You are on page 1of 15

Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market

Author(s): Daniel Kahneman, Jack L. Knetsch and Richard Thaler


Source: The American Economic Review , Sep., 1986, Vol. 76, No. 4 (Sep., 1986), pp. 728-
741
Published by: American Economic Association

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1806070

REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/1806070?seq=1&cid=pdf-
reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic
Review

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking:
Entitlements in the Market

By DANIEL KAHNEMAN, JACK L. KNETSCH, AND RICHARD THALER*

Community standards of fairness for the setting of prices and wages were elicited
by telephone surveys. In customer or labor markets, it is acceptable for a firm to
raise prices (or cut wages) when profits are threatened and to maintain prices
when costs diminish. It is unfair to exploit shifts in demand by raising prices or
cutting wages. Several market anomalies are explained by assuming that these
standards of fairness influence the behavior of firms.

Just as it is often useful to neglect friction tickets at standard prices for events
in elementary mechanics, there may be good that clearly generate excess demand.
reasons to assume that firms seek their maxi- Popular new models of automobiles
mal profit as if they were subject only to may have waiting lists that extend for
legal and budgetary constraints. However, months. Similarly, manufacturers in a
number of industries operate with
the patterns of sluggish or incomplete ad-
backlogs in booms and allocate ship-
justment often observed in markets suggest ments when they obviously could raise
that some additional constraints are oper- prices and reduce the queue. [p. 1701
ative. Several authors have used a notion of
fairness to explain why many employers do Okun explained these observations by the
not cut wages during periods of high unem- hostile reaction of customers to price in-
ployment (George Akerlof, 1979; Robert creases that are not justified by increased
Solow, 1980). Arthur Okun (1981) went fur- costs and are therefore viewed as unfair. He
ther in arguing that fairness also alters the also noted that customers appear willing to
outcomes in what he called customer accept "fair" price increases even when de-
markets-characterized by suppliers who are mand is slack, and commented that "...in
perceived as making their own pricing deci- practice, observed pricing behavior is a vast
sions, have some monopoly power (if only distance from do it yourself auctioneering"
because search is costly), and often have (p. 170).
repeat business with their clientele. Like The argument used by these authors to
labor markets, customer markets also some- account for apparent deviations from the
times fail to clear: simple model of a profit-maximizing firm is
that fair behavior is instrumental to the max-
... firms in the sports and entertain- imization of long-run profits. In Okun's
ment industries offer their customers model, customers who suspect that a sup-
plier treats them unfairly are likely to start
searching for alternatives; Akerlof (1980,
*Kahneman: Department of Psychology, University
1982) suggested that firms invest in their
of California, Berkeley, CA 94720; Knetsch, Depart-
reputation to produce goodwill among their
ment of Economics, Simon Fraser University; Thaler:
Johnson School of Management, Cornell University.
customers and high morale among their em-
The research was carried out when Kahneman was at ployees; and Arrow argued that trusted sup-
the University of British Columbia. It was supported by pliers may be able to operate in markets that
the Department of Fisheries and Oceans Canada. are otherwise devastated by the lemons
Kahneman and Thaler were also supported by the U.S.
Office of Naval Research and the Alfred P. Sloan
problem (Akerlof, 1970; Kenneth Arrow,
1973). In these approaches, the rules of fair-
Foundation, respectively. Conversations with J. Brander,
R. Frank and A. Tversky were very helpful. ness define the terms of an enforceable im-

728

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 76 NO. 4 KA HNEMA N ETA L: PROFIT SEEKING 729

plicit contract: Firms that behave unfairly ployees). The scenario was read to the par-
are punished in the long run. A more radical ticipants, who evaluated the fairness of the
assumption is that some firms apply fair action as in the following example:
policies even in situations that preclude en-
forcement- this is the view of the lay public, Question 1. A hardware store has been sell-
as shown in a later section of this paper. ing snow shovels for $15. The morning after
If considerations of fairness do restrict the a large snowstorm, the store raises the price
actions of profit-seeking firms, economic to $20. Please rate this action as:
models might be enriched by a more detailed Completely Fair Acceptable
analysis of this constraint. Specifically, the Unfair Very Unfair
rules that govern public perceptions of fair-
ness should identify situations in which some The two favorable and the two unfavor-
firms will fail to exploit apparent opportuni- able categories are grouped in this report to
ties to increase their profits. Near-rationality indicate the proportions of respondents who
theory (Akerlof and Janet Yellen, 1985) sug- judged the action acceptable or unfair. In
gests that such failures to maximize by a this example, 82 percent of respondents (N
significant number of firms in a market can =107) considered it unfair for the hardware
have large aggregate effects even in the pres- store to take advantage of the short-run in-
ence of other firms that seek to take ad- crease in demand associated with a blizzard.
vantage of all available opportunities. Rules The approach of the present study is purely
of fairness can also have significant eco- descriptive. Normative status is not claimed
nomic effects through the medium of regu- for the generalizations that are described as
lation. Indeed, Edward Zajac (forthcoming) "rules of fairness," and the phrase "it is
has inferred general rules of fairness from fair" is simply an abbreviation for "a sub-
public reactions to the behavior of regulated stantial majority of the population studied
utilities. thinks it fair." The paper considers in turn
The present research uses household sur- three determinants of fairness judgments:
veys of public opinions to infer rules of the reference transaction, the outcomes to
fairness for conduct in the market from the firm and to the transactors, and the
evaluations of particular actions by hypo- occasion for the action of the firm. The final
thetical firms.' The study has two main ob- sections are concerned with the enforcement
jectives: (i) to identify community standards of fairness and with economic phenomena
of fairness that apply to price, rent, and that the rules of fairness may help explain.
wage setting by firms in varied circum-
stances; and (ii) to consider the possible I. Reference Transactions
implications of the rules of fairness for
market outcomes. A central concept in analyzing the fairness
The study was concerned with scenarios in of actions in which a firm sets the terms of
which a firm (merchant, landlord, or em- future exchanges is the reference transaction,
ployer) makes a pricing or wage-setting de- a relevant precedent that is characterized by
cision that affects the outcomes of one or a reference price or wage, and by a positive
more transactors (customers, tenants, or em- reference profit to the firm. The treatment is
restricted to cases in which the fairness of
the reference transaction is not itself in
question.
'Data were collected between May 1984 and July
1985 in telephone surveys of randomly selected resi- The main findings of this research can be
dents of two Canadian metropolitan areas: Toronto and summarized by a principle of dual entitle-
Vancouver. Equal numbers of adult female and male ment, which governs community standards
respondents were interviewed for about ten minutes in
of fairness: Transactors have an entitlement
calls made during evening hours. No more than five
to the terms of the reference transaction and
questions concerned with fairness were included in any
interview, and contrasting questions that were to be firms are entitled to their reference profit. A
compared were never put to the same respondents. firm is not allowed to increase its profits by

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
730 THE A MERICA N ECONOMIC RE VIE W SEPTEMBER 1986

arbitrarily violating the entitlement of its painter decides to quit house painting and
transactors to the reference price, rent or go into the business of providing landscape
wage (Max Bazerman, 1985; Zajac, forth- services, where the going wage is lower. He
coming). When the reference profit of a firm reduces the workers' wages to $7 per hour
is threatened, however, it may set new terms for the landscaping work.
that protect its profit at transactors' expense. (N = 94) Acceptable 63% Unfair 37%
Market prices, posted prices, and the his-
tory of previous transactions between a firm Note that the same reduction in wages
and a transactor can serve as reference trans- that is judged acceptable by most respon-
actions. When there is a history of similar dents in Question 3 was judged unfair by 83
transactions between firm and transactor, the percent of the respondents to Question 2A.
most recent price, wage, or rent will be Parallel results were obtained in questions
adopted for reference unless the terms of the concerning residential tenancy. As in the
previous transaction were explicitly tem- case of wages, many respondents apply dif-
porary. For new transactions, prevailing ferent rules to a new tenant and to a tenant
competitive prices or wages provide the nat- renewing a lease. A rent increase that is
ural reference. The role of prior history in judged fair for a new lease may be unfair for
wage transactions is illustrated by the fol- a renewal. However, the circumstances un-
lowing pair of questions: der which the rules of fairness require land-
lords to bear such opportunity costs are nar-
Question 2A. A small photocopying shop rowly defined. Few respondents consider it
has one employee who has worked in the unfair for the landlord to sell the accom-
shop for six months and earns $9 per hour. modation to another landlord who intends
Business continues to be satisfactory, but a to raise the rents of sitting tenants, and even
factory in the area has closed and unemploy- fewer believe that a landlord should make
ment has increased. Other small shops have price concessions in selling an accommoda-
now hired reliable workers at $7 an hour to tion to its occupant.
perform jobs similar to those done by the The relevant reference transaction is not
photocopy shop employee. The owner of the always unique. Disagreements about fairness
photocopying shop reduces the employee's are most likely to arise when alternative
wage to $7. reference transactions can be invoked, each
(N = 98) Acceptable 17% Unfair 83% leading to a different assessment of the par-
ticipants' outcomes. Agreement on general
Question 2B. A small photocopying shop has principles of fairness therefore does not pre-
one employee... [as in Question 2A]... The clude disputes about specific cases (see al-
current employee leaves, and the owner de- so Zajac, forthcoming). When competitors
cides to pay a replacement $7 an hour. change their price or wage, for example, the
(N = 125) Acceptable 73% Unfair 27% current terms set by the firm and the new
terms set by competitors define alternative
The current wage of an employee serves as reference transactions. Some people will
reference for evaluating the fairness of fu- consider it unfair for a firm not to raise its
ture adjustments of that employee's wage wages when competitors are increasing theirs.
but not necessarily for evaluating the fair- On the other hand, price increases that are
ness of the wage paid to a replacement. The not justified by increasing costs are judged
new worker does not have an entitlement to less objectionable when competitors have led
the former worker's wage rate. As the follow- the way.
ing question shows, the entitlement of an It should perhaps be emphasized that the
employee to a reference wage does not carry reference transaction provides a basis for
over to a new labor transaction, even with fairness judgments because it is normal, not
the same employer: necessarily because it is just. Psychological
studies of adaptation suggest that any stable
Question 3. A house painter employs two state of affairs tends to become accepted
assistants and pays them $9 per hour. The eventually, at least in the sense that alterna-

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 76 NO. 4 KA HNEMA N ET A L.: PROFIT SEEKING 731

tives to it no longer readily come to mind. commonly evaluate outcomes as gains or


Terms of exchange that are initially seen as losses relative to a neutral reference point
unfair may in time acquire the status of a rather than as endstates (Kahneman and
reference transaction. Thus, the gap between Amos Tversky, 1979). In violation of norma-
the behavior that people consider fair and tive standards, they are more sensitive to
the behavior that they expect in the market- out-of-pocket costs than to opportunity costs
place tends to be rather small. This was and more sensitive to losses than to foregone
confirmed in several scenarios, where differ- gains (Kahneman and Tversky, 1984; Thaler,
ent samples of respondents answered the 1980). These characteristics of evaluation
two questions: "What does fairness require?" make preferences vulnerable to framing ef-
and " What do you think the firm would fects, in which inconsequential variations in
do?" The similarity of the answers suggests the presentation of a choice problem affect
that people expect a substantial level of con- the decision (Tversky and Kahneman, 1986).
formity to community standards-and also The entitlements of firms and transactors
that they adapt their views of fairness to the induce similar asymmetries between gains
norms of actual behavior. and losses in fairness judgments. An action
by a firm is more likely to be judged unfair if
II. The Coding of Outcomes it causes a loss to its transactor than if it
cancels or reduces a possible gain. Similarly,
It is a commonplace that the fairness of an an action by a firm is more likely to be
action depends in large part on the signs of judged unfair if it achieves a gain to the firm
its outcomes for the agent and for the indi- than if it averts a loss. Different standards
viduals affected by it. The cardinal rule of are applied to actions that are elicited by
fair behavior is surely that one person should the threat of losses or by an opportunity
not achieve a gain by simply imposing an to improve on a positive reference profit
equivalent loss on another. -a psychologically important distinction
In the present framework, the outcomes to which is usually not represented in economic
the firm and to its transactors are defined as analysis.
gains and losses in relation to the reference Judgments of fairness are also susceptible
transaction. The transactor's outcome is sim- to framing effects, in which form appears to
ply the difference between the new terms set overwhelm substance. One of these framing
by the firm and the reference price, rent, or effects will be recognized as the money illu-
wage. The outcome to the firm is evaluated sion, illustrated in the following questions:
with respect to the reference profit, and in-
corporates the effect of exogenous shocks Question 4A. A company is making a small
(for example, changes in wholesale prices) profit. It is located in a community experi-
which alter the profit of the firm on a trans- encing a recession with substantial unem-
action at the reference terms. According to ployment but no inflation. There are many
these definitions, the outcomes in the snow workers anxious to work at the company.
shovel example of Question 1 were a $5 gain The company decides to decrease wages and
to the firm and a $5 loss to the representa- salaries 7% this year.
tive customer. However, had the same price (N = 125) Acceptable 38% Unfair 62%
increase been induced by a $5 increase in the
wholesale price of snow shovels, the outcome Question 4B....with substantial unemploy-
to the firm would have been nil. ment and inflation of 12% ... The company
The issue of how to define relevanit out- decides to increase salaries only 5% this year.
comes takes a similar form in studies of (N = 129) Acceptable 78% Unfair 22%
individuals' preferences and of judgments of
fairness. In both domains, a descriptive anal- Although the real income change is ap-
ysis of people's judgments and choices in- proximately the same in the two problems,
volves rules of naive accounting that diverge the judgments of fairness are strikingly dif-
in major ways from the standards of ratio- ferent. A wage cut is coded as a loss and
nality assumed in economic analysis. People consequently judged unfair. A nominal raise

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
732 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1986

which does not compensate for inflation is not increased as it had before. The owners
more acceptable because it is coded as a gain reduce the workers' wages by 10 percent for
to the employee, relative to the reference the next year.
wage. (N =100) Acceptable 39% Unfair 61%
Analyses of individual choice suggest that
the disutility associated with an outcome Question 6B. A small company employs
that is coded as a loss may be greater than several people. The workers have been re-
the disutility of the same objective outcome ceiving a 10 percent annual bonus each year
when coded as the elimination of a gain. and their total incomes have been about
Thus, there may be less resistance to the average for the community. In recent months,
cancellation of a discount or bonus than to business for the company has not increased
an equivalent price increase or wage cut. As as it had before. The owners eliminate the
illustrated by the following questions, the workers' bonus for the year.
same rule applies as well to fairness judg- (N = 98) Acceptable 80% Unfair 20%
ments.
III. Occasions for Pricing Decisions
Question SA. A shortage has developed for a
popular model of automobile, and customers This section examines the rules of fairness
must now wait two months for delivery. A that apply to three classes of occasions in
dealer has been selling these cars at list which a firm may reconsider the terms that it
price. Now the dealer prices this model at sets for exchanges. (i) Profit reductions, for
$200 above list price. example, by rising costs or decreased de-
(N = 130) Acceptable 29% Unfair 71% mand for the product of the firm. (ii) Profit
increases, for example, by efficiency gains or
Question B..... A dealer has been selling reduced costs. (iii) Increases in market power,
these cars at a discount of $200 below list for example, by temporary excess demand
price. Now the dealer sells this model only at for goods, accommodations or jobs.
list price.
(N = 123) Acceptable 58% Unfair 42% A. Protecting Profit

The significant difference between the re- A random sample of adults contains many
sponses to Questions SA and SB (chi- more customers, tenants, and employees than
squared = 20.91) indicates that the $200 price merchants, landlords, or employers. Never-
increase is not treated identically in the two theless, most participants in the surveys
problems. In Question 5A the increase is clearly consider the firm to be entitled to its
clearly coded as a loss relative to the unam- reference profit: They would allow a firm
biguous reference provided by the list price. threatened by a reduction of its profit below
In Question SB the reference price is a positive reference level to pass on the
ambiguous, and the change can be coded entire loss to its transactors, without com-
either as a loss (if the reference price is the promising or sharing the pain. By large
discounted price), or as the elimination of a majorities, respondents endorsed the fairness
gain (if the reference price is the list price). of passing on increases in wholesale costs, in
The relative leniency of judgments in Ques- operating costs, and in the costs associated
tion 5B suggests that at least some respon- with a rental accommodation. The following
dents adopted the latter frame. The follow- two questions illustrate the range of situa-
ing questions illustrate the same effect in the tions to which this rule was found to apply.
case of wages:
Question 7. Suppose that, due to a transpor-
Question 6A. A small company employs tation mixup, there is a local shortage of
several people. The workers' incomes have lettuce and the wholesale price has in-
been about average for the community. In creased. A local grocer has bought the usual
recent months, business for the company has quantity of lettuce at a price that is 30 cents

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 76 NO. 4 K4HNEMAN ETAL.: PROFIT SEEKING 733

per head higher than normal. The grocer ploys two workers at $7 an hour, learns that
raises the price of lettuce to customers by 30 other equally competent workers are willing
cents per head. to do the same work for $6 an hour. Some
(N =101) Acceptable 79% Unfair 21% respondents were told that Mr. Green's busi-
ness was doing well, others were told that it
Question 8. A landlord owns and rents out a was doing poorly. The questions, presented
single small house to a tenant who is living in open format, required respondents to state
on a fixed income. A higher rent would "what is fair for Mr. Green to do in this
mean the tenant would have to move. Other situation," or "what is your best guess about
small rental houses are available. The land- what Mr. Green would do...." The informa-
lord's costs have increased substantially over tion about the current state of the business
the past year and the landlord raises the rent had a large effect. Replacing the employees
to cover the cost increases when the tenant's or bargaining with them to achieve a lower
lease is due for renewal. wage was mentioned as fair by 67 percent of
(N = 151) Acceptable 75% Unfair 25% respondents when business was said to be
poor, but only by 25 percent of respondents
The answers to the last question, in par- when business was good. The proportion
ticular, indicate that it is acceptable for firms guessing that Mr. Green would try to reduce
to protect themselves from losses even when his labor costs was 75 percent when he was
their transactors suffer substantial incon- said to be doing poorly, and 49 percent
venience as a result. The rules of fairness when he was said to be doing well. The
that yield such judgments do not correspond differences were statistically reliable in both
to norms of charity and do not reflect dis- cases.
tributional concerns. A firm is only allowed to protect itself at
The attitude that permits the firm to pro- the transactor's expense against losses that
tect a positive reference profit at the transac- pertain directly to the transaction at hand.
tors' expense applies to employers as well as Thus, it is unfair for a landlord to raise the
to merchants and landlords. When the profit rent on an accommodation to make up for
of the employer in the labor transaction falls the loss of another source of income. On the
below the reference level, reductions of even other hand, 62 percent of the respondents
nominal wages become acceptable. The next considered it acceptable for a landlord to
questions illustrate the strong effect of this charge a higher rent for apartments in one of
variable. two otherwise identical buildings, because a
more costly foundation had been required in
Question 9A. A small company employs the construction of that building.
several workers and has been paying them The assignment of costs to specific goods
average wages. There is severe unemploy- explains why it is generally unfair to raise
ment in the area and the company could the price of old stock when the pnrce of new
easily replace its current employees with good stock increases:
workers at a lower wage. The company has
been making money. The owners reduce the Question 10. A grocery store has several
current workers' wages by 5 percent. months supply of peanut butter in stock
(N = 195) Acceptable 23% Unfair 77% which it has on the shelves and in the
storeroom. The owner hears that the whole-
Question 9B.... The company has been los- sale price of peanut butter has increased and
ing money. The owners reduce the current immediately raises the price on the current
workers' wages by 5 percent. stock of peanut butter.
(N = 195) Acceptable 68% Unfair 32% (N =147) Acceptable 21% Unfair 79%

The effect of firm profitability was studiedThe principles of naive accounting ap-
in greater detail in the context of a scenario parently include a FIFO method of inven-
in which Mr. Green, a gardener who em- tory cost allocation.

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
734 THE A MER ICA N ECONOMIC RE VIEW SEPTEMBER 1986

B. The Allocation of Gains factory does not change its price for the
tables.
The data of the preceding section could be (N = 100) Acceptable 53% Unfair 47%
interpreted as evidence for a cost-plus rule
of fair pricing, in which the supplier is ex- The even division of opinions on Question
pected to act as a broker in passing on 11B confirms the observations of the previ-
marked-up costs (Okun). A critical test of ous study. In conjunction with the results of
this possible rule arises when the supplier's the previous section, the findings support a
costs diminish: A strict cost-plus rule would dual-entitlement view: the rules of fairness
require prices to come down accordingly. In permit a firm not to share in the losses that
contrast, a dual-entitlement view suggests it imposes on its transactors, without impos-
that the firm is only prohibited from increas- ing on it an unequivocal duty to share its
ing its profit by causing a loss to its transac- gains with them.
tors. Increasing profits by retaining cost re-
ductions does not violate the transactors'
entitlement and may therefore be acceptable. C. Exploitation of Increased Market Power
The results of our previous study (1986)
indicated that community standards of fair- The market power of a firm reflects the
ness do not in fact restrict firms to the advantage to the transactor of the exchange
reference profit when their costs diminish, as which the firm offers, compared to the trans-
a cost-plus rule would require. The questions actor's second-best alternative. For example,
used in these surveys presented a scenario of a blizzard increases the surplus associated
a monopolist supplier of a particular kind of with the purchase of a snow shovel at the
table, who faces a $20 reduction of costs on regular price, compared to the alternatives of
tables that have been selling for $150. The buying elsewhere or doing without a shovel.
respondents were asked to indicate whether The respondents consider it unfair for the
"fairness requires" the supplier to lower the hardware store to capture any part of the
price, and if so, by how much. About one-half increased surplus, because such an action
of the survey respondents felt that it was would violate the customer's entitlement to
acceptable for the supplier to retain the en- the reference price. Similarly, it is unfair for
tire benefit, and less than one-third would a firm to exploit an excess in the supply of
require the supplier to reduce the price by labor to cut wages (Question 2A), because
$20, as a cost-plus rule dictates. Further, and this would violate the entitlement of em-
somewhat surprisingly, judgments of fairness ployees to their reference wage.
did not reliably discriminate between pri- As shown by the following routine exam-
mary producers and middlemen, or between ple, the opposition to exploitation of short-
savings due to lower input prices and to ages is not restricted to such extreme cir-
improved efficiency. cumstances:
The conclusion that the rules of fairness
permit the seller to keep part or all of any Question 12. A severe shortage of Red Deli-
cost reduction was confirmed with the sim- cious apples has developed in a community
pler method employed in the present study. and none of the grocery stores or produce
markets have any of this type of apple on
Question IIA. A small factory produces ta- their shelves. Other varieties of apples are
bles and sells all that it can make at $200 plentiful in all of the stores. One grocer
each. Because of changes in the price of receives a single shipment of Red Delicious
materials, the cost of making each table has apples at the regular wholesale cost and raises
recently decreased by $40. The factory re- the retail price of these Red Delicious apples
duces its price for the tables by $20. by 25% over the regular price.
(N = 102) Acceptable 79% Unfair 21% (N = 102) Acceptable 37% Unfair 63%

Question I B. .... the cost of making each Raising prices in response to a shortage is
table has recently decreased by $20. The unfair even when close substitutes are read-

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 76 NO. 4 KA HNEMA N ET A L.: PROFIT SEEKING 735

ily available. A similar aversion to price ra- difficulties in preventing resale. The survey
tioning held as well for luxury items. For results suggest the addition of a further re-
example, a majority of respondents thought straint: some forms of price discrimination
it unfair for a popular restaurant to impose a are outrageous.
$5 surcharge for Saturday night reservations.
Conventional economic analyses assume Question 14. A landlord rents out a small
as a matter of course that excess demand for house. When the lease is due for renewal, the
a good creates an opportunity for suppliers landlord learns that the tenant has taken a
to raise prices, and that such increases will job very close to the house and is therefore
indeed occur. The profit-seeking adjustments unlikely to move. The landlord raises the
that clear the market are in this view as rent $40 per month more than he was plan-
natural as water finding its level-and as ning to do.
ethically neutral. The lay public does not (N = 157) Acceptable 9% Unfair 91%
share this indifference. Community stan-
dards of fairness effectively require the firm The near unanimity of responses to this
to absorb an opportunity cost in the pres- and similar questions indicates that an ac-
ence of excess demand, by charging less than tion that deliberately exploits the special
the clearing price or paying more than the dependence of a particular individual is ex-
clearing wage. ceptionally offensive.
As might be expected from this analysis, it The introduction of an explicit auction to
is unfair for a firm to take advantage of an allocate scarce goods or jobs would also
increase in its monopoly power. Respon- enable the firm to gain at the expense of its
dents were nearly unanimous in condemning transactors, and is consequently judged un-
a store that raises prices when its sole com- fair.
petitor in a community is temporarily forced
to close. As shown in the next question, even Question 15. A store has been sold out of the
a rather mild exploitation of monopoly power popular Cabbage Patch dolls for a month. A
is considered unfair. week before Christmas a single doll is dis-
covered in a storeroom. The managers know
Question 13. A grocery chain has stores in that many customers would like to buy the
many communities. Most of them face com- doll. They announce over the store's public
petition from other groceries. In one com- address system that the doll will be sold by
munity the chain has no competition. Al- auction to the customer who offers to pay
though its costs and volume of sales are the the most.
same there as elsewhere, the chain sets prices (N = 101) Acceptable 26% Unfair 74%
that average 5 percent higher than in other
communities. Question 16. A business in a community
(N = 101) Acceptable 24% Unfair 76% with high unemployment needs to hire a new
computer operator. Four candidates are
Responses to this and two additional ver- judged to be completely qualified for the job.
sions of this question specifying average price The manager asks the candidates to state the
increases of 10 and 15 percent did not differ lowest salary they would be willing to accept,
significantly. The respondents clearly viewed and then hires the one who demands the
such pricing practices as unfair, but were lowest salary.
insensitive to the extent of the unwarranted (N = 154) Acceptable 36% Unfair 64%
increase.
A monopolist might attempt to increase The auction is opposed in both cases, pre-
profits by charging different customers as sumably because the competition among
much as they are willing to pay. In conven- potential buyers or employees benefits the
tional theory, the constraints that prevent a firm. The opposition can in some cases be
monopolist from using perfect price dis- mitigated by eliminating this benefit. For
crimination to capture all the consumers' example, a sentence added to Question 15,
surplus are asymmetric information and indicating that " the proceeds will go to

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
736 THE A MERICA N ECONOMIC RE VIEW SEPTEMBER 1986

UNICEF" reduced the negative judgments the offer or rejects it, in which case both
of the doll auction from 74 to 21 percent. players get nothing. The standard game the-
The strong aversion to price rationing in oretic solution is for the allocator to make
these examples clearly does not extend to all a token offer and for the recipient to accept
uses of auctions. The individual who sells it, but Guth et al. observed that many allo-
securities at twice the price paid for them a cators offer an equal division and that re-
month ago is an object of admiration and cipients sometimes turn down positive of-
envy-and is certainly not thought to be fers. In our more detailed study of resistance
gouging. Why is it fair to sell a painting or a to unfairness (1986), recipients were asked
house at the market-clearing price, but not to indicate in advance how they wished to
an apple, dinner reservation, job, or football respond to a range of possible allocations:
game ticket? The rule of acceptability ap- A majority of participants were willing to
pears to be this: Goods for which an active forsake $2 rather than accept an unfair allo-
resale market exists, and especially goods cation of $10.
that serve as a store of value, can be sold Willingness to punish unfair actors was
freely by auction or other mechanisms allow- observed in another experiment, in which
ing the seller to capture the maximum price. subjects were given the opportunity to share
When resale is a realistic possibility, which is a sum of money evenly with one of two
not the case for most consumer goods, the anonymous strangers, identified only by the
potential resale price reflects the higher value allocation they had proposed to someone
of the asset and the purchaser is therefore else in a previous round. About three-
not perceived as sustaining a loss. quarters of the undergraduate participants in
this experiment elected to share $10 evenly
with a stranger who had been fair to some-
IV. Enforcement one else, when the alternative was to share
$12 evenly with an unfair allocator (see our
Several considerations may deter a firm other paper).
from violating community standards of fair- A willingness to punish unfairness was
ness. First, a history or reputation of unfair also expressed in the telephone surveys. For
dealing may induce potential transactors to example, 68 percent of respondents said they
take their business elsewhere, because of the would switch their patronage to a drugstore
element of trust that is present in many five minutes further away if the one closer to
transactions. Second, transactors may avoid them raised its prices when a competitor was
exchanges with offending firms at some cost temporarily forced to close; and, in a sep-
to themselves, even when trust is not an arate sample, 69 percent indicated they
issue. Finally, the individuals who make de- would switch if the more convenient store
cisions on behalf of firms may have a prefer- discriminated against its older workers.
ence for acting fairly. The role of reputation The costs of enforcing fairness are small
effects is widely recognized. This section pre- in these examples-but effective enforce-
sents some indications that a willingness to ment in the marketplace can often be
resist and to punish unfairness and an intrin- achieved at little cost to transactors. Retailers
sic motivation to be fair could also contrib- will have a substantial incentive to behave
ute to fair behavior in the marketplace. fairly if a large number of customers are
A willingness to pay to resist and to punish prepared to drive an extra five minutes to
unfairness has been demonstrated in incen- avoid doing business with an unfair firm.
tive compatible laboratory experiments. In The threat of future punishment when com-
the ultimatum game devised by Werner Guth, petitors enter may also deter a temporary
Rolf Schmittberger, and Bernd Schwarze monopolist from fully exploiting short-term
(1982), the participants are designated as profit opportunities.
allocators or recipients. Each allocator anon- In traditional economic theory, compli-
ymously proposes a division of a fixed ance with contracts depends on enforcement.
amount of money between himself (herself) It is a mild embarrassment to the standard
and a recipient. The recipient either accepts model that experimental studies often pro-

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 76 NO. 4 KAHNEMAN ETAL.: PROFIT SEEKING 737

duce fair behavior even in the absence of The mechanic would make much more
enforcement (Elizabeth Hoffman and Mat- money by replacing the part than by repair-
thew Spitzer, 1982, 1985; our paper, 1986; ing it. Assuming the [customer/tourist] can-
Arvin Roth, Michael Malouf, and J. Keith not be reached, what do you think the mech-
Murninghan, 1981; Reinhard Selten, 1978). anic would do in this situation?
These observations, however, merely confirm Make more money by replacing the part
common sense views of human behavior. customer: 60% tourist: 63%
Survey results indicate a belief that unen- Save the customer money by repairing the
forced compliance to the rules of fairness is part
common. This belief was examined in two customer: 40% tourist: 37%
contexts: tipping in restaurants and sharp
practice in automobile repairs. Question 18B. Of ten mechanics dealing with
a [regular customer/tourist], how many
Question 17A. If the service is satisfactory, would you expect to save the customer mon-
how much of a tip do you think most people ey by repairing the part?
leave after ordering a meal costing $10 in a Mean response
restaurant that they visit frequently? customer: 3.62 tourist: 3.72
(N = 122) Mean response = $1.28
The respondents do not approach garages
Question 17B.....in a restaurant on a trip to with wide-eyed naive faith. It is therefore all
another city that they do not expect to visit the more noteworthy that they expect a
again? tourist and a regular customer to be treated
(N = 124) Mean response = $1.27 alike, in spite of the obvious difference be-
tween the two cases in the potential for any
The respondents evidently do not treat the kind of enforcement, including reputation
possibility of enforcement as a significant effects.2
factor in the control of tipping. Their opin- Here again, there is no evidence that the
ion is consistent with the widely observed public considers enforcement a significant
adherence to a 15 percent tipping rule even factor. The respondents believe that most
by one-time customers who pay and tip by mechanics (usually excluding their own)
credit card, and have little reason to fear would be less than saintly in this situation.
embarrassing retaliation by an irate server. However, they also appear to believe that
The common belief that tipping is con- the substantial minority of mechanics who
trolled by intrinsic motivation can be accom- would treat their customers fairly are not
modated with a standard microeconomic motivated in each case by the anticipation of
model by extending the utility function of sanctions.
individuals to include guilt and self-esteem.
A more difficult question is whether firms,
which the theory assumes to maximize prof- V. Economic Consequences
its, also fail to exploit some economic op-
portunities because of unenforced compli- The findings of this study suggest that
ance with rules of fairness. The following many actions that are both profitable in the
questions elicited expectations about the short run and not obviously dishonest are
behavior of a garage mechanic dealing with likely to be perceived as unfair exploitations
a regular customer or with a tourist. of market power.3 Such perceptions can have

Question 1 8A. [A man leaves his car with the 'Other respondents were asked to assess the prob-
mechanic at his regular / A tourist leaves his able behavior of their own garage under similar cir-
car at a] service station with instructions to cumstances: 88 percent expressed a belief that their
garage would act fairly toward a regular customer, and
replace an expensive part. After the [custo-
86 percent stated that their garage would treat a tourist
mer/tourist] leaves, the mechanic examines and a regular customer similarly.
the car and discovers that it is not necessary 3This conclusion probably holds in social and cul-
to replace the part; it can be repaired cheaply. tural groups other than the Canadian urban samples

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
738 THE A MERICA N ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1986

significant consequences if they find expres- vertically integrated, had no such excuse for
sion in legislation or regulation (Zajac, 1978; raising price. They conclude from confiden-
forthcoming). Further, even in the absence tial SOCal documents that SOCal officers
of government intervention, the actions of "...were clearly concerned with their pub-
firms that wish to avoid a reputation for lic image and tried to maintain the appear-
unfairness will depart in significant ways ance of being 'fair"' (p. 1053).
from the standard model of economic behav-
ior. The survey results suggest four proposi- PROPOSITION 2: Hhen a single supplier
tions about the effects of fairness considera- provides a family of goods for which there
tions on the behavior of firms in customer is differential demand without corresponding
markets, and a parallel set of hypotheses variation of input costs, shortages of the most
about labor markets. valued items will occur.

A. Fairness in Customer Markets There is considerable support for this


proposition in the pricing of sport and enter-
PROPOSITION 1: When excess demand in tainment events, which are characterized by
a customer market is unaccompanied by in- marked variation of demand for goods or
creases in suppliers' costs, the market will fail services for which costs are about the same
to clear in the short run. (Thaler, 1985). The survey responses suggest
that charging the market-clearing price for
Evidence supporting this proposition was the most popular goods would be judged
described by Phillip Cagan (1979), who con- unfair.
cluded from a review of the behavior of Proposition 2 applies to cases such as those
prices that, "Empirical studies have long of resort hotels that have in-season and out-
found that short-run shifts in demand have of-season rates which correspond to predict-
small and often insignificant effects [on able variations of demand. To the extent
prices]" (p. 18). Other consistent evidence that constraints of fairness are operating, the
comes from studies of disasters, where prices price adjustments should be insufficient, with
are often maintained at their reference levels excess demand at the peak. Because naive
although supplies are short (Douglas Dacy accounting does not properly distinguish be-
and Howard Kunreuther, 1969). tween marginal and average costs, customers
A particularly well-documented illustra- and other observers are likely to adopt off-
tion of the behavior predicted in proposition peak prices as a reference in evaluating the
1 is provided by Alan Olmstead and Paul fairness of the price charged to peak cus-
Rhode (1985). During the spring and summer tomers. A revenue-maximizing (low) price in
of 1920 there was a severe gasoline shortage the off-season may suggest that the profits
in the U.S. West Coast where Standard Oil achievable at the peak are unfairly high. In
of California (SOCal) was the dominant sup- spite of a substantial degree of within-season
plier. There were no government-imposed price variation in resort and ski hotels, it
price controls, nor was there any threat of appears to be the rule that most of these
such controls, yet SOCal reacted by impos- establishments face excess demand during
ing allocation and rationing schemes while the peak weeks. One industry explanation is:
maintaining prices. Prices were actually "If you gouge them at Christmas, they won't
higher in the East in the absence of any be back in March."
shortage. Significantly, Olmstead and Rhode
note that the eastern firms had to purchase PROPOSITION 3: Price changes will be
crude at higher prices while SOCal, being more responsive to variations of costs than to
variations of demand, and more responsive to
cost increases than to cost decreases.

studied here, although the detailed rules of fairness for The high sensitivity of prices to short-run
economic transactions may vary. variations of costs is well documented

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 76 NO. 4 KA HNEMA N ET A L.: PROFIT SEEKING 739

(Cagan). The idea of asymmetric price rigid- contract theories, such a model predicts that
ity has a history of controversy (Timur wage changes in a firm will be more sensitive
Kuran, 1983; Solow; George Stigler and to recent firm profits than to local labor
James Kindahl, 1970) and the issue is still market conditions. However, unlike the im-
unsettled. Changes of currency values offer a plicit contract theories that emphasize risk
potential test of the hypothesis that cost shifting (Costas Azariadis, 1975; Martin
increases tend to be passed on quickly and Baily, 1974; Donald Gordon, 1974), ex-
completely, whereas cost decreases can be planations in terms of fairness (Akerlof,
retained at least in part. When the rate of 1979, 1982; Okun; Solow) lead to predic-
exchange between two currencies changes tions of wage stickiness even in occupations
after a prolonged period of stability, the that offer no prospects for long-term em-
prediction from Proposition 3 is that upward ployment and therefore provide little protec-
adjustments of import prices in one country tion from risk. Okun noted that "Casual
will occur faster than the downward adjust- empiricism about the casual labor market
ments expected in the other. suggests that the Keynesian wage floor
nonetheless operates; the pay of car washers
PROPOSITION 4: Price decreases will often or stock clerks is seldom cut in a recession,
take the form of discounts rather than reduc- even when it is well above any statutory
tions in the list or posted price. minimum wage" (1981, p. 82), and he
concluded that the employment relation is
This proposition is strongly supported by governed by an "invisible handshake," rather
the data of Stigler and Kindahl. Casual than by the invisible hand (p. 89).
observation confirms that temporary dis- The dual-entitlement model differs from a
counts are much more common than tem- Keynesian model of sticky wages, in which
porary surcharges. Discounts have the im- nominal wage changes are always nonnega-
portant advantage that their subsequent tive. The survey findings suggest that nomi-
cancellation will elicit less resistance than an nal wage cuts by a firm that is losing money
increase in posted price. A temporary sur- or threatened with bankruptcy do not violate
charge is especially aversive because it does community standards of fairness. This mod-
not have the prospect of becoming a refer- ification of the sticky nominal wage dictum
ence price, and can only be coded as a loss. is related to Proposition 3 for customer
markets. Just as they may raise prices to do
B. Fairness in Labor Markets so, firms may also cut wages to protect a
positive reference profit.
A consistent finding of this study is the Proposition 2 for customer markets as-
similarity of the rules of fairness that apply serted that the dispersion of prices for simi-
to prices, rents, and wages. The correspon- lar goods that cost the same to produce but
dence extends to the economic predictions differ in demand will be insufficient to clear
that may be derived for the behavior of the market. An analogous case in the labor
wages in labor markets and of prices in market involves positions that are similar in
customer markets. The first proposition nominal duties but are occupied by individu-
about prices asserted that resistance to the als who have different values in the employ-
exploitation of short-term fluctuations of de- ment market. The prediction is that dif-
mand could prevent markets from clearing. ferences in income will be insufficient to
The corresponding prediction for labor mar- eliminate the excess demand for the individ-
kets is that wages will be relatively insensi- uals considered most valuable, and the ex-
tive to excess supply. cess supply of those considered most dis-
The existence of wage stickiness is not in pensable. This prediction applies both within
doubt, and numerous explanations have been and among occupations.
offered for it. An entitlement model of this Robert Frank (1985) found that the indi-
effect invokes an implicit contract between viduals in a university who already are the
the worker and the firm. Like other implicit most highly paid in each department are also

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
740 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIEW SEPTEMBER 1986

the most likely targets for raiding. Frank initially unfair practice (for example, charg-
explains the observed behavior in terms of ing above list price for a popular car model)
envy and status. An analysis of this phenom- may spread slowly until it evolves into a new
enon in terms of fairness is the same as for norm-and is no longer unfair. In all these
the seasonal pricing of resort rooms: Just as cases, perceptions of transactors' entitle-
prices that clear the market at peak demand ments affect the substantive outcomes of ex-
will be perceived as gouging if the resort can changes, altering or preventing the equilibria
also afford to operate at off-peak rates, a predicted by an analysis that omits fairness
firm that can afford to pay its most valuable as a factor. In addition, considerations of
employees their market value may appear to fairness can affect the form rather than the
grossly underpay their less-valued colleagues. substance of price or wage setting. Judg-
A related prediction is that variations among ments of fairness are susceptible to substan-
departments will also be insufficient to clear tial framing effects, and the present study
the market. Although salaries are higher in gives reason to believe that firms have an
academic departments that compete with the incentive to frame the terms of exchanges so
private sector than in others, the ratio of job as to make them appear "fair."
openings to applicants is still lower in classics
than in accounting.
The present analysis also suggests that REFERENCES
firms that frame a portion of their com-
pensation package as bonuses or profit shar- Akerlof, George A., "The Market for 'Lemons':
ing will encounter relatively little resistance Quality Uncertainty and the Market
to reductions of compensation during slack Mechanism," Quarterly Journal of Eco-
periods. This is the equivalent of Proposition nomics, August 1970, 84, 488-500.
4. The relevant psychological principle is _ "The Case against Conservative
that losses are more aversive than objectively Macroeconomics: An Inaugural Lecture,"
equivalent foregone gains. The same mecha- Economica, August 1979, 46, 219-37.
nism, combined with the money illusion, , "A Theory of Social Custom, of
supports another prediction: Adjustments of Which Unemployment May Be One Con-
real wages will be substantially greater in sequence," Quarterly Journal of Econom-
inflationary periods than in periods of stable ics, June 1980, 94, 749-75.
prices, because the adjustments can then be _ " Labor Contracts as Partial Gift
achieved without making nominal cuts- Exchange," Quarterly Journal of Econom-
which are always perceived as losses and are ics, November 1982, 97, 543-69.
therefore strongly resisted. An unequal dis- _ and Yellen, Janet L., " Can Small Devi-
tribution of gains is more likely to appear ations from Rationality Make Significant
fair than a reallocation in which there are Differences to Economic Equilibrium?,"
losers. American Economic Review, September
This discussion has illustrated several ways 1985, 75, 708-20.
in which the informal entitlements of cus- Arrow, Kenneth, "Social Responsibility and
tomers or employees to the terms of refer- Economic Efficiency," Public Policy, Sum-
ence transactions could enter an economic mer 1973, 21, 303-17.
analysis. In cases such as the pricing of Azariadis, Costas, "Implicit Contracts and
resort facilities, the concern of customers for Unemployment Equilibria," Journal of
fair pricing may permanently prevent the Political Economy, December 1975, 83,
market from clearing. In other situations, the 1183-202.
reluctance of firms to impose terms that can Baily, Martin N., "Wages and Employment
be perceived as unfair acts as a friction-like Under Uncertain Demand," Review of
factor. The process of reaching equilibrium Economic Studies, January 1974, 41, 37-
can be slowed down if no firm wants to be 50.
seen as a leader in moving to exploit chang- Bazerman, Max H., "Norms of Distributive
ing market conditions. In some instances an Justice in Interest Arbitration," Industrial

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 76 NO. 4 KA HNEMA N ET A L.: PROFIT SEEKING 741

and Labor Relations Review, July 1985, 38, economic Analysis, Washington: The
558-70. Brookings Institution, 1981.
Cagan, Phillip, Persistent Inflation: Historical Olmstead, Alan L. and Rhode, Paul, "Rationing
and Policy Essays, New York: Columbia Without Government: The West Coast
University Press, 1979. Gas Famine of 1920," American Economic
Dacy, Douglas C. and Kunreuther, Howard, The Review, December 1985, 75, 1044-55.
Economics of Natural Disasters, New York: Roth, Alvin, Malouf, Michael and Murnighan, J.
Free Press, 1969. Keith, "Sociological Versus Strategic Fac-
Frank, Robert H., Choosing the Right Pond; tors in Bargaining," Journal of Economic
Human Behavior and the Quest for Status, Behavior and Organization, June 1981, 2,
New York: Oxford University Press, 1985. 153-77.
Gordon, Donald F., "A Neo-Classical Theory Selten, Reinhard, "The Equity Principle in
of Keynesian Unemployment," Economic Economic Behavior," in Hans W. Got-
Inquiry, December 1974, 12, 431-59. tinger and Werner Leinfellner, eds., Deci-
Guth, Werner, Schmittberger, Rolf and Schwarze, sion Theory and Social Ethics: Issues in
Bernd, "An Experimental Analysis of Ulti- Social Choice, Dordrecht: D. Reidel, 1978,
matum Bargaining," Journal of Economic 289-301.
Behavior and Organization, 1982, 3, 367- Solow, Robert M., "On Theories of Unem-
88. ployment," American Economic Review,
Hoffman, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L., " The March 1980, 70, 1-11.
Coase Theorem: Some Experimental Stigler, George J. and Kindahl, James K., The
Tests," Journal of Law and Economics, Behavior of Industrial Prices, NBER, New
April 1982, 25, 73-98. York: Columbia University Press, 1970.
and -__ Entitlements, Rights, Thaler, Richard, " Toward a Positive Theory of
and Fairness: An Experimental Examina- Consumer Choice," Journal of Economic
tion of Subjects' Concepts of Distributive Behavior and Organization, March 1980,
Justice,"' Journal of Legal Studies, June 1, 39-60.
1985, 14, 259-97. a_ "Mental Accounting and Consumer
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack L. and Thaler,Choice," Marketing Science, Summer 1985,
Richard, "Fairness and the Assumptions of 4 199-214.
Economics," Journal of Business, forth- Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel, "Ra-
coming, 1986. tional Choice and the Framing of Deci-
and Tversky, Amos, "Prospect Theory: sions," Journal of Business, forthcoming,
An Analysis of Decision Under Risk," 1986.
Econometrica, March 1979, 47, 263-91. Zajac, Edward E., Fairness or Efficiency: An
and _ _ "Choices, Values, and Introduction to Public Utility Pricing, Cam-
Frames," American Psychologist, April bridge: Ballinger, 1978.
1984, 39, 341-50. __ "Perceived Economic Justice: The
Kuran, Timur, "Asymmetric Price Rigidity and example of Public Utility Regulation,"
Inflationary Bias," American Economic in H. Peyton Young, ed., Cost Alloca-
Review, June 1983, 73, 373-82. tion: Methods, Principles and Applications,
Okun, Arthur, Prices and Quantities: A Macro- Amsterdam: North-Holland, forthcoming.

This content downloaded from


13.234.121.200 on Sat, 26 Jun 2021 03:20:53 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like