You are on page 1of 14

Group Dynamics: Theory.

Research, and Practice © 2013 American Rsychological Association


2013. Vol. 17. No. 2. 124-136 t089-269W13/$12.00 DOI: 10.1037/a0O31346

A New Perspective on Coalitions: What Motivates Membership?

Christopher J. Meyer
Baylor University

The author seeks to advance coalition theories by integrating the idea of prevention-
and promotion-focused motivation from psychology and the activation of a gain or loss
frame by the group. This frame is then applied to explain the effects on four classic
outcomes: size of the coalition, membership of the coalition, distribution of the
outcomes within the coalition, and stability or duration of the coalition.

Keywords: coalitions, regulatory focus theory, decision making

It has long been asserted that organizational coalition formation that allows for multiple in-
goals are determined through the behavior and teractions over time, nonrational behavior, and
decisions of coalitions (Cyert & March, 1963; information asymmetry. This view adds to the
Thompson, 1967). Coalitions have always ex- previous game theoretic views of coalitions and
isted within organizations (Gamson, 196Í), but will inform scholars about the operation of co-
the shift away from the hierarchical, militaristic alitions outside of a purely economic context.
organization to a fiat, egalitarian, knowledge- My goal in this article is to extend and inte-
based stmcture (Cappelli, 1999) has thmst co- grate the previous application of coalitions from
alitions into prominence as an important deter- varied fields to the field of organizational be-
minant of organizational outcomes. Although havior. I draw from sociology, social psychol-
the coalition is an important means of making ogy, psychology, and organizational behavior to
decisions and directing the organization (Ko- build a theory of coalitions that is more broad
morita & Parks, 1995; Thompson, 1967), the and explanatory of the impact of the motivation
idea of coalitions has been studied very little, for coalitions on the process. I begin by defining
and what little has been done have been labo- the term coalition. Lack of a consistent defini-
ratory experiments that have been very limited tion has led to some disparity and difficulty in
in scope (Stevenson, Pearce, & Porter, 1985) the study of coalitions, and this definition is
and have focused on the economic value of meant to contribute stability to the meaning of
particular coalitions. Stevenson and colleagues coalition. Second, I introduce motivation to
(1985) point out that the previous research on form a coalition and how this may impact the
coalitions has limited generalizability to orga- coalition. Finally, I introduce several important
nizations because organizational actors have outcomes of the coalitional process and make
both a history and a future together, which is not predictions about the impact of the differences
taken into account by the myriad previous the- based on the motivation of the coalition.
ories of coalitions. In addition, empirical work
in the area of coalitions generally focuses on a
single interaction, economic rationality, and Definition of Coalition and Review of
perfect information (Lopes, Santos, & Teles, Literature
2009; Mumighan & Brass, 1991; Shellshear &
Sudholter, 2009). Building on these two short- Definition
falls in the literature, I propose a theory of
Some confusion stems from the similarity
between coalitions and small groups, informal
groups and work teams. Coalitions are similar
to these more familiar entities. Small groups, a
This article was published Online First February 11, 2013. term that is used to describe these various other
Correspondence concerning this article should be ad-
dressed to Christopher J. Meyer, Department of Manage- groups, are an important means of directing
ment, Baylor University, One Bear Place #98006, Waco, organizations (Levine & Moreland, 1998).
TX 76798-8006. E-mail: christopher_meyer@bayior.edu Small groups have been studied extensively
124
A NEW PERSPECTIVE ON COALITIONS 125

from the standpoint of work teams, formal gain. Tbis is the definition that is generally used
groups, and informal groups, both in the labo- in the literature to define coalitional behavior.
ratory and in the field. However, small groups Levine and Moreland (1998) define a coali-
differ from coalitions in several ways, most tion as "subsets of members [that] agree to
significantly in visibility (Mumighan & Brass, cooperate in order to secure mutually desired
1991). Small groups operate with the sanction outcomes" (p. 432). This definition differs in
of management, and are generally put in place that it assumes that the benefit will imbue to
hy management, either directly or through the multiple parties, rather than a single party, to the
norms of the organization. Most coalitions are coalition. Levine and Moreland remove the idea
not sanctioned; other organizational members that if one (or more) party(s) benefit, the other
may not even know that coalitions exist because parties will be negatively impacted. Rather,
they take place outside of the view of manage- they propose in their definition that the outcome
ment (and organizational researchers) and are is desired by multiple parties and can be shared
therefore difficult if not impossible to observe by multiple parties. By working together in a
(Mumighan, 1978). Coalitions, by nature, oper- coalition, the benefits increase. This is a differ-
ate outside the organizational structure, with ence from the "zero-sum" perspective of Thi-
coalition members building support and negoti- baut and Kelley (1959). Where the Thibaut and
ating distribution of outcomes independent of Kelley perspective put a negative connotation
the organizational hierarchy. Many coalitions on the idea of coalition, the Levine and More-
may never meet as an identifiable unit, but land perspective is a more neutral perspective.
rather meetings take place hetween dyads or
triads (Mumighan & Brass, 1991). Because of A third perspective is proposed by Stevenson
the hidden nature of coalitions and the lack of et al. (1985), who define coalitions as
an easily identifiable membership, many of the an interacting group of individuals, deliberately con-
previous studies of coalitions have been labora- structed, independent of the formal structure, lacking
tory based, game theoretic, and short term in its own internal formal stracture, consisting of a mu-
nature. tually perceived membership, issue oriented, focused
on a goal or goals external to the coalition, and requir-
The new outlook on coalitions proposed here ing concerted member action, (p. 261)
builds on several definitions of coalitions de-
scribed in the literature. The first defitiition that I This is a much more comprehensive defini-
consider was proposed hy Thibaut and KeUey tion. This view of coalitions differs from the
(1959). This definition describes a coalition as previous two views. Stevenson et al. provide us
"two or more persons (or groups) acting jointly to with the view that coalitions are calculated and
affect the outcomes of one or more persons"(Thi- highly developed forms of organization tbat de-
haut & Kelley, 1959, p. 205). This definition im- velop with an intention and purpose.
plies that two (or more) of the parties to the Building on these previous definitions for
coalition are engaged in a collusive arrangement coalitions, I propose the following definition: A
to the benefit of one (or more) party(s) and to the coalition is an interacting group of individu-
detriment of the remaining parties. The use of this als—the totality of which is not known to those
definition has led to many of the economic outside of the coalition (and may not be known
models of coalition behavior (Gamson, 1961; to those inside the coalition)—deliberately con-
Komorita & Chertkoff, 1973). This definition structed, independent of the formal organiza-
relies on a "zero-sum" perspective; that is, one tional structure, focused on a goal or goals
party will gain at the expense of another party. extemal to the coalition, and requiring con-
This would lead the individual members of a certed member action with the intent of bene-
coalition to different ideas about who they will fiting certain members of the coalition.
include in a coalition, how many members, who An interacting group of individuals—the
gets what if the coalition is successful, and how totality of which is not known to those out-
long to endure in the coalition. If the individuals side of the coalition (and may not be known
presume that there is a fixed amount of re- to those inside the coalition). First, a coali-
sources, there will he a definite effect on the tion must be made up of individuals who inter-
formation and duration of a coalition, assuming act. This does not mean that the individuals will
that each individual will attempt to maximize meet as a whole. In fact, coalitions will rarely
126 MEYER

meet, relying on meetings between dyads and Kelley, 1959). This shared interest is an impor-
triads to decide on direction and build consen- tant distinction between a coalition and a group
sus (Mumighan & Brass, 1991). This allows the that is formed by organizational mandate. The
coalition to operate outside the formal structure groups that are formed by the organization may
of the organization. If the coalition were out in have a shared goal through the mandate, but not
the open, the organization could take steps to necessarily through the shared interest of the
influence the coalition or impact the member- members of the group. The coalition, by defi-
ship. Given the clandestine nature of the coali- nition, will share this goal, not because there is
tion, the entire membership is rarely known to some external body or superior requiring this
the organization and just as rarely known to the goal focus, but rather because the coalition
members of the coalition. There are even argu- members believe it is important and worth pur-
ments that revealing all of the connections suing the goal.
would cause great harm to the organization as a Requiring concerted member action.
whole (Gallicano, 2009). Even the individual Within the coalition, the members must contrib-
who set out to form the coalition may not know ute some action or activity to the coalition (Ste-
the membership if other members recruited in- venson et al., 1985). This activity could be an
dividuals into the coalition without his or her individual activity that supports the agenda of
knowledge (Mumighan & Brass, 1991). This is the coalition or some coordinated group effort
one very important difference between a coali- (Bottom, 2001). This action could also include
tion and a small group. In most small groups, bypassing or refraining from some action in
the membership is known and the group meets which the coalition member would otherwise
in its entirety on numerous occasions to achieve have participated.
goals or complete tasks. With the intent of benefiting certain mem-
Deliberately constructed. A coalition bers of the coalition in the process. The goal
must be created by its membership (Stevenson of a coalition is to increase the influence beyond
et al., 1985). If the group is mandated or formed what could be accomplished by an individual
through the typical organizational structuring (Lopes et al., 2009; Stevenson et al., 1985). The
process, then it is a small group (or work team), intent of the coalition is to affect outcomes and
not a coalition. The coalition is self-forming. provide an advantage or positive effect to the
Independent of the formal organizational coalition or a member of the coalition (Mur-
structure. The coalition operates outside the nighan, 1978). This definition does not preclude
formal organizational structure (Murnighan, the opportunity for the benefit to flow to all
1978; Stevenson et al., 1985). Any group man- members of the coalition, to the organization, or
dated by the organization will also be required to individuals (or parties) excluded from the
to follow the organizational goals and work coalition. Rather, the coalition has every oppor-
toward organizational outcomes. As I argue in tunity to benefit others that are outside of the
the next section, the coalition will be focused on coalition. The important factor is that the coali-
its own goals rather than the goals of the orga- tion would not form without the opportunity to
nization. The coalition also needs the freedom benefit at least one member of the coalition.
to form. As noted above, the coalition is created
by its membership, not by the formal structure Earlier Theories of Coalitions
of the organization. Entities created by the for-
mal structure would be small groups, work Much of the previous work on coalitions has
teams, or departments (Levine & Moreland, been limited in scope; for example, Bacharach
1998; Stevenson et al, 1985). and Lawler (1980) and many others focused
Focused on a goal or goals external to the only on the triad. In the realm of organizational
coalition. A coalition will not form except to behavior, coalitions have been studied in the
pursue a goal. This goal or issue is the impetus context of negotiations (Bottom, Holloway,
for the coalition. Past scholars have agreed that McClurg, & Miller, 2000; Polzer, Mannix, &
the coalition must have a reason to exist and to Neale, 1998), as well as a more psychological
go through the process of forming and acting outlook (Pearce & DeNisi, 1983) that applied
(Bacharach & Law 1er, 1980; Murnighan & attribution theory to the formation of coalitions.
Brass, 1991; Stevenson et al., 1985; Thibaut & Other work has applied a game theoretic or
A NEW PERSPECTIVE ON COALITIONS 127

economic viewpoint to coalition formation in an proposed above. For example, for the distribu-
organizational context (Bottom, 2001; Bottom, tion of outcomes to conform to an equity prin-
Eavey, & Miller, 1996; Murnighan & Brass, ciple, all coalition members would need to
1991). Theories have generally focused on the know not only who else is involved in the
players and the coalition that would form, with coalition, but also the amount of resources that
limited work concerning the distribution of each person contributed. Anything less would
outcomes. amount to an inequitable distribution because of
Past scholars focused on the potential size of the lack of referent others to determine whether
the coalition (Gamson, 1961; Riker, 1962). equity was being enforced (Adams, 1965),
Gamson's (1961) minimum resource theory These views also ignore many other aspects of
predicts not only the coalition that may form, the definition of coalitions, such as the lack of
but also the payoff to each member, based on visibility, concerted member action, and the
economic rationality. Gamson predicts that the presence of a collective goal.
coalition that forms will control the least
amount of resources necessary to form a major- More Recent Views of Coalitions
ity and that the members will determine the
outcomes using an equity-like principle. That is, Bottom and colleagues (Bottom, 2001; Bot-
the distribution is based on the relative percent- tom et al., 1996; Bottom et al., 2000) have
age of resources contributed to the coalition. focused on the economic aspects of coalition
Similarly, Riker's (1962) size principle states formation such as the formation of the core
that the minimum winning coalition will form. coalition needed to win, the influence of norms
Riker focuses on the individuals in the coalition, on the coalition, and quota shaving, which is
such that if one member were removed from the how individuals negotiate the payoff and join a
coalition, they would no longer control the coalition based on the economic outcome. Al-
amount of resources necessary to win (Mur- though this view is greatly improved over the
nighan, 1978). Riker did acknowledge that the prior iterations of economic or game theoretic
coalition members may not have the informa- views of coalitions, it is still more limited in
tion that would allow them to determine the scope. Bottom has focused on the rational or
minimum winning size and, therefore, coali- mathematical view of coalitions while greatly
tions that were larger than the minimum win- improving theory by incorporating such ad-
ning size were not only possible, but also heav- vances as coalitional history, social constraints
ily dependent on the amount and the quality of (Bottom et al., 1996), risk preferences (Bottom
information available to coalition members. et al., 2000), and cognitive illusions (Bottom,
2001). These studies add an important element
Bargaining theory introduced a negotiated into the previous theories of coalition forma-
group (Komorita & Chertkoff, 1973) as the ba- tion. Bottom's work includes some of the non-
sis for coalition formation. Komorita and Chert- economic factors that are important to coali-
koff (1973) predicted that individuals would use tions, but are absent from the previous theories.
alternative coalitions as threats during the bar-
gaining process. They also predicted a distribu- Past theories of coalition formation assume
tion of outcomes that tended toward equality. that coalitions will form for either short-term or
Individuals that formed a coalition under bar- one-shot processes such that individuals will
gaining theory were thought to be maximizers coalesce, act, and disband (Murnighan & Brass,
of individual outcome, but would also form a 1991). Individuals will join, maximize value,
coalition only if the outcome was somewhere and not worry about others or repercussions—
between equity (based on what each member because there is no tomorrow.
contributes to the coalition) and equality.
Although these views of coalition formation Motivations for Coaiitions
give a baseline for the phenomena, they are not
realistic in an organizational sense because of In this article, I propose that individuals or
the bounded rationality of the individuals in- groups will form coalitions for two different
volved in the coalition as well as other factors motivations—for preservation or promotion.
that may impact the coalition. The earlier views Higgins (1997) builds on the hedonic principle
of coalitions do not agree with the definition and theorizes that individuals will be motivated
128 MEYER

in different situations by either a prevention to develop the theory at a simple level and
focus or a promotion focus. This view is built expand it in future empirical studies that could
on prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, allow the motivation of the group to vary natu-
1979; Tversky & Kahneman, 1992). A preven- rally. However, these extreme cases may not be
tion focus is characterized by a concern for entirely fictitious. A coalition generally has a
safety and protection. A promotion focus is single founder, coupled with more joiners (Mur-
characterized by a concern for advancement and nighan & Brass, 1991). The founder of the
growth. These foci can be applied to long-term coalition could very easily, and very likely
activations of motivation or to momentary situ- would, control the motivation as members join
ations (Higgins, 1997). Keltner, Gruenfeld, and the coalition. The coalition builds incremen-
Anderson (2003) link the prevention motivation tally, adding a single member at a time (Mur-
with a loss frame and the promotion motivation nighan & Brass, 1991); therefore, the frame can
with a gain frame. That is, those with a preven- be controlled by the founder.
tion focus will adopt a loss frame, and those As each new member joins the coalition,
with a promotion focus will adopt a gain frame. the founder would apply the motivation by
The frame placed on a situation is known to saying, "Something important to us is at risk"
cause differential reaction, even if the economic to activate the prevention motivation and the
value is the same, independent of the frame loss frame, or "We have something to gain
(Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). with this action" to activate a promotion mo-
Regulatory focus theory (Higgins, 1997) ex- tivation and gain frame. This possibility is left
tends the hedonic principle by taking the plea- to be empirically tested at a later time and for
sure-seeking and pain-avoiding viewpoint a bit the purposes of this article, I assume a group-
further. Not only do individuals approach plea- level motivation.
sure and avoid pain, but the ways in which they As indicated above, this focus, whether pre-
do this are substantially different from one an- vention or promotion, could be something that
other. Individuals can take on either a promo- is a persistent trait-like chronic outlook. That is,
tion focus or a prevention focus. The promotion every time an individual is involved in an in-
focus is characterized by sensitivity to positive teraction that leads to a coalition, s/he takes on
outcomes, approach strategies, and taking risks the same focus—whether prevention or promo-
to ensure hits rather than commit errors of omis- tion. Alternatively, this focus can be more situ-
sion. A promotion focus is characterized by a ationally induced. An individual could take on a
concem for advancement and growth. Con- specific focus based on the desired outcome of
versely, the prevention focus is one that pre- the interaction. Those potential outcomes are
scribes that negative outcomes will be salient, the subject of this article.
avoidance strategies will dominate, and there Preservation motives for forming coalitions
will be more risk aversion to ensure against have been well reported in earlier work (Mur-
errors of commission. A prevention focus is nighan, 1978). Much of this earlier work builds
characterized by a concern for safety and pro- on a self-preservation outlook based on the
tection. An individual can have a chronic, or work of Simmel (1955), which contends that
trait-like, focus in either promotion or preven- individuals will form a coalition to defend
tion, but also be placed into a temporary state of against a threat or to gain some resources that
promotion or prevention based on the situation they may be in jeopardy of losing. I posit that
or context. individuals will also form coalitions for promo-
I focus on how this differential motivation tion reasons—that is, to make a preemptive
can cause different outcomes in the coalition strike on the resources that they need or want or
through the activation of a gain or loss frame. In to quash a threat before it arises. This is not a
this initial work, I assume a homogeneous completely foreign idea in the literature of co-
group in regard to motivation, that is, I focus on operation and group action. Others have pro-
the extremes. I assume that a group will share a posed a proactive motivation when it serves
collective motivation, that the average or aggre- self-interest (Lopes et al., 2009).
gate motivation of the group will be either a Differential motivation in forming coalitions
prevention or promotion focus. Although this is is only interesting if this causes differences in
unlikely to happen in organizations, it is useful outcomes. In this article, I focus on the differ-
A NEW PERSPECTIVE ON COALITIONS 129

enees that can be produced in four areas based how this frame will affect the distribution of the
on motivation (see Table 1). These four out- outcome.
comes have been the subject of theory and dis- Finally, the stability or endurance of the co-
cussion in many previous papers. The first im- alition will also be affected by the different
portant outcome from the formation stage is the motivations. Mumighan and Brass (1991) argue
number of members in the coalition, or the size. for the importance of duration when consider-
Size has been predicted to vary based on the ing coalitions in organizations. Individuals
minimum needed to win (Gamson, 1961 ; Riker, within organizations have not only a past with
1962) or the minimum impact on the projected coalitional partners, but also a future to take into
payout (Komorita & Chertkoff, 1973). The size account when operating in coalitions. I propose
of the coalition is important to managers who that the motivation, which activates the framing
are trying to manage a situation that is being for the coalition, will affect the stability or the
driven by a powerful coalition. How many in- duration of the coalition differently in each case
dividuals are attempting to influence an out- (see Figure 1).
come? What would be the impact of opposing
the coalition? How many people are attempting Prevention-Versus Promotion-Motivated
to affect the organization? The size is also im- Coalitions
portant to the members of the coalition. The
larger the coalition, the smaller each person's Scholars have argued for a differential moti-
share of the outcome will be of the outcome. As vational scheme of prevention and promotion
the coalition increases in size, the distribution focus extending the pleasure-seeking and pain-
of the outcome will flow to more individuals avoidance motivation (Anderson & Berdahl,
and the size of each member's portion will 2002; Higgins, 1997; Higgins, Shah, & Fried-
decrease. man, 1997; Keltner et al., 2003). This difference
An important attribute of the coalition that in motivation applies in situations that can be
follows from the size and has been discussed classified as momentary or temporary, as well
in much of the previous literature (Gamson, as a more stable trait-like attribute (Higgins,
1961; Komorita & Chertkoff, 1973; Mur- 1997). Individuals can react to a situation in one
nighan, 1978) is the membership of the coali- of two ways. One possible activation is a pre-
tion. Different motivations will affect the vention focus. The prevention focus will be
membership differently. activated by a threat; this threat will lead to
Another important factor in the study of co- security needs or the need to protect an individ-
alitions is the distribution of the resources or ual or some resource. This focus becomes im-
outcomes that will be affected by the motivation portant in a loss-nonloss situation. That is,
of the coalition. Distribution has been explicitly when some resource is threatened and the op-
predicted (Gamson, 1961; Riker, 1962) in past portunity is present to lose the resource or to
theories that have been based on the economic retain the use of the resource, a prevention focus
function of the coalition. Past predictions have will be activated (Higgins, 1997). Keltner and
been limited by a game theoretic viewpoint. I colleagues (2003) theorize that this prevention
consider how the motivation for the coalition— focus will then activate a loss frame. The loss
either prevention or promotion—will activate a frame of the situation will cause losses to loom
gain frame or a loss frame in the coalition and larger (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979), a sensi-

Table 1
Four Outcome Areas Based on Motivation in Coalition Formation
Motivation Size Membership Distribution Duration
Prevention Larger than the Similarity: demography, Based on an equity principle Until the objective is reached
minimum skills, knowledge
Promotion Minimum Complementary: Based on bargained Will endure past the
winning size demography, skills, outcomes tending toward accomplishment of the
knowledge equality objective
130 MEYER

Figure 1. Proposed relationships between motivation, frame, and coalition outcomes.

tivity to negative outcomes, and avoidant be- Size of the Coalition


havior (Keltner et al, 2003). This prevention
focus, when applied to coalitions, will have an The bargaining theory of coalition formation
effect on the outcomes of size, membership, (Komorita & Chertkoff, 1973) as well as Rik-
distribution of outcomes, and stability or dura- er's (1962) size principle and Gamson's (1961)
tion of the coalition. minimum resource theory make predictions for
In contrast, a promotion focus is activated one-shot or short-term coalitions. These theo-
by an opportunity; this opportunity will lead ries have in common the ability of members to
join and exit as needed, but do not consider
to the need for growth or advancement. The
history or future interactions. Bargaining theory
promotion focus is salient in situations that
(Komorita & Chertkoff, 1973) states that indi-
are presented as gain-nongain. That is, when
viduals will be added to the coalition as needed
the opportunity to better oneself is present
to win and that the individuals will be offered
and there is the possibility to gain some re-
enough that the coalition is attractive, but not so
source or not, a promotion focus will he ac- much that the existing members of the coalition
tivated (Higgins, 1997). Keltner and col- will lose any economic value hy adding the
leagues (2003) theorize that this promotion member. Riker's size principle states that the
focus will then activate a gain frame. The gain minimum number of individuals needed to
frame of the situation will cause a greater win will come together, and no more. Gam-
sensitivity to positive outcomes and approach son's minimum resource theory looks at the
behavior (Keltner et al., 2003). This promo- resources needed to win rather than the num-
tion focus, when applied to coalitions, will ber of players. Minimum resource theory
have an effect on the outcomes of size, mem- states that the individuals who control the
bership, distribution of the outcome, and sta- minimum amount of resources necessary to
bility or duration of the coalition. win will form the coalition.
As the coalition is built in response to a
Proposition 1: (a) The stronger the preven- threat, with the prevention motivation, the loss
tion motivation, the stronger the loss fram- frame will be activated. The loss will loom
ing, (b) The stronger the promotion moti- largely for the coalition and an avoidance he-
vation, the stronger the gain framing. havior and sensitivity to negative outcomes
A NEW PERSPECTIVE ON COALITIONS 131

(Keltner et al., 2003) will cause the coalition to study were more likely to reverse their loss
attempt to protect the resources that are being aversion when small amounts of money were
threatened. This protection mechanism will im- concerned. They reported more satisfaction in
pact the size of the coalition. The prevention receiving a small amount of money than they
motivation is activated by uncertainty (Keltner did in losing a small amount of money. Taken
et al., 2003), and as Riker (1962) tells us, due to together, this would indicate that in the case of
the uncertainty of the outcome, the size of a small amounts of money—and broadened to
coalition will continue to increase past the min- small outcomes—individuals are more likely to
imum size originally predicted, van Beest, van be motivated to share this with a larger group.
Dijk, De Drue, and Wilke (2005) studied the However, there is no evidence that when faced
size issue in a different way. They found that with distribution of a large outcome, individuals
when there was an actual loss in a coalition will put self-interest behind them and grow the
decision-making exercise, the coalition grew to coalition to a larger size.
a larger size to share the loss with more indi- In a coalition, the person who forms the co-
viduals. Because losses loom larger than gains alition or asks individuals to join the coalition is
(Tversky & Kahneman, 1992), the coalition, in a position of weakness—due to the apparent
which operates in a condition of uncertainty, dependence on the other party (Mumighan &
will then expand to reduce the uncertainty and Brass, 1991). For that reason in a gain-framed
hedge for the prevention of the loss. As the size coalition, it will be less likely that the coalition
increases, the uncertainty will decrease, until will surpass the minimum winning size. Rather,
the outcome is known, at which point there will the coalition will follow Riker's (1962) mini-
no longer be any uncertainty and the coalition mum winning size principle.
will cease to expand. Proposition 3: The stronger the gain framing,
Proposition 2: The stronger the loss framing, the smaller the coalition.
the larger the coalition.
In a coalition that is formed based on the Membership of the Coalition
promotion motivation, the gain ñ-ame will be
activated. Because losses loom larger than Again, the prevention motivation of the co-
gains, there will be less motivation to try to alition will cause a loss frame, which will lead
expand the coalition. The gain frame is acti- to more concern with safety and preservation
vated by opportunity (Keltner et al., 2003). The (Keltner et al., 2003). Individuals will also be
coalition will face less uncertainty and will more likely to coalesce with individuals who
build to confront this uncertainty, but because have a similar interest (Polzer et al., 1998).
this is a gain-framed situation, there will not be Simmel (1955) reported that individuals will
the same urgency as a loss-framed situation, coalesce if they share a common mood, such as
causing the coalition to be smaller. There will the solidarity of workers trying to improve
also be less uncertainty in a coalition that is working conditions. In a second line of thought
motivated in a promotion focus, van Beest et al. proposed by Simmel, individuals of similar ed-
(2005) examined this phenomenon in the con- ucation or background will join in aversion to
text of the payoff valence in multiparty negoti- other individuals or groups that may offend
ation. They found that individuals who were them, van Beest, van Dijk, and Wilke (2004b)
concerned with the perspective of others were examined the formation issue in coalitions as a
not willing to "do harm" to them. That is, those function of resources and altematives. They
who were concerned with others shared out- found that individuals with more altematives
comes with more individuals, thus growing the for coalition formation were more likely to de-
coalition. The research was conducted with mand a premium to join a coalition. However,
small outcomes available; therefore, self- this self-serving did not hold for those individ-
interest was less important to the individuals uals who maintained control over more re-
than was fairness. In a similar study, Harinck, sources than others. Having more altematives
van Dijk, van Beest, and Mersmann (2007) leads individuals to demand a premium, making
found that when the amount of money available them more difficult to bring into the coalition.
in the final outcome was small, individuals re- Having more alternative coalitions that one
versed their loss aversion. Participants in the can join is indicative of a person who has
!32 MEYER

membership in wide and varied groups. Distribution of the Outcomes


Therefore, these persons are likely more di-
verse. In a loss-framed coalition, these indi- Distribution of outcomes is an area that has
viduals are less likely to be approached to join been focused on in a number of theoretical and
the coalition because they will demand a pre- empirical papers. Because we are concerned
mium. Similarly, those individuals who are with what we get out of an interaction, the
able to facilitate an equitable outcome are distribution of outcomes moves to the forefront
more likely to be brought into the coalition of many decisions about whether or not to form
(van Beest, van Dijk, & Wilke, 2004a). coalitions. Certainly, the motivation and fram-
Therefore, those with similar concerns for ing of the situation play a roll in the way the
equity are likely to join in a coalition. outcomes are distributed. The bargaining theory
of coalition formation (Komorita & Chertkoff,
In addition, the loss frame is connected with
1973) as well as Riker's (1962) size principle
more risk-seeking behavior. Building a coali- and Gamson's (1961) minimum resource theory
tion that is homogeneous in demography, skills, make predictions for distribution of outcomes in
and abilities could be interpreted as risk seek- one-shot or short-term coalitions. Bargaining
ing, as there is no diversity to minimize risk. theory (Komorita & Chertkoff, 1973) states that
When these conditions are taken in conjunction individuals will be added to the coalition as
with the general risk-seeking nature connected needed to win and that the individuals will be
with a loss frame (Neale & Bazerman, 1991), offered enough that the coalition is attractive,
this will lead the coalition to contain members but not so much that the existing members of
who are similar. the coalition will lose any economic value by
Proposition 4: The stronger the loss framing, adding the member.
the more homogeneous the coalition.
In a coalition that has a prevention focus and
Keltner and colleagues (2003) tell us that
a loss frame, the coalition members will tend
those with a promotion motivation view others toward a distribution of outcomes that is equal
in terms of how they satisfy their own goals and across members of the coalition, van Beest and
needs. These individuals will be risk averse and colleagues (2005) found that in a loss situation,
will therefore diversify (Neale & Bazerman, coalition members were more likely to share the
1991) to add knowledge, skills, and abilities to loss equally, regardless of what would be con-
the coalition. Diversity was found to be a sig- sidered equitable in that situation. Similarly, it
nificant predictor of high-performing work has been shown that in a negatively valenced
teams (Neuman, Wagner, & Christiansen, situation, individuals are more likely to split a
1999). This study, which was based on the negotiated outcome in an equal division rather
personality diversity in the work team, found than based on decision rules or equity (Leliveld,
that the complementary model was the best van Beest, van Dijk, & Tenbrussel, 2009). It has
determinant of a high-performing team. Teams been shown in the negotiation literature that
that had diversity, with each member contribut- parties that are bargaining from the loss frame
ing unique attributes to the cause, were more are less willing to give concessions and will be
successful. Phillips (2001) found a positive link more risk seeking, that is, they will be less
between success of the team and continued likely to take the initial offer that is put on the
viability. 7,,; table (Neale & Bazerman, 1991). This behavior
Extrapolating from the work done by van when attempting to distribute the outcomes of
Beest and colleagues (2005), we know that in- the coalition will lead to members of the coali-
dividuals in a gain frame formed more small tion standing strong against any distribution
coalitions in an experimental setting than did other than an equal distribution.
those in a loss frame. That would lead to the On the other hand, in a promotion motivation
conclusion that in the gain frame negotiators and a gain frame, individuals will be more con-
saw more possible partners, were more open to cessionary (Neale & Bazerman, 1991). This
people who were dissimilar to themselves, and concessionary behavior will lead to a higher
were more likely to coalesce with others. Thus, likelihood that the distribution will be differen-
Proposition 5: The stronger the gain framing, tiated based on contribution. Individuals will be
the more heterogeneous the coalition. more likely to come to a bargained agreement
A NEW PERSPECTIVE ON COALITIONS 133

on the distribution. In promotion-focused coali- Discussion


tions, the concem over an equitable distribution
facilitates an agreement (van Beest et al., This is the initial work on a theory of coali-
2004a). Those negotiators who are in a posi- tions that takes the motivation for the coalition
tively valenced situation are less likely to make into consideration. It would seem that to truly
offers that are based on equality (Leliveld et al., understand this phenomenon and its importance
2009). Much of what motivates individuals in a to the organization, scholars would have to un-
gain-framed situation is the ability to provide derstand the "why" of coalitions. Previous work
equitable payouts. Thus, in the area of coalitions has looked at the for-
Proposition 6: The stronger the loss framing, mation from a very mathematical standpoint
the more the outcomes of the coalition will be (Mumighan, 1978). This is a very useful out-
determined based on equality. look to have, but it is also very limited. Kahne-
Proposition 7: The stronger the gain framing, man and Tversky (1979) found that humans do
the more the outcomes of the coaUtion will be not always focus on the mathematical value of
determined based on equity. an outcome when making a decision. This new
outlook takes the motivation of the coalition
into account and the subsequent framing that
Stability or Duration of the Coalition
this motivation will activate.
Most coalitions form, act, and disband (Mur- This article contributes to our understanding
nighan & Brass, 1991). One explanation for this of coalitions in three distinct ways. First, a
finding is because the focus of research is on comprehensive definition of the term coalition
prevention-motivated coalitions, "they do not is given. The concept of coalition has been
usually coordinate long term political planning defined on numerous occasions: Some have at-
except in times of severe threat" (Mumighan & tempted very comprehensive definitions (Ste-
Brass, 1991, p. 301). Riker's (1962) size prin- venson et al., 1985), whereas others have at-
ciple states that the minimum number of indi- tempted to get by with very shallow definitions
viduals needed to win will come together, and (Thibaut & Kelley, 1959; Thompson, 1967).
no more. Gamson's (1961) minimum resource The definition that I suggest is both comprehen-
theory looks at the resources needed to win sive and deep. The pieces of the definition are
rather than the number of players. Minimum necessary and sufficient for a coalition to exist.
resource theory states that the individuals who Second, a frame for the motivation of coali-
control the minimum amount of resources nec- tions based on the prevention-promotion focus
essary to win will form the coalition. These casts a new light on the ideas and predictions
theories describe a defensive coalition and pre- about coalitions. Coalitions have previously
dict that individuals will join, achieve a goal, been predicted from an economic or mathemat-
and disband. After the threat has been dissi- ical standpoint. Although some prior work has
pated, there is no reason for the coalition. Thus, considered how individual differences may im-
Proposition 8: The stronger the loss framing, pact coalitions (Bottom, 2001; Bottom et al.,
the shorter the duration of the coalition. 2000; Polzer et al., 1998), the human compo-
The coalition must be fluid, constantly nents of the coalition are only recently being
forming and disbanding, to maintain any lon- considered. Rather, most work has assumed that
gevity (Mumighan & Brass, 1991). As I noted the coalition will operate in a rational or logical
above, the promotion focus will generate a sense, absent of human irrationality. The theory
diverse team that is more likely to attain some proposed here takes the motivation of the coali-
type of success (Neuman et al., 1999) and tion into account. Although this is a constrained
teams that are successful maintain longer viewpoint, which aggregates the motivation of
(Phillips, 2001). Because there is a promotion many individuals into a "coalitional motiva-
focus with a gain frame that is focused on tion," it is still an important step to understand-
achievement, the coalition will remain to- ing how coalitions function. Future work should
gether past the current opportunity to address consider how the different levels of individual
subsequent opportunities. motivation operate within the coalition. That is,
Proposition 9: The stronger the gain framing, future empirical and theoretical work could con-
the longer the duration of the coalition. sider the impact of different levels of promotion
134 MEYER

and prevention focus within the coalition and the laboratory (1979; Tversky & Kahneman,
how that affects the predictions made here. This 1992). The manipulation of the motivation
is discussed in greater detail below. and frame could easily be accomplished by
Finally, I consider the effects of the motiva- following the framework laid out by previous
tion of the coalition on the four most studied research. Once the frame has been manipu-
and most important outcomes. These four out- lated, researchers could allow the subjects to
comes—size of the coalition, membership of coalesce as they pleased and test the propo-
the coalition, distribution of the outcomes, and sitions laid out in this article. Although the
duration of the coalition—have been consid- situation is still a bit contrived, it would pro-
ered since the earliest work on coalitions (Ca- vide incremental knowledge to a field that
plow, 1956; Gamson, 1961; Riker, 1962). Much generally relies on game theoretic models to
of the previous work has made predictions that inform it. This would be a good first step to
are very limited in scope and are constrained by test whether this is how coalitions work in
the game theoretic viewpoint and the triadic organizations.
methods that have been employed (Mumighan, Building on this step, further research
1978). These theories give us a good starting could manipulate the frame in a classroom
point from which to build, but there is more at setting. The end goal could be more salient in
work than merely a mathematical function. I the classroom than the laboratory, such as a
have attempted to broaden that viewpoint in this final project or some other outcome that could
article. By adding in the differential effects of impact the subjects' grade. This would pro-
the coalition's motivation, predictions can bet- vide a more realistic setting for coalition
ter account for some of the deviations from a building and would allow for a unique oppor-
purely mathematical model. The application of tunity to test the propositions put forth in this
prospect theory to the coalition gives us a better article.
f'ramework to make predictions and allows us to Final steps to test these propositions would
make better predictions by taking the reaction to allow the motivations of the subject to be
the frame into account. free. These motivations could be measured
initially, and again at the time of coalescing,
Future Research to determine whether each subject has a pre-
vention or promotion focus and the intensity
An obvious shortcoming of the previous in- of the focus. Once these foci are determined
camations of coalition theory has been the lack for each subject, the effects of differential
of a good test. Previous theories have been focus could be seen by testing each of these
easily tested in the laboratory, but these tests propositions. This final laboratory test would
lack generalizability because of the specific na- need to include some developmental work on
ture of the tests. Game theory and economic the proper method for aggregating team mo-
viewpoints are important to the underlying tivation, the discussion of which is outside
framework of our understanding of coalitions, of the scope of this article. After development
but are not the totality of the unit. Theories that of this method for aggregating (or determin-
generalize well to organizational application ing) group-level motivation, regression could
may be difficult to test because of the embedded be used to examine the effects of different
nature of coalitions. The coalition can have dif- levels of prevention and promotion motiva-
ferent motivations, goals, and attributes. For tion on the four outcomes, as proposed in this
this reason, I have proposed the promotion- article.
prevention focus in this article. Future research
could test these propositions first in a laboratory Implications
setting and subsequently in field studies.
Laboratory studies could build on the work The idea of coalitions has been with us for
of Higgins et al. (1997) who have manipu- quite some time. The effects have been talked
lated the differential motivations of promo- about in anecdotes and popular press stories, but
tion focus and prevention focus by manipu- little scientific research has undertaken to un-
lating the goal. Kahneman and Tversky have derstand the inner workings of the coalition.
also manipulated the frame of their subjects in This article attempts to integrate past and près-
A NEW PERSPECTIVE ON COALITIONS 135

ent theoretical and empirical work with a novel Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral
viewpoint from the field of motivation. Many theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Hall.
people have examined the "how" of coalitions
Gallicano, T. D. (2009). Personal relationship strat-
and the "who" of coalitions, but very littie work egies and outcomes in a membership organization.
has been done on the "why." Journal of Communication Management, 13, 310-
My hope is that this integration of preven- 328. doi: 10.1108/13632540911004597
tion-promotion focus and coalitions will spur Gamson, W. A. (1961). A theory of coalition forma-
future work in the area of coalitions. By open- tion. American Sociological Review, 26, 565-573.
ing the field to scholars who may not be math- doi: 10.2307/2090664
ematicians or game theorists, I hope to integrate Harinck, F., van Dijk, E., van Beest, I., & Mers-
these viewpoints with the viewpoints of sociol- mann, P. (2007). When gains loom larger than
ogists and psychologists. This will allow for a losses. Reversed loss aversion for small amounts
of money. Psychological Science, 18, 1099-1105.
much richer understanding of coalitions.
doi:10.1111/j.l467-9280.2007.02031.x
As I stated in the introduction, the coalition is
Higgins, E. T. (1997). Beyond pleasure and pain.
an important means of direct organizations and American Psychologist, 52, 1280-1300. doi:
making decisions in organizations. A richer un- 10.1037/0003-066X.52.12.1280
derstanding of coalitions and the outcomes pro- Higgins, E. T., Shah, J., & Friedman, R. (1997).
posed in this article will help both scholars and Emotional responses to goal attainment: Strength
mangers understand coalitions. of regulatory focus as moderator. Journal of Per-
sonality and Social Psychology, 72, 515-525. doi:
10.1037/0022-3514.72.3.515
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect the-
References
ory: An analysis of decision under risk. Economet-
Adams, J. S. (1965). Inequity in social exchange. In rica, 47, 263-291. doi: 10.2307/1914185
L. Berkowitz (Ed.), Advances in experimental so- Keltner, D., Gruenfeld, D. H., & Anderson, C.
cial psychology (Vol. 2, pp. 267-299). New York, (2003). Power, approach, and inhibition. Psycho-
NY: Academic Press. logical Review, 110, 265-284. doi: 10.1037/0033-
Anderson, C , & Berdahl, J. L. (2002). The experi- 295X. 110.2.265
ence of power: Examining the effects of power on Komorita, S. S., & Chertkoff, J. M. (1973). A bar-
approach and inhibition tendencies. Journal of gaining theory of coalition formation. Psycholog-
Personality and Social Psychology, 83, 1362- ical Review, 80, 149-162. doi:10.1037/h0034341
1377. Komorita, S. S., & Parks, C. D. (1995). Interpersonal
Bacharach, S. B., & Lawler, E. J. (1980). Power and relations: Mixed-motive interaction. Annual Re-
politics in organizations. San Francisco, CA: view of Psychology, 46, 183-207. doi:10.1146/
Jossey-Bass. annurev.ps.46.020195.001151
Bottom, W. P. (2001, June). Cognitive illusion as the Leliveld, M. C , van Beest, I., van Dijk, E., & Ten-
impetus for concession making and coalition for- brussel, A. E. (2009). Understanding the influence
mation. Paper presented at the Intemationai Asso- of outcome valence in bargaining: A study on
ciation for Conflict Management, ESSEC Business fairness accessibility, norms, and behavior. Jour-
School, Cergy, France. nal of Experimental Social Psychology, 45, 505-
Bottom, W. P., Eavey, C. L., & Miller, G. J. (1996). 514. doi:10.1016/j.jesp.2009.02.006
Getting to the core: Coalition integrity as a con- Levine, J. M., & Moreland, R. L. (1998). Small
straint on the power of agenda setters. Journal of groups. In D. T. Gilbert, S. T. Fiske, & G. Linzey
Confiict Resolution, 40, 298-319. doi:10.1177/ (Eds.), Handbook of social psychology (4th ed..
0022002796040002004 Vol. 2, pp. 415-469). Boston, MA: McGraw Hill.
Bottom, W. P., Holloway, J., McClurg, S., & Miller, Lopes, H., Santos, A. C , & Teles, N. (2009). The
G. J. (2000). Negotiating a coalition: Risk, quota motives for cooperation in work organizations.
shaving, and learning to bargain. Journal of Con- Journal of Institutional Economics, 5, 315-338.
fiict Resolution, 44, 147-169. doi:10.1177/ doi:10.1017/S1744137409990038
0022002700044002001 Mumighan, J. K. (1978). Models of coalition behav-
Caplow, T. (1956). A theory of coalitions in the triad. ior: Game theoretic, social psychological, and po-
American Sociological Review, 21, 489-493. doi: litical perspectives. Psychological Bulletin, 85,
10.2307/2088718 1130-1153. doi: 10.1037/0033-2909.85.5.1130
Cappelli, P. (1999). The new deal at work: Managing Mumighan, J. K., & Brass, D. J. (1991). Intraorga-
the market-driven workforce. Boston, MA: Har- nizational coalitions. In M. H. Bazerman, R. J.
vard Business School Press. Lewicki, & B. H. Sheppard (Eds.), Research on
136 MEYER

negotiation in organizations (Vol. 3, pp. 283-306). Stevenson, W. B., Pearce, J. L., & Porter, L. W.
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. (1985). The concept of coalition in organization
Neale, M. A., & Bazerman, M. H. (1991). Cognition theory and research. Academy of Management Re-
and rationality in negotiation. New York, NY: view, 10, 256-267.
Free Press. Thibaut, J., & Kelley, H. (1959). The social psychol-
Neuman, G. A., Wagner, S. H., & Christiansen, N. D. ogy of groups. New York, NY: Wiley.
(1999). The relationship between work-team per- Thompson, J. D. (1967). Organizations in action.
sonality composition and the job performance of New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
teams. Group & Organization Management, 24, Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in
28-45. doi:10.1177/1059601199241003 prospect theory: Cumulative representation of un-
Pearce, J. A., II, & DeNisi, A. S. (1983). Attribution certainty. Joumal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297-
theory and strategic decision making: An applica- 323. doi:10.1007/BF00122574
tion to coalition formation. Academy of Manage- van Beest, I., van Dijk, E., De Drue, C. K. W., &
ment Joumal, 26, 119-128. doi: 10.2307/256138 Wilke, H. A. M. (2005). Do-no-harm in coalition
Phillips, J. M. (2001). The role of decision influence formation: Why losses inhibit exclusion and pro-
and team performance in member self-efficacy, mote fairness cognitions. Joumal of Experimental
withdrawal, satisfaction with the leader, and will- Social Psychology, 41, 609-617. doi:10.1016/j
ingness to return. Organizational Behavior and .jesp.2005.01.002
Human Decision Processes, 84, 122-147. doi: van Beest, I., van Dijk, E., & Wilke, H. (2004a). The
10.1006/obhd.2000.2922 interplay of self-interest and equity in coalition
Polzer, J. T., Mannix, E. A., & Neale, M. A. (1998). formation. European Joumal of Social Psychol-
Interest alignment and coalitions in multiparty ne- ogy, 34, 547-565. doi:10.1002/ejsp.216
gotiation. The Academy of Management Journal, van Beest, I., van Dijk, E., & Wilke, H. (2004b).
41, 42-54. doi: 10.2307/256896 Resources and altematives in coalition formation:
Riker, W. H. (1962). The theory of political coali- The effects on payoff, self-serving behaviour, and
tions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. bargaining length. European Journal of Social
Shellshear, E., & Sudholter, P. (2009). On core sta- Psychology, 34, 713-728. doi:10.1002/ejsp.226
bility, vital coalitions, and extendability. Games
and Economic Behavior, 67, 633-644. doi:
10.1016/j.geb.2009.01.005 Received January 14, 2010
Simmel, G. (1955). Confiict and the web of group Revision received November 9, 2012
affiliations. New York, NY: Free Press. Accepted November 21, 2012 •
Copyright of Group Dynamics is the property of American Psychological Association and its
content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the
copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email
articles for individual use.

You might also like