Harmath2021 Article ProducersBrand-dealerDualLoyal

You might also like

You are on page 1of 18

Journal of Marketing Analytics

https://doi.org/10.1057/s41270-021-00137-4

ORIGINAL ARTICLE

Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment


Pedro Harmath1 · Roberto Feeney2 · Josefa Ramoni‑Perazzi3 

Revised: 9 August 2021 / Accepted: 20 September 2021


© The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Springer Nature Limited 2021

Abstract
This paper aims to identify the factors that affect agricultural producers’ loyalty to brand and dealer, jointly and individually,
when buying agricultural capital equipment. A second objective is exploring the influence of one type of loyalty over the
other, for which we resort to different settings. Our findings show distinctive determining factors for each type of loyalty, the
bi-univocity of these two loyalties, and the necessary farm profile to achieve dual loyalty. Agricultural equipment companies
demand this information to target farmers and design marketing strategies to make farmers loyal or disloyal, strengthen their
distribution channels, and identify the best communication lines to reach potential and current customers.

Keywords  Agricultural capital equipment · Loyalty to brand and dealer · Argentinian Ag equipment market · Probit
regression models

Introduction Alternatively, producers can be loyal both to the brand and


the dealers at the same time.
Agricultural capital equipment markets are fiercely competi- However, the factors that explain brand and dealer loyalty
tive (Reportlinker 2019), and firms selling these products for capital equipment, and the interplay between brand and
need agricultural producers’ loyalty to be profitable (Ag dealer loyalty, have scarcely been studied in the agribusiness
Equipment Intelligence 2018). In this purchasing process, context. Thus, this research aims to fill a gap in the literature
establishing long-term bonds with producers can become concerning the issue of which are the determining factors of
a key asset not only for manufacturers but also for dealers. agricultural producers’ loyalty to capital equipment brands
Dealers are important figures to capital equipment manu- and dealers, what is the influence of one type of loyalty over
facturers as they sell new products and provide after-sales the other, and which are the factors that define producers’
services: fast delivery of parts and services in the event the dual loyalty to agricultural capital equipment.
equipment fails or collapses (Walley et al. 2007). Consequently, this paper has three main goals: (1) iden-
There is often interplay between brand and dealer loyalty, tify the factors that determine Argentinian producers’ brand
as many times brand loyalty may depend on the dealer’s loyalty and dealer loyalty when in need of agricultural capi-
performance (Verhoef et al. 2007). In this context, producers tal equipment, using univariate probit models; (2) study the
can show their loyalty to the Ag capital equipment brand or influence of one type of loyalty over the other (brand and
the dealer, according to the specific value each can supply. dealer loyalty), using seemingly unrelated bivariate probit
models; and (3) identify the factors that determine dual loy-
alty, using multinomial probit models.

* Josefa Ramoni‑Perazzi
jramonip@uis.edu.co Literature review
1
Department of Mathematics, Austral University, Rosario,
Argentina Agricultural producers act as business customers when inter-
2
Center for Food & Agribusiness, Austral University, Rosario,
acting with capital equipment suppliers, just like in a non-
Argentina farm business-to-business (B2B) environment. Purchasers
3
Escuela de Economía y Administración, Universidad
in the B2B markets are characterized by being professional,
Industrial de Santander, Carrera 27, Calle 9, rational, and expert buyers (Harbor 2006).
Bucaramanga 680001, Colombia

Vol.:(0123456789)
P. Harmath et al.

Despite the significant contribution of brands to indus- According to Huber and Herrmann (2001), custom-
trial firms’ value and profitability (Cassia and Magno 2019; ers do not see brand and dealer loyalty as one unit. The
Nyström et al. 2018; Cassia et al. 2017; Viardot 2017; Wal- authors used confirmatory factor analysis with unweighted
ley et al., 2007), branding in industrial contexts is an under- least squares to analyze the information collected through
researched area due to the implicit assumption that brands telephone interviews, from a sample of 615 driver license
are not relevant for industrial customers (Seyedghorban et al. holders who had purchased a vehicle in Germany. They
2016; Hinterhuber and Hinterhuber 2012). However, previ- found evidence that supports the idea that customer satis-
ous research has established the importance of reputation faction with the product increases brand loyalty, which, in
and trust that brands may convey to industrial customers turn, increases dealer loyalty. At the same time, satisfaction
(Lynch and De Chernatony 2004), and the fact that brands with the services provided by the dealer can increase dealer
can mitigate the uncertainty and risk that professional pur- loyalty and lead to greater brand loyalty.
chasers experience in industrial markets (Leek and Christo- In the same line of thought, Akaeze and Akaeze (2017)
doulides 2012; Mudambi 2002). concluded that customer satisfaction, product quality, and
Industrial brands are valuable for end-users and industrial service quality are, in that order, the most important factors
distributors or dealers. Manufacturers’ brands are an impor- affecting customer loyalty to the dealer in the automobile
tant factor in the dealership´s performance, as the brand can market. The authors arrived at this conclusion by using the
be a valuable resource to attract customers, increase demand, information gathered from a structured questionnaire, self-
revenues, and profits. At the same time, the dealer is the administered to 50 customers in New York, and analyzed
customer’s point of contact with the product; higher levels of it in the theory of reasoned action conceptual framework.
service quality tend to increase customer satisfaction. This Verhoef et  al. (2007) also established that brand and
would result in loyalty to the dealer, which in turn would dealer loyalty are interconnected. Consumers’ decisions
lead to greater loyalty to the brand (Anisimova and Mavondo are influenced by the quality of the service provided by
2014; Glynn 2010; Huber and Herrmann 2001). the dealer and, at the same time, dealer loyalty depends on
Focusing on the relationship between brands and dealers, brand loyalty. The lower the brand tier, the more oppor-
Hinterhuber and Hinterhuber (2012) analyzed the impor- tunities for dealers to add value to the brand and improve
tance of the manufacturer’s brands for industrial dealers in customer satisfaction. Once again, the purchasing decision
the agrochemical industry. The analysis was based on a set starts with the brand and moves to the dealer, meaning that
of three unrelated studies, one of which includes the role brand loyalty precedes dealer loyalty. At the same time,
of the customer (end-users). This last study was conducted dealer performance affects brand retention. The authors
through face-to-face interviews with farmers who were focused on disloyalty (switching behavior) rather than loy-
asked to rank the herbicides attributes they value the most. alty and accounted for brand tier since it determines the level
Factors related to quality came first, followed by the brand at which dealers may add value and develop customer loy-
in second place. alty. The study also considered information regarding the
According to Hinterhuber and Hinterhuber (2012), brands alignment between brand and dealer, and the institutional
drive industrial retailers’ and users’ decisions more than any environment.
change in price and margins, implying that brand loyalty Ewing (2000) found evidence supporting the idea that
comes first and has an impact on dealer loyalty. The brand the expectation of a customer purchasing a given brand in
itself denotes a perception of quality, credibility, and reli- the future is influenced by past brand or dealer repeated pur-
ability that leads to relatively higher returns; price, then, chasing behavior. However, past repeated brand or dealer
becomes a not so relevant variable. Therefore, industries purchasing behavior does not seem to affect anyone’s expec-
should focus on building a brand rather than on designing tation to purchase from a given dealer. The author concludes
marketing strategies based on prices, which calls for a coop- that the brand/end-user interface offers a greater predictive
erative relationship between manufacturers and retailers or capacity than the retail/end-user interface. The hypotheses
dealers. Trust in a brand facilitates the production process, were tested with a one-way analysis of variance, using infor-
leading to deep-rooted brand loyalty. mation from a self-administered questionnaire answered by
Similarly, Walley et al. (2007) analyzed the role of brand- a random sample of small and medium-sized new-vehicle
ing in the purchase decisions made in the UK tractor market, owners in Johannesburg.
based on the information collected from a sample of 428 In all these papers, loyalty to brand and dealer are pre-
farmers and contractors. Participants were asked to rank the sented as related concepts, as each influences the other.
attributes that influence their decisions. The results of the However, brand loyalty impacts first and foremost on dealer
conjoint analysis pointed out that brand name was the most loyalty, since product satisfaction leads to brand loyalty
important factor, followed by price, and service (dealer prox- and only indirectly would impact on dealer loyalty. Subse-
imity and quality of service). quently, the dealer loyalty contributes to loyalty to brand:
Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment

a customer satisfied with the dealers’ services would have Methods


a positive effect on dealer loyalty, which would lead to
higher brand loyalty, in a sort of loop effect (Anisimova and According to Cameron and Trivedi (2005), Greene (2012),
Mavondo 2014; Glynn 2010; Harbor 2006; Huber and Her- Seyoum (2018), and Wooldridge (2010), among others, let
rmann 2001). Y ∗ be a latent variable such as the producers’ commitment
The same business and economic principles of B2B for brands or dealers if brand loyalty or dealer loyalty is
branding should hold for agricultural capital equipment mar- being modeled. Then, the natural regression model for this
kets (Walley et al. 2007; Harbor 2006; Kool et al. 1997). variable is given by
However, the authors are ignorant of the factors that lead to
brand and dealer loyalty, which directed them to questions Y ∗ = X𝛽 + 𝜀 (1)
asking about the factors that explain brand loyalty and dealer where 𝜀 is the disturbance component or error assumed to
loyalty: Are they the same, or do brand and dealer loyalty be normal with mean zero and variance one, (𝜀|X) ∼ N[0,1] .
involve different sets of variables? On the other hand, are However, model (1) cannot be estimated as Y ∗ is not
there factors that can explain loyalty to brand and dealer? observed. Instead, we observe
{
1 if Y ∗ > 0,
Y= (2)
Methodology 0 if Y ∗ < 0

Data The univariate probit model can be written as



( � ) X 𝛽


This paper´s main source of information is the survey “The P(Y = 1|X) = Φ X 𝛽 = 𝜙(z)dz (3)
Needs of the Argentine Agricultural Producer” conducted −∞
during June and July 2017. The survey aims at analyzing
where Φ(⋅) is the standard normal cumulative distribu-
farmers’ purchasing behavior and at understanding their
tion function (cdf), and the correspondent standard nor-
underlying preferences when making decisions. It defines
mal probability
√ density function (pdf) is the derivative
agricultural producers as physical or legal persons growing
𝜙(z) = (1∕ 2𝜋)exp(−z2 ∕2) . The coefficients (𝛽) are esti-
soybeans, wheat, corn, and other grains on owned and/or
mated using the maximum likelihood estimation.
rented land. (for more details, see e.g. Mohammadi et al.
This study also considers the application of a seemingly
2020). In this research, we consider a random sample of
unrelated bivariate probit model, used when two equations
564 farmers, where ‘loyalty to brands’, ‘loyalty to dealers’,
are estimated and the dependent variable on one of them is
‘dual loyalty’ or ‘concurrent loyalty to brands and dealers’
independent in the other, assuming the possibility that one
are defined as dependent variables.1
kind of loyalty influences the other. Let Y1∗ be the producers’
Based on the general literature, we selected the independ-
commitment for dealers (brands), and Y2∗ be the producers’
ent variables that influence these types of loyalty. The lit-
commitment for brands (dealers). The resulting equations
erature suggests that certain demographic characteristics of
are:
the producer such as age, education, and income, as well as
other characteristics related to the nature of the firm such Y1∗ = X1 𝛽1 + 𝜀1 (4)
as farm size, can influence loyalty to brands and dealers. It
is expected that price, performance, the valuation of possi-
Y2∗ = 𝛾Y 1 +X 2 𝛽2 + 𝜀2 (5)
ble differences between products, and preferences towards
different means of communication that producers use to where 𝜀1 and 𝜀2 are jointly normal with zero means, unit
acquire capital equipment provided by the supplier, play an variances, and correlation 𝜌 . Succinctly
important role in determining brand loyalty. Additionally, we ( ) [( ) ( )]
include variables that are relevant in the Argentine context 𝜀1 0 1 𝜌
|X1 , X2 ∼ N , (6)
and which have been acknowledged by the literature: the 𝜀2 0 𝜌1
distance between the place where the producer often lives
and his/her farm, the percentage of rented land, and produc- with
ers’ cognitive styles (in terms of being analytical, intuitive, {
1 if Y1∗ > 0,
or balanced). The list of the variables is shown in Table 1. Y1 =
0 if Y1∗ < 0 (7)

and
1
  These were built through cluster analysis. For details, see Appendix
A.
P. Harmath et al.

Table 1  Dependent and independent variables list


Name of the variable Categories of response

Dependent variable
 BLOYALTY Loyalty to brands 1 = loyal; 0 = disloyal
 DLOYALTY Loyalty to dealers 1 = loyal; 0 = disloyal
 BDLOYALTY1 Dual loyalty (loyalty to brands and dealers 1 = loyal to both brands and dealers; 0 = oth-
simultaneously) erwise
 BDLOYALTY2 1 = loyal to brands and disloyal to dealers
0 = otherwise
 BDLOYALTY3 1 = loyal to dealers and disloyal to brands
0 = otherwise
 BDLOYALTY4** 1 = disloyal to both brands and dealers;
0 = otherwise
Independent variable
 Dimension 1 for brands and dealers: farm and farmer characteristics
  EDUC Farmer education level 0 = high school or less
1 = more than high school
  AGEG1* Farmer age group 1 =  ≤ 44; 0 = otherwise
  AGEG2 1 = 45–54; 0 = otherwise
  AGEG3 1 =  ≥ 55; 0 = otherwise
  RESID Residence (distance to farm) 0 = In the facilities or less than 50 kms. away
1 = more than 50 kms. away
  FSIZE1* Farm size 1 = mid-sized; 0 = otherwise
  FSIZE2 1 = commercial; 0 = otherwise
  FSIZE3 1 = large; 0 = otherwise
  PRL % of rented land 0 = less than 50%
1 = 50% or more
  GS1* Gross Sales (U$D) 1 =  ≤ 499,999; 0 = otherwise
  GS2 1 = 500,000–999,999
0 = otherwise
  GS3 1 =  ≥ 1,000,000; 0 = otherwise
 Dimension 2 for brands: farmer beliefs and attitudes
  CS Cognitive Style 1 = analytic
0 = intuitive/balanced
  DBEBP1* Differences between expendable and branded 1 = strongly disagree—disagree; 0 = otherwise
  DBEBP2 products 1 = partially disagree
0 = otherwise
  DBEBP3 1 = partially agree—agree—strongly agree;
0 = otherwise
 Dimension 3 for brands: products characteristics
  PRICE Appreciation of the attribute: Price 1 = most important
0 = least important/neutral
  PERFORM Appreciation of the attribute: Performance 1 = most important
0 = least important/neutral
 Dimension 4 for brands: media exposure
  MEDSOU More visited media source 1 = traditional and personal communication;
0 = social media
  MEANVAL Index measuring reported media exposure
ranging from 1 to 6
 Dimension 2 for dealers: supplier characteristics
  FPDR Financing provided by dealer/retailer 0 = 0–50%; 1 = 51–100%
 Dimension 3 for dealers: relationship with supplier
  REL Appreciation of the attribute: Relationship with 1 = most important
dealer 0 = least important/neutral

*Category of reference or control, **base outcome


Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment

{ � � � � � � �

1 if Y2∗ > 0, 𝜕Φ2 X1 𝛽1 , X2 𝛽2 , 𝜌 � � � X2 𝛽2 − 𝜌X1 𝛽1
Y2 =
0 if Y2∗ < 0 (8) = 𝜙 Xi 𝛽i Φ √ 𝛽i , i = 1,2
𝜕Xi 1 − 𝜌2
respectively. In short, the seemingly unrelated probit (15)
( � )
model can be denoted by 𝜕Φ X 𝛽i ( � )
( ) ( � ) = 𝜙 X 𝛽i 𝛽j , i = 0,1, 2,3 (16)
� 𝜕Xj
P Y1 = 1, Y2 = 1|X1 , X2 = Φ2 X1 𝛽1 , 𝛾Y1 , X2 𝛽2 , 𝜌 (9)

where Φ2 (⋅) is the bivariate standard normal cdf with our


correspondent bivariate standard normal pdf 𝜙2 (⋅) . The
development of maximum likelihood of the expression (9) is
( ) Results and discussion
appropriate for the estimation of the coefficients 𝛽1 , 𝛾, 𝛽2 , 𝜌  ,
respectively.
Descriptive statistics and chi‑square test
On the other hand, regarding the Argentinian producers’
of association
dual loyalty, let Y1∗ be the producers’ commitment for both
brands and dealers, Y2∗ be the producers’ commitment for
The results shown in Table 2 indicate that farmers are more
brands but not for dealers, Y3∗ be the producers’ commitment
likely to be loyal to the dealer rather than to the brand. In any
for dealers but not for brands, and Y0∗ be the general indif-
case, loyal farmers are never the majority. Producers typi-
ference or producers’ lack of commitment for both brands
cally have more than a high school diploma, especially those
and dealers. In this case, the regression equation is given by
who consider themselves brand loyal. Their average age is
Yi∗ = X𝛽i + 𝜀i (10) 47 years, older among disloyal. They tend to live close to the
farm and have gross sales that do not exceed half a million
for i = 0,1, 2,3 , where the errors are jointly normally dis- dollars, which may be explained by the fact that 60% or more
tributed, with are commercial farms. They mostly rent less than 50% of the
total area, especially those that are not loyal to either brand
(𝜀|X) ∼ N[0, Σ] (11)
or dealer. Except for brand loyalists, farmers typically use an
where 𝜀 = [𝜀0 , 𝜀1 , 𝜀2 , 𝜀3 ] , such that Σ is the correlation intuitive style when making purchasing decisions. Also, they
matrix between these random components with values one tend to resort to traditional media sources to find information
at the principal diagonal of Σ , and about the equipment they are planning to buy, and less than
{ one-third of the producers are financed by dealers for more
1 if Yi∗ > 0, than 50% of their purchases.
Yi =
0 if Yi∗ < 0 (12)
On the other hand, before adjusting the corresponding
probit models, as a first step, we review the relationship
The multinomial probit model can be written as
between each dependent variable and the corresponding
( ) ( � )

X 𝛽i explanatory variables, making use of a Chi-square test.

P Yi = 1|X = Φ X 𝛽i = 𝜙(z)dz (13) As shown in Table 3, in the brand loyalty column (BLOY-
−∞ ALTY), all the explanatory variables are associated with
where Φ(⋅) and 𝜙(⋅) are the respective standard normal cdf the Chi-square test, except the gross sales volume (GS), and
and pdf like in the model defined in Eq. (3), considering one the appreciation of the attribute price (PRICE). Regarding
of the categories in the dependent variable Yi as the base dealer loyalty (DLOYALTY), all the explanatory variables
outcome, with i = 0,1, 2,3. Naturally, the coefficients ( 𝛽i , all are associated with this loyalty, except the producer's educa-
the elements of Σ ) can be estimated using the maximum tion level (EDUC), the farm size (FSIZE), and the apprecia-
likelihood estimation. tion of the producer-dealer (REL) relationship.
Finally, the marginal effects for the univariate probit model For dual loyalty (BDLOYALTY), all the explanatory
(3), the seemingly unrelated probit model (9), and the multi- variables are associated with this loyalty except the pro-
variate probit model (13) are defined by ducer education level (EDUC), the distance between the
( � ) place where the producer usually resides and his/her farm
𝜕Φ X 𝛽 ( � ) (RESID), the appreciation of the price attribute (PRICE),
= 𝜙 X 𝛽 𝛽j (14) and the assessment of the relationship between the producer
𝜕Xj
and the dealer (REL). Regarding the media assessment
(MEANVAL), the only quantitative variable in our study, it
differs significantly on average between producers that are
loyal or disloyal to agricultural machinery brands; but not
P. Harmath et al.

Table 2  Descriptive statistics Variable Description Loyalty to Loyalty to dealers


brands
Loyal Disloyal Loyal Disloyal

EDUC Level of education (%)


Highschool (0) 38.03 27.07 32.30 30.29
More (1) 61.97 72.93 67.70 69.71
RESID Distance to farm (%)
 ≤ 50 Kms (0) 69.95 64.39 68.87 64.50
 > 50 Kms (1) 30.05 35.61 31.13 35.50
FSIZE Farm size (%)
Mid (1) 63.38 64.10 59.14 67.75
Commercial (2) 29.11 21.37 29.57 19.87
Large (3) 7.51 14.53 11.28 12.38
PRL Rented land (%)
 ≤ 50% (0) 56.81 67.52 59.14 67.10
 > 50% (1) 43.19 32.48 40.86 32.90
GS Gross Sales (%)
 < 500,000 US$ (1) 45.54 42.74 42.80 44.63
500,000–999,999 US$ (2) 24.88 31.05 26.85 30.29
 > 999,999 (3) 29.58 26.21 30.35 25.08
CS Cognitive Style (%)
Intuitive (0) 45.54 55.27 51.75 51.47
Analytical (1) 54.46 44.73 48.25 48.53
DBEBP Differences between expendable and
branded products (%)
Strongly disagree/disagree (1) 30.99 59.26 42.80 53.42
Partly disagree (2) 16.43 7.98 14.79 8.14
Agree/strongly agree (3) 52.58 32.76 42.41 38.44
PRICE Importance of attribute price (%)
Less importance/neutral (0) 71.83 77.78 75.88 75.24
Most important (1) 28.17 22.22 24.12 24.76
PERFORM Importance of attribute performance (%)
Less importance/neutral (0) 50.70 43.87 46.69 46.25
Most important (1) 49.30 56.13 53.31 53.75
REL Importance of relation with dealer (%)
Less importance/neutral (0) 78.40 78.92 78.21 79.15
Most important (1) 21.60 21.08 21.79 20.85
MEDSOU Most frequent media source (%)
Traditional (1) 61.50 54.99 57.20 57.65
Personal (2) 20.66 12.25 15.18 15.64
Social (3) 17.84 32.76 27.63 26.71
FPDR Financing provided by dealer/retailer (%)
 ≤ 50% (0) 69.01 80.91 72.37 79.80
 > 50% (1) 30.99 19.09 27.63 20.20
AGE Age of farmers (years)
Mean 43.38 49.49 45.74 48.39
Standard deviation 12.13 11.62 11.89 12.29
MEANVAL Index reported media exposure (1–6)
Mean 3.47 3.19 3.35 3.25
Standard deviation 0.69 0.78 0.71 0.77
Number of observations 213 351 257 307
Percent of total (%) 37.77 62.23 45.57 54.43
Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment

Table 3  Chi-square test between the dependents and each independent variable


Variable Name of the variable BLOYALTY: loy- DLOYALTY: loy- BDLOY-
alty to brands alty to dealers ALTY: dual
loyalty

EDUC Farmer education level 3.936** 1.963 5.279


AGEG Farmer age group 59.016*** 17.384*** 60.330***
RESID Residence (distance to farm) 2.942* 2.702* 5.335
FSIZE Farm size 9.304*** 2.997 14.492**
PRL % of rented land 16.212*** 18.869*** 25.492***
GS Gross Sales (U$D) 4.078 8.609** 21.861***
CS Cognitive Style 23.512*** 25.010***
DBEBP Differences between expendable and branded products 52.026*** 53.391***
PRICE Appreciation of the attribute: Price 1.343 5.235
PERFORM Appreciation of the attribute: Performance 7.882*** 11.559***
MEDSOU More visited media source 9.697*** 12.280***
MEANVAL Index measuring reported media exposure ranging from 1 to 6 tc = 3.414*** Fc = 0.909
FPDR Financing provided by dealer 6.163** 9.781**
REL Appreciation of the attribute: Relationship with dealer 1.341 5.561

T—mean sample comparison test with equal variances for MEANVAL. Levene’s test for equality of variances was not significant, with
Fc = 2.277. Chi-square statistic between BLOYALTY and DLOYALTY = 115.4***
(*), (**) and (***) indicate significance at the 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively

so when the four categories of loyalty to brands and deal- than those who do not consider such differences. Produc-
ers together are considered. As an additional test, the Chi- ers who attach great importance to product performance are
square test between BLOYALTY and DLOYALTY shows 13.89% more likely to be considered loyal to such brands,
that both variables are not statically independent, which is compared to those that give less value to this attribute. On
why it makes sense to examine the influence of one type of the other hand, agricultural producers with a higher level
loyalty over the other, as presented below (see note at the of education are 9.50% less likely to be considered loyal to
end of Table 3). agricultural machinery brands. Older producers (45–54, ≥
54 years old) are 16.8% and 28.5% less likely to be loyal to
Univariate analysis for brand loyalty and dealer agricultural machinery brands, respectively, when compared
loyalty to the younger ( ≤ years old).
Producers who rent at least 50% of the land where they
To identify the factors affecting one type of loyalty or the carry out their agricultural operations are 14.87% more
other, several univariate probit models were adjusted consid- likely to be loyal to agricultural machinery dealers, com-
ering the variables identified in the previous section. Among pared to those who rent less than 50%. Those with medium
the results shown in Table 4, for analysis purposes, the focus and high gross sales volumes have 13.4% and 11.07% more
was on models (1.4) and (2.3) because they are the most chances of loyalty than those with the lowest gross sales
parsimonious (see note at the end of Table 4). For brand volumes. As a counterpart, similar to observations made
loyalty (BLOYALTY), the factors that statistically determine about brand loyalty, older producers above 55 years old are
this variable are CS (+), DBEBP2 (+), DBEBP3 (+), PER- 11.5% and 13.4% less likely to be loyal to distributors of
FORM (+), and EDUC (−), AGEG2 (−), AGEG3 (−). As agricultural machinery compared with the youngers, below
to dealer loyalty (DLOYALTY), the factors that statistically 55 years, while the loyalty of those who reside farther from
determine it are PRL (+), GS2 (+), GS3 (+), and AGEG2 their farm is 11% less likely, compared to those who reside
(−), AGEG3 (−), RESID (−). closer or even in the same farm.
The average marginal effects of the statistically significant
coefficients indicate that analytical agricultural producers Bivariate analysis for brand loyalty and dealer
are 8.88% more likely to be considered loyal to agricultural loyalty
machinery brands than intuitive or balanced producers.
Those who partially or strongly consider that there are differ- To quantify the impact of one type of loyalty over the other,
ences between generic and trademark products are 19.59% some seemingly unrelated bivariate probit models were
and 13.18%, respectively, more prone to be considered loyal adjusted. Table 5 shows the models where dealer loyalty
P. Harmath et al.

Table 4  Univariate probit models for brand loyalty and dealer loyalty


Variable Dep. Variable: BLOYALTY Dep. Variable: LOYALTY
(1.1) (1.2) (1.3) (1.4) Marg. eff (2.1) (2.2) (2.3) Marg. eff

CONSTANT − 0.7136* − 0.6858* − 0.513*** − 0.539*** 0.1863 0.0275 0.0467


(0.3834) (0.3633) (0.1850) (0.1841) (0.1564) (0.1237) (0.1216)
EDUC − 0.272** − 0.275** − 0.2885** − 0.3201** − 0.095 − 0.1769
(0.1381) (0.1373) (0.1350) (0.1333) (0.1226)
AGEG2 − 0.53*** − 0.50*** − 0.529*** − 0.560*** − 0.168 − 0.2896** − 0.2990** − 0.3056** − 0.115
(0.1466) (0.1450) (0.1412) (0.1397) (0.1311) (0.1302) (0.1300)
AGEG3 − 0.90*** − 0.90*** − 0.958*** − 0.953*** − 0.285 − 0.380*** − 0.3437** − 0.3561** − 0.134
(0.1786) (0.1774) (0.1701) (0.1697) (0.1484) (0.1448) (0.1440)
RESID − 0.303** − 0.2731* − 0.2121 − 0.2720** − 0.2935** − 0.2940** − 0.110
(0.1419) (0.1399) (0.1318) (0.1254) (0.1222) (0.1222)
FSIZE2 0.0808 0.1788 − 0.0489
(0.1586) (0.1421) (0.1494)
FSIZE3 0.1152 0.3118 − 0.0285
(0.2383) (0.2004) (0.2236)
PRL 0.1026 0.0956 0.3483*** 0.3736*** 0.3960*** 0.1487
(0.1298) (0.1292) (0.1229) (0.1205) (0.1178)
GS2 0.0784 0.3717*** 0.3512*** 0.3570*** 0.1340
(0.1571) (0.1390) (0.1344) (0.1341)
GS3 0.2949 0.3228* 0.2805* 0.2948** 0.1107
(0.1966) (0.1807) (0.1469) (0.1460)
CS 0.309** 0.3108** 0.3284** 0.2971** 0.0888
(0.1328) (0.1324) (0.1292) (0.1275)
DBEBP2 0.64*** 0.624*** 0.650*** 0.655*** 0.1959
(0.2018) (0.2003) (0.1964) (0.1960)
DBEBP3 0.390** 0.3788** 0.435*** 0.440*** 0.1318
(0.1530) (0.1525) (0.1435) (0.1432)
PRICE − 0.0643
(0.1879)
PERFORM 0.391** 0.425*** 0.4650*** 0.4645*** 0.1389
(0.1610) (0.1241) (0.1215) (0.1213)
MEDSOU 0.2340 0.1961
(0.1532) (0.1501)
MEANVAL − 0.0200 − 0.0149
(0.0863) (0.0859)
FPDR 0.1154 0.1163
(0.1345) (0.1342)
REL − 0.1420
(0.1335)
Log-likelihood − 294.289 − 295.567 − 298.538 − 299.8417 − 367.6518 − 369.1304 − 369.5071
Likelihood Ratio Chi-squared 120.8*** 118.2*** 112.3*** 109.7*** 44.52*** 41.56*** 40.80***
Pseudo R2 0.1703 0.1667 0.1583 0.1546 0.0571 0.0533 0.0523
Correctly classified 70.74% 71.10% 71.28% 70.74% 62.94% 63.65% 63.30%

(1.1) included all the independent variables for brands; (1.2) included all the variables except GS, PRICE (see Chi-square test); (1.3) included
only the variables statistically significant in (1.1) and (1.2); (1.4) included only the variables statistically significant in (1.3)
(2.1) included all the independent variables for dealers; (2.2) included all the variables except EDUC, FSIZE, REL (see Chi-square test); (2.3)
included only the variables statistically significant in (2.1) and (2.2)
Standard errors in (). (*), (**) and (***) indicate significance at the 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively
Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment

Table 5  Seemingly unrelated bivariate probit models: first dealer loyalty as the dependent, and then brand loyalty as the dependent
Dependent variable Variable (3.1.1) (3.2.1) (3.3.1) (3.4.1) Mar-
ginal  effects

DLOYALTY CONSTANT 0.1809 0.0260 0.0454 0.0573


(0.1569) (0.1234) (0.1211) (0.1221)
EDUC − 0.1769
(0.1228)
AGEG2 − 0.2859** − 0.2979** − 0.3067** − 0.3038** − 0.1206
(0.1314) (0.1302) (0.1298) (0.1296)
AGEG3 − 0.3790** − 0.3421** − 0.3548** − 0.3597** − 0.1427
(0.1485) (0.1449) (0.1440) (0.1444)
RESID − 0.2715** − 0.2959** − 0.2990** − 0.3237*** − 0.1285
(0.1258) (0.1224) (0.1225) (0.1220)
FSIZE2 − 0.0527
(0.1499)
FSIZE3 − 0.0354
(0.2233)
PRL 0.3516*** 0.3737*** 0.3926*** 0.3823*** 0.1503
(0.1232) (0.1205) (0.1183) (0.1198)
GS2 0.3757*** 0.3469** 0.3545*** 0.3450** 0.1354
(0.1398) (0.1366) (0.1346) (0.1357)
GS3 0.3226* 0.2864* 0.3130** 0.3230** 0.1268
(0.1804) (0.1472) (0.1486) (0.1440)
FPDR 0.1234 0.1209
(0.1326) (0.1340)
REL − 0.1381
(0.1343)
BLOYALTY CONSTANT − 1.7737*** − 1.7828*** − 1.5745*** − 1.7191***
(0.5895) (0.6128) (0.4224) (0.3451)
DLOYALTY 1.7635* 1.5535* 1.5929*** 1.8237*** 0.5280
(1.0686) (0.9049) (0.6222) (0.5262)
EDUC − 0.2028 − 0.2451* − 0.2472* − 0.2596* − 0.0861
(0.1885) (0.1478) (0.1454) (0.1435)
AGEG2 − 0.4504* − 0.4648** − 0.4664*** − 0.4448** − 0.1362
(0.2627) (0.2012) (0.1798) (0.1889)
AGEG3 − 0.7531** − 0.7917*** − 0.8109*** − 0.7311*** − 0.2054
(0.3597) (0.2666) (0.2474) (0.2587)
RESID − 0.2148 − 0.2233 − 0.1780
(0.2208) (0.1874) (0.1546)
FSIZE2 0.1249 0.1605
(0.1678) (0.1620)
FSIZE3 0.1407 0.2689
(0.2554) (0.2291)
PRL − 0.0796 − 0.0639
(0.2125) (0.1952)
GS2 − 0.0973
(0.2334)
GS3 0.1225
(0.2710)
CS 0.2999** 0.2955** 0.3021** 0.2617* 0.0844
(0.1446) (0.1433) (0.1414) (0.1347)
P. Harmath et al.

Table 5  (continued)
Dependent variable Variable (3.1.1) (3.2.1) (3.3.1) (3.4.1) Mar-
ginal  effects

DBEBP2 0.5909*** 0.6110*** 0.6146*** 0.5950*** 0.2145


(0.2291) (0.2134) (0.2100) (0.2081)
DBEBP3 0.4036** 0.4055*** 0.4330*** 0.4185*** 0.1377
(0.1715) (0.1639) (0.1552) (0.1546)
PRICE − 0.1950
(0.2009)
PERFORM 0.3376 0.4765*** 0.5013*** 0.4872*** 0.1543
(0.2099) (0.1359) (0.1324) (0.1351)
MEDSOU 0.1198 0.0913
(0.1619) (0.1606)
MEANVAL 0.0355 0.0444
(0.0909) (0.0923)
rho − 0.3095 − 0.1674 − 0.1948 − 0.3649
(0.7745) (0.6051) (0.4234) (0.3951)
Log-likelihood − 614.1192 − 616.7137 − 618.5792 − 619.2541
Wald Chi-squared 195.67*** 161.25*** 162.88*** 198.91**
Likelihood-ratio test 0.1425 0.0775 0.2126 0.81
of rho = 0:

(3.1.1) included all the independent variables for dealers in the first equation, and then, all the independent variables for brands, and DLOY-
ALTY in the second
(3.2.1) included all the variables for dealers except EDUC, FSIZE, REL (see Chi-square test), and then, all the variables for brands except GS,
PRICE (see Chi-square test), and DLOYALTY
(3.3.1) included only the variables statistically significant for dealers in the models (2.1)–(2.2), and then, only the variables statistically signifi-
cant for brands in the models (1.1)–(1.2), and DLOYALTY
(3.4.1) included the variables for dealers in the model (2.3), and then, the variables for brands in the model (1.4), and DLOYALTY
Standard errors in (). (*), (**) and (***) indicate significance at the 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively
Bold letters are used to highlight the presence of one type of loyalty as an explanatory variable for another type of loyalty

serves as the dependent variable in the first stage, and as model (3.4.1) and that of BLOYALTY in the model (3.4.2)
an independent variable in the second stage, while Table 6 are statistically significant under any confidence level. Thus,
shows the models where brand loyalty acts as the dependent while dealer loyalty is approximately 7% above brand loy-
variable in the first stage, and as an independent variable alty, in our modeling dynamics and under the context of
in the following. For analysis purposes, the focus is on the some kind of ‘empirical causality’, it is not possible to rank
models (3.4.1) and (3.4.2) respectively because they are the the type of loyalty that influences the most the other loy-
most parsimonious. At this stage of the analysis, it is crucial alty. Therefore, it is possible to conclude that the statistical
to note that, according to the statistically significant coef- influence of one type of loyalty over the other is strictly bi-
ficients in both biprobit models, the same influential factors univocal. Reference can also be made to an ‘average loyalty
on both types of loyalty detected in the univariate approach attraction’ in the agricultural machinery market under study
appear again as the determinants in our bivariate approach. of approximately 49% on the part of producers.
That is, there is statistical consistency through our estima-
tions (see notes at the end of Tables 5 and 6, respectively). Multivariate analysis for dual loyalty
The following is a crucial result of our research: produc-
ers considered loyal to agricultural machinery dealers will To analyze the dual loyalty to brands and dealers alike, a
have a 52.80% better chance of being brand loyal, com- couple of multinomial probit models which results are
pared to producers regarded as disloyal to these dealers. On summarized in Table 7, were adjusted. However, our final
the other hand, producers considered loyal to agricultural analysis is based on the second model (see note at the end
machinery brands have a 45.82% better chance of being loyal of Table 7).
to dealers, compared to producers regarded as disloyal to the It is a known fact that the factors determining Argen-
brands. The two estimated parameters, DLOYALTY in the tinian producers’ loyalty to agricultural machinery brand
Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment

Table 6  Seemingly unrelated bivariate probit models: first brand loyalty as the dependent, and then dealer loyalty as the dependent
Dependent variable Variable (3.1.2) (3.2.2) (3.3.2) (3.4.2) Marginal effects

BLOYALTY CONSTANT − 0.7262* − 0.6946* − 0.5153*** − 0.5397***


(0.3836) (0.3655) (0.1849) (0.1842)
EDUC − 0.2726** − 0.2743** − 0.2863** − 0.3198** − 0.1122
(0.1379) (0.1375) (0.1352) (0.1334)
AGEG2 − 0.5385*** − 0.5073*** − 0.5294*** − 0.5606*** − 0.1802
(0.1468) (0.1449) (0.1421) (0.1397)
AGEG3 − 0.8959*** − 0.9029*** − 0.9574*** − 0.9533*** − 0.2748
(0.1787) (0.1781) (0.1700) (0.1697)
RESID − 0.3114** − 0.2769** − 0.2170
(0.1437) (0.1414) (0.1330)
FSIZE2 0.0807 0.1811
(0.1585) (0.1425)
FSIZE3 0.1141 0.3121
(0.2384) (0.2003)
PRL 0.1072 0.0973
(0.1304) (0.1296)
GS2 0.0875
(0.1589)
GS3 0.2969
(0.1969)
CS 0.3092** 0.3110** 0.3293** 0.2972*** 0.1014
(0.1325) (0.1323) (0.1291) (0.1275)
DBEBP2 0.6386*** 0.6224*** 0.6476*** 0.6543*** 0.2451
(0.2028) (0.2007) (0.1966) (0.1962)
DBEBP3 0.3910*** 0.3793** 0.4361*** 0.4411*** 0.1531
(0.1526) (0.1524) (0.1433) (0.1432)
PRICE − 0.0742
(0.1890)
PERFORM 0.3922** 0.4282*** 0.4670*** 0.4652*** 0.1563
(0.1606) (0.1245) (0.1240) (0.1215)
MEDSOU 0.2198 0.1890
(0.1587) (0.1548)
MEANVAL − 0.0128 − 0.0150
(0.0886) (0.3655)
DLOYALTY CONSTANT − 0.3961 − 0.5096** − 0.4784* − 0.5207**
(0.3229) (0.2458) (0.2500) (0.2423)
BLOYALTY 1.1557** 1.2518*** 1.2168*** 1.2984*** 0.4582
(0.5126) (0.4382) (0.4244) (0.4193)
EDUC − 0.0670
(0.1398)
AGEG2 − 0.0494 − 0.0269 − 0.0388 − 0.0201
(0.1818) (0.1728) (0.1704) (0.1731)
AGEG3 − 0.0538 − 0.0022 − 0.0228 0.0049
(0.2234) (0.2056) (0.2073) (0.2060)
RESID − 0.1994 − 0.2010 − 0.2020 − 0.1954
(0.1368) (0.1326) (0.1341) (0.1298)
FSIZE2 − 0.0891
(0.1600)
FSIZE3 − 0.0781
(0.2442)
P. Harmath et al.

Table 6  (continued)
Dependent variable Variable (3.1.2) (3.2.2) (3.3.2) (3.4.2) Marginal effects

PRL 0.3304** 0.3295** 0.3427*** 0.3392*** 0.1328


(0.1337) (0.1340) (0.1270) (0.1274)
GS2 0.4101*** 0.3890*** 0.3905*** 0.3941*** 0.1529
(0.1456) (0.1420) (0.1423) (0.1420)
GS3 0.2825 0.2108 0.2148 0.2172
(0.1955) (0.1584) (0.1577) (0.1578)
FPDR 0.0739 0.0704
(0.1451) (0.1448)
REL − 0.0594
(0.1468)
rho 0.1043 0.0494 0.0729 0.0212
(0.3006) (0.2625) (0.2517) (0.2533)
Log-likelihood − 612.3061 − 613.9158 − 616.9800 − 618.3201
Wald Chi-squared 145.26*** 146.35*** 137.10*** 137.63***
Likelihood-ratio test 0.1197 0.0352 0.0832 0.0070
of rho = 0

(3.1.2) included all the independent variables for brands in the first equation, and then, all the independent variables for dealers, and BLOY-
ALTY in the second
(3.2.2) included all the variables for brands except GS, PRICE (see Chi-square test), and then, all the variables for dealers except EDUC, FSIZE,
REL (see Chi-square test), and BLOYALTY
(3.3.2) included only the variables statistically significant for brands in the models (1.1)–(1.2), and then, only the variables statistically signifi-
cant for dealers in the models (2.1)–(2.2), and BLOYALTY
(3.4.2) included the variables for brands in the model (1.4.), and then, the variables for dealers in the model (2.3), and BLOYALTY
Standard errors in (). (*), (**) and (***) indicate significance at the 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively
Bold letters are used to highlight the presence of one type of loyalty as an explanatory variable for another type of loyalty

(BLOYALTY) are inherent characteristics of this market. loyalty, which is not the case with some aspects linked to
The following are to be outlined: producers’ age and educa- the producer’s beliefs, attitudes, and appreciations. Moreo-
tion level (EDUC, AGEG), their cognitive style (CS), their ver, producers who live far from their farms may not have
appreciation towards product performance (PERFORM), a very close relationship with the agricultural machinery
and their perception of any notable differences between dealer and may not be very familiar with the brands, which
generic and branded products (DBEBP). may affect their loyalties. This is likely to narrow their
On the other hand, the factors that determine loyalty loyalty, as well as the possible links that may exist between
to dealers (DLOYALTY) correspond to a combination producers and various agricultural machinery brands and
of the following: the producer’s age (AGEG), and three dealers channeled through more traditional means of com-
other variables exposing a ‘symbiosis’ prototype between munication than those currently used (social networks).
the producer and his farm: the percentage of rented land Finally, we cannot lose sight that, according to Eq. (4.2)
(PRL), his/her gross sales volume (GS), and the distance that the estimated BDLOYALTY2 and BDLOYALTY3, resi-
between his/her farming operations and his/her residence dence (RESID) is an important factor for producers who are
(RESID). The Eq. (4.2) for BDLOYALTY1 shows that loyal to brands but not to dealers, and to those producers
these are the factors that determine loyalty to brands and who are otherwise loyal to dealers but not to brands. The
dealers jointly or individually. There is an additional ele- same is true for producers with midsize gross sales volumes
ment (factor): producers now use traditional media or (GS2). In addition, the producer's cognitive style (CS) influ-
personal communication, which will probably have them ences their loyalty to brands and not to dealers; while the
more likely to be considered loyal to both agricultural percentage of rented land (PRL) is an important factor for
machinery brands and dealers, compared to those produc- producers’ loyalty to dealers, but not to brands.
ers who are more inclined to use media and social media
(MEDSOU) as a source of information.
It is interesting to note that the producer’s education
level and age are contrasted with his/her possible level of
Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment

Table 7  Multinomial probit models for dual loyalty


Variable Dependent variable: BDLOYALTY
BDLOYALTY1 BDLOYALTY2 BDLOYALTY3
(4.1) (4.2) Marg. eff (4.1) (4.2) Marg. eff (4.1) (4.2) Marg. eff

CONSTANT − 0.6320 − 0.980*** − 1.6178* − 1.58*** − 0.1641 − 0.5841*


(0.5483) (0.3459) (0.7803) (0.4783) (0.5426) (0.3353)
EDUC − 0.3808* − 0.3599* − 0.0556 − 0.4433 − 0.1694
(0.2046) (0.2028) (0.2897) (0.2009)
AGEG2 − 0.674*** − 0.657*** − 0.1344 − 0.5210 − 0.0029
(0.2178) (0.2157) (0.3243) (0.2246)
AGEG3 − 1.159*** − 1.137*** − 0.2428 − 0.5983 0.0496
(0.2647) (0.2578) (0.3708) (0.2508)
RESID − 0.4838** − 0.4784** − 0.0623 − 0.4909 − 0.5655* − 0.0217 − 0.3191 − 0.3545* − 0.033
(0.2077) (0.2040) (0.3118) (0.3084) (0.1953) (0.1931)
FSIZE2 0.0243 − 0.1102 − 0.1776
(0.2371) (0.3375) (0.2380)
FSIZE3 0.0607 − 0.8959 − 0.4438
(0.3494) (0.6488) (0.3648)
PRL 0.3492* 0.3848** 0.0263 0.4522 0.6366*** 0.6130*** 0.1046
(0.1958) (0.1902) (0.2844) (0.2034) (0.1962)
GS2 0.3700 0.3837* 0.0145 0.6128* 0.5659* 0.0169 0.7537*** 0.7020*** 0.1216
(0.2355) (0.2240) (0.3192) (0.3054) (0.2183) (0.2104)
GS3 0.5765** 0.6084*** 0.1171 0.3851 0.3824
(0.2892) (0.2349) (0.4335) (0.2921)
CS 0.4090** 0.3937** 0.0551 0.7092** 0.6828** 0.0364 0.2021
(0.1964) (0.1940) (0.2939) (0.2872) (0.1996)
DBEBP2 0.9274*** 0.8976*** 0.1758 0.5996 0.1036
(0.3066) (0.3030) (0.4183) (0.3266)
DBEBP3 0.4918** 0.4479** 0.1129 0.0738 − 0.1730
(0.2269) (0.2207) (0.3288) (0.2323)
PERFORM 0.4650* 0.4886*** 0.1113 0.3768 − 0.1607
(0.1827) (0.1800) (0.2666) (0.1758)
MEDSOU 0.3954* 0.3885* 0.0922 − 0.1526 − 0.0056
(0.2255) (0.2239) (0.3098) (0.2096)
MEANVAL − 0.1109 0.0054 − 0.1342
(0.1280) (0.1869) (0.1297)
FPDR 0.1529 − 0.1174 − 0.0165
(0.2088) (0.3234) (0.2185)

BDLOYALTY4 is the base outcome. (4.1) included all the variables except PRICE, REL (see Chi-square test). Log- likelihood for
(4.1) = −  598.3216. Wald Chi-squared = 141.27***. (4.2) included only the variables statistically significant in (4.1). Log-likelihood for
(4.2) = − 601.7991. Wald Chi-squared = 135.95***
Standard errors in (). (*), (**) and (***) indicate significance at the 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively

Conclusions education, his cognitive style, his appreciation of the dif-


ferences between expendable and branded products, and
The following are the main conclusions of this work for the product performance. Dealer loyalty, on the other hand, is
Argentinian Ag equipment market. First, the results show explained by the farmer’s age and residency, the percentage
that even if brand loyalty and dealer loyalty to agricultural of rented land, and his/her gross sales volume. No evidence
capital equipment are related, the factors that determine supporting the idea that the variables ‘relationship with
brand and dealer loyalty are not the same. Brand loyalty dealer’ and ‘price’ affect dealer loyalty and brand loyalty
depends on five explanatory variables: the farmer’s age and
P. Harmath et al.

was found. Also ‘farm size’ and ‘media sources’ do not seem happens in the car industry, which is an industrial market
to explain either brand or dealer loyalty. that shares some similar characteristics with agricultural
The results establish that farmers will tend to be more machinery. However, unlike the automotive market, where
loyal to capital equipment brands if they are young, have the customer goes to the dealer when he needs to make a
received a less formal education, and are more analytic, if trade, in the agricultural machinery market the relationship
they can perceive the difference between expendable and with the dealer is much closer, precisely because the farmer
branded products, and if they value the product performance. is buying a capital good, which requires reviewing, repair-
Also, farmers will tend to be more loyal to the Ag capital ing, advising on use, etc.
equipment dealer if they are younger, live near the farm, rent This third conclusion establishes that achieving dual
more land, and have larger gross sales. loyalty is a very challenging goal, as the farmer fulfilling
This first conclusion establishes that dealer loyalty is this profile would have to sum up the factors explaining
more linked to demographic and farm characteristics, while both brand and dealer loyalty, when considered separately,
brand loyalty relates to a combination of demographic data plus the preference for personal and traditional communi-
and farm, characteristics, farmers’ beliefs and attitudes, cation media.
product characteristics, and media exposure. Thus, the contribution of this paper is to have defined
Second, considering how brand loyalty impacts dealer the factors that explain brand and dealer loyalty for capi-
loyalty and vice versa, we found that the influence of one tal equipment, as well as the interplay between these two
type of loyalty over the other is strictly bi-univocal: none of loyalties, in the agribusiness context using probit models,
the two loyalties predominate, as each needs the other. The which has scarcely been researched up to now. This not
results show that among producers loyal to dealers they will only contributes to the literature but also has interesting
have a 52.80% better chance of being brand loyal, compared business implications, such as that Ag equipment compa-
to producers considered disloyal to these dealers. Producers nies should invest in understanding the factors that drive
loyal to agricultural machinery brands will have a 45.82% agricultural producers to purchase agricultural equipment.
better chance of being loyal to dealers, compared to produc- This would help them to identify the purchasing factors
ers considered disloyal to these brands. However, it is not and segment farmers accordingly and develop appropriate
possible to establish a hierarchy for which type of loyalty marketing strategies to attract different types of producers.
exerts the greatest influence over the other. A second implication is the advantage for a given capital
This is consistent with comments from Ag equipment equipment branded product to strengthen its distribution
managers we interviewed, who consider that in Argentina channel, which calls for a cooperative relationship between
the agricultural machinery purchasing process is a result of manufacturers and dealers. A third implication is that in
a combination of the two loyalties. A good brand with a order to reach loyal farmers, Ag equipment companies
poor dealership will negatively impact the brand, and a good should identify the best communication channels. In the
dealership without a brand has no sales. Argentine context, agricultural producer mostly appreci-
This second conclusion determines that neither of the two ates the information received first-hand, face-to-face, and
types of loyalty individually prevails over the other, and both the information obtained through the Internet and social
are required to attract customers and commit them to pur- networks was the least appreciated by producers by the
chase the Ag equipment. This result differs from the one time they were surveyed. However, this will surely change
obtained by Harbor (2006), which concluded that the statisti- in different contexts and time, which should be the object
cal factors that directly impact dealer loyalty may indirectly of future studies.
impact brand loyalty. The limitations of this work are related to the specific-
Third, we also identified the factors that explain dual ity of the information used, as the data was obtained in a
loyalty, represented by the sum of factors explaining brand 2017 survey from a geographic region (Humid Pampa, in
loyalty and dealer loyalty plus the use of traditional media or Argentina), for agricultural producers who operate farms
personal communication by farmers. This third conclusion of at least 200–300 hectares. Our estimations were made
ratifies conclusions one and two, as it considers the same in a specific time framework, they are of the cross-section
factors that explain brand loyal and dealer loyalty separately, type, with information of several periods we will be able
adding another factor which is the personal and traditional to make panel estimations. Also, a large number of media
communication media. communication variables were included in this survey, and
This conclusion is conceptually similar to the one reached time and technological changes tend to change farmers’
by Harbor (2006) who established that activities that asso- communication preferences.
ciate the dealer with the brand are likely to help to build Future research should be directed in search for panel-
dual loyalty (loyalty to brands and dealers) in the agricul- based data to analyze this same situation for farmers who
tural machinery market. This would be analogous to what were already surveyed, in order to see if the loyalty factors
Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment

change over time. Likewise, the possibility of compar-


ing the behavior of this market with other similar ones in
other regions seems interesting, whether or not it has panel
data. Also, we could develop a conceptual framework to
analyze, from a qualitative perspective, how the differ-
ent dimensions of variables defined in Table 1 affect the
diverse types of loyalties in the agricultural machinery
market, similarly as done by Dhiman and Arora (2020) for

− 25.29***
− 10.81***

34.66***

10.13***

24.54***
2.09**
the hospitality industry in India. It would also be interest-
ing to analyze loyalty in the capital equipment market from

t-test
a value chain approach, following the work presented by
Ho et al. (2019).

Appendix A: Cluster analysis


for the construction of the dependent
variables

T-mean sample comparison test with unequal variances. (*), (**) and (***) indicate significance at the 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively
24% (100–76%)

79% (100–21%)

39% (100–61%)
% of response
As it has been done in previous work such as Roucan-Kane

Cluster 2
et al. (2011), we apply cluster analysis to identify groups of

n = 382
producers based on their loyalty to capital equipment brands

76%

26%

8%
and dealers, using the options available in questions 40 and
41 of the “The Needs of the Argentine Agricultural Pro-
ducer” questionnaire:

a. I will do more business with this brand/dealer.

Levene's test for equality of variances was performed for each variable and was significant at p < 0.01
b. I endorse this brand/dealer to my neighbors.
c. I try products from other brands/dealers.
d. I would switch to another brand/dealer to save 5%.
% of response

e. I would switch to another brand/dealer to save 10%.


Cluster 1
n = 182

f. I am loyal to this brand/dealer (I do not change brands/


100%

100%

100%

85%
68%

70%

dealers even if prices increase more than 10%).


Table 8  Cluster solution for capital equipment brand loyalty with two groups

To interpret the results, options c, d and e are considered


responses associated with disloyalty, since they show a dis-
position to switch brands (even when this switching may not
happen in practice). On the other hand, options a, b and f are
considered replies associated with loyalty, since they imply
that the producer is somehow involved with the brand (he
49% (100–51%)

86% (100–14%)

59% (100–41%)
% of response

would not switch even with higher prices, recommend it to


neighbors or seek to do more business with it).
n = 564
Total

We use a hierarchical clustering agglomeration method


33%
73%

40%

called linkage by averages between groups or inter-groups,


proposed by Sokal and Michener (1958). We calculate the
change brand if the price increases
I am loyal to this brand (I would not
DID NOT SELECT I would change

DID NOT SELECT I would change


DID NOT SELECT I try different

brand if the price increases 10%

similarities between the individuals in the sample based on


I will do more business with this

brand if the price increases 5%


I recommend this brand to other

the binary Euclidean distance since the variables selected


to carry out the cluster analyzes are all qualitative, each one
brands of this product

with two response categories, 0: no and 1: yes.


In Table 8, we observe a first group of 182 produc-
ers who will continue doing business with the brand and
Characteristic

show a strong commitment to it. They recommend the


farmers
brand

brand to their neighbors, and none of them try different


10%)

products nor will switch brands facing a 5% or even a


Table 9  Cluster solution for capital equipment dealer loyalty with two groups
Characteristic Total Cluster 1 Cluster 2 t-test
n = 564 n = 299 n = 265
% of response % of response % of response

I will do more business with this 74% 78% 69% − 2.38**


dealer
I recommend this dealer to other 47% 63% 28% − 8.87***
farmers
DID NOT SELECT I try different 57% (100–43%) 97% (100–3%) 13% (100–87%) 35.82***
dealers of this product
DID NOT SELECT I would change 88% (100–12%) 98% (100–2%) 77% (100–23%) 7.64***
dealer if the price increases 5%
DID NOT SELECT I would change 66% (1–34%) 83% (100–17%) 48% (100–52%) 9.29***
dealer if the price increases 10%
I am loyal to this dealer (I would not 27% 48% 3% − 14.43***
change dealer if the price increases
10%)

T-mean sample comparison test with unequal variances. (*), (**) and (***) indicate significance at the 0.10, 0.05 and 0.01, respectively
Levene's test for equality of variances was performed for each variable and was significant at p < 0.01
P. Harmath et al.
Producers’ brand‑dealer dual loyalty to capital equipment

10% price increase. Additionally, 85% of them claim that Anisimova, T., and F. Mavondo. 2014. Aligning company and dealer
they would stick to the brand even when facing a price perspectives in corporate branding: Implications for dealer satis-
faction and commitment. Journal of Business-to-Business Market-
increase above 10%. This group of producers can be con- ing 21: 35–56. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1080/​10517​12X.​2014.​857501.
sidered ‘empirically loyal’ to capital equipment brands. Cameron, A.C., and P.K. Trivedi. 2005. Microeconometrics: Methods
On the other hand, a second group includes 382 produc- and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
ers, which are ‘empirically disloyal’ to capital equipment Cassia, F., N. Cobelli, and M. Ugolini. 2017. The effects of goods-
related and service related B2B brand images on customer loyalty.
brands. With respect to dealer loyalty, as we see in Table Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing 32: 722–732. https://​
9, the first cluster is a group of 299 producers, whom we doi.​org/​10.​1108/​JBIM-​05-​2016-​0095.
call ‘empirically loyal’ to the dealer. In the second cluster, Dhiman, P., and S. Arora. 2020. A conceptual framework for identify-
there is a different group of producers, whom we call the ing key employee branding dimensions: A study of hospitality
industry. Journal of Innovation & Knowledge 5 (3): 200–209.
‘empirically disloyal’. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1016/j.​jik.​2019.​08.​003.
In both cluster solutions, we may see that the t-tests for Ewing, M.T. 2000. Brand and retailer loyalty: Past behavior and future
percentage comparison (assuming that the population vari- intentions. The Journal of Product and Brand Management 9:
ances are different) indicate that the differences for each 120–127.
Greene, W.H. 2012. Econometric analysis. Hoboken: Prentice-Hall
variable between the groups are statistically significant. Publishing, Pearson Education Limited.
Therefore, we can conclude that there are two significantly Glynn, M.S. 2010. The moderating effect of brand strength in manufac-
different groups in terms of brand loyalty and dealer loy- turer–reseller relationships. Industrial Marketing Management 39:
alty, as defined by the combination of six proposed vari- 1226–1233. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1016/j.​indma​rman.​2010.​02.​019.
Harbor, A. 2006. Assessing agricultural input brand loyalty among
ables; that is, the cluster solutions are statistically valid. United States mid-size and commercial producers. Doctoral dis-
Consequently, in terms of dual loyalty, we identify 156 sertation, Purdue University, West Lafayette, Indiana.
producers considered loyal to both brands and dealers, 26 Ho, K.L.P., C.N. Nguyen, R. Adhikari, M.P. Miles, and L. Bonney.
loyal to brands and disloyal to dealers, 143 loyal to deal- 2019. Leveraging innovation knowledge management to cre-
ate positional advantage in agricultural value chains. Journal
ers and disloyal to brands, and 239 producers considered of Innovation & Knowledge 4 (2): 115–123. https://​doi.​org/​10.​
disloyal to both brands and dealers. 1016/j.​jik.​2017.​08.​001.
Huber, F., and A. Herrmann. 2001. Achieving brand and dealer loy-
Acknowledgements  Not applicable. alty: The case of the automotive industry. The International
Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research 11:
Author contributions  All authors contributed to the design of the work. 97–122. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1080/​71377​0584.
PH and JRP analyzed and interpreted data. RF and PH drafted the work. Kool, M., M. Meulenberg, and D. Browns. 1997. Extensiveness of
JRP revised it. All authors read and approved the final manuscript. farmers’ buying processes. Agribusiness 13: 301–318.
Lynch, J., and L. De Chernatony. 2004. The power of emotion-brand
communication in business-to-business markets. Journal of
Funding  Not applicable. Brand Management 11: 403–419. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1057/​palgr​
ave.​bm.​25401​85.
Availability of data and materials  The dataset supporting the conclu- Leek, S., and G. Christodoulides. 2012. A framework of brand
sions of this article is available from the Universidad Austral. Restric- value in B2B markets: The contributing role of functional and
tions apply to the availability of this data, which were used under emotional components. Industrial Marketing Management 41:
license for this study. Data are available from the authors with the 106–114. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1016/j.​indma​r man.​2011.​11.​009.
permission of the Universidad Austral. Mohammadi, Z.M., P. Mac Clay, R. Feeney, P. Harmath, M. Kes-
havarz, and M.A. Gunderson. 2020. Characterization of farm-
Declarations  ers’ management practices and strategies: A comparison
between Argentine and U.S. farmers. International Food and
Agribusiness Management Review 23: 235–251.
Competing interests  The authors declare that they have no competing Mudambi, S. 2002. Branding importance in business-to-business
interests. markets: Three buyer clusters. Industrial Marketing Manage-
ment 31: 525–533. https://​d oi.​o rg/​1 0.​1 016/​S 0019-​8 501(02)​
00184-0.
Nyström, A.G., J.A. Törnroos, N. Koporcic, and M. Ivanova-Gongne.
References 2018. Summary: Branding in the B2B context and future chal-
lenges. In Developing insights on branding in the B2B context,
Ag Equipment Intelligence. 2018. Brand Loyalty in the Farm Equip- ed. N. Koporcic, M. Ivanova-Gongne, A.G. Nyström, and J.A.
ment Business. https://​www.​farm-​equip​ment.​com/​ext/​resou​rces/​ Törnroos, 219–229. Bingley: Emerald Publishing Limited. https://​
aei/​Repor​ts/​AEI_​Brand-​Loyal​ty-​in-​the-​Farm-​Equip​ment-​Busin​ doi.​org/​10.​1108/​978-1-​78756-​275-​22018​1013.
ess_​Report_​0418_​web.​pdf. Accessed 6 Mar 2021. Reportlinker. 2019. The global agriculture equipment market size is
Akaeze, C.O., and N.A.S. Akaeze. 2017. Exploring factors that influ- expected to reach USD 244.2 billion by 2025, expanding at a
ence consumer loyalty to automotive dealership in New York. CAGR of 8.9% from 2019 to 2025. https://w ​ ww.p​ rnews​ wire.c​ om/​
Journal of Business Theory and Practice 5: 98–119. https://​doi.​ news-​relea​ses/​the-​global-​agric​ulture-​equip​ment-​market-​size-​is-​
org/​10.​22158/​jbtp.​v5n2p​98. expec​ted-​to-​reach-​usd-​244-2-​billi​on-​by-​2025--​expan​ding-​at-a-​
cagr-​of-8-​9-​from-​2019-​to-​2025--​30079​4964.​html. Accessed 6
Mar 2021.
P. Harmath et al.

Roucan-Kane, M., C. Alexander, M. Boehlje, S. Downey, and A. Gray. Strategy & Management 5(3): 252–265. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1108/​
2011. A large commercial producer market segments for agri- 17554​25121​12475​62
cultural capital equipment. International Food and Agribusiness
Management Review 14: 127–143. Publisher's Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to
Seyedghorban, Z., M.J. Matanda, and P. La Placa. 2016. Advancing jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
theory and knowledge in the business-to-business branding lit-
erature. Journal of Business Research 69: 2664–2677. https://​doi.​
org/​10.​1016/j.​jbusr​es.​2015.​11.​002.
Seyoum, S. 2018. Analysis of prevalence of malaria and anemia using Pedro Harmath  Associate Professor and researcher of the School of
bivariate probit model. Annals of Data Science 5: 301–312. Business Sciences, Department of Mathematics, Universidad Austral,
https://​doi.​org/​10.​1007/​s40745-​018-​0138-3. Argentina. He has a Ph.D. in Mathematics (Universidad Centrocciden-
Sokal, R.R., and C.D. Michener. 1958. A statistical method for evaluat- tal Lisandro Alvarado), a Master’s in Quantitative Economics (Univer-
ing systematic relationship. University of Kansas Scientific Bul- sidad de Los Andes) and a Bachelor’s Degree in Statistics (Universidad
letin 28: 1409–1438. de Los Andes). He does research in applied statistics in the fields of
Verhoef, P.C., F. Langerak, and B. Donkers. 2007. Understanding brand agricultural economics and behavioral economics.
and dealer retention in the new car market: The moderating role
of brand tier. Journal of Retailing 83: 97–114. https://​doi.​org/​10.​ Roberto Feeney  Associate Professor of the Center for Food and Agri-
1016/j.​jretai.​2006.​10.​007. business, Universidad Austral, Argentina. His educational background
Viardot, E. 2017. Branding in B2B: The value of consumer goods includes a Ph.D. in Business Administration, MBA, and a bachelor’s
brands in industrial markets. Journal of Business and Indus- degree in Economics. His main research interest is on topics such as
trial Marketing 32: 337–346. https:// ​ d oi. ​ o rg/ ​ 1 0. ​ 1 108/​ innovation management, bio-based economics, Ag value chains, and
JBIM-​11-​2014-​0225. behavioral economics and agribusiness decision making.
Walley, K., P. Custance, S. Taylor, A. Lindgreen, and M. Hingley. 2007.
The importance of brand in the industrial purchase decision: A Josefa Ramoni‑Perazzi  Full Professor of the Escuela de Economía,
case study of the UK tractor market. Journal of Business & Indus- Universidad Industrial de Santander (Bucaramanga, Santander, Colom-
trial Marketing 2: 383–393. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1108/​08858​62071​ bia). She has a Bachelor´s Degree in Economics (Venezuela), M.Sc.
07801​45. in Statistics (Venezuela) and in Economics (USA), and a PhD. in Eco-
Wooldridge, J.M. 2010. Econometric analysis of cross section and nomics (USA). Member of the research group in Regional Develop-
panel data. Cambridge: The MIT Press. ment and Territorial Planning (GIDROT-UIS) and Study Group on
Hinterhuber, A., and Hinterhuber, G. 2012. An empirical analysis of Applied Microeconomics and Regulation (EMAR-UIS).
the role of industrial brands for industrial distributors. Journal of

You might also like