You are on page 1of 11

Financing Constraints in the Inter

Firm Diffusion of New


Alessandra Canepa1
Process Technologies Paul Stoneman2

ABSTRACT. This paper explores why finance constraints particular a measure of firm liquidity (the ratio
may impact upon the inter firm diffusion of new technology, of the firm’s current assets to liabilities in the
incorporates these arguments in a hazard rate formulation of
a diffusion model and then estimates that model using data
2 years prior to when it began to dieselize) was
relating to the adoption of CNC machine tools in the UK. found to have a positive and significant impact
The results indicate that financial constraints can be a signifi- upon intra firm diffusion. Although this result
cant factor in the diffusion process. suggests that financial factors (defined to encom-
Key words: technological diffusion, CNC, financial constraints pass all issues relating to the funding of those
capital expenditures that are a part of the tech-
JEL Classification: O3
nological diffusion process) may play a role in
the diffusion process, later diffusion research has
1. Introduction not tended to pick up on Mansfield’s lead, and
has instead somewhat ignored this line of
Ed Mansfield stands with Zvi Griliches as a
enquiry (Stoneman, 2001). This is despite the
founding father of diffusion analysis in Econom-
fact that within the literature upon investment
ics. Even today, 40 years on, it is impossible to
in general (Hubbard, 1998) and even R&D
properly work in this field without referring
(Hall, 2002) there has been a growing emphasis
back to Mansfield’s path breaking work in the
upon the importance of financial factors and con-
1960s as published in Mansfield (1968). This
straints. In this paper we partially correct that
body of work stresses that diffusion is a process
omission by exploring the impact of financial con-
driven, or at the least conditioned by, economic
straints upon the inter (rather than intra) firm dif-
factors, a finding that over the years has been
fusion of a new process technology. We initially
extended and elaborated upon but not refuted
discuss the rationale for expecting finance con-
(see, for example, Hall, 2004). In one of his ear-
straints to have an impact and then incorporate
liest diffusion papers, Mansfield (1963), the intra
these arguments in a reasonably standard hazard
firm diffusion of new technology (in this case
rate formulation of a diffusion model and esti-
diesel engines) was modelled and certain firm
mate that model using data relating to the adop-
level financial variables were included as poten-
tion of CNC machine tools in the UK.
tial determinants of the diffusion process. In
In the following Section we discuss the nature
of financial constraints and the reasons why they
might exist and in Section 3 the existing empiri-
1
University of York
cal evidence relating to their existence and pat-
Department of Economics and Department of Mathematics terns. In Section 4 a diffusion model that can test
Heslington, York Y010 5DD for the existence of such constraints in the inter
United Kingdom firm diffusion process is proposed and we discuss
E-mail: ac48@york.ac.uk the data and estimation methods to be employed
2
Warwick Business School, University of Warwick in that testing. The results are presented and dis-
Coventry CV4 7AL cussed in Section 5 and conclusions offered in
United Kingdom
Section 6.
E-mail: paul.stoneman@warwick.ac.uk

Journal of Technology Transfer, 30 1/2, 159–169, 2005


 2005 Springer Science+Business Media, Inc. Manufactured in The Netherlands.
160 Canepa and Stoneman

cost and/or availability. This is because: (i) in


2. What are financial constraints and why might
riskier industries it may be more difficult to raise
they exist?
funding from outside the firm purely because of
According to Hall (2002) a financial constraint is the risk factor; (ii) in more high-tech sectors not
said to exist when, even if there are no externali- only may risk itself be a factor but also the
ties involved in the firm’s investment activity, proportion of assets that are realisable may be
there is a wedge (perhaps even a large wedge) lower; (iii) in high-tech industries innovation is
between the rate of return required by an entre- more likely to be of a sort that has not been
preneur investing his own funds and that undertaken before elsewhere and it may be par-
required by external investors. Stiglitz and Weiss ticularly difficult to observe the systematic risk of
(1981) consider a firm to be credit rationed if it such projects (Goodacre and Tonks, 1985) and
does not get as much credit as it wants although thus difficult to determine the appropriate dis-
it is willing to meet the conditions set by the len- count rate to use in evaluating investments in the
der on equivalent credit contracts. In essence firm; and (iv) information asymmetries may also
therefore a firm is credit or financially con- be greater in such industries.
strained if it cannot raise external funding at the Differences in national systems of innovation
market price or in order to raise external funding (see Nelson, 1993) across countries may lead to
it has to pay over the market price. differing financial constraints upon firms operat-
There are many reasons postulated as to why ing in different economies (as the result, for
such financial constraints might exist. These are example, of differing taxes and subsidy regimes,
reviewed in Canepa and Stoneman (2003) as well the completeness of markets for finance, the legal
as in Hall (2002). The existence of uncertainty environment as regards bankruptcy, government
and thus risk is a sine qua non of such con- intervention etc.). Of particular interest are differ-
straints. Beyond this, the most commonly argued ences in the financial environments in different
reasons for such constraints are asymmetric countries (Mayer, 1990). Financial environments
information between borrower and lender and are both heterogeneous and changing. On the
moral hazard resulting from the separation of one hand, there are bank-based systems as typi-
ownership and control, although capital market fied by the German system and on the other,
incompleteness and inefficiency, taxes, subsidies, market-based systems as typified by the UK or
bankruptcy costs, and the problems of measuring US system. Most continental European systems
risk may also have roles to play. The literature are largely bank-based although there are signs
argues that the importance and relevance of such of some movement in certain countries (e.g.
financial constraints may differ across firm sizes, France) from a bank-based to a market-based
industries and countries. system. Alongside these different financial system
Smaller firms may be relatively more tightly environments there are different patterns of own-
constrained because (i) the availability of inter- ership of industry. The German system, for
nally generated funds may be more limited for example, reflects greater private control, more
smaller firms than larger firms (ii) problems of concentrated ownership and more pyramid own-
information asymmetries for small firms may also ership. In the UK the pattern is for less concen-
be more severe (iii) smaller, newer firms may trated holdings, less private control and few
have no track record upon which to base a case inter-corporate holdings. The financing of invest-
for funding and/or there may be fewer realisable ment by firms also differs across systems.
assets to use as collateral and (iv) the costs (to Although self-generated funds are the main
funding providers) of search may mean also that finance sources for firms in all countries (except
the supply of finance to smaller firms is more perhaps for SMEs) these are more important in
severely limited. the UK, for example, whereas bank finance is
Differences across industries may also exist so more important in bank-based systems.
that, for example, firms in high-tech and newer It is argued that such differences across sys-
industries may face stricter constraints to raising tems have important implications for the way
external (and internal) funding either in terms of firms behave. The argument is that bank-based
Financing Constraints in the Inter Firm Diffusion 161

systems with insider control are particularly  The diffusion process will generate (and require
favourable to longer term steady development funding to acquire) a number of assets that may
built upon the construction of trust-based rela- well be intangible, and/or firm specific (e.g.
tions, firm-specific investments and gradual con- learning economies of various kinds, knowledge
tinual change but may generate a higher cost of from search, and/or product goodwill). Such
capital due to bank monopoly power, informa- assets may not be realisable in the event of
tional capture (of the firm by the bank) and per- bankruptcy and/or may not be appropriately
haps undue conservatism. On the other hand valued by the market. Once again this may
market-based systems with outsider control and make raising external finance problematic espe-
more arms-length relationships between financiers cially for firms without other assets that may act
and managers are seen as more favourable to as collateral (unless, and this is possible taking a
major change and switches of strategic direction creative destruction viewpoint, successful diffu-
(but with no obligation for financiers to take any- sion causes losses in the value of other assets).
thing other than a short-term view, encouraging
liquidation of investment in the event of dissatis- Taken together these factors suggest that
faction). These arguments lead us to believe that finance constraints may play a major role in the
firms will be differentially affected by financial con- diffusion process with firms possibly being credit
straints under different national financial systems. rationed.1 The importance of this role may differ
The above discussion relates to investment in across firm sizes, industries and countries.
general in plant and machinery and/or R&D.
However the diffusion process has a number of
3. Financial constraints to innovation: the evidence
characteristics that might lead one to consider
that financial issues will perhaps play a more There is a growing body of empirical research
important role in that process than investment in relating to the relationship between finance and
general. In particular: investment in plant and machinery and or inno-
vation (largely measured by R&D). The two
 Given that diffusion is concerned with doing main strands in the literature investigate (i) the
something new the extent of uncertainty sensitivity of the investment rate to cash flow (ii)
attached to a diffusion process may be greater the results of innovation questionnaire surveys.
than that attached to replication of existing The correlation between cash flow and invest-
activities. For example Stoneman and Toiva- ment is usually investigated by estimating a stan-
nen (2000) show that across countries, invest- dard investment demand function (see, for
ment in robot technologies shows much greater example, the surveys by Hall, 2002 and Hubbard,
volatility than investment in machine tools in 1998). Three main approaches can be identified:
general. This higher level of uncertainty may
exacerbate for the diffusion of new products  estimating a dynamic neoclassical accelerator
and processes any problems that exist in rais- model in which the profit maximizing firm equates
ing finance for investment. It may also cause the marginal cost of capital to the marginal prod-
problems in determining the appropriate cost uct (see, for example, Carpenter and Petersen,
of capital in that for new projects it may be dif- 2002; and Fazzari et al., 1988 for the US, Deve-
ficult to determine the systematic risk of simi- reux and Schiantarelli, 1989 for the UK).
lar projects as there are no similar projects.  estimating an Euler equation derived for the
 As diffusion is concerned, by definition, with profit-maximizing firm without including the
new technologies, it may well be that the sup- shadow value of capital among the regressors
pliers and users of those technologies are (see, for example, Bond et al., 2003).
much more aware of their true nature and  estimating directly the investment demand
characteristics than potential financiers. Such function where the shadow value of capital is
information asymmetries may lead to credit proxied by a VAR forecast of firm fundamen-
rationing and or difficulties for the firm in tals observable to the econometrician (see, for
raising external finance. example, Bond, et al., 1999).
162 Canepa and Stoneman

These methodologies have been applied to firms are constrained such that their innovative
investment data for a number of different coun- activity is delayed or reduced, then financial fac-
tries. Overall the voluminous literature presents tors (the cost or availability of finance) are more
strong empirical evidence of a correlation likely to have a high (as opposed to medium or
between cash flow and investment in plant and low) impact for small firms than for large firms.
machinery and/or R&D. For example, an early Their results also confirm that differences in
paper, Fazzari et al. (1988) found that cash flow financial systems also matter: the market-based
tends to affect the investment of low-dividend economies (e.g. the UK) exhibit greater sensitiv-
firms more than that of high dividend firms lead- ity of innovation to financial constraints than
ing them to conclude that finance rationing mat- bank-based economies (e.g. Germany).
ters. An example of the later literature is Further research also suggests that capital
Carpenter and Petersen (2002) who find that for market imperfections affect firms more in high-
small, quoted firms in the US, the sensitivity of tech industries than in traditional sectors.3 For
growth to cash flow of firms that use external example, Westhead and Storey (1997) examine
equity is lowered. Bond et al. (2003)2 estimate the relative importance of several potential prob-
accelerator, error correction model and Euler lems faced by high-tech SMEs. Their multivariate
equations for different countries. Although they analysis on a sample of UK firms shows that
find that the simple accelerator equations tend to technologically sophisticated high-tech firms were
exaggerate the importance of financial variables significantly more likely to report the presence of
relative to richer dynamic specifications, they also a continued financial constraint than less high-
find robust results across all econometric models tech firms. In a similar study of italian high-tech
indicating that the sensitivity of investment to firms, Giuduci and Paleari (2000) confirm that
financial variables (and thus the importance of 50% of the sample companies experienced diffi-
financial constraints) is both statistically and culties in financing their innovative projects. The
quantitatively more significant in the UK than in work of Canepa and Stoneman (2003) confirms
France, Germany or Belgium. these findings and extends them to the majority
In contrast, Kaplan and Zingales (1997) have of European countries.
argued that studies such as those cited above To summarise, although there is not universal
which estimate the sensitivity of investment to agreement (see, for example, Wagenvoort, 2003),
cash flow are fundamentally flawed in that such the overview of various empirical studies relating
sensitivities are unable to reflect financial con- to investment in plant and machinery and R&D
straints in an unbiased manner. However, the suggest that (Hall, 2002):
empirical evidence on the relationships between
finance, investment and innovation has been fur-  small firms are more likely to be financially
ther augmented and extended through the analy- constrained in their investment activity;
sis of innovation survey data. Canepa and  firms (especially small and start-up firms) in
Stoneman (2003) for example explore Commu- R&D intensive industries face a higher cost of
nity Innovation Survey (CIS) questionnaire capital;4
response data to investigate whether European  the evidence for a financing gap for large and
firms consider themselves to be financially con- established firms is harder to establish; and
strained in their innovative activity. They find  the Anglo Saxon economies, with their thick
that (i) the cost of finance or the availability of and developed stock markets and relatively
finance ranks among the more significant factors transparent ownership structures typically
that have acted as hindrances to innovation in exhibit greater sensitivity of investment to
Europe, both in 1994–1996 and 1998–2000; (ii) cash flow than continental economies.
the probability that a firm’s innovative activity
will be financially constrained is greater for small Despite the various studies of investment in
firms than for medium and larger firms, in the plant and machinery and in R&D there is very
latter case there being only minor differences little evidence directly relating to the role of
between the UK and other countries; (iii) when financial factors in the diffusion of new technol-
Financing Constraints in the Inter Firm Diffusion 163

ogy. Differences in diffusion rates across coun- Controlled machine tools (CNC), this being rea-
tries are notoriously difficult to measure (Canepa sonably well defined and a technology for which
and Stoneman, 2004) and to the best of our higher quality data is available. CNC first
knowledge there has been no explicit testing of appeared in the early 1970s and by incorporating
the impact of different financial regimes on differ- micro computer technology into numerically con-
ent national diffusion experiences. The empirical trolled machines provided the capability of auto-
work on diffusion as surveyed in Stoneman matic and flexible machining. CNC also
(2001) indicates that there is clear evidence that facilitated the introduction of flexible automation
larger firms are earlier adopters and smaller firms systems (Cainarca et al., 1990; Mansfield, 1995).
are later adopters, which is consistent with smal- Suitable data is only available as regards inter
ler firms being finance constrained. Generally firm rather than intra firm diffusion. The empiri-
however this is attributed to scale economies cal analysis thus addresses the inter firm diffusion
rather than financial factors. Davies (1979) shows of CNC machine tools in the UK. This topic has
differences in the diffusion of simple and complex been analysed before using the same data set but
technologies. Stoneman and Toivanen (2000) without inclusion of financial constraints (Karsh-
show that uncertainty has an impact upon the enas and Stoneman, 1993, where further data
diffusion process. Both observations would be details can be found).
consistent with financing difficulties in the face of The data that we employ was collected in
uncertainty, however, such results are rarely con- three surveys undertaken by the Centre for
sidered to be the result of financial factors. One Urban and Regional Development Studies of the
of the very few pieces of evidence available to us University of Newcastle upon Tyne (CURDS) in
is that Mansfield (1968) explicitly incorporated a 1980, 1986 and 1993 of a given sample of estab-
liquidity term (measured as the ratio of the firms lishments (some stand-alone that we label firms,
current assets to liabilities) in an empirical diffu- some part of multi establishment organisations
sion equation explaining the intra firm spread of that we label groups) in the UK engineering and
diesel locomotives in US railroads and found a metalworking industry. Although our analysis of
positive and significant coefficient. this data may be better described as a study of
inter establishment diffusion, to relate more clo-
sely to the existing literature we continue to talk
4. A model
throughout of inter firm diffusion, assuming5
On the basis of the arguments above the diffu- each establishment to be an autonomous decision
sion of new technology will probably not be making unit which we label the firm.
independent of financial factors. The rest of this The surveys6 contain information on the date
paper is directed towards an empirical analysis of at which each firm in the sample first adopted
the role of such financial factors or constraints. CNC. They also contain longitudinal data on
However the impact of such factors may differ establishment characteristics,7 such as employ-
across firms (according to, for example, size), ment in 1970–1975, 1981, 1985 and 1993, year of
technologies (reflecting complexity and cost), start-up, information on R&D, whether the firm
industries (reflecting technological state and/or is export oriented, as well as on certain manage-
competitiveness) countries (reflecting national rial and technological characteristics of the firm.
systems of innovations) and time (reflecting expe- By 1993 the proportion of potential users8 that
rience and information asymmetries). have adopted CNC is about 80%. The revealed
Empirical analysis of these issues is itself how- time profile of the whole inter firm diffusion of
ever constrained. Although it would have been CNC is illustrated in Figure 1. Of the 1993 sam-
most informative to have data across several ple of 343 firms, 222 had adopted CNC at or
countries such data is not generally available before 1993 of whom 212 were still users in 1993
(see, Stoneman and Canepa, 2004). The empirical (i.e. 10 were no longer users by 1993).
analysis below is thus restricted to one country, The data set is quite rich and as it offers firm
the UK. In addition efforts are concentrated level data the best use of that data will be if the
upon one technology, Computer Numerically analysis is also undertaken at the firm level. We
164 Canepa and Stoneman

100
90
80
Adopters (%)
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990

Figure 1. The Inter Firm diffusion of a new technology: CNC machine tools in the UK.

thus proceed using a hazard rate adoption model experience (i.e. the probability of adoption after
as previously employed by Hannan and Macdo- time t) for each plant in the sample: i.e. if the
well (1984) and Karshenas and Stoneman (1993). plant did not adopt during the period t0 <t<tj ,
Specifically, it is assumed that the probability then at t ¼ tj the firm either adopted (dj ¼ 1) or
that a firm j will adopt a new technology at time was censored (dj ¼ 0). If dj ¼ 0 then (2) gives the
t, conditional on not having previously adopted, probability that the firm does not adopt from
is determined by a vector of covariates xj , reflect- 1981 to tj . if dj ¼ 1 then (2) is the probability of
ing the costs and benefits of adoption. Defining tj adopting
 at time tj . The denominator
(measured from a start date t0 ¼ 1981) as the X0 t0 jxj bx ; H gives the probability of not adopt-
date of adoption by firm j, the estimated survival ing up to time t0 , so when t0 ¼ 1981 then
model9 is X0 t0 jxj bx ; H =1, for t0 <t<tj :
  To apply the model requires specification of
ln tj ¼ xj bx þ lnðsj Þ; ð1Þ the elements of the vector xj . The key issue
addressed in this paper is the impact of financial
where sj is distributed as a Weibull. In order to constraints and thus although the procedure is
check the parametric specification of the model disputed (Kaplan and Zingales, 1997) a cash
the cumulative hazard function based on the non flow variable is included as an element in xj and
parametric Kaplan–Meier estimator was com- the sensitivity of adoption times to this variable
puted. The plot of the Kaplan–Meier estimates is interpreted as an indicator of the impact of
against the Cox–Snell residuals suggested that financial constraints. The only variable available
the Weibull model fitted the data better than the in the data set to reflect cash flow is the pre-tax
exponential model. Model (1) has been estimated profit, in £ 100s, declared by firms in time t,
by maximum likelihood with the likelihood func- pt;j .
tion given by As inter firm analysis addresses whether firms
invest in CNC or not, and the size of the
  1dj n  d o investment necessary to meet this requirement
X tj jxj bx ;H f tj jxj bx ;H j
Lj ðbx ;HÞ ¼   ; need not differ across different sized firms, this
X0 t0 jxj bx ;H variable is introduced without the correction for
ð2Þ firm size that is common in the standard invest-
ment literature. As cash flow data were not
where fðtÞ ¼ ptp1 expðtp Þ is the density function available before 1981 the sample was restricted
of the Weibull distribution and XðtÞ ¼ expðtÞp to those firms that had not adopted CNC
the corresponding survivor function. The param- before 1981 yielding a usable panel of 87 estab-
eters bx , and the ancillary parameters lishments for 10 years of whom 25 adopt in the
H ¼ ðb0 ; pÞ; (where b0 is the scale parameter and sample period.
p is the shape parameter)
  are estimated from the The other control variables to be introduced
data. The triple tj ; dj ; xj summarises the survival in to the vector xj were determined using both
Financing Constraints in the Inter Firm Diffusion 165

the literature as a guide and data availability as a EDj , the difference in years between time t
constraint.10 Many different combinations were and the date of start up of the establishment
tried and many empirical models were estimated. reflecting experience and perhaps vintage effects
The results presented below relate to the most (see Karshenas and Stoneman, 1993).
parsimonious of these models. The variables that Ij , a vector of dummies reflecting the industry
have remained are as follows. within engineering and metalworking to which
Pt , the quality adjusted factory gate price of the establishment belonged (see Dunne, 1994).
CNC technology deflated by the retail price index Table I reports descriptive statistics on the
at time t, reflecting the costs of adoption. Price explanatory variables described above.
data on CNC machine tools was supplied by the
Office of National Statistics (ONS) but unfortu-
5. Estimates
nately for a number of years the data for CNC
and NC (its previous non-computerised version) The estimating equation is given by
were not separately distinguished. The adjust-
ment for quality has been carried out using a lnðtj Þ ¼ b0 þ b1 pj þ b2 Pj þ b3 RDj þ b4 EDj
modified version of the hedonic price approach þ b5 Sj þ b6 STj þ b7 Ij þ b7 Ij þ lnðsj Þ:
whereby, given that data upon CNC generations
are not available, the quality change was approx- The model in (3) contains three dichotomous co-
imated by the trend in the quality improvements variates (STj , EDj , RDj ) plus industry dummies
of computers outsourced from Triplett (1989) and three continuous variables (pj , Pj , Sj ). In
and Stoneman et al. (1992). Further details can order to test if the log-time ratio is linear in the
be found in Battisti (2000). covariates we used the fractional polynomial
St; j , the size of the establishment given by method suggested by Royston and Altman
the number of employees at time t sourced from (1994).11
the CURDS survey. This variable is usually con- The analysis indicates that the best non-linear
sidered as a proxy for several other factors, par- transformations are not significantly different
ticularly scale and the relative risk faced by from the linear model for Pt and pt;j but suggests
different-sized firms (see, for example, Karshenas the following specification for the variable St;j
and Stoneman, 1993). An alternative turnover
measure of firm size was also tried without any  2  
St;j;1 ¼ St;j =100 ; St;j;2 ¼ St;j;1  ln St;j =100 :
significant impact on the results.
STj, a dummy variable taking the value one if
the firm is an independent unit and zero if the In our unrestricted initial estimates pt;j ,Pt , St;j;1 ,
establishment is part of a corporate ‘‘group’’, St,j,2, STj all carried coefficients significantly dif-
reflecting the possible impact of both internally ferent from zero.12 However, the industry dum-
sourced information relating to technology per- mies were not significant and were dropped. The
formance and technological competencies (and conventional 0.05 p-value for the covariates RDt
may also pick up whether there are different and EDj suggested that these covariates did not
degrees of autonomy for firms that are indepen-
dent as opposed to being part of a group) (see
TABLE I
Astebro, 2002; Cainarca et al., 1990; and Dunne,
Descriptive statistics
1994).
A dummy variable, RDj , that takes the value Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max.
unity if the number of employees engaged full
j 424.07 1022.04 )800 8000
time in R&D at time t is positive and zero other- Pj 103.32 4.240 99.88 109.45
wise. An alternative measure, the number of RDj 0.784 0.412 0 1
employees engaged full time in R&D at time t, EDj 31.32 156.86 1 89
was correlated with firm size. This variable Sj 117.34 0.412 1 950
STj 0.260 0.439 0 1
reflects innovativeness (see, for example, Hall,
Ij 7.230769 2.99 1 13
2004).
166 Canepa and Stoneman

exert a significant influence on the speed of adop-


tion (their p-values being 0.057 and 0.068, respec- gðSj þ 5; zÞ  gðSj ; zÞ ¼ ac1 þ bc2 ;
tively) although both carried positive signs.
Although there is a growing literature showing where a ¼ ððSj;1 þ 5Þ  Sj;1 Þ and b ¼ ððSj;2 þ 5Þ
(see Mickey and Greenland, 1989, for example) Sj;2 Þ; and from Table I we have c1 ¼ 0.0039 and
that strict adherence to the 0.05 p-value as a c2 ¼ 0.00085. The estimated survivor function
screening criterion for variable selection often corresponding to the accelerated failure time
fails to identify variables known to be important, form of the hazard function in (2) is
parsimony in model specification has particular
Xðt; x; b; pÞ ¼
advantages in term of parameter stability. RDt n  o
and EDj thus were also excluded. The results of exp tb0 =p exp p1 ðb0 þ ða^c1 þ b^c2 ÞÞ ;
fitting the final restricted model are reported in
Table I. The main difference compared to the
estimates including RDt and EDj is that the coef- by evaluating the survivorship function at the
ficient on STj in the unrestricted estimates is 50% quantile and solving for time we obtain
increased by 45% and on Pt reduced by 13% (in  
absolute value) but the other estimated coeffi- t50 Sj ; b; p ¼ ½lnð0:5Þp eb0 þða^c1 þb^c2 Þ
cients do not change significantly.
From Table II the estimated coefficient on Pt, the so that the time-ratio at the median survival time
real quality adjusted price of CNC, is negative, with a is
10-unit increase in the real price index producing a  
reduction in the estimated date of adoption by TR Sj þ 5; Sj ; z
0.91 ¼ exp[10 · ()0.092)]—a reduction of 9%. ½lnð0:5Þp eb0 þðc1 ðS1;j þ5Þþc2 ðS2;j þ5ÞÞ
¼ ¼ eða^c1 þb^c2 Þ :
The coefficient on STj implies that if the firm ½lnð0:5Þp eb0 þðc1 S1;j þc2 S2;j Þ
is independent rather than a member of a group
the speed of adoption is reduced by about 0.5% Figure 2 shows how TR c changes as a result of a
(i.e. 0.995 ¼ exp[()0.0046)]). Both St,j,1, and St,j,2 five-unit increase in establishment size keeping
carry positive coefficients (in line with results in all the other covariates fixed. The estimated
the existing literature). However, given that the time-ratios increase quite rapidly with size up to
estimated time-ratio (TR) c is modelled as a non- unity at a threshold of around 60 employees,
linear function of establishment size, TR c changes above which the marginal effect of size on the
with St;j . The TR c resulting from five-unit time of adoption seems to vanish. Such a non-
increases in plant size has been calculated as linearity in the impact of size on the probability
follows. Let z denoted the vector of the fixed of adoption has not been emphasised in the lit-
variables; then the estimated difference in the erature before. The pattern suggests that the
log-time function is obtained by evaluating ratio of the benefits to the cost of adoption

TABLE II
Estimated coefficients for the restricted model, robust standard errors, z-Scores, p-value, 95% and confidence intervals

T Coef. Rob. Std. Err. z P> z [Conf. Interval]

St;1 0.00393 0.000021 191.16 0.0000 0.0039 0.0040


St;2 0.00085 0.000005 175.75 0.0000 0.0008 0.0009
Pt )0.00916 0.000109 )83.81 0.0000 )0.0094 )0.0089
STt )0.00457 0.000193 )23.66 0.0000 )0.0049 )0.0042
t 0.00245 0.000459 5.34 0.0000 0.0016 0.0034
Cons 5.46810 0.015116 361.75 0.0000 5.4385 5.4977

ln(p) 3.24265 0.065580 49.45 0.0000 3.1141 3.3712

Log Likelihood = )757.868, LR test: Pr (v2 (5)> 12.02) = 0.034.


Financing Constraints in the Inter Firm Diffusion 167

1.02
1.00
0.98
Time Ratio

0.96
0.94
0.92
0.90
0.88
0.86
0.84
0.00 50.00 100.00 150.00 200.00 250.00
Number of Employees

Figure 2. Estimated time ratio for five-unit increases in size as a function of firm size.

Lowess smoother, bandwidth = .8

-2

-4

-6

0 5000 10000
Profit

Figure 3. Univariate lowess smoothed logit scatterplot of CNC adoption versus pj .

increases quite rapidly with size but only up to increases sharply in the profit level when profit is
quite a low threshold. negative or around zero but the rate of growth of
The profit variable, our proxy for financial the logit is much lower when profit is positive.
constraints, carries a positive and highly signifi- This pattern suggests that in exploring the
cant estimated coefficient, indicating that finan- impact of financial factors upon adoption it is
cial constraints have a significant impact upon the difference between profit and loss that is most
the diffusion of new technology. The estimates important. A firm that is registering negative
indicate that a £ 100 increase in profit produces profits is much less likely to adopt new technol-
an estimated time ratio of approximately ogy than a firm making positive profits. The two
1.00245, which is an increase in the speed of obvious reasons for this are that a loss making
adoption of approximately 0.0025%. Testing for firm: (i) will have less internal funding available
the interaction pt;j  STj failed to give significant for investment; and (ii) will be giving a negative
results, suggesting that it is establishment rather signal to outside lenders and thus find it more
than group cash flow that matters. difficult to borrow.
To further explore the relationship between
profit and CNC adoption we compute the lowess
6. Conclusions
smoothed weighted average of dj (dj takes the
value unity if the plant adopted at time t and zero The literature on the diffusion of new technology
otherwise) over the pt;j .13 The resulting pattern, has largely ignored any impact that financial fac-
illustrated in Figure 3, shows that the logit initially tors may have upon the process whereby new
168 Canepa and Stoneman

technology spreads across its potential market. tematic risk, information asymmetries may reduce and learn-
This is in contrast to the general literature on ing and intangible assets may decline in relative importance.
2. See also Bond, Harhoff, and Van Reenan (1999).
investment in plant and machinery and R&D 3. In reviewing the financial environment in which European
where there is a growing body of evidence that SMEs operate, the European Commission (2000), using a very
financial factors do act as a constraint upon different methodology, argues that SMEs do face specific
investment spending. problems in accessing finance and early stage enterprises in
In this paper we have proposed a reasonably particular face the most severe financial constraints.
4. Although we do not know of any particular evidence that
standard hazard rate formulation of an adoption this is true risk adjusted.
model incorporating therein a cash flow covariate 5. We do not have any data available that would generate
to reflect financial constraints and, using the any advantage from doing otherwise.
example of CNC adoption in the UK metal work- 6. Between 1980, 1986 and 1993, the survey experienced con-
ing and engineering industry, shown empirically siderable sample attrition as UK manufacturing industry
declined. In a previous paper, Karshenas and Stoneman
that such constraints have a significant impact (1993) have shown that this sample attrition is independent of
upon the rate at which new technologies are whether new technology was adopted and thus the attrition
adopted. This is confirmation in the inter firm will not cause bias.
context of a proposition first made and tested by 7. We would like to thank Guiliana Battisti who provided
Mansfield in the intra firm context in 1963. the actual data used.
8. The sample of potential users excludes from the full sam-
Our findings suggest that the financial con- ple those firms who consider that the technology is not appro-
straints largely impact upon firms near the priate to their production activities (59 of the 343).
break-even point and that for more profitable 9. For an excellent reference on survival models see, for
firms there are no such constraints. This non-lin- example Kalbfleisch and Prentice, 1980.
earity is also apparent in the impact of firm size 10. A number of experiments with additional independent
variables were also undertaken but provide little further
upon adoption rates. The non-linearity with insight and are thus not reported here.
respect to profitability however makes policy pre- 11. Denoting xt;j as the continuous covariate of interest, this
scriptions difficult. If there are financial con- method involves estimating by maximum likelihood the fol-
straints then government assistance to overcome lowing set of equations
  Xm
such constraints appears appropriate. However, ln tj ¼ d0 þ G ðx Þd
i¼1 i j i
if the constraints mainly bind upon firms that are  
only marginally profitable, there would be con- where G1 xj;t ¼ xnt 1 ð for N 2 f2; 1; 0:5; 0; 0:5; 1; 2; 3gÞ:
The
 remaining power functions are defined as Gi ðxj Þ ¼
siderable problems in separating out those firms
xnj i ; ni 6¼ ni1
that are temporarily suffering ill fortune but for i ¼ 2; . . . ; m and fng. The best
Gi1 ðxj Þlnðxj Þ ni ¼ ni1
merit support in the adoption of new technology model is chosen on the base of likelihood ratio test. The results
from those that are inefficient and for whom sup- on the LR test are available from the authors on request.
port is likely to be wasted. 12. The LR test comparing the model to the saturated
model rejects the null hypothesis that the estimated coeffi-
cients are equal to zero.
13. The lowess smoothed weighted average of d over pt;j has
Acknowledgment been calculated as follows. Let dj the logit transformation for
dj the and assume that dj  djþ1 for j ¼ l; . . . ; N  l. For each
This work has been financed under the Fifth EU we dl;j we compute a smoothed value dl;js
Framework Programme, Contract No. HPSE-
Piu
CT-1999–00039 with additional financial support j¼i wðpi ; pj Þdj
provided under the project ‘‘The Euro, SMEs ds
j ¼ Piul ;
and Banks’’ by the the Department of Econom- j¼il wðpi ; pj Þ

ics, University of Western Piedmont. where wðxi ; xj Þ represents the weight function, il and iu include
the bandwidth k ¼ 0.8 ( see Cleveland (1979) for more details).

Notes References
1. There is the possibility that as the diffusion process pro- Astebro, T., 2002, ‘Non-capital Investment Costs and the
ceeds these problems will be ameliorated. For example, an Adoption of CAD and CNC in US Metalworking Indus-
increasing number of projects may help in determining sys- tries,’ RAND Journal of Economics Winter 33 (4), 672–688.
Financing Constraints in the Inter Firm Diffusion 169

Battisti, G., 2000, The Intra-Firm Diffusion of New Technolo- Kalbfleisch, J.D. and R.L. Prentice, 1980, The Statistical
gies, PhD Thesis, Warwick University. Analysis of Failure Time Data, New York: John Wiley &
Bond, S., J.A. Elston, J. Mairesse, and B. Mulkay, 2003, Sons.
‘Financial Factors and Investment in Belgium, France, Karshenas, M. and P. Stoneman, 1993, ‘Rank, Stock, Order
Germany and the UK: A Comparison using Company and Epidemic Effects in the Diffusion of New Process
Panel Data’, Review of Economics and Statistics 85 (1), Technologies: An Empirical Model,’ RAND Journal of
153–165. Economics 24 (4), 503–528.
Bond, S., H. Harhoff, and J. Van Reenen, 1999, ‘Investment, Kaplan, S. and L. Zingales, 1997, ‘Do Investment Cash Flow
R&D and Financial Constraints in Britain and Germany,’ Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Financing Con-
IFS Working Paper No. 99/5. straints,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 169–215.
Cainarca, G., M.G. Colombo, and S. Mariotti, 1990, ‘Firm Mansfield, E., 1963 ‘Intrafirm Rates of Diffusion of an Inno-
Size and the Adoption of Flexible Automation,’ Small vation,’ The Review of Economics and Statistics XLV, 348–
Business Economics 2, 129–140. 359.
Canepa, A. and P. Stoneman, 2003, Financial Constraints to Mansfield, E., 1968, Industrial Research and Technological
Innovation in the UK and Other European Countries: Evi- Innovation, New York: Norton.
dence from CIS2 and CIS3, paper presented at a CIS user Mayer, C.P., 1990 ‘Financial Systems, Corporate Finance and
group conference, Modelling Innovation, DTI Conference Economic Development,’ in R.G. Hubbard, (ed.), Asym-
Centre, London. metric Information, Corporate Finance and Investment, Chi-
Carpenter, R.E. and B.C. Petersen, 2002, ‘Is the Growth of cago: NBER, and University of Chicago Press.
Small Firms Constrained by Internal Finance?’ The Review Mickey, J. and S. Greenland, 1989, ‘A Study of the Impact of
of Economics and Statistics 84 (2), 298–309. Confounder-Selection Criteria on Effect Estimation,’
Cleveland, W.S., 1979, ‘Robust Locally Weighted Regression American Journal of Epidemiology 129, 125–137.
and Smoothing Scatterplots’ Journal of the American Nelson, R., 1993, (ed.), National Innovation Systems: A Com-
Statistical Association 74, 829–836. parative Analysis, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Davies, S., 1979, The Diffusion of Process Innovation, Cam- Royston, P. and D.G. Altman, 1994, ‘Regression Using Frac-
bridge: Cambridge University Press. tional Polynomials of Continuous Covariates: Parsimoni-
Devereux, M. and F. Schianterelli, 1989, ‘Investment, Finan- ous Parametric Modelling,’ Applied Statistics, 43, 429–467.
cial Factors and Cash flow: Evidence from UK Panel Data,’ Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss, 1981 ‘Credit Rationing in Markets
NBER Working Papers No. 3116, New York: NBER. with Imperfect Information,’ American Economic Review
Dunne, T., 1994, ‘Plant Age and Technology Use in the U.S. 71 (3), 393–410.
Manufacturing Industries,’ RAND Journal of Economics Stoneman, P., 2001, The Economics of Technological Diffusion,
Autumn, 25 (3), 488–499. Oxford: Blackwells.
European Commission, 2000, The European Observatory for Stoneman, P. and A. Canepa, 2004, ‘Comparative Interna-
SMEs, Sixth Report, Executive Summary, Enterprise Pol- tional Diffusion: Patterns, Determinants and Policies,’
icy, Brussels. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 13 (3), 279–
Fazzari, S., R.G. Hubbard, and B. Petersen, 1988, ‘Finance 298.
Constraints and Corporate Investment,’ Brookings Papers Stoneman, P. and O. Toivanen, 2000, Technological Diffusion
on Economic Activity 1, 141–195. Under Uncertainty: A Real Options Model Applied to the
Goodacre, A. and I. Tonks, 1985. ‘Finance and Technological International Diffusion of Robot Technology. presented at a
Change,’ in P. Stoneman (ed.), Handbook of the Economics Conference in Honour of Paul David, Turin, May 19–21,
of Innovation and Technological Change, Oxford: Black- 2000.
wells, pp. 298–341. Stoneman, P., D. Bosworth, D. Leech, and D. McCausland,
Giudici, G. and S. Paleari, 2000, ‘The Provision of Finance to 1992, ‘Quality Adjusting the Producer Price Index for
Innovation: A Survey Conducted Among Italian Technol- Computers in the UK,’ Report to the Central Statistical
ogy-Based Small Firms,’ Small Business Economics, 14, Office 1–45.
37–53. Triplett, J., 1989, ‘Price and Technological Change in a Capi-
Hall, B., 2004, ‘Innovation and Diffusion,’ NBER Working tal Good. A survey on Computers,’ in D. Jorgenson and
Paper, No. 10212, Cambridge, MA: NBER. R. Landau, (eds.), Technology and Capital Formation,
Hall, B., 2002, ‘The Financing of Research and Develop- Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
ment,’ Oxford Review of Economic Policy 18, 35–51. Wagenvoort, R., 2003, ‘SME finance in Europe, Introduction
Hannan, T.H. and J.M. Mcdowell, 1984, ‘The Determinants and Overview,’ EIB Papers 8 (2), 11–20.
of Technology Adoption: The Case of the Banking Firm,’ Westhead, P. and D.J. Storey, 1997, ‘Financial Constraints
RAND Journal of Economics 15, 328–335. on the Growth of High Technology Small Firms in the
Hubbard, R.G., 1998, ‘Capital Market Imperfections and United Kingdom,’ Applied Financial Economics 7, 197–
Investment,’ Journal of Economic Literature 36, 193–225. 201.

You might also like