to the dictable economic policy, or policies favora-
industrial; and high state spending on invest- ble to private investors in order to secure
ment, subsidies, social programs, and public revenue flows, and thus the economic pres-
employment. Since state spending outran tax sure to initiate institutional constraints on
collection, budget deficits were very common, rulers’ arbitrary powers was low. Since the
as were trade deficits caused by the overvalued 1980s, the state investment strategy has
exchange rates. An inflow of foreign capital in become unworkable except possibly in coun-
the form of investment, loans, and/or aid was tries reliant on the export of oil or other high
routinely needed to balance these deficits. priced natural resources. Consequently, gov-
During the 1970s, the sharp rise in the price of ernments have sought to attract private invest-
oil increased the availability and lowered ment. In short, changes in the international
the cost of international borrowing, as capital economy changed the costs and benefits
rich oil exporters put their excess into devel- associated with choices made by dictators,
oped country banks. The banks then lent it to political elites, and ordinary citizens.

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


290 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Attracting investment depends on credible nearby countries that took steps toward democ-
policy commitments and secure property rights. ratization ended, and aid to dictatorships from
As noted by North and Weingast (1989), both sides fell. For recipient countries, the
Acemoglu and Robinson (2001), Escribà Folch drop in aid further reduced the resources avail-
(2003), and others, policy promises made by able for distribution to the dictator’s support-
dictators inherently lack credibility. Dictators ers, compounding the problems caused by the
can increase the credibility of these promises debt crisis and its aftermath.
by creating institutions that give capital holders For countries in the former Soviet sphere of
a say in policy-making and that increase the influence, the desire to enter the European
constraints on the dictator’s arbitrary power. Union increased incentives to democratize.
Democratic institutions such as legislatures and Developing countries have been more influ-
multiparty electoral competition can create enced by international financial institutions
those constraints if the commitment to the insti- (IFIs), which have pressured dictatorships that
tutional change is itself considered credible need their help to adopt democratic political
(Roberts, 2006). If the institutions benefit both institutions along with neoliberal economic
the ruler, by increasing revenues, and the ruled, reforms. Many autocrats did follow at least
by increasing productivity or welfare, then the some of the IFIs’ prescriptions, though – as
institutional bargain is self-enforcing and thus with economic reforms – rulers have strong
credible.11 The need to attract private invest- incentives to undermine in practice the reforms
ment suggests why democratization and eco- they adopt on paper. In response to this pres-
nomic liberalization tended to vary together in sure, many African autocrats agreed to hold
the late twentieth century (Hellman, 1998).12 multiparty elections for the first time since
The political effects of the economic crisis achieving office. Some were defeated in those
of the 1980s and subsequent economic reforms elections, which ushered in democratic gov-
are described and analyzed in numerous coun- ernments. Others managed through various
try studies, notably Magaloni’s (2006) analy- means to hang onto power despite multiparty
sis of the effect of economic crisis on the fall elections and thus avoid transitions.
of the PRI in Mexico. A number of multi- So far, the effects of these geopolitical
country comparisons of democratization expe- changes have been tested only in limited
riences also emphasize the importance of ways. In a sample of hegemonic party regimes,
economic crises in the 1980s and 1990s Levitsky and Way (2005) find that since 1990
(Bratton and van de Walle, 1997; Haggard and alliance with the US or Western Europe leads
Kaufman, 1995). In large-N studies, the effect autocrats to adopt democratic-seeming institu-
of the economic dislocations of the 1980s and tions, but not to democratization. Gibson and
1990s is captured by coefficients for the effect Hoffman (2007) show that fungible aid, that
of growth on the likelihood of transition. Most is, aid that is not earmarked or monitored by
empirical studies have found that autocratic donors contributes toward the survival of
governments are destabilized by poor eco- African dictators. Dunning (2004) shows that
nomic performance (e.g., Gandhi and Reuter, foreign aid contributed to democratization in
2007; Geddes, 2003), though Przeworski et al. Africa after the end of the Cold War but not
(2000) are an exception. before.
Many scholars focused primarily on the
domestic causes of regime change have dis-
Geopolitical changes cussed and tried to assess the importance of
the international influences and changes
During the Cold War, one superpower or the described above. The scholars most interested
other provided resources to help many auto- in international influences on transitions,
crats survive in power. With the Soviet col- however, have focused on other issues, espe-
lapse in 1990, the Soviet threat to invade cially the effects of war, civil war, sanctions,

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 291

international organizations, and diffusion World War II is as rule by the military as an


from neighbors. These topics reflect the core institution,14 hegemonic party rule, personal-
interests of international relations scholars and istic dictatorship,15 and monarchy. Defining
data availability. Gleditsch and Choung (2004) regime characteristics emerge from struggles
and Gleditsch and Ward (2006) interpret their among elite contenders with different back-
finding that having democratic neighbors grounds, support bases, and resources, often
reduces the coefficient on level of develop- after seizures of power. They do not derive in
ment to insignificance as a challenge to argu- an obvious way from underlying social or
ments linking development to democracy. political structures, and all have been com-
Without an explanation of why there are more patible with a wide range of economic ide-
democratic neighbors in some times and ologies. These types were common in the late
places than others, however, their results add twentieth century while oligarchy was not,
little to explanations of democratization. Other which might help to explain why post 1950
international influence findings do not chal- democratizations have been different from
lenge the predominance of domestic explana- those that came before.16
tions of regime change, though they make the I have argued elsewhere that these different
picture more complete. kinds of autocracy break down in different
What has been lacking in most of the ways (Geddes, 1999, 2003). To summarize,
efforts to link international causes to regime rule by the military as an institution is more
transition are theoretical arguments about the fragile than other forms of authoritarianism
interaction between international factors and because officers’ dread of factional strife
the behavior of domestic political actors. causes them to prefer returning to the barracks
Empirical tests of the effects of international to remaining in power when factionali-
factors have treated domestic politics as a zation threatens to destroy military unity.
black box that might be shoved this way or Consequently, the first moves toward liberali-
that by neighbors, sanctions, or whatever.13 zation often arise within the military elite, as
Instead, domestic political leaders should be noted by O’Donnell and Schmitter (1986).
modeled as strategic actors who respond to Furthermore, stepping down is relatively
price changes and other international trends costless for intact militaries because they
that change the costs associated with various can usually return to their military careers
choices they can make, as well as to the unpunished.
equally strategic actors in other countries In contrast to the military, several scholars
who seek to influence them. The elaboration have noted the robustness of hegemonic
of such theories, along with tests of them, party regimes (Gandhi and Przeworski, 2006;
could potentially transform the study of Geddes, 2003; Magaloni, 2007). Rule by
democratization. hegemonic party regimes tends to be stable
and long-lived because party institutions
encompass a broad range of citizens and also
create strong incentives for the continued
Characteristics of the old regime
cooperation of both elites and masses.17
If authoritarian regimes with different kinds The loss of their monopoly over office is
of leadership tend to have different institu- costly to dominant parties but not disastrous,
tional structures and different relationships since most of them can transform themselves
with supporters and ordinary citizens, into successful competitors in democratic
then we would expect them to break down systems.
differently because different institutions priv- In personalist dictatorships, the autocrat
ilege and disadvantage different groups. A trades private goods for the support of a
simple and intuitive way to categorize the relatively small group of allies. The loss of
kinds of autocracy most common since resources to distribute to supporters can

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


292 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

destabilize such regimes, as can the leader’s negotiated democratization to revolution,


death, since personalist rulers resist creating popular uprising or civil war. Dominant par-
institutions that might dilute their per- ties prefer democracy, in which they have a
sonal control. Loss of office, however, can be good chance of competing successfully, to
catastrophic for personalist dictators and autocracy that excludes them. Monarchs
their closest allies. Many of them have suf- prefer constitutional monarchy to ouster.
fered exile, prosecution for corruption and Most personalist dictators, however, care
human rights violations, or assassination little about what kind of regime follows
(Kaminski et al., 2006), though a few of them them; if they negotiate their exit, it is usually
have transformed themselves into successful with foreign leaders who can offer them
democratic politicians. safe exile.
Less systematic research has been done on These differences in willingness to negoti-
regime change from monarchies. The stabil- ate and second-best choices affect the likeli-
ity of the authoritarian monarchies that cur- hood that democracy will emerge from
rently exist is often attributed to possession authoritarian collapse. Negotiated transitions
of oil, but in fact not all monarchies export lead to democracy more often than violent
oil, and some that had oil were overthrown ones. Because they refuse to negotiate or
decades ago. Herb (1999) shows that monar- renege on agreements made earlier, personal-
chies that include the whole extended royal ist dictatorships more often end in revolution,
family in decision making and distribution popular uprising, civil war, invasion, or assas-
last longer than those in which power is con- sination than do other kinds of dictatorship.
centrated. His argument thus explains why a The new rulers brought to power by these
number of monarchies were overthrown means are less likely to opt for democratic
within a decade or two of independence institutions than are those who negotiate
while others have persisted for a very long transitions.
time. Lust-Okar and Jamal (2002) argue that These observations are consistent with the
monarchs are more likely to take initial steps model of regime change proposed by Bueno
toward democratization, such as agreeing to de Mesquita et al. (2003). They expect dicta-
multiparty elections, than single-party lead- tors supported by small coalitions to respond
ers because their own rule is less threatened to challenges with repression and by further
by these institutional changes. narrowing their support base, as personalist
These basic characteristics of different dictators tend to do. When rebellions over-
kinds of autocracy affect the likelihood of throw dictators, Bueno de Mesquita et al.
democratization. Poor economic perform- expect the new regime to become autocratic
ance more quickly destabilizes military regardless of earlier promises its leaders may
regimes than other forms of autocracy have made to supporters. In contrast, they
because disagreements over how to respond expect dictators supported by large coalitions
to economic crisis lead to factionalism and to further increase coalition size when chal-
thus back to the barracks (Geddes, 2003). lenged. In the real world, we see negotiated
Regime leaders who face relatively low exit transitions from hegemonic to multiparty
costs (i.e., military and dominant-party lead- government. In short, the Bueno de Mesquita
ers) are more willing to negotiate transitions et al. (2003) model seems to fit the experi-
than are personalist dictators who risk losing ence of late twentieth century transitions
their lives and fortunes if they step down from personalist and hegemonic party rule,
(cf. Bratton and van de Walle, 1997). though it fits older transitions and contempo-
Democracy is a second-best political out- rary transitions from military rule less well.
come for monarchs, military rulers, and These arguments have a reasonable amount
dominant-party leaders who face serious of empirical support, though they have also
challenges to their rule. Military rulers prefer been challenged. The finding that military

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 293

regimes are relatively fragile has been con- disagreement is that democratization occurs
firmed by Smith (2004) and Gasiorworski through several different processes, depend-
(1995).18 Geddes (2003) shows that regimes ing on basic features of the economy from
ruled by dominant parties last substantially which the autocracy draws resources, inter-
longer than other non-monarchic forms of national economic and political pressures
autocracy, though this finding is challenged that have varied over time, and characteris-
by Smith (2004).19 Gandhi and Przeworski tics of the old regime itself.
(2006) show that dictators supported by A number of the theoretical arguments and
single parties survive longer. Bratton and van empirical findings summarized above fit some
de Walle (1997) find that dictatorships that of these processes quite well, but do not apply
allow more political competition, a category to all democratizations. Of course, no theory
that overlaps what I label hegemonic party ever explains all outcomes, but I argue that
regimes, are more likely to democratize than there are systematic reasons why these theo-
those that do not. ries explain only some democratizations.
Regimes in which power has been person- Consequently, I suggest that the domains of
alized under one individual are more likely to theories of democratization should be limited
be replaced by a new dictatorship than by a to cases that fit their basic assumptions about
democracy (Hadenius and Teorell, 2007). conditions in the old regime. If a model
Transitions from personalist dictatorship are assumes that the central actors in the struggle
seldom initiated by regime insiders; instead, over democratization are rulers endowed with
popular opposition, strikes, pressure from private wealth and relatively poor citizens,
IFIs, and demonstrations often force dicta- then the domain of the argument should be
tors to allow multiparty elections (Bratton defined by old regimes that fit those assump-
and van de Walle, 1997). Personalistic dicta- tions. Since many modern autocracies do not,
tors are more likely to be overthrown in revo- the model should not be expected to explain
lutions, civil wars, popular uprisings, or democratization in them.
invasions (Geddes, 2003; Goodwin and Models that emphasize the conflict of inter-
Skocpol, 1989). Linz and Chehabi (1998) est between rich rulers and poor ruled, such as
have described the difficulties of democrati- those proposed by Boix (2003) and Acemoglu
zation following what they call sultanistic and Robinson (2001) are plausible simplifica-
regimes. Wright (2007) shows that aid con- tions of reality during pre-World War II transi-
tingent on steps toward democratization per- tions from oligarchy to democracy. These
suades the leaders of single-party regimes to transitions occurred in market-oriented econo-
hold multiparty elections, but that contingent mies at a time when international economic
aid has no effect on personalist leaders, as and political forces were probably less intru-
would be expected if personalist dictators sive than they have since become. In short,
have much more to fear from loss of office these early democratizations fit the implicit
than do dominant-party rulers. assumptions on which these models rely as
well as the explicit.
Models that emphasize conflict between
revenue-maximizing rulers and their support
CONCLUSION coalitions (for example, Bueno de Mesquita
et al., 2003) capture elements of reality in many
Nearly all arguments about the causes of recent transitions in developing countries. Their
democratization are contested. No store of focus on redistribution from the ruled to rulers
knowledge accepted by most analysts has as a central feature of dictatorship fits well with
accumulated during the decades of research what we know about many of the autocracies
on the subject. In the discussion above, I sug- labeled personalistic, sultanistic, or patrimonial
gest that one of the reasons for this continuing by different authors.

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


294 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Similarly, some of the differences in democratization will require theoretical argu-


empirical findings can be explained by dif- ments and empirical studies that either incor-
ferences in samples used. Since democratiza- porate these differences or limit what they
tion processes have tended to vary over time, claim to explain to particular kinds of proc-
and types of autocracy have been somewhat esses. As Diamond (2002) notes, ‘if we are to
regionally concentrated, samples drawn from understand the contemporary dynamics,
different time periods or different regions can causes, limits, and possibilities of regime
yield different results.20 change (including future democratization),
Nearly all empirical research on democra- we must understand the different, and in
tization has focused on post-1950 experi- some respects new, types of authoritarian
ences because data for earlier periods requires rule’ (p. 33). If we have fairly well developed
great effort to gather. During the post-war theoretical reasons to expect the economy,
period, no single kind of autocracy was the the international context, and institutional
most common starting point for democratiza- characteristics of the old regime to affect
tion; state intervention in the economy rose both the likelihood of democratization and
for the first thirty years and then fell rapidly; how it takes place, then the research frontier
and international influences not only for the study of democratization should
increased over time but reversed directions. include: the development of theories of
These important influences on democratiza- democratization that explicitly identify the
tion have not been included in most large-N contextual domain to which they apply; the
studies. development of theories of how particular
The failure to include them may explain kinds of contextual and regime characteris-
why so few uncontested findings have tics affect democratization; empirical investi-
emerged from this research. The Boix and gations of implications of these models; and
Stokes (2003) finding that development has a the incorporation of more nuanced model
big influence on democratization before 1950 specifications to accommodate contextual
but little after 1950 provides strong evidence and regime-type differences into large-N
that the modal transition process prior to statistical tests.
1950 differed from that after 1950. Scattered
empirical evidence suggests that early democ-
ratizations may well be explained by the
arguments proposed by modernization theo- NOTES
rists and the modelers who emphasize the
importance of income equality and capital 1. Along with several less developed Latin American
mobility (i.e., Acemoglu and Robinson, countries (the Dominican Republic in 1978, Ecuador
in 1979, Honduras in 1981, Bolivia in 1982, El
2001; Bates and Lien, 1985; Boix, 2003;
Salvador in 1984), to which less attention was paid.
Rogowski, 1998). For the post-1950 period, 2. Polychotomous measures include multiple dis-
however, empirical findings are either nega- crete categories. I use this term because the most
tive or inconclusive. That is, Przeworski et al. commonly used democracy scales are made up of
(2000) and Boix and Stokes (2003) show scores that are not equidistant from each other (as in
interval scales) and may not even be ranked ordinally
little effect of development on democratiza-
in the middle areas of the scales. See Gleditsch and
tion, but this finding does not take us very far Ward (2000) for a demonstration.
toward explaining what does cause democra- 3. Though serious questions can and have been
tization. Other results remain contested. raised about what the numbers between the end
If there are theoretically relevant differ- points of the most commonly used scales really
mean. One of the issues is that the same scores can
ences among authoritarian governments
be achieved in multiple ways, and it seems reasona-
themselves and in the ways that they interact ble to doubt that one combination of yes answers to
with their economies, the international con- questions about political characteristics is equivalent
text, and the ruled, then progress explaining to other combinations that yield the same score.

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 295

Another issue is that many users of these scales and preferences of domestic political actors. They do
implicitly assume that every one-unit change in the not test any of these specific arguments, however.
scores is equal in effect to every other one, which is 14. As defined by O’Donnell (1973).
empirically implausible. Gleditsch and Ward (2000) 15. Hadenius and Teorell (2007) argue that per-
have shown that nearly all the explanatory power of sonalism should be seen as a characteristic that varies
the Polity scale, the one most commonly used, independently of regime type. They have a point
resides in one component, Executive Constraint. since personalism results from struggles to monopo-
Little explanatory power is added by using the full lize power and resources within the ruling elite. See
ten or twenty point scales. This result is what we Svolik (2007) for a very insightful model of this strug-
would expect if the intermediate scores are made up gle between the dictator and ruling elite. Personalist
of varying combinations of characteristics, the indi- dictatorship, as I use the term here, refers to the set
vidual importance of which is unknown. of institutions that are created by the dictator to
4. This is Barrington Moore’s summary of Marx maintain his dominance as he wins this struggle.
(1966: 416). 16. Linz and Stepan (1996) offer an alternative
5. Larry Bartels (2005) has christened the real life though somewhat similar theoretically based classifi-
low-income voter who favors more social spending cation that might help explain differences in democ-
but who nevertheless opposes the estate tax Homer ratization processes. They expect the usual
after the famous Homer Simpson. characteristics of the different kinds of autocracy
6. Boix (2003) challenges this result. they identify to have systematic effects on different
7. But see Bravo (2006) for evidence that the exit aspects of democratic consolidation, but their expec-
of those citizens most dissatisfied with a ruler’s poli- tations have not been tested.
cies may increase the probability that he survives in 17. For detailed discussions of how this works in
office – thus giving the ruler a reason to provide practice, see Lust-Okar (2005a, 2005b) and Magaloni
policies that induce the exit of those citizens most (2006, 2007).
likely to join the opposition. 18. Gandhi and Przeworski fail to find a relation-
8. He does not test the effect of sanctions on ship between military rule and regime survival
economic performance and growth is included as a because their definition of military rule is different
control variable in the test of the effect of sanctions, from that used by most others. They code any ruler
so it is quite possible that sanctions do affect author- who ever wore a uniform as a military ruler, regard-
itarian survival through their effect on growth. In less of whether the military institution supports or
democracies, though, sanctions affect leadership participates in ruling.
survival even with growth controlled for. 19. Hadenius and Teorell (2007) find different
9. See, for example, Mainwaring and Pérez-Liñán survival rates than do most other scholars because
(2003) for evidence that Latin American democrati- their coding rules do not distinguish between what
zations do not fit generalizations made by Przeworski most other analysts would identify as regime changes
et al. (2000). and smaller institutional changes that occur while a
10. Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003) are a partial regime, in the usual sense, survives.
exception in that they expect the likelihood of 20. Mainwaring and Pérez-Liñán (2003) show, for
democratization to be affected by the size of the example, that democratization in Latin America dif-
winning coalition in the pre-existing authoritarian fers from the general path shown by Przeworski et al.
regime. This is a step in the right direction, though in (2000). Stokes (2004) provides a thoughtful discus-
my view, size is not the most important characteristic sion of why regional differences in democratization
of the autocratic support coalition that affects the processes might occur.
likelihood of democratization.
11. This logic, in other words, provides a reason
for expecting institutional bargains to be more cred-
ible than offers to provide desired policies in the
absence of institutional change, which the Acemoglu REFERENCES
and Robinson (2001) model does not.
12. Milner and Kubota (2005) argue that the Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. (2001) ‘A
causal arrow points in the other direction, that is, theory of political transitions’, American
that the median voter in new democracies demands
Economic Review, 91 (4): 938–63.
economic liberalization, but empirical research on
public opinion in these settings does not support this
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. (2005) Economic
view. origins of dictatorship and democracy. New
13. Gleditsch and Ward (2006) are a partial excep- York: Cambridge University Press.
tion in that they catalog a number of ways that Alvarez, M., Cheibub, J., Limongi, F., and
international forces can influence the relative power Przeworski, A. (1996) ‘Classifying political

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 18 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


296 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

regimes’, Studies in Comparative Crystal, J. (1995) Oil and politics in the Gulf:
International Development, 31 (2): 3–36. Rulers and merchants in Kuwait and Qatar.
Anderson, L. (1987) ‘The state in the Middle Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
East and North Africa’, Comparative Politics, Diamond, L. (2002) ‘Thinking about hybrid
20 (1): 1–18. regimes’, Journal of Democracy, 13 (2):
Barro, R. (1999) ‘Determinants of democracy’, 21–35.
Journal of Political Economy, 107 (6): Diamond, L., Linz, J. and Lipset, S.M. (edss)
S158–S183. (1988) Democracy in developing countries.
Bartels, L. (2005) ‘Homer gets a tax cut: Boulder: Lynne Rienner.
Inequality and public policy in the American Dunning, T. (2004) ‘Conditioning the effect of
mind’, Perspectives on Politics, 3 (1): 15–31. aid: Cold war politics, donor credibility, and
Bates, R. (1981) States and markets in tropical democracy in Africa’, International
Africa: The political basis of agricultural Organization, 58 (2): 409–23.
policy. Berkeley: University of California Dunning, T. (2006) ‘Does oil promote democ-
Press. racy? Regime change in rentier states’, Paper
Bates, R. and Lien, D. (1985) ‘A note on taxa- presented to the International Society for
tion, development, and representative gov- New Institutional Economics, Boulder.
ernment’, Politics and Society, 14 (1): 1–15. Elkins, Z. (2000) ‘Gradations of democracy?
Boix, C. (2003) Democracy and redistribution. Empirical tests of alternative conceptualiza-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. tions’, American Journal of Political Science,
Boix, C. and Stokes, S. (2003) ‘Endogenous 44 (2): 292–300.
democratization’, World Politics, 55 (4): Epstein, D., Bates, R., Goldstone, J., Kristensen,
517–49. I., and O’Halloran, S. (2006) ‘Democratic
Bollen, K. and Jackman, R. (1985) ‘Economic transitions’, American Journal of Political
and non-economic determinants of Science, 50 (3): 551–69.
political democracy in the 1960s’, in R.G. Escribà Folch, A. (2003) Legislatures in authori-
Braungart and M.M. Braungart (eds), tarian regimes (Working Paper 196) Instituto
Research in political sociology. Greenwich, Juan March de Estudios e Investigaciones.
CT: JAI Press. pp. 27–48. Fish, M.S. (2002) ‘Islam and authoritarianism’,
Bratton, M. and van de Walle, N. (1997) World Politics, 55 (1): 4–37.
Democratic experiments in Africa: Regime Gandhi, J. and Przeworski, A. (2006)
transitions in comparative perspective. ‘Cooperation, cooptation, and rebellion
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. under dictatorships’, Economics and Politics,
Bravo, J. (2006) The Political Economy of 18 (1): 1–18.
Recent Mexico–U.S. Migration: A view into Gandhi, J. and Reuter, O.J. (2007) Dictatorial
Mexican sub-national politics. PhD disserta- institutions and their impact on economic
tion. Duke University. performance. Paper presented at the
Bueno de Mesquita, B. and Siverson, R. (1995) American Political Science Association
‘War and the survival of political leaders: A (APSA), Chicago.
comparative study of regime types and Gasiorowski, M. (1995) ‘Economic crisis and
political accountability’, American Political political regime change: An event history
Science Review, 89 (4): 841–55. analysis’, American Political Science Review,
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Siverson, R., and 89 (4): 882–97.
Woller, G. (1992) ‘War and the fate of Geddes, B. (1999) ‘What do we know about
regimes: A comparative analysis’, American democratization after twenty years?’, Annual
Political Science Review, 86 (3): 638–46. Review of Political Science, 2: 115–44.
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R., Geddes, B. (2003) Paradigms and sand castles:
and Morrow, J. (2003) The logic of political Theory building and research design in com-
survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. parative politics. Ann Arbor: University of
Burkhart, R. and Lewis–Beck, M. (1994) Michigan Press.
‘Comparative democracy: The economic Gibson, C. and Hoffman, B. (2007) Can foreign
development thesis’, American Political aid help produce democracy? A political
Science Review, 88 (4): 903–10. concessions model of Africa’s transition

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 19 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


CHANGES IN THE CAUSES OF DEMOCRATIZATION THROUGH TIME 297

period. Unpublished manuscript. UC San Levitsky, S. and Way, L. (2005) ‘International


Diego. linkage and democratization’, Journal of
Gleditsch, K. and Choung, J.L. (2004) Democracy, 16 (3): 20–34.
Autocratic transitions and democratization. Lindert, P. (1994) ‘The rise of social spending,
Paper presented at the International Studies 1880–1930’, Explorations in Economic
Association, Montreal. History, 31 (1): 1–37.
Gleditsch, K. and Ward, M. (1997) ‘Double Linz, J. and Chehabi, H.E. (eds) (1998)
take: A reexamination of democracy and Sultanistic regimes. Baltimore: The Johns
autocracy in modern polities’, Journal of Hopkins University Press.
Conflict Resolution, 41 (3): 361–83. Linz, J. and Stepan, A. (1996) Problems of
Gleditsch, K. and Ward, M. (2000) ‘Peace and democratic transition and consolidation:
war in time and space: The role of democra- Southern Europe, South America, and Post–
tization’, International Studies Quarterly, 43: Communist Europe. Baltimore: The Johns
1–29. Hopkins University Press.
Gleditsch, K. and Ward, M. (2006) ‘Diffusion Lipset, S.M. (1959) ‘Some social requisites of
and the international context of democrati- democracy: Economic development and
zation’, International Organization, 60 (4): political legitimacy’, American Political
911–33. Science Review, 53 (1): 69–105.
Goodwin, J. and Skocpol, T. (1989) ‘Explaining Lust-Okar, E. (2005a) Structuring conflict in the
revolutions in the contemporary third world’, Arab world: Incumbents, opponents and insti-
Politics and Society, 17 (4): 489–509. tutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Hadenius, A. and Teorell, J. (2007) ‘Pathways Press.
from authoritarianism’, Journal of Democracy, Lust-Okar, E. (2005b) Elections under authori-
18 (1): 143–56. tarianism: Preliminary lessons from Jordan.
Haggard, S. and Kaufman, R. (1995) The Paper presented at the APSA. Washington,
political economy of democratic transitions. DC.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Lust-Okar, E. and Jamal, A. (2002) ‘Rulers and
Hellman, J. (1998) ‘Winner take all: The politics rules’, Comparative Political Studies, 35 (3):
of partial reform in postcommunist transi- 337–66.
tions’, World Politics, 50 (2): 203–34. Magaloni, B. (2006) Voting for autocracy: The
Herb, M. (1999) All in the family: Absolutism, politics of party hegemony and its decline.
revolution, and democracy in the Middle Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Eastern monarchies. Albany: SUNY Press. Magaloni, B. (2007) Elections under autocracy
Herb, M. (2005) ‘No representation without and the strategic game of fraud. Paper pre-
taxation? Rents, development and democ- sented at the APSA, Chicago.
racy’, Comparative Politics, 37 (3): 297–317. Mainwaring, S. and Pérez–Liñán, A. (2003)
Huntington, S. (1991) The third wave: ‘Levels of development and democracy: Latin
Democratization in the late twentieth cen- American exceptionalism, 1945–1996’,
tury. Norman, OK: Oklahoma University Comparative Political Studies, 36 (9):
Press. 1031–67.
Inkeles, A. and Smith, D.H. (1974) Becoming Marinov, N. (2005) ‘Do economic sanctions
modern: Individual change in six developing destabilize country leaders?’, American
countries. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Journal of Political Science, 49 (3): 564–76.
Press. Milner, H. and Kubota, K. (2005) ‘Why the
Kaminski, M., Nalepa, M., and O’Neill, B. move to free trade? Democracy and trade
(2006) ‘Normative and strategic aspects of policy in the developing countries’,
transitional justice’, Journal of Conflict International Organization, 59 (4): 107–43.
Resolution, 50 (3): 292–302. Moore, B. (1966) Social origins of dictatorship
Karl, T. (1997) The paradox of plenty: Oil and democracy: Lord and peasant in the
booms and petro–states. Berkeley: University making of the modern world. Boston: Beacon
of California Press. Press.
Levi, M. (1988) Of rule and revenue. Berkeley: Mulligan, C., Gil, R., and Sala-i-Martin, X.
University of California Press. (2004) ‘Do democracies have different public

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 20 3/11/2009 4:14:47 PM


298 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

policies than non-democracies?’, Journal of Ross, M. (2001) ‘Does oil hinder democracy?’,
Economic Perspectives, 18 (1): 51–74. World Politics, 53 (3): 325–61.
North, D. and Weingast, B. (1989) ‘Constitutions Sarkissian, A. (2006) An unholy alliance?
and commitment: Evolution of the institu- Religion and democratization in Christian
tions governing public choice in 17th century and Islamic societies. PhD dissertation.
England’, Journal of Economic History, 49 UCLA.
(4): 803–32. Smith, B. (2004) ‘Oil wealth and regime survival
O’Donnell, G. (1973) Modernization and in the developing world’, American Journal
bureaucratic-authoritarianism: Studies in of Political Science, 48 (2): 232–46.
South American politics. Berkeley: Institute Stokes, S. (2004) Region, contingency, and
of International Studies. democratization. Paper presented at a
O’Donnell, G. and Schmitter, P. (1986) Conference on Contingency in the Study of
Transitions from authoritarian rule: Tentative Politics, Yale University.
conclusions about uncertain democracies. Svolik, M. (2007) Power-sharing and leadership
Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University dynamics in authoritarian regimes. Paper
Press. presented at APSA, Chicago.
Olson, M. (1993) ‘Dictatorship, democracy, Tessler, M. (2002) ‘Islam and democracy in the
and development’, American Political Science Middle East: The impact of religious orienta-
Review, 87 (3): 567–76. tions on attitudes toward democracy in four
Pevehouse, J. (2002) ‘Democracy from the Arab countries’, Comparative Politics, 34 (3):
outside-in? International organizations and 337–54.
democratization’, International Organization, Weingast, B. (1997) ‘The political foundations
56 (3): 515–49. of democracy and the rule of law’,American
Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M.E., Cheibub, J.-A., Political Science Review, 91 (2): 245–63.
and Limongi, F. (2000) Democracy and devel- Whitehead, L. (1996) ‘Three international
opment: Political institutions and well–being dimensions of democratization’, in L.
in the world, 1950–1990. Princeton, NJ: Whitehead (ed.), International dimensions of
Princeton University Press. democratization: Europe and the Americas.
Roberts, T. (2006) An international political Oxford: Oxford University Press.
economy theory of democratic transition. Wong, S.H. (2007) Endogenous capital mobil-
Unpublished manuscript. UCLA. ity and regime transitions. Ph.D. dissertation.
Rogowski, R. (1998) ‘Democracy, capital, skill, UCLA.
and country size: Effects of asset mobility Wright, J. (2007) Political regimes and foreign
and regime monopoly on the odds of demo- aid: How aid affects growth and democrati-
cratic rule’, in P. Drake and M. McCubbins zation. Ph.D. dissertation. UCLA.
(eds), The origins of liberty: Political and eco- Zak, P. and Feng, Y. (2003) ‘A dynamic
nomic liberalization in the modern world. theory of the transition to democracy’,
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Journal of Economic Behavior and
pp. 48–69. Organization, 52 (1): 1–25.

9781412919760_Chap15.indd 21 3/11/2009 4:14:48 PM


16
Political Culture
Christian Welzel

A stable and effective democratic government … DEFINITION


depends upon the orientations that people have to
the political process – upon the political culture.
Going back to Almond and Verba (1963: 13)
(Almond and Verba, 1963: 498) the term political culture is usually understood
‘as the particular distribution of patterns of
orientation toward political objects among the
INTRODUCTION members of a nation.’ Thus, political culture is
about the psychological dimension of political
This chapter describes the place of the politi- systems, including all politically relevant
cal culture paradigm in comparative politics. beliefs, values, and attitudes. Depending on
It outlines the paradigm’s fundamental what is the reference population one can dis-
premises and assumptions and sketches how tinguish elite and mass cultures, local, regional
research in this field has developed. Special and national cultures, as well as the subcul-
emphasis will be placed on where I see the tures of specific groups. Usually one would
greatest contribution of the political culture refer the concept to collective units of which
approach: understanding the societal funda- people are aware and have some feeling of
ments of democracy and how these are trans- belongingness.
forming in the process of cultural change. In To what extent actual political behavior is to
thinking about the driving forces behind be included in the notion of political culture is
democracy, the most basic assumptions of not always perfectly clear. Insofar, however, as
the political culture approach will be juxta- certain patterns of behavior become habitual-
posed to those of the political economy ized, they manifest beliefs in the legitimacy of
approach. The chapter closes with some this behavior. In that sense, political habits can
thoughts about the future research agenda of be considered as behavioral manifestations of
the political culture paradigm. political culture.

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


300 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Because individuals are the carriers of government (Nolan and Lenski, 1999). In a
political orientations, adherents of the political modern version we find this model outlined
culture approach gather data from surveying in more detail in the work of Huntington
individuals. But the unit of interest in political (1991: 69).
culture studies is a given population (which Aristotle’s idea that the citizens’ beliefs
can be defined by spatial, organizational or determine the fate of political systems was
identification boundaries), so individual-level plausible in the world of the Greek city
data are aggregated to arrive at descriptions states. In the history of the Greek poleis, the
of entire populations. Since these descrip- citizenry itself appeared several times as an
tions should be representative of the respec- agent in engineering political institutions, for
tive population, the political culture approach instance when democracy movements were
has an inbuilt tendency to focus on repre- formed to chase away rulers considered as
sentative population surveys as its major illegitimate tyrants (Finer, 1999: Book II).
analytical tool. But the idea of civic agency became unreal-
istic in the eras of Roman imperialism and
medieval feudalism, falling into oblivion for
centuries. A belief in civic agency returned
THE ROOTS OF THE CONCEPT with a vengeance only when the liberal revo-
lutions of early modern times and the first
The most basic assumption of the political political mass movements brought the people
culture paradigm suggests that the orienta- back in, in mobilizing wider parts of the
tions, beliefs, and values prevailing among a public for political goals. Thus, some 2000
population constitute a crucial determinant years after Aristotle, Montesquieu et al.
of the type of political system by which a (1748/1989) argued in De L’Esprit des Lois
given population is governed. This axiom has that whether a nation is constituted as a tyr-
been formulated more than 2300 years ago anny, a monarchy or a republic depends on
by Aristotle (ca. 350 BC/1984) in Book IV of the prevalence of servile, honest, or egalitar-
The Politics. In this opus, Aristotle argued ian orientations among the people. Likewise,
that democracies are typically found in mid- de Tocqueville (1837/1994) reasoned in De
dle-class dominated societies in which an la Démocratie en Amérique that the flourish-
egalitarian worldview is predominant among ing of democracy in the United States reflects
the citizens. the liberal, egalitarian, and participatory ori-
Here we find the classical formulation of a entations among the American people.
two-step causal process in which (1) the In modern times the most flagrant illustra-
social structures characterizing a given popu- tion of the fact that people’s orientations
lation make certain beliefs predominant influence a regime’s chances to survive was
among its members; and then (2) these the failure of democracy in Weimar Germany.
beliefs make specific types of political sys- Because this failure had such catastrophic
tems accepted and considered legitimate. consequences as the Holocaust and World
Thus, there is a sequence from social struc- War II, it troubled social scientists, psycholo-
tures to subjective beliefs to the legitimacy of gists, and public opinion researchers alike.
political institutions. This sequence provides Much of the research inspired by this break
an early theory to explain the origins of dic- in civilization shared the premise that democ-
tatorship and democracy: hierarchical social racy is fragile when it is a ‘democracy with-
structures lead to authoritarian beliefs under out democrats’ (Bracher, 1971).
which dictatorship becomes the legitimate In this vein, Lasswell (1951) claimed that
form of government; horizontal social struc- democratic regimes emerge and survive
tures lead to egalitarian beliefs under which where a majority of the people share orienta-
democracy becomes the legitimate form of tions that are compatible with the operation

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 301

of democracy. In Lasswell’s eyes these orien- type of democracy in which mass participa-
tations are rooted in ‘freedom from anxiety’ tion is limited to elections, citizens must be
which he saw nurturing a general ‘belief in able to understand the electoral process.
human potentialities,’ a sense of ‘self-esteem’ They must be capable to evaluate what the
as well as a sense of ‘respect for others.’ parties in power have done and what opposi-
Similarly, when Lipset (1959: 85–9) rea- tion parties are proposing as alternatives,
soned why modernization is conducive to should they make reasonable choices in an
democracy he concluded that this is so election. If these conditions are not met, the
because modernization changes mass orien- electoral process will be irrational and
tations in ways that make them more compat- democracy itself will not make sense. Thus,
ible with the operation of democracy, by civic competence is a fundamental precondi-
increasing people’s appreciation of opposi- tion for a rational democratic process.
tion, criticism, and political pluralism. Since then the field has explored the citi-
Most explicit on this topic, Almond and zens’ political competence both in cognitive
Verba (1963) and Eckstein (1966) introduced and perceptive terms. To capture cognitive
the term ‘congruence,’ claiming that in order competence scholars issue survey studies
to be stable political institutions must corre- asking people about their political under-
spond to people’s legitimacy beliefs. This is standing and their political knowledge in an
all the more true for democratic institutions, attempt to evaluate an electorate’s sophistica-
for democracies cannot survive on the basis of tion, and hence its ripeness for democracy
suppression (at least not without corrupting (Zaller, 1992). Inspired by an early study of
their own principles). The congruence theo- Converse (1964) emphasizing the inconsist-
rem has since then been the political culture ency of most voters’ political attitudes, other
school’s most paradigmatic assumption. studies followed, demonstrating a fundamen-
tal lack of political knowledge and under-
standing, even among the electorates of the
most advanced democracies (McClosky and
THE QUESTION OF CITIZENS’ Brill, 1983). Quite often it was concluded
CIVIC COMPETENCE from such studies that one should not project
too high expectations into democracy because
Almond and Verba’s (1963) Civic Culture in general the democratic process over-
study is the founding piece of work of the whelms most people’s cognitive capacities.
political culture paradigm, especially in its These conclusions then served as a justifica-
cross-national comparative orientation. tion of elite-guided, strictly representative
Comparing two old democracies (UK, US), versions of democracy. This position rejected
two at the time young democracies (Italy, any attempt at extending democracy into a
Germany), and a developing nation (Mexico), more mass-participative version. Indeed,
this study aimed to identify the psychological mass apathy was considered a stabilizing
attributes of a culture that is able to sustain feature of democracy (Crozier et al., 1975;
democracy. In identifying these attributes, Dye and Ziegler, 1970).
the authors emphasized two concepts: civic The description of modern mass publics as
competence and civic allegiance. insufficiently competent has not remained
Like most scholars of democracy Almond unopposed, of course (Delli Carpini and
and Verba assumed that democracies put Keeter, 1996; Lupia and McCubbins, 1998).
higher demands on the citizens than authori- Invoking the theory of informational short-
tarian forms of government. For democracy cuts scholars argue that the demands for
requires voluntary participation in the politi- voter competence are more modest than the
cal process, at least in elections to fill posi- critics of insufficient voter sophistication
tions of power. Even in a purely representative suggest. Politics is a remote area that ranks

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


302 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

low in most people’s daily priorities, so it helps to change things to the better.
people economize the time they invest to Certainly, citizens can heavily misperceive
obtain the information needed to make rea- their political competence. But whether mis-
sonable judgments. Instead of studying given perceived or not, subjective competence is at
policy proposals in all detail, most people any rate a consequential political orientation.
pay attention to how the representatives of For people who feel competent and effica-
various social and political groups position cious about what they can contribute are
themselves to a proposal. From this they more likely to participate in politics. They
draw conclusions on whether or not the pro- have a stronger sense of agency, which gen-
posal is in their own interest, saving the time erally motivates action (Verba et al., 1995).1
to study the proposal by themselves. What is
important then for people to make reasonable
choices is to have easy access to a diversity
of views on an issue. THE ALLEGIANCE MODEL OF
The theory of informational shortcuts DEMOCRATIC CITIZENSHIP
shifts the burden of reasonable choice from
the expertise of the citizens to the quality of As much as Almond and Verba’s (1963)
the intermediary system. To be capable to Civic Culture study emphasized civic compe-
make reasonable choices, the citizens do not tence, it also emphasized the importance of
have themselves to become political experts. civic allegiance. In contrast to competence,
What is needed is political pluralism involv- allegiance is an entirely affective mode of
ing a diversity of group representatives who orientation. A minimum of civic competence
provide informational shortcuts in identifia- is thought to be necessary to make the demo-
ble ways (Dalton, 2006: 20–31). cratic process rational. A basic dose of civic
Still another approach opposing the criti- allegiance to the norms, institutions, and
cism of incompetent citizens refers to the actors of democracy is supposed to be neces-
phenomenon of cognitive mobilization in sary to stabilize democracy as a form of
postindustrial societies (Dalton, 2004: 20–31). government.
It is argued that rising levels of education, the The emphasis on allegiance was strongly
expansion of intellectual tasks in the growing inspired by Easton’s (1965) concept of polit-
knowledge sector, and the increasing exposure ical support. Easton thought that because
to informational diversity, have each contrib- modern polities involve the broader masses
uted to expand people’s ability to arrive at into politics they need mass support to be
independent judgments of given matters. stable. This is all the more true for democra-
People’s factual political knowledge might not cies. They allow collective actors to compete
have significantly increased in postindustrial for power and this always involves the pos-
societies (Wattenberg, 2006), but their skills to sibility to vote anti-democratic actors into
acquire information and to process it have office, actors who might abandon democracy.
certainly increased through cognitive mobili- To minimize this possibility, mass support
zation, enabling people to make independent for democracy must be so widespread that
judgments. anti-democratic forces have no real chance to
Civic competence has not only an objec- receive sufficient electoral support. In a
tive cognition component. It also has a sub- stable democracy citizen disaffection must
jective perception component. Subjective be limited to particular policies and specific
political competence has been defined by actors and must not spill over to dissatisfac-
Almond and Verba (1963: Chapter 8) as peo- tion with the democratic process and the
ple’s feeling to understand the political proc- basic principles of democracy, especially
ess and the belief that they can participate in representation. Democracy is designed to
meaningful ways, and when they do so, that digest lacking ‘specific’ support for concrete

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 303

policies and actors but it cannot cope with lack- As a consequence, the allegiance model is
ing ‘diffuse’ support for its basic norms, princi- in danger when party–voter alignments
ples, and institutions (Klingemann, 1999). decrease in general. Three decades of amount-
More recently a new twist has been given to ing evidence from cross-national survey data
this theme by Anderson and Tverdova’s (2003) seem to suggest that exactly this is about to
work on ‘losers’ consent.’ The authors argue happen, throughout postindustrial societies
that the requirement of preserving diffuse sup- (Dalton and Wattenberg, 2000).
port applies in particular to the supporters of
the losing party in an election. Quite naturally,
voters of losing parties show less specific
support for incumbent governments. It is PARTY–VOTER DEALIGNMENT
important, however, that this lack of specific
support does not translate into a lack of diffuse The allegiance model of citizenship came
support of the democratic process writ large. under strain with the emergence of protest poli-
Accordingly, a democracy is thought to be tics and new social movements in the late
more stable not only when diffuse support is 1960s. Scholars sharing the view that democ-
high on average but also when the gap in dif- racy suffers from mass mobilization outside
fuse support between the winning and the institutionalized channels, saw this develop-
losing camps of the electorate remains small. ment very critically, fearing an overload of
At any rate, among scholars concerned with government with excessive demands by too
the concept of political support, the ideal highly mobilized publics. It was stated that
democratic citizen is usually seen as a person civic mobilization outside the channels of rep-
who participates in elections but is not active resentative institutions will render governments
outside the institutional channels of represen- unable to fulfill inflated demands. This will
tation. This is so because representation is the disappoint the citizens and democratic institu-
constitutive principle of modern democracies. tions will fall in disfavor. Thus, a legitimacy
To retain legitimacy this principle needs reli- crisis and a governability crisis have been pre-
able party–voter alignments. This requires dicted as the consequence of increasingly elite-
voters to be loyal to representatives once these challenging masses (Crozier et al., 1975).
representatives have been voted into office The first comparative empirical study of
and bestowed with legitimate decision making protest politics came to different conclu-
power. Allegiant democratic citizen do not sions, however (Barnes and Kaase, 1979).
disobey or oppose decisions made by demo- Based on surveys among representative sam-
cratically elected representatives. They accept ples of the US, Great Britain, Germany, The
the leadership role of their representatives and Netherlands, and other countries the study
when they are not in line with their policies, found that
they respond by changing their political align-
ment, giving the vote to another party. The 1. protest participants had higher levels of formal
allegiant democratic citizen is supposed to education, better political skills, and felt more
efficacious than non-participants;
operate strictly within party–voter alignments.
2. that protest participants emphasized democratic
They can change their alignment but not oper- norms more, not less, than non-participants; and
ate in a free floating space outside alignments. 3. that protest participants were in general more
In the allegiant model, specific support for engaged and active than non-participants.
particular actors and parties is allowed to
erode but it must be compensated by re-align- Follow-up studies on new social movements
ments to new actors and parties, should the in fields of environmental protection, gender
principle of representation continue to work equality, human rights, fair trade, and equal
(Jennings and van Deth, 1989; Kaase and opportunities confirmed these findings
Newton, 1995). (McAdam et al., 2001). This line of research

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


304 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

helped reshape our understanding of protest rather than deprived in resources who organ-
behavior and its role in democratic politics. ize and express complaints most effectively
The predominant view in explanations of and vigorously (Welzel et al., 2005).
elite-challenging mass activities was for a This is a paradox only if one believes that
long time influenced by deprivation theories protest results from misery. In fact, people do
whose object of explanation were in most not raise their voice when they are the most
cases violent mass upheavals (Gurr, 1970). deprived. People raise their voice when they
But this is a form of expressing dissent cate- have the capability to do so and the critical
gorically different from the peaceful forms of attitude that motivates the expression of dis-
mass dissent observed in postindustrial soci- sent. As argued by Inglehart (1990), the
eties since the late 1960s. Still, under the transition from industrial to postindustrial
impression that some sort of grievance and societies increases both factors, enabling as
frustration is motivating protest behavior, the well as motivating citizens to put elites under
emphasis of revolution theories on depriva- increasingly effective mass pressures.
tion influenced the initial views on the rising
protest movements in postindustrial socie-
ties. But what is true for the supporters of
violent activities – that frustration about social THE SELF-EXPRESSION MODEL
marginalization is a prime motivation – is not OF DEMOCRATIC CITIZENSHIP
true for peaceful forms of dissent in advanced
societies. It is not marginalized parts of the The rise of postindustrial societies nurtures
population and people most deprived of basic elite-challenging mass activities in two ways.
resources that constitute the support basis of On one hand, it increases the participatory
elite-challenging activities. Rather it is those resources that make people capable to initiate
who are rich in participatory resources and and sustain the kinds of activities that put
who have the skills and education enabling pressure on elites. On the other hand, it nur-
them to initiate and join in various campaign tures value changes that give rise to the sort
activities (Dalton and Kuechler, 1990; Verba of expressive attitude that motivates people
et al., 1995). to make their voices heard.
The transition to postindustrial societies This process has first been described in
has been linked with rising levels of formal Inglehart’s (1977) Silent Revolution where he
education, more easily accessible informa- argues that the ‘existential security’ and
tion, improved means of communication and ‘cognitive mobilization’ coming along
mobility, and wider opportunities to connect with postindustrial society nurture post-
people across the boundaries of locality, eth- materialist value priorities. These priorities
nicity, religion, or class. These processes emphasize people power and freedom of
have increased the part of the population pos- expression.
sessing the participatory resources that are In his later work Inglehart (1997) embeds
critical for the campaign activities needed to rising post-materialist priorities in the wider
nurture social movements and mass pres- context of self-expression values, which is a
sures on elites. As paradoxical as it may whole syndrome of orientations intertwining
seem, societies that are most advanced in five components. As shown in Table 16.1, it
providing their populations long, secure, and comprises
prosperous lives show the highest rates of
protest activity. In other words, people 1. democratic orientations that aim at giving more
complain the most in societies in which they power to the people;
have the least to complain by means of their 2. liberal orientations that tolerate diverse and non-
objective living conditions. And within these conform lifestyle choices, including the practice of
societies it is mostly those being privileged homosexuality;

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 305

Table 16.1 The concept of self-expression values


DIRECTION of orientation WVS measurement INSTRUMENT LOADING on common COMMON over-
dimension: aggregate arching orientation
(individual) level
Democratic Orientation (i.e., an Priority on giving people more say 0.890 (0.566)
emphasis on people power) in ‘government decisions,’ ‘jobs
and communities’ and ‘freedom of
speech’.
Liberal Orientation (i.e., tolerance Respondent’s rating on a 1 to 10 0.841 (0.575)
of nonconform lifestyle choices) scale indicating the justifiability of
‘homosexuality’. EMANCIPATIVE
Activist Orientation (i.e., Readiness (coded 0.15) or actual 0.837 (0.598) Orientation
inclination to actively voice participation (coded 1.0) in (‘self-
one’s opinion) petitions, demonstrations, and expression
boycotts. values’)
Efficacious Orientation (i.e., belief Rating on 1 to 10 scale indicating 0.596 (0.566)
in having control over one’s life) one’s sense of freedom of choice
and control in shaping life.
Trusting Orientation (i.e., belief in Belief that ‘most people can be 0.627 (0.366)
others’ trustworthiness) trusted’ instead of that ‘once cannot
be too careful enough in dealing
with other people.’
Data Source: World Values Surveys I–V (1981–2006, www.worldvaluessurvey.org) N (aggregate level) = 237 country-year
units, N (individual level) = 320,000 respondents. Loadings on first and only principal component reported.

3. activist orientations that make people inclined to practice basic freedoms. As a consequence,
make their voices heard in such elite-challenging people strive to actualize these capabilities, for
actions as petitions, boycotts, and demonstrations; self-actualization makes people feel fulfilled,
4. efficacious orientations that give people the feel- satisfied, and happy (Inglehart and Welzel,
ing of having control in shaping their lives; and
2005: 140–1).
5. trusting orientations that make people believe
that others can in general be trusted.2
Based on prior work by Welzel (2002),
Inglehart and Welzel (2005) theorize in a
‘human empowerment framework’ the close
These five orientations show a large overlap, connection that ties self-expression values to
reflecting an overarching emancipative orien- socioeconomic development, on one hand,
tation that emphasizes human self-expression. and effective democracy, on the other hand.
Appreciating and tolerating human self- In this framework (see Figure 16.1), socio-
expression involves a belief in people’s posi- economic development is thought to empower
tive potential, for which reason generalized people on the level of capabilities, by widen-
trust is part of the syndrome. ing the means, skills, and opportunities that
As Flanagan and Lee (2003) show self- enable people to pursue self-chosen activities
expression values take shape and grow stronger and to practice democratic freedoms. Self-
with the rise of postindustrial societies. This expression values are thought to empower
type of society satisfies most people’s funda- people on the level of motivations, by increas-
mental survival needs, such that freedom of ing their willingness to pursue self-chosen
expression becomes more important to make activities and to practice democratic freedoms.
people satisfied with their lives. Also the Effective democracy, then, empowers people
growth of material means, intellectual skills, on the level of entitlements, by giving
and social opportunities resulting from postin- them the rights that allow one to pursue
dustrial society makes people more capable to self-chosen activities and practice freedoms.

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


306 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

EMPOWERING ECONOMY:
Action Resources
(enabling people to govern their lives)

EMPOWERING CULTURE:
Self-Expression Values
(motivating people to govern their lives)

EMPOWERING REGIME:
Democratic Freedoms
(entitling people to govern their lives)

HUMAN EMPOWERMENT
(people being capable, willing, and allowed to govern their lives)

Figure 16.1 The human empowerment framework

The common focus on human empowerment Democratic Phoenix finds various forms of
holds these three elements together, such that self-initiated and elite-challenging activities
democracy becomes increasingly effective in to be on a long-term rise.
response to people’s growing willingness to The self-expression model of citizenship
practice freedoms, which in turn arises in has various consequences, some of which are
response to people’s capability to do so. outlined below. These consequences are
Rising self-expressive publics emphasize strikingly evident from the temporally and
new citizenship norms, as Dalton (2008) spatially widest exploration into political
notes in the Good Citizen. The allegiance culture ever, the World Values Surveys (www.
model according to which the good citizen is worldvaluessurvey.org).
a follower of elected elites does not attract
self-expressive citizens. This is the reason
why Putnam (2000) observes in Bowling
Alone a decline in various sorts of civic CRITICALITY AND DISAFFECTION
activities, including participation in elections
and voluntary work in a number of formal As outlined in Nevitte’s (1996) Decline of
associations. Most of these activities are Deference and Norris’s (1999) Critical
linked with the allegiance model of citizen- Citizens, the value changes proceeding in the
ship in which citizens are supposed to func- wake of the postindustrial transformation of
tion as followers. But this is only one flip side modern societies make people increasingly
of the coin. The other side is an increase in critical of institutionalized authority over
activities linked to the new, expressive model people. Indeed all societies for which survey
of citizenship. Citizens are less attracted by data are available in considerable time series
those parts of the democratic process that are show a decline of people’s confidence in hier-
designed to legitimize elites. They are more archically structured mass organizations and
attracted to activities in which they express in institutions that exert authority over people,
themselves and challenge elites. This is part as Dalton (2004) illustrates in Democratic
of the explanation why Norris (2002) in Choices – Democratic Challenges.

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 307

This tendency affects representative institu- channels, they are feeling more efficacious
tions directly, for the principle of representation about their possibilities to shape their lives by
is designed to transfer authority from the people themselves. This rising sense of civic agency
to institutions. Accordingly, rates of confidence seems to be a consequence of the emancipa-
in parliaments and identification with political tive tendencies coming along with post-
parties are on a constant decline (Dalton and industrialization and rising self-expression
Wattenberg, 2000). These tendencies seem to values. Throughout postindustrial societies,
be most pronounced in societies in which self- people have come to feel more efficacious, as
expression values have grown strong. Figure 16.2 illustrates.
This is important in the context of a soci-
ety’s capacity to initiate and sustain elite-
challenging actions, and thus for democratic
EFFICACIOUS AND mass power. It is known from protest mobili-
ELITE-CHALLENGING PUBLICS zation research that dissatisfaction provides
an important motivation for the mass actions
At the same time as people tend to become that challenge elites (Klandermans, 1997).
more dissatisfied about politics in representative But dissatisfaction is only a necessary and

0.70
SEV10
0.65 SEV10

0.60 2006
1981
0.55
Elite-Challenging Action

SEV09 SEV08
0.50
SEV08 SEV09

0.45
SEV07
SEV07
0.40 SEV06
SEV06
SEV05 SEV05
0.35 SEV04
SEV04
SEV03
0.30 SEV03
SEV02
SEV02 SEV01
0.25
SEV01 Data Source: WVS I and V, constant set of post-
industrial societies, weighted to equal size.
0.20 SEV: Self-expression values ordered in increasing
intensity from 01 to 10.
0.15
0.57 0.59 0.61 0.63 0.65 0.67 0.69 0.71 0.73 0.75
Self-Efficacy
Figure 16.2 Self-expression values related to elite-challenging actions and efficacious
orientations
Note: Reduced version of self-expression values measuring the intersection of democratic, liberal, and trusting
orientations, as indicated in Table 16.1. Scale is collapsed into an ordinal index with rank 1 representing the
weakest and 10 the strongest emphasis on self-expression. Elite-challenging Activities measure readiness to
participate (coded .10) or actual participation (coded .33) in three elite-challenging actions (petitions, dem-
onstrations, boycotts), yielding a maximum of 1.0. Self-Efficacy is the feeling of having control over one’s life,
transformed into a scale of minimum 0 and maximum 1.0. Countries included at both points in time (weighted
to equal sample size): Australia, Canada, Finland, France, Germany (West), Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Spain,
Sweden, the UK and the USA.

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:16:21 PM


308 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

not a sufficient condition to motivate people Third, people’s assessment of their society’s
to elite-challenging actions. When dis- actual level of democracy becomes more accu-
satisfaction goes together with low feelings rate, when one uses the expert democracy rat-
of agency, it results in resignation and passiv- ings of Freedom House as a benchmark. In the
ity. Only when dissatisfaction goes together new round of the World Values Surveys people
with strong feelings of agency do people are asked to rate their country’s level of democ-
feel encouraged to actively express their racy on a scale from 1 (‘not at all democratic’)
dissatisfaction in public. Hence the combina- to 10 (‘fully democratic’). After having equal-
tion of rising dissatisfaction with a growing ized scale polarities and ranges, one can com-
sense of agency is a powerful engine in pare people’s democracy ratings of their own
increasing a public’s tendency to initiate and country with the expert ratings of Freedom
sustain elite-challenging activities. House. Doing so it turns out that some people
Both people’s sense of agency and their overrate and others underrate their country’s
participation in elite-challenging activities level of democracy, these overratings and
are part of self-expression values. As Figure underratings varying greatly in extent. As is
16.2 illustrates for a group of post-industrial obvious from Figure 16.4, stronger self-
societies, both components have been increas- expression values make people assess their
ing from 1981 to 2006 and at both points in country’s level of democracy more accurately:
time they are being stronger along a sequence among people underrating democracy, stronger
ordering self-expression values from weak to self-expression diminish the extent of underrat-
strong over the other three components of ing; among people overrating democracy,
this syndrome. stronger self-expression values diminish the
extent of overrating.

DEMOCRACY: STRONGER DEMAND,


BETTER UNDERSTANDING, MORE WIDER CIRCLES OF SOLIDARITY
ACCURATE ASSESSMENT
The most surprising result perhaps is that
With rising self-expression values, the demo- rising self-expression values do not bring
cratic idea that power has to rest among the greater selfishness, as Flanagan and Lee
people resonates stronger in a society. This (2003) assume. On the contrary, the evidence
has three consequences. First, it becomes seems to be clear by now that stronger self-
more important for people to live in a demo- expression values widen the circle of others
cratic society, so the public demand for with whom people build up solidarities
democracy is increasing. Second, people’s (Inglehart and Welzel, 2005: 285–98).
understanding of democracy becomes more Self-expression values are weak when
liberal: people base their definition of democ- pressing socioeconomic conditions force
racy more on the freedoms that empower people into group bonding behavior. Bonding
people and less on strong leadership and behavior means that people ally with members
popular policy outcomes such as order and of their in-group while discriminating mem-
prosperity. This becomes obvious from bers of out-groups (Tajfel, 1970). When more
Figure 16.3, mapping self-expression values permissive socioeconomic conditions give rise
in a space constituted by people’s demands to self-expression values, group boundaries
for democracy and the liberalness of their become more variegated, porous, and perme-
understanding of democracy. With stronger able (Simmel, 1908/1984). This diminishes
self-expression values people’s demand for both the forcefulness of intra-group harmony
democracy becomes stronger and their defi- and the fierceness of inter-group conflict,
nition of it more liberal. allowing people to overcome group bonding

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 309

0.83
Data Source: WVS V, constant set of post-
0.81 industrial societies, weighted to equal size.
SEV: Self-expression values ordered in increasing SEV10
intensity from 01 to 10.
Liberalness In Definition of Democracy 0.79

0.77
SEV09

0.75

0.73
SEV08
0.71

0.69
SEV07

0.67
SEV06
0.65

0.63 SEV05

0.61 SEV01 SEV04


SEV03
0.59
SEV02
0.57

0.55
0.50 0.55 0.60 0.65 0.70 0.75 0.80 0.85 0.90 0.95 1.00
Strength of Demand for Democracy

Figure 16.3 Self-expression values related to individual’s definition of democracy and their
demand for democracy
Note: Self-expression values measure the intersection of democratic, liberal, activist, efficacious, and trusting
orientations, as indicated in Table 16.1. Scale is collapsed into an ordinal index with rank 1 indicating the weak-
est and 10 the strongest emphasis on self-expression. Strength of Demand for Democracy relates to a question
asking people how important it is for them to live in a democratic society (minimum is 0, maximum is 1.0).
Liberalness in Definition of Democracy reaches a maximum of 1.0 when respondents rate on 10 (‘definitional
element of democracy’) items referring to free elections, civil rights, referenda votes and gender equality and
when they rate at the same time on 1 (‘not a definitional element of democracy’) items referring to military
coups, religious rule, a prosperous economy and a punishing state. Same countries included as in Figure 16.1.

and to engage in group bridging. This process unselfish values, on the other hand.3 Related
places human solidarity on a different basis. to these distinctions, it is interesting to note
Familiarity, belongingness, and alikeness with that, in postindustrial societies, stronger self-
others are becoming less important while expression values do not only go together with
mutually agreed interests as well as empathy stronger individualistic values (which is not
with the situation of others are becoming more surprising) but also with stronger unselfish
important for creating solidarities. Solidarities values (Deutsch et al., 2008). Apparently, self-
are becoming more chosen and less enforced. expression values merge individualism and
Evidence supporting these claims is availa- altruism into what one might call humanism.
ble from the newest round of the World Values These findings seem paradoxical if one
Surveys which uses for the first time a value- equates individualism with selfishness, which
item battery designed by Schwartz and is indeed a widespread misconception.
Ros (1995). This battery allows one to distin- Scholars often think of collectivism as the
guish between collectivist and individualistic basis of human solidarity and of individualism
values, on one hand, and between selfish and as its destructor (Triandis, 1995). In fact,

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


310 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

0.40
Data Source: WVS V, constant set of post- SEV01
0.39 industrial societies, weighted to equal size.
SEV: Self-expression values ordered in increasing SEV02
intensity from 01 to 10.
0.38
Extent of Underrating Democracy

0.37 SEV03

0.36

SEV04
0.35

0.34 SEV05

0.33
SEV06

0.32 SEV07
SEV08
0.31
SEV10
0.30

0.29 SEV09

0.28
0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.10 0.12 0.14 0.16 0.18 0.20 0.22 0.24 0.26 0.28 0.30 0.32
Extent of Overrating Democracy
Figure 16.4 Self-expression values related to the over- and underrating of democracy
Note: Self-expression values measured as indicated in the note of Figure 16.2. Citizens have been asked to
rate their country’s level of democracy. Citizens’ ratings of their country’s democracy levels are related to the
expert ratings of Freedom House (after having standardized both ratings into the same scale range), such
that (a) when a citizen’s rating exceeds the expert rating the Extent of Overrating has been measured and (b)
when the citizen’s rating falls short of the expert rating the Extent of Underrating has been measured. Same
countries included as in Figures 16.2 and 16.3.

however, individualism does not destroy soli- Collectivism means that people see others
darity but places it on a different basis. not as autonomous individuals but as group-
This was recognized early on by sociolo- members in the first place (Triandis, 1995).
gists Durkheim (1893/1988) and Tönnies When group categorization dominates peo-
(1887/1955). They described the individuali- ple’s views of others, people almost auto-
zation trend of modernity as bringing a transi- matically start privileging members of their
tion from ‘mechanical’ solidarity to ‘organic’ own group and discriminating members of
solidarity, or from ‘community’ to ‘associa- other groups (Tajfel, 1970). Collectivism in
tion.’ Both descriptions refer to a transition this sense is a form of group-egoism that
from externally imposed to internally chosen hinders the creation of solidarities across
forms of solidarity. Beck (2002) describes the group boundaries. Individualism, by contrast,
solidarity effects of individualization in simi- means that one does not consider others as
lar terms, speaking of a transition from ‘com- members of groups but as autonomous indi-
munities of necessity’ to ‘elective affinities.’ viduals in the first place. This mode of orien-
Empirical research of interpersonal networks tation provides a common ground – human
supports the view that modern individualized individuality – on which one can place all
societies integrate people into more wide- people equally. This is why individualism
spread and more diverse solidarity networks and altruism go together with stronger self-
(Wellman and Frank, 2001). expression values (Deutsch et al., 2008).

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 311

SELF-EXPRESSION VALUES ‘self-esteem,’ and ‘respecting others.’ The


AS A DEMOCRATIZING assembly of democratic, liberal, efficacious,
MOTIVATIONAL FORCE activist, and trusting orientations that consti-
tute self-expression values comes indeed
If one looks at entire societies’ aggregate close to Lasswell’s democratic character.
levels of self-expression values, these values What gives self-expression values an
appear to be a first-rate indicator of a socie- inherently democratic thrust is the fact that
ty’s quality of life. On one hand, this is obvi- they place authority into the people them-
ous from these values very close association selves. This implies a rejection of uncon-
with any indicator of socioeconomic devel- trolled and unlimited authority over people,
opment, as demonstrated by Inglehart and making authoritarian systems appear illegiti-
Welzel (2005: 150). As these authors argue, mate. Because of these implications, self-
this relationship exists because more com- expression values constitute an inherently
fortable socioeconomic conditions on a mass pro-democratic regime predisposition. The
level tend to give rise to self-expression civil and political freedoms defining democ-
values. racy intuitively resonate with these values.
An equally strong relationship exists Because they are anchored in people’s values,
between self-expression values and indica- regime dispositions have strong motivational
tors of the quality of a society’s institutions. power, even though these predispositions are
Measures of democracy and of ‘good gov- only implicit. Regime preferences, by contrast,
ernance,’ including rule of law, absence of are explicit but their motivational effects are
corruption, and accountable governance, all unsure. In surveys, people express a preference
correlate strongly positively with mass self- for democracy for many reasons (Bratton and
expression values (Inglehart and Welzel, Mattes, 2001; Mishler and Rose, 2001; Bratton
2005: 151). Here the causal relationship et al., 2005; Shin and Wells, 2005). It might be
seems to operate in a different direction. that they feel attracted by the fashionableness of
Self-expression values are not growing the term or that social desirability guides their
stronger because more democratic and responses or that they prefer democracy simply
accountable governance nurture these values. because they associate other desirable things,
Instead, it is stronger self-expression values such as prosperity, peace, and low corruption,
that motivate elite-challenging mass actions, with it (Inglehart, 2003). In none of these cases
and these mass actions help to remove is the motivation to prefer democracy based on
authoritarian elites from power and to make an inner valuation of the civil and political
democratic elites behave in a more respon- freedoms defining democracy. Hence, it is
sive manner (Welzel, 2007: 417–8). Thus, unlikely that these preferences motivate people
mass self-expression values constitute a deci- strongly to struggle for democratic freedoms, be
sive motivational force in bringing about it to defend them when they are challenged or to
democracy where it not yet exists and in attain them when they are denied. When, how-
strengthening it where it is already in place. ever, people have an inner valuation for free-
dom, which they do when they emphasize
self-expression, then there is a strong motivation
to struggle for democratic freedoms. In this case
IMPLICIT REGIME DISPOSITIONS the emergence of effective mass pressures in
AND EXPLICIT REGIME PREFERENCES support of these freedoms is more likely.
Accordingly, Inglehart and Welzel (2005)
Self-expression values resemble the attributes find that predispositions for democracy implied
that Lasswell (1951) described as a ‘democratic in self-expression values provide a stronger
character,’ which is composed of a ‘sense force in sustaining and attaining democracy
of security,’ a ‘belief in human potentials,’ than do explicit preferences for democracy.

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


312 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Self-expression values motivate people to to social networks, Putnam’s understanding


initiate and sustain elite-challenging actions of social capital emphasizes psychological
that put effective pressure on power holders, orientations that facilitate human interaction.
even if the political system is undemocratic The orientation supposed to be most effective
and confronts people with the risk of sup- in this respect is social trust (Gibson, 2001).
pression (Welzel, 2007). Trust is understood to overcome collective
From the perspective of this research, the action dilemmas, for people who trust others
mainstream in political culture research has do not see themselves playing in prisoner’s
been too obsessed with measuring explicit dilemma games when interacting with people
regime preferences, rather than implicit regime (Uslaner, 2001). Hence, social trust shapes
dispositions based on given values. This is a the collective action capacity of a society. It
legacy of the Civic Culture study. In this study, enables the masses to initiate and sustain the
Almond and Verba (1963: 10) explicitly disso- actions that put elites under popular pressure
ciated themselves from Lasswell’s measures of and make them responsive.
attitudinal predispositions for democracy Social trust certainly increases a society’s
because they could not see anything specifi- collective action capacity. But it does not tell
cally political in orientations such as freedom us for which ends this capacity will be used
from anxiety, self-esteem, and openness to because purely by itself trust is not directed
other people. What is true is that orientations toward a particular end, such as democratic
such as these provide no direct measure of freedoms. This is often overlooked in theo-
regime preferences. Yet, they constitute predis- ries of trust or implicitly it is assumed that
positions with strong motivational implications people anyways strive for liberty and democ-
because these predispositions are anchored in racy, so the only thing that matters in making
people’s values. When a self-expressive world- this strive effective is social trust. Research
view arises, it is hardly imaginable how this in the context of the World Values Surveys,
view can be compatible with political systems however, shows that trust matters mostly as a
exerting uncontrolled and unlimited authority component within the broader syndrome of
over people. If this worldview emerges, the self-expression values. In other words, trust
legitimacy of authoritarianism erodes and the matters for democracy in connection with
democratic idea of power to the people reso- democratic, liberal, activist, and efficacious
nates more strongly among the masses. orientations that let people strive for demo-
cratic freedoms. In isolation from orienta-
tions that give trust a direction, it does not
show a strongly pro-democratic effect, nei-
TRUST, CONFIDENCE, AND ther in helping to attain democracy nor to
SOCIAL CAPITAL sustain it (Welzel, 2007: 405).
Another aspect of trust that has been con-
Putnam’s (1993) Making Democracy Work sidered important for democracy is political
gave the political culture approach greater trust, usually measured as confidence in a set
attention in comparative politics. In stark of basic societal institutions, including the
contrast to neo-institutional approaches, this national parliament, the civil service and the
study seemed to demonstrate that differences like (Newton, 2001). Inspired by the alle-
in the design of institutions can be ignored giance model of democratic citizenship
and that to explain a community’s political scholars still think that in order to flourish,
performance civic traditions account for most democracy needs people who have trust in
of the differences. This study brought an basic institutions. However, evidence that a
emphasis on civic orientations back in. society’s democratic performance depends
In contrast to scholars who insist that the on how much political trust its citizens
definition of social capital has to be limited express is non-existent. To the contrary,

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 313

Welzel (2007: 405) finds that higher political As Welzel et al. (2003) outline, this criti-
trust affects a society’s democratic perform- cism overlooks an important point: the five
ance negatively, even controlling for a soci- components constituting self-expression
ety’s democratic tradition and various other values show weak individual-level correla-
factors. tions only if one looks at each country sepa-
When social capital is understood to include rately, ignoring the massive between-country
orientations that motivate people to initiate differences in these components. As soon,
and sustain collective actions, self-expression however, as one merges the data from various
values should certainly be included into the countries into a pooled dataset, the syndrome
notion of social capital. For these values do of self-expression values appears to be as
motivate people to collective actions, espe- consistent at the individual level as at the
cially the elite-challenging actions that have aggregate level. What does this mean?
been found to help bringing about and For instance, Swedes who are more activ-
strengthening democracy. In that sense, self- ist in their orientations than the Swedish
expression values constitute a particularly average are not necessarily more trusting
pro-democratic form of social capital. than the Swedish average. More generally, the
correlation between trusting and activist ori-
entations (or any other pair of self-expressive
orientations) tends to be weak when country-
ON THE COHERENCE OF specific averages are taken as the reference
SELF-EXPRESSION VALUES line. But this is the wrong reference line
when most variation is between persons from
The concept of self-expression values has different countries, not between persons from
been criticized on two accounts. On one hand, the same country. Many Swedes might be
it has been shown that the democratic, liberal, above the Swedish average in one self-
activist, efficacious, and trusting tendencies expressive attitude and below the Swedish
representing this concept do not cluster into a average in another self-expressive attitude,
coherent syndrome at the individual level which makes these attitudes appear incon-
within populations. The claim that trusting, sistent. However, on a global scale Swedish
liberal, efficacious, democratic, and activist averages are exceptionally high in all five
orientations merge into a robust generic atti- self-expressive attitudes, so Swedes who are
tude, called self-expression values, has thus less expressive according to Swedish stand-
been disqualified as a fallacious inference, ards are still very expressive on the global
drawn from ecological correlations (Muller standard. Under the global standard, the five
and Seligson, 1994; Seligson, 2002). self-expressive attitudes are highly consist-
More substantively it has been argued that ent. They do not constitute different social
when these attitudes do not strongly correlate circles.
at the individual level within populations, Another point of criticism that has been
this means that the high scorers in these atti- raised is that the concept of self-expression
tudes fall into different social circles with values is not theoretically deduced but instead
only a small overlap between them (Teorell has been discovered inductively by means of
and Hadenius, 2006). Thus, the social circle factor analyses (Haller, 2002). It appears then
of people that can be mobilized on the basis that self-expression is just a label tagged on a
of a consistent set of self-expression values bewildering assembly of different attitudes,
remains always small. This questions the not each of which is actually a measure of
theoretical status of self-expression values as values.
a motivational basis on which to mobilize However serious one takes this criticism, it
wider parts of a public for elite-challenging does not do away with the finding that human
actions. populations tend to score consistently high or

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


314 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

low in all five components of self-expression identified the reasons why modernization
values. This finding is so robust that it must works in favor of democracy. These claims
have some meaning. Hence, one should try to are in direct contradiction to each other.
make sense of it rather than ignoring it simply From the point of view of political econo-
because it has not been theoretically deduced. mists Acemoglu and Robinson (2006), mod-
The fact that a finding has not been fully ernization operates in favor of democracy
anticipated by a ready-made theory does not because it makes the idea of democracy more
make it less important. acceptable in the eyes of elites. From the
It is true that the five components of self- viewpoint of political culturalists Inglehart
expression values cover a diversity of domains, and Welzel (2005), modernization operates
from efficacy to activity to trust. But the point in favor of democracy because it confronts
is that these components cluster into a coherent elites with masses that are more capable and
syndrome despite this diversity. The diversity willing to struggle for democratic freedoms
of domains just underlines that self-expression and to practice them.
values constitute a pervasive phenomenon that These opposing views reflect different
radiates into many spheres. To be sure, not each understandings of democracy and its driving
component is by itself a direct and perfect forces. In political economy it is thought that
indication of the generic syndrome of self- the driving force behind democracy is a
expression values. Participating in elite- redistributive interest of the impoverished
challenging actions, for example, is not a value. masses in universal suffrage. It is argued that
It is not even an attitude but a behavior. But the the masses always profit from universal suf-
fact that each component is related to all others frage because it enables them to impose
implies that none of the components can just be redistributive policies, so the masses always
taken by itself. It has to be seen in connection prefer democracy. The privileged elites, by
with the other components, which changes the contrast, fear it for exactly the same reason.
interpretation. Merely by itself, partaking in Authoritarian regimes thus do not survive
elite-challenging actions is not necessarily an because majorities would not prefer democ-
indication of a self-expressive orientation. But racy: Majorities prefer democracies anyways.
insofar as it is linked with democratic, liberal, Instead, authoritarian regimes survive
efficacious, and trusting attitudes it certainly is because elites are capable to repress dissent-
a reflection of a self-expressive orientation, or ing majorities. Consequently, the only way
at a least a behavioral manifestation of it. how democracy can be established is to make
It makes sense to consider participation in elites accept it so that they concede it to the
elite-challenging actions as a valid indication of masses. This is where political economists
self-expression values, insofar as such partici- see the impact of modernization. If it pro-
pation overlaps with the other components of ceeds, it tends to equalize the income distri-
self-expression values. The way in which these bution to an extent that makes democracy
values are measured extracts exactly that over- appear less threatening to the elites because
lap. At any rate, self-expression values seem to if the median income comes closer to them,
be a real, meaningful, and consequential syn- it becomes unlikely that majorities can be
drome of orientations. rallied around extensive redistributive poli-
cies. If this moment comes elites will start to
see the costs of repressing the masses’ desire
for democracy as more costly than the option
POLITICAL ECONOMY AND to concede democracy.
POLITICAL CULTURE From a political culture perspective vari-
ous doubts can be cast on these assumptions.
Both political economy approaches and To begin with, most authoritarian regimes
political culture approaches claim to have did not survive because of an impressive

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 315

capacity to suppress dissenting majorities but which is linked with a comprehensive array
because they never had been confronted with of major societal transformations, from
dissenting majorities, reflecting the fact that increasingly equal opportunities for women
throughout most of pre-modern history the and other previously under-privileged groups
wider masses had neither the capacities nor to the strengthening of democracy.
the will to express and organize political dis- What seems to be clear then is that the
sent (Gat, 2006: 570–661; Nolan and Lenski, syndrome of self-expression values is of
1999: 233–55). The major effect of moderni- major importance. What is not exactly clear,
zation is not that it makes democracy more though, is how these values translate into
acceptable in the eyes of the elites but, behavior. The precise micro-level mechanism
instead, that it confronts elites with increas- of how self-expression values create certain
ingly efficacious and ambitious masses. forms of elite-challenging activities is unob-
When the masses are becoming capable and served so far and it is also not known how
willing to struggle for democratic freedoms, these activities aggregate into the mass-level
the elites are left with little choice in the patterns that have been shown to work so
matter. It is also not true that the masses strongly in favor of democracy. Future
always invariantly prefer democracy. Quite research should work on these research gaps.
the contrary, how strongly the people aspire An obvious way to do this is to connect the
for democracy depends heavily on their survey method with experimental methods
values: The desire for democracy is the targeted at actual behavior, something that is
stronger, the more people value human free- done far too little so far in the empirical
dom and self-expression. Where these values social sciences.
are weak, people emphasize authority and
strong leadership instead. This might not
prevent people from expressing a preference
for democracy, yet these preferences are NOTES
groundless as they are inconsistent with peo-
ple’s deep-seated values. 1. Scholars distinguish ‘internal’ and ‘external’
While in the eyes of political economists efficacy but there are two versions of this distinction.
the driving force behind democracy is a One version defines internal efficacy as the feeling of
redistributive interest of the impoverished being capable to shape one’s own life and external
efficacy as the feeling of being capable to shape
masses in universal suffrage, from the politi- one’s environment. The other version defines internal
cal culture point of view it is an emancipative efficacy as the feeling that one’s own participation in
striving for freedom by increasingly capable a collective activity is a significant contribution to this
and ambitious masses. It is up to future activity’s success, whereas external efficacy is the
research to clarify in how far these opposing feeling that authorities are responsive to one’s par-
ticipation. Wherever the dividing line between inter-
views are reconcilable. nal and external efficacy is drawn, both tend to go
closely together as they have a common ground in
reflecting people’s sense of human agency.
2. In a factor analysis these five orientations load
THE RESEARCH AGENDA on the one and only principal component, represent-
ing a common underlying dimension, labeled self-
expression values or emancipative values. To measure
It belongs perhaps to the more important this dimension each orientation is standardized into
discoveries of the political culture paradigm a similar scale range and then an average is calcu-
that there is a coherent syndrome of demo- lated over all five orientations (in such a way that
cratic, liberal, activist, efficacious, and each orientation is weighted for its loading on the
common dimension).
trusting orientations, called self-expression 3. Schwartz (1992) himself uses other labels:
values, that takes shape and grows stronger collectivist versus individualistic values are
with the rise of postindustrial societies and conservative versus openness to change values in

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


316 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Schwartz’s language. And selfish versus unselfish Dalton, R.J. (2006) Citizen politics. Washington,
values are self-enhancement versus self-transcend- DC: CQ Press.
ence values in his terminology. Dalton, R.J. (2008) The good citizen.
Washington, DC: CQ Press.
Dalton, R.J. and Kuechler, M. (1990)
Challenging the political order. Oxford:
REFERENCES Oxford University Press.
Dalton, R.J. and Wattenberg, M. (2000) Parties
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J.A. (2006) without partisans. Oxford: Oxford University
Economic origins of dictatorship and democ- Press.
racy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Delli Carpini, M.X. and Keeter, S. (1996)
Almond, G.A. and Verba, S. (1963) The civic What Americans know about politics and
culture: Political attitudes in five Western why it matters. New Haven: Yale University
democracies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Press.
University Press. Deutsch, F., Grzechnik, E., Held, M., Mueller, J.
Anderson, C.J. and Tverdova, Y.V. (2003) and Welzel, C. (2008) ‘On the dimensionality
‘Corruption, political allegiances, and atti- of human values’, World Values Surveys
tudes towards government in contemporary Paper Series, 1 (1): http://www.worldvalues-
democracies’, American Journal of Political survey.org/
Science, 47: 91–109. de Tocqueville, A. (1837/1994) Democracy in
Aristotle (1984) The politics (C. Lord, Trans. America. New York: Knopf.
and Intro.) Chicago: Chicago University Durkheim, É. (1988) Über soziale arbeitsteilung
Press. [On social division of labor]. Frankfurt a. M.,
Barnes, S.H. and Kaase, M. (1979) Political Germany: Suhrkamp. (Original work pub-
action: Mass participation in five Western lished 1893)
democracies. Beverly Hills: Sage. Dye, T. and Ziegler, H. (1970) The irony of
Beck, U. (2002) ‘Losing the traditional: democracy. Belmont: Duxbury.
Individualization and “precarious freedoms”’, Easton, D. (1965) A system’s analysis of politi-
in U. Beck and E. Beck-Gernsheim (eds), cal life. New York: Wiley.
Individualization. London: Sage, pp. 1–21. Eckstein, H. (1966) A theory of stable democracy.
Bracher, K.D. (1971) ‘Problems of parliamen- Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
tary democracy in Europe’, in H. Hirsch and Finer, S. (1999) The History of Government I.
M.D. Hancock (eds), Comparative legislative Ancient Monarchies and Empires, Oxford:
systems: A reader in theory and research. Oxford University Press.
New York: The Free Press. Flanagan, S. and Lee, A.-R. (2003) ‘The new
Bratton, M. and Mattes, R. (2001) ‘Support for politics, culture wars, and the authoritarian-
democracy in Africa: Intrinsic or instrumen- libertarian value change in advanced indus-
tal?’, British Journal of Political Science, 31: trial societies’, Comparative Political Studies,
447–74. 36 (3): 235–70.
Bratton, M., Mattes, R. and Gymiah-Boadi, E. Gat, A. (2006) War in human civilization. New
(2005) Public opinion, democracy, and York: Oxford University Press.
market reform in Africa. New York: Gibson, J.L. (2001) ‘Social Networks, civil soci-
Cambridge University Press. ety, and the prospects for consolidating
Converse, P. (1964) ‘The nature of belief sys- Russia’s democratic transition’, American
tems in mass politics’, in D. Apter (ed.), Journal of Political Science, 45: 51–69.
Ideology and discontent. New York: Free Gurr, T.R. (1970) Why men rebel. Princeton,
Press. NJ: Princeton University Press.
Crozier, M., Huntington, S.H. and Watanuki, J. Haller, M. (2002) ‘Theory and method in the
(1975) The crisis of democracy. New York: comparative study of values: critique and
New York University Press. alternative to Inglehart’, European
Dalton, R.J. (2004) Democratic challenges, Sociological Review, 18: 139–58.
democratic choices. Oxford: Oxford University Huntington, S.P. (1991) The third wave.
Press. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 18 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


POLITICAL CULTURE 317

Inglehart, R. (1977) The silent revolution. Nevitte, N. (1996) The decline of deference.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Ontario: Broadview Press.
Inglehart, R. (1990) Culture shift in advanced Newton, K. (2001) ‘Trust, social capital, civil
industrial societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton society, and democracy’, International
University Press. Political Science Review, 22: 201–14.
Inglehart, R. (1997) Modernization and post- Nolan, P. and Lenski, G. (1999) Human socie-
modernization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton ties. New York: McGraw-Hill.
University Press. Norris, P. (1999) Critical citizens. Oxford: Oxford
Inglehart, R. (2003) ‘How solid is mass support University Press.
for democracy – and how do we measure it?’, Norris, P. (2002) Democratic phoenix.
PS Political Science and Politics, 36: 51–7. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Inglehart, R. and Welzel, C. (2005) Putnam, R.D. (1993) Making democracy work.
Modernization, cultural change, and democ- Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
racy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Putnam, R.D. (2000) Bowling alone. New York:
Jennings, M.K. and van Deth, J. (eds) (1989) Simon & Schuster.
Continuities in political action. Berlin: Schwartz, S.H. and Ros, M. (1995) 'Values in the
deGruyter. West: A theoretical and empirical challenge to
Kaase, M. and Newton, K. (eds) (1995) Beliefs the individualism–collectivism cultural dimen-
in government (Vols. 1–4) Oxford: Oxford sion. World Psychology, 1 (2): 91–122.
University Press. Seligson, M. (2002) ‘The renaissance of politi-
Klandermans, B. (1997) The social psychology cal culture or the renaissance of the ecologi-
of protest. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers. cal fallacy’, Comparative Politics, 34 (April):
Klingemann, H.-D. (1999) ‘Mapping political 273–92.
support in the 1990s: A global analysis’, in P. Shin, D.C. and Wells, J. (2005) ‘Is democracy
Norris (ed.), Critical citizens: Global support the only game in town?’, Journal of
for democratic governance. New York: Democracy, 16 (2): 88–101.
Oxford University Press, pp. 31–56. Simmel, G. (1984) Das individuum und die
Lasswell, H.D. (1951) Democratic character. freiheit [The individual and freedom]. Berlin:
Glencoe: The Free Press. Duncker and Humblodt. (Original work pub-
Lipset, S.M. (1959) ‘Some social requisites of lished 1908).
democracy: Economic development and Tajfel, H. (1970) ‘Experiments in intergroup
political legitimacy’, American Political discrimination’, Scientific American, 223:
Science Review, 53: 69–105. 96–102.
Lupia, A. and McCubbins, M. (1998) The Teorell, J. and Hadenius, A. (2006) ‘Democracy
democratic dilemma. New York: Cambridge without democratic values’, Studies in
University Press. Comparative International Development, 41
McAdam, D., Tarrow, S. and Tilly, C. (2001) (3): 95–111.
Dynamics of contention. New York: Tönnies, F. (1955) Community and association.
Cambridge University Press. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. (Original
McClosky, H. and Brill, A. (1983) Dimensions of work published 1887).
tolerance. New York: Russell Sage. Triandis, H.C. (1995) Individualism and collec-
Mishler, W. and Rose, R. (2001) ‘Political sup- tivism. Boulder, CO: West View Press.
port for incomplete democracies: Realist vs. Uslaner, E. (2001) ‘Producing and consuming
idealist theories and measures’, International trust’, Political Science Quarterly, 115: 569–90.
Political Science Review, 22: 303–20. Verba, S., Schlozman, K.L., and Brady, H.E.
Montesquieu, C.d.S., Cohler, A.M., Miller, (1995) Voice and equality. Cambridge:
B.C., and Stone, H. (1748/1989) The spirit of Harvard University Press.
the laws. Cambridge: Cambridge University Wattenberg, M. (2006) Is voting for the young?
Press. London: Longman.
Muller, E.N. and Seligson, M.A. (1994) ‘Civic Wellman, B. and Frank, K. (2001) ‘Network
culture and democracy: The question of capital in a multi-level world’, in N. Lin,
causal relationships’, American Political K. Cook, and R. Burt (eds), Social capital.
Science Review, 88: 635–52. Chicago: Aldine DeGruyter.

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 19 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


318 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Welzel, C. (2002) Fluchtpunkt humanentwick- capital have the greatest civic payoff?’,
lung (Focal point human development) Journal of Civil Society, 1 (2): 121–46.
Opladen, Germany: Westdeutscher Verlag. Welzel, C., Inglehart, R. and Klingemann, H.-D.
Welzel, C. (2007) ‘Are levels of democracy (2003) ‘The theory of human development:
influenced by mass attitudes?’, International A cross-cultural analysis’, European Journal
Political Science Review, 28 (4): 397–424. of Political Research, 42: 341–80.
Welzel, C., Inglehart, R., and Deutsch, F. (2005) Zaller, J. (1992) The nature and origin of mass
‘Social capital, voluntary associations, and opinion. New York: Cambridge University
collective action: Which aspects of social Press.

9781412919760_Chap16.indd 20 3/11/2009 4:16:22 PM


17
Revolution
Jack A. Goldstone

INTRODUCTION long-term processes of social and political


change, rather than as self-contained epi-
Revolutions are rapid changes in the institu- sodes of permanent transformation.
tions of government, carried out by non-
institutional means, and usually with the
support of popular groups mobilized for
demonstrations, local revolts, guerilla war- WHAT EVENTS ARE CONSIDERED
fare, civil war, mass strikes, or other revolu- REVOLUTIONS?
tionary actions. Until the 1960s, revolutions
were viewed as major turning points in his- Definitions of revolution
tory, ending traditional systems of govern-
ment and ushering in modern political For most of the twentieth century, studies of
organization. However, the proliferation of revolution focused on explaining the causes
revolutionary movements and of rapid shifts and outcomes of a handful of great revolutions
in governments throughout the twentieth in Europe and Asia, including the British
century has led to a more open and ambigu- Revolution (1640), the American Revolution
ous view. Revolutions – even ‘great social (1776), the French Revolution (1789), the
revolutions’ such as the French Revolution of Russian Revolution (1917), and the Chinese
1789 and the Russian Revolution of 1917 – Communist Revolution (1949). In the 1970s
are now seen as bringing a mixture of change and 1980s, the dominant approach to explain-
and continuity. ing these revolutions was structural analysis,
Revolutions include many different kinds rooted in Marxist historical perspectives in
of social change, including anti-colonial which the action of capitalist competition on
independence revolts, anti-dictatorial revolu- class and state structures produced class-based
tions, and anti-communist revolutions. These conflicts that transformed society. Skocpol’s
brought political and social changes of vary- (1979: 4) definition of social revolutions,
ing degrees, some of which were lasting and which stressed class conflicts – ‘rapid, basic
some of which were not. Revolutions are transformations of a society’s state and class
still considered to mark major, sudden, dis- structures; accompanied and in part carried
continuities in political organization within through by class-based revolts from below’ –
states. Yet they also need to be seen as part of was taken as standard.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


320 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Skocpol’s work led what I have called the a new model in which the revolutionary col-
‘third generation’ of theories of revolution lapse of the old regime led either to relatively
(Goldstone, 1980). Those theories, devel- nonviolent transitions to democracy or to
oped by Skocpol and other scholars includ- cyclic movements between unstable democ-
ing Moore (1966), Paige (1975), and racy and moderate authoritarianism (Bunce
Eisenstadt (1978) attributed revolutions to a and Wolchik, 2006; Diamond and Plattner,
conjunction of multiple conflicts involving 1993; Hale, 2005).
states, elites, and the lower classes, exacer- In response to these events, theories of
bated by international economic and military revolution evolved in three directions. First,
pressures. This was a major improvement on researchers sought to modify the structural
simple descriptive generalizations, such as theory of revolution to suit an increasingly
those of Brinton (1938), or of analyses that diverse set of cases. These included studies
rested on such broad single factors as mod- of guerrilla wars and popular mobilization in
ernization (Huntington, 1968) or relative Latin America (Eckstein, 1989b; McClintock,
deprivation (Davies, 1962; Gurr, 1970). 1998; Wickham-Crowley, 1991, 1992; Wood,
From the 1970s through the 1990s, how- 2000); studies of anticolonial and antidicta-
ever, the world saw a host of revolutions that torial revolutions in developing nations
challenged the class-based understanding of (Dunn, 1989; Foran, 2005; Goldstone et al.,
revolutions. In Iran and Nicaragua in 1979 1991; Goodwin, 2001; Kim, 1991); studies
and in the Philippines in 1986, multi-class of revolutions and rebellions in Eurasia from
coalitions toppled dictators who had long 1500 to 1850 (Goldstone, 1991; Tilly, 1993);
enjoyed strong support from the world’s studies of the Islamic revolution against the
leading superpower, the United States (Farhi, Shah in Iran (Keddie, 1995; McDaniel, 1991;
1990; Parsa, 2000). In Eastern Europe and Moaddel, 1993; Parsa, 1989; Skocpol, 1982);
the Soviet Union in 1989–1991, socialist and and studies of the collapse of communism in
totalitarian societies that were supposed to be the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe
impervious to class conflict collapsed amid (Beissinger, 2002; Chirot, 1991; Fenger,
popular demonstrations and mass strikes 2007; Goldstone, 1998a).
(Banac, 1992; Beissinger, 1998; Oberschall, Second, scholars called for greater atten-
1994a; Stokes, 1993). The Iranian Revolution tion to conscious agency, to the role of ideol-
and the Afghan Revolution of 1979 proudly ogy and culture in shaping revolutionary
proclaimed themselves as religious struggles, mobilization and objectives, and to contin-
not based primarily on class issues (Arjomand, gency in the course and outcome of revolu-
1988; Moaddel, 1993; Moghadam, 1989). tions (Eisenstadt, 1992, 2006; Emirbayer and
And the host of anticolonial and antidictato- Goodwin, 1996, Foran, 1997a, 2005;
rial revolutions in the Third World, ranging Goodwin, 1994a, 1997; Kimmel, 1990;
from Angola to Zaire, became so numerous Parsa, 2000; Rule, 1988, 1989; Selbin, 1993,
and affected so many people that the paro- 1997; Sewell, 1985).
chial practice of defining revolutions in terms Third, analysts of both revolutions and
of a few cases in European history plus social movements realized that many of the
China became untenable (Foran, 2003, 2005; processes underlying revolutions – for exam-
Zartmann, 1995). In addition, whereas the ple, mass mobilization, ideological conflicts,
great revolutions had all led fairly directly to confrontation with authorities – have been
populist dictatorship and civil wars, a number well studied in the analysis of social move-
of the more recent revolutions – including ments. Indeed, some of the more extensive
that of the Philippines, the revolutionary and radical social movements that involved
struggle in South Africa, and several of the major changes to the distribution of power,
anticommunist revolutions of the Soviet such as the international movement for
Union and Eastern Europe – seemed to offer women’s rights, the labor movement, and the

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 321

US civil rights movement, were revolution- no effort to transform institutions or the


ary in the risks taken by activists and the justification for authority. It also excludes
institutional restructurings produced by their peaceful transitions to democracy through
efforts. Thus, a new literature on ‘contentious institutional arrangements such as plebiscites
politics’ has developed that attempts to com- and free elections, as occurred in Chile under
bine insights from the literature on social Pinochet or in Spain after Franco.
movements and revolutions to better under-
stand both phenomena (Aminzade et al., 2001;
Goldstone, 1998b; McAdam et al., 2001; Types of revolutions
Tarrow, 1998).
The class-based conception of revolutions Revolutions are distinguished sometimes by
advanced by Skocpol, therefore, no longer outcomes, sometimes by actors. Other typo-
seems adequate. A huge range of events now logies distinguish revolutions according to
claim our attention as examples of revolu- how they unfold, or the goals they seek.
tion, ranging from the fascist, Nazi, and com- Revolutions that transform economic and
munist transformations of nations in the first social structures as well as political institu-
part of the twentieth century to the collapses tions, such as the French Revolution of 1789,
of communist regimes at its end; from the are called great revolutions; those that change
idealistic revolutions of America and France only state institutions are called political
at the end of the eighteenth century to the revolutions. Revolutions that involve autono-
chaotic revolutionary wars in Africa at the mous lower-class revolts are labeled social
end of the twentieth. Two major surveys of revolutions (Skocpol, 1979), whereas sweep-
revolution (Goldstone, 1998c; Tilly, 1993) ing reforms carried out by elites who directly
list literally hundreds of events as revolution- control mass mobilization are sometimes
ary in character. Nonetheless, these events called elite revolutions or revolutions from
still have a common set of elements at their above (Trimberger, 1978). Revolutions that
core: (a) efforts to change the political regime fail to secure power after temporary victories
that draw on a competing vision (or visions) or large-scale mobilization are often called
of a just order, (b) a notable degree of informal failed or abortive revolutions (Foran, 2005);
or formal mass mobilization, and (c) efforts oppositional movements that either do not
to force change through non-institutionalized aim to take power (such as peasant or worker
actions such as mass demonstrations, pro- protests) or focus on a particular region or
tests, strikes, or violence. subpopulation are usually called rebellions
These elements can be combined to pro- (if violent) or protests (if predominantly
vide a broader and more contemporary defi- peaceful).
nition of revolution: an effort to transform Revolutions do not always feature the
the political institutions and the justifications same set of key actors, nor do they all unfold
for political authority in a society, accompa- in the same way. Popular mobilization may
nied by formal or informal mass mobilization be primarily urban (as in Iran and Eastern
and non-institutionalized actions that under- Europe), feature extensive peasant revolts
mine existing authorities or seek to change (Wolf, 1969), or involve organized guerrilla
prior political, social, or economic relation- war. Huntington (1968) pointed out that
ships. This definition is broad enough to major revolutions show at least two distinct
encompass events ranging from the relatively patterns of mobilization and development. If
peaceful revolutions that overthrew commu- military and most civilian elites initially are
nist regimes to the violent Islamic revolution actively supportive of the government, popu-
in Afghanistan. At the same time, this defini- lar mobilization must take place from a
tion is strong enough to exclude coups, secure, often remote, base. In the course of a
revolts, civil wars, and rebellions that make guerrilla or civil war in which revolutionary

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


322 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

leaders gradually extend their control of the sometimes major confrontations in the capital
countryside, they need to build popular sup- cities (as in Moscow, Prague, and Bucharest),
port while waiting for the regime to be weak- the critical popular actions in several cases
ened by events – such as military defeats, were taken by workers far from the capital –
affronts to national pride and identity, or its such as coal miners in the Soviet Union and
own ill-directed repression or acts of corrup- Yugoslavia and shipyard workers in Gdansk in
tion – that cost it domestic elite and foreign Poland – or by urban protestors in other cities,
support. Eventually, if the regime suffers such as Leipzig in East Germany. There was
elite or military defections, the revolutionary thus no need for the revolutionary leaders
movement can advance or begin urban insur- taking power in the capital to spread their
rections and seize the national capital. revolution by force throughout the country;
Revolutions of this type, which we may call the very breadth of the prior totalitarian
peripheral revolutions, occurred in Cuba, regimes ensured that when they collapsed
Vietnam, Nicaragua, Zaire, Afghanistan, and there were few or no competing power cent-
Mozambique. ers, except for the centrifugal forces lurking in
In contrast, revolutions may start with the autonomous and ethnically distinctive provin-
dramatic collapse of the regime at the center cial governments (Bunce, 1999). The main
(Huntington, 1968). If domestic elites are problem facing the new post-socialist regimes
seeking to reform or replace the regime, they was not spreading the revolution but rather
may encourage or tolerate large popular dem- building new national institutions that could
onstrations in the capital and other cities, and cope with the emergent private, criminal, and
then withdraw their support from the govern- bureaucratic entrepreneurs rushing to fill the
ment, leading to a sudden collapse of the old vacuum of power (McFaul, 2005; Stark and
regime’s authority. In such cases, although the Bruszt, 1998).
revolutionaries take power quickly, they then Another typology rests on the guiding
need to spread their revolution to the rest of ideology of revolutionary movements. It dis-
the country, often through a reign of terror or tinguishes liberal or constitutional revolu-
civil war against new regional and national tions, which dominated the eighteenth and
rivals or remnants of the old regime. nineteenth centuries and seem to be reap-
Revolutions of this type, which we may call pearing with the revolutions in the Philippines
central revolutions, occurred in France, Russia, and Eastern Europe (Parker, 2000; Sohrabi,
Iran, the Philippines, and Indonesia. 1995); communist revolutions, which became
Recent events suggest yet a third pattern of prominent in the twentieth century; and
revolution, a general collapse of the govern- Islamic revolutions, which appeared in the
ment, as occurred in the totalitarian states of last quarter of the twentieth century.
Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union. In these Modern studies of revolution thus embrace
countries, the state socialist regimes main- a wide variety of events. This essay exam-
tained firm control of rural and urban society ines what we know (or think we know)
through the party apparatus. When a combina- about the causes, processes, and outcomes of
tion of elite-led reform efforts, changing inter- revolutions.
national alignments (the economic advance of
capitalist countries, the Soviet Union’s peace
talks with the United States, and Hungary’s
open borders allowing mass German emigra- CAUSES OF REVOLUTIONS
tion), and popular strikes and demonstrations
undermined the resolve of communist leaders,
The international system
the entire national state apparatus rapidly
degenerated (Hough, 1997; Karklins, 1994; Skocpol (1979) was crucial in pointing out
Lane and Ross, 1999). Although there were the effects that international military and

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 323

economic competition can have on domestic was diminishing; and the reduction of cold
political stability. The costs of war or eco- war tensions between the United States and
nomic shifts can undermine elite and popular the Soviet Union under Gorbachev provided
support for a government and put state an opening for dissidents, workers, and urban
finances in disarray. Yet this only begins to protestors to test the resolve of communist
suggest how international influences can regimes.
shape revolutions. Given the many ways in which revolutions
Ideological influences can spread across can influence, or be influenced by, interna-
state boundaries, with both the example and tional trends and events, it is not surprising
the content of revolutionary movements in that revolutions are rarely isolated, but gener-
one nation influencing others (Colburn, 1994; ally cluster in waves of similar events. One
Fenger, 2007; Halliday, 1999; Katz, 1997). can point to several such waves of revolu-
Revolutionary texts often carry revolutionary tions in history, including the Atlantic revolu-
messages across borders, and revolutionary tions of the United States (1776), Holland
heroes in one country can inspire similar (1787), and France (1789), propelled by anti-
efforts elsewhere. monarchical sentiment; the European
Direct military and diplomatic interven- Revolutions of 1830 and 1848, propelled by
tion by other countries can also shape revolu- liberalism; and the anticolonial revolutions
tions, although often not as the interveners of the 1950s through 1970s, propelled by
might have wished. Intervention by the Soviet nationalism. Other waves include the com-
Union could not defeat the Islamic Afghan munist revolutions of 1945–1979 in Eastern
Revolution, and interventions by the United Europe, China, Cuba, Vietnam, and other
States not only failed to prevent, but probably developing countries; the Arab nationalist
helped radicalize, the revolutions in Cuba, revolutions in the Middle East and North
Nicaragua, Vietnam, and Iran by supporting Africa in 1952–1969; the Islamic revolutions
the prerevolutionary regimes (Halliday, 1999; in Iran, Sudan, and Afghanistan in the 1970s
Snyder, 1999; Wickham-Crowley, 1992). On and 1980s; and the anticommunist revolu-
the other hand, US intervention did head off tions in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe
attempted revolutions in El Salvador and in 1989–1991. In each of these waves, inter-
Guatemala, and Soviet support did encour- national influences powerfully shaped the
age Marxist revolutions around the globe onset and outcomes of the revolutionary
(Foran, 2005). movements (Johnson, 1993; Katz, 1997).
In some cases, it is the absence of inter-
vention or the withdrawal (or threatened
withdrawal) of ongoing support for a regime Relationships among states,
that allows a revolutionary movement to elites, and popular groups
grow. Goldfrank (1979) and other scholars
(Goodwin and Skopol, 1989; Wickham- International pressures can create challenges
Crowley, 1992) have labeled this a per- for states, or in the extreme case of total
missive or favorable world context. US military defeat destroy a state’s power. Yet
preoccupation with World War I helped create it is the reaction of state officials, military
an interval for Mexican revolutionary move- forces, elites, and popular groups to such
ments to spread; the exhaustion of European pressures that determine whether or not the
states and the defeat of Japan provided open- result is a revolution, rather than merely state
ings for multiple anticolonial revolutions reform or conservative reconstruction.
after World War II; US concern for global Skocpol (1979) specified two structural
human rights under President Carter spread conditions that, when combined with mili-
the perception that support of the Shah of tary and economic pressures from the inter-
Iran and the Somoza regime in Nicaragua national system, make a state vulnerable to

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


324 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

social revolution: autonomous elites able to expected to promote economic growth


hamper state actions and organized peasant (Goodwin and Skocpol, 1989; Tilly, 1993).
communities capable of autonomous resist- States have a wide range of resources on
ance to landlord rule. However, her analysis which to draw to meet these goals and expec-
underestimated the role of urban workers, tations. Domestic revenues in the form of
as in the Russian Revolution of 1917 taxation and exploitation of natural resources
(Bonnell, 1983); her scheme thus misses the may be complemented by revenues from
overwhelming impact of urban protests by foreign aid and direct foreign investment.
workers and students in shaping such events Funds may be borrowed and resources sold
as the Iranian Revolution, the Nicaraguan or mortgaged against future expectations of
Revolution, the Philippines Revolution and increased tax or other revenues. Some gov-
the Great Cultural Revolution and Tiananmen ernments may also gain revenue from nation-
revolts in China (Calhoun, 1994b; Farhi, alized enterprises – although these often fail
1990; Parsa, 2000; Perry and Li, 1997; to yield projected profits.
Wasserstrom and Perry, 1994). In addition, Trouble arises when revenues no longer
her treatment of ideologies simply as elite meet state expenses, whether because of an
blueprints for political change leads her to enlargement of state goals or a reduction in
overlook the key role that ideologies play in income. The ways in which trouble can arise
popular mobilization by shaping perceptions are so many as to defy brief listing.
of state weakness and injustice and forging a Overambitious military and/or development
sense of identity among revolutionary actors. adventures can strain state finances; so can a
Although these omissions indicate the weak- failure to adjust revenues to keep pace with
ness of Skocpol’s structuralist approach, the inflation and growing national populations.
richness of her overall analysis has spurred a Overestimates of future revenues can lead to
deeper understanding of how shifting state/ reckless borrowing; corruption can drain
elite/popular relationships lead to state funds away from useful purposes and leave
breakdown and upheavals. state coffers bare. Small but growing deficits
The key issues in the relationships among can gradually eat away at state fiscal strength;
states, elites, and popular groups that govern military debacles or deadlocks with elites
political stability are (a) whether states have over fiscal matters can precipitate loss of
the financial and cultural resources to carry fiscal control and either runaway inflation or
out the tasks they set for themselves and sudden state bankruptcies. In some cases,
are expected to carry out by elites and popu- price shifts in key commodities in the econ-
lar groups; (b) whether elites are largely omy can adversely affect economic growth
united or deeply divided and polarized; and and state revenues. Symptoms of fiscal ill-
(c) whether elites opposing the state spur ness can thus range from a slow depletion of
mass mobilization and link up with protests state credit to ballooning debts to rapid price
by popular groups. inflation to military incapacity to unantici-
The tasks that rulers set for themselves vary pated shortfalls and bankruptcies.
enormously from state to state. Large states Still, state rulers can usually cope with
may have imperial ambitions, whereas small adversity if elites will contribute their efforts
states may seek merely to survive in peace. and resources to state reorganization. The
Personalist rulers need to maintain flexible threat of revolution appears when fiscal
resources to support extensive patronage; weakness arises while elites are reluctant to
democratic states need to manage party com- support the regime or are severely divided
petition while still maintaining an effective over whether and how to do so (Higley and
bureaucratic and judicial government. Almost Burton, 2006).
all states are also expected to uphold national Such reluctance may reflect the financial
pride and traditions; modern states are also difficulties of elites themselves. Elites who

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 325

are struggling to maintain their wealth, or stronger among countries that initiated wars
who see themselves being arbitrarily or and then lost them. It is this combination that
unfairly fleeced by their rulers, will not read- produces the greatest joint loss of both effec-
ily support a weak and needy regime. Elites tiveness and cultural standing for the state.
may also be alienated by exclusion from Second, sustained population growth in
power or by assaults on their privileges or excess of economic growth frequently alters
control of elite positions. But just as often the relationships among states, elites, and
elite (and popular) allegiance is lost through popular groups in ways that undermine sta-
squandering or neglect of cultural resources. bility. If increased demand produces infla-
State rulers operate within a cultural tion, real revenues to the government will fall
framework involving religious beliefs, unless taxes are raised; but that may be seen
nationalist aspirations, and notions of justice as highly unreasonable if peasants have less
and status. Rulers violate these at their peril. land and workers are finding jobs scarce and
Rulers who sell offices or appoint favorites to their pay declining due to increased competi-
high positions may win their loyalty but tion for jobs and resources. Youth cohorts
incur the resentment of those left out. Rulers will rapidly grow larger, creating problems of
who seek to overturn traditional religious and the demand for jobs growing faster than the
cultural habits had better be sure of strong population as a whole. Urban population
military and bureaucratic support to with- may increase disproportionately – and faster
stand the popular and elite protests that will than urban administrations can increase hous-
ensue (Oberschall and Kim, 1996). Rulers ing, health, and police services – if the agri-
who appear too dependent on the whims of cultural sector cannot absorb the population
foreign powers may also lose the faith and increase. Moreover, as the price of land or
support of their own peoples. other scarce resources rises, those elites or
The joint need to manage state tasks and aspiring elites who control those resources
cultural standing can be summed up in two will benefit disproportionately to other elite
words: effectiveness and justice. States and groups, upsetting the normal processes of
rulers that are perceived as ineffective may elite recruitment and social mobility. If the
still gain elite support for reform and restruc- state demands higher taxes while popular
turing if they are perceived as just. States that living conditions are declining, and if elite
are considered unjust may be tolerated as patterns of hierarchy and mobility are being
long as they are perceived to be effective in upset while the state is demanding more
pursuing economic or nationalist goals, or resources or more authority, then perceptions
just too effective to challenge. However, of both effectiveness and justice may be
states that appear both ineffective and unjust severely damaged. Although some states may
will forfeit the elite and popular support they find the means, through economic growth or
need to survive. making favorable elite alliances, to cope with
Three social changes or conditions, though rapid population increase, it is not surprising
neither necessary nor sufficient to bring that rebellions and revolutions have been
about revolution, nevertheless so commonly exceptionally widespread during periods
undermine both effectiveness and justice that when population has grown exceptionally
they deserve special mention. First is defeat fast – for example, in the late sixteenth and
in war – or even overextension, when a state early seventeenth century, the late eighteenth
attempts military tasks beyond its fiscal and and early nineteenth century, and in parts of
logistic capacity. Particularly galling is the the developing world in the twentieth century
waste of lives and resources for a losing (Goldstone, 1991, 2002a).
cause. Bueno de Mesquita et al. (1992) found Third, colonial regimes and personalist dic-
a weak association between war and ensuing tatorships are particularly prone to the dual
revolution but found this relationship much faults that lead to revolution (Goodwin, 2001).

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


326 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Colonial regimes, by their nature, are an levels of taxation. Direct attacks on landlords
affront to the nationalist aspirations and are less common and are usually prompted
power aspirations of native elites. While by news that the state’s authority has been
effective, they may be able to co-opt local challenged or broken down. Traditional
elites; however, should the balance of power mobilization may also take place in cities
shift between the colonial regime and the through traditional workers’ guilds, or
domestic elites with their potential popular through religious communities, and it too is
support, colonial regimes will degenerate often defensive and conservative in intent
into revolutionary confrontations. Similarly, (Calhoun, 1983).
personalist dictatorships, because they Informal mobilization occurs when indi-
exclude all but a tiny proportion of the elites viduals’ decisions to engage in protest actions
from sharing in the fruits of power, have far are made not through communal organiza-
less justice in the eyes of elites than more tions to which they have long-standing formal
broadly based authoritarian regimes, such as ties but instead through loosely connected
military juntas, or regimes with a clear networks based on personal friendship,
ethnic, regional, or class base. Personalist shared workplace, or neighborhood. Such
regimes may support themselves by claiming informal organization generally occurs in
to offer exceptional nationalist achievements response to a crisis; neighborhoods or friends
or by being ruthless and effective in manag- then mobilize themselves to take unconven-
ing domestic affairs. However, economic tional actions. Gould (1995) demonstrated
reverses, loss of foreign support, or loss of the role of neighborhood ties in popular
nationalist credentials through corruption or mobilization during the French commune of
excessive subordination to foreign powers 1870; Opp et al. (1995) and Pfaff (1996) have
can fatally undermine their effectiveness shown that informal organization lay behind
and spur a multi-class coalition against the spontaneous Leipzig protests that brought
their narrow base (Dix, 1983; Foran, down the East German communist regime;
1997b; Goldstone, 2003; Goodwin, 1994b; Denoeux (1993) detailed the role played by
Goodwin and Skocpol, 1989; Snyder, 1998; informal networks in urban protest in the
Wickham-Crowley, 1992). Middle East. Proximity and friendships
Of course, even if elites are divided and among students helped mobilize protest in
sharply opposed to the state, the result may the Tiananmen revolt in China (Zhao, 2001)
merely be coups d’état (Jenkins and Kposowa, and in the revolutions of 1979 in Iran and of
1990) or reforms. In order for a revolutionary 1986 in the Philippines (Parsa, 2000).
situation to develop, there must also be mass Traditional and informal organization are
mobilization. This may be traditional, infor- not inherently revolutionary in themselves
mal, elite-directed, or some combination of and usually lead only to abortive rural rebel-
these types. lions and urban protest. They become effec-
Traditional mobilization occurs within the tive in creating revolutionary change when
context of local communities to which indi- they link up with elite opposition to the
viduals have long-standing commitments, regime. In some cases, as in the rural revolts
such as peasant villages or urban craft guilds of the French and Russian Revolutions and
(Magagna, 1991). Usually triggered by some the Irish revolts of 1640, their impact is to
news of political change, such as plans for frighten authorities into taking radical steps,
state reforms, elections, or news or even shattering efforts by elites to move slowly or
rumors of war or local attacks [as Markoff wrangle indefinitely. In other cases, dissident
(1996) has shown in the case of the French elites place themselves at the head of popular
Revolution of 1789], much peasant mobiliza- revolts, linking up varied local movements
tion is defensive, even reactionary, aimed at and giving them direction and coherence,
calling attention to economic distress or high as the Bolsheviks did with workers’ revolts

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 327

in 1917, or as the radical clerical leader the state and elite responses and alliances
Ayatollah Khomeini did with protests based they encounter. The single constant that one
in the mosques, universities, and bazaars of can derive from experience is that successful
Iran. revolutions occur only where there is some
A third way for elites to link up with linkage or coalition between popular mobili-
popular mobilization is to create and direct the zation and elite anti-regime movements (Dix,
organizations through which mobilization 1983; Eckstein, 1989a; Farhi, 1990; Foran,
takes place. Although it would be too much to 1997b; Goldstone et al., 1991; Goodwin
say that the Communist Party fully controlled and Skocpol, 1989; Liu, 1988; Wickham-
rural revolt in China in the 1940s, the Chinese Crowley, 1992).
Communist Party nonetheless played a key
role in organizing peasants to redistribute
land, curb landlord influence, and undertake
armed struggle against the Nationalist regime PROCESSES OF REVOLUTIONS:
(Friedman et al., 1991; Selden, 1995). In Latin NETWORKS, IDEOLOGY,
America in the 1970s, most effectively in LEADERSHIP, AND GENDER
Nicaragua, priests established Christian base
communities to mobilize opposition to the Networks, organizations,
existing economic and political regimes and identities
(Levine and Manwaring, 1989; Van Vugt,
1991). At the same time, radical students and The varied and contingent patterns of revolu-
politicians, following the model of Fidel tionary mobilization have led scholars to
Castro in Cuba, sought to mobilize Latin place far more emphasis on the processes by
American peasantries through communist which revolutions develop. Structural condi-
guerrilla movements (Wickham-Crowley, tions may set the stage for conflict, but the
1992). In the 1980s, church leaders in Poland, shape and outcome of that struggle is often
the Philippines, and East Germany played a determined only in the course of the revolu-
critical role in creating formal and informal tionary conflict itself. How do elites link up
linkages between workers, intellectuals, and with popular movements of protest? How do
professionals in opposition to the regime (Osa, individuals come together to act collectively,
2003; Parsa, 2000; Stokes, 1993). often in the face of great risk of repression or
Given this enormous range of modes of even death? How are diverse groups with
popular organization, there is no easy way to distinct interests brought together to form
predict the form or direction that popular wide-ranging coalitions? And how do par-
mobilization will take simply from structural ticular leaders and groups emerge to domi-
factors. Although there is a substantial litera- nate and set the course of a revolution?
ture on peasants in revolutions (Migdal, These questions can only be addressed by
1974; Paige, 1975; Popkin, 1979; Scott, attention to the organizational and ideologi-
1976; Skocpol, 1994; Wickham-Crowley, cal elements of revolutionary action.
1991; Wolf, 1969), and an ongoing debate One key finding is that revolutionary actors
about the degree to which inequality leads to do not act, or even think of themselves as
revolutionary unrest (Lichbach, 1989; acting, alone. They are recruited through pre-
Macculloch, 2005; Midlarsky, 1986; 1999; existing networks of residence, occupation,
Muller, 1985; Muller and Seligson, 1987; community, and friendship. They are set in
Weede, 1987), none of these literatures has motion by organizations that range from
produced consensus. As Zamosc (1989) argues, small and informal bands of activists, such as
it appears that peasants are not inherently the Charter 77 group in the Czechoslovak
conservative or revolutionary; rather, their Revolution, to the highly disciplined, central-
aspirations take different forms depending on ized, and bureaucratic revolutionary parties

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


328 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

of China and the Soviet Union. They identify In recent years, much attention has focused
themselves with broader causes and groups on the construction of terrorist networks
and make sacrifices in their name (Calhoun, (Sageman, 2004, 2007). Here too, it is evi-
1994a; Cohen, 1985; Somers and Gibson, dent that loose and informal networks can
1994). This is even true of revolutionary ter- function effectively as alternatives or com-
rorists and suicide bombers (Pape, 2006; plements to more formal organizations.
Sageman, 2004). Moreover, it is striking that the international
Identities, however, are not inherent – jihadist movement has flourished in large
particularly protest identities (Abrams and part by recruiting individuals and groups
Hogg, 1990). In order to create and maintain drawn to specific nationalist liberation strug-
identities relevant to revolutionary action, gles, and infusing them with an identity
elites and states must produce and cement focused on a global revolutionary movement
novel identifications for people who nor- of Islamism against Western powers as well
mally just think of themselves as workers or as local regimes (Goldstone, 2002b).
peasants, friends or neighbors. Making cer- Protest identities – feelings of attachment
tain identities more salient, indeed creating and affection for a protest group – appear to
protest identities – that is, a sense of being have three sources. First, the group helps to
part of a group with shared and justified justify and validate the individual’s griev-
grievances, with the ability to remedy those ances and anger against the status quo.
grievances by collective action – is a consid- Second, the group – if it provides concrete
erable project (Snow and Benford, 1988; benefits or takes actions that seem effective
Snow et al., 1986). in defending its members and pursuing
For many years, resource mobilization change – gives a sense of empowerment,
theorists argued that mobilizing people for autonomy, and efficacy to its members, earn-
collective action revolved around building ing their affective allegiance (Knoke, 1988;
organizations, such as unions, revolutionary Lawler, 1992). Third, the state itself may
parties, and grass-roots movement organiza- create or reinforce a sense of oppositional
tions such as the National Organization for identity by labeling a group as its enemies or
Women or the Southern Christian Leadership by acting against the group, thus demonstrat-
Conference (McCarthy and Zald, 1977; Tilly, ing that the group is now outside the protec-
1978). Such social movement organizations tion and justice of the state. Members then
were held to be at the heart of sustained col- are forced to look to the group for justice and
lective actions. However, recent studies of protection (Oberschall and Seidman, 2005).
recruitment and of the experience of move- The protest group, in other words, gains
ment participants has shown that formal commitment through giving followers their
organization is neither necessary nor suffi- own sense of justice and effectiveness.
cient to create the sense of commitment and Indeed, it is precisely because the protest
energy needed for risky collective action to group fulfils these functions in ways that the
occur (Calhoun, 1994b; Gould, 1995; state has failed to do, or in a way deemed
McAdam, 1988; Pfaff, 1996). Instead, the superior to that of the state, that individuals
formation of protest identities seems to be are willing to transfer their allegiance from
critical. Although formal organizations can the state to the protest or revolutionary group
often help choose tactics for protest and sus- (Finkel et al., 1989). In some cases, the revo-
tain a movement through reverses and lean lutionary movement literally becomes the
times, informal organization – as shown in the state in the areas under its control, as did the
1989–1991 revolutions in Eastern Europe – Communist Party in the 1940s in rural China
can also bring people together for large- and many guerrilla movements in Latin
scale, risky, and effective challenges to state America, taking over functions of law
authority. enforcement, justice, and even taxation

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 329

(McClintock, 1998; Selden, 1995; Wickham- manipulate perceptions by relating their


Crowley, 1991). In other cases, the revolu- actions and current conditions to existing
tionary movement gains allegiance by cultural frameworks and to carefully con-
validating the grievances and aspirations of structed ideologies (Berejikian, 1992; Chong,
its members through solidarity rituals and by 1991; DeNardo, 1985).
taking actions against the state that may be Analysts of revolution use the term cul-
largely symbolic (Melucci, 1989). tural frameworks or discourses to denote the
The darkest side of protest identity appears long-standing background assumptions,
when revolutionary movements see them- values, myths, stories, and symbols that are
selves as surrounded by enemies, and treat widespread and actively recounted in the
opponents to their rule or outsiders to their population (Foran, 2005). Naturally, the
group as targets to be eliminated. In such frameworks of elites and popular groups may
cases, revolutionary movements can lead not differ, and those of different regional, ethnic,
only to terror and civil war, but to ethnic and occupational groups may vary. Thus, we
cleansing and genocide, as in Cambodia, find a set of roughly overlapping frameworks
Rwanda, and the former Yugoslavia (Harff, rather than a homogenous set of beliefs.
1991, 1995). Ideologies, in contrast, are consciously con-
The creation and maintenance of protest structed, perhaps eclectic but more coherent
identities is a substantial task that depends beliefs, arguments, and value judgments that
on cultural frameworks, ideologies, and are promulgated by those advocating a par-
powerful leadership. ticular course of action. In the early twentieth
century, Christianity, German patriotism, and
a belief in the virtues of the Frankish tribes
Ideology and cultural and pioneers who conquered the forests of
frameworks central Europe were part of the cultural
framework of Germany; Nazism in contrast
The perception that the state is ineffective was an ideology (Skocpol, 1994).
and unjust whereas revolutionary movements As this example shows, those ideologies
of opposition are virtuous and efficacious is that are most effective are those that strike
rarely a direct outcome of structural condi- roots in prevailing cultural frameworks,
tions (Gamson, 1988; Gamson and Meyer, appropriating older stories and images and
1996). Material deprivations and threats need retooling them to resonate with the issues of
to be seen not merely as miserable conditions the present day (Nash, 1989; Shin, 1996).
but as a direct result of the injustice and the The Chinese Communists initially linked
moral and political failings of the state, in their justification for ruling China to restor-
sharp contrast to the virtue and justice of the ing the patriarchal order of the traditional
opposition (Martin et al., 1990). Even defeat Chinese family, which had been undone by
in war, famine, or fiscal collapse may be seen the economic chaos and military defeats suf-
as natural or unavoidable catastrophes rather fered under the Nationalist regime (Stacey,
than as the handiwork of incompetent or 1983). Similarly, Communist organizers in
morally bankrupt regimes. Similarly, acts of Vietnam had no success until they incorpo-
state repression against protesters may be rated ethnic Vietnamese content and cultural
seen as necessary peacekeeping or conversely themes into their appeals (Popkin, 1988).
as unjustified repression; kidnappings, arson, Foran (2005) has argued that revolution is
and bombings may be painted as reprehensi- impossible without drawing on a ‘culture of
ble and cowardly terrorist acts or as patriotic rebellion’ from widely remembered prior
measures for liberation of the oppressed. conflicts. For example, the 1970s Sandinista
Which interpretation prevails depends on the revolt in Nicaragua drew its name and its
ability of states and revolutionary leaders to claim to virtue from the peasant leader

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


330 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Sandino, who fought against US domination Whether or not a revolutionary ideology


of Nicaragua at the beginning of the century. emerges from a given cultural framework
Similarly, the Zapatista rebellion in Chiapas, seems to depend entirely on how elements of
Mexico in the 1980s drew its name and iden- that framework are adapted to particular cir-
tified its ideals with the peasant leader Zapata cumstances or combined with new elements
of the Mexican Revolution of 1910. However, and adopted by particular groups.
these examples do not imply that only coun- Ideologies, in addition to providing value
tries that have actively recalled rebellions in judgments and clothing of virtue for revolu-
their recent past have the cultural foundation tionaries, may accelerate revolutionary
for later uprisings. Revolutionary entrepre- momentum in two other, reinforcing ways.
neurs have proved quite nimble at appropriat- First, revolutionary ideologies usually present
ing cultural foundations for revolt from the their struggle as destined to succeed; having
distant past, or even the imagined past or history or God on their side will ensure the
future. Millennial beliefs dating back to triumph of their followers (Martin et al.,
Native American legends were appropriated 1990). Second, revolutionary ideologies aim
and reconfigured to draw popular support for to bridge the varied cultural frameworks of
the Mexican Revolution; similarly, the different groups and provide a basis for the
millennial beliefs of Chinese Buddhist multi-group and cross-class coalitions so
sects undergirded some of the revolutionary important for challenging state power (Chong,
imagery of the Chinese Communists 1993). These functions reinforce each other.
(Rinehart, 1997). In the English Revolution As a revolutionary group attracts a broader
of 1640, regicides drew on the myth of the range of followers, it begins to seem destined
Norman yoke (though they were of ancient to succeed; at the same time, the more likely
Norman lineage themselves), in which the a movement’s success appears, the more
English royal line planted in 1066 by the followers it will attract.
invasion of William of Normandy was decried Constructing an ideology that will
as a foreign oppressor that enslaved free
Anglo-Saxon Englishmen. In their revolt (a) inspire a broad range of followers by resonating
with existing cultural guideposts;
against Spain in the sixteenth and seven-
(b) provide a sense of inevitability and destiny about
teenth centuries, the Dutch presented them- its followers’ success; and
selves as descendants of the ancient Helvetian (c) persuade people that the existing authorities are
tribes who had fought Roman imperial rule; unjust and weak
in the French Revolution, in an ironic turna-
round, the French revolutionaries liked to is no simple task. Neither is planning a stra-
identify with the Roman founders of the tegic and tactical campaign of opposition or
Republic and their struggle against the skillfully taking advantage of spontaneous
Tarquin kings. uprisings and chance events. Thus, the course
Any cultural framework may provide and outcomes of revolutions depend to a
the basis for revolutionary or anti-revolution- considerable degree on the skills and actions
ary ideologies. Christianity and Islam have of state and revolutionary leaders.
long been the bastion of conservative estab-
lished church organizations; but in recent
years Islamic fundamentalists and Christian Leadership
base communities seem as radical as the
English Puritans of the seventeenth century. Popular histories of revolutions are filled
Communism has been both a revolutionary with accounts of larger-than-life personali-
ideology and the cloak for a conservative and ties: Cromwell, Washington, Robespierre,
privileged elite that was overthrown by lib- Napoleon, Lenin, Stalin, Mao, Castro,
eral intellectuals and nationalist workers. Guevarra, Cabral, Mandela, Aquino.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 331

Sometimes it seems that the origins and out- indulge in megalomaniac fantasies. Thus it
come of the revolutions are inseparable from is no surprise that revolutions often fail to
the will and fate of these revolutionary lead- achieve their pre-revolutionary aims. However,
ers. Yet collective biographies of revolution- this does not mean leadership is insignificant,
ary leaders have shown that although many only that its impact is complex. It requires
are exceptionally charismatic, many are not, varied kinds of leadership not only to build a
and indeed as a whole the background and revolutionary movement that can help topple
personality profiles of revolutionary leaders an old regime, but also to win the internecine
do not markedly differ from those of conven- struggles that follow the collapse of the old
tional political leaders (Rejai and Phillips, order, and to withstand the military blows that
1988). Moreover, in structural theories of often rain down on a new regime. Sometimes,
revolution, these leaders hardly ever appear, ruthless manipulation of vital resources such
or if mentioned, they seem to be unwitting as food supplies is critical to revolutionaries
dupes of history whose best intentions are depriving their enemies of support, and keep-
always frustrated by deeper social, political, ing control over their own supporters
or economic forces. (Oberschall and Seidman, 2005). If a revolu-
This disconnect can be understood by tionary leadership survives all this and falls
focusing on the skills of revolutionary lead- into megalomaniac excess, the suffering
ers themselves. Successful leaders excel at that follows only underlines the impact of
taking advantage of favorable political and revolutionary leaders on the fate of ordinary
economic circumstances. Poor leaders gener- people and of nations (Chirot, 1994; Friedman
ally act when circumstances are highly et al., 1991).
unfavorable to success. The resulting Studies of leadership have found that there
pattern – leaders appear to succeed only are two distinct types and that they usually
when conditions favor them and to fail must be combined – either in one person or
otherwise – makes revolutionary success through the cooperation of two or more – for
appear to be strictly a matter of background an enterprise to succeed. Interestingly, these
conditions and obscures the role of leader- two types of leadership, ‘people-oriented’
ship in actually making a revolution out of and ‘task-oriented’ (Aminzade et al., 2001;
merely potentially favorable circumstances. Selbin, 1993), mirror the two dimensions of
The importance of leadership is clear in successful governance or mobilization,
fairly extreme cases such as the ‘New Jewel’ namely justice and effectiveness. People-
Revolution in Grenada, where poor leader- oriented leaders are those who inspire people,
ship led an apparently successful revolution give them a sense of identity and power, and
to self-destruct (Selbin, 1993), or cases such provide a vision of a new and just order
as the Chinese Communist Revolution, where around which their followers unite their ener-
outstanding leadership was able to sustain a gies and their purposes. Task-oriented lead-
revolutionary movement through apparently ers are those who can plot a strategy suitable
crushing defeat and to plan for circumstances to resources and circumstances, set the time-
that would allow victory (Selden, 1995). tables for people and supplies to reach spe-
The failure of revolutionary leaders to cific ends, manage money effectively, and
achieve their proclaimed aims – liberty, equal- respond to shifting circumstances with appro-
ity, prosperity – is also taken as evidence of priate strategies and tactics. The purely peo-
the minor impact of leadership. Yet it is not ple-oriented leader is personified by the
that simple; after a revolution, its supporters religious prophet; the purely task-oriented
often divide and fall out among themselves, leader is figured by the brilliant military gen-
military confrontations test and reshape revo- eral. Movements with only strong people-
lutionary regimes, and once they attain abso- oriented leadership may end up as devoted
lute power, many leaders are blinded by it and but tiny cults (Hall et al., 2000); movements

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


332 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

that have strong task-oriented leadership but visionaries, and the current counterthrust of
no vision often fail to consolidate themselves moderates remains weak; in Nicaragua, US
in popular consciousness, and their revolu- pressure weakened the visionaries and
tionary character will soon fade away allowed a pragmatic coalition under Violetta
(Selbin, 1993). Chamorro to rise to power. Thus, there is no
It generally seems to require two or more guarantee that the right balance of people-
people or groups to fulfill the roles of vision- oriented and task-oriented leadership will be
aries and organizers of a revolution, even sustained, and the course of a revolution can
though the division of tasks is not always veer in different directions accordingly.
clear-cut. Puritan preachers and Oliver
Cromwell’s generalship combined to inspire
and effect the Puritan Revolution in Britain; Gender relations and
Jefferson and Adams were firebrands of the revolutionary movements
American Revolution, but it would have
failed without Washington’s generalship and Numerous studies have now documented the
power brokering at the Constitutional extensive role played by women in revolu-
Convention; the Jacobins’ vision for France tions, from the English and French
might have failed sooner if not for Napoleon’s Revolutions (Davies, 1998; Hufton, 1992) to
military victories; Lenin had Trotsky to lead recent Third World revolutions (Diamond,
the uprising of the workers and to build the 1998; Tétreault, 1994; Wasserstrom, 1994).
Red Army; Fidel Castro had Ché Guevarra Women have been active in street demonstra-
and his brother Raul to fuel and organize the tions, guerrilla warfare, provision of food
Cuban Revolution; the Ortega brothers had and supplies, and local leadership. However,
complementary ideological and military roles despite this massive participation, there is
in leading the Nicaraguan Revolution; and often less connection than one would expect
Ayatollah Khomeini relied on the liberal pro- between female participation in revolutions
fessional Bani-Sadr to help institutionalize and the gender character of the movement or
the Iranian Revolution and ward off the the emergence of women as autonomous
military attack from Iraq. leaders.
In many cases, the visionary and practical Moghadam (1997) and Taylor (1999) have
leaders clash in the course of the revolution, pointed out that protest and revolutionary
and one side takes over. In China, Mao and movements always, whether implicitly or
his initial successors, the Gang of Four, explicitly, have a gender agenda in their own
clearly leaned toward the visionary side organization and goals. Since almost all soci-
regardless of the practical costs; in Russia, eties in history have been patriarchal, protest
the dull and practical party-builders under movements and revolutions generally oppose
Brezhnev won out a little over a decade after patriarchal regimes and institutions. They
Stalin’s death. Interestingly, in both these therefore must make a choice. While oppos-
cases, the result was a counterthrust – in ing the existing political institutions, do they
China the ultrapragmatic Deng regime, in the nonetheless adopt and reproduce the patriar-
Soviet Union the attempt to reinspire the chal character dominant in society in their
nation with an infusion of more liberal ideas own movement? Or do they seek to overturn
under Gorbachev. In Iran, the more extreme that character in their movement and in their
ideological clerical groups initially won out vision of a new society?
over liberal pragmatists, as did the commu- Often, there is a significant divergence
nist-leaning Sandinistas in Nicaragua over between rhetoric and practice. The Russian
their more liberal allies. In the Iranian case, and Cuban revolutions consciously aimed to
US pressure actually reinforced the extreme create a gender-equal society, and they did

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 333

succeed in bringing many more women into transformations in the household and leader-
the workplace and the professions (Goldman, ship status of women in their societies.
1993; Smith and Padula, 1996). However,
they recruited few women to major leader-
ship roles and did not alter the basically
male-biased values of their societies. The A PARADOX OF REVOLUTIONARY
English, French, and American Revolutions PROCESSES: IS REPRESSION
inspired many women to play critical grass- A BARRIER OR SPUR TO
roots roles and even included female ideals in REVOLUTIONS?
their revolutionary iconography (Hunt, 1992).
However, they took no action to change the The perception that structural conditions are
traditional role of women in society. The the main, if not the sole, determinant of revo-
Iranian Revolution involved many western- lutions is strengthened by the fact that revo-
ized, educated women who consciously lutions sometimes seem to come about
adopted traditional Islamic female dress as a despite all efforts of the state to appease
symbol of their opposition to Western cul- or repress them. Often, paradoxically,
tural imperialism and their support for the fierce repression is unable to daunt, or
revolution. Yet these women were surprised even inflames, revolutionary opposition
to find that they were excluded from further (Davenport, 2007; Khawaja, 1993; Kurzman,
efforts to shape the revolution, and that the 1996; Lichbach, 1987; Moore, 1998; Olivier,
very anti-western Islamist modes of self- 1991; Rasler, 1996; Weede, 1987). In many
representation they adopted to help make the cases, state reforms only encourage revolu-
revolution became part of their enhanced tionaries to demand more. Yet in other cases,
repression afterward (Fantasia and Hirsch, most recently in the democracy movements
1995; Moghadam, 1994). in Burma and in China, apparently highly
The key question about engendering favorable conditions and considerable mass
revolutionary movements is whether in patri- mobilization were crushed by state repres-
archal societies women can ever be suffi- sion (Brook, 1998; Carey, 1997; Walder,
ciently persuasive and powerful to become 1989). When do repression and reform work
visionary or effective leaders in their to halt the progress of revolution, and when
own right. The major female revolutionary do they fail or even backfire and provoke or
leaders – Aquino in the Philippines, Chamorro inflame revolutionary action?
in Nicaragua, Aung San Suu Ki in Burma – While perceptions of state injustice and
all acquired a leadership mantle from mar- ineffectiveness may lead to opposition, the
tyred husbands or fathers. This pattern also development of such conflicts has a contin-
appears among democratic female leaders in gent and metamorphic character. The actions
Asia, such as India’s Indira Ghandi, Pakistan’s and reactions of regimes, regime opponents,
Benazir Bhutto, and Sri Lanka’s Sirimavo counter-movements, and the broader public
Bandaranaike. To date, despite the wide- all reshape the processes of group identifica-
spread participation of women in revolution- tion, perceptions of the efficacy and justice
ary movements and their crucial contribu- of the regime and its opponents, and esti-
tions as bridge leaders, they have yet to play mates of what changes are possible (Gartner
an independently dominant leadership role and Regan, 1996; Kurzman, 1996; Rasler,
(except in the movement for women’s politi- 1996; Zhao, 2001). Movements of reform
cal equality, if one treats it as revolutionary). may become radicalized and revolutionary,
Nor have revolutions, even where they have initially small confrontations may spiral into
brought women full participation in voting mass uprisings, or large popular movements
and workplace opportunities, brought rapid may be crushed.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


334 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

It is well known that many revolutions and erratic that innocents are persecuted, or that
rebellions, from the English and French is aimed at groups that the public considers
Revolutions to the Kenyan Mau-Mau revolt representative and justified in their protest,
and Colombia’s La Violencia, grew out of can quickly undermine perceptions of the
efforts to reform, not overthrow, the ruling regime’s effectiveness and justice (Goldstone
regimes (Speck, 1990; Walton, 1984). A and Tilly, 2001; White, 1989). Thus, the
combination of unexpected popular pressures deaths of Pedro Chamorro in Nicaragua and
from below, conflicts between conservative of Benigno Aquino in the Philippines, the
and radical factions of the reform movement, diffuse persecution of ordinary citizens by
reactions to international interventions, Batista in Cuba, and the deaths inflicted on
and temporizing or provocative actions by protestors in Iran by the forces of the Shah in
the regime, gave precedence to both more 1978 spurred accelerations of popular pro-
radical leadership and more revolutionary test. In contrast, the overwhelming force
policies (Furet, 1981). In fact, the structural used against the Tiananmen Square protes-
conditions that give rise to social protest tors, who were publicly labeled as counter-
movements, unsuccessful rebellions, and revolutionary traitors, broke public resistance
revolutions are generally quite similar. The to communist rule in China for at least two
transformation of social movements into decades (Zhao, 2001).
rebellions or revolutions depends on how Perception of the vulnerability of rulers
regimes, elites, and publics respond to the also makes a difference to the effect of
conflict situation (Goldstone, 1998b). repression. When the regime is judged to be
When facing demands for change, ruling losing support and capable of being over-
regimes may employ any combination of thrown, protestors may bear great risks, and
concessions and repression to defuse the great regime violence may simply further
opposition (Davenport, 1995). Choosing the persuade people that the regime has got to
right combination is not an easy task. If a go; yet when a regime is seen as unshakeable,
regime that has already lost its perceived indiscriminate violence and terror may
effectiveness and justice offers concessions, simply reduce the opposition to silence
these may be seen as ‘too little, too late,’ and (Brockett, 1995; Mason and Krane, 1989;
simply increase the popular demands for Opp, 1994).
large-scale change. This is why Machiavelli Rulers, however, have few guideposts to
advised rulers to undertake reforms only help them determine in advance whether a
from a position of strength; if undertaken given level of concession or repression is
from a position of weakness, they will further sufficient. Lack of information and overcon-
undermine support for the regime. The efforts fidence further conspire to produce inappro-
of the Dowager Empress in late Imperial priate responses. Worse yet, rulers often veer
China, and of Gorbachev in the waning days back and forth between concessions and
of the Soviet Union, to encourage western- repression, appearing inconsistent and there-
izing reforms led to escalating criticism of fore both ineffective and unjust (Goldstone
the old regimes and ultimately to their com- and Tilly, 2001). For example, both Marcos
plete rejection and overthrow (Teitzel and in the Philippines and Milosevic in Serbia
Weber, 1994). believed they could rig victory in elections,
Repression is also a matter of degree and and therefore they made the apparent conces-
of context. Repression that is powerful, or sion of calling elections to justify their
that is focused on a small and deviant group, authoritarian rule. When, despite their efforts,
may be seen as evidence of state effective- it was widely perceived that they lost the
ness and cow the opposition. However, elections, they then had to fall back on
repression that is not strong enough to sup- repression to maintain their rule. But because
press opponents, or that is so diffuse and of the perceived electoral losses, military and

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 335

police resolve to defend the regime was own decisions, would logically choose not to
weakened, and repression of popular protests join in revolutionary action. Since all indi-
failed, leading to the collapse of the regime. viduals face some risks and costs if they
An apparently strong regime that represses participate in revolutionary actions, but will
weakly or inconsistently, or that offers con- reap the same benefits if a revolution suc-
cessions deemed inadequate, can quickly ceeds whether they participated or not, indi-
undermine its own position (Kurzman, 1996). viduals who are rational will spare themselves
Because authoritarian regimes are often so the risks and let others act (Olson, 1965;
distant from understanding their own sub- Tullock, 1971). However, scholars have now
jects, or so overconfident in their estimation demonstrated that in practice, this collective
of their own power, errors by such regimes action problem for individuals can be resolved
are common, and often an apparently secure in many ways, and that revolutionary action
regime that has lasted many years suddenly can indeed have solid micro-level founda-
unravels in the face of a rapidly expanding tions in rational behavior.
opposition that in prior years no one had Lichbach (1995) has shown that there are
anticipated – Iran in 1979, the Philippines in four main families of solutions to the collec-
1986, and the Eastern European and Soviet tive action problem, each offering a way to
communist regimes in 1989–1991. In con- motivate individuals to join in protest –
trast, regimes that appear structurally weak, changing incentives, using community obli-
such as the personal rule of Mobutu in Zaire, gations, arranging contracts, and using
can persist for many years if the use of con- authority. In practice, they appear in various
cessions and repression is skillful in dividing combinations and provide a plethora of ways
and neutralizing, rather than uniting and to create collective action. Thus, the research
inflaming, the opposition (Snyder, 1998). agenda of rational-choice theory in regard to
revolutions is no longer one of posing obsta-
cles to collective action; instead rational-
choice analysis has joined with other
MICRO-LEVEL FOUNDATIONS approaches in seeking to identify the proc-
AND QUALITATIVE ANALYSIS esses by which collective action solutions are
achieved, and the general characteristics of
The study of revolutions has been dominated those solutions.
in the past two decades by scholars using the The general character of these solutions is
case-study approach with national trajecto- to change the decision to engage in revolution-
ries as cases. However, political science in ary action from an individual decision to a
general has moved strongly in the direction group decision, relying on prior network ties
of micro-level analysis of the motivations of or forging group identities. People who
individuals involved in political actions, strongly identify with a group generally feel
using rational choice modeling. A number of an obligation to act if the group acts, and
scholars have applied rational choice analy- believe that other group members will act with
sis to the study of revolutionary origins and them (Oliver, 1984). The main check on pro-
dynamics. test activity then is not the collective action
problem but whether people believe that the
group will succeed if action is taken (Chong,
Micro-level foundations: 1991; Goldstone, 1994; Hardin, 1995; Macy,
The rationality of revolution 1990, 1991; Moore, 1995; Oberschall, 1994b;
Opp, 1989; Taylor, 1988).
Revolution is described by rational-choice Rational choice models also demonstrate
theorists as a ‘collective action problem.’ why revolutionary mobilization is prone to
This is because individuals, making their rapid and often surprising spirals of escalation.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


336 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

If the key to protest mobilization is convincing have on outcomes contradicts this assump-
groups that their actions will be effective tion, for revolutionary outcomes often take
against the regime, then two bits of information unexpected twists and turns.
are crucial: the relative weakness or resolve of Stinchcombe (1999) offered the reasonable
the regime and the number of other groups that argument that a revolution is over when the
support the action. Shifts in perception or infor- stability and survival of the institutions
mation can suddenly make groups that long imposed by the new regime are no longer in
harbored concerns about regime injustice or doubt. Yet even this definition is ambiguous,
effectiveness believe that now their action can as it can take weak and strong forms. By the
make a difference. Single events or crises that weak definition, a revolution is over when the
provide new information can thus precipitate basic institutions of the new regime are no
sudden mobilization based on previously con- longer being actively challenged by revolu-
cealed preferences and beliefs, producing a tionary or counterrevolutionary forces. By this
bandwagon effect as more groups add their standard, the French Revolution ended in
actions to what appears to be an increasingly Thermidor 1799 when Napoleon took power,
favorable juncture for action (Chong, 1991; the Russian Revolution of 1917 ended in 1921
Karklins and Peterson, 1993; Kuran, 1989; with the Bolshevik victory over the White
Lichbach, 1995; Lohmann, 1993). These armies, and the Mexican Revolution of 1910
models provide a framework for understanding ended in 1920 with Obregon’s presidency. Yet
the explosive mobilization seen in events a strong definition, by which a revolution has
such as the sudden collapse of communist con- ended only when key political and economic
trol in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe institutions have settled down into forms that
(Kuran, 1991). will remain basically intact for a substantial
Finally, recent rational choice models of period, say 20 years, gives far different results.
regime survival and transformation also By this definition, as Furet (1981) has argued,
stress the pivotal role of elites. In these the French Revolution ended only with the
models, it is the ability of elites to maintain start of the French Third Republic in 1871.
unity and respond to popular demands with The Russian Revolution of 1917 would not be
reasonable concessions, or shifts in elite/ considered over until after Stalin’s purges of
popular coalitions, that determine the fate of the 1930s; and the Mexican Revolution of
regimes (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005; 1910 would be dated as lasting through the
Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2004). Cárdenas reforms, to 1940. For that matter, the
The past decade of rational choice research Chinese Revolution that began in 1910 has yet
on revolutions has thus underlined the same to end, as none of the Republican, Nationalist,
topics – group identity, network ties, and Communist, or Great Proletarian Cultural
elite/popular relationships – emphasized in Revolutions produced a lasting socioeconomic
recent comparative historical studies. order. Goldstone and Becker (2005), using the
strong definition, found that it generally takes
quite a long time to restore stability after a
revolution. Across 47 cases of revolution from
OUTCOMES OF REVOLUTIONS the sixteenth to the twentieth century, the aver-
age time to restore order was 12 years, or 18
The outcomes of revolutions have generated years if only major social revolutions were
far less scholarly inquiry than the causes, considered. Only revolutions that avoided
with the possible exception of outcomes major civil wars were able to restore order in
regarding gender. This may be because the a relatively short period, five years or less.
outcomes of revolutions are assumed to Sadly, there is no scholarly consensus
follow straightforwardly if the revolutionar- on what constitutes the end of a revolution,
ies succeed. However, such research as we and different analysts use weak, strong, or

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 18 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 337

idiosyncratic definitions to determine when a against strong expectations of reversion to


revolution has ended. Yet although it is diffi- dictatorship (Foran and Goodwin, 1993;
cult to say precisely when a revolution is Pastor, 2001; Weitman, 1992). The factors
over, it is nonetheless possible to discuss the that allowed democracy to emerge in these
consequences that most commonly unfold cases appear to be several: a lack of external
after the fall of the old regime. military threat, a strong personal commit-
ment to democracy by revolutionary leaders,
and consistent external support of the new
Domestic outcomes democratic regimes by foreign powers.
Economic performance is more puzzling.
Revolutionaries frequently claim that they One might expect revolutions to unleash
will reduce inequality, establish democracy, great energy for rebuilding economic sys-
and provide economic prosperity. In fact, the tems, just as they lead to rebuilding of politi-
record of actual revolutions is rather poor cal institutions. Yet in fact this rarely if ever
in regard to all of these claims (Weede and takes place. For the most part, long-term
Muller, 1997). economic performance in revolutionary
Although many revolutions engage in regimes lags that of comparable countries
some initial redistribution of assets (particu- that have not experienced revolutions
larly land), no revolutionary regime has been (Eckstein, 1982, 1986). This may be in part
able to maintain more than a symbolic equal- because the elite divisions and conflicts that
ity. Rewards to administrators and top eco- both precede and often follow revolution are
nomic producers quickly lead to differentiation inimical to economic progress (Haggard and
of incomes (Kelley and Klein, 1977). This Kaufman, 1995).
has been true in both capitalist and commu- It appears that the very effort that goes into
nist revolutionary regimes. In addition, many rebuilding political institutions throttles
regimes that begin with radical and populist economic growth (Zimmermann, 1990).
economic schemes eventually revert to bour- Revolutionary regimes are generally more
geois and capitalist economic organization, centralized and more bureaucratic than the
such as Mexico, Egypt, and most recently ones they replace (Skocpol, 1979). In addi-
China (Katz, 1999). tion, to secure their authority, revolutionary
Until very recently, revolutions have invar- leaders are often quite restrictive in regard to
iably failed to produce democracy. The need entrepreneurial activity; five-year plans and
to consolidate a new regime in the face of state supervision or ownership of major eco-
struggles with domestic and foreign foes has nomic enterprises place economic activity in
instead produced authoritarian regimes, often narrow channels.
in the guise of populist dictatorships such as Revolutionary regimes can often focus
those of Napoleon, Castro, and Mao, or of resources and create hothouse growth in
one-party states such as the PRI state in selected industries. The Soviet Union and
Mexico or the Communist Party-led states of China were fairly successful in creating
the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. Indeed, nineteenth-century-style heavy industrial
the struggle required to take and hold power in complexes. Yet neither of them, nor Iran, nor
revolutions generally leaves its mark in the Nicaragua, nor any other revolutionary
militarized and coercive character of new revo- regime, has succeeded in generating the
lutionary regimes (Gurr, 1988). It is therefore broad-based economic innovation and entre-
striking that in several recent revolutions – in preneurship required to generate sustained
the Philippines in 1986, in South Africa in rapid economic advance (Chirot, 1991).
1990, in Eastern European nations in 1989– It may be, however, that the new democra-
1991 – the sudden collapse of the old regime tizing revolutions will prove an excep-
has led directly to new democracies, often tion. They appear to be less economically

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 19 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


338 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

restrictive and less heavily bureaucratic causal factor – the role of leadership – and
than the regimes they replaced. Poland, the the one area in which revolutionary outcomes
Czech Republic, and the former East have generally met or even exceeded expec-
Germany have all shown strong economic tations, namely the augmentation of state
gains. Nonetheless, most revolutionary states power.
even recently have either been so rigid as to The major objectives of revolutionary
continue to restrain economic activity (e.g., leaders are to restructure the bases of politi-
Belarus and the Central Asian post-soviet cal power, to leave their mark on the political
republics), or so weak and disorganized as to and/or economic and social organization of
be unable to promote and secure a broad society, and to alter the status of their nation
economic advance (e.g., Russia, Georgia, in the international system. Whatever
South Africa). The general tendency of revo- their other failings, revolutions have been
lutions to produce poor economic perform- remarkably successful in mobilizing popula-
ance thus seems intact, although with a few tions and utilizing that mobilization for polit-
hopeful exceptions. ical and military power (Skocpol, 1994).
As noted above, another area in which Although the eventual goals of democratiza-
revolutionary outcomes usually fall short of tion or equality or prosperity have often been
expectations is the social emancipation of elusive, for the immediate aims of seizing
women and their elevation to leadership and expanding state authority, changing the
roles. Although modern socialist revolutions rules for access to political power, improving
have generally brought women into the pro- standing in the international system, and
fessions and the labor force, they have not restructuring beliefs and institutions, revolu-
changed their essentially secondary status tions have been wildly successful for leaders
(Lapidus, 1978). Despite women’s extensive from Napoleon to Hitler to Lenin to Castro.
participation and grass-roots leadership in The ability of successful revolutionary
most of the revolutions in history, gender leaders to reshape their societies (if not
equality has remained absent, or if articu- always with the expected ultimate results)
lated, still illusory, in the outcome of revolu- thus continues to inspire revolutionary entre-
tionary struggles (Foran et al., 1997; Lobao, preneurs. As we have seen, a major feature of
1990; Randall, 1993). revolutionary mobilization is the effort of a
Religious and ethnic minorities often do committed core or vanguard to mobilize a
worse, rather than better, under revolutionary mass following based on ideological depic-
regimes. While revolutions often promise tions of the present regime as fundamentally
equality in the abstract to all followers, when ineffective and unjust. The continued appeal
counterrevolution or external interventions of revolution, despite a lengthy history of
threaten the revolutionary regime, any groups frustration of mass aspirations, must be
not bound by ethnic and religious solidarity understood in the context of leadership
to the new government become suspect in dynamics and mobilization processes that
their loyalties and may be singled out for focus attention on present injustices rather
persecution. Such has been the fate of the than future results (Martin et al., 1990).
Bahai under the Islamic revolution in Iran,
the Miskito Indians in Nicaragua, and those
Croats, Muslims, and Serbs who found them- Outcomes in the
selves on the wrong sides of borders in the international system
revolutionary breakup of Yugoslavia.
With so many disappointments in the out- Walt (1996) has demonstrated why one of
comes of revolutions, why have they none- the first results of revolutions is often exter-
theless been so vigorously pursued? To nal war. The sudden appearance of a
answer that question, we need to recall one new regime upsets old alliances and creates

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 20 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 339

new uncertainties. Foreign powers may judge revolution in Russia and the Nazi revolution,
the new regime as either vulnerable or dan- brought Soviet expansionism into Eastern
gerous; either judgment can lead to war. New Europe and split the German nation, shaping
revolutionary regimes, inexperienced in for- the major cleavages in the international
eign affairs, may make similar errors of system for 50 years. Anti-colonial revolu-
judgment regarding their neighbors (Conge, tions, of course, add new states to the inter-
1996). national system and reduce the influence of
Aside from these miscalculations, revolu- colonial powers in the regions they formerly
tionary regimes may take actions that pre- ruled. Many other revolutions occur in defi-
cipitate or exacerbate military strife. Many ance of foreign patrons who supported the
revolutions, from the Puritan Revolution in old regime; in Afghanistan, Vietnam,
England and the liberal French Revolution to Nicaragua, Cuba, and Iran, such revolutions
the communist revolutions in Russia, China, led to extended hostilities between the old
and Cuba and the Islamic revolution in Iran, patron power and the new regime. Both kinds
explicitly made changing the world part of of revolution satisfy revolutionary elites’
their revolutionary program. Armstrong strong yearnings for nationalist assertiveness
(1993) has shown how these efforts upset the and autonomy while reinforcing the general
existing international balance of power. population’s sense of power. Even in Mexico
Moreover, we have noted that revolutions are and the Philippines, where the revolutionar-
made by coalitions and involve both vision- ies did not assume a strongly hostile stance
ary and pragmatic wings of leadership. toward the United States (which had sup-
Foreign threats may give leverage to the ported their prevolutionary regimes), the
more visionary and radical elements in the eruption of nationalist sentiment accompany-
revolutionary coalitions, who deliberately ing the revolutions led to nationalizing of
seek combat and missionary adventures assets in Mexico and expulsion of the United
(Blanning, 1986; Sadri, 1997). In contrast, States from its Philippine military bases.
where more moderate and pragmatic leaders Thus, in ways subtle as well as dramatic, the
remain in charge, and foreign powers support outcomes of revolutions reshape interna-
rather than threaten the new regime, internal tional relations for many decades, often
impetus for war is likely to be weak, as was giving new initiative and autonomy to states
the case following the revolutions in the in which revolutions took place (Siverson
United States, Bolivia, and Zimbabwe and Starr, 1994).
(Snyder, 1999).
Eventually, even revolutionary regimes
must accommodate to the reality of the inter-
national states system and assume a position CONCLUSION
in the constellation of international powers
(Armstrong, 1993). Revolutions can produce Theories of revolution are moving away from
long-lasting shifts in national standing and a predominantly structural view, in which a
alignments in the international system. Some set of economic or political conditions gener-
revolutions provide new aggressive energy to ate revolutions, in favor of a more process-
older nations, leading them to become oriented view. In this approach, revolutionary
regional or global threats to older powers. situations emerge from a combination of
Thus, Japan after the Meiji Restoration, structural background factors that present
Germany after the Nazi revolution, and challenges to states or that increase conflicts
Russia after Stalin’s consolidation of the among states, elites, and popular groups,
communist revolution became expansionary along with contingent decisions and interac-
states. The outcome of World War II, tions among key actors. Those decisions and
arguably a product of both the communist interactions in turn are shaped by state rulers

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 21 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


340 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

and revolutionary leaders, networks of mobi- Arjomand, S.A. (1988) The turban for the
lization and multi-class alliances, and state crown: The Islamic revolution in Iran. New
and revolutionary ideologies. York: Oxford University Press.
Revolutions continue to reshape both Armstrong, D. (1993) Revolution and world
domestic regimes and the international order. order: The revolutionary state in international
As authoritarian and semi-authoritarian society. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
regimes continue to evolve in the Middle Banac, I. (ed.) (1992) Eastern Europe in revolu-
East, central and south Asia, North Korea, tion. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
China, Africa, and parts of Latin America, Beissinger, M. (1998) ‘Event analysis in transi-
tional societies: Protest mobilization in the
the potential for clashes among rulers seek-
former Soviet Union’, in D. Rucht, R. Koopmans
ing to hold power and revolutionary oppo-
and F. Neidhardt (eds), Acts of dissent. New
nents remains. The relatively peaceful and developments in the study of protest. Berlin:
democratic ‘color’ revolutions in the Sigma, pp. 284–316.
Philippines, Ukraine, Georgia, and other Beissinger, M. (2002) Nationalist mobilization
countries has provided an attractive model and the collapse of the soviet state.
for overturning semi-authoritarian regimes Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
(Bunce and Wolchik, 2006). At the same Berejikian, J. (1992) ‘Revolutionary collective
time, the ‘internationalization’ of revolution- action and the agent-structure problem’,
ary fundamentalist Islamism, and its use of American Political Science Review, 86:
terror tactics, has captured the attention of 647–57.
Blanning, T.C.W. (1986) The origins of the
the world and shaped the foreign relations
French revolutionary wars. London: Longman.
and domestic policies of dozens of nations.
Bonnell, V.E. (1983) Roots of rebellion: Workers,
Whether those clashes lead to further vio- politics and organizations in St. Petersburg
lence or to more peaceful transformations of and Moscow, 1900–1914. Berkeley: University
states and authorities will depend on the of California Press.
actions of leaders, the clash of ideologies and Brinton, C. (1938) The anatomy of revolution.
perceptions, and the patterns of mobilization New York: Norton.
and elite responses that emerge. Brockett, C. (1995) ‘A protest–cycle resolution
of the repression/popular protest paradox’, in
M. Traugott (ed.), Repertoires and cycles of
collective action. Durham, NC: Duke University
REFERENCES Press, pp. 117–44.
Brook, T. (1998) Quelling the people. Stanford,
Abrams, D. and Hogg, M.A. (1990) Social CA: Stanford University Press.
identity theory: Constructive and critical Bueno de Mesquita, B., Siverson, R.M., and
advances. London: Harvester-Wheatsheaf. Woller, G. (1992) ‘War and the fate of
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J.A. (2005) regimes: a comparative analysis’, American
Economic origins of dictatorship and democ- Political Science Review, 86 (3): 638–45.
racy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson,
Aminzade, R., Goldstone, J.A., and Perry, E.J. R.M., and Morrow, J.D. (2004) The logic of
(2001) ‘Leadership dynamics and dynamics political survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
of contention’, in R. Aminzade, J.A. Bunce, V. (1999) Subversive institutions: the
Goldstone, D. McAdam, E.J. Perry, W. design and the destruction of socialism and
Sewell Jr., S. Tarrow and C. Tilly (eds), Silence the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University
and voice in contentious politics. Cambridge: Press.
Cambridge University Press. Bunce, V. and Wolchik, S. (2006) ‘Favorable
Aminzade R., Goldstone J.A., McAdam D., Perry conditions and electoral revolutions’, Journal
E.J., Sewell W. Jr., Tarrow, S., and Tilly, C. of Democracy, 17 (4): 5–18.
(2001) Silence and voice in contentious Calhoun, C. (1983) ‘The radicalism of tradition’,
politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University American Journal of Sociology, 88 (5):
Press. 886–914.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 22 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 341

Calhoun, C. (1994a) ‘The problem of identity in Diamond, M.J. (ed.) (1998) Women and revolu-
collective action’, in J. Huber (ed.), Macro- tion: Global expressions. Dordrecht and
micro linkages in sociology. Newbury Park, Boston: Kluwer.
CA: Sage, pp. 51–75. Diamond, L.J. and Plattner, M.F. (eds) (1993)
Calhoun, C. (1994b) Neither gods nor emperors: Capitalism, socialism and democracy.
Students and the struggle for democracy in Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University
China. Berkeley: University of California Press. Press.
Carey, P. (1997) From Burma to Myanmar: mili- Dix, R. (1983) ‘The varieties of revolution’,
tary rule and the struggle for democracy. Comparative Politics, 15 (3): 281–95.
London: Research Institute for the Study of Dunn, J. (1989) Modern revolutions: An intro-
Conflict and Terrorism. duction to the analysis of a political phenom-
Chirot, D. (ed.) (1991) The crisis of Leninism and enon (2nd edition) Cambridge: Cambridge
the decline of the left: the revolutions of 1989. University Press.
Seattle: University of Washington Press. Eckstein, S. (1982) ‘The impact of revolution on
Chirot, D. (1994) Modern tyrants. New York: social welfare in Latin America’, Theory and
Free Press. Society, 11 (1): 43–94.
Chong, D. (1991) Collective action and the civil Eckstein, S. (1986) ‘The impact of the Cuban
rights movement. Chicago: University of revolution: A comparative perspective’,
Chicago Press. Comparative Studies in Sociology and History,
Chong, D. (1993) ‘Coordinating demands for 28: 503–34.
social change’, The Annals of the American Eckstein, S. (1989a) ‘Power and popular pro-
Academy of Political and Social Science, 2 tests in Latin America’, in S. Eckstein (ed.),
(1): 126–41. Power and popular protest: Latin American
Cohen, J. (1985) ‘Strategy or identity: New social movements. Berkeley: University of
theoretical paradigms and contemporary California Press, pp. 1–60.
social movements’, Sociological Research, 52 Eckstein, S. (ed.) (1989b) Power and popular
(4): 663–716. protest: Latin American social movements.
Colburn, F.D. (1994) The vogue of revolution in Berkeley: University of California Press.
poor countries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Eisenstadt, S.N. (1978) Revolution and the
University Press. transformation of societies. New York: Free
Conge, P.J. (1996) From revolution to war: Press.
State relations in a world of change. Ann Eisenstadt, S.N. (1992) ‘Frameworks of the
Arbor: University of Michigan Press. great revolutions: culture, social structure,
Davenport, C. (1995) ‘Multi-dimensional threat history, and human agency’, International
perception and state repression: An inquiry Social Science Journal, 133 (3): 385–401.
into why states apply negative sanctions’, Eisenstadt, S.N. (2006) The great revolutions
American Journal of Political Science, 39 (3): and the civilizations of modernity. Leiden:
683–713. Brill.
Davenport, C. (2007) ‘State repression and Emirbayer, M.E. and Goodwin, J. (1996)
political order’, Annual Review of Political ‘Symbols, positions, objects: Toward a new
Science, 10 (1): 1–23. theory of revolutions and collective action’,
Davies, J.C. (1962) ‘Toward a theory of revolu- History and Theory, 35 (3): 358–74.
tion’, American Sociological Review, 27 (1): Fantasia, R. and Hirsch, E.L. (1995) ‘Culture in
5–19. rebellion: The appropriation and transforma-
Davies, S. (1998) Unbridled spirits: Women of tion of the veil in the Algerian Revolution’, in
the English revolution, 1640–1660. London: H. Johnston and B. Klandermans (eds), Social
Women’s Press. movements and culture. University of
DeNardo, J. (1985) Power in numbers. Princeton, Minnesota Press.
NJ: Princeton University Press. Farhi, F. (1990) States and urban-based revolu-
Denoeux, G. (1993) Urban unrest in the Middle tion: Iran and Nicaragua. Urbana and Chicago:
East: A comparative study of informal net- University of Illinois Press.
works in Egypt, Iran, and Lebanon. Albany, Fenger, M. (2007) ‘The diffusion of revolutions:
NY: SUNY Press. Comparing recent regime turnovers in five

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 23 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


342 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

post-communist countries’, Demokratizatsiya, Mexico’, Theory and Society, 7 (1–2):


15 (1): 5–28. 135–65.
Finkel, S.E., Muller, E.N., and Opp, K.-D. (1989) Goldman, W.Z. (1993) Women, the state, and
‘Personal influence, collective rationality, and revolution: Soviet family policy and social life,
mass political action’, American Political 1917–1936. Cambridge: Cambridge
Science Review, 83 (3): 885–903. University Press.
Foran, J. (1997a) ‘Discourses and social forces: Goldstone, J.A. (1980) ‘Theories of revolution:
the role of culture and cultural studies in the third generation’, World Politics,
understanding revolutions’, in J. Foran (ed.), 32 (3): 425–53.
Theorizing revolutions. London: Routledge, Goldstone, J.A. (1991) Revolution and rebellion
pp. 203–26. in the early modern world. Berkeley: University
Foran, J. (ed.) (1997b) Theorizing revolutions. of California Press.
London: Routledge. Goldstone, J.A. (1994) ‘Is revolution individually
Foran, J. (ed.) (2003) The future of revolutions: rational?’, Rationality and Society, 6 (1):
Radical change in an age of globalization. 139–66.
London: Zed. Goldstone, J.A. (1998a) ‘The Soviet Union: revo-
Foran, J. (2005) Taking power: On the origins lution and transformation’, in M. Dogan and
of third world revolutions. Cambridge: J Higley (ed.), Elites, crises, and the origins of
Cambridge University Press. regimes. Boulder, CO: Rowman & Littlefield,
Foran, J. and Goodwin, J. (1993) ‘Revolutionary pp. 95–123.
outcomes in Iran and Nicaragua: coalition Goldstone, J.A. (1998b) ‘Social movements or
fragmentation, war, and the limits of social revolutions? On the evolution and outcomes
transformation’, Theory and Society, 22 (2): of collective action’, in M. Guigni, D. McAdam
209– 47. and C. Tilly (eds), Democracy and contention.
Foran, J., Klouzal, L., and Rivera, J.-P. (1997) Boulder, CO: Rowman & Littlefield, pp.
‘Who makes revolutions? Class, gender and 125–45.
race in the Mexican, Cuban, and Nicaraguan Goldstone, J.A. (ed.) (1998c) The encyclopedia
Revolutions’, Research in Social Movements, of political revolutions. Washington, DC:
Conflict, and Change, 20 (1): 1–60. Congressional Quarterly.
Friedman, E., Pickowicz, P.G., and Selden, M.J. Goldstone, J.A. (2002a) ‘Population and secu-
(1991) Chinese village, socialist state. New rity: How demographic change can lead to
Haven: Yale University Press. violent conflict’, Journal of International
Furet, F. (1981) Interpreting the French Affairs, 56 (1): 245–63.
Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge Goldstone, J.A. (2002b) ‘States, terrorists, and
University Press. the clash of civilizations’, in C. Calhoun,
Gamson, W.A. (1988) ‘Political discourse P. Price and A. Timmer (eds), September 11:
and collective action’, in B. Klandermas, H. Context and consequences. New York: New
Jriesi and S. Tarrow (eds), International Press, pp. 139–58.
social movement research, Vol 1. From Goldstone, J.A. (2003) ‘Revolution in modern
Structure to Action. Greenwich, CT: JAI dictatorships’, in J.A. Goldstone (eds),
Press, pp. 219–44. Revolutions: Theoretical, comparative, and
Gamson, W.A. and Meyer, D.S. (1996) ‘Framing historical studies. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth,
political opportunity’, in D. McAdam, J.D. pp. 70–77.
McCarthy and M. Zald (eds), Comparative Goldstone, J.A. and Becker, J. (2005) ‘How fast
perspectives on social movements. Cambridge: can you build a state? – State building in
Cambridge University Press, pp. 275–90. revolutions’, in M. Lange and D. Rueschemeyer
Gartner, S.S. and Regan, P.M. (1996) ‘Threat (eds), States and development. New York:
and repression: the non-linear relationship Palgrave-Macmillan, pp. 183–210.
between government and opposition Goldstone, J.A. and Tilly, C. (2001) ‘Threat (and
violence’, Journal of Peace Research, opportunity): popular action and state
33 (3): 273–88. response in the dynamics of contentious
Goldfrank, W.L. (1979) ‘Theories of revolution action’, in R. Aminzade, J.A. Goldstone,
and revolution without theory: The case of D. McAdam, E.J. Perry, W. Sewell Jr., S. Tarrow,

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 24 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 343

and C. Tilly (eds), Silence and voice in con- Harff, B. (1995) ‘Rescuing endangered peoples:
tentious politics. Cambridge: Cambridge missed opportunities’, Sociological Research,
University Press, pp. 179–94. 62 (1): 23–40.
Goldstone, J.A., Gurr, T.R., and Moshiri, F. (eds) Higley, J. and Burton, M. (2006) Elite founda-
(1991) Revolutions of the late twentieth cen- tions of liberal democracy. Lanham, MD:
tury. Boulder, CO: Westview. Rowman & Littlefield.
Goodwin, J. (1994a) ‘Toward a new sociology Hough, J. (1997) Democratization and revolu-
of revolutions’, Theory and Society, 23 (6): tion in the USSR 1985–1991. Washington,
731–66. DC: Brookings Institute.
Goodwin, J. (1994b) ‘Old regimes and revolu- Hufton, O.H. (1992) Women and the limits of
tions in the Second and Third Worlds: A citizenship in the French Revolution. Toronto:
comparative perspective’, Social Science University of Toronto Press.
History, 18 (4): 575–604. Hunt, L. (1992) The family romance of the
Goodwin, J. (1997) ‘State-centered approaches French Revolution. Berkeley: University of
to social revolutions: strengths and limitations California Press.
of a theoretical tradition’, in J. Foran (ed.), Huntington, S.P. (1968) Political order in
Theorizing revolutions. London: Routledge, changing societies. New Haven, CT: Yale
pp. 11–37. University Press.
Goodwin, J. (2001) No other way out: States Jenkins, J.C. and Kposowa, A.J. (1990)
and revolutionary movements 1945–1991. ‘Explaining military coups d’état: Black Africa,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1957–1984’, American Sociological Review,
Goodwin, J. and Skocpol, T. (1989) ‘Explaining 55 (6): 861–75.
revolutions in the contemporary Third World’, Johnson, V. (1993) ‘The structural causes of
Politics and. Society, 17 (4): 489–507. anticolonial revolutions in Africa’, Alternatives,
Gould, R.V. (1995) Insurgent identities: Class, 18 (2): 201–27.
community, and protest in Paris from 1848 to Karklins, R. (1994) ‘Explaining regime change
the commune. Chicago: University of Chicago in the Soviet Union’, Europe–Asia Studies,
Press. 46 (1): 29–45.
Gurr, T.R. (1970) Why men rebel. Princeton, NJ: Karklins, R. and Petersen, R. (1993) ‘Decision
Princeton University Press. calculus of protesters and regimes:
Gurr, T.R. (1988) ‘War, revolution, and the Eastern Europe 1989’, Journal of Politics,
growth of the coercive state’, Comparative 55 (3): 588–614.
Political Studies, 21 (1): 45–65. Katz, M. (1997) Revolutions and revolutionary
Haggard, S. and Kaufman, R.R. (1995) waves. New York: St. Martin’s.
The political economy of democratic transi- Katz, M. (1999) Reflections on revolutions.
tions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University New York: St. Martin’s.
Press. Keddie, N.R. (1995) Iran and the Muslim world:
Hale, H. (2005) ‘Regime cycles: Democracy, Resistance and revolution. New York:
autocracy, and revolution in post-Soviet New York University Press.
Eurasia’, World Politics, 58 (1): 133–65. Kelley, J. and Klein, H.S. (1977) ‘Revolution and
Hall, J.R., Schuyler, P.D., and Trinh, S. (2000) the rebirth of inequality: A theory of stratifi-
Apocalypse observed: Religious movements cation in post-revolutionary society’, American
and violence in North America, Europe, and Journal of Sociology, 83 (1): 78–99.
Japan. New York: Routledge. Khawaja, M. (1993) ‘Repression and popular
Halliday, F. (1999) Revolution and world politics. collective action: Evidence from the West
London: Macmillan. Bank’, Sociological Forum, 8: 47–71.
Hardin, R. (1995) One for all. Princeton, NJ: Kim, Q.-Y. (ed.) (1991) Revolutions in the Third
Princeton University Press. World. Leiden, the Netherlands: Brill.
Harff, B. (1991) ‘Cambodia: revolution, geno- Kimmel, M.S. (1990) Revolution: A sociological
cide, intervention’, in J.A. Goldstone, T.R. interpretation. Cambridge: Polity.
Gurr and F. Moshiri (eds) Revolutions of the Klosko, G. (1987) ‘Rebellious collective action
late twentieth century. Boulder, CO: revisited’, American Political Science Review,
Westview, pp. 218–34. 81 (2): 557–61.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 25 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


344 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Knoke, D. (1988) ‘Incentives in collective action Lohmann, S. (1993) ‘A signaling model of


organizations’, American Sociological Review, information and manipulative political
53 (3): 311–29. action’, American Political Science Review,
Kuran, T. (1989) ‘Sparks and prairie fires: A 86: 319–33.
theory of unanticipated political revolution’, Macculloch, R. (2005) ‘Income inequality and
Public Choice, 61 (1): 41–74. the taste for revolution’, Journal of Law and
Kuran, T. (1991) ‘Now out of never: The element Economics, 48 (1): 93–123.
of surprise in the Eastern European Revolution Macy, M. (1990) ‘Learning theory and the logic
of 1989’, World Politics, 44 (1): 7–48. of the critical mass’, American Sociological
Kurzman, C. (1996) ‘Structural opportunity Review, 55 (6): 809–26.
and perceived opportunity in social- Macy, M. (1991) ‘Chains of cooperation: thresh-
movement theory’, American Sociological old effects in collective action’, American
Review, 61 (1): 153–70. Sociological Review, 56 (6): 730–47.
Lachmann, R. (1997) ‘Agents of revolution: Magagna, V.V. (1991) Communities of grain:
elite conflicts and mass mobilization from Rural rebellion in comparative perspective.
the Medici to Yeltsin’, in J. Foran (ed.), Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Theorizing revolutions. London: Routledge, Markoff, J. (1996) The abolition of feudalism:
pp. 73–101. Peasants, lords, and legislators in the French
Lane, D. and Ross, C. (1999) The transition Revolution. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania
from communism to capitalism. New York: State University Press.
St. Martin’s. Martin, J., Scully, M., and Levitt, B. (1990)
Lapidus, G.W. (1978) Women in Soviet society: ‘Injustice and the legitimation of revolution:
Equality, development, and social change. damning the past, excusing the present,
Berkeley: University of California Press. and neglecting the future’, Journal of
Lawler, E.J. (1992) ‘Affective attachments to Personality and Social Psychology, 59 (2):
nested groups: A choice-process theory’, 281–90.
American Sociological Review, 57 (3): Mason, T.D. and Krane, D.A. (1989) ‘The
327–39. political economy of death squads: Toward a
Levine, D.H. and Manwaring, S. (1989) ‘Religion theory of the impact of state-sanctioned
and popular protest in Latin America: terror’, International Studies Quarterly, 33
Contrasting experiences’, in S. Eckstein (ed.), (2): 175–98.
Power and popular protest: Latin American McAdam, D. (1988) Freedom summer.
Social Movements. Berkeley: University of New York: Oxford University Press.
California Press, pp. 203–34. McAdam, D. (1995) ‘Recruitment to high-risk
Lichbach, M.I. (1987) ‘Deterrence or escalation? activism: The case of freedom summer’,
The puzzle of aggregate studies of repression American Journal of Sociology, 92 (1):
and dissent’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 64–90.
31 (2): 266–97. McAdam, D., Tarrow, S., and Tilly, C. (2001)
Lichbach, M.I. (1989) ‘An evaluation of “Does Dynamics of contention. Cambridge:
economic inequality breed political conflict?” Cambridge University Press.
studies’, World Politics, 41 (4): 431–70. McCarthy, J.D., and Zald, M.N. (1977) ‘Resource
Lichbach, M.I. (1995) The rebel’s dilemma. Ann mobilization and social movements’, American
Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Journal of Sociology, 82 (6): 1112–41.
Liu, M.T. (1988) ‘States and urban revolutions: McClintock, C. (1998) Revolutionary move-
Explaining the revolutionary outcomes in ments in Latin America: El Salvador’s FMLN
Iran and Poland’, Theory and Society, 17 (2): and Peru’s shining path. Washington, DC: US
179–210. Institute of Peace.
Lobao, L. (1990) ‘Women in revolutionary McDaniel, T. (1991) Autocracy, modernization,
movements: changing patterns of Latin and revolution in Russia and Iran. Princeton,
American guerrilla struggles’, in G. West, and NJ: Princeton University Press.
R.L. Blumberg (eds), Women and social McFaul, M. (2005) ‘Transitions from post-
protest. Oxford: Oxford University Press, communism’, Journal of Democracy, 16 (3):
pp. 180–204. 5–19.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 26 3/11/2009 4:19:12 PM


REVOLUTION 345

Melucci, A. (1989) Nomads of the present: Oberschall, A. and Kim, H.-J. (1996) ‘Identity
Social movements and individual needs in and action’, Mobilization, 1 (1): 63–86.
contemporary society. Philadelphia: Temple Oberschall, A. and Seidman, M. (2005) ‘Food
University Press. coercion in revolution and civil war: Who wins
Midlarsky, M.I. (ed.) (1986) Inequality and and how they do it’, Comparative Studies in
contemporary revolutions. Denver, CO: Sociology and History, 47 (2): 372–402.
University Denver Press. Oliver, P. (1984) ‘If you don’t do it, nobody will’,
Midlarsky, M.I. (1999) The evolution of inequality. American Sociological Review, 49 (5): 601–10.
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Olivier, J. (1991) ‘State repression and collective
Migdal, J.S. (1974) Peasant politics and revolu- action in South Africa, 1970–84’, South
tion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. African Journal of Sociology, 22: 109–17.
Moaddel, M. (1993) Class, politics, and ideology Olson, M., Jr. (1965) The logic of collective
in the Iranian revolution. New York: Columbia action: Public goods and the theory of groups.
University Press. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Moghadam, V.M. (1989) ‘Populist revolution Opp, K.-D. (1989) The rationality of political
and the Islamic states in Iran’, in T. Boswell protest. Boulder, CO: Westview.
(ed.), Revolution in the world-system. New Opp, K.-D. (1994) ‘Repression and revolutionary
York: Greenwood, pp. 147–63. action: East Germany in 1989’, Rationality
Moghadam, V.M. (1994) ‘Islamic populism, and Society, 6 (1): 101–38.
class, and gender in post-revolutionary Iran’, Opp, K.-D., Voss, P., and Gern, C. (1995)
in J. Foran (ed.), A Century of Revolution: Origins of a spontaneous revolution: East
Social Movements in Iran. Minneapolis: Germany, 1989. Ann Arbor: University of
University of Minnesota Press, pp. 189–222. Michigan Press.
Moghadam, V.M. (1997) ‘Gender and revolu- Osa, M. (2003) Solidarity and contention:
tions’, in J. Foran (ed.), Theorizing revolu- Networks of Polish opposition. Minneapolis,
tions. London: Routledge, pp. 137–67. MN: University of Minnesota Press.
Moore, B., Jr. (1966) Social origins of dictator- Paige, J.M. (1975) Agrarian revolution. New
ship and democracy. Boston: Beacon. York: Free Press.
Moore, W.H. (1995) ‘Rational rebels: Overcoming Pape, R. (2006) Dying to win: The strategic logic
the free-rider problem’, Political Research of suicide terrorism. New York: Random
Quarterly, 48 (2): 417–54. House.
Moore, W.H. (1998) ‘Repression and dissent: Parker, D. (2000) Revolutions and revolutionary
Substitution, context, and timing’, American tradition in the West 1560–1991. London:
Journal of Political Science, 42 (3): 851–73. Routledge.
Muller, E.N. (1985) ‘Income inequality, regime Parsa, M. (1989) The social origins of the Iranian
repressiveness, and political violence’, revolution. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers
American Sociological Review, 50 (1): 47–61. University Press.
Muller, E.N. and Seligson, M.S. (1987) ‘Inequality Parsa, M. (2000) States, ideologies, and social
and insurgency’, American Political Science revolutions: A comparative analysis of Iran,
Review, 81 (2): 425–51. Nicaragua, and the Philippines. Cambridge:
Nash, J. (1989) ‘Cultural resistance and class Cambridge University Press.
consciousness in Bolivian tin-mining commu- Pastor, R. (2001) ‘Preempting revolutions: the
nities’, in S. Eckstein (ed.), Power and popu- boundaries of U.S. influence’, in M. Katz
lar protest: Latin American Social Movements. (ed.), Revolution: International dimensions.
Berkeley: University of California Press, Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly,
pp. 182–202. pp. 169–97.
Oberschall, A. (1994a) ‘Protest demonstrations Perry, E.J. and Li, X. (1997) Proletarian power:
and the end of communist regimes in 1989’, Shanghai in the cultural revolution. Boulder,
Research in Social Movements, Conflicts and CO: Westview.
Change, 17 (1): 1–24. Pfaff, S. (1996) ‘Collective identity and informal
Oberschall, A. (1994b) ‘Rational choice in groups in revolutionary mobilization: East
collective protests’, Rationality and Society, Germany in 1989’, Social Forces, 75 (1):
6 (1): 79–100. 91–10.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 27 3/11/2009 4:19:13 PM


346 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Popkin, S. (1979) The rational peasant: The Shin, G.-W. (1996) Peasant protest and social
political economy of rural society in Vietnam. change in colonial Korea. Seattle: University
Berkeley: University of California Press. of Washington Press.
Popkin, S. (1988) ‘Political entrepreneurs and Siverson, R.M. and Starr, H. (1994) ‘Regime
peasant movements in Vietnam’, in M. Taylor change and the restructuring of alliances’,
(ed.), Rationality and revolution. Cambridge: American Journal of Political Science,
Cambridge University Press. 38: 145–61.
Randall, M. (1993) Gathering rage: The failure Skocpol, T. (1979) States and social revolu-
of twentieth century revolutions to develop a tions. Cambridge: Cambridge University
feminist agenda. New York: Monthly Review. Press.
Rasler, K. (1996) ‘Concessions, repression, and Skocpol, T. (1982) ‘Rentier state and Shi’a Islam
political protest in the Iranian Revolution’, in the Iranian Revolution’, Theory and Society,
American Sociological Review, 61 (1): 132–52. 11 (3): 265–303.
Rejai, M. and Phillips, K. (1988) ‘Loyalists and Skocpol, T. (1994) Social revolutions in the
revolutionaries’, International Political Science modern world. Cambridge: Cambridge
Review, 9 (2): 107–18. University Press.
Rinehart, J. (1997) Revolution and the Smith, L.M. and Padula, A. (1996) Sex and revo-
millennium: China, Mexico, and Iran. lution: Women in socialist Cuba. New York:
Westport, CT: Praeger. Oxford University Press.
Rule, J. (1988) Theories of civil violence. Snow, D.A. and Benford, R.D. (1988) ‘Ideology,
Berkeley: University of California Press. frame resonance, and participant mobiliza-
Rule, J. (1989) ‘Rationality and non-rationality in tion’, International Social Movement
militant collective action’, Sociological Theory, Research, 1: 197–217.
7 (2): 145–60. Snow, D.A., Rochford, E.B., Jr., Worden, S.K.,
Sadri, H.A. (1997) Revolutionary states, leaders, and Benford, R.D. (1986) ‘Frame alignment
and foreign relations: A comparative study of processes, micromobilization, and movement
China, Cuba, and Iran. Westport, CT: participation’, American Sociological Review,
Praeger. 51 (4): 464–81.
Sageman, M. (2004) Understanding terror net- Snyder, R. (1998) ‘Paths out of sultanistic
works. Philadelphia, PA: University of regimes: combining structural and voluntarist
Pennsylvania Press. perspectives’, in H.E. Chehabi and J.J.
Sageman, M. (2007) Leaderless Jihad: Terror Linz (eds), Sultanistic Regimes. Baltimore,
networks in the twenty–first century. MD: Johns Hopkins University Press,
Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania pp. 49–81.
Press. Snyder, R.S. (1999) ‘The U.S. and third world
Scott, J.C. (1976) The moral economy of the revolutionary states: understanding the
peasant: Rebellion and subsistence in South breakdown in relations’, International Studies
East Asia. New Haven, CT: Yale University Quarterly, 43 (2): 265–90.
Press. Sohrabi, J. (1995) ‘Historicizing revolutions: con-
Scott, J.C. (1985) Weapons of the weak: stitutional revolutions in the Ottoman Empire,
Everyday forms of peasant resistance. New Iran, and Russia 1905–1908’, American
Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Journal of Sociology, 100 (6): 1383–447.
Selbin, E. (1993) Modern Latin American revolu- Somers, M. and Gibson, G. (1994) ‘Reclaiming
tions. Boulder, CO: Westview. the epistemological “other”: Narrative and
Selbin, E. (1997) ‘Revolution in the real world: the social constitution of identity’, in C.
Bringing agency back in’, in J. Foran (ed.), Calhoun (ed.), Social theory and the politics
Theorizing revolutions. London: Routledge, of identity. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 37–99.
pp. 123–36. Speck, W.A. (1990) Reluctant revolutionaries:
Selden, M. (1995) China in revolution: The Englishmen and the revolution of 1688. New
Yenan way revisited. Armonk, NY: Sharpe. York: Oxford University Press.
Sewell, W., Jr. (1985) ‘Ideologies and social Stacey, J. (1983) Patriarchy and socialist revolu-
revolutions: Reflections on the French case’. tion in China. Berkeley: University of
Journal of Modern History, 57 (1): 57–85. California Press.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 28 3/11/2009 4:19:13 PM


REVOLUTION 347

Stark, D.C. and Bruszt, L. (1998) Postsocialist Wasserstrom, J.N. (1994) ‘Gender and revolu-
pathways: Transforming politics and property tion in Europe and Asia’, Journal of Women’s
in East Central Europe. New York: Cambridge History, 6 (1): 109–20.
University Press. Wasserstrom J.N. and Perry, E.J. (Eds.)
Stinchcombe, A.L. (1999) ‘Ending revolutions (1994) Popular protest and political culture
and building new governments’, Annual in modern China (2nd ed.) Boulder, CO:
Review of Political Science, 2 (1): 49–73. Westview.
Stokes, G. (1993) The walls came tumbling Weede, E. (1987) ‘Some new evidence on cor-
down: The collapse of communism in Eastern relates of political violence: Income inequal-
Europe. New York: Oxford University Press. ity, regime repressiveness, and economic
Tarrow, S. (1998) Power in movement: Social development’, European Sociology Review,
movements and contentious politics (2nd ed.) 3 (2): 97–108.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Weede, E. and Muller, E.N. (1997) ‘Consequences
Taylor M. (ed.) (1988) Rationality and revolution. of revolutions’, Rationality and Society,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 9 (3): 327–50.
Taylor, V. (1999) ‘Gender and social move- Weitman, S. (1992) ‘Thinking the revolutions
ments’, Gender and Society, 13 (1): 8–33. of 1989’, British Journal of Sociology,
Teitzel, M. and Weber, M. (1994) ‘The eco- 43 (1): 13–24.
nomics of the Iron Curtain and the Berlin White, R. (1989) ‘From peaceful protest to guer-
Wall’, Rationality and Society, 6: 58–78. rilla war: micromobilization of the Provisional
Tétreault, M.A. (ed.) (1994) Women and Irish Republican Army’, American Journal of
revolution in Africa, Asia, and the new Sociology, 94 (6): 1277–302.
world. Columbia: University of South Carolina Wickham-Crowley, T. (1991) Exploring revolu-
Press. tion: Essays on Latin American insurgency
Tilly, C. (1978) From mobilization to revolution. and revolutionary theory. Armonk, NY:
Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Sharpe.
Tilly, C. (1993) European revolutions 1492– Wickham-Crowley, T. (1992) Guerrillas and
1992. Oxford: Blackwell. revolution in Latin America. Princeton, NJ:
Tilly, C. (1995) ‘To explain political processes’, Princeton University Press.
American Journal of Sociology, 100 (6): Wolf, E.R. (1969) Peasant wars of the twentieth
1594–610. century. New York: Harper & Row.
Trimberger, E.K. (1978) Revolution from Wood, E. (2000) Forging democracy from below.
above: Military bureaucrats and develop- Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
ment in Japan, Turkey, Egypt, and Peru. Zamosc, L. (1989) ‘Peasant struggles of the
New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books. 1970s in Columbia’, in S. Eckstein (ed.),
Tullock, G. (1971) ‘The paradox of revolution’, Power and popular protest: Latin American
Public Choice, 11 (1): 89–99. Social Movements. Berkeley: University of
Van Vugt, J.P. (1991) Democratic organization California Press, pp. 102–31.
for social change: Latin American Christian Zartman, W.I. (1995) Collapsed states: The dis-
base communities and literary campaigns. integration and restoration of legitimate
New York: Bergin and Garvey. authority. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Walder, A.G. (1989) ‘The political sociology of Zhao, D. (2001) The power of Tiananmen:
the Beijing Upheaval of 1989’, Problems of State-society relations and the 1989 Beijing
Communism, 38 (5): 41–48. student movement. Chicago: University of
Walt, S.M. (1996) Revolution and war. Ithaca, Chicago Press.
NY: Cornell University Press. Zimmermann, E. (1990) ‘On the outcomes of
Walton, J. (1984) Reluctant rebels. New York: revolutions: Some preliminary considerations’,
Columbia University Press. Sociological Theory, 8 (1): 33–47.

9781412919760_Chap17.indd 29 3/11/2009 4:19:13 PM


18
Social Movements
Vincent Boudreau and David S. Meyer

INTRODUCTION parts of the world. Particularly, studies of


movements that press for political reform in
Comparative politics has often been a little the global North generally bear little resem-
unsure about what exactly needed to be com- blance to studies of social movements that
pared when it comes to social movements. In seek to hold state power in the global South.
some studies, the operational definition of a Within the thus far distinct literatures on
social movement shifts to fit the empirical case protest movements, scholars have made sub-
or cases at hand, while in others, the term does stantial progress in identifying the proximate
not appear at all, replaced by non-governmental causes and consequences of social move-
organizations, democratization campaigns, ments. Broader comparisons have been slower
labor movements, agrarian mobilization, and to emerge, presenting a continuing challenge
revolutions – among other terms. As with other for synthetically minded scholars of compara-
subjects, comparative politics has produced a tive politics. It is quite likely that such broader
large number of single country case studies, synthesis will reveal relationships within
informed by explicitly comparative theoretical social movement theory similar to those
concerns, which often address larger theoretical between Einsteinian and Newtonian physics.
questions. And, as with other subjects, the field While the latter is perfectly adequate for
has produced a number of explicitly compara- making predictions within certain circum-
tive studies that sacrifice some amount of detail stances, the former offers a deeper and more
for theoretical parsimony. Also, again as in comprehensive understanding that contextual-
other areas of comparative politics, there has izes and unifies apparent anomalies. Einstein’s
been broad recognition that the international broader compass revealed Newton’s physics
context offers constraints and opportunities as particular cases of more universal laws, and
for both authorities and their challengers, set the key variables for a more unified science
such that we need not see states as autonomous as residing in contextual factors like gravity
ecological units. and speed. Not only does Einstein tell us that
The raft of research on a range of (poten- things work differently outside the Newtonian
tially) related phenomena is greater than the world, he also suggests that earlier under-
theoretical sum of its parts – a result of dis- standings of familiar conditions were incom-
crepancies in subject matter and the theoreti- plete. In a similar vein, we argue that the way
cal barriers between those who study different forward for the comparative study of social

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:19:53 PM


SOCIAL MOVEMENTS 349

movements lies in the development of a allows considerable flexibility in the range of


broader and more synthetic analysis. Recently political formations and sequences of events
some scholars have suggested a broader theo- that might be included in an analysis. Despite
retical framework, sometimes termed ‘conten- this flexibility – or perhaps because of it –
tious politics,’ (McAdam et al., 2001; Tarrow scholars with a range of relevant concerns
and Tilly, 2006) which promises to provide have often ignored the broader connections
greater synthesis and conceptual unity. that were possible in their findings.
Here, we review some of the major contri- Most generally, political scientists have
butions from comparative politics to the struggled to consider whether protest politics
study of social movements, noting signifi- and social movements were an extension of
cantly different areas of inquiry in the North more conventional political participation or a
and in the South. We focus on the range of rejection of more conventional politics. Classic
independent variables that scholars use to comparative literature of the 1960s (e.g.,
explain the origins, emergence, development, Huntington, 1968; Lipset, 1960) saw the
organization, and ultimate impact of social emergence of protest politics as a failing of
movements. By situating our review in a sys- established political institutions to integrate
tematic retracing of major differences in the and process grievances and constituencies.
organization of political authority, we mean Indeed, scholars contended that the forms,
to suggest grounds for a larger, contextual, claims, and ultimate influence of social move-
understanding of how social movements ments emerged as an almost direct reflection
relate to other political phenomena, enabling of state structures and governing coalitions.
the development of broader comparisons The premise underlying this work was that the
across different political contexts. We begin social movement was a temporary, transitional
by offering a brief history of the field of phenomenon, which would fade when estab-
social movements within comparative lished institutions responded to it.
politics, then turn to review major issues in In the wake of the social movements of the
studies of unrest in the North, then in the 1960s, political scientists emphasized the
South. We consider the influence of interna- policy payoff of protest. For Lipsky (1968)
tional context on social movement develop- and then for Piven and Cloward (1977), pro-
ment, and conclude with suggestions for test was the best strategy for affecting influ-
further research. ence for poor people and minorities, unlikely
to be able to make political gains in other
ways. Although protestors need not come to
their strategic decisions through rational cal-
PROTEST POLITICS AND culations, their choice of strategy nonetheless
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS was, strictly speaking, rational. This approach
dovetailed with an emerging rational choice
The term, ‘social movements’ is inclusive, perspective within political science that
perhaps overly so, referring to a wide range of focused on the problem of collective action
political phenomena. Indeed, scholars fre- and group size (e.g., Olson, 1967), and which
quently offer a specific definition that applies was applied to some of the emerging social
to the case at hand, and talk past other work on movements of the time (e.g., McCarthy and
the topic. For our purposes, we appreciate Zald, 1977).
Tarrow’s (1998: 4) handy definition of social The resource mobilization tradition was
movements as ‘collective challenges by people later challenged by ‘new social movement’
with common purposes and solidarity in sus- scholars who noted that the causes around
tained interaction with elites, opponents, and which contemporary movements organized,
authorities.’ This definition locates social particularly peace, the environment, gay and
movements firmly as political phenomena, but lesbian rights, and feminism, were poorly

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:19:53 PM


350 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

explained by a narrow rational choice account both political structures and activist tactics.
(e.g., Melucci, 1989; Offe, 1985). These Later, he would catalog all ‘revolutionary
scholars emphasized the context of relative situations’ in Europe over a 500 year period,
affluence in West Europe and the US, and the noting that only a tiny fraction resulted in
relatively advantaged status of those engaged regime change (Tilly, 1993b). Tilly (1993a)
in protest, and questioned whether tactics of would also trace the development of a ‘reper-
mobilization reflected only instrumental con- toire of contention’ through which actors
cerns. They suggested, instead, that new social made claims and authorities responded;
movement politics contained expressive ele- he contended that this repertoire provided
ments whose justification was not based on an empirical and theoretical link between
likely efficacy (e.g., Cohen, 1985). Ultimately, revolutions and social movements.
they came to argue that social movements Tilly’s efforts to provide an overarching
were an alternative and additional mode of framework for understanding what he would
democratization, characteristic of the advanced call ‘contentious politics,’ that is, the links
industrialized world and ‘post-industrial soci- between a spectrum of political claims
ety.’ Buechler (1999) has persuasively argued making that ranges from activity centered
that the so-called new movements did not mostly within conventional political institu-
represent as dramatic break with the past tions toward violent revolutionary move-
as earlier scholars had argued, but did reflect ments, has developed in specificity through
the significant issues and opportunities of the collaborative efforts (McAdam et al., 2001;
contemporary period. Tarrow and Tilly, 2006); it includes a new
Starting at about the same time as the emphasis on identifying a large number of
resource mobilization perspective emerged, mechanisms surrounding the interaction
other scholars examined the development between claim makers and authorities, but
and outcome of social and political rebellions the initial theoretical separation between
and revolutions. Research focused on the scholarship on revolutions and on reform-
circumstances under which revolutions took oriented social movements has largely con-
place, and the factors affecting the eventual tinued. This separation, we argue, is supported
outcomes of those revolutions. Barrington by the geographic separation of the locations
Moore’s (1968) classic treatment of histori- of different movements, and the attendant
cal revolutions traced the outcomes of those questions that follow from different forms of
revolutions to the composition of the coali- contentious politics.
tions seeking to replace authorities. Gurr Thus, those who studied revolutions con-
(1969) argued that revolutionary campaigns centrated on the challenges confronting state
emerged when the economy’s capacity to efforts to build, consolidate, or merely retain
deliver benefits was outstripped by growing power (Goldstone, 2003; Huntington, 1968;
expectations. Skocpol (1979) attributed the Skocpol, 1979). Those who examined transi-
success or failure of a revolutionary move- tions to democracy looked at the realignment
ment in seeking power to the weight of exog- of political elites, and the rise of moderate
enous challenges on the state. coalitions that displaced hardliners (Karl,
For the most part, despite potential con- 1990; Linz and Stepan, 1996; O’Donnell et
nections which seem obvious in retrospect, al., 1986). Those who studied reform-ori-
these literatures developed in isolation from ented social movements paid particular atten-
each other. Charles Tilly (e.g., 1978), how- tion to changes that encouraged individuals
ever, contended that the same processes were to move from routine to non-routine forms of
at work in both smaller scale social move- participation – focusing on the question of
ments and large scale social revolutions, mobilization over other considerations
with differential outcomes as contingent (McCarthy and Zald, 1977; Tarrow, 1989).
upon a large number of factors, including Comparativists compared the differential

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


SOCIAL MOVEMENTS 351

outcomes of similar movements, again, with extremely open political structures


focusing on the connections between move- preempted riots by inviting conventional
ments and more conventional politics. In political participation, and others without
these pursuits, comparative analysts employed room for political input, repressed unrest and
a broad range of research methods, ranging robbed dissatisfied people of the organiza-
from large sample comparisons of individu- tional space and political hope necessary to
als or nations to detailed single case studies stage unrest. Tilly (1978) expanded this con-
of particular movements in particular set- cept of a ‘political opportunity structure’ to a
tings. We believe that there is the potential larger field, arguing that the same patterns
for a richer theoretical framework to connect could be found in mobilization at the national
ostensibly distinct phenomena and litera- level. This political opportunity approach has
tures. We will review the distinctions, and been developed in a variety of different ways
then point to potential connections. (see Meyer, 2004 for review), including
single country case studies (e.g., Costain,
1992; McAdam, 1982; Meyer, 1990;
Schurman, 2004; Tarrow, 1989) and cross-
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS IN ADVANCED national comparisons (e.g., Kitschelt, 1986;
INDUSTRIALIZED COUNTRIES Kriesi et al., 1995).
Particularly important and frutiful is Tarrow’s
Many authors who would offer general (1989) study of unrest in Italy over a conten-
statements on protest and social movements tious decade, 1965–1975. Offering a more
studied political unrest in the United States dynamic analysis of Italian politics inside and
and Europe, mostly Western Europe. Scholars outside institutions, Tarrow focused on changes
of the wealthy world studied, mostly, cam- in political opportunities to explain a very
paigns for such things as civil rights, wom- broad range of protest politics over the decade.
en’s rights, the environment, and peace – very Offering the concept of a ‘cycle of protest,’
much like contemporary social movements which includes decline, and by considering
in the United States and Europe. They bor- institutional politics, including elections and
rowed literature from political sociology and policy initiatives, as both responses and sources
opinion research conducted in both political for protest, Tarrow placed social movements
science and sociology. Cross-sectional com- firmly within a political context.
parisons, often of similar movements in dif- In the Italian case, Tarrow contends that
ferent countries, emphasized the origins, government openings and efforts at democra-
forms, and outcomes of movements in rela- tization in the 1960s reduced the costs and
tion to their political context, which analysts increased the promise of political mobiliza-
treated as a constant. In contrast, longitudinal tion. The initial mobiliation of one constitu-
studies of particular movements – or sets of ency encouraged others to emulate potentially
movements – generally limited the context to successful actions, leading to a cascade of
one country and focused on the iterative protest. Workers, students, religious reform-
development of social movements, institu- ers, and leftist factions within parties all took
tional politics, and public policy, in response to the streets. As newly mobilized groups
to one another. sought to gain political attention in a sud-
Much of this work focuses on political denly crowded field, they sometimes experi-
context. Looking at the 1960s riots in mented with violent action. The government
American cities, Peter Eisinger (1973) was responded to violence with harsh repression,
concerned with why some cities experienced raising the costs of collective action, and
violent unrest while others did not. He found diminishing protest. At the same time,
that the nature of the political system in each some of the social movement actors turned
city explained the occurrence of riots: cities their attention to more conventional political

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


352 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

activity, reducing their claims and moderat- out generalizations that would apply to other
ing their tactics, effectively institutionalizing movements in other contexts.
dissent (Meyer and Tarrow, 1998). Beyond In contrast, scholars embarking on explicit
the empirical case, Tarrow’s work was par- comparisons across states simplify the range
ticularly important because it made method- of political opportunities to make translation
ological and theoretical advances. across contexts possible, following Eisinger’s
Methodologically, Tarrow (1989) devel- (1973) model study. As a key example, Herbert
oped ‘events data’ analysis, imported from Kitschelt’s (1986) study of antinuclear move-
sociology (see McAdam, 1982), as a means of ments in four democracies, France, Sweden,
deriving information about the peaks and the United States, and West Germany, used
troughs of social movements, as well as their political opportunity theory to explain the
claims from coded newspaper accounts. style and development of social movement
European political scientists would extend this politics, as well as their ultimate influence.
analysis further through largescale collabora- Although he explicitly recognizes broad con-
tive efforts to compile large data sets on com- ceptions of opportunities, including resources,
parative collective action (see especially Rucht institutions, and historical precedents, for the
et al., 1999). Events data analysis would purposes of the analysis Kitschelt provides a
develop to compare political tactics over time much narrower specification. He sorts the four
and across contexts (e.g., Kriesi et al., 1995; states along two dimensions: input structures
Rucht, 1990), the claims of various social (open or closed) and output capacity (strong
movement actors made (e.g., Koopmans and or weak), and argues that this simple classifi-
Statham, 1999a, 1999b), and social move- cation explains the strategies challengers
ments policy outcomes (e.g., Giugni, 2004). employed in all four states, as well as their
Both here (Tarrow, 1989) and in his ultimate influence. The available options for
expressly theoretical work (Tarrow, 1998), participation comprise a menu for collective
Tarrow stresses the connections between action from which activists choose. In
mainstream politics and protest movements. Kitschelt’s terms, activists choose confronta-
He argues that movements are best understood tional strategies in response to institutional
when studied in the context of a wide range of blockages – as the best available approach for
other political phenomena, which may some- expression; in contrast, activists employ
times spill over into movement actions. The assimilative strategies when opennings appear.
structure of available political opportunities He contends that state capacity determines
can provide incentives for particular kinds of influence – greater procedural innovation or
mobilization strategies as well as cues the substantive change in response to pressures in
savvy activist can read in making decisions weaker states. This sparse model offers
about claims, tactics, and potential allies. an advantage of clarity, but at the cost of
Activists, authorities, opponents – sometimes simplifying and flattening a broad range of
in movement forms themselves (Meyer and factors critical to the development of a social
Staggenborg, 1996), and allies all operate in movement over time.
response to each other and their own percep- On occasion, teams of scholars have worked
tions of their interests, changing the field of to combine the virtues of cross-sectional com-
opportunities for all concerned. In this way, parison with over-time observation. Kriesi and
activists, by provoking response from authori- his colleagues (Kriesi et al., 1995) combine
ties, can generate subsequent opportunities for the complexity and nuance of the longitudinal
themselves and for other activists. The focus studies with the analytical leverage of cross-
on the interaction of social movement opposi- sectional studies, comparing ‘new social
tion and political opportunties provides a movements’ [the ‘family’ of left-libertarian
useful focus for analysts, but in the midst of a movements in advanced industrialized states
wide range of contingencies, it is hard to tease (see della Porta and Rucht, 1995)] across four

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


SOCIAL MOVEMENTS 353

European states (France, Germany, the view their efforts as potentially successful or
Netherlands and Switzerland) over time. They particularly necessary to avoid a bad outcome
see opportunity structures as including the (also see Meyer, 2007).
nature of political cleavages, institutional Donatella della Porta and Herbert Reiter
structures, alliance structures (for these move- (1998) focus on the development of the actual
ments, the openness and political position of conduct of protest by focusing on police
left parties), and prevailing strategies of social behavior in Western democracies. In effect,
movements. By focusing on the effects of two police and courts present an extremely proxi-
factors, the configuration of power on the left mate element in the structure of political
and its presence or absence in government, opportunities that would-be activists face.
they offer a fuller picture of citizen mobiliza- Demonstrators and authorities (in this case,
tion as it responds to political opportunity. police) seek to minimize the costs and disrup-
Thinking of movement participation tion of protest by adhering to familiar routines.
as including less disruptive and confronta- Della Porta and Reiter contend that the national
tional tactics such as petitions and peaceful styles of policing reflect larger patterns of
demonstrations, Kriesi et al. (1995) examine authority and policy making in the polity.
the full range of activist mobilization. Their Importantly, they contend that opportunities
analysis focuses on the role of the state in for protesters are not simply ‘open’ or ‘closed,’
facilitating some kinds of access, and also in but instead are specific to particular groups
setting the agenda for challengers through and constituencies and their relationship to the
the policies it adopts – sometimes raising the political mainstream (see Meyer and Minkoff,
threat of inaction. 2004). This emergent and increasingly
State action affects the volume, form, common style over the past few decades, how-
and location of protest. Surprisingly, they find ever, is one in which protest is facilitated to
the highest per capita level of activism in minimize disruption and uncertainty for all
Switzerland, but it is predominantly expressed concerned; this is likely to limit political influ-
through conventional political participation and ence as well (see McCarthy and McPhail,
membership in social movement organizations. 1998; Piven and Cloward, 1977).
In contrast, France demonstrates lower levels of Giugni (2004) focuses on the influence of
participation, but events are frequently dramatic the total impact of the range of movement
and disruptive. Kriesi et al.’s (1995) explana- activity on public policy. Considering the
tion is far more nuanced and comprehensive intervening effects of public opinion and
than Kitschelt’s (1986), but also harder to trans- political structures, he assesses the compara-
late easily to other cases. tive impact of the environmental, peace, and
Drawing from insights in a number of antinuclear movements in three different
single case studies, however, we can discern countries. He finds that movements matter,
general patterns in the development of social but only when deployed in conjunction with
movements in advanced industrialized coun- a favorable political climate, including sup-
tries. Koopmans’ (1995) analysis of ‘new’ portive public opinion and available political
social movements in West Germany, for exam- allies. Following a similar track, other schol-
ple, traces the development of movement ars have traced an interactive relationship
politics to particular elements of the German between social movements and public policy
political system. Focusing on the interplay of (e.g., Banaszak, 1996; Meyer et al., 2005)
social movements and the political system, he and assessed the impact of public policy on
identifies discrete policy opportunities, which social movements (e.g., Mettler, 2005). It is
he describes ‘concrete opportunities’ which clear that social movements can help affect
have direct motivational consequences for public policies, building state action, which
movements. In other words, activists are most in turn, creates the conditions for subsequent
likely to mobilize when they have reason to social movements.

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


354 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

More generally, scholars have observed a through personalistic and discretionary alloca-
modal pattern of political mobilization in tions of resources, in conjunction with more
advanced industrialized states, in which pro- or less selective repression (Bratton and Van
test as a viable political tactic diffuses broadly de Walle, 1997). Here, representative struc-
throughout the populace, such that it is used tures or shifting access to government proba-
by a broader range of constituencies (see bly influence mobilization patterns less than
Dalton, 2005). As this diffusion takes place, patterns of political alliance, repression, or
however, citizens increasingly employ less exclusion. Social movements may seek (and
disruptive forms of protest, and states adapt to sometimes win) substantial institutional
facilitate this kind of participation. Protest is restructuring rather than more limited reforms.
no longer a tool employed by those unlikely to To make sense of movements in the global
affect influence in other ways, but has become South, we will pay particular attention to these
a strategic component of a broad range of distinct, but interrelated topics: revolution,
political actors and causes. The ultimate repression, and democratization.
impact of this kind of ‘institutionalization
of dissent’ remains an open question for schol-
ars (Meyer and Tarrow, 1998). In the
Revolution
global South, we will see that the nature of
existing governmental institutions dramati- The extraordinary occasion of a social revolu-
cally affects the nature of protest and the tion has spurred a great deal of research, and
nature of comparative analysis. scholars differ on whether such occurrences
reflect a relatively infrequent and distinct phe-
nomenon (e.g., Skocpol, 1979) or a relatively
infrequent outcome of a rather common set of
REVOLUTION, REPRESSION, processes (Tilly, 1993b). The latter course of
AND DEMOCRATIZATION analysis underscores the relationship of revo-
IN THE GLOBAL SOUTH lutionary outcomes to the development of
politically oriented movements.
The empirical material scholars address Jack Goldstone (2003) argues that the
understandably affects the theoretical litera- emergence and location of successful revolu-
tures with which they engage. In the global tionary movements can best be explained by
south, both activists and authorities are less considering the stability and nature of state
certain that existing political institutions will structures and their relationship to challeng-
survive a movement challenge intact. The ers. Structural theories show that revolutions
stakes generally appear higher for all ‘begin from some combination of state weak-
involved, challengers can rely far less on the ness, conflicts between states and elites, and
protection of national laws and authorities’ popular uprisings’ (Goldstone, 2003: 6).
tolerance, and outside actors can exert more Revolutionary movements are critical, but
influence. As a result, the nature of claims, they do not make history in the circumstances
organizations, and tactics differ accordingly. they choose; a state with weakened capacity
When we turn our analysis to include stud- to buy off or repress insurgents will be more
ies of contention under weak states, we see vulnerable to revolution.
shifts in the nature of the political contest. In The opposition is still viewed as a key com-
such settings, normal politics may include ponent of revolution, but it is recognized that a
systems of repression or patronage that keep state with weakened structural capabilities and
claim makers at arms length, distant from any a predilection for conflict between the state and
meaningful access to political institutions; the elites will be vulnerable to revolution.
further, authorities may lean very heavily on a When the grievances of peasants or urban
narrow band of supporters, addressing claims dwellers meet with ‘conducive structural

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


SOCIAL MOVEMENTS 355

conditions,’ such as landlord vulnerability or bureaucracy (Eckstein, 1990). In this regard, as


weakly policed cities, there is the possibility Suh (2001) has argued in relation to Korean
of effective revolutionary action (Goldstone, labor movements, activists’ policy demands
2003: 10–11). Further, when conflict between can best be seen as targeted at mobilizing
the state and powerful elites coincides and con- broad constituencies, rather than provoking
nects with the structural conditions and popular actual reforms.
uprisings, revolution becomes possible. Those shut out of meaningful politics are
Building on Huntington (1968), Goldstone likely to think less about petitioning govern-
adopts a focus on political institutions and ment, and more about replacing it, in order to
particularly their decay, in the makings of a produce a system to which they have more
revolution. He writes: access, or carving out autonomous spaces for
local community self governance (Ramos,
A marked imbalance between the demands of
a changing population on the economy and 2002): both tendencies move the politics of
the government, and the ability of the govern- protest away from policy issues and more
ment to respond creates a situation of declining toward issues of governance and (potentially)
political stability. Whenever such imbalances state control (Davis, 1994). Absent state crisis,
become widespread, so too does the risk of revo-
activists can still make claims to bureaucratic
lutions (Goldstone, 2003: 18).
line agencies, or denounce government devel-
In short, social movements emerge to present opment projects, repression, or corruption
claims to a state; when that state is incapable of (Loveman, 1998; Navarro, 1989; O’Brien and
responding effectively to either the claims or Li, 2006).
the activities of its challengers, a social move- Paradoxically, the loss of local control,
ment may become revolutionary. Essentially, primarily to waves of neoliberal economic
when an insurgent movement lines up with a reform, reinforces and politicizes ethnic
‘revolutionary situation’ (Tilly, 1993b), that is, identities, making different sorts of mobiliza-
a large opportunity, social revolutions are pos- tion possible (Yashar, 2005). Episodic mobi-
sible. As Skocpol (1979) pointed out, the inter- lizations (Almeida, 2007) can produce
national system and the challenges it offers are modest reforms or somewhat improved posi-
critical influences on state vulnerability. The tioning of challengers, but often the most
organization and claims of challengers, respond- significant effect is the development of a his-
ing to the strengths, weaknesses and openings tory of contention, and the enhanced will to
in the state, shape the development of social challenge government in the future (Almeida,
movements. 2007). When central authority falters, protest
Weak or patrimonial states often cannot can escalate precipitously to regime chang-
address social concerns via formal public policy ing programs (Boudreau, 2004; Kim, 1996).
processes, relying instead on a mix of repres- Most theorists acknowledge that authori-
sion and selective patronage (e.g., Eckstein, tarian regimes do not fall apart simply
1989). Even where ideas about democratic because they encounter mass opposition, but
policy making (often popularized following rather that protest and resistance encourages
transitions from authoritarian rule) convince or accelerates nascent splits in the regime,
authorities to adopt policies that promise public and encourages processes of dissonance and
services or protections, administrative capacity decay that might have already been under-
may not be up to the task, creating a disconnect way (Bermeo, 1999; Wood, 2000). Movement
between written policy and government action. outcomes reflect the interaction between
Eckstein’s analysis of popular protest in Mexico, structural features favoring (respectively)
for instance, demonstrates how government policy or regime change, and pressure from a
action may require private petitions, off-stage political movement. Still, how authorities
from public political processes that depend respond to protest will also have a great deal
on the discretion of a less than ideal-type to do with the choices that activists make.

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


356 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Repression repression against a more limited student


movement. Misagh Parsa (2000) concentrates
Although explicitly theoretical work (e.g., on middle class entrepreneurs during regime
Coleman, 1990), has specifically linked transitions in Iran and the Philippines, noting
repression of protest in authoritarian settings that the exclusionary nature of the two states
to the same sorts of factors that expand pushed middle class entrepreneurs in each set-
movement opportunities in democratic set- ting to adopt regime displacing politics that
tings, only recently have scholars offered gathered steam when authorities suddenly
empirical illustrations of these links, offering grew weaker. Elizabeth Wood’s (2000) account
a more variegated analysis of repression that of anti-regime insurgencies in South Africa
links to challengers’ mobilization strategies and El Salvador locates the resistance in mili-
(e.g., Boudreau, 2004; Ray, 1999). tary formations designed to fight, rather than
In such settings, key political opportuni- appeal to, the state. Boudreau’s (2004) analy-
ties, primarily located in the strength of a sis of protest in Southeast Asia describes how
regime rather than in the nature of routine different forms of state repression shaped
political processes, can activate networks of movements, both by eliminating some politi-
challengers differentially, and result in mobi- cal forms, and forcing activists to seek out
lizing better-positioned cosmopolitan actors each regime’s weak flank. In these treatments,
first (DeNardo, 1985; Oliver et al., 1985). movement forms are shaped by the need to
The critical issues that determine the extent of confront state authorities, and to survive that
a challenge and the key mechanisms for mobi- confrontation – rather than to directly influ-
lization may exist in new connections between ence state policy or to take advantage of
sociologically different populations – as, for access to the state.
instance, between residents of towns and rural Just as activists may turn to broader claims
villages. Other substantial opportunities may and more aggressive strategies, states under
be found in processes that undermine authori- pressure are also likely to turn to harsher
ties’ coercive capacities (Wood, 2000) – such responses, producing a cycle of escalation that
as exogenous economic or political pres- may end in revolution (Goldstone, 2003;
sures. Such pressures can weaken regime Mason, 1998). While we might expect more
alliances or strengthen opposition coalitions general social support for radicalization in
against the state or regime, rather than in poorer settings, an increasing number of ana-
those that provide easier access to policy lysts are advising that social movement trajec-
making or regime officials. The mechanisms tories treat the opportunity for more modest
associated with political mobilization are political institutionalization as movement-spe-
likely to differ across subgroups within a cific; some issues have greater potential to
polity, such as residents of cities versus those evolve into more moderate policy based strug-
in rural areas. gles (Kowalchuk, 2005). For example, Trevizo
In settings where government is less able or (2006) describes the crucial difference between
inclined to redress broad popular grievances, Mexican student protests that ended in mass
mainstream politics becomes less representa- murder and those that produced policy reform
tive, often less institutionalized and more as a function of whether activists framed their
brutal. Social movements may regularly fail to protest in terms of revolution or policy reform,
secure policy reform and wider representation but his analysis also emphasizes the willing-
(Brockett, 1991), but that failure may contrib- ness of the Mexican state at the time to use
ute to the emergence of broader and more violence.
fundamental challenges to state power Over time, both authorities and movements
(Almeida, 2007). Kim (1996), for instance, can alter the conditions of protest. State repres-
explains the mobilization of a regime- sion may eliminate some movement forms, or
displacing uprising in Korea in terms of state impose new and serious threats to proscribed

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


SOCIAL MOVEMENTS 357

modes of activity (Boudreau, 2004), while violence did not derail the transition to
accepted groups and claims can work to navi- democracy. Indeed, the mobilization of vio-
gate new relationships with authorities. Further, lence may have promoted these transitions.
repression that produces strong social dissent Bermeo contends that the threat of vio-
may also encourage learning and strategic lence can also encourage authorities to pursue
adjustment among security forces, and efforts reforms, depending upon their perception of
to make the expression of dissent less danger- the difficulties and costs of repression and
ous, and ultimately, more routine (della Porta their likely fates in a new setting. Given the
and Rieter, 1998). Still, whether claim making presence of challengers threatening violent
produces greater openness or closure depends disruption, authorities calculate both the dif-
on the character of interactions between author- ficulties of repression and the likely fortunes
ities and challengers. Harsher repression and of their challengers under a new regime. If
democratization represent different futures. key elites predict that their opponents will
not win in a new democratic setting, they are
likely to allow democratic transitions to
progress; they may even welcome demo-
Democratization
cratic elections to legitimate their claims to
Interestingly, most of the literature that deals state power.
with social movements and state repression Elisabeth Jean Wood (2000) also formulates
focuses on the (potential) outcome of democra- a democratization argument based on elite per-
tization, attending less to an analysis of process ception of mass mobilization. She examines El
and more to an evaluation of outcome. Further, Salvador and South Africa as examples of suc-
the democratization literature tends to focus on cessful democracy movements forged from
top-down, elite initiated transitions and authors below by the insurgency of poor people. These
often issue warnings about too much citizen insurgencies, she argues, reshaped economic
mobilization during a transition from authori- interests and opportunities and forced eco-
tarian rule. Democratic transitions are particu- nomic, and then political, elites to share power
larly vulnerable to the threats posed by violent and/or wealth. Focusing on the economic
action. Most analysts see moderation, or the impact of protest, Wood shows how civil war
rejection of radical mass mobilization, as the transformed the political economy of El
preferable choice during the untenable transi- Salvador, directly reshaping elite interests.
tion process; these authors promote temperate Sustained unrest led to a structural transforma-
progress: negotiations, pacts, and peace agree- tion characterized by declining economic pro-
ments. In this view, protest, political violence, duction and export agriculture, as well as
and radical mobilization are obstacles to democ- capital flight. Repression and resistance became
ratization; disruption is a threat rather than a costly strategies for economic elites, less prom-
subject of inquiry. ising than adopting neo-liberal economic
Others suggest, however, that a heated reforms and a market economy. The market
political process can provide the cauldron for would provide more effective discipline for
making democracy. Bermeo (1999), for workers than state repression.
example, criticizes analysts’ ‘fear of the Similar processes occurred in South Africa,
masses’ and their insistence on moderating Wood (2000) argues. Again, she focuses on
threats from below. Acknowledging that vio- the link between mass mobilization and elites’
lence can disrupt democratic transitions, she changing perception of their economic inter-
contends that ‘these negative cases do not in ests. Increased strikes, township unrest, and
themselves make an argument for modera- growing labor militancy all produced domes-
tion’ (Bermeo, 1999: 127). In contrast, she tic instability – as well as an extremely nega-
cites the cases of Spain, Portugal, Peru, and tive international image. Domestic pressures
South Korea, where instances of political were intensified by international economic

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


358 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

sanctions, all undermining the viability of an portions of the economic elite. In Indonesia,
economic model based on apartheid. As neo- keterbukaan (political reforms akin to glas-
liberal market alternatives grew comparatively nost) in the 1980s relaxed restrictions on
more attractive, business elites began negotiat- activists and allowed for more institutional-
ing with Nelson Mandela’s African National ized resistance activity. Finally, Burma’s mili-
Congress, seeking to limit their losses. Like tary leaders have not yet reached a position
Bermeo (1999), Wood (2000) sees the power where the social challengers couldn’t be con-
of mass mobilization in a democratic transi- tained, and repression not only continued, but
tion less in its force than in its capacity to alter it intensified.
authorities’ perceptions of their own pros- Writing directly in response to developing
pects. Elites undertake democratic reforms in social movement literature (especially,
response to social movements when they McAdam et al., 2001), Boudreau adopts the
begin to think it is in their own best interest to focus on the interactions of challengers and
do so. Disruptive action affects their calcula- authorities, particularly resistance and repres-
tions about their interests. sion. He argues the particular modes of coer-
Ruth Berins Collier (1999) explicitly chal- cion pattern the resistance. His work suggests
lenges the notion that a particular set of the kinds of analytical syntheses available
actors, either elites or masses, is generically through focused comparisons of state struc-
critical to the process of democratization. tures and challengers’ choices.
Comparing 27 cases across Latin America
and Europe, over a period of roughly 100
years, she emphasizes the contingencies
inherent in the process of democratization. CONCLUSION
Elites may initiate democratization efforts, as
Wood suggests, when they see it in their In this chapter, we have attempted to think in
interests to do so, but change is sometimes the broadest terms possible about a compara-
spurred by collective action from below, par- tive politics of social movements and political
ticularly when organized labor is able to find contention. We have concentrated on varia-
potential allies among the elite. For Collier, tions in states’ capacities and policy processes,
the particular path of democratization reflects and the ways in which variations in these fac-
the available coalition partners for would-be tors influence the emergence, forms, processes
reformers. and outcomes of political contention. The
Boudreau (2004) also focuses on contin- review reveals some substantial foundations
gencies, unpacking repression to understand for a broader comparative analysis than has
the dynamics of social movement challenges frequently been attempted heretofore.
in Burma, Indonesia, and the Philippines. He Processes of political change and democrati-
compares the repressive strategies of these zation make it more likely that reform move-
states and the subsequent modes of collective ments targeting policy processes will emerge
action and resistance that arose in response. in all corners of the world, including places
Boudreau identifies a range of responsive where movements with displacement or sepa-
strategies available to state authorities and the ratist goals had been more common. In ana-
choices they made in each setting. He con- lyzing these movements, there is much that
tends that repressive strategies don’t just stoke we can learn from examining protest move-
or dampen mass mobilization, but actually ments in wealthier settings, with particular
sculpt it over a long period of time through attention to variations in the openness of the
sustained interaction. In the Philippines, he policy making process. While weaker state
contends, the regime’s social control strategies capacities in poorer settings will probably
became increasingly ineffective as Ferdinand make policy reform less likely, this is increas-
Marcos lost the capacity to buy off substantial ingly an empirical matter, particularly as both

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


SOCIAL MOVEMENTS 359

democratic procedures and social movement Europe and South America. New York:
techniques diffuse across the globe. Similarly, Cambridge University Press.
processes of insurgent mobilization in the Costain A. (1992) Inviting women’s rebellion:
global south have much to teach those inter- A political process interpretation of the
ested in advocacy on the part of systematically women’s movement. Baltimore, MD: Johns
excluded populations in all settings. Focusing Hopkins University Press.
on the capacity and the willingness of authori- Dalton, R.J. (2005) Citizen politics: Public
ties to resolve movement grievances, the exis- opinion and political parties in advanced
tence and salience of unresolved grievances in industrial democracies (fourth edition)
Washington, DC: CQ Press.
different societies, and the extent to which
Davis, D.E. (1994) ‘Failed democratic reform
movements advocate specific policy reforms
in contemporary Mexico: From social
rather than broader displacement goals, pro- movements to the state and back again’,
vides the basis for some of these broader Journal of Latin American Studies, 26
comparisons. (2): 375–408.
della Porta, D. and Reiter, H. (eds) (1998)
Policing protest: The control of mass demon-
strations in western democracies.
Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
REFERENCES della Porta, D. and Rucht, D. (1995) ‘Left-
libertarian movements in context: A com-
Almeida, P.D. (2007) Waves of protest: Popular parison of Italy and West Germany,
struggle in El Salvador, 1925–2005. 1965–1990’, in J.C. Jenkins, and
Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. B. Klandermans (eds), The politics of social
Banaszak, L.A. (1996). Why movements protest. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota
succeed or fail: Opportunity, culture, and Press, pp. 229–72.
the struggle for woman suffrage. Princeton, DeNardo, J. (1985) Power in numbers: The
NJ: Princeton University Press. political strategy of protest and rebellion.
Bermeo, N. (1999) ‘Myths of moderation’, in Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
L. Anderson (ed.), Transitions to democracy. Eckstein, S. (1989) ‘Power and popular protest
New York: Columbia University Press, in Latin America’, in S. Eckstein (ed.), Power
pp. 120–39. and popular protest: Latin American social
Boudreau, V. (2004) Resisting dictatorship: movements. Berkeley: University of California
Repression and protest in Southeast Asia. Press, pp. 1–60.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Eckstein, S. (1990) ‘Formal vs. substantive
Bratton, M. and Van de Walle, K. (1997) democracy’, Mexican Studies/Studios
Democratic experiments in Africa: Regime Mexiscanos, 6 (2): 213–39.
transition in comparative perspective. Eisinger, P.K. (1973) ‘The conditions of protest
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. behavior in American cities’, The American
Brockett, C. (1991) ‘The structure of political Political Science Review, 67: 11–28.
opportunities Central America’, Comparative Giugni, M. (2004) Social protest and policy
Politics, 23 (3): 253–74. change: Ecology, antinuclear, and peace
Buechler, S. (1999) Social movements in movements in comparative perspective.
advanced capitalism. New York: Oxford Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.
University Press. Goldstone, J. (ed.) (2003) Revolutions:
Cohen, J.L. (1985) ‘Strategy or identity: New Theoretical, comparative, and historical stud-
theoretical paradigms and contemporary social ies. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thomson
movements’, Social Research, 52: 663–716. Learning.
Coleman, J.S. (1990) Foundations of social Gurr, T.R. (1969) Why men rebel. Princeton,
theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University NJ: Princeton University Press.
Press. Huntington, S.P. (1968) Political order in
Collier, R.B. (1999) Paths toward democracy: changing societies. New Haven: Yale
The working class and elites in Western University.

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


360 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Karl, T. (1990) ‘Dilemmas of democratization McAdam, D. (1982) Political process and the
in Latin America’, Comparative Politics, development of black insurgency, 1930–
23: 1–21. 1970. Chicago, IL: University Chicago Press.
Kim, Q.Y. (1996) ‘From protest to change of McAdam, D., Tarrow, S., and Tilly, C. (2001)
regime: The 4-11 revolt and the fall of the Dynamics of contention. New York:
Rhee regime in South Korea’, Social Forces, Cambridge University Press.
74 (4): 1179–208. McCarthy, J.D. and McPhail, C. (1998)
Kitschelt, H.P. (1986) ‘Political opportunity ‘The institutionalization of protest in
structures and political protest: Anti-nuclear the United States’, in D.S. Meyer, and
movements in four democracies’, British S. Tarrow (eds), The social movement
Journal of Political Science, 16 (1): 57–85. society. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield,
Koopmans, R. (1995) Democracy from below: pp. 83–110.
New social movements and the political McCarthy, J.D. and Zald, M.N. (1977) ‘Resource
system in West Germany. Boulder: Westview mobilization and social movements: A partial
Press. theory’, American Journal of Sociology, 82
Koopmans, R. and Statham, P. (1999a) (6): 1212–41.
‘Challenging the liberal nation-state? Melucci, A. (1989) Nomads of the present:
Postnationalism, multiculturalism, and Social movements and individual needs in
the collective claims making of migrants contemporary society. Philadelphia: Temple
and ethnic minorities in Britain and University Press.
Germany’, American Journal of Sociology, Mettler, S. (2005) ‘Policy feedback effects for
105 (2): 652–96. collective action: Lessons from veterans’ pro-
Koopmans, R. and Statham, P. (1999b) ‘Political grams’, in D.S. Meyer, V. Jenness, and H.
claims analysis: Integrating protest event Ingram (eds), Routing the opposition: Social
and political discourse approaches’, movements, public policy, and democracy.
Mobilization, 4 (2): 40–51. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press,
Kowalchuk, L. (2005) ‘The discourse of pp. 211–35.
demobilization: Shifts in activists’ priorities Meyer, D.S. (1990) A winter of discontent: The
and the framing of political opportunities in nuclear freeze and American politics. New
a peasant land struggle’, The Sociological York: Praeger.
Quarterly, 46 (2): 237–61. Meyer, D.S. (2004) ‘Protest and political oppor-
Kriesi, H., Koopmans, R., Duvydenak, J.W., tunity’, Annual Review of Sociology, 30:
and Giugni, M.G. (1995) New social move- 125–45.
ments in Western Europe: A comparative Meyer, D.S. (2007) The politics of protest:
analysis. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Social movements in America. New York:
Press. Oxford University Press.
Linz, J. and Stepan, A. (1996) Problems Meyer, D.S., Jenness, V., and Ingram, H. (eds)
of democratic transition and consoli- (2005) Routing the opposition: Social move-
dation. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins ments, public policy, and democracy.
University Press. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Lipset, S.M. (1960) Political man. New York: Meyer D.S. and Minkoff, D.C. (2004)
Anchor. ‘Conceptualizing political opportunity’, Social
Lipsky, M. (1968) ‘Protest as a political resource’, Forces, 82 (4): 1457–92.
American Political Science Review, 62 (4): Meyer, D.S. and Staggenborg, S. (1996)
1144–58. ‘Movements, countermovements, and the
Loveman, M. (1998) ‘High-risk collective action: structure of political opportunity’, American
Defending human rights in Chile, Uruguay, Journal of Sociology, 101 (6): 1628–60.
and Argentina’, American Journal of Meyer D.S. and Tarrow, S. (eds) (1998) The
Sociology, 104 (2): 477–525. social movement society: Contentious poli-
Mason, T.D. (1998) ‘Take two acres and call tics for a new century. Lanham, MD: Rowman
me in the morning: Is land reform a prescrip- and Littlefield.
tion for agrarian unrest?’, The Journal of Moore, B. (1968) Social origins of dictatorship
Politics, 60: 199–230. and democracy. Boston: Beacon.

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


SOCIAL MOVEMENTS 361

Navarro, M. (1989) ‘The personal is political: movements in Western democracies.


Las madres de la Plaza de Mayo’, in Eckstein, New York: Oxford University Press,
S. (ed.), Power and popular protest: Latin pp. 156–75.
American social movements. Berkeley: Rucht, D., Koopmans, R., and Neidhardt, F.
University of California Press, pp. 241–58. (1999) Acts of dissent: New developments in
O’Brien, K.J. and Li, L. (2006) Rightful resist- the study of protest. Berlin: Sigma.
ance in rural China. New York: Cambridge Schurman, R. (2004) ‘Fighting frankenfoods:
University Press. Industry structures and the efficacy of the
O’Donnell, G., Schmitter, P.C., and Whitehead, L. anti-biotech movement in Western Europe’,
(1986) Transitions from authoritarian rule Social Problems, 51 (2): 243–68.
(Vols. 1–4) Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Scott, J.C. (1985) Weapons of the weak:
University Press. Everyday forms of peasant resistance. New
Offe, C. (1985) ‘New social movements: Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Challenging the boundaries of institutional Skocpol, T. (1979) States and social revolu-
politics’, Social Research, 59: 817–68. tions: A comparative analysis of France,
Oliver, P., Marwell, G. and Teixeira, R. (1985) Russia, and China. New York: Cambridge
‘A theory of critical mass I: Interdependence, University Press.
group heterogeneity and the production of Suh, D. (2001) ‘How do political opportunities
collective action’, American Journal of matter for social movements?: Political
Sociology, 91 (3): 522–56. opportunity, misframing, pseudosuccess,
Olson, M. (1967) The logic of collective action. and pseudofailure’, Sociological Quarterly,
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 42 (3): 437–60.
Parsa, M. (1996) ‘Entrepreneurs and democra- Tarrow, S. (1989) Democracy and disorder:
tization: Iran and the Philippines’, Comparative Protest and politics in Italy, 1965–1975.
Studies in Society and History, 37 (4): Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
803–30. Tarrow, S. (1998) Power in movement: Social
Parsa, M. (2000) States, Ideologies, and Social movements and contentious politics (second
Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of Iran, edition) Cambridge: Cambridge University
Nicaragua, and the Philippines. Cambridge: Press.
Cambridge University Press. Tarrow, S. and Tilly, C. (2006) Contentious
Piven, F.F. and Cloward, R.A. (1977) Poor peo- politics. Boulder, CO: Paradigm.
ple’s movements. New York: Vintage. Tilly, C. (1978) From mobilization to revolution.
Ramos, A. (2002) ‘Cutting through state and Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
class: Sources and strategies of self-repre- Tilly, C. (1993a) ‘Contentious repertoires in
sentation in Latin America’, in K.B. Warren Great Britain, 1758–1834’, Social Science
and J.E. Jackson (eds), Indigenous History, 17 (2): 253–80.
Movements, Self-Representation, and the Tilly, C. (1993b) European revolutions.
State in Latin America. Austin, Texas: Cambridge, MA: Blackwell, pp. 1492–1992.
University of Texas Press, pp. 251–79. Trevizo, D. (2006) ‘Between Zapata and Che:
Ray, R. (1999) Fields of protest: Women’s A comparison of social movement success
movements in India. Minneapolis: University and failure in Mexico’, Social Science History,
of Minnesota Press. 30 (2): 197–229.
Rojas, F. (2006) ‘Social movement tactics, Wood, E.J. (2000) Forging democracy from
organizational change, and the spread of below: Insurgent transitions in South Africa
African American studies’, Social Forces, 84 and El Salvador. Cambridge: Cambridge
(4): 2147–66. University Press.
Rucht, D. (1990) ‘The strategies and action Yashar, D.J. (2005) Contesting citizenship:
repertoires of new movements’, in R.J. Indigenous movements and democracy in
Dalton and M. Kuechler (eds), Challenging Latin America. New York: Cambridge
the political order: New social and political University Press.

9781412919760_Chap18.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:19:54 PM


19
Corruption
Paul Heywood

INTRODUCTION about corruption. After all, corruption is hardly


a new phenomenon in politics: from the accu-
After decades during which corruption received sations against Socrates, through Livy’s lament
relatively little attention from academics and on the decadence and moral decline of Rome,
political practitioners alike, there was a verita- to the endemic ‘Old Corruption’ evident
ble explosion of interest in the issue after the throughout much of eighteenth and nineteenth
end of the Cold War. Not only did corruption century Europe, the charge of corruption has
scandals become major news stories in both been a constant motif in political life. Indeed,
the developed and developing worlds, but a corruption has existed in all societies and at
consensus began to emerge amongst both anti- all times, so the current concern requires some
corruption activists and western governments explanation. However, in order to provide
alike that corruption represented a major risk such an explanation, we first of all need to
to socio-economic progress and development. understand what we mean by corruption. This
Indeed, there is a sense in which corruption chapter opens with a discussion of how to
replaced another ‘c-word’ as the major threat define corruption, before addressing the issue
facing western democracies, a view most of why it is seen as so important in contempo-
explicitly expressed by the controversial former rary politics. It then turns to the question of
governor of the World Bank, Paul Wolfowitz, what causes corruption, before looking at the
when he called corruption the ‘greatest evil problems associated with attempts to measure
facing the world since communism’ (Wintour how much corruption takes place across the
and Leigh, 2005). Certainly, a range of interna- world. There then follows an assessment of
tional organizations, including the World Bank, the impact of corruption, and the chapter con-
the International Monetary Fund, and the cludes with an overview of the key strategies
Organization for Economic Co-operation employed to combat corruption.
and Development (OECD), as well as the
European Union (EU) and many national gov-
ernments, began in the 1990s to devote major
attention to the issue of corruption, which was WHAT DO WE MEAN
almost universally seen as an impediment to BY CORRUPTION?
economic growth.
The obvious question is why there has Corruption is not easy to define. There is a
been such a dramatic increase in concern considerable literature, stretching back over

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:21:06 PM


CORRUPTION 363

several decades, which seeks to identify the will vary with the nature of the political
core characteristics of the concept – but, as system itself, and any definition will inevita-
yet, there is no universally agreed definition. bly depend upon normative – and therefore
Until the post-Cold War resurgence of interest inevitably contestable – judgements.
in the topic, much of the literature followed A wide-ranging, generic definition of cor-
Arnold J. Heidenheimer (1970) in distinguish- ruption can at best provide a starting point
ing between definitions based respectively on for identifying and analyzing a range of dif-
public office (violation of trust placed in the ferent types of corruption, which would need
office), public interest (officials engineer to be broken down according to a number of
private benefit at the expense of the public different dimensions. These more taxonomi-
interest), and the market (maximization of cal approaches run the risk of becoming
personal gains through dispensing public overly descriptive, but they are probably an
goods). In more recent years, the most com- essential first step in developing a basis for
monly cited definition has been that developed meaningful comparison. A good example of
and refined by the anti-corruption non- such an approach is that by Alatas (1990),
governmental agency, Transparency who distinguishes between ‘transactive’ and
International (TI), which states that corruption ‘extortive’ corruption. The former refers to
is ‘the misuse of entrusted power for private situations in which there is a mutually entered
gain’, further differentiated between ‘accord- into arrangement between the donor and
ing to the rule’ and ‘against the rule’ variants recipient of a corrupt exchange, and can be
(Transparency International, 2008). The further broken down into a variety of sub-
former refers to situations in which, for types, including ‘investive’ (where goods and
instance, facilitation payments (‘speed favours are offered with a view to future
money’) are given to a public official in order returns), ‘nepotistic’ (the unjustified appoint-
to secure preferential treatment in an area ment of friends and relatives to positions of
where the official is legally entitled to act; the authority), ‘autogenic’ (where one person
latter involve bribes paid to secure services benefits from misuse of privileged informa-
which the official is not entitled to provide. tion), and ‘supportive’ (action to protect
While the TI definition has the virtue of existing corruption networks, such as machine
parsimony, it seems to imply that all corrup- politics). Extortive corruption, meanwhile,
tion is characterized by the search for private involves some form of compulsion, often
pecuniary gain. Corruption, though, involves through the threat of violence. More recently,
much more than simply securing private Johnston (2005) has drawn a distinction
profit through the breaking of rules. In real- between different ‘syndromes’ of corruption,
ity, it is probably fruitless to try to identify according to the political and economic
one generic catch-all definition of corruption opportunities provided by different regime
which captures the complexity of the concept types. Thus, he identifies ‘influence markets’
in such a way that it can inform research into (mature democracies), ‘elite cartels’ (consol-
why it takes place and how to combat it. One idating or reforming democracies), ‘oligarchs
reason for that fruitlessness is that in order to and clans’ (transitional regimes), and ‘offi-
judge whether something has been corrupted, cial moguls’ (undemocratic regimes).
we need an understanding of its proper or A further important distinction referred to
un-corrupt state – and in the case of ‘politics’ in the literature is that between ‘low-level’
that is almost impossible. Logically, any corruption and ‘high-level’ corruption. Low-
definition of political corruption entails an level corruption, which is often also labelled
implicit notion of ‘un-corrupt’ politics, and bureaucratic corruption or petty corruption,
therefore our definition of politics itself will refers to corruption by state officials in their
affect our understanding of political corrup- interaction with the public. For instance, when
tion (Philip, 1997). It therefore follows that traffic police or doctors accept bribes in the
the meaning of corruption in political life day-to-day performance of their duties, we

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


364 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

talk about petty corruption. Low level corrup- more indirect. For instance, corrupt client
tion can be both particularly widespread and actors can donate funds to political parties,
also hugely damaging to the functioning of a which can subsequently be used for the financ-
state, and is arguably the most difficult to root ing of electoral campaigns (as has happened in
out since it often takes place in contexts where many established democracies). Benefits may
corrupt exchanges are effectively embedded also be handed out at some future stage when
into the daily fabric of social existence. In politicians or top officials are given jobs or
many poor or developing countries where cor- other rewards for loyalty and favourable
ruption is endemic, such exchanges have behaviour in the past, or even more indirectly,
become simply a way of life, usually met with when these benefits are handed out to third
resignation rather than outrage. parties at a later point in time. Corruption is
By contrast, high-level corruption refers to therefore not just about paying bribes.
corrupt acts performed by politicians and other There is some disagreement as to whether
top state officials. High level corruption is corruption necessarily entails illegal activity.
sometimes also labelled as ‘grand corruption’ It could be argued that the most sinister forms
or ‘political corruption’, though this form of of corruption in a democracy are those which
corruption is not limited to political office- ‘betray the democratic transcript’ by under-
holders but may also concern top officials in – mining mechanisms of accountability – that
at least nominally – administrative positions. is, by failing to keep citizens fully informed
Consistent with the Alatas and Johnston or by not operating in a transparent manner.
approaches, high level corruption also entails For instance, a privatization process may
different forms (see Rose-Ackerman, 1999, take place formally according to prevailing
2006). It may refer to the organization of legal requirements, but if the valuation of the
entire state sectors into corrupt rent-seeking state assets being sold is deliberately kept
machines, whereby institutions such as the low without the public being informed (per-
police force are organized as corrupt networks haps to ensure more bids) then that could be
from top to bottom (Warburton, 2007). It may seen as a form of corruption. This means that
also refer to forms of illegal campaign financ- corruption is sometimes hard to distinguish
ing and to the payment of kickbacks and from other, legitimate, political activities –
other private benefits for the award of public especially in the arena of winning votes or
contracts and positions. securing support. Party patronage for
In its most damaging form, however, high- instance, which essentially refers to public
level corruption refers to the purchase of laws sector appointments made by political parties
and regulations, since senior public officials (Kopecky and Mair, 2006), is seen by some
are in a position to influence the formulation as corrupt but by many others as just a
and adoption of laws and regulations, which normal part of the political process.
can subsequently work in favour of specific Rent-seeking and pork-barrel politics are
client groups. This form of high-level corrup- other forms of behaviour which to some seem
tion has also been labelled ‘state capture’ corrupt, but they do not in themselves necessar-
(Hellman et al., 2003; World Bank, 2000) in ily entail corruption. Rent-seeking (Tullock,
order to indicate that the law-making process 1987) refers to situations where firms or other
is biased and that the regulatory output tends economic actors are able to secure benefits
to work to the advantage of particular groups without compensatory costs as a result of
of captors. A key point is that ‘state capture’ as public policy decisions which work in their
a form of high-level corruption does not auto- favour (for instance, the granting of monopoly
matically entail the direct exchange of money rights over the import or export of certain
between politicians or senior officials on the goods). Since public officials are often able to
one hand and some client firm or organization grant monopoly rights, there is suspicion that
on the other. Corrupt transactions can also be firms lobby to secure such rent-seeking

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


CORRUPTION 365

opportunities. Whilst rent-seeking may be seen rent-seeking opportunities than by any


as improper and immoral in many social and rationale based on economic productivity or
cultural settings, it can really be considered cor- growth – hence the existence of so-called
rupt only if accompanied by some breaking of ‘white elephant’ projects, often associated
rules by public officials in exchange for private with poor standards in construction and safety
benefit. The term pork-barrel politics (Ferejohn, (Cartier-Bresson, 2000). Corruption also
1974), meanwhile, was originally coined in the means that the rules of economic activity are
US and refers to the attempt by politicians to arbitrarily enforced, that property rights are
channel public resources to their constituen- insecure, and that the administrative capacity
cies. Pork-barrel politics may be criticized to provide services is diminished, all of which
using economic efficiency arguments. However, translates into a highly uncertain business
as long as this form of biased distribution of environment (World Bank, 1997: 18–20).
public resources takes place within a formal Uncertainty in turn raises the costs of private
legal framework of law-making and is subject investment and damages the growth of pro-
to public debate and scrutiny, it can hardly be ductive capacity. At the same time, corruption
considered as corrupt. undermines the effectiveness of public invest-
Corruption is thus a difficult concept to pin ment (Tanzi and Davoodi, 1997) – it leads not
down. It does not always imply formal just to higher public investment expenditure,
breaches of rules (even though it usually but also to lower productivity of such invest-
does), and interpretations of corruption are ment. Corruption also hurts prospects for for-
also influenced by public reactions to differ- eign direct investment, put off by concern
ent forms of behaviour. There is thus an at the misappropriation of funds (World
inescapably normative dimension to the con- Bank, 2000: 23, note 2). In addition, corrup-
cept: what is deemed acceptable in one con- tion decreases the efficiency of resource allo-
text may not be in another. Moreover, we cation by introducing severe distortions into
need to be careful not to confuse arguments the price system (Shleifer and Vishny, 1993:
about the economic efficiency of public poli- 599–617) and, by creating incentives for
cies with judgements on corrupt processes of lower budget revenues and higher budget
policy making, especially since judgements expenditures, generates unsustainable fiscal
on efficiency are themselves influenced by positions (Tanzi and Davoodi, 1997; World
underlying value assumptions. Bank, 2000: 21–22) which result in high infla-
tion and again in lower effectiveness of the
price system. The impact on the price system
results in a misallocation of resources towards
WHAT IS THE IMPACT sub-optimal uses. Ultimately, low investments
OF CORRUPTION? and poor allocation of resources spell low
growth in the long run.
Concern about corruption is driven not just Second, corruption not only hurts citizens’
(or even mainly) by moral repugnance. long-term welfare, but it does so in an unfair
Recent literature on corruption (see World way. The costs associated with corruption fall
Bank, 2000: 18–24) has reached several con- primarily on the weakest and most vulnerable
clusions about the direct and indirect impacts groups in society. Societies in which corruption
of corruption on the economic well-being of is widespread experience more poverty and
society, using both theoretical arguments and higher inequality than those where there is only
empirical case studies. limited corruption. This is due not only to lower
First, corruption hurts economic growth. It growth, but to the fact that corrupt governments
does so by undermining investments and by are effectively financed through regressive,
distorting the allocation of resources towards rather than progressive taxes, that they cannot
inefficient ends, driven more by corrupt successfully establish and maintain social safety

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


366 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

nets, and that they divert resources away from major attention since the early 1990s. How
investment in human and social capital, both of can we explain this surge of interest in an
which are important for reducing poverty and age-old phenomenon? It is tempting to point
inequality (Gupta et al., 1998; World Bank, to the extraordinary events surrounding the
2000: 20–21). Tangentopoli scandal in Italy, when the entire
Third, corruption is a key factor in the body politic was shaken by revelations of
erosion of trust in institutions, and therefore endemic deep-rooted corruption, as the starting
damages the social fabric more generally. point. The scale of Italian corruption was mas-
That corruption leads to lower revenues and sive, and implicated politicians at the very
higher expenditure justifies people in thinking highest level from all the major parties (della
that they are paying more for less. Moreover, Porta and Vannucci, 1999). In the wake of
those who foot the bill – mainly the poor and events in Italy, a series of further scandals were
the disadvantaged – get almost nothing revealed in a number of European states –
from the services they are in fact financing. notably Belgium, France, Germany and
Logically, this leads to a very low level of Spain. However, if the scale of corruption in
public trust in state organs and in political lead- Italy had not been fully appreciated, the fact
ers, thereby further reducing the capacity of the of its existence was hardly news: indeed, it
state to provide welfare enhancing services had long been widely recognized that corrup-
(Gupta et al., 1998; Tanzi, 1998; Tanzi and tion was widespread in the country. So, in a
Davoodi, 1997; Shleifer and Vishny, 1993; sense, the scandal surrounding corruption in
World Bank, 2000: 21–22). Italy simply adds force to the question of
Fourth, as della Porta (2000) has persua- why the issue emerged in the early 1990s,
sively argued, the spread of corruption over rather than at some earlier point. Whilst it is
time generates a vicious circle in which wide- impossible to provide a definitive answer, we
spread corruption undermines confidence in the can identify four main factors which have
government and public officials and thereby contributed to the increased visibility and
encourages the search for ways to by-pass or salience of corruption.
short-circuit the official state machinery; in First, the end of the Cold War was itself
turn, the readiness to pay for privileged access an unanticipated stimulus. Following the
to services which should by rights be provided collapse of the Soviet Union, there was no
free of charge, or at least without favour or longer any reason for Western democracies to
discrimination, generates further incentives for support corrupt dictators who had sought to
public officials to engage in corrupt activity and use anti-communism as a legitimizing ration-
thereby further undermines trust and confi- ale: it was neither necessary nor credible to
dence in the political process. As in post-war continue turning a blind eye to corruption
Italy, public officials may wish to be seen as under the pretext of security issues. The end of
inefficient, since that will increase their scope the Cold War also effectively ended the great
for charging a premium price to perform what ideological confrontation between capitalism
should be routine duties. In this way, corruption and communism in both the developed and
and poor governance feed off each other in a developing world. When asked to explain the
self-sustaining manner. success of the operation Mani Pulite (‘Clean
hands’) in Italy, Romano Prodi, the Italian
premier and former President of the EU
Commission, simply answered ‘Yalta’. What
WHY HAS CORRUPTION he meant was that the end of the geo-strategic
BECOME SO SALIENT? political framework established by Yalta
helped convince Italian businesses that paying
Despite the difficulties in defining corrup- the ‘party tax’ to lock out the communists
tion, the issue has none the less attracted was no longer legitimate.

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


CORRUPTION 367

In fact, the end of communism gave rise to Perceptions Index (CPI) has become a signifi-
an unanticipated challenge to the very legiti- cant international news event, which attracts
macy of the democratic states which had considerable attention. Indeed, the CPI
‘won’ the Cold War. Deprived of this great has become the standard reference point
ideological clash, citizens in the established for assessing levels of corruption across
democracies were able increasingly to focus the world.
their attention on the integrity of the political Fourth, increased mobility and increas-
class (Heywood and Krastev, 2006). Debate ingly globalized markets have also contrib-
about moral values and the personal integrity uted to corruption’s greater visibility. In the
of political leaders became increasingly words of Vito Tanzi (1998: 559),
widespread, and general elections in particu-
globalization has brought individuals from coun-
lar saw ever more references to the personal tries with little corruption into frequent contacts
attributes of the candidates for top office as a with those from countries where corruption is
key factor in appealing for votes. Any scan- endemic. These contacts have increased the inter-
dals involving the party in government national attention paid to corruption, especially
prompted opposition leaders to emphasize when some companies believed that they were cut
out of some contracts because the winning com-
their own trustworthiness as a marked con- pany has paid a bribe.
trast to the alleged dishonesty of the incum-
bent governments (especially as regards This links in to the unexpectedly prominent
financial matters), a pattern repeated through- role played by multinational corporations,
out many of the world’s democracies and one which have moved from being viewed as
which maintained the visibility of corruption major sources of corruption to posing as
as a political issue. fighters against corruption. Multinational
A second factor relates to changes in corporations have long used bribery to win
global communication technologies. In a contracts or favourable terms, especially for
world where ‘infotainment’ has become a public sector construction works and the
major growth industry, and in which investiga- supply of military equipment. Indeed, until
tive journalism seeks to generate high profile recently, bribery was seen as a normal busi-
news stories in order to supply 24/7 coverage ness practice, which was even tax-deductible
of world events, corruption scandals offer a in states such as France, Germany, the
potent mix of newsworthiness and sensation- Netherlands, and Norway.
alism. Moreover, the exponential growth of In the 1960s and 1970s, foreign investors
access to information and communication saw corruption as a useful way to open up
technologies (ICT) means that people can and modernize the economies of developing
easily learn about the latest corruption scan- countries. Corruption was used as an instru-
dals in all corners of the world (Thompson, ment to break the protectionist barriers that
2000). Linked in some ways to these ICT were imposed by the governments of post-
developments, a third factor relates to the role colonial states, and could therefore even be
of civil society and public awareness cam- seen positively. And multinational corpora-
paigns organized by NGOs to mobilize anti- tions were able to exert persuasive influence
corruption sentiments. Civic advocacy has through their financial power, their value
been partially responsible for making corrup- often dwarfing the GDP of those developing
tion a problem not just in corrupted countries, countries in which they sought to invest.
but also for those involved in corrupting them. However, two significant changes combined
In particular, the emergence of Transparency to alter the perspective of many multinational
International (TI) as a highly visible interna- corporations. First, the US Foreign Corrupt
tional NGO dealing with corruption has sig- Practices Act (FCPA) of 1977, designed to
nificantly shaped the anti-corruption agenda. prevent corporate bribery of foreign officials,
The publication of TI’s annual Corruption represented a significant (if flawed) step

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


368 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

adopted in the wake of the Watergate investi- and the rise of organized crime and, indeed,
gations by the Security and Exchange terrorism. For instance, an official report by
Committee, which revealed widespread pay- the Russian secret services documented that
ments by US companies to foreign govern- widespread bribery in the Russian police
ments – notably the so-called Lockheed made it possible for Chechen terrorists to
scandal, in which the US company bribed smuggle in the explosives used in the 2002
Japanese government officials to buy its air- attack on a Moscow theatre. Elsewhere across
craft. The FCPA made the issue of corporate the world, various separatist and rebel organ-
corruption prominent, but it was not really izations have imposed so-called ‘revolution-
until the anti-protectionist stance of the World ary taxes’ on local businesses, enforced via
Trade Organization (WTO) that the need to the threat of kidnap or assassination, whilst
combat corruption in international business the Mafia (and national variants thereof) is
transactions was widely recognized by most believed to be responsible for much organ-
developed countries. ized crime in a wide range of countries, but
Such anti-corruption sentiments were not especially in Russia, Ukraine, and other tran-
inspired by any moral conversion on the part sition economies in East-Central Europe.
of multi-national corporations, nor arguably The link between corruption, crime, and ter-
even by the WTO initiative and subsequent rorism is one which has generated major
anti-bribery convention promoted by the international concern since 9/11.
OECD. Instead, as more developing and post-
communist transition economies came to rely
on IMF loans and foreign direct investment,
so competition forced them to become more WHAT CAUSES CORRUPTION?
open and to abandon protectionism. However,
compared with the more regulated markets in Not only is it difficult to define corruption,
established democracies (themselves not there has also been much debate about its
immune to corruption), corrupted markets are causes. One kind of approach focuses on
characterized by the very high value of local identifying incentives and opportunity struc-
knowledge. In order to corrupt public officials tures. These can range from the level of an
and win contracts, it is not enough simply to individual (for instance, venal public ser-
offer the biggest bribe. The market in corrup- vants who abuse their position for personal
tion services is necessarily clandestine and financial gain) to a more structural level (for
closed, and in order to be competitive within instance, the increasing cost of the political
it, players need to know when, to whom and process generates incentives for political par-
how to give a bribe. Local businesses are ties to find innovative ways to secure funds,
much better positioned in this market because and the readiness of corporate interests to
they are plugged into existing networks and buy access to the policy process provides the
possess local knowledge: thus, a corrupted opportunity). This kind of analysis requires
business environment is much more favoura- detailed process tracing of actual cases of
ble to local businesses than to foreign inves- corruption, usually based on exploring exam-
tors. Unlike the Lockheed scandal which ples which have resulted in prosecution and
prompted the FCPA, corruption scandals conviction (for an outstanding example, see
(especially in the transition economies) have della Porta and Vannucci, 1999). Another
often seen multinational corporations losing approach seeks to develop testable hypothe-
contracts or even seeing their property rights ses about the factors which lead to corrup-
undermined – hence their support for stronger tion, using existing indices and measures of
action against corruption. corruption to inform various regression
Finally, there is increasing concern about models based on factor analysis (for a
the links between the spread of corruption recent overview, see Rose-Ackerman, 2006).

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


CORRUPTION 369

Such factors include religion (with individu- as a means to combat and reduce corruption
alist doctrines seen as less prone to corrup- (Klitgaard, 1988; Weingast, 1995).
tion than hierarchical ones), culture (more Fourth, the dominant approach to analyzing
homogeneous societies being seen as more the causes of corruption tends to test correla-
likely to be corrupt), the geographical posi- tions between systemic, economic, and/or
tion of a country (in Europe, countries below political input variables, on the one hand, and
‘the olive line’ are seen as more corrupt, with indices which rank perceptions of corruption
southern hemisphere countries in general on the other. These approaches develop causal
more corrupt than their northern counter- mechanisms that connect factors such as the
parts), the level of economic development level of state decentralization with levels of
(poorer countries as more corrupt), the size corruption. Yet, they usually do not examine
of the public sector (the larger the sector, the the causal mechanisms themselves nor do they
more likely it is to be corrupt), the type of investigate whether the conditions for the
political regime (presidential systems being emergence of different mechanisms of corrup-
seen as more corrupt than parliamentary tion are present or not. However, given the
ones, federal states more corrupt than unitary nature of corruption, it is arguably very diffi-
ones), different types of legal codes (civil law cult to investigate causal mechanisms by trac-
being less adept at prosecuting corruption ing individual corrupt acts back to the presence
than non-hierarchical common law) as well or absence of institutional arrangements, the
as the quality of bureaucracy (linked in turn constellation of actors, and the incentives and
to the status of public officials and pride in identities of individuals. Ultimately – and
holding office). consistent with the argument that there is no
Most of these alleged determinants of cor- one definition of corruption – there is no
ruption are contested. First, it is often unclear single set of causal determinants to explain the
whether they cause or are in fact consequences emergence of corruption. We need to draw
of corruption (Lambsdorff, 2006). For instance, distinctions between macro-level factors and
a low level of economic development has long individual incentives, and accept that there are
been argued to produce higher levels of cor- always likely to be a host of intervening vari-
ruption (Huntington, 1968). Yet, international ables in any given instance of corruption
organizations also identify corruption as one which makes it impossible to specify a casual
of the main obstacles to economic develop- chain with any precision. At best, we can
ment. Second, there is often a discrepancy highlight what appear to be some of key risks
between conventional wisdom and the find- for corruption.
ings of corruption research, for instance, low
public sector wages are commonly associated
with higher levels of corruption but research
does not usually find a significant relationship HOW MUCH CORRUPTION
between the two variables (Treisman, 2000). IS THERE?
Third, research on the causes of corruption,
especially the impact of different ‘patterns of As we have seen, there has been a significant
democracy’ (Lijphart, 1999), has produced growth in attempts to identify the causes of cor-
contradictory results. Kunicova (2006), for ruption through the use of statistical regression
instance, finds that presidential systems of models. A key stimulus to that approach, as
government combined with proportional rep- well as to various other attempts to measure the
resentation electoral systems and federalism amount of corruption, has been Transparency
are associated with highest levels of corrup- International’s Corruption Perceptions Index
tion. Yet, academic debate and international (CPI). First released in 1995 and published
organizations such as the World Bank tend to annually since then, the CPI has become estab-
praise decentralization of the state apparatus lished as the most widely cited indicator of

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


370 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

levels of corruption across the world. The CPI Since the CPI is a composite index which
is a composite index, calculated using data draws upon a series of surveys mainly aimed
sources from a variety of other institutions at western business leaders and expert assess-
which seek to measure ‘the overall extent of ment, in practice the questions in many of the
corruption (frequency and/or size of bribes) in surveys relate specifically to business trans-
the public or political sectors’ (Transparency actions (for instance, the need to pay bribes
International, 2007). The Transparency Inter- to secure contracts). Perceptions of corrup-
national website provides a detailed account of tion are likely to be seen primarily in terms
the various sources used (which vary from year of bribery, which cannot capture either the
to year) as well as the non-parametric statistics level of grand versus petty corruption, or
used to standardize these sources. indeed the impact of corruption (Kenny,
The CPI has become controversial. Although 2006: 19; Knack, 2006: 2; Olken, 2005: 3).
widely credited with playing a crucial role in Moreover, the focus of questions is often on
focusing attention on the issue of corruption, the bribe-takers rather than bribe-givers: the
index has none the less been subject to many implicit suggestion is that bribes are paid
criticisms both on account of its methodology only when required by agents in the receiv-
and the use to which it has been put (Andersson ing country, rather than that they may be used
and Heywood, forthcoming). As is explicit in proactively as a means to secure contracts.
the title of the index, it measures perceptions A second problem relates to the question
rather than, for example, reported cases, prose- of how we can properly interpret what
cutions or proven incidences of corruption. This respondents to the various surveys under-
matters because perceptions can influence stand by corruption. Each of the surveys
behaviour in significant ways: for instance, if operates with its own understanding of cor-
we believe that all around us people are engag- ruption (which may focus on different
ing in corrupt behaviour that may make us more aspects, such as bribery of public officials,
likely to adopt such practices ourselves. Yet, embezzlement, and so forth), and seeks to
research conducted by Miller et al. (2001) dem- assess the ‘extent’ of corruption (Lambsdorff,
onstrated that there can be a striking disjuncture 2005: 4). However, although the surveys
between perceptions and personal experience of often ask a panel of experts to rank corrup-
corruption: for instance, citizens in the Czech tion on a scale of low to high (or some varia-
Republic are much less likely than those in tion thereof), we cannot know whether the
Ukraine to have had direct involvement in cor- experts share a common assessment of what
rupt exchanges with public officials, yet in both constitutes any particular location on such a
countries there is a widespread perception of scale: what seems a ‘low/modest’ level of
corruption being rife. A recent detailed study of corruption to one person, may look high to
the relationship between the CPI and TI’s another (cf. Knack, 2006: 18; Søreide, 2006:
Global Corruption Barometer, which seeks to 6). In the absence of clear indicators, such
capture the lived experience of corruption rankings must be largely impressionistic. A
through the eyes of ordinary citizens, has also third problem relates to the interval scales
shown convincingly that experience is a poor used in the CPI index, which ranks on a scale
predictor of perceptions and that ‘the ‘distance’ of 100 (1–10 to one decimal place). This sug-
between opinions and experiences vary haphaz- gests a high degree of accuracy can be
ardly from country to country’ (Weber Abramo, achieved, and that a material difference can
2007: 6). Moreover, general perceptions cannot be identified between a country which scores,
differentiate between various types of corrup- say, 7.0 and one which scores 6.9. That
tion, nor different sectors within countries. So, impression of accuracy is reinforced by the
the question of whose perceptions, what their ranking being presented in a ‘league table’
perceptions are of, and where those perceptions format, with countries given a position within
derive from is important. that table – although, since the number of

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


CORRUPTION 371

countries included in each CPI varies, the perception-based measures in general, and in
position in the table can be influenced simply the case of the widely used World Bank indica-
by the how many countries are covered in tor ‘control of corruption’ the problems are very
any year (see Knack, 2006: 20). similar to those outlined above for the CPI (see
Although the CPI has been very important Thomas, 2007).
for research, there are other types of data, also
based primarily on perceptions, that have been
developed to some extent as a response to criti-
cisms of the CPI. For example, Transparency COMBATING CORRUPTION
International itself has published since 2003 the
annual Global Corruption Barometer, based on Since the increasing attention on corruption
a Gallup survey which seek to tap both into really began to take root in the 1990s, the issue
perceptions and lived experience of corruption, of how best to combat it has become a core
and the World Values Survey (approximately focus both of international organizations such
quinquennial since the early 1980s) includes as the World Bank, IMF, OECD, and various
questions on attitudes to corruption (e.g., Gatti non-governmental organizations, especially
et al., 2003). The World Bank’s widely used Transparency International. Although there
Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) are successful examples of combating corrup-
includes ‘control of corruption’ (identified as tion, notably Hong Kong and Singapore, over-
the exercise of public power for private gain) as all the results of the major efforts to fight
one of six elements (Kaufmann et al., 2003; corruption since the early 1990s have yielded
2006) and is also a perception-based measure rather meager results (see Bertucci and
constructed through weighted averages and to Armstrong, 2000; Cirtautas, 2001; DeWeaver,
some extent based on the same polls and sur- 2005; Doig and Marquette, 2004; Keuleers,
veys as the CPI (for examples, see Barbier 2005). Naturally, fighting corruption when it
et al., 2005; for a comprehensive critique of the has already become established at a high level,
WGI’s construct validity, see Thomas, 2007). and is also embedded within society, is not
The World Bank Institute’s diagnostic surveys easy to accomplish. Moreover, since many
provide in-depth surveys of countries by using anti-corruption campaigns take place in
both experience- and perception-based ques- tandem with efforts to fight poverty in coun-
tions, whilst the EBRD-World Bank Business tries where corruption is often very wide-
survey asks more than 10,000 firm managers to spread, we should perhaps not be surprised by
estimate unofficial payments to public officials poor results. Put simply, it is very difficult to
as a share of annual sales in firms ‘like theirs’ break the vicious circle of corruption, since
(although it is arguable that these types of ques- even if corruption is very obviously detrimen-
tions are not, as often claimed, indirectly expe- tal to economic and social development from
rience based, since they ask how respondents a macro perspective, from the micro perspec-
perceive their surroundings rather than ser- tive of an individual facing a given situation it
ving as an indirect way of reporting own may still be the least bad alternative (Grødeland
experience – see Andvig, 2005). Finally, the et al., 1988). Thus, although research has
International Crime Victim Survey asks established a clear relationship between
respondents if government officials had solic- democracy and economic development, it
ited or expected bribes for service during the has been argued that the relationship
last year (see Svensson, 2005). So, since the exists only when democracy has been an
mid-1990s, an increasing number of academic established feature for a very long time, or
studies have begun to use these alternative that it even disappears when controlling for
measures of corruption either instead of or other factors (see Lane and Ersson, 2000:
as a complement to the CPI. But many of 110–13; Sandholtz and Koetzle, 1998: 11;
these measures face the same problems of Treisman, 2000).

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


372 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

In developing mechanisms to combat purchase of influence and ‘state capture’ and


corruption, the World Bank (and the World their impact on reform measures (see Hellman
Bank Institute) as well as Transparency et al., 2000: 1; Hellman and Kaufmann, 2001;
International, itself founded by former World Kaufmann, 2003: 21–22; see also Heywood
Bank executives in 1993, have been very and Krastev, 2006: 19).
influential in formulating the dominant Whilst much of the fundamental understand-
approaches. The prevailing view has been to ing of what causes corruption and how to
focus on broad reforms, rather than to combat combat it remains in place, some changes have
concrete cases of corruption and corrupt indi- been introduced in response to the criticisms,
viduals (Krastev, 2003: 5). The aim has been and the dominant approaches to combating cor-
to limit opportunities for corruption and the ruption are moving away from directly targeting
incentives involved. In the words of the corruption towards broader and more inclusive
World Bank (2004). measures. Transparency International has deve-
loped the National Integrity System approach
Corruption prevails where there is ample opportu-
nity for corruption at little cost. Incentive structures which takes a holistic view of fighting corrup-
encourage corrupt behavior. Anticorruption strate- tion, pinpointing the pillars of integrity –
gies therefore aim at reducing the opportunities key institutions, laws and practices that
for corruption while increasing the expected contribute to integrity, transparency, and
cost, i.e. the risk of being caught and severely
accountability – to identify causes of corruption
punished.
and the effectiveness of anti-corruption measu-
This has meant that, when the World Bank res. It now dismisses the idea that a single ideal-
started to deal with corruption in the mid- type model can be implemented in any country,
1990s there was a strong focus on state dere- and it reflects a practitioner perspective on ear-
gulation, and on reducing opportunities for lier failures (Doig and McIvor, 2003: 318–19;
corruption. However, this approach has met Transparency International, 2006). The revised
with much criticism. First, it has been seen emphasis of the World Bank is illustrated by
by some as having a damaging impact on the Daniel Kaufmann, Director of Global Programs
quality of public service and social welfare at the World Bank Institute (WBI) who states,
in general.
A fallacy promoted by some in the field of anti-
Second, the state downsizing argument in corruption, and at times also by the international
general seems generally unsupported by empi- community, is that the best way to fight corrup-
rical examples of success. Third, the World tion is by fighting corruption – that is, by means
Bank has often been criticized for not giving of yet another anti-corruption campaign, the crea-
enough consideration to indirect means of tion of more anti-corruption commissions and
ethics agencies, and the incessant drafting of new
reducing corruption, such as strengthening laws, decrees, and codes of conduct. (Kaufmann,
public institutions and improving public educa- 2005: 88)
tion and awareness. Moreover, the principal-
agent framework that underpinned the approach So anti-corruption programmes are now
partly hinges on the notion of the principal as beginning to look beyond just public admin-
always non-corrupt and committed to reform, istration and financial management reform to
which is obviously problematic in many coun- broader structural relationships, for example
tries. However, this has to some extent been the internal organization of the political
taken into account by acknowledging the need system, state-firms relationship, and the rela-
for different policies in high-level and medium- tionship between the state and civil society
level corrupt countries (Andvig and Fjeldstad, (World Bank, 2004).
2001: 105–6; Shah and Schacter, 2004). Fourth, More specifically, ‘good governance’ has
the role of the private sector as a driver of cor- become the keyword in fighting corruption
ruption was insufficiently acknowledged, over- and in development literature more generally,
looking major forms of corruption such as the reflecting a high association between good

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


CORRUPTION 373

governance and key development outcomes management. In a speech delivered in


across countries (see Kaufmann, 2003: 17), 2001, the Vice-President of Europe and
although the direction is not always clear. Central Asia Region at the World Bank stated
International financial institutions and major that because of the power of vested interest to
donors are in turn increasingly making their resist change, ‘Promoting good governance
aid and loans conditional on the undertaking therefore, tends to require fundamental
of good governance reforms; recently, the changes in the nature of incentives that are
World Bank has cancelled or suspended closely intertwined with the existing
loans to India, Bangladesh, Argentina, and structure of political and economic power’
Kenya following evidence of corruption (Linn, 2001: 1).
(The Economist, 2006). The results of efforts to improve gover-
This emphasis on good governance, which nance are not conclusive, but overall it appe-
could be regarded as a result of a ‘post- ars that there has been stagnation or
Washington consensus’, suggests the need for deterioration in governance, as measured by
states with a stronger regulatory capacity as a the World Bank’s governance indicators
precondition for liberal markets, since deregu- (Kaufmann, 2003: 10). However, the same
lation in the absence of frameworks like com- research also shows that between 1996 and
petition policy may risk power transfer from 2004 some countries did succeed in impro-
state to private sector oligarchies. Such an ving governance in a rather short time, nota-
approach is based on a particular understand- bly in some of the transition countries that
ing of politics that can serve to ground the were promised membership of the European
economic reforms advocated by multilateral Union, whilst governance stagnated or dete-
agencies such as the World Bank (Jayasuriya, riorated in those that were not offered mem-
2002: 26–29). Governance, in general, is a bership (Kaufmann, 2005: 87–88).
broader concept than corruption but the two So the contrast between the period before
are increasingly treated as being directly and after 1995 is stark. For example, the World
linked – that is, environments characterized by Bank did not really engage in anti-corruption
bad governance offer more opportunities and projects before 1995 as they were regarded as
incentives for corruption (see IMF, 2003; interfering in the politics of recipient countries,
Kaufmann, 2003: 5). Essentially, governance which according to its articles of agreement is
is about the process of decision making and not allowed. This led to criticism of the Bank
the process by which decisions are implemen- for lending to corrupt regimes and regimes that
ted. It can operate at various levels such violated human rights (Marquette, 2004:
as national, local, and international, and – 413–14). The subsequent approach, with
depending on context and level – may include involvement in far-reaching anti-corruption
various actors such as the government, indus- programmes in recipient countries to improve
try, associations, NGOs, religious leaders, governance, is mainly defended against allega-
finance institutions, political parties, and so tions of political interference by the claim that
forth. Good governance is described as par- action is undertaken only at the request of the
ticipatory, accountable, transparent, respon- recipient country. However, help is only pro-
sive, consensus orientated, effective and vided with the proviso that programmes address
efficient, equitable, and inclusive and follows not just corruption, but broader governance
the rule of law (see UNDP, 1997). issues as well; one-off activities are discour-
In general, good governance has implied a aged. And earlier governance programmes did
very broad approach to tackling corruption, not pay as much attention to the regulatory
focusing on improving political account- capacity of the state and the creation of market
ability, strengthening civil society, competi- order (Jayasuriya, 2002: 29).
tiveness in the private sector, institutional The current approach naturally raises
restraints on power, and public sector other questions. What are the risks with

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


374 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

anti-corruption strategies which so overtly reach a point in which all politics can come to
champion western democratic ideals or at least be seen as corrupt.
liberal democratic values (see Hindess, 2005: At one level, that generates the risk of dis-
1396)? In relation to East European transitions illusionment and disaffection with the politi-
countries, Cirtautas (2001: 1) argues, ‘It is clear cal process; at another level, however, it may
that the heavily promoted, supposedly univer- inure citizens to corruption, making it ever
sal standards, derived mainly from idealized harder to generate a sense of outrage or scan-
Western standards, are meant to supersede dal over corrupt activity by politicians. There
completely local customs and practices.’ Even is evidence from recent elections in various
if good governance and anti-corruption are not parts of the world that citizens may ‘dis-
the same, in practical terms anti-corruption count’ corruption as a factor influencing their
programmes that fully address governance voting choice. Indeed, some of the more
make the two look the same. Moreover, the apocalyptic claims about the dangers of cor-
broad approach and range of criteria might also ruption may become counter-productive,
undermine the credibility of sincere reformers whilst the emphasis on ‘good governance’ as
if judged by standards that in many cases took the best means to combat corruption risks
decades to achieve elsewhere (see Linn, 2001). placing insurmountable hurdles in the way of
Credibility may be further undermined if anti- effective action. Ultimately, it is impossible
corruption approaches seem to reflect a double to eliminate corruption and any attempts to
standard, such as membership conditions do so are doomed to failure.
imposed by the EU, which the present mem-
bers could probably not meet themselves,
judging by recent profile corruption cases
since the early 1990s (see Cirtautas, 2001: 3; REFERENCES
EurActiv, 2003).
Alatas, S.H. (1990) Corruption: Its nature, causes
and consequences. Aldershot: Averbury.
Andersson, S. and Heywood, P.M. (forthcoming)
CONCLUSION ‘The politics of perception: Use and abuse of
Transparency International’s approach to
As has been shown, corruption remains a measuring corruption’, Political Studies, DOI:
10.1111/j.1467–9248.2008.00758.x.
deeply contested concept. The grounds of
Andvig, J.C. (2005) ‘A house of straw, sticks or
contention relate to its very definition, its bricks’? Some notes on corruption empirics.
impact, its extent, its causes and how to (NUPI Working Paper No. 678)
combat it. What is really striking is that cor- Andvig, J.C. and Fjeldstad, O.-H. (2001)
ruption has assumed such a prominent place in Corruption: a review of contemporary
the discourse on development, and is also seen research (Report R 7, Development Studies
as a serious threat to the functioning of estab- and Human Rights) Chr. Michelsen Institute,
lished democracies. One of the reasons for Norway.
that is that corruption has come to be seen as Barbier, E.B., Damania, R. and Leonard, D.
both cause and explanation of a host of politi- (2005) ‘Corruption, trade and resource con-
cal difficulties facing developed and develop- version’, Journal of Environmental Economics
and Management, 50 (2): 229–446.
ing societies. That it can serve both roles is a
Bertucci, G. and Yi Armstrong, E. (2000,
reflection of the conceptual confusion which September) Why anti-corruption crusades
surrounds the term. In practice, the word ‘cor- often fail to win lasting victories. The anti-
ruption’ is now so widely used that it risks corruption summit, Arlington, Virginia, USA.
losing any analytical purchase: as ever more Cartier-Bresson, J. (2000) ‘The economics of cor-
activities are defined as corrupt, so there is ruption’, OECD Observer. Retrieved 10 March,
ever more corruption to be discovered until we 2008, from http://www.oecdobserver.org/

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


CORRUPTION 375

news/fullstory.php/aid/239/Economics_of_ Hellman, J. and Kaufmann, D. (2001)


corruption.html ‘Confronting the challenge of state capture
Cirtautas, A.M. (2001) ‘Corruption and the in transition economies’, Finance and
new ethical infrastructure of capitalism’, East Development, 38 (3): 1–8.
European Constitutional Review, 10 (2/3): Hellman, J.S., Jones, G. and Kaufmann, D.
79–84. (2000) ‘Seize the state, seize the day’: State
della Porta, D. (2000) ‘Social capital, beliefs in capture, corruption, and influence in transi-
government, and political corruption’, in S.J. tion (Policy Research Working Paper 2444)
Pharr and R. Putnam (eds), Disaffected Washington DC: World Bank.
democracies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Hellman, J.S., Jones, G. and Kaufmann, D.
University Press, pp. 202–28. (2003) ‘Seize the state, seize the day: State
della Porta, D. and Vannucci, A. (1999) Corrupt capture and influence in transition econo-
exchanges. actors, resources and mecha- mies’, Journal of Comparative Economics,
nisms of political corruption. New York: 31 (4): 751–73.
Aldine de Gruyter. Heywood, P.M. and Krastev, I. (2006) ‘Political
DeWeaver, M. (2005) ‘Hidden motives in anti- scandals and corruption’, in P.M. Heywood, E.
corruption campaign’, Asia Times Online. Jones, M. Rhodes and U. Sedelmeier (eds),
Retrieved 10 March, 2008, from http:// Developments in European politics. Basingstoke:
www.atimes.com/atimes/China_Business/ Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 157–77.
GJ29Cb05.html Hindess, B. (2005) ‘Investigating international
Doig, A. and Marquette, H. (2004) ‘Corruption anti-corruption’, Third World Quarterly,
and democratisation: the litmus test of inter- 26 (8): 1389–98.
national donor agency intentions?’, Futures, Huntington, S. (1968) Political order in chang-
37: 199–213. ing societies. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Doig, A. and McIvor, S. (2003) ‘The national Press.
integrity system: Assessing corruption and IMF (2003) The IMF and good governance. A
reform’, Public Administration and factsheet – April 2003. Retrieved 10 March,
Development, 23: 317–32. 2008, from http://www.imf.org/external/np/
EurActiv (2003) Good governance and corrup- exr/facts/gov.htm
tion. Retrieved 10 March, 2008, from www. Jayasuriya, K. (2002) ‘Governance, post-
euractiv.com/en/corruption Washington consensus and the new anti-
Ferejohn, J.A. (1974) Pork-barrel politics: Rivers politics’, in T. Lindsey and H. Dick (eds),
and harbors legislation, 1947–1968. Corruption in Asia: Rethinking the governance
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. paradigm. Sydney: The Federation Press.
Gatti, R., Paternostro, S. and Rigolini, J. (2003) Johnston, M. (2005) Syndromes of corruption:
Individual attitudes toward corruption: Do Wealth, power, and democracy. Cambridge:
social effects matter? (World Bank Policy Cambridge University Press.
Research Working Paper No. 3122) Kaufmann, D. (2003) ‘Rethinking governance:
Washington DC: World Bank. Empirical lessons challenge orthodoxy’
Grødeland, A.B., Koshechkina, T.Y. and Miller, (Discussion Draft 11 March) Retrieved 10
W.L. (1988) ‘“Foolish to give and yet more March, 2008, from http://www.worldbank.
foolish not to take” – In-depth interviews org/wbi/governance/pdf/rethink_gov_stan-
with post-communist citizens on their every- ford.pdf
day use of bribes and contacts’, Europe-Asia Kaufmann, D. (2005) ‘Myths and realities of
Studies, 50 (4): 651–77. governance and corruption’ In World
Gupta, S., Davoodi, H. and Alonso-Terme, R. Economic Forum, The global competitiveness
(1998) Does corruption affect income ine- report 2005–2006: Policies underpinning
quality and poverty? (IMF Working Paper No. rising prosperity (Augusto Lopez–Claros,
76) Washington, DC: International Monetary director; Klaus Schwab, Michael E. Porter, co-
Fund. directors). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Heidenheimer, A.J. (1970) Political corruption: Kaufmann D., Kraay, A. and Mastruzzi, M.
Readings in comparative analysis. New (2003) Governance matters III: Governance
Brunswick, NJ: Transaction. indicators for 1996–2002 (World Bank Policy

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


376 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Research Working Paper 3106) Washington Linn, J.F. (2001) Good governance and transpar-
DC: World Bank. ency in the transition countries. Speech by the
Kaufmann D., Kraay, A. and Mastruzzi, M. Vice President, Europe and Central Asia Region,
(2006) Governance matters IV: Governance the World Bank; OCSE conference on Good
indicators for 1996–2005 (World Bank Paper) Governance and Transparency in the Transition
Washington DC: World Bank Countries, Prague.
Kenny, C. (2006) Measuring and reducing the Marquette, H. (2004) ‘The creeping politicisa-
impact of corruption in infrastructure (World tion of the World Bank: The case of corrup-
Bank Working Paper No. 4099). tion’, Political Studies, 52: 413–30.
Keuleers, P. (2005, September) Corruption, pov- Miller, W.L., Grodeland, A.B. and Koshechkina,
erty and development. Background paper T.Y. (2001) A culture of corruption: coping
(Plenary 2), ADB/OECD Anti-corruption initia- with government in post–communist Europe.
tive for Asia and the Pacific, 5th regional anti– Budapest: CEU Press.
corruption conference, Beijing, P. R. China. Olken, B.A. (2005) Monitoring corruption:
Klitgaard, R. (1988) Controlling corruption. Evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. (National Bureau of Economic Research
Knack, S. (2006) Measuring corruption in Working Paper No. W11753).
Eastern Europe and Central Asia: A critique Philip, M. (1997) ‘Defining political corruption’,
of the cross-country indicators (World Bank in P. Heywood (ed.), Political corruption.
Working Paper No. 3968). Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 20–46.
Kopecký, P. and Mair, P. (2006, April) Political Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999) Corruption and gov-
parties and patronage. Paper prepared for ernment: Causes, consequences and reforms.
ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops, Nicosia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Krastev, I. (2003) When ‘should’ does not imply Rose-Ackerman, S. (2006) ‘Introduction and
‘can’: the making of the Washington con- overview’, in S. Rose-Ackerman (ed.),
sensus on corruption. Retrieved March 10, International handbook on the economics
2008, from http://www.colbud.hu/honesty– of corruption. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
trust/krastev/pub01.PDF pp. xiv–xxxviii.
Kunicova, J. (2006) ‘Democratic institutions Sandholtz, W. and Koetzle, W. (1998) Accounting
and corruption: Incentives and constraints in for corruption: Economic structure, democratic
politics’, in S. Rose-Ackerman (ed.), norms, and trade (Center for the study of
International handbook on the economics of democracy, UC Irvine Research Papers).
corruption. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. Shah, A. and Schacter, M. (2004) ‘Combating
140–60. corruption: Look before you leap’, Finance
Lambsdorff, J.G. (2005) Consequences and and Development, 41 (3): 40–3.
causes of corruption – What do we know Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1993) ‘Corruption’,
from a cross–section of countries. Retrieved Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108:
10 March, 2008, from www.icgg.org/ 599–617.
corruption.research_contributions.html Søreide, T. (2006) Is it wrong to rank? A critical
Lambsdorff, J.G. (2006) ’Measuring assessment of corruption indices (Working
corruption – The validity and precision of paper 1) Chr. Michelsen Institute, Norway.
subjective indicators (CPI)’, in C. Sampford, Svensson, J. (2005) ‘Eight questions about cor-
A. Shacklock, C. Connors, and F. Galtung ruption’, Journal of Economic Perspectives,
(eds), Measuring corruption. Aldershot: 19 (3): 19–42.
Ashgate, pp. 81–99. Tanzi, V. (1998) ‘Corruption Around the World:
Lane, J.-E. and Ersson, S. (2000) The new insti- Causes, Consequences, Scope, and Cures’,
tutional politics: Performance and outcomes. Staff Papers – International Monetary Fund,
London: Routledge. 45 (4): 559–94.
Lijphart, A. (1999) Patterns of democracy: Tanzi, V. and Davoodi, H. (1997) Corruption,
Government forms and performance in public investment, and growth (IMF Working
thirty-six countries. New Haven, CT: Yale Paper No.139) Washington, DC: International
University Press. Monetary Fund.

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


CORRUPTION 377

The Economist (2006) ‘The World Bank. Just UNDP (1997) Governance for sustainable
saying no: Paul Wolfowitz takes on graft’, human development: A UNDP policy docu-
March, 378 (8467), 83. ment. United Nations Development
Thomas, M. (2007) What do the worldwide Programme. Retrieved 10 March, 2008,
governance indicators measure? SSRN. from http://mirror.undp.org/magnet/policy/
Retrieved 10 March, 2008, from http://ssrn. default.htm
com/abstract=1007527 Warburton, J. (2007) The social nature of cor-
Thompson J.B. (2000) Political scandal: Power rupt networks in the Queensland police
and visibility in the media age. Cambridge: force 1960–1987 (Unpublished PhD thesis,
Polity. University of Sydney).
Transparency International (2006) TI’s national Weber Abramo, C. (2007) How much do per-
integrity system approach. Retrieved 10 ceptions of corruption really tell us?
March, 2008, from www.transparency.org/ (Economics Discussion Papers 19) Retrieved
policy_and_research/nis 10 March, 2008, from www.economics-
Transparency International (2007) Persistent ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles
corruption in low income countries requires Weingast, B.R. (1995) ‘The economic role
global action. Retrieved 10 March, 2008, of political institutions: Market-preserving
from http://www.transparency.org/content/ federalism and economic development’,
download/23972/358236 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization,
Transparency International (2008) How do you 11 (1): 1–31.
define corruption?’ – frequently asked ques- Wintour P. and Leigh, D. (2005) ‘Bucking a
tions. Retrieved 10 March, 2008, from http:// legacy of corruption’, The Guardian, 3 June.
www.transparency.org/news_room/faq/cor- World Bank (1997) Helping countries combat
ruption_faq corruption. The role of the World Bank.
Treisman, D. (2000) ‘The causes of corruption: Washington, DC: World Bank.
A cross-national study’, Journal of Public World Bank (2000) Anti-corruption in transi-
Economics, 76: 399–457. tion. A contribution to the policy debate.
Tullock, G. (1987) ‘Rent seeking’, in J. Eatwell, Washington: The World Bank.
M. Milgate, P. Newman, R.H.I. Palgrave World Bank (2004) Multi-pronged strategies
(eds), The New Palgrave: A dictionary of eco- for combating corruption. Retrieved 10
nomics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. Vol. 4, March, 2008 from http://go.worldbank.
pp.147–9. org/0U9HJ3QWP0

9781412919760_Chap19.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM


9781412919760_Chap19.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:21:07 PM
PART III

New and Emerging Issues


in Comparative Politics

9781412919760_Chap20.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:21:58 PM


9781412919760_Chap20.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM
20
Electoral Authoritarianism
Andreas Schedler

INTRODUCTION an analytical overview over central concep-


tual, methodological, theoretical, and empiri-
The literature on comparative democratization cal themes the emerging literature on electoral
is turning into a misnomer. Instead of studying authoritarian regimes has been revolving
processes of democratic change it is more and around: the strategies of electoral control
more dedicated to the study of authoritarian authoritarian rulers have at their disposition;
regimes that prove resistant to the chants of the contested line of demarcation that sepa-
transition, even while going through consider- rates electoral authoritarian regimes from
able theatrical efforts to appear as democratic, electoral democracies; the challenge of con-
or at least as dutifully democratizing. A large structing valid and reliable databases for com-
number of political regimes in the contempo- parative research; the internal differentiation
rary world, ranging from Azerbaijan to of electoral authoritarian regimes; the consti-
Zimbabwe, from Russia to Singapore, from tutive role of elections in the inner workings
Belarus to Cameroon, from Egypt to Malaysia, of electoral autocracies; and the tentative
have established the institutional facades of empirical generalizations we have been gath-
democracy, including regular multiparty elec- ering regarding the dynamics and trajectories
tions for the chief executive, in order to conceal of these regimes.
(and reproduce) harsh realities of authoritarian
governance. In historical perspective, the
authoritarian use of elections is nothing new;
yet contemporary electoral authoritarian THE RISE OF ELECTORAL
regimes take the time-honored practice of elec- AUTHORITARIANISM
toral manipulation to new heights. In response,
an increasing number of comparative scholars, Since the Portuguese Revolution of the
both in the case study and the statistical tradi- Carnations in April 1974, the political drama
tion, have been turning their attention to that marked the official starting point of the
the study of these new forms of regimes that ‘third wave’ of global democratization
preach electoral democracy while they practice (Huntington, 1991), the number of democratic
electoral authoritarianism. regimes worldwide has roughly doubled.
After sketching the global rise of electoral Although different counts yield different pic-
authoritarianism, the present chapter provides tures, the overall trend is quite clear.

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:3 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


382 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

For instance, the annual Freedom House parties, while denied victory, are allowed to win
report on political rights and civil liberties in votes and seats), and minimally open (opposi-
the world identified 42 ‘free’ countries in the tion parties are not subject to massive repres-
year 1974. More than three decades later, in sion, although they may experience repressive
2006, it judged 90 countries to be ‘free’ (out of treatment in selective and intermittent ways).
a total of 123 countries it classified as ‘elec- Overall, however, electoral contests are subject
toral democracies’).1 Without doubt, these to state manipulation so severe, widespread,
numbers are impressive. The breadth and and systematic that they do not qualify as
resilience of the ‘third wave’ of democratic democratic.
expansion is without precedents in the history Today, electoral authoritarian regimes prob-
of the international system. However, today ably (depending on definition) comprise the
the flurry of optimism sparked by the fall of modal type of political regime in the develop-
the Berlin Wall in 1989 has subsided. Multiple ing world. An incomplete list of contemporary
experiences of state collapse and ethnic war, instances (as of early 2007) includes, in the
the terror unleashed inside advanced democra- post-soviet region, Armenia, Azerbaijan,
cies by the transnational crime syndicate Belarus, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Russia, and
Al Qaeda, and more recently, the externally Tajikistan; in Northern Africa and the Middle
induced civil war in Iraq explain part of the East, Algeria, Egypt, Tunisia, and Yemen; in
new skepticism. Persisting realities of authori- Sub-Saharan Africa, Burkina-Faso, Cameroon,
tarian rule explain the other part. Chad, Congo (Kinshasa), Ethiopia, Gabon,
On the one hand, a significant number of Gambia, Guinea, Mauritania, Tanzania, Togo,
old autocracies are surviving in different and Zambia; and in South and East Asia,
parts of the world, untouched by the stirs of Cambodia, Malaysia, and Singapore.
regime crisis. This is true, for example, for
the single-party regimes of Cuba, China,
Laos, North Korea, Vietnam, Eritrea, Libya,
and Syria, for the military regimes of Pakistan, STRATEGIES OF
Myanmar, and Sudan, and for the traditional AUTHORITARIAN CONTROL
monarchies of the Arab world. On the other
hand, numerous transition processes, even if A widespread, two-fold consensus exists in
they led to an initial opening crowned by free the scholarly community regarding the role
and fair elections (as in many parts of Sub- of elections for democratic governance. On
Saharan Africa and the former Soviet Union), the one hand, elections are essential ingredi-
ended up establishing electoral authoritarian ents of liberal democracy. No elections, no
regimes, that is, new forms of authorita- democracy. On the other hand, not any theat-
rianism behind electoral façades. rical performance does the trick. To qualify
Electoral authoritarian regimes play the as democratic, elections have to be competi-
game of multiparty elections, as they hold regu- tive, free, and fair. Thus, while recognizing
lar elections for the chief executive and a the centrality of elections, the current liberal-
national legislative assembly. Yet they violate democratic mainstream is sensitive to the
the liberal-democratic principles of freedom ‘fallacy of electoralism’ (Karl, 1995).
and fairness so profoundly and systematically Electoral institutions are commonly consid-
as to render elections instruments of authoritar- ered to form part of a minimal, procedural
ian rule, rather then ‘instruments of democracy’ definition of democracy. Yet, at close exami-
(Powell, 2000). Under electoral authoritarian nation, it turns out that they involve a demand-
rule, elections are broadly inclusive (they are ing set of normative conditions. In a previous
held under universal suffrage) as well as mini- essay (Schedler, 2002b), I stipulated that
mally pluralistic (opposition parties are permit- democratic elections are supposed to offer
ted to run), minimally competitive (opposition ‘effective choice of political authorities among

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:4 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


ELECTORAL AUTHORITARIANISM 383

a community of free and equal citizens’. In


Freedom of demand
order to meet this broad normative principle, I
further claimed, building on Robert Dahl Democratic elections presuppose the free
(1971), that elections must form a coherent formation of voter preferences. Citizens who
‘chain of democratic choice.’ They must vote on the basis of induced preferences are
comply with seven more specific normative no less constrained than those choosing from
demands that mold and restrain the entire a manipulated set of alternatives. Unless par-
electoral process, from its initial design to its ties and candidates enjoy free and fair access
final outcomes. Authoritarian rulers may break to the public space, the will of the people as
the chain at any link and thus deprive an expressed at the ballot box will mirror their
election of its democratic character. structurally induced ignorance. To prevent
voters from acquiring fair knowledge about
available choices, incumbent parties may
Access to power strive to prevent opposition forces from dis-
seminating their campaign messages. They
Political elections are exercises of power. may try to shut them out of the public space
Voters do not take part in beauty contests or by either denying them freedom of speech,
market surveys but in the binding selection of assembly, and movement (repression) or
the ‘most powerful collective decision by denying them reasonable access to media
makers’ (Huntington, 1991: 7) in the political and campaign resources (unfairness).
system. Authoritarian rulers may preempt
potential threats emanating from popular
elections by circumscribing either the scope
Universal suffrage
or the jurisdiction of elective office. They
may allow voters to fill subordinate positions In the contemporary world, democracy
of public authority, while keeping the ‘high demands universal suffrage. The modern
center’ of power shut off from electoral pres- demos includes everybody, except those who
sures (reserved positions). Alternatively, they are assumed to lack minimal capacities of
may keep elected officials from acquiring rational decision-making (children and the
real power by removing crucial policy areas mentally ill). Since the invention of repre-
from their jurisdiction (reserved domains). sentative governance, political actors have
been tempted to control electoral outcomes
by controlling the composition of the elector-
Freedom of supply ate, either by legal means (formal disenfran-
chisement) or bureaucratic practice (informal
The notion of electing involves the availabil- disenfranchisement).
ity of alternatives. Elections without choice
(Hermet et al., 1978) do not qualify as demo-
cratic, nor do elections with choice confined The free expression
to a narrow menu of state licensed options.
of preferences
Most transitional regimes do not count with
anything resembling a consolidated party Once citizens have formed their preferences
system. Authoritarian rulers may take oppor- freely, they must be able to express them freely.
tunity of such fluid situations by manipulat- The secrecy of the voting is designed to shield
ing the number and nature of nascent them from undue outside pressures. It pretends
opposition actors. They may restrict the free to insulate voters from the distorting force of
formation of electoral alternatives by exclud- violence, money, and social control. A regime
ing opposition parties, fragmenting them, or that unleashes electoral competition and public
controlling them from within.2 debate may wish to put voters on chains the

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:5 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


384 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

moment they express their preferences at the The idea of a multifaceted menu of elec-
polls. Violence (voter intimidation) and money toral manipulation has found broad accept-
(vote buying) are common means to prevent ance in the scholarly community. Numerous
citizens from voting their genuine preferences. definitions of democracy more broadly,
as well as numerous treatments of the
democratic quality of elections more specifi-
The fair aggregation cally, have been conceiving the minima mor-
alia of liberal democracy in similar,
of preferences
multi-dimensional ways.3 Scholarly disa-
In democracy, once citizens have given free greements concern less the normative foun-
expression to their will at the polls, compe- dations of democratic elections than the
tent and neutral election management must methodological possibility of clearing the
have their votes weighed equally and counted ‘gray zone’ (Carothers, 2002) of ‘ambiguous
honestly. Undemocratic distortions may regimes’ (Diamond, 2002) and drawing sharp
result either from ‘redistributive’ practices qualitative distinctions between democratic
(vote rigging) or from ‘redistributive’ rules of and authoritarian elections.
aggregation (self-serving institutions).

ESSENTIALLY CONTESTED
The decisiveness of results BOUNDARIES
As has been mentioned above, elections are
only meaningful exercises of democratic Tracing the boundary between democratic
governance when they endow elected offi- and authoritarian elections is an essentially
cials with real power. Even if elections are contested enterprise. Compelling political
decisive ex ante, with elected representatives and methodological reasons conspire against
enjoying full constitutional authority, they consensual boundary settlements. Naturally,
may fail to be decisive ex post. They may extreme cases of repression and electoral
turn inconsequential, too, when undemo- manipulation are easy to assess. Few observ-
cratic actors tie the hands of elected officials ers would doubt, for instance, that contempo-
(authoritarian tutelage) or terminate the elec- rary Belarus, Egypt, and Zimbabwe pertain
toral regime by either preventing them from to the family of authoritarian regimes. The
taking office or removing them from their whole point of electoral authoritarianism,
positions (authoritarian abortion). however, is to escape the category of easy
cases. While all authoritarian regimes pos-
Compliance with democratic minimum sess certain theatrical qualities, public simu-
norms is not, of course, a matter of reaching lation defines the very nature of electoral
unattainable democratic ideals. All existing authoritarian regimes. Electoral autocracies
democracies deviate from ideal institutions are stage performances by definition. They
and practices in manifold ways. No democ- practice ‘democracy as deception’ (Joseph,
racy is fully sovereign, no electoral system 1998: 59), displaying ‘the trappings but not
entirely neutral, no party system completely the substance of effective democratic partici-
open, no electoral campaign absolutely fair pation’ (Marshall and Jaggers, 2002: 12).
(as democracy involves normative tensions For impartial efforts to assess the democratic
and trade-offs, there is no such thing as an (or authoritarian) quality of an election, the
unequivocal democratic optimum anyway). purposeful democratic masquerade of elec-
Only if democratic norm violations are toral autocracies poses two intricate meth-
profound and systematic do they cancel the odological problems: factual opacity and
democratic quality of an electoral regime. normative ambiguity.

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:6 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


ELECTORAL AUTHORITARIANISM 385

Obscure facts a pervasive lack of normative clarity. Less


repressive than closed regimes, while less open
Closed dictatorships want everyone to know than democratic systems, electoral autocracies
who is in charge. They want to crush and con- put our judgment to test. They force us to reach
trol dissidence even before it arises. Carried inferences on the basis of pressing factual
out in broad daylight, their repression is reme- uncertainties; to weight and balance contradic-
dial as much as preventive. They want every- tory features of the political system; and to
body to see how much it costs rising up make sense of a conflicting chorus of voices
against the system. Electoral autocracies are trying to make sense of these uncertainties and
different. Rather than publicizing their repres- ambiguities. If we add the fact that people may
sive capacities, they aspire to practice authori- differ in their concrete definitions of demo-
tarianism by stealth. They strive to control and cratic minimum standards, we can understand
distort opposition actors in indirect, oblique why the frontier between electoral democracy
ways, with no one noticing. The very notion of and electoral authoritarianism represents essen-
electoral manipulation that is central for the tially contested terrain.
idea of electoral authoritarianism hints at
backstage activities hidden from the public Passionate debates over the true nature of
eye. To a large extent, electoral manipulation the system form an intrinsic element of elec-
is an undercover activity. Some things we can toral authoritarian regimes. But it is not just
see, such as the enactment of discriminatory citizens and opposition parties who struggle
election laws, the repression of protest with the structural ambiguities of manipulated
marches, or the exclusion of candidates from elections. International election observers,
the ballot by administrative fiat. Such manipu- too, have been wrestling with the empirical
lative efforts take place in broad daylight, and normative complexities involved in evalu-
mobilize agents of the central state, and invoke ating flawed elections. Election monitoring
the language of legality and public reason for agencies have become more and more meth-
their justification. By contrast, many other odologically sophisticated (as well as more
authoritarian strategies of electoral control, and more demanding) in their assessments of
such as the alteration of electoral lists, the political elections. They have broadened their
purchase and intimidation of voters, or the presence and perspective much beyond elec-
falsification of ballots on election day, consti- tion day; they have developed more precise
tute more decentralized activities that involve and cautious vocabulary; they have written
myriads of public and private agents trying to elaborate checklists, manuals, and codes of
do their job without leaving public traces. conduct; and they have made increasing use of
statistical techniques of sampling, data
processing, and inference. Overall, they have
accepted the methodological challenge of
Normative ambiguities
catching up with electoral authoritarian rulers
Electoral autocracies are normatively ambigu- who incessantly innovate their toolset of
ous by design. They open up spaces of political authoritarian strategies.5
contestation at the same time they strive to Given the blurred and controversial nature
contain them through a broad variety of author- of the boundaries between electoral democra-
itarian measures – the more subtle, selective, cies and electoral authoritarian regimes, many
and subterranean, the better. Preaching the authors have been treating the substandard
virtues of modern democracy, and even estab- electoral regimes that inhabit the contempo-
lishing the formal institutions of modern rary world as genuine mid-points between
democracy, while practicing the ancient democracy and authoritarianism. As these
art of manipulation, they are purposefully regimes combine democratic and authoritar-
contradictory creatures.4 The intended result is ian features, some scholars locate them at the

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:7 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


386 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

very center of the conceptual spectrum and as Besides, their measurement scales do not
a result consider them to be neither demo- offer obvious cutting points for distinguish-
cratic nor authoritarian. Concepts such as ing democratic from authoritarian regimes.
‘hybrid regimes’ (Diamond, 2002), ‘semi- Moreover, if much of electoral manipula-
democracy’ (Smith, 2005), ‘semi-authoritari- tion is not susceptible to public observation,
anism’ (Ottaway, 2003), ‘semi-dictatorship’ how can we ever aspire to classify either his-
(Brooker, 2000: 252), and ‘the gray zone’ toric or contemporary electoral authoritarian
(Carothers, 2002) express the idea of genu- regimes in valid and reliable ways? Some
inely ‘mixed regimes’ situated in the messy authors are convinced that passing judgment
middle ground between the poles of democ- on the authoritarian quality of elections is
racy and dictatorship. an impossible mission, as attempts ‘to assess
The notion of electoral authoritarianism, by the degree of repression, intimidation, or
contrast, classifies these regimes as instances fraud … cannot be made in a reliable way’
of non-democratic governance, and the same (Przeworski et al., 2000: 24). They propose
is true for akin concepts, such as ‘pseudo- that we should instead rely on official elec-
democracy’ (Diamond et al., 1995: 8), ‘dis- tion results, in particular the absence of alter-
guised dictatorship’ (Brooker, 2000: 228), and nation in power, a crucial non-event that may
‘competitive authoritarianism’ (Levitsky and serve as objective indicator of authoritarian
Way, 2002). They all assume that the electoral conditions.6
regimes in question have crossed the contested Nevertheless, over the past years, a growing
threshold of democratic minima, despite their number of comparative scholars have been
best efforts at maintaining the ambiguity of accepting the challenge of constructing
democratic facades. large-N datasets that do try to capture one of
the core strategies of electoral control: elec-
toral fraud. Most of them have been tracing
reports on election fraud in international news
THE CONSTRUCTION OF sources and observer reports. To date, the
COMPARATIVE DATA most prominent measure of fraud has been a
variable in the World Bank Database on
If country experts look at individual regimes, Political Institutions (DPI). The DPI database
their fine-grained local knowledge may includes a categorical measure that responds
enable them to ascertain with reasonable to the question of whether ‘vote fraud or can-
confidence whether the regime under inspec- didate intimidation were serious enough to
tion complies, or fails to comply, with certain affect the outcome of elections.’ Even if a
democratic standards. However, if we ‘go growing number of comparative studies have
comparative’ and wish to study medium to been using this variable (e.g., Hyde and
large numbers of electoral regimes, measure- Beaulieu, forthcoming; Simpser, 2004), it suf-
ment problems turn daunting. Leading fers from significant conceptual, methodologi-
datasets in comparative politics are not spe- cal, and empirical flaws. Conceptually, it fuses
cifically designed to identify electoral autoc- two dimensions that should better be kept
racies. The two most commonly used apart (electoral fraud and candidate intimida-
historical time series of political regimes in tion). Methodologically, it violates basic
the world, the Polity dataset and the annual requirements of transparency, as it does not
Freedom House reports on civil liberties and reveal its definitions nor its operational deci-
political rights, do contain partial assess- sions, coding rules, coding procedures, or
ments of the democratic quality of national sources.7
elections. Yet both are omnibus measures that Empirically, the DPI variable contains
include several additional dimensions that numerous entries that raise serious doubts
bear little relation with the electoral arena. about their validity. It registers several

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:8 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


ELECTORAL AUTHORITARIANISM 387

instances of incisive fraud or intimidation Bratton (1998) to second elections. In a more


that do not coincide with election dates. Most comprehensive effort, Staffan Lindberg
countries maintain their scores between elec- (2006b) traces the democratic quality of both
tions. Yet, in some cases, scores change even presidential and legislative elections in Sub-
though no national-level elections were held Saharan Africa from 1989 through 2004.
(as in Colombia in 1999). In others, registries I myself have been constructing a dataset on
of fraud and intimidation start one year after electoral fraud in electoral autocracies world-
first elections took place (as in Nicaragua, wide, from 1980 to 2002 (see Schedler,
Ghana, Kenya, and Senegal). The database 2006b). Overall, these parallel and partially
also contains numerous false positives, that overlapping efforts are setting the bases for
is, registries of decisive fraud and intimida- empirical examinations of electoral authori-
tion in cases that seemed fundamentally tarian regimes that have been unavailable
clean (like in Panama after 1990, Nicaragua until very recently.
after 1984, and Ghana in 1996). False nega-
tives are frequent, too, that is, registries of
electoral integrity in cases that seemed heav-
ily contaminated by fraud and/or intimida- THE CONSTITUTIVE
tion. Glaring examples are Mexico in 1988, POWER OF ELECTIONS
Peru in 2000, communist Poland and
Romania, the Soviet Union, Iran, Iraq, Syria, Electoral authoritarian regimes set up the
Ghana, and Kenya in 1992, Zimbabwe in the whole institutional landscape of representa-
1990s, Indonesia, Pakistan, and Singapore. tive democracy. They establish constitutions,
All in all, the DPI data on fraud and elections, parliaments, courts, local govern-
intimidation appear ill-conceived, methodo- ments, subnational legislatures, and even
logically opaque, and inconsistent with agencies of accountability. They also permit
known facts. They are a sharp reminder of private media, interest groups, and civic
the fact that in the measurement of behavio- associations. While none of these institutions
ral variables as opaque and controversial as are meant to constitute countervailing powers,
the commission of electoral fraud, cheap all of them represent potential sites of dissi-
shortcuts to high-quality data do not exist. dence and conflict. Without ignoring these
Taking the quick and easy way in such com- multiple sites of contestation, the notion of
plex fields of data construction may well lead electoral authoritarianism privileges one of
right into the desert of measures drained of them – the electoral arena. It assumes elec-
validity as well as reliability. tions to constitute the central arena of strug-
Other recently developed databases on the gle (see also Levitsky and Way, 2002: 54).8
incidence of electoral fraud are of better Designating elections as the defining feature
quality, although limited in geographic, tem- of a distinct category of non-democratic regimes
poral, and substantive coverage. Jonathan makes sense only if they are more than mere
Hartlyn, Jennifer McCoy, and Thomas adornments of authoritarian rule. Talking about
Mustillo (2008) assess the integrity of presi- electoral authoritarianism involves the claim
dential elections in Latin America since the that elections matter, and matter a lot, even in
1990s. Daniela Donno (2006) works with an contexts of authoritarian manipulation. Still
original dataset on ‘electoral manipulation’ stronger, it involves the claim that it is the
(broadly conceived) in Eastern Europe, Latin intrinsic ‘power of elections’ (Di Palma, 1993:
America, and the Caribbean from 1990 85), more than anything else, that drives the
through 2004. Michael Bratton and Nicolas dynamic of stability and change in such regimes.
van de Walle (1997) offer dichotomous eval- In electoral authoritarian regimes, if they are to
uations of first or ‘founding’ presidential deserve their name, elections are more than
elections in Sub-Saharan Africa, extended by rituals of acclamation. They are constitutive of

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:9 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


388 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

the political game. Even if they are marred regimes establish the primacy of democratic
by repression, discrimination, exclusion, or legitimation. They may feed themselves from
fraud, they are constitutive of the playing field, various ideological sources of legitimacy:
the rules, the actors, their resources, and their revolutionary (the creation of a new society),
available strategies. transcendental (divine inspiration), tradi-
While electoral authoritarian regimes estab- tional (hereditary succession), communitar-
lish multiparty elections as the official route of ian (nation building, anti-imperialism, ethnic
access to state power, they do not, as a matter of mobilization), charismatic (magical leader-
course, establish electoral competition as ‘the ship), or substantive (material welfare, public
only game in town.’ At the same time they set integrity, law and order, external security). In
up the electoral game (competition for votes), the last instance, however, popular consent
they introduce the meta-game of institutional carries the day. Political elections recognize
change (struggle over rules). In addition to subjects as citizens. They endow them with
seeking popular support, ruling parties seek ‘the ultimate controlling power’ (Mill, 1991:
to control the substantive outcomes of elec- 97) over the occupation of the summit of the
toral competition (electoral manipulation), state. By establishing multiparty elections for
while opposition parties seek to dismantle non- highest office, electoral authoritarian regimes
democratic restrictions that choke their struggle institute the principle of popular consent,
for votes (electoral reform). Authoritarian elec- even as they subvert it in practice.
tions are no conventional ‘games’ in which The institutional concessions electoral
players compete within a given institutional authoritarian regimes make to the principle of
framework, known, accepted, and respected by popular sovereignty endow citizens with nor-
all. They are fluid, adaptive, contested games mative as well as institutional resources. Most
whose basic rules players try to redefine as they importantly, elections open up avenues of col-
play the game itself. In the language proposed lective protest. They provide ‘focal points’ that
by George Tsebelis, they form ‘nested games’ may create convergent social expectations and
in which strategic interaction within rules goes thus allow citizens to overcome problems of
hand in hand with strategic competition over strategic coordination. Elections constitute
rules (Tsebelis, 1990). Given formal institu- citizens as individual carriers of political roles,
tions do not represent stable equilibria, but but they also enable them to turn into collec-
temporary truces. If the substantive outcomes tive actors, be it at the polls or on the streets.
of the game change, or if its underlying correla- Authoritarian elections that do not open
tions of force change, actors will strive to alter genuine venues for peaceful alternation in
its basic rules – either to prevent or to promote power may nevertheless allow discontent to
more democratic outcomes. The partisan strug- crystallize into ‘electoral revolutions.’9
gle for votes is embedded in a partisan struggle
over the fundamental conditions of voting (see
also Schedler, 2002a). As authoritarian elec- Opposition parties
tions constitute the game of electoral competi-
tion, perpetually put into question by the By admitting multiparty competition for
meta-game of manipulation and reform, positions of state power, electoral autocracies
they are also constitutive of its component legitimate the principle of political opposi-
parts, in particular, its lead actors and their tion. They may still try to shape the field of
available strategies. opposition actors to their own liking. Some
regimes create official opposition parties and
even assign convenient ideological positions
Citizens to them, as in Egypt under Anwar Sadat and
Senegal under Léopold Senghor. Others
By opening the peaks of state power to mul- exclude uncomfortable opposition parties
tiparty elections, electoral authoritarian and candidates at their convenience, which is

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:10 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


ELECTORAL AUTHORITARIANISM 389

a standard operating procedure in the post- and official results are published, they have
soviet regimes of Eurasia. Yet they still have to decide whether to swallow the outcome or
to live with opposition forces that enjoy at to take their complaints to the media, the
least minimal degrees of autonomy. By the courts, the streets, or the international arena
simple fact of instituting multiparty politics, (acceptance versus protest).10
they abandon ideologies of collective har-
mony, accept the existence of societal cleav-
ages, and give up their monopolistic hold Ruling parties
on the definition of the common good.
Subjecting the opposition to repressive treat- Electoral authoritarian regimes may display
ment does not affect its basic legitimacy ‘sultanistic tendencies,’ with patrimonial
embodied in the formal institution of com- rulers ratifying themselves in power through
petitive elections. Quite to the contrary, once periodic multiparty elections. The organiza-
regimes recognize the principle of pluralism, tional demands of authoritarian elections,
silencing dissidence is likely to turn counter- however, limit the degree of personalism they
productive; it is likely to augment the status of can afford. Rulers who wish to govern
opposition forces, rather than diminishing it. through controlled multiparty elections need
As electoral authoritarian regimes are sys- a party (as well as a subsidiary state) to
tems in which opposition parties (are sup- mobilize voters, and they need a state (as
posed to) lose elections, electoral contests well as a subsidiary party) to control elec-
are profoundly ambiguous affairs for opposi- tions.11 Electoral authoritarian regimes do
tion parties. To the extent that they serve to not rest upon single parties, but on parties
legitimate the system, demonstrate the power they rest.
and popularity of the ruling party as well as For the ruling party, elections are ambivalent
the weakness of its opponents, elections tend tools, as they are for opposition parties. They
to demoralize and demobilize opposition create opportunities for distributing patronage,
forces. To the extent that they allow opposi- settling disputes, and reinforcing the ruling
tion forces to get stronger and to demonstrate coalition, but they also mobilize threats of dis-
that the emperor is naked, that his cling on sidence and scission. Like their opponents in
power is based on manipulation rather than the opposition camp, rulers have to take some
popular consent, elections tend to reinvigor- key decisions regarding their strategic behavior
ate opposition parties. In any case, authori- in the electoral arena. Most importantly, they
tarian elections do not provide any of the have to decide how to mix electoral manipula-
normative reasons for accepting defeat losers tion and electoral persuasion in order to keep
have under democratic conditions. They fail winning electoral contests. To what extent
to display the procedural fairness and sub- should they rely on authoritarian controls, and
stantive uncertainty that makes democratic which strategies are they to pick from the vari-
elections normatively acceptable, and they egated menu of electoral manipulation? And to
fail to offer the prospects of a government what extent should they rely on the persuasion
pro tempore losers may hope to replace after of voters, and which strategies are they to
the next round of elections. What remains is choose from the variegated menu of electoral
a calculus of protest in which opposition mobilization?12
actors have to weigh the uncertain pros and
cons of different strategic options both within
and outside the electoral arena. Most impor-
tantly, as authoritarian rulers convoke elec- TRAJECTORIES OF ELECTORAL
tions, opposition forces have to decide AUTHORITARIANISM
whether to enter the game of unfree competi-
tion or to boo from the fences (participation Authoritarian elections are creative institu-
versus boycott). Once the polls have closed tions insofar as they constitute these three

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:11 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


390 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

classes of actors (citizens, opposition, and 2005: 109), we have been learning some
ruling parties) and their respective bundles of things about the sources and consequences of
core strategies. They are not determinative, opposition behavior. To begin with, when do
however, insofar as the actual outcomes of opposition parties boycott an election? As it
the conflictive interaction between the three seems, they do so if the election is subject to
groups are open. The ‘nested game’ of severe manipulation, if they are strong
authoritarian elections may facilitate gradual enough to miss a turn in the electoral game,
processes of ‘democratization by elections,’ and if they are few enough to make an impact
as in Senegal or Mexico. It may lead to even if other opposition forces do not join
democracy through the sudden collapse of them (Beaulieu, 2006; Lindberg, 2006a;
authoritarianism, as in Peru, Serbia, and Pripstein, 2005). Do election boycotts aid the
Ukraine. It may provoke an authoritarian process of democratization? They seem to
regression, with a breakdown of the electoral augment the likelihood of posterior electoral
cycle through military intervention, as in reform, especially if all relevant opposition
Azerbaijan in 1993 and Côte d’Ivoire in parties band together. They also appear to be
1999. Too, it may lead to extended periods of effective in capturing the attention of interna-
static warfare in which authoritarian incum- tional election observers. At the same time,
bents prevail over opposition parties that they seem to strengthen ruling parties and to
neither succeed in gaining terrain nor accede prolong the lifespan of the authoritarian
to disband and abandon the unequal battle. regime (Beaulieu, 2006; Lindberg, 2006a;
Under which conditions do authoritarian Pripstein, 2005).
elections fulfill a ‘stabilizing’ role (Martin, When do opposition parties take to the
1978: 120) and when do they act as ‘subver- streets to protest the outcome of an election?
sive’ forces (Schedler, 2002a)? How do hegem- Again, the unfairness of the elections seems to
onic regimes differ in their dynamics from be close to a necessary condition. Opposition
competitive authoritarian regimes? Under actors acquiesce to many manipulated elec-
which conditions do government and opposi- tions, and they protest some that look clean to
tion forces succeed in maintaining their coher- outside observers. Yet, they almost invariably
ence and act as unitary actors? Under which protest if ruling parties carry out incisive
conditions do rulers and opposition parties fraud. When they do engage in frivolous pro-
adopt which kind of strategies and to what test, they tend to desist within a couple of
effect? When are they successful and when do weeks (Hartlyn et al., 2008; Lindberg, 2006a;
they fail? How do their strategic decisions in Schedler, 2006b). Are opposition protests
the conflictive game of authoritarian elections effective means of pushing an authoritarian
shape their correlations of strength? To what regime on a democratizing path? Although
extent do the nature of actors and their choices opposition protest tends to trigger ‘liberalizing
respond to the endogenous dynamics of unfree outcomes’ (Howard and Roessler, 2006), it
competition and to what extent are they molded may well be that opposition acquiescence
by structural conditions, institutional factors, constitutes a more effective vehicle of incre-
and external actors? mental democratization (Lindberg, 2006b).
The emerging comparative literature on When do opposition protests crystallize into
electoral authoritarian regimes is beginning an ‘electoral revolution’ that topples the
to provide tentative empirical answers to authoritarian incumbent? Well, if the prevail-
several of these questions (as political regimes ing correlation of strength between civil soci-
are evolving creatures whose lead actors ety and the state permits the effective
adapt and learn, there will never be definitive mobilization of the former as well as the effec-
answers to any of them). For instance, despite tive paralysis of the latter, an electoral rebel-
the continuing ‘paucity of comparative litera- lion may well happen and happen to be
ture on opposition strategies’ (Posusney, successful (McFaul, 2005).

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:12 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


ELECTORAL AUTHORITARIANISM 391

Naturally, even if our areas of ignorance 8. The present section draws on Schedler (2006a:
are shrinking step by step, the concluding 12–15).
9. On the role of stolen elections in coordinating
balance of an emerging field of inquiry citizens and triggering protest movements, see
cannot be otherwise than the sober recogni- Thompson and Kuntz (2004). On electoral revolu-
tion that much comparative research still tions, see McFaul (2005).
needs to accomplished. Meanwhile, both 10. See also Schedler (2002a; 2006c). In his case
authoritarian rulers and their democratic study of Indonesia under Suharto, Edward Aspinall
(2005) offers an insightful analysis of how the struc-
opponents will continue to play their com- tural ambiguity of a regime produces structurally
plex game of strategic conflict, always open ambiguous opposition forces. In a similar vein, Ellen
to learn and to ruin our incipient insights. Lust-Okar (2005) shows how differential treatment
of opposition forces by the electoral monarchies
of Morocco and Jordan induces divisions within
the opposition camp (between included and
excluded actors).
NOTES 11. As Richard Snyder states succinctly, ‘in the
absence of a state, there is no regime’ (2006: 224).
1. The author counts on the basis of the Freedom On the organizational demands of electoral fraud,
House 1975 and 2007 Annual Report on Political see Way (2006).
Rights and Civil Liberties (www.freedomhouse.org). 12. Most empirical analyses of electoral authoritar-
As the number of nation states augmented, in particu- ian regimes stress the pursuit of electoral manipula-
lar with the disintegration of the Soviet Empire in tion over efforts at electoral mobilization. Notable
1991, the proportions are somewhat less impressive. exceptions are Greene (2002), Langston and
2. The ‘virtual politics’ practiced in electoral Morgenstern (2007), and Magaloni (2006).
authoritarian Russia and Ukraine (and lucidly
described by Wilson, 2005) constitute breathtaking
instances of comprehensive and profound manipula-
tion of electoral realities, including the invention and
simulation of opposition parties. REFERENCES
3. Illustrative syntheses of manifold strategies
of authoritarian manipulation carried out in
Aspinall, E. (2005) Opposing Suharto:
different contexts can be found, for example, in Case
(2006), Conaghan (2005), Daniel and Southall Compromise, resistance, and regime change
(1999: 38–47), Ottaway (2003: 137–160), Pripstein in Indonesia. Stanford University Press:
(2005: 94–108), Schedler (2002b). Schaffer (2007) Stanford.
contains empirical analyses of one specific strategy, Beaulieu, E. (2006) Protesting the contest:
the purchase of votes, situated within the larger Election boycotts around the world, 1990–
menu of manipulation. 2002. (PhD Dissertation, San Diego, University
4. I borrow the notion of manipulation as art-form of California).
from Riker (1986), even if his discussion focuses on Bjornlund, E.C. (2004) Beyond free and
the manipulation of voting processes in democratic
fair: Monitoring elections and building
contexts.
democracy. Washington, DC: Woodrow
5. Bjornlund (2004) offers a fine overview of
the evolution of international election monitoring. Wilson Center Press.
Munck (2006) gives testimony to the efforts by elec- Bratton, M. (1998) ‘Second elections in Africa’,
tion monitors to tap academic knowledge about Journal of Democracy, 9 (3): 51–66.
empirical research for their practical purposes. Elklit Bratton, M. and van de Walle, N. (1997)
and Reynolds (2005) translate the common checklist Democratic experiments in Africa:
approach into a framework for empirical research. Regime transitions in comparative perspec-
Kelly (2006) provides a literature review on the rele- tive. Cambridge: Cambridge University
vance of international election observation and lays Press.
out the contours of an ambitious research program
Brooker, P. (2000) Non-democratic regimes:
on international election monitoring.
Theory, government, and politics. New York:
6. For a more extensive discussion of the ‘alterna-
tion rule,’ see Schedler (2006a: 10). St. Martin’s Press.
7. For critical discussions of these datasets, see Carothers, T. (2002) ‘The end of the transition
Munck and Verkuilen (2002), Schedler (2006a: paradigm’, Journal of Democracy, 13 (1):
10–12; 2006b: 15–16). 5–21.

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:13 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


392 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Case, W. (2006) ‘Manipulative skills: How do authoritarian regimes’, Journal of Politics, 50


rulers control the electoral arena?’, in (2): 365–81.
A. Schedler (ed.), Electoral authoritarianism: Huntington, S.P. (1991) The third wave:
The dynamics of unfree competition. Boulder: Democratization in the late twentieth cen-
Lynne Rienner Publishers. pp. 95–112. tury. Norman and London: University of
Conaghan, C.M. (2005) Fujimori’s Peru: Oklahoma Press.
Deception in the public sphere. Pittsburgh: Hyde, S.D. and Beaulieu, E. (forthcoming)
University of Pittsburgh Press. ‘In the Shadow of Democracy Promotion:
Dahl, R. (1971) Polarchy. Hew Haven: Yale Strategic Manipulation, International
University Press. Observers, and Election Boycotts’, Comparative
Daniel, J. and Southall, R. (1999) ‘Electoral cor- Political Studies.
ruption and manipulation in Africa’, in Joseph, R. (1998) ‘Is Ethiopia democratic?
J. Daniel, R. Southall and M. Szeftel (eds), Oldspeak vs. newspeak’, Journal of
Voting for democracy: Watershed elections Democracy, 9 (4): 55–61.
in contemporary Anglophone Africa. Karl, T. L. (1995) ‘The hybrid regimes of Central
Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 37–56. America’, Journal of Democracy, 6 (3):
Diamond, L. (2002) ‘Elections without democ- 72–87.
racy: Thinking about hybrid regimes’, Journal Kelly, J. (2006) ‘New wine in old wineskins:
of Democracy, 13 (2): 21–35. Promoting political reforms through the new
Diamond, L., Linz, J.J., and Lipset, S.M. (1995) European Neighborhood policy’, Journal of
‘Introduction: What makes for democracy?’, Common Market Studies, 44 (1): 29–55.
in L. Diamond, J.J. Linz, and S.M. Lipset Langston, J. and Morgenstern, S. (2007)
(eds), Politics in developing countries: Campaigning in an electoral authori-
Comparing experiences with democracy. tarian regime: The case of Mexico.
Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers, Unpublished typescript. Mexico City and
pp. 1–66. Pittsburgh: CIDE and University of
Di Palma, G. (1993) To craft democracies: An Pittsburgh.
essay on democratic transitions. Berkeley, Levitsky, S. and Way, L.W. (2002) ‘The rise of
CA: University of California Press. competitive authoritarianism’, Journal of
Donno, D. (2006) Cheating pays: The impact of Democracy, 13 (2): 51–65.
electoral manipulation on party systems. Lindberg, S.I. (2006a) ‘Tragic protest: Why do
Paper presented at the 102nd Annual opposition parties boycott elections?’, in
Meeting of the American Political Science A. Schedler (ed.), Electoral authoritarianism:
Association (APSA), Philadelphia. The dynamics of unfree competition. Boulder:
Elklit, J. and Reynolds, A. (2005) ‘A framework Lynne Rienner Publishers. pp. 149–163.
for the systematic study of election quality’, Lindberg, S.I. (2006b) Democracy and elections
Democratization, 12 (2): 147–62. in Africa. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University
Greene, K.F. (2002) ‘Opposition party strategy Press.
and spatial competition in dominant Lust-Okar, E. (2005) ‘Opposition and economic
party regimes: A theory and the case of crises in Jordan and Morocco’, in M.P.
Mexico’, Comparative Political Studies, 35 Posusney and M.P. Angrist (eds),
(7): 755–83. Authoritarianism in the Middle East: Regimes
Hartlyn, J., McCoy, J., and Mustillo, T.J. (2008) and resistance. Boulder: Lynne Rienner
‘The “quality of elections” in contemporary Publishers, pp. 143–68.
Latin America: Issues in measurement and Magaloni, B. (2006) Voting for autocracy:
explanation’, Comparative Political Studies, Hegemonic party survival and its demise
41 (1): 73–98. in Mexico. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Hermet, G., Rouquié, A., and Linz, J.J. Press.
(1978) Des élections pas comme les autres. Marshall, M.G. and Jaggers, K. (2002) Polity IV
Paris: Presses de la Fondation nationale des project: Political regime characteristics and
sciences politiques. transitions, 1800–2002: Dataset users’
Howard, M.M. and Roessler, P. (2006) ‘Liberal- manual (College Park, MD: Integrated
izing electoral outcomes in competitive Network for Societal Conflict Research,

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:14 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


ELECTORAL AUTHORITARIANISM 393

Center for International Development and Schedler, A. (2002a) ‘The nested game of
Conflict Management, University of democratization by elections’, International
Maryland) Retrieved March 14, 2008, from Political Science Review, 23 (1): 103–22.
www.cidcm.umd.edu Schedler, A. (2002b) ‘Elections without democ-
Martin, D. (1978) ‘The 1975 Tanzanian elec- racy: The menu of manipulation’, Journal of
tions: The disturbing six per cent’, in G. Democracy, 13 (2): 36–50.
Hermet, R. Rose, and A. Rouquié (eds), Schedler, A. (2006a) ‘The logic of electoral
Elections without choice. New York: Halsted authoritarianism’, in A. Schedler (ed.),
Press, pp. 108–28. Electoral authoritarianism: The dynamics of
McFaul, M. (2005) ‘Transitions from postcom- unfree competition. Boulder: Lynne Rienner
munism’, Journal of Democracy, 16 (3): 5–19. Publishers, pp. 1–23.
Mill, J.S. (1991) Considerations on representa- Schedler, A. (2006b) Patterns of repression and
tive government. Amherst, New York: manipulation: Towards a topography of
Prometheus Books. (Original work published authoritarian elections. Paper presented at
in 1861). the 20th World Congress of the International
Munck, G.L. (2006) Standards for evaluating Political Science Association (IPSA). Fukuoka,
electoral processes by OAS election observa- Japan.
tion Missions. Unpublished typescript. Los Schedler, A. (2006c) When do losers protest?
Angeles, CA: University of Southern Opposition strategies under electoral author-
California. itarianism. Paper presented at the 102nd
Munck, G.L. and Verkuilen, J. (2002) Annual Meeting of the American Political
‘Conceptualizing and measuring democracy: Science Association (APSA), Philadelphia.
Evaluating alternative indices’, Comparative Simpser, A. (2004) Making votes not count:
Political Studies, 35: 5–34. Strategic incentives for electoral corruption
Ottaway, M. (2003) Democracy challenged: (Working paper, Stanford University).
The rise of semi-authoritarianism. Smith, P. (2005) Democracy in Latin America:
Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for Political change in comparative perspective.
International Peace. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Posusney, M.P. (2005) ‘Multiparty elections in Snyder, R. (2006) ‘Beyond electoral authoritari-
the Arab world: Election rules and opposi- anism: The spectrum of nondemocratic
tion responses’, in M.P. Posusney and M.P. regimes’, in A. Schedler (ed.), Electoral
Angrist (eds), Authoritarianism in the Middle authoritarianism: The dynamics of unfree
East: Regimes and resistance. Boulder: Lynne competition. Boulder: Lynne Rienner
Rienner Publishers, pp. 91–118. Publishers, pp. 219–31.
Powell, B.G. (2000) Elections as instruments Thompson, M. and Kuntz, P. (2004) ‘Stolen
of democracy: Majoritarian and propor- elections: The case of the Serbian October’,
tional visions. New Haven: Yale University Journal of Democracy, 15 (4): 159–72.
Press. Tsebelis, G. (1990) Nested games: Rational
Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M.E., Cheibub, J.A., choice in comparative politics. Berkeley:
and Limongi, F. (2000) Democracy and devel- University of California Press.
opment: Political institutions and well–being Way, L. (2006) ‘Authoritarian failure. How
in the world, 1950–1990. Cambridge, UK: does state weakness strengthen electoral
Cambridge University Press. competition?’, in A. Schedler (ed.), Electoral
Riker, W.H. (1986) The art of political manipu- authoritarianism: The dynamics of unfree
lation. New Haven: Yale University Press. competition. Boulder: Lynne Rienner
Schaffer, F.C. (ed.) (2007) Elections for Publishers, pp. 224–41.
sale: The causes and consequences of Wilson, A. (2005) Virtual politics. Faking
vote buying. Boulder: Lynne Rienner democracy in the post–Soviet world. New
Publishers. Haven: Yale University Press.

9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:15 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM


9781412919760_Chap20.indd Sec1:16 3/11/2009 4:21:59 PM
21
Electoral Corruption
Sarah Birch

INTRODUCTION interest in the topic of electoral corruption by


students of the so-called third and fourth
Modern authoritarian and semi-authoritarian waves of democratization. Unlike the histori-
states hold elections; even text-book autocra- cal accounts, much of this work has an
cies such as Saudi Arabia and China have explicitly comparative focus, and it has led to
recently begun experimenting on a small the creation of a new sub-field of the com-
scale with electoral mechanisms for the parative study of electoral corruption.
choice of public officials. The prevalence of Research in this emerging field includes
elections is not, however, associated with an practitioner guides to electoral best practice
equal prevalence of democracy, in the sense (e.g., Goodwin-Gill, 1994; 1998; IDEA,
that this term is commonly understood in 2002), and a handful of short comparative
Western political science. The discrepancy analyses of the topic.1
between the institution of elections and the This chapter reviews key developments
reality of democracy can be largely (though and debates in the field of electoral corrup-
not exclusively) traced directly or indirectly tion, with a particular emphasis on the more
to electoral corruption and manipulation. recent comparative studies of this phenome-
The modern study of electoral corruption non. It addresses the three topics that have, to
takes two principal forms: historical studies date, received the most attention in this area:
of corruption in unreformed electoral sys- approaches to defining the concept of elec-
tems, and studies of electoral malpractice toral integrity/corruption, the measurement
following (notional) democratization. The of this phenomenon, and its explanation. It
historical accounts of electoral corruption also provides an assessment of future direc-
have in some cases been carried out by tions for research in this field and an over-
political scientists and in other cases by his- view of the main tasks that confront it.
torians. They tend to be single country case But first a word on the basic rationale for the
studies employing either qualitative or quan- study of electoral corruption. While the holding
titative techniques (see Lehoucq, 2003 for an of high-quality elections is not a sufficient con-
overview). Work in this field has been under- dition for a polity to be considered a democ-
taken fairly regularly since the nineteenth racy, it is nevertheless a necessary condition.
century, largely by country specialists. More Yet very often elections fail to embody the
recently, however, there has been an increased popular will, especially in the context of new,

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:25:55 PM


396 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

emerging and semi-democracies. This may be Finally, electoral fraud and other forms of
due to manipulation by incumbent elites or by manipulation can, under certain circumstances,
others in the political process such as candi- lead to violent protest, and can sometimes even
dates, media outlets, voluntary organizations, spark civil unrest.
and individual voters. It is therefore not surprising that electoral
Most analyses of electoral behaviour in corruption is fast coming to be seen as one of
established liberal democracies rest on the the main obstacles to the establishment of
twin assumptions that the values and evalua- genuine and meaningful democracy in many
tions of voters are primary determinants of post-transitional contexts (Elklit, 1999;
vote choice, and that vote choices are the sole Lehoucq, 2003; Mozaffar and Schedler, 2002;
determinant of electoral outcomes (mediated, Pastor, 1999a; Schedler, 2002a, 2002b). Even
of course, by the electoral system). However, in established democracies, there has been
in many or even most parts of the world, nei- renewed interest in the topic of electoral cor-
ther of these assumptions holds; rather, lead- ruption, following several high-profile scan-
ers employ a variety of methods to shape vote dals surrounding electronic and postal voting
options, vote choice, and vote counts such that and vote counting technologies (e.g., Herron
genuinely-held values and evaluations play and Sekhon, 2003; Herron and Wand, 2007;
only a marginal role in determining the result Tomz and Van Houweling, 2003).
of elections. Many of these practices fall
under the rubric of electoral corruption, and
they have a profound impact on the way the
electoral process is understood and used, as DEFINITIONS: THE CONCEPT OF
well as the role of elections in the larger ELECTORAL CORRUPTION
political process. With the increasing number
of semi-democratic states in the world, this Drawing on common definitions of ‘general’
topic is of growing importance. corruption as the abuse of public office for
Electoral corruption has a number of serious private gain,2 electoral corruption can be
consequences for democratic performance: it defined at a basic level as the manipulation of
reduces the objective quality of representation, electoral outcomes so as to substitute per-
in that those elected in rigged elections may be sonal or partisan benefit for the public inter-
less skilled at representing voters’ genuine est. It is possible to identify three main forms
interests, and they will have less incentive to do of electoral corruption: the manipulation of
so. Electoral malpractice also affects subjective rules, the manipulation of voters, and the
evaluations of the quality of democracy in a manipulation of votes. The manipulation of
polity and thereby compromises the legitimacy rules includes efforts to alter electoral laws
of the regime; in addition, it reduces levels of and other administrative regulations to parti-
trust – both in political leaders by the general san advantage. The manipulation of voters
population and inter-personal trust between includes systematic media bias and deceptive
political actors. An additional consequence of political communication during election
electoral malfeasance is that it is likely to campaigns, as well as the provision of par-
spawn corruption in other spheres, as those ticularistic incentives or sanctions (vote-
elected through illegitimate means will tend to buying, intimidation, coercion, and other
use similar tactics to achieve their ends while in forms of ‘undue influence’). The manipula-
office. Moreover, poorly-conducted elections tion of votes is a matter of maladministration
entail costs that go beyond democracy; not only and fraud: altering the implementation of the
are they likely to lead to allocative inefficiency procedures governing elections so as to bias
in policy-making, but the misuse of state the outcome.
resources during the electoral period This basic conceptualization is relatively
often results in a drain on the public purse. straightforward and uncontroversial, but the

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:25:55 PM


ELECTORAL CORRUPTION 397

picture becomes more complicated when which political actors see the entire process as
one attempts to define the concept in more legitimate and binding’ (pp. 86–87). This
precise operational terms. It is in this context approach has the advantage that it is relatively
that the principal debates have arisen over the straightforward and it obviates the need for the
definition of electoral corruption – and its researcher to make potentially arbitrary distinc-
obverse, electoral integrity. Four main tions between legitimate and illegitimate prac-
approaches to specifying the quality of elec- tices, as these distinctions are attributed by the
toral conduct can be identified: definitions in actors themselves. The problems with a purely
terms of the laws of a given state, in terms of perceptual definition of corruption are firstly,
the perceptions of actors in a polity, induc- that defining electoral quality in terms of legiti-
tively in terms of ‘best practice’, and deduc- macy precludes exploration of the complex
tively in terms of the normative principles of relationship between the two concepts. It would,
democracy. The first two approaches take as for example, be interesting to study how the
their framework a single social and legal accuracy of voters’ perceptions of the extent of
context, while the last two are more general electoral fraud and other forms of malpractice
in scope.3 affect their propensity to collude with politi-
cians in perpetuating such practices. Definitions
of corrupt practice in terms of perceptions also
The legal approach run up against the problem that populations
may become inured to forms of behaviour that
From a legalistic point of view, electoral mal- are indisputably corrupt by most common
practice can be defined as any act that violates sense definitions (Philip, 1997). Thirdly, per-
the electoral and other laws of a given state. ceptions vary among groups within a state
This is probably the most common practical (a fact that Elklit and Reynolds acknowledge),
approach to issues of electoral integrity, as leading to difficulties in knowing whose view is
discussions and debates within a state tend most relevant – ordinary citizens (who may not
often to take the legal framework as their prin- have an accurate view of the scale of malfea-
cipal point of reference, and formal sanctions sance), those actively involved in politics (who
only apply to acts that violate the law. are likely to have a clearer picture, but whose
According to Lehoucq (2003: 235), ‘A key view may well be biased by their partisan
advantage of the legalistic conception of fraud affiliations), or those directly involved in run-
is that it permits assessing the location of the ning elections (who have the best view of what
boundaries between acceptable and unaccept- is really going on, but who cannot be assumed
able political activity’). The main problem to be forthcoming when asked their opinion).
with the legal approach is that, as noted above, This last point relates to a fourth problem with
the laws themselves may be the object of employing a perceptual definition: even if per-
manipulation by political leaders, who may ceptions of electoral integrity are themselves
well seek to alter the ‘rules of the game’ as a accurate, the researcher may find it difficult to
prerequisite to engaging in other forms of obtain an accurate picture of them, because
manipulation. While useful for the study of those who are most likely to be in the know
electoral fraud in the narrow sense, the legal may also be least likely to tell the truth.
approach is therefore not ideal when we want
to assess the overall quality of elections.
The inductive (best practice)
approach
The perceptual approach
The assessment of electoral integrity accord-
In a 2002 article, Elklit and Reynolds ‘concep- ing to international standards is commonly
tualise the quality of an election as the extent to undertaken by those who are involved in

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:25:55 PM


398 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

practical electoral assistance and monitoring. believe that a variety of different practices
Following W.J.M. Mackenzie’s seminal work are acceptable (often with reference to the
Free Elections (1958), many legal scholars specific context in the state in question). As
and political scientists have also adopted this Goodwin-Gill (1994: 7) argues, the general
approach, whose aim is to establish standards principle behind international commitments
of ‘best practice’ in the electoral realm on the to hold free and fair elections is one of ‘obli-
basis of observed practice in states considered gation of result’; states are judged by the
to be exemplary, and seek to identify the scope result of the electoral processes they imple-
of ‘legitimate’ deviations from established ment, but they have a degree of choice in the
norms (e.g., Beigbeder, 1994; Boda, 2005; means chosen to effect that result. Michael
Goodwin-Gill, 1994, 1998; López-Pintor, Boda (2005) elaborates on this concept and
2000; Pastor, 1999b). Malpractice can then be relates it to the related principle of ‘obliga-
defined as acts of manipulation that fall with- tion of conduct’.
out the acceptable range of electoral practice. While useful in practical situations, the inter-
This approach tends to focus largely on national standards approach can be seen to
the many discrete processes that make up suffer from the fact that it is so clearly embed-
electoral administration (voter registration, ded in political processes – the processes that
boundary delimitation, campaign finance reg- have generated the international legal structure
ulation, polling, etc.) and the norms appropri- governing elections, and the historical proc-
ate to each. esses within states that have resulted in the
International legal instruments that bear on electoral practices of some states gaining more
elections are largely codified best practice as prestige than those of others.
it has developed over time in the world’s core
democratic states. According to international
law (the Universal Declaration of Human The deductive (democratic theory)
Rights, the International Covenant on Civil
approach
and Political Rights), elections must be held
periodically; in addition they must meet five The deductive approach based on normative
criteria to be considered free and fair: they democratic theory starts from the premise
must be held that to evaluate the quality of elections it is
necessary to assess the extent to which a
1. by secret ballot; given electoral process is performing the
2. under universal and equal suffrage; function intended for it within the context of
3. in a non-discriminatory manner; the democracy in question. Jorgen Elklit and
4. allowing direct choice; and colleagues have perhaps gone furthest in
5. free expression (see Beigbeder, 1994; Goodwin- developing electoral assessment methodolo-
Gill, 1994, 1998; relevant extracts from these gies on the basis of the deductive approach
documents are presented in the Appendix). (Elklit, 1994; Elklit and Reynolds, 2005a,
2005b; Elklit and Svensson, 1997; cf.
As a result of debate and analysis Schedler, 2002a; 2002b). There are several
undertaken by organizations such as the common problems associated with this
United Nations, Inter-Parliamentary Union, approach, however. As Richard Katz points
International IDEA, and regional bodies, out, there are many different normative
there are currently many aspects of electoral models of democracy and a minimal thresh-
procedures that have been recognized as old of democratic acceptability, understand-
‘best practice’.4 Yet there are also areas on ings of electoral integrity and electoral
which the experts and practitioners involved corruption will depend on the democratic
in these deliberations have either failed to model adopted (Katz, 2005). Moreover, as
agree on what constitutes ‘best practice’ or Elklit and Svennson (1997) note, the terms

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:25:55 PM


ELECTORAL CORRUPTION 399

‘free’ and ‘fair’ are used in a variety of differ- safeguards that prevent other actors in soci-
ent ways, and they are not always clearly ety from committing acts of electoral viola-
distinguished. tion. It is not entirely realistic to expect the
Whatever definitional approach is adopted, state to bear all responsibility in this domain;
it is also necessary to bear in mind three key meaningful elections are the result of efforts
distinctions: firstly the distinction between by state, citizens, and politicians alike. Yet it
the intentional manipulation of electoral is worth bearing in mind that many practical
processes for political and/or material ends assessments of elections are effectively
(what is commonly termed electoral ‘corrup- assessments of the state’s efforts to regulate
tion’), and secondly unintentional malprac- the electoral process, which depends on a
tice arising from lack of experience, lack of variety of factors that extend well beyond the
resources, or sheer incompetence. In prac- electoral arena, on factors such as state
tice, of course, the distinction is often diffi- capacity, rule of law, corruption in other
cult to make; electoral administrators may be spheres, resources, etc.
deprived of proper training and resources
because incumbent power-holders perceive
that this will be to their benefit; conversely,
unintentional deficiencies in electoral admin- MEASUREMENT ISSUES
istration are often interpreted as the result of AND DATA SOURCES
intentional manipulation when the result
benefits one group over another. Yet what- For comparative political scientists, evaluat-
ever the practical difficulty in distinguishing ing the quality of elections has traditionally
benign from maleficent misconduct, the the- been viewed as fairly straightforward from a
oretical distinction between the two is useful definitional point of view, yet fraught with
for analytic purposes. measurement problems due to the fact that,
The second distinction that needs to be like any form of corruption, electoral corrup-
borne in mind, within the category of inten- tion is by definition extremely difficult, if not
tional corruption, is the distinction between impossible, to observe directly. There are
attempted and achieved malpractice. A polit- also obvious difficulties associated with
ical actor may, for example, make extensive obtaining reliable and comparable data for
but ultimately unsuccessful efforts to bribe any reasonably large number of states. It is
voters; in this case there has been much effort perhaps for this reason that studies of elec-
but little result. A slightly different situation toral malpractice have largely been case stud-
is that in which an actor is successful in alter- ies. But possibilities for data collection are
ing the votes of a significant proportion of improving, opening up opportunities for
the electorate but not enough to alter the out- developing new measurement strategies.
come of the election. We may therefore dis-
tinguish between attempted and achieved
malfeasance, bearing in mind that ‘achieve-
Measurement
ment’ can in this context itself be measured
in a variety of ways – in terms of votes, seats The measurement of electoral corruption can
(in a parliamentary election) or the overall almost never be direct. As with any covert
result of the election (who wins). activity, those who perpetrate electoral mal-
A third distinction relates to the agent of practice have every incentive to cover their
corruption. We typically hold a state respon- tracks, and it is rarely possible to obtain suf-
sible for the quality of its elections. The state ficiently comprehensive direct evidence of
is understood as the main agent that main- this sort of activity for valid measures to be
tains electoral integrity, by abstaining from made. The measurement of electoral corrup-
engaging in violations and/or by providing tion therefore relies on a variety of strategies

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:25:55 PM


400 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

designed to gauge the scale of improper activ- tabulation, and reporting of results, and dis-
ity in the electoral arena through indirect pute adjudication.
means. These strategies can be grouped into The other main type of comparative data
two principal approaches: (1) the use of per- available for use in cross-national analysis
ceptual data (reports of voters, election observ- of electoral corruption is perceptual data
ers, and experts as well as legal complaints, derived from mass surveys. Surveys that
charges and court rulings); and (2) the statisti- include questions on electoral quality include
cal analysis of patterns in electoral results. As the Latinobarometer and Afrobarometer
these two approaches are closely linked to the survey series, as well as Module I of the
types of data they employ, it is worth consider- Comparative Study of Electoral Systems
ing them in the context of data sources. project and the 2004 International Social
Survey Programme. In addition, the
International Foundation for Electoral Systems
has conducted a number of surveys in indi-
Data sources
vidual countries that ask similar, and in some
Data sources can be divided into comparative cases identical, questions about electoral qual-
and country-specific. Within each category ity and electoral corruption. Such survey data
we can distinguish between data sources have been used in several studies to probe the
based on official reports, those based on sur- correlates of confidence in the electoral proc-
veys, and other types of data. Report-based ess (e.g., Anderson et al., 2005; Birch, 2005a,
comparative datasets include Taylor and 2005b; Norris, 2002, 2004: 216–62; Zovatto
Hudson’s coding of electoral irregularity in and Payne, 2003).
112 states in the mid-1960s (Taylor and Data available for analysis at the country
Hudson, 1972: 57); the ‘fraud’ indicator in the level include the report-based and survey-
World Bank Database of Political Institution based data mentioned above, as well as reports
(Beck et al., 2001), Robert Pastor’s database and surveys conducted in individual countries.
of ‘flawed’ elections (Pastor, 1999a), and the Single country studies that have relied on
Freedom House Freedom in the World subcat- report-based data include Cox and Koussner
egory score for ‘electoral process’ (www. (1981); studies of electoral corruption that
freedomhouse.org). have employed survey-data at the country
In addition, regional comparative databases level include McCann and Dominguez
that have been compiled on the basis of elec- (1998). Within a given state it is often also
tion observation reports (see, for example, possible to rely on other types of data, includ-
Birch’s dataset based on OSCE monitoring ing official criminal data on election-related
reports, as described in Birch, 2007, or the crime, which has been used in several studies
dataset compiled on post-communist and (e.g., Eisenstadt, 2002; Lehoucq and Molina,
Latin American elections by Donno and 2002; Molina and Lehouq, 1999). Official
Roussias, as described in Donno and Roussias, election results data themselves can also pro-
2006). Such reports provide rich detail on the vide a rich source of data that, when suitably
quality of the legislative framework govern- analyzed can lead to the discovery of anoma-
ing elections, campaign practices (including lies consistent with certain forms of corrup-
media bias, the use of illegal campaign tac- tion and abuse; studies that have undertaken
tics and undue influence), and various aspects such analysis include Baum (1991); Berezkin
of the electoral process including electoral et al. (1989); Christensen (2005); Elklit (1994);
management body design, voter registration, Herron and Johnson (2007); King (2001);
candidate/party registration, polling arrange- Mayfield (1993); Oberst and Weilage (1990);
ments, polling day activities, the count, vote and Powell (1989).

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:25:55 PM


ELECTORAL CORRUPTION 401

EXPLANATIONS: HOW AND WHY crises that they are obliged to ‘clean up’ their
DO POLITICAL ACTORS ENGAGE IN electoral process to prevent mass disturbances,
ELECTORAL CORRUPTION? as happened in Argentina prior to the Sáenz
Peña law of 1912 (Díaz, 1983). In other cases,
Explanations of electoral corruption have incompetence and miscalculation may gener-
typically been couched in terms of three ate unacceptable levels of fraud and abuse,
main aims: to understand how actors manip- which lead to popular demands for reform.
ulate elections,5 to understand what accounts The ‘electoral revolutions’ in Yugoslavia
for the presence or absence of electoral (2000), Georgia (2003), and Ukraine (2004)
corruption,6 and to understand what causes are dramatic examples of this.
the quality of elections to improve or deterio- It is also worth mentioning that electoral
rate over time.7 corruption occurs in contexts that place it
Much of the literature on electoral corruption below the threshold of systematicity. It is well-
has been devoted to the first of these aims, to known that a number of US states have long
understanding the forms, prevalence, and histories of dubious electoral practices that
mechanics of electoral corruption. This is par- have not died out with the gradual sanitation
ticularly true of the historical literature, but it is of elections that has taken place in most other
also true of much writing on the electoral parts of the country. Other examples include
dynamics of developing countries.8 We know, revelations of fraud and abuse that have
for example, that electoral corruption takes an received prominent coverage in several
almost infinite number of guises, depending on European democracies in recent years, includ-
the opportunities available in the institutional ing the UK and France, not to mention the
architecture under which elections are con- notoriously corrupt Italian system that is still,
ducted and the socio-economic structure of the for all its faults, considered to be on the right
polity in question. We also know that electoral side of democracy. As with the cases of ‘sys-
abuse tends for the most part to be systemic, in temic’ corruption noted above, low-level and
the sense that it is deeply embedded in the relatively isolated electoral abuse can often
political culture of the context in which it continue for long periods of time, until revela-
occurs, and it involves relatively stable electoral tion and subsequent scandal puts pressure on
economies based on the exchange of votes for the state to take measures to eliminate it.
some form of benefit. Such economies may be There is thus considerable piecemeal
based on clientelism of different types,9 on knowledge of the context in which electoral
systems of direct exchange,10 on structures of corruption occurs, yet general explanatory
intimidation and coercion,11 on the abuse of accounts of variations in levels of electoral
state resources,12 or on intra-party bargaining to corruption across countries or over time have
divvy up the spoils of government.13 been relatively poorly developed in the exist-
Whatever their basis, corrupt electoral ing literature. Fortunately this has begun to
economies often go undisturbed for extended change in recent years, as scholars of elec-
periods. Yet gradual socio-economic change toral corruption have begun increasingly to
and exogenous shocks can and do disrupt such investigate why malpractice occurs and what
systems. This may be due to population factors are associated with either increases or
increase and relatively minor changes in suf- decreases in this phenomenon. Basic to the
frage requirements that gradually make vote- understanding of electoral corruption is the
buying too expensive, which then generates recognition that political elites face a trade-
impetus for reform (Lehoucq and Molina, off between power and legitimacy (Birch,
2002; O’Gorman, 1996; O’Leary, 1962). Or 2007; Schedler, 2002a; 2002b). Power-
governments may face such severe legitimacy holders have a strong incentive to stay in

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


402 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

power as long as they can, even if this political actors select manipulation strategies
involves manipulating electoral processes. At carefully, depending on their political and
the same time the security of their tenure in material endowments.
power rests also on the legitimacy of their Further work needs to be done to examine
rule, and legitimacy has since pre-modern the strategic considerations of those who par-
times been negotiated by means of elections ticipate in or are subject to electoral corrup-
(O’Gorman, 1996). Moreover, in a globalized tion. The factors that have to date been
world the international standing of leaders is employed to account for the level or rate of
increasingly important as a determinant of change of electoral corruption can, for the
their ability to maintain power, and adverse sake of convenience, be divided into two main
reaction by the international community to categories: institutional and contextual
evidence of electoral abuse virtually always factors. On the institutional side, electoral
has a negative impact on leaders’ legitimacy management body independence is the institu-
in the international sphere. If leaders do not tional variable most clearly associated with
have sufficiently high levels of genuine pop- electoral conduct (Lopez-Pintor, 2000). In the
ularity to keep them in power by means of African context, independent electoral com-
fair elections, then they may find themselves missions (introduced in Burkina Faso, Bénin,
tempted to engage in a variety of ‘foul’ Ghana, Mali, Niger, Nigeria, Sénégal, and
means of maintaining power, electoral Togo) have been linked to improved election
corruption being the most obvious and typi- quality (Mozaffar, 2002). Electoral commis-
cally the most effective. sion independence has also been found to
But not all forms of electoral corruption influence the quality of elections in Latin
are equally appealing. The manipulation of America (Hartlyn, 1994; McCoy and Hartlyn,
legal framework governing elections is often 2006). Single member district electoral sys-
costless to incumbent rulers, and if it is car- tems have also been found in some studies to
ried out within certain bounds, it often car- be associated with higher levels of electoral
ries a limited risk to legitimacy. Other forms corruption than more proportional systems
of manipulation such as vote-buying may (Birch, 2007; Lehoucq and Molina, 2002).
also entail low risk to legitimacy in that such Contextual factors that have been found to be
acts may often be tolerated or even wel- associated with electoral malpractice include
comed by the domestic population, and they levels of socio-economic development (Akhter,
are difficult for the international community 2001; Gosnell, 1968; Hartlyn, 1994; Lehoucq,
to monitor. Vote-buying has the added advan- 2003; McDonald, 1972; Scott, 1969), bureau-
tage for non-incumbents that no formal polit- cratic structure (Christensen, 2002; McCoy
ical power is required; it can be engaged in and Hartlyn, 2006), the presence of observers
by anyone with sufficient funds. Vote-buying (McCoy and Hartlyn, 2006), the existence of
is costly, however, which may well be a other forms of corruption (Birch, 2007), and
potential deterrent to many actors. In the traditional culture (Beck, 1997; Callahan,
light of these considerations, it becomes 2000; McDonald, 1972; Schaffer and
clear that outright fraud, such as impersona- Schedler, 2005).
tion, ballot-box stuffing, and manipulation of
the vote-counting process are unattractive.
They carry a very high risk, as they are often
detectable by local and international actors, DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE
and they can also carry high material costs, RESEARCH
as all those who are complicit in such activity
typically have to be compensated for their As a relatively new field, the comparative study
collusion, either directly or in terms of career of electoral corruption offers a wide range of
rewards. We can therefore speculate that opportunities for further development. The

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


ELECTORAL CORRUPTION 403

paucity of existing research is partly the gateway to power in the vast majority of con-
result of a lack of suitable cross-national temporary states, one can hypothesize that
databases, but it is also a product of the fact corruption of the electoral process has a
that most research on electoral corruption to knock-on effect on a wide range of political
date has taken a historical or ideographic processes and outcomes, but little work has
approach, and has simply not sought to con- so far been done on delineating these impacts
ceptualize the broad determinants and conse- or assessing their magnitude. We do know
quences of this phenomenon. that electoral corruption depresses turnout
There is a pressing need in the study of (Birch, 2005a; Bratton, 1998; Bratton and
electoral corruption for better cross-national van de Walle, 1997: 206–10; McCann and
databases. In this connection it is worth Dominguez, 1998). We also know that anger
pointing to the dramatic increases in studies about electoral corruption can result in
of ‘general’ corruption that was sparked by popular unrest or even civil war. For exam-
the creation and dissemination of the ple, the 1992 elections in Mauritania sparked
Transparency International’s Corruption bouts of violence (Wiseman, 1992), as did
Perceptions Index, which includes annual the 2000 elections on Zanzibar (Pottie, 2002).
cross-national data on a large number of Some commentators have also linked the
countries. The development of a reliable violence in the Congo (Brazzaville) in the
comparative database of electoral corruption mid-1990s to the questionable elections of
would undoubtedly significantly spur aca- 1993 (see Fleischhacker, 1999). Yet current
demic research in this field. knowledge about the impacts of electoral
It would also be useful if surveys routinely corruption is fragmentary at best.
incorporated questions on perceptions of In short, the comparative study of electoral
electoral fairness into their questionnaires. corruption is an emerging field in which much
It is striking that survey researchers have for remains to be done. With the recent rise of
decades asked respondents across the world ‘illiberal’ or ‘authoritarian’ democracies (cf.
about their attitudes toward and trust in a chapter by Schedler, this volume), it is also a
variety of institutions, but they have for field that is of increasing relevance to contem-
the most part neglected to ask about the insti- porary politics. And as more and more authori-
tution that is arguably most central to tarian and semi-authoritarian leaders are pressed
democracy – the electoral process. Most to legitimate their power through the ballot box,
election studies fail to ask respondents about the ‘demand’ for electoral corruption is bound
their views on the quality of electoral con- to increase. Likewise, as comparative datasets
duct, and the assumption of unmanipulated on elections increase in breadth to take in sets
choice subtends most research in the field of of states that are ever more diverse in political
electoral behaviour, even when circumstances terms, electoral behaviouralists are going to be
would suggest that this in unlikely to be an obliged to confront the possibility that the data
accurate assumption. on which they base their analyses do not reflect
There is also a need for better explanatory the free expression of the voters’ will. There
theories of electoral corruption. As noted can thus be expected to be a commensurate
above, most attention so far has been devoted increase in the ‘demand’ for a political science
to conceptualizing and describing this phe- understanding of electoral corruption.
nomenon, and relatively little effort has gone
into explaining it. Political science would
also benefit from a more detailed understand-
ing of the impact of electoral corruption on CONCLUSION
other aspects of politics, including other
aspects of corruption. In as much as elections Political elites want to win elections. They
are the lynchpin of democracy and the may have other motives for becoming active

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


404 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

in politics, but it can generally be assumed APPENDIX: EXTRACTS FROM


that in a polity where leaders are selected INTERNATIONAL AGREEMENTS
through electoral mechanisms, winning elec- RELATING TO ELECTIONS
tions is a precondition for achieving most of
the other aims of politicians. Any given UNIVERSAL DECLARATION ON
member of the elite has a variety of different
HUMAN RIGHTS, GENERAL
electoral strategies at his or her disposal. The
ASSEMBLY RESOLUTION 217 A (III)
vast majority of the previous research on
electoral strategies has focused on legitimate (10 DECEMBER 1948)
strategies. Yet there are a large number of
illegitimate and semi-legitimate strategies Article 21
that are also potentially in the choice set 1. Everyone has the right to take part in the
considered by elites. government of his country, directly or through
Preventing electoral corruption is key to freely chosen representatives. …
maintaining and enhancing the seeds of elec- 3. The will of the people shall be the basis of
toral accountability in new and emerging the authority of government; this will shall
democracies. Likewise, reducing electoral be expressed in periodic and genuine elec-
corruption in authoritarian states is in many tions which shall be by universal and equal
cases the surest means of bringing about suffrage and shall be held by secret vote or
democratic change. It was small-scale elec- by equivalent free voting procedures.
toral reform in 1989 in what was still a one-
party state that opened the way for the collapse
of communism in the Soviet Union and ulti-
mately the collapse of the country itself. INTERNATIONAL COVENANT
Likewise, it was the introduction of an inde- ON CIVIL AND POLITICAL
pendent electoral court in Mexico that is RIGHTS, GENERAL ASSEMBLY
widely credited with bringing about the demise RESOLUTION 2200A (XXI)
of the dominant Institutional Revolutionary (16 DECEMBER 1966)
Party in Mexico. Democratization is inti-
mately associated with electoral reform, and Article 25
electoral corruption is associated in an equally
intimate manner with many forms of authori- Every citizen shall have the right and the
tarianism. The comparative study of electoral opportunity, without any of the distinctions
corruption is therefore central to understand- mentioned in article 2 and without unreason-
ing the difference between the two principal able restrictions:
regimes types in the modern world; it also has (a) To take part in the conduct of public
substantial practical value to regimes that affairs, directly or through freely chosen
decide – for whatever reason – to clean up representatives;
their elections; finally, the study of electoral (b) To vote and to be elected at genuine peri-
corruption is of considerable relevance to odic elections which shall be by universal
decision-makers and aid workers from devel- and equal suffrage and shall be held by secret
oped democracies seeking to improve the ballot, guaranteeing the free expression of
quality of democracy elsewhere. the will of the electors; …

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


ELECTORAL CORRUPTION 405

NOTES REFERENCES

1. See, for example, Birch (2005a, 2005b, 2007); Akhter, M.Y. (2001) Electoral corruption in
Boda (2005); Christensen (2005); Elklit (1999); Elklit Bangladesh. Aldershot: Ashgate.
and Reynolds (2002, 2005a, 2005b); Hartlyn and Anderson, C.J., Blais, A., Bowler, S., Donovan,
McCoy (2006); Lehoucq (2002); Mozaffar (2002); T., and Listhaug, O. (2005) Losers’ consent:
Mozaffar and Schedler (2002); Pastor (1999a);
Elections and democratic legitimacy. Oxford:
Posada-Carbó (2000); Schaffer (2002); Schedler
(2002a, 2002b, 2004, 2006).
Oxford University Press.
2. For an overview of different approaches to Argersinger, P.H. (1985/86) ‘New perspectives
defining corruption, see Part I of the anthology on on election fraud in the gilded age’, Political
corruption compiled by Arnold Heidenheimer and Science Quarterly, 100 (4): 669–87.
Michael Johnston (Heidenheimer and Johnston, Baum, D. (1991) ‘Pinpointing apparent fraud in
2002). the 1861 Texas secession referendum’,
3. It is not surprising, therefore, that the percep- Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 22 (2):
tual and legal approaches are employed more com- 201–21.
monly in single case studies, whereas the more Beck, L.J. (1997) ‘Senegal’s ‘patrimonial demo-
general inductive and deductive approaches are
crats’: Incremental reform and the obstacles
better suited to the comparative context.
4. See, for example, Council of Europe (2002);
to the consolidation of democracy’, Canadian
CSES (1990); International Institute for Democracy Journal of African Studies, 31 (1): 1–31.
and Electoral Assistance (2002); Inter-Parliamentary Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., and
Union (1994); Organization for American States Walsh, P. (2001) ‘New tools and new tests in
(2001). See also the international documents referred comparative political economy: The database
to in the Appendix below. of political institutions’, World Bank Economic
5. For example, Beck (1997); Case (2006); Review, 15 (1): 165–76.
Figueroa and Sives (2002); McDonald (1972); Beigbeder, Y. (1994) International monitoring
Mozaffar and Schedler (2002); Posada-Carbó (2000); of plebiscites, referenda and national elec-
Posusney (1998); Schedler (2002a, 2002b, 2006);
tions: Self-determination and transition to
Wilson (2005b).
6. Examples include Birch (2007); Gosnell (1968);
democracy. Dordrecht, Boston and London:
Lehoucq (2003); McCoy and Hartlyn (2006); Scott Martinus Nijhoff.
(1969). Berezkin, A.V., Kolosov, V.A., Pavlovskaya,
7. See, for instance, Eisenstadt (2002); Howard M.E., Petrov, N.V., and Smirnyagin, L.V.
and Roessler (2006); Lehoucq (2000); Lehoucq and (1989) ‘The geography of the 1989
Molina (2002); McCoy and Hartlyn (2006); Molina elections of people’s deputies of the USSR
and Lehoucq (1999); O’Leary (1962). (Preliminary Results)’, Soviet Geography, 30
8. See, for example, the contributions to the (8): 607–34.
edited volumes by Posado-Carbo (1996) and Hermet Birch, S. (1997) ‘Nomenklatura democratiza-
et al. (1978).
tion: Electoral clientelism in post-soviet
9. See, for example, Akhter (2001); Birch (1997);
Dardé (1996); Gosnell (1968); Rouquié (1978); Scott
Ukraine’, Democratization, 4 (4): 40–62.
(1969). Birch, S. (2005a, September) Perceptions of
10. See Argersinger (1985/86); Brusco et al. electoral fairness and voter turnout. Paper
(2004); Callahan (2000); Callahan and McCargo presented at the Annual Meeting of the
(1996); Cox and Thies (2000); Schaffer (2005; 2007); American Political Science Association.
Schaffer and Schedler (2005). Washington, DC.
11. See Baum (1991); Darden (2001); Figueroa Birch, S. (2005b, September) A cross-national
and Sives (2002); Powell (1989); Pravda (1978). analysis of confidence in the conduct of elec-
12. See Argersinger (1985/86); Beck tions. Elections, Public Opinion and Political
(1997); D’Anieri (2005); Dardé (1996); Deas (1996);
Parties Conference, University of Essex.
McDonald (1972); Wilson (2005a: Chapter 4:
2005b).
Birch, S. (2007) ‘Electoral systems and electoral
13. See Eisenstadt (1999); Wilson, (2005b: misconduct’, Comparative Political Studies,
60–69). 40 (12): 1533–56.

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


406 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Boda, M.D. (2005) ‘Judging elections by public D’Anieri, P. (2005) ‘The last hurrah: The 2004
international law: A tentative framework’, Ukrainian presidential elections and the limits
Representation, 41 (3): 208–29. of machine politics’, Communist and
Bratton, M. (1998) ‘Second elections in Africa’, Postcommunist Studies, 38 (2): 231–49.
Journal of Democracy, 9 (3): 51–56. Dardé, C. (1996) ‘Fraud and the passivity of
Bratton, M. and van de Walle, N. (1997) the electorate in Spain, 1875–1923’, in
Democratic experiments in Africa: Regime E. Posada-Carbó (ed.), Elections before
transitions in comparative perspective. democracy: The history of elections in Europe
Cambridge; Cambridge University Press. and Latin America. Basingstoke: Macmillan,
Brusco, V., Nazareno, M., and Stokes, S.C. pp. 201–21.
(2004) ‘Vote-buying in Argentina’, Latin Darden, K.A. (2001) ‘Blackmail as a tool of
American Research Review, 39 (2): 66–88. state domination: Ukraine under Kuchma’,
Callahan, W.A. (2000) Pollwatching, election East European Constitutional Review, 10
and civil society in Southeast Asia. Aldershot: (2/3): 67–71.
Ashgate. Deas, M. (1996) ‘The role of the church, the
Callahan, W.A. and McCargo, D. (1996) ‘Vote- army and the police in Colombian elections,
buying in Thailand’s Northeast’, Asian Survey, c. 1850–1930’, in E. Posada-Carbó (ed.),
36 (4): 376–92. Elections before democracy: The history of
Case, W. (2006) ‘Manipulative sills: How do elections in Europe and Latin America.
rulers control the electoral arena’, in A. Schedler Basingstoke: Macmillan, 163–80.
(ed.), Electoral authoritarianism: The dynam- Díaz, H.A. (1983) Ley Sáenz-Peña: Pro y contra.
ics of unfree competition. Boulder: Lynne Buenos Aires: Centro Editor de América
Rienner, 95–112. Latina.
Christensen, R. (2002) The drawing of electoral Donno, D. and Roussias, A. (2006, September)
boundaries in Japan. Paper presented at the Cheating pays: The impact of electoral manip-
annual meeting of the American Political ulation on party systems. Paper presented at
Science Association, Boston, MA. the Annual Meeting of the American Political
Christensen, R. (2005) Stealing elections on Science Association, Philadelphia.
election night: A comparison of statistical Eisenstadt, T.A. (1999) ‘Off the streets and
evidence from Japan, Canada, and the into the courtrooms: Resolving postelectoral
United States. Paper presented at the annual conflicts in Mexico’, in A. Schedler, L. Diamond,
meeting of the American Political Science and M.F. Plattner (eds), The self-restraining
Association, Washington, DC. state: Power and accountability in new
Council of Europe (2002) Code of good prac- democracies. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner,
tice in electoral matters. Venice Commission. pp. 83–103.
Retrieved March 20, 2008, from http:// Eisenstadt, T.A. (2002) ‘Measuring electoral
www.venice.coe.int/docs/2002/CDL– court failure in democratizing Mexico’,
AD(2002)023rev–e.asp International Political Science Review, 23 (1):
Cox, G.W. and Kousser, J.M. (1981) ‘Turnout 47–68.
and rural corruption: New York as a test Elklit, J. (1994) ‘Is the Degree of Electoral
case’, American Journal of Political Science, Democracy Measurable? Experiences from
25 (4): 646–63. Bulgaria, Kenya, Latvia, Mongolia, and
Cox, G.W. and Thies, M.F. (2000) ‘How much Nepal’, in D. Beetham (ed.), Defining
does money matter? “Buying” votes in and Measuring Democracy. London: Sage,
Japan, 1967–1990’, Comparative Political pp. 89–111.
Studies, 33 (1): 37–57. Elklit, J. (1999) ‘Electoral institutional change
CSES (1990) Copenhagen document. Retrieved and democratization: You can lead a horse
March 20, 2008, from http://www.osce.org/ to water, but you can’t make it drink’,
documents/mcs/1990/11/4045_en.pdf Democratization, 6 (4): 28–51.
Dahl, R. (1971) Polyarchy: participation and Elklit, J. and Reynolds, A. (2002) ‘The
opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University impact of election administration on the
Press. legitimacy of emerging democracies’,

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


ELECTORAL CORRUPTION 407

Common-wealth and Comparative Politics, revolution III: elections in Post-Soviet


40 (2): 86–119. Ukraine, Stuttgart: Ibidem-Verlag.
Elklit, J. and Reynolds, A. (2005a) ‘A frame- Herron, M.C. and Sekhon, J.S. (2003)
work for the systematic study of election ‘Overvoting and representation: An exami-
quality’, Democratization, 12 (2): 147–62. nation of overvoted presidential ballots in
Elklit, J. and Reynolds, A. (2005b) ‘Judging Broward and Miami-Dade counties’, Electoral
elections and election management Studies, 22 (2): 21–48.
quality by process’, Representation, 41 (3): Herron, M.C. and Wand, J. (2007) ‘Assessing
189–207. partisan bias in voting technology: The case
Elklit, J. and Svensson, P. (1997) ‘What makes of the 2004 New Hampshire recount’,
elections free and fair?’, Journal of Electoral Studies, 26 (1): 247–61.
Democracy, 8 (3): 32–45. Howard, M.M. and Roessler, P.G. (2006)
Figueroa, M. and Sives, A. (2002) ‘Homogenous ‘Liberalizing electoral outcomes in competi-
voting, electoral manipulation and the ‘gar- tive authoritarian regimes’, American Journal
rison’ process in post-independence Jamaica’, of Political Science, 50 (2): 365–81.
Commonwealth and Comparative Politics, International Institute for Democracy and
40 (1): 81–108. Electoral Assistance (IDEA) (2002)
Fleischhacker, H. (1999) ‘Congo (Brazzaville)’, International Electoral Standards: Guidelines
in D. Nohlen, M. Krennerich and B. Thibaut for Reviewing the Legal Framework of
(eds) Elections in Africa: A data handbook. Elections, Stockholm: International IDEA.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, Inter-Parliamentary Union (1994) Declaration
pp. 259–80. on criteria for free and fair elections. Retrieved
Goodwin-Gill, G.S. (1994) Free and fair elec- March 20, 2008, from http://www.ipu.org/
tions, Geneva: Inter-Parliamentary Union. Cnl–e/154–free.htm
Goodwin-Gill, G.S. (1998) Codes of conduct Katz, R.S. (2005) ‘Democratic principles and
for elections. Geneva; Inter-Parliamentary judging “free and fair”’, Representation, 41
Union. (3): 161–79.
Gosnell, H.F. (1968) Machine politics: Chicago King, R.F. (2001) ‘Counting the votes:
model (2nd edition) Chicago: University of South Carolina’s stolen elections of 1876’,
Chicago Press. Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 32 (2):
Hartlyn, J. (1994) ‘Crisis-ridden elections 169–91.
(again) in the Dominican Republic: Lehoucq, F.E. (2000) ‘Institutionalizing democ-
Neopatrimonialism, presidentialism, and racy: Constraint and ambition in the politics
weak electoral oversight’, Journal of of electoral reform’, Comparative Politics, 32
Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, 36 (4): 459–77.
(4): 91–144. Lehoucq, F.E. (2002) ‘Can parties police them-
Hartlyn, J. and McCoy, J. (2006) ‘Observer para- selves? Electoral governance and democrati-
doxes; How to assess electoral manipulation’, zation’, International Political Science Review,
in A. Schedler (ed.), Electoral authoritarian- 23 (4): 29–46.
ism: The dynamics of unfree competition. Lehoucq, F.E. (2003) ‘Electoral fraud: Causes,
Boulder: Lynne Rienner. pp. 41–54. types, and consequences’, Annual Review of
Heidenheimer, A.J. and Johnston, M. (eds) Political Science, 6: 233–56.
(2002) Political corruption: Concepts and Lehoucq, F.E. and Molina, I. (2002) Stuffing the
contexts (3rd edition) New Brunswick: ballot-box: fraud, electoral reform, and
Transaction. democratization in Costa Rica. Cambridge:
Hermet, G., Rose, R., and Rouquié, A. (eds) Cambridge University Press.
(1978) Elections without choice. London: López-Pintor, R. (2000) Electoral management
Macmillan. bodies as institutions of governance.
Herron, E.S. and Johnson, P.E. (2007) New York: United Nations Development
‘Fraud before the “revolution”: Special Programme.
precincts in Ukraine’s 2002 parliamentary Mackenzie, W.J.M. (1958) Free elections: An
election’, in I. Bredies, V. Yakushev, and elementary textbook. London: George Allen
A. Umland (eds), Aspects of the Orange and Unwin.

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


408 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Mayfield, L. (1993) ‘Voting fraud in early O’Leary, C. (1962) The elimination of corrupt
twentieth-century Pittsburgh’, Journal of practices in British elections, 1868–1911.
Interdisciplinary History, 24 (1): 59–84. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
McCann, J.A. and Domínguez, J.I. (1998) Organization for American States (2001) Inter-
‘Mexicans react to political fraud and corrup- American democratic charter. Retrieved
tion: An assessment of public opinion and March 20, 2008, from http://www.oas.org/
voting behavior’, Electoral Studies, 17 (4): OASpage/eng/Documents/Democractic_
483–503. Charter.htm
McCoy, J. and Hartlyn, J. (2006, August– Pastor, R.A. (1999a) ‘The role of electoral
September) Election processes in Latin administration in democratic transitions’,
America: Historical legacies and proximate Democratization, 6 (4): 1–27.
causes. Paper delivered at the Annual Pastor, R.A. (1999b) ‘A third dimension of
Meeting of the America Political Science accountability: The international community
Association, Philadelphia. in national elections’, in A. Schedler, L.
McDonald, R.H. (1972) ‘Electoral fraud and Diamond, and M. F. Plattner (eds), The self-
regime controls in Latin America’, Western restraining state: Power and accountability in
Political Quarterly, 25 (1): 81–93. new democracies. Boulder, CO: Lynne
Molina, I. and Lehoucq, F. (1999) ‘Political Rienner, pp. 123–42.
competition and electoral fraud: A Latin Philip, M. (1997) ‘Defining political corruption’,
American case study’, Journal of Inter- Political Studies, 45 (3): 436–62.
Disciplinary History, 30 (2): 199–234. Posada-Carbó, E. (ed.) (1996) Elections before
Mozaffar, S. (2002) ‘Patterns of electoral gov- democracy: The history of elections in Europe
ernance in Africa’s emerging democracies’, and Latin America. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
International Political Science Review, 23 (1): Posada-Carbó, E. (2000) ‘Electoral juggling:
85–101. A comparative history of the corruption of
Mozaffar, S. and Schedler, A. (2002) ‘The com- suffrage in Latin America, 1830–1939’,
parative study of electoral governance – An Journal of Latin American Studies, 32 (2):
introduction’, International Political Science 611–44.
Review, 23 (2): 5–27. Posusney, M.P. (1998) ‘Behind the ballot box:
Norris, P. (2002) ‘Ballots not bullets: Electoral engineering in the Arab World’,
Testing consociational theories of ethnic Middle East Report, 209: 12–15, 42.
conflict, electoral systems, and democ- Pottie, D. (2002) ‘Party strife and political
ratization’, in A. Reynolds (ed.), The impasse in Zanzibar’s October 2000 elec-
architecture of democracy: Constitutional tions’, Representation, 38 (4): 340–50.
design, conflict management, and Powell, L.N. (1989) ‘Correcting for fraud:
democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, A quantitative reassessment of the Mississippi
pp. 206–47. ratification election of 1868’, Journal of
Norris, P. (2004) Electoral engineering: Voting Southern History, 55 (4): 633–58.
rules and political behaviour. Cambridge; Pravda, A. (1978) ‘Elections in communist party
Cambridge University Press. states’, in G. Hermet, R. Rose, and A. Rouquié
Oberst, R.C. and Weilage, A. (1990) (eds), Elections without choice. London:
‘Quantitative tests of electoral fraud: The Macmillan, pp. 169–95.
1982 Sri Lankan referendum’, Corruption Rouquié, A. (1978) ‘Clientelist control and
and Reform, 5 (1): 49–62. authoritarian contexts’, in G. Hermet, R. Rose,
O’Gorman, F. (1996) ‘The culture of elections and A. Rouquié (eds), Elections without
in England: From the Glorious Revolution choice. London: Macmillan. pp. 9–35.
to the First World War, 1688–1914’, in Schaffer, F.C. (2002) ‘Might cleaning up elec-
E. Posada-Carbó (ed.), Elections before tions keep people away from the polls?
democracy: The history of elections in Europe Historical and comparative perspectives’,
and Latin America. Basingstoke: Macmillan, International Political Science Review, 23:
pp. 17–31. 69–84.

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


ELECTORAL CORRUPTION 409

Schaffer, F.C. (2005) Clean elections and the Electoral authoritarianism: The dynamics of
great unwashed: Vote buying and voter edu- unfree competition. Boulder: Lynne Rienner,
cation in the Philippines (Occasional Paper pp. 1–23.
No. 21) School of Social Science, Institute for Scott, J.C. (1969) ‘Corruption, machine politics
Advanced Study, Princeton, NJ. and political change’, American Political
Schaffer, F.C. (ed.) (2007) Elections for sale: Science Review, 63 (4): 1142–58.
The causes an consequences of vote buying. Taylor, C.L. and Hudson, M. (1972) World
Boulder: Lynne Rienner. handbook of political and social indicators.
Schaffer F.C. and Schedler, A. (2005, November– New Haven: Yale University Press.
December) What Is vote buying? The limits of Tomz, M. and Van Houweling, R.P.
the market model. Paper presented at the (2003) ‘How does voting equipment
conference on Poverty, Democracy and affect the racial gap in voided ballots?’,
Clientelism: The Political Economy of Vote American Journal of Political Science, 47 (1):
Buying, Stanford University. 46–60.
Schedler, A. (2002a) ‘Elections without democ- Wilson, A. (2005a) Virtual politics: Faking
racy: The menu of manipulation’, Journal of democracy in the post-Soviet world. New
Democracy, 13 (2): 36–50. Haven and London: Yale University Press.
Schedler, A. (2002b) ‘The nested game of Wilson, A. (2005b) Ukraine’s Orange
democratization by elections’, International Revolution. New Haven: Yale University
Political Science Review, 23 (1): 103–22. Press.
Schedler, A. (2004) Degrees and patterns of Wiseman, J.A. (1992) ‘Early post-redemocrati-
party competition in electoral autocracies. zation elections in Africa’, Electoral Studies,
Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of 11 (4): 279–91.
the American Political Science Association, Zovatto, D. and Payne, M. (2003, October)
Chicago, IL. Trends in electoral participation in Latin
Schedler, A. (2006) ‘The logic of electoral America. Paper prepared for the 2003 CSES
authoritarianism’, in A. Schedler (ed.), Plenary Session, Stockholm.

9781412919760_Chap21.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:25:56 PM


22
Comparative Federalism
David McKay

INTRODUCTION the 1950s and 1960s.1 Within political science


the study of federalism also waned – partly
In relation to the study of other political insti- because practitioners of the new behavioural
tutions and processes in comparative govern- approach dismissed the normative assump-
ment, scholarly work on federalism has always tions adopted by so many of its proponents.
had uncertain status within political science. Most recently, the study of federalism in
There are a number of reasons for this. First, comparative context has experienced some-
students of federalism have long tended to thing of a renaissance as federal arrangements
conflate the normative and scientific by ascrib- have been advanced both as possible solutions
ing political desiderata such as freedom or to inter-ethnic and religious conflicts in such
democracy to the institution of federalism places as Indonesia, Belgium and South Africa
when this is patently not always the case. As a and as the basis for inter-state cooperation as
result many studies in the area have been dis- in the case of the European Union (EU).
missed as subjective and unscientific (Riker, The purpose of this review is threefold. First,
1964, Chapter 1). Second, because federalism to catalogue the ways in which the comparative
involves the analysis of sub national govern- study of federalism has evolved over the last
ment it has attracted scholars with interests in several decades; second, to evaluate the most
state and local government and in particular, recent scholarly trends in the subject area
American inter-governmental relations. Often, with a special emphasis on rational choice and
the resulting research has been largely descrip- comparative government approaches; third, to
tive or has limited implications beyond the speculate on future developments in the study
limited world of US state and local politics. of comparative federalism.
Third, the appeal of federal institutional
arrangements has waxed and waned with
changes in intellectual and political fashion.
Having been popular among utopian thinkers COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM
prior to the Second World War and again RESEARCH IN HISTORICAL
among decolonizing powers in the post war PERSPECTIVE
period, federalism as a novel institutional
device declined in popularity with the failure Early approaches to the study of federalism
of so many post colonial federations during including Althusius’s seminal 1603 work

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:32:34 PM


COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM 411

Politica stressed the idea of autonomous ter- of polity. Intuitively it is obvious that federal-
ritorial units as part of broader political com- ism is most likely to work in the context of
munities. Althusius argued for freedom for ethnically or culturally similar and contiguous
the City of Emden from both the regional collections of states that would reap some
Calvinist lord and the more distant Catholic advantage from association with a larger
emperor. To this end he propounded the idea entity. For this reason early political science
of territorial hierarchies where each unit studies of federalism strove to identify the
would have some autonomy in its rightfully likely necessary conditions for federation
assigned area (for a discussion, see Friedrich, formation. Having observed the experience of
1968, chapter 2). Implicit in this scheme was the USA, Switzerland, Canada and other
the theme of effective state autonomy in the federations, most identified the existence of
context of a larger community – in this case a ‘common interest’ as the spur to federation.
Christendom – a view that was later rein- Hence in 1957, Karl Deutsch named the
forced by the Kantian notion of a community ‘essential’ conditions of federation as:
of independent nation states each committed
to perpetuating peaceful co-existence in a 1. mutual compatibility of main values;
broader community of nations (Kant, 1784; 2. a distinctive way of life;
in Reiss, 1970). 3. expectation of stronger economic ties or gains;
Thus early conceptions of federalism 4. marked increase in administrative capabilities of
belonged more to the genus confederal rather at least some participating units;
than federal. Few argued for political arrange- 5. superior economic growth on the part of at least
some participating units;
ments involving constitutionally assigned
6. superior economic growth;
powers between two levels of government. 7. unbroken links of social communication both
In other words, federal association was seen geographically between territories and socio-
more as a voluntary arrangement than one logically between different social strata;
that sealed relations between central and 8. a broadening of the political elite;
regional powers in a negotiated and perma- 9. mobility of persons at least among the politically
nent pact. Such arrangements could apply in relevant strata; and
the absence of democratic institutions that 10. a multiplicity of ranges of communications and
would be required to endorse the territorial transactions (Deutsch et al. 1957: 58).
division of power. All this was to change
with the signing of the United States consti- Critics quickly noted that this list specified
tution in 1789 which enshrined the concept neither the necessary let alone sufficient con-
of citizens holding identities at two levels, ditions for federations, and in particular points
the state and the federal. At the same time 1, 2, 6, 8 and 10 were absent in many of the
powers were assigned to the two tiers of gov- newer federations such as Malaysia and India
ernment establishing the notion of shared (Birch, 1966). Moreover some groups of
sovereignty. So the US Constitution estab- countries displayed most or all of these fea-
lished a political authority where both govern- tures (for example the Nordic states) but had
mental power and citizen identity were shared not formed federations. Attempts to refine
between different levels within a single polity. Deutsch’s taxonomy by developing the
And this division of authority was legitimized ‘common interest’ condition failed to advance
through popular, democratic approval. This the argument much further (Wheare, 1964:
construct has become the standard measure of 37–38; Watts, 1966: 42). One obvious prob-
federalism ever since (see, for example, lem related to the fact that federation as a
Wheare, 1964, Chapter 1). political form emerged in a wide variety of
From the outset both scholars and political historical, geographical and political settings.
practitioners understood that federal arrange- In some – for example, the Soviet Union and
ments were appropriate only in certain types Yugoslavia, hegemonic political parties were

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:32:34 PM


412 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

the driving force behind federation among of European integration who sometimes
groups of states that had little in the way of imply something inevitable about ‘ever closer
common interest between them. In others, union.’ As Noel Malcolm (1995) has noted
political parties exploited territorial entities federalist ideologues seem to subscribe to
inherited from colonial rule and forged new some ‘kind of cartographic mysticism that
federal arrangements out of them. In some, intuits that certain large areas of the map are
these arrangements succeeded (India), in crying out to merge as single geographical
others they faltered and ended in civil war units’ (p. 53). This partiality is part of a long
(Nigeria) and in others again they failed line of idealist views of supranational gov-
almost immediately after inception (the East ernance stretching all the way back to
African and West Indian federations). Emmanuel Kant and which gained particular
The failure of federations raises the ques- currency during the latter half of the nine-
tion of sustainability. After all, specifying the teenth century and between the two world
conditions for federation formation becomes wars. After 1945, realism rather than ideal-
a meaningful exercise only if the federation ism dominated thinking on international
is sustained over a reasonable span of time. cooperation, but in Europe at least many
One of the first scholars to address this ques- assumed that the drive towards functional
tion was Thomas Franck in his edited 1968 integration might lead to federalist political
collection Why Federations Fail where he arrangements on the Continent of Europe
argues that although common interest of (see Duff et al., 1994, and sources cited). As
some sort such as protection against an exter- will be developed later, the increasing powers
nal threat or the need for economic growth of the EU led to fierce debate in the literature
may be a necessary condition for federation as to how to classify the EU political system,
building, it is certainly not sufficient on its with many scholars believing that it was
own. Instead, what is needed is an ideologi- essentially sui generis and not amenable to
cal commitment on the need for federation. comparison with other systems, while others
This may come from elites or from the viewed the EU as a nascent federal state.
broader society, although in the case of post As should be clear from this brief review,
colonial states (the main focus of his study) by the 1960s the study of federalism in com-
federation building was likely to come from parative context had not advanced much
elites (Franck, 1968, Chapter 5). Although beyond simple classifications and descrip-
Franck suggests that an ideological commit- tions. In addition, many students of the subject
ment to federation is clearly linked to eco- were also proponents of federalism as a pre-
nomic and political interest, he does not ferred political system, thus blurring the line
develop the relationship in ways that allow between scientific inquiry and political advo-
for causal inference. In other words why cacy. Over the subsequent three decades,
some elites favour federation while others do however, all this was to change with the pub-
not and how this relates to territorial or lication of theoretically more ambitious and
national interests, is left unexplained, as is empirically more sophisticated studies which
the longer term elite commitment to federa- we will now review.
tion that Franck claims is needed to sustain
polities over time.
As a result, it is not surprising that ideo- Rational choice approaches
logical explanations of federation formation
are open to accusations of tautology, that is: The first major theoretical breakthrough in
that the existence of federal political institu- the study of comparative federalism came
tions can be explained by the process of with the publication of William Riker’s
‘federalizing’ (Riker, 1975: 131). This accu- Federalism: Origins, Operation, Significance
sation has often been levelled at proponents in 1964 (Riker, 1964). Having surveyed the

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:32:34 PM


COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM 413

origins of all modern federations, Riker the structure of issues for political advantage.
concluded that in all cases the decision to However, Riker introduced a number of
form a federation was a rational bargain insights into the study of federalism that
between regional and national political elites were later to result in important research.
both of whom saw some advantage in form- Apart from seeing federation formation as a
ing a larger association of states. Further, in rational bargain, Riker also understood the
all cases the bargain involved two conditions importance of political party structure and
that Riker claimed must always be present function in the sustainability of federations
before a successful bargain is struck. First, over time. Hence, inclusive political parties
a desire on the part of those offering the with appeals across diverse territories and
bargain peacefully to expand territory by social groups were more likely to sustain
combining constituent governments into a federation than territorially and socially
new political entity in order to meet an exter- exclusive parties. He also understood the
nal military threat or to prepare for diplo- importance of the relationship between par-
matic aggrandizement. Second, for those ties and interests on the one hand and politi-
accepting the bargain some sacrifice of cal institutions on the other. Hence federations
political control is exchanged for the promise were more likely to function effectively if
of security provided by the new federal diverse regional interests were represented at
government. Both in his 1964 volume and the national level in senates or second cham-
a subsequent 1975 version, Riker is sure of bers. Indeed, drawing on the American expe-
the empirical validity of his theory. As he rience, Riker realized that the entire
claims: constitutional structure needed to be con-
In order to prove this hypothesis I have examined structed in ways that facilitated effective
all instances of the creation of federalism since bargaining and coalition formation between
1786 … For those federalisms that have survived, regional and national interests (Riker, 1975).
I am able to show that the two conditions existed It was not until the 1990s and beyond,
at the origin; and for those that failed, I am able to
however, that further empirical research
show that either the conditions never existed, or
they existed only momentarily. Though such evi- using Riker’s theoretical insights was forth-
dence does not constitute absolute proof of the coming. Peter Ordeshook and his collabora-
hypothesis, it comes as close to a proof as a non- tors was one of the first to elaborate on the
experimental science can offer (Riker, 1964: 10, relationship between federalism and consti-
see also Riker, 1975).
tutional design by stressing the particular
Riker later accepted that the threat might advantages that the United States enjoyed at
be internal (as in the case of Malaysia and its inception. A longstanding democratic and
Nigeria) as well as external (see Birch, 1966; constitutional tradition, even as early as
Riker, 1975). Although Riker’s theoretical 1789, became the foundation of a democratic
insights represented a major advance it did federalism. By way of contrast the task for
not immediately spawn further research – emerging democratic federations such as
although it did provoke criticism from estab- post Soviet Russia was much more daunting.
lished students of the subject (see Dikshit, This opus came to full fruition with the
1971, 1975: 222–7; King, 1982). Instead, for publication of Filippov et al.’s Designing
much of the 1970s and 1980s federalism Federalism: A Theory of Self Sustainable
studies remained either country specific or Federal Institutions in 2004.
were confined to theoretically-limited taxo- Drawing on the experience of a number
nomic approaches (Watts, 1996). Riker him- of political systems and especially the
self left the sub area and devoted most of the ex-Communist states, the authors’ main objec-
rest of his academic career to the application tive is to specify those design rules and modes
of rational choice theory to coalition building of representation that would sustain federa-
and to heresthetics or the manipulation of tions over the longer term. With respect to

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:32:34 PM


414 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

federations, special rules should apply that representation because delegates are more
have a specifically territorial dimension, likely to defer to regional interests rather than
namely: ‘go national’ and betray their regional base; and
separation of powers rather than parliamentary
1. ‘A system of individual level incentives designed arrangements because independent legislatures
to ensure federal stability should apply not to are more likely to check the centralizing ten-
individual citizens but to political elites, since it dencies of chief executives. As can easily be
is they, even in a democracy, who lead society inferred from the above, Filippov et al. are actu-
from one equilibrium to another’ (Filippov et al., ally contrasting ‘favourable’ US institutional
2004: 163). Both regional and national elites
arrangements with the ‘unfavourable’ institu-
must accept what Filippov et al. call Level 1
constraints, or an acceptance of the provisions
tional features of those of Canada and post
of the constitutional settlement. Elites should Soviet Russia.
also accept Level 2 constraints or the rules of the The same applies to their deliberations on
game and informal norms and procedures inher- how political parties interact with political
ent in the constitutional settlement that govern institutions. Inclusive parties with little or no
day-to-day bargaining and negotiation. territorially specific base are preferred to
2. The constitution should provide for ‘effective territorially exclusive parties, and such devices
co-ordination devices [that] must give local and as the separation of powers, proportional
regional political elites an incentive to uphold representation, power sharing and bicameral-
federative constraints even when their con- ism, are more likely to encourage the growth
stituents prefer otherwise’. So, individual level
of decentralized, inclusive parties.
incentives (what Filippov et al. call Level 3 rules)
must operate in such a way as to legitimise the
As the authors readily admit their work
constraints inherent in federal arrangements owes a great intellectual debt to William
(Filippov et al., 2004: 163). Riker, but they develop Riker’s perspectives
3. In addition the federal constitution ‘must create radically by concentrating not on the origins
(office related) rewards for national [federal] of federation but on the conditions that sus-
elites that dissuade them from overstepping tain federations over time (Filippov et al.,
their constitutionally prescribed authority and 2004, chapter 1). Working in the same tradi-
to acquiesce in the legitimate authority of the tion, Bednar, Eskridge and Ferejohn, argue
regional governments’ (Filippov et al., 2004: that legal rules alone are insufficient to contain
163–4). central governments intent on predatory judi-
4. The final constitutional principle is ‘federal sta-
cial expansion of their powers (Bednar et al.,
bility requires that regional and national elites
maintain some (possibly evolving) consensus
2001; see also Bednar et al., 1996). In addition
over the definitions of “constitutionally pre- structural constitutional constraints are
scribed” and “legitimate authority”’ (Filippov required. Like Filippov et al., Bednar et al. are
et al., 2004: 164). This appears to suggest that trying to solve the intellectual puzzle of what
acceptance of the basic design rules should per- sort of constitutional architecture should be
sist through time and eventually be enshrined in employed to ensure that state and federal
custom and practice. governments stay within their legitimate
spheres of activity. They too opt for devices
Filippov et al. also specify appropriate modes that formally fragment central authority such
of representation that will facilitate cooperation as the separation of powers. However sophis-
bargaining rather than conflict and confronta- ticated the analyses, however, all of these
tion between the parties to the federal bargain. efforts face a familiar problem: how,
It is easy to infer which modes of representa- in diverse political and cultural contexts do
tion are most likely to uphold these consti- you create ‘appropriate’ constitutional struc-
tutional principles. They include within as tures given inherited patterns of power and
opposed to without representation, or the formal authority? Creating inclusive parties, for
incorporation of the states into decision making example, is highly problematical if existing
in upper houses; delegated rather than direct historically determined patterns of power

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:32:34 PM


COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM 415

encourage territorially specific exclusive par- One, in the rational choice tradition, focussed
ties. Aware of this problem the authors con- on the relationship between the incentives of
struct a fourth analytical category, level ‘0’ to political actors and institutional environ-
characterize those features of political sys- ments. The method was deductive with
tems that are ‘beyond design’ (Filippov et al., empirical examples used to confirm or dis-
2004: 294–98). Included in this list are such confirm theoretical insights. The second
features as the presence or absence of a approach grew out of the traumas of the
democratic tradition, public access to deci- Second World War, with scholars searching
sion making, the status of public office hold- for patterns of political development that
ers and the absence of ethnic, religious and might help reduce conflict and succour
linguistic cleavages with a history of redis- democracy (see in particular the work of
tributive conflict. In other words, they are Stein Rokkan, for a review see Flora, 1994).
aware of the fact that cultural and historical This approach was more inductive and taxo-
baggage cannot easily be manipulated merely nomic. By classifying diverse political sys-
by constitutional design. In the end the tems students of comparative politics
authors are forced to concede that ‘one gradually built up a bank of knowledge in
should not assume that an endogenously sus- such areas as electoral and party systems,
tainable institutional equilibrium within the government structures and public opinion.
federal format is even theoretically attainable We have already referred to the post war
in every contiguous part of the world’ federalism literature that attempted to make
(Filippov et al., 2004: 331, emphasis added). sense out of diverse patterns of federalization
A further problem with the more recent and thus identify general patterns and trends.
rational choice literature is a reluctance to be We also noted the normative element to
empirically inclusive. Typically, authors look much of this literature with some writers
for examples from the American experience conflating the process of federalizing with a
or, as in the case of Filippov et al., from preference for federal institutional arrange-
Communist and post Communist states that ments. By the 1990s, however, a number
confirm their theoretical insights. As a result of scholars were avoiding these pitfalls
selection bias tends to confirm their general and were instead intent on more careful and
hypotheses. But evidence from two other fed- comprehensive taxonomies of federal and
eral systems – India and Switzerland – raises federal like arrangements. Two of the most
the greatest intellectual challenge. India is ambitious of these taxonomies was Daniel
interesting because it seems to fail almost Elazar’s Federal Systems of the World: A
every institutional and constitutional design Handbook of Federal, Confederal and
test, bar one – the existence of inclusive Autonomy Arrangements (1994), and Ronald
political parties. Yet it has survived, and even Watts’ Comparing Federal Systems in the
thrived for more than half a century. 1990s (1996). Both of these authors are sen-
Switzerland is interesting for quite different sitive to the sheer complexity of federal-like
reasons, namely its ability to hold together and arrangements, and also to the fact that some
maintain a national identity in the almost com- political systems, were very difficult to char-
plete absence of central authority. It is for this acterize. In some systems constitutional cen-
reason that Switzerland has been cited as an tralization was accompanied by de facto
exemplar for the nascent European Union decentralization (Canada); in others the
federation. We will return to this point later. powers of the central authorities were greater
than in many unitary systems (India); in
others again a degree of administrative
Comparative politics approaches and cultural decentralization was paired
with extreme political centralization (the
The study of comparative politics has taken Soviet Union). In addition, by the end of the
two distinct (and now converging) paths. twentieth century the world had acquired a

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:32:34 PM


416 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

large number of non-federal political systems associations and the like to develop into fed-
ranging from the United Nations to func- erations. Indeed the only plausible recent
tional economic associations including the example is the transition of the EEC to the
EU, Mercosur and NAFTA. So apart from EU, and as we will see later, even this claim is
the obvious centralization/decentralization disputed. In Figure 22.1, there is often move-
dimension, at least two others became ment between the top left hand and middle
obvious. One was the extent of coercive as cells and some from imperial to federal but
opposed to consensual exercise of power almost none from functional, confederal or
among member states, and the other was the condominial to federal.
extent of mass public involvement, through In one important respect the taxonomic
democratic institutions, in decision making literature confirms Riker’s assertion that what
processes. While it is difficult to capture all explains federations is the presence of an
of the possible arrangements in one diagram, external or internal threat that is sufficiently
Phillip Schmitter had made a reasonable serious for collectivities of states to cede
attempt at it. Hence in Figure 22.1 ‘Coerced’ power to a central authority capable of avert-
federations such as in the Soviet Union, ing the threat. Absent the threat – or the
Yugoslavia and Imperial India would be mutual appreciation of the threat – and there
placed in the top right hand box, while is no incentive to form a federation, which
modern democratic federations would be strongly suggests that the causal dynamic
placed in the bottom right hand box. The behind other regional associations is quite
early EEC and most regional economic asso- different.
ciations would be classified as functional This accepted, Riker clearly oversimpli-
associations with consensual decision rules fied the nature of the threat. Using a crude
and low exit costs for members. realist perspective he lumped together cases
The problem with such taxonomies, how- as varied as the United States, the Soviet
ever, is that they tell you nothing about why Union, Malaysia and India. All did experi-
regional associations take the shape that ence external or internal threats of sorts,
they do, nor do they explain the transition but in wildly different historical and geopo-
from one form of association to another. In litical circumstances. Writing in 2001 Alfred
fact, it is extremely rare for regional economic Stepan used comparative method to refine

Cooperative Low Moderate High

Unanimity
Symbolic Status Conferring Imperial
(Holy Roman (British India
Empire) USSR)

Consensus Functional Confederal Consortial


(early EEC, (later EC) (Cold War NATO)
regional trade
associations)
Majority
UN Condominial FEDERAL
(EU?) (USA, Switzerland)

Integrative
Figure 22.1 Forms of regional cooperation and integration decision making rules x costs
and benefits of membership
Source: Schmitter (2007) adapted from Figure 1

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:32:35 PM


COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM 417

the Rikerian perspective by distinguishing As such it fails to provide a theoretical


between ‘coming together’, ‘holding together’ framework that allows us to draw meaningful
and ‘putting together’ federations. According causal inferences from a universe of cases.
to Stepan, in the first category which includes Instead, we are provided with refinements
the USA, Switzerland and Australia, rela- and modifications of Riker’s opus. Stepan’s
tively autonomous states come together vol- major theoretical claim is that federal institu-
untarily and bargain between themselves on tions – that is, the detailed arrangements for
the best form of federal arrangements. In all the building of coalitions and exercise of ter-
these cases, security is the motivating force, ritorially based vetoes – really do matter for
so they conform nicely to the Rikerian imper- public policy, something that he claims Riker
ative. Holding together federations are char- denied (p. 337). Yet what Riker argued was
acterized by parliamentary decisions to create that institutions are essentially expressions of
federal structures in order to placate ethnic, political power that ultimately is rooted in
religious or linguistic differences. India, culture and history. They are, if you like,
Spain and Switzerland are examples here. intervening variables between culture and
Finally ‘putting together’ federations are cre- policy. Yet in his later work on coalitions and
ated by a coercive centralizing power intent in the work of his intellectual heirs such as
on incorporating previously independent Shepsle and Weingast, the role of institutions
states. The USSR in 1922 is the exemplar is elevated to a new height. Often they help
case here (Stepan, 2001: 320–22). shape preferences and incentives rather then
Stepan further refined the Rikerian perspec- merely reflect them – something that
tive by distinguishing between asymmetrical Ordeshook and his collaborators were to
and symmetrical federalism which he defines refine with specific reference to the sustain-
both in terms of socio-economic and constitu- ability of federal systems of government.
tional asymmetry. Thus some federations are The final strand in the comparative politics
multinational (Canada, Spain, Belgium) while literature relates to the evolution of the
others (USA, Germany) are not. Asymmetry European Union (EU) from a system based on
holds important lessons for bargaining between limited functional integration to one with most
groups and often results in constitutional asym- of the hallmarks of federalism. For students of
metry or special provisions designed to accom- the subject the EU presents something of an
modate one or more sub group within the intellectual challenge. It is the only system in
federation. India has many such provisions, recent history that has migrated to the bottom
while the United States has none (Stepan, 2001: left hand cell from one of the others cells in
323–33). Stepan makes further distinctions Figure 22.1. Moreover, at precisely the time
including what he calls ‘demos enabling’ versus when the EU acquired the trappings of feder-
‘demos constraining’ institutional structures. alism, the external military threat from the
So while all federations are ipso facto centre Soviet bloc was declining rapidly, effectively
constraining some (Russia) inhibit popular par- to disappear by the early 1990s. Why then
ticipation in decision making while others have so many European countries ceded
(Switzerland) facilitate it (pp. 333–37). Finally, important area of national sovereignty to what
with Riker, he accepts that the most important increasingly resembles a federal state? Until
institutional feature for the adaptability and quite recently students of the European Union
survival of federations is the nature of the party had great difficulty answering these questions.
system and in particular whether or not political In particular, the ‘second wave’ of EU schol-
parties are territorially inclusive or exclusive ars (after the early integration theorists), who
(pp. 354–60). classified the EU as an international organiza-
While Stepan’s work claims to advance tion characterized by inter- and intra-state
our knowledge of federalism ‘beyond Riker’ patterns of cooperation and conflict, simply
it is essentially taxonomic in approach. lacked the analytical tools to make sense of its

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:32:35 PM


418 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

growing state like characteristics (for the most variety of international organization. As a
influential of these studies, see Moravscik, result, all the accumulated research in com-
1998). Nation states may conclude bargains parative politics from elections and voting to
with neighbours to accommodate domestic parties and regulation, could be utilized with
economic interests but why should they cede specific application to the EU (see, for exam-
important aspects of their sovereignty to ple, Hesse and Wright, 1996; Menon and
supranational political institutions with all the Schain, 2006; Nicolaidis and Howse, 2001).
trappings of statehood, including citizenship With the coming of the new EU draft constitu-
and a common currency? tion, further comparisons were drawn from
The answer was to be provided, at least in democratic and constitutional theory (Dobson
part, not from the international relations and Follesdal, 2004). In effect, federalist
scholars but from students of comparative theory and comparative politics replaced inter-
politics and especially those influenced by national relations as the main intellectual
rational choice theory. In particular, David framework for the study of the European
McKay (1999b) in Federalism and European Union, with some scholars making systematic
Union attempts to explain the transformation comparisons between the EU and other feder-
of the EU from an international organization ations (see McKay, 2001; Treschel, 2006). In
to a federal like state in Rikerian terms. He Designing Europe: Comparative Lessons for
argues that the ceding of national sovereignty the European Union, McKay (2001) was one
in monetary policy was motivated by a desire of the first specifically to use comparative
on most of the signatories at Maastricht to method to place the EU in historical context.
transfer the control of inflation to a European In particular, he links regional/national identi-
Central Bank, because of the inherent politi- ties to the policy scope of the federal govern-
cal problems of solving this problem domes- ment in six federal systems and relates these
tically. German motives were somewhat outcomes to party structures and constitutional
different: they saw in Maastricht an opportu- arrangements (McKay, 2001: Chapter 9). Like
nity for diplomatic aggrandizement that many other scholars working in the field he
would result from playing a major part in a identifies the highly devolved Swiss system as
larger territorial entity. And in order to avoid holding the most lessons for the EU (Chap. 9;
inflationary recidivism on the part of past also Treschel, 2006).
offenders such as Italy, they insisted, via the Although the federal status of the EU can
Convergence Criteria and the Stability and be exaggerated – especially given the limited
Growth Pact, that these countries be forced to membership of European Monetary Union
adopt German standards of fiscal rectitude (EMU), recent enlargements and the ratifica-
(McKay, 1999a). McKay specifically argues tion failure of the draft constitution – there is
that the EU’s federal status applies only to no doubt that applying comparative method
EMU members, for only these countries have to Europe has given a considerable boost to
ceded complete control of one of the main research on federalism, although as we will
policy areas associated with statehood to a discuss in the concluding section, serious
supranational institution (McKay, 1999b, research lacunae in the disciplinary sub area
Chapter 8). Clearly this perspective extends remain.
Riker’s rationale for federalising to economic
as well as traditional security threats.
Other scholars were quick to note that the Comparative federalism: What we
new policy responsibilities of the EU com- know, what we don’t know and
bined with a constitutional architecture that
what we should know
looked for all intents and purposes like that of
a nation state, justified classifying the EU as a As this brief review shows, early research on
nascent federation rather than a sui generis comparative federalism was bedevilled by the

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:32:35 PM


COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM 419

conflation of scientific inquiry with normative This is clearly the case with regard to Quebec,
concerns. During the 1950s and 1960s most of Scotland and both communities in Belgium.
the leading scholars in the area were also advo- In all these cases novel institutional devices,
cates of federalism as a system of government. including referenda, have been employed to
In part this derived from the generally self- maintain the integrity of states and policy
congratulary mood within American political makers in these and other examples such as
science at the time and what was widely South Africa and Northern Ireland have been
regarded as the success of US federalism. quick to innovate on the basis of shared expe-
Riker’s work transformed the scholarly land- rience. Much more difficult are those cases
scape by demonstrating that federal arrange- where democratic processes are absent or are
ments were the result of hard fought bargains incomplete, such as in Indonesia and Russia
between state and central level politicians, where force has been used and local political
whose need for external or internal security preferences have been largely ignored.
trumped all other considerations including More difficult again are those cases where
economic advantage and other non-security an external power attempts to build demo-
common interests. It was not until the 1990s, cratic federalism in complex ethnic and cul-
however, that federalism studies progressed tural states with little in the way of a democratic
further, partly in response to the challenges of tradition such as Iraq and Afghanistan. Here
building democratic polities in post Communist mistakes have been legion with, in the absence
states and partly in response to developments in of a return to despotism, the prospects of even-
the European Union. Valuable contributions tual territorial disintegration, very high.
both from rational choice theorists and from It is with respect to these latter groups of
students of comparative politics advanced our cases that our knowledge is most limited. For
understanding of federalism and in particular while millions of words have been written on
the relationship between institutional arrange- the EU’s slow transition to federalism and
ments and the sustainability of federal systems many more on the evolution of American fed-
of government. In sum, the most important eralism, we know relatively little about the
advance is the addition of a territorial dimen- precise dynamics of how, for example, Indian
sion to both the rational choice literature and to federalism works (but see Lijphart, 1996;
comparative politics approaches. With regard to Manor, 1998; Mitra, 2005).
the latter, for example, the seminal work by Future research should, therefore, employ
Lijphart and others (see in particular, Lijphart, those methods and approaches drawn from
1977) on those consociational devices that can the established federalism literature to fur-
best sustain democracy in multi-cultural societ- ther our understanding of the following:
ies, has been developed and refined to include
territoriality.2 In this sense we are now much 1. The Puzzle of Indian Federalism. As previously
more sensitive to the problems inherent in hold- noted, India’s constitutional arrangements are
ing multi-cultural states together. Long gone hardly conducive to sustainable federation yet
are the days when colonial administrators Indian federalism has not only survived, but has
almost casually imposed federal arrangements also thrived in an increasingly democratic context
in inappropriate contexts such as East Africa, in recent years. Most commentators point to the
the West Indies or (in its original form, at least) party system as the major integrative force in the
system, yet we know relatively little about the ter-
in Nigeria.
ritorial dimension to Indian political parties.
Another advance is in relation to the link 2. Would federalism help hold together multi-cultural
between federalism and democratic prefer- states such as Indonesia that are making a transi-
ences. Few, if any, democratic federations tion to democracy. After a long period of despot-
today would use coercion to maintain the ter- ism, Indonesia is experimenting with devolution
ritorial integrity of the whole, should a major- to accommodate its ethnic variety. Could asym-
ity in one of the sub units wish to secede. metric federal arrangements help legitimize the

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:32:35 PM


420 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Indonesian state among minorities? Even more where many interesting questions remain but
challenging are cases such as Tibet in China and where the opportunity costs of further research
Chechnya in Russia where the transition to democ- are high. This would include using the US as a
racy has been halting or has yet to begin. comparator case both for the EU and elsewhere
3. Are federal arrangements appropriate in states
when there are so many more pressing research
such as Iraq and Afghanistan presently subject to
military intervention by external powers? Can the
cases where the American experience is of lim-
post intervention end game in these countries ited utility. It is also clear that the priority
include federalism and if so of what variety? As should be on countries making the transition to
with the Soviet Union, ‘solution’ might include democracy or those emerging, very often in a
secession and federalism for some part or parts highly untidy manner, from dictatorial regimes,
of the remaining states. for it is in these cases that federal institutional
4. How might the federalism in such countries arrangements may be useful in reducing con-
as Argentina, Brazil and Mexico evolve in rap- flict and reconciling differences. But to echo
idly changing political and economic contexts? Riker, there is nothing intrinsically meritorious
Hitherto, federalism in these countries has been about federalism. Whether it works or not is
viewed as ancillary to other patterns of political
strictly a matter for empirical enquiry. Should
power, and especially the role of the military,
hegemonic political parties and dominant politi-
unitary arrangements or secession be more
cal elites. With globalization and democratiza- appropriate, then so be it. What is essential is
tion, however, constitutional arrangements do that scholars of the subject use comparative
provide the potential for the assertion of regional method in a theoretically informed manner
and provincial power organized as an opposi- when researching existing federations
tional force to central authority. and making judgements as to the appropriate-
5. What is the status of highly devolved regions ness of federal institutions in different
such as the Spanish autonomous regions and geographical contexts.
Scotland? In these and other cases the extent
of devolution has led some commentators to
assume that these areas are developing into
federal like entities (on Spain, see Burgess and
NOTES
Gagnon, 1993; on Scotland, see McKay, 2006).
Research on the changing entire of central/
1. The list of post colonial federations that failed is
regional relations in devolved systems would
quite long and includes the West Indies, East African
show how the incentives of regional and national Federation, The Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland,
politicians are changing in ways that might lead Malaysia (in part at least), Indonesia and Pakistan.
to even grater autonomy or even independence. 2. In many respects reconciling cultural difference
6. Can the EU continue on its ‘federalizing’ path is easier in those states where ethnic and other
given recent enlargements and problems with groups are territorially separated. In such instances
ratifying a new constitution? Little of the literature the option of secession is usually available. Where
on enlargement adopts a federalist approach, yet groups are territorially mixed as in Northern Ireland,
it is clear that the social and economic inequalities Brussels, the Baghdad region of Iraq and parts of
between new members and existing members are South Africa, federal arrangements are of more lim-
ited utility, although it is possible to have federal-like
such that asymmetric arrangements in such areas
institutions in combination with other consociational
as monetary policy and right to work will likely devices. Lijphart’s work concentrated on these latter
continue for the foreseeable future. cases, rather then on federalism per se.

This is by no means an exhaustive list but in


all cases the main challenge involves specifying
the institutional conditions for sustaining fed- REFERENCES AND BIBLIOGRAPHY
eral arrangements and confronting the often
intractable problem of reconciling the ‘ideal’ Bednar, J., Eskridge, W.N. and Ferejohn, J.
conditions with prevailing patterns of political (2001) ‘A political theory of federalism’, in
power rooted in culture and history. It would, of J. Ferejohn, J.N. Rakove and R. Riley (eds),
course, be possible to produce another list Constitutional culture and democratic rule.

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:32:35 PM


COMPARATIVE FEDERALISM 421

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Friedrich, C.J. (1968) Trend of federalism


pp. 223–67. in theory and practice. London: Pall Mall
Bednar, J., Ferejohn, J. and Garrett, G. (1996) Press.
‘The politics of European federalism’, Hesse, J.J. and Wright, V. (eds) (1996)
International Review of Law and Economics, Federalizing Europe: The costs, benefits and
16 (2): 279–94. preconditions of federal political systems.
Birch, A.H. (1966) ‘Approaches to the study of Oxford: Oxford University Press.
federalism’, Political Studies, 14 (1): 15–33. Kant, I. (1970/1784) ‘Perpetual peace: A philo-
Burgess, M. (2000) Federalism and European sophical sketch’, in H. Reiss (ed.), Kant’s
Union. London: Routledge. political writings. Cambridge: Cambridge
Burgess, M. and Gagnon, A.G. (eds) (1993) University Press, pp. 93–130.
Comparative federalism and federation: Karmis, D. and Norman, W. (eds) (2005) Theories
Competing traditions and future directions. of federalism: A reader. London: Palgrave.
London: Harvester Wheatsheaf. King, P. (1982) Federalism and federation.
Deutsch, K., et al. (1957) Political community in London: Croom Helm.
the North Atlantic area. Princeton, NJ: Kymlicka, W. (2002) Contemporary political
Princeton University Press. philosophy: An introduction. Oxford:
Dikshit, R.D. (1971) ‘Military interpretations of Clarendon Press.
federal constitutions: A critique’, Journal of Lijphart, A. (1977) Democracy in plural socie-
Politics, 33 (2): 180–9. ties: A comparative exploration. New Haven:
Dikshit, R.D. (1975) The political geography of Yale University Press.
federalism: An enquiry into origins and sta- Lijphart, A. (1996) ‘The puzzle of Indian democ-
bility. New Delhi: Macmillan. racy: A consociational interpretation’,
Dobson, L. and Follesdal, A. (2004) Political American Political Science Review, 90 (2):
theory and the European Constitution. 258–68.
London: Routledge. Manor, J. (1998) ‘Making federalism work’,
Duff, A., Pinder, J. and Pryce, R. (eds) (1994) Journal of Democracy, 9 (3): 29–36.
Maastricht and beyond: Building the Malcolm, N. (1995) ‘The case against Europe’,
European Union. London: Routledge. Foreign Affairs, March/April.
Dyson, K. (ed.) (2002) European states and McKay, D. (1999a) ‘The political sustainability
the euro: Europeanization, variation and of European Monetary Union’, British Journal
convergence. Oxford: Oxford University of Political Science, 29 (4): 463–85.
Press. McKay, D. (1999b) Federalism and European
Elazar, D. (1987) Exploring federalism. Union: A Political Economy Perspective.
Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Elazar, D. (1994) Federal systems of the world: McKay, D. (2001) Designing Europe:
A handbook of federal, confederal and Comparative lessons from the federal
autonomy arrangements. Harlow, Essex: experience. Oxford: Oxford University
Longman. Press.
Filippov, M., Ordeshook, P.C. and Shvetsova, O. McKay, D. (2004) ‘The EU as a self
(2004) Designing federalism: a theory of self- sustaining federation: Specifying the consti-
sustainable federal institutions. Cambridge: tutional conditions’, in L. Dobson and
Cambridge University Press. A. Follesdal (eds), Political theory and
Flora, P. (ed.) (1994) State formation, nation- the European Constitution. London:
building, and mass politics in Europe: The Routledge.
theory of Stein Rokkan. Oxford: Oxford McKay, D. (2004) ‘William Riker on federalism:
University Press. Sometimes wrong but more right than
Forsyth, M. (1981) Union of states: The theory anyone else?’, Regional and Federal Studies,
and practice of confederation. Leicester: 14 (2): 167–86.
University of Leicester Press. Mckay, D. (2004) ‘What is Scotland: Incentives
Franck, T.M. (1968) Why federations fail: An ands Sustainability,’ in Iain Cameron (ed),
enquiry into the requisites for successful fed- Good Governance: Scottish and Swedish
eralism. New York: New York University Perspectives,’ Uppsala, Uppsala University,
Press. Faculty of Law, 2004, 23–38.

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:32:35 PM


422 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Menon, A. and Schain, M.A. (2006) Comparative Riker, W.H. (1982) Liberalism against populism:
federalism: The EU and the US in compara- A confrontation between the theory of
tive perspective. Oxford: Oxford University democracy and the theory of social choice.
Press. IL: Waveland Press.
Mitra, S.K. (2005) The puzzle of India’s govern- Riker, W.H. (1987) The development of
ance. Culture, context and comparative American federalism. Boston: Kluwer.
theory. London: Routledge. Riker, W.H. (1996) ‘European federation: Lessons
Moravcsik, A. (1998) The choice for Europe: of past experience’, in J.J. Hesse and V. Wright
Social purpose and state power from Messina (eds), Federalizing Europe: The costs, benefits
to Maastricht. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University and preconditions of federal political systems.
Press. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 9–24.
Nicolaidis, K. and Howse, R. (eds) (2001) The Riker, W.H. and Lemco, J. (1987) ‘The relation
federal vision: Legitimacy and levels of gov- between structure and stability in federal
ernance in the United States and the governments’, in W.H. Riker (1987), The
European Union. Oxford: Oxford University development of American federalism.
Press. Boston: Kluwer, pp. 113–34.
Norman, W.J. (2006) Negotiating nationalism: Schmitter, P.C. (2007) Regional cooperation
Nation-building, federalism and secession and regional integration: Concepts, meas-
in multilateral states. Oxford: Oxford urement and a bit of theory. Unpublished
University Press. manuscript. Fiesole, European University
Ordeshook, P.C. and Shetsova, O. (1997) Institute.
‘Federalism and constitutional design’, Stepan, A. (1999) ‘Federalism and democracy:
Journal of Democracy, 8 (1): 27–42. Beyond the US model’, Journal of Democracy,
Rabushka, A. and Shepsle, K.A. (1972) 10: 19–34.
Politics in plural societies: A theory of demo- Stepan, A. (2001) Arguing comparative poli-
cratic instability. Columbus, OH: Bobbs tics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Merrill. Treschel, A. (ed.) (2006) Towards a federal
Riker, W.H. (1955) ‘The Senate and American Europe? London: Routledge.
federalism’, American Political Science Watts, R.L. (1966) New federations: Experiments
Review, 49 (2): 452–69. in the Commonwealth. Oxford: Oxford
Riker, W.H. (1964) Federalism: Origins, opera- University Press.
tion, significance. Boston: Little, Brown. Watts, R.L. (1996) Comparing federal
Riker, W.H. (1975) ‘Federalism’, in F.I. systems in the 1990s. Ontario: Institute
Greenstein and N. Polsby (eds), The Handbook of Intergovernmental Relations, Queens
of political science, Volume V: Government University.
institutions and processes. Reading, MA: Wheare, K. (1964) Federal government (4th
Addison Wesley, 93–172. edition). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

9781412919760_Chap22.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:32:35 PM


23
Human Rights
Todd Landman

INTRODUCTION real constraints of international human rights


law and practice.
The analysis of the relationship between the The aspiration of the scholarly and practi-
state and citizen has a long tradition in com- cal community to establish a universal system
parative politics dating back to Aristotle’s for the promotion and protection of human
evaluation of ‘good’ and ‘corrupt’ forms of rights provides an extraordinary set of chal-
government and has included many strands of lenges for empirical research in comparative
research within the field, including constitu- politics. First, human rights are themselves
tions and political institutions; political behav- the product of normative political theory and
iour, choice, and agency; and subjective philosophy, which have attempted to estab-
experiences, cultural orientations, and percep- lish the foundations for their existence and to
tions of the good life under different forms of make them universally applicable. Human
government. Human rights, in their modern rights are of deep moral concern and neces-
manifestation, are a collection of individual sarily involve a particular set of value orien-
and group rights that establish certain entitle- tations to the kind of empirical research
ments for rights holders and corresponding carried out by comparativists interested in
legal obligations for duty bearers to uphold researching human rights problems. Second,
those rights, while the relationship between any comparison of human rights problems
rights holders and duty bearers is meant to be necessarily relies on some form of measure-
one of constraint, tolerance, accountability, ment, where the variation in a state’s ability
and respect. While human rights and the to respect, protect, and fulfil human rights
development of international and national serves as the main object of inquiry, and
systems for their protection are relatively new, where the comparison variously includes
the fuller notion of rights has a long history in large-N statistical analysis of many countries
normative political theory and the struggle for over time and space, small-N qualitative or
rights is grounded in the comparative political quantitative analysis of ‘most similar’ or
sociology of the modern state. The human ‘most different countries’, or a single country
rights movement has sought to make human study of human rights developments at the
rights universally applicable, indivisible, inter- national or sub-national level (Landman,
related, and mutually reinforcing in ways that 2002, 2003, 2008). Third, the establishment
no modern state is free from the potential and and proliferation of international human

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:34:29 PM


424 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

rights norms and mechanisms that seek to used to study human rights problems and
constrain state behaviour in ways that lead to how human rights measurement plays a
greater promotion and protection of human major role in these efforts. Third, it reviews
rights means that much comparative research many of the key extant comparative studies
in the field needs to take into account the on human rights, including global compara-
international dimension. This dimension tive quantitative studies, small-N quantitative
includes the theoretical insights and empiri- and qualitative studies, and key single case
cal realities of international relations and the studies that have made valuable contributions
precepts, assumptions, and analyses in the to the field. The fourth and final section
field of international law (Landman, 2005b; looks to the future of comparative human
Slaughter Burley, 1993). rights analysis.
The comparative politics of human rights
thus needs to overcome significant ontologi-
cal, epistemological, and methodological
challenges in order to provide valid, mean- HUMAN RIGHTS AS AN
ingful, and reliable inferences in this bur- OBJECT OF INQUIRY
geoning sub-field of research. Ontologically,
foundations for the existence of human rights Human rights are a modern set of individual
have not been established and the core sub- and collective rights that have been formally
stantive content of many human rights promoted and protected through international
remains contested, making the relative pro- and domestic law since the 1948 Universal
tection and/or enjoyment of human rights Declaration of Human Rights. Since 1948,
problematic for systematic comparative anal- the international community has established
ysis. Epistemologically, there remains a ten- a series of legally binding international trea-
sion between and among the normative ties that have expanded both the scope and
origins of human rights, different empirical depth of those rights that ought to be pro-
theories used to explain variation in their tected, such that they now include civil,
protection, and the use of rigorous compara- political, social, economic, and cultural
tive methods that draw on more positivistic rights. A comparative politics that seeks to
elements within the philosophy of social sci- make human rights its main object of inquiry
ence. Methodologically, the field has strug- must confront two significant challenges.
gled with providing systematic measures of The first involves the fact that normative
the variation in human rights protection over political theory and philosophy have failed to
time and space, as well as standard problems establish any consensus on the grounds for
associated with different comparative meth- the existence of human rights (Landman,
ods, such as indeterminate research designs, 2005a; Mendus, 1995). The second involves
omitted variable bias, and problems associ- the fundamental moral nature of human
ated with case selection. rights, which has led some to question
This chapter examines the different ways whether the theories and methods of contem-
in which the field of comparative politics has porary social science can be applied to their
sought to overcome these challenges. First, study especially those approaches that are
the chapter examines the normative and more positivistic in their stance (see Freeman,
empirical problems associated with human 2001, 2002). In other words, can comparativ-
rights as an object of inquiry, and then exam- ists conduct systematic research on social
ines how the field has concentrated on par- phenomena for which there are no agreed
ticular sets of human rights that have thus far philosophical foundations, and is such
been more tractable for systematic compara- research appropriate for studying something
tive analysis. Second, it outlines how large-N, that is fundamentally moral in character? A
small-N, and single case analysis have been comparative politics of human rights needs

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:34:29 PM


HUMAN RIGHTS 425

to address these questions and it is apparent and conditions of power whose struggles
from the burgeoning comparative literature have led to greater protection of rights
that scholars have begun to do so. (Barbalet, 1988; Foweraker and Landman,
There are several answers to the problem 1997; Marshall, 1963). While a large part of
concerning the absence of agreed philosophi- the political sociology and history of such
cal foundations for the existence of human struggles focuses on rights and citizenship
rights. First, there are many concepts and rights, more recent comparative politics
subjects of study in political science and the research has focused on the ways in which
social sciences more generally for which the struggle for human rights has led to state
there are no agreed philosophical founda- concessions and ultimately the development
tions. One need only think of social class, the of more rights protective political regimes
market, and/or democracy. And for some of (see Hawkins, 2002; Risse et al., 1999). For
these, such as democracy, there are no agreed some, human rights are the ‘bulwarks against
definitions, making them what Gallie (1956) the permanent threat of human evil’ (Mendus,
has called ‘essentially contested concepts’. 1995), while for others they are those sets of
The absence of agreed foundations or defini- protections that guarantee human agency
tions has not precluded vast amounts of (Ignatieff, 2001), or are an important politi-
research conducted on these and other such cal lever for the realization of global justice
similar subjects. Second, efforts by political (Falk, 2000). This more pragmatic approach
leaders, scholars, and practitioners have led suggests that in the absence of philosophical
to the construction of an increasingly global foundations, human rights can still be thought
consensus about the main core content of of as important catalysts for political and
human rights, as represented by the promul- social transformation and as the kinds of
gation of international human rights treaties protections against arbitrary state and non-
and the ever increasing numbers of state and state action that impinges on the lives of
non-state actors declaring the importance of ordinary citizens. As above, this does not
human rights. Many have argued that this deny the need to continue to find the founda-
construction of rights is a sufficient demon- tions for human rights, but rather shows how
stration of their importance if not their exist- rights are used to improve the lives of ordi-
ence (see e.g., Donnelly, 1999). Freeman nary people around the world.
(1994: 493) celebrates the passion of human Such a pragmatic approach suggests that
rights activism that has led to the generation systematic research on the conditions under
of such consensus, but he questions the which such protections are (or are not) made
degree to which it has been achieved and possible can help us understand how best to
warns that ‘rights without reasons are vulner- prevent human beings from doing their worst
able to denial and abuse’. But he does not to one another, as well as how to overcome
appear to make a compelling case to preclude some of the structural barriers to achieving
systematic analysis of the various levels of greater human dignity for a larger cross-
promotion and protection of human rights in section of humankind. Indeed, these argu-
the world. Rather, it seems that the opposite ments suggest that not only is a comparative
is true, describing, mapping, and explaining politics of human rights possible, but it is
the variety of practices in the world that vio- also essential for explaining and understand-
late human integrity and human dignity may ing the conditions under which human beings
well help us find the kinds of reasons that forge their existence, assert their dignity, and
Freeman demands. seek protections for their different identities,
Third, whatever their provenance, rights pursuit of self-determination, and exercise of
have proved to be useful ‘tools’ that have agency and autonomy. Like the study of
given subordinated groups throughout his- markets, social classes, and democracy, the
tory a language to confront agents, structures, study of human rights reveals much about

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:34:29 PM


426 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

human nature, the ways in which structure MEASURING HUMAN RIGHTS


and agency interact to create extraordinarily
different life experiences across the globe, The comparative analysis of human rights
and provide valuable insights into the types problems is predicated on our ability as
of protections that need to be in place. To scholars to provide comparable measures of
eschew comparative research on the basis human rights practices either within states or
that there are no agreed philosophical foun- across states. Such measures can be qualita-
dations for the phenomena under study tive or quantitative and both types of mea-
would, in contrast to Freeman, be irresponsi- sures provide some gauge of the degree to
ble, dangerous, and hugely short sighted.1 which human rights are being respected, pro-
There are also several ways to address the tected, and fulfilled by states. The obligation
problem of whether it is appropriate to use to respect human rights requires the state and
reputedly ‘value free’ techniques to carry out all its organs and agents to abstain from car-
research on such a ‘value-laden’ concept as rying out, sponsoring or tolerating any prac-
human rights. There are many public goods tice, policy or legal measure violating the
whose promotion, protection, and realization integrity of individuals or impinging on their
go well beyond the fulfilment of individual freedom to access resources to satisfy their
interests and needs, and that include an needs. It also requires that legislative and
appeal to a distinct set of values that have administrative codes take account of guaran-
been the subject of systematic research in teed rights. The obligation to protect human
comparative politics. Democracy is a value- rights obliges the state and its agents to pre-
laden subject. Environmental degradation vent the violation of rights by other individu-
and or environmental protection are laden als or non-state actors. Where violations do
with a particular set of value orientations. occur the state must guarantee access to legal
Economic development, in most modern remedies. The obligation to fulfil human
definitions, includes dimensions of self-es- rights involves issues of advocacy, public
teem in addition to raising living standards expenditure, governmental regulation of the
and increasing access to life-sustaining goods economy, the provision of basic services and
(e.g., Todaro, 1997). Finally, the study of related infrastructure and redistributive mea-
post-material values themselves has been sures. The duty of fulfilment comprises those
conducted using standard comparative analy- active measures necessary for guaranteeing
sis of survey data (Inglehart, 1977, 1990, opportunities to access entitlements (see
1997, 1998; Inglehart and Welzel, 2005). UNDP, 2006).
These examples are in line with the general The obligation to respect, protect, and
position adopted by Max Weber that it is pos- fulfil applies to all categories of human rights
sible to carry out research on topics that have found in the international law of human
been influenced by values but that the research rights, including civil, political, economic,
process itself should not have been so influ- social, and cultural rights. The combination
enced. Such an approach to research is not to of these categories of human rights with the
conflate the normative and the empirical, but three dimensions of respect, protect, and
to use the tools of the empirical analysis to fulfil provides a useful heuristic device for
research real-world problems that have sig- understanding what needs to be measured,
nificant normative importance (McCamant, which aspects of human rights can be meas-
1981: 534). It is also entirely possible for ured, and which of those aspects have been
those that are against human rights or measured to date. Figure 23.1 shows the
highly sceptical of their realization and matrix which results from combing the dif-
enforcement to use comparative analysis (see ferent categories of rights with their different
e.g., Watson, 1999). dimensions. Such a matrix of rights and their

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


HUMAN RIGHTS 427

Dimensions of human rights

Respect Protect Fulfil


No interference in the Prevent violations from Provision of resources
exercise of the right third parties and the outcomes of
policies
1 2 2
Civil Torture, extra-judicial Measure to prevent non- Investment in judiciaries,
and killings, disappearances, state actors from prisons, police forces,
Categories of human rights

Political arbitrary detention, unfair committing violations, such electoral authorities, and
trials, electoral as militias, uncivil resource allocations to
intimidation, movements, or private ability.
disenfranchisement sector firms and
organizations.
4 5 6
Economic, Ethnic, racial, gender, or Measures to prevent non- Progressive realization
Social linguistic discrimination in state actors from engaging Investment in health,
and health, education, and in discriminatory behaviour education and welfare,
Cultural welfare, and resource that limits access to and resource allocations
allocations below ability. services and conditions. to ability.

Figure 23.1 The categories and dimensions of human rights


Source: Adapted from UNDP (2006: 5)

different dimensions means that there are a that the attempt to operationalize these rights
variety of ways to measure human rights. for comparative analysis has left out consid-
Indicators for column 1 in the table on the eration of violations by non-state actors and
respect for human rights measure the degree state fulfilment of civil and political rights
to which states are responsible for violating (cells 2 and 3), as well as the complete
human rights (e.g., measures of incidences of neglect of any consideration for economic,
torture, or acts of discrimination in public social, and cultural rights (cells 4, 5 and 6).
health authorities). Indicators for column For example, the global quantitative com-
2 measure the degree to which non-state parative analysis since the 1980s has been
actors and other third parties violate human dominated by studies on the protection of
rights (e.g., incidences of third party depriva- civil and political rights, or ‘personal integ-
tion of liberty or denial of access to private rity rights’, (Davenport, 1999; Hafner-Burton
sector health provision). Indicators for and Tsutsi, 2005, 2007; Henderson, 1993;
column 3 measure the degree to which states Landman, 2005a, 2005b; Mitchell and
provide the necessary resources and policies McCormick, 1988; Neumayer, 2005; Poe
for realizing and promoting the protection of and Tate, 1994; Poe et al., 1999; Zanger,
human rights (e.g., investment in police 2000a) while many qualitative studies have
training on issues of torture and inhuman focused on that set of basic ‘“rights of the
treatment or investment in the infrastructure person” [that] have been most accepted as
for health, education, and welfare). universal rights’ (Risse and Sikkink, 1999: 2;
Traditionally, political science has been see also Landman, 2005b: 52). Some of the
heavily influenced by liberal conceptions of quantitative studies have sought to analyze
the ‘negative’ rights of liberty and has there- the relative protection of ‘subsistence rights’
fore concentrated on the relative respect for but the measures that they use, such as the
civil and political rights (cell 1). This means ‘physical quality of life index’ (PQLI) or the

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


428 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

‘human development index’ (HDI) are at best programmes in the health, education, and wel-
‘distant’ proxy measures that are better fare sectors that result in vast sectors of the
understood as development measures than any population being excluded from essential
kind of rights measure per se (see Landman services could be understood as indicators for
and Häusermann, 2003; Milner et al., 1999). the ways in which a state is failing to uphold
Only recently, have political scientists begun its international human rights obligations
to assemble large data sets on some social as laid out, for example, in the International
and economic rights. For example, David Covenant on Social, Economic, and Cultural
Cingranelli and David Richards have devel- Rights.
oped a series of standards-based measures But these efforts to track patterns of social
(i.e., interval scales derived from narrative exclusion and discrimination imply an agent
reporting of rights conditions around the that may be responsible for such patterns but
world) of worker rights and women’s eco- do not adopt a ‘violations’ approach to the
nomic rights (www.humanrightsdata.com), measurement of social and economic rights
and have developed a new measure of the (see Chapman, 1996). Intensive case study
effort of states to promote economic rights analysis conducted by a combination of aca-
derived from regressing the PQLI on ratifica- demics, official truth commissions, and non-
tion of the International Covenant on governmental organizations has adopted a
Economic, Social, and Cultural Rights (as a violations approach and has begun to collect
measure of willingness) and per capita GDP large amounts of events-based data on viola-
(as a measure of capacity) (Cingranelli and tions, but the focus has thus far been on civil
Richards, 2007). and political rights, and laterally, some cul-
More progress on the measurement of tural rights. These efforts collect data derived
social and economic rights has been made by from a quantitative ‘deconstruction’ of human
the international development community, rights violation events using the ‘who did
which has long worked on social exclusion what to whom’ model (Ball et al., 2000) and
indicators. In addition, work on patterns of in many cases, multiple sources of data. This
discrimination has contributed to the measure- model is explicit in identifying the agent of
ment of some social and economic rights. For the violation, the type of violation, and the
example, work carried out by the Bangladesh context in which it has happened. The most
Rural Action Committee (BRAC), a large and sophisticated studies to date that use this
well-funded non-governmental organization model include those carried out on the armed
based in Dhaka has been able to show patterns conflict in Guatemala from 1962 to 1996
of social exclusion for the ‘ultra poor’ across (Ball, 2000; REMHI, 1999), Peru from 1980
the country over time. Work carried out by the to 2000 (Ball et al., 2003) and on the
UK Department for International Development Indonesian occupation of East Timor from
in Brazil has been able to show patterns of 1974 to 1999. Subsequent analysis of these
social exclusion in Brazil based on race. In a data has also shown, particularly in the case
governmental impact assessment carried out of Guatemala and Peru that ethnic identity
in Australia, a Heckmann selection model was was a key category that explained the dispro-
used to estimate patterns of discrimination in portionate pattern of violations in which
the labour market due to disability (Productivity indigenous groups suffered the brunt of
Commission, 2004). These different examples political violence.
suggest ways in which the disproportionality Attempts to apply this kind of model to
of access to service delivery or participation in social and economic rights have to date
the market can be measured. From a human proved intractable (Chapman, 1996), although
rights perspective, such methods of estimation it is possible to conceive of specific agents
could be used to provide indicators for the who are responsible for the denial of access
protect dimension outlined above. Privatization to certain social and economic entitlements,

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


HUMAN RIGHTS 429

as well as specific instances in which social around the world (Europe, Latin America,
and economic rights have been violated that Africa, and Asia) use mass surveys of repre-
could be counted and or measured. Moreover, sentative national samples, while the work of
in a classic illustration of one of the main organizations such as Physicians for Human
trade-offs that confronts all comparative Rights uses surveys collected from ‘at risk’
research (see below), what these data gain in populations in countries such as Sierra Leone,
validity and reliability in measuring a par- Iraq, and Afghanistan (Physicians for Human
ticular set of human rights (i.e., civil rights Rights, 2002a, 2002b, 2002c, 2003).
and integrity rights) they lose in their ability
to make empirical generalisations beyond the
cases under scrutiny. They also tend to be
collected for specific periods of heightened COMPARING HUMAN RIGHTS
violence making their use for comparative
research that seeks to compare across similar Despite the relative dearth of comparative
time periods problematic. Brockett’s (2005) measures across the different categories and
comparative study on mobilization and repres- dimensions of human rights outlined above,
sion in Guatemala and El Salvador is a notable much comparative research has been carried
exception, since both countries experienced out in an effort to explain and understand
similar types of political violence during simi- cross-national similarities and differences in
lar time periods. the protection of human rights. There is now a
To date, there are various sources of data on large body of large-N quantitative studies,
the de jure protection of human rights, their small-N qualitative and quantitative studies, as
de facto realization, and socio-economic and well as a vast array of single case studies that
administrative statistics on the different dimen- examine the causes, conditions, and conse-
sions of respect, protect, and fulfil. Measures quences of human rights protection around the
of de jure commitments of states code treaty world. Extant global comparative studies on
signature, ratification, and reservations (see human rights protection have tended to focus
e.g., Keith, 1999; Hafner-Burton and Tsutsui, on a narrow set of civil and political rights and
2005, 2007; Hathaway, 2002; Landman, 2004, carried out diachronic and synchronic
2005a, 2005b; Neumayer, 2005), as well as analyses to estimate the effects of a series of
national level legal frameworks (Keith and important explanatory variables that account
Poe, 2002; van Maarseveen and van der Tang for their variation. Such explanatory variables
1978). Measures of de facto realization have have included economic development
relied on events-based, standards-based, and (Henderson, 1993; Mitchell and McCormick,
survey-based measures of human rights, where 1988), population and population growth
the tendency has been to focus on civil and (Dixon and Moon, 1986; Poe and Tate, 1994;
political rights. For example, as mentioned Poe et al., 1999), democracy and democratiza-
above, the events-based data projects tend to tion (Davenport, 1999; Henderson, 1993; Poe
cover a limited number of countries typically and Tate, 1994; Poe et al., 1999; Zanger,
that have undergone periods of extreme politi- 2000a), multi-national corporations (MNC)
cal violence. The ‘political terror scale’, Oona (Meyer, 1996, 1998, 1999a, 1999b), internal
Hathway’s (2002) torture scale, and Cingranelli and external violent conflict (Poe and Tate,
and Richards (CIRI) data are interval scales of 1994; Poe et al., 1999; Zanger, 2000a), the end
personal integrity rights and torture coded of the Cold War (Cingranelli and Richards,
from the US State Department and Amnesty 1999), US and European foreign aid (Cingranelli
International country reports, although the and Pasquarello, 1985; Hofrenning, 1990;
CIRI data set has begun to focus on some Poe, 1990; Poe and Sirirangsi, 1993, 1994;
social and economic rights. The World Values Regan, 1995; Stohl et al., 1984; Zanger,
Surveys and various ‘barometer’ projects 2000b), domestic constitutional provisions

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


430 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

(Davenport, 1996, 1999), and religious differ- Hathaway (2002) has had similar findings for a
ences and ethnic diversity (Park, 1987). Outside broader range of treaties and rights. Hafner-
consideration of civil and political rights, other Burton and Tsutsiu (2005, 2007) and Neumayer
global comparative projects have focussed (2005) added a layer of complexity to the rela-
on discrimination, minorities, and conflict tionship by specifying models that included an
(Caprioli, 2000; Caprioli and Trumbore, interaction effect between treaty ratification
2003; Krain, 1997), US refugee policy (Gibney and democracy, which in turn has an effect on
et al., 1992), and the provision of basic human human rights protection. In similar fashion,
needs (Dixon and Moon, 1986; Moon and Landman’s (2005b) analysis includes both the
Dixon, 1985). level and timing of democratization, a feedback
The most recent area of interest has been process between treaty ratification and human
the examination of the growth and effective- rights protection, as well as a weighted measure
ness of the international human rights regime. of treaty ratification that took into account the
The field of international law has examined filing of reservations across the main interna-
the proliferation of international human rights tional human rights treaties. While the earlier
norms and argued that the growth of the studies find little empirical support for a rela-
regime represents a consensus about the tionship between the regime and domestic
universality of human rights as well as a rights protection, the later studies find support
‘language of commitment’ among states com- for a significant but limited effect of the regime,
prising the international system. Realists in which is modelled as the product of changes
international relations, on the other hand, have occurring at the domestic and international
long claimed that international law reflects the levels, including democratization, economic
distribution of power among states and that it development, and greater inter-state interde-
is difficult to demonstrate how international pendence (see also Landman, 2006: 100–3).
law can have any independent effects on state Large-N comparative analysis has begun to
behaviour (see Mearsheimer, 1994–1995). illuminate a number of processes and factors
Interestingly, the field of comparative politics at work that help account for cross-national
has begun to include international variables variation in human rights protection. The key
(Landman, 2008), and in the area of human findings of this literature about which there is
rights, one such set of variables has become greatest consensus include the importance of
those that measure the international human economic development, democracy, and con-
rights regime. Moreover, since the interna- flict resolution for better protection of human
tional human rights regime represents one rights. There is certainly less consensus on the
way in which inter-state relations can influ- possible effects for foreign aid, direct foreign
ence domestic state-citizen relations, large-N investment, and international human rights
comparison has been one research design that law itself. Moreover, as in many research
has been adopted to analyse this important areas in comparative politics, there are signifi-
question. cant limitations to this mode of analysis. First,
Linda Camp Keith (1999) was the first to there is the absence of significant variables on
analyze the relationship between comparing the the ‘left hand’ side of the regression equations,
cross-national differences in ratification of the such as economic and social rights, as well as
International Covenant on Civil and Political the absence of significant ‘right hand’ variables,
Rights to differences in human rights protec- such as poverty, income distribution, and human
tion, while controlling for a variety of other development. Further research is needed
variables such as economic development and on testing the robustness of extant findings
democracy. While her bi-variate relationships across a wider range of human rights as well as
proved to be significant, her multivariate alongside additional independent variables.
analysis showed that ICCPR ratification made Are the tangible benefits for human rights
no difference for human rights protection. from higher levels of wealth the same even if

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


HUMAN RIGHTS 431

that wealth is differently distributed? What is there has been a dearth of integrated theoretical
the relationship between the distribution of accounts from which a series of testable propo-
land and human rights violations? Is there a sitions have been derived, which is in part due
significant interaction effect between develop- to the fact that it is difficult to operationalize
ment and democracy that will have an impact variables for ‘agential’ and ‘cultural’ accounts
on human rights protection? Are countries of human rights violations for large-N analysis.
with persistent problems in upholding social Even those studies that focus on structural
and economic rights more or less likely to explanations have tended to not look at why
receive foreign aid? processes and dynamics of economic develop-
Second, there is a certain ‘a-historical’ qual- ment would necessarily be related to human
ity to the large-N analysis. While the more rights protection despite the statistical signifi-
recent analysis uses time-series cross-national cance of such relationships, but focus more on
data, the data sets tend to have highly restricted the significant empirical relationships between
time periods that generally start in the 1970s such variables.
and extend to 2003 or 2004. This 30-year Finally, this particular research design is
period was, of course, highly influenced by a not appropriate for a series of issue areas that
particular set of events, such as decolonization remain crucial for the field of human rights.
and the struggle for independence, the Cold For example, while the studies on multi-
War and its demise, and now the ‘War on national capital test for the overall presence
Terror’. While such events necessarily shaped of multi-nationals in a country in terms
the struggle for rights, it is only a very small of direct foreign investment, they do not
fragment of world history to be using as a base examine the specific practices of multina-
for empirical generalizations. Analyses that go tional corporations (MNCs) nor do they cap-
back before the 1948 Universal Declaration of ture the diverse forms of MNCs that operate in
Human Rights would help build a fuller pic- countries (i.e., export platform and manufac-
ture of the possible dynamic process at work turing, mineral extraction, textiles, etc.), which
in which different rights protections were may have different kinds of impact on differ-
secured. The 30 year time period in the extant ent categories of human rights. Global com-
studies also reflects a certain structure of parative analysis cannot capture the intricacies
world politics, where there is a large of mobilization from human rights non-
collection of wealthy democracies, as well as governmental organizations (NGOs) or other
countries in the core, semi-periphery, and civil society organizations. While the number
periphery of the global economy. Greater of international non-governmental organiza-
attention should be given to the possible tions (INGOs) with registered offices in coun-
biases and effects that the inclusion of such tries has featured in Landman’s (2005b)
countries in the absence of controls might analysis of the relationship between human
have on any empirical generalizations that are rights norms and practices, such a variable
being made. will only every be a proxy measure for the
Third, the studies remain thin on their use of freedom of association in civil society and/or
empirical theories. With a few minor excep- the penetration of international civil society.
tions (e.g., Barratt, 2004; Hathaway, 2002; Mitchell (2004) salutes the achievements of
Landman, 2005b; Meyer, 1996; Poe, 2004), the global studies in establishing the broad
there has been little theoretical reflection about parameters for understanding patterns in
why certain variables have been selected for human rights violations, but in order to test the
inclusion in these global analyses. In general, observable implications of his ‘principal-
the variables that have been chosen reflect an agent’ model, he adopts a small-N compara-
orientation to economic structures and political tive research design (see below). Finally, such
institutions, with certain references to culture analyses are limited in their ability to
(e.g., British colonial experience). But to date map inter-subjective meanings and different

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


432 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

cultural understandings of human rights, outcomes across different cases (e.g., Hayner,
which may or may not have an effect on 1994, 2002; Risse et al., 1999). For example,
human rights practices. The cross-national Mitchell (2004) compares widely different
work on ‘values’ and value change tends to levels of atrocity across three similar instances
employ survey data that collects relatively of civil war to support his model of the
abstract and general attitudes about human dynamic relationship between differently
rights rather than deeper identification with motivated ‘principals’ and the agents to whom
human rights that could be differentiated they delegate authority to carry out their bid-
significantly across specific cultural contexts. ding. The focus on a smaller set of country
Analyses of human rights problems and cases allows for greater attention to processes,
puzzles that use a relatively small and inten- decision-making, historical dynamics, and
tional selection of countries address a number more discrete causal mechanisms, but brings
of common themes and adopt a wide range of with it limits to the ability to draw larger infer-
comparative methods. The dominant themes ences that extend far beyond the confines of
in comparative politics include the struggle the countries that feature in the comparison
for rights and the relationship between social (see Landman, 2000, 2003, 2008).
mobilization, political liberalization, and Single country studies have long played an
repression (Brockett, 2005; de Brito, 1997; important part of comparative politics and
Foweraker and Landman, 1997); the simi- social science more generally (Eckstein,
larities and differences in the formation, 1975; George and Bennett, 2005). While
function, outcomes and impact of truth com- some have dismissed them as providing ‘evi-
missions (De Brito et al., 2001; Hayner, dence without inference’ (Almond, 1996) or
1994, 2002; Skaar, 1999; Skaar et al., 2005); as having only comparative ‘merit’, others
the legacies of authoritarian rule (Hite and have been more robust in the contribution
Cesarini, 2004; Roniger and Sznajder, 1999; that single case studies can make to compara-
see also Cesarini, this volume); non-state tive politics and such a claim is certainly
violence, ‘uncivil’ movements, and death supported by the work being done in the field
squads (Campbell and Brenner, 2000; Payne, of human rights. Eckstein (1975) among
2000); and the ways in which human rights others reminds us that single country studies
norms have transcended state sovereignty are useful for description and classification,
through the use of ‘transnational advocacy ‘plausibility probes’, generating and testing
networks’ that help form alliances and infor- hypotheses, and as crucial cases (i.e., ‘most
mational networks between domestic and likely’ and ‘least likely’ examples) that can
international human rights organizations that confirm, infirm, or disconfirm theories (see
are able to put pressure on rights violating Landman, 2008: Chapter 5). The themes that
states (Keck and Sikkink, 1998; Risse et al., are addressed in single country studies vary
1999; Tarrow, 2005). little from those that have featured in the
These various small-N studies have adopted large-N and small-N comparative studies, but
a range of comparative cases, or ‘focussed as in the comparison of a few countries,
comparison’ strategies, including most similar single country analysis has allowed for much
systems designs (MSSD) that compare differ- greater attention to process tracing and
ent human rights related outcomes across dynamic relationships between actors, condi-
similar cases (e.g., Brockett, 2005; Mitchell, tions, and rights.
2004), most different systems designs The work of Hawkins (2002) provides a
(MDSD) that compare similar outcomes good example of how process tracing pro-
across different cases (Bob, 2005), the ‘mirror vides deeper insight into causal mechanisms
image’ of MSSD that compares similar varia- within a single county. In his study of author-
tion across similar cases (Foweraker and itarianism in Chile and the response of
Landman, 1997; Payne, 2000), and different the Pinochet regime to international human

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


HUMAN RIGHTS 433

rights pressure, Hawkins (2002) examines all from the same country. In this way, com-
thousands of internal communiqués within parative research in federal systems is a form
the Chilean military to show that there was a of most similar systems design (MSSD) and
‘rule-oriented’ faction within the regime that offers tremendous promise for research in the
grew increasing wary of the possible delegit- field of human rights.
imizing power of international human rights
pressure. This faction increasingly gained
ground within the regime, which ultimately
held a national plebiscite for the new consti- THE FUTURE OF COMPARATIVE
tution in 1980 and for President Pinochet HUMAN RIGHTS RESEARCH
himself in 1988. The defeat of Pinochet ush-
ered in a relatively rapid transition to democ- Systematic analysis of human rights prob-
racy. But the Hawkins (2002) analysis lems is a burgeoning sub-field in compara-
demonstrates several things that go far tive politics and in many ways is a natural
beyond the explanation of democratic transi- place in the larger discipline of political sci-
tion in a particular country. First, he retains ence in which to locate such analysis. While
considerable leverage for the rationalist the international human rights regime seeks
account of regime change that has been too to use the mechanism of international law to
easily dismissed by normative and construc- govern the ways in which states relate to their
tive accounts. Second, he showed the discrete citizens, it is within states and it is across
causal chains that lie between broader pat- states that the promotion and protection of
terns of international human rights pressure human rights varies. This variation, which
and regime change by getting inside the fac- makes reference to an ideal standard outlined
tional tension within the regime itself. Third, within the many international human rights
he showed how the ‘two-level’ game (Putnam, norms and instruments, is best analyzed
1988) originally devised to explain the behav- through the various methods available to
iour of democratic regimes also applies to comparativists. These methods, which have
non-democratic regimes (see also Landman, developed through the analysis of many areas
2005b). Finally, he extends his findings from of research outside any concern for human
the Chilean case to South Africa and Cuba to rights, have served and will serve human
test the applicability of his explanation to rights well for the future.
contexts outside the focus of the study. But despite the many virtues of compara-
Increasingly, and in following the general tive analysis for human rights research, there
methodological tenor of King et al. (1994) the are many challenges that remain in the field.
inferential logic of large-N studies has begun Comparative politics does not have its own
to be applied to single country studies using distinct theoretical tradition, but engages in
sub-national divisions within individual coun- rationalist, structuralist, and culturalist theo-
tries, such as democracy and human rights in rising in ways that can be developed more
the federal systems of Mexico (Mitchell and fully and fruitfully for human rights research.
Beer, 2004) and India (Beer and Mitchell, The attention to rationalism in Mitchell
2006), and democracy and political violence (2004) and Hawkins (2002) is laudable,
across the administrative districts of Nepal especially since both afford an equally large
(Mitchell et al., 2006). In these studies, the use role for ideational approaches. Mitchell’s
of states in a federal structure as the basic (2004) principals are motivated by material
units of analysis allows for a large number of self interest, as well as ideology and it is
observations (or increased degrees of free- precisely the differences in these motivations
dom) for the analysis of variation in human that help explain the differences in levels of
rights protection, while at the same time con- atrocity that he observes. In similar fashion,
trolling for similarities, since these units are the different factions in Hawkins’ (2002)

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


434 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

analysis of the military regime in Chile are REFERENCES


motivated by the quest to maintain power, but
also by a particular attachment to legal rules Almond, G. (1996) ‘Political science: The
and standards both within and outside the history of the discipline’, in R.E. Goodin
Chilean constitutional order. It is precisely and H. Klingemann (eds), The new hand-
this kind of innovative development and test- book of political science. Oxford: Oxford
ing of theories that is needed in future com- University Press, pp. 50–96.
parative research on human rights. Ball, P.B. (2000) ‘The Guatemalan commission
Finally, it is clear that more attention is for historical clarification: Generating ana-
lytical reports, inter-sample analysis’, in P.B.
needed on methodological issues. For ques-
Ball, H. F. Spirer and L. Spirer (eds), Making
tions of measurement, more attention is needed
the case: Investigating large scale human
on the sources of human rights information, rights violations using information systems
the procedures for coding human rights infor- and data analysis. Washington DC: American
mation, the development of measures of eco- Association for the Advancement of Science,
nomic and social rights, and the provision of pp. 259–86.
indicators that capture the many different Ball, P.B., Asher, J., Sulmont, D., and Manrique, D.
dimensions of human rights outlined in Figure (2003) How many Peruvians have died?
23.1. These measurement issues are pertinent Washington, DC: American Association for
to all forms of comparative analysis from the Advancement of Science (AAAS)
large-N studies to single country analysis. For Retrieved March 26, 2008, from http://shr.
aaas.org/peru/aaas_peru_5.pdf
studies that compare a few countries or a
Ball, P.B., Spirer, H.F., and Spirer, L. (eds)
single country, more attention to the process
(2000) Making the case: Investigating
of case selection is needed to avoid indetermi- large scale human rights violations using
nate research designs and severe forms of information systems and data analysis.
selection bias. ‘Most similar’ and ‘most differ- Washington DC: American Association for
ent’ systems designs offer good first solutions the Advancement of Science.
for case selection, while greater attention to Barbalet, J.M. (1988) Citizenship: Rights,
‘negative’ cases (Goetz, 2006; Mahoney and struggle and class inequality. Milton Keynes:
Goetz, 2004) and ‘crucial’ cases (Eckstein, Open University Press.
1975; Gerring, 2004, 2006) is required to Barratt, B. (2004) ‘Aiding or abetting: British
make the most of single country studies of foreign aid decisions and recipient country
human rights’, in S.C. Carey and S.C. Poe
particular human rights problems. Human
(eds), Understanding human rights viola-
rights research is a fascinating field and
tions: New systematic studies. Aldershot:
ought to be a central concern to comparative Ashgate, pp. 43–62.
politics, since it has so many overlaps with Beer, C. and Mitchell, N. J. (2006) ‘Comparing
other substantive topics in the discipline nations and states: Human rights and democ-
contained within this Handbook. But like racy in India’, Comparative Political Studies,
these other fields, the standards for high qual- 39 (8): 996–1018.
ity and systematic rules of inquiry apply Bob, C. (2005) The marketing of rebellion:
equally to this field. Insurgents, media, and international activism.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Brockett, C. (2005) Political movements and
violence in Central America. Cambridge:
NOTE Cambridge University Press.
Campbell, B.B. and Brenner, A.D. (eds) (2000)
Death squads in global perspective: Murder
1. Freeman (1994: 493) contends that ‘evading
the task of finding the best grounding for human with deniability. New York: St. Martin’s
rights, in the face of philosophical sceptics and Press.
political opponents, demonstrates a lack of intellec- Caprioli, M. (2000) ‘Gendered conflict’, Journal
tual responsibility.’ of Peace Research, 37 (1): 51–68.

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


HUMAN RIGHTS 435

Caprioli, M. and Trumbore, P. (2003) ‘Ethnic Falk, R. (2000) Human rights horizons. London:
discrimination and interstate violence: Routledge.
Testing the international impact of domestic Foweraker, J. and Landman, T. (1997)
behavior’, Journal of Peace Research, 40 Citizenship rights and social movements: A
(1): 5–23. comparative and statistical analysis. Oxford:
Chapman, A. (1996) ‘A “violations approach” Oxford University Press.
for monitoring the International Covenant Freeman, M. (1994) ‘The philosophical founda-
on Economic, Social, and Cultural Rights’, tions of human rights’, Human Rights
Human Rights Quarterly, 18 (1): 23–66. Quarterly, 16 (3): 491–514.
Cingranelli, D.L. and Pasquarello, T. (1985) Freeman, M. (2001) ‘Is a political science of
‘Human rights practices and the distribution human rights possible?’, The Netherlands
of U.S. foreign aid to Latin American coun- Quarterly of Human Rights, 19 (2): 121–37.
tries’, American Journal of Political Science, Freeman, M. (2002) Human rights: An interdis-
29 (3): 539–63. ciplinary approach. Cambridge: Polity.
Cingranelli, D.L. and Richards, D.L. (1999) Gallie, W.B. (1956) ‘Essentially contested con-
‘Measuring the level, pattern, and sequence cepts’, Proceedings of the Aristotelian
of government respect for physical integrity Society, 51 (2): 167–98.
rights’, International Studies Quarterly, George, A.L. and Bennett, A. (2005) Case
43 (2): 407–17. studies and theory development in the social
Cingranelli, D.L. and Richards, D.L. (2007) sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University
‘Measuring government effort to respect Press.
economic and social human rights: A peer Gerring, J. (2004) ‘What is a case study and
benchmark’, in S. Hertel and L. Minkler (eds), what is it good for?’, American Political
Economic rights: Conceptual, measurement Science Review, 98 (2): 341–54.
and policy issues. Cambridge: Cambridge Gerring, J. (2006) Case study research: Principles
University Press, pp. 214–32. and practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Davenport, C. (1996) ‘Constitutional promises Press.
and repressive reality’, Journal of Politics, Gibney, M., Dalton, V., and Vockell, M. (1992)
58 (3): 627–54. ‘USA refugee policy: A human rights analysis
Davenport. C. (1999) ‘Human rights and the update’, Journal of Refugee Studies,
democratic proposition’, Journal of Conflict 5: 33–46.
Resolution, 43 (1): 92–116. Goetz, G. (2006) Social science concepts:
De Brito, A.B. (1997) Human rights and democ- A user’s guide. Princeton: Princeton University
ratization in Latin America: Uruguay and Press.
Chile. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hafner-Burton, E.M. and Tsutsui, K. (2005)
De Brito, A., González-Enríquez, C., and ‘Human rights in a globalizing world: The
Aguilar, P. (2001) The politics of memory: paradox of empty promises’, American
Transitional justice in democratizing socie- Journal of Sociology, 110 (5): 1373–411.
ties. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hafner-Burton, E.M. and Tsutsui, K. (2007)
Dixon, W. and Moon, B. (1986) ‘Military ‘Justice lost! The failure of international human
burden and basic human rights needs’, rights law to matter where needed most’,
Journal of Conflict Resolution, 30 (4): Journal of Peace Research, 44 (4): 407–25.
660–83. Hathaway, O. (2002) ‘Do treaties make a dif-
Donnelly, J. (1999) ‘The social construction of ference? Human rights treaties and the
human rights’, in T. Dunne and N. Wheeler problem of compliance’, Yale Law Journal,
(eds), Human rights in global politics. 111 (8): 1932–2042.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Hawkins, D. (2002) International human rights
pp. 71–102. and authoritarian rule in Chile. Lincoln:
Eckstein, H. (1975) ‘Case-study and theory in University of Nebraska Press.
political science’, in F.I. Greenstein and N.S. Hayner, P.B. (1994) ‘Fifteen truth
Polsby (eds), Handbook of political science, commissions – 1974–1994: A comparative
Vol. 7: Strategies of inquiry. Reading, MA: study’, Human Rights Quarterly, 16 (4):
Addison-Wesley, pp. 79–137. 597–655.

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


436 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Hayner, P.B. (2002) Unspeakable truths: Facing in qualitative research. Princeton, NJ:
the challenge of truth commissions. London: Princeton University Press.
Routledge. Krain, M. (1997) ‘State-sponsored mass murder:
Henderson, C. (1993) ‘Population pressures The onset and severity of genocides and
and political repression’, Social Science politicides’, Journal of Conflict Resolution,
Quarterly, 74 (3): 322–33. 41 (3): 331–60.
Hite, K. and Cesarini, P. (eds) (2004) Landman, T. (2000) Issues and methods in
Authoritarian legacies and democracy in comparative politics: An introduction.
Latin America and Southern Europe. Notre London: Routledge.
Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press. Landman, T. (2002) ‘Comparative politics and
Hofrenning, D.J.B. (1990) ‘Human rights and human rights’, Human Rights Quarterly,
foreign aid: A comparison of the Reagan and 24 (4): 890–923.
Carter administrations’, American Political Landman, T. (2003) Issues and methods
Quarterly, 18 (4): 514–26. in comparative politics: An introduction
Ignatieff, M. (2001) Human rights as politics (2nd edition) London: Routledge.
and idolatry. Princeton: Princeton University Landman, T. (2004) ‘Measuring human rights:
Press. Principle, practice, and policy’, Human Rights
Inglehart, R. (1977) The silent revolution: Quarterly, 26 (November): 906–931.
Changing values and political styles among Landman, T. (2005a) ‘Review article: The
Western publics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton political science of human rights’, British
University Press. Journal of Political Science, 35 (3):
Inglehart, R. (1990) Culture shift in advanced 549–72.
industrial societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Landman, T. (2005b) Protecting human rights:
University Press. A global comparative study. Washington
Inglehart, R. (1997) Modernization and post- DC: Georgetown University Press.
modernization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Landman, T. (2006) Studying human rights.
University Press. London: Routledge.
Inglehart, R. (1998) ‘Political values’, in J. W. Landman, T. (2008) Issues and methods
van Deth (ed.), Comparative politics: The in comparative politics: An introduction
problem of equivalence. London: Routledge, (3rd edition) London: Routledge.
pp. 61–85. Landman, T. and Häusermann, J. (2003)
Inglehart, R. and Welzel, C. (2005) Map-making and analysis of the main
Modernization, cultural change, and democ- international initiatives on developing
racy: The human development sequence. indicators on democracy and good
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. governance. Report to the European
Keck, M. and Sikkink, K. (1998) Activists Commission.
beyond borders: Advocacy networks in inter- Mahoney, J. and Goertz, G. (2004) ‘The possi-
national politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University bility principle: Choosing negative cases in
Press comparative research’, American Political
Keith, L.C. (1999) ‘The United Nations Science Review, 98 (4): 653–69.
International Covenant on Civil and Political Marshall, T.H. (1963) ‘Citizenship and social
Rights: Does it make a difference in human class’, in T.H. Marshall (ed.), Sociology at the
rights behavior?’, Journal of Peace Research, crossroads and other essays. London:
36 (1): 95–118. Heinemann.
Keith, L.C. and Poe, S.C. (2002) Personal integ- McCamant, J.F. (1981) ‘Social science and
rity abuse during domestic crises: Exploring human rights’, International Organization,
the relationships between constitutional pro- 35 (3): 531–52.
tections, formal judicial independence, and Mearsheimer, J.J. (1994–1995) ‘The false prom-
executive constraint. Paper presented at the ise of international institutions’, International
Annual meeting of the American Political Security, 19 (3): 5–49.
Science Association, Boston, MA. Mendus, S. (1995) ‘Human rights in political
King, G., Keohane, R.O., and Verba, S. (1994) theory’, Political Studies, 43 (Special Issue):
Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference 10–24.

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


HUMAN RIGHTS 437

Meyer, W.H. (1996) ‘Human rights and MNCs: rights?’, Journal of Conflict Resolution,
Theory vs. quantitative evidence’, Human 49 (6): 925–53.
Rights Quarterly, 18 (2): 368–97. Park, H. (1987) ‘Correlates of human rights:
Meyer, W.H. (1998) Human rights and interna- Global tendencies’, Human Rights Quarterly,
tional political economy in Third World 9 (3): 405–13.
nations: Multinational corporations, foreign Payne, L. (2000) Uncivil movements: The armed
aid, and repression. Westport, CT: Praeger. right wing and democracy in Latin America.
Meyer, W.H. (1999a) ‘Confirming, infirming, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
and falsifying theories of human rights: Physicians for Human Rights (2002a) Maternal
Reflections on Smith, Bolyard, and Ippolito mortality in Herat province, Afghanistan.
through the lens of Lakatos’, Human Rights Boston MA and Washington, DC: Physicians
Quarterly, 21 (1): 220–28. for Human Rights.
Meyer, W.H. (1999b) ‘Human rights and inter- Physicians for Human Rights (2002b) War-
national political economy in Third World related sexual violence in Sierra Leone:
nations: Multinational corporations, foreign A population-based assessment. Boston MA
aid, and repression’, Human Rights Quarterly, and Washington, DC: Physicians for Human
21 (3): 824–30. Rights.
Milner, W., Poe, S., and Leblang, D. (1999) Physicians for Human Rights (2002c) A
‘Security rights, subsistence rights, and liber- survey of human rights abuses among new
ties: A theoretical survey of the empirical internally displaced persons Herat,
landscape’, Human Rights Quarterly, 21 (2): Afghanistan, A briefing paper. Boston MA
403–44. and Washington, DC: Physicians for Human
Mitchell, N. (2004) Agents of atrocity: Leaders, Rights.
followers, and the violation of human rights Physicians for Human Rights (2003) Southern
in civil war. London: Palgrave. Iraq: Reports of human rights abuses and
Mitchell, N. and Beer, C. (2004) ‘Democracy views on justice, reconstruction and govern-
and human rights in the Mexican states: ment, A briefing paper. Boston MA and
Elections or social capital’, International Washington, DC: Physicians for Human
Studies Quarterly, 48 (2): 293–312. Rights.
Mitchell, N., Bohara, A., and Nepal, M. (2006). Poe, S. (1990) ‘Human rights and foreign aid:
‘Opportunity, democracy and political vio- A review of quantitative studies and sugges-
lence: A sub–national analysis of conflict in tions for future research’, Human Rights
Nepal’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50 (1): Quarterly, 12 (4): 499–509.
108–28. Poe, S. (2004) ‘The decision to repress: An
Mitchell N.J. and McCormick, J.M. (1988) integrative theoretical approach to research
‘Economic and political explanations of on human rights and repression’, in S. Carey
human rights violations’, World Politics, and S. Poe (eds), Understanding human
40: 476–498. rights violations: New systematic studies.
Mitchell, C., Stohl, M., Carleton, D., and Lopez, Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 16–42.
G. (1986) ‘State terrorism: Issues of concept Poe, S. and Sirirangsi, R. (1993) ‘Human rights
and measurement’, in M. Stohl and G. Lopez and U.S. economic aid to Africa’, International
(eds), Government violence and repression: Interactions, 18 (4): 1–14.
An agenda for research. New York, Poe, S. and Sirirangsi, R. (1994) ‘Human rights
Greenwood Press, pp. 202–21. and us economic aid during the Reagan
Moon, B. and Dixon, W. (1985) ‘Politics, the Years’, Social Science Quarterly, 75 (3):
state, and basic human needs: A cross- 444–509.
national study’, Journal of Political Science, Poe, S. and Tate, C.N. (1994) ‘Repression of
29 (4): 661–94. human rights to personal integrity in the
Moon, B. and Dixon, W. (1992) ‘Basic needs 1980s: A global analysis’, American Political
and growth: Welfare trade-offs’, International Science Review, 88 (4): 853–72.
Studies Quarterly, 36 (2): 191–212. Poe, S.C., Tate, C.N., and Keith, L.C. (1999)
Neumayer, E. (2005) ‘Do international human ‘Repression of the human right to personal
rights treaties improve respect for human integrity revisited: A global cross-national study

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


438 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

covering the years 1976–1993’, International transitions’, Third World Quarterly, 20 (6):
Studies Quarterly, 43 (2): 291–313. 1109–28.
Productivity Commission (2004) Review of the Skaar, S., Gloppen, S., and Surhke, A. (eds)
disability discrimination act 1992 (Report, (2005) Roads to reconciliation. Lexington,
no. 30) Melbourne: Commonwealth of MA: Lexington Books.
Australia. Slaughter Burley, A. (1993) ‘International law
Putnam, R. (1988) ‘Diplomacy and and international relations theory: A dual
domestic politics: The logic of two-level agenda’, American Journal of International
games’, International Organization, 42 (3): Law, 87 (2): 205–39.
427–60. Stohl, M., Carleton, D., and Johnson, S. (1984)
Recovery of Historical Memory Project (REMHI) ‘Human rights and U.S. foreign assistance’,
(1999) Guatemala never again! The official Journal of Peace Research, 21 (3): 215–226.
report of the human rights office, Archdiocese Tarrow, S. (2005) The new transnational activ-
of Guatemala, Mayknoll. New York: Orbis ism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Books. Todaro, M. (1997) Economic development (6th
Regan, P.M. (1995) ‘US economic aid and edition) London: Longman.
political repression’, Political Research UNDP (2006) Indicators for rights-based
Quarterly, 48 (3): 613–28. approaches to development programming:
Risse, T. and Sikkink, K. (1999) ‘The socializa- A user’s guide. Oslo: Oslo Governance
tion of international human rights norms Centre.
into domestic practices: Introduction’, in T. van Maarseveen H. and van der Tang, G.
Risse, S.C.Ropp and K. Sikkink (eds), The (1978) Written constitutions: A computer-
power of human rights: International norms ized comparative study. New York: Oceana
and domestic change. Cambridge: Cambridge Publications.
University Press, pp. 1–38. Watson, J.S. (1999) Theory and reality in the
Risse, T., Ropp, S.C., and Sikkink, K. (1999) The international protection of human rights.
power of human rights: International norms Ardsley, NY: Transnational Publishers.
and domestic change. Cambridge: Cambridge Zanger, S.C. (2000a) ‘A global analysis of the
University Press. effect of regime changes on life integrity
Roniger, L. and Sznajder, M. (1999) The legacy violations, 1977–1993’, Journal of Peace
of human rights violations in the Southern Research, 37 (2): 213–33.
Cone: Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay. Oxford: Zanger, S.C. (2000b) ‘Good governance
Oxford University Press. and European aid: the impact of political
Skaar, E. (1999) ‘Truth Commissions, trials – conditionality’, European Union Politics,
or nothing? Policy options in democratic 1 (3): 293–317.

9781412919760_Chap23.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:34:30 PM


24
Governance
Philip Keefer

INTRODUCTION are explained below, the focus here is there-


fore on the literature that links economic
A growing body of evidence points to govern- development to secure property rights, voice
ance failures as a root cause of slow and ineq- and accountability, or the performance of the
uitable economic growth and as a defining bureaucracy. Each of these seems to be at the
characteristic of most poor countries. These core of all definitions of governance.
findings justify placing governance high on The basic conclusions of this review are
any research agenda aimed at better under- threefold. First, further research on govern-
standing the political economy of economic ance-related issues remains a high priority, but
development. Already, research into govern- progress is likely to be fastest and most con-
ance and development has had a notable vincing when future work addresses the com-
impact: some dimensions of governance now ponents of governance rather than aggregated
sit at the center of academic and policy discus- concepts of governance. In many cases, the
sions of economic development. This chapter components of governance do not even bear
reviews the known effects of governance on the same causal relationship to development,
development, the interrelationship among the nor is one component necessarily a good
different dimensions of governance, and the proxy for other components. The security of
origins of ‘good’ governance. The review property rights, for example, can be consid-
highlights where important questions remain ered a proximate contributor to economic
to be answered, particularly with respect to the development, in much the same way as macr-
origins of good governance. oeconomic or social policy. Voice and account-
Although this chapter is a critical review of ability, however, matter indirectly, through
the governance literature, it turns out that most their influence on government decision making
of that literature does not use the term ‘gov- or the security of property rights. The review
ernance.’ Moreover, there is no agreed defini- spells out the differences across governance
tion of governance that would provide a indicators and their links to development.
convenient device for organizing the litera- The second conclusion of this review is that
ture. Finally, there are few research efforts that evidence and theory better support the
set out to analyze all dimensions or even most influence of some components of gover-
dimensions of governance jointly. For various, nance on development than others. The secu-
sometimes necessarily arbitrary reasons that rity of property rights and the credibility of

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 1 3/13/2009 12:10:15 PM


440 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

governments emerge as the components with incentive to be responsive to citizens. Though


the best documented and strongest influence similar, in fact the first are ‘outcomes’ while
on economic development. Causality prob- the second are ‘causal’ or more fundamental
lems cloud estimates of the influence of concepts. Corruption and bureaucratic qual-
bureaucratic (or ‘state’) capacity and corrup- ity are more direct indicators of lack of
tion on development. The most critical of responsiveness, and only indirect indicators
these causality problems results from the of government incentives; measures of
omission from most analyses of political democracy or voice and accountability, in
variables that are likely to influence both contrast, directly capture the second more
bureaucratic efficiency and integrity, and than the first.
development outcomes. Finally, analyses of In 2001, the Institute on Governance, in
voice and accountability, or ‘democracy’, Canada, defined governance squarely in the
while the subject of substantial attention, have second category, as comprising ‘the traditions,
suffered from a lack of theoretical and empiri- institutions and processes that determine how
cal precision that clouds interpretation. power is exercised, how citizens are given a
Third, future research that deepens our voice, and how decisions are made on issues
understanding of the determinants of good of public concern’. Currently, it lists funda-
governance is likely to have the greatest mental principles of good governance: legiti-
payoff. Although progress has been made in macy and voice, direction, performance,
identifying the political and social conditions accountability and fairness. (IOG, 2008). The
that lead to more secure property rights, journal Economics of Governance essentially
greater voice and accountability, or more views governance as synonymous with gov-
efficient and honest bureaucracy, much erning, and encourages submissions that deal
remains unknown or puzzling. In addition, with all manner of problems that emerge in
the governance literature has so far been iso- the way groups of individuals govern
lated from much of the progress that has been themselves in the public or private sectors. Its
made along these lines in the broader politi- statement of aims and objectives, however,
cal economy literature. A growing literature evades the tricky issue of how to define
outside the realm usually defined as govern- governance.
ance describes the effects of voter informa- More common are definitions and realms
tion and political institutions on political of activity that straddle the outcome and insti-
incentives to seek rents; the tools and results tutional sides of governance. In 2002, the
of this literature have yet to be integrated into website of the OECD described governance as
work on governance. relating to ‘institutions, policy making and
participation of civil society. The Ford
Foundation views governance as the extent to
which government institutions are ‘transpar-
WHAT IS GOVERNANCE? ent, accountable and responsive’.1 The US
Agency for International Development focused
Whether in policy or academic settings, gov- on outcomes in defining good governance.
ernance is among the more elastic concepts In 2002, its website indicated that governance
in the social science and development lexi- is present when governments can ‘maintain
cons. Definitions tend to encompass one or social peace, guarantee law and order,
both of the following: the extent to which promote or create conditions necessary for
governments are responsive to citizens economic growth, and ensure a minimum level
and provide them with certain core services, of social security’. However, underlying
such as secure property rights and, more gen- good governance are transparent and account-
erally, the rule of law; and the extent to able government institutions, and USAID work
which the institutions and processes of gov- on governance focuses explicitly on strength-
ernment give government decision makers an ening democratic institutions. In 2002, the

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 2 3/13/2009 12:10:16 PM


GOVERNANCE 441

United Nations Development Program referred the term has acquired popularity only recently
to ‘democratic governance,’ but its description and with two particular concerns. Governance
of its goals implies that governance is the is first associated with establishing causal
responsiveness of state institutions and proc- relationships between economic development
esses to the needs of ordinary citizens (UNDP, and particular performance characteristics of
2008). developing countries to which earlier litera-
Perhaps not surprisingly, since their char- ture paid less attention. These characteristics
ters discourage engagement with countries include, especially, such phenomena as the
on more overtly political issues, the least security of property rights, the performance of
political definitions of governance can be bureaucracies and the predictability and cred-
found at the World Bank and International ibility of government decision making.
Monetary Fund. The World Bank (2008) Second, governance is associated with estab-
introduces its work on governance and links lishing causal relationships between the
it intrinsically to public sector reform, char- underlying institutional characteristics of gov-
acterizing governance and public sector ernments (typically, democracy or voice and
reform jointly as focused on ‘building effi- accountability) and either the performance of
cient and accountable public sector institu- governments (e.g., with respect to the rule of
tions’. Governance, then, is the extent to law) or economic development, or both.
which public sector institutions are account- The discussion below therefore takes these
able and capable of sustaining development. two lines of inquiry as comprising the study
The emphasis, however, is on the implement- of governance. Although the literature does
ing or administrative agencies of government not always follow this division and often
rather than the incentives of the political conflates the study of less and more funda-
actors who sit atop them. Similarly, the mental notions of governance, in principle
International Monetary Fund views good these are clearly two different and well-
governance as encompassing (but not neces- defined lines of inquiry that mark a litera-
sarily exclusive to) the rule of law, the effi- ture that has grown in rigor and volume
ciency and accountability of the public sector, since the 1980s.
and corruption (IMF, 1997).
The various definitions of governance are
evidently expansive. In fact, if the study of
governance extends to all questions related to THE HAZARDS OF AGGREGATION
how groups of people govern themselves, as IN GOVERNANCE RESEARCH
might be inferred from many of these defini-
tions, then there are few subjects in all of Policy and some academic discussions fre-
political science and political economy that quently refer to good governance, implicitly
do not fall within the governance domain. aggregating all of the underlying dimensions
Taken to this extreme, one might reasonably into a single concept. Kaufmann et al. (2002)
doubt whether the study of governance is at reflect the breadth of this concept in their
all novel or of independent analytic interest. efforts to devise systematic measures of gov-
There are two responses to this. First, in one ernance. They take 194 measures variously
sense it does not really matter. As long as the used in the literature as measures of govern-
literature labeled governance generates impor- ance, from 17 sources, and divide them into
tant findings about critical topics and does not 6 categories: voice and accountability, politi-
ignore the broader research domain in which cal stability, government effectiveness, regu-
those topics may be nested, the label is irrele- latory quality, rule of law and control
vant. Second, it is still possible to establish of corruption. Theirs is a reasonable break-
useful – if somewhat arbitrary – boundaries on down of governance concepts, and there are
governance as an independent sphere of few analyses of governance, implicit or
inquiry. In both policy and academic circles explicit, that do not fall into one or more of

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 3 3/13/2009 12:10:16 PM


442 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

these categories. Aggregation of these con- government has fallen precipitously, despite
cepts makes sense if all good things go worsening corruption perceptions.
together. In fact, they may not. One explanation for this paradox is that cor-
Kaufmann and Kraay (2002) highlight rupt transactions became less credible after
the difficulty of casually aggregating these Suharto’s departure, suggesting that voice and
governance components. They show that accountability (at least as generated by new
good performance on some of these dimen- and imperfect democracies) may also diverge
sions does not imply good performance on from government credibility. Under Suharto,
others. Most countries in Latin America turn businesses believed that if they paid a US
out to do better than other countries with $1,000,000 bribe they would get a high return
similar per capita incomes with respect to on their investment because the underlying
voice and accountability, but worse with agreement was credible (or, in terms of the
respect to government effectiveness, rule of Kaufmann et al. variables, either the rule of
law and corruption, and both better and law or political stability were high). They
worse with respect to political stability and could be confident that they would, in fact,
regulatory quality. Recognizing this, in their receive the rents conferred by the monopoly or
substantive analysis of the effect of govern- regulatory privilege provided in exchange for
ance on growth they focus only on one of the bribe. The political uncertainty of the post-
their indicators, the rule of law. Suharto era lowered the credibility of these
Studies of specific countries reveal how transactions. Consequently, even if the bribe-
divergence among indicators might emerge. price of entry or regulatory privileges fell
Figure 24.1 records the assessment by one since the end of the Suharto regime, the effec-
political risk service of corruption percep- tive value of the privileges may have fallen by
tions in Indonesia. It shows clearly that cor- even more. Although total corrupt payments
ruption perceptions rose with the advent of may have fallen, the perceived damage of
democratic elections on June 7, 1999 and the corruption might have risen. The Indonesia
demise of the Suharto autocracy. Voice and case demonstrates that two components of
accountability therefore seem to have moved governance – corruption and the credibility of
inversely with corruption perceptions. The government – may also move in opposite
paradox here is acute: the Suharto regime directions, at least as they are measured.
was widely regarded as among the most cor- One final example of the potential diver-
rupt in the world, and no observer doubts that gence among typical dimensions of govern-
the absolute value of bribes going to the ance relates to the credibility of government

0
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Figure 24.1 The evolution of corruption perceptions, Indonesia, 1995–2001
Note: Political Risk Services Corruption assessment, 0–6 scale, higher implies less corruption.

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 4 3/13/2009 12:10:16 PM


GOVERNANCE 443

and bureaucratic quality. North and Weingast key obstacle to development as capital, so
(1989) argue that credibility is a function of that economic development (or at least
checks and balances among political deci- growth) depended on the transfer of capital
sion makers. We can therefore imagine two to capital-starved poor countries. By the
governments, one exhibiting checks and bal- 1980s development thinking had shifted to
ances, and one not. Which will have an easier concern with the economic policies of devel-
time ensuring a high level of performance by oping country governments, typically trade
civil servants? Keefer and Stasavage (2002) barriers, state ownership of industry, and
argue that independent central banks are loose management of the macro-economy.
much more likely to succeed in generating Experience and research then showed that
low inflation outcomes in the presence of reasonable economic policies were possibly
checks and balances. This seems to suggest a necessary but certainly not a sufficient con-
that credibility and bureaucratic quality might dition for economic growth and develop-
go together. However, problems of special ment. This motivated a renewed look at other
interest capture of regulatory agencies are aspects of public sector performance. The
well-documented in many other contexts. To work of North (1981; 1990) was particularly
the extent that checks and balances insulate important in setting the intellectual stage for
captured regulators from political interfer- this new focus. He systematically linked
ence, we might expect poor regulatory/ country characteristics such as the security of
bureaucratic performance to be greater when property rights directly to the prosperity of
political institutions are associated with more nations. From this evolution, then, emerged
credibility. Contributors to Libecap (1996) one part of the governance research agenda:
make exactly this point and Wallsten (2002) improved understanding of the effects of the
has documented worse outcomes in electric- non-policy characteristics of government
ity regulation when regulators are fully inde- performance on economic development.
pendent of political authorities (when they The research stemming from this strand of
cannot be removed from office and they have the governance literature brought to the fore-
an independent source of financing). front the contribution to development of such
previously under-examined phenomena as
the security of property rights, the rule of
law, expropriation, bureaucratic quality, red
AN ABRIDGED INTELLECTUAL tape, and the quality of government regula-
HISTORY OF GOVERNANCE tion – concepts falling squarely under the
rubric of governance. While these ideas flow-
The concerns motivating the governance lit- ered in the academic literature, they were
erature have a distinct intellectual heritage. also given great policy impetus by work not
Broadly speaking, of course, analysis of the primarily intended for the research commu-
operation of bureaucracies and their honesty nity, particularly the controversial, though
and efficiency dates back to Max Weber. The influential contribution of de Soto (1989).
connection to economic development, a cru- A second pillar of development wisdom in
cial component of the governance literature, the 1950s – or, at least, an unexamined and
is more recent. Similarly, though research on implicit assumption – was that governments
democracy and democratization goes back would, by and large, act in the general interests
generations, it is only more recently that of society. Most explanations of underdevelop-
scholars have begun to ask systematic ques- ment ignored the incentives of the governments
tions relating the incentives of government of developing countries and focused instead on
actors to outcomes in developing countries. exogenous or purely economic constraints on
In the 1950s, the common wisdom in development or, in the political sphere, the role
policy and academic circles characterized the of industrialized countries in perpetuating

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 5 3/13/2009 12:10:16 PM


444 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

underdevelopment. This was a reasonable focus apparatus of the state in promoting develop-
for the times, since the colonial legacy was both ment. Like the rent-seeking literature, however,
recent and bitter in many developing areas. this literature does not specify the conditions
Bates (1981) broke with this tradition by under which politicians support or demand
documenting how the political or economic high performance from the bureaucracy. In
self-interest of political actors could yield both cases, therefore, this work abstracts from
policies that were devastating for society at the political considerations that are at the core
large, independent of external influence. He of arguments such as those of Bates (1991).
specifically showed that governments in the The conclusion of Evans (1989), for exam-
countries he considered sought the support of ple, suggests that politicians are but back-
powerful interest groups and favored them at ground or ancilliary actors in development:
the expense of the unorganized or less threat- ‘The comparative evidence suggests that the
ening interest groups. This work inspired a efficacy of the developmental state depends
new question: why did interest groups in the on a meritocratic bureaucracy with a strong
African countries that he examined have a sense of corporate identity and a dense set of
more pernicious effect on outcomes than institutionalized links to private elites.’ This
interest groups elsewhere – in Germany or the evidence could be persuasive if the politi-
United States, for instance? Under what con- cians in the different countries confronted
ditions, that is, do governments in some coun- approximately the same electoral and institu-
tries pursue socially beneficial policies while tional constraints on their actions. This may
in other countries they do not? From these not be the case, however, since the conclu-
questions flows the second part of the govern- sion rests on a comparison of Brazil, Japan,
ance research agenda: under what conditions and Zaire. Evans (1989: 583) acknowledges
do governments pursue the public interest and some of these uncertainties, pointing out that
promote development in poor countries? despite evidence of the connection between
This overly – even unreasonably – condensed development success and meritocratic
intellectual history of governance excludes bureaucracies working hand in hand with the
some concepts and literature that others rea- private sector, ‘[t]he constraints that keep the
sonably include within the governance domain. inevitable clientelism and corruption from
In particular, the inadequacy of development overwhelming the utility of ties to private
explanations rooted in capital inflows and capital are still not defined’.
economic policy choices led many researchers At the same time, however, analyses such
to focus not on self-interested political leaders as those of Evans and, in a different tradition,
but rather on broader characteristics of the those contained in Libecap (1996), suggest
state or the bureaucracy. This research has that it may also be problematic to ignore the
introduced concepts such as the rent-seeking independent role for the bureaucracy in public
state (Buchanan et al., 1980), embedded policy formation. The argument made below,
autonomy (Evans, 1995), and state capacity however, is that the analysis of political incen-
using analytical approaches that are useful to tives without taking into account bureaucratic
contrast with the more overtly political analy- capacity may be a more tenable strategy than
ses spawned by Bates. the reverse.
The literature on rent-seeking generally takes
for granted that governments use the coercive
power of the state for self-aggrandizement.
It does not take into account the limits that GOVERNANCE AND ECONOMIC
political competition might impose on these DEVELOPMENT: REVIEWING
efforts. Arguments about embedded autonomy THE THEORY
and state capacity take a more benign view of
the state than the rent-seeking literature. The governance literature is largely empirical.
They emphasize the role of the administrative The successes and failures on the empirical

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 6 3/13/2009 12:10:16 PM


GOVERNANCE 445

side of the literature, however, are related to is somewhat divorced from a sophisticated
the clarity and precision of its theoretical and rapidly growing literature exploring the
underpinnings. Clarity is of course inherently political and electoral determinants of politi-
difficult to achieve with a concept as heteroge- cian incentives to act in the public interest.
neous as governance. It helps to consider Nevertheless, the introduction of notions of
two sets of governance concepts separately, voice, accountability and democracy have
those related to government performance of been critical in pointing development research
its core functions and those related to the toward the question, ‘Under what conditions
incentives of government officials to perform do governments have the incentive to ensure
those functions. the rule of law, secure property rights, and a
The former is the most successful strand of well-functioning bureaucracy, and, more
the governance literature, making the argu- generally to serve the public interest?’
ment that secure property rights, predictable
and credible government, and honest and effi-
cient bureaucracy have a significant impact on
The security of property rights
economic development. The second strand of
and economic growth
the governance literature concerns the incen-
tives of government actors to act in the public The theoretical case for secure property
interest. This strand has confronted greater rights is simple: growth is a prerequisite for
challenges and is the most promising and economic development (even if not a suffi-
important for future research. cient condition for it). Growth is not possible
Within the first strand, the theoretical argu- without investment. However, investors do
ments are not equally strong or unambiguous. not invest when they fear confiscation of
Least disputed and most clear is the theory their assets by government. North (1981)
linking insecure property rights to slow makes this point repeatedly, and a plethora of
growth. Similarly, credible government is gen- formal models explicitly chart the path from
erally and unambiguously regarded as good property rights insecurity to slow growth2. In
for public policy. The frequent confusion of its bare essentials, few propositions are less
credibility with predictability undermines controversial than this argument. Still, there
clarity, however, since the latter is not strongly are objections to the theoretical case linking
related to development and the quality of the security of property rights to growth. One
public policy. However, as the foregoing brief relates to definitional confusion; the other to
references to embedded autonomy and state the effects of institutional influences that
capacity suggest might be the case, the influ- might explain both the security of property
ence of an honest and efficient bureaucracy on rights and economic growth.
economic development is most ambiguous of Definitional confusion emerges because
all. On the one hand, this influence depends, two important notions of property rights are
as a matter of logic, on what the bureaucracies often confused, the allocation of property
are doing; on the other hand, what bureaucra- rights and the security of property rights. The
cies do is generally controlled by politicians. governance literature deals only with the
Each of these is considered separately in the latter: do property owners have protection
sections that follow. from the arbitrary confiscation of their assets
The second strand of the governance lit- (either through expropriation, tax law
erature focuses on voice, accountability, and changes, or through interpretations of exist-
democracy and their effects on growth and ing regulation)?3 Discussions of central plan-
development. It pays less attention to specific ning, the transition from communism, and
implications of different electoral and politi- the costs and benefits of privatization address
cal institutions within democracies and to the the other notion of property rights, their allo-
dynamics of electoral competition, all of cation. Przeworski and Limongi (1993) pro-
which vary across countries. In this sense, it vide one example of the ease with which the

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 7 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


446 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

two notions can be conflated. They point to An important contribution of Acemoglu


arguments that democracy may render prop- et al. (2001) to scholarship on property rights
erty rights less secure because the introduction and growth is an ingenious econometric
of democracy creates opportunities for the instrument that they discovered for the
poor to redistribute incomes away from the security of property rights (settler mortality
rich.4 However, it is not democracy, per se, rates in the eighteenth and nineteenth centu-
that creates insecurity, but the transition to ries). They use this variable as an econometric
democracy. In equilibrium, or once democ- instrument for the property rights variable
racy is established, there is no reason to used in Knack and Keefer (1995), though they
expect the distribution of property rights to refer not to the security of property rights but
change further. Property rights, after the ini- to ‘institutions’. They emphasize that their
tial redistribution, can therefore still be contribution is large because institutions are
secure.5 Similarly, Rodrik et al. (2002) argue notoriously endogenous: ‘It is quite likely that
that the success of countries such as China rich economies choose or can afford better
creates difficulty for the thesis that property institutions. Perhaps more important, econo-
rights matter for growth. Again, they are mies that are different for a variety of reasons
referring to the allocation of property rights will differ both in their institutions and in their
rather than the security of the allocation. income per capita’ (p. 1369).
As long as economic actors are confident Ironically, the theoretical (though not empir-
that the rules will not change arbitrarily, ical) reasons to be concerned about whether
even if the rules imply high tax rates, their secure property rights ‘cause’ economic growth
rights are secure; it is when the rules are sub- are not particularly convincing.7 If property
ject to arbitrary and significant alteration – rights are expensive to secure, for example,
regardless of whether they are initially one might argue that rich countries are more
favorable or not to the economic actors – that likely than poor countries to secure them; fast-
rights are insecure. There is ample evidence growing countries would therefore be more
of this. Countries that have the highest scores likely to improve property rights. However, to
on the security of property right measures, the extent that the security of property rights
such as Australia, Germany, New Zealand, relates to the absence of expropriatory deci-
and the United States, collect taxes ranging sions by the state, there seem to be few finan-
from 18 per cent of national income (the US) cial costs to protecting property rights and little
to 36 per cent (Sweden). Tax collection in reason to argue that secure property rights
countries rated as posing high risks of con- should be sensitive to wealth. Even elaborate
tract repudiation or expropriation are often in judicial systems are not particularly expensive.
the teens and rarely above 25 per cent of Alternatively, it might be that citizens of
national income.6 rich countries prefer secure property rights
The second objection that arises to the more than citizens of poor countries. This is
property rights arguments in the governance a more complex and interesting argument,
literature relates to causality. Arguments but there is little evidence or support for any
linking property rights to growth are some- of its variants. For example, the citizens of
times asserted to be vulnerable to both of the poor countries, being poor, might discount
usual causality flaws: either the association the future more heavily and thus be more
of secure property rights and economic willing to incur the future costs of expropria-
growth is a reflection of reverse causality, tion in return for the short-run benefits.
from the second to the first, or, more difficult While persuasive in principle, this argument
and interesting, the security of property is inconsistent with the observed willingness
rights and economic growth are both deter- of the poor to take actions with distant pay-
mined simultaneously by some third and offs and high current costs, such as investing
omitted factor. heavily in the education of their children.

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 8 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


GOVERNANCE 447

Poor countries might also exhibit higher security of property rights. These are in fact
income inequality, and therefore more policy the arguments in Acemoglu and Robinson
volatility or willingness to expropriate (as, for (2001), Keefer and Knack (2002a) and
example, Knack and Keefer, 1997a argue). Svensson (1998). Such omitted factors do not
However, it is well-known that income inequal- cause a spurious relationship between the
ity and income exhibit an inverted U-shaped security of property rights and growth. On the
relationship: inequality is low at both low and contrary, they precipitate the causal chain that
high levels of income per capita, and higher runs from the first to the second.
over middle ranges. Such a relationship cannot
generate a spurious correlation between growth
and the security of property rights unless slow-
Predictability and credibility
growing countries are on average richer and
fast-growing countries on average poorer. Some contributions to the governance litera-
Evidence from the growth literature suggests ture refer not only to the security of property
that the reverse may be true, however. rights but to the closely related but somewhat
A related literature argues that as countries broader concept of ‘government credibility.’
grow wealthier, more effort and resources are This is the case with Knack and Keefer
spent to define and protect property rights. (1995), for example. Only credible govern-
The insights of this literature are important in ments can assure investors that their assets
their own right, but they cannot be taken to are safe from expropriation. In addition,
support the argument that growth leads to however, governments that are not credible
secure property rights. The arguments here cannot elicit any actions from citizens or
are simply that as countries grow, assets that investors in return for any future promise of
previously held little value and were not government action. In times of fiscal crisis,
worth protecting become more valuable, for example, the non-credible government
increasing the payoffs to defining ownership cannot offer future rewards to constituencies
rights to them carefully.8 The governance in exchange for current cutbacks. These gov-
literature focuses on the insecurity of prop- ernments cannot use any policy instrument
erty rights to valuable assets. to stimulate investment short of outright
Even if reverse causality is not an issue in subsidies to investors that compensate them
the relationship between property rights secu- for their risk.
rity and economic growth, it is possible that As in the case of property rights, an impor-
other factors, omitted from most analyses, tant definitional confusion arises in the area
might simultaneously drive down the security of credibility, particularly in empirical appli-
of property rights and economic growth, cations. Attempts to capture credibility issues
yielding a spurious correlation between the in surveys tend to rely (as in many World
latter two. Social polarization, political insta- Bank surveys, for example) on questions to
bility, the absence of political checks and bal- respondents on their perceptions of the ‘pre-
ances, or unfortunate geographic location all dictability of decision making’. At first
might explain both insecure property rights glance, this seems a perfectly reasonable
and slow economic growth. However, for approach to governance: no one likes unpre-
these omitted variables to create a problem of dictable decision making, and unpredictable
causality, it must also be the case that their and arbitrary decision making are surely pil-
effect on economic growth is largely through lars of bad governance. The problem is not
channels other than the security of property that unpredictable decision making is good,
rights. This seems unlikely. If political insta- however, but rather that it is not necessarily
bility or social polarization matter for growth, so bad and does not capture the sort of asym-
it is most reasonable to assume that they metrical and unbounded threat that is implied
matter exactly because they drive down the by the lack of government credibility.

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 9 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


448 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Strictly speaking, unpredictability is a The classic conundrum is therefore the fol-


‘mean-preserving’ increase in the variance of lowing: are societies better off when honest
future government policies. That is, unpredict- bureaucracies rigorously and predictably
ability leaves the average or expected policy apply abusive regulations of firms and indi-
unchanged, but increases the range of poten- viduals or, given the existence of such laws
tial policies that could emerge in the future. and regulations, would citizens prefer that
Predict-ability should have only a modest they be implemented by corrupt bureaucra-
effect on economic outcomes (see Aizenman, cies? In the context of corruption, Leff
1995, for example). Assuming plausible (1964) was the first of many to make the
parameters and an often-used functional form argument that corruption could be beneficial
for investor utility, it is easy to show that a if it allowed citizens to circumvent welfare-
moderately risk-averse investor who would reducing laws and regulations. More recent
demand, say, a 10 per cent rate of return for a analyses have emphasized that arguments
sure investment would demand just 11 to 12 such as Leff’s assume that bureaucracies
per cent for an investment with a payoff that have no influence on the content of the regu-
with 50 per cent probability returns 50 per lations that they implement. If they do,
cent less than the sure payoff, and with 50 per though, the potential for lucrative bribes
cent probability returns 50 per cent more. This would spur bureaucracies to generate abusive
sort of risk premium cannot explain the dif- regulations that maximize bribes. Kaufmann
ferential investment flows into Russia and and Wei (1999) have argued and provided
Poland, or Zaire and Botswana. Credibility, evidence that in this more dynamic world,
on the other hand, is not mean-preserving: bureaucrats react to the opportunities for cor-
Instead, it is an asymmetric risk that emerges ruption by actually increasing red tape and
whenever investors or households make illiq- reducing their (bribe-free) performance.
uid investments that governments can subse- This later literature, in turn, relies on the
quently expropriate.9 assumption that bureaucracies enjoy signifi-
cant discretionary authority. It is a character-
istic of the governance literature that,
although it gives apparently great weight to
Bureaucratic efficiency and honesty
political processes in its emphasis on democ-
A long line of research, stemming from Max racy, voice and accountability, it tends to
Weber and extending to many current discus- analyze bureaucratic performance in isola-
sions of state capacity or the strength of tion and to ignore the intimate relationship of
states, such as Evans (1995), argues that the bureaucrats and politicians. If one were sure
actions of bureaucracies have an independent that bureaucrats could exploit information
effect on economic development. However, and other advantages to act independently
although it is well-known that bureaucratic and even in opposition to the objectives of
quality is lower and corruption higher in poor their political superiors, this assumption
countries, the inference that these phenom- would be entirely appropriate. One could
ena cause poverty and slow growth is more immediately begin to examine the effects of
difficult to draw. Of course, to the extent that corruption or bureaucratic incompetence on
government policies are ideal and govern- outcomes. However, research into the delega-
ment spending ideally allocated, then any tion of authority by political actors to
bureaucratic breakdown must lower social bureaucracies has made clear that politicians
welfare and, to the extent that the policies expend considerable effort to rein in deviant
and spending are connected to economic bureaucrats and to circumvent or compel
growth, slow growth. What, however, if the recalcitrant ones.
policies and spending decisions are entirely Weingast and Moran (1983) and Keefer and
deficient? Stasavage (2003) show systematic differences

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 10 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


GOVERNANCE 449

in the behavior of bureaucracies (the Federal Voice and accountability


Trade Commission and central banks, respec-
as governance
tively) depending on the partisan control of
government and the number of political checks A vast literature considers the importance
and balances (respectively). Epstein and of politics and political institutions in the
O’Halloran (1999) document how politicians process of economic development, covering
limit the information advantages that bureau- topics ranging from regime type to political
crats have over them. McCubbins et al. instability to clientelism to the institutions of
(1987) have described in detail the constraints electoral competition and political decision
on bureaucratic discretion imposed by the making. The subset of that literature that falls
US Congress through the Administrative under the governance rubric centers on voice,
Procedures Act and other vehicles. Kang accountability and democracy. This focus
(2002), while not relying on this literature dates at least to Albert Hirschman (1970),
himself, still demonstrates the intimate link who introduced ‘voice’ and ‘exit’ into the
between political imperatives and the nature development lexicon.
of corruption in South Korea and the The emphasis on voice and accountability
Philippines. In view of this literature, it seems rests on a natural and persuasive logic: gov-
likely that the observed effects of corruption ernments that pay little attention to citizen
or bureaucratic inefficiency on economic out- concerns – because citizens are unable to
comes are more properly attributed to politi- voice them or are unable to sanction govern-
cian behavior that undermines both outcomes ments that ignore them – are less likely to
and bureaucratic performance, rather than to pursue policies that further social welfare.
the specifics of bureaucratic organization. Less clear are the specific attributes of politi-
This logic raises doubts about the causal cal and social organization in a country that
relationship between growth or development improve voice and accountability. The gov-
and the characteristics of a country’s bureauc- ernance literature has explored systemati-
racy. First, political incentives and politician cally only one aspect of political organization
actions are likely to generate both bad poli- that bears on voice and accountability, regime
cies and a neglected, inefficient and/or cor- type, or democratic versus autocratic govern-
rupt bureaucracy. Second, it is likely that the ment. The presumption is that democracy is
bad policies, as much as or more than the the only regime type that affords voice
characteristics of the bureaucracy, drive bad and accountability to citizens on a regular
development outcomes, potentially giving basis. Democracy should therefore promote
rise to a spurious association between bureau- economic development.
cratic characteristics and development. In fact, most of the research into democ-
This is not to say that the bureaucracy is racy and economic growth is empirical and
unimportant. Even if politicians substantially yields ambiguous results. Przeworski and
constrain bureaucratic discretion, residual Limongi (1993) underline the theoretical
discretion could nevertheless have meaning- obstacles that might be responsible for this
ful economic consequences. However, there ambiguity. They begin by pointing out that
is substantial justification – not least of much of the democracy literature argues that
which are the numerous examples of well- democracies raise growth rates by providing
oiled bureaucracies implementing cata- stronger guarantees for the security of
strophic policies – to demand that any property rights. But they argue that nothing
examination of this issue must be careful to about democratic decision making, seen
control for the possibility that observed rela- as majority rule, makes expropriation more
tionships between bureaucratic performance difficult, while long-lived dictatorships
and economic growth or development might might provide even stronger protection for
be spurious. property rights.10

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 11 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


450 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Their critique of the democracy and growth Empirical tests of the effects of
literature follows both the governance work government credibility/secure
on voice and accountability and the literature
property rights on development
on democracy in treating the state as a uni-
tary actor. Such analyses abstract from the With respect to the issue of property rights or
substantial variation among polities in their the rule of law, fairly exhaustive attempts
political and electoral institutions, the dynam- have been made to control for empirical dif-
ics of electoral competition, and differences ficulties ranging from endogeneity to meas-
in the constellations of interest groups across urement error. Results documenting the
countries.11 Integrating results and tools from importance of secure property rights for
the vast political economy literature that growth have been robust to causality testing
focuses on precisely these details is likely to (Calderón and Chong, 2000), ingenious
provide fertile ground for assessing the instruments and historical investigation
underlying institutions that influence voice, (Acemoglu et al., 2001), and to the substitu-
accountability and, ultimately, economic tion of income for growth as the dependent
development. The final section of this chap- variable (Hall and Jones, 1999). Although
ter discusses the significant payoffs to future there is still room for skepticism, it is never-
research that bridges the governance litera- theless true that the influence of secure prop-
ture with new developments in political erty rights has withstood an unusually large
economy. amount of scrutiny.
The security of property rights has also
been linked to development phenomena other
than economic growth. Dollar and Kraay
EVIDENCE OF THE EFFECTS OF (2002) consider the impact of secure prop-
GOVERNANCE ON ECONOMIC erty rights on inequality, via growth. They
DEVELOPMENT find that the security of property rights raises
the incomes of the rich and poor equally.
Evidence from cross-country statistical Using beginning of period measures of prop-
research amply supports the importance of erty rights and later measures of inequality.
secure property rights, the rule of law, or the In Knack (2002), secure property rights are
credibility of government for growth actually progressive, raising the incomes of
(Acemoglu et al., 2001; Knack and Keefer, the poor faster than those of the rich. The
1995; Rodrik et al., 2002) or per capita security of property rights is also negatively
incomes (Hall and Jones, 1999). However, related to rates of deforestation (Deacon,
large potential econometric problems emerge 1999).
in this literature. For example, the empirical The hypothesis that secure property rights
governance measures are usually subjective, accelerate economic development is supported
introducing noise and, possibly, bias into the by quantitative approaches other than those
resulting estimates. Nevertheless, they repre- employing cross-country data, as well. Natural
sent a quantum leap in the ability to experiments involving property rights include
bring statistical analysis to bear on topics that work by Feder (1993) on the consequences of
were previously investigated only in theory land titling for farmers in Thailand; Jiménez
or case studies, a leap that can be measured (1984) on the effects of titling on investment
in terms of the sharp increase in research in and prices of homes in Manila; Alston et al.
on governance-related topics that followed (1999) on the effects of property rights secu-
the introduction of these measures into rity on farm productivity and deforestation in
the literature. Some of this literature is the Brazilian Amazon; and O’Rourke (1999)
reviewed here. on the effects of land tenure insecurity on the

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 12 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


GOVERNANCE 451

adoption of efficient butter production meth- (2000) present quantitative evidence support-
ods in Ireland contrasted with Denmark. ive of the ‘embedded autonomy’ hypothesis
One caveat that is useful to recall in review- of Evans and, controlling for income, educa-
ing the empirical work on property rights and tion and ethnic and linguistic diversity, find
growth is that this work often contains broader that some characteristics of an ‘autonomous’
statements about the importance of ‘institu- bureaucracy (especially meritocratic recruit-
tions’ more generally. Knack and Keefer ment) predict property rights security and
(1995), Acemoglu et al. (2001), and Rodrik bureaucratic quality.
et al. (2002) all argue for the dominant effect It is, however, more difficult to draw firm
of ‘institutions’ on growth, but all use meas- conclusions about the effect of corruption and
ures of the security of property rights as their bureaucratic quality on economic develop-
measures of institutions. In the case of Knack ment. On the one hand, in the cross-
and Keefer (1995), despite the use of the word country work exemplified by Mauro (1995),
‘institutions’ in the title of the paper, both the the corruption variables exhibit considerable
hypotheses and the tests relate to the security overlap with the measures used in the property
of property rights and the rule of law. In other rights literature. Mauro’s variable is highly
cases, however, the property rights variables correlated, for example, with the property
are meant to stand for broader, less well- rights variable of Knack and Keefer, which is
specified institutional concepts. The thrust of consistent with endogeneity problems to
these papers is that ‘institutions’ matter, not which the analysis of corruption is likely
that ‘secure property rights’ matter. This would exposed.12
be entirely benign if all of the institutional and On the other hand, as the earlier discussion
governance forces that promote development foreshadows, the more fundamental diffi-
were captured by measures of the security of culty in drawing inferences about the impact
property rights. This does not seem to be the of corruption and bureaucratic quality on
case, however – nor would one expect it to be development is their greater vulnerability to
in view of the heterogeneity in the theoretical causality problems. Corruption in govern-
links between the different components of ment is sensitive to the incentives of the
governance and economic outcomes. political leadership, which are typically not
controlled for in corruption work and are
sure to have a significant independent effect
Empirical research into corruption on government performance and economic
development. These causality problems
and bureaucratic quality
emerge in at least two specific ways.
The conclusions from the empirical work on First, governments often put into place
corruption and bureaucratic quality are distortionary policies that directly slow eco-
broadly similar to the work on property nomic development but also give rise to cor-
rights. In the first and prototypical empirical ruption. Broadman and Recanatini (2002)
contribution, Mauro (1995) shows that cor- use evidence from surveys of businesspeople
ruption reduces growth, though Li et al. in transition countries regarding corruption
(2000) show that taking inequality into and the effects of regulation to show that
account reduces the estimated effect of cor- high regulatory barriers to entry and soft
ruption. Gupta et al. (2002) present evidence budget constraints on firms are both condu-
that corruption exacerbates income inequal- cive to corruption. More optimistically,
ity and poverty. Mo (2001) documents a Cheng et al. (1998) argue that well-function-
causal chain linking higher corruption to ing bureaucracies in South Korea and Taiwan
lower growth through reduced investment in were the result of conscious decisions by
human and private capital. Rauch and Evans political actors who, in turn, were motivated

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 13 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


452 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

by a desire to avert past crises or to deter The democracy literature, relying on more
aggression by large neighbors. structural and objective characteristics of
Second, corruption can emerge from other polities, yields more ambiguous results. One
governance problems that also directly limit source of confusion is that democratic coun-
development. Keefer and Knack (2007) tries are both richer and better performing.
present a model and evidence that if political This naturally gives rise to the difficult ques-
decision makers find it difficult or costly to tion: are countries better performing because
guarantee the security of property rights of they are rich, or because they are democratic?
private investors, they will change their poli- For example, as we would expect, corruption
cies accordingly. In particular, they will sup- and rent-seeking are higher in countries
press productive public investment and lacking fully competitive elections, as are
increase rent-seeking or corruption. The evi- the risks of expropriation.14 However, coun-
dence in this paper suggests that countries tries with competitive elections are also sub-
with less credible governments (countries with stantially richer than other countries, even
less secure property rights) spend 60 per cent excluding the richest 20 democracies from
more on public investment as a fraction of the comparison (in 2000, excluding the
national income than countries with more richest 20, 97 countries with competitive
secure property rights and that the difference elections had purchasing power parity
is due the effect of insecure property rights on adjusted per capita incomes of US $5,470,
incentives to divert rents.13 No investigations compared to US $3,121 for the countries that
of the effect of corruption and bureaucratic did not have fully competitive elections). In
quality on economic development take such part because of this, a large literature that
endogeneity issues into account either at the always controls for per capita incomes at the
level of theory or empirical testing. beginning of the period finds only an ambig-
uous relationship between democracy and
growth. Many of the income gains that
Voice, accountability, and democracy generates may already be embed-
ded in the higher initial per capita incomes of
democracy: The evidence
democratic countries.15
There are no agreed indicators of the con- A number of investigations use more
cepts ‘voice’ and ‘accountability’, either in global indicators to test broader notions of
theory or in the empirical literature. The lit- governance or institutions on economic
erature employs proxies ranging from development. Easterly and Levine (2002),
Freedom House indicators of political also engaging the debate on the role of insti-
freedoms and civil liberties (found by Scully, tutions versus geography in economic devel-
1988 to be predictors of growth), to structural opment, use the global governance index of
indicators of democracy – whether there are Kaufmann et al. (2002), rather than more
competitive elections and the executive is narrow property rights and rule of law indica-
constrained by a legislature. With respect to tors. The broad governance index has the
the Freedom House indicators, the empirical advantage of including more dimensions of a
record is reasonably convincing that these country’s institutional performance. However,
variables are important for development. the aggregate measure exacerbates the prob-
Like governance itself, they are also multi- lem of interpretation. Provided the coeffi-
dimensional. This makes it difficult to deter- cient estimates are significant, one can only
mine which concrete and objectively say that some factors related to governance
observable characteristics can be traced spe- are positively associated with growth. One
cifically to notions of voice and accountabil- cannot say, however, which factors those are,
ity, and to observed changes in development nor even be sure that some other factors do
outcomes. not also have a negative impact on growth.

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 14 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


GOVERNANCE 453

THE RESEARCH FRONTIER: and voter information on government incen-


IDENTIFYING THE DETERMINANTS tives regarding fiscal policy, including
OF GOOD GOVERNANCE rent-seeking (the textbook by Persson and
Tabellini, 2000, provides a wide-ranging and
While governance research has made con- complete summary). This literature focuses on
vincing contributions to the study of develop- the information of voters, the ability of gov-
ment, crucial questions remain. Some of ernments to make credible pre-electoral prom-
these have to do with endogeneity issues ises to voters, and the details of the institutions
raised by much of the governance literature. of government decision making (parliamen-
For example, does corruption suppress devel- tary or presidential; if presidential, is it the
opment or is corruption just symptomatic of president or the legislature that prepares the
a deeper problem in the political environ- budget? What are the amendment powers of
ment of a country? Understanding the deter- the respective entities?). The power of the
minants of good governance can help answer analysis lies not so much in the accuracy of its
this question. However, regardless of the assumptions about the political process, but
endogeneity and causality issues that are rather in the coherent way in which the analy-
preoccupations of the governance literature, sis marshals the many influences, ranging
the determinants of good governance – of from institutions to information, that act on
secure property rights, voice and accounta- political decision makers’ policy making
bility, or honest and efficient bureaucratic incentives.
behavior – are key issues in their own One particular emphasis in Persson and
right. Intellectually, they are some of the Tabellini (2000) is the role of political and
most challenging in the social sciences. From electoral institutions on political incentives.
a policy perspective, they are essential to For example, they predict that financing of
understand if one is to move forward in public goods (those that benefit the whole
developing sustainable and effective reforms population) relative to more targeted goods is
for countries suffering from, for example, higher in parliamentary democracies. In fact,
insecure property rights. among 24 parliamentary democracies for
There are two important political economy which data are available, the ratio of educa-
research efforts that relate to the sources of tion (broad and relatively untargeted) to
good governance. One relates the structure of public investment spending (narrow and rela-
political institutions and competition, includ- tively targeted to specific voters) is about
ing the information of voters, the credibility 20 percentage points higher than in 18 presi-
of political competitors, and the underpin- dential democracies.16 This has direct impli-
nings of intra-party competition, to broad cations for governance work, which is
decisions of government, particularly related concerned precisely with using government
to fiscal allocations but extending to corrup- to efficiently improve the welfare of the aver-
tion. The second focuses more specifically age citizen – a goal that is more difficult to
on the conditions under which countries achieve when political institutions give policy
exhibit secure property rights. makers incentives to provide inefficient tar-
geted goods that benefit narrow slices of the
population.
The political economy of Models from this literature also predict that
government spending corruption (rent-seeking) should be higher
under presidential systems and under
and corruption
non-proportional electoral systems with larger
Recent important advances have brought great district magnitudes (legislative seats per
rigor to our understanding of the impact of electoral district). Empirical research has pro-
political and electoral institutions, credibility vided support for these predictions, as well.

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 15 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


454 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Persson et al. (2002) find that electoral sys- and Bratton and van de Walle (1994) argue
tems with non-proportional electoral rules and that African democracies are different
larger district magnitudes discourage corrup- because they have their roots in neopatrimo-
tion. Lederman et al. (2001) conclude that nial forms of government, where the execu-
presidential systems are more corrupt. tive maintains authority by dispensing
The predictions regarding political and personal patronage. In neither case are the
electoral institutions and their effects on policy authors explicit about the underlying charac-
outcomes or governance are sensitive to the teristics of political competition or political
underlying assumptions regarding how well- institutions that permit elected officials to be
informed voters are, how ideologically divided exclusionary or neo-patrimonial. Whereas
they are, and how credible political promises Bratton and van de Walle take as a character-
to voters are prior to elections. Direct exami- istic feature of regimes the personal dispen-
nation of these assumptions is a natural and sation of targeted or private goods to
important direction for future research. individuals or small groups, the literature
Already, however, research has provided early summarized in Persson and Tabellini (2000)
insights into the independent role of many of seeks to explain the reliance on targeted
these assumptions on development outcomes. public spending.
Besley and Burgess (2001), for example, Efforts to bridge these two literatures can
document the role of citizen information on yield critical insights into the nature of eco-
political decision making. They show that in nomic development. For example, the new
Indian states with greater literacy, electoral political economy literature regularly makes
turnout and newspaper circulation (controlling explicit and often different assumptions about
for per capita incomes), state governments the credibility of political promises, but it
were more likely to respond to food shortages rarely analyzes variation in credibility across
via the public distribution of food. Their work countries as a key determinant of differences
takes just one of many potential information in development outcomes. Keefer and Vlaicu
problems as a point of departure. They leave (2008) makes an attempt in this direction,
aside the information issues prominent in arguing that clientelism prevails when com-
Persson and Tabellini (2002), particularly the peting politicians can make credible pre-
effects of voter and politician uncertainty election promises to only a few people and
about their respective ideological biases. dissipates when their promises are credible to
They also apply their analysis to one particu- the whole country. Lacking institutionalized
lar policy problem, necessarily abstracting bases for credibility (such as long-standing
from, for example, the security of property political parties with well-identified ideo-
rights. logical platforms), political competitors can
Much of this work follows the ‘rational therefore only make credible promises to a
choice’ or ‘new political economy’ style small fraction of the population, leading to a
of analysis – bringing more quantitative preference for targeted, personalized and
approaches to the study of individual actors inefficient spending rather than efficient and
and their incentives and largely ignoring his- broad-based public good provision.17
torical or cultural differences that might This argument is rooted in the detailed
influence outcomes. The comparative poli- observations of clientelism (e.g., by Scott,
tics literature is full of valuable contributions 1972) and of the patterns of political recruit-
that follow the reverse strategy, differentiat- ment in relatively clientelist democracies
ing regime types by referring to historical (e.g., the work of Krishna (n. d.) on candidate
and broad characteristics rather than to the recruitment in India), but uses the tools sum-
incentives of the actors that run them. marized in Persson and Tabellini (2000) to
Remmer (1986) categorizes democracies as explain why these patterns exist in some
‘exclusionary’ and inclusive, for example, countries and not others and to sort out their

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 16 3/13/2009 12:10:17 PM


GOVERNANCE 455

policy implications. The value of the effort much-publicized corruption episodes in France
can be measured by its success in explaining over the 1970s–1990s demonstrates the role
important puzzling phenomena. There are of personal relationships – networks – among
two, in particular, to which the conclusions in key decision makers. These informal networks
Keefer and Vlaicu (2008) seem to apply. circumvented or short-circuited apparently
First, to the extent that political actors in robust institutional checks and balances meant
poor countries are less able to make credible to control corrupt behavior. As a result,
promises to voters, they are more likely to although one party was consistently associ-
spend on targeted and narrow constituencies, ated with massive campaign spending scan-
such as most public investments, than untar- dals, including large procurement bribes
geted constituencies, as is the case with most associated with the purchase of warships by
education spending. In fact, in 1997, the ratio the Taiwanese and the diversion of money
of education to public investment was 70 per from the state oil company to party coffers and
cent higher in the 12 richest parliamentary to the bank account of the chief judge of the
democracies than in the 12 poorest (that is, Supreme Court, the other party refrained from
holding institutions constant). At the same pushing for prosecution.
time, the 12 poorest parliamentary democra- Personal, cross-party ties – much as in
cies allocated resources in almost the same many developing countries – seem to explain
way as 14 other countries that could not this. Heilbrunn (2002) argues that the cir-
be considered functioning democracies at cumstances that allowed these personalized
all (and for which data are available on ties to overwhelm the institutional checks
education spending). and balances include members of the net-
Second, as Bratton and van de Walle have work controlling sufficient levers of power
argued, history seems to matter in the develop- and network members being able to insure
ment of democracies. Bratton and van de that the rewards of loyalty to other network
Walle argue that there is a relationship between members would exceed the potential costs of
the nature of the pre-democratic regime and subverting the institutional checks and bal-
the subsequent possibilities for consolidating ances. The unraveling of these cases provides
democracy, although they are less clear about further evidence for the importance of net-
the underlying causal relationship. Keefer and works: prosecution of these officials was
Vlaicu (2008) argues that the pre-democratic eventually undertaken, but only at the initia-
period determines whether political competi- tive of a Norwegian-born female prosecutor,
tors in a democracy have credible policy someone outside the networks documented
stances on a wide range of issues. Evidence by Heilbrunn.
for this comes from the contrasting experience In sum, the literature on the political roots
of British democracy after the massive expan- of good governance offers promising direc-
sion of the franchise in the early nineteenth tions for future research. The most promising
century and the evolution of democracy in the seem to relate to the specific conditions of
Dominican Republic following the death of political decision making and electoral deci-
Rafael Trujillo. The first succeeded because of sion making, specifically to information,
a history of political competition between credibility and the nature of inter-personal
relatively coherent and therefore credible relationships among politicians.
political alternatives; the second has pro-
ceeded haltingly because of the absence or
ruthless suppression of political competition The political economy of
prior to democracy.
secure property rights
The personalized relationships that charac-
terize clientelism are found in other contexts The literature on the determinants of secure
as well. Heilbrunn’s (2002) examination of property rights emphasizes especially the

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 17 3/13/2009 12:10:18 PM


456 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

role of political checks and balances, but also econometric difficulties that can explain the
social characteristics such as polarization weak statistical relationship: the inevitable
and social capital. Substantial puzzles remain, correlation of other explanatory variables,
however. For example, property rights are such as per capita income, with checks and
insecure in many countries with formal insti- balances and the fact that empirical variables
tutional checks and balances, secure in others used to represent checks and balances repre-
lacking them. sent more accurately the number of institu-
North and Weingast (1989) ask why the tional veto gates, but less accurately the
interest rates charged by Dutch lenders to the preference alignments of the veto players who
English Crown fell after the Glorious occupy those veto gates. However, beyond
Revolution and argue that the introduction of these difficulties, it is clear as well that the
checks and balances in government (a more conditions under which non-democracies can
powerful parliament) reduced the risk to lend- establish credible commitments and some
ers that the English Crown would renege on its democracies cannot remains an open and
contractual obligations. Stasavage (2003) and important area of inquiry.
others have pointed out the substantial time The work of Clague et al. (1996) deepens
lag (as much as 60 years) between the the property rights puzzle, highlighting the
Revolution and the decline in interest rates, role of regime longevity. They find that long-
however. He argues that the introduction of lived autocrats offer as much or more protec-
additional institutional checks is insufficient tion to property rights than short-lived
to secure property rights. He shows that the democracies, though long-lived democracies
time lag can be explained by the slow evolu- are the most secure of all. This conclusion
tion of the preferences of the different actors reinforces the idea that the protection of
who controlled the newly instituted checks property rights depends on more than formal
and balances. To the extent that the prefer- institutional rules, but it also guides future
ences of at least one ‘veto player’ were aligned research toward a more specific puzzle: what
with those of lenders to the English Crown, changes over time in democracies, such that
checks and balances secured lender contrac- older democracies provide more secure prop-
tual rights; this did not occur, however, until erty rights than younger ones? Keefer and
some years after the institutional change took Vlaicu (2008) suggests that young democra-
place.18 Keefer and Stasavage (2002) also find cies are more vulnerable to clientelism and,
that both preferences and institutional veto by implication, restricting to clients the frac-
points matter in ensuring credibility with tion of investors to whom the government
respect to monetary policy. can make credible promises about the secu-
The literature is convincing that checks and rity of property rights. The literature has yet
balances are important to government credi- to rigorously link clientelism and the security
bility and secure property rights, but suggests of property rights, however.
as well that they are neither necessary nor suf- Social explanations for the security of
ficient. Essays in Boortz and Haber (2002), property rights also abound. Knack and
about the ability of the Mexican dictator Keefer (1997b) find that measures of social
Porfirio Diaz to entice considerable invest- capital – essentially, measures of the extent
ment in the absence of institutional checks and to which people in different countries believe
balances, make it clear that checks and bal- that others in their country are trustworthy –
ances may not be necessary for government are positively associated with the security of
credibility or secure property rights. In cross- property and contract rights. Naturally, cau-
country comparisons, checks and balances sality problems emerge here: do people trust
have some effect on the security of property each other because their institutions make
rights, but the effect is not robust to the pres- property rights and contractual commitments
ence of controls. There are straightforward reliable, or the other way around? In either

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 18 3/13/2009 12:10:18 PM


GOVERNANCE 457

direction, however, there are important impli- implying that pre-democratic forms of politi-
cations for development that have yet to be cal exchange survive the introduction of dem-
explored. ocratic institutions – but we do not know how
Polarization in society might also under- or under what conditions they disappear. A
mine property rights security – the argument promising line of research is surely to link
being either that the more polarized are citi- these observations with the vast literature on
zens, the less likely they are to respect the the dynamics of political party evolution and
rights of others, or more in the vein of social the conditions under which political parties
choice, the more polarized are citizens, the can make credible promises to voters.
more volatile is policy likely to be. Svensson
(1998) has found inequality and property rights
to be inversely associated, and offers econo-
metric evidence that the effect is from the first CONCLUSION: HOW CAN WE
to the second. Keefer and Knack (2002a) show IMPROVE GOVERNANCE?
that other forms of polarization – ethnic and
linguistic – suppress the security of property Governance reform prospects and strategies
rights, and it is in part through this channel depend significantly on whether one believes
that they affect growth. Acemoglu and that flaws in the state apparatus (e.g., public
Robinson (2001) argue that wealth inequality administration) lie at the heart of governance
can increase political instability and, thereby, failures, or whether one believes that they are
the insecurity of property rights. Keefer and more deeply embedded in the political and
Knack (2002a) find evidence that income social dynamics of a country. If the former,
inequality reduces insecurity, but no support significant opportunities for reform can open
for the role of political instability. up. For example, corruption can be addressed
All of these contributions still leave up in by reforms to government financial manage-
the air the specific channels through which ment, procurement and audit systems. Voice
polarization undermines the security of prop- and accountability can be addressed by requir-
erty rights, however. Though following simi- ing bureaucracies to open up the rule making
lar empirical strategies, for example, Svensson process (the regulatory process) to more popu-
(1998) and Keefer and Knack (2002a) propose lar participation. Bureaucratic quality can be
completely different channels: Svensson improved by boosting pay and strengthening
argues that property rights security are the meritocratic recruitment procedures.
result of investments by government – a fiscal If, on the other hand, governance failures
decision – while Knack and Keefer model the are more deeply rooted in the incentives of
security of property rights as the propensity of political actors, these reforms may not trans-
government decisions to change dramatically late into significant change in the way gov-
and unpredictably. ernment operates – in the security of property
In sum, then, large questions about the rights, in the quality of regulation, or in the
determinants of property rights remain. There services provided by governments to citi-
is evidence that long-running democracies zens. This does not imply, however, that
promote property rights, broadly defined, but reform is impossible or that there is no role
we do not know which characteristics of long- for outside assistance. Instead, it implies that
running democracies endow them with this reform must be structured to address or adapt
characteristic. Nor do we have micro-level to the underlying difficulties in the relation-
evidence that more systematically outlines the ship between voters and politicians. Those
actions that are open to decision makers in outside the political process can potentially
short-lived democracies that are foreclosed to change the political equilibrium by providing
those in long-lived democracies. One might relevant information about candidate per-
interpret the observation about clientelism as formance to voters, verifying or debunking

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 19 3/13/2009 12:10:18 PM


458 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

chronically unstable. The insights they develop from


political claims of responsibility for good
this model are significant, but the empirical relevance
outcomes, and the mobilization of voters of this particular case has not yet been established.
around service delivery issues (that is, making 6. There is little evidence that redistribution – or
it more credible to politicians that voters more broadly, the allocation of property rights – is
whose apathy or support they took for granted systematically associated with low growth. See, for
example, Knack and Keefer (1997b).
might actually vote against them on the basis
7. There are, however, sound empirical reasons to
of service delivery or other dimensions of be concerned about causality in the relationship
government performance that were not previ- between the security of property rights and eco-
ously relevant). There is unlikely to be a nomic growth. Among these, measurement error –
generic blueprint good for all reforms in all observer bias that boosts assessments of the security
of property rights in fast-growing countries – is the
countries. However, the literature is moving
most important.
toward the identification of key, concrete 8. Rangeland in the American West had this
political obstacles to good governance characteristic – not so valuable prior to the arrival of the
that, like the extent of voter information, are railroads, but very valuable and worth fencing after
amenable to change. their arrival. Esther Boserup (1965) first argued that
population pressure increases the value of land, leading
to greater efforts to protect rights to land. Anderson
and Hill (1990) show that the conditions under
which investors (farmers, in this case) are allowed to
DISCLAIMER establish property rights also has a significant effect
on productivity. However, none of these studies show
(nor are they intended to show) that growth
The contents and conclusions of this chapter
makes insecure property rights secure. They demon-
are the author’s own and are not intended to strate instead that growth makes it worthwhile to
represent the views of the World Bank, its define previously worthless property rights. Worthless
Executive Directors, or the countries they property rights are not, however, at the heart of the
represent. debate linking the security of property rights to eco-
nomic development.
9. If there is a high correlation between the
answer to the simple question (‘how predictable is
government decision making?’) and the nuanced
NOTES issues of credibility (‘How easy would it be for a gov-
ernment official to make a decision or take some
1. http://www.fordfound.org/fields/governance/ action that would reduce your profits by 50 per
overview cent?’), then this strong theoretical distinction is less
2. Keefer and Knack (2002b), for example, show important for empirical work.
that whether property rights insecurity is the product 10. Przeworski, et al. (2000) introduce and provide
of a general level of insecurity in a society that makes substantial evidence for several novel variations on
it costly for governments to protect property rights, the theme of democracy and growth, showing in
or as the product of particularly short horizons of particular (though not explaining) that population
government leaders that makes it more likely for growth is faster in dictatorships; controlling for this,
them to prefer expropriation over growth, property per capita income growth is approximately the same
rights insecurity slows growth. in both dictatorships and democracies.
3. It should not go without saying that other, non- 11. They summarize democratization as giving the
economic rights tend also to be insecure in these median voter control over policy, leading to a shift in
same countries. distribution towards the median voter and a conse-
4. They point to Marx’s argument that capitalism quent disruption, rather than reinforcement, of
and democracy are inherently incompatible, since property rights.
democracy enables the poor to tax the rich, giving 12. Still, it is fair to point out that, among the
the rich an incentive to buy military intervention to variables that make up these risk guide indices, the
overturn the democracy, an argument formalized by lowest inter-variable correlation is with corruption,
Acemoglu and Robinson (2001). suggesting that the risk guide indicators are able to
5. Acemoglu and Robinson (2001) develop a differentiate at least somewhat between corruption
model in which, when the cost of coups by the rich and other governance problems.
against poor democracies and wealth inequality are 13. Political Risk Services generates the International
in precisely the right combination, democracy is Country Risk Guide, assessments of country risk

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 20 3/13/2009 12:10:18 PM


GOVERNANCE 459

widely used by foreign investors. Two variables in the Aizenman, J. (1995) ‘Investment in new activi-
ICRG, bureaucratic quality and corruption, comprise ties and the welfare cost of uncertainty’,
the measure of ‘bureaucratic performance’ used in NBER Working Paper 5041 (February).
Keefer and Knack (2002b). Alston, L., Libecap, G., and Mueller, B. (1999)
14. This comparison is between countries that
Titles, conflict and land use: The develop-
have competitive legislative and executive elections
(LIEC and EIEC equal to seven, from the Database on
ment of property rights and land reform on
Political Institutions, Beck et al., 2001) and countries the Brazilian Amazon frontier. Ann Arbor:
that do not. University of Michigan Press.
15. Of course, Przeworski and Limongi (1993) Anderson, T.L. and Hill, P.J. (1990) ‘Race for
would argue that there is in fact no theoretical case property rights’, Journal of Law and
for arguing in favor of the superior economic or Economics, 33 (April): 177–97.
growth performance of democratic countries. Among Bates, R. (1981) Markets and states in tropical
the research documenting the empirical ambiguity Africa. Berkeley: University of California
are de Haan and Siermann (1998) and, especially, Press.
Przeworski et al. (2000). On the other hand, Quinn
Bates, R. (1991) ‘The economics of the transi-
and Woolley (2001) argue that the effect of democ-
racy is to make the economy less volatile, reflecting
tion to democracy’, PS: Political Science and
the preferences of citizens for lower risk (which, in Politics, 24 (1): 24–27.
democracies, they are better able to express). Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., and
16. Using political measures from the Database on Walsh, P. (2001) ‘New tools in comparative
Political Institutions, Beck et al. (2001). political economy: The database of political
17. Though the credibility approach to clientelism institutions’, World Bank Economic Review,
is arguably most consistent with the literature on 15 (1): 165–76.
clientelism and neo-patrimonialism, there are two Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2001) ‘Political
important alternative theories. Robinson and Verdier agency, government responsiveness and the
(2002) argue that clientelism emerges when politi-
role of the media’, European Economic
cians can make no credible promises to anyone, but
have a high regard for the welfare of some small
Review, 45 (4–6): 629–40.
group of citizens (e.g., members of the same tribe or Boortz, J.L. and Haber, S. (2002) The
citizens from the same region). Medina and Stokes Mexican economy, 1870–1930: Essays on the
(2002) assume politicians are always credible, but economic history of institutions, revolution and
that clientelism emerges when some politicians have growth. Stanford, CA: Stanford University
monopoly control over assets that voters value. Press.
18. Keefer and Stasavage (2002) show, however, Boserup, E. (1965) The conditions of agricul-
that policy stability and policy credibility are not the tural growth: The economics of agrarian
same. Policy can be stable (e.g., policy will always change under population pressure. New
equal the median voter’s preferred outcome in a one
York: Aldine Publishing Co.
dimensional, simple model of policy making) but still
not be credible (since, conditional on the response of
Bratton, M. and van de Walle, N. (1994)
citizens to the median voter’s decision in the first ‘Neopatrimonial regimes and political
period, the median voter may still gain from reneging transitions in Africa’, World Politics, 46
or changing the policy, in the next period). (4): 453–89.
Broadman, H. and Recanatini, F. (2002)
‘Corruption and policy: Back to the roots’,
Journal of Policy Reform, 5 (1): 37–49.
REFERENCES Buchanan, J.M., Tollison, R.D., and Tullock, G.
(eds) (1980) Toward a theory of the rent-
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. (2001) ‘A seeking society. College Station, TX: Texas
theory of political transitions’, American A & M University Press.
Economic Review, 91 (4): 938–63. Calderón, C. and Chong, A. (2000) ‘Causality
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. and feedback between institutional meas-
(2001) ‘The colonial origins of com- ures and economic growth’, Economics and
parative development: An empirical investiga- Politics, 12 (1): 69–81.
tion’, American Economic Review, 91: Cheng, T.J., Haggard, S., and Kang, D.
1369–401. (1998) ‘Institutions and growth in Korea and

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 21 3/13/2009 12:10:18 PM


460 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Taiwan: The bureaucracy’, Journal of and states. Cambridge, MA: Harvard


Development Studies, 34 (6): 87–111. University Press.
Clague, C., Keefer, P., Knack, S., and Olson, M. IMF (1997) Good governance: The IMF’s role.
(1996) ‘Property and contract rights under Retrieved March 31, 2008, from http://
democracy and dictatorship’, The Journal of www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/exrp/govern/
Economic Growth, 1 (2): 243–76. govindex.htm
Deacon, R.T. (1999) ‘Deforestation and owner- IOG (2008) What we do. Retrieved March 31,
ship: Evidence from historical accounts and 2008, from http://www.iog.ca/about_us.
contemporary data’, Land Economics, 75 (3): asp?strTextSite=false
341–59. Jímenez, E. (1984) ‘Tenure security and urban
de Haan, J. and Siermann, C.L.J. (1998) ‘Further squatting’, Review of Economics and
evidence on the relationship between eco- Statistics, 66 (4): 556–67.
nomic freedom and economic growth’, Kang, D. (2002) Crony capitalism: Corruption
Public Choice, 95 (3/4): 363–80. and development in South Korea and the
de Soto, H. (1989) The other path. New York: Philippines. New York: Cambridge University
Harper and Row. Press.
Dollar, D. and Kraay, A. (2002) ‘Growth is Kaufmann, D. and Kraay, A. (2002) Growth
good for the poor’, Journal of Economic without governance. Economia, 3 (1): 169–
Growth, 7 (3): 193–225. 229.
Easterly, W. and Levine, R. (2002) Tropics, Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Zoído-Lobatón,
germs and crops: How endowments affect P. (2002) Governance matters III – Updated
economic development (National Bureau of indicators for 2000/01 (World Bank Policy
Economic Research Working Paper 9106) Research Department Working Paper
Epstein, D. and O’Halloran, S. (1999) Delegating No. 2772).
powers: A transaction cost politics approach Kaufmann, D. and Wei, S.J. (1999) Does
to policy making under separate powers. ‘grease money’ speed up the wheels of com-
New York: Cambridge University Press. merce? (National Bureau of Economic
Evans, P. (1989) ‘Predatory, developmental, Research Working Paper 7093, April).
and other apparatuses: A comparative politi- Keefer, P. and Vlaicu, R. (2008). “Democracy,
cal economy perspective’, Sociological Credibility and Clientelism.” Journal of Law,
Forum, 4 (4): 561–87. Economics and Organization 24 (2): 371–
Evans, P. (1995) Embedded autonomy: States 406.
and industrial transformation. Princeton, NJ: Keefer, P. and Knack, S. (2002a) ‘Polarization,
Princeton University Press. politics and property rights: Links between
Feder, G. (1993) ‘The economics of land and inequality and growth’, Public Choice, 111
titling in Thailand’, in K. Hoff, A. Braverman (1–2): 127–54.
and J.E. Stiglitz (eds), The economics of Keefer, P. and Knack, S. (2007)
rural organization: Theory, practice, and policy. ‘Boondoggles, rent-seeking and political
New York: Oxford University Press, pp. checks and balances: Public investment
259–68. under unaccountable governments’, The
Gupta, S., Davoodi, H., and Alonso-Terme, R. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89 (3):
(2002) ‘Does corruption affect income ine- 566–72.
quality and poverty’, Economics of Keefer, P. and Stasavage, D. (2002)
Governance, 3 (1): 23–45. ‘Checks and balances, private information,
Hall, R.E. and Jones, C.I. (1999) ‘Why do some and the credibility of monetary commit-
countries produce so much more output per ments’, International Organization, 56 (4):
worker than others?’, Quarterly Journal of 751–74.
Economics, 114 (1): 83–116. Keefer, P. and Stasavage, D. (2003) The limits
Heilbrunn, J. (2002) Oil and water? Elite politi- of delegation: Veto players, central bank
cians and corruption in France. Mimeo, independence and the credibility of mone-
Colorado School of Mines. tary policy. Mimeo: The World Bank.
Hirschman, A. (1970) Exit, voice and loyalty: Knack, S. (2002) ‘Social capital, growth and
Responses to decline in firms, organizations poverty: A survey of cross-country evidence’,

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 22 3/13/2009 12:10:18 PM


GOVERNANCE 461

in C. Grootaert and T. van Bastelaer, (eds), North, D. and Weingast, B. (1989) ‘Constitutions
The role of social capital in development: An and commitment: The evolution of institu-
empirical assessment. 42–82. New York: tions governing public choice in seventeenth-
Cambridge University Press. century England’, Journal of Economic
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1995) ‘Institutions History, 49 (4): 803–32.
and economic performance: Cross- O’Rourke, K.H. (1999) Culture, politics and
country tests using alternative institutional innovation: Creamery diffusion in late 19th
measures’, Economics and Politics, 7 (3): century Denmark and Ireland. Mimeo.
207–28. Department of Economics, University College
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1997a) ‘Does inequal- Dublin.
ity harm growth only in democracies? A Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2000) Political
replication and extension’, American Journal economics: Explaining public policy.
of Political Science, 41 (1): 323–32. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1997b) ‘Does social Persson, T., Tabellini, G., and Trebbi, F. (2002)
capital have an economic payoff? A cross- Electoral rules and corruption. Mimeo.
country investigation’, Quarterly Journal of Institute for International Economic Studies,
Economics, 112: 1251–88. Stockholm University.
Krishna, A. (n.d.) Seizing the middle ground: Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M., Cheibub, J.A., and
New political entrepreneurs in India. Mimeo, Limongi, F. (2000) Democracy and develop-
Sanford Institute for Public Policy, Duke ment: Political institutions and well-being in
University. the world, 1950–1990. New York: Cambridge
Lederman, D., Loayza, N., and Reis Soares, R. University Press.
(2001) Accountability and corruption: Przeworski, A. and Limongi, F. (1993) ‘Political
Political institutions matter. (World Bank regimes and economic growth’, The Journal
Policy Research Working Paper 2708, of Economic Perspectives, 7 (3): 51–69.
November). Quinn, D. and Woolley, J. (2001) ‘Democracy
Leff, N.H. (1964) ‘Economic development and national economic performance: The
through bureaucratic corruption’, The preference for stability’, American Journal of
American Behavior Scientist, 8 (2): 8–14. Political Science, 45 (July): 634–57.
Li, H., Xu, L.C., and Zou, H.-F. (2000) ‘Corruption, Rauch, J. and Evans, P. (2000) ‘Bureaucratic
income distribution and growth’, Economics structure and bureaucratic performance in
and Politics, 12 (2): 155–82. less developed countries’, Journal of Public
Libecap, G.D. (ed.) (1996) Reinventing govern- Economics, 75 (1): 49–71.
ment and the problem of bureaucracy. Remmer, K. (1986) ‘Exclusionary democracy’,
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. Studies in Comparative International
Mauro, P. (1995) ‘Corruption and growth’, The Development, 20 (4): 64–8.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (3): Robinson, J. A. and Verdier, T. (2002) The
681–712. political economy of clientelism (Center for
McCubbins, M., Noll, R. and Weingast, B. Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper
(1987) ‘Administrative procedures as instru- No. 3205, February).
ments of political control’, Journal of Law, Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., and Trebbi, F.
Economics and Organization, 3 (2): 243–77. (2002) Institutions rule: The primacy of insti-
Medina, L.F. and Stokes, S. (2002) Clientelism tutions over geography and integration in
as political monopoly. Mimeo. Department economic development (National Bureau of
of Political Science, University of Chicago. Economic Research Working Paper 9305,
Mo, P.H. (2001) ‘Corruption and economic November).
growth’, Journal of Comparative Economics, Scott, J.C. (1972) ‘Patron-client politics and
29 (1): 66–79. political change in Southeast Asia’, American
North, D. (1981) Structure and change in eco- Political Science Review, 66 (1): 91–113.
nomic history. New York: W.W. Norton. Scully, G.W. (1988) ‘The institutional
North, D. (1990) Institutions, institutional framework and economic development’,
change and economic performance. Journal of Political Economy, 96 (31):
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 652–62.

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 23 3/13/2009 12:10:18 PM


462 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Stasavage, D. (2003) Public debt and the birth www.usaid.gov/our_work/democracy_and_


of the democratic state: France and Great governance/technical_areas/governance/
Britain 1688–1789. New York: Cambridge Wallsten, S. (2002) Of carts and horses:
University Press. Regulation and privatization in telecommu-
Svensson, J. (1998) ‘Investment, property rights nications (World Bank Policy Research
and political instability: Theory and evi- Working Paper, October).
dence’, European Economic Review, 42 (7): Weingast, B. and Moran, M. (1983) ‘Bureaucratic
1317–41. discretion or congressional control?
UNDP (2008) Democratic governance. Retrieved Regulatory policymaking by the federal trade
March 31, 2008, from http://www.undp.org/ commission’, Journal of Political Economy,
governance/ 91 (October): 765–800.
USAID (2005) Promoting more transparent World Bank (2008) Public sector governance:
and accountable government institutions. An overview. Retrieved March 31, 2008, from
Retrieved March 31, 2008, from http:// http://www1.worldbank.org/publicsector/

9781412919760_Chap24.indd 24 3/13/2009 12:10:18 PM


25
Terrorism
Jennifer S. Holmes

INTRODUCTION unify the subject matter or gain broad agree-


ment about basic concepts or definitions.
In the past, the study of terrorism has been
divided into two competing paradigms, mirror-
ing general fault lines in comparative politics
between the qualitatively and quantitatively FOUR FUNDAMENTAL DISPUTES
inclined scholars. This separation has post-
poned progress in clarifying continuing dis- The field has progressed in a disjointed fash-
putes in the field. In general, the study of ion due to four unresolved challenges about
terrorism is fragmented, conceptually muddled, terrorism and its study: contested concepts,
handicapped by a lack of data, and troubled by the division of the phenomenon, questions of
political connotations. However, the challenge perspective, and problems of quantification.
of understanding terrorism is urgent due to both
Frequently neglected and often overlooked, the
its theoretical and substantive importance. science of terror has been conducted in the cracks
Terrorism touches on many crucial areas of and crevices which lied between the large aca-
research, from violence and conflict, to issues demic disciplines. There has been a chronic short-
of political stability and government response. age of experienced researchers – a huge proportion
Within the last few years, a plethora of of the literature is the work of fleeting visitors:
individuals who are often poorly aware of what
studies have been published dealing with ter- has already been done and naïve in their methods
rorism. According to CSA Worldwide and conclusions (Silke, 2004a: 1).
Political Science Abstracts, there were 1853
published works categorized with a variation This chapter will discuss the four fundamen-
of terror as a keyword from 1960 to 1989. tal disputes and propose possible solutions to
This number increased to 1949 from 1990 to create linkages among the different areas of
2000, and ballooned to an astonishing 6564 research.
works from 2001 to 2006. ‘The widespread
literature in this field … is neither suffi-
ciently coordinated nor channeled so that it Disagreement about concepts
can build the cognitive and social structure of
terrorism’ (Gordon, 1999: 150). Despite the Defining terrorism has been a longstanding
proliferation of publications within the last issue in the field, which hinders theory devel-
few years, little progress has been made to opment, testing, and comparison. As Crenshaw

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:40:24 PM


464 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

(2000) notes, ‘the problem of defining terror- scholars attempt to generalize without
ism has hindered analysis since the inception falling into problems of concept stretching
of studies in the early 1970s’ (p. 406). It is (Collier and Mahon, 1993; Sartori, 1970).
doubtful that one definition of terrorism will What is clear is that terrorism is used for a
be uniformly accepted as definitive and ‘there political and rhetoric effect, suffers from
appears to be a war-weariness among estab- ‘border’ and ‘membership’ problems, and
lished researchers over definitional issues’ ‘suffers from ‘stretching’ and ‘traveling’
(Silke, 2004c: 208). Despite the frustration problems’ (Weinberg et al., 2004: 778). In
with repeated efforts to create a broadly other words, it is difficult to differentiate ter-
accepted definition, more progress is needed rorism from other types of violence.
in coming to a consensus on at least a few Additionally, the same acts tend to be labeled
definitions of terrorism. differently relative to the relationship or per-
spective of the observer. Finally, the mean-
A more refined, integrated and cumulative theoriz-
ing, likely to allow the formulation of sound
ing tends to be historically specific and
hypothesis, would undeniably contribute to unconducive to comparison, resulting in
expected major developments in the academic ‘analytic vagueness as categories developed
understanding of terrorism. Unfortunately though, in one context are transported to another’
there is still a persistent debate on the delimitation (Weinberg et al., 2004: 779).
of this phenomenon and its analytical conceptuali-
zation (Reinares, 2003: 315).
These well recognized problems pose unu-
sual challenges that must be addressed.
Additionally, it is important to at least clarify Scholars need to be aware and pragmatic
meanings to facilitate the creation of sound about choice of concept. ‘When such [con-
policy. As Schmid earlier warned, a resistance ceptual] confusion arises, it is essential for
to creating a clear definition is a ‘dangerous scholars to engage in a self-conscious, criti-
attitude that plays into the hands of those cal evaluation that systematically appraises
experts from the operation antiterrorist camp existing usage of concepts and seeks to chan-
who have a ‘know-it-when-we-see-it’ attitude nel it in more productive directions’ (Collier,
that easily leads to double standards which 1998a: 5). A good first step is to address the
produce bad science, and arguably, bad poli- ‘border and membership problems’ by creat-
cies’ (Schmid and Jongman, 1988: 1). ing different divisions of the phenomenon
Many scholars view terrorism as an essen- with an architectonic view of diverse types of
tially contested concept. ‘Agreement on defi- violence and governmental relations. Even
nition, alas, does not exist, and there is no scholars who may never agree with a general
reason to assume that it will in the foreseeable definition of terrorism can often agree to a
future’ (Laqueur, 1986: 88). The fear is that less comprehensive definition of different
the term terrorism may not ‘point to detectable types of terrorism.
phenomena that exhibit some degree of causal
coherence’ (Tilly, 2004: 8). Despite this, defi-
nitions of terrorism typically involve a version Division of the phenomena
of ‘a conspiratorial style of violence calcu-
lated to alter the attitudes and behavior of Questions of how to categorize terrorism or
multiple audiences … terrorism is distin- political violence are difficult. Mirroring the
guished by its high symbolic and expressive disagreement about how to define the concept,
value’ (Crenshaw, 1995: 4). In addition to is a lively debate over how to subdivide differ-
violence and intent, most definitions include ent types of terrorism. Seemingly, the sole
requirements of victim and perpetrator (Enders point of agreement is that the range is wide.
and Sandler, 2006: 3). The ‘geographical, ideological, cultural, con-
Classic issues of conceptual validity textual and operational diversity of the prob-
are applicable to the study of terrorism as lem cast doubt on the very justification for

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


TERRORISM 465

identifying terrorism as a fairly homogenous In fact, this flexibility in classification may


phenomenon’ (Merari, 1991: 89). This multi- be productive by facilitating the broad per-
formity of terrorism causes other problems, spective necessary to clarify the relevant
especially in terms of quantifying terrorism domain of the concept, its subcategories, and
and comparability. ‘Terrorism is an ambigu- its relationship to other types of political
ous variable not easily measured or quantified, violence.
in part because there are multiple forms of ter-
rorism, and they are easily confused with Chronological categories
other styles of violence’ (Crenshaw, 1995: 6). In general, Crenshaw has advocated the rec-
Laqueur sternly warns scholars ‘there is no ognition of the historical context of terrorism
such thing as terrorism pure and unadulter- to identify the ‘causal relationship between
ated, specific and unchanging, comparable to terrorism and its political, social and eco-
a chemical element; rather, there are a great nomic environment’ and the ‘impact of ter-
many terrorisms’ (Laqueur, 1986: 88). While rorism on this setting’ (Crenshaw, 1995: 4).
the heterogeneity of the types of terrorism Scholars can turn to development studies for
creates difficulty, it also adds richness to how to identify appropriate groupings;
the field.
assuming that the time and place in which a struc-
The variety of terrorism can make ‘descrip- ture or process appears make a difference to its
tive, explanatory and predictive generaliza- character, that the sequence in which similar
tions, which are the ultimate products of events occur has a substantial impact on their
scientific research, inherently questionable’ outcomes, and that the existing record of past
(Merari, 1991: 89). Fortunately, progress can structures and processes is problematic, requiring
systematic investigation in its own right instead of
be made by clearly identifying and justifying
lending itself immediately to social scientific syn-
comparisons. The creation of a typology is theses (Tilly, 1984: 79).
important. Schmid attempted to create a typol-
ogy that would ‘not subdivide terrorism – both In other words, careful scholars get ‘the his-
state and non-state – in the political context tory right before generalizing, in order to be
between the forces of order and the forces of able to generalize soundly’ (Tilly, 1984: 79).
change, between power holders and power Specifically, in terms of studying terrorism,
challengers, between the forces of social Rapoport (2001) has proposed dividing up
control and of social dissent’ (Schmid and terrorism into analytically distinct waves,
Jongman, 1988: 56). Instead, he listed divi- which may have different causal factors. The
sions based upon actor, political orientation, first wave began with Russian rebellions
and purpose, in addition to considering mul- against limited czarist reforms, in addition to
tidimensional categories. There are at least Armenian, Balkan, anarchist violence that
four different ways of dividing terrorism for lasted from the late nineteenth century until
analytical purposes: time, substance, strat- the outbreak of World War I. The second
egy, and stages. However, it may be best for wave lasted from the 1920s through the
the field to remain flexible in terms of 1960s and was precipitated by movements of
accepting multiple categorizations; national self-determination. The third wave
was motivated by the success of the Vietcong.
Shifts in meaning … can push the analyst to adjust
the corresponding domain of cases, and shifts It includes separatist, revolutionary, and
in the domain of cases can necessitate an adjust- international terrorism. The fourth wave of
ment in the meaning, so as to maintain conceptual ‘religious based separatist movements’ began
validity … Given that establishing the domain of with the 1989 defeat of the Soviets in
relevant cases is an essential underpinning for Afghanistan and the Iranian Islamic revolu-
addressing various methodological issues, it is pro-
ductive to recognize that this initial fluidity in tion of 1979. Conflating different waves can
defining this domain does indeed occur in many result in misleading results because groups
studies (Collier, 1998a: 4). within each wave are different both in terms

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


466 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

of origin, but also in terms of action. Rapoport view is essential, especially given the con-
(2006) states: ‘Modern terrorist organiza- ceptual confusion. For example, when study-
tions … learn from each other and from the ing a case of domestic terrorism, which
experiences of groups that existed previously literature is more useful, terrorism or coun-
in the earlier modern waves. No matter when terinsurgency? A ‘central characteristic of
those organizations operated, groups in the insurgency is the reliance on population for
pre-modern period did not learn or copy active support or at least passive acquies-
methods from each other’ (pp. xxviii–xxix). cence’ (Long, 2006: 15). General principles
However, Rapoport himself notes that the about hearts and minds, holding territory, and
waves overlap to some extent. The implica- so forth, can be analogous to maintaining
tion is that scholars should be wary of com- support of the population, creating an effec-
bining groups and movements from one tive government presence, and so forth.
wave with another – without sufficient atten- Moreover, classic questions of balance of
tion to the historical context or theoretical response can be found in both literatures.
motivation in order to justify the comparison. Additionally, reflecting the confusion in the
Additionally, time is not the only possible concept of terrorism, many of the cases pre-
way to create subcategories. To some extent, viously categorized as insurgencies would
appropriate divisions will be determined by now be called terrorism. Although much of
specific research questions. the counterinsurgency literature is not theo-
retically driven, it contains rich case studies
Substantive categories and policy oriented lessons learned (Long,
Typically, terrorism is divided by type, for 2006; O’Neill, 2001). These guiding princi-
example ideological terrorism (right or left ples may also provide a basis for questions
wing), religious terrorism, nationalist terror- regarding international terrorism, substitut-
ism, and so forth. However, a second pro- ing international cooperation for domestic
posed division is to analyze terrorism within support or legitimacy. Similarly, the bound-
a broader perspective of political violence; ary between civil war and insurgency or ter-
rorism is not always clear. Given that part of
Where does terrorism stop and other forms of
political violence begin, guerrilla warfare or urban Crenshaw’s 1995 definition of terrorism is
warfare, for example? The same acts, such as air size, the progression from being a terrorist
piracy or assassinations, may be considered terror- movement to a party in a civil war may occur.
ist acts on some occasions but not on others, usu- Because of this, studies of civil war (Collier
ally based upon the assumed motivation of the and Hoeffler, 2004), insurgency (Fearon and
perpetrators or the social standing of their victims
(Weinberg et al., 2004: 778–9). Laitin, 2003; Wood, 2004), extremism
(Eatwell and Mudde, 2004; Mudde, 2005) or
For example, when is an attack against non- rebellion and revolution (Lichbach, 1994;
combatant citizens terrorism? When is it a Seligson, 1996; Wickham-Crowley, 1992)
war crime? It may be useful to examine other can be insightful. Similarly, studies of ethnic
types of political violence – ‘collective or religious conflict may also be instructive.
attacks within a political community against For example, is a comparison of Algiers to
a political regime’ (Gurr, 1970: 3–4) includ- Iraq appropriate, or Vietnam to Central
ing rebellion, revolution, extremism, insur- America, or Spain to Northern Ireland, or
gency and so forth, in order to gain insight lessons learned from cases of domestic ter-
into contemporary terrorism. For example, in rorism to international terrorism? The bound-
the study of the Basque separatist group aries of appropriate comparison are in dispute
ETA, it is also useful to examine the politi- and in need of identification.
cally motivated street violence committed by The contemporary civil war literature from
the MLNV (Basque National Liberation economics revolves around greed versus
Movement) (Van den Broek, 2004). A broad grievance or motive versus opportunity or

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


TERRORISM 467

‘atypical grievance versus atypical opportu- study incorporates both collective action
nities’ (Collier and Hoeffler, 2004: 564). A models and case studies.
good overview to the debate can be found in However, a general focus on the economic
Collier and Sambanis (2002). The general foundations of violent movements has been
idea behind ‘greed’ driven conflicts is that criticized. Kalyvas characterizes the greed
economic resources can serve as a financial literature as frighteningly ignorant of context.
basis for insurgent groups. In general, Collier He states; ‘ideological motivations are simply
(2000) finds: not always visible to observers looking for
‘Western’ patterns of allegiance and discourse?
The factors which account for this difference
between failure and success are to be found not in They also make the failed assumption that
the ‘causes’ which these two rebel organizations organizations using religious idioms and local
claim to espouse, but in their radically different cultural practices to mobilize people – rather
opportunities to raise revenue … the economic than easily recognizable universalistic
theory of conflict argues that the motivation of
appeals – lack any ideology’ (Kalyvas, 2001:
conflict is unimportant; what matters is whether the
organization can sustain itself financially … (p. 9). 104–5). Instead, he advocates a microlevel
approach that can identify relevant motiva-
This prominent theory focuses on lootable tions. Some scholars, such as Crenshaw
primary exports and the onset of conflict (1981), propose that grievance is mediated
(See also Collier et al., 2003). Scholars such by elite actions:
as Arbelaez et al. (2002: 42–3) find the onset
Terrorism per se is not usually a reflection of mass
of violence in areas ‘related to the sudden discontent or deep cleavages in society. More
development of primary products (gold, often it represents the disaffection of a fragment
emeralds, oil, bananas, cocaine)’ especially of the elite, who may take it upon themselves to
in the context of low state presence. Scholars act on the behalf of a majority unaware of its
plight, unwilling to take action to remedy griev-
have taken the theory beyond onset to explain
ances, or unable to express dissent (p. 396).
magnitude and persistence of conflict:
Studies that apply the collective action
Conflicts … which are sustained by marketable
natural resources (diamonds, crude oil, coca) are approach to case studies are more immune to
difficult to bring to a conclusion. All too often, the these types of criticism.
perpetrators, both state actors and rebels, find the On the side of state actors, scholars have
chaos of war conducive to the accumulation of found the concept of state terrorism (Stohl and
personal wealth. Ongoing conflict provides oppor- Lopez, 1984), human rights violations
tunities for looting or the collection of protection
money (Silberfein, 2003). (Davenport, 1996), or repression (Moore,
1998; Poe and Tate, 1994) to be useful. The
Another interesting focus on resources key is to be cognizant of the conceptual
applies the development concept of ‘resource boundaries of different clusters. More studies
curse’ to the evolution of violent groups. on differentiating various types of violence are
How do resources influence ‘character and necessary to determine which types of vio-
conduct of rebel groups’ (Weinstein, 2005: lence are analogous to others in terms of cau-
598)? With initial resources, recruits ‘are sality. What lessons can we draw from other
unwilling to make investments of time, types of violence to terrorism? Considering
energy, and resources without receiving the the border and membership problems, this is a
materials rewards they have been promised’ pragmatic approach to a perennial problem.
(Weinstein, 2005: 621). Without initial
resources, opportunistic types are kept out Strategic categories
and the true believers ‘sacrifices are a form Terrorism can also be divided up in terms
of investment, with future rewards made of choice of different strategies or stages of
credible by ties of social and political iden- conflict. Some concepts of terrorism define
tity’ (Weinstein, 2005: 622). This particular the phenomenon as a ‘widely recurrent but

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


468 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

imprecisely bounded political strategy’ (Tilly, Questions of perspective


2004: 5). Some scholars have found it produc-
tive to focus on particular actions that are rec- Alex Schmid (1992) counsels to divide ter-
ognized as terrorism, such as hijackings, suicide rorism discussions into distinct areas, each
bombing and so forth. Recently, the suicide with a separate purpose: academic area of
bombing literature has greatly expanded, as study, state statements of terrorism and/or
reflected by the works of Pape (2006), Bloom juridical definitions, public debate, and oppo-
(2005), Hoffman and McCormick (2004), or sitional discourse. It is crucial to note the
Pedahzur (2006). Others have focused on the term terrorism is ‘an organizing concept that
different choice of attacks, such as identified both describes the phenomenon as it exists
substitution effects in terms of attack mode, and offers a moral judgment’ (Crenshaw,
across countries, and inter-temporal, resulting 1995: 9). Moreover, it is widely used in the
from different responses (Enders and Sandler, media and by policy makers.
1993, 2004; Rosendorff and Sandler, 2004). Because of the political and moral connota-
Another cluster of research examines the tions of the term, it is essential to be aware ‘of
relationship of organizations to terrorist groups the perspective of researchers and research
and the choices of organizations to pursue institutes in order to better understand the prob-
terrorism (Pedahzur and Weinberg, 2003; able flaws and strengths of work coming from
Weinberg, 1991). different sources’ (Silke, 2004a: 16). In fact,
some have charged that the vast majority of
Stages of conflict studies on terrorism are done from the perspec-
A particularly interesting focus could be on tive of the government, and therefore, have
the stage of violence. The civil war literature reduced the term terrorism to mean nothing
differentiated among emergence/onset, dura- more than violence against the West. ‘The “pri-
tion, intensity (Collier and Hoeffler, 2004: vate sector” of the industry is heavily inter-
564), and to allow for the possibility that differ- locked with government intelligence, military
ent factors influence separate stages differently. and foreign policy agencies, and is funded by
For example, in the case of the FARC, Daniel and serves both governments and corporate
Pecaut (1997) and Sánchez et al. (2003) remind establishments’ (Herman and O’Sullivan, 1990:
scholars that factors contributing to later growth 8). This potentially raises issues of objectivity
can be independent of factors that encouraged when research projects or scholars are funded
its emergence. Reinares (2004) documents the by separate sources. ‘If a researcher obtains
changing demographic composition of ETA, funding from an organization or government
suggesting that scholars take into consideration entity with a known bias or agenda then his/her
the life cycle of terrorist groups. In general, role as an impartial observer or when engaging
Crenshaw differentiated precondition ‘factors in participant observation may be jeopardized’
that set the stage for terrorism in the long run’ (Schultz, 2004: 167). Even attempts to define
from precipitant ‘specific events that immedi- terrorism according to international law change
ately precede the occurrence of terrorism’ according to foreign policy objectives among
(Crenshaw, 1981: 381). states (Ganor, 2002). Dedeoglu (2003) finds a
Diverse clusters of terrorism are appropri- divergence of labeling groups as terrorist, even
ate according to different research questions. if they commit the same acts that are recog-
More work directed at solving the ‘border nized as terrorist. The political and foreign
and membership problems’ of terrorism will policy implications often clearly determine
help to unify the subject matter, identify the application of the term terrorist to particular
types of terrorism that share causal factors or groups:
consequences, and clarify the bounds of While the concepts defined as ‘terrorist-terrorism-
useful and valid comparisons. terrorist organization’ have not been defined, lists

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


TERRORISM 469

of ‘terror criminals’ have been published. States


terrorism’ (Schultz, 2004: 161). There are
have taken a common position about a few terror
crimes, yet could not come up with a consensus on three reasons for this continued state of
such issues as the crime itself, penalization and all affairs.
terror criminals … This difference is based on the First, the above mentioned contested con-
various interests of the states in the international cept of terrorism results in the creation of
system (Dedeoglu, 2003: 103).
datasets that do not measure the same thing
Similarly, Silke (2004a) notes that ‘despite and are not comparable. The ‘problems of
the similarities in how both countries [US conceptual fuzziness … and the resulting
and UK] define terrorism, the lists they pro- problems with the operationalization and
scribed were quite different’ (p. 5). Thus, a measurement of phenomena of violence
clear academic definition of terrorism is nec- should continue to have the highest priority’
essary to avoid the pitfalls found in the public (Dollase and Ulbrich-Herrmann, 2003: 1233).
domain. This problem reflects the longstanding disa-
Part of the problem relates to the fact that greements about concepts and definitions of
terrorists, especially when limited to non-state terrorism. For example, back in 1981, Martha
actors, are acting against the existing author- Crenshaw warned ‘an initial obstacle to iden-
ity, most often with aims of replacing it. tification of propitious circumstances for ter-
‘Violence is clearly an extremely complex rorism is the absence of significant empirical
phenomenon involving major ambiguity studies of relevant cross-national factors’
between the destruction and the creation of (Crenshaw, 1981: 381).
order’ (Imbusch, 2003: 13). Scholars should Second, the political connotations of the
embed the notion of terrorism within the con- term create additional difficulties and may
text to identify the type of political order that is result in reporting bias both in terms of inter-
being challenged, instead of blindly accepting views and in terms of data creation. In terms
the status quo as legitimate (Holmes, 2001). of interviews and fieldwork, it is difficult to be
This is essential given the political aspect of a perceived as an objective observer. Scholars
terrorist conflict, in which legitimacy or sup- can become directly or indirectly involved in
port is often an aim at least – if not more – events, regardless of intention: ‘There is no
important than military objectives. Because of ‘observation’ when people are at war and you
this, there is a battle of perception that must be arrive asking them about it. You are, whether
accounted for ‘as a political issue – the self- you wish to be or not, a participant. When
presentation of those who use terrorism and terror weaves its way through a community,
the construction governments and publics words are no longer mere information – words
place on it’ (Crenshaw, 1995: 7). become weapons’ (Theidon, 2001: 20). In
terms of statistics, the illegal status of the vio-
lence may lead to distortion:
Problems of quantification These particular problems are to be found not
only in surveys of individuals, but also in analy-
Many scholars are concerned by the lack of ses of police crime statistics, insurance company
accident statistics, and the like … As a result,
good data to study terrorism. In 1988, Ted
there is a particularly strong risk that data on
Gurr described a ‘disturbing lack of good violence and aggression from official statistics
empirically-grounded research’ (Gurr, 1988: will give a distorted picture of reality … the
115). Others have continued to note the prob- frequency of real violence and aggression vary
lem, such as Merari (1991: 89). After the quite considerably as a function of whether
they are given from the offender, victim, or
burst of scholarly activity following 2001,
observer perspective. This is because each perspec-
the problem is still noted: ‘the overriding tive tries to give a different definition of violence
deficiency of this state of stagnation is a or aggression (Dollase and Ulbrich-Herrmann,
dearth of empirically-grounded research on 2003: 1221).

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


470 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Because of this, it is a good idea to incorpo- (1998-present) is the MIPT dataset, which
rate different sources of data. For example, builds upon RAND’s data. However, use and
Holmes et al. (2006) compare two identical replication of these data is strictly limited by
models, but using different indicators, copyright (Shellman, 2006). Moreover, exist-
one using terrorism statistics from the ing databases need to clearly identify their
Colombian government and another using definition of terrorism and include sufficient
human rights violations from a CINEP, a information so that scholars may recode the
leading Colombian human rights organiza- database in order to be useful to others using
tion. Especially in politically sensitive areas a separate concept of terrorism. More com-
such as violence statistics, it is prudent to prehensive comparisons are necessary utiliz-
compare non-government and government ing diverse data sources and providing
numbers since different groups may have transparent and detailed definitions of terror-
incentives to over or under report, respec- ism. ITERATE and Project Civil Strife (Asal
tively or use completely different standards et al., 2006) are good examples of projects
for inclusion of an event. that provide sufficiently detailed codebooks
Finally, some scholars doubt whether acts to enable scholars to recode the data to fit
of terrorism can be extracted from the histori- other uses and concepts.
cal context: ‘The common weakness of these
quantitative methods when applied to terror-
ism is a reflection of the fact that this form of
violent subversion erupts at various times in INCORPORATING INSIGHTS FROM
various places as the result of an often idio- DIVERSE APPROACHES AND
syncratic combination of factors and condi- DISCIPLINES
tions’ (Hoffman and Morrison-Taw, 2000: 7).
A richly detailed accounting of the conflict Much of the literature on terrorism has been
and context work to alleviate such concerns. criticized according to basic research design
However, despite these difficulties, a few principles. For example, Silke (2004a) states
datasets have been created. Shellman (2006) ‘terrorism literature is composed mainly of
provides an overview of leading events data- studies which rely on relatively weak research
sets. Although some scholars have criticized methods … There is a heavy reliance on
statistics drawn from media sources because qualitative and journalistic approaches which
of concerns such as accuracy, bias, and audi- lack the validity and reliability generally
ence content (Silke, 2004b: 62–3), many expected within mainstream social science
others find them to be fairly reliable research’ (p. 11). However, many of these
(Davenport and Ball, 2002; King and Lowe, problems are the result of the muddled con-
2003) and open to verification through com- ceptual foundation of the subject. Despite
parison with other sources. Jongman (2001) this, progress can be made, especially in
provides an overview of internal conflict and middle range theory and by the pragmatic,
human rights violations datasets. Despite the question driven incorporation of different
recent improvement of available data, lack of approaches and methodologies.
coverage and comparability remains a severe The understanding of terrorism is greatly
problem, especially for domestic terrorism. enhanced by an interdisciplinary approach,
Although a database of international terror- analogous to calls for an interdisciplinary
ism is available for purchase (ITERATE is approach to political science (Scott, 1995:
available with coverage from 1968 to 2005, 37). Insights from geography, history, eco-
see, Mickolus, 1980, 1982 and Mickolus nomics, sociology, and psychology can all be
et al., 1989), few datasets of domestic terror- useful to understand terrorism. Terrorism is a
ism exist or are accessible. An attempt to complex phenomenon. Because of this, it is
create a global dataset of domestic terrorism particularly useful to incorporate a variety of

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


TERRORISM 471

tools, questions, and methods. The field des- can delve into case studies both historically
perately needs to avoid the type of situation, and statistically, by using a sub-national analy-
as described by Wickham-Crowley (1991), in sis (Holmes et al., 2006; Sambanis, 2004).
regard to the study of revolutions: Scholars have noted a lack of both ‘theo-
retically grounded case studies’ (Schultz,
The former group [the quantitatively inclined]
views with disdain the more ‘impressionistic’ 2004: 183–4) and ‘comprehensive historical
research tools employed by the latter, and suspects comparisons’ (Rapoport, 2006: xxvii).
them moreover of finding precisely whatever their Schultz calls for more historically grounded
ideological bent would desire … The qualitatively comparisons and stresses the need for
inclined are not without their own profound suspi-
researchers to ‘become familiar with the his-
cions, perhaps best exemplified by the more or less
massive statisticophobia that prevails (p. 83) tory of terrorism’ (Schultz, 2004: 183). More
case studies need to be focused on what sta-
Instead, consistent with the need of compara- tistical analyses identify as deviant and rep-
tive politics in general, studies of terrorism resentative cases to identify omitted variables
need a dialogue between them. Moreover, the and to more fully illustrate causal mecha-
collaboration – or at least cross fertilization – nisms. Moreover, insights from formal
between area specialists and generalists is models can be explored in case studies, just
essential to grapple with the challenges of as patterns identified in case studies can be
studying the topic. Unfortunately, there is a formalized (George and Bennett, 2004:
‘troubling lack of cross-method communica- 34–5). Additionally, this collaboration can
tion’ in studies of conflict (George and help to identify the boundaries among differ-
Bennett, 2004: 4). Recently, however, trends ent types of terrorism and political violence
in articles published in the major terrorism that plagues the definition of terrorism. This
journals, Terrorism and Political Violence is a best practice in comparative politics,
and Studies in Conflict and Terrorism dem- where ‘scholars routinely go back to a small
onstrate an increasing openness to multiple number of cases to assess the validity of con-
styles of analysis. This is especially promis- ceptualization and measurement, as well as to
ing given the apparent multiple causal path- refine causal inferences (Collier, 1998a: 2).
ways and potentially probabilistic causation This type of collaboration is both helpful to
of terrorism. This situation, in general, calls clarify concepts and identify appropriate
for synergetic studies that integrate findings boundaries and typologies.
from works with different methodologies An example of the potential fruitfulness of
(Collier, 1998b: 4). For example, Gates the combination of approaches can be seen by
(2002), uses a microfoundational approach to some of the works focusing on collective action
understanding rebellion/internal conflict, but and terrorism. Many scholars have noted the
also incorporates geography and ideology importance of strategies and constraints on the
(Gates, 2002: 112). Holmes et al. (2006) choices of main actors to understand terrorism.
incorporate geography and economics to For example, Crenshaw highlights the impor-
understand conflict in Colombia. tance of ‘interactions among political actors,
Similarly, multiple levels of analysis are primarily governments and oppositions, at spe-
useful. Crenshaw notes that it is ‘possible to cific points in history’ (Crenshaw, 1995: 5). The
integrate macro and micro levels of analysis in study of strategic interactions naturally calls for
order to discover which elements in what situ- insights of collective action. Oberschall (2004)
ations encourage oppositions or states to turn identifies four dimensions of collective action
to terrorist tactics’ (Crenshaw, 1995: 5). In appropriate to examine in terms of terrorism,
general, della Porta (2003: 388) calls for a including ‘(1) discontent; (2) ideology-feeding
multi-level analysis (macro, meso, and micro) grievances; (3) capacity to organize; and
because of the complex nature of the phenom- (4) political opportunity’ (p. 27). According
enon of political violence. Moreover, scholars to Sandler and Arce (2003), game theory

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


472 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

illuminates strategic interactions ‘between ter- behavior and choices, scholars may find a com-
rorists and a targeted government … among bination of historical work and collective action
rational actors …’ as a struggle to gain strategic approaches useful.
advantage and maximize goals. This approach One strength of the existing terrorism litera-
is also useful to analyze issues of asymmetric ture is that much of the work does cross disci-
information and resources (Sandler, 2003: 780), plinary lines. Some of the unanswered questions
common to conflicts between states and non- of rationality can be probed in other studies of
state actors, and choices of strategy, for exam- terrorism that use a psychological approach
ple, substitution effects (Enders and Sandler, (Horgan, 2005; Kruglanski and Fishman, 2006;
2004). In general, game theory and formal Victoroff, 2005). Others have focused on the
theory can help us work through questions group level, instead of examining individual
without the restrictions of data limitations, and level choices (Goodwin, 2001; Kalyvas, 2003;
can be tested with available cases and data. Pedahzur and Perliger, 2006; Tilly, 2003; Turk,
Three successful examples of game theory 2004). Additionally, some have begun to look
tested against real data include the following. at network theory to understand group dynam-
First, Kydd and Walter (2002) use game theory ics (Asal et al., 2007; Sageman, 2004). The
to understand the use of terrorism to disrupt field of terrorism should resist attempts to
peace processes, based on a ‘problem of trust impose theoretical unity at the cost of gaining
between the moderate opposition group and a interdisciplinary insights.
target government’ (p. 265). The models are
tested against data covering the Palestinian
Israeli conflict from 1988 to 1998. Second,
Sandler uses collective action to analyze inter-
CONCLUSION
national terrorism. The theories are tested
against the ITERATE data of transnational ter- Despite the fragmented nature of the study of
rorism to understand deterrence, substitutions, terrorism, the pursuit of middle range theory
externalities of actions and so forth. Third, and pragmatic, question driven research may
Azam and Hoeffler (2002) develop two models offer concrete progress in clarifying the four
(with radically different policy prescriptions) areas of dispute. This more modest initial goal
and then test them against real data. may be frustrating to some. Previously, the field
However, some scholars are concerned was thought to be under-theorized. Now, there
about the conceptualization of rationality in is a flood of different theoretical approaches.
game theory or rational choice: However, in the rush to promote theory devel-
opment, the field should not be artificially nar-
Our underlying hypothesis is not that fundamen-
talists will never utilize a rational calculus in limited
rowed. Middle range theory can be most useful
spheres but that they will demonstrate a particular to identify different categories of terrorism. It is
perspective that differs in significant ways from also more likely to produce lessons learned
nonfundamentalists’ and, in particular, that this from other case studies and to illuminate under
fundamentalist perspective will be one in which which circumstances those lessons apply.
religious considerations will dominate over any
‘Middle-range theories attempt to formulate
rational calculus (Monroe and Kredie, 1997: 26).
well-specified conditional generalizations of
However, critics must be careful not to equate more limited scope. These features make them
rationality with objectives. Similarly, Crenshaw more useful for policymaking’ (George and
warns against ascribing a ‘calculated rationality Bennett, 2004: 266). Moreover, this approach is
to past actions that is ultimately misleading’ more likely to satisfy scholars who doubt
(Crenshaw, 1995: 5). These types of concerns whether general theories of terrorism are even
may be alleviated by a rich understanding of possible:
rationality that includes norms, in the style of It would be wiser to proceed from the more prudent
Ostrom (1998). To understand individual assumptions that, for civil violence as for other

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


TERRORISM 473

things, what appears to be ‘the same’ effect may Global Development Network/Interamerican
proceed from a variety of causes, and that ‘the same’ Development Bank Project on ‘Economic
causal influences may yield a variety of different Growth in Latin America and the
effects in different settings (della Porta, 2003: 395). Caribbean.’
Asal, V., Nussbaum, B., and Harrington, W.
Above all, pragmatic, problem driven research
(2007) ‘Terrorist transnational terrorist net-
is more likely to take advantage of the insights works’, Studies in Conflict and Terrorism, 30:
of research from different approaches and 15–39.
disciplines. Even progress on the concept of Asal, V.H., Shellman, S.M., and Meek, S.
terrorism is possible given this inclusive (2006, November) How have you killed
approach: lately? A substitution model of domestic
terrorism in India 1980–2005. Paper
While recognizing that usage is shaped and con- presented at the Peace Science Society
strained by the broader scholarly understanding of
(International) annual meeting.
a concept’s meaning, we hold that specific meth-
odological choices are often best understood and
Azam, J.P. and Hoeffler, A. (2002) ‘Violence
justified in light of the theoretical framework, ana- against civilians in civil wars: looting or
lytical goals, and context of research involved in terror?’, Journal of Peace Research, 39 (4):
any particular study. As theory, goals, and context 461–85.
evolve, choices about concepts likewise may Bloom, M. (2005) Dying to kill the allure of
evolve. (Collier and Adock, 1999: 539) suicide terror. New York: Columbia University
Press.
In an unsettled field such as terrorism, such Collier, D. (1998a) ‘Comparative method in the
a pragmatic approach may be particularly 1990s’, APSA Comparative Politics
productive. Newsletter, 9 (1): 1–5.
With a pragmatic and open approach, incre- Collier, D. (1998b) ‘Comparative historical
mental progress can be made in the study of analysis: Where do we stand?’, APSA
terrorism. The more modest aims of middle Comparative Politics Newsletter, 9 (2): 1–5.
range theory, may clarify the currently trou- Collier, D. and Adock, R. (1999) ‘Democracy
and dichotomies: A pragmatic approach to
bled theoretical state of the field. Specifically,
choices about concepts’, Annual Review of
it may help to identify areas of productive Political Science, 2: 537–65.
comparison, alleviate the border and member- Collier, D. and Mahon, J. (1993) ‘Conceptual
ship problems, clarify concepts, find insight in stretching revisited: Adapting categories in
other disciplines, and facilitate data collection comparative analysis’, American Political
and usage. Science Review, 87 (4): 845–55.
Collier, P. (2000) Economic causes of civil con-
flict and their implications for policy.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Collier, P., Elliot, L., Hegre, H., Hoeffler, A.,
Reynal-Querol, M., and Sambanis, N. (2003)
Special thanks to Sheila Amin Gutíerrez Breaking the conflict trap: Civil war and
de Piñeres, Victor Asal, Todd Sandler, development policy. Washington, DC: World
Bank Group.
Ami Pedahzur, and Steve Shellman for their
Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A. (2004) ‘Greed and
constructive comments. grievance in civil war’, Oxford Economic
Papers, 56 (4): 663–95.
Collier, P. and Sambanis, N. (2002)
‘Understanding civil war: A new agenda’,
REFERENCES Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46,: 3–12.
Crenshaw, M. (1981) ‘The causes of terrorism’,
Arbelaez, M.A., Echavarria, J.J., and Gaviria, A. Comparative Politics, 13 (4): 379–99.
(2002) Colombian long run growth and the Crenshaw, M. (1995) ‘Relating terrorism to
crisis of the 1990s. Report submitted to historical contexts’, in M. Crenshaw (ed.),

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


474 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Terrorism in context edited. University Park, Gates, S. (2002) ‘Recruitment and allegiance:
PA: Penn State Press, pp. 3–26. The microfoundations of rebellion’, Journal
Crenshaw, M. (2000) ‘The psychology of ter- of Conflict Resolution, 46 (1): 111–30.
rorism: An agenda for the 21st century’, George, A. and Bennett, A. (2004) Case studies
Political Psychology, 21 (2): 405–20. and theory development in the social sci-
Davenport, C. (1996) ‘The weight of the past: ences. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Exploring lagged determinants of political Goodwin, J. (2001) No other way out: States
repression’, Political Research Quarterly, 49 (2): and revolutionary movements, 1945–1991.
377–403. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Davenport, C. and Ball, P. (2002) ‘Views to a Gordon, A. (1999) ‘The road less traveled:
kill: Exploring the implications of source Trends in terrorism research’, Terrorism and
selection in the case of Guatemalan state Political Violence, 11 (2): 141–50.
terror, 1977–1996’, Journal of Conflict Gurr, T.R. (1970) Why men rebel. Princeton,
Resolution, 46 (3): 427–50. NJ: Princeton University Press.
Dedeoglu, B. (2003) ‘Bermuda triangle: Gurr, T.R. (1988) ‘Empirical research on politi-
Comparing official definitions of terrorist cal terrorism: The state of the art and how it
activity’, Terrorism and Political Violence, might be improved’, in R.O. Slater and
15 (3): 81–110. M. Stohl (eds), Current perspectives on inter-
della Porta, D. (2003) ‘Violence and the new national terrorism. London: Macmillan Press,
Left’, in W. Heitmeyer and J. Hagen pp. 115–54.
(eds), International handbook of violence Herman, E. and O’Sullivan, G. (1990) The ter-
research. New York, NY: Kluwer Academic rorism industry: The experts and institutions
Publishers, pp. 382–98. that shape our view of terror. NY: Pantheon
Dollase R. and Ulbrich–Herrmann, M. (2003) Books.
‘Strategies and problems in quantitative Hoffman, B. and McCormick, G. (2004)
research on aggression and violence’, in W. ‘Terrorism, signaling, and suicide attack’,
Heitmeyer and J. Hagen (eds), International Studies in Conflict and Terrorism, 27 (4):
handbook of violence research. New York: 243–81.
Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 1203–18. Hoffman, B. and Morrison-Taw, J. (2000) ‘A
Eatwell, R. and Mudde, C. (2004) Western strategic framework for countering terror-
democracies and the new extreme right ism’, in F. Reinares (ed.), European democra-
challenge. New York: Routledge. cies against terrorism: governmental policies
Enders, W. and Sandler, T. (1993) ‘The effec- and intergovernmental cooperation. UK:
tiveness of antiterrorism policies: A vector- Ashgate Aldershot, pp. 3–29.
autoregression-intervention analysis’, Holmes, J.S. (2001) Terrorism and democratic
American Political Science Review, 87 (4): stability. Perspectives on democratization.
829–44. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Enders, W. and Sandler, T. (2004) ‘What do we Holmes, J.S., Amin Gutiérrez de Piñeres, S., and
know about the substitution effects in Curtin, K. (2006) ‘Drugs, violence and devel-
transnational terrorism?’, in A. Silke and opment in Colombia: A department level
G. Ilardi (eds), Researching terrorism trends, analysis’, Latin American Politics and Society,
achievements, failures. London: Frank Cass, 48 (3): 157–84.
pp. 99–137. Horgan, J. (2005) The psychology of terrorism.
Enders, W. and Sandler, T. (2006) The political New York: Routledge.
economy of terrorism. Cambridge: Imbusch, P. (2003) ‘The concept of violence’,
Cambridge University Press. in W. Heitmeyer and J. Hagen (eds),
Fearon, J. and Laitin, D. (2003) ‘Ethnicity, insur- International handbook of violence research.
gency, and civil war’, American Political New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers,
Science Review, 97 (1): 75–90. pp. 13–39.
Ganor, B. (2002) ‘Defining terrorism: Is one Jongman, A. (2001) ‘Database section:
man’s terrorist another man’s freedom Dimensions of contemporary conflict and
fighter’, Police Practice and Research, 3 human rights violations’, Terrorism and
(4): 287–304. Political Violence, 13 (2): 143–77.

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


TERRORISM 475

Kalyvas, S. (2001) ‘“New” and “old” wars: A Oberschall, A. (2004) ‘Explaining Terrorism:
valid distinction?’ World Politics, 54 (1): The contribution of collective action theory’,
99–118. Sociological Theory, 22 (1): 26–37.
Kalyvas, S. (2003) ‘The ontology of political O’Neill, B.E. (2001) Insurgency and Terrorism:
violence: Action and identity in civil wars’, Inside modern revolutionary warfare.
Perspectives on Politics, 1 (3): 475–94. Potomac Books.
King, G. and Lowe, W. (2003) ‘An automated Ostrom, E. (1998) ‘A behavioral approach to
information extraction tool for international the rational choice theory of collective
conflict data with performance as good as action’, American Political Science Review,
human coders: A rare events evaluation 92 (1): 1–22.
design’, International Organization, 57 (3): Pape, R.A. (2006) Dying to win: The
617–42. strategic logic of suicide terrorism. Random
Kruglanski, A. and Fishman, S. (2006) ‘The House.
psychology of terrorism: “Syndrome” versus Pecaut, D. (1997) ‘Presente, pasado y futuro de
“tool” perspectives’, Terrorism and Political la violencia en Colombia’, Desarrollo
Violence, 18 (2): 193–215. Económico, 36 (144): 891–930.
Kydd, A. and Walter, B. (2002) ‘Sabotaging the Pedahzur, A. (ed.) (2006) The roots of suicide
peace: The politics of extremist violence’, terrorism: The globalization of martyrdom.
International Organization, 56 (2): 263–296. London: Routledge.
Laqueur, W. (1986) ‘Reflections on terrorism’, Pedahzur, A. and Perliger, A. (2006) ‘The
Foreign Affairs, 65 (1): 86–100. changing nature of suicide attacks – A social
Lichbach, M. (1994) ‘What makes rational network perspective’, Social Forces, 84 (4):
peasants revolutionary: Dilemma, paradox, 1987–2008.
and irony in peasant rebellion’, World Politics, Pedahzur, A. and Weinberg, L. (2003) Political
46 (3): 383–418. parties and terrorist groups. New York:
Long, A. (2006) On ‘other war’ lessons from Routledge.
five decades of RAND counterinsurgency Poe, S. and Tate C.N. (1994) ‘Repression
research. Santa Monica, CA: Rand. of human rights to personal integrity in
Merari, A. (1991) ‘Academic research and gov- the 1980s: A global analysis’, The
ernment policy on terrorism’, Terrorism and American Political Science Review, 88 (4):
Political Violence, 3 (1): 88–102. 853–72.
Mickolus, E.F. (1980) Transnational terrorism: Rapoport, D.C. (2001) ‘The fourth wave:
A chronology of events 1968–1979. September 11 in the history of terrorism’,
Westport, CT: Greenwood Press. Current History, 100 (650): 419–424.
Mickolus, E.F. (1982) International terrorism: Rapoport, D.C. (2006) ‘General introduction’,
Attributes of terrorist events, 1968–1977 in D.C. Rapoport (ed.), Terrorism: Critical
(ITERATE 2) ICPSR ed. Ann Arbor, MI: concepts in political science. New York:
Interuniversity Consortium for Political and Routledge, pp. xxvii–xxxvii.
Social Research [producer and distributor]. Reinares, F. (2003) ‘Terrorism’, in W. Heitmeyer
Mickolus, E.F., Sandler, T., and Murdock, J.M. and J. Hagen (eds), International handbook
(1989) International terrorism in the 1980s: of violence research. New York: Kluwer
A chronology of events (2 volumes) Ames, Academic Publishers, pp. 309–21.
IA: Iowa State University Press. Reinares, F. (2004) ‘Who are the terrorists?
Monroe, K.R. and Kredie, L.H. (1997) ‘The per- Analyzing changes in sociological profile
spective of Islamic fundamentalists and the among members of ETA’, Studies in Conflict
limits of rational choice theory’, Political and Terrorism, 27 (6): 465–88.
Psychology, 18 (1): 19–43. Rosendorff, B.P. and Sander, T. (2004) ‘Too
Moore, W. (1998) ‘Repression and dissent: much of a good thing? The proactive
Substitution, context and timing’, American response dilemma’, Journal of Conflict
Journal of Political Science, 42 (3): 851–73. Resolution, 48 (5): 657–71.
Mudde, C. (2005) Racist extremism in Sageman, M. (2004) Understanding terror net-
Central and Eastern Europe. New York: works. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania
Routledge. Press.

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


476 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Sambanis, N. (2004) ‘Expanding economic Silke, A. (2004b) ‘The devil you know’, in A.
models of civil war using case studies’, Silke (ed.), Research on terrorism: Trends,
Perspectives on Politics, 2 (2): 259– 80. achievements and failures. New York:
Sánchez, F.J., Díaz, A.M., and Formisano, M. Routledge, pp. 57–71.
(2003) Conflicto, violencia y actividad crimi- Silke, A. (2004c) ‘The road less travelled:
nal en Colombia: Un análisis espacial Recent trends in terrorism research’, in A.
(Archivos de Economíıa, Documento 219) Silke (ed.), Research on terrorism: Trends,
Retrieved March 17, 2008, from http://www. achievements and failures. New York:
dotec–colombia.org/index.php?option= Routledge, pp. 186–213.
com_contentandtask=viewandid=2185 Stohl, M. and Lopez, G. (1984) State as terror-
andItemid=15 ist. Portsmouth, NH: Greenwood.
Sandler, T. (2003) ‘Collective action and Theidon, K. (2001) ‘Terror’s talk: Fieldwork and
transnational terrorism’, World Economy, war’, Dialectical Anthropology, 26 (1): 19–35.
26 (6): 779–802. Tilly, C. (1984) Big structures, large processes,
Sandler, T. and Arce, D. (2003) ‘Terrorism and huge comparisons. New York: Russell Sage
game theory’, Simulation and Gaming, Foundation.
34 (3): 319–37. Tilly, C. (2003) The politics of collective violence.
Sartori, G. (1970) ‘Concept misinformation in Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
comparative politics’, American Political Tilly, C. (2004) ‘Terror, terrorism, terrorists’,
Science Review, 14 (4): 1033–53. Sociological Theory, 22 (1): 5–13.
Schmid, A., and Jongman, A. (1988) Political Turk. A.T. (2004) ‘Sociology of terrorism’,
terrorism: A new guide to actors, authors, Annual Review of Sociology, 30: 271–86.
concepts, data bases, theories, and litera- Van den Broek, H. (2004) ‘Borroka – The legiti-
ture. New Brunswick: Transaction Books. mation of street violence in the political dis-
Schmid, A.P. (1992) ‘Terrorism and democ- course of radical Basque nationalists’, Terrorism
racy’, Terrorism and Political Violence, 4 (4): and Political Violence, 16 (4): 714–36.
14–25. Victoroff, J. (2005) ‘The mind of the terrorist:
Schultz, F. (2004) ‘Breaking the cycle: Empirical A review and critique of psychological
research and postgraduate studies on terror- approaches’, Journal of Conflict Resolution,
ism’, in A. Silke (ed.), Research on terrorism: 49 (1): 3–42.
Trends, achievements and failures. Weinberg, L. (1991) ‘Turning to terror. The
New York: Routledge, pp. 161–85. conditions under which parties turn to
Scott, J. C. (1995) ‘The role of theory in com- terrorist activities’, Comparative Politics, 23
parative politics: A symposium’, World (4): 423–38.
Politics, 48 (1): 1–49. Weinberg, L., Pedahzur, A., and Hirsch–Hoefler, S.
Seligson, M. (1996) ‘Agrarian inequality and the (2004) ‘The challenges of conceptualizing
theory of peasant rebellion’, Latin American terrorism’, Terrorism and Political Violence,
Research Review, 31 (2): 140–57. 16 (4): 777–94.
Shellman, S. (2006) Quantifying violence and Weinstein, J. (2005) ‘Resources and the infor-
nonviolence: Terrorism and political violence mation problem in rebel recruitment’, Journal
events datasets. e–Extreme, 7(4) Retrieved of Conflict Resolution, 49 (4): 598–624.
March 17, 2008, from http://webhost.ua. Wickham-Crowley, T. (1991) ‘A qualitative
ac.be/extremismanddemocracy/newsletter/ comparative approach to Latin American
Article7_4.htm revolutions’, International Journal of
Silberfein, M. (2003) ‘Insurrections’, in S. Cutter, Comparative Sociology, 32 (1 and 2):
D. Richardson and T. Wilbanks (eds), The 82–109.
geographical dimensions of terrorism. New Wickham-Crowley, T. (1992) Guerrillas and
York: Routledge, pp. 67–74. revolution in Latin America. Princeton, NJ:
Silke, A. (2004a) ‘An introduction to terrorism Princeton University Press.
research’, in A. Silke (ed.), Research on ter- Wood, E. (2004) Insurgent collective action
rorism: Trends, achievements and failures. and civil war in El Salvador. Cambridge:
New York: Routledge, pp. 1–29. Cambridge University Press.

9781412919760_Chap25.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:40:25 PM


26
Comparative Regional
Integration and Regionalism
Fredrik Söderbaum

INTRODUCTION Cumulative knowledge has grown within


the study of regionalism and regional inte-
Since the mid-1980s there has been an explo- gration during the last two decades, espe-
sion of various forms of regionalist projects on cially on aspects of European integration, the
a global scale. The widening and deepening of institutional design of regional organizations,
the European Union (EU) is the most pervasive the problems of collective action on the
example, but regionalism is also made visible regional level, and the relationship between
through the revitalization or expansion of many globalization and regionalism. However, the
other regional projects around the world, such challenges and weaknesses in the study of
as the Association of Southeast Asian Nations regionalism and regional integration are pri-
(ASEAN), the Economic Community of marily related to the fragmented nature of
West African States (ECOWAS), the North this research field, in particular the weak
American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), the debate around comparative analysis.
Southern African Development Community Despite a growing number of specific
(SADC), and the Southern Common Market comparisons of selected aspects of regional-
(Mercosur). ism (especially regarding regional institu-
Today’s regionalism is closely linked with tions and the role of power) in selected
the shifting nature of global politics and the regions (particularly in the triad: Europe,
intensification of globalization. Regionalism is East Asia, and North America), there is virtu-
characterized by the involvement of almost all ally no systematic debate regarding the fun-
governments in the world, but it also involves a damentals of comparison, such as ‘what to
rich variety of non-state actors, resulting in compare’, ‘how to compare’, or ‘why com-
multiplicities of formal and informal regional pare’. Consequently, the purpose of this
governance and regional networks in most chapter is to contribute to the general discus-
issue areas. This pluralism and multidimen- sion about ‘the problem of comparison’ in
sionality of contemporary regionalism gives the study of regionalism and regional inte-
rise to a number of new puzzles and challenges gration. It does not attempt a detailed empir-
for comparative politics. ical comparison of a set of pre-defined

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


478 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

regions according to a fixed set of variables. often a province. Historically, the concept of
The chapter will provide an overview of the region has evolved primarily as a space
state of comparative regional integration and between the national and the local within a
regionalism, an outline of the main debates particular state. These types of regions are
and controversies, and a discussion of the here referred to as micro-regions. The con-
state of the research field and directions in cept of region can also refer to macro-regions
which it ought to be moving. (so-called world regions), which are larger
This chapter is organized in four main sec- territorial (as distinct from non-territorial)
tions. The first discusses the main concepts units or sub-systems, between the state level
in the field, and the implications of this for and the global system level.
comparative analysis. The second provides The macro-region has been the most
an overview of the development of the early common object of analysis in international
and the more recent debates on regional inte- studies, while micro-regions have more com-
gration and regionalism in terms of theoreti- monly been considered in the realm of the
cal focus, empirical practices and the study of domestic politics and economics. In
treatment of comparative analysis. The third current international affairs, with blurred
and most extensive section provides an over- distinctions between the domestic and the
view of the debates about regionalism in international, micro-regions have increas-
some of the most critical regions of the world ingly become cross-border in nature, precipi-
in this regard (Europe, East Asia, the tating an emerging debate about the
Americas, and Africa), highlighting in par- relationship between macro-regionalism and
ticular the tension between regional speciali- micro-regionalism within the context of
zation and comparative analysis. The chapter globalization (Perkmann and Sum, 2002;
concludes with suggestions for improving Söderbaum, 2005).
the comparative element in the study of The minimum classical definition of a
regionalism and regional integration. macro-region is ‘a limited number of states
linked together by a geographical relationship
and by a degree of mutual interdependence’
(Nye, 1971: vii). During the early debate
CONCEPTUALIZATIONS about regional integration a large amount of
research capacity was invested in trying to
It is natural to begin with the problem of define regions scientifically (Cantori and
definition, notwithstanding that such an exer- Spiegel, 1970); a plethora of opinions were
cise has often proved problematic, due to the advanced regarding what mutual interdepend-
fact that regional integration and regionalism encies mattered the most (such as economic,
are elusive and evolving concepts. Definitions political and social variables, or historical,
are of course essential in comparative cultural and ethnic bonds). The results of this
research, since the definition and choice of research were not compelling, however, and
what is a comparable case will affect the parsimonious attempts to define regions have
ability to generalize. There have also been essentially come to an end. Most scholars
shifting and competing views regarding the engaged in the contemporary debate agree that
dependent variable, which also results in there are no natural or ‘scientific’ regions, and
problems in comparison. that definitions of a region vary according to
The concept of ‘region’ derives from the the particular problem or question under inves-
Latin word ‘regio’, which means direction tigation. This problem about how to define a
(Jönsson et al., 2000: 15). It also derives region may pose certain challenges for com-
from the Latin verb ‘regere’: ‘to rule’ or ‘to parative analysis, but many scholars solve the
command’. Later in history the concept of problem by concentrating on regional organi-
region denoted border or a delimited space, zations and regional economic frameworks

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 479

(Acharya and Johnston, 2007; Fawcett and with a formal programme, and often leads to
Hurrell, 1995), or security complexes/com- institution building. ‘Regionalization’ refers
munities (Adler and Barnett, 1998; Buzan and to the process of cooperation, integration,
Waever, 2003), which tend to make cases cohesion, and identity creating a regional
more ‘comparable’. space (issue-specific or general):
The view that regions must not be taken for At its most basic it means no more than a concen-
granted or be reduced to regional organiza- tration of activity – of trade, peoples, ideas, even
tions is particularly emphasized in construc- conflict – at the regional level. This interaction
tivist and post-structuralist scholarship. As may give rise to the formation of regions, and in
turn to the emergence of regional actors, net-
Jessop (2003) points out, ‘rather than seek an
works, and organisations (Fawcett, 2005: 25).
elusive objective … criterion for defining a
region, one should treat regions as emergent, The majority of studies in this field of politi-
socially constituted phenomena’ (p. 183). cal science continue to focus on the policies
From such a perspective, all regions are of (formal and largely state-led) regionalism
socially constructed and hence politically con- as opposed to the processes of regionaliza-
tested. Emphasis is placed on how political tion (Fawcett and Hurrell, 1995; Gamble and
actors perceive and interpret the idea of a Payne, 1996), although there is, as we should
region and notions of ‘regionness’ (Hettne and see below, an increasing amount of research
Söderbaum, 2000). It is clear that such (inter) on the relationship between regionalism and
subjective understandings of regions pose regionalization.
certain challenges for systematic comparison. In summary, regions, regional cooperation,
Just as there are competing understandings regional integration, regionalism, and region-
about how to define a region, there are many alization are contested concepts that are used
contrasting and sometimes incompatible defini- differently across disciplines, and frequently
tions of related concepts. One distinction is also within disciplines. Communication
between regional cooperation and regional inte- between different standpoints has been diffi-
gration. Regional cooperation can be defined as cult because of the incomparability between
an open-ended process, whereby individual different phenomena, resulting in problems of
states (or possibly other actors) within a given not only what to compare, how to compare,
geographical area act together for mutual ben- but also why to compare at all.
efit, and in order to solve common tasks, in
certain fields, such as infrastructure, water and
energy, notwithstanding conflicting interests in
other fields of activity. Regional integration EARLY AND RECENT DEBATES ON
refers to a deeper process, whereby the previ- REGIONALISM: CONTINUITIES
ously autonomous units are merged into a AND DISCONTINUITIES
whole. A fruitful distinction is between politi-
cal integration (the formation of a transnational The phenomenon of regional integration/
political system), economic integration (the regionalism can be traced far back in history,
formation of a transnational economy), and as seen in the rich variety of geographically
social integration (the formation of a transna- confined ‘Staatenbünde’, ‘leagues’, ‘unions’,
tional society) (Nye, 1971: 26–7). ‘pacts’, and ‘confederations’ (Mattli, 1999: 1).
The concepts of regionalism and region- The protectionist and neo-mercantilist trend
alization have entered the discussion during of the 1930s is considered by some to have
the recent debate.1 ‘Regionalism’ represents been the first main wave of regionalism.
the policy and project, whereby state and However, more often it is argued that volun-
non-state actors cooperate and coordinate tary and comprehensive regionalism is
strategy within a particular region or as a predominantly a post-World War II phenom-
type of world order. It is usually associated enon, which therefore (according to some

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


480 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

definitions) reduces the number of cases of cooperation was preferred to regional coop-
regionalism. It is common to distinguish eration. Mitrany criticized both federalism
between an earlier wave of regionalism in the and neofunctionalism on the basis that both
1950s and 1960s (then often referred to as were primarily based on territory rather than
‘regional integration’) and a more recent function. He saw territoriality as part of the
wave or generation of regionalism (often Westphalian logic, which was taken to imply
referred to as ‘new regionalism’) beginning conflict and war, although Mitrany considered
in the latter half of the 1980s and now a the European Coal and Steel Community
prevalent phenomenon throughout the world. (ECSC) an acceptable organization.
But after more than two decades of so-called Neofunctionalism enjoyed an enormous
‘new regionalism’, the distinction between reputation during the 1960s. The central
‘old’ and ‘new’ has lost much of its original figure was Ernst Haas, who challenged the
meaning (Hettne, 2003, 2005). It is arguably functionalists, and claimed a greater concern
more appropriate to identify continuities for the centres of power (Haas, 1958, 1964).
and discontinuities between what can be Haas, in fact, theorized the ‘community
understood as the early and the more recent method’ pioneered by Jean Monnet. Even if
debates. the outcome of this method could be a fed-
eration, it was not to be constructed through
constitutional design. The basic mechanism
The early debate 2 in neofunctionalist theorizing was ‘spill-
over’, which referred to ‘the way in which
The early or classical approaches to regional the creation and deepening of integration in
integration were foremost concerned with one economic sector would create pressures
peace, and tended to view the nation-state as for further economic integration within and
the problem rather than the solution. The beyond that sector, and greater authoritative
most relevant theories were federalism, func- capacity at the European level’ (Rosamond,
tionalism, neofunctionalism, and transaction- 2000: 60).
alism (Rosamond, 2000). Federalism, which In the 1960s the neofunctional description
inspired the pioneers of European integra- (and prescription) became increasingly
tion, was less a theory than a political pro- remote from the empirical world, now domi-
gramme; it was sceptical of the nation-state, nated by Charles de Gaulle’s nationalism.
although its project was in fact to create a Stanley Hoffman (1966) asserted that regional
new kind of ‘state’. In Europe there was no integration could not spread from ‘low poli-
obvious theorist associated with federalism, tics’ (economics) to the sphere of ‘high poli-
whereas, functionalism has been much tics’ (security), contrary to the stipulations of
strongly identified with David Mitrany the (neo)functionalists. Perceptions of the
(1966). role of the EC began to diverge. According to
Functionalism was primarily a strategy (or Alan Milward (1992) and the intergovern-
a normative method) designed to build peace, mentalist response, the EC should instead be
constructed around the proposition that the seen as a ‘rescue of the nation-state’.
provision of common needs and functions can Haas (1975) responded to critics by label-
unite people across state borders. Form, in the ling the study of regional integration ‘pre-
functionalist view, was supposed to follow theory’ (on the basis that there was no clear
function, whereas for federalists it was prima- idea about dependent and independent varia-
rily form that mattered. Functional coopera- bles), then referred to the field in terms of
tion should concentrate on technical and basic ‘obsolescence’, and ended up suggesting that
functional programmes and projects within the study of regional integration should cease
clearly defined sectors. Usually, the nation- to be a subject in its own right. Rather, it
state should be bypassed, and international should be seen as an aspect of the study of

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 481

interdependence (a concept popularized at that theorists undertook comparative analysis can


time by Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye). In serve as an inspiration for the development of
retrospect it would appear that the neofunc- a more genuinely ‘comparative’ regionalism.
tionalists expected too much too quickly. They What can be broadly understood as a model
underestimated the anti-pluralist, centralist for regionalism among developing countries
and nationalist orientations of their time, at the emerged in response to the Europe-centred
same time as the theory had relatively little classical models in political science (particu-
regard for exogenous and extra-regional forces larly neofunctionalism) and economics (par-
(Breslin and Higgott, 2000). ticularly neoclassical market integration)
The early debate was always centred on during the early debate. This model can be
Europe, and Europe was in many ways treated understood within the structuralist tradition of
as a single case. Gradually the comparative economic development, pioneered by Gunnar
element in the field grew stronger and some of Myrdal, Arthur Lewis, and Raul Prebisch
the most respected (mainly neofunctionalist) (Prebisch, 1963). From this perspective the
theorists of their time also conducted com- rationale of regional cooperation and integra-
parisons. For instance, Ernst Haas, Philippe tion among less developed countries was not
Schmitter, and Sydney Dell studied regional to be found in functional cooperation or mar-
integration (or the lack of it) in Latin America ginal economic change within the existing
(Dell, 1966; Haas, 1967; Haas and Schmitter, structure, but rather, through the fostering of
1964; Schmitter, 1970). Amitai Etzioni com- ‘structural transformation’ and the stimulation
pared the United Arab Republic, the Federation of productive capacities, whereby investment
of West Indies, the Nordic Association, and and trading opportunities were being created.
the European Economic Community (Etzioni, This school thus shifted focus away from eco-
1965). Joseph Nye studied East Africa and nomic integration as a means of political
conducted comparisons of the Arab League, unification to one of regional economic coop-
the Organization of American States (OAS) eration/integration as a means of economic
and the Organization of African Unity (OAU) development. Hence the dependent variable,
(Nye, 1970, 1971). as well as the underlying conditions for
Even if many of these and other like- regionalism, was so different that it called for
minded scholars were conscious of their own a different theory, according to which Europe
Eurocentrism, they searched above all for and the developing world were not compara-
those ‘background conditions’, ‘functional ble cases (Axline, 1994a: 180).
equivalents’, and ‘spill-over’ effects that were
derived from the study of Europe. As Breslin
et al. (2002) point out, they ‘used the
The recent debate 3
European experience as a basis for the pro-
duction of generalizations about the pros- The 1970s was a period of ‘Eurosclerosis’
pects for regional integration elsewhere’ within the EC, but the 1985 White Paper on
(p. 2). This resulted in difficulties in identify- the internal market and the Single European
ing comparable cases, or anything that cor- Act resulted in a new dynamic process of
responded to their definition of ‘regional European integration. This was also the start
integration’. As will be discussed below, the of what has often been referred to as the ‘new
treatment of European integration as the pri- regionalism’ on a global scale. To some
mary case or ‘model’ of regional integration observers regionalism was ‘new’, mainly in
still dominates many of the more recent stud- the sense that it represented a revival of pro-
ies of regionalism and regional integration, tectionism or neomercantilism (Bhagwati,
which is an important part of ‘the problem of 1993). But most observers highlighted the
comparison’ within this research area. fact that closure of regions was not on the
Nonetheless, the rigour with which earlier agenda; rather, the current regionalism was

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


482 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

to be understood as ‘open regionalism’ Historically the study of regional coopera-


(Anderson and Blackhurst, 1993; Cable and tion and integration has strongly emphasized
Henderson, 1994). Indeed, one of the charac- states as actors, or political unification within
terizing features of the more recent debate on (formal) regional organizations – although
regionalism, especially within the field of neofunctionalist, institutionalist, and especially
international relations, is its focus on the transactionalist approaches certainly consider
conditions related to what has increasingly the underlying social fabric of non-state actors
been called globalization, occurring in the and interest groups. In contrast, many recent
context after the end of the Cold War. There perspectives have placed additional emphasis
are many ways in which globalization and on ‘soft’, de facto, or informal regionalism/
regionalism interact and overlap, according regionalization, acknowledging the fact that a
to this type of scholarship (Bøås et al., 1999; rich variety of non-state actors have begun to
Coleman and Underhill, 1998; Cooper et al., operate within as well as beyond state-led
2008; Farrell et al., 2005; Hettne et al., 1999; institutional frameworks. For instance, busi-
Schulz et al., 2001). ness interests and multinationals not only
One prominent scholar of the recent debate, operate on the global sphere, but also tend to
Björn Hettne, emphasizes that regionalism create regionalized patterns of economic activ-
needs to be understood both from an exoge- ity (Rugman, 2005). Similarly, civil society is
nous perspective (according to which region- often neglected in the study of regionalism,
alization and globalization are intertwined notwithstanding that its impact is increasing,
articulations of global transformation) and as evident in the transnational activist
from an endogenous perspective (according to networks and processes of civil society
which regionalization is shaped from within regionalization emerging around the world
the region by a large number of different (Acharya, 2003; Söderbaum, 2007; Warleigh,
actors) (Hettne, 2002). As mentioned above, 2001).
the exogenous perspective has primarily devel- As mentioned earlier, the distinction and
oped during the recent debate, whereas the causal relationship between formal and infor-
endogenous perspective underlines the conti- mal regionalism (or between state-led region-
nuities back to functionalist and neofunction- alism and non-state regionalization) has
alist theorizing about the integration of Europe, attracted considerable attention during the
the role of agency and the long-term transfor- recent debate. Key issues in this debate are
mation of territorial identities. But in contrast whether or not formal regionalism precedes
with the time in which Haas and the early informal regionalization, and the various
regional integration scholars were writing, ways in which state, market, and civil society
today there are many regionalisms and thus a actors relate and come together in different
very different base for comparative studies. It formal and informal coalitions, networks
is apparent that neither the object for study and modes of regional and multilevel govern-
(ontology) nor the way of studying it (episte- ance (Bøås et al., 2005; Christiansen and
mology) has remained static. One indication Piattoni, 2004; Katzenstein and Shiraishi,
of this is the emergence of a rich variety of 1997; Sandholtz and Stone-Sweet, 1998).
theoretical frameworks for the study of region- According to Breslin et al. (2002) the distinc-
alism and regional integration.4 Indeed, cur- tion between formal and informal regional-
rent regionalism may be seen as a new political ism helps ‘break out of the teleological
landscape in the making, characterized by an shackles of the first wave and may help us to
increasing set of actors (state and non-state) move our focus to different types of regional
operating on the regional arena and across response [and] to more issue-specific ques-
several interrelated dimensions (security, tions’ (p. 13). From a comparative perspec-
development, trade, environment, culture, and tive, the fundamental problem is that the
so on). current field of study is still fragmented,

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 483

lacking communication between the many Debates about regionalism


theoretical standpoints and various regional
in Europe
debates.
Europe has a long history of integrative and
disintegrative processes (Mattli, 1999). During
recent decades the regionalization process has
COMPARING DEBATES ON ultimately centred around one dominant
REGIONALISM IN EUROPE, project – what is today the EU – which has
EAST ASIA, THE AMERICAS, widened and deepened in scope, reach and
AND AFRICA ambition to a remarkable degree. Historically,
an intense debate has swirled around varieties
This section provides an overview and of realist/intergovernmental and functional/
compares some of the main features of the liberal/institutional perspectives. These differ-
debates about regionalism in Europe, East ent approaches focus largely on different
Asia, the Americas, and Africa. Worldwide aspects of the integration process. For instance,
regionalism is not, of course, restricted to realists and intergovernmentalists appear to
these regions, but the ‘sample’ is broad enough have the most to say about the logic behind
to illustrate the pluralism of contemporary large Council meetings and treaty reforms
regionalism. such as Maastricht, Amsterdam, and Nice
The ambition in this section is to describe (Grieco, 1997; Moravcsik, 1998). Meanwhile,
and compare some of the general characteris- the functional/liberal/institutional approaches
tics of each regional debate, rather than focus more on economic integration and other
attempt to compare pre-defined regions or issue areas (especially under the first pillar) in
regional organizations according to a fixed which the EU’s central institutions such as the
and narrow set of variables (an exercise Commission and the Court have a more
which would not be able to address the more prominent role (Pollack, 2003; Sandholtz and
general problem of comparison in this area of Stone-Sweet, 1998).
research). It should be stated that the analysis Other scholars emphasize other variables
draws attention to the tension between again, such as the fundamentally changed
regional specialization and comparative political landscape in Europe, blurring the
research. The main reason for this tension is distinction between international and domes-
that the majority of scholars tend to special- tic politics. One such perspective is ‘multi-
ize in a particular region – regardless what level governance’, which posits that power
discipline they come from (comparative poli- and decision-making in Europe are not con-
tics, international relations, area studies). centrated at one level (national or suprana-
Sometimes comparisons are made within tional), but are rather characterized by a
each region (for instance, comparing the dif- complex web of relations between public and
ferent regionalisms in Asia), and an increas- private actors nested in supranational,
ing number of scholars compare across national and micro-regional levels (Hooghe
regions as well. The fundamental problem is and Marks, 2001).
that many case studies and the vast majority In recent years social constructivism has
of comparisons tend to use theoretical frame- gained a more prominent place in the study
works that are biased towards European of European integration (Christiansen et al.,
integration theory and practice. Indeed, as 2001). This line of thinking has entered the
this section will draw attention to, the com- discussion on European integration mainly as
parative element is underdeveloped and a spillover from the discipline of interna-
European integration has become an obstacle tional relations, and as a means of transcend-
for developing a comparative regionalism ing the rather introverted debates between
and regional integration.5 the conventional and rationalist theories of

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


484 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

European integration referred to initially. The Debates about regionalism


social constructivist approach emphasizes in East Asia
the mutual constitutiveness of structure and
agency, and pays particular attention to the There exists no overall consensus for a defi-
role of ideas, values, norms and identities in nition of the Asian region or about the funda-
the social construction of Europe (rather than mental nature of regionalism in Asia. The
EU per se) (Christiansen et al., 2001). This meaning of regionalism has changed in rela-
theoretical approach has undoubtedly revital- tion to the question of what sub-regions to
ized the study of European integration, but it include and exclude, what dimensions of
makes its comparisons between Europe and regionalism to investigate (such as security,
international regimes rather than between economics, politics and identity) and over the
Europe and other regions. There is therefore particular theoretical perspectives employed.
considerable scope for an increase in com- Conventionally Asia has been divided into
parison of the social construction of various the regions Central Asia, Northeast Asia,
global regions. Southeast Asia and South Asia, with a blurred
The lack of communication and interac- border towards the Middle East. Most litera-
tion between EU studies and regionalism in ture in relation to regionalism has focused
the rest of the world is stark, although some on East Asia, that is, Northeast Asia and
recent attempts have begun to remedy this Southeast Asia. Since East Asia is arguably
lack (Laursen, 2003; Telo, 2007; Warleigh, the most interesting region, from a theoreti-
2004, 2006). Indeed, there has been a ten- cal, empirical as well as comparative per-
dency within EU studies during the recent spective, it is also the focus adopted here.
decade to consider the EU as a nascent, if A considerable body of literature is con-
unconventional, polity in its own right (the cerned with the study of the Association
‘n=1’ problem). This view holds that the EU of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) (see
should be studied as a political system rather Acharya, 2001). A major reason for this
than as a project of regional integration or emphasis, at least historically, appears to be
regionalism (Caporaso and Keeler, 1995; that ASEAN has been one of the few sustain-
Hix, 1994, 1999). The corollary is that estab- able regional organizations in the larger East
lished tools of political science and compara- Asian region. During the Cold War the core
tive politics should be used in EU studies and of ASEAN cooperation was in its joint effort
that international studies and relations are to consolidate the member nation states and
not equipped to deal with the complexity of to enhance stability. These goals were driven
the contemporary EU.6 This view has also by a narrow political elite in what were, at
reinforced the notion that the EU is sui that time, relatively fledgling and fragile
generis, thereby downplaying the similarities state formations. Communism was the pri-
between the EU and other regionalist projects. mary internal and external threat. The raison
According to Ben Rosamond, one prominent d’être of ASEAN – bulwarking against com-
EU scholar, the parochialism inherent in this munist expansion – has of course been long
particular strand of EU studies has contrib- absent from the political landscape; focus has
uted little in deepening our understanding of shifted to achieving increased economic
the EU as a political system. He argues that development and to ensuring security in a
EU studies should return to the broader new context.
ambitions of the comparative and classical During recent decades an important part
regional integration theory (especially neo- of the debate about regionalism in East Asia
functionalism), at least to the extent of devel- has focused on collective identity formation
oping generalizable and comparative and informal or ‘soft’ regionalism (Acharya,
conceptual and theoretical frameworks 2001; Katzenstein, 2002). This scholarship
(Rosamond, 2005). seeks to account for the non-legalistic style of

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 485

decision-making in this region, and the fact development, agriculture, tourism, and infor-
that there is no transfer of national sovereignty mation technology (Nesudurai, 2005: 167).
to a supranational authority. Nevertheless, It is too early to see what institutional
there exists a dense network of informal gath- structures will emerge, but as Higgott (2006:
erings, working groups and advisory groups, 32) points out, ‘the range of interactions
particularly within ASEAN, but also in the developing is unprecedented, with a consid-
ASEAN Regional Forum, the Asia-Pacific erable number of regular meetings across
Economic Cooperation forum (APEC), and most policy domains, especially economics
more recently the Asia-Europe Meeting and finance, agriculture, forestry (and) tour-
(ASEM) and ASEAN Plus Three (China, ism.’ He also stresses that to ‘see ASEAN+3
Japan and the Republic of Korea). This infor- as but an exercise in extended conference
mal style of decision-making incorporates its diplomacy, reflecting weakness rather
own innate code of conduct that is often than strength, would be misleading’ (Higgott,
referred to as the ‘ASEAN Way’, which, in 2006: 32).
contrast with European-style formal bureau- Most research concerning East Asian
cratic structures and legalistic decision-making regionalism is based on case studies rather
procedures, is built around discreetness, infor- than comparisons. There are an increasing
mality, pragmatism, consensus-building, and number of regional processes in East Asia,
non-confrontational bargaining styles which provide a large base for comparison
(Acharya, 1997: 329). Further, the ASEAN within the region. Generally speaking, stud-
Way reflects to an extent the illiberal under- ies on East Asian regionalism present a sig-
pinnings of the ‘Asian values’ construct, which nificant number of loose comparisons with,
stresses a communitarian ethic (‘society over or sweeping references to, European integra-
the self’) in explaining the region’s economic tion theories and practices. The great major-
dynamism (Acharya, 2002: 27–8). ity of such references or comparisons with
The 1997/98 Asian financial crisis under- Europe characterize East Asian regionalism
lined not only the interdependence of as looser and more informal, sometimes even
Northeast and Southeast Asian countries, but, as ‘underdeveloped’ (Choi and Caporaso,
according to Higgott (2002: 2), also ‘exposed 2002: 485). It is problematic to regard
the weakness of existing regional institu- EU-style institutionalization as an ideal
tional economic arrangements’. This in turn model for regionalism. A particularly effec-
appears also to have undermined the confi- tive remedy for such misplaced comparison
dence in the soft institutionalism of the with European integration is the edited col-
‘ASEAN Way’ and underscored the need for lection by Bertrand Fort and Douglas Webber
deeper institutionalization and stronger com- (2006), Regional Integration in East Asia
mitments from countries. Following the and Europe: Convergence or Divergence?
region’s recovery from the 1997/98 financial Amitav Acharya (2006: 312–3), a leading
crisis the East Asian countries moved to scholar on East Asian regionalism and con-
institutionalize annual leaders’ summits and tributor to this book, points out that rather
ministerial dialogues through the ASEAN+3 than elevating the European model over the
(China, Japan and the Republic of Korea) Asian experience as a preferred model of
framework. The most concrete project is the regionalism, it is more productive to recog-
Chiang Mai Initiative (CMI), which was nize that regional cooperation is a difficult
adopted in May 2000 in order to provide and contested process that will throw up dif-
emergency foreign currency liquidity support ferent, equally legitimate, outcomes. There is
in the event of a future financial crisis. But room for a more mutually reinforcing cross-
broader cooperation also exists across a fertilization in the study of European, East
range of areas such as small and medium- Asian, and also other regionalisms. There is,
scale industry development, human resource for instance, no reason to believe that soft

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


486 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

institutionalism is a uniquely Asian phenom- ‘anti-gringoism’ is still evident, but the coun-
enon. Further, comparisons should not be try’s self-reliance based on an oil economy
limited to contemporary Asia and Europe, has now lost credibility. Mexico, which had
but would benefit from considering regional- earlier harboured the ambition of becoming a
ism experience across various time periods. regional power, was the first Latin American
country to conclude, in joining NAFTA in
1992, that a free trade policy was the path out
Debates about regionalism of stagnation.
The North American integration process is
in the Americas
characterized by a close cooperation between
Historically, the Americas have been divided the US administration and American busi-
and described according to North America, ness interests. The NAFTA proposals were
Latin America, and the Caribbean. Since the hotly debated in the US, where criticism
end of the Cold War this division has become focused particularly on the issues of migra-
increasingly inadequate for understanding tion, the relocation of manufacturing indus-
regional processes on the American conti- tries to Mexico and, to some extent,
nent. There are strong convergences both environment and labour issues. In Canada
within Latin America and between Latin and Mexico, discussion concerning NAFTA
America and North America. As Phillips predominantly related to the particular neo-
(2005: 58) asserts; liberal character of the agreement and the
dominant position of the US. It is hard to
(t)he most profitable way of proceeding is there-
fore to abandon traditional categories in favour of
dispute that the NAFTA project is elite-
a mode of analysis which seeks to advance an driven and based on a neoliberal philosophy.
integrated understanding of the Americas as a Significantly, opposition to the project from
region, the various parts of which are best disag- civil society has taken a regional form.
gregated into … distinctive but interlocking subre- According to Marchand (2001: 210), the
gions (that is, Andean, Caribbean, Central America,
North America and the Southern Cone).
‘hyperliberal’ NAFTA constitutes the worst
of the new regionalism in North America,
An important aspect of the transformation while the mobilization of a regionalized civil
of the Americas is linked to the changing society constitutes the best of the new region-
strategy of the US and to the consolidation of, alism in North America.
and resistance towards, neoliberal policies. NAFTA maintains a strong emphasis on
Although there is a plethora of sub-regional trade and market liberalization in combina-
projects across the Americas, most attention in tion with a weak institutional structure and
the debate has focused on NAFTA in the north, weak political ambitions, respecting the sov-
and Mercosur in the south. These two projects ereignty of each member state, which con-
are intriguing from a comparative perspective trasts sharply with the emphasis on deep and
and they are therefore contrasted here. institutional integration of the EU. Although
The origins of NAFTA can be traced to the the NAFTA treaty is binding on its member
growing concerns of Canada and Mexico that states and involves certain dispute settlement
protectionist US policies could potentially mechanisms, these are ad hoc and NAFTA’s
devastate their economies (Pastor, 2005: 220). objectives are limited to the regulation of
NAFTA was preceded by a bilateral free trade trade and investment flows and the protection
agreement between Canada and the USA; of property rights. ‘The style of NAFTA’s
when a similar agreement was proposed governance is laissez-faire, reactive, and
between Mexico and the US, Canada sought a legalistic: problems are defined by plaintiffs
tripartite agreement. Mexico’s involvement is and settled by litigation’ (Pastor, 2005: 220).
particularly intriguing. Mexico’s tradition of a While NAFTA emerged more or less as a
combined nationalism, protectionism, and consequence of US bilateralism, Mercosur

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 487

emerged both as a consequence of the demo- ‘political’ and intergovernmental solutions in


cratic and economic reforms in Brazil and lieu of the ‘legal’ avenue through the supra-
Argentina, and as a planned and intended national court of justice. Brazil’s individual-
regional venture. Mercosur has been istic strategy implies weak central institutions
described in terms of ‘open regionalism’ and trade integration only. Conversely, Brazil
(regionalismo abierto) (ECLAC, 1994), favours a strengthened political role for
pointing to that it is an outward-oriented Mercosur in the Americas, as a mechanism
regional response to the challenges of eco- of resistance towards the US, including the
nomic globalization and a mechanism for the FTAA. It appears that this emphasis on
governments to ‘lock in’ economic and polit- political counterweight has been emphasized
ical reform programmes. In this sense with Venezuela’s entry into the organization
Mercosur represents a clear shift in the inte- in 2006. In this sense Mercosur might repre-
gration model in South America away from sent a Latin alternative, resisting ‘North
the inward-oriented model of the past. Americanization’, reminiscent of earlier
According to Alvaro Vasconcelos (2007: models of regionalism in Latin America.
166), the main motivation of the Mercosur There is a rich base for comparative analy-
lay in the desire to create a common market sis in the Americas in time and space, due to
labelled on the European Community. In the the considerable number of old and more
1990s Mercosur was widely considered a recent regional projects across the Americas.
‘success’ (Malamud, 2003), particularly Empirically most of the comparisons con-
because the participant countries agreed on ducted are between sub-regional frameworks
far-reaching tariff liberalization, and because within the Americas in general, or more spe-
of the significant increase in the level of cifically within Latin America. However, as
intra-regional trade, at least compared with far as theory and cross-regional comparison
previous failed projects, such as the Latin are concerned, the EU is by far the most sali-
American Integration Association (LAIA). ent point of reference or model, particularly
However the Mercosur of today faces serious when we are dealing with variations on the
problems, largely stemming from the crisis theme of the common market model rather
set off in 2002–3 in the context of Free Trade than the free trade model. This implies that
of the Americas (FTAA) negotiation, from European integration theory and practice
which Mercosur has not fully emerged. strongly influences the debate in and com-
Mercosur has been a strongly statist parisons with Latin America, but not as much
project. Its formal institutions are weak and regarding NAFTA or the FTAA.7
directly dependent on national administra-
tions, which are responsible for the coordina-
tion and preparation of negotiations between Debates about regionalism
the member governments. This can be under-
in Africa
stood as an intergovernmental negotiating
structure, or as ‘presidentialism’, the latter The ideological foundation of regional coop-
should, according to Malamud (2003: 56), be eration and integration in Africa is evidenced
seen as a ‘functional equivalent’ to regional in the pan-African visions and series of trea-
institutions within the EU. The intergovern- ties developed within the framework of the
mental institutions exist alongside an embry- OAU and more recently the African Union
onic legal doctrine in two areas: common (AU) and the New Partnership for Africa’s
trade regulations and a system for the resolu- Development (NEPAD) (Asante, 1997;
tion of disputes. The number of issues that Murithi, 2005; Taylor, 2005). While earlier
inevitably require community level regula- strategies were built around state-led indus-
tion has grown. However, the key member trialization, import substitution and collec-
states (especially Brazil) appear to prefer tive self-reliance, the dominant view today is

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


488 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

that Africa ‘must unite’ in order to avoid their goals of highly developed institutional
marginalization in the global economy and frameworks – nearly always modelled on the
instead exploit the opportunities provided by EC/EU – with attendant economic and politi-
economic globalization. Indeed, an overarch- cal integration. The scepticism of this group
ing market orientation in combination with has generated a radically different interpreta-
EU-style institutionalization is the official tion of regionalism in Africa, associated with
strategy adopted by most of Africa’s main various approaches centring on critical politi-
regional cooperation and integration schemes, cal economy and new regionalism (Bach,
such as AU/NEPAD, the Common Market 1999; Bøås et al., 2005; Grant and Söderbaum,
for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA), 2003; Hentz and Bøås, 2003; Söderbaum,
the Economic Community of West African 2004). These approaches transcend the narrow
States (ECOWAS), the Southern African focus on inter-state regional frameworks,
Development Community (SADC), and the and obviate the artificial separation, in the
West African Economic and Monetary Union African context, of state and non-state actors,
(UEMOA). that are associated with traditional regional
The academic debate about regionalism in approaches.
Africa often focuses on state-led regional An important argument within this rather
integration frameworks. Two partly overlap- loose school of thought is the claim that many
ping schools of thought dominate the debate. ruling regimes and political leaders in Africa
The first line of thinking is mainly associated engage in symbolic and discursive activities –
with institutionalist and liberal lines of praising the goals of regionalism and regional
thought, concentrating on formal inter-state organizations, signing cooperation treaties
frameworks and/or official trade and invest- and agreements, and taking part in ‘summitry
ment flows, commonly with reference to the regionalism’ – while remaining uncommitted
EC/EU as a comparative marker or model to, or unwilling to implement, jointly agreed
(Fourutan, 1993; Holden, 2001; Jenkins and policies. Regionalism is thus used as a discur-
Thomas, 2001). What distinguish the second, sive and image-boosting exercise: leaders
‘pan-African’, school of thought are synoptic demonstrate support and loyalty towards one
overviews of African regional organizations another in order to raise the status, image and
and political-economic relationships, which formal sovereignty of their often-authoritarian
are then coupled with demands for the regimes, both domestically and internationally
strengthening of pan-African regional organ- (Bøås, 2003; Clapham, 1996).
izations and the so-called regional economic This type of ‘regime-boosting’ regionalism
communities (RECs) of the envisioned may be a goal in itself, but it may also be
African Economic Community (AEC) closely related to ‘shadow regionalization’;
(Asante, 1997; Muchie, 2003). It is notewor- what Bach refers to as ‘trans-state regionaliza-
thy that the pan-African line of thought often tion’ (Bach, 1999, 2005). Shadow regionaliza-
takes the EC/EU experience as inspiration tion draws attention to the potential for public
and as a justification for the development of officials and various actors within the state to
pan-African regionalism. Indeed, despite be entrenched in informal market activities in
their foundational differences, the two strands order to promote either their political goals or
of thought make implicit or explicit compari- their private economic interests. This particu-
sons with the EU, and also come to a similar lar type of regionalization grows from below
conclusion that, notwithstanding the ‘failure’ and is built upon rent seeking or the stimula-
of regionalism in Africa hitherto, there is still tion of patron-client relationships. Bach
great potential to build successful regional- claims, for instance, that regional organiza-
ism in the future. tions constitute a means for ‘resource capture’
A third and smaller group of scholars is and international patronage (Bach, 2005). It
more sceptical about whether the restructured implies regionalization without regional inte-
regional organizations will be able to attain gration or formal regionalism.

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 489

Many of the shadow networks are closely comparative research. The ongoing develop-
tied to the complex wars on the African con- ment of comparative regionalism rests there-
tinent. Taking the example of the Great Lakes fore upon finding a more mutually reinforcing
region, Taylor and Williams argue that for relationship between these standpoints. This
well-placed elites and business people the section begins with some conclusions regard-
war in this region offers potentially substan- ing the problematic role of European integra-
tial resources for those able to exploit them. tion theory and practice for comparative
Foreign involvement is not only about pre- regionalism, before outlining a general way
serving national security and defeating ene- of thinking about comparison which will be
mies, but also about securing access to able to facilitate dialogue in this fragmented
resource-rich areas and establishing priva- field of study.
tized accumulation networks that can emerge
and prosper under conditions of war and
anarchy (Taylor and Williams, 2001: 273). The problem of European
In summary, both the mainstream and pan-
integration theory and practice
African line of thought tend to elevate
in comparative regionalism
European integration theory and practice.
Although the critical and new regionalism This chapter reveals the tension between
approaches are often cast within a general regional specialization and comparative
discussion about regionalism, there is little research in the study of regionalism and
cross-fertilization and deep comparisons regional integration. At least empirically,
between Africa and regions in other parts of most scholars specialize in a particular
the world, including European integration. region, which they will often consider ‘spe-
This is unfortunate, since it is unlikely that the cial’ or ‘unique’. Even if intra-regional and
phenomena highlighted through this scholar- cross-regional comparisons may be under-
ship are uniquely ‘African’. Any particularity taken, there remains a strong bias towards
appears to be related to the nature of the European integration theory and
African state-society complex and Africa’s practice in the field; most other regionalisms
insertion in the global order. This specializa- are compared – implicitly or explicitly –
tion tends to reflect the tendency in the other against the backdrop of European theory
regional debates, namely that many scholars and practice.
tend to use specific contextual language to Two broad attitudes towards comparative
describe rather similar phenomena instead of analysis within the field of regionalism are
applying general concepts and developing distinguishable, which revolve around two
questions and hypotheses that can be trans- competing attitudes towards European inte-
ferred to cross-regional comparisons. gration theory and practice. One strand of
thinking tends to elevate European integration
theory and practice through comparative
research, while the other is considerably less
CONCLUSION convinced of the advantages of comparative
research and Europe-centred theories. The
This chapter has highlighted deep divisions first perspective – especially variants of real-
regarding the problem of comparison within ist/intergovernmental and liberal/institutional
the study of regionalism and regional inte- scholarship – strongly emphasizes Europe-
gration. Contestations regarding what to centred generalizations. This type of research
compare, how to compare and sometimes has been dominated by a concern to explain
even why to compare at all, arise predomi- variations from the ‘standard’ European case.
nantly as a consequence of the tension in the Indeed, other modes of regionalism are, where
field between regional specialization (that is, they appear, characterized as loose and infor-
in the form of case study or area study) and mal (such as Asia) or ‘failed’ (such as Africa),

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


490 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

reflecting ‘a teleological prejudice informed a simple point of reference, or to a model/


by the assumption that ‘progress’ in regional anti-model. Further, many comparisons and
organization is defined in terms of EU-style generalizations, which depart from the
institutionalization’ (Breslin et al., 2002: 11). European context, are skewed through a lack
One reason for this bias lies in the ways the of sensitivity to the issues around comparing
underlying assumptions and understandings regions with different levels of development
about the nature of regionalism (which most and holding unequal positions in the current
often stem from a particular reading of world order.
European integration) influence perceptions A more advanced debate about regional-
about how regionalism in other parts of the ism will not be reached through simply cel-
world does (and should) look. As the authori- ebrating differences from European
tative scholar, Andrew Hurrell (2005), asserts, integration theory and practice, but rather in
‘the study of comparative regionalism has going beyond dominant interpretations of
been hindered by so-called theories of region- European integration, and drawing more
alism which turn out to be little more than the broadly upon alternative theories (Diez and
translation of a particular set of European Wiener, 2003; Rosamond, 2000). To neglect
experiences into a more abstract theoretical Europe is to miss the opportunity to take
language’ (p. 39). advantage of the richness of the EU project
Avoiding Europe-centredness has been an and laboratory. As Warleigh and Rosamond
ongoing issue in the study of regionalism (2006) argue, comparative regionalism
among developing countries and for critical ‘cannot afford to lock itself away from the
scholarship in the field of international rela- most advanced instance of regionalism in
tions. There are persuasive reasons for taking world politics’ (p. 2). The challenge for com-
stock of cumulative research on regional parative regionalism is to both include and
integration in the developing world and for transcend European integration theory and
being cautious regarding EU-style institu- practice. But this requires enhanced commu-
tionalization inherent in most classical or nication between various specializations and
mainstream perspectives or policies. Indeed, theoretical standpoints.
there have been a number of innovative
efforts to develop a regional approach spe-
cifically aimed at the developing world The future of comparative
(Axline, 1994c; Bøås et al., 1999). However
regionalism
even these perspectives tend to mirror the
Europe-centred view, thus celebrating the Some of the most informative studies in the
differences in theory and practice between field of regionalism are case studies or stud-
regionalism in Europe and in the developing ies situated in debates within a particular
word. According to Warleigh and Rosamond region, such as Europe, East Asia, the
(2006), this has even resulted in a caricature Americas, or Africa. Detailed case studies of
of European integration or of classical regionalism are certainly necessary; these
regional integration theory, giving rise to identify historical and contextual specifici-
unnecessary fragmentation within the field. ties and allow for a detailed and ‘intensive’
The barrier for achieving a nuanced com- analysis of a single case (according to mono-,
parative analysis is not European integration multi- or interdisciplinary studies). The dis-
experience or theory per se, but rather the advantage of case studies is, however, that a
dominance of certain constructions and single case is a weak base for creating new
models of European integration. Conversely, generalization or invalidating existing gener-
discussions about regionalism in Africa or alizations (Axline, 1994b: 15).8
Asia have often reduced the EC/EU to the Comparative analysis has sometimes
community method or a common market, or been heavily criticized by area specialists,

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 491

post-modernists and others, who emphasize Such a middle ground can avoid the equal
cultural relativism and the importance of a deep interlopers of exaggerated contextualization
multidisciplinary knowledge of various con- on the one hand, and over-generalized (or
texts and people. Given that the comparative irrelevant) theory on the other. Achieving this
method is ultimately based on the same logic as perspective on the eclectic centre of compara-
‘the experimental method’, it is reasonable that tive studies will be inclusive rather than exclu-
it should be used with care in the social sci- sive – even if it will be too ‘social sciency’ for
ences. But comparative analysis helps guard some and too much of ‘storytelling’ for others
against ethnocentric bias and culture-bound (World Politics, 1995). There need not be any
interpretations that can arise when a specializa- opposition between area studies and discipli-
tion is over-contextualized or the area of study nary studies/international studies, or between
is too isolated. particularizing and universalizing studies. The
The next step in the study of regionalism is eclectic centre perspective should enable area
to develop its comparative element, which will studies, comparative politics and international
be crucial for enhancing cross-fertilization studies to engage in a more fruitful dialogue,
between various theoretical standpoints and and through that process overcome the frag-
regional specializations. For; mentation in the field of regionalism and
regional integration. Such a perspective should
when conducted properly, the comparative
approach is an excellent tool … In particular, it is a
be able to bridge divisions between earlier
key mechanism for bringing area studies and disci- (‘old’) and more contemporary (‘new’) theo-
plinary studies together, and enhancing both. It ries and experiences of regionalism and
provides new ways of thinking about the case regional integration. It should also enable
studies whilst at the same time allowing for the cross-fertilization between different regional
theories to be tested, adapted and advanced
(Breslin and Higgott, 2000: 341).
debates and specializations. Finally, an eclec-
tic centre perspective will highlight the rich-
While doing comparative research, it is ness of comparative analysis, and enhance a
crucial to move beyond the ‘false universal- dialogue about the fundamentals of compara-
ism’ inherent in a selective reading of region- tive analysis (for example, what constitute
alism in the core, and in the EU in particular. comparable cases, and the many different
As Hurrell (2005: 39) asserts, rather than forms, methods and designs of comparative
trying to understand other regions through the analysis). This chapter will have achieved its
distorting mirror of Europe, it is better to think aim if it has contributed to furthering such a
in general theoretical terms and in ways that dialogue.
draw both on traditional international relations
theory, comparative politics and on other areas
of social thought. This will only be possible
if the case of Europe is integrated within a ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
larger and more general discourse of compara-
tive regionalism, built around general con- A great deal of the author’s work on region-
cepts and theories, but that remains culturally alism during the last decade has been carried
sensitive. out in liaison with Björn Hettne, and his con-
This calls for a middle ground to be estab- tribution to this chapter has been invaluable.
lished between context and case/area studies on The author is also grateful for the helpful
the one hand, and ‘hard’ social science as comments on an earlier version, especially
reflected in the use of ‘laborative’ comparisons by Ian Taylor, and also by Daniel Bach,
on the other. This middle ground has been Shaun Breslin, Todd Landman, Philippe
referred to as the ‘eclectic center’ of comparative de Lombaerde, Nicola Phillips, Rodrigo
studies (World Politics, 1995; also see Africa Tavares, Luk van Langenhove, and Alex
Today, 1997; Axline, 1994c; Payne, 1998). Warleigh-Lack. The research funding from

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


492 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

the Swedish International Development 6. See Rosamond (2000: Chapter 7) for a detailed
Cooperation Agency (Sida) is gratefully discussion about the relationship between EU studies
and international studies. Also see Warleigh (2004;
acknowledged. 2006).
7. Thanks to Nicola Phillips for this point.
8. According to Axline (1994b: 15–16), case stud-
ies must be cast within a comparative context in
NOTES order to contribute to general propositions. Drawing
on Lijphart’s work, Axline clarifies that six types of
case studies can give a cumulative contribution to
1. Hurrell (1995: 39–45) makes a more nuanced
knowledge: (1) atheoretical case studies; (2) interpre-
distinction between five different categories of
tative case studies; (3) hypothesis-generating case
regionalism: (1) social and economic regionalization;
studies; (4) theory-confirming case studies; (5) theory-
(2) regional awareness and identity; (3) regional
infirming case studies; and (6) deviant case studies.
inter-state cooperation; (4) state-promoted regional
Atheoretical case studies have little utility for gener-
integration; and (5) regional cohesion.
alization in themselves, but may indirectly lead to
2. Parts of this section draw on Hettne and
theory-generation. Interpretative case studies may
Söderbaum (2008). See also Hettne (2005).
or may not include a theoretical element, and may or
3. According to Axline (1994b: 1–5) the evolution
may not contribute to generalizations applicable to
of regional cooperation since the 1950s can be
a number of different cases. The other four types of
divided into four (rather than two) generations of
case studies do contribute to the building of general-
regional cooperation: (1) traditional free trade areas;
izable knowledge through their contribution to
(2) regional import substitution; (3) collective self-
theory building.
reliance; and (4) regional cooperation in the new
world order (that is, the ‘recent debate’).
4. The recent debate has seen the proliferation of
a large number of theories and approaches to
regional integration and regionalism. For instance, REFERENCES
Mansfield and Milner’s (1997) The Political Economy
of Regionalism highlights neorealist and neoliberal
Acharya, A. (1997) ‘Ideas, identity and
institutional theories, new trade theories and
the new institutionalism. Theories of New institution-building: from the “ASEAN way”
Regionalism by Söderbaum and Shaw (2003) draws to the “Asia-Pacific way”?’ The Pacific
attention to variants of liberalism institutionalism, Review, 10 (3): 319–46.
security complex theory, to a variety of constructivist, Acharya, A. (2001) Constructing a security
critical and ‘new regionalism’ approaches, such community in Southeast Asia: ASEAN and
as the world order approach (WOA), new regional- the problem of regional order. London:
ism approach (NRA) and region-building approach. Routledge.
Laursen’s Comparative Regional Integration (2003) Acharya, A. (2002) ‘Regionalism and the
emphasizes a variety of governmentalist, power,
emerging world order: sovereignty, auton-
constructivist, neofunctionalist and historical institu-
omy, identity’, in S. Breslin, C. Hughes,
tionalist perspectives, whereas Wiener and Diez
(2005) is a coherent exposé of the richness of N. Phillips, and B. Rosamond (eds), New
European Integration Theory, highlighting: federal- regionalisms in the global political economy.
ism, neo-neo-functionalism, liberal intergovernmen- London: Routledge, pp. 20–32.
talism, multi level governance, policy networks, new Acharya, A. (2003) ‘Democratisation and
institutionalisms, social constructivism, integration the prospects for participatory regionalism
through law, discursive approaches and gender in Southeast Asia’, Third World Quarterly,
perspectives. 24 (2): 375–90.
5. At least three distinctions can be made regard- Acharya, A. (2006) ‘Europe and Asia: reflec-
ing the impact of EU integration on other cases of
tions on a tale of two regionalisms’, in
regionalism: (1) EU as the paradigm of regionalism;
B. Fort and D. Webber (eds), Regional inte-
(2) EU as a model of regionalism; and (3) the empiri-
cal relationship between EU and various world gration in Europe and East Asia: Convergence
regions (which includes the EU’s ideational and or divergence? London and New York:
financial support of other regional organizations). Routledge, pp. 312–21.
These distinctions are analytically separate but rather Acharya, A. and Johnston, A. (eds) (2007)
difficult to keep completely apart. Crafting cooperation. Regional international

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 493

institutions in comparative perspective. Breslin, S. and Higgott, R. (2000) ‘Studying


London: Oxford University Press. regions: Learning from the old, constructing
Adler, E. and Barnett, M. (eds.) (1998) Security the new’, New Political Economy, 5 (3):
communities. Cambridge: Cambridge 333–52.
University Press. Breslin, S., Higgott, R., and Rosamond, B.
Africa Today (1997) Special issue: The future (2002) ‘Regions in comparative perspective’,
of regional studies, 44 (2): April–June, in S. Breslin, C. Hughes, N. Philips, and
pp.111–93. B. Rosamond (eds), New regionalisms in the
Anderson, K. and Blackhurst, R. (eds) (1993) global political economy. London: Routledge,
Regional integration and the global trading pp. 1–19.
system. Harvester: Wheatsheaf. Buzan, B. and Waever, O. (2003) Regions and
Asante, S.K.B. (1997) Regionalism and Africa’s powers: The structure of international secu-
development. Expectations, reality and chal- rity. Cambridge: Cambridge University
lenges. Basingstoke: Macmillan. Press.
Axline, W.A. (1994a) ‘Cross-regional compari- Cable, V. and Henderson, D. (eds) (1994) Trade
son and the theory of regional cooperation: blocs? The future of regional integration.
Lessons from Latin America, the Caribbean, London: Royal Institute of International
South East Asia and the South Pacific’, in Affairs.
W.A. Axline (ed.), The political economy of Caporaso J.A. and Keeler, J. (1995) ‘The
regional cooperation. Comparative case stud- European Union and regional integration
ies. London: Pinter Publishers, pp.178–224. theory’, in S. Mazey and C. Rhodes (eds) The
Axline, W.A. (1994b) ‘Comparative case stud- state of the European Union Volume 3:
ies of regional cooperation among develop- Building a European polity? Boulder, CO:
ing countries’, in W.A. Axline (ed.), The Lynne Rienner, pp. 20–40.
Political Economy of Regional Cooperation. Cantori, L.J. and Spiegel, S.L. (1970) The inter-
Comparative case studies. London: Pinter national politics of regions: A comparative
Publishers, pp. 7–33. framework. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice
Axline, W.A. (ed.) (1994c) The political econ- Hall.
omy of regional cooperation. Comparative Choi, Y.J. and Caporaso, J.A. (2002)
case studies. London: Pinter Publishers. ‘Comparative regional integration’, in
Bach, D.C. (1999) Regionalisation in Africa. Carlsnaes, W., T. Risse and B. Simmons (eds),
Integration and disintegration. London: Handbook of international relations. London:
James Currey. Sage. pp. 480–99.
Bach, D.C. (2005) ‘The global politics of region- Christiansen, T., Jørgensen, K.E. and Wiener,
alism: Africa’, in M. Farrell, B. Hettne and L. A. (eds) (2001) The social construction of
van Langenhove (eds), Global politics of Europe. London: SAGE.
regionalism. Theory and practice. London: Christiansen, T. and Piattoni, S. (eds) (2004)
Pluto Press, pp. 171–86. Informal governance in the European Union.
Bhagwati, J. (1993) The world trading system Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
at risk. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Clapham, C. (1996) Africa and the interna-
Bøås, M. (2003) ‘Weak states, strong regimes: tional system. The politics of state survival.
Towards a “real” political economy of Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
African regionalization’, in J. Andrew and F. Coleman, W.D. and Underhill, G.R.D. (eds)
Söderbaum (eds), The new regionalism in (1998) Regionalism and global economic
Africa. Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 31–46. integration. Europe, Asia and the Americas.
Bøås, M., Marchand, M.H., and Shaw, T.M. London: Routledge.
(eds) (1999) ‘New regionalisms in the new Cooper, A., Hughes, C., and de Lombaerde, P.
millennium’, special issue of Third World (eds) (2008) Regionalisation and Global
Quarterly, 20 (5, October), pp. 897–1070. Governance. The Taming of Globalisation.
Bøås, M., Marchand, M.H., and Shaw, T.M. London: Routledge.
(2005) The political economy of regions and Dell, S.S. (1966) A Latin American common
regionalism. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. market? New York: Oxford University Press.

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


494 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Diez, T. and Wiener, A. (eds) (2003) Theories of Haas, E.B. (1975) The obsolescence of regional
European integration. Oxford: Oxford integration theory (Working paper) Institute
University Press. of International Studies: Berkeley, CA.
ECLAC (1994) Open regionalism in Latin Haas, E.B. and Schmitter, P. (1964) ‘Economics
America and the Caribbean: Economic inte- and differential patterns of integration:
gration as a contribution to changing pro- Projections about unity in Latin America’,
duction patterns with social equity. Santiago: International Organization, 18 (4): 259–99.
ECLAC. Hentz, J.J. and Bøås, M. (eds) (2003) New and
Etzioni, A. (1965) Political unification: A com- critical security and regionalism: Beyond the
parative study of leaders and forces. New nation state. Aldershot: Ashgate.
York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston. Hettne, B. (2002) ‘The Europeanization of
Farrell, M., Hettne, B., and van Langenhove, L. Europe: Endogenous and exogenous dimen-
(eds) (2005) The global politics of regionalism. sions’, Journal of European Integration, 24
Theory and practice. London: Pluto Press. (4): 325–40.
Fawcett, L. (2005) ‘Regionalism from a histori- Hettne, B. (2003) ‘The new regionalism revis-
cal perspective’, in M. Farrell, B. Hettne, and ited’, in F. Söderbaum and T.M. Shaw (eds),
L. van Langenhove (eds), Global politics of Theories of new regionalism: A Palgrave
regionalism. Theory and practice. London: reader. Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 22–42.
Pluto Press, pp. 21–37. Hettne, B. (2005) ‘Beyond the ‘new’ regional-
Fawcett, L. and Hurrell, A. (eds) (1995) ism’, New Political Economy, 10 (4):
Regionalism in world politics. Regional 543–72.
organization and international order. Oxford: Hettne, B., Inotai, A., and Sunkel, O. (eds)
Oxford University Press. (1999) Globalism and the new regionalism.
Fort, B. and Webber, D. (eds) (2006) Regional Basingstoke: Macmillan.
integration in Europe and East Asia: Hettne, B. and Söderbaum, F. (2000) ‘Theorising
Convergence or divergence? London and the rise of regionness’, New Political
New York: Routledge. Economy, 5 (3): 457–74.
Fourutan, F. (1993) ‘Regional integration in Sub- Hettne, B. and Söderbaum, F. (2008) ‘The
Saharan Africa: Past experience and future future of regionalism: Old divides, new fron-
prospects’, in J. de Melo and A. Panagariya tiers’, in A. Cooper, C. Hughes, and P. de
(eds), New dimensions in regional integra- Lombaerde (eds), Regionalization and the
tion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, taming of globalization. London: Routledge,
pp. 234–76. pp. 61–79.
Gamble, A. and Payne, A. (eds) (1996) Higgott, R. (2002) From trade-led to monetary-
Regionalism and global order. Basingstoke: led regionalism: Why Asia in the 21st century
Macmillan. will be different to Europe in the 20th century
Grant, A.J. and Söderbaum, F. (eds) (2003) The (UNU/CRIS e-Working Papers 2002/1) Bruges:
new regionalism in Africa. Aldershot: UNU/CRIS.
Ashgate. Higgott, R. (2006) ‘The theory and practice of
Grieco, J.M. (1997) ‘Systemic sources of varia- region: the changing global context’, in
tion in regional institutionalization in Western B. Fort and D. Webber (eds), Regional inte-
Europe, East Asia and the Americas’, in E.D. gration in Europe and East Asia: Convergence
Mansfield and H.V. Milner (eds), The political or divergence? London and New York:
economy of regionalism. New York: Colombia Routledge, pp. 17–38.
University Press, pp. 164–87. Hix, S. (1994) ‘The study of the European
Haas, E.B. (1958) The uniting of Europe: Community: The challenge to comparative
Political, social and economic forces 1950– politics’, West European Politics, 17 (1):
1957. Stanford: Stanford University Press. 1–30.
Haas, E.B. (1964) Beyond the nation-state. Hix, S. (1999) The political system of the
Stanford: Stanford University Press. European Union. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Haas, E.B. (1967) ‘The uniting of Europe and Hoffman, S. (1966) ‘Obstinate or obsolete? The
the uniting of Latin America’, Journal of fate of the nation state and the case of
Common Market Studies, 5 (4): 315–45. Western Europe’, Daedalus, 95 (3): 862–915.

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 18 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


COMPARATIVE REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND REGIONALISM 495

Holden, M. (2001) ‘Is a free trade agreement Marchand, M.H. (2001) ‘North American
the answer for Southern Africa? Insights regionalisms and regionalization in the
from development economic theory’, in 1990s’, in M. Schulz, F. Söderbaum and
P. Vale, L. Swatuk and B. Odén (eds), Theory, J. Öjendal (eds), Regionalization in a globaliz-
change and Southern Africa’s future. ing world. A comparative perspective on
Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 148–65. actors, forms and processes. London: Zed
Hooghe, L. and Marks, G. (2001) Multi-level Books, pp. 198–210.
governance and European integration. Mattli, W. (1999) The logic of regional integra-
Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield. tion. Europe and beyond. Cambridge:
Hurrell, A. (1995) ‘Regionalism in theoretical Cambridge University Press.
perspective’, in L. Fawcett and A. Hurrell Milward, A.S. (1992) The European rescue of
(eds) Regionalism in world politics. Regional the nation state. London: Routledge.
organization and international order. Oxford: Mitrany, D. (1966) A working peace system.
Oxford University Press, pp. 37–73. Chicago: Quardrangle Books. (1st edition
Hurrell, A. (2005) ‘The regional dimension 1946).
in international relations theory’, in M. Farrell, Moravcsik, A. (1998) The choice for Europe:
B. Hettne and L. van Langenhove (eds), social purpose and state power from Messina
The global politics of regionalism. Theory to Maastricht. Ithaca: Cornell University
and practice. London: Pluto Press, pp. Press.
38–53. Muchie, M. (ed.) (2003) The making of the
Jenkins, C. and Thomas, L. (2001) ‘African Africa-nation: Pan-Africanism and the African
regionalism and the SADC’, in M. Telò renaissance. London: Adonis and Abbey.
(ed.), European Union and new regionalism. Murithi, T. (2005) The African Union. Pan-
Regional actors and global governance in a Africanism, peace-building and develop-
post-hegemonic era. Aldershot: Ashgate, ment. Aldershot: Ashgate.
pp. 153–75. Nesudurai, H.E.S. (2005) ‘The global politics of
Jessop, R. (2003) ‘The political economy of regionalism: Asia and the Asia Pacific’, in
scale and the construction of cross-border M. Farrell, B. Hettne, and L. van Langenhove
regions’, in F. Söderbaum and T.M. (eds), The global politics of regionalism.
Shaw (eds), Theories of new regionalism. Theory and practice. London: Pluto Press,
A Palgrave reader. Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 155–70.
pp. 179–196. Nye, J.S., Jr. (1970) ‘Comparing common mar-
Jönsson, C., Tägil, S., and Törnqvist, G. kets: A revised neo-functionalist model’,
(2000) Organizing European space. London: International Organization, 24 (4): 796–835.
Sage. Nye, J. (1971) Peace in parts: Integration and
Katzenstein, P.J. (2000) ‘Regionalism and Asia’, conflict in regional organization. Boston:
New Political Economy, 5 (3): 353–68. Little, Brown and Company.
Katzenstein, P.J. (2002) ‘Regionalism and Pastor, R.A. (2005) ‘North America and the
Asia’, in C. W. Hughes, N. Phillip, and Americas’, in M. Farrell, B. Hettne, and L. van
B. Rosamond (eds), New regionalism in the Langenhove (eds), The global politics of
global political economy. London: Routledge. regionalism. Theory and practice. London:
pp. 104–18. Pluto Press, pp. 202–21.
Laursen, F. (ed.) (2003) Comparative regional Payne, A. (1998) ‘The new political economy of
integration. Theoretical perspectives. area studies’, Millennium: Journal of
Aldershot: Ashgate. International Studies, 27 (2): 253–73.
Malamud, A. (2003) ‘Presedentialism and Perkmann, M., and Sum, N.L. (eds) (2002)
Mercosur: A hidden cause for a successful Globalization, regionalization and the building
experience’, in F. Laursen (ed.), Comparative of cross-border regions. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
regional integration. theoretical perspectives. Phillips, N. (2005) ‘The Americas’, in A. Payne
Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 53–74. (ed.), The new regional politics of develop-
Mansfield, E.D. and Milner, H.V. (eds) (1997) ment. Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 29–58.
The political economy of regionalism. New Pollack, M.A. (2003) The engines of European
York: Colombia University Press. integration. Delegation, agency, and agenda

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 19 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


496 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

setting in the EU. Oxford: Oxford University Taylor, I. (2005) NEPAD. Toward Africa’s devel-
Press. opment or another false start? Boulder:
Prebisch, R. (1963) Towards a dynamic devel- Lynne Rienner.
opment policy for Latin America. United Taylor, I. and Williams, P. (2001) ‘South African
Nations. foreign policy and the Great Lakes crisis:
Rosamond, B. (2000) Theories of European inte- African renaissance meets vagabonde poli-
gration. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. tique’, African Affairs, 100 (399): 265–86.
Rosamond, B. (2005) ‘The uniting of Europe Telo, M. (2007) European Union and new
and the foundation of EU studies: Revisiting regionalism. Regional actors and global gov-
the neofunctionalism of Ernst B. Haas’, ernance in a post-hegemonic era (2nd edi-
Journal of European Public Policy, 12 (2): tion) Aldershot: Ashgate.
April, 237–54. Vasconcelos, À. (2007) ‘European Union and
Rugman, A.M. (2005) The regional multina- MERCOSUR’, in M. Telo (ed.), European
tionals: MNEs and ‘global’ strategic manage- Union and new regionalism. Regional actors
ment. Cambridge: Cambridge University and global governance in a post-hegemonic
Press. era (2nd edition) Aldershot: Ashgate,
Sandholtz, W. and Stone–Sweet, A. (1998) pp. 165–184.
European integration and supranational Warleigh, A. (2001) ‘Europeanizing civil soci-
governance. Oxford: Oxford University ety: NGOs as agents of political socialisa-
Press. tion’, Journal of Common Market Studies,
Schmitter, P.C. (1970) ‘A revised theory 39 (4): 619–39.
of regional integration’, International Warleigh, A. (2004) ‘In defence of intra-
Organization, 24 (4): 836–68. disciplinarity: “European Studies”, the “new
Schulz, M., Söderbaum, F., and Öjendal, J. regionalism” and the issue of democratisa-
(eds) (2001) Regionalization in a globalizing tion’, Cambridge Review of International
world. A comparative perspective on Affairs, 17 (2): 301–18.
actors, forms and processes. London: Zed Warleigh, A. and Rosamond, B. (2006)
Books. Comparative regional integration: Towards a
Söderbaum, F. (2004) The political economy of research agenda. Description of Workshop
regionalism. The case of Southern Africa. for the ECPR Joint Sessions, Nicosia, Cyprus,
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. 25–30 April 2006.
Söderbaum, F. (2005) ‘Exploring the links Warleigh-Lack, A. (2006) ‘Towards a concep-
between micro-regionalism and macro-re- tual framework for regionalisation: bridging
gionalism’, in M. Farrell, B. Hettne, and L. van “new regionalism” and “integration theory”,
Langenhove (eds), Global politics of regional- Review of International Political Economy,
ism. Theory and practice. London: Pluto Press, 13 (5): 750–71.
pp. 87–103. Wiener, A. and Diez, T. (2005) European inte-
Söderbaum, F. (2007) ‘Regionalisation and civil gration theory. Oxford: Oxford University
society: The case of Southern Africa’, New Press.
Political Economy, 12 (3) September: 319–37. World Politics (1995) The role of theory in com-
Söderbaum, F. and Shaw, T.M. (eds) (2003) parative politics. A Symposium, 48(1),
Theories of new regionalism. A Palgrave October, pp. 1–49.
reader. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

9781412919760_Chap26.indd 20 3/11/2009 4:43:38 PM


27
Transitional Justice
Paola Cesarini

INTRODUCTION involved in formulating ‘covering laws’ and


carrying out empirical testing. In contrast, it
Over the last three decades, close to eighty is enthusiastically embraced by scholars from
countries have experienced democratization other disciplines who – while focusing on the
and, in turn, the related challenges of dealing legal, social, moral, cultural, or psychologi-
with previous authoritarian rulers and their cal dimensions of transitional justice – often
crimes. In the face of this growing universe ‘leave it up to the reader’ to sort out the key
of cases, ‘transitional justice’ has rapidly political issues involved, or explore them
grown from a minor area of investigation into with quite different theoretical ambitions and
a massive inter-disciplinary field1 of study, methodological tools than mainstream politi-
full of promising avenues for academic cal scientists. This paradox unfortunately
research and practical experimentation. At translates in to a body of scholarship that,
the same time, the discipline of transitional while rather interesting, also frequently dis-
justice is still in its adolescence – that is, plays conceptual ambiguity, scarce apprecia-
eager to grow up, yet insecure about its core tion for existing political constraints, limited
identity. And while most scholars and activ- theoretical claims, and lack of systematic
ists in the field concur that unresolved prob- empirical testing.
lems of transitional justice have a lasting The potential for political scientists’ con-
impact on new democracies (Teitel, 2000: 9) tribution to the field of transitional justice is
significant disagreement remains on key con- therefore considerable on many different
ceptual and theoretical issues. levels. First, political scientists can help for-
Transitional justice and comparative poli- mulate a sound definition of transitional jus-
tics often intersect. Thus, for example, most tice that captures its essential features,
theories in the field touch on political varia- differentiates ‘transitional’ from other forms
bles and adopt the comparative method. The of justice, and readily leads to operationali-
discipline of transitional justice, however, is zation and testing. Second, they can provide
affected by a deplorable paradox: Despite its a healthy dose of political realism to comple-
clear political content, it is rarely frequented ment current normative approaches to transi-
by political scientists on account of its com- tional justice. Third, leaving aside the perhaps
plex interdisciplinary nature, allegedly unrealistic goal of formulating covering
‘normative’ qualities, and the many obstacles laws, political scientists can contribute useful

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


498 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

analyses ‘of smaller-scale causal mecha- Other definitions conceptualize transitional


nisms [of transitional justice] that recur in justice even more extensively. Thus, for exam-
different combinations with different aggre- ple, in 2006 the International Center for
gate consequences in varying historical set- Transitional Justice characterized it as: ‘a
tings’ (McAdam et al., 2001: 24). Fourth, range of approaches that societies undertake
political scientists can shed light on the opti- to reckon with legacies of widespread or sys-
mal combination and sequence of transitional tematic human rights abuse as they move from
justice choices. Finally, political scientists a period of violent conflict or oppression
(and especially comparativists) can rigor- toward peace, democracy, the rule of law, and
ously test existing theories of transitional respect for individual and collective rights’.
justice against the available empirical evi- These and other such broad conceptualiza-
dence from several national transitional jus- tions2 have led scholars to argue about quite
tice experiences around the world. Alas, to different issues under the same ‘transitional
do all this political scientists also need to justice’ label. Most frequently, transitional
venture outside the confines of their own justice is used as a synonym for the criminal
discipline, contemplate using more eclectic prosecution of former authoritarian rulers
epistemologies, and vigorously challenge (and their agents) for alleged mass atrocities
their more ‘traditional’ colleagues’ skepti- (i.e., war crimes, politically motivated disap-
cism about the scientific potential of a transi- pearances, murder, torture, ethnic cleansing,
tional justice research agenda. genocide, and rape, etc.) Following World
In keeping with the Sage Handbook tradi- War II, transitional justice includes domestic
tion, this chapter provides a detailed discus- as well as international criminal prosecu-
sion of the main conceptual and theoretical tions (e.g., the Nuremberg and Tokyo trials,
debates on transitional justice, with a special the International Courts for the former
focus on contributions by political scientists. Yugoslavia and Rwanda; the International
In particular, it addresses questions such as: Criminal Court; etc.); hybrid national/inter-
What is transitional justice? What determines national courts (e.g., Sierra Leone and
a post-authoritarian society’s transitional jus- Cambodia); and national courts operating
tice choices? Why do different countries under the doctrine of universal jurisdiction3
adopt different transitional justice choices? (e.g., Spain and Belgium).
What is the impact of different transitional In practice, however, transitional justice
justice choices on the future of new democra- goes well beyond criminal prosecution. As the
cies? And which new areas of transitional most recent democratization ‘wave’ in Latin
justice research show promise for adding to America, Eastern Europe and Africa shows, it
our knowledge about how countries can deal may also involve a wide range of extra-judicial
with their past during difficult social and efforts – such as: official historical investiga-
political transformation? tions of the authoritarian record,4 purges,5
reparations,6 and traditional and community-
based mechanisms of conflict resolution.7
Finally, many scholars and practitioners
DEFINING TRANSITIONAL point out that carrying out democratic and
JUSTICE even socio-economic reforms often provides
the best guarantee of preventing future
Transitional justice is a broad – if not ‘over- instances of authoritarianism and large-scale
stretched’ – concept. According to a popular atrocities. These authors thus extend the con-
definition, it refers to all ‘the choices made and cept of transitional justice well beyond
quality of justice rendered when new leaders backward looking measures, to include for-
replace authoritarian predecessors presumed ward looking institutional, social and eco-
responsible for criminal acts’ (Siegel, 1998) nomic engineering. Such a ‘holistic approach’

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 2 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 499

(Boraine, 2006) to transitional justice actors (e.g., former rulers, democratizing


presents, of course, both benefits and costs. agents, victims, etc.) and, in the end, produce
Benefits amount to coverage of a wider range both winners and losers. They are also deeply
of phenomena and greater richness of detail, ethical, because transitional justice is expected
while costs include conceptual ambiguity to redraw a firm boundary between good and
which, in turn, may discourage scientifically evil in societies that experienced violent con-
minded social scientists from pursuing flict (including civil war) and massive human
research in the field of transitional justice. rights abuse – principally, but not exclusively,
It is thus paramount for comparative anal- at the hands of the state.12 Finally, transi-
ysis that any useful conceptualization of tional justice choices are historic, as they
transitional justice should strive to do two ultimately determine whether or not a
things: capture its essential features and dif- severely divided society embarks on a path
ferentiate ‘transitional’ from other forms of toward pacification and, eventually, political
justice. To encapsulate its fundamental char- reconciliation.
acteristics, a good definition of transitional
justice should situate it exclusively in coun-
tries experiencing democratic transition
(Teitel, 2000: 6), so that it would be impos- SUB-TYPES OF TRANSITIONAL
sible to speak of it in the context of other JUSTICE
kinds of regime change (e.g., from totalitari-
anism to authoritarianism) or no regime To make the concept more manageable,
change.8 Second, transitional justice should scholars have attempted to formulate various
address mainly the problematic legacies of typologies of transitional justice. At a general
the past, so that it would be difficult to speak level, the literature offers several dichoto-
of it in the absence of trauma and abuse at mous classifications of transitional justice
both the individual and societal level. Third, choices. According to these, transitional jus-
to differentiate transitional justice from other tice can be retributive or restorative – with
kinds of justice, a good definition should the former seeking the punishment of perpe-
concentrate on a post-authoritarian society’s trators of atrocities, and the latter the political,
own democratically formulated choices. In moral, and material rehabilitation of victims.
this fashion, transitional justice would be It can be retrospective or prospective – with
confused neither with ‘victors’ justice’,9 nor the former concentrating on past misdeeds,
with ‘wild’ or ‘people’s’ justice.10 Finally, a and the latter on future objectives. It can be
good definition of transitional justice should exclusive or inclusive – with the former being
take note of the latter’s positive purpose, led by a restricted and insulated circle of
which usually goes beyond the mere sanction decision-makers, and the latter being carried
of past injustices to include both the pacifica- out in close collaboration with victims and
tion and democratization of formerly author- broad sectors of civil society. It can be
itarian societies. narrow or extensive – with the former target-
In light of the above, this chapter argues ing only top-level crimes and/or perpetrators,
that transitional justice should be parsimoni- and the latter seeking to go after everyone
ously defined as: the legitimate choices involved in carrying out atrocities. It can be
that post-authoritarian societies make with endogenous or exogenous – with the former
respect to the legacies of previous repressive initiated by domestic actors, and the latter
rule11 to build a future of enduring peace by external entities. It can be top-down or
and democracy. Such choices are exqui- bottom-up – with the former instigated by
sitely political, in the sense that they go political elites, and the latter by civil society.
well beyond the judicial sphere; trigger It can be immediate and delayed – with the
intense confrontation among competing former taking place right after regime change,

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 3 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


500 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

and the latter many years (even decades) Table 27.1 Sub-types of transitional justice
after democratization. It can be bounded or Sub-type Objectives Methods
open-ended – with the former taking place Criminal Retribution Trials (domestic,
within clearly defined temporal boundaries international,
and the latter lasting over the course of sev- hybrid, etc.)
Historical Truth Official bodies of
eral generations. It can be confidential or
inquiry with public
public – with the former taking place behind disclosure of
closed doors and the latter in open view (and findings
with broad dissemination of outcomes.) Reparatory Rehabilitation Restitution,
Finally, transitional justice can focus either and compensation,
on individuals (perpetrators and victims) reintegration of apology, and
victims memorialization
or collectives (groups of perpetrators and Administrative Marginalization Purges, lustration and
victims, and society as a whole). of authoritarian vetting
While some of the classifications just men- elites and
tioned are quite useful, others offer false collaborators
dilemmas. In effect, ‘transitional justice mech- Institutional Democratization Institutional reform,
civil and political
anisms are not a dichotomous choice but a
rights
continuum of options, and those countries that Redistributive Socio-economic Socio-economic
choose one option are more likely to choose justice rights,
others as well’ (Sikkink and Walling, 2007: redistribution,
442). In both Latin America and Europe, for affirmative action
example, transitional justice processes have Source: With the exception of ‘redistributive transitional
often been (and still are) multilayered affairs, justice’, these categories are adapted from Teitel (2000).
crafted so as to be simultaneously retributive
and restorative, retrospective and prospective,
confidential and public, etc. collective ‘rebirth’ that – perhaps more than
Luckily, other more detailed classifications any other instance of transitional justice –
are also available. The one presented in Table effectively build ‘a permanent, unmistakable
27.1 divides transitional justice into six differ- wall between the new beginnings and the old
ent sub-types distinguished according to the tyranny’ (Kirchheimer, 1961: 308). Criminal
different objectives and methods involved. transitional justice, however, is also highly
controversial. Supporters and opponents rou-
tinely confront each other over the appropri-
‘Criminal’ transitional justice ateness of criminal prosecution of former
undemocratic rulers and their agents. What is
Criminal transitional justice refers to the more, even advocates of transitional justice
prosecution by an official judiciary body (be often disagree on whether punishment should
it domestic, international or hybrid) of the be more important than truth (or vice-versa),
previous authoritarian regime’s individual and on whether criminal transitional justice
leaders and agents allegedly responsible for should be a purely domestic or an interna-
human rights abuse. It is largely retrospective tional affair.
and generally focuses on crimes committed In practice, however, criminal transitional
by single individuals. Its main purpose is justice choices are not always clear-cut. As
retribution – that is, the punishment of indi- Teitel points out, countries’ experiences with
vidual perpetrators. criminal transitional justice often result in the
Criminal transitional justice continues to so-called ‘limited criminal sanction’ –
attract the greatest attention of scholars and that is, in ‘prosecution processes [carried
activists, since public trials of former dicta- out by official judiciary bodies] that do not
tors often provide spectacular occasion of necessarily culminate in full punishment’

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 501

(Teitel, 2000: 47).13 Furthermore, external Finally, criminal transitional justice highlights
intervention in national criminal transitional individual rather than collective blame. This,
justice processes currently consists, not only in turn, deters ‘people’s’ justice; prevents
of the establishment of international criminal destructive cycles of collective reprisals, and
courts à la Nuremberg, but also of hybrid even eases the social divisions that led to mass
national/international courts and/or financial atrocities in the first place (Boraine, 2006: 19;
and technical assistance to domestic prosecu- Teitel, 2000: 28–30).
tion efforts. Supporters of criminal transitional justice
Supporters point to several positive features often debate the following question: should
of criminal transitional justice. First, it sup- perpetrators be brought before the domestic
plies the most effective deterrent of mass courts of the nation where the atrocities were
atrocities,14 because transitional criminal jus- committed, or should they be prosecuted
tice not only prevents established or would-be through international criminal justice?
perpetrators from returning to positions of Those who privilege domestic criminal jus-
authority, but it also credibly threatens them tice15 point to several benefits that derive
with serious personal consequences in case from holding public trials of perpetrators in
they attempt to do so. Second, trials of former and by the same country where the mass
dictators often constitute victims’ most pressing atrocities took place. First, domestic trials
transitional justice demand. Thus, democratiz- provide both a formal mechanism to confront
ing societies seeking to attend to victims’ needs past atrocities, and a means to rebuild a
promote trials of former dictators and their secure, just, and liberal new order (see
agents as a way to restore dignity and respect to Rothenberg, 2002; Teitel, 2000). In short,
those who suffered at the hands of the former they help establish a new government’s dem-
regime (Rothenberg, 2002). Third, criminal ocratic credentials. Second, domestic trials
transitional justice often fulfills a state’s inter- advance the rule of law, since the latter
national obligation under customary interna- requires that civilized societies carry out,
tional law and international treaty – especially ‘within defined but principled limits, prose-
in case of mass atrocities (Orentlicher, 1991). cution of especially atrocious crimes [… to
In other words, through criminal transitional unequivocally reaffirm] the authority of law
justice, democratizing societies effectively itself’ (Orentlicher, 1991). Third, domestic
signal their adoption of universally recognized trials powerfully underscore a new democra-
standards of human rights (Finnemore and cy’s break with the past. They constitute
Sikkink, 1998). Fourth, through ‘secular rites ‘foundational and forward-looking affirma-
of commemoration’ (Osiel, 1997, 2000: 6), tion that no group, including public officials
criminal transitional justice promotes the kind and the armed forces, is above the law and
of behavioral change that is most conducive to that the new democracy will not tolerate such
democratic stability over time, and re-crafts behavior’ (Brody, 2001). Moreover, they pro-
post-authoritarian societies’ political identity vide ‘a ritual of liberalizing states. […]
in a more democratic fashion (Sarat and Through known, fixed processes, a line is
Kearns, 1999: 2). Fifth, criminal transitional drawn, liberating a past that allows the soci-
justice prevents impunity and, in so doing, ety to move forward’ (Teitel, 2000: 67).
promotes reconciliation. In contrast, ‘allowing Fourth, domestic trials ensure that control
for impunity for those responsible [of mass over transitional justice remains at home.
atrocities …] is not a good strategy of recon- Conversely, when trials take place abroad,
ciliation because it rests upon an uncertain ownership of the transitional justice process
foundation. It is like a house built on shifting is effectively in the hands of foreign actors
sand. Sooner or later, it will collapse because whose interests may diverge from those of
the [past] will return’ (Rothenberg, 2002) the affected society. Finally, only domestic
to reignite conflict among old enemies. trials can effectively fulfill the ‘national’

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


502 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

pedagogical purpose exemplified by the far more toward democratic transition than the
motto ‘never again’. punishment of prior leaders and their follow-
Supporters of international criminal justice ers’ (Siegel, 1998). Third, individual trials are
counter with the following arguments. First, ‘ill suited to communal conflicts characterized
they point out how international criminal by the targeting and terrorizing of civilian
justice is relatively immune from domestic populations, neighbor attacking neighbor, and
political pressure. Both international conven- the breakdown of societal structures’ (Gready,
tions and customary international law, in fact, 2005: 6; see also Fletcher and Weinstein,
effectively ‘remove certain atrocious crimes 2002). Fourth, trials may rule out alternative
from the provincial realm of a country’s inter- measures of transitional justice and, in turn,
nal politics, and thereby place those crimes reduce a country’s flexibility in addressing the
squarely within the scope of universal concern complexity of its post-authoritarian predica-
and the conscience of all civilized people’ ment. Thus, for example, when emerging
(Orentlicher, 1991).16 Second, domestic legal democracies employ criminal trials as the
systems in democratizing contexts are often principal tool to establish a historical record of
either unwilling or unable to prosecute perpe- the undemocratic experience, they risk sacri-
trators of mass atrocities. When this is the ficing individual rights on the altar of society’s
case, international criminal justice can (and need for an official interpretation of the past
must) step in – with or without the agreement that may foster political stability. In short,
of the country in question. Third, international ‘trials run the risk of being perceived as
criminal justice is likely to offer wider guaran- political justice’ (Teitel, 2000: 76) rather than
tees of impartiality, equal protection under the as an honest search for the truth. Fifth, crimi-
law and due process for the accused than nal transitional justice does not eliminate the
domestic courts in post-authoritarian contexts. problem of shared guilt. Thus, when both
Finally, international proceedings may bolster opposition groups and governmental forces
domestic criminal transitional justice efforts, committed mass atrocities (and many ordinary
by effectively urging national courts in post- people served as indirect accomplices) ‘a gen-
authoritarian societies to take on litigation of eral amnesty for all provides a far stronger
previously barred cases (as it recently hap- base for democracy than efforts to prosecute
pened in Chile, Argentina, and Chad; see one side or the other’ (Huntington, 1991: 214).
Dicker and Keppler, 2004). Sixth, atrocities committed by a former
Opponents of criminal transitional justice authoritarian regime were often perfectly legal
rely on several realist-type arguments. First at the time they were perpetrated. Criminal
and foremost, they argue that a transitional trials, therefore, are often carried out on the
pact negating justice for the victims of past questionable basis of ex-post facto law, which
mass atrocities is often the necessary precur- negates the very same principle of nullo crime
sor of the political order required for success- sine lege (there’s no crime without a previ-
ful democratization (see Snyder and Vinjamuri, ously established law) that a new democratic
2003). In effect, to induce tyrants to relinquish regime is supposed to uphold. Finally, since it
power without making their people suffer fur- is virtually impossible to indict all perpetra-
ther, new democratic governments have often tors of mass atrocities, criminal transitional
been willing to negotiate a bargain with the justice is often reduced to selective prosecu-
‘devil’. These type of bargains usually provide tion of emblematic cases which often consti-
former rulers with concrete guarantees rang- tutes injustice (Brody, 2001) and – what is
ing from impunity for past crimes worse – undermines a new democracy’s rule
(e.g., Spain), to continuing influence over the of law.
political, military and international affairs of When international prosecution of perpetra-
the nation (e.g., Chile.) Second, opponents of tors of mass atrocities is at stake, opponents
criminal transitional justice often point out rely on at least four additional arguments.
that institutional reform17 often ‘contributes First, by keeping the specter of prosecution

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 503

alive (including for those alleged perpetrators parties, rather than through courtroom confron-
who were granted amnesty at the national tation. Its main goal is not to declare a winner,
level) – international criminal justice unduly but to heal old wounds and prevent past pat-
interferes with the legitimate political choice terns of conflict and atrocities from recurring in
by democratically elected governments to the future (Boraine, 2006: 20–21).
forgive perpetrators of mass atrocities, rather When it involves a government-sponsored
than prosecute them (see Kissinger, 2001; official public body of inquiry – for example, a
Nino, 1991). It does so by effectively placing ‘truth commission’ – historical transitional jus-
national politicians (including democratically tice presents a few similarities with criminal
elected ones) under the supervision of une- trials. Like trials, in fact, truth commissions
lected foreign judges (Kissinger, 2001). focus on past wrongdoings, and provide highly
Second, international prosecution undermines symbolic public rituals of political transforma-
national extra-judicial reconciliation efforts tion. Unlike trials, however, truth commissions
carried out by a newly democratic society to lack many of the powers associated with tribu-
deal with its questionable past (Kissinger, nals; include non-judiciary membership; inves-
2001). Third, where international tribunals tigate ‘a pattern of abuses over a period of time
have been created (e.g., former Yugoslavia or (rather than a specific event)’ (Hayner, 2002:
Rwanda,) they have proven highly ineffective 14); explore institutional or group responsibil-
in deterring subsequent human rights abuses ity (rather than just individual ones); refrain
(Snyder and Vinjamuri, 2003). Finally, inter- from meting out punishment; make a point of
national criminal justice predominantly reflect addressing victims’ specific needs through
western values, with little or no concern for public testimony; construct pedagogical narra-
indigenous methods of conflict resolution.18 tives designed to promote democratization and
national reconciliation; and are often empow-
ered to recommend – not only amnesty for
perpetrators – but also much needed repara-
‘Historical’ transitional justice
tions and/or memorialization for individual
In general, historical transitional justice refers victims, as well as institutional and cultural
to the efforts by a new democracy to officially reforms for the whole of society.
pursue and publicize the truth about the former While trials and truth commissions are often
authoritarian/totalitarian regime, often after portrayed in the literature as alternative to each
long periods of state-sponsored denial or amne- other, they need not be. Indeed, criminal transi-
sia. Historical transitional justice is restorative, tional justice and historical transitional justice
in the sense that it seeks to establish the truth mechanisms often operate simultaneously in
about the former regime, rather than the pun- the same country, in a fashion that is both com-
ishment of perpetrators. By focusing on the plementary and cooperative. See, for example,
past, historical transitional justice is also largely the cases of Argentina (where the work of the
retrospective. In contrast to trials, it represents CONADEP19 was later used as a basis for
a non-adversarial process that links ‘historical criminal prosecution of military leaders) or
judgment with a potential consensus […] pred- South Africa (where the judiciary was man-
icated on the truth’s dissemination and accept- dated to prosecute individuals who refused to
ance in the public sphere’ (Teitel, 2000: 81–83, appear before the Truth and Reconciliation
emphasis added). Furthermore, it is designed to Commission.)
go beyond the objective or factual truth typical Supporters point to at least five advantages
of trials, by pursuing not only the personal of historical transitional justice. First, histori-
truth of victims, but also a social truth that may cal transitional justice often constitutes the
later provide the basis for a shared national col- most effective means to uncover the truth
lective memory. Finally, historical transitional about a country’s difficult past. Thus, while
justice is achieved through dialogue, transpar- ‘the purpose of criminal trials is […] to find
ency, and the participation of all interested out whether the criminal standard of proof has

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


504 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

been satisfied on specific charges’ (Hayner, of the deceased). In short, ‘the report of a
2002: 100–1), a truth commission’s main truth commission reclaims a country’s
task is instead to expose the factual truth. history and opens it for public review’ (Hayner,
Moreover, historical transitional justice often 2002: 25).
provides the sole available tool to pursue the Opposition against historical transitional
truth about the past, especially in countries justice comes from several sources, includ-
where the democratic transition is the result of ing: champions of institutionalized amnesia;
a ‘pact’ between authoritarian rulers and mental health experts; post-modernist schol-
democratizing agents; the judiciary is com- ars; victims and human rights activists.
promised or in shambles; and the perpetrators Supporters of institutionalized amnesia argue
are too many (Hayner, 2002: 12). Thus, where that ‘forgetting’ is also a legitimate – if not
transitional criminal ‘justice is not possible necessary – transitional justice choice. In
due to force majeure or other considerations, effect, in many post-authoritarian countries21
then the second best process is that of maxi- ‘where collective political catastrophes have
mum discovery and dissemination of truth taken place, the institutional response has
which gives authoritative testimony to crimes been to forget and to neutralize what hap-
and violations of rights’ (Siegel, 1998). pened’ (Marques et al., 1997: 254–55).
Second, while trials generally aim to establish Moreover, amnesia may sometimes be neces-
individual responsibility, historical transitional sary because as Nietzsche instructs us:
justice seeks to uncover systematic patterns of it is altogether impossible to live at all without
abuse, as well as clarify the role of state insti- forgetting. […] There is a degree of sleeplessness,
tutions – for example, the military, the police, of rumination, of the historical sense, which is
the judiciary, and so forth – in committing or harmful and ultimately fatal to the living thing,
covering up mass atrocities. Historical transi- whether this […] be a man or a people or a culture
(Nietzsche, 1997: 62).
tional justice ‘thus emerges as the leading
mechanism to cope with the evil of the modern Mental health experts, on their part, caution
repressive state’ (Teitel, 2000: 78). Third, that public testimony about their ordeal might
unlike trials, historical transitional justice re-traumatize victims of abuse, especially when
mechanisms (such as truth commissions) the latter already suffer from post-traumatic
may be charged with broader and forward- stress disorder. ‘When victims are asked to
looking tasks, such as: the elaboration of an relate the details of their heart-wrenching
official national narrative of the past; com- story in one sitting, and are then given no fol-
memoration of and reparations to victims; low-up support, the emotional and psycho-
recommendations for institutional and cultural logical impact can be great’ (Hayner, 2002:
reform, and ‘non-judicial sanctions against 141). Post-modernist scholars claim that his-
named [perpetrators,] such as banning them torical transitional justice’s objective of uncov-
from public positions of authority’ (Hayner, ering the ‘truth’ is hopeless – when not
2002: 132). Fourth, especially in post-civil misguided. This is because an ‘official’ truth is
war situations, historical transitional justice also inevitably a partial one. From this point of
is well suited to investigate all sides’ atrocities view, then, ‘transitions are vivid instances of
simultaneously and – in so doing – promote conscious historical production […] in a height-
a culture of evenhandedness that may, in ened political context and driven by political
the end, ‘create the moral climate in which purposes’ (Teitel, 2000: 70) where not all
reconciliation and peace will flourish.’20 voices are necessarily heard. Furthermore, cer-
Finally, historical transitional justice funda- tain key aspects of the truth – such as
mentally promotes official acknowledgement international complicity in coups d’état or
of a country’s difficult past through testimony in the state’s persecution of political
by the heretofore oppressed (i.e., the former opponents – cannot be realistically unveiled
regime’s surviving victims, and the families by purely domestic historical transitional

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 505

justice. In a similar vein, victims often criti- some form of material or symbolic recompense
cize historical transitional justice’s ‘hidden’ for that which cannot be returned, such as
goal of ‘reconciliation’ as both misguided and human life, culture, and identity’ (Barkan,
immoral. In particular, they claim that histori- 2002). And apology refers ‘to an admission of
cal transitional justice mechanisms that offer wrongdoing; a recognition of its effects; and –
forgiveness to perpetrators without their in some cases – an acceptance of responsibil-
explicit consent only deliver ‘reconciliation ity for those effects and an obligation to its
without justice’ (see Mamdani, 1996). On victims’ (Barkan, 2002). Reparatory transi-
their part, legal scholars warn that (especially tional justice also often entails official public
when they name perpetrators) truth commis- acts of rehabilitation and/or commemoration
sions – to all intents and purposes – convict of individual victims that greatly contribute to
suspects without due process (José Maria shaping the new political identity of the
Zalaquett, quoted in Heyner, 2002: 127–29). incoming democratic regime. Concrete exam-
In other words, they illegitimately perform as ples of reparatory transitional justice thus
judicial bodies, assigning guilt and distribut- range from financial payment, to the creation
ing punishment without, however, giving of memorials for those persecuted by the pre-
alleged perpetrators a fair chance to defend vious undemocratic regime; from reintegra-
themselves. Finally, human rights activists tion of stolen property, to public and official
often criticize historical transitional justice as admission of government wrongdoing; from
a stratagem to avoid trials for alleged perpetra- the establishment of public holidays in honor
tors of mass atrocities. In this view, a govern- of the dead, to a thorough revision of the con-
ment-sponsored truth commission search for temporary history curriculum taught in public
‘truth’ and ‘reconciliation’ only disguises a schools; and so forth.
politically expedient amnesty. The policy debate on reparatory transitional
justice centers on the following issues: the
identity and size of its target population (small
‘Reparatory’ transitional number of individuals vs. entire victim
groups); the forms of reparation (symbolic
justice
vs. material); and their magnitude (how much
Reparatory transitional justice deals with the and for how long?) Thus, for example, while
moral and material rehabilitation of specific some countries have awarded substantial
individuals (or groups) singled out for persecu- financial reparation to a restricted group of
tion by the former authoritarian regime (see individual victims (e.g., Chile), others have
Elster, 1998). It is, therefore, victim-centered – opted for smaller monetary payments to a
in the sense that its main purpose is not the larger population (e.g., Argentina). And in at
punishment of perpetrators, but the restoration least one instance (e.g., Germany) a consider-
of citizenship and dignity to the casualties of able sum was disbursed to a broad-based
the dictatorship, so that they (and their fami- group of victims (of the Holocaust) Moreover,
lies) may be fully reintegrated into the new whereas some countries have opted for sub-
political order. Reparatory transitional justice stantial financial compensation (Argentina),
is retrospective, as it largely focuses on others (South Africa) have chosen more sym-
redressing past wrongs. It also generally bolic reparations on account of the large
involves accurately targeted acts of symbolic number of victims involved. Finally, while
as well as material restitution, compensation some countries have granted monetary pay-
and apology. Restitution ‘strictly refers to the ments exclusively to abuse victims, others
return of the specific actual belongings that have awarded a wide range of reparations
were confiscated, seized, or stolen, such as (such as life-long pensions or even substantial
[real estate], land, art, remains, and the like’ welfare and educational benefits) not only to
(Barkan, 2002: xix). Compensation ‘refers to victims, but also to their descendants.

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


506 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

According to supporters, there are at least ‘Administrative’ transitional


four reasons why reparatory transitional jus- justice
tice serves the public interest during demo-
cratic transition. First, it provides concrete Administrative transitional justice attempts
evidence of a state’s acknowledgement of to ‘redefine the parameters of political mem-
responsibility for its past wrongdoing (Teitel, bership, participation, and leadership that
2000: 127), which is often one of victims’ constitute the political community’ in democ-
most pressing demands of the new demo- ratizing societies (Teitel, 2000: 8). In prac-
cratic government. Second, reparatory transi- tice, it seeks to marginalize former ruling
tional justice has a direct and immediate elites, so that they cannot exercise any influ-
impact on victims’ lives, by providing ‘a ence over the new democracy in the future. It
most tangible manifestation of the state’s also seeks to penalize those employed in the
effort to remedy the harms they (or their public (and sometimes also in the private)
loved ones) have suffered’ (Boraine, 2006: sector who collaborated or compromised
24). Moreover, reparatory transitional justice with the former undemocratic regime. Finally,
helps victims regain the reputation and administrative transitional justice seeks to
resources needed to regain active citizenship reintegrate/rehabilitate those who had been
in the new democracy. Third, reparatory tran- ‘purged’ by the dictatorship on political
sitional justice corrects the former regime’s grounds. Historically, administrative transi-
‘derogation from equal protection under the tional justice has taken on different names.
law’ (Teitel, 2000: 126). In so doing, it also Post-World War II France and Italy carried
helps restore the collective faith in the rule of out ‘epuration’ and ‘purghe’, respectively,
law that the dictatorship had previously shat- while post-communist Eastern European
tered. Finally – especially when it takes countries chose ‘lustration’ or ‘vetting’.
the form of solemn public rituals, holidays, Purges refer first and foremost to the removal
monuments, or memorials – reparatory of all people associated with the earlier
transitional justice reshapes the national undemocratic regime from positions in gov-
identity in a more democratic fashion. ernment, politics, education, media, culture,
In this sense, it is an important component business, and other sensitive professional sec-
of the tool kit known as ‘symbolic tors. Lustration (or vetting) refers instead to
politics’, whose importance in democratizing ‘the procedures for screening persons seeking
contexts is well established in the social selected public positions for their involvement
science literature. with the [previous undemocratic] regime’
Reparatory transitional justice is likely to (Letki, 2002: 530–31), ‘and/or for their ‘integ-
face opposition when it appears to be tied to rity – including adherence to relevant human
impunity for perpetrators of mass atrocities rights standards’ (International Center for
and/or fails to be accompanied by any form Transitional Justice, 2008).
of truth-telling. In other words, restitution, Administrative transitional justice is
compensation, apologies, and memorializa- strongly demanded by both victims and
tion are generally rejected by victims when- opponents of the previous dictatorship, as
ever such measures are perceived as a well as by dedicated supporters of demo-
governmental payoff in exchange for cratic reform. ‘Particularly in the security
their acquiescence to amnesty or national and justice sectors, [administrative transi-
amnesia. Finally, reparatory transitional jus- tional justice] is widely recognized as helpful
tice’s targeted and one-off features raise in reestablishing civic trust and re-legitimiz-
eyebrows among those seeking broader and ing abusive public institutions, disabling
long-lasting socio-economic reforms of post- structures within which individuals carried
authoritarian societies. out serious abuses, and removing obstacles to

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 507

transitional reform’ (International Center for regime – especially when the previous
Transitional Justice, 2008). Supporters point undemocratic government involved a sub-
to several benefits of administrative transi- stantial proportion of citizens only guilty of
tional justice. First, it effectively restores minor wrongdoing (such as membership in
public confidence in government institutions the previously dominant political party.)
after a period of state-sponsored abuses. ‘The Second, administrative transitional justice
public may reasonably be skeptical when jeopardizes the smooth functioning of the
told they will now be treated differently, if state, especially during the pivotal transition
these institutions simply retain all their exist- period. This is not only because the targets of
ing personnel. These, after all, are the same epuration often possess critical expertise to
people who kept the engine of the repressive run the government, but also because some
state operating’ (Kritz, 1995). Second, renew- of them (e.g., judges) are hardly replaceable
ing personnel in the public administration in the short run. Third, legal experts under-
and other visible sectors of the state, busi- score that administrative transitional justice
ness, media, and cultural establishments is often consists of ‘the imposition of punitive
one of the most effective tools to communi- measures without full judicial process’
cate to the public at large that a break with (Teitel, 2000: 159). When this is the case,
the past has finally occurred. Third, adminis- administrative transitional justice sends the
trative transitional justice contributes to ease wrong message – that is, that the new democ-
the democratic transition. This is because racy will not shy away from undemocratic
loyal employees from the previous undemo- measures in order to settle accounts with the
cratic regime will be – at best – less than previous regime. Finally, administrative transi-
enthusiastic supporters of democratic reform tional justice can be – and in practice often is –
and – at worse – active saboteurs of the new abused for political motives (Kritz, 1995) – for
regime. Hence, their removal can only speed example, to reward supporters or clients,
up democratic reform. Finally, it makes sense eliminate unwanted competition for public
for the new democratic government to office, or push through a particular set of poli-
distribute key jobs in the public service, cies that would not otherwise be implemented.
not only to those who supported the opposi- When this is the case, the new democracy’s
tion struggle, but also to individuals who practices will suspiciously resemble those of
demonstrate a solid record of competence the previous undemocratic regime.
and professionalism.
Administrative transitional justice has
many critics. First and foremost it is vehe- ‘Institutional’ transitional
mently rejected by members and collaborators
justice
of the previous undemocratic regime –
for obvious reasons. However, it is also Institutional transitional justice endeavors to
frequently opposed by those who passively re-establish peace and order through behav-
acquiesced to its policies and actions, espe- ioral change. More specifically, it creates
cially when the dictatorship was widely institutions and procedures to ‘engender a
popular and lasted for many years (as in pattern of behavior which […] ultimately
the case of post-World War II Italy and reshapes political culture and common con-
Germany). Administrative transitional justice ceptions of justice, as actors bring their
is criticized by scholars and practitioners beliefs into harmony with their actions’
on several additional grounds. First, exces- (Sa’adah, 1998: 3). In practice, institutional
sively broad sweeps of administrative transi- transitional justice promotes democratic
tional justice often end up alienating the reform in key areas such as: the rule of law;
general population from the new democratic separation of powers; checks and balances;

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


508 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

legal codes; access to the legal profession contraband a set of institutional reforms they
and the police; civil and political rights; and would have to adopt anyway as justice for the
so forth. In contrast to other sub-types, insti- victims of earlier state repression.
tutional transitional justice is largely Scholars concur that, ‘from a transitional
prospective,22 and more concerned with the perspective, what is considered constitution-
good of society as a whole, than with the fate ally just is contextual and contingent, relat-
of individual perpetrators and victims. ing to the attempt to transform legacies of
Supporters list the following benefits of past injustice’ (Teitel, 2000: 196). In other
institutional transitional justice. First, it is one words, ‘constitutionalism’ is often regarded
of the most effective means to achieve regime as part and parcel of transitional justice
change, because – since democracy is largely because post-authoritarian reforms are also
a matter of incentives – when ‘domestic fac- often motivated by a society’s desire to
tors durably cripple the reproductive capaci- redress the abuses of the previous regime.
ties of a fallen dictatorship and replace the Others, however, reject this overlap between
dictatorship’s institutions with democratic transitional justice and institutional reform as
ones, then the dictatorship is finished’ an unnecessary conceptual muddle, under-
(Sa’adah, 1998: 280). Second, institutional scoring that – in the context of democratiza-
transitional justice is necessary, because ‘to tion – the notion of institutional transitional
achieve a just society, more than punishment justice is often a clever spin to conceal a
is required. […] Equally important is the need deliberate (albeit perfectly legitimate) politi-
to begin transforming institutions: institutional cal choice: that of foregoing transitional
structures must not impede the commitment to justice altogether.
consolidating democracy and establishing a Undoubtedly, the relationship between tran-
culture of human rights’ (Boraine, 2006: 20). sitional justice and institutional reform is
Third, institutional transitional justice is less difficult to disentangle. On the one hand, tran-
contentious than other kinds of transitional sitional justice frequently requires key institu-
justice, because it does not target any specific tional changes to be implemented. What is
group or individual and is often perceived as more, in cases where former authoritarian
part of the ‘package deal’ of democratization. elites maintain significant power, democrati-
Fourth, because it focuses on feasible short zation must precede transitional justice. Few,
run objectives, institutional transitional justice in fact, would dispute that the trial of a former
is likely to register immediate results and, in dictator serves transitional justice’s purpose
turn, increase popular support for the new better if carried out by reformed courts and
democratic regime. judicial procedures, rather than by the same
Detractors point out several shortcomings judiciary institutions or personnel that actively
of institutional transitional justice. First, it collaborated with the previous authoritarian
fails to affect victims’ lives in any direct fash- regime; or that a truth commission carries
ion, as it is only concerned with what is good greater legitimacy if established by a demo-
for society as a whole. Second, it neglects to cratically elected executive or legislative,
persuade new democracies to learn from rather than by the arbitrary fiat of an interim
their difficult past. Indeed, because it is unelected administration or an external occu-
largely forward-looking, institutional transi- pation force; or that financial or symbolic
tional justice spares former authoritarian reparations to individual victims of the former
societies the necessary introspection that regime acquire greater significance if inher-
may lead them to acknowledge past mis- ited authoritarian patterns of systematic social
takes. Finally, to most human rights activists, and economic discrimination are also simulta-
institutional transitional justice is no justice neously eliminated. On the other hand, for-
at all, but rather a cunning attempt on the part ward-looking institutional engineering stands
of new pragmatic ‘democratic’ leaders to to acquire greater popular legitimacy when

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 509

complemented by sincere efforts to confront and economic rights (e.g., fiscal and welfare
a traumatic authoritarian past. When all is reform) to wide-ranging redistribution (e.g.,
said and done, then, it may be a good idea nationalization of major economic and indus-
to keep transitional justice and constitutional- trial sectors; land reform; etc.) and affirmative
ism conceptually separate while, at the same action programs. In its most radical form,23
time, paying close attention to their close – redistributive transitional justice aims to level
and often necessary – connections. the social and economic playing field so as to
approximate equality.
Needless to say, redistributive transitional
‘Redistributive’ transitional justice undermines the entrenched socio-
economic interests of former ruling elites and
justice
privileged classes. Therefore;
Redistributive transitional justice aims to the challenge for transitional [redistributive] justice
‘redress not only the direct abuses perpetrated […] is even more daunting than preventing revenge
in conflict, but also their social and economic and forgetting, or promoting democratic account-
[…] consequences and ramifications’ (Mani, ability. It must grapple too with people’s aspirations
2005: 523), so as to grant fairness and equal to reverse the legacy of socio-economic discrimina-
tion if it is to be meaningful to those most affected
opportunity to the broader array of victims of by past atrocities (Krieger, 2000: 65).
the dictatorship. To realize this goal, redis-
tributive transitional justice systematically As a result, new democracies rarely choose
addresses the socio-economic exploitation to carry out redistributive transitional
carried out by the former authoritarian regime. justice:
In so doing, it goes beyond an exclusive focus
This hesitation […] stems from a complex mix of
on victims and perpetrators of political vio- factors. They include: the risk of a backlash from
lence to include a broader range of actors – elite groups and powerful institutions opposed to
such as those who suffered from past redistribution; the fear of alienating the business
socio-economic discrimination, as well as community and scaring off foreign investment; the
those who benefited from it. Redistributive desire to safeguard individual liberty even at the
expense of equity; and the lack of resources to
transitional justice differs from the reparatory finance redistribution of assets or employment
sub-type mentioned earlier, because it focuses (Mani, 2002: 151).
more on the collective socio-economic dimen-
sion of authoritarian abuse. Thus, while on the Supporters list the following benefits of
one hand the state pursues reparatory justice redistributive transitional justice. First, it is
to correct individual wrongs and – in turn – the only kind of transitional justice that
restores the dignity of victims, on the other it directly addresses one of the most urgent
carries out redistributive justice to realize demands of post-authoritarian societies –
broader social objectives, such as: fairness, that of social justice. According to Mamdani
economic growth, political stability and even (2000);
a new collective national identity. when there has been a political community based
In practice, redistributive transitional jus- on conquest and dispossession, the task is to
tice seeks to improve the opportunity structure create a political community based on consent and
of individuals (or groups) that were deprived justice. […] Only social justice that underlines the
in the past by eliminating – through reform – empathy within a community of survivors can lay
the foundation of a new political community
existing ‘gross or unjustifiable inequalities in based on consent (pp. 182–83).
the distribution of, access to, and/or opportu-
nities for socio-economic […] power and their Second, by attending to victims’ material
accruing benefits’ (Mani, 2002: 127). Thus, needs – such as housing, health care, educa-
concrete redistributive transitional justice tion, employment, and so forth – redistributive
measures range from the introduction of social transitional justice is often ‘more significant to

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


510 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

their ability to lay the past to rest than testify- possess a great amount of financial resources,
ing before truth commissions or at trials’ redistributive transitional justice indirectly
(Fletcher, 2001: 434). Third, in directly weakens democratization efforts in other
addressing socio-economic disparity, redis- areas.
tributive transitional justice tackles one of the Does including redistribution into the
pre-eminent root causes of dictatorship and definition of transitional justice add to the
conflict. In so doing, it actively prevents the conceptual muddle mentioned earlier?24 If one
rise of authoritarianism in the future. Fourth, believes that the more the concept of transi-
because redistributive transitional justice tional justice embraces, the less analytically
actively promotes structural change, it offers a useful it becomes, the answer is yes. This
more solid and long-lasting solution for pre- chapter, however, argues in favor of including
venting future abuse than other kinds of tran- redistribution into the definition of transitional
sitional justice. Finally, redistributive justice, not only so that the latter may embrace
transitional justice contributes to economic fairness (in addition to truth and retribution),
growth, especially in those countries where but also because excluding it produces several
the authoritarian regime was actively protect- relevant drawbacks. First, it drastically reduces
ing a relatively small and indolent land- the number of those who may legitimately
owning oligarchy. In such contexts, in fact, claim victim status after the fall of a dictator-
the right mix of redistribution and liberaliza- ship. Second, it favors individual over group
tion policies can create the kind of small claims. And third, it conceives of democrati-
property-owner class that has historically zation in minimalist or ‘procedural’ terms,
provided the backbone of democracy around privileging civil and political rights over eco-
the world. nomic, social and cultural ones. At the same
Critics list at least four problems with time, one should keep in mind that equating
redistributive transitional justice. First, it is transitional justice with redistribution alone
likely to trigger a backlash from powerful presents negative consequences as well,
elite groups opposed to redistribution. Thus, because it discourages a new democratic soci-
because democratic transition often impinges ety from confronting sources of tension unre-
on the collaboration of such elites, redistribu- lated to socio-economic factors, or promoting
tive transitional justice directly jeopardizes the full moral and political rehabilitation of
regime change. Second, even when domestic individual victims of the former authoritarian
elites consent to it, redistributive transitional regime.
justice still alienates the international business
and financial community and – in turn –
discourages foreign investment. Thus,
because a new democracy’s longevity is EXPLAINING TRANSITIONAL
often tied to its initial economic success, JUSTICE
redistributive transitional justice weakens
democratic stability by undermining the new Transitional justice is potentially shaped by
regime’s economic potential. Third, with its several factors – for example, the specific
emphasis on equality, redistributive transi- political circumstances surrounding a coun-
tional justice sacrifices individual liberty on try’s democratization; the political culture
the altar of social justice. This, in turn, under- prevalent at the time; the unique legacies of
mines the new regime’s legitimacy in the injustice inherited from previous authoritar-
eyes of many. Finally, redistributive transi- ian regimes; the number and nature of the
tional justice requires considerable invest- actors involved; and so forth.25 Most scholars
ment to finance a redistribution of assets or note that the wide array of causal variables
employment (Mani, 2002: 151). Because and the marked ‘context-dependence’ of tran-
post-authoritarian societies do not often sitional justice provide insuperable obstacles

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 511

to the formulation of covering laws (Elster, This is because ‘pacted’ transitions necessar-
2004: 77).26 Consequently, there is also little ily imply a compromise with former dicta-
consensus in the field both in terms of theory tors, who often hold the upper hand during
and policy. Disagreements notwithstanding, the negotiations. In contrast, when democra-
several arguments currently offer useful tization results out of a ‘collapse’ of the
insights into the determinants of transitional authoritarian regime, dictators are severely
justice, providing precious practical knowl- weakened (by either vigorous internal oppo-
edge for those countries still hoping to settle sition or external intervention) and, in turn,
accounts with their difficult past. transitional justice is more likely to take
Political scientists usually seek to explain place (see Huntington, 1968; O’Donnell
what determines a post-authoritarian socie- et al., 1986). This theory is quite powerful in
ty’s transitional justice choices, why differ- explaining why different democratizing
ent countries adopt different paths of countries make different transitional justice
transitional justice, and why the same coun- choices (including amnesia). It emphasizes
try may choose different transitional justice the distribution of power between incoming
strategies at different times. They also often and outgoing elites, while largely discount-
provide recommendations on which transi- ing the influence of civil society. It regards
tional justice measures are most effective in a transitional justice essentially as a one-shot
particular case. Compared to other scholars’, bargaining game between departing authori-
political scientists’ work on transitional jus- tarian rulers and new democratic leaders.
tice tends to be theoretically ambitious and And it claims that transitional justice merely
empirically sound. However, also among reflects power relations and material inter-
political scientists, there is ample disagree- ests, rather than universal moral principles.
ment. The greatest divide is between ‘realist’ While undoubtedly appealing, this theory
students of international relations and ‘con- can be challenged on several fronts. First and
structivist’ human rights scholars. Realists foremost, recent events in Spain and Chile
insist that; ‘in a world of failed states and show that even the most ‘pacted’ of transitions
weak institutions – a world where politics in is – in the long turn – vulnerable to transitional
fact often trumps law – prosecutors should justice, as both civil society and the interna-
show deference to responsible political lead- tional community resist institutionalized
ers who have the skills and the mandate to amnesia for very long periods of time.
make choices based on prudence and politi- Conversely, in countries where the authoritar-
cal consequences’ (Snyder and Vinjamuri, ian regimes ‘collapsed’ as a result of military
2006). Constructivists, in contrast, claim defeat and occupation, transitional justice has
that transitional justice does not inadvert- often been only timid or pro-forma (e.g., Japan
ently promote atrocities, increase human and Austria). Second, the empirical evidence
rights violations, exacerbate conflict or reveals, not only that most post-authoritarian
threaten democracy (see Sikkink and Walling, countries have carried out some form of transi-
2007). tional justice, but also that citizens of recent
A first theory that holds both theoretical democracies have often rejected ‘pacts’ at the
breadth and scholarly appeal among political polls on moral principle, by rewarding demo-
scientists focuses on the nature of the demo- cratic leaders who promised to deliver – if not
cratic transition. Thus, when the latter is the end of injustice – at least the best available
‘pacted’ (as in the cases of Spain and Chile), treatment for it (e.g., Argentina). Finally, several
transitional justice is more likely to be countries’ experience bears witness to the fact
eschewed or consist exclusively of proce- that even a ‘pacted’ democratization is not
dural democratic reforms (institutional tran- merely a pragmatic, forward-looking agreement
sitional justice) and/or timid investigations among old and new elites to rewrite the rules
of the past (historical transitional justice). of the political game (see Przeworski, 1986).

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


512 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

It can also provide an ambitious social process empirically minded social scientists who
of confronting and re-interpreting the past that contend that it is virtually impossible to
heals a divided political community (e.g., verify whether or not a norm has concretely
South Africa). When it is all said and done, ‘cascaded’ and – in turn – been ‘internalized’
then, it would be more correct to say that on a global scale. It is nevertheless a power-
‘pacted’ transitions often dilute or delay transi- ful theory which ‘allows us to treat our moral
tional justice, rather than prevent it altogether. and legal values, including justice, as both
A second, and largely alternative, theory historically situated constructs and powerful
underscores the role of universal principles, tools for bringing about social and political
in general (and of international norms in par- change’ (Smiley, 2001: 1332).
ticular), in instigating transitional justice. Another set of theoretically ambitious –
More specifically, it holds that, in this day albeit widely divergent – arguments focuses
and age, new democracies are far more likely on the historical and cultural contexts of tran-
to embrace transitional justice than in the sitional justice. Thus, while some authors find
past because punishing former rulers for that ‘the nature and extent of past abuses does
human rights abuses is no longer just a moral not have any clear impact on transitional out-
imperative. Following the ‘Pinochet effect’27 comes’ (Sriram, 2005: 521), others argue that
and the establishment of the International transitional justice is more likely to be carried
Criminal Court, it is also an international out when the former authoritarian regime was
legal obligation that not only implies serious particularly oppressive and short-lived (Elster,
‘limits on the immunity of government offi- 2004: 75) (vs. relatively benign and long-
cials when hauled before national courts, lasting). Another group of scholars claims that
accused of international crimes, [… but also institutional continuity with the previous
mandates] that domestic laws enshrining regime provides a major obstacle to transi-
unfair trials or shielding perpetrators [be] tional justice (Cesarini, 2004). Thus, for exam-
subject to outside scrutiny’ (Roht-Arriaza, ple, when the same loyalists who faithfully
2005: 197–8). Echoing Finnemore and served the dictatorship remain at their posts,
Sikkink’s (1998) ‘Norm Life Cycle’ thesis, or when established ‘informal’ rules of the
this theory submits that – following the vari- game persist despite regime change, it is very
ous democratization ‘waves’ of the twentieth difficult for a new democratic government to
century – the norm concerning ‘crimes against implement any measure mandated by the tran-
humanity’ (which first surfaced at the post- sitional justice process. On their part, students
World War II Nuremberg Trials)28 has now of political culture underscore the need for a
been embraced by a critical mass of states – significant evolution of the collective authori-
that is, it has ‘cascaded’ (Lutz and Sikkink, tarian mentality that facilitated injustice in the
2001). It also implies that during the next and past. In this view, without an ‘active and ongo-
final phase of this norm’s life cycle – that of ing intellectual and emotional confrontation
‘internalization’ – transitional justice will with the experience of dictatorship’ (Sa’adah,
become ‘the prevailing standard of appropri- 1998: 4) that transforms subjects into citizens;
ateness against which new norms emerge and public diffidence into civic trust; and former
compete for support’ (Finnemore and Sikkink, enemies into legitimate political rivals, the
1998: 895). Finally, this theory explains dif- same undemocratic culture that led to atroci-
ferences among countries’ transitional justice ties in the past is likely to undermine any
choices in light of the different degree of future transitional justice effort.
‘internalization’ of the international norms Other theories focus on the influence of
concerning crimes against humanity. This specific actors (such as: the state, civil soci-
theory is vigorously rejected, not only by ety, political parties, international organiza-
‘realist’ scholars who doubt the relevance of tions, etc.) on transitional justice. Most
international regimes tout court, but also by scholars agree that the state is a key – if not

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:46:15 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 513

‘the’ key – actor of transitional justice. Only what is often perceived as unwarranted exter-
the state, in fact, can provide ‘a process of nal interference into delicate matters of
public reinterpretation of past horrors to national sovereignty.29
create a new national narrative about the past
and help frame a new vision for the future of
the community’ (Fletcher, 2001: 436). And
only the state can take responsibility for past THE IMPACT OF TRANSITIONAL
atrocities, make amends to victims, and JUSTICE
commit to prevent future human rights viola-
tions. Scholars, however, vigorously disagree According to several scholars, transitional
on the relevance of civil society. Thus, most justice is much more than the inert by-
human rights experts and activists argue that product of democratization: It plays an impor-
state-led transitional justice processes with tant transformative role in its own right.
little or no involvement by civil society are Transitional justice should thus be treated
either incomplete or doomed to failure. Other
in the following ways: first, as part of institutional
scholars, in contrast, claim that – on account life, rather than as an ideal imposed from above;
of its excessive idealism and unrealistic second, as infused with the practicalities of institu-
expectations – civil society-led transitional tional life, rather than as tainted by them; third, as
justice is generally impractical or (even manifested differently at various stages of history
and within distinct social and political institutions;
worse) counterproductive. Not in the least
and fourth, as a powerful tool for bringing about
because it often sets in motion judicial social and political change (Smiley, 2001: 1333).
processes that take on a life of their own.
These, in turn, risk disrupting the fragile This ‘constructivist’ notion of transitional
political balance that sustains democratiza- justice (best exemplified by Ruti Teitel’s
tion (see Kissinger, 2001; Nino, 1991). work)30 is unfortunately at odds with that
Analyzing the role of political parties, espoused by most political scientists.
Elster (2004) tentatively concludes that their Lamenting the ‘scant evidence on the rela-
influence on transitional justice ‘can be deci- tionships between choices made concerning
sive, but may also be limited by other politi- transitional justice and the outcomes sought’
cal actors’ (p. 245). Thus, traditional political (Siegel, 1998), political scientists are quick
parties are more likely to play a fundamental to conclude that ‘there is no strict causal link
role in the democratic transition and, in turn, between measures of retroactive justice and
champion transitional justice when they the nature of a newly established democratic
actively opposed the former authoritarian regime’ (de Brito et al., 2001: 35). They also
regime and became a main target of the lat- note that many countries have successfully
ter’s repression. Political parties’ support of achieved democratic consolidation despite
transitional justice, however, can be (and taking very different transitional justice
often is) weakened by contingent political paths. Finally, they point out that, because
circumstances – such as: the residual power numerous internal and external factors –
of outgoing authoritarian elites and/or the other than transitional justice choices – shape
military; international influences; and the long-term democratic development, it is
rise of new political organizations. Finally, almost impossible to pinpoint the direction of
there is little agreement among scholars causality between transitional justice and
regarding the influence of international actors democratization (see de Brito et al., 2001;
on transitional justice. While some conclude Snyder and Vinjamuri, 2003).
that international actors help democratizing These critiques are challenging indeed.
societies promote transitional justice (see Undeniably, the empirical evidence on the
Sriram, 2005), others find that the latter effects of transitional justice choices on new
might be delayed or deterred altogether by democracies is hard to come by. Nevertheless,

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


514 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

old and new democratic leaders alike continue of future conflict (Rothenberg, 2002), but
to agonize over transitional justice – in some also creates a political environment that is
cases, even several generations after the conducive to both civility and pragmatism. A
alleged mass atrocities took place. So, the third theory argues that transitional justice
question arises: Why do they do so, if they did benefits democracy by (re)creating the bonds
not sincerely believe that transitional justice of civic trust that authoritarianism dispensed
has a profound impact on their societies’ with. In so doing, it adds to the legitimacy of
future? As far as the assertion that democra- the new democratic government, and pro-
cies ‘consolidate’ despite making different motes confidence in the new democratic
transitional justice choices is concerned, it institutions (see Cesarini, 2004; Orentlicher,
would indeed be a lethal criticism were it not 1991). Yet another theory underscores that
for the fact that ‘consolidation’ is a vague and transitional justice benefits democracy by
contested concept in its own right. Furthermore, fostering the renewal of a society’s political
only rarely do transitional justice’s effects identity. In effect, transitional justice is often
become apparent during the time horizon associated with secular ceremonies that mark
associated with ‘consolidation’. Usually, much a definite break with the past, re-establish a
longer is needed, as many countries often lost sense of community; foster democratic
revisit and revise their transitional justice over attitudes; and celebrate regime change (see
time (see Sikkink and Walling, 2007) – some- Osiel, 1997, 2000).
times even several generations after the fact. On the other hand, there are scholars who
Finally, very few scholars – including con- believe that transitional justice harms post-
structivist ones – would argue that democrati- authoritarian democracies. Some claim that
zation outcomes are entirely dependent on transitional justice undermines the political
transitional justice choices. After all, good bargain struck between democratization’s
theories are less a matter of ‘artificial choice winners and losers. In so doing, it hurts
between key factors’, than a question of democracy by creating a source of political
specifying ‘how variables are joined together instability that may lead to military coups or
in specific historical instances’ (Katznelson, renewed civil war (Kissinger, 2001; Snyder
1997: 93; 99) – which is exactly what any and Vinjamuri, 2003). Others argue that tran-
good argument on the impact of transitional sitional justice harms democratization by pro-
justice should attempt to do. moting indiscriminate collective punishment.
Several scholars have sought to establish In so doing, it subtracts precious human capi-
whether transitional justice benefits or harms tal to the new regime, and may even produce
the democratization of post-authoritarian dangerous backlash against democracy.31 Yet
societies. Those who believe in the positive another theory submits that transitional justice
influence of transitional justice advance sev- involves acts of political justice which are, by
eral interesting arguments. A first theory sug- definition, unjust.32 In so doing, it undermines
gests that transitional justice benefits democracy by weakening the very same basic
democracy by ending impunity. Transitional principles of fairness that the new regime is
justice, in fact, eliminates undemocratic supposed to uphold.
actors from the political stage and promotes Unfortunately, to date only very few stud-
legality and accountability at the highest ies have focused on transitional justice’s
levels of government. A second theory claims long-term implications. Of these, most do not
that transitional justice benefits democracy even analyze transitional justice for its own
by providing the necessary precondition for sake. Rather, they do so incidentally, as part
the pacification between members of the of an overall effort to study post-authoritarian
former authoritarian regime and their vic- societies’ attempts to deal with their difficult
tims. In effect, transitional justice not only past. It is also interesting to note that, while
eliminates potentially destabilizing sources there are several theories on the causes of

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 18 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 515

transitional justice and its short-term impact, ways that directly affect democracy’s chances
only a handful of political scientists have and quality. Thus, different choices about
ventured to formulate hypotheses about the their past led Costa Rica and Nicaragua to
long-term impact of transitional justice. In very different political outcomes, whereby
this context, four works deserve particular the former is the most enduring democracy in
mention: Paloma Aguilar’s Memoria y Olvido Latin America, while the latter one of the
de la Guerra Civil Espanola (1996); Anne most unstable.
Sa’adah’s Germany’s Second Chance (1998); After a careful comparative analysis of the
Consuelo Cruz’s Political Culture and different ways in which Austria and Germany
Institutional Development in Costa Rica and dealt with the legacy of the Third Reich,
Nicaragua (2005); and David Art’s The David Art (2005) traces the long-term politi-
Politics of the Nazi Past in Germany and cal consequences of such differences. He
Austria (2005). concludes that, while Germany’s critical
Paloma Aguilar’s (1996) book analyzes the confrontation of its own Nazi past has
influence of the memory of the Civil War on prevented – thus far – far-right parties from
Spain’s democratic transition and beyond, and becoming permanent political forces in this
argues that the traumatic nature of the war’s country, Austrians’ stubborn denial of their
memory led Spain to choose amnesia over active role in the Third Reich created an envi-
retribution and truth. Aguilar also shows that ronment in which right-wing populist parties
Spain’s peculiar transitional justice choice – continue to meet significant electoral suc-
the ‘pacto del olvido’33 – and its political cess. Different choices about the Nazi past,
ramifications have become so enshrined in the then, led to very different political outcomes,
country’s institutions that they continue to whereby Germany appears to enjoy a higher
influence Spanish politics to the present day. quality of democracy than Austria.
In her book, Anne Sa’adah (1998) com- These excellent studies show that it is
pares the transitional justice processes in the indeed feasible and productive to theorize
Bonn Republic after the Third Reich with about transitional justice’s long-term impli-
that of post-unification Germany after the cations. They also confirm that ‘it is much
(East) German Democratic Republic (GDR) more interesting to examine […] what
experience. After thoughtful and detailed sequencing or judicious combination of tran-
analyses of the different transitional justice sitional justice mechanisms can help build
strategies in question, Sa’adah argues that the democracy and resolve conflicts’ (Sikkink
limited success of the Bonn Republic’s top- and Walling, 2007: 443), than focusing on
down institutional approach toward the Nazi the alleged short-term trade off between
past effectively set the stage for a remarkable peace and justice. Finally, these studies illus-
political learning process. She also shows trate how, in seeking to formulate broader
how, almost fifty years later, such learning theories (but not necessarily covering laws)
process bore fruit, leading reunified Germany of transitional justice, scholars should
to adopt more extensive and culturally based analyze the latter both as a key effect of a
transitional justice choices vis-à-vis the country’s democratic transition, and as a
GDR. relevant influence on its further democratic
On the basis of five centuries of political development. This, in turn, implies a two-
history in Costa Rica and Nicaragua, stage approach to theory-building. In the
Consuelo Cruz’s (2005) volume demonstrates first stage, scholars should study the specific
that political culture – and, in particular, transitional justice process(es) in question,
how countries rework their past experiences and explain the latter’s relationship with
into practical lessons for building a ‘better’ the democratic transition. In the second
future – configures economic development, stage, scholars should formulate and test
institutional choices and political pacts in concrete hypotheses about the evolution and

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 19 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


516 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

broader transformative role of transi- their past during difficult social and political
tional justice over time – a role that transformation.
might well be quite different than the one
originally envisaged at the time of demo-
cratic transition. Evolution and long-term
In my own work, I implement this two-stage
effects
approach to study transitional justice’s role in
shaping the quality of post-authoritarian Recent research has finally put to rest the
democracies over time (Cesarini, 2009). idea that choices about transitional justice are
To help separate the two analytical stages of confined to the relative short time interval of
my inquiry, I introduce the notion of transi- the democratic transition, and that what mat-
tional justice ‘regime’ – defined as a distinc- ters most is transitional justice’s short-term
tive and enduring set of socially constructed impact on democratic consolidation. The
principles, institutions and narratives that empirical evidence from ‘historical’ cases, in
post-authoritarian actors commit to in order fact, unquestionably shows that transitional
to carry out transitional justice over time. justice is a much more complex, nuanced,
Thus, I first analyze the emergence of shifting, long-lasting, broad-based and con-
the transitional justice regimes of Italy, sequential affair than most social scientists
Portugal, and Argentina, and detail their have thus far imagined. Scholars should
main characteristics and short-term effects. therefore look at transitional justice as an
Then, I illustrate how these transitional jus- ongoing process, and seek to find out more
tice regimes evolved and became entrenched about the factors that prompt democratic
over time, eventually acquiring a key trans- societies to revisit their transitional justice
formative role of their own: that of structur- choices even many decades after regime tran-
ing Italy’s, Portugal’s, and Argentina’s sition. Scholars also need to dedicate much
relationships with their authoritarian past, more effort to evaluating the long-
and the latter’s influence on the present. term impact of transitional justice. In
Finally, I argue that the role of transitional particular, they need to formulate effective
justice in these countries was highly conse- policy insights about which combination,
quential, not only at the abstract level of their sequence, and timing of available transitional
collective memories, but also on the more justice sub-types (among those listed in
concrete plane of the design and practice of Table 27.1) are most appropriate to promote
Italy’s, Portugal’s, and Argentina’s institu- the quality of a particular democratic society
tions and, in turn, of the long-term quality of over time.
their democracies.

Redistributive transitional
NEW AREAS OF TRANSITIONAL justice
JUSTICE RESEARCH The redistributive sub-type remains the most
under-researched category of transitional jus-
The field of transitional justice is an interest- tice. This is a consequence of the fact that,
ing and thriving one. However, much work with very few exceptions, the debate on tran-
remains to be done. This last section identi- sitional justice has largely bypassed social
fies a select number of new areas for transi- and economic policies, while privileging
tional justice research by political scientists judicial and institutional expedients. It also
in general – and comparativists in particular. reflects the pre-eminence of civil and politi-
These areas show great promise for adding to cal rights in the current democratization dis-
our knowledge about how countries deal with course. However, as several scholars point

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 20 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 517

out, while ‘trials and conventional legal recognized knowledge-based networks, the
infrastructures […] are important, […] they members of which share a common under-
are not enough, especially in countries char- standing of a particular problem/issue or a
acterized by poverty and illiteracy. […] If common worldview and seek to translate
justice is to contribute to peace and democ- their beliefs into dominant social discourse
racy […], the imbalances within transitional and social practices’ (p. 26). There are at
justice need to be redressed’ (Gready, 2005: least two challenges for any research of this
18–19), both in terms of academic research kind. The first is to establish the existence of
and concrete policy measures. a transitional justice epistemic community
by identifying its membership and detailing
its intellectual and advocacy activities over
Constituencies of transitional time. The second is to demonstrate that such
epistemic community played (and continues
justice
to play) a critical role within the current
When is transitional justice more likely? international human rights regime in setting
When the state and civil society collaborate; norms affecting transitional justice on a
when the state leads; or when civil society global scale.
takes the initiative? Any research on effective
constituencies of transitional justice should
focus on the relationship between incoming Transitional justice and
democratic elites and organizations of
collective memory
civil society – especially human rights
groups. It should treat transitional justice as a While several good studies on the influence
process that requires negotiation, not only of the past on democratization are currently
among elites, but also between a country’s available,34 much work remains to be done
leaders and its citizens. It should leave room on the specific relationship between transi-
for relevant actors to engage in political tional justice and collective memory. This
learning – not only from their own past, but kind of research inevitably requires a major
also from other countries’ experiences. It interdisciplinary effort – one that, unfortu-
should seek to explain, not only why some nately, only very few scholars are willing or
societies may skip or backtrack from transi- able to undertake. Jon Elster is one of those
tional justice, but also why they may re- few. After a careful analysis of the ‘intricate
embrace it several decades after democratic interplay’ between memory, emotions,
transition. Finally, this research should pro- democratization, and transitional justice, he
vide a solid empirical counterpoint to the concludes that the desire for transitional jus-
more prevalent normative studies of transi- tice ‘is blunted, if there is a long time interval
tional justice. between the wrongdoings and the transition,
and also if there is a long delay between the
transition and the trials’ (Elster, 2004: 222).
Epistemic communities This is because the memory of even the more
horrific of atrocities tends to decay over time,
of transitional justice
unless some mechanism intervenes to slow
How and why did transitional justice become or arrest such decay.35
an international cause celébre? One possible What Elster scarcely emphasizes, however,
answer to this question involves theorizing is that transitional justice choices shape col-
the rise of an epistemic community of transi- lective memories well beyond the democratic
tional justice. According to Antoniades transition. Thus, for example, a new democ-
(2003), epistemic communities are ‘thought racy’s initial choice to forget may render vic-
communities […] made up of socially tims (or their families) subsequently more

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 21 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


518 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

resolute in their refusal to let the memory of preponderant role in destabilizing transitional
their beloved’s plight fade. In contrast, the justice compromises? (If yes, why?)
selection of a particular official narrative of
the past may – over the years – influence
selective collective amnesia. More research on
the long-run feedback effects of transitional NOTES
justice on collective memory is therefore in
order. Such research necessarily requires a 1. Transitional justice spans at least across
constructivist view of transitional justice – six different disciplinary fields – that is, law,
that is, as a process that is shaped by the recent history, sociology, political science, anthropology,
authoritarian experience in the short run and, and psychology.
2. See also Bickford’s definition of transitional
in turn, also shapes the collective memory of a justice as ‘a field of activity and inquiry focused on
post-authoritarian society over time. how societies address legacies of past human rights
abuses, mass atrocity, or other forms of severe social
trauma, including genocide or civil war, in order to
build a more democratic, just, or peaceful future’
Transitional justice (Bickford, 2004: 1045–47).
and gender 3. The doctrine of universal jurisdiction allows
countries to prosecute crimes against humanity in
Women have always been at the forefront of domestic courts, regardless of the nationality of vic-
demands for transitional justice both as direct tims and perpetrators, or the place where the atroci-
victims of crimes against humanity, and as rela- ties were committed.
4. These include: truth commissions, historical
tives of the tortured, the murdered, and the research, compilation of victims’ testimonials or oral
disappeared. However, it was only after the histories, forensic anthropological research, and
2001 sentence by the International Criminal exhumation of victims’ bodies. See Bickford (2004).
Tribunal for the Former Yugoslavia that made 5. These include: wholesale dismissal of abu-
rape a separate war crime (as well as an act of sive, corrupt, or incompetent officials from the public
administration, the police, the security services, the
genocide), that transitional justice officially military, and the judiciary that served the previous
acquired a gender dimension. Since then, the regime.
international community has made significant 6. These include: economic, rehabilitative and
progress in recognizing gender based war symbolic measures, such as: monetary compensa-
crimes – such as: rape, sexual slavery, forced tion, health and education benefits, official apolo-
gies, memorials, etc.
pregnancy, enforced sterilization, and so forth 7. See, for example, Rwanda’s Gacaca courts.
(see Franke, 2006). In turn, women are gradu- 8. It might be objected that such stringent cri-
ally evolving from passive victims, into active teria would leave important cases – such as Northern
participants of the transitional justice process. Ireland – outside the realm of transitional justice. This
While several interesting policy studies are objection fails, however, to appreciate the fact that
– for the most part – Northern Ireland’s Catholics do
emerging,36 the gender dimension of transi- not perceive British rule as ‘democratic’, since it
tional justice still needs more abstract theo- equated for so long with Unionist supremacy. As
retical work. Under-analyzed questions seen from their point of view, then, the peace proc-
include the following: Are there gender- ess also harbors regime change.
specific conceptions of transitional justice? 9. That is with military or international trials car-
ried out by foreign powers in connection with inter-
(If yes, why? And what do they look like?); state war crimes, whose primary goal is the punishment
Do women have a key role in expanding the of aggression to global peace and security, rather than
concept of transitional justice into the cultural the democratization of the defeated country.
and socio-economic realms?; Why does wom- 10. That is summary judgments carried out in
en’s clout as protagonists of the opposition to time of war by kangaroo courts set up by particular
factions whose main goal is revenge rather than
authoritarian regimes so rarely transfer justice.
into decision-making power in matters of 11. Katherine Hite and Paola Cesarini (2004: 4)
transitional justice?; Do women play a define ‘authoritarian legacies’ as ‘those rules,

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 22 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 519

procedures, norms, patterns, practices, dispositions, 28. The Nuremberg Charter defined ‘crimes
relationships, and memories originating in well- against humanity’ as: ‘murder, extermination,
defined authoritarian experiences of the past that, as enslavement, deportation, and other inhumane acts
a result of specific historical configurations and/or committed against any civilian population, before or
political struggles, survive democratic transition during the war, or persecutions on political, racial or
and intervene in the quality and practice of post- religious grounds in execution of, or in connection
authoritarian democracies’. with any crime within the jurisdiction of the Tribunal,
12. In some cases – such as Peru – the bulk of whether or not in violation of the domestic law of
human rights violations are committed by opposition the country where perpetrated’. See Charter of the
forces. International Military Tribunal (also known as
13. ‘In the limited sanction, the phases of ascer- Nuremberg Charter), art. 6(c).
taining guilt and of ascribing penalty are differenti- 29. Rwanda is a case in point.
ated. […] Investigations may or may not lead to 30. See Teitel (2000) and Shapiro (1999).
indictments, adjudication, and conviction. Moreover, 31. See Germany after World War I.
convictions are commonly followed by light or no 32. Criminal prosecution of perpetrators of mass
punishment’ (Teitel, 2000: 47). atrocities is often carried out on the basis of ex-post
14. See Human Rights Watch official website at: facto law or without proper guarantees of due proc-
http://hrw.org/justice/about.htm ess, equal protection and statutes of limitation for
15. Exemplified by the successful trials of the the accused. See Kirchheimer (1961) and Siegel
former members of the military juntas in 1975 (1998).
Greece and 1983 Argentina. 33. ‘Agreement to forget’.
16. The recent trial and execution of Saddam 34. See, among others, Aguilar (1996); Booth
Hussein in Iraq under the aegis of a domestic (2001); Cruz (2005); de Brito et al. (2001); Mahoney
tribunal convened under US watch, appear support (2002); Müller (2002); Osiel (1997, 2000); and
this argument. Torpey (2003).
17. Such as putting the military under civilian 35. Such mechanisms include the following:
control and creating an independent judiciary. ‘communication among the victims of wrongdoing,
18. See, for example, Rwanda’s Gacaca courts. codes of honor that keep memory alive until the
19. Comisión Nacional de Investigación sobre la desire for revenge has been satisfied, visible physical
Desapareción de Personas – National Investigative reminders of the wrongdoing, and perpetuation of
Commission on the Disappeared. the state of affairs caused by the wrongdoing’
20. From Chile’s President Patricio Aylwin’s (Elster, 2004: 223).
statement on public television in occasion of the 36. See, for example, Rubio-Marín (2006).
presentation of the Report of the Chilean National
Commission on Truth and Reconciliation.
21. See, for example, Spain, Mozambique, or
Cambodia.
22. Except, of course, when it deliberately seeks REFERENCES
to re-establish a democratic status quo ante.
23. Radical versions of redistributive transitional
Aguilar Fernández, P. (1996) La memoria
justice are usually supported by actors imbued with a
histórica de la guerra civil española (1936–39):
communist or socialist ideology.
24. See under the previous section dedicated to
Un proceso de aprendizaje político. Madrid:
institutional transitional justice. Alianza Editorial.
25. See, among others, Teitel (2000) and Elster Antoniades, A. (2003) ‘Epistemic communities,
(2004). epistemes and the construction of (world)
26. For a similar conclusion, see de Brito et al. politics’, Global Society, 17 (1): 21–38.
(2001). Art, D. (2005) The politics of the Nazi past in
27. This refers to the 1998 house arrest in Germany and Austria. Cambridge: Cambridge
England of General Augusto Pinochet – military dicta- University Press.
tor of Chile from 1973 to 1990 – for human rights Barkan, E. (2002) The guilt of nations:
abuses carried out under his rule. Pinochet’s arrest
Restitution and negotiating historical
was executed on the basis of the principle of universal
jurisdiction following a request of extradition by
injustices. New York: Norton.
Spanish judge Baltasar Garzón. The ensuing legal Bickford, L. (2004) ‘Transitional justice’, in D.L.
battle greatly emboldened activists worldwide and, Shelton (ed.), The encyclopedia of genocide
according to many scholars, opened a new era in and crimes against humanity. Macmillan
international human rights law. Reference USA. Vol. 3, pp. 1045–47.

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 23 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


520 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Booth, J. W. (2001) ‘The unforgotten: Memories Franke, K.M. (2006) ‘Gendered subjects on
of justice’, American Political Science Review, Transitional Justice’, Columbia Journal of
95 (4): 777–92. Gender and Law, 15 (3): 813–27.
Boraine, A.L. (2006) ‘Transitional justice: A Gready, P. (2005) ‘Reconceptualising transi-
holistic interpretation’, Journal of tional justice: Embedded and distanced
International Affairs, 60 (1): 17–30. justice’, Conflict, Security and Development,
Brody, R. (2001, April 20) ‘Justice: The first 5 (1): 3–21.
casualty of truth?’, The Nation, 25–31. Hayner, P. (2002) Unspeakable truths:
Cesarini, P. (2004) ‘Authoritarian legacies and Facing the challenge of truth commissions.
justice in Italy and Argentina’, in Hite, K. and New York and London: Routledge.
Cesarini, P. (eds), Authoritarian legacies and Hite, K. and Cesarini, P. (2004) Authoritarian
democracy in Latin America and Southern legacies and democracy in Latin America and
Europe. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Southern Europe. Notre Dame, IN: University
Dame Press. pp. 159–90. of Notre Dame Press
Cesarini, P. (2009) Unforgettable justice: Huntington, S.P. (1968) Political order in chang-
Transitional justice and the quality of ing societies. New Haven: Yale University
democracy in post-authoritarian Italy, Press.
Portugal and Argentina (unpublished PhD Huntington, S.P. (1991) The third wave:
Dissertation). Democratization in the late twentieth
Cruz, C. (2005) Political culture and institu- century. University of Oklahoma Press.
tional development in Costa Rica and International Center for Transitional Justice
Nicaragua. Cambridge: Cambridge University (2006) What is transitional justice? Retrieved
Press. March 26, 2008, from http://www.ictj.org/
de Brito, A., Gonzales-Enriques, C., and Aquilar, en/tj/
P. (2001) The politics of memory. Oxford: International Center for Transitional Justice
Oxford University Press. (2008) Vetting research project. Retrieved
Diamond, L. and Morlino, L. (2004) ‘The quality March 27, 2008, from http://www.ictj.org/
of democracy: An overview’, Journal of en/research/projects/vetting/index.html
Democracy, 15 (4): 20–31. Katznelson, I. (1997) ‘Structure and configura-
Dicker, R. and Keppler, E. (2004) Beyond The tion in comparative politics’, in M. Irving
Hague: The challenges of international jus- Lichbach and A.S. Zuckerman (eds),
tice. Human rights watch world report 2004. Comparative politics: Rationality, culture,
Retrieved March 26, from, http://hrw.org/ and structure. Cambridge: Cambridge
wr2k4 /10.htm University Press. pp. 81–112.
Elster, J. (1998) ‘Coming to terms with the Kirchheimer, O. (1961) Political justice. Westport,
past: A framework for the study of justice in CT: Greenwood Press. Reprinted by arrange-
the transition to democracy’, European ment with Princeton University Press.
Journal of Sociology, 39: 7–48. Kissinger, H. (2001) ‘The pitfalls of universal
Elster, J. (2004) Closing the books. Cambridge: jurisdiction’. Foreign Affairs, 80 (4): 86–96.
Cambridge University Press. Krasner, S. (ed.) (1983) International regimes.
Finnemore, M. and Sikkink, K. (1998) Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
‘International norm dynamics and political Krieger, N. (2000) ‘Transitional justice as
change’, International Organization, 52 (4): socioeconomic rights’, Peace Review, 12 (1):
887–917. 59–65.
Fletcher, L. (2001) ‘Between vengeance Kritz, N. (1995) ‘The dilemmas of transitional
and forgiveness: Facing history after geno- justice’, in N. Kritz (ed.), Transitional justice:
cide and mass violence (Book review)’, How emerging democracies reckon with
Berkeley Journal of International Law, 19 (2): former regimes. USIP Press Books. Retrieved
428–42. March 26, 2008, from http://www.usip.org/
Fletcher, L.E. and Weinstein, H.M. (2002) ruleoflaw/pubs/tjintro.html#non
‘Violence and social repair: Rethinking the Letki, N. (2002) ‘Lustration and democratiza-
contribution of justice to reconciliation’, tion in East-Central Europe’, Europe-Asia
Human Rights Quarterly, 24 (3): 573–639. Studies, 54 (4): 530–31.

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 24 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


TRANSITIONAL JUSTICE 521

Lutz, E. and Sikkink, K. (2001) ‘The justice cas- Przeworski, A. (1986) ‘Some problems in the
cade: The evolution and impact of foreign study of transition to democracy’, in G.
human rights trials in Latin America’, Chicago O’Donnell, P. C. Schmitter and L. Whitehead
Journal of International Law, 2 (1): 1–33. (eds), Transitions from authoritarian rule.
Mahoney, J. (2002) The legacies of liberalism: Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Path dependence and political regimes in pp. 47–63.
Central America. Baltimore: The Johns Roht-Arriaza, N. (2005) The Pinochet effect.
Hopkins University Press. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania
Mamdani, M. (1996) ‘Reconciliation without Press.
justice’, Southern African Review of Books, Rothenberg, D. (2002) ‘“Let justice judge”: An
46 (November/December): 3–5. interview with Judge Baltasar Garzón and
Mamdani, M. (2000) ‘The truth according to the analysis of his ideas’, Human Rights Quarterly,
TRC’, in I. Amadiume and A. An-Naim (eds), 24: 924–73.
The politics of memory: Truth, healing and Rubio-Marín, R. (ed) (2006) What happened to
social justice. London: Zed. pp. 182–83. the women? Gender and reparations for
Mani, R. (2002) Beyond retribution: Seeking human rights violations. New York: Social
justice in the shadows of war. Cambridge, Science Research Council.
UK: Polity Press. Sa’adah, A. (1998) Germany’s second chance:
Mani, R. (2005) ‘Rebuilding an inclusive politi- Trust, justice and democratization. Cambridge,
cal community after war’, Security Dialogue, MA: Harvard University Press.
36 (4): 511–26. Sarat, A. and Kearns, T.R. (1999) History,
Marques, J., Paez, D., and Serra, A. (eds) memory and the law. Ann Arbor, MI: The
(1997) Collective memory of political events: University of Michigan Press.
Social psychological perspectives. Mahwah, Shapiro, I. (1999) Democratic justice. New
NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Haven: Yale University Press.
McAdam, D., Tilly, C., and Tarrow, S. (2001) Siegel, R.L. (1998) ‘Transitional justice: A
The dynamics of contention. New York: decade of debate and experience’, Human
Cambridge University Press. Rights Quarterly, 20 (2): 431–54.
Müller, J. W. (ed.) (2002) Memory and power Sikkink, K. and Walling, C.B. (2007) ‘The
in post-war Europe. Cambridge, UK: impact of human rights trials in Latin
Cambridge University Press. America’, Journal of Peace Research, 44 (4):
Nietzsche, F. (1997) ‘On the uses and disadvan- 427–45.
tages of history for life’, in Friedrich Nietzsche, Smiley, M. (2001) ‘Democratic justice in
Daniel Breazeale, and R.J. Hollingdale (eds) transition’, Michigan Law Review, 99 (6):
Untimely Meditation. (Cambridge Texts in 1332–48.
the History of Philosophy). Cambridge: Snyder, J. and Vinjamuri, L. (2003) ‘Trials and
Cambridge University Press. pp. 57–124. errors: Principle and pragmatism in strategies
Nino, C. (1991) ‘The duty to punish past abuses of international justice’, International
of human rights put into context: The case Security, 28 (3): 5–44.
of Argentina’, Yale Law Journal, 100 (8): Snyder, J. and Vinjamuri, L. (2006, September
2619–40. 26) A midwife for peace. International Herald
O’Donnell, G., Schmitter, P.C., and Whitehead, L. Tribune.
(eds) (1986) Transitions from authoritarian rule. Sriram, C.L. (2005) ‘Transitional justice
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. comes of age: Enduring lessons and chal-
Orentlicher, D.F. (1991) ‘Settling accounts: The lenges’, Berkeley Journal of International
duty to prosecute human rights violations of Law, 23 (2): 506–23.
a prior regime’, Yale Law Journal, 100 (8): Teitel, R.G. (2000) Transitional justice.
2537–615. New York: Oxford University Press.
Osiel, M. (1997/2000) Mass atrocity, collective Torpey, J. (ed) (2003) Politics and the past.
memory and the law. New Brunswick, NJ: Rowman and Littlefield Publishers.
Transaction Books.

9781412919760_Chap27.indd 25 3/11/2009 4:46:16 PM


28
The Globalization of Comparative
Public Opinion Research
Pippa Norris

INTRODUCTION chapter examines the globalization of the study


of cross-national public opinion over succes-
One of the most dramatic recent develop- sive decades. The statistical revolution spurred
ments, transforming the field of comparative the initial growth in survey research in Europe
politics during recent decades, has been and the United States, emphasizing individual-
the expanding range of survey resources level social-psychological variables and quanti-
facilitating the systematic cross-national tative scientific methods. More recently the rise
analysis of public opinion around the globe. of the European Union (EU), international net-
This process started more than four decades works in the social sciences, the diffusion of the
ago, with Gabriel Almond and Sidney market research industry, and the expanding
Verba’s path-breaking The civic culture number of democratic states worldwide have
(1963), which was immediately recognized all facilitated the growth and scope of data
and acclaimed by Philip Converse (1964) as resources. This chapter compares and contrasts
‘an instant classic’. Previously a few other the major series of cross-national social survey
cross-national attitudinal studies had been datasets which are now available, summarized
deployed, notably, William Buchanan in Table 28.1, defined as those covering more
and Hadley Cantril’s 9-country How nations than one independent nation-state which have
see each other (1953), sponsored by established a regular series of surveys of social
UNESCO, sociological surveys of social and political attitudes and behavior. This
stratification, and USIA surveys of attitudes includes the Euro-barometer and related EU
toward international affairs.1 The civic cul- surveys (which started in 1970), the European
ture survey laid the foundation for the com- Election Study (1979), the European Values
parative study of public opinion and Survey and the World Values Survey (1981),
subsequent cross-national survey research as the International Social Survey Programme
a distinctive sub-field in political science (1985), the Global Barometers (1990 and vari-
open to empirical investigation. ous), the Comparative National Elections
To explore the nature and evaluate the contri- Project (1990), the European Voter and the
bution of this sub-field, the first part of this Comparative Study of Electoral Systems

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 1 3/11/2009 4:49:13 PM


Table 28.1 Key features of the cross-national series of surveys
Series Series Frequency Total nations Data Coordinating Online resources
started (latest downloadable organization

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 2
(i) survey) (ii) (iii)
Euro-barometer and 1970 Bi-annual 27 Public archives Directorate General Press Organizing and reports:
related studies and Comms, European http://europa.eu.int/comm/public_opinion/
Commission Data and continuity guides from ZUMA, Cologne Archive:
www.gesis.org/en/data_service/eurobarometer
European Values/ 1981–1983 Approx. 5 years 92 Public archives Ronald Inglehart, Institute Organizing and data;
World Values of Social Research, www.worldvaluessurvey.org/
Study- Study University of Michigan
International Social 1985 Annual 38 Public archives Secretariat: Bjørn Organizing:
Survey Program Henrichsen, Norwegian www.issp.org/
(ISSP) Social Science Data Data and continuity guide from the ZUMA Cologne Archive:
Services (NSD), Bergen www.gesis.org/en/data_service/issp/
Comparative Study of 1996–2001 Module every 5 31 Public archives Secretariat: David Howell, Organizing and data:
Electoral Systems years ISR, University of http://www.cses.org
(CSES) Michigan. Chair:
Ian McAllister, ANU
Comparative National 1990 Irregular 19 Public archives Richard Gunther, Organizing and data:
Election Study Ohio State University http://www.cnep.ics.ul.pt/
Global-barometers, http://www.globalbarometer.net/
including:
New Europe 1991 Irregular 16 Richard Rose, CSPP, www.cspp.strath.ac.uk
Barometers Aberdeen University
Afrobarometer 1999 Annual 18 Public archives Michael Bratton (Michigan www.afrobarometer.org
State), Robert Mattes
(IDASA, SA) and Dr E.
Gyimah-Boadi (CDD
Ghana)
Latino-barometer 1995 Annual 18 Tables only Marta Lagos, www.latinobarometro.org
MORI, Santiago
Continued

3/11/2009 4:49:13 PM
Continued
Table 28.1 Key features of the cross-national series of surveys
Series Series Frequency Total nations Data download- Coordinating Online resources
started able (iii)

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 3
(latest organization
(i) survey) (ii)
Asian barometer 2001 Annual 17 Yun-han Chu, Taiwan www.eastasiabarometer.org
http://www.asianbarometer.org/
Arab Barometer 2005 Annual 5 Mark Tessler, University of http://arabbarometer.org/
Michigan
The European Social 2002 Biennial 21 Public archives Roger JOWELL, Center Organizing:
Survey (ESS) for Comparative Social http://www.europeansocialsurvey.org/
Surveys, City University Data from the Norwegian archive:
http://ess.nsd.uib.no.
Transatlantic Trends 2002 Annual 13 Public archives German Marshall Fund of http://www.transatlantictrends.org
the United States and the
Compagnia di San Paolo
The Pew Global 2002 Irregular 54 Via website Andrew KOHUT, Director, http://pewglobal.org/
Attitudes Survey The Pew Research Center
for the People and the
Press
Gallup International 2002 Annual 60 Only tables Meril JAMES, Secretary www.voice-of-the-people.net/
Voice of the People released General
Gallup International
Notes: (i) In some cases there were often pilot studies and forerunners, such as the European Community Study, but this date is the recognizable start of the series in its present form.
(ii) The number of countries included in each survey often varies by year. (iii) If not deposited in public archives or directly downloadable, access to some data may be available from the
surveys organizers on request, but there might also be charges for access.

3/11/2009 4:49:13 PM
THE GLOBALIZATION OF COMPARATIVE PUBLIC OPINION RESEARCH 525

(1995), the European Social Survey (2002), the the precision of the results were developed at
Transatlantic Trends survey (2002), the Pew the LSE by the statistician Arthur L. Bowley
Global Attitudes project (2002), and the Gallup (Bulmer, 1998). Bowley also devised and
World Poll (2005). conducted sample surveys of working-class
The final section of this chapter considers households in four English towns and pre-
some of the perennial critiques of cross- sented the results in Livelihood and poverty
national surveys, including issues about the (with A. R. Burnett-Hurst, 1915). The earli-
quality of the data, the equivalence of con- est social surveys in Britain called attention
cepts, and the need to understand public opin- to issues of political reform to improve the
ion within a broader structural context, and living conditions for the urban poor.
considers how far these raise valid concerns Building on this work, in the United States
about the limits of this method. The conclu- the founders of the Chicago school, Harold
sion argues that, despite important limitations, Gosnell and Charles Merriam, had experi-
cross-national survey research is invaluable mented with applying statistical and survey
for establishing generalities about human methods in pursuit of a new science of poli-
behavior in a way that allows us to test regu- tics during the 1920s and 1930s (Bulmer,
larities established in single-nation studies. 1986). This approach was exemplified by
The multiplicity of datasets which are now Merriam and Gosnell, (1924), which
available for analysis strengthens replication, employed sampling techniques and survey
to ensure robust findings and generalizations. data. Prior to this, the Swedish social scien-
In particular, when large-scale multi-national tist, Herbert Tingsten (1937/1963), had
surveys covering many societies are combined employed aggregate data to understand polit-
with systematic variations in institutional and ical behavior, voting choice and turnout. The
societal contexts, this process is capable of advantage of representative sample surveys
providing powerful insights for the study of is that these provided direct insights into the
comparative politics. social and attitudinal characteristics of the
electorate. Many of the leaders associated
with the behavioral revolution were associ-
ated as faculty or graduates with the Chicago
THE EARLY EVOLUTION school, including Harold Lasswell, V. O. Key
OF SURVEY RESEARCH Jr., David Truman, Herbert Simon, and
Gabriel Almond. Meanwhile the commercial
The earliest development of large-scale social applied uses of market survey research were
surveys can be traced to the statistical move- also being developed. George Gallup experi-
ment in late-Victorian Britain (Bulmer et al., mented with using voting forms among a
1992). Surveys arose with the comprehensive scientific sample of voters in each state in
street-by-street investigations into the condi- 1933, using this to predict the results of the
tions of poverty in London led by the busi- 1934 Congressional races. He founded the
ness philanthropist Charles Booth (which American Institute of Public Opinion in 1935
started in 1886), building on Mayhew’s more and the British Institute of Public Opinion
impressionistic observations thirty years two years later. Straw polls and even large-
earlier, and a similar social survey of scale house-to-house surveys based on self-
working class living conditions which the selection had been used in many studies. The
social reformer and businessman Seebohm superiority of opinion surveys based on a
Rowntree conducted in York in 1897. small but scientifically selected random
Some of the earliest work on probability sample of the adult population came to
sampling was developed by the Norwegian public attention when Gallup used these
statistician Kiaer around 1890, while esti- techniques to predict successfully a Roosevelt
mates of the sources of error which influence victory in the 1936 presidential election, in

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 4 3/11/2009 4:49:13 PM


526 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

marked contrast to the forecast of a Landon the following decades, public opinion surveys
win based on the far larger but non-random based on scientific sampling techniques
poll published in the Literary Digest became more widely used by social science
(Crossley, 1937). researchers and governments, reflecting the
The first issue of the journal Public growth of the market research industry and the
Opinion Quarterly was published in 1937, expansion in social science grants available
seeking to document ‘what public opinion is, from major agencies and foundations
how it generates, and how it acts’ (Clinton (Converse, 1987). The US was far from alone
Poole, 1937). A bibliography published in in this regard; many affluent postindustrial
the first issue listed 5,000 titles on mass societies such as Britain saw the establishment
public opinion. Market research and public of commercial market research companies,
opinion surveys rapidly expanded in America including Gallup, Harris, MORI, and Roper,
in the next few years, including a wide range and the spread of behavioral techniques in the
of polls conducted by George Gallup, Elmo social sciences in Scandinavia and many
Roper and Archibald Crossley (Geer, 2004). countries in Western Europe (Dahl, 1961). A
During World War II, many social psycholo- strong international community of market
gists, sociologists and economists also gained research and survey researchers has long
first-hand experience of opinion surveys existed, exemplified by coverage of public
while working in Washington DC for govern- opinion in different countries in the first issue
ment agencies and bureaus, such as the of Public Opinion Quarterly and the establish-
Department of Agriculture’s Division of ment of the World Association of Public
Program Surveys studying attitudes among Opinion Research (WAPOR) in 1947.
farmers and the Federal Reserve Board which
analyzed economic behavior and consumer
sentiment. The most well-known use of these
techniques was exemplified by the American DEMOCRATIC PARTICIPATION
Soldier study, led by Samuel A. Stouffer for AND THE CIVIC CULTURE
the War Department, examining the social
psychology of the armed forces through over Despite important transatlantic connections
one hundred questionnaires administered to in the community of social scientists and
military personnel (Stouffer et al., 1949). market research organizations, the vast
Non-profit organizations also played an majority of political and social attitudinal
important role, notably the Rockefeller foun- surveys were based on samples of the popu-
dation which sponsored research on mass lation in each nation. The use of dedicated
communications and the effects of radio. cross-national surveys using a single common
Following these initiatives, academic survey instrument or battery of questions first arose
institutions studying public opinion and social with the 1948 study How nations see each
change became established in the US through other by Buchanan and Cantril, the USIA
pioneering work at the National Opinion International Relations survey, the 1956
Research Center (1941) which settled at the International Stratification survey by the
University of Chicago, Paul Lazarsfeld’s sociologists Ganzeboom and Nieuwbeerta,
Bureau for Applied Social Research (1944) at the 1957 Pattern of human concerns survey
Columbia University, and the Survey Research also by Cantril, and the 1959 Civic culture
Center (1946) at the University of Michigan. study by Almond and Verba.
In particular, Lazarsfeld’s Erie County, Ohio The focus of Almond and Verba’s work
study used probability samples in a campaign reflected contemporary concern to understand
panel survey during the Roosevelt-Wilkie the underlying causes of regime instability
presidential race, generating the landmark The reflected in the rise of Nazi Germany and
people’ choice (Lazarsfeld et al., 1944). During Italian fascism. The ground-breaking study

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 5 3/11/2009 4:49:13 PM


THE GLOBALIZATION OF COMPARATIVE PUBLIC OPINION RESEARCH 527

presented an ambitious theory of cognitive seeking to build upon this foundation and to
and affective orientations among the mass expand the study of participation to understand
population, developing concepts which ‘unconventional’ forms of protests and mass
remain central in the contemporary lexogra- demonstrations which were widespread among
phy of political science. The intellectual roots the trilateral democracies during this decade
of the Civic culture, and the sociological and (Barnes et al., 1979).
psychological explanation for political behav-
ior, originated during the inter-war era with
the Chicago school, notably Charles Merriam’s
study on The making of citizens (1931), as THE EXPANSION OF THE EU
well as Harold Lasswell’s Psychopathology AND THE EURO-BAROMETER
and politics (1930). Harry Eckstein’s (1961)
work A theory of stable democracy was also Meanwhile in a parallel development, the use
highly influential. Building upon this founda- of survey methods in international affairs and
tion, Almond and Verba’s theory emphasized by multilateral organizations saw important
that stable democracies required equilibrium advances. The 1948 study How nations see
with the mass public finely balanced between each other sought to document attitudes and
the dangers of either an excessively apathetic prejudices among the public and perceptions
and disengaged citizenry, on the one hand, or of foreign affairs. In Europe, in 1962 Jacques-
an overly-agitated and heated engagement, Rene Rabier, in his role as Director General
on the other.2 The idea that societies differed of Press and Information for the European
in their political culture was hardly novel; Community, pioneered the first five-nation
indeed it had been the subject of philosophi- cross-national survey of mass attitudes
cal speculation for centuries, in classic works toward European integration and institutions,
from Montesquieu to de Tocqueville. But as the fore-runner of the Euro-Barometer. In
one of the more radical aspects of the civic 1970, Rabier carried out a seven-nation
culture study was the way that empirical sup- survey to understand public support for and
port for the theory was derived from a path- against European integration, including
breaking cross-national opinion survey, measures of Materialist/Post-Materialist
demonstrating that citizen’s orientations could values, with Ronald Inglehart serving as a
be examined empirically among the mass consultant in the design and analysis. The
publics in Mexico, Italy, Britain, France, and results generated additional cross-national
Germany. surveys in 1971 and 1973, leading to the
This influential model established a quantum launch of the Euro-barometer surveys in
leap in the methods and concerns common in 1974. These studies have now been carried
comparative political science. It was followed out every spring and fall since then, reflect-
in 1963 by the 8-nation Political Participation ing the steadily expanding borders of the
study sponsored by the International Social European Union, now covering 27 countries.
Science Council, with Asher, Richardson and The program was later enlarged by small
Weisberg et al. as the principle investigators. A scale but topical Flash Euro-barometers and
few years later, Sidney Verba expanded upon the Central and Eastern Euro-barometers;
his earlier work to develop the Political later replaced by the Candidate Countries
Participation and Equality survey in seven Euro-barometers. The project was designed
nations in 1966, with collaborators Norman to be useful primarily for European Union
Nie and Jae-On Kim. The eight-nation 1973 officials and only secondarily for the research
and 1981 Political Action Surveys by community.
Klaus Allerbeck, Max Kaase, Hans-Dieter Questions can be identified, trends for the
Klingemann, Samuel Barnes, Alan Marsh, and standard items in the Euro-barometer series
Ronald Inglehart shared similar concerns, 1973–2004 can be generated interactively,

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 6 3/11/2009 4:49:13 PM


528 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

and descriptive tables, graphs, or data down- Jesuit sociologist, Father Jan Kerkhofs, and a
loaded via the EB website.3 Data were also Dutch sociologist, Ruud de Moor, initially to
integrated into the Mannheim Euro-barometer understand why church attendance was falling
Trend File 1970–1999 and ZUMA also main- sharply across Western Europe. The investiga-
tain the online Main Trends Documentation.4 tors were aware of the Euro-Barometer sur-
The data received from the principal investi- veys and they contacted Jacques Rabier, who
gator are checked, corrected, and formatted joined them in designing the surveys. Rabier
to archival standards by the Inter-university persuaded them to do a broader study of
Consortium for Political and Social Research values, on the basis that attitudes toward reli-
(ICPSR), in cooperation with ZUMA’s gion were linked to one’s entire worldview.
Zentralarchiv at Cologne and the Swedish The European Values Survey based at the
Social Science Data Service (SSD). ZUMA University of Tilburg was modeled on the
maintains a codebook and questionnaire con- Euro-barometer, with some of the same survey
tinuity guide, which is an invaluable short- organizations and advisers.7
cut since around seventy separate surveys are In 1990 the survey was replicated as the
available. Euro-barometer raw data and doc- World Values Study (WVS) and Ronald
umentation (questionnaires and codebooks Inglehart was charged with widening the
etc.) are stored at the ICPSR and at the geographic coverage, which doubled from
Zentralarchiv and made available for research 22 countries in 1981 to 41 in 1990–1991. The
purposes by other social science Data third wave of the WVS was carried out in
Archives. Survey results are also regularly 55 nations in 1995–1996. The fourth WVS
published in official reports issued by the wave, with 59 nation-states, took place in
Euro-barometer unit of the European 1999–2001. The fifth WVS wave was carried
Commission.5 The Euro-barometer series has out in 2005–2007.8 The World Values Survey
been commonly used in studies of the poli- represents a worldwide investigation of
tics of the European Union, but, despite socio-cultural and political change. This
the richness of the accumulated datasets, the project has carried out representative national
full potential of this series for comparative surveys of the basic values and beliefs of the
politics remains relatively under-utilized. publics in more than 90 independent coun-
The exemplification of its potential con- tries, containing over 88 per cent of the
tribution includes Ingehart’s The silent revo- world’s population and covering all six
lution (1977) as well as, more recently, the inhabited continents. This project is carried
Beliefs in Government project headed by out by an international network of social sci-
Max Kaase and Kenneth Newton (1995). The entists, with local funding for each survey,
latter generated a five-volume book series, although in some cases supplementary funds
published in 1995 by Oxford University have been used from outside sources. In
Press, exploring trends in a wide range exchange for providing the data from inter-
of social and political orientations, patterns views with a representative national sample
of political activism, and international of at least 1,000 people in their own society,
attitudes. each participating group gets access to the
data from all of the other participating socie-
ties. The project is guided by the World
Values Survey Association, representing all
GOING GLOBAL: THE WORLD VALUES regions of the world. Coordination is man-
SURVEY/EUROPEAN VALUES SURVEY aged by an executive steering committee and
secretariat, chaired by Ronald Inglehart at
The Euro-Barometer also contributed directly the University of Michigan.
toward the European Values Survey.6 This The World Values Study remains the only
project was launched in 1981 by a Belgian academic global public opinion survey

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 7 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


THE GLOBALIZATION OF COMPARATIVE PUBLIC OPINION RESEARCH 529

with a standard instrument administered in in 43 nations, including many industrial and


countries in all world regions, including post-industrial societies.11 Each survey covers a
growing geographic coverage of societies in representative sample of the national popula-
the Middle East, Asia, and Africa. Time- tion. The focus is the inclusion of a thematic
series analysis is hindered by the fact that annual module with a battery of items carried in
country coverage and certain items vary existing social national surveys, with the annual
across successive waves, and the 1981–1983 theme covering rotating issues in the social sci-
first wave focused on post-industrial socie- ences, such as national identity, the role of
ties. Nevertheless the WVS provides a bench- government, religion, the environment, work
mark for many developing societies, such as orientations, and gender roles. Considerable
South Africa, where for many years it was attention is paid toward standardizing the social
the only widely available cross-national and demographic background information in
survey monitoring a wide range of social and the surveys. The ISSP has a more limited geo-
political values. This study has given rise to graphic scope than the World Values Survey,
numerous publications, in 16 languages.9 and a narrower thematic focus than the WVS or
The Human beliefs and values sourcebook the Euro-Barometers. Nevertheless, the survey
(Inglehart et al., 2004) makes the data easily provides considerable depth on each thematic
available. The WVS website facilitates the topic, with some comparisons over time where
online generation of simple descriptive sta- modules are repeated, and a rigorous focus
tistics, such as frequencies and cross-tabula- on establishing the quality of cross-national
tions, as well as making available the survey methods. The ISSP has generated almost
questionnaires, technical details and the 3,000 publications, including various edited
downloadable dataset.10 collections.12

THE INTERNATIONAL SOCIAL THE COMPARATIVE STUDY


SURVEY PROGRAM OF ELECTORAL SYSTEMS

In 1972, in the University of Chicago, One of the most notable off-springs of the
NORC started the General Social Survey, an behavioral revolution were the programs of
annual (subsequently biennial) study of academic election surveys based on national
social and political attitudes. Other countries probability samples of the electorate, which
followed suit, including the Allgeme- followed the establishment in 1948 of the
inen Bevolkerungsumfragen der Social- American National Election Study series at
wissenschaften (ALLBUS) of the Zentrum für the University of Michigan. Similar pro-
Umfragen, Methoden, und Analysen (ZUMA) grams of national election studies were estab-
in Mannheim, Germany in 1980 and the British lished in Sweden (1956), Germany (1961),
Social Attitudes series conducted by Social and Norway (1965), Britain (1963), and the
Community Planning Research (SCPR), Netherlands (1971). Often there were direct
London in 1983. The International Social exports from the Michigan team, a process
Survey Program (ISSP) was established in exemplified by the establishment of the
1985 to expand cross-national collaboration by British Election Study by Donald Stokes and
bringing together pre-existing, social science David Butler, a series carried out by teams of
projects. The ISSP coordinates research goals scholars in each subsequent British general
among the consortium, thereby adding a cross- election. Stokes also collaborated with Don
national perspective to the individual, national Aitkin in the first Australian national election
studies. The ISSP started with just six countries study in 1967. Election studies shared many
but it has gradually grown to cover attitudes common intellectual roots, commonly using

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 8 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


530 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

a similar (although not identical) survey (within a year following each of the elections),
research design and questions to monitor provide a unique opportunity to compare
long-term patterns of social, partisan and voting behavior in a way that is not possible
ideological alignments, political and social through other common sources of compara-
values, attitudes toward specific election tive data such as the World Values Survey.
issues and government performance, and Fieldwork, data-collection, and integration of
voting choice and participation. Nevertheless, the third module are underway. Data for each
at least until recently, important inconsisten- wave is released for analysis as soon as it has
cies of methodology and questionnaire design been collected and deposited. The CSES
even in the same series of elections within facilitates cross-national electoral analysis
countries, as well as between nations, ham- although data analysis is complicated by the
pered comparative research efforts over time, diverse range of global regions, regimes, and
as well as cross-nationally. levels of democracy included in the study.
The launch of the Comparative Study of This suggests adoption of a ‘most different’
Electoral Systems in the mid-1990s strength- comparative strategy, rather than the familiar
ened collaborative links among national elec- regional/area approach. The integration of the
tion studies in over 50 nation-states, by data collected from each national election
developing a common battery of questions to survey, for example the demographic and
be carried in each country. The International social coding, is also far more complicated
Committee for Research into Elections and than in a single-funded or single-instrument
Representative Democracy (ICORE), founded survey, such as the Euro-barometer. The main
at the 1989 ECPR Joint Workshops, played an strength of the CSES is the capacity for multi-
important role in getting the project off the level analysis combining analysis of voting
ground. The initial idea was to try to under- behavior and political participation within
stand voting choices under varying conditions contrasting institutional contexts.
and institutional rules, suggesting the need to
maximize the number of countries and types
of national election under comparison.13 The
Comparative Study of Electoral Systems THE EUROPEAN VOTER, THE
(CSES) brings together an international team EUROPEAN ELECTION STUDY,
of collaborators who have incorporated a spe- THE COMPARATIVE NATIONAL
cial battery of survey questions into the ELECTIONS PROJECT
national election studies, based on a repre-
sentative sample of the electorate in each Resources for the comparative study of voting
country. Data from each of the separate elec- behavior are supplemented by the integration
tion studies is coordinated, integrated and of six separate national election studies series,
cleaned by the Center for Political Studies, including those conducted over successive
Institute for Social Research, at the University decades in Denmark, Sweden, Norway, the
of Michigan. The dataset is designed to facili- Netherlands, Germany, and Britain, into the
tate the comparison of macro and micro-level European Voter dataset.14 One important limi-
electoral data. Module 1 of the CSES (1996– tation concerns how far differences in wording
2001) allows comparison of a representative and classification schemas used in separate
cross-section of the electorate in 37 legislative questionnaires in the series of national elec-
and presidential national elections in 32 coun- tion studies can be regarded as providing
tries. The geographic coverage is remarkably conceptual equivalence. This is important for
diverse, ranging from Belarus and Ukraine to reliable comparisons of basic background
Canada, Australia, and Belgium. The focus on variables, such as social stratification and
voters’ choices, the cross-national integration, religiosity, as well as for analysis of ideologi-
and above all the timing of the data collection cal and issue positions. Where successive

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 9 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


THE GLOBALIZATION OF COMPARATIVE PUBLIC OPINION RESEARCH 531

teams of researchers lead the research design, through which citizens receive information
amendments to coding schemes, core topics, about policies, parties, candidates during the
or question wording are often introduced over course of election campaigns, thus reviving
time into national election surveys. In such the long neglected research perspective of the
situations, it is difficult to establish if these Columbia School established by Paul
discontinuities produced subtle but significant Lazarsfeld and his colleagues in the 1940s
differences in responses, or whether public and 1950s. The study is particularly rich on
opinion has indeed altered. In addition, the questions about information flows via pri-
comparative framework is limited to parts of mary and secondary networks, as well as the
Northern Europe; the dataset excludes avail- role of the mass media.17
able series such as the American National
Election Study, as well as many European
countries, such as France, Spain, and Ireland,
which have not established an equivalent con- THE GLOBAL-BAROMETERS
tinuous series. The time-series is also irregu-
lar, with series starting in 1956 in Sweden but Rather than a single entity, the global-
only in 1971 in the Netherlands and Denmark. barometer series consists of five separate
Nevertheless, with these provisos, the inte- regional projects, loosely coordinated, and
grated European Voter dataset has facilitated originally inspired by the Eurobarometer
systematic cross-national time-series analysis model. These focus upon attitudes toward
for classic issues in voting behavior, such as democracy, governance, economics, political
whether social cleavages and partisan identifi- participation, and national identity, with a
cation have gradually weakened their imprint special focus on newer democracies in devel-
on the electorate in successive elections across oping nations. The New Europe series, coor-
West European polities. dinated by Richard Rose, has focused upon
Since 1979, the quinquennial series of monitoring the process of cultural change in
European Election Study (EES) has also political and economic attitudes following
explored voting choice, participation, and the breakdown of communism. The annual
ideological issues in the direct elections to survey has been conducted in selected Central
the European Parliament, as well as facilitat- and Eastern European countries and it has
ing comparison of mass-elite attitudes, the resulted in numerous papers and books.
evolution of the European community, and Under the leadership of Marta Lagos (MORI,
perceptions about the EU’s performance.15 Santiago), the Latinobarometer has con-
The scope of the survey has expanded with ducted pioneering work monitoring annual
EU membership. The EES has generated a trends in attitudes toward democracy. The
series of books and articles, contributing to series started with eight nations in 1995, ini-
important methodological innovations as tially funded by the EU, and it has subse-
well as expanding our understanding of the quently expanded to cover representative
conditions of voting choice and turnout in samples of the publics in eighteen countries
‘second-order’ contests.16 in the region. Founded as a private, non-
The Comparative National Elections profit institution, the survey has been less
Project (CNEP) is another related study, widely utilized by Latin Americanists than
coordinated by Richard Gunther, currently might be expected, given the topic and the
including two-dozen national election sur- quality of the data. Online interactive access
veys conducted in 19 countries since 1990. It to the questionnaire database is available.18
has evolved in three distinct phases: CNEP I, The Afro-barometer was pioneered by
CNEP II, and CNEP III, which have steadily Michael Bratton et al. who developed net-
widened the global coverage. All share a works of surveyors in many countries, such
concern with the processes of intermediation as Mali, Tanzania, and Zambia which have

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 10 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


532 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

never had a series of social scientific surveys generation of graduate students with the nec-
of political and social attitudes.19 The Afro- essary intellectual frameworks, skills, and
barometer has conducted three rounds of infrastructure to exploit the data.
national probability sample surveys covering
18 African countries in the most recent study.
It also serves as a model of transparency by
releasing full information about the work in THE EUROPEAN SOCIAL
progress, including questionnaires, publica- SURVEY
tions, funding, and associates, as well as
depositing all data through archives and its The European Social Survey (the ESS), which
own dedicated website.20 started in 2002, is an academically-driven
The East Asia Barometer joined the net- social survey designed to chart and explain the
work in 2002, sharing similar concerns to interaction between Europe’s changing insti-
monitor public attitudes toward democratiza- tutions and the attitudes, beliefs and behavior
tion and economic development, with eight patterns of its diverse populations.25 The
nations coordinated in the survey by Yun-han survey covers two-dozen nations (in Western
Chu in Taiwan.21 The study expanded in and Central Europe) and it uses rigorous
2006 to become the Asian Barometer cover- methodologies. The survey contains a core
ing 17 nations (Japan, Mongolia, South battery of questions that is replicated every
Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, China, the two years in addition to rotating thematic
Philippines, Thailand, Vietnam, Cambodia, modules, allocated to teams of scholars on a
Singapore, Indonesia, India, Pakistan, competitive basis. Core funding comes from
Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, and Nepal).22 Lastly, the European Commission’s 5th Framework
under the leadership of Mark Tessler at the Programme, with supplementary funds from
University of Michigan, in 2006 the Arab the European Science Foundation which also
Barometer conducted surveys of economic sponsored the development of the study over a
and political attitudes in five Arab societies number of years, while surveys in each coun-
(the Palestinian Territories, Jordan, Morocco, try are funded by each national social science
Algeria, and Kuwait).23 council. The project is directed by a Central
Contemporary survey research is therefore Coordinating Team led by Roger Jowell at the
now covering large parts of the developing Centre for Comparative Social Surveys, City
world, such as Africa and the Middle East, University. The organization of the survey
which were previously neglected, thereby emphasizes transparency and employing high
building up the infrastructure of experienced standards in sampling and fieldwork practices,
fieldwork teams, market and social science and it is carefully standardizing the collection
research organizations, and survey analysts of social and demographic background data.
that will pay dividends in future. The surveys The central coordination and funding of
facilitate cross-national networks among net- the ESS, the care in crafting and testing the
works of collaborators, while also retaining questionnaire, and the development of addi-
the flexibility of regional autonomy to focus tional contextual data, provides a model for
on specific themes of most interest to cross-national survey research.
each area. The Global-barometer project is
seeking to strengthen the collaborative link-
ages to use consistent question wording and
methodologies.24 An important challenge is THE PEW GLOBAL
to make sure that this data is not simply ATTITUDES SURVEY
exported to the west but that it is available
and utilized by the social science communi- US-based survey organizations have
ties within each region, by equipping the next also contributed toward the expansion of

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 11 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


THE GLOBALIZATION OF COMPARATIVE PUBLIC OPINION RESEARCH 533

global resources. In response to the aftermath and the role of public opinion in foreign
of 9/11, Afghanistan and Iraq, attention in the policy. Sponsored by the German Marshall
United States has turned increasingly toward Fund of the United States and the Compagnia
understanding how the world (particularly di San Paolo, with additional support from
Muslim societies) views America. ‘Soft other foundations, the survey focuses upon
diplomacy’ through the mass media has also attitudes in the United States and up to a
spurred greater interest among the interna- dozen European countries. The study looks
tional relations and foreign policy commu- at a range of issues including the state of
nity into issues of global cultural similarity transatlantic relations; perceptions of inter-
and difference. national threats, such as terrorism, energy
In response, in 2002 Andrew Kohut at the dependence, immigration, and global warm-
Pew Center for the People and the Press ing; attitudes toward the EU as a global actor
launched the Pew Global Attitudes Survey, an in development, trade, peacekeeping, recon-
annual attempt to monitor public opinion in struction, and combat; transatlantic coopera-
many countries, using market research. The tion on international challenges such as
project is a series of worldwide public opin- Afghanistan, Iran and Russia, and democracy
ion surveys, originally of more than 38,000 promotion as a foreign policy goal. The sur-
people in 44 countries in 2002, and expanded veys are designed primarily for journalists
in 2003 with additional surveys to a total of and policymakers, rather than for academic
nearly 75,000 people among the 50 popula- research.
tions surveyed (49 countries plus the
Palestinian Authority). The initiative built on
an earlier study, the Pulse of Europe (1991).
The project encompasses a broad array of GALLUP INTERNATIONAL
subjects ranging from people’s assessments VOICE OF THE PEOPLE
of their own lives to their views about the
current state of the world and important The last survey under comparison, coordi-
issues of the day. The Pew Global Attitudes nated by Gallup International, is similar in
Project is chaired by former US Secretary of orientation to the Pew survey but with a more
State Madeleine K. Albright. The project is commercial orientation. In 2002, Gallup
funded by The Pew Charitable Trusts, with a International conducted a worldwide survey
supplemental grant from the William and of 60 nations monitoring attitudes toward
Flora Hewlett Foundation. The published issues such as the environment, terrorism,
reports have attracted considerable media global issues, governance and democracy. In
attention as well as interest in the 2003 this survey was conducted again cover-
State Department and in the broader policy ing Western Europe, the USA, and Canada
community. but also Africa, the Middle East, Asia, Eastern
Europe, and Latin America. Highlights of the
results are published on their website but the
published report (containing detailed cross-
TRANSATLANTIC TRENDS tabulations) and the electronic data are avail-
able only for commercial purchase. Gallup
Similar factors prompted the launch of the International offers the opportunity for cli-
Transatlantic Trends project in 2002, an ents to add items to the questionnaire, also at
annual public opinion survey examining cost. Information about the quality of the
American and European attitudes toward the detailed methodology, sampling, and field-
transatlantic relationship.26 Indeed this con- work practices in countries where surveys
cern reflects some of the earliest surveys are uncommon, such as in the Middle East
about how national publics regard each other, and Africa, are available on Gallup’s website.

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 12 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


534 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Both Pew and Gallup are therefore breaking and global barometers, have been driven by
new ground by expanding their geographic the urge to understand the process of democ-
coverage in ambitious attempts to monitor racy and democratization. International devel-
public opinion around the world. This con- opment agencies, such as the UNDP, the
tributes to the resources available for analysis World Bank, and Transparency International,
although it remains too early to evaluate the have increasingly recognized that programs
quality and utility of these surveys. seeking to expand democracy and good gov-
ernance need to monitor public opinion, as
well as using the standard ‘objective’ develop-
mental indicators.
THE GLOBALIZATION OF PUBLIC Particular scholars in the field have had a
OPINION SURVEYS decisive and enduring impact. Many col-
leagues have contributed to this process,
What facilitated these developments? Many including early pioneers such as Sidney
political and intellectual factors have contrib- Verba at Harvard University, Jacques-Rene
uted toward the internationalization of attitu- Rabier in the European Union, Ronald
dinal and behavioral survey. As the world has Inglehart at the University of Michigan,
become more interconnected through globali- Jaques Thomassen at the University of
zation, the social sciences have been tugged in Twente, Richard Gunther at Ohio State
its wake. The gradual expansion of the borders University, Marta Lagos at MORI-Chile, and
of the European Union played a direct role, as Roger Jowell at City University, all of whom
the European Commission has monitored played seminal roles, through initiating, man-
public opinion on a regular basis since the aging, and sustaining major cross-national
early-1970s through the Euro-barometer and surveys which have had multiplier effects
related surveys of mass and elite opinion. In through funding public opinion institutes and
turn, the existence of the Euro-barometer, training the next generation of field-work
including the fieldwork organizations and col- staff and survey analysts. The availability of
laborators, served as a model shaping many training institutes has also contributed, such
other initiatives, such as the 1981 European as the Michigan and Essex summer schools
Values Study and the 1979 European Elections in social statistics, through strengthening
Study. Regional and international associations skills in quantitative analysis among the
of political scientists have strengthened pro- younger generation of social scientists in
fessional networks and institutional linkages, many countries. Modern international com-
notably the International Political Science munications, notably the ease of communi-
Association and especially the European cating among colleagues and distributing
Consortium of Political Research, with regu- electronic datasets online through the stand-
lar workshops and conferences which strength- ard social science archives and dedicated
ened intellectual and social networks among websites, have greatly facilitated awareness
teams of collaborators. The growth of elec- and use of these resources. Whether leading
toral democracies has also probably facilitated or following, intellectual fashions have also
the study of public opinion, since this devel- contributed toward this process, eroding
opment facilitates freedom of expression for interest in traditional approaches to area
conducting independent social surveys and studies focused on specific countries, and
publishing the results of the analysis, also trig- encouraging the demand among the younger
gering the demand for commercial market generation of researchers in Asia, Latin
research companies and non-profit social sci- America, and Eastern Europe for more sys-
ence institutes, free from political interference tematic cross-national comparison of politi-
and overt state censorship. Many of the sur- cal culture and behavior, conducted within
veys, from the Civic culture study to the CSES varying institutional contexts.

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 13 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


THE GLOBALIZATION OF COMPARATIVE PUBLIC OPINION RESEARCH 535

The most recent spur has been the events of left-right continuum or the liberal-conserva-
9/11 and their aftermath in the Afghanistan tive scale are interpreted quite differently in
and Iraq war, renewing American interest different societies; for example ‘liberal’ in
about public opinion in the rest of the world. the United States is usually understood as
In particular, this has stimulated new research social liberalism located on the ‘left’ of the
in areas such as the Middle East where previ- political spectrum, while ‘liberal’ in Europe
ously cross-national social science surveys is commonly regarded as ‘economic’ or ‘free
have been non-existent or scarce. These devel- market’ liberalism located on the center-
opments have gradually transformed the geo- right. The complexity of notions which are
graphic scope of coverage, with an exponential carried in social surveys, such as the con-
surge in the available survey resources occur- cepts of ‘democracy’, ‘corruption’, ‘religios-
ring during the last decade, allowing compara- ity’, or ‘nationalism’, may well generate
tivists to move ‘from nations to categories’, responses to the same words and phrases
one of the key but elusive goals of the which are far from functionally-equivalent.
sub-discipline. At the same time, while a particular chal-
lenge in interpreting the results of cross-
national surveys, this problem is far from
unique to these studies. Multilingual and
METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES ARISING plural societies face similar language issues,
FROM CROSS-NATIONAL SURVEYS for example in India, as do cities and regions
of the United States, such as California and
Nevertheless the expansion worldwide that New York, with a high proportion of immi-
has occurred has also raised critical challenges grants and non-native speakers. Indeed the
about ensuring the quality and comparability broader issue of whether the same wording
of the cross-national surveys (Jowell, 1998; generates the equivalent meaning also applies
Kuechler, 1987, 1998). Some of these con- to interpreting any group differences in
cerns are far from novel; indeed concern dates response within any society, for example
back to the original Almond and Verba study whether there are shared understandings
(Verba, 1971). These concerns have arisen among social classes, regions, or sexes. The
with greater urgency, however, with the grow- most appropriate, although not the perfect,
ing spread of methods, techniques and theo- standard way to try to ensure language equiva-
retical frameworks in diverse cultures and lence uses processes of translation and then
contexts, including across varied developing ‘back’ translation, which seeks to ensure lin-
societies (Park and Jowell, 1997). guistic consistency. The questionnaire design-
The first issue which is often raised is ers should also provide supplementary notes
about conceptual equivalence (van Deth, for translators explaining the intended mean-
1998; and in this volume). McIntyre (1973) ing of questions, to help identify functionally-
voiced the concern whether core concepts equivalent phrases (Harkness, 2007). Rigorous
such as national pride, used in the civic cul- tests should ideally also be employed, includ-
ture study, carried similar meanings in the ing piloting new questions prior to wholesale
context of societies such as Italy, Germany roll out and also checking by comparing the
and Britain. This issue is a constant challenge error structure for several items, and thus the
for cross-national questionnaires which reliability and validity of these questions in
extends far beyond matters of linguistic different languages.27 In addition exploratory
translation. Languages are not just ways to factor analysis can be used as a check on
communicate the same ideas and values; whether attitudinal and ideological scales
instead they may carry alternative ways of have similar meaning in different societies.
thinking and understanding. This problem is Another major issue concerns the strict
often encountered when ideas such as the standards which should be used to evaluate the

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 14 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


536 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

quality of any survey data and any systematic conventions, question order, fieldwork timing,
sources of error or bias. Even modest meth- or sampling procedures can seriously limit the
odological differences in coding schemes, comparability of the responses. Unfortunately
questionnaire design and item order, sampling demographic and social classifications,
processes, fieldwork and interview techniques, random probability or quota sampling meth-
or cooperation and response rates can contrib- ods, and forms of interviewing or non-
ute toward misleading interpretations of the response rates may be deeply institutionalized
significance of any cross-national differences in the procedures used by each survey organi-
in attitudes and values (Heath et al., 2005; zation. Piggybacking a few questions into
Kuechler, 1998). There are three main catego- omnibus commercial or attitudinal surveys in
ries of cross-national datasets, and these differ each country is highly problematic, due to dif-
substantially in how far they facilitate control ferences of sequencing and item order. Where
of standards. Centralized surveys are adminis- there are common resources sponsoring the
tered and coordinated by a team of investiga- survey instrument and fieldwork, and a tight
tors, who raise and pool common core organizational and decision-making structure
resources, with a single dedicated question- among teams of collaborators, as with the
naire instrument translated into different lan- European Social Survey, this is most likely to
guages (exemplified by the Euro-barometers ensure the most rigorous and consistent tech-
directed by the European Commission). nical standards. Yet for many reasons, includ-
Collaborative surveys are also centrally ing lack of resources, most cross-national
administered by a core team with a single surveys do not have this framework. The best
common survey instrument, but fieldwork for approach in these circumstances is to make
each national survey is mainly funded from sure that all procedures and technical matters
local sources (e.g., the World Values Survey). are clearly documented and that this is avail-
Lastly, integrative projects bring together able to researchers, who can then decide how
locally administered and locally-funded best to handle any inconsistencies. In addition,
surveys (e.g., The European Voter Study). the expansion in the availability of surveys in
Common standards are easiest to maintain multiple countries facilitates replication of
in the first category, and most difficult in the results, so that generalizations made on the
last. Making sure that methods and techniques basis of a few cases, or a single region, can
are similar is a considerable challenge even be tested in other contexts and different
with the same survey instrument, such as the conditions.
European Social Survey, used by different
fieldwork organizations. It is even more prob-
lematic in projects such as the Comparative
Study of Electoral Systems and the European CONCLUSIONS
Voter, which seek to integrate standards used
in independent parallel national surveys. The Opportunities for cross-national survey
battery of items in the CSES, for example, can research have been transformed out of all rec-
be carried in the main face-to-face question- ognition over the last decades. Until the early-
naire or it may be administered through a self- 1970s, most cross-national surveys of public
completion supplementary questionnaire. opinion were largely focused upon affluent
Standardization is as important for the back- post-industrial societies, particularly Western
ground demographic and social variables, Europe as a natural comparative laboratory,
especially classifications based on social strat- where market research organizations had
ification, religious faith and ethnic identity, as become widely established, where there
it is for attitudinal and behavioral items, such were dense networks of scholars and data
as voting and party choice or ideological self- archives, and where foundations and social
placement. Even modest variations in coding science councils had the resources to support

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 15 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


THE GLOBALIZATION OF COMPARATIVE PUBLIC OPINION RESEARCH 537

academic research. The 1985 launch and up experienced market research companies
gradual expansion of the International Social and established social science institutes.
Survey Program, accompanied by the trans- There are also issues about the reliability of
formation of the European Values Survey into conducting public opinion surveys in coun-
the World Values Survey in 1990, represented tries such as Belarus and China with repres-
the start of the globalization of public opinion sive regimes which regularly suppress
research, a trend which continues today. freedom of expression and opinion.
Developing societies had most commonly Nevertheless the expansion of datasets has
used administrative and social surveys, as well the important benefit of allowing replication
as collecting census data, for information across different surveys, thereby allowing
about social conditions. An example was the independent cross-checks. Questions can be
first national household survey, which was raised about the quality of questionnaire
pioneered in India in 1950 (Bulmer, 1993). translations and the employment of equiva-
Mexico had also been included in some of the lent standards across different nations –
earliest surveys on political participation. But debates which have been with us ever since
until the early-1990s, few cross-national sur- The civic culture. Yet in counterbalance there
veys which systematically monitored social are certain distinct practical advantages asso-
and political attitudes and behavior based on ciated with conducting surveys in developing
random samples of the general population nations, namely much lower refusal and non-
were available covering a wide range of response rates (currently approaching record
developing nations. The availability of cross- levels for opinion polls conducted in the US),
national datasets was transformed by the as well as relatively low budgets for field-
gradual expansion of successive waves of the work. Over time, as greater experience is
World Values Survey since 1991 to over 90 gained, and as an institutional survey infra-
nation-states, the network of national electoral structure is developed in the social
studies brought together under the umbrella of sciences, these initiatives will gradually
the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems, mature.
the global barometer series covering a wide Therefore despite important limitations,
range of countries in Latin America, post- cross-national survey research is invaluable
Communist states in the New Europe barom- for establishing generalities about human
eter, Africa, and Asia, as well as the 2002 behavior, allowing us to test regularities aris-
European Social Survey, Transatlantic Trends, ing from single-nation studies. The multi-
and the Pew and Gallup global surveys plicity of datasets which are now available
launched in recent years. for analysis in different societies strengthens
The multiplicity of surveys is to be wel- replication, to ensure robust findings and
comed by facilitating replication both across generalizations, for example comparing
years and among nations. Some of the more trends in religiosity or class voting in the
commercial initiatives may fail, for example same countries using the Euro-Barometer,
if America withdraws into itself and turns the World Values Survey and the European
away from the world again, in its periodic Voter study. Most importantly, the availabil-
cyclical fashion. Yet it seems likely that the ity of many large-scale multi-national sur-
underlying momentum will continue in sub- veys covering many societies allows us to
sequent decades, as younger generations of move from the analysis of countries to the
social scientists trained in survey methods study of public opinion under a wide variety
and public opinion analysis are developing of institutional and societal contexts, such as
in each world region. Questions can be in developing and post-industrial economies,
raised about the quality of sampling and in predominately Muslim or Orthodox socie-
fieldwork, especially for surveys conducted ties, in newer democracies in Mediterranean
in developing nations which have not built and Eastern Europe, or under democratic and

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 16 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


538 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

autocratic regimes. Aggregating public opin- 6. I greatly appreciate the comments that Ronald
ion at societal level across multiple countries Inglehart conveyed in personal communications about
the historical evolution of the Euro-barometer and the
allows systematic tests of some of the core European Values/World Values Surveys.
concerns in the discipline, such as whether 7. http://www.europeanvalues.nl
underlying individual-level attitudes such as 8. Full methodological details about the World
trust or political efficacy are conducive to the Values Surveys, including the questionnaires, sam-
stability of democratic stability, as the civic pling procedures, fieldwork procedures, principle
investigators, and organization can be found at:
culture study suggested. With a sufficiently www.worldvaluessurvey.org.
large number of countries, the linkages 9. Among the many publications emerging
between culture, social structure, and regime from this project, books include Inglehart and Norris
institutions can be examined. Through this (2003), Inglehart and Welzel (2005), Norris and
process, the sub-field is gradually moving Inglehart (2004).
10. www.worldvaluessurvey.org.
from the comparison of individuals and 11. ISSP has grown to 43 nations, the founding
groups within countries as the core unit of four – Germany, the United States, Great Britain, and
analysis toward the comparison of people Australia – plus Austria, Ireland, Hungary, the
living under different types of societies and Netherlands, Italy, Israel, Norway, the Philippines, New
regimes, a development which is capable of Zealand, Russia, Japan, Bulgaria, Canada, the Czech
Republic, Slovenia, Poland, Sweden, Spain, Cyprus,
providing powerful new insights for the France, Portugal, Slovakia, Latvia, Chile, Denmark,
study of comparative politics. Brazil, South Africa, Switzerland, Venezuela, Belgium,
Finland, Mexico, Taiwan, South Korea, Uruguay,
Croatia, the Dominican Republic, Turkey, and China.
In addition, East Germany was added to the German
sample upon reunification.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS 12. For instance, Jowell et al. 1993, 1989,
1998.
This chapter greatly benefited from detailed 13. For the use of the dataset for this purpose, see
and invaluable comments and observations Norris (2004).
made to an earlier draft by Ronald Inglehart 14. See Thomassen (2005). Data and
methodological details are available from ZUMA
and Ian McAllister, including information (2008).
about the historical evolution of the Euro- 15. For details about the methodology, research
barometer and the European Values/World design and questionnaire, see http://www.europe-
Values Surveys, as well as background to the anelectionstudies.net/.
CSES. 16. Book publication include, amongst others,
Katz and Wessels (1999), Schmitt and Thomassen
(2000), van der Brug and van der Eijk’s (forthcom-
ing), van der Eijk and Arbor (1996).
17. See Gunther et al. (2007), and http://www.
NOTES cnep.ics.ul.pt.
18. http://www.latinobarometro.org/
1. A comprehensive chronological list of compar- 19. Publications emerging from the
ative survey research resources and datasets is availa- Afrobarometer series include Bratton et al. (2004).
ble at http://www.gesis.org/en/data_service/ 20. For information about the methodology and
eurobarometer/handbook/index.htm; see also data, see http://www.afrobarometer.org.
Donsbach and Traugott (2008). 21. See http://www.eastasiabarometer.org.
2. For the intellectual history of the origins of the 22. http://www.asianbarometer.org/; see also,
civic culture study, see Almond (1996) and Munck Inoguchi et al. (2006).
and Snyder (2007). 23. http://arabbarometer.org/
3. EB website: http://ec.europa.eu/public_opin- 24. http://www.globalbarometer.net/
ion/cf/index_en.cfm 25. For details, http://www.europeansocialsur-
4. Details can be found at: http://www.za.uni- vey.org/. See also Jowell et al. (2007).
koeln.de/ 26. http://www.transatlantictrends.org.
5. Details can be found at: http://europa.eu.int/ 27. See the recommendations by Saris and
en/comm/dg10/infcom/epo/eb.html. Gallhofer (2007).

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 17 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


THE GLOBALIZATION OF COMPARATIVE PUBLIC OPINION RESEARCH 539

Dahl, R.A. (1961) ‘The behavioral approach in


REFERENCES political science: Epitaph for a monument to
a successful protest’, The American Political
Almond, G. (1996) The civic culture: Prehistory, Science Review, 55 (4): 763–72.
retrospect, and prospect (Center for the Donsbach, W. and Traugott, M. (2008) The
Study of Democracy paper 96-01) University SAGE handbook of public opinion research.
of California, Irvine. Retrieved March 27, London: Sage.
2008, from http://repositories.cdlib.org/ Eckstein, H. (1961) A theory of stable democracy.
csd/96–01 Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Almond, G. and Verba, S. (1963) The civic Geer, J. (ed.) (2004) Public opinion and polling
culture. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University around the world: A historical encyclopedia.
Press. Santa Barbara, CA: ABC-Clio.
Barnes, S., Kaase, M., and Allerbeck, K.R. Gunther, R., Puhle, H.J., and Montero, J.R.
(1979) Political action: Mass participation in (eds) (2007) Democracy, intermediation, and
five Western democracies. Beverley Hills, voting on four continents. Oxford: Oxford
CA: Sage Publications. University Press.
Bowley, A.L. and Burnett-Hurst, A.R. (1915) Harkness, J.A. (2007) ‘Improving the compara-
Livelihood and poverty: A study in the eco- bility of translations’, in R. Jowell, C. Roberts,
nomic conditions of working-class house- R. Fitzgerald, and G. Eva (eds), Measuring
holds. Bell. attitudes cross-nationally: Lessons from the
Bratton, M., Mattes, R., and Gyimah-Boadi, E. European Social Survey. London: Sage
(2004) Learning about reform in Africa: Publications.
Public opinion, democracy, and markets. Heath, A., Fisher, S., and Smith, S. (2005)
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ‘The globalization of public opinion
Buchanan, W. and Cantril, H. (1953) How research’, Annual Review of Political Studies,
nations see each other: A study in public 8: 297–333.
opinion. Urbana: University of Illinois Press. Inglehart, R. (1977) The silent revolution.
Bulmer, M. (1986) The Chicago school of soci- Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
ology: Institutionalization, diversity, and the Inglehart, R. and Norris, P. (2003) Rising tide:
rise of sociological research. Chicago: Gender equality and cultural change world-
University of Chicago Press. wide. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Bulmer, M. (1993) Social research in develop- Press.
ing countries: Surveys and censuses in the Inglehart, R., Basàñez, M., Dìez-Medrano, J.,
Third World. London: Routledge. Halman, L., and Luijkx, R. (eds) (2004)
Bulmer, M. (1998) ‘The problem of exporting Human beliefs and values: A cross-cultural
social survey research’, The American sourcebook. Mexico: Siglo XXI Editores.
Behavioral Scientist, 42 (2): 153–67. Inglehart, R. and Welzel, C. (2005)
Bulmer, M., Bales, K., and Sklar, K.K. (eds.) Modernization, cultural change and democ-
(1992) The social survey in historical perspec- racy: The human development sequence.
tive, 1880–1940. Cambridge: Cambridge Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
University Press. Inoguchi, T., Tanaka, A., Sonoda, S., and
Clinton Poole, D. (1937) ‘Forward’, The Public Dadabaev, T. (eds) (2006) Human beliefs and
Opinion Quarterly, 1 (1): 3–5. values in striding Asia. East Asia in focus:
Converse, J.M. (1987) Survey research in the Country profiles, thematic analysis, and sour-
United States: Roots and emergence 1890– cebook based on the AsiaBarometer Survey
1960. Berkeley: University of California of 2004. Japan: Akashi Shoten.
Press. Jowell, R. (1998) ‘How comparative is com-
Converse, P.E. (1964) ‘Review of Almond and parative research?’, American Behavioral
Verba’s “The civic culture: Political attitudes Scientist, 42: 168–77.
and democracy in five nations”’, Political Jowell, R., Brook, L., Dowds, L., and Ahrendt,
Science Quarterly, 79 (4): 591–93. D. (eds) (1993) International social attitudes:
Crossley, A.M. (1937) ‘Straw polls in 1936’, The 10th British social attitudes report.
The Public Opinion Quarterly, 1 (1): 24–35. Aldershot: Dartmouth.

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 18 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


540 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Jowell, R., Curtice, J., Park, A., Brook, L., Norris, P. and Inglehart, R. (2004) Sacred and
Thomson, K., and Bryson, C. (eds) (1998) secular: Religion and politics worldwide.
British – and European – social attitudes: The Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
15th BSA report. Aldershot: Ashgate. Park, A. and Jowell, R. (1997) Consistencies
Jowell, R., Roberts, C., Fitzgerald, R., and Eva, G. and differences in a cross-national survey.
(eds) (2007) Measuring attitudes cross- London: SCPR.
nationally: Lessons from the European Social Saris, W.E. and Gallhofer, I. (2007) ‘Can ques-
Survey. London: Sage Publications. tions travel successfully?’, in R. Jowell, C.
Jowell, R., Witherspoon, S., and Brook, L. (eds) Roberts, R. Fitzgerald and G. Eva (eds),
(1989) British social attitudes: Special inter- Measuring attitudes cross-nationally: Lessons
national report. Aldershot: Gower. from the European Social Survey. London:
Kaase, M. and Newton, K. (1995) Beliefs in Sage Publications.
government. Oxford: Oxford University Schmitt, H. and Thomassen, J. (eds) (2000)
Press. Political representation and legitimacy in the
Katz, R. and Wessels, B. (1999) European par- European Union. Oxford: Oxford University
liament and European integration. Oxford, Press.
Oxford University Press. Stouffer, S.A., et al. (1949) The American sol-
Kuechler, M. (1987) ‘The utility of surveys for dier. Studies in social psychology in World
cross-national research’, Social Science War II (Vol 1–2) Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Research, 16: 229–44. University Press.
Kuechler, M. (1998) ‘The survey method: An Tingsten, H. (1937/1963) Political behavior:
indispensable tool for social science research Studies in election statistics. Totowa, NJ:
everywhere?’, American Behavioral Scientist, Bedminster Press.
42 (2): 178–200. Thomassen, J. (ed.) (2005) The European voter.
McIntyre, A. (1973) ‘Is a science of comparative Oxford: Oxford University Press.
politics possible?’, in A. Ryan (ed.), The van der Brug, W. and van der Eijk, C. (eds)
Philosophy of social explanation. Oxford: (forthcoming) European elections and
Oxford University Press. domestic politics. Lessons from the past and
Lasswell, H.D. (1930) Psychopathology and scenarios for the future. Southbend:
politics. Chicago: Chicago University Press. University of Notre Dame Press.
Lazarsfeld, P.F., Gaudet, H., and Berelson, B. van der Eijk, C. and Franklin, M. (eds) (1996)
(1944) The people’s choice: How the voter Choosing Europe? The electorate and
makes up his mind in a presidential cam- national politics in the face of union. Ann
paign. New York: Duell, Sloan and Pearce. Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Merriam, C.E. (1931) The making of citizens: van Deth, J. (ed.) (1998) Comparative politics:
A comparative study of methods of civil The problem of equivalence. London:
training. Chicago: University of Chicago Routledge.
Press. Verba, S. (1971) ‘Cross-national survey research:
Merriam, C.E. and Gosnell, H.F. (1924) Non- the problem of credibility’, in I. Vallier (ed.),
voting, causes and methods of control. Comparative methods in sociology: Essays
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. on trends and applications. Berkeley:
Munck, G.L. and Snyder, R. (2007) Passion, University of California Press.
craft, and method in comparative politics. ZUMA (2008) The European Voter – database
Johns Hopkins Press. description. Retrieved March 31, 2008, from
Norris, P. (2004) Electoral engineering. New York: https://info1.za.gesis.org/cei/evoter-db.asp
Cambridge University Press.

9781412919760_Chap28.indd 19 3/11/2009 4:49:14 PM


Index

(page references followed by f indicate a figurative illustration, t indicates a table)

Abbott, A., 80, 113, 115 Alston et al., 450


Abdelal et al., 132 Alt, J. E., 200
Abrams, D., 328 Althusius, 410–11
accountability and democracy, 439, 440, 441, Alvarez, R. M., 265
442, 445, 448, 449–50, 452, 457 Alvarez et al., 37, 201, 280
Acemoglu, D., 282, 283, 287, 290, 293, 294, American Institute of Public Opinion, 525
295, 314, 336, 447, 457, 458 American National Election Study, 264, 529, 531
Acemoglu et al., 446, 450, 451 American Journal of Political Science, 1, 52
Acharya, A., 479, 482, 484, 485 American Political Science Association on
Achen, C. H., 60 Comparative Politics, 1, 51, 160
Ackerman, B., 254 newsletter, 159
activism, 305t, 309f, 311, 312, 313, 315 American Political Science Review (APSR), 1, 2,
see also social movements 52, 250
Adams, J., 147, 156 Aminzade et al., 321, 331
Adams et al., 102, 108, 111 Amnesty International, 74, 429
Adcock, R., 473 Amorim, N. O., 227
Adler, E., 479 Amsterdam Treaty, 483
Administrative Procedures Act, USA, 449 anarchy, 179, 180, 181, 465
administrative transitional justice, 500t, 506–7 Andersen, G. E., 207
Adrian, C. R., 229 Anderson, C. J., 270, 272, 303
Afghanistan, 168, 320, 322, 323, 339, 419, 420, Anderson, K., 482
429, 465, 533, 535 Anderson, L., 279
Africa, 97, 105, 112, 165, 167, 171, 195, 248, 250, Anderson, P., 107, 109
279, 290, 340, 382, 387, 444, 454, 478, 483, Anderson, T. L., 458
487–9, 490, 491, 498, 529, 532, 533, 537 Anderson et al., 272, 400
African Economic Community (AEC), 488 Andersson, S., 370
African National Congress (ANC), 358 Andrain, G. F., 112
African Union (AU), 487, 488 Andvig, J. C., 371
‘Afro-Asian’, 166 Angola, 320
Afrobarometer, 400, 429, 523t, 531–2, 538 Antoniades, A., 517
Aguilar, P., 515, 519 Apter, D., 101, 112, 163, 164
Aitkin, D., 529 Arab barometer, 524t, 532, 538
Aizenman, J., 448 Arab League, 481
Akhter, M. Y., 402, 405 Arabian countries, 39, 251, 252, 481, 532
Al Qaeda, 382 see also United Arab Emirates
Alatas, S. H., 363, 364 Arbelaez et al., 467
Albright, M., 533 Arbor, A., 538
Albrow, M., 111 Arce, D., 471
Alesina, A., 200 area studies, role of, 159–74
Alesina et al., 146 defining an area, 135–7
Alexander, J., 104, 111 institutional legacies, diffusion, and verstehen,
Algeria, 382, 466, 532 167–70
Alker, H. R. Jr., 78 stereotypes, 161–5
Allan, J. P., 218 Archer, M., 107
ALLBUS, 529 archival information, 53
Allen, M., 205 Argentina, 60, 168, 198t, 373, 401, 420, 487,
Allerbeck, K., 527 502, 505, 511, 516, 519
Almeida, P. D., 355, 356 Argersinger, P. H., 405
Almond, G., 2, 3, 93, 94, 101, 267, 268, 269, 299, 300, Aristotle, 281, 300, 423
302, 312, 432, 522, 525, 526, 527, 535, 538 ‘aristocratic international’ epoch, 183

9781412919760_Index.indd 1 3/13/2009 12:09:39 PM


542 INDEX

Arjomand, S. A., 320 Barbier et al., 371


Armenia, 382, 465 Barkan, E., 505
Armstrong, D., 339 Barnes, S. H., 113, 303, 527
Armstrong, Y., 371 Barnes et al., 527
Arnason, J., 112 Barnett, M., 479
Arnason et al., 112 barometer projects, 400, 429, 522, 523–4t, 527–8
Aron, R., 106 Baron, D. P., 235
Art, D., 515 Barratt, B., 431
Asal et al., 470, 472 Barro, R., 279, 281
Asante, S. K. B., 487, 488 Bartels, L., 146, 295
ASEAN, 477, 484–5 Bastow, S., 234
Asia, 105, 171, 184, 214–15, 248, 279, 319, Bates, R., 127, 159–60, 239, 251, 282, 284, 294, 444
429, 489, 490, 529, 533, 534, 537 Bates et al., 78, 127, 132, 133, 239
Asia-Pacific region, 168 Baum, D., 400, 405
APEC, 485 Bayart, J-F., 108
Asian barometer, 524t Beaulieu, E., 390
Asian financial crisis, 485 Beck, N., 46, 58, 155
Aspinall, E., 391 Beck, T., 402, 405
assemblies, large, 257–8 Beck et al., 155, 400, 459
assignations, 74, 80, 292 Becker, H. S., 28, 75, 80, 81
Assyria, 251 Becker, J., 336
atrocities, 498, 501, 502, 504, 517, 518 Bednar et al., 414
Austen-Smith, D., 235, 241 Beer, C., 433
Australia, 170, 195, 198t, 208, 215, 221, 258, Behaviourism, 179
266, 275, 307f, 309f, 310f, 417, 428, 446, Beichelt et al., 112
529, 530, 538 Beigbeder, Y., 398
Austria, 74, 75, 104, 136, 194, 198t, 213, 215, Beissinger, M., 320
221, 238, 511, 515, 538 Belarus, 381, 382, 384, 537
authoritarianism, 17, 37, 111, 112, 194, 221, 255, Belgium, 196, 198t, 213, 215, 217, 219, 221,
314–15, 320, 340, 403, 432, 498, 504, 514, 366, 410, 417, 498, 530, 538
518–19 Belkin, A., 55
electoral authoritarianism, 381–94; rise of electoral Bellah, R., 109
authoritarianism, 381–2; strategies of Bellamy, R., 252
authoritarian control, 381–4; trajectories of, Bendix, R., 105, 109
389–91 Benford, R. D., 328
post-authoritarian societies, 499, 501, 502, 506, 509, Bénin, 402
510, 511, 514, 515, 516, 518 Benoit, K., 196, 234, 240, 256
see also democratisation, changes in causes through Bennett, A., 2, 14, 50, 52, 53, 55, 56, 57, 58,
time; dictatorships; fascism; Nazism 59, 72, 432, 471, 472
autocorrelation, 41, 44, 45–6, 47 Beramendi, P., 212
autoregression, 41–3, 45, 46, 47, 51 Berejikian, J., 329
ARMA see GLS-ARMA Berelson, B., 275
Axelrod, R., 231, 233 Berezkin et al., 400
Axline, W. A., 481, 490, 491 Berg-Schlosser, D., 17–18, 38
Azam, J. –P., 472 Berger, P., 113, 132
Azerbaijan, 381, 382, 390 Bergman, T., 236, 238
Berman, S., 137, 139f, 169
Bach, D. C., 488–9 Bermeo, N., 355, 357, 358
Bach, M., 111, 112 Bertucci, G., 371
Bäck, H., 239 Besley, T., 149, 454
Badie, B., 251 Bevir, M., 137
Bahcheli et al., 249 Beyer, J., 207
Bahro et al., 254 Beyme, K., 230
Balarus, 338, 530 Bhagwati, J., 481
Baldwin, P., 211, 212 bias, 85, 86–9, 88t, 95–6, 97, 155, 156, 536
Balkans, 465 construct bias, 88t, 89–90
Ball, P. B., 428, 470 instrument bias, item bias and functional
Ball et al., 428 equivalence, 88t, 91–3, 95, 96
Banac, J., 320 sample bias, 87, 88t, 89, 90–1, 96
Banaszak, L. A., 353 bicameralism, 153–4
Bandyopadhyay, S., 241 Bickford, L., 518
Bangladesh, 373, 532 Big Mac Index, 96
Bangladesh Rural Action Committee (BRAC), 428 Binder et al., 104
Banks, J., 235, 241 Birch, A.H., 411, 413
Barbalet, J. M., 425 Birch, S., 400, 401, 402, 403, 404, 405

9781412919760_Index.indd 2 3/13/2009 12:09:39 PM


INDEX 543

Birnbaum, P., 151 Browne, E. C., 229, 230, 236, 237, 241
Bjornlund, E. C., 391 Brubaker, R., 109
Black, C., 104 Brusco et al., 405
Black, D., 233 Bruszt, L., 322
Blackhurst, R., 482 Bryce, J., 228
Blais, A., 256, 265 Buchanan, S. M., 144
Blais et al., 266 Buchanan, W., 522, 526
Blalock, H. A., 69 Buchannan et al., 444
see also Simon-Blalock model Budge, I., 230, 231, 232, 233, 234, 236, 238, 241
Blanning, T. C. W., 339 Budge et al., 231
Bloom, M., 468 Buechler, S., 350
Blyth, M. M., 127, 128, 133, 137, 139f, 169 Bueno de Mesquita et al., 284, 285–6, 292,
Bøås, M., 488 293, 295, 336
Bøås et al., 482, 488, 490 Bulgaria, 538
Bobbitt, P., 251 Bull, H., 182
Boda, M. D., 398 Bulmer, M., 525, 537
Bogdanor, V., 241, 253 Bulmer et al., 525
Boix, C., 256, 279, 282, 284, 287, 288, 293, 294 Bunce, V., 320, 322
Boldrin et al., 216 Bunge, M., 70, 71
Boli, J., 111, 112 Burchill, S., 179
Bolívar, S., 253 Bureau for Applied Social Research, USA, 526
Bolivia, 294, 339 Burgess, M., 420
Bollen, K. A., 37–8, 105, 279, 283 Burgess, R., 454
Bönker et al., 111 Burkhart, R. E., 46–7, 279
Bonnell, V. C., 324 Burkina-Faso, 382, 402
Boolean algebra, 26, 28, 29, 30, 61, 62, 68 Burma, 170, 333, 358, 382
Boortz, J. L., 456 Burnett-Hurst, A. R., 525
Booth, C., 525 Burns, J., 254
Booth, J. W., 519 Burton, M., 324
Boraine, A. L., 499, 501, 503, 506, 508 business cycle, 150–1, 200
Boserup, E., 458 Büthe, T., 239
Boswell, C., 23–4, 25, 31 Butler, D., 529
Botswana, 198t, 448 Buzan, B., 184, 479
Bottomore, T., 102, 107 Byrnes, T., 113
Boudon, R., 71, 79 Byzantine Empire, 251
Boudreau, V., 355, 356, 357, 358
Bourdieu, P., 106, 110 Cable, V., 482
Bowley, A. L., 525 Cable Street riots, London, 275
Bracher, K. D., 300 Calderon, C., 450
Bradley et al., 211 Calhoun, C., 324, 326, 328
Brady, H. E., 1, 2, 14, 50, 52 Callahan, W. A., 402, 405
Bratton, M., 285, 290, 292, 293, 311, 354, 387, Calmfors, L., 149, 200
403, 454, 455 Cambodia, 38, 498, 519, 532
Bratton et al., 311, 531, 538 Cameron, C. M., 152, 153
Braumoeller, B. F., 32, 62, 81 Cameron, D., 200
Braun, M., 87, 92, 97 Cameroon, 381, 382
Braungart, M. M., 101, 116 Campbell, B. B., 432
Braungart, R. G., 101, 116 Campbell, J. L., 131, 132, 136, 139
Brauns et al., 94 Canada, 74, 198t, 215, 221, 258, 264, 266, 275,
Bravo, J., 295 307f, 309f, 310f, 411, 414, 415, 417,
Brazil, 60, 165, 168, 420, 428, 444, 450, 487, 538 486, 530, 533, 538
Brenner, A. D., 432 Institute of Governance, 440
Breslin, S., 481, 491 Cantori, L. J., 478
Breslin et al., 481, 490 Cantril, H., 522, 526
Brewer, J., 21 capitalism, 18, 19–20, 31, 102, 103, 104, 105, 106,
Brill, A., 301 107, 108, 109, 112, 114, 149, 194, 195, 196, 197,
British Election Study, 529 199, 203, 204, 205, 206, 207, 212, 220, 221
British Journal of Political Science, 1 Caporaso, J. A., 484, 485
British National Party, 151 Caporaso et al., 252
Broadman, H., 451 Caprioli, M., 430
Brockett, C., 334, 356, 429, 432 Carey, J. M., 254, 271
Brody, R., 501, 502 Carey, P., 333
Brook, T., 333 Caribbean, 387, 412, 419, 481, 483, 486, 490
Brooker, P., 386 Carnegie Foundation, 161
Brown, C., 23–4, 25, 31 Carothers, T., 386

9781412919760_Index.indd 3 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


544 INDEX

Carr, E. H., 177, 178, 179, 183 Christiansen et al., 483, 484
Carrubba, C. J., 236, 241 Christian Democrats, 53, 207, 211, 219, 231
Carter, President, 323 Chu, Y. –H., 532
Cartier-Bresson, J., 365 CIA, 248
Casanova, J., 109 CINEP, 470
Case, A., 149 Cingranelli, D., 428, 429
Case, W., 391, 405 CIRI data, 429
case-oriented research, 14–15, 16, 18, 29, 50–66, Cirtautas, A., 371, 374
68, 102, 103, 278, 424, 429 cities, 247, 249, 250, 300, 325, 326, 354–5
coalitions, 238–9 see also urbanization
‘crucial case’, 60–1 citizenship, 109, 275, 301–3, 304–7, 388, 411,
prominence, definitions and scope, 51–5 449–50, 452, 457
qualitative analysis and causal mechanisms, 69–79 self-expression values, 304–15, 305t, 306f,
techniques, 55–9 307f, 309f, 310f
trade offs, 59–64 civic culture, 522, 526–7, 534, 535, 537, 538
within-case, 20–1, 57, 63 civic trust, 506, 512, 514
Castles, F. G., 39, 210, 221 civil law, 369
Castro, F., 327, 332 civil rights, 321, 424, 426, 427, 428, 429, 430,
Caterino, B., 1, 2 431, 432, 508, 516
causality, 19, 20, 21–3, 24t, 25, 30–1, 44, 55, civil society, 106, 110, 113, 372, 390, 431, 440,
57–61, 64, 109, 110, 137 486, 499, 511, 513, 517
causal mechanisms versus causal effects, 61–2 civil war 21, 51, 53–4, 55, 58, 290, 292, 293, 320, 321,
causal mechanisms and qualitative analysis, 69–81 357, 412, 466, 468, 499, 504, 514, 515, 518
see also Stokke Clague et al., 456
Central America, 466 Clapham, C., 488
Central and Eastern Europe, 40, 106, 112, 168, 170 Clark et al., 63
Central and Eastern Euro-barometer, 527, 531 Clarke, K. A., 32
see also Europe, Eastern class, 55, 102, 110, 114, 206, 210, 267, 319, 320
Central Asia, 168, 338, 340, 373 see also middle class; peasants; upper class;
central banks, 149, 150, 156, 201, 202, 449 working class
Centre for Comparative Social Surveys, UK, 532 Clausen, A. R., 94
Cesarini, P., 432, 512, 514, 516, 518–19 Clausen, T. H., 15
Chad, 382, 502 Cloward, R. A., 349, 353
Chapman, A., 428 coalition governments, 228, 229–39, 270, 295
Charrad, M., 109 cognitive mobilization, 302, 304
Chase-Dunn, C., 107 Cohen, J., 14, 16, 328, 350
Chatterjee, K., 241 Cohen, S., 161, 162
Chaturvedi, V., 102, 108 Colburn, F. D., 323
Chechnya, 420 Cold War, 161–2, 165, 183, 289, 290, 366, 367,
Checkel, J., 132 429, 431, 484, 486
Chehabi, H. C., 293 post Cold War, 162, 362, 363, 482
Cheibub, J. A., 253 Coleman, J. S., 356
Cheibub et al., 227 Coleman, W. D., 482
Cheng et al., 451 collective action, 55, 63, 102, 125, 349, 351,
Chiang Mai Initiative (CMI), 485 352, 358, 467
Chicago school, 525, 526, 527, 529 collectivism, 309, 310, 315
Chilcote, R. 2, 114 Collier, D., 1, 2, 50, 52, 53, 80, 97, 114, 128,
child care, 209, 211, 215, 216, 217, 218 464, 465, 471, 473
Chile, 198t, 321, 432–3, 434, 502, 505, 511, Collier, P., 169, 466, 467, 468
519, 534, 538 Collier, R. B., 80, 128, 358
China, 22, 112, 163, 167, 333, 334, 337, 340, 382, 395, Collier et al., 52, 54, 55, 56, 57, 58, 59, 60, 467
420, 446, 485, 532, 537, 538 Collins, R., 31, 80
Buddhists, 330 Colombia, 334, 470, 471
Communist Party, 327, 328, 329, 330 Colomer, J. M., 60, 252, 253, 254, 255, 256, 257
empire, 250, 251, 252 colonial studies, 102, 108, 288, 325–6, 431, 444
revolution, 21, 176, 319, 320, 323, 324, see also post colonialism
332, 336, 339 Columbia school, 526, 531
Tiananmen square, 324, 326, 334 Comaroff and Comaroff, 108, 111
Chirot, D., 320, 331, 337 COMESA, 488
Choi, Y. J., 485 commemoration, 505, 506
Chong, A., 450 common law, 368
Chong, D., 329, 330, 335, 336 Commonwealth of Independent States, 112
Choung, J. C., 279, 285, 286, 291 communism, 21, 111, 112, 113, 161, 236, 283, 288,
Christensen, R., 400, 402, 404 320, 321, 322, 326, 327, 328, 329, 330, 336, 337,
Christiansen, T., 482 367, 368, 415, 419, 445, 484, 537

9781412919760_Index.indd 4 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 545

community-building, 247–52 credibility, 445, 447–8, 450–1


Compagnia di San Paola, 533 Crenshaw, M., 463–4, 465, 466, 468, 471, 472
Comparative Manifesto Project, 237–8 criminal law, 500–3, 500t
Comparative Political Studies, 1, 52 critical theory, 102, 106, 107, 108, 114
Comparative Politics, 1, 52 Croatia, 198t, 538
Comparative National Elections Project (CNEP), 522, Crossley, A. M., 526
523t, 531, 538 Crozier et al., 301, 303
Comparative Study of Electoral Systems, 271, 400, Crouch, C., 130, 20
522, 523t, 525, 529–30, 537 Cruz, C., 515, 519
compensation, 505, 506 Crystal, J., 279
Conaghan, C. M., 391 Crystal, K. A., 200
conflict theory, 102, 106, 109, 114, 179 CSES, 404, 534, 536
Conge, P. J., 339 Cuba, 322, 323, 327, 332–3, 334, 339, 382, 433
Congo, 382, 403 Cukierman, A., 149
congruence method, 56–7 cultural-constructivist approaches to politics, 108–11
Conrad, S., 108 cultural frameworks and ideology, 329–30
consistency, 93–5 cultural institutions, 131
constitutive compared to causal analysis, 19 cultural-scientific analysis, 102, 103, 109, 114, 115
construct bias and construct equivalence, 88t, 89–90 cultural pluralism, 107, 108
construct validity versus generalizability, 59–61 Cusack, T. R., 212, 218
constructivist scholarship, 125, 132, 134–5, 136, 137, Cutrone, M., 153
138, 139f, 186, 483, 511, 513, 514, 518 Cyprus, 198t, 538
consumption, 208, 209, 210, 212, 216–18, 217t, Czech Republic, 198t, 338, 370, 538
219, 220, 221, 222 Czechoslovakia, 18, 42
Converse, P. E., 526 Charter 77, 327
Convergence Criteria, 418
Converse, P. E., 156, 522 Dahrendorf, R., 106
Cooper, F., 108, 111 Dahl, R., 2, 17, 18, 38, 101, 249, 253, 283, 526
Cooper, R., 252 six institutions of democracy, 36, 37
Cooper et al., 482 Dalton, R., 197, 268, 275, 301, 303, 304,
coordinated market economies (CMEs), 194, 203, 306, 307, 354
204, 205, 206, 207, 213, 214, 215, 216, Daniel, J., 391
217, 218, 219, 220, 221 Danto, A. C., 81
Coppedge, M., 37, 69 Dárde, C., 405
Cornelisen, A., 68 Darden, K. A., 405
corporatism, 199–200, 203, 210 Database on Political Institutions (DPI), 386–7,
corporatist countries, 18, 200, 203 400, 459
Correlates of War (University of Michigan), 249 d’Aubuisson, R., 53
corruption, 292, 311, 324, 362–77, 387, 440, Davenport, C., 333, 334, 427, 429, 430, 467, 470
442f, 448, 451–2, 535 Davies, J. C., 332
causes of, 368–9 Davis, D. E., 355
definition, 362–5 Davodi, H., 365, 366
electoral, 395–409; best practice (inductive) Dawisha, K, 112
approach, 397–8; data sources, 400; democratic De Brito, A. B., 432
theory approach (deductive) 398–9; legal De Brito et al., 432, 513, 519
approach, de Haan, J., 459
397; measurement, 399–400; perceptual de Meur, G., 17–18, 38
approach, 397; reasons for, 400–2; research, de Moor, R., 528
future directions for, 402–3 de Soto, H., 443
government spending, political economy and, 453–5 de Swaan, A., 109, 230, 231, 233
impact of, 365–6 de Tocqueville, 300, 527
importance of, 366–8 de Winter, L., 236–7, 241
scale of, 369–71 de Winter et al., 239
Corruption Perception Index (CPI), 367, 369–71, 403 Deacon, R. T.,
Coser, L. A., 102 debt, 289, 324
Costa Rica, 515 deconstructive research, 102, 103, 107, 109, 114, 115
Costain, A., 351 Dedeoglu, B., 468–9
Côte d’Ivoire, 390 Dell, S., 481
Council of Europe, 404 Della Porta, D., 352, 353, 357, 366, 368, 471, 473
counterfactual analysis, 28–30 Delli Carpini, M. X., 301
Country Risk Guide, 458 democracy, 2, 4, 5, 6, 7, 17–18, 45, 46–7, 53, 59, 60,
coups d’état, 97, 321, 326 63, 67, 74, 81, 94, 97, 104, 105, 106, 111, 112,
covariance and causal mechanism 71–3 115, 127, 164, 169, 183, 247, 249, 250, 252, 253,
Cox, G., 127, 227, 400, 405 258, 259, 356, 359, 374, 383, 420, 426, 430, 431,
Crawford, R. A., 182 487, 531, 533, 535, 537–8

9781412919760_Index.indd 5 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


546 INDEX

democracy (Continued) Doig, A., 371, 372


accountability and, 439, 440, 441, 442, 445, 448, Dollar, D., 450
449–50, 452, 457 Dollase, R., 469
democratic partisan competition and political Domhoff, G. W., 106
economy, 193–226, 198t Dominguez, J. I., 400, 403
global south, 357–8 Dominican Republic, 294, 455, 538
law and, 498, 499, 501, 502, 503, 505, 507, 508, Dommo, D., 387
510, 511, 513, 514, 515, 516, 517 Donnelly, J., 425
Moore’s five conditions for, 21–2 Donno, D., 400
small countries, 248–50 Donsbach, W., 538
synchronic analysis with large-N design, 36, 38–40, Dornbos, M., 112
39t Downs, A., 144, 147, 156
see also elections; governance; government Doyle, W., 251
formation; political culture; Drazen, A., 146
wealth and democracy Dreijmanis, J., 237, 241
democratization, changes in causes through time; Driffill, J., 149, 200
278–98 Druckman, J. N., 236, 274
development and democracy, 278, 279–80, 282, 289, Druckman et al., 236
291, 293, 294; Duch, R. M., 266, 268, 274
disagreements about measurement, 280–1, 294 Duff et al., 412
how democratisation has changed, 286–4 Dumont, P., 236–7, 239, 241
international influences on, 285–6 Dunleavy, P., 234, 258
strategic interactions between elites Dunn, J., 320
and citizens, 281–5 Dunne, T. J., 182
Denmark, 17, 198t, 215, 221, 451, 530, 531, 538 Dunning, T., 279, 285, 290
DeNardo, J., 329, 356 Durkheim, E., 96, 104, 114, 310
Denoeux, G., 326 Durbin-Watson statistic, 41–2, 45
dependency theory, 60 Duverger, M., 251, 254, 255–6
depth versus breadth, 59 Dye, T., 301
Denton, T., 21
determinism, 62–3 East, the, 103
Deutsch et al., 309, 310, 411 East Africa, 412, 419, 420
developing countries, 102, 106, 107, 108, 251, East Asia, 161, 165, 166, 382, 477, 478, 481,
320, 332, 401, 428 483, 484–6, 490
development and democracy, 278, 279–80, East Asia barometer, 532
282, 289, 291, 293, 294 East Timor, 428
see also governance Easton, D., 101, 302
DeWeaver, M., 371 Eatwell, R., 466
Di Palma, G., 387 Ebbinghaus, B., 84
Diamond, L., 38, 105, 294, 320, 386, 519 Eckstein, H., 15, 53, 54, 60, 63, 101, 103, 104, 164,
Diamond, M. J., 332 165–6, 301, 432, 434, 527
Diamond et al., 279 Eckstein, S., 320, 327, 337, 355
Díaz, H. A., 401 ECLAC, 487
Dicker, R., 502 economic factors, 7, 38, 39t, 46–7, 60, 78, 94, 96,
Diez, T., 490 105, 107, 112, 126, 134, 139, 160, 175,
dictatorships, 255, 279–80, 283–4, 287, 289–90, 184–5, 278, 290–1, 311, 324, 337–8, 416,
291–3, 295, 325, 326, 385, 386, 506, 508, 510 418, 426, 428, 431, 433, 434, 467, 485, 487,
Diermeier, D., 235, 236, 241 488, 498, 506, 509, 518, 535
Diermeier et al., 235 corruption, 364, 365, 367–8, 371, 372, 373
DIFD, UK, 248, 428 growth and governance, 439–62; evidence of effects
diffusion, 167, 168, 169, 170, 171 of governance on economic development,
Dikshit, R. D., 413 450–2
DiMaggio, P. J., 130, 131, 139f market economy vs. state ownership and regulation,
Dion, D., 60, 62, 63 287–8
disaffection, 306–7 see also political economy; tax; wealth and
discursive institutionalism see institutional analysis, democracy
discursive institutionalism Economics of Governance, 440
districts, small, 257–8 Economist, The, 96, 373
Dix, R., 326, 327 ECOWAS, 477, 488
Dixon, W., 429, 430 ECPR, 534
Dobbin, F., 130, 137 ECSC, 480
Dobryzynska, A., 265 Eder, K, 113
Dobson, L., 418 education, 105, 195, 207, 208, 211, 214, 215, 216, 217,
Dodd, L. C., 228 218, 220, 221, 281, 287, 288, 428, 446, 455, 505
Dogan, M., 114, 115 Egypt, 337, 381, 382, 384, 388

9781412919760_Index.indd 6 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 547

Egypt, Ancient, 252 Ethopia, 382


Ehling, M., 87, 89, 97 Etzioni, A., 481
Ehrlich et al., 95 Eurasia, 320, 389
Eisenstadt, S. N., 101, 103, 105, 112, 250, 320 Euro-barometer, 522, 523t, 527–8, 530, 531,
Eisenstadt, T. A., 400, 405 534, 536, 537, 538
Eisinger, P., 351, 352 Europe, Eastern, 236, 268, 282, 320, 321, 322, 323,
El Salvador, 51, 53–4, 55, 58, 294, 323, 356, 357, 429 328, 334, 336, 337, 339, 374, 387, 498, 533, 534
Elazar, D., 415 see also Central and Eastern Europe
elections, 78, 90, 94, 105, 135, 137, 146–8, 200, Europe, medieval, 251
253, 259, 263–77, 293, 415, 452 Europe, Southern, 112
comparative mass behaviour across nations, 266–70 Europe, Western, 17, 74–5, 91, 94, 95, 101, 102, 103,
corruption, 395–409; concept of electoral corruption, 105, 130, 160, 163, 165, 167, 171, 175, 184,
396–9; measurement and data, 399–400; 187, 193, 200, 203, 205, 207, 215, 216, 218,
reasons for, 400–2; research, directions for 219–20, 221, 222, 236, 246, 248, 251, 258,
future, 402–3 279, 283, 287, 290, 319, 320, 323, 350,
decision dependence, institutional approach to cross- 351, 352, 358, 369, 373, 429, 526, 533, 536
national variation, 270–4 Europeanization, 111–13
electoral authoritarianism, 381–94; contested European Central Bank, 155
boundaries of elections, 384–6; construction of European Consortium for Political Research
comparative data, 386–7; results, decisiveness (ECPR), 1, 530
of, 384; strategies of authoritarian control, European Election Study, 522, 530–1, 534
381–4; trajectories of, 389–91 European Monetary Fund (EMU), 418
electoral rules, 254, 255–7, 258 European Social Survey (ESS), 89, 96, 97, 524t,
macroeconomic consequences of elections and 525, 532, 536, 537, 538
electoral systems, 149–2 European Union, 127, 134, 153, 154, 168, 169, 170,
manifestos, 234; Comparative Manifesto Project, 194, 248, 250, 251–2, 266, 290, 374, 410, 412,
237–8 415, 417, 418, 419, 420, 533, 534, 535
opinion poles, 266, 267–8, 271, 274 see also EEC, 481; transition from EEC to EU, 416
opinion, mass; surveys regionalism, 477, 478, 480, 481, 483–4, 486, 487,
party identification and economic voting, 264–5 488, 489, 490, 491; Single European Act, 481;
political regime performance, 254–5 White Paper on internal market, 481
universal suffrage, 383 European Values Survey, 522, 523t, 528–9, 534,
voters, 147–8, 156, 194, 196, 215, 256, 258, 259, 537, 538
303, 383–4, 385, 396, 522, 530–1, 536, 537 European Voter Study, 522, 530–1, 536, 537
women’s suffrage, 194 Evans, G., 266
Elgie, R., 254 Evans, P. B., 168, 247, 444, 448, 451
Elkins, Z., 155, 280 Evans et al., 109, 128, 168, 186
Elklit, J., 397, 398–9, 400, 404 ex-ante strategies, 87, 88t, 89, 96
Elster, J., 70, 79, 126, 127, 505, 511, 512, 513, 517, ex-post strategies, 87, 88t, 89, 90, 91, 96, 97
519 exchange rate, 150–1
Ekiert, G., 168 exclusion, social, 428
Emirbayer, M. E., 320
empire, 247, 249, 250–2, 258 Falk, R., 425
employment, 195, 197, 201, 202, 204, 213, 214, 216, Fantasia, R., 333
325 FARC, 468
see also labour market; unemployment Farhi, F., 320, 327
empowerment, 305, 306f Farish, M., 161
Enders, W., 468, 472 Farr, J., 160
English School of IR, 182, 184 Farrell, D., 271
environmental issues, 426, 533 Farrell et al., 482
Epstein, D., 449 fascism, 17, 21, 104, 105, 321, 526
Epstein et al., 280 Faure, A., 1
equifinality, 58, 62 Fawcett, J., 479
equilibrium, 127, 128, 129, 201, 202 Feagin et al. 84
equivalence, 84–100, 88t Fearon, J. D., 29, 466
Eritrea, 382 Feder, G., 450
Ersson, S., 38, 44 Federal Reserve Bank, 155
Ernst Haas, 480 Federal Trade Commission, 449
Ertmann, T., 109 federalism, 153–4, 250, 259, 410–22, 433, 480
Escribà Folch, A., 282, 284, 290 comparative politics approaches, 415–18, 416f
Esping-Andersen, G., 18, 109, 209, 216, 221 rational choice approaches, 412–15
Esser, H., 97 feminism, 107, 349
Estevez et al., 221 Feng, Y., 281, 282
Estonia, 198t, 257 Fenger, M., 320, 323
ethnicity, 109, 338, 419, 428, 430, 478, 479, 536 Ferdinand, F., 74, 80

9781412919760_Index.indd 7 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


548 INDEX

Ferejohn, J., 149, 365 Gagnon, A. G., 420


Ferguson, J., 108, 111 Gallagher, M., 256
feudalism, 107, 109, 183, 184, 300 Gallhofer, I., 538
Fianna Fàil, 231 Gallie, W. B., 425
Figueroa, M., 405 Gallup, G., 525–6
Filippov et al., 413–14, 415 Gallop et al., 169
Finer, S. E., 251, 300 Gallup International Voice of the People,
Finkel et al., 328 524t, 525, 533–4
Finkle, T., 104 Gambia, 382
Finland, 215, 307f, 309f, 310f, 538 Gamble, A., 479
Finnemore, M., 130, 182, 501, 512 game theory, 234–6, 239, 471–2
Fish, M. S., 279, 280 Gamson, W., 22, 229, 329
fishing agreements, international, 26 Riker-Gamson theory, 229
Fishman, S., 472 Gandhi, J., 290, 291
Flanagan, S., 305, 308 Ganor, B., 468
Fleischhacker, H., 403 Gans, H., 68
Fletcher, L. E., 502, 510, 513 Garrett, G., 46, 155, 185, 201, 202, 206, 221
Fligstein, N., 130, 135, 139f Gartner, S. S., 333
Flora, P., 415 Gasiorworski, R., 279, 285, 293
Flinders, M., 253 Gat, A., 315
Flyvbjerg, B, 1, 2 Gates, S., 471
FMLN, 53 Gatti et al., 371
Fobden, S., 113 GDP, 195, 198t, 217t, 221, 222, 280, 367, 428
Follesdal, A., 418 Geddes, B., 2, 60, 290, 291, 292, 293
Foran, J., 320, 323, 326, 327, 329, 337 Geer, J., 526
Foran et al., 338 Geertz, C., 104, 164, 171
Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA), USA, 367–8 Gellner, E., 109, 163
Ford Foundation, 161, 162, 440, 458 gender, 332–3, 518
Fordism, post, 107 generalizations, 59–61, 85, 125, 127, 164–5
Fort, B., 485 generative theory, 70
Foster, G. M., 163 geopolitical changes, 290–1
Foster, W. Z., 23 Georgia, 338, 401
Foucault, M., 107, 110 George, A. L., 2, 14, 50, 52, 53, 56, 57, 58,
Fourutan, F., 488 72, 432, 471, 472
Foweraker, J., 425, 432 Gerber, A. S., 274
France, 18, 103, 104, 106, 128, 130, 134, 136, 163, Germany, 18, 75, 91, 103, 104, 106, 114, 129, 132,
198t, 199, 205, 215, 216, 219, 221, 254, 258, 134, 135, 136, 153, 184, 185, 194, 195, 198t, 202,
307f, 309f, 310f, 352, 353, 366, 367, 401, 455, 206, 207, 213, 215, 219, 250, 264, 266, 267, 300,
527, 531, 538 301, 303, 307f, 309f, 310f, 329, 339, 352, 353,
Gaullists, 211, 219, 480 366, 367, 382, 418, 444, 446, 505,
Republic, Third, 336; Fourth and Fifth, 77 507, 515, 519, 526, 527, 529, 530, 538
revolution, 20, 21, 22, 77, 176, 319, 321, 322, 323, Germany, East, 322, 326, 327, 338, 538
326, 330, 332, 333, 334, 336, 339 Gerring, J., 2, 50, 53, 59, 60, 61, 62, 81, 237, 238, 434
Franck, T., 412 Gerschenkron, A., 176
Franco, 321 Ghana, 387, 402
Frank, K, 310 Ghandi, J., 290, 291, 295
Franke, K. M., 518 Giannetti, D., 240
Franklin, M. N., 229, 234, 237, 240, 265, 267 Gibney et al., 430
Franzese, R., 150, 155, 200, 201, 202, 221 Gibson, C., 290, 312
free markets, 146, 175, 184, 185, 487, 535 Gibson, G., 328
Freedom House, 37, 46, 308, 382, 386, 391, 452 Giddens, A., 31, 107, 109
Freeman, M., 424, 425, 426, 434 Gieson, B, 113
Friedman, T. L., 163 Gingerich, D. W., 205, 206
Friedman et al., 327, 331 Giugni, M., 352
fsQCA, 24, 29, 31 Gleditsch, K. S., 249, 278, 279, 285, 286, 291, 295
FTAA, 487 Global Corruption Barometer, 370, 371
Fukuyama, F., 162, 248 global governance index, Kaufmann et al., 452
Fund for Peace and Foreign Policy, 248 global south, 354–8
Furet, F., 334, 336 globalization, 111–13, 115, 116, 145, 155, 161,
162, 163, 169, 184, 185, 186, 197,
Gable, R., 104 213, 214, 216, 220, 288, 420, 478, 482
Gabler, S., 89, 91 meaning of, 113
Gabon, 382 public opinion research, 522–40
Gabriel, O. W., 94, 97 GLS (generalized least squares), 46
Gaddis, J. L., 28 GLS-ARMA, 47

9781412919760_Index.indd 8 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 549

GNI, 195, 197, 198t, 221 Gschwend, T., 271


Goertz , G., 1, 16, 22, 61, 62, 63, 64, 434 Guardian, The,199
Golden, M., 159 Guatemala, 323, 428, 429
Golder, S. N., 236 guerrilla war, 320, 321, 332
Goldfrank, W. L., 323 Guillory, C. A., 272
Goldman, W. Z., 333 Guinea, 382
Goldstein, J., 133, 139f Gulf War 1990–1991, 78
Goldstone, J., 109, 320, 321, 325, 326, 328, Gumplowicz, L., 104
334, 335, 336, 350, 354–5, 356 Gunther, R., 531, 534
Goldstone et al., 320, 327 Gunther et al., 538
Goldthorpe, J. H., 18 Gupta et al., 366, 451
Goodwin, J., 472 Gurr, T., 2, 37, 166, 304, 337, 466, 469
Goodwin, J., 293, 320, 323, 324, 325, 326, 327, 337
Goodwin-Gill, G. S., 395, 398 Haas, P. M., 135, 139f, 163, 481
Gorbachev, M., 323, 332, 334 Haber, S., 456
Gordon, A., 463 Habermas, J., 106, 135
Gorski, P., 109 Hadenius, A., 293, 295, 313
Gosnell, H. F., 274, 402, 405, 525 Häder, S., 89, 91
Gould, R. V., 326, 328 Hafner-Burton, E. M., 427, 429, 430
Gourevitch, P., 176–7, 185 Haggard, S., 290, 337
governance, 439–62 Halbwachs, M., 104
definition of, 440–1 Hale, H., 320
determinants of good, 453–7 Hall, P., 84, 109, 114, 115, 126, 127, 128, 129,
evidence of effects of governance on economic 130, 131, 134, 139f, 164, 203, 205, 206
development, 450–2 Hall, R. B., 184
hazards of aggregation in research, 441–3, 442f Hall, R. E., 450
history of literature on, 443–4 Hall et al., 331
improving, 457–8 Haller, M., 313
reviewing theory of, 444–50 Hallerberg, M., 201
government formation, 227–45 Hallerberg et al., 201
coalition formation, 236–9; case studies, 238–9; Halliday, F., 323
quantitative comparative studies, 236–7; single Hamilton, 254
country studies, 237–8 Hammond, T., 253
coalition theory, 228, 229–36; non-cooperative game Hanson, J. M., 274
theory and institutions, 234–6, 239; office- Hanson, S., 156, 168, 169, 171
seeking, 229–31; policy-seeking, 231–4 Hardin, R., 126, 144, 335
single party system, 227, 228, 229, 231, 236 Harkness, J. A., 87, 89, 96, 535
two-party system 227 Harkness et al., 86, 92
see also elections Harré, R., 70
Government and Opposition, 1 Harris Market Research, 526
Grabbe, H., 113 Hartlyn, J., 402, 404, 405
Gramsci, A., 107 Hartlyn et al., 387, 390
Grancelli, B., 102, 112 Harvey, F. P., 60
Grant, A. J., 488 Hathaway, O., 429, 430, 431
Graziano, P., 112 Häusermann, J., 428
Gready, P., 502, 517 Häussermann, S., 219, 222
Great Depression, 160, 211 Hawkins, D., 61, 425, 432, 433–4
Greece, 18, 197, 198t, 519 Hay, C., 132, 133, 135, 137, 139f
Greece, Ancient, 183–4, 251, 300 Hayner, P. B., 432, 503, 504, 505
Green, D., 127, 274 Hays, J. C., 155
Green parties, 264 Heaney, M. T., 274
Greene, K. F., 391 Heath et al., 536
Greenfeld, L., 109 Hechter, M., 102, 110
Grenada, 331 Heckmann selection model, 428
Grew, R., 104 Hedström, P., 70, 71, 110, 238
Grieco, J. M., 483 Heidenheimer, A. J., 363, 404
Grief, A., 169 Heilbrunn, J., 455
Griffiths, M., 178, 179 Held et al., 103, 111, 113
Grilli et al., 149 Hellman, J., 290, 372
Grødeland et al., 371 Hellman et al., 364, 372
Groennings et al., 241 Helpman, E., 144, 148
Grofman, B., 229, 237, 256 Hempel, C. G., 78, 80
Groseclose, T., 153 Henderson, C., 427, 429
Grossman, G. M., 144, 148 Henderson, D., 482
Grumm, J. G., 256 Hentz, J. J., 488

9781412919760_Index.indd 9 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


550 INDEX

Herb, M., 280, 292 Human Development Index (HDI), 40, 428
hermeneutic-interpretive analysis, 68, 102, 110 human rights, 292, 323, 373, 398, 423–38, 467, 470,
Herman, E., 468 506, 508, 511, 512, 517, 519
Herman, V., 230, 231 as an object of inquiry, 424–6
Hermens, F. A., 17 comparing, 429–33
Hermet et al., 405 future of human rights research, 433–4
Herron, E. S., 400 gay and lesbian rights, 349
Herron, M. C., 396 measurement of, 426–9, 434; dimensions of, 427f
Hesse, J. J., 418 Human Rights Watch, 519
heteroscedasticity, 44, 45, 47 humanities, 163–4, 165
Hettne, B., 479, 480, 482 Hume, D., 70, 72, 73, 79, 246, 247
Hettne et al., 482 Hungary, 198t, 288, 322, 538
Heywood, P. M., 367, 370, 372 Hunt, B. W., 234
Hibbs, D., 150, 200 Hunt, L., 333
Hicks, A., 210, 221 Hunter, A., 21
Higley, J., 324 Huntington, S., 2, 105, 112, 113, 171, 279, 300, 321,
Higgott, R., 481, 485, 491 349, 350, 355, 369, 381, 383, 502
Hill, P. J., 458 Hunyady, G., 94
Hindess, B., 374 Hurrell, A., 479, 491
Hintze, O., 104 ‘hybrid regimes’, 386
Hirsch, E. L., 333 Hylland, A., 126, 127
Hirschman, A., 162, 449
Hispanic America, 248 Iceland, 197, 198t
historical approaches, 53, 102, 105, 107, 109, 127, Ichijo, A., 113
160, 178, 180, 183–4, 240, 251–2, 465–6, 525–6 ICORE, 530
causal mechanism and, 73–9, 80, 81 ICPSR, 528
federalism, 410–20 IDEA, 272, 395, 398
governance, 443–4, 454 identity, 84, 85–6, 91, 95, 131, 134, 163,
see also democratization, changes in causes through 327–9, 335, 336, 411
time; institutional analysis, historical identity-equivalence method, 95
historical transitional justice, 500t, 503–5, 516 ideology and cultural frameworks, 329–30
Hite, K., 432, 518–19 Imbusch, P., 469
Hobden, S., 186 Immergut, E., 127, 129
Hobsbawn, E. J., 21 Index of Democratization, 36–7
Hobson, J. M., 113, 176, 178, 179, 183, India, 22, 112, 165, 250, 258, 266, 333, 373, 411, 412,
184–5, 186, 187 415, 416, 417, 419, 454, 532, 535, 537
Hoeffler, A., 466, 467, 468, 472 Individualism compared to collectivism, 309,
Hoffman, B., 290, 468, 470 310, 315
Hoffman, S., 480 individualizing, 110, 111, 115, 125
Hoffmann, S., 178, 182 Indonesia, 322, 358, 387, 391, 419–20, 428,
Hoffmann-Martinot et al., 272 442f, 532
Hoffmeyer-Zlotnik, J. H. P., 87, 89, 92, 96, 97 industrial revolution, 103
Hofrenning, D. J. B., 429 industrialization, 107, 163, 164, 205, 283, 287,
Hogg, M. A., 328 337, 444
Holden, M., 488 post industrial democracies, 193–226, 198, 302, 303,
Holmes, J. S., 469 304, 305, 306, 307f, 308, 309f, 310f, 315
Holmes et al., 470, 471 inequality, 73, 102, 327
Holocaust, 300, 505 inflation, 60, 150, 201, 202, 418
Honduras, 294 information technology, 195, 205, 214, 215, 216,
Hooghe, L., 483 220, 367
Hooghe, M., 269 Inglehart, R., 93, 113, 197, 267–8, 275, 304, 305, 308,
Hoogvelt, A., 108 311, 314–15, 426, 527, 528, 534, 538
Honderich, T., 96 Inkeles, A., 281
Hong Kong, 197, 198t, 221, 371, 532 Inoguchi et al., 538
Höpner, M., 207 institutional analysis, comparative, 6–7, 102, 110, 115,
Horgan, J., 472 125–4, 182, 228, 229, 233, 234–6, 237,
Hough, J., 162, 322 238, 240, 444
How Nations See Each Other, 527 discursive, 126, 132, 134, 135–7, 138t, 139f
Howard, M. M., 390, 405 historical, 126, 128–30, 131, 132, 134, 136, 138t,
Howe, P., 179 139f
Howes, R., 418 rational choice, 126–8, 130, 131, 132,
Huber, E. 109, 113, 218, 221 133, 136, 138t, 139f
Huber et al., 221 sociological, 126, 130–2, 134–5, 136, 138t, 139f
Hudson, C. L., 400 institutional and comparative turns in
Hufton, O. H., 332 political economy, 149–55

9781412919760_Index.indd 10 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 551

institutional approach to cross-national Jenkins, C., 488


variation, decision dependence Jenkins, J. C., 326
of voting, 270–4 Jenkins-Smith, H. C., 133, 135
institutional design, 246–62 Jennings, M. K., 303
choice of institutions, 252–8 Jessop, R., 479
community-building, 247–52 Jiménez, E., 450
institutional legacies, 167–70 Jobert, B., 135, 139f
institutional transitional justice, 500t, 507–9 Johnson, C., 160, 162, 163
institutionalization of democracy, 38, 39t, 488, 490 Johnson, P. E., 400
inter-governmental organizations (INGOs), 431 Johnson, T. P., 96
Inter-Parliamentary Union (IPU), 404 Johnson, V., 323
interest groups, 148, 200 Johnston, A., 479
interest rates, 150, 201, 202 Johnston, M., 364, 404
International Center for Transitional Justice Jones, C. I., 450
(ICTJ), 498, 506, 507 Jones, R., 252
International Covenant on Civil and Jongman, A., 464, 465, 470
Political Rights, 398, 430 Joppke, C., 109
International Covenant on Economic, Jordan, 391, 532
Social, and Cultural Rights, 428 Journal of Conflict Resolution, 1
International Crime Victim Survey, 371 Journal of Peace Research, 1
International Criminal Court, 498, 512, 518 Journal of Politics, 1, 52
International Foundation for Electoral Systems, 400 journalistic approach to research, 470
International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Jowell, R., 532, 534, 535
Assistance (IDEA), 404 Jowell et al., 538
international law, 430 Jungar, A. C., 228
International Monetary Fund (IMF), 362, 368, 371, 534 Jupille et al., 132
International Political Science Association, 534 justice, transitional see transitional justice
international relations (IR), 7–8, 130, 175–89, 291
comparative politics/economics in IR, 184–5 Kaase, M., 303, 527, 528
comparative-sociological method in IR, 183–4 Kaelble, H., 115
distinguishing between IR and comparative Kahn, H., 162
politics, 176–82 Kalyvas, S., 467, 472
reconciling comparative politics and IR, 185–7 Kaminski et al., 292
International Relations Survey, USIA, 526 Kane, J., 109
International Social Survey Programme (ISSP), 96, Kang, D., 449
400, 522, 523t, 529, 537, 538 Kant, I, 411, 412
International Stratification Survey (Ganzeboom and Karklins, R., 322, 336
Nieuwbeerta), 526 Karl, T., 279, 350, 382
International Studies Quarterly, 1 Kato, J., 212
intuitive regression, 56 Katz, J., 46, 155
INUS, 23, 30, 61, 62 Katz, M., 323, 337
Iran, revolution, 320, 321, 322, 323, 324, 326, 327, Katz, R., 398, 538
332, 333, 335, 337, 338, 339, 387, 465, 533 Kazakhstan, 382
Iraq, 169, 332, 387, 420, 429, 466, 519, 533, 535 Katzenstein, P., 128, 130, 132, 134–5, 139f,
Ireland, 194, 197, 198t, 231, 451, 466, 518, 531, 538 185, 200, 482, 484
Israel, 198t, 217, 236, 472, 538 Katznelson, I., 109, 113, 130, 514
Italy, 18, 104, 136, 151, 194, 196, 198t, 205, 213, 215, Kaufman, R., 290, 337
219, 221, 231, 238, 264, 266, 267, 301, 307f, Kaufmann, D., 372, 373, 442, 448
309f, 310f, 351, 366, 401, 507, 516, 526, 527, 538 Kaufmann et al., 371, 441, 442, 452
ITERATE, 470, 472 Kaviraj, S., 112
Iverson, T., 201, 202, 206, 210, 212–13, 215, 218, 221 Kean, J., 106
Keck, M. C., 135, 432
Jackman, R. W., 97, 265, 279, 283 Keddie, N. R., 320
Jaggers, K., 37, 384 Keefer, P., 443, 446, 447, 448–9, 450, 451,
Jacobsen, J. K., 136 452, 454, 455, 456, 457, 458, 459
Jamal, A., 292 Keeler, J., 484
Janoski, T., 113 Keeter, S., 301
Janoski et al., 101 Keith, L. C., 429, 430
Japan, 51, 112, 129, 132, 160, 167, 193, 194, Kelley, J., 337
195, 196, 198t, 213, 250, 266, 307f, Kelly, J., 391
309f, 310f, 323, 444, 485, 511, 532, 538 Keman, H., 36, 37, 38, 230, 231
Meiji Restoration, 21, 176, 339 Kenny, C., 370
Jarvis, D. S. L., 182 Kenworthy, L., 199, 206, 211, 212, 220
Jayasuriya, K., 373 Kenya, 334, 373, 387
Jefferson, 254 Keohane, R., 133, 139f, 182, 185,

9781412919760_Index.indd 11 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


552 INDEX

Keppler, E., 502 Kuwait, 78, 198t, 532


Kerkhofs, Fr. J., 528 Kydd, A., 472
Keuleers, P., 371
Key, V. O., 147–8 Labao, L., 338
Keynesianism, 134, 200, 201 labour markets, 23, 150, 155, 202–3,
Khawaja, M., 333 204, 208, 213, 216, 220, 428
Khomeini, Ayatollah, 327, 332 see also strikes
Kiaer, 525 Labour Party, UK, 227
Kim, J-O., 527 Laclau, E., 107
Kim, Q-Y., 320, 325, 355, 356 Lagos, M., 531, 534
Kimmel, M. S., 320 LAIA, 487
Kimmerling, B., 101 Laitin, D., 109, 164, 466
King, D., 134 Lakoff, G., 78
King, G., 470 Lambsdorff, J. G., 369, 370
King, P., 413 Landman, T., 1, 2, 38, 40, 101, 115, 423,
King, R. F., 400 424, 425, 427, 428, 429, 430, 432, 433
King et al., 1, 2, 4, 14, 21, 50, 52, 54, 57, 60, 433 Lane, D., 322
Kirchheimer, O., 500, 519 Lane, J. E., 38, 44
Kiser, E., 102, 109 Lang, P., 201, 206
Kissinger, H., 503, 513, 514 Langston, J., 391
Kitschelt, H., 193, 196, 197, 219, language, relevance of, 68, 87, 96, 97, 109,
221, 351, 352, 353 110, 168, 169, 535
Kittel, B., 46 Laos, 382
Kjaer, P., 132, 135 LaPalombara, J., 104
Klandermans, B., 307 Lapidus, G. W., 338
Klein, H. S., 337 Laqueur, W., 464, 465
Klingemann, H-D., 303, 527 Laski, H., 104
Klingemann et al., 231 Lasswell, H., 104, 300–1. 311, 312, 525, 527
Klitgaard, R., 369 Latham, M., 102, 106
Knack, S., 370, 371, 446, 447, 450, 451, Latin-America, 38, 60, 63, 105, 162, 166, 167, 195,
452, 456, 457, 458, 459 253, 254, 257, 279, 283, 287, 294, 295, 320, 327,
Knöbl, W., 101, 109 328, 340, 358, 387, 400, 402, 442, 481, 483, 486,
Knock, T. J., 162 487, 490, 498, 515, 531, 533, 534, 537
Knoke, D., 328 Latinobarometer, 400, 429, 523t, 531, 538
Koetzle, W., 371 Latvia, 198t, 538
Kohn, M., 114 Laursen, F., 484
Kohut, A., 533 Laver, M., 196, 229, 231, 232, 233, 234,
Koopmans, R., 137, 352, 353 235, 236, 237, 238, 240, 241
Kopecky, P., 364 Lawler, E. J., 328
Kopstein, J., 169, 171 Lazarsfeld, P., 526, 531
Korea, North, 74, 340, 382 Lazarsfeld et al., 526
Korea, South, 74, 198t, 355, 357, 449, Lazarus, N., 108
451, 485, 532, 538 leadership, 330–2, 338, 339
Korpi, J. P., 218, 221 League of Nations, 171
Koussner, J. M., 400 Lebow, R. N., 74
Kowalchuk, L., 356 Lechner, F., 111, 113
Kposowa, A. J., 326 Lederman et al., 454
Kraay, A., 442, 450 Lee, A-R., 305, 308
Krain, M., 430 legitimacy, 110, 135, 145, 184, 303, 357, 388,
Krane, D. A., 334 389, 401–2, 506, 508, 510, 514
Krasner, S., 128, 139f, 162 Lehmbruch, G., 113, 149
Krastnev, I., 367, 372 Lehoucq, F. E., 395, 396, 400, 401, 402, 404, 405
Krehbiel, K., 253 Leibniz, 85
Kreidie, L. H., 472 Leigh, D., 362
Kriesi et al., 196, 351, 352, 353 Leiserson, M., 229, 231, 241
Krishna, A., 454 Lenski, G., 300, 315
Kritz, N., 507 Lerner, D., 102, 104, 163, 164
Kruglanski, A., 472 Letki, N., 506
Kubota, K., 295 Leung, K., 86, 88, 92, 94, 97
Kuechler, M., 94, 304, 535, 536 Levi, M., 110, 127–8, 251, 282, 284
Kumar, K., 101, 103, 107 Levine, D. H., 327
Kunicova, J., 369 Levitsky, S., 97, 290, S., 386, 387
Kuntz, P., 391 Lewis, A., 481
Kuran, T., 336 Lewis-Beck, M. S., 46–7, 279
Kurzman, C., 333, 335 Li, L., 355

9781412919760_Index.indd 12 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 553

Li et al., 451 macro-sociology, 102, 103–6, 113–14, 115,


Libecap, G. D., 443, 444 128, 131, 139
liberalism, 17, 18, 103, 106, 108, 186–7, 194, 196–7, macroeconomics, 7, 94
200, 201, 203, 204, 207, 211, 213, 214, consequences of electoral systems, 151–2
215, 216, 217, 218, 219, 220, 221, consequences of elections, 149–51
304, 305f, 309f, 311, 312, 313, 315, 510, 535 Madison, 254
neo-liberalism, 182 Magagna, V. V., 326
Libya, 382 Magaloni, B., 290, 291, 295, 391
Lichbach, M. I., 1, 2, 327, 333, 335, 336, 466 Mahon, J., 464
LICUS, 248 Mahoney, J., 1, 2, 16, 52, 56, 57, 61, 62,
Lieberman, E. S., 239 63, 81, 95, 102, 111, 128, 168, 434, 519
Lieberson, S., 13, 29 Maine, H., 104
Lien, D., 282, 284, 294 Mainwaring, S., 63, 254, 295, 327
Lijphart, A., 2, 63, 151, 152, 194, 230, 253, Mair, P., 364
256, 275, 369, 419, 420 Malamud, A., 487
limited criminal sanction, 500, 519 Malaysia, 163, 198t, 381, 382, 411, 413, 416, 420
Limongi, F., 253, 445–6, 449, 459 Malcolm, N., 412
Lindberg, S., 387, 390 Mali, 402, 431
Lindblom, C., 145 Malia, M., 162
Lindert, P. H., 221, 283 Malta, 198t
Linn, J. F., 373, 374 Mamdani, M., 505, 509
Linz, J. J., 17, 18, 104, 112, 153, 253, 254, Mani, R., 509, 510
293, 295, 350 Mann, M., 109, 113, 176
Lipset, S. M., 2, 17, 101, 105, 195, 256, Mannheim, K., 104
278, 279, 281, 287, 301, 349 Mannheim Euro-barometer, 528
Lipsky, M., 349 Manor, J., 419
Lister, R., 107 Mansbridge, J., 127
Lithuania, 198t Mara-Drita, I., 135
Little, R., 184 March, J., 125–6, 130, 131, 139f, 149
Locke, R., 95 Mares, I., 202, 203, 212, 221
Lohmann, S., 336 Marginson, P., 113
London School of Economics (LSE), 525 Marinov, N., 286
Long, A., 466 Markov, J., 326
Long Jusko, K., 15 Markov process, 80
Lopez, G., 467 Marks, G., 105, 234, 483
López-Pintor, R., 398, 402 Marques et al., 504
Loth, W., 112 Marquette, H., 371, 373
Louch, A. R., 75, 76–7 Marsh, A., 527
Loveman, M., 355 Marsh, M., 272
Lowe, E. J., 96 Marshall, M. G., 384
Lowe, W., 470 Marshall, T., 104, 106, 425
Lowell, A. L., 228 Marshall, W., 126
Lowenthal, R., 163 Marshall Fund, 533
LSDV (least squares dummy variable), 45 Martin, C. W., 147
Luebbert, G. M., 17, 80, 232 Martin, D., 390
Luhmann, N., 91 Martin, L., 127, 139f, 229, 233, 234, 236, 237
Lui, M. T., 327 Martin, S., 105
Lukes, S., 104 Martin et al., 329, 330, 338
Lupia, A., 232, 274 Martinelli, A., 113
Lust-Okar, E., 292, 295, 391 Marx, K., 6, 17, 102, 103, 107, 127, 145,
Luther, M., 20 199, 281, 295, 319, 323, 458
Luxemburg, 197, 198t Mason, T. D., 334, 356
Lynch, J., 208 Massicotte, L., 256
Lynn, P., 89, 97 Mattilia, M., 240
Lynn et al., 90 Mattes, J., 311
Matthes, J., 110, 111
Maastricht Treaty, 194, 418, 483 Mattli, W., 479, 483
Macculloch, R., 327 Mauro, P., 451
Macy, M., 335 Mauritania, 382, 403
Machiavelli, 334 Mauritius, 198t
Mackenzie, W. J. M., 398 May, J. D., 232
Mackie, J. L., 22–3, 30, 61 Mayfield, L., 400
Mackie, T. T., 229, 234, 237, 240 Mayhew, 525
macro-political economy, explaining economic McAdam, D., 328, 351, 352
performance, 199–207 McAdam et al., 110, 303, 321, 349, 350, 358, 498

9781412919760_Index.indd 13 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


554 INDEX

McCamant, J. A., 426 Milner et al., 428


McCann, J. A., 400, 403 Milward, A., 480
McCargo, D., 405 minorities, 338, 420
McCarthy, J. D., 328, 349, 353 MIPT, 470
McCarty, N., 153 Mishler, W., 311
McClintock, C., 320, 329 Mitchell, D., 46
McClosky, H., 301 Mitchell, N., 427, 429, 431, 432, 433
McCormick, G., 468 Mitchell, P. L., 229, 233, 236, 256
McCormick, J. M., 427, 429 Mitchell, T., 164
McCoy, J., 402, 404, 405 Mitchell et al., 433
McCubbins, M., 127, 139f, 274 Mitra, S. K., 419
McCubbins et al., 449 Mitrany, D., 480
McDaniel, T., 109, 320 Mjoset, L., 15
McDonald, R. H., 402, 405 MNCs, 431
McEvedy, C., 252 Mo, P. H., 451
McFaul, M., 322, 390, 391 Moaddel, M., 320
McIntyre, A., 535 modernization, 17, 38, 39–40, 60, 101, 102–3, 103–6,
McIvor, S., 372 107–8, 109, 114, 116, 163, 164, 281, 301, 314
McKay, D., 418 counter-currents, 106–8; common denominator of,
McKelvey, R. D., 233 108–111
McKeown, T. J., 29, 52, 55, 84 neo-modernization, 111–13, 114
McMichael, P., 108, 113 Moe, T., 126, 127
McNamara, K., 134, 139f Moene, K. O., 209
McPhail, C., 353 Moghadam, V. M., 320, 332, 333
MDSD, 432 Mokken, R. J., 93
Mearsheimer, J. J., 430 Molina, I., 400, 401, 402, 405
Medina, L. F., 459 Mommsen, W., 104
Melucci, A., 329, 350 monarchies, authoritarian, 284, 287, 291, 292
Meltzer, A. H., 209 Money, J., 153
Mendus, S., 424, 425 Mongolia, 532
Menon, A., 418 Monnet, J., 480
Menzel, U., 108, 113 Monroe, K. R., 472
Merari, A., 465, 469 Montesquieu, Charles, 20, 300
Mercosur, 416, 477, 487 Moon, B., 429, 430
Merlo, A., 235 Moore, B., 2, 17, 21, 80, 105, 109, 162, 164,
Merriam, C., 160, 274, 525, 527 295, 333, 335, 350
Mershon, C., 230, 238 five conditions for democracy, 21–2
Mesopotamia, 251, 252 Moore, W., 467
Mettler, S., 353 Moran, M., 448–9
Meyer, D. S., 329, 351, 352, 353, 354 Moravscik, A., 418, 483
Meyer, J. W., 130, 131 Morgan et al., 130
Meyer, W. H., 429, 431 Morgenstern, C., 227
Meyer et al., 353 Morgenstern, O., 229, 254
Mexico, 16, 59, 60, 163, 198t, 267, 290, 301, Morgenstern, S., 391
330, 336, 337, 339, 356–7, 387, 390, Morgenthau, H., 177, 178, 179, 183
420, 433, 456, 486, 527, 537, 538 Mori, 526, 531, 534
Michels, R., 104 Morlino, L., 519
Mickolus, E. F., 470 Morocco, 391, 532
Mickolus et al., 470 Morrison-Taw, J., 470
micro-foundations of politics, 108–11, 114, 203 Morrow, J. D., 234
revolutions, 335–6 Mosca, G., 104
middle class, 22, 105, 281 Mouffe, C., 107
Middle East, 166, 167, 248, 252, 279, 323, Mozaffar, S., 396, 402, 404, 405
326, 340, 382, 529, 532, 535 Mozambique, 322, 519
Midlarsky, M. I., 327 MSSD, 432, 433
Migdal, J. S., 327 Muchie, M., 488
Miliband, R., 107 Mudde, C., 221, 466
military governments, 287, 291, 292–3, 295, Muller, E. N., 313, 327, 337
434, 514, 519 Muller, P., 135, 139f
military trials, 518, 519 Müller, W., 94, 97, 230, 232, 233, 234, 238,
Mill, J. S., 1, 5, 25, 26, 28, 56, 103, 114, 275, 388 239, 240, 241, 519
Miller, G., 253 Mulligan et al., 283
Miller et al., 370 multi-culturalism, 107
Mills, C. W., 106 multinational corporations, 367
Milner, H., 185, 295 Munck, G., 51, 52, 64, 391, 538

9781412919760_Index.indd 14 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 555

Münnich, A., 93, 94 Nuremberg Charter, 519


Murithi, T., 487 Nyasaland, 420
Musallam, A., 169 Nyblade, B., 229, 233, 236, 241
Mutz et al, 135 Nye, J., 478, 479, 481
Myanmar see Burma
Myrdal, G., 481 Oberschall, A., 320, 325, 328, 331, 335, 471
O’Brien, K. J., 355
N analysis 13, 31, 240 Oberst, R. C., 400
large-N analysis, 2, 4, 14, 15, 36, 38–40, 39t, 50, 51, observation, 54, 55, 64, 77
68, 69, 70, 77, 79, 81, 163, 200–1, 278, 279, Occam, William of, 73
285, 285, 294, 423, 424, 429, 430, 431, 432, O’Donnell, G., 291, 295, 350
433, 434 OECD, 40, 44, 90, 91, 154, 206, 217, 218, 221,
small-N analysis, 2, 4, 15, 80, 200, 278, 423, 424, 248, 362, 368, 371, 440, 458
431, 432 Offe, C., 107, 350
Nacif, B., 254 O’Gorman, F., 401
NAFTA, 416, 477, 486, 487 oil, 42, 279–80, 287, 289
Nagel, E., 78, 80 O’Halloran, S., 449
Nagler, J., 265 O’Kane, R. H. T., 97
Narud, H. M., 232 O’Leary, C., 401, 405
Nash, K., 101, 102, 107, 110, 116, J., 329 oligarchy, 287, 288
National Defence Education Act, 1958, 161, 171 Olivier, J., 333, 335
National Health Service, UK, 211 Olivier et al., 356
National Integrity System, 372 Olken, B. A., 370
National Investigative Commission for the OLS (ordinary least squares), 41–2, 45, 46, 47
Disappeared, 519 Olsen, J., 126, 130, 131, 139f, 144, 148, 149, 200, 284
National Opinion Research Center, USA, 526 Olson, M., 335, 349
National Organization for Women, 328 Oman, 198t
nationalism, 104, 109, 250, 287, 326, 327, O’Neill, B. E., 466
329, 33, 480, 535 opinion, mass, 135, 137, 353, 415, 522–40
‘nationalistic universalism’, 183 opinion poles, 266, 267–8, 271, 274
Navarro, M., 355 see also citizenship; elections
Nazism, 134, 135–6, 321, 329, 339, 515, 526 Opp, K. -D., 334, 335
Negretto, G. L., 254, 257 Opp et al., 326
neo-Marxism, 6, 102, 106, 107, 108, 109, Ordeshook, P. C., 156, 230, 413
111, 114, 162, 164 Orentlicher, D. F., 501, 502, 514
NEPAD, 487, 488 Organization of African Unity (OAU), 481, 487
Nepal, 532 Organization of American States, 404–5, 481
Netherlands, 195, 198t, 215, 216, 217, 219, 231, organizations, 145, 268, 327–9
264, 273, 303, 307f, 309f, 310f, 323, 330, organizational theory, 130, 131
352, 367, 456, 530, 531, 538 Orientalism, 103, 108, 163, 164
Neumayer, E., 427, 429, 430 Orloff, A., 109
New Europe Barometers, 523t, 531, 537 O’Rouke, K. H., 450
New Zealand, 170, 273, 275, 446, 538 Orum, A. M., 101
Newton, K., 269, 303, 312, 528 Osa, M., 327
Nevitte, N., 306 Osiel, M., 501, 514, 519
Nicaragua, 320, 322, 323, 324, 327, 329–30, 332, O.S.C.E., 400
333, 334, 337, 338, 339, 387, 515 Osgood, C. E., 97
Nice Treaty, 483 O’Sullivan, G., 468
Nicolaidis, K., 418 Osterhammel, J., 104, 113
Nie, N., 527 Ostrom, E., 126, 472
NieBen, M., 92 Ostrom, V., 248
Nietzsche, F., 504 Ottaway, M., 386, 391
Niger, 402 Ottoman Empire, 250
Nigeria, 402, 413, 419 Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, 154
Nino, C. S., 254, 503, 513 Owen, D., 107
Nolan, P., 300, 315
non-governmental organisations (NGOs), 362, 367, 431 Padula, A., 333
NORC, 529 Paige, J. M., 327
Nordhaus, W., 150, 200 Pakistan, 165, 333, 382, 387, 420, 532
Norris, P., 38, 256, 268, 306, 400, 538 Palestine, 472, 532
North, D. C., 127, 133, 282, 284, 290, 443, 445, 456 Palme, 218
North Africa, 166, 323, 382 Palmer, H., 274
Norway, 17, 164, 198t, 221, 367, 455, 525, Panama, 387
529, 530, 538 Pape, R., 328, 468
Nuremberg trials, 498, 501, 512 Pareto, V., 104

9781412919760_Index.indd 15 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


556 INDEX

Park, A., 535 policy, 73, 145, 147, 148, 150, 151, 152, 155,
Park, H., 430 156, 353, 479, 505, 510
Parker, D., 322 coalitions, policy-seeking, 231–4
participation, 38, 39t, 281, 303, 338, 526–7 fiscal, 199, 200, 201, 219, 216
see also activism; citizenship; opinion, social, 194, 201, 202, 209–10, 211, 212,
mass; social movements; surveys 213, 214, 216, 218
Parks-Kmenta method, 46 see also governance
parliamentary regimes compared to political culture, 299–318
presidential, 253–4, 255, 453 allegiance model of democratic citizenship, 302–3
Parrot, B., 112 civic competence, 301–2
Parsa, N., 320, 324, 326, 327, 356 criticality and disaffection, 306–7, 308
Parsons, C., 134, 137 definition, 299–300
Parsons, T., 104, 163, 164 demand, understanding, assessment, 308, 309f
Pastor, R., 337, 396, 398, 400, 404, 486 efficacious and elite-challenging publics,
Pasquarello, T., 429 307–8, 307f, 315
Paxton, P., 37–8 party-voter dealignment, 303
Payne, A., 479, 491 political economy and, 314–15
Payne, L., 432 roots of concept, 300–1
Payne, M., 400 self-expression model of citizenship, 304–6, 305t,
PCSEs (panel corrected standard errors), 46 306f; as a democratizing
peasant revolution, 21, 22, 326, 327, 329–30 motivational force, 311; coherence of self
Pecaut, D., 468 expression values, 313–14
Pedahzur, A., 468, 472 social capital, trust and confidence, 312–13
Pederson, O., 132, 135, 219 solidarity, 308–10, 310f
Pelassy, D., 114, 115 political economy, 144–58, 175, 185–7, 278
Pennings et al., 40 democratic partisan competition and, 193–226, 198t
Percival et al., 272 government spending and corruption, 453–5
Pérez-Liñán, A., 63, 295 institutional and comparative turns, 149–55
Perkmann, M., 478 meaning and purpose of, 145–6
Perliger, A., 472 open economies, 155
Perry, E. J., 324 political culture and, 314–15
Persia, 251 property rights, 455–7
Perspectives on Politics, 1 role of assumptions in, 149
Persson, T., 152, 453, 454 understanding influence of, 146–9
Persson et al., 454 political parties, 146–7, 151–2, 196–7, 200, 206, 210,
Perotti, R., 200 212, 215, 216, 219, 270, 303–4, 364, 415, 457
Peru, 54, 357, 390, 428, 519 center-left, 196, 199, 206, 219
Peterson, R., 336 center-right, 196, 219, 221
Petersson, N., 113 left-wing, 196, 200, 201, 206, 208, 210, 211, 212,
Pevehouse, J., 279, 285, 286 213, 219, 264, 267
Pew Charitable Trusts, 533 opposition parties, 388–9
Pew Global Attitudes Survey, 524t, 525, 532–3, 534 party identification, 264–5; disaffection, 306–7
Pfaff, S., 326, 328 right-wing, 196–7, 200, 206, 211, 216, 219, 221, 264
Philip, M., 397 ruling parties, 389
Philippines, 320, 322, 324, 326, 327, 333, 334, 335, see also government formation
337, 339, 356, 358, 449, 450, 532, 538 Political Risk Services, 458–9
Philips curve, 150 ‘Polity III’, 37
Phillips, K., 331 Pollack, M., 127, 483
Phillips, N., 486 polyarchy, 36–8, 39t, 40
‘physical quality of life index’ (PQLI), 427, 428 Pontusson, J., 206, 211
Physicians for Human Rights, 429 Pokin, S., 327
Piattoni, S., 482 Poole, C., 526
Pierson, P., 67, 79, 80, 128, 129, 130, 139f, 219 pork-barrel politics, 364, 365
Pinto-Duchinksy, M., 275 Portugal, 197, 198t, 357, 381, 516, 538
Piven, F. F., 349, 353 Pòsada-Carbó, E., 404, 405
Plattner, M. F., 38, 105, 112, 320 post-colonialism, 103, 106, 107, 108, 110,
Playne, A., 479 114, 168, 184, 410
Plümper, T., 46, 147, 155 post-modernism, 103, 106, 107, 108, 114, 184, 504
Plümper et al., 46 positivism, 125, 135, 136, 137, 138, 139f, 179
pluralism, 36, 37, 38, 39t, 40 Posousney, M. P., 405
Poe, S., 427, 429, 431, 467 Poulantzas, N., 107
Poe et al., 427, 429 poverty, 55, 59, 209, 281, 282–4, 293, 366, 450, 525
Poggi, G., 109 Powell, B. G., 101, 194, 270–1, 275
Poguntke, T., 227 Powell, L. N., 400, 405
Poland, 151, 198t, 322, 327, 338, 387, 448, 538 Powell, W. W., 130, 131, 139f

9781412919760_Index.indd 16 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 557

power politics, 102, 106, 107, 110, 114, 253–4 Radaelli, C., 132, 137
power resource theory (PRT), 210, 211, 212, 214, Ragin, C. C., 5, 13, 14, 15, 18, 19, 22, 23, 25, 26,
218, 221 28, 30, 31, 56, 60, 62, 68, 69, 77, 81, 84,
PPP, 195, 197, 198t, 221 103, 109, 111, 113, 114, 115
Pravda, A., 405 Ragin et al., 24, 29, 31
Prebisch, R., 481 Ramos, A., 355
predictability and credibility, 445, 447–8 RAND, 470
presidentialism, 152–3, 227, 369 Randall, M., 338
comparing presidential and parliamentary regimes, Randeria, S., 108
253–4, 255, 453, 454 random walk (RW), 43
Press, C., 229 Rapoport, D., 465, 466, 471
Prewitt, K., 162 Rashid, A., 168
Princip, G., 74, 80 Rasler, K., 333
Pridham, G., 241 rational choice, 126–8, 130, 131, 132, 133,
Pripstein Posusney, M., 390, 391 136, 138t, 139f, 160, 412–15, 433
privatisation, 445 Rauch, J., 451
probability, 80 Raunio, T., 240
probabilistic compared to deterministic Ray, R., 356
arguments, 62–3 realism, political, 178
process tracing, 57–9, 70, 76, 79 classical, 177, 178–9
Productivity Commission, 428 neo-realism, 176, 177, 181, 184, 186
Project Civil Strife, 470 Recanatini, F., 451
property rights, 445–7, 449, 450–1, 452, 453, 454, reconciliation, 499, 503, 505
455–7 redistribution, 281, 283, 284, 337
proportional representation, 255–6, 257, 258, 259 social protection and, 207–20
protectionism, 184 redistributive transitional justice, 500t, 509–10,
protest, 109, 137, 269, 303–4, 307, 320, 321, 325, 516–17
326, 327 Regan, P. M., 333, 429
see also social movements regional economic communities (RECs), 488
Protestantism, 19, 20, 31 regionalism, 184, 477–96
Prussia, 21, 176 definitions, 478–9
Przeworski, A., 2, 56, 84, 92, 95, 97, 114, 127, debates, chronological: early, 480–1, 491; recent,
149, 166, 291, 293, 295, 445–6, 449, 459, 511 481–3, 491
Przeworski et al., 44, 279, 280, 283, 287, 288, debates, regions: Africa, 483, 487–9, 490, 491;
294, 295, 386, 458, 459 Americas, 483, 486-, 490; East Asia,
pseudo equivalence, 90 483, 484–6, 490; Europe, 483–4, 491
psychoanalysis, 107 future of comparative, 490–1
Public Choice Society, 155–6 Rehm, P., 193, 193
public opinion see opinion, mass Reif, K., 272
Public Opinion Quarterly, 526 Reilly, D., 169
public sector, 441, 443 Rein, M., 135
Pulse of Europe, 533 Reinares, F., 468
Putnam, R. D., 40, 110, 164, 268, 306, 433 Reinharz, S., 21
Putnam et al., 268 Reinicke, W. H., 37
Pye, L., 104, 164 Reiss, H., 411
Reiter, H., 353, 357
qualitative research, 14, 15, 18, 20, 23, 24, 26–30, Rejai, M., 331
31, 51, 52, 53, 54, 56, 59, 62, 63, 64, religion, 19, 89–90, 105, 109, 112, 163, 210,
67–83, 102, 103, 105, 111, 114, 335–6, 424, 470 211, 279, 325, 326, 327, 329, 330,
case study, 68, 81 see also case-orientated research 338, 430, 467, 533, 536
causal mechanisms and, 69–81 Islamic women’s dress, 333
claims of, 68–9 Muslims and democracy, 279, 280, 320, 537
interpretive or hermeneutic, 68 religious fundamentalism, 18, 168, 169, 340
quality as the property itself, 67–8 see also Iran, revolution
verbal aspects, 68 REMHI, 428
quantitative research, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 30, 35–6, Remmer, K., 454
46, 47, 50, 51, 52, 53, 54, 56, 58, 59, 61, rent-seeking politics, 364, 365, 444, 452, 453
62, 63, 64, 67–8, 69–70, 72, 73, 74, 75, reparatory transitional justice, 500t, 505–6
77, 79, 80, 81, 102, 103, 114, 154, repression, 333–5, 356–7, 384, 432, 467
155, 236–7, 424, 429 see also authoritarianism
see also N analysis research, distinctiveness of, 13–34
Quinn, D., 459 comparative methods as a bridge, 14–18
distinctiveness of comparative method, 18–23
Rabier, J.-R., 527, 528, 534 methods of comparative analysis,
race relations, 23–4, 24t, 25, 31 23–30, 24t, 27t

9781412919760_Index.indd 17 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


558 INDEX

research, global comparative methods, 35–49 Rouquié, A., 405


synchronic analysis with large-N design, 36, Roussias, A., 400
38–40, 39t Rowan, B., 130, 131
time series analysis, 40–7 Rowntree, S., 525
Reus-Smit, C., 183 Rubinson, C. 13, 14, 31
Reuter, O. J., 290 Rubio-Marin, R., 519
revolution, 21–2, 42, 60, 109, 176, 282, 283, 285, 287, Rucht, D., 110, 352
292, 293, 319–47, 350, 354–5, 401, 466, 471 Rucht et al., 352
causes, international system, 322–3; relationships Rueda, D., 212
among states, elites and popular groups, 323–7 Rueschemeyer, D., 2, 84, 95, 102, 109, 111,
definitions of, 319–21; types of, 321–2 113, 168, 247
micro-level foundations and qualitative Rueschemeyer et al., 40
analysis, 335–6 Ruggie, J., 131, 171, 180, 184
outcomes, 336–9; domestic, 337–8; Rugman, A. M., 482
international, 338–9 Rule, J., 320
peasant, 21, 22, 326, 327, 329–30 Rupnik, J., 166
processes, networks, gender relations and Russia, 75, 112, 161, 163, 184, 185, 198t, 250, 252,
revolutionary movements, 332–3; 338, 339, 368, 381, 391, 413, 414, 420, 448,
ideology and cultural frameworks, 320, 329–30; 465, 533, 538
leadership, 330–2, 338, 339; organizations and Russian revolution, 21, 22, 176, 319, 322, 324, 326–7,
identities, 327–9 332–3, 336, 339
repression and, 333–5 Rwanda, 498, 503, 518, 519
Reynal-Querol, M., 255
Reynolds, A., 397, 398, 404 Sabatier, P., 133, 135, 139f
Rhodes, R. A. W., 137 Sachsenmaier, D., 112
Rhodesia, 420 Sa’adah, A., 507, 508, 512, 515
Richards, D., 428, 429 SADC, 477, 488
Richards, S, F., 209 Sadri, H. A., 339
Riedel, J., 112 Sáenz Peña law, 401
Riggs, F. W., 37, 253 Sage methods series, 53
Riker, W., 126, 229, 230, 241, 252, 253, 391, 410, Sageman, M., 328, 472
412–13, 416, 417, 418, 419, 420 Said, E., 108, 163
Riker-Gamson theory, 229 Saideman et al., 275
Rinehart, J., 330 Sainsbury, D., 209
riots, 351 Sambanis, N., 81, 467, 471
Risse, T., 135, 139f, 185, 427 sample bias, 87, 88t, 89, 90–1, 96
Risse et al., 425, 432 Samuelson, P. A., 77
Roberts, C., 77, 81 Sánchez et al., 468
Roberts, T., 290 sanctions, 290, 295
Robertson, R., 103, 113 Sandholtz, W., 371, 382, 483
Robinson, J., 282, 283, 287, 290, 293, 294, 295, Sandler, T., 468, 471, 472
314, 336, 447, 457, 458, 459 Sani, D., 17
Rockefeller Foundation, 161, 526 Santiago, 531
Roessler, P. G., 405 Saris, W. E., 93, 94, 538
Rodbertus, K. J., 20 Sarkissian, A., 280
Rodrik et al., 446, 450, 451 Sartori, G. 2, 17, 59, 90, 97, 152, 254, 464
Rogowski, R., 77–8, 282, 284, 294 Saudi Arabia, 198t, 395
Roht-Arriaza, N., 512 Scandinavia, 205, 207, 213, 214, 215, 217, 218,
Rokkan, S., 105, 250, 254, 415 219, 221, 222, 238, 481, 526
Roman Empire, 251, 252, 300, 330, 362 Schäfer, J., 91
Romania, 387 Schaffer, F. C., 391, 402, 404, 405
Romer, T., Romer-Rosenthal model, 152, 153 Schain, M. A., 418
Roniger, L., 112, 432 Scharpf, F., 113, 127, 133, 139f, 153, 201
Roper market research, 526 Schedler, A., 382, 387, 390, 391, 396, 398,
Roosevelt, T., 171 401, 402, 403, 404, 405
Rosamond, B., 480, 484, 490 Scherpenzeel, A., 94
Rose, R., 311, 531 Schludi, M., 219
Rose-Ackerman, S., 364 Schmid, A. P., 464, 465, 468
Roessler, R., 390 Schmidt, B. C., 177
Rosenbluth, F., 213, 221 Schmidt, M. G., 36, 38
Rosendorff, B. P., 468 Schmidt, V. A., 125, 129, 130, 132, 135, 136,
Rosenthal, H., 200 137, 139f, 140
Romer-Rosenthal model, 152, 153 Schmitt, H. H., 272
Ross, M., 279, 322Rostow, W. W., 163 Schmitter, P. C., 149, 291, 416f, 481
Rothstein, B., 133, 139f Schneider, C. Q., 84

9781412919760_Index.indd 18 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 559

Schofield, N., 229, 231, 232, 233, 235, 240, 241 Sisson, K., 113
Scholte, J. A., 103, 113 Sives, A., 405
Schön, D. A., 135 size principle, 230, 234, 237, 241
Schram, S. F. 1, 2 Skaar, S., 432
Schroeder, R., 109 Skaar et al., 432
Schudson, M., 110 Skocpol, T., 16, 21, 22, 60, 102, 105–6, 109, 111, 115,
Schultz, F., 468, 469, 471 128, 139f, 168, 176, 186, 247, 293, 319–20, 321,
Schultz et al., 482 322–3, 323–4, 326, 327, 329, 337, 338,
Schumpeter, J., 199, 227 350, 354, 355
Schwartz, B., 20–1 Slaughter-Burley, A., 424
Schwartz, S. H., 309, 315–16 slogans, 269
Schwierer, J., 115 Slovakia, 198t, 538
Scotland, 420 Slovenia, 166, 170, 198t, 538
Scott, J., 106 Smelser, N. T., 97, 114
Scott, J. C., 163, 327, 402, 405, 454, 470 Smiley, M., 512, 513
SCRP, 529 Smith, A., 103, 109, 146, 247
Scruggs, L., 206, 218 Smith, B., 293
Scully, G. W., 452 Smith, D. H., 281
Scully, R., 271 Smith, L. M., 333
Seabrooke, L., 185, 187 Smith, S., 178, 182
Seawright, J., 52, 53, 69 Snidal, D., 60
Seidelman, R., 160 Snow, D. A., 328
Seidman, M., 328, 330 Snow et al., 328
Selbin, E., 320, 331, 332 Snyder, J., 502, 503, 511, 513, 514
Selden, M., 327, 329, 331 Snyder, R., 51, 52, 64, 323, 326, 335,
Seligson, M. S., 313, 327, 466 339, 391, 538
Sekhon, J. S., 395 So, A., 112
Sened, I., 232 social capital, 312–13, 456
Senegal, 387, 388, 390, 402 social democratic countries, 18, 200, 201,
Serbia, 74–5, 334, 390 207–8, 211, 212, 215, 219, 220
Sewell, W., 109, 110, 163, 320 social movements, 348–61
Shalev, M., 31 advanced industrialized countries, 351–4
shaming, 26–8, 27t, 29 protest and, 349–51
Shannon, J., 160 social protection and redistribution, 207–20
Shapiro, I., 127, 519 see also welfare
Shellman, S., 470 Social Security Act, USA, 211
Shepsle, K, 126, 139f, 233, 234, 235, 238, 241, 417 Social Science Research Council, 104, 162, 527
Shils, E., 104 social-scientific approaches to politics, 108–11, 115
Shin, D. C., 311 sociological institutionalism see institutional analysis,
Shiraishi, T., 482 sociological institutionalism
Shiveley, W. P., 271 sociology, 101–24, 145, 175, 179, 183
Shleifer, A., 366 macro-sociology, 102, 103–6, 113–14, 115,
shocks, 43, 201, 289 128, 131, 139
Shonfield, A., 199 Söderbaum, F., 478, 479, 482, 488
Shugart, M. S., 254, 257, 271 Sohrabi, J., 322
Shurman, R., 351 solidarity, 349
Siam, 252 Somalia, 164
Siaroff, A., 199 Sombart, W., 104
Siegel, R. L., 498, 502, 504, 513, 519 Somers, M., 328
Siermann, C. L. J., 459 Somit, A., 125
Sierra Leone, 429, 498 Sonnett, J., 29, 30
Sikkink, K., 135, 136, 427, 432, 500, 501, 511, 512, Søreide, T., 370
514, 515 Sørenson, G., 184
Silberfein, M., 467 Soroka et al., 216
Silke, A., 463, 464, 468, 469, 470 Soskice, D., 129, 130, 194, 202, 203, 206, 221
Silverson, R., 285, 339 South Africa, 198t, 320, 337, 338, 356,
Simmel, G., 308 357–8, 410, 419, 420, 433, 477,
Simmons, B. A., 155 488, 505, 512, 538
Simon, H. M., 69, 525 South America, 112, 166
Simon-Blalcock model, 69, 79 South Asia, 166, 167, 168, 340, 382
Simon, J., 113 Southall, R., 391
Simpser, A., 386 Southeast Asia, 165, 166, 170
Singapore, 197, 198t, 221, 371, 381, 382, 387, 532 Southern Christian Leadership Conference, 328
Sinnott, R., 266 Southern Political Science Association, 160
Sirirangsi, R., 429 sovereignty, 184, 247–8, 418

9781412919760_Index.indd 19 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


560 INDEX

Soviet Union, 74, 161, 162, 166, 167, 170, 171, 279, succession theory, 70
290, 320, 322, 323, 328, 332, 334, 335, 336, 337, Sudan, 323, 382
366, 382, 387, 415, 416, 417, 420, 465 Suh, D., 355
Soysal, Y., 110, 130, 139f Sullivan, T., 127, 139f
Spain, 18, 60, 198t, 252, 307f, 309f, 310f, 321, Sum, N. –L., 478
330, 357, 366, 417, 420, 498, 502, 511, Survey Research Centre, USA, 526
515, 519, 531, 538 surveys, 53, 137, 234, 241, 256, 266, 267–8, 271, 400,
ETA, 466, 468 429, 447, 522, 523–4t, 525
MLNV, 466 evolution of survey research, 525–6
Speck, W. A., 334 methodological issues, 535
Spiegel, S. L., 478 see also opinion, mass; World Values Surveys
Spohn, W., 109, 113, 114 Svensson, J., 371, 447
Sprinz, D. F., 51, 53 Svensson, P., 398–9, 447, 457
Spruyt, H., 251 Svolik, M., 295
Squire, J., 107 Swank, D., 216
Sri Lanka, 333, 532 Swedberg, R., 70, 71, 110, 238
Sririam, C. L., 512, 513 Sweden, 17, 134, 198t, 213, 215, 238, 307f, 309f, 310f,
Stability and Growth Pact, 418 313, 352, 446, 525, 529, 530, 531, 538
Stacey, J., 329 Swenson, P., 212, 213, 214
Staggenborg, S., 352 Switzerland, 154, 198t, 208, 221, 353, 411, 415,
standardization, 536 417, 538
Stanford University, 160 Syria, 382, 387
Stark, D. C., 322 Sznajder, M., 432
Starr, H., 22, 339
Stasavage, D., 443, 448–9, 456, 459 Taagepera, R., 252, 257
state, 105, 107, 109, 128, 130–1, 134–5, 146, 168, 246, Tabellini, G., 152, 453, 454
247, 249, 250–1, 254, 284, 289, 323, 325, 355, Taiwan, 451, 455, 532, 538
356, 357, 372, 399, 403, 418, 426, 427, 479, 482, Tajfel, H., 308
506, 507, 512–13, 517 Tajikistan, 166, 170, 382
bureaucratic efficiency and honesty, 448–9 Tanenhaus, J., 125
decline and failure of sovereign state, 247–8 Tanzania, 382, 531
market economy vs. state ownership and Tanzi, V., 365, 366, 367
regulation, 287–8 Tarrow, S., 52, 110, 164, 321, 349, 350, 351,
states, nations and empires, 251–2 352, 354, 432
see also governance; international relations Tate, C. N., 427, 429, 467
Statham, P., 352 Taylor, C. L., 400
statistical method, 58 Taylor, I, 487, 489
Steinmo et al., 128, 134, 168 Taylor, M., 236, 268, 335
Steinmetz, G., 109 Taylor, R., 126, 127, 128, 129, 131
Stepan, A., 112, 295, 350, 416–17 Taylor, V., 332
Stephens, J., 109, 113, 215, 218, 221 tax, 127, 154, 184–5, 202, 207, 212, 216, 217,
Stevenson, R. T., 229, 233, 234, 236, 237 218, 221, 281, 282, 284–5, 287, 293,
Stinchcombe, A. L., 81, 336 324, 325, 326, 446
Stokes, D., 529 Tabellini, G., 453
Stokes, G., 327 Teitel, R. G., 497, 499, 500t, 501, 502, 503, 504, 506,
Stokes, S., 279, 294, 295, 459 507, 508, 513, 519
Stokke, O. S., 26–8, 27t, 29, 31 Teitzel, M., 334
Stohl, M., 467 Telo, M., 484
Stohl et al., 429 Teorell, J., 293, 295, 313
Stolle, D., 269 Terrel, K., 94
Stolper, W. F., 77 terrorism, 328, 340, 368, 382, 431, 463–76, 533, 535
Stolper-Samuelson theorem, 77–8 definition of, 463–4
Stone-Sweet, A., 482, 483 divisions of, 464–70; chronological, 465–6;
Stoneholtz, W., 482, 483 problems of quantification, 469–70; questions
Stouffler, S. A., 526 of perspective, 468–9; stages of conflict, 468;
Stouffler et al., 526 strategic, 467–8; substantive, 466–7
Strauss, L., 160 interdisciplinary approaches, 470–2
Streeck, K., 129, 130, 136 Terrorism and Political Violence, 471
strikes, 23–4 24t, 25, 31, 320, 321 Tessler, M., 280, 532
Strøm, K., 230, 232, 233, 234, 236, 238, 239, 240, 241 Tetlock, P. E., 55–6
Strøm et al., 236, 237, 238, 241 Tétreault, M. A., 332
structural-functionalism, 163 Teune, H., 2, 56, 84, 92, 95, 97, 114, 166
Studies in Political Development, 104 Thailand, 252, 450, 532
Studies in Political Violence, 471 Thatcher, M., 134
subsidiarity, 153 Theidon, K., 469

9781412919760_Index.indd 20 3/13/2009 12:09:40 PM


INDEX 561

Theis, M. F., 405 Tucker, R. C., 163


Thelen, K., 95, 110, 128, 129, 130, 136, 139f Tufte, E., 150, 200, 249
theory, 70, 149, 160, 164–7, 179 Tullock, G., 144, 335, 364
adjudicating between theories, 16–18 Tunisia, 382
developing, testing and revising, 1 Turk, A. T., 472
non-cooperative game theory and institutions, 234–6, Turkey, 538
239 see government Tverdova, Y. V., 303
formation, coalition theory for wider discussion
theoretical narrative, causal mechanism and UEMOA, 488
covariance, 71–3, 81 UK, 18, 20, 21, 22, 59, 103, 104, 106, 128, 129,
theory generation versus theory testing, 63–4 134, 136, 151, 171, 182, 184, 185, 198t,
set theory, 18–21 199, 213, 215, 222, 227, 248, 253, 254,
Therborn, G., 107 255, 258, 27, 301, 303, 307f, 309f, 310f,
Third World see developing countries 319, 401, 428, 431, 469
Thomas, L., 488 civil war, 21, 330, 332, 333, 334, 339, 456
Thomas, M., 371 election study, 264, 266, 267, 273, 274, 275
Thomassen, J., 534, 538 empire, 250, 252
Thompson, E. P., 20, 21, 74, 109, 110 National Health Service, 211
Thompson, M., 391 surveys, 525, 527, 529, 530, 532, 538
Thorsen, N., 162 Ulysses, theme of, 78–9
Thries, M. F., 236 Ukraine, 390, 391, 401, 530
Tibet, 420 Ulbrich-Herrmann, M., 469
Tilly, C., 79, 102, 105, 109, 110, 111, 115, 176, 186, Underhill, G. R. D., 482
251, 320, 321, 334, 349, 350, 351, 354, 355, unemployment, 150, 201, 202, 203, 207, 209,
464, 465, 468, 472 212, 213, 221
time series analysis, 40–7 unions, labour, 201–2, 204
pooled, 43–7 United Arab Emirates, 198t
Timmons, J., 212 United Nations, 74, 78, 248, 398, 416
Tingsten, H., 525 UNDP, 426, 440–1, 534
Tipps, D., 101 UNESCO, 522
Tiryakian, E. A., 111, 116 Universal Declaration of Human Rights, 398, 424, 431
Tocqueville, de, A., 103 universal jurisdiction, concept of, 498, 518, 519
Todaro, M., 426 University of Michigan, 523t, 524t, 526, 528,
Togo, 382, 382 529, 530, 532, 534
Tokyo trial, 498 upper class, 18, 22, 105
Tomz, M., 396 urbanization, 38, 39t, 163, 164, 281
Tönnies, F., 104, 310 see also cities
Torpey, J., 519 Uruguay, 538
trade offs, 59–64, 209, 270 USA, 22, 67, 74, 78, 86, 94, 101, 102, 103, 104, 106,
transitional justice, 497–521 112, 127, 128, 129, 130, 134, 153, 154, 182, 187,
defining, 498–9 195, 198t, 199, 205, 211, 213, 215, 218, 220, 221,
explaining, 510–13 222, 248, 250, 252, 253–4, 256, 258, 265, 290,
impact of, 513–16 300, 301, 303, 307f, 309f, 310f, 320, 321, 322,
new areas of research, 516–18 323, 352, 428, 430, 444, 446, 449, 458, 469
sub-types of, 499–510, 500t area studies, 159–62, 163, 165, 167, 170–1
Translantic Trends, 524t, 525, 533, 537 civil war, 21
Transparency International (TI), 363, 367, 369, corruption, 367–8, 401, 404–5
370, 371, 372, 403, 534, 538 election study, 264, 265, 267, 270, 272, 274, 275
Traugott, M., 538 federalism, 410, 411, 413, 414, 416, 417, 419, 420
Treiman, D. J., 94 functionalism, 91
Treschel, A., 418 Native Americans, 330
Trevizo, D., 356 1919 steel strike, 23–4, 24t, 25, 31
Triandafyllidou, 113 regionalism, 477, 483, 486, 490
Triandis, H. C., 309, 310 Revolution, 319, 332, 333, 33
Treisman, D., 369, 371 riots, 351
Trimberger, E. K., 321 surveys, 522, 525, 526, 527, 529, 530, 531,
Trinidad and Tobago, 198t 532–3, 535, 537, 538
Troeger, V. E., 46, 155 USAID, 440
Trujillo, R., 455 USIA, 522, 526
Truman, D., 525 Uslaner, E., 312
Trumbore, P., 430
Truth and Reconciliation Commission, 503, 519 Vachudova, M. A., 168
truth table, 23, 24t, 25, 26, 27t, 29, 31 Valen, H., 232
Tsebelis, G., 153, 239, 275, 388 Valenzuela, A., 1, 254
Tsutsui, K., 427, 429, 430 Vallier, I., 114

9781412919760_Index.indd 21 3/13/2009 12:09:41 PM


562 INDEX

Van Creveld, M. L., 251 War on Terror, 431


Van de Vijver, F. J. R., 86, 87, 88, 89, 92, 94, 97 Ward, M., 278, 285, 291, 295
Van de Walle, N., 285, 290, 292, 293, 354, Ward, R. E., 160
387, 403, 454, 455 Warwick, N., 229, 233
Van den Broek, H., 466 Warwick, P. V., 196, 234, 236
Van der Brug, W., 538 Wasserstrom, J. N., 324, 332
Van der Eijks, C., 538 Waters, M., 113
Van Deth, J. W., 87, 93, 95, 96, 269, 303, 535 Wattenberg, M., 302, 303, 307
Van Evera, S., 56, 63 Watts, R. L., 411, 413, 415
Van Houweling, R. P., 396 Way, L., 290, 386, 387
Van Roozendaal, P., 233, 236 wealth and democracy, 279–80, 281–5, 287–90, 292,
Van Vugt, J. P., 327 293, 294, 357–8, 371, 458
Vanberg, G., 236 Weaver, O., 479
Vanhanen, T., 17, 36, 47, 112 Webb, P., 227
Vannucci, A., 366, 368 Webber, D., 485
Vargwese, R., 128 Weber, M., 19–20, 29, 31, 104, 110, 114, 163, 169,
variable-oriented analysis, 13, 14, 15, 16, 18, 25, 30, 31 184, 269, 334, 426, 443, 448
Venezuela, 487, 538 Weede, E., 333, 337
Verba, S., 85, 93, 94, 104, 267, 268, 269, Wei, S. –J., 448
299, 300, 302, 312, 522, 526, 527, 534, 535 Weilage, A., 400
Verba et al., 302, 304 Weinberg, L., 468
Verdier, T., 459 Weinberg et al., 464, 466
Verkuilen, J., 391 Weiner, M., 102, 104
verstehen, 167, 169 Weingast, B., 126, 130, 133, 139f, 146, 149, 282,
Verzichelli, L., 230 284, 290, 369, 417–18, 443, 448–9, 456
veto-players, 144, 153 Weinstein, H. M., 502
vetting, 506 Weinstein, J., 467
Victoroff, J., 472 Weir, M., 134
Vietnam, 16, 78, 322, 323, 329, 339, 382, Weiss, L., 185
465, 466, 532 Weiss, S., 113
Vinjamuri, L., 502, 503, 511, 513, 514 Weitman, S., 337
Vink, M., 112 welfare, 18, 38, 90–1, 105, 203,
Vishny, R., 366 428, 448, 449, 505
VoC literature, 206 welfare production regime theory (WPRT), 210,
Voegelin, E., 160 212, 213, 214, 216, 218
Volden, C., 236, 241 welfare state, political economy of, 207–20, 217t
voluntary associations, 209, 210 wellman, M., 310
Von der Muhill, G. E., 251 Wells, J., 311
Von Eye, A., 31 Welzel, C., 305, 308, 311, 312, 313, 314, 426, 538
Von Neumann, J., 229 Welzel et al., 304, 313
Von Stein, L., 103 Wendt, A., 131, 135, 137, 139f, 182
Wessels, B., 538
wage bargaining, 149, 201–2, 203, 204, 207, 208 Wessels, W., 112
Wagemann, C., 84 West Africa, 488
Waisbrod, S., 110 Wheare, K., 411
Waisman, C., 112 Wheeler, N. J., 182
Walder, A. G., 333 White, L. G., 46
Wallace, H., 111 White, R., 334
Wallace, W., 111 Whitefield, S., 266
Walling, C. B., 500, 511, 514, 515 Whitehead, L., 285
Wallsten, S., 443 Whitt, S., 274
Wallerstein, I., 107, 168 Wickham-Crowley, T., 320, 323, 326, 327,
Wallerstein, M., 149, 209 329, 466, 471
Walt, S. M., 338 Wiener, A., 490
Walter, B., 472 Wilensky, H., 209–10
Walton, J., 334 Wilkinson, S. I., 168
Waltz, K., 177, 178–82, 183, 184, 186 William and Flora Hewlett Foundation, 533
Wand, J., 396 Williams, P., 489
Wang, F., 113 Williamson, O., 126, 139f
Wantchekon, L., 274 Willis, P., 68
war, 286, 290 Wilson, A., 391, 405
see also civil war; guerrilla war; war crimes, War on Wilson, R., 274
Terror, World War I; World War II Wilson, W., 160, 162, 171
war crimes, 498, 518 Winner, H., 46
see also atrocities Wintour, P., 362

9781412919760_Index.indd 22 3/13/2009 12:09:41 PM


INDEX 563

Wiseman, J. A., 403 Worldwide Political Science Abstracts, 436


Wittgenstein, 85–6 Wren, A., 221
Wittman, D., 146 Wright, J., 293
Wlezien, C., 270 Wright, V., 418
Wolchik, S., 320 Wuthnow, R., 110
Wolf, C., 87, 89, 92, 96, 97
Wolf, E. R., 321 Yack, B., 102, 106
Wolfowitz, P., 362 Yashar, D. J., 355
Wolinski-Nahmias, Y., 51, 53 Yemen, 382
women, 332, 333 Yin, R. K., 53
economic opportunities, 209, 211, 213, 219 Yugoslavia, former, 322, 338, 401, 416, 498, 503, 518
leaders, 333, 338
transitional justice, 518 Zaire, 320, 322, 335, 444, 448
vote, 194 Zak, P., 281, 282
Wong, S. H., 282, 288 Zaller, J., 301
Wood, E. J., 51, 53–4, 55, 58, 62, 63, 320, 355, 356, Zalaquett, J. M., 505
357–8, 466 Zald, M. N., 328, 349, 350
Woolley, J., 459 Zambia, 382, 384, 531
working class, 105 Zanger, S. C., 427
England, 20, 21 Zanosc, L., 327
World Bank, 195, 196, 197, 248, 362, 364, 365, 366, Zanzibar, 403
369, 371, 372, 373, 386–7, 400, 447, 534 Zapf, W., 106
World Bank Institute, 372 Zaret, D., 109
World Economic Forum, 196 Zartmann, W. I., 320
World Politics 1, 52, 491 Zhao, D., 326, 333, 334
World Trade Organization (WTO), 368 Ziegler, H., 301
World Values Surveys, 305t, 306, 308, 309f, 310f, 312, Zielonka, J., 252
371, 429, 522, 523t, 528–9, 537, 538 Zimbabwe, 339, 381, 387
World War I, 74–5, 80, 104, 256, 323, 519 Zimmermann, E., 337
World War II, 39, 42, 101, 104, 105, 160, 161, Zolberg, A., 109
162, 163, 177, 193, 194, 208, 236, 250, Zovatto, D., 400
266, 268, 282, 283, 286, 287, 290, Zukerman, A. S., 1, 2
293, 300, 339, 410, 415, 479, 498 ZUMA, 528, 529, 538
Worldwide Governance Indicators, (WGI), 371 Zysman, J., 128

9781412919760_Index.indd 23 3/13/2009 12:09:41 PM

You might also like