You are on page 1of 15

Available online at www.sciencedirect.

com

Borsa _Istanbul Review


_
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019
http://www.elsevier.com/journals/borsa-istanbul-review/2214-8450

Full Length Article

Confucian culture and informal household financing: Evidence from China's


counties
Xiaohui Hou a,*, Rui Yang a, Chun Liu b
a
School of Economics and Finance, Xi'an Jiaotong University, PR China
b
School of Economics, Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, PR China
Received 12 June 2022; revised 21 July 2022; accepted 21 July 2022
Available online 5 August 2022

Abstract

A growing body of literature is investigating the social and cultural determinants of household financing activity. This paper examines the
impact of traditional culture, specifically Confucian culture in China, on informal household financing at the county level. We find that Confucian
culture has a significant and positive impact on informal household financing activity, and a higher degree of digitally inclusive finance can
strengthen the positive relation between Confucian culture and informal household financing. This positive relation between culture and financing
appears to be stronger in regions where Chinese traditional culture is well preserved and more pronounced in regions with a better business
environment. Our study offers insights for policy makers, revealing the importance of the impact of cultural factors on informal financial activity
in emerging economies based on their particular cultural traditions.
Copyright © 2022 Borsa İstanbul Anonim Şirketi. Published by Elsevier B.V. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

JEL classification: D14; G19; Z10


Keywords: Confucian culture; Household finance; Informal financing activities

1. Introduction growth in an economy in which formal financing is also


available. Ahamed, Ho, Mallick, and Matousek (2021) show
The role of informal financing, which occurs without a that areas with more informal lending tend to have less inclu-
formal financial intermediary between borrowers and savers in sive formal banking, which implies a substitution relationship
economic development, particularly in emerging economies, between informal and formal finance.
has come to the fore in recent years. Informal financing in- China has achieved rapid economic growth in the past few
cludes trade credit, private money houses, pawnshops, com- decades, but financial repression and variations in the flow of
munity cooperatives, and interpersonal borrowing (money from capital remain systemic characteristics of China's financial
friends or family). To differentiate formal from informal system (Allen, Qian, Zhang, & Zhao, 2013). The financial
financing, Kandori (1992) and Udry (1994) document the na- system is not yet able to cope adequately with the considerable
ture of self-enforcing contracts for repayment, as opposed to financing demand by the many small and micro enterprises and
social sanctions. Allen, Qian, and Xie (2019) confirm the households. One of the enduring puzzles is how China ach-
crucial role of informal financing in supporting economic ieved rapid economic growth with an underdeveloped financial
system.
Allen, Qian, and Gu (2017) provide an overview of China's
* Corresponding author. P. O. Box 1787, Xi'an Jiaotong University, Xian financial system, concluding that the informal alternative
Ning West Road No.28, 710049, Xi'an, Shaanxi Province, PR China. financial sector played a significant role in supporting the
E-mail address: hxiaoh2006@163.com (X. Hou). growth of the most active sector of the economy, compared to
Peer review under responsibility of Borsa İstanbul Anonim Şirketi.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bir.2022.07.007
2214-8450/Copyright © 2022 Borsa İstanbul Anonim Şirketi. Published by Elsevier B.V. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://
creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

the formal sector of the financial system, including a large household characteristics and the variety of institutional envi-
intermediation sector with dominant state-owned banks and a ronments in which households operate.
rapidly growing capital market. This informal sector supported Ménard and Shirley (2008) demonstrate that, to reduce risk
the growth of a hybrid sector with various structures of and transaction costs, humans create formal institutions,
ownership and coexisted with the formal financial sector to including writing and enforcing constitutions, laws, contracts,
provide more financing sources for the private sector and and regulations, and informal institutions, such as structuring
households to improve the efficiency of resource allocation and inculcating norms of conduct, beliefs, and habits of
across the economy. Allen et al. (2019) distinguish constructive thought and behavior. The formal and informal institutions
informal financing, such as trade credit and family borrowing develop systemic modes of organization that are embedded in
that relies on information advantages and altruistic relation- these settings and provide different incentives, which vary in
ships, and underground financing, such as money lenders who their capacity to motivate agents. According to Ménard and
use violence as a means of enforcement. In this study, using the Shirley (2008), the performance of a market economy de-
China Household Finance Survey, we focus on informal pends on the institutions and modes of organization that
household financing—that is, family borrowing—in Chinese facilitate private transactions and cooperative behavior.
counties. Nee and Swedberg (2008) assert that the stability of
Specifically, we empirically investigate the impact of informal institutional elements—traditional cultural customs,
China's Confucian culture on informal household financing. norms, and beliefs—combined with a distinct constellation of
We choose households at the county level as our sample interests accounts for path dependence in institutional ar-
because the current controversy in the literature regarding the rangements. Traditional culture can shape different arrange-
role of informal financing comes primarily from Chinese evi- ments that support production, exchange, and intertemporal
dence (Allen et al., 2019) and because traditional culture is resource allocation. The role of culture in financial activities
preserved at the county level to a greater extent than the city has gaining increasing attention (Bitar, Hassan, & Saad, 2020;
level due to its higher degree of modernization. Additionally, Trinh, Nguyen, Sgro, & Pham, 2020). Despite the growing
households often rely on financial services and instruments. body of literature on household finance (Guiso & Sodini,
This household financing, as a part of informal financing, has 2013), how traditional culture affects informal household
attracted substantial academic attention and has formed a lively financing remains unclear. To fill this research gap, we inves-
stream in the literature (Guiso & Sodini, 2013). In informal tigate the impact of Confucian culture on informal household
family financing, households must make many decisions that financing in the context of rural China. Confucian culture as a
are unrelated to the focus of firms, investors, and financial state philosophy helped to promote social order and stability by
institutions, which sets them apart from other economic agents. defining justifiable methods, legitimating justice in human re-
In particular, many households have limited access to credit, lationships through defining duties, responsibilities, and rights
which reduces their welfare immensely because it restricts their among individuals and groups and accommodating and
ability to transfer resources intertemporally and smooth con- compromising with groups that have conflicts of interest. Thus,
sumption over time. Confucian culture is expected to have important effects on the
As of 2013, more than 40 percent of China's rural house- achievement of harmonious relationships, enhancement of
holds engaged in private lending, which substantially bridged mutual trust, and compromise in terms of the conflicting in-
the gap between supply and demand in the rural lending terests between borrowers and lenders, therefore, reducing
market, which has severe information asymmetry. Families transaction costs and information asymmetry in informal
borrow money from relatives, friends, colleagues, and private household financing activities.
financial firms, rather than commercial banks and rural credit Confirming our conjecture, our empirical results show that
cooperatives. Because it is difficult for formal financial in- Confucian culture has a significantly positive impact on
stitutions to obtain or confirm information on a potential bor- informal household financing. Additionally, a higher degree of
rower's repayment ability, households tend to seek funding development of digitally inclusive finance can strengthen the
from informal sources in rural areas, and this informal positive association between Confucian culture and informal
financing enhances household income and reduces rural household financing. This positive association appears to be
poverty (Gan, Yin, & Tan, 2016). stronger in regions where Chinese traditional culture is well
Guiso and Sodini (2013) also emphasize that household preserved and is more pronounced in regions with a better
financing decisions, and their outcomes, are often shaped by business environment.
the institutional environment in which they are made. For Our study contributes to the household finance literature by
example, in the absence of the historical and cultural reasons, it focusing on informal household financing. We also identify
would be difficult to explain why households in the US pre- traditional culture as a determinant of decisions on informal
dominantly rely on fixed-rate mortgages and households in the household financing in China, a large emerging economy. Our
UK primarily use variable rates. However, the impacts of study also sheds light on the relationship between culture and
institutional factors on household financial decisions are largely finance. Modernization and economic transformation are pro-
overlooked in corporate finance and are not emphasized in ceeding in countries around the world, however, little is known
asset pricing theory. Hence, studying household financial de- about the role of traditional culture in current financial activ-
cisions requires consideration of the heterogeneity of ities. Our results have contemporary relevance, as a debate
1006
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

concerning the role of cultural traditions in transitional econ- Niu, Wang, Li, and Zhou (2020) find that having more brothers
omies is ongoing. Our findings explore the positive value of increases both the probability of stock market participation and
historical and cultural traditions in a contemporary financial portfolio shares in stocks. Li, Wang, and Zhou (2021) charac-
economy, complementing formal financial systems, particu- terize the impact of entrepreneurship on household portfolio
larly in emerging market economies. choice and two underlying channels of the diversification effect
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section and the risk substitution effect.
2 describes the related literature and develops our hypotheses. Some previous literature brings the availability of household
Section 3 describes the sample selection, variable construction, credit into sharp focus. For instance, the ratio of loan to value
and our empirical strategy. In section 4, we present the results in Europe, the ratio of loans to income in the US, and the
of our baseline empirical analysis and all extended robustness conditional acceptance rates of loan applications all increased
tests. Section 5 shows the results of several further analyses. in the 1990s. The securitization process and the development of
Section 6 provides this paper's summary and concluding the subprime mortgage market in the US, innovations in the
remarks. consumer loan industry, and the massive liberalization of credit
and financial markets in many countries in continental Europe
2. Literature review and development of our hypothesis encouraged considerable growth in household debt and access
to credit since then (Dynan & Kohn, 2007).
In a 2006 Presidential Address to the American Financial From a historical perspective, China has had fewer
Association, John Campbell coined the term “household formally organized means to bring capital access to the
finance” to describe the field of research that analyzes how public than Western countries. Despite having vast, orga-
households use financial instruments and markets to achieve nized marketplaces for goods and commodities, China had
their objectives. Since then, household finance has attracted less well-developed capital markets and financial institutions.
substantial academic attention. Guiso and Sodini (2013) assert This “financial divergence” historically offers a promising
that household finance is now a thriving, vibrant, and inde- potential answer to the question: How could China have been
pendent field of inquiry. so far ahead of the rest of the world technologically and yet
Tufano (2009) demonstrates that the financial services and have stumbled economically on the eve of the Industrial
products used by households make up a large portion of the Revolution? It also had a profound impact on Chinese private
finance industry in all advanced countries. Households must economic activities (Goetzmann, 2016). Additionally,
make a number of decisions that are not the theoretical or Fukuyama (1995) emphasizes the importance of familism in
empirical focus of asset pricing and corporate finance but are China's economic traditions. Scholars have argued that
central considerations in household finances and welfare. Many kinship and collegiality in China have a cultural influence
households have limited access to credit, which impairs their analogous to that of law and individuality in the West
ability to transfer resources intertemporally and smooth con- (Hamilton, 1996).
sumption over time. A growing body of literature on household Although China achieved rapid economic growth in the past
finance examines the facts about household assets and liabil- few decades, financial repression and disparities in the flow of
ities, household risk preferences and beliefs, household port- capital remain systemic characteristics of its financial system
folio decisions, and household borrowing decisions (Allen et al., 2013). Therefore, informal household financing is
(Brunnermeir & Nagel, 2008; Calvet, Campbell, & Sodini, bound to have an essential function in China's financial system
2007; Chiuri & Jappelli, 2002; Fagereng, Gottlieb, & Guiso, because of constraints on credit availability. Informal house-
2011; Gollier, 2006; Guiso, Sapienza, & Zingales, 2008; hold finance can help to mitigate households' limited access to
Piazzesi & Schneider, 2009; Yao & Zhang, 2005). credit resources under conditions characterized by high trans-
With respect to household finance in the context of China, action costs, severe information asymmetry, and underdevel-
Gan et al. (2016) report the status and development of household oped formal financial sectors.
finance in rural China comprehensively and systematically. Greif (1989, 1993) suggests that elements of traditional
Liao, Xiao, Zhang, and Zhou (2017) examine the correlation of culture, such as implicit contractual relations and coalitions,
financial literacy and risky asset holding behavior by Chinese can complement formal legal and contract enforcement and
households, revealing that consumers with higher levels of address the problems of asymmetric information. Breuer,
financial literacy are more likely to hold risky assets than those Riesener, and Salzmann (2014) focus on the concept of na-
with lower levels. Cooper and Zhu (2018) use a lifecycle model tional culture as a way of capturing and measuring information
to investigate household finance in China, focusing on high about individual psychology. Culture is defined as customary
savings rates, low stock market participation rates, and low beliefs, social norms, and opinions regarding the values that
shares of stocks in wealth. They conclude that, compared to the social groups transmit, relatively unchanged, from one gener-
US, the distinctive financial choices of households in China are ation to another. Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales (2006) state
driven more by institutional factors, as well as by preference that national culture is reflected in individuals’ sense of what is
variations. Gao (2019) finds that household investment decisions good, right, fair, and just. Restricting the potential channels of
are influenced by beliefs regarding gains. Song, Wu, and Zhou cultural influence to beliefs and value judgments establishes an
(2020) demonstrate that inequality of opportunity raises both the approach for identifying a causal relationship from culture to
probability and the share of household risky asset investment. financial behaviors.
1007
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

In the literature on behavioral household finance surveyed social order” (li), and “moral integrity and virtue” (de). This
by Williamson (2010) and Beshears, Choi, Laibson, and doctrine holds that its place in society is eternal, and Confu-
Madrian (2018), culture, as a relatively stable determinant, cian literati play an irreplaceable role; tian and dao became
has a profound impact on economic and financial activities. principles that dictated Chinese everyday life; ren, the essence
Guiso et al. (2006) reject a relationship of potential reverse of civilization, embodies people's dignity and value as human
causality between culture and finance. People in a culture beings and social harmony; a better interpretation of li is
might tend to rely more on financial instruments and funding “harmonious social order”; Confucian belief comprises the
resources because of public opinion on the values embedded in view that a “harmonious social order” (li) and “sage-like
social organization forms, and reliable means of resource humanity” (ren) can be achieved through having moral
accumulation and allocation are molded and profoundly integrity and virtue (de).
affected by a country's traditional culture. The significant im- As summarized by Deng (1999), if one assumes that
pacts of culture on corporate and individual financial decisions Confucian culture is a state philosophy, it is undeniable that,
are documented by Shao, Kwok, and Guehami (2008), Chui, beginning in the Western Han dynasty (202 B.C. - 8 A.D.), the
Titman, and Wei (2010), and Hilary and Hui (2009). state philosophy helped to promote social order and stability by
Karolyi (2016) sounds a note of particular caution about the defining justifiable methods, legitimating justice in human re-
role of culture in guiding financial decisions because scholar- lationships by defining duties, responsibilities, and rights
ship on finance has paid relatively little attention to the role of among individuals and groups, and accommodating and
culture in financial decision-making compared to other busi- compromising with conflicting interest groups. Thus Confucian
ness disciplines and economics. Chen, Ma, and Sinclair (2021) culture is assumed to have important effects on harmonizing
assert that, despite China's modernization efforts in the early relationships, enhancing mutual trust, and compromise in terms
twentieth century, Confucianism continues to stifle financial of the conflicting interests of borrowers and lenders—therefore,
development by reducing demand for external finance. Finan- reducing transaction costs and information asymmetry in
cial development is path dependent. As Confucianism devel- informal household financing activities.
oped over more than two millennia, its effect on Chinese Based on this discussion, our primary hypothesis, which we
people's economic way of life is likely to persist (Chen, Chen, test using several analyses, is as follows:
& He, 2019; Kung & Ma, 2014; Yuchtman, 2017).
Hypothesis. Confucian culture has a significant positive
Furthermore, Greif and Tabellini (2017) state that China and
impact on informal household financing in China, given the
the West have established different approaches for achieving
lack of well-developed financial services for households.
interpersonal cooperation, leading to distinct paths in institu-
tional and cultural development. Ma (2011) emphasizes that
the most fundamental economic institutions in the major
3. Data, variables, and empirical strategy
developing countries derived from long-established social
norms and traditions. Historically and actually, informal in-
stitutions, such as culture, have a significant influence on 3.1. Data
constraining people's behaviors because of a higher degree of
The main data come from the 2013, 2015, and 2017 waves
official intervention. Traditional culture favors a reduction in
of the China Household Financial Survey (CHFS). The CHFS
transaction costs and information asymmetry. Shiga (2002)
is conducted by the Survey and Research Center of China
notes that the legal trial procedure in traditional Chinese so-
Household Finance and is a nationwide survey of households
ciety closely approximates a process of didactic conciliation,
across China, excluding Tibet, Xinjiang, Inner Mongolia,
and the fulfillment of contracts is guaranteed by informal and
internal cultural norms. Additionally, Liang (1996) claims that Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan.1 Comprehensive informa-
traditional rules and customs in China have binding force and tion on household assets, liabilities, family members’ de-
mographic characteristics, employment status, and financial
effectiveness based solely upon local social environments.
circumstances are included in this dataset. Gan et al. (2016)
Chen et al. (2021) also assert that China's early adoption of
provide a comprehensive report on the development of
Confucianism as the state orthodoxy for structuring society in
household finance in rural China. We draw our data from the
favor of interpersonal risk sharing and resource pooling made
CHFS dataset, in which the respondent is the head of a
the country both uninterested in and unprepared for subsequent
household (the member with the best knowledge about
external financial development. Thus, China, like other tradi-
tional societies, has long relied on household financing activ- household conditions) registered in a permanent rural place of
ities for risk sharing and resource pooling. Deng (1999) deeply residence. In addition, the registered permanent residence of a
head of household is consistent with the habitation place.
explores the connotation and influence of Confucian ideology
Fig. 1 shows the ratio of private borrowers to total survey
as a primary factor in the Chinese socioeconomic system.
Confucianism is commonly viewed as both the core of the
code of conduct for Chinese people in all walks of life and the 1
Detailed information about the CHFS is available at http://www.chfsdata.
guidelines for the imperial government in ruling the country. org. The CHFS has publicly released four waves of data. The first wave of
Confucian doctrine consists of the “way” (dao), the “will of the CHFS (2011) is not used in this study because it did not include various
Heaven” (tian), “authoritative humanity” (ren), “harmonious questions related to financial characteristics.

1008
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

information on Confucian culture at the county level. The data


on counties’ economic circumstances are collected from the
China Stock Market and Accounting Research database and
China Statistical Yearbook (county level) over the relevant
years. To remove the influence of outliers on our results, we
winsorized the data of continuous variables at an interval of 1
percent and 99 percent. Finally, all data for the value variables
were inflation adjusted to eliminate the impact of price
fluctuations.

3.2. Variable definition and summary statistics

We employ two measures of informal household financing


as dependent variables. The first measure, Privatefin, is a
dummy variable that equals 1 if the household is involved in
informal family borrowing. The second measure, Privatodebt,
is a ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt.
The main explanatory variable in our analysis is Confucian
culture, Confuciancul, which is represented by the logarithm of
the number of academies in a county during the Tang, Song,
Yuan, Ming, and Qing dynasties, Lgnacademy, and the density
of a county's academies, Densityaca, which is the number of
academies per 100 square kilometers.2 Fig. 2 shows the spread
of Confucian academies in the counties, demonstrating that
ancient academies are discretely distributed across the whole
country.
We also include a wide range of household socioeconomic
characteristics identified in existing literature as control vari-
ables to account for household heterogeneity (Campbell, 2006;
Christiansen, Joensen, & Rangvid, 2008; Cyganrehm &
Maeder, 2013; Guiso & Sodini, 2013; Li et al., 2021; Liao
et al., 2017; McCrary & Royer, 2011; Niu et al., 2020;
Renneboog & Spaenjers, 2012).
More specifically, we control for the individual character-
istics of the head of a household, such as the logarithm of the
age of the household head (Age), the education level (Edu),3 a
dummy variable for gender (Male), a dummy variable for
marital status (Married ), health status (Health), attitude toward
risk (Riskpre), and a dummy variable reflecting membership in
the Chinese Communist Party (Partymember). We also control
for several variables regarding household characteristics, such
as the household size (Size), the logarithm of total family
wealth (Lgwealth), the logarithm of family income (Lgincome),
a dummy variable to capture consanguinity in the same place
of residence (Relat), the status of the family social network
measured as a logarithm of cash gift payments made by a
Fig. 1. The ratio of private borrowers to total survey respondents in each household (Housenet), and a dummy variable for credit con-
county. Note: This figure shows the ratio of private borrowers to total survey
respondents in counties, with provincial capitals indicated to show geographic
straints (Creditconst). Year and county fixed effects are
location. controlled for to ensure that our main results are not affected by

respondents in counties, with provincial capitals indicated to


show their geographic location. We find that this proportion 2
In ancient China, academies were set up as educational institutions to
varies across counties over years. spread Confucian culture. Our empirical results do not suffer from reverse
The data regarding Confucian culture come from the Chi- causality because the main explanatory variables are constructed using data in
nese Research Data Services Platform (CNRDS). As a subset the Ming and Qing dynasties (hundreds of years ago), which predate measures
of informal household financing.
of CNRDS, the Chinese Confucian Culture Database gathers 3
It is the logarithm of the years of schooling.

1009
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

Fig. 2. The distribution of the number of ancient academies across the country. Note: This figure shows the number of ancient academies in the counties, which
demonstrates that ancient academies are discretely distributed across the whole country.

unobserved heterogeneity across regions and years. Table 1 impact of Confucian culture on households’ informal financing
presents detailed variable definitions. participation and ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions to
Table 2 details the summary statistics of our main variables. investigate its effect on the ratio of private loan arrears to total
We also tested for multicollinearity between the explanatory and household debt. The general baseline model is as follows4:
the main control variables, including continuous variables and
dummy variables, to guard against the impacts of highly mul- Houseinfinict = α + β⋅Confucianculc + δ′ Xict + τt + λc + εict
ticollinear regressors on our parameter estimates. The resulting (1)
value of condition number and the mean variance inflation
factors all imply that high multicollinearity is not found. Table 3 where Houseinfinict is Privatefinict and Privatodebtict, respec-
presents the correlation coefficients among our main variables, tively, to indicate the informal financing status of household i
providing a preliminary confirmation of our argument and in county c at time t. Confucianculc is represented by Lgna-
constructive clues to our subsequent regression analysis. cademyc and Densityacac. Xict represents a group of control
variables. τt is the year fixed effect, λc denotes the county
3.3. Econometric specification dummies, and εict is the error term. The OLS method is
employed to estimate Equation (1), and standard errors are
Pooled data on the three waves of the CHFS are used for our clustered at the county level. Additionally, probit models are
baseline regression models. Following Hellevik (2009), Chatla used as a robustness check on the empirical relationship be-
and Shmueli (2017), Niu et al. (2020), and Li et al. (2021), we tween Confucianculc and Privatefinict; we also employ a Tobit
employ a linear probability model (LPM) to estimate the model to examine the robust impact of Confucian culture on
Privatodebtict, which is bounded between 0 and 1.

4
Greene (2017) and Chatla and Shmueli (2017) document that LPMs are
more attractive and appropriate for investigating a causal relationship than
obtaining valid predicted probabilities.

1010
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

Table 1 Table 2
Variable definitions. Summary statistics for the main variables.
Variable Definition Variable N Mean Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum
Privatefin Dummy variable that equals 1 if the household is Privatefin 39,900 0.241 0.427 0.000 1.000
involved in informal family borrowing and 0 Privatodebt 13,136 0.505 0.465 0.000 1.000
otherwise. Lgnacademy 39,900 0.534 0.487 0.000 1.908
Privatodebt Ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt. Densityaca 39,900 0.332 0.825 0.000 19.104
Lgnacademy Logarithm of the number of academies in a county Age 39,896 47.787 21.182 14.000 77.000
during the Tang, Song, Yuan, Ming, and Qing Edu 28,721 0.908 0.127 0.778 1.342
dynasties (618 A.D. - 1912 A.D.). Male 39,899 0.509 0.499 0.000 1.000
Densityaca Number of academies per 100 square kilometers. Married 34,386 0.827 0.378 0.000 1.000
Lgage Logarithm of the age of household head. Health 39,865 0.775 0.418 0.000 1.000
Edu Logarithm of the years of schooling. Riskpre 13,769 1.617 0.659 0.000 2.000
Male Dummy variable that equals 1 if the head of a Partymember 19,160 0.079 0.270 0.000 1.000
household is male and 0 otherwise. Size 39,900 0.557 0.216 0.000 1.279
Married Dummy variable that equals 1 if the head of a Lgwealth 39,875 1.212 0.730 −4.000 3.985
household is married and 0 otherwise. Lgincome 6708 0.272 0.410 −3.523 1.857
Health Dummy variable that equals 1 if the member of a Relat 15,904 0.884 0.321 0.000 1.000
family is healthy and 0 otherwise. Housenet 26,452 −0.732 0.535 −5.000 1.653
Riskpre The attitude of the household head toward risk, Creditconst 36,443 0.106 0.308 0.000 1.000
which equals 0, 1, or 2 if the risk attitude is risk- Note: Std. Dev. is standard deviation.
preference, risk-neutral, or risk-averse, respectively.
Partymember Dummy variable that equals 1 if the household head
is a member of the Chinese Communist Party and 0 Table 3
otherwise. Correlation coefficients of the main variables.
Size Logarithm of the number of members of a family.
Lgwealth Logarithm of total family wealth. Lgnacademy Densityaca
Lgincome Logarithm of family income. Privatefin 0.021*** 0.009*
Relat Dummy variable that equals 1 if the household head Privatodebt 0.041*** 0.047***
has consanguinity in the same place of residence
Note: *, **, and *** denote statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,
and 0 otherwise.
respectively.
Housenet Logarithm of cash gift payments made by a
household.
Creditconst Dummy variable that equals 1 if the household's Now that contemporary informal household financing has
application for loans is not submitted or is rejected been determined not to affect Confucian culture, represented
by banks and 0 otherwise. by the variables that formed historically, no further discussion
is needed about reverse causality. Moreover, in the light of the
geographic divisions, as well as strong information asymme-
To address the potential endogeneity problem, we imple- try and the high risk of private lending, the spatial correlation
ment sensitivity analysis of the omitted variables, as described and spillover of informal household financing are not a
in Cinelli, Ferwerda, and Hazlett (2020). Additionally, several concern.
potential interference factors, such as financial literacy In addition, we further address potential endogeneity
(Financeknown),5 the growth rate of the gross domestic prod- problems following the matched sample analysis proposed by
uct (GDP) at the county level (Countygrowth), a logarithm of Francis, Lennox, and Wang (2012). We then employ placebo
the number of Confucian temples (Lgnconfutemp) and density tests, in which we randomly assign (with replacement)
(Densityctemple) of Confucian temples in a county,6 and a Confucianculc to each household in a county at time t based
dummy variable that equals 1 if a region has been the seat of a on the sample distribution of our explanatory variables and
local government at the province level since the Tang dynasty, rerun the baseline regressions, repeating them 500 times. The
and 0 otherwise (Admincenter)7 are controlled for to address average coefficient for the main explanatory variables over
concerns regarding alternative hypotheses and further confirm the 500 repetitions and the corresponding one-sample t-test
our empirical results. results, in which the null hypothesis is that the mean coef-
ficient for our main explanatory variable equals 0, are
reported.
Additionally, we use instrumental variable regressions to
further alleviate concerns regarding the endogeneity of our
5
Financeknown equals 1 if a household head received financial training, and
0 otherwise. explanatory variables. Finally, in a section on further analysis,
6
We controlled for these variables to factor out the influence of the power of we then address possible endogeneity issues driven by unob-
county clan organizations, represented by Confucian temples, thereby capturing servable variables by investigating cross-sectional variations in
the effect of Confucian culture more precisely. the relationship between Confucian culture and informal
7
Admincenter is controlled for because a place that is the seat of a local
household financing. Following Allen et al. (2019), we perform
government at the province level historically obtained more support from the
central government to promote Confucian culture, which reflects the influence a series of heterogeneity analyses to examine variations in
of the intervention of the central government, rather than Confucian culture. cross-sectional pattern based on several dimensions, including

1011
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

the development of a county's digitally inclusive finance, a informal financing and the ratio of private loan arrears to total
geographic variable indicating the western region of China, and household debt, which holds when the attitude of the household
the county business environment. If our empirical results hold, head toward risk and the political status variable are controlled
we should find the expected variations in the main effects with for in Column 2. Moreover, after controlling for all individual
changes in the external environment. characteristics, household features, year dummies, and county
dummies in Column 3, the significant coefficient estimates of
4. Empirical results Lgnacademy are 0.395 and 0.652 for the dependent variables
Privatefin and Privatodebt, respectively. In Panel B, we find the
4.1. Baseline results same pattern when the explanatory variable is represented by the
density of a county's academies. After controlling for all indi-
Table 4 presents the results of our baseline regressions. In our vidual characteristics, household characteristics, year dummies,
sample dataset, 24.1 percent of rural households participate in and county dummies, the significant coefficient estimates of
informal financing activities. On average, the ratio of private Densityaca are 0.096 and 0.325 for the dependent variables
loan arrears to total household debt is 50.5 percent. In Panel A of Privatefin and Privatodebt, respectively.
Table 4, Column 1 shows that Confucian culture is positively Table 4 provides strong empirical evidence that Confucian
related to both a household's likelihood of involvement in culture has a significantly positive impact on informal

Table 4
Results of baseline regressions.
Panel A Privatefin Privatodebt
(1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3)
Lgnacademy 0.097*** (0.009) 0.122*** (0.016) 0.395** (0.160) 0.101*** (0.018) 0.443*** (0.154) 0.652*** (0.198)
lgage −0.375*** (0.024) −0.571*** (0.072) −0.350 (0.323) −0.024 (0.039) −0.369 (0.299) −0.362 (0.907)
Edu −0.026 (0.025) −0.019 (0.048) 0.015 (0.171) −0.176*** (0.049) −0.301*** (0.074) −0.182 (0.443)
Male 0.005 (0.003) 0.022*** (0.005) 0.031 (0.031) 0.007 (0.006) 0.028*** (0.009) 0.026 (0.085)
Married 0.029*** (0.007) 0.066*** (0.022) 0.091 (0.102) −0.055*** (0.016) −0.006 (0.034) 0.247 (0.319)
Health −0.055*** (0.007) −0.073*** (0.012) −0.131* (0.076) 0.009 (0.014) −0.046** (0.019) −0.158 (0.163)
Riskpre −0.023** (0.009) 0.005 (0.032) 0.014 (0.013) −0.064 (0.077)
Partymember −0.037** (0.018) −0.052 (0.064) −0.087*** (0.033) −0.140 (0.194)
Size −0.078 (0.153) −0.499 (0.384)
Lgwealth 0.039 (0.039) −0.086 (0.125)
Lgincome −0.010 (0.055) 0.016 (0.127)
Relat 0.012 (0.099) −0.046 (0.185)
Housenet 0.033 (0.043) −0.033 (0.125)
Creditconst 0.118* (0.070) −0.111 (0.145)
County dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 28,007 9497 908 9175 3372 279
R-squared 0.197 0.230 0.525 0.280 0.357 0.753
Panel B
Densityaca 0.049*** (0.001) 0.039*** (0.002) 0.096** (0.039) 0.034*** (0.002) 0.006** (0.003) 0.325*** (0.087)
lgage −0.375*** (0.024) −0.571*** (0.072) −0.350 (0.323) −0.024 (0.039) 0.155 (0.104) −0.362 (0.907)
Edu −0.026 (0.025) −0.020 (0.048) 0.015 (0.171) −0.176*** (0.049) −0.345*** (0.076) −0.182 (0.443)
Male 0.005 (0.003) 0.022*** (0.005) 0.031 (0.031) 0.007 (0.006) 0.034*** (0.009) 0.026 (0.085)
Married 0.029*** (0.007) 0.066*** (0.022) 0.091 (0.102) −0.055*** (0.016) 0.007 (0.037) 0.247 (0.319)
Health −0.055*** (0.007) −0.073*** (0.012) −0.131* (0.076) 0.009 (0.014) −0.045** (0.021) −0.158 (0.163)
Riskpre −0.023** (0.009) 0.005 (0.032) 0.015 (0.013) −0.064 (0.077)
Partymember −0.037** (0.018) −0.052 (0.064) −0.077** (0.032) −0.140 (0.194)
Size −0.078 (0.153) −0.499 (0.384)
Lgwealth 0.039 (0.039) −0.086 (0.125)
Lgincome −0.010 (0.055) 0.016 (0.127)
Relat 0.012 (0.099) −0.046 (0.185)
Housenet 0.033 (0.043) −0.033 (0.125)
Creditconst 0.118* (0.071) −0.111 (0.146)
County dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 28,007 9497 908 9175 3372 279
R-squared 0.197 0.230 0.525 0.280 0.357 0.753
Note: The first dependent variable is involvement in informal household financing, Privatefin. The second dependent variable is the ratio of private loan arrears to
total household debt, Privatodebt. In Panel A, the explanatory variable is Lgnacademy. In Panel B, it is the density of a county's academies, Densityaca. *, **, and
*** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Corresponding standard errors clustered at the county level are reported in
parentheses.

1012
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

household financing. Additionally, although Hünermund and Table 5


Louw (2020) document that there is no need to consider the Results of sensitivity analysis to omitted variables.
estimated coefficients of control variables in multivariate re- Privatefin Privatodebt
gressions because control variables cannot provide structural Lgnacademy 2.000 4.000
explanations, we still find that the coefficient estimates of our Densityaca 2.000 6.000
control variables are mainly consistent with the directions Note: The benchmark variables used in the analysis of sensitivity to omitted
identified in previous studies, such as Niu et al. (2020) and Li variables, compared to potentially unobserved confounders, are Relat, House-
et al. (2021). net, and Creditconst. Our main control variables are also included.
The sensitivity analysis to omitted variables in Table 5,
proposed by Cinelli et al. (2020), shows that when the literature (e.g., Acemoglu & Restrepo, 2022), our results
dependent variable is Privatefin, it needs almost twice the remain conceivable, especially as the robustness tests for our
explanatory power of the potentially omitted variables primary empirical results.
compared withRelat, Housenet, and Creditconst to influence
our baseline regression results. When the dependent variable is 4.3. Further robustness checks and addressing
Privatodebt, based on the same benchmark variables, it needs endogeneity
almost four times the explanatory power to influence our
baseline regression results if the explanatory variable is 4.3.1. Alternative regression specifications
Lgnacademy and the six times the explanatory power if the A probit model is employed as a robustness check in the
explanatory variable is Densityaca. Therefore, our results are estimation of the relationship between Confucian culture and
robust because Relat, Housenet, and Creditconst, reflecting households’ participation in informal financing. We also use a
family networks and financing constraints, are relatively sig- Tobit model to investigate the impact of Confucian culture on
nificant influential factors identified in previous literature. the proportion of informal household financing. Table 7 pre-
sents the results of these robustness tests, showing that the
4.2. Results for potential alternative explanations relationship identified between Confucian culture and informal
household financing still holds when the alternative model
Several potential interference factors are included, such as specifications are used.
financial literacy (Financeknown), the GDP growth rate at the
county level (Countygrowth), the logarithm of the number 4.3.2. Regression results of matched sample and placebo
(Lgnconfutemp) and density (Densityctemple) of Confucian tests
temples in a county in the Ming and Qing dynasties, and a We further address potential endogeneity problems using
dummy variable for the seat of a local government at the the matched sample analysis method proposed by Francis
province level since the Tang dynasty (Admincenter). According et al. (2012). We perform matching based on the propensity
to Guiso and Sodini (2013), Gan et al. (2016), and Liao et al. scores of our main explanatory variables. In the first stage,
(2017), financial literacy and local GDP growth often boost following Al-Thaqeb and Algharabali (2019), we model the
household finance. Additionally, a county's clan organizations likelihood that a household is highly influenced by traditional
and social power, represented by Confucian temples, can pro- culture in a county as a function of variables for all charac-
mote informal household financing8; thus we include Lgncon- teristics (Guiso & Sodini, 2013). Households are highly
futemp and Densityctemple to observe their potential influence. influenced by Confucian culture when the corresponding
Finally, when a place that is the seat of a local government at the values of Confucian culture variables are above the upper
province level historically obtained more support from the quartile. We then conduct radius matching, pairing highly
central government to promote Confucian culture, which reflects influenced households with minimally influenced households
the influence of the intervention of the central government, that have the closest propensity scores, in which the absolute
rather than Confucian culture, the impact of Admincenter on difference between the two households’ propensity scores is
informal household financing should also be eliminated. no greater than 0.01. The LPM on the propensity score
In Table 6, the potential alternative explanations do not matched sample under our specification of Equation (1) is re-
abate the significantly positive impacts of our main explanatory estimated. Table 8 reports the results, which are consistent
variables on informal household financing. The coefficient with our hypothesis.
estimates of Lgnacademy and Densityaca are all significantly We next employ placebo tests, in which we randomly assign
positive, regardless of whether the dependent variable is Pri- (with replacement) Confucianculc to each household in a
vatefin or Privatodebt. In addition, the number of observations county at time t based on the sample distribution of our
for a few regressions is relatively small because of the missing explanatory variables and rerun the baseline regressions,
values of some interference factors in the context of our defined repeating the exercise 500 times. The average coefficient for
research sample. Nevertheless, according to the existing the main explanatory variables over the 500 repetitions and
corresponding one-sample t-test results, in which the null hy-
pothesis is that the mean coefficient of our main explanatory
8
The construction of Confucian temples was mostly sponsored and orga- variable equals 0, are reported in Table 9.
nized by big local clans.

1013
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu
Table 6
Results for potential alternative explanations.
Panel A Privatefin Privatodebt
(1) (2) (3) (4) (1) (2) (3) (4)
Lgnacademy 0.693*** (0.126) 0.554* (0.293) 0.395** (0.160) 0.395** (0.160) 0.635*** (0.242) 0.131* (0.076) 0.652*** (0.198) 0.410* (0.233)
Financeknown 0.097 (0.264) −0.219 (0.501)
Countygrowth 0.004 (0.009) −0.007 (0.045)
Lgnconfutemp 1.219** (0.557) 0.647 (0.811)
Admincenter −0.034 (0.076) −0.413*** (0.151)
All control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
County dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 423 663 908 908 154 211 279 279
R-squared 0.504 0.556 0.525 0.525 0.729 0.790 0.753 0.753
1014

Panel B
Densityaca 0.431*** (0.122) 0.214** (0.083) 0.383*** (0.101) 0.096** (0.039) 0.124** (0.053) 0.453** (0.225) 0.477* (0.292) 0.325*** (0.087)
Financeknown 0.097 (0.264) −0.219 (0.501)
Countygrowth 0.004 (0.009) −0.007 (0.045)
Densityctemple −0.110 (0.118) 0.108 (0.301)
Admincenter 0.587** (0.249) −1.279*** (0.461)
All control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
County dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 423 663 676 908 154 211 213 279
R-squared 0.504 0.556 0.520 0.525 0.729 0.790 0.759 0.753

Borsa Istanbul
Note: The first dependent variable is informal household financing involvement, Privatefin, defined as a dummy variable that equals 1 if the household is involved in informal family borrowing, and 0 otherwise. The
second dependent variable is the ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt, Privatodebt. In Panel A, the explanatory variable, Lgnacademy, is the logarithm of the number of academies in a county during

_
the Tang, Song, Yuan, Ming, and Qing dynasties. In Panel B, it is the density of a county's academies, Densityaca. *, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Corresponding standard errors clustered at the county level are reported in parentheses.

Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019


X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

Table 7 Table 9
Results of Probit and Tobit regressions. Placebo test results.
Privatefin Privatodebt Dependent variable Privatefin Privatodebt
Panel A Mean coefficient for 0.000005 (0.001) −0.004 (0.003)
Lgnacademy 1.626***(0.279) 0.504***(0.152) Lgnacademy
All control variables Yes Yes Mean coefficient for −0.0003 (0.0009) −0.001 (0.002)
County dummies Yes Yes Densityaca
Year dummies Yes Yes N 500 500
N 552 279 Note: This table presents the summary statistics of the regression estimates for
Pseudo R-squared 0.302 0.192 the baseline model with the full set of control variables when we randomly
Panel B assigned Confucianculc to each household based on the sample distribution of
Densityaca 2.268***(0.389) 1.132***(0.110) explanatory variables. For each replication, we recorded the estimated coeffi-
All control variables Yes Yes cient and associated p-value. We repeat this procedure 500 times. The mean
County dummies Yes Yes coefficient estimates for the main explanatory variables across the 500 repli-
Year dummies Yes Yes cations are presented. Corresponding standard errors of one-sample t tests are
N 552 279 displayed in parentheses where the null hypothesis is that the mean coefficient
Pseudo R-squared 0.302 0.205 for our main explanatory variable equals 0. *, **, and *** indicate significance
Note: The first dependent variable is informal household financing involve- at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
ment, Privatefin, defined as a dummy variable that equals 1 if the household is
involved in informal family borrowing, and 0 otherwise. The second dependent
variable is the ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt, Privatodebt. Privatefin or Privatodebt, the percentage of significantly pos-
In Panel A, the explanatory variable, Lgnacademy, is the logarithm of the itive coefficient estimates at the 5 percent level is less than 2
number of academies in a county during the Tang, Song, Yuan, Ming, and Qing percent. This evidence strongly suggests that the measures of
dynasties. In Panel B, it is the density of a county's academies, Densityaca. A
Probit model is used for the first dependent variable; a Tobit model is employed
Confucian culture are positively associated with informal
for the second dependent variable. *, **, and *** denote statistical significance household financing, as opposed to random noise.
at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Corresponding clustered standard
errors are reported in parentheses. 4.3.3. Instrumental variable estimation results
Table 10 presents the estimation results using instrumental
variables (IV) as our explanatory variables and fitting the
As demonstrated, we cannot reject that the means of esti- baseline models with the standard errors clustered at the county
mated coefficients for our main explanatory variables are not level. A logarithm of the number of jinshi (a successful candi-
different than 0. In addition, all estimated coefficients are date in the highest imperial examinations) and the density of
roughly equally split between positive and negative. Moreover, jinshi in the Ming and Qing dynasties in the prefecture-level
in all cases, regardless of whether the dependent variable is cities closest to various counties, are employed as the IVs for
Lgnacademy and Densityaca, respectively.9 We adjust the de-
Table 8 grees of freedom and report small-sample statistics. These
Results of matched sample analysis. findings once again suggest that our empirical results are truly
Privatefin Privatodebt robust after the primary endogeneity concerns are addressed.
Panel A
Lgnacademy 0.400** (0.163) 0.658*** (0.206) 5. Further analysis
All control variables Yes Yes
County dummies Yes Yes Finally, following Allen et al. (2019), we use a series of
Year dummies Yes Yes
N 898 276
heterogeneity analyses to examine variation in cross-sectional
R-squared 0.522 0.751 patterns based on several dimensions, such as the development
Panel B of digitally inclusive finance in a county, a geographic variable
Densityaca 0.098** (0.040) 0.331*** (0.094) indicating a location in western China, and the county's business
All control variables Yes Yes
environment. This evidence further supports our main findings.
County dummies Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes
N 898 276 5.1. Augmented mechanism from digitally inclusive
Pseudo R-squared 0.522 0.751 finance in a county
Note: The first dependent variable is involvement in informal household
financing, Privatefin, defined as a dummy variable that equals 1 if the house- We further investigate whether a higher degree of devel-
hold is involved in informal family borrowing, and 0 otherwise. The second opment of digitally inclusive finance promotes informal
dependent variable is the ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt,
household financing activities at the county level. Financial
Privatodebt. In panel A, the explanatory variable, Lgnacademy, is the logarithm
of the number of academies in a county during the Tang, Song, Yuan, Ming, inclusion is defined as a financial system that effectively and
and Qing dynasties. In panel B, it is the density of a county's academies, comprehensively provides services to all groups in society. Its
Densityaca. The matched sample analyses are employed. *, **, and *** denote
statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Corre-
9
sponding standard errors clustered at the county level are reported in They are correlated with our explanatory variables but cannot be used to
parentheses. explain informal household financing at the county level directly.

1015
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

Table 10
The impact of Confucian culture on informal household financing based on IV estimators.
Privatefin Privatodebt Privatefin Privatodebt
Lgnacademy 0.395**(0.181) 0.652***(0.158) Densityaca 0.096**(0.047) 0.032***(0.007)
All control variables Yes Yes All control variables Yes Yes
County dummies Yes Yes County dummies Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes Year dummies Yes Yes
N 908 279 N 908 279
R-squared 0.525 0.753 R-squared 0.525 0.753
Note: The first dependent variable is informal household financing involvement, Privatefin, defined as a dummy variable that equals 1 if the household is involved in
informal family borrowing, and 0 otherwise. The second dependent variable is the ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt, Privatodebt. Explanatory
variables are the logarithm of the number of academies in a county, Lgnacademy, during the Tang, Song, Yuan, Ming, and Qing dynasties and the density of a
county's academies, Densityaca, respectively. Our estimations pass the tests of underidentification and weak identification. The p-value of F tests are all less than
0.01. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Corresponding robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.

Table 11
Augmented mechanism analysis.
Privatefin Privatodebt Privatefin Privatodebt
Diglgnacademy 0.316*(0.180) 0.602**(0.303) Digdensityaca 0.592** (0.285) 1.142** (0.563)
Explanatory and all control Yes Yes Explanatory and all control Yes Yes
variables variables
County dummies Yes Yes County dummies Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes Year dummies Yes Yes
N 908 279 N 908 279
R-squared 0.527 0.761 R-squared 0.527 0.759
Note: The first dependent variable is informal household financing involvement, Privatefin, defined as a dummy variable that equals 1 if the household is involved in
informal family borrowing, and 0 otherwise. The second dependent variable is the ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt, Privatodebt. Explanatory
variables include Lgnacademy, the logarithm of the number of academies in a county during the Tang, Song, Yuan, Ming, and Qing dynasties, and the density of a
county's academies, Densityaca, respectively. The Diglgnacademy is an interaction term of Digitalin and Lgnacademy; the Digdensityaca is an interaction term of
Digitalin and Densityaca. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Corresponding standard errors clustered at the county
level are reported in parentheses.

original intention was to emphasize continuous improvement in finance of each county in the corresponding years. This index
financial infrastructure to increase the availability of financial has been widely used, and high values of the index suggest a
services and provide convenient financial services at lower cost higher degree of development of rural digitally inclusive
to all people, particularly those in underdeveloped areas and finance.10 We define a dummy variable (Digitalin) that equals 1
those who have lower income. The new digital financial if a county's digitally inclusive finance development level is
businesses, represented by financial services that rely on higher than the sample median of the index of digitally inclu-
internet technology companies through information technology sive finance, and 0 otherwise. Then, we add Digitalin, an
and product innovation, reduce the cost of financial services interaction term of Digitalin, and an explanatory variable to our
and expands the ability to engage in financial activities. baseline model to test our hypothesis.11
Therefore, new digital financial businesses are the primary We report the results in Table 11, showing that the signif-
source of inclusive finance. Even in the absence of physical icantly positive impact of Confucian culture on informal
facilities, such as bank branches and ATMs, customers in some household financing is stronger when the degree of digitally
areas can still obtain needed financial services with electronic inclusive finance development in a county is higher. The esti-
devices, such as computers and mobile phones. mated coefficients of Diglgnacademy and Digdensityaca
The development of digitally inclusive finance might remain significantly positive. The empirical result supports our
reduce households’ reliance on formal financial institutions contention that a higher degree of digitally inclusive finance
and instruments and increase consensus about integrity and development can strengthen the positive association between
compliance by reducing information asymmetry and trans-
action costs, extending the positive influence of traditional
culture on informal financing activities. This mechanism im- 10
The Peking University Digital Financial Inclusion Index of China is con-
plies that the positive relationship between Confucian culture structed from the perspective of the breadth of digital finance coverage, the
and informal household financing should be significantly depth of digital finance use, and the degree of digitization of inclusive finance.
strengthened in regions with higher development of digitally This comprehensive index consists of three dimensions and 33 specific
inclusive finance. indicators.
11
The approach based on an interaction term, rather than seemingly unrelated
To test our conjecture, we employ the index of digitally estimation based on the group samples, is employed here because the number of
inclusive finance compiled by the Institute of Digital Finance at households in the group with a low level of digitally inclusive finance is not large
Peking University for the development of digitally inclusive enough for using a seemingly unrelated estimation based on the sample groups.

1016
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

Table 12
Geographic heterogeneity analysis based on seemingly unrelated estimations.
Privatefin Privatodebt Privatefin Privatodebt
Lgnacademy for western −0.008 (0.150) −0.652**(0.302) Densityaca for Western China −0.241 (0.509) −0.021 (0.301)
China
Lgnacademy for other regions 0.437***(0.144) 0.722***(0.135) Densityaca for other regions 0.092*** (0.035) 0.093** (0.040)
All control variables Yes Yes All control variables Yes Yes
County dummies Yes Yes County dummies Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes Year dummies Yes Yes
N 908 279 N 908 279
Note: The first dependent variable is informal household financing involvement, Privatefin, defined as a dummy variable that equals 1 if the household is involved in
informal family borrowing, and 0 otherwise. The second dependent variable is the ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt, Privatodebt. Explanatory
variables are the logarithm of the number of academies in a county, Lgnacademy, during the Tang, Song, Yuan, Ming, and Qing dynasties and the density of
academies in a county, Densityaca, respectively. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Standard errors are clustered at the
county level in the seemingly unrelated estimations.

Table 13
Business environment heterogeneity analysis based on seemingly unrelated estimations.
Privatefin Privatodebt Privatefin Privatodebt
Lgnacademy for high-level 0.424*** (0.136) 0.612*** (0.133) Densityaca for high-level 0.096*** (0.033) 0.110*** (0.042)
business environment business environment
Lgnacademy for low-level 0.228 (0.425) 0.274 (0.635) Densityaca for low-level −0.018 (0.198) 0.240 (0.173)
business environment business environment
All control variables Yes Yes All control variables Yes Yes
County dummies Yes Yes County dummies Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes Year dummies Yes Yes
N 908 279 908 279
Note: The first dependent variable is informal household financing involvement, Privatefin, defined as a dummy variable that equals 1 if the household is involved in
informal family borrowing, and 0 otherwise. The second dependent variable is the ratio of private loan arrears to total household debt, Privatodebt. Explanatory
variables are the logarithm of the number of academies in a county, Lgnacademy, during the Tang, Song, Yuan, Ming, and Qing dynasties and the density of a
county's academies, Densityaca, respectively. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Standard errors are clustered at the
county level in the seemingly unrelated estimations.

Confucian culture and informal household financing, which other than those in western China. The coefficient estimates of
further confirms our main hypothesis. our explanatory variables for various groups significantly
differ. The Breusch–Pagan independence tests for the error
5.2. Geographic heterogeneity analysis terms of various estimation equations confirm the inference
efficiency of the seemingly unrelated estimations. Additionally,
We preliminarily confirm the significantly positive impact the χ2 test results for the differences in coefficient estimates
of Confucian culture on informal household financing, and this reveal that these differences are all significant, at a level of at
impact is expected to be stronger in regions where Chinese least 10 percent.
traditional culture is well preserved. Deng (1999) and Ma
(2008) assert that cultural heritage and customs are preserved 5.3. Business environment heterogeneity analysis
to a greater degree in southern China than in western China,
which historically experienced more frequent wars and in- Formal institutions, consisting of laws, rules, and regula-
vasions.12 If we combine this with official contemporary tions, are closely related to the local business environment. A
geographic divisions, we conjecture that the positive relation- better local business environment effectively augments the
ship between Confucian culture and informal household influence of formal institutions over informal institutions, such
financing might not be as strong in western China as in other as traditional culture. In light of their mutual reinforcement
regions. (Ménard & Shirley, 2008), we expect the impact of Confucian
According to Equation (1), and employing a seemingly culture on informal household financing to be more pro-
unrelated estimation, we test our assumption. Table 12 reports nounced in counties with a better business environment.13
the results, showing that informal household financing, whether Table 13 presents the results of our business environment
represented by Privatefin or Privatodebt, is significantly posi- heterogeneity analysis.
tively affected by Confuciancul, primarily among households

12 13
The western region includes Chongqing, Gansu, Guangxi, Guizhou, Inner It is hard to imagine that traditional culture could work alone, without basic
Mongolia, Ningxia, Qinghai, Shaanxi, Sichuan, Tibet, Xinjiang, and Yunnan. assurances from informal institutions.

1017
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

The local business environment is proxied by a logarithm of business environments. Our empirical results are confirmed
the amount of foreign capital investment in each prefecture. We through several robustness checks.
then divide the counties in our sample into two groups, high- Our findings have meaningful policy implications. In the
and low-level business environments, using a split point of the process of accelerated work on the modernization trans-
sample median of the business environment variable. The formation, maintaining cultural traditions in China, a large
Breusch–Pagan independence tests for the error terms of emerging economy characterized by an underdeveloped
various estimation equations confirm the inference efficiency of financial system, might significantly reduce transaction costs
the seemingly unrelated estimations, supporting our assump- and information asymmetry and promote further development
tions.14 The impacts of Confucian culture on informal house- of informal finance to reduce the gap in the supply and demand
hold financing are far more pronounced in regions with a better for financial services and raise allocative efficiency in financial
business environment. resources. Finally, the impact of traditional culture documented
in this paper might not be limited to China. It would be
5.4. Additional robustness checks promising and interesting to investigate whether culturally
based factors in other countries, in a broad sense, also have an
We conduct several additional robustness tests that are not impact on informal household financial activities.
presented here in detail for the sake of brevity, but they are
available upon request. First, we further incorporate the expec- Declaration of competing interest
tations of a household head about stock market quotations into our
baseline regression as a control variable. The expectations about None.
stock market quotations reflect a judgment about recent economic
trends that could affect household borrowing decisions. The Acknowledgements
empirical results are highly accordant, leading to the same con-
clusions as our earlier analysis. Second, our conclusions are We greatly appreciate the enlightenment, comments, and
robust to the inclusion of a dummy variable for whether a suggestions given by the anonymous referees, the editor, Ming
household is engaged in business activities as an additional Liu, Kong-lin Ke, Ding Chen, Maoyong Cheng, Rui Li, and the
control variable to capture changes in demand for financing. seminar participants at the School of Economics and Finance of
Finally, the variable for fiscal expenditure per capita in a county is Xi'an Jiaotong University. All errors remain our responsibility.
also controlled for. This variable partly reflects the power of
government intervention because data regarding the proportion of References
the state-owned economy at the county level is unobtainable.
These additional robustness checks all support our main results. Acemoglu, D., & Restrepo, P. (2022). Demographics and automation. The
Review of Economic Studies, 89(1), 1–44.
Ahamed, M. M., Ho, S. J., Mallick, S. K., & Matousek, R. (2021). Inclusive
6. Conclusion banking, financial regulation and bank performance: Cross-country evi-
dence. Journal of Banking & Finance, 124, 106055.
China, a large country with a long history and cultural tra- Al-Thaqeb, S. A., & Algharabali, B. G. (2019). Economic policy uncertainty: A
ditions, has achieved rapid economic growth in the past few literature review. The Journal of Economic Asymmetries, 20(C), Article
decades. The informal alternative financial sector in China has e00133.
Allen, F., Qian, J., & Gu, X. (2017). An overview of China's financial system.
played a significant role in supporting the growth of the most Annual Review of Financial Economics, 9, 191–231.
dynamic sector in the economy. This informal sector offers Allen, F., Qian, M., & Xie, J. (2019). Understanding informal financing.
more sources of financing for the private sector and house- Journal of Financial Intermediation, 39, 19–33.
holds, raising the efficiency of resource allocation in the entire Allen, F., Qian, J., Zhang, C., & Zhao, M. (2013). China's financial system:
economy. The study of household finance is a thriving, vibrant, Opportunities and challenges. In P. H. J. Fan, & R. Morck (Eds.), Capi-
talizing China, 63–143. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
and separate field, and a growing body of literature investigates Beshears, J., Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., & Madrian, B. C. (2018). Behavioral
the determinants of household financing activities. household finance. In B. D. Bernheim, S. DellaVigna, & D. Laibson (Eds.),
This study examines the impact of Confucian culture on Handbook of behavioral economics: Applications and foundations (Vol. 1,
informal household financing in China by counties. We pp. 177–276) (Amsterdam: North-Holland).
demonstrate that Confucian culture has a significant and posi- Bitar, M., Hassan, M. K., & Saad, W. (2020). Culture and the capital–performance
nexus in dual banking systems. Economic Modelling, 87, 34–58.
tive impact on informal household financing activities, and a Breuer, W., Riesener, M., & Salzmann, A. J. (2014). Risk aversion vs. indi-
higher degree of digitally inclusive finance development can vidualism: What drives risk taking in household finance? The European
strengthen the positive relation between Confucian culture and Journal of Finance, 20(5), 446–462.
informal household financing. This positive association appears Brunnermeir, M., & Nagel, S. (2008). Do wealth fluctuations generate time-
to be stronger in regions where Chinese traditional culture is varying risk aversion? Micro-evidence on individuals' asset allocation.
The American Economic Review, 98, 713–736.
well preserved and is more pronounced in regions with better Calvet, L. E., Campbell, J. Y., & Sodini, P. (2007). Down or out: Assessing the
welfare costs of household investment mistakes. Journal of Political
Economy, 115, 707–747.
Campbell, J. Y. (2006). Household finance. The Journal of Finance, 41(4),
14
The χ2 test results are also consistent with our expectation. 1553–1604.

1018
X. Hou, R. Yang and C. Liu _
Borsa Istanbul Review 22-5 (2022) 1005–1019

Chatla, S. B., & Shmueli, G. (2017). An extensive examination of regression Hilary, G., & Hui, K. W. (2009). Does religion matter in corporate decision
models with a binary outcome variable. Journal of the Association for making in America? Journal of Financial Economics, 93, 455–473.
Information Systems, 18(4), 340–371. Hünermund, P., & Louw, B. (2020). On the nuisance of control variables in
Chen, Y. J., Chen, Z., & He, S. (2019). Social norms and household savings regression analysis. arXiv preprint arXiv: 2005.10314.
rates in China. Review of Finance, 23(5), 961–991. Kandori, M. (1992). Social norms and community enforcement. The Review of
Chen, Z., Ma, C., & Sinclair, A. J. (2021). Banking on the Confucian clan: Economic Studies, 59, 63–80.
Why China developed financial markets so late. Economic Journal. https:// Karolyi, G. A. (2016). The gravity of culture for finance. Journal of Corporate
doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueab082. ueab082. Finance, 41, 610–625.
Chiuri, M. C., & Jappelli, T. (2002). Financial market imperfections and home Kung, J. K., & Ma, C. (2014). Can cultural norms reduce conflicts? Confu-
ownership: A comparative study. European Economic Review, 47, cianism and peasant rebellions in Qing China. Journal of Development
857–875. Economics, 111, 132–149.
Christiansen, C., Joensen, J. S., & Rangvid, J. (2008). Are economists more Liang, Z. (1996). Customary law in qing: Society and the state. Beijing:
likely to hold stocks. Review of Finance, 12, 465–496. Zhongguo Zhenfa University Press.
Chui, A. C. W., Titman, S., & Wei, K. C. J. (2010). Individualism and mo- Liao, L., Xiao, J. J., Zhang, W., & Zhou, C. (2017). Financial literacy and risky
mentum around the world. The Journal of Finance, 65, 361–392. asset holdings: Evidence from China. Accounting and Finance, 57,
Cinelli, C., Ferwerda, J., & Hazlett, C. (2020). SENSEMAKR: Stata module to 1383–1415.
provide sensitivity tools for OLS. Statistical Software Components (p. Li, R., Wang, T., & Zhou, M. (2021). Entrepreneurship and household portfolio
S458773). Boston College Department of Economics. choice: Evidence from the China household finance survey. Journal of
Cooper, R., & Zhu, G. (2018). Household finance in China. NBER Working Empirical Finance, 60, 1–15.
Paper No. 23741 http://www.nber.org/papers/w23741. Ma, D. (2008). Economic growth in the lower Yangzi region of China in 1911-
Cyganrehm, K., & Maeder, M. (2013). The effect of education on fertility: 1937: A quantitative and historical analysis. The Journal of Economic
Evidence from a compulsory schooling reform. Labour Economics, 25, History, 68, 355–392.
35–48. Ma, D. (2011). Law and economy in traditional China: A "legal origin"
Deng, K. G. (1999). The premodern Chinese economy: Structural equilibrium perspective on the great divergence. In D. Ma, & J. L. V. Zanden (Eds.),
and capitalist sterility. London: Routledge. Law and long-term economic change: A eurasian perspective (pp. 46–67).
Dynan, K. E., & Kohn, D. L. (2007). The rise in US household indebtedness, Stanford: Stanford University Press.
causes and consequences. Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 37, McCrary, J., & Royer, H. (2011). The effect of female education on fertility and
1–45. infant health: Evidence from school entry policies using exact date of birth.
Fagereng, A., Gottlieb, C., & Guiso, L. (2011). Asset market participation and The American Economic Review, 101, 158–195.
portfolio choice over the life-cycle. European University Institute. Working Ménard, C., & Shirley, M. M. (2008). Handbook of new institutional eco-
paper. nomics. Heidelberg: Springer.
Francis, J., Lennox, C., & Wang, Z. (2012). Selection models in accounting Nee, V., & Swedberg, R. (2008). Economic sociology and new institutional
research. The Accounting Review, 87(2), 589–616. economics. In C. Ménard, & M. M. Shirley (Eds.), Handbook of new
Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust. The social virtues and the creation of prosperity. institutional economics, 789–818. Heidelberg: Springer.
London: Hamish Hamilton. Niu, G., Wang, Q., Li, H., & Zhou, Y. (2020). Number of brothers, risk
Gan, L., Yin, Z., & Tan, J. (2016). Report on the development of household sharing, and stock market participation. Journal of Banking & Finance,
finance in rural China (2014). Singapore: Springer. 113, 105757.
Gao, M. (2019). No pain, no gain? Household beliefs and stock market Piazzesi, M., & Schneider, M. (2009). Momentum traders in the housing
participation. Economics Letters, 181, 81–84. market: Survey evidence and a search model. The American Economic
Goetzmann, W. N. (2016). Money changes everything: How finance made Review: Papers and Proceedings, 99, 406–411.
civilization possible. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Renneboog, L., & Spaenjers, C. (2012). Religion, economic attitudes, and
Gollier, C. (2006). Does ambiguity aversion reinforce risk aversion? Appli- household finance. Oxford Economic Papers, 64, 103–127.
cations to portfolio choices and asset prices. Mimeo: University of Shao, L., Kwok, C. C. Y., & Guedhami, O. (2008). Is national culture a
Toulouse. missing piece of the dividend puzzle? University of South Carolina.
Greene, W. H. (2017). Econometric analysis. Prentice Hall: Pearson Working Paper.
Education. Shiga, S. (2002). Law and adjudication in qing China (2nd ed.). Tokyo:
Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: Evidence on the Soubunsha.
Maghribi traders. The Journal of Economic History, 49, 857–882. Song, Y., Wu, W., & Zhou, G. (2020). Inequality of opportunity and household
Greif, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early risky asset investment: Evidence from panel data in China. China Economic
trade: The Maghribi traders. The American Economic Review, 83, Review, 63, 101513.
525–547. Trinh, C. T., Nguyen, X., Sgro, P., & Pham, C. S. (2020). Culture, financial
Greif, A., & Tabellini, G. (2017). The clan and the corporation: Sustaining crisis and the demand for property, accident and health insurance in the
cooperation in China and Europe. Journal of Comparative Economics, OECD countries. Economic Modelling, 93, 480–498.
45(1), 1–35. Tufano, P. (2009). Consumer finance. Annual Review of Financial Economics,
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2006). Does culture affect economic 1, 227–247.
outcomes? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2), 23–48. Udry, C. (1994). Risk and insurance in a rural credit market: An empirical
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Trusting the stock market. The investigation in northern Nigeria. The Review of Economic Studies, 61,
Journal of Finance, 63, 2557–2600. 495–526.
Guiso, L., & Sodini, P. (2013). Household finance: An emerging field. In Williamson, R. (2010). The role of culture in finance. In H. K. Baker, &
G. M. Constantinides, M. Harris, & R. M. Stulz (Eds.), Vol. 2. Handbook of J. R. Nofsinger (Eds.), Behavioral finance: Investors, corporations, and
the economics of finance (pp. 1397–1532). Amsterdam: Elsevier/North markets, 631–646. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.
Holland. Yao, R., & Zhang, H. (2005). Optimal consumption and portfolio choices with
Hamilton, G. G. (1996). The organization foundations of westsern and Chinese risky housing and borrowing constraints. Review of Financial Studies, 18,
commerce: A historical and comparative analysis. In G. G. Hamilton (Ed.), 197–239.
Asia business networks. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter. Yuchtman, N. (2017). Teaching to the tests: An economic analysis of tradi-
Hellevik, O. (2009). Linear versus logistic regression when the dependent tional and modern education in late imperial and Republican China. Ex-
variable is a dichotomy. Quality and Quantity, 43, 59–74. plorations in Economic History, 63, 70–90.

1019

You might also like