You are on page 1of 31

Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 28, Number 1—Winter 2014—Pages 167–188

From Sick Man of Europe to Economic


Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy†

Christian Dustmann, Bernd Fitzenberger,


Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener

I
n the late 1990s and into the early 2000s, Germany was often called “the sick
man of Europe” (for example, Economist 2004), a phrase usually attributed
to comments by Czar Nicholas  I of Russia about the troubles faced by the
Ottoman Empire in the mid-19th  century. Indeed, Germany’s economic growth
averaged only about 1.2 percent per year from 1998 to 2005, including a recession
in 2003, and unemployment rates rose from 9.2 percent in 1998 to 11.1 percent in
2005 (according to World Bank data). Today, after the Great Recession, Germany is
described as an “economic superstar” (for example, in the movie “Made in Germany:
Europe’s Economic Superstar,” http://films.com/ItemDetails.aspx?TitleId=29218).
Germany’s number of total unemployed fell from 5  million in 2005 to about
3 million in 2008, and its unemployment rate had declined to 7.7 percent in 2010
(according to data from Germany’s Federal Employment Agency, the Bundesagentur
für Arbeit). In contrast to most of its European neighbors and the United States,
Germany experienced almost no increase in unemployment during the Great
Recession, despite a sharp decline in GDP in 2008 and 2009 (an episode discussed

■ Christian Dustmann is Professor of Economics, University College London, London,


United Kingdom. Bernd Fitzenberger is Professor of Statistics and Econometrics, Univer-
sity of Freiburg, Freiburg, Germany. Uta Schönberg is Associate Professor of Economics,
University College London, London, United Kingdom. Alexandra Spitz-Oener is Professor
of Economics, Humboldt University Berlin, Berlin, Germany. Fitzenberger is also Research
Associate at ZEW Mannheim, and Schönberg and Spitz-Oener are also Research Associ-
ates at the IAB, Nuremberg, Germany. Their email addresses are c.dustmann@ucl.ac.uk,
bernd.fitzenberger@vwl.uni-freiburg.de, u.schoenberg@ucl.ac.uk, and alexandra.spitz-oener
@wiwi.hu-berlin.de.

To access the Appendix, visit
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.28.1.167 doi=10.1257/jep.28.1.167
168 Journal of Economic Perspectives

in Möller 2010;  Burda and Hunt 2011). Germany’s exports reached an all-time
record of $1.738 trillion in 2011, which is roughly equal to half of Germany’s GDP,
or 7.7 percent of world exports. Even the euro crisis seems not to have been able to
stop Germany’s strengthening economy and employment.
How did Germany, with the fourth-largest GDP in the world (after the United
States, China, and Japan) transform itself from “the sick man of Europe” to an
“economic superstar” in less than a decade? One common answer points to a series
of legislative labor market reforms that started in the mid 2000s, the so-called “Hartz
reforms.” Another explanation focuses on the evolution of Germany’s economy and
trade balance in the context of the eurozone. However, we will argue that these
factors did not play a decisive role for the transformation of the German economy,
namely the restructuring of its labor market and the increase in competitiveness
that has helped German exports. We instead present evidence that the specific
governance structure of the German labor market institutions allowed them to
react flexibly in a time of extraordinary economic circumstances, and that this
distinctive characteristic of its labor market institutions has been the main reason
for Germany’s economic success over the last decade.1
We begin by arguing that the evolution of Germany’s per unit labor costs—that
is, labor costs relative to productivity—in both the manufacturing sector and the
other sectors in the economy has played an important role in the favorable evolution
of German tradable manufacturing industry. We then investigate the mechanisms
that allowed for wage restraints and the dramatic decrease in real wages at the lower
end of the wage distribution.
The specific feature of the German system of industrial relations that we stress
is that it is not rooted in legislation, but instead is laid out in contracts and mutual
agreements between the three main actors in Germany: employer associations, trade
unions, and works councils. The institutional setup of this system, which is dominated
by industry-wide wage bargaining, remained basically unchanged. However, many indi-
cators demonstrate that it did change in the way it operates. For example, the share of
German workers covered by any kind of union agreement has sharply declined, and
the number of firm-level deviations from industry-wide union agreements has sharply
increased since the mid 1990s. Overall, these gradual changes within the system led
to an unprecedented decentralization of the wage-setting process from the industry
level to the firm level. Alternatively, one may refer to this process as an increasing
localization of Germany’s industrial relations.
The decentralization in wage setting in Germany is in contrast to many of its
neighbors where the statutory minimum wage is often high (relative to produc-
tivity), where union wages and work hour regulations apply to all firms in the

1
Our argument is similar in spirit to that of Carlin and Soskice (2008, 2009), who argue that it is restruc-
turing by Germany’s private sector, using traditional German institutions based on employer-worker
cooperation, and not government labor market and welfare state reforms that are to be credited for the
German recovery.
Christian Dustmann, Bernd Fitzenberger, Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener 169

industry, and where institutional change therefore requires broad consensus along
the political spectrum.
We then turn to a discussion of why Germany’s labor market experience has
been so distinctive within continental Europe. On the one side, the fall of the Berlin
Wall in 1989 and the dramatic cost of reunification burdened the German economy
in an unprecedented way, leading to a prolonged period of dismal macroeconomic
performance. On the other side, it gave German employers access to neighboring
East European countries that were formerly locked away behind the Iron Curtain,
and that were characterized by low labor cost, yet stable institutions and political
structures. These factors changed the power equilibrium between employer and
employee associations and forced the latter to respond in a far more flexible way
than many would ever have expected. Finally, we discuss the relationship between
our analysis of the flexibility of Germany’s labor market institutions and two other
events: Germany’s Hartz reforms of 2003 and the arrival of the euro in 1999.

How Did Germany Improve its Competitiveness?

Relative Unit Labor Cost


In Figure 1, we plot the “relative unit labor costs” for a country’s overall economy
adjusted for the changing composition of the markets in which it competes, for a
selection of countries, in dollar terms. This index is computed by the OECD based
on year-to-year changes of unit labor costs and shows the relative change in the unit
labor costs over time (normalized to 1995) translated into US dollars at the current
exchange rate compared to a weighted average of a country’s trading partners. The
weights of the trading partners adjust annually to changes in trading patterns. An
increase in this index indicates a deterioration of the competitive position. A drop
in this index—that is, an improvement in competitiveness—is caused by some
combination of three factors: 1) a decrease in the wage per worker (or per hour);
2) an increase in productivity (per worker or per hour); and 3) a nominal deprecia-
tion of a country’s foreign exchange rate.
Since 1995, Germany’s competitive position has persistently improved, while
the competitiveness of some of its main European trading partners has deteriorated
(Spain and Italy) or remained close to the 1995 position (France). The competi-
tiveness of the United Kingdom has likewise deteriorated, although it improved
dramatically between 2007 and 2009 due to the sharp depreciation of the British
pound against other currencies. The US economy also lost competitiveness rela-
tive to Germany in the late 1990s as the US dollar appreciated in value relative
to European currencies, but improved consistently after the 2001 recession, partly
achieved through a dollar depreciation (for instance, while the euro/dollar exchange
rate was around 1 in 2001, it had depreciated to 0.8 in 2009). However, Germany’s
gains in competitiveness with regard to France, Italy, and Spain cannot be due to
currency depreciation (and in fact the euro appreciated relative to the currency of
most trading partners), because these countries all share the euro, and so it must
170 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Figure 1
Evolution of Competition-Weighted Relative Unit Labor Costs, Selected Countries,
1994–2012

1.4

1.3
Italy
Index (1995 = 1)

1.2
United Kingdom
1.1 Spain

1.0 France
United States
0.9

0.8
Germany
0.7
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
94
95
96
97
98
99
00
01
02
03
04
05
06
07
08
09
10
11
12
Source: OECD Economic Indicators.
Notes: This index accumulates the annual change in the relative unit labor costs of country i compared
to a weighted average of its main trading partners where labor costs are translated into dollars and the
weights are adjusted annually to the change in trade pattern. The annual change in logs is calculated
as 4log(RULCit) = 4log(ULCit eit) – ∑ j≠i g ijt–1 4log(ULCjt ejt) where ULCit = (wit Lit)/Yit is the unit labor
cost for country i in period t, computed as the total wage bill wit Lit divided by the value added of the
country’s industry Yit . The unit labor costs are translated into US dollars using the exchange rate eit .
Both the unit labor costs and the exchange rates are defined as index relative to some base year. The
weighting scheme g ijt–1 takes account of the structure of competition in both export and import markets
of the goods sector of those countries, and it adjusts on a year-by-year basis. See OECD Economic Outlook
(2012, Issue 2, No. 92) and OECD Economic Outlook Sources and Methods (http://www.oecd.org/eco
/sources-and-methods) for details on the method of calculation.

have arisen because German wages grew at a slower pace than productivity relative
to these other eurozone countries.

Wage Trends and Wage Inequality


Figure 2 shows the evolution of real wages in West Germany since 1990. The
figure illustrates the dramatic development in wage inequality in West Germany
over the past 15  years or so (Dustmann, Ludsteck, and Schönberg 2009; see also
Antonczyk, Fitzenberger, and Sommerfeld 2010; Card, Heining, and Kline 2013).2
Real wages at the 15th  percentile fell dramatically from the mid 1990s onwards.
From the early 2000s onwards, median real wages started to fall, and only wages
at the top of the distribution continued to rise. Notice that all wage figures that
we report stand for West Germany (although, henceforth, we refer to them as
“Germany”), because developments in East Germany are strongly affected by the
transition after German unification.

2
Details on the wage data are in Appendix A available online with this journal at http://e-jep.org.
From Sick Man of Europe to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy 171

Figure 2
Indexed Wage Growth of the 15th, 50th, 85th Percentiles, West Germany, 1990–2008

.15

85th percentile

.1
Indexed wage growth

50th percentile
.05

0
15th percentile

–.05

–.1
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Year

Notes: Calculations based on SIAB Sample for West German Full-Time Workers between 20 and 60 years
of age. The figure shows the indexed (log) real wage growth of the 15th, 50th, and 85th percentiles of
the wage distribution, with 1990 as the base year. Nominal wages are deflated using the consumer price
index (1995 = 100) provided by the German Federal Statistical Office.

If the increase in wage inequality and the modest growth in wages overall—and
in particular the dramatic decline in real wages at the bottom of the wage distribu-
tion—has contributed to the favorable evolution of unit labor costs in Germany
relative to the United States and other eurozone countries, then one should expect
this development to have been particularly pronounced in the tradable manu-
facturing sector—the backbone of the German exporting industries accounting
for 80 percent
80  percent of German exports. This insight turns out to hold true, but in an
unexpected way.
To further explore the increase in wage inequality, we classify sectors with
export volumes below the 25th percentile of the distribution of export volumes in
1995 as “nontradable sectors,” and those with export volumes above this threshold
as “tradable sectors.” “Tradable manufacturing” are all those tradable sectors that
belong to the manufacturing sector, and “tradable services” are all other trad-
able sectors.3 Figure  3 breaks down the evolution of real wages along the wage

3
Details on the construction of these categories can be found in Appendix A, available with this paper
at http://e-jep.org.
172 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Figure 3
Indexed Wage Growth of the 15th, 50th, 85th Percentiles, West Germany, by
Sectors, 1990–2008

A: Nontradable Sectors B: Tradable Manufacturing


.1 .2
85th percentile

Indexed wage growth


85th percentile
Indexed wage growth

.05 .15
50th percentile
50th percentile
0 .1

–.05 .05
15th percentile 15th percentile

–.1 0
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20

19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20 6
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
04
06
08

90
92
94
96
98
00
02
04
0
08
Year Year

C: Tradable Services
.2
Indexed wage growth

85th percentile
.1

0 50th percentile

–.1 15th percentile

–.2
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
04
06
08

Year

Notes: Calculations based on SIAB Sample for West German Full-Time Workers between 20 and 60 years
of age. The figures show the indexed (log) real wage growth of the 15th, 50th, and 85th percentiles of the
wage distribution, with 1990 as the base year. Nominal wages are deflated using the consumer price index
(1995 = 100) provided by the German Federal Statistical Office. Panel  A shows the evolution of these
figures for the nontradable sectors, panel B for tradable manufacturing, and panel C for tradable services.
We classify sectors with export volumes below the 25th percentile of the distribution of export volumes in
1995 as “nontradable sectors”, and those with export volumes above this threshold and that belong to the
manufacturing sector as “tradable manufacturing.” The sectors above this threshold that do not belong to
the manufacturing sector are classified as “tradable services.”

distribution separately for the nontradable sector, tradable manufacturing sector


(henceforth denoted as manufacturing), and tradable services sector. By this
measure, real wages in the manufacturing sector rose at all percentiles of the wage
distribution until the mid 2000s and afterwards continued to rise at the median
and the 85th  percentile. Germany’s real wages in the nontradable sector hardly
increased at all at any part of the wage distribution during the 1990s and started to
decline from the early 2000s onwards even at the 85th percentile, but particularly so
at the 15th percentile. The sharpest increase in inequality occurred in the tradable
service sector, where between 1990 and 2008 real wages did not show an increase at
the median, increased by 12 percent at the 85th percentile and declined by almost
Christian Dustmann, Bernd Fitzenberger, Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener 173

15 percent at the 15th percentile. At first glance, these figures do not seem to lend
support to the hypothesis that wage restraint in the manufacturing sector was an
important factor in improving competitiveness in that sector.

Exports, Tradable Manufacturing, and Domestic Inputs


The end product in manufacturing, however, contains a large share of inputs
produced in other sectors: in Germany, the value added in manufacturing is only
roughly one-third of the value of the end product, with the remainder of value
added being contributed through inputs from other industries, either domesti-
cally or from abroad (the literature so far has focused on Germany’s imports of
intermediate products from abroad, see Geishecker 2006; Sinn 2006; OECD 2007,
chap. 3; OECD 2012, chap. 3). Hence, the manufacturing sector may have benefited
from low wages in other domestic sectors and from cheap imports from abroad.
In addition, Germany’s manufacturing sector may have experienced increases in
productivity which exceeded the increases in wages in the manufacturing sector.
More detailed evidence suggests that both of these factors may be at play.4 In
Germany, the manufacturing sector comprised 21.6 percent of all jobs in 1995, but
17.7  percent of all jobs in 2007, while the value added of this sector (in current
prices) remained essentially unchanged at 22.8 percent of all value added in 1995
compared with 22.7 percent of value added in 2007. This pattern suggests larger
productivity increases in the manufacturing sector than in the other sectors, where
employment shares increased over the same period, with value added remaining
roughly constant. This pattern is not uncommon across high-income countries.5
However, the share of manufacturing in output value (value of final products),
as opposed to value added, rose steadily from 35 percent of all output in 1995 to
39.3  percent of all output in 2007. This pattern reflects that the manufacturing
sector indeed relies to an increasing extent on inputs from other domestic sectors
and on imported inputs (because the share in final products has increased while the
share in value added has remained the same), and may thus have benefited from
the low wage growth in other domestic sectors and from cheaper imports.
Digging down into the more detailed data, shown in Table 1, the value of inputs
over the value of output is nearly twice as high in manufacturing as in the other
two sectors (66.1 percent in 1995 versus 37.8 percent in the tradable service sector)
and this share increased by about 7  percentage points to 72.9  percent in 2007.
The share of domestic inputs remained constant over the same period at about
51  percent. Thus, the increase in the share of inputs used by Germany’s manu-
facturing sector, relative to the output value in that sector, is driven by increased

4
See Table 1 and Table A1 in Appendix C available online with this paper at http://e-jep.org for details
and data sources.
5
Pilat, Cimper, Olsen, and Webb (2006) point out that the relatively fast productivity growth in manufac-
turing is associated with relative declines of the prices for manufacturing products (this is Baumol’s cost
disease). Thus, shares in value added at current prices understate the share of value added at constant
prices in manufacturing to total value added at constant prices, which makes it remarkable that manu-
facturing in Germany has retained its share in value added at current prices.
174 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Table 1
Evolution of the Share of Value of Total Inputs and Domestic Inputs over the
Value of Output, Overall and by Sector, 1995–2007

  Overall Nontradable sectors Tradable manufacturing Tradable services

Panel A: Value of Total Inputs/Output Value


1995 48.2% 39.9% 66.1% 37.9%
2000 51.0% 37.9% 70.1% 41.4%
2007 53.2% 38.2% 72.9% 41.6%

Panel B: Value of Domestic Inputs/Output Value


1995 39.8% 35.3% 51.7% 32.4%
2000 40.3% 32.2% 51.7% 34.8%
2007 40.5% 32.1% 51.2% 34.2%

Panel C: Value of Domestic Inputs/Value of Total Inputs


1995 82.6% 88.3% 78.1% 85.6%
2000 79.0% 84.9% 73.7% 84.0%
2007 76.1% 83.9% 70.3% 82.2%

Notes: Calculations based on input-output statistics from the German Statistical Office (Fachserie  18,
Reihe  2, Years:  1995 –2007). We classify sectors with export volumes below the 25th  percentile of the
distribution of export volumes in 1995 as “nontradable sectors” and those with export volumes above
this threshold and that belong to the manufacturing sector as “tradable manufacturing.” The sectors
above this threshold that do not belong to the manufacturing sector are classified as “tradable services.”

use of inputs from abroad relative to inputs from domestic industries. However,
even in 2007, 70 percent of overall inputs in Germany’s manufacturing sector were
domestically produced. Thus, the argument that Germany’s manufacturing sector
has become nothing more than an assembly place for foreign produced inputs (for
example, Sinn 2006) is unjustified. In fact, while German manufacturing has made
increasing use of imported inputs, the share of domestic inputs in manufacturing
final output value had remained high and relatively stable between 1995 and 2007.
To what extent have Germany’s domestic inputs contributed to competitiveness
in its export-oriented manufacturing sector and the two other sectors? In Figure 4,
we plot the evolution of unit labor costs in the three  sectors, where industries are
weighted with respect to their exports for the two tradable sectors.6 When computing
unit labor costs, we first consider only the value added in the sector, as denoted by
solid lines in Figure 4. We then consider final output value in the sector, which is the
sum of value added in the sector and all inputs into the sector denoted by dotted lines
in Figure  4. This index (Unit Labor Costs: “End Products”) incorporates gains in
competitiveness in a sector due to the usage of inputs from other domestic sectors. We
also plot median real wages, adjusted using Germany’s Consumer Price Index, for the
three sectors. While real wage growth in the manufacturing sector is relatively modest,

6
Details on how unit labor costs are calculated can be found in Appendix A and in Appendix C, which
are available online with this article at http://e-jep.org.
From Sick Man of Europe to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy 175

Figure 4
Evolution of Real Daily Wages and Unit Labor Costs by Sector, 1995–2007

A: Nontradable Sectors B: Tradable Manufacturing


110 110
Indexeded wage growth

Indexeded wage growth


Real daily wages
105 105
Real daily wages
100 100
95 Unit labor costs:
95
Unit labor costs:
90 “Value added” 90 “Value added”
85 85
80 Unit labor costs: 80
“End product” 75 Unit labor costs:
75
“End product”
70 70

19

19

19

20

20

20

20
19

19

19

20

20

20

20

95

97

99

01

03

05

07
95

97

99

01

03

05

07
C: Tradable Services
Unit labor costs:
110 “Value added” Real daily wages
105
100
95
90 Unit labor costs:
85 “End product”

80
75
70
19

19

19

20

20

20

20
95

97

99

01

03

05

07

Notes: The figures show indexed real mean daily wages by sector (base year 1995 = 100). Nominal wages
are deflated using the consumer price index (1995 = 100) provided by the German Federal Statistical
Office. The data underlying these indices are in columns (1), (4), and (7) of Table A2. The figure also
shows indexed unit labor costs both “Value added” and “End product” by sector. The data underlying
these indices are in columns (2), (3), (5), (6), (8), and (9) of Table A2 of the online Appendix. Table A2
includes a detailed description of data and methods of calculations.

at about 8.2 percent over the 11-year period, in the other two sectors average wages
fell in real terms by 1.2 and 4.1 percent, respectively, over this time period.
As visible in the figure, domestic unit labor cost for total production in manu-
facturing, taking account of inputs produced in other sectors (”end products”),
declined far more rapidly than unit labor costs in value added—a decline that cannot
be explained by the increase in the share of imported inputs in total output value.
Moreover, unit labor costs in end products start to decline at the start of the observa-
tion period in 1995, while unit labor costs in value added decrease rapidly only from
2003 onwards when mean wages, and in particular wages at the 15th percentile of
the wage distribution start to decrease in real terms (as shown earlier in Figure 3).
Thus, Germany’s manufacturing sector improved competitiveness in several
ways. First, manufacturing drew on inputs from domestically provided nontradable
and especially tradable services, where real wages fell between 1995 and 2007. Second,
the decline in unit labor costs, coupled with the increase in mean real wages in
manufacturing, implies that productivity increases in the manufacturing sector have
176 Journal of Economic Perspectives

outpaced wage increases in that sector. In comparison, total unit labor costs fell less in
the nontradable sectors (minus 22.2 percent) and much less in the tradable services
(minus 9.7 percent), even though nominal wages grew much less in these two sectors
compared to tradable manufacturing. Note also that productivity increases in the
manufacturing sector have exceeded the increases in the two other sectors. Finally, to
increase the competitiveness of its own final products, the manufacturing sector has
made increased use of trade integration with Eastern European countries through
inputs imported from abroad, and far more so than other European countries.
These inputs made up 14.5 percent of total output in the manufacturing sector in 1995
and 21.5 percent in 2007. Calculating the outsourcing indicator suggested by Egger and
Egger (2003, p.  642) for Germany, France, and Italy regarding imported inputs
from Poland, Hungary, and the Czech and the Slovak Republics, using data from
the OECD Input-Output-Tables (at http://www.oecd.org/trade/input-outputtables
.htm) and OECD International Trade and Balance of Payments Statistics (at http://
www.oecd.org/std/its/), shows that in the year 2000, imported inputs from these
four countries amounted to about 8.5 percent of inputs in Germany, compared to
2.5 percent in Italy and 1.9 percent in France (relative to GDP).

The Increase in Competitiveness and Germany’s Labor Market


Institutions

The movements in German wages, within and across sectors, belie the common
belief that Germany’s labor market institutions are overly rigid. Instead, we argue that
the specific governance structure of the German system of industrial relations offers
various margins of flexibility. In the early to mid 1990s, these institutions allowed for
an unprecedented increase in the decentralization (localization) of the process that
sets wages, hours, and other aspects of working conditions, from the industry- and
region-wide level to the level of the single firm or even the single worker, which in
particular helped to bring down wages at the lower end of the wage distribution.
This decentralization took place even though the institutional setup of the domi-
nating system of industry-wide wage bargaining basically remained unchanged.
The specific feature which we stress here is that the governance structure of
the German system of industrial relations is not rooted in legislation and is not
governed by the political process, but instead is laid out in contracts and mutual
agreements between the three main labor market parties: trade unions, employer
associations, and works councils (the worker representatives who are typically
present in medium-sized and large firms).7 For this reason, Germany was in the
position to react in an unprecedented way to the challenges of the early 1990s.

7
Works councils have to be set up in establishments with more than five employees when demanded so
by the employees. About 92 percent of employees in establishments that have more than 50 employees
work in establishments with a works council, but only 18 percent of employees in establishments that are
smaller (Addison. Schnabel, and Wagner 1997; Beckmann, Föhr, and Kräkel 2010).
Christian Dustmann, Bernd Fitzenberger, Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener 177

The principle of autonomy of wage bargaining is laid down in the German


constitution and implies that negotiations take place without the government
directly exerting influence. As such, Germany has had no statutory minimum wage
imposed by the political process over the period we study. Rather, an elaborate
system of wage floors is negotiated periodically between trade unions and employer
associations, typically at the industry and regional level.
This model of industrial relations has been very successful in Germany, where
negotiation with unions and participation of work councils in decision-making
processes are widely regarded as an important cornerstone in furthering
common interests and even improving productivity. As a consequence, negotia-
tions are usually far more consensus-based and less confrontational than in other
countries. For example, Germany lost on average 11  days of work each year per
1,000 employees by strikes and lock-outs between 1991 and 1999, but only five days
per 1,000 employees between 2000 and 2007. These figures for the earlier and later
time period compare to 40 and 32 days per 1,000 employees in the United States,
30 and 30 days in the United Kingdom, 73 and 103 days in France, 158 and 93 days
in Italy, and 220 and 164 days in Canada (Lesch 2009).
Germany’s culture of common interest is dissimilar to the view about worker
representations commonly held in the United States. A recent US example is the
attempt of the management of the German company Volkswagen to introduce
a works council at its Chattanooga plant in Tennessee. While the participation of
works councils in management decisions is considered by Volkswagen as a corner-
stone of successful firm policy that helps furthering common interests, Tennessee
Governor Bill Haslam has been outspoken in opposing any union formation at the
plant, fearing that it endangers the state’s effort to attract investment (Greenhouse
2013). A key difference between US and German labor market institutions lies in the
fact that a works council in Germany elected by the employees does not have to be a
union representative (although in practice the majority of works councils are union
representatives), while the installation of a works council in a US firm automatically
involves the firm becoming unionized. Thus, works councils in Germany may act in
greater independence from a union if the survival of their firm is at stake.

Unions and Employer Associations


In Germany, contractual agreements between unions and employer associations
are negotiated either on the region-industry level or on the firm level. In addition to
wages, working time regulations are an important component of the negotiations.
A distinguishing feature from US labor market institutions is that the recogni-
tion of trade unions in Germany is at the discretion of the firm, and union contracts
cover only the workers in firms that recognize the relevant sectoral wage bargaining
(union) contract—regardless of whether the worker is a union member (for discus-
sion, see OECD 2004; Dustmann and Schoenberg 2009; Fitzenberger, Kohn, and
Lembcke 2013). Also, German firms that once recognized the union contracts can
later opt out at their own discretion. Even within union wage contracts negotiated
at the industry level, there is scope for wage flexibility at the firm level through
178 Journal of Economic Perspectives

so-called “opening” or “hardship” clauses, provided that workers’ representatives


agree (for example, Hassel 1999; Hassel and Rehder 2001; Carlin and Soskice 2009;
Brändle, Heinbach, and Meier 2011; Bispinck, Dribbusch, and Schulten 2010).
After opting out of a collective agreement, firms still have to pay wages for the
incumbent employees according to the collective agreement until a new agreement
at the firm level has been reached, but they do not have to honor new negotiated
wage increases and the firm need not follow the old collective agreements for new
hires. Thus, over time a firm may be able to lower wage costs considerably by opting
out of the union contract—provided its employees accepted this.
After 1995, there was indeed a dramatic decline in union coverage in Germany.
This decline is almost entirely driven by a decline in industry-wide agreements.8
From 1995 to 2008, the share of employees covered by industry-wide agreements
fell from 75 to 56  percent, while the share covered by firm-level agreements fell
from 10.5 to 9 percent. The percentage of German workers that were not covered
by an agreement in 1995 –1997 was highest in the tradable services (22 percent), as
compared to tradable manufacturing (9.8 percent) and nontradables (12 percent).
By 2006 –2007, noncoverage had sharply increased in all three sectors to 40, 27, and
32 percent in the tradable services, manufacturing, and nontradables respectively,
and this share continued to rise. By 2010, according to the German Structure of
Earnings Survey, 41 percent of all employees in firms with at least 10 employees in
the sectors Manufacturing, Mining, and Services are not covered by any collective
wage agreement (StaBu 2013).
Has this decrease in union coverage rates contributed to a reduction in wage
growth and to an increase in inequality? We investigate this question in Figure 5,
where we plot the observed changes in log real wages between 1995 and 2008 along
the wage distribution. We also plot the counterfactual changes that would have
occurred if unionization rates had remained at the same level as in 1995, using the
reweighting approach developed in DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux (1996), which
essentially reweighs wages observed in 2008 with the odds-ratio that a worker with
specific observed characteristics has been observed in the 2008-coverage-status in
1995 versus being observed in the 2008-coverage-status in 2008. Notice that this
constructed counterfactual exercise is by no means “causal,” among other reasons
because it ignores general equilibrium effects of de-unionization. The figure
suggests that Germany’s wages in 2008 would have been higher if union coverage
had remained the same as in 1995 throughout the entire wage distribution, but the
difference is particularly large at the lower end of the wage distribution.

Works Councils and Opening Clauses


Wage inequality has also increased strongly among employees covered by union
contracts, thus suggesting that the German system of industrial relations has allowed
for wage adjustments even within the unionized sector. This pattern is illustrated in

8
See Data Appendix A and Table A3 in Appendix C, available online with the paper at http://e-jep.org.
From Sick Man of Europe to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy 179

Figure 5
Observed versus Counterfactual Wage Growth between 1995 and 2008 along the
Wage Distribution: The Role of De-unionization

.1

Unionization at 1995 level


Change in log real wage

0
Observed change

–.1

–.2
5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75 85
Percentile

Notes: The figure shows the observed wage growth by percentile between 1995 and 2008, as well as
the counterfactual wage growth which would have prevailed if the share of workers covered either
by industry-wide or firm-wide agreements had remained at its 1995 level. The counterfactual wage
distribution is computed using the reweighting approach developed by DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux
(1996). Calculations are based in the LIAB.

Figure 6, where we show the evolution of the 15th, 50th, and 85th percentile of the
wage distributions, indexed at 0 in 1995, for those covered by a union (panel A) and
uncovered by a union (panel B) sectors. The figure shows that wage inequality rose
strongly in the covered sector both at the bottom and the top of the wage distribu-
tion, while in the uncovered sector it remained basically constant at the bottom
of the wage distribution and only increased at the top of the wage distribution.
However, notice that due to the indexation the figures hide the larger differentials
in wage levels at specific percentiles in the uncovered sector relative to the covered
sector: While the 85–50th and 50–15th differentials were on average 0.4 and 0.34
in the covered sector between 1995 and 2008, they were about 0.5 in the uncovered
sector. Thus, three factors contributed to the rise in overall inequality during the
time period under consideration, namely, the shift of workers from the covered to
the uncovered sector (which led, due to the larger differences in wage levels in the
uncovered sector, to an increase in lower tail inequality), the increase in inequality
in the covered sector, and the increase in inequality at the top of the wage distribu-
tion in the uncovered sector.
180 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Figure 6
Indexed Wage Growth of the 15th, 50th, 85th Percentiles, West Germany,
by Union Coverage Status, 1995–2008

A: Covered Sector

.15

.1 85th percentile
Wage growth

.05

50th percentile

15th percentile
–.05

–.1
1995 1998 2001 2004 2007
Year

B: Uncovered Sector

.15

.1

85th percentile
Wage growth

.05

–.05
50th percentile 15th percentile

–.1
1995 1998 2001 2004 2007
Year

Notes: Calculations based on LIAB Sample for West German Full-Time Workers between 20 and 60 years
of age. The figure shows the indexed (log) real wage growth of the 15th, 50th, and 85th percentiles of
the wage distribution, with 1995 as the base year. Nominal wages are deflated using the consumer price
index (1995 = 100) provided by the German Federal Statistical Office.
Christian Dustmann, Bernd Fitzenberger, Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener 181

We think that the change in wage inequality in the covered sector is due
to the decentralization of wage setting since the beginning of the 1990s, when
industry-level collective bargaining came under increasing pressure from employers
who demanded more firm-specific and differentiated regulations. Works councils
accommodated this decentralization to secure jobs in Germany, which also strength-
ened their role in the industrial relations. As another response, the trade unions
and employers’ associations agreed on an increasing number of “opening clauses”
in industry-level collective agreements. Opening clauses allow firms to deviate from
collectively agreed industry-wide standards. At first, these opening clauses focused
on hours of work, but later they also affected wages. Also, the opening clauses were
initially only temporary to avoid bankruptcy, but later they were also implemented
to ensure competitiveness in more general terms. Firms that use opening clauses
negotiate the details concerning pay and working time agreements with the works
council. Under German law, firms without a works council cannot use opening
clauses, but such firms may instead decide to stop recognizing a union contract.
Firms with a works council not covered by a union contract may reach an agreement
on wages with the works council.
Brändle, Heinbach, and Meier (2011, Figure 1) report that opening clauses for
wages only started to gain importance in 1995 (opening clauses regarding hours of
work had existed before 1995). Among industry-wide collective contracts in manu-
facturing, less than 5 percent involved opening clauses for wages in 1995, but this
had risen to about 60 percent in 2004. According to a survey of works councils in
2005, about 75 percent of all firms with collective agreements use opening clauses
(Bispinck 2007; Bispinck, Dribbusch, and Schulten 2010).
To summarize, the specific governance structure of the German system of
industrial relations allowed for an unprecedented increase in the decentralization
of the wage setting process, leading to a decrease in real wages, in particular at the
lower end of the wage distribution. This was driven by two main developments:
1)  a sharp decline in the share of workers covered by union agreements; and
2) an increase in opening clauses that strengthened the role of firm-based works
councils in wage determination relative to trade unions. This argument is consis-
tent with the finding that the rise in firm-level differences in wages contributes
strongly to the rise in wage inequality in Germany (Antonczyk, Fitzenberger, and
Sommerfeld 2010; Card, Heining, and Kline 2013).

What Led to Greater Flexibility in the German Labor Market?

Why were wage restraints and decreasing real wages at the lower end of the
wage distribution in Germany possible after the mid 1990s but not before? After
all, German firms have always had the option not to recognize a union contract
and to pay wages below the union wage, provided their employees accepted this.
Opening clauses had been possible before the mid 1990s. Our answer traces
to the major changes in Germany’s economy in the early 1990s related to the
182 Journal of Economic Perspectives

reunification of Germany and the opening up of the nearby central and eastern
European economies.
On one hand, the extraordinary cost of German unification burdened the
German economy in an unprecedented way, which is partly responsible for Germany’s
dismal performance throughout the 1990s and early 2000s. The German Council of
Economic Experts (SVR 2004, table  100, p.  644) estimates net transfers of about
900 billion euros from former West Germany to East Germany during the time period
1991 to 2003. The total sum of net transfers corresponds to about half of one year’s
GDP in Germany during that time period. On the other hand, the opening of central
and eastern European countries constituted a unique opportunity for German
industry to move production abroad. They offered a stable investment climate, as
well as (despite being locked away for several decades behind the Iron Curtain) a
long history of trade and interaction with Germany. The structure of industry and
education systems, for instance, shared many similarities, which survived the Soviet
era. Vocational training plays a key role in the education system, in a way similar to
Germany, in countries like Hungary or Poland. German was also widely spoken in
parts of Central and Eastern Europe. At the same time, wages in these countries were
far lower than in Germany, and working regulations more flexible (for example,
Geishecker 2006; Marin 2006). Moving production abroad to these countries took
place at a moderate pace: for example, the stock of German foreign direct invest-
ment to Poland, Hungary, as well as the Czech and the Slovak Republics amounted to
about 1 percent of German GDP in 2000 and about 2.3 percent in 2010 (according to
our calculations and data from http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DatasetCode=FDI
_POSITION_PARTNER). However, the possibility that German firms might relocate
production to these low-wage countries was very credible, and widely discussed in
public (among German media outlets, see the articles in DIHK 2003; Mihm and
Knop 2004; Hawranek, Hornig, and Jung 2004).
The fiscal burden of German reunification, coupled with an immediately
more competitive global environment, made it increasingly costly for German
firms to pay high union wages. The new opportunities to move production abroad,
while remaining still nearby, changed the power equilibrium between trade unions
and employer federations, and forced unions and/or works councils to accept
deviations from industry-wide agreements which often resulted in lower wages
for workers. In a similar vein, Burda (2000) predicted that the EU-accession of
Eastern European countries would foster a reduction of labor market rigidities in
the old EU member countries (including Germany). Germany’s unions and works
councils realized that they had to make concessions in order not to be further
marginalized, and the specific characteristics of the German system of industrial
institutions allowed the trade unions to adapt to the new economic realities and to
make these concessions. As a result, the German labor market appeared to be far
more flexible than many would ever have expected.
Why did other continental European countries not react in the same way as
Germany? One important reason is that the particularly difficult economic situa-
tion in which Germany found itself in the early 1990s was to a large part specific to
From Sick Man of Europe to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy 183

Germany, due to the reunification of Germany, which was not felt in other European
countries. This was reinforced by Germany’s geographic vicinity to the countries of
central and eastern Europe, which gave Germany an early taste of the challenges
of globalization. This decade of economic stagnation and hardship, when Germany
was the “sick man of Europe,” prepared the population for accepting agreements
for the sake of economic growth, which saw inequality rise dramatically for the first
time in the after-war period.
In addition, the system of industrial relations in other continental European
countries does not allow for the same inherent opportunities of flexible adaptation
as the German system. For example, in countries like France and Italy, union wages
are often bargained at the national level and apply to all firms in the economy,
regardless of whether the firm explicitly recognizes the union contract. Coverage
by union wage contracts has remained remarkably stable at very high levels at about
90 percent in France and 80 percent in Italy during the 1990s and the 2000s (OECD
2004, 2012; Visser 2013). Furthermore, in contrast to Germany, union wage contracts
are typically extended to all workers in an industry (OECD 2004, table 3.4, p. 148;
Visser 2013, table 4, pp. 96 –98). In these and other continental European countries,
adding flexibility into collective agreements would require political reforms at the
national level. More generally, many of the regulations which are determined by
labor contracts in Germany are either legally enforced in other countries (such
as the minimum wage in France) or nationally implemented (for example, union
agreements extend to all firms in the economy), and therefore require consent
on a much higher level (nationally, or even on the political level) to be modified
and changed. There is much less scope in these countries for a decentralization
of wage setting (and other aspects of working conditions) within their system of
industrial relations.
In general, the decentralization of union agreements is certainly being
discussed more widely across Europe, but whether or when such changes might
occur more widely remains uncertain.

Discussion and Outlook

We have argued that the remarkable transformation of the German economy


from the “sick man of Europe” to a lean and highly competitive economy within
little more than a decade is rooted in the inherent flexibility of the German system
of industrial relations. This system allowed German industry to react appropriately
and flexibly over time to the demands of German unification, and the global chal-
lenges of a new world economy. However, this intrinsic flexibility became only
evident under the extraordinary difficult economic circumstances and the extreme
duress in which Germany found itself in the decade after reunification. How does
our thesis fit with two other possible explanations for Germany’s increased competi-
tiveness: Germany’s Hartz labor market reforms of 2003, or the changes brought
about by the adoption of the euro?
184 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Germany’s government under Gerhard Schröder implemented the so-called


“Hartz Reforms” to the labor markets in 2003, which are often credited for spur-
ring Germany’s economy (for example, Rinne and Zimmermann 2012, 2013; see
Fitzenberger 2009 for a critical assessment of the Hartz Reforms). These reforms
were extremely controversial at the time. They reduced and limited the benefits while
unemployed, liberalized agency work, reformed “active” labor market policies, and
reorganized the Federal Labor Agency, but did not make any institutional changes in
the wage setting process.
The Hartz reforms were implemented starting in 2003, hence nearly a decade
after the process of wage decentralization and the improvement in competitive-
ness had begun in Germany. It seems plausible that the changes already underway
in Germany’s labor markets helped in preparing the political ground for the Hartz
reforms. In addition, as the enumeration of the main components of the reforms
makes clear, the scale of the reforms is modest enough that they seem unlikely to
have triggered the dramatic increase in competitiveness or the enormous drop in
German unemployment or to have led Germany’s labor market through the deep
recession in 2008–2009. Further, while the focus of the reforms was on creating
incentives for seeking employment, they did little to support the remarkable wage
restraint witnessed since the mid 1990s, which is the key factor in explaining the
gain in competitiveness.
We therefore believe that while the Hartz reforms have contributed to the
recent decline in long-term unemployment and to the continued increase in wage
inequality at the lower end of the wage distribution, they were not central or
essential in the process of improving the competitiveness of German industry.
Moreover, although one sometimes hears the argument that other continental
European countries should muster the political will to adopt their own version
of the Hartz reforms, we believe that such a recommendation may be misleading.
In our view, the specific governance structure of the German system of indus-
trial relations—activated under extreme duress—is what paved the way for the
remarkable decentralization of wage determination from the industry level to
the level of the single firm or single worker, and which together with a significant
increase in productivity ultimately improved Germany’s competitiveness. Whether
the political process would have been able to achieve a similar degree of wage
decentralization, had the autonomy of wage bargaining not existed in Germany,
is doubtful. In our view, the policy recommendation from Germany for the rest
of continental Europe should not be the Hartz reforms (the advice given often by
policymakers, as in a February 2013 speech by German Chancellor Angela Merkel
reported in de Weck 2013), but reforms that would target the system of industrial
relations by decentralizing bargaining to the firm level while keeping workers’
representatives involved to secure that employees benefit again when economic
conditions improve.
Some argue that the adoption of the common European currency is a main
factor that has helped Germany to improve competitiveness. Again, we believe that
the arrival of the euro may have been a contributing factor, but not the main one.
Christian Dustmann, Bernd Fitzenberger, Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener 185

First, recall that Germany was shifting its labor market institutions and improving
its competitiveness during the mid 1990s, and the euro did not start until 1999.
Second, within the common currency area, and after 2001, Germany continued
to gain competitiveness with respect to its main trading partners such as Italy
and Spain. Third, the euro has persistently appreciated against the US dollar,
leading to the increase in competitiveness of the United States as we illustrated
in Figure 1. It seems unlikely that Germany’s deutschemark (if the euro had not
been introduced) would have appreciated much more against the dollar than the
euro has, at least not before the start of the global financial crisis around 2008 and
the ongoing European debt crisis. Finally, it is not clear whether an appreciation
of a German currency (which probably would not have taken place before 2008)
would have had a dramatic impact on Germany’s overall competitiveness at least
in the medium-term, because it would also have made imported inputs less costly
and it would possibly have fostered even stronger labor market adjustments of
the type we have described above. For example, the depreciation of the British
pound by nearly 30  percent in 2008 –2009 has done little to help UK manufac-
turing exports.
Of course, the existence of the common euro currency area raises a number
of issues for countries within the eurozone. Without the possibility to depreciate
national currencies, the only way for countries like France, Italy, and Spain to
gain competitiveness relative to other countries of the eurozone is to reduce unit
labor costs—that is, by increasing productivity relative to real wages. Whether
these countries will succeed in this endeavor remains an open question. The
more centralized and legally anchored nature of their labor market institutions,
in comparison to Germany, does put them at a disadvantage in making such an
adaptation. Boeri (2011) provides an assessment of the political economy of labor
market reforms with a particular focus on countries of southern Europe. He
argues that the political process often allows only for two-tier reforms (affecting
only a subset of all employees) instead of complete reforms, which may not result
in an increase of competitiveness
The rise in inequality in Germany has led to an intensive debate about its social
consequences, and its effect on poverty and social justice. For example, recent nego-
tiations between employers and employee associations in Germany suggest that
future wage settlements will try to make up for the loss in real wages many workers
experienced in recent decades. It is also likely that certain aspects of labor and wage
regulations will in the future be “put in legislative stone.” As one example, the new
coalition government in Germany will introduce a nationally legislated minimum
wage. Thus, the possibility for Germany to rely on its system of industrial relations to
improve its competitive position by having a decentralized decision making process
may be cut back, and this may restrict Germany’s ability to react in similar ways to
future economic challenges. If that occurs, then future gains in German competi-
tiveness will need to be accomplished rather through increases in productivity that
outstrip wage increases. This pattern may help to bring convergence in the competi-
tiveness of the countries in the eurozone.
186 Journal of Economic Perspectives

■ Christian Dustmann is grateful for insightful and stimulating discussions with Wendy
Carlin. We thank Wendy for comments on earlier drafts. We also benefited from excellent
research assistance by Marina Furdas, Stefanie Licklederer, Olga Orlanski, and Florian Weiss.
Bernd Fitzenberger dedicates his contribution for this paper to John Pencavel, his fabulous
teacher in labor economics.

References

Addison, John T., Claus Schnabel, and Joaquim der EU-Osterweiterung auf die europäischen
Wagner. 1997. “On the Determinants of Mandatory Arbeitsmärkte im Osten und Westen [More unem-
Works Councils in Germany.” Industrial Relations ployment—the price of eastwards expansion? The
36(4): 419–45. impact of the eastwards expansion of the EU on
Antonczyk, Dirk, Bernd Fitzenberger, and Katrin European labor markets in the East and West].”
Sommerfeld. 2010. “Rising Wage Inequality, the Duncker & Humblot, Serientitel: Schriften des Vereins
Decline of Collective Bargaining, and the Gender für Socialpolitik Neue Folge 274, 79–102.
Wage Gap.” Labour Economics 17(5): 835–47. Burda, Michael, and Jennifer Hunt. 2011. “What
Beckmann, Michael, Sylvia Föhr, and Matthias Explains the German Labor Market Miracle in the
Kräkel. 2010. “Rent Seeking, Employment Security Great Recession?” Brookings Papers on Economic
and Works Councils: Theory and Evidence for Activity 42(1): 273–335.
Germany.” Schmalenbach Business Review 62(1): 2–40. Card, David, Joerg Heining, and Patrick Kline.
Bispinck, Reinhard. 2007. “Löhne, Tarifver- 2013. “Workplace Heterogeneity and the Rise
handlungen und Tarifsystem in Deutschland of German Wage Inequality.” Quarterly Journal of
1995–2005.” WSI Discussion Paper No.  150, Economics 128(3): 967–1015.
Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut, Carlin, Wendy. 2012. “Real Exchange Rate
Düsseldorf. Adjustment, Wage-setting Institutions, and Fiscal
Bispinck, Reinhard, Heiner Dribbusch, and Stabilization Policy: Lessons of the Eurozone’s First
Thorsten Schulten. 2010. “German Collective Decade.” CESifo Economic Studies 59(3): 489–519.
Bargaining in a European Perspective: Continuous Carlin, Wendy, and David Soskice. 2008.
Erosion or Re-Stabilisation of Multi-Employer “Reforms, Macroeconomic Policy and Economic
Agreements?” WSI Discussion Paper No.  171, Performance in Germany.” In Economic Policy
Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaftliches Institut, Proposals for Germany and Europe, edited by
Düsseldorf. Ronald Schettkat, and Jochem Langkau, 72–118.
Boeri, Tito. 2011. “Institutional Reforms and Routledge.
Dualism in European Labor Markets.” Chap. 13 in Carlin, Wendy, and David Soskice. 2009.
Ashenfelter, Orley, and David Card, eds., Handbook “German Economic Performance: Disentangling
of Labor Economics, Volume  4A and 4B. North the Role of Supply-side Reforms, Macroeconomic
Holland, Elsevier. Policy and Coordinated Economy Institutions.”
Brändle, T., W. D. Heinbach, and M. F. Meier. Socio-Economic Review 7(1): 67–99.
2011. “Tarifliche Öffnung in Deutschland: Dauth, Wolfgang, Sebastian Findeisen, and Jens
Ausmaß, Determinanten, Auswirkungen.” Journal Suedekum. 2012. “The Rise of the East and the Far
for Labour Market Research 44(1–2): 163 –72. East: German Labor Markets and Trade Integra-
Burda, Michael. 2000. “Mehr Arbeitslose—der tion.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 6685.
Preis für die Osterweiterung? Zur Auswirkung de Weck, Joseph. 2013. “Merkel Cites East
From Sick Man of Europe to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy 187

German Lessons for EU’s Problem States. Bloomberg. Manual Workers’ Jobs in Germany?” World Economy
com. February 19. http://www.bloomberg.com 29(5): 559–83.
/news/2013-02-18/merkel-cites-east-german Greenhouse, Steven. 2013. “VW and Its
-lessons-for-crisis-wracked-euro-states.html. Workers Explore a Union at a Tennessee Plant.”
DIHK [Deutscher Industrie- und Handels- New York Times, September 6. http://www.nytimes
kammertag]. 2003. “Produktionsverlagerung .com/2013/09/07/business/vw-and-auto-workers
als Element der Globalisierungsstrategie von -explore-union-at-tennessee-plant.html.
Unternehmen: Ergebnisse einer Unterneh- Hassel, Anke. 1999. “The Erosion of the
mensbefragung Mai 2003.” [“Offshoring of German System of Industrial Relations.” British
Production as Part of the Globalization Strategy Journal of Industrial Relations 37(3): 483–505.
of Firms: Results of a Firm Survey in May 2003, Hassel, Anke, and Britta Rehder. 2001. “Insti-
Berlin.”] http://www.dihk.de/ressourcen tutional Change in the German Wage Bargaining
/downloads/produktionsverlagerung.pdf. System—The Role of Big Companies.” MPIfG
DiNardo, John, Nicole Fortin, and Thomas Working Paper 01/9.
Lemieux. 1996. “Labor Market Institutions Hawranek, Dietmar, Frank Hornig, and Alex-
and the Distribution of Wages, 1973–1992: A ander Jung. 2004. “Bye-bye ‘Made in Germany.’”
Semiparametric Approach.” Econometrica 64(5): Der Spiegel 44: 94–109.
1001–1044. Jacobebbinghaus, Peter, and Stephan Seth.
Dorner, Matthias, Jörg Heining, Peter 2010. “Linked Employer-Employee Data from the
Jacobebbinghaus, and Stephan Seth. 2010. IAB: LIAB Cross-sectional (Model 2, 1993-2008).”
“Sample of Integrated Labour Market Biographies FDZ-Datenreport 05/2010.
(SIAB) 1975–2008.” FDZ-Datenreport 01/2010. Lesch, Hagen. 2009. “Erfassung und Entwick-
Dustmann, Christian, and Uta Schönberg. 2009. lung von Streiks in OECD-Ländern.” IW Trends,
“Training and Union Wages.” Review of Economics 1/2009, Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft, Koln.
and Statistics 91(2): 363–76. Marin, Dalia. 2006. “A New International
Dustmann, Christian, Johannes Ludsteck, and Division of Labor in Europe: Outsourcing and
Uta Schönberg. 2009. “Revisiting the German Offshoring to Eastern Europe.” Journal of the Euro-
Wage Structure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics pean Economic Association 4(2/3): 612–22.
124(2): 843–81. Mihm, Andreas, and Carsten Knop. 2004.
Economist. 2004. “Germany on the Mend.” “Outsourcing: Bis ich mit der Gewerkschaft
November 17. http://www.economist.com/node klar bin, hat die Konkurrenz schon geliefert
/3352024. [Outsourcing: Until I have reached an agree-
Egger, Harmut, and Peter Egger. 2003. ment with the union, the competitor has already
“Outsourcing and Skill Specific Employment in a delivered].” FAZ [Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung],
Small Economy: Austria after the Fall of the Iron March  21. http://www.faz.net/aktuell/wirtschaft
Curtain.” Oxford Economic Papers 55(4): 625–43. /outsourcing-bis-ich-mit-der-gewerkschaft-klar-bin
Fitzenberger, Bernd. 2009. “Nach der Reform -hat-die-konkurrenz-schon-geliefert-1144367.html.
ist vor der Reform? Eine arbeitsökonomische Möller, Joachim. 2010. “The German Labor
Analyse ausgewählter Aspekte der Hartz-Reformen.” Market Response in the World Recession—
In Reformen für Deutschland—Die wichtigsten De-mystifying a Miracle.” Journal for Labour Market
Handlungsfelder aus ökonomischer Sicht,” edited by Research 42(4): 325–36.
Günther Schulze pp. 21–48. Schäffer-Poeschel Verlag. OECD. 2004, 2007, 2012. Employment Outlook.
Fitzenberger, Bernd, Karsten Kohn, and Pilat, Dirk, Agnès Cimper, Karsten Olsen,
Alexander C. Lembcke. 2013. “Union Density and Colin Webb. 2006. “The Changing Nature
and Varieties of Coverage: The Anatomy of Union of Manufacturing in OECD Economies.” OECD,
Wage Effects in Germany.” Industrial Labor Rela- STI Working Paper 2006/9.
tions Review 66(1): 169–97. Rinne, Ulf, and Klaus F. Zimmermann. 2012.
Fitzenberger, Bernd, Karsten Kohn, and Qingwei “Another Economic Miracle? The German Labor
Wang. 2011. “The Erosion of Union Membership Market and the Great Recession.” IZA Journal of
in Germany: Determinants, Densities, Decomposi- Labor Policy 1/3.
tions.” Journal of Population Economics 24(1): 141–65. Rinne, Ulf, and Klaus F. Zimmermann. 2013. “Is
Gartner, Hermann. 2005. “The Imputa- Germany the North Star of Labor Market Policy?”
tion of Wages above the Contribution Limit IMF Economic Review 61(4): 702–729.
with the German IAB Employment Sample.” Sinn, Hans-Werner. 2006. “The Pathological
FDZ-Methodenreport 02/2005. Export Boom and the Bazaar Effect: How to
Geishecker, Ingo. 2006. “Does Outsourcing Solve the German Puzzle.” World Economy 29(9):
to Central and Eastern Europe really threaten 1157–75.
188 Journal of Economic Perspectives

Spermann, Alexander. 2012. “The New Role Streeck, Wolfgang. 1997: “German Capitalism:
of Temporary Agency Work in Germany.” In Die Does It Exist? Can It Survive?” New Political Economy
neue Rolle der Zeitarbeit in Deutschland, Beiträge zur 2(2): 237–56.
Flexibilisierung edited by Richarda B. Bouncken, SVR [German Council of Economic Experts].
Lutz Bellmann, and Manfred Bornewasser, 2004. “Erfolge im Ausland—Herausforderungen
Volume 3, 203–224. München and Mering. im Inland.” Annual Report to the Government,
StaBu [German Federal Statis- Wiesbaden. http://www.sachverstaendigenrat
tical Office]. 2013. Verdienste und -wirtschaft.de/fruehere_jahresgutachten.html.
Arbeitskosten–Tarifbindung in Deutschland 2010. Visser, Jelle. 2013. “Wage Bargaining Institu-
Statistisches Bundesamt, Wiesbaden. https:// tions from Crisis to Crisis.” Economic Papers 488,
www.destatis.de/DE/Publikationen/Thematisch European Commission. April. http://ec.europa
/VerdiensteArbeitskosten/Tarifverdienste .eu/economy_finance/publications/economic
/Tarifbindung.html. _paper/2013/ecp488_en.htm.
This article has been cited by:

1. Chih-Mei Luo. Are Labour Market Reforms the Answer to Post-Euro Crisis Management?
Reflections on Germany’s Hartz Reforms 45-69. [Crossref]
2. Dirk Antonczyk, Bernd Fitzenberger, Enno Mammen, Kyusang Yu. 2020. A nonparametric approach
to identify age, time, and cohort effects. Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference 204, 96-115.
[Crossref]
3. Michele Gazzola, Daniele Mazzacani. 2019. Foreign language skills and employment status of
European natives: evidence from Germany, Italy and Spain. Empirica 46:4, 713-740. [Crossref]
4. Sabine Klinger, Enzo Weber. 2019. GDP-Employment Decoupling in Germany. Structural Change
and Economic Dynamics . [Crossref]
5. Rosalia Castellano, Gaetano Musella, Gennaro Punzo. 2019. Wage dynamics in light of the structural
changes in the labour market across four more economically developed countries of Europe. Review
of Social Economy 4, 1-39. [Crossref]
6. Asaf Levanon, Evgeny Saburov, Markus Gangl, Jan Brülle. 2019. Trends in the demographic
composition of poverty among working families in Germany and in Israel, 1991–2011. Social Science
Research 83, 102318. [Crossref]
7. Juan Carlos Cuestas, Javier Ordóñez, Karsten Staehr. 2019. Unit labour costs and the dynamics
of output and unemployment in the southern European crisis countries. Empirica 46:3, 597-616.
[Crossref]
8. Shabneez Bhankaraully. 2019. Contested firm governance, institutions and the undertaking of
corporate restructuring practices in Germany. Economic and Industrial Democracy 40:3, 511-536.
[Crossref]
9. Sebastian Schmitz. 2019. The Effects of Germany's Statutory Minimum Wage on Employment and
Welfare Dependency. German Economic Review 20:3, 330-355. [Crossref]
10. Regina T. Riphahn, Rebecca Schrader. 2019. Institutional Reforms of 2006 and the Dramatic Rise in
Old-Age Employment in Germany. ILR Review 51, 001979391986337. [Crossref]
11. Matthias Dütsch, Ralf Himmelreicher. 2019. Characteristics Contributing to Low- and Minimum-
Wage Labour in Germany. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, ahead of print. [Crossref]
12. Martin Biewen, Matthias Seckler. 2019. Unions, Internationalization, Tasks, Firms, and Worker
Characteristics: A Detailed Decomposition Analysis of Rising Wage Inequality in Germany. The
Journal of Economic Inequality 118. . [Crossref]
13. Mark S. Manger, Thomas Sattler. 2019. The Origins of Persistent Current Account Imbalances in
the Post-Bretton Woods Era. Comparative Political Studies 26, 001041401985903. [Crossref]
14. Ronald Bachmann, Merve Cim, Colin Green. 2019. Long‐Run Patterns of Labour Market
Polarization: Evidence from German Micro Data. British Journal of Industrial Relations 57:2, 350-376.
[Crossref]
15. Francesco Devicienti, Bernardo Fanfani, Agata Maida. 2019. Collective Bargaining and the Evolution
of Wage Inequality in Italy. British Journal of Industrial Relations 57:2, 377-407. [Crossref]
16. Sofía A. Pérez. 2019. A Europe of creditor and debtor states: explaining the north/south divide in the
Eurozone. West European Politics 15, 1-26. [Crossref]
17. Bernd Brandl, Christian Lyhne Ibsen. 2019. Collective wage bargaining and the role of institutional
stability: a cross-national comparison of macroeconomic performance. Cambridge Journal of Economics
43:3, 677-694. [Crossref]
18. Sofia A. Perez, Manos Matsaganis. 2019. Export or Perish: Can Internal Devaluation Create Enough
Good Jobs in Southern Europe?. South European Society and Politics 24:2, 259-285. [Crossref]
19. Jake Bradley, Alice Kügler. 2019. Labor market reforms: An evaluation of the Hartz policies in
Germany. European Economic Review 113, 108-135. [Crossref]
20. Benjamin Bruns. 2019. Changes in Workplace Heterogeneity and How They Widen the Gender
Wage Gap. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 11:2, 74-113. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
21. Nicholas Giannakopoulos, Ioannis Laliotis. 2019. Industrial Relations Reform, Firm‐Level Bargaining
and Nominal Wage Floors. The Manchester School 55. . [Crossref]
22. AUGUSTIN IGNATOV. 2019. ANALYZING THE DETERMINANTS OF THE EUROPEAN
UNION’S REGIONAL ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT. Global Economy Journal 19:01, 1950002.
[Crossref]
23. Peter S. Eppinger. 2019. Service offshoring and firm employment. Journal of International Economics
117, 209-228. [Crossref]
24. Jürgen Wandel. 2019. Prospects for an ordoliberal reform of the European Union. Economic Affairs
39:1, 28-43. [Crossref]
25. John T. Addison, Paulino Teixeira. 2019. Workplace Employee Representation and Industrial
Relations Performance: New Evidence from the 2013 European Company Survey. Jahrbücher für
Nationalökonomie und Statistik 239:1, 111-154. [Crossref]
26. Katharina Dengler. 2019. Effectiveness of sequences of classroom training for welfare recipients: what
works best in West Germany?. Applied Economics 51:1, 1-46. [Crossref]
27. Merika Anna, Triantafyllou Anna, Zombanakis George. 2019. Wage and tax competitiveness: The
case of Hellenic shipping. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice 119, 255-270. [Crossref]
28. Golo Henseke. 2019. Against the Grain? Assessing Graduate Labour Market Trends in Germany
Through a Task-Based Indicator of Graduate Jobs. Social Indicators Research 141:2, 809-840.
[Crossref]
29. Werner Eichhorst, Paul Marx. Der Wandel der Arbeitswelt als Herausforderung für die Sozialpolitik
409-430. [Crossref]
30. KATRIN HOHMEYER, TORSTEN LIETZMANN. 2019. Persistence of Welfare Receipt and
Unemployment in Germany: Determinants and Duration Dependence. Journal of Social Policy 1.
[Crossref]
31. Jörg Bibow. 2019. How to Redesign the Fiscal Regime of the Eurozone: An Alternative Take on
Lessons from Us and Eurozone Experiences. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
32. Herbert Dawid, Philipp Harting, Michael Neugart. 2019. The Role of (De-)Centralized Wage Setting
for Industry Dynamics and Economic Growth: An Agent-Based Analysis with the Eurace@Unibi
Model. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
33. 2019. OUP accepted manuscript. European Sociological Review . [Crossref]
34. Sebastian Ludwig Hirn, Joachim Thomas, Christof Zoelch. 2019. The role of empathy in the
development of social competence: a study of German school leavers. International Journal of
Adolescence and Youth 24:4, 395. [Crossref]
35. David B. Audretsch, Apexa Mamtora, Hugo Menendez. 2018. Creating an entrepreneurial society in
Europe. The Journal of Technology Transfer 43:6, 1437-1448. [Crossref]
36. Martin Biewen, Bernd Fitzenberger, Jakob de Lazzer. 2018. The role of employment interruptions
and part-time work for the rise in wage inequality. IZA Journal of Labor Economics 7:1. . [Crossref]
37. Torsten Müller, Jon Erik Dølvik, Christian Ibsen, Thorsten Schulten. 2018. The manufacturing
sector: Still an anchor for pattern bargaining within and across countries?. European Journal of
Industrial Relations 24:4, 357-372. [Crossref]
38. Malte Ehrich, Abdul Munasib, Devesh Roy. 2018. The Hartz reforms and the German labor force.
European Journal of Political Economy 55, 284-300. [Crossref]
39. Michael Hüther. 2018. Überlegungen zur makroökonomischen Koordination im Lichte der deutschen
Erfahrungen: Geldpolitik und Lohnpolitik im Konflikt?. List Forum für Wirtschafts- und Finanzpolitik
44:3, 283-310. [Crossref]
40. Pablo de Pedraza, Kea Tijdens, Stefano Visintin. 2018. The matching process before and after the
crisis in the Netherlands. International Journal of Manpower 39:8, 1010-1031. [Crossref]
41. Tobias Brändle, Laszlo Goerke. 2018. The one constant: a causal effect of collective bargaining
on employment growth? Evidence from German linked-employer-employee data. Scottish Journal of
Political Economy 65:5, 445-478. [Crossref]
42. Britta Gehrke, Enzo Weber. 2018. Identifying asymmetric effects of labor market reforms. European
Economic Review 110, 18-40. [Crossref]
43. Monica Amici, Emmanuele Bobbio, Roberto Torrini. 2018. Patterns of Convergence (Divergence) in
the Euro Area: Profitability Versus Cost and Price Indicators. Italian Economic Journal 4:3, 367-384.
[Crossref]
44. Marco Francesconi, Matthias Parey. 2018. Early gender gaps among university graduates. European
Economic Review 109, 63-82. [Crossref]
45. Georg Cremer. 2018. Armutsbekämpfung – Was hat sich in der letzten Dekade getan?. Zeitschrift für
Außen- und Sicherheitspolitik 11:4, 459-466. [Crossref]
46. Luo Chih-Mei. 2018. Are Labour Market Reforms the Answer to Post-Euro-Crisis Management?
Reflections on Germany’s Hartz Reforms. European Review 26:4, 738-754. [Crossref]
47. Jörg Bibow. 2018. How Germany’s anti-Keynesianism has brought Europe to its knees. International
Review of Applied Economics 32:5, 569-588. [Crossref]
48. Bibek Adhikari, Romain Duval, Bingjie Hu, Prakash Loungani. 2018. Can Reform Waves Turn the
Tide? Some Case Studies using the Synthetic Control Method. Open Economies Review 29:4, 879-910.
[Crossref]
49. Kerstin Tanis. 2018. Regional distribution and location choices of immigrants in Germany. Regional
Studies 7, 1-12. [Crossref]
50. Olivier Giraud, Arnaud Lechevalier. 2018. The grey zone and labour market dynamics in Germany.
Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research 24:3, 317-336. [Crossref]
51. Stefan Etgeton. 2018. The effect of pension reforms on old-age income inequality. Labour Economics
53, 146-161. [Crossref]
52. Henning Jørgensen,, Michaela Schulze. 2018. Das Aktivierungsparadigma als dominantes Prinzip der
Arbeitsmarktpolitik in Deutschland und Dänemark im Vergleich. Sozialer Fortschritt 67:8-9, 627-643.
[Crossref]
53. Enno Schröder. 2018. Offshoring, employment, and aggregate demand. Journal of Evolutionary
Economics 20. . [Crossref]
54. Dirk Antonczyk, Thomas DeLeire, Bernd Fitzenberger. 2018. Polarization and Rising Wage
Inequality: Comparing the U.S. and Germany. Econometrics 6:2, 20. [Crossref]
55. Fabian Ochsenfeld. 2018. The Relational Nature of Employment Dualization: Evidence from
Subcontracting Establishments. European Sociological Review 34:3, 304-318. [Crossref]
56. Mario Holzner, Marina Tkalec, Maruška Vizek, Goran Vukšić. 2018. Fiscal devaluations: evidence
using bilateral trade balance data. Review of World Economics 154:2, 247-275. [Crossref]
57. Maria K. Pavlova, Clemens M. Lechner, Rainer K. Silbereisen. 2018. Social Comparison in Coping
With Occupational Uncertainty: Self‐Improvement, Self‐Enhancement, and the Regional Context.
Journal of Personality 86:2, 320-333. [Crossref]
58. Anna Goeddeke, Justus Haucap, Annika Herr, Christian Wey. 2018. Flexibility in Wage Setting
Under the Threat of Relocation. LABOUR 32:1, 1-22. [Crossref]
59. Uwe JIRJAHN, Stephen C. SMITH. 2018. NONUNION EMPLOYEE REPRESENTATION:
THEORY AND THE GERMAN EXPERIENCE WITH MANDATED WORKS COUNCILS.
Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 89:1, 201-233. [Crossref]
60. Tobias Schulze-Cleven. 2018. A Continent in Crisis: European Labor and the Fate of Social
Democracy. Labor Studies Journal 43:1, 46-73. [Crossref]
61. Hazhir Rahmandad, Rebecca Henderson, Nelson P. Repenning. 2018. Making the Numbers? “Short
Termism” and the Puzzle of Only Occasional Disaster. Management Science 64:3, 1328-1347.
[Crossref]
62. Christian Rammer, Torben Schubert. 2018. Concentration on the few: mechanisms behind a falling
share of innovative firms in Germany. Research Policy 47:2, 379-389. [Crossref]
63. Peter S. Eppinger, Nicole Meythaler, Marc-Manuel Sindlinger, Marcel Smolka. 2018. The great trade
collapse and the Spanish export miracle: Firm-level evidence from the crisis. The World Economy
41:2, 457-493. [Crossref]
64. Peter A. Hall. 2018. Varieties of capitalism in light of the euro crisis. Journal of European Public Policy
25:1, 7-30. [Crossref]
65. Antonella Cavallo, Pietro Dallari, Antonio Ribba. The Labor Market Outcomes of Austerity. Evidence
for Europe 153-176. [Crossref]
66. Jakob de Haan, Jante Parlevliet. Structural Reforms: An Introduction 1-20. [Crossref]
67. Jante Parlevliet, Simon Savsek, Máté Tóth. The Impact of Structural Reforms: A Review of the
Literature 21-37. [Crossref]
68. Markus Gangl. Lohnbildung und Lohnverteilung 261-309. [Crossref]
69. Mijo Božić, Gerald G. Sander. Temporary Agency Work in Germany: A Short History and the
Situation de lege lata 223-240. [Crossref]
70. Jens Südekum. Der Aufstieg der Roboter im deutschen Arbeitsmarkt 91-100. [Crossref]
71. Nicolas Canry. Can We Explain German and French Trajectories in the 2000s by Their Institutional
Setting During Fordism? 197-209. [Crossref]
72. Jörg Bibow. 2018. Twenty Years of the German Euro are More than Enough. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
73. Pierre Cahuc, Francis Kramarz, Sandra Nevoux. 2018. When Short-Time Work Works. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
74. Christian Dustmann, Bernd Fitzenberger, Markus Zimmermann. 2018. Housing Expenditures and
Income Inequality. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
75. Dustin Voss. 2018. The Political Economy of European Populism: Labour Market Dualisation and
Protest Voting in Germany and Spain. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
76. Renato Faccini, Eirini Konstantinidi, George Skiadopoulos, Sylvia Sarantopoulou-Chiourea. 2018. A
New Predictor of U.S. Real Economic Activity: The S&P 500 Option Implied Risk Aversion. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
77. Berndt Keller. Regulierung atypischer Beschäftigungsverhältnisse 215-245. [Crossref]
78. Tingyun Chen, Jean-Jacques Hallaert, Alexander Pitt, Haonan Qu, Maximilien Queyranne, Alaina
Rhee, Anna Shabunina, Jerome Vandenbussche, Irene Yackovlev. 2018. Inequality and Poverty Across
Generations in the European Union. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
79. Donato Masciandaro, Davide Romelli. 2018. To Be or Not to Be a Euro Country? The Behavioural
Political Economics of Currency Unions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
80. Fabian Ochsenfeld. 2018. Mercantilist dualization: the introduction of the euro, redistribution of
industry rents, and wage inequality in Germany, 1993–2008. Socio-Economic Review 16:3, 499.
[Crossref]
81. Tingyun Chen, Jean-Jacques Hallaert, Alexander Pitt, Haonan Qu, Maximilien Queyranne, Alaina
Rhee, Anna Shabunina, Jérôme Vandenbussche, Irene Yackovlev. 2018. Inequality and Poverty across
Generations in the European Union. Staff Discussion Notes 18:01, 1. [Crossref]
82. Tobias Brändle. 2017. Flexible collective bargaining agreements: Still a moderating effect on works
council behaviour?. Managerial and Decision Economics 38:8, 1137-1153. [Crossref]
83. Mattias Vermeiren. 2017. One-size-fits-some! Capitalist diversity, sectoral interests and monetary
policy in the euro area. Review of International Political Economy 24:6, 929-957. [Crossref]
84. Martin Biewen, Martin Ungerer, Max Löffler. 2017. Why Did Income Inequality in Germany Not
Increase Further After 2005?. German Economic Review 17. . [Crossref]
85. Adrian Chadi, Matthias Krapf. 2017. THE PROTESTANT FISCAL ETHIC: RELIGIOUS
CONFESSION AND EURO SKEPTICISM IN GERMANY. Economic Inquiry 55:4, 1813-1832.
[Crossref]
86. Christian Pfeifer, Gesine Stephan, Matthias D?tsch, Olaf Struck. 2017. Do workers perceive high
wage settlements of craft unions as fair?. Applied Economics Letters 24:15, 1093-1096. [Crossref]
87. John T. Addison, Paulino Teixeira, Katalin Evers, Lutz Bellmann. 2017. Contract Innovation in
Germany: An Economic Evaluation of Pacts for Employment and Competitiveness. British Journal of
Industrial Relations 55:3, 500-526. [Crossref]
88. Deborah Goldschmidt, Johannes F. Schmieder. 2017. The Rise of Domestic Outsourcing and the
Evolution of the German Wage Structure*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132:3, 1165-1217.
[Crossref]
89. Mario Reinhold, Stephan Thomsen. 2017. The changing situation of labor market entrants in
Germany. Journal for Labour Market Research 50:1, 161-174. [Crossref]
90. Wolfgang Dauth, Sebastian Findeisen, Jens Suedekum. 2017. Trade and Manufacturing Jobs in
Germany. American Economic Review 107:5, 337-342. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
91. Jan Niklas Kalden, James Cunningham, Alistair R. Anderson. 2017. The social status of
entrepreneurs. The International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation 18:2, 91-104. [Crossref]
92. GABRIELE CARDULLO. 2017. The Welfare and Employment Effects of Centralized Public Sector
Wage Bargaining. Journal of Public Economic Theory 19:2, 490-510. [Crossref]
93. Ensar Yilmaz, Sayin San. 2017. Wage gap and dispersion in a partially unionized structure in Turkey.
Empirical Economics 52:2, 577-597. [Crossref]
94. Heiko Stüber. 2017. The Real Wage Cyclicality of Newly Hired and Incumbent Workers in Germany.
The Economic Journal 127:600, 522-546. [Crossref]
95. Michael Schweiker, Martin Groß. 2017. Organizational environments and bonus payments: Rent
destruction or rent sharing?. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility 47, 7-19. [Crossref]
96. Zihui Yang, Yinggang Zhou. 2017. Quantitative Easing and Volatility Spillovers Across Countries and
Asset Classes. Management Science 63:2, 333-354. [Crossref]
97. Aida Caldera Sánchez, Alain de Serres, Naomitsu Yashiro. 2017. Reforming in a Difficult
Macroeconomic Context: A Review of Issues and Recent Literature. Journal of International
Commerce, Economics and Policy 08:01, 1750002. [Crossref]
98. John T Addison, Paulino Teixeira, André Pahnke, Lutz Bellmann. 2017. The demise of a model?
The state of collective bargaining and worker representation in Germany. Economic and Industrial
Democracy 43, 0143831X1455978. [Crossref]
99. Sandra K. Gill. Conclusion 97-108. [Crossref]
100. Vladimir M. Adamović, Davor Z. Antanasijević, Mirjana Đ. Ristić, Aleksandra A. Perić-Grujić, Viktor
V. Pocajt. 2017. Prediction of municipal solid waste generation using artificial neural network approach
enhanced by structural break analysis. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 24:1, 299-311.
[Crossref]
101. Philipp Hessinger. Globalisierung und Arbeitsmarktpolitik anders gedacht: das Konzept der
Übergangarbeitsmärkte. Eine international vergleichende Perspektive 251-288. [Crossref]
102. André Hedlund, Aline Regina Alves Martins. 2017. Germany and Greece in the Eurozone Crisis from
the Viewpoint of the Neo-Neo Debate. Brazilian Political Science Review 11:1. . [Crossref]
103. Steffen Schneider, Henning Schmidtke. A Legitimation Crisis of the Capitalist Market Economy?
1-35. [Crossref]
104. George Bratsiotis, David Cobham. German Macroeconomic Thought and Its Effects 93-116.
[Crossref]
105. JJrg Bibow. 2017. How Germany's Anti-Keynesianism Has Brought Europe to Its Knees. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
106. Maria Grazia La Spada. 2017. Restrictive Economic Policies of European Economic and Monetary
Union: A Critical Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
107. German Gutierrez Gallardo. 2017. Declining Competition and Labor Shares in the US. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
108. Alexander Hijzen, Pedro S. Martins, Jante Parlevliet. 2017. Collective Bargaining Through the
Magnifying Glass: A Comparison Between the Netherlands and Portugal. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
109. International Monetary Fund.. 2017. Germany: Selected Issues. IMF Staff Country Reports 17:193,
1. [Crossref]
110. Daniel Kinderman. 2016. Challenging varieties of capitalism’s account of business interests: Neoliberal
think-tanks, discourse as a power resource and employers’ quest for liberalization in Germany and
Sweden. Socio-Economic Review mww040. [Crossref]
111. Lucio Baccaro, Chiara Benassi. 2016. Throwing out the ballast: growth models and the liberalization
of German industrial relations. Socio-Economic Review mww036. [Crossref]
112. Michael Stops. 2016. Revisiting German labour market reform effects—a panel data analysis for
occupational labour markets. IZA Journal of European Labor Studies 5:1. . [Crossref]
113. John T. Addison. 2016. Collective bargaining systems and macroeconomic and microeconomic
flexibility: the quest for appropriate institutional forms in advanced economies. IZA Journal of Labor
Policy 5:1. . [Crossref]
114. Sabine Klinger, Enzo Weber. 2016. Decomposing Beveridge Curve Dynamics By Correlated
Unobserved Components. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 78:6, 877-894. [Crossref]
115. Niklas Gadatsch, Nikolai Stähler, Benjamin Weigert. 2016. German labor market and fiscal reforms
1999–2008: Can they be blamed for intra-euro area imbalances?. Journal of Macroeconomics 50,
307-324. [Crossref]
116. Gianna C. Giannelli, Ursula Jaenichen, Thomas Rothe. 2016. The evolution of job stability and wages
after the implementation of the Hartz reforms. Journal for Labour Market Research 49:3, 269-294.
[Crossref]
117. Deborah Mabbett. 2016. The minimum wage in Germany: what brought the state in?. Journal of
European Public Policy 23:8, 1240-1258. [Crossref]
118. Ferdi De Ville, Mattias Vermeiren. 2016. The Eurozone crisis and the rise of China in the global
monetary and trading system: The political economy of an asymmetric shock. Comparative European
Politics 14:5, 572-603. [Crossref]
119. 박박박. 2016. Is inclusive labor market reform impossible?: A Tentative Typification and Reflection on
the Current Situation of South Korea. Economy and Society null:111, 108-141. [Crossref]
120. Engelbert Stockhammer, Cédric Durand, Ludwig List. 2016. European growth models and working
class restructuring: An International post-Keynesian Political Economy perspective. Environment and
Planning A: Economy and Space 48:9, 1804-1828. [Crossref]
121. Carlos Gradín. Why is Income Inequality so High in Spain? 109-177. [Crossref]
122. Claire Giordano, Francesco Zollino. 2016. Shedding Light on Price- and Non-price-competitiveness
Determinants of Foreign Trade in the Four Largest Euro-area Countries. Review of International
Economics 24:3, 604-634. [Crossref]
123. Hyunjin Seo, Stuart Thorson. 2016. A mixture model of global internet capacity distributions. Journal
of the Association for Information Science and Technology 67:8, 2032-2044. [Crossref]
124. John T. Addison, Paulino Teixeira, Katalin Evers, Lutz Bellmann. 2016. Is the Erosion Thesis
Overblown? Alignment from Without in Germany. Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and
Society 55:3, 415-443. [Crossref]
125. Torben Iversen, David Soskice, David Hope. 2016. The Eurozone and Political Economic Institutions.
Annual Review of Political Science 19:1, 163-185. [Crossref]
126. Jan Hogrefe, Yao Yao. 2016. Offshoring and labor income risk: an empirical investigation. Empirical
Economics 50:3, 1045-1063. [Crossref]
127. . World Economic Outlook, April 2016 . [Crossref]
128. Johannes F. Schmieder, Till von Wachter, Stefan Bender. 2016. The Effect of Unemployment Benefits
and Nonemployment Durations on Wages. American Economic Review 106:3, 739-777. [Abstract]
[View PDF article] [PDF with links]
129. Stephen Machin. Rising Wage Inequality, Real Wage Stagnation and Unions 329-354. [Crossref]
130. Thomas Beissinger, Nathalie Chusseau, Joël Hellier. 2016. Offshoring and labour market reforms in
Germany: Assessment and policy implications. Economic Modelling 53, 314-333. [Crossref]
131. Nicolas Afflatet. 2016. La malaise française – Frankreichs Haushaltskrise und warum sie anhalten
wird. Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftspolitik 65:1. . [Crossref]
132. Christakis Georgiou. 2016. The Eurozone crisis and the European corporate elite: bringing corporate
actors into focus. Economy and Society 45:1, 51-76. [Crossref]
133. Michael Siegenthaler, Michael Graff, Massimo Mannino. 2016. Characteristics and Drivers of the
Swiss “Job Miracle”. Review of Economics 67:1. . [Crossref]
134. Andreas Nölke. 2016. Economic causes of the Eurozone crisis: the analytical contribution of
Comparative Capitalism. Socio-Economic Review 14:1, 141-161. [Crossref]
135. Ferdi De Ville, Mattias Vermeiren. CMEs: Profiting from the BICs’ Industrialization 71-96. [Crossref]
136. Henri Sneessens. Growth and Welfare: Shifts in Labour Market Policies 139-172. [Crossref]
137. Jasmine Lorenzini, Swen Hutter, Hanspeter Kriesi. The Restructuring of the Western European Party
Space in the Crisis: A Comparative Study of Austria, France and Germany 269-302. [Crossref]
138. Florian Hoffmann, Thomas Lemieux. 2016. Unemployment in the Great Recession: A Comparison
of Germany, Canada, and the United States. Journal of Labor Economics 34:S1, S95-S139. [Crossref]
139. Hartmut Berghoff. 2016. Varieties of Financialization? Evidence from German Industry in the 1990s.
Business History Review 90:1, 81-108. [Crossref]
140. Chiara Benassi. 2016. Extending Solidarity Rather than Bargaining Concessions: The IG Metall
Campaign for Agency Workers. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
141. Simon JJger. 2016. How Substitutable Are Workers? Evidence from Worker Deaths. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
142. Gustav A. Horn. Ungleichheit als gesamtwirtschaftliches Phänomen 55-96. [Crossref]
143. Mark S. Manger, Thomas Sattler. 2016. Mercantilism in a Liberal World Order: The Origins of
Persistent Current Account Imbalances. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
144. International Monetary Fund. 2016. France: Selected Issues. IMF Staff Country Reports 16:228, 1.
[Crossref]
145. Bibek Adhikari, Romain Duval, Bingjie Hu, Prakash Loungani. 2016. Can Reform Waves Turn the
Tide? Some Case Studies Using the Synthetic Control Method. IMF Working Papers 16:171, 1.
[Crossref]
146. Alexander Hijzen, Pedro Martins. 2016. No Extension without Representation? Evidence from a
Natural Experiment in Collective Bargaining. IMF Working Papers 16:143, 1. [Crossref]
147. Maximilian J. Blömer, Mathias Dolls, Clemens Fuest, Max Löffler, Andreas Peichl. 2015. German
Public Finances through the Financial Crisis. Fiscal Studies 36:4, 453-474. [Crossref]
148. Bas ter Weel. 2015. Unemployment: The Great Recession and Beyond. De Economist 163:4, 405-413.
[Crossref]
149. Antoine Bozio, Carl Emmerson, Andreas Peichl, Gemma Tetlow. 2015. European Public Finances
and the Great Recession: France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Spain and the United Kingdom Compared.
Fiscal Studies 36:4, 405-430. [Crossref]
150. Enzo Weber. 2015. The Labour Market in Germany: Reforms, Recession and Robustness. De
Economist 163:4, 461-472. [Crossref]
151. Gregory T. Papanikos. 2015. The real exchange rate of euro and Greek economic growth. The Journal
of Economic Asymmetries 12:2, 100-109. [Crossref]
152. John T. Addison, Paulino Teixeira, Jens Stephani, Lutz Bellmann. 2015. Declining Unions and the
Coverage Wage Gap: Can German Unions Still Cut It?. Journal of Labor Research 36:3, 301-317.
[Crossref]
153. Roberta Capello, Andrea Caragliu, Ugo Fratesi. 2015. Global trends and the economic crisis: Future
alternative European growth strategies. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 98, 120-136.
[Crossref]
154. Werner Eichhorst, Verena Tobsch. 2015. Not so standard anymore? Employment duality in Germany.
Journal for Labour Market Research 48:2, 81-95. [Crossref]
155. Joachim Möller. 2015. Did the German Model Survive the Labor Market Reforms?. Journal for Labour
Market Research 48:2, 151-168. [Crossref]
156. Jan C. van Ours. 2015. The Great Recession was not so great. Labour Economics 34, 1-12. [Crossref]
157. Giacomo Corneo. 2015. Kreuz und quer durch die deutsche Einkommensverteilung. Perspektiven der
Wirtschaftspolitik 16:2, 109-126. [Crossref]
158. John T. Addison. 2015. Holding the shop together: German industrial relations in the postwar era.
Labor History 56:3, 370-374. [Crossref]
159. Martyn Andrews, Hans-Dieter Gerner, Thorsten Schank, Richard Upward. 2015. More hours, more
jobs? The employment effects of longer working hours. Oxford Economic Papers 67:2, 245-268.
[Crossref]
160. David G. Blanchflower. 2015. As Good as it Gets? The UK Labour Market in Recession and Recovery.
National Institute Economic Review 231:1, F76-F80. [Crossref]
161. Robert Kollmann, Marco Ratto, Werner Roeger, Jan in ’t Veld, Lukas Vogel. 2015. What drives the
German current account? And how does it affect other EU Member States?. Economic Policy 30:81,
47-93. [Crossref]
162. Xavier Giroud, Holger M. Mueller. 2015. Firm Leverage and Unemployment During the Great
Recession. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
163. Maximilian Blömer, Mathias Dolls, Clemens Fuest, Max Loeffler, Andreas Peichl. 2015. German
Public Finances Through the Financial Crisis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
164. Timm BBnke, Matthias Nicolas Giesecke, Holger LLthen. 2015. The Dynamics of Earnings in
Germany: Evidence from Social Security Records. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
165. CentER Submitter, Jan C. van Ours. 2015. The Great Recession Was Not so Great. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
166. Deborah Goldschmidt, Johannes F. Schmieder. 2015. The Rise of Domestic Outsourcing and the
Evolution of the German Wage Structure. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
167. Bernd Venohr, Jeffrey Fear, Alessa Witt. 2015. Best of German Mittelstand - The World Market
Leaders. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
168. Niklas Engbom, Enrica Detragiache, Faezeh Raei. 2015. The German Labor Market Reforms and
Post-Unemployment Earnings. IMF Working Papers 15:162, 1. [Crossref]
169. Bernd Fitzenberger. 2014. Comments on “Wage determination and imperfect competition”. Labour
Economics 30, 59-61. [Crossref]
170. Jan Fries. 2014. Age and Skill Bias of Trade Liberalisation? Heterogeneous Employment Effects of
EU Eastern Enlargement. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
171. Daniel P. Kinderman. 2014. Challenging Varieties of Capitalism's Account of Business Interests: The
New Social Market Initiative and German Employers' Quest for Liberalization, 2000-2014. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
172. Bernd Fitzenberger, Stefanie Licklederer. 2014. Skill Formation, Career Planning, and Transitions:
The Last Two Years in a German Lower Track Secondary School. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
173. David Woodruff. 2014. Governing by Panic: The Politics of the Eurozone Crisis. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
174. Jan Hogrefe, Andreas Sachs. 2014. Unemployment and Labor Reallocation in Europe. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
175. Michael Siegenthaler, Michael Graff, Massimo Mannino. 2014. The Swiss 'Job Miracle'. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
176. International Monetary Fund. 2014. Germany: Selected Issues. IMF Staff Country Reports 14:217,
1. [Crossref]
177. Igor Lebrun, Esther P�rez Ruiz. 2014. Demand Patterns in France, Germany, and Belgium: Can We
Explain the Differences?. IMF Working Papers 14:165, 1. [Crossref]

You might also like