You are on page 1of 13

The Effects of Price on

Alcohol Consumption and

Alcohol-Related Problems

Frank J. Chaloupka, Ph.D., Michael Grossman, Ph.D., Henry Saffer, Ph.D.

The most fundamental law of economics links the price of a product to the demand for that product.
Accordingly, increases in the monetary price of alcohol (i.e., through tax increases) would be
expected to lower alcohol consumption and its adverse consequences. Studies investigating such a
relationship found that alcohol prices were one factor influencing alcohol consumption among youth
and young adults. Other studies determined that increases in the total price of alcohol can reduce
drinking and driving and its consequences among all age groups; lower the frequency of diseases,
injuries, and deaths related to alcohol use and abuse; and reduce alcohol-related violence and other
crime. KEY WORDS: alcohol or other drug (AOD) price; economic theory of AOD use (AODU); elasticity
of demand; underage drinking; minimum drinking age; drinking and driving; AOD related (AODR)
accident mortality; AOD availability; AODR injury; AODR crime; AODR violence; sales and excise tax

S
ince the early 1980s, a growing between alcohol price and alcohol con­ abuse are sensitive to price, as economists
number of economists have exam­ sumption clearly are relevant for policy- have found, however, a decrease in the
ined the impact of the price of makers interested in reducing alcohol real value of alcoholic beverage taxes
alcoholic beverages on alcohol consump­ consumption and its adverse conse­ and, consequently, prices will exacerbate
tion. Other studies have evaluated the quences. Indeed, Federal, State, and the problems associated with alcohol
effects of price on various outcomes local governments have implemented use and abuse. Governments may be
related to alcohol consumption, includ­ many policies to combat alcohol abuse reluctant to increase taxes to discourage
ing nonfatal and fatal motor vehicle in the past two decades (see sidebar). alcohol abuse, however, because the
crashes and other injuries, liver cirrho­ One policy that has largely been increased taxes raise prices not only for
sis and other alcohol-related mortality, ignored, however, is an increase in the alcohol abusers but also for light and
and violence and other crime. This monetary price of alcohol, which could moderate drinkers who do not abuse
research, which has used a wide variety be achieved by raising taxes on alcoholic alcohol and therefore do not need to be
of data, generally has concluded that beverages. At least in part as a result of discouraged from drinking. (For more
increases in the prices of alcoholic bev­ this stability of Federal, State, and local detailed discussion of the appropriate
erages lead to reductions in drinking alcoholic beverage taxes, the real prices level of alcohol taxation in this context,
and heavy drinking as well as in the of alcoholic beverages (i.e., the prices see Pogue and Sgontz 1989; Saffer and
consequences of alcohol use and abuse. after accounting for the effects of infla­ Chaloupka 1994.)
This conclusion concurs with a funda­ tion) have declined significantly over This article reviews studies that have
mental law of economics called the time. For example, between 1975 and analyzed the effects of price increases
downward sloping demand curve, which 1990, the real price of distilled spirits on alcohol consumption and its adverse
states that as the price of a product rises, fell by 32 percent, the real price of wine consequences. After discussing some
the quantity demanded of that product fell by 28 percent, and the real price analytical considerations, the article
falls. Since the price of alcohol can be of beer fell by 20 percent.1 A Federal
manipulated through excise tax policies, tax increase in 1991 only temporarily 1
These computations are based on Bureau of Labor Statistics
the findings regarding the relationship reversed this trend. If alcohol use and data from various years.

22 Alcohol Research & Health


Effects of Price on Alcohol Consumption and Consequences

focuses on the effects of alcohol prices Analytical Considerations studies attempt to control for as many
and taxes on consumption by youths confounding variables (i.e., variables
and young adults. It then considers the Economic studies of alcohol demand that may be correlated with price and
impacts of prices and taxes on indica­ focus mainly on the effects of price on consumption) as possible, these efforts
tors of alcohol abuse, such as motor alcohol consumption. To describe the can never be complete. These caveats
vehicle crashes, health effects, and vio­ sensitivity of consumption to changes place limits on the ability to infer
lence and other crime, among drinkers in monetary price, economists fre­ cause-and-effect relationships from the
of all ages, including youths and young quently refer to the price elasticity of study findings.
adults. The studies discussed in this demand2 (i.e., the percentage change Another consideration when analyz­
article capitalize on the substantial varia­ in consumption resulting from a 1- ing price effects on alcohol consump­
tion in alcohol prices across the United percent increase in price). For example, tion is the potentially addictive nature
States that exists primarily as a result of a price elasticity of alcohol demand of of alcohol. Next to cigarette smoking,
the vastly differing State excise tax rates -0.5 means that a 1-percent increase in excessive drinking is the most common
on alcoholic beverages. Most of the price would reduce alcohol consumption example of legally consuming an addic­
studies employ the price of beer or the by 0.5 percent (or a 10-percent increase tive substance. However, alcohol and
State excise tax on beer as a measure of in price would reduce consumption by tobacco are linked to adverse health
the cost of alcohol because beer is the 5 percent). An extensive review of the outcomes and to addiction in different
beverage of choice among Americans, economic literature on alcohol demand ways. For example, overwhelming evi­
particularly among youths. concluded that based on studies using dence indicates that any level of smok­
aggregate data (i.e., data that report the ing has detrimental health effects.
amount of alcohol consumed by large Furthermore, a large proportion of
FRANK J. CHALOUPKA, PH.D., is a profes­ groups of people), the price elasticities smokers become addicted to nicotine
sor in the Department of Economics and of demand for beer, wine, and distilled and therefore smoke a substantial quan­
director of ImpacTeen: A Policy Research spirits are -0.3, -1.0, and -1.5, respec­ tity of cigarettes each day. Accordingly,
Partnership to Reduce Youth Substance tively (Leung and Phelps 1993).3 These researchers can usually focus their anal­
Abuse at the Health Research and Policy estimates suggest that beer consumption yses on whether and how much a per-
Centers, University of Illinois at Chicago, is relatively insensitive to price changes, son smokes because these measures are
Chicago, Illinois. He is also a research asso­ whereas demand for wine and distilled highly correlated with the smoking-
ciate in the Health Economics Program, spirits is very responsive to price. related costs of interest.
National Bureau of Economic Research Analyses using individual-level data With alcohol, however, the situation
(NBER), New York. (i.e., data that report the amount of is more complex. Many people regularly
alcohol consumed by specific persons) consume small quantities of alcohol
MICHAEL GROSSMAN, PH.D., is a research suggest that alcohol demand may be without becoming addicted. Further-
associate and director of the Health Economics even more responsive to price than these more, most people who drink alcohol
Program, NBER, and Distinguished estimates indicate, possibly because this do not harm themselves or others;
Professor of Economics at the City University approach can obtain differential price indeed, moderate alcohol consumption
of New York Graduate Center, New York. responses among respondents of different has been shown to lower the risk of
age groups (Leung and Phelps 1993). coronary heart disease in men (Camargo
HENRY SAFFER, PH.D., is a research asso­ More recent studies have confirmed et al. 1997). The adverse effects of
ciate in the Health Economics Program, the price responsiveness of alcohol con­ alcohol, such as liver cirrhosis, drunk-
NBER, New York, and professor of eco­ sumption (Nelson 1999; Kenkel 1993, driving crashes, workplace injuries, and
nomics at Kean University of New Jersey, 1996; Manning et al. 1995). various forms of violent behavior, pri­
Union, New Jersey. One consideration that must be marily result from excessive consump­
kept in mind when interpreting price tion (regardless of whether the person is
Research described in this paper was sup- effects such as those discussed through- actually addicted to alcohol). Researchers
ported by National Institute on Alcohol out this article is that these effects are must consider these complex interactions
Abuse and Alcoholism (NIAAA) grants not based on natural experiments. For (e.g., specific drinking patterns) when
RO1–AA–05849, RO1–AA–07593, example, no data are available comparing exploring the relationship between
RO1–AA–08359, and RO1–AA–10817 the amounts of alcohol consumed by alcohol price and alcohol consumption
and National Institute on Drug Abuse individuals or groups at different prices, or alcohol-related adverse effects.
(NIDA) grant RO1–DA–07111 to the with all other variables held constant.
NBER. This article has not undergone Instead, researchers use cross-sectional
the review accorded official NBER publi­ data, which measure consumption for 2
For a definition of this and other economic terms used in
cations; in particular, it has not been sub­ individuals or groups at a given moment this article, see the glossary, p. 32.
mitted for approval by the board of direc­ in time, or time series of such cross- 3
Leung and Phelps (1993) emphasize that these numbers
tors. Any opinions are those of the authors sectional analyses from more than 1 represent “best guesses” because of the wide range of
and not of NIAAA, NIDA, or the NBER. year. And although investigators in these estimates contained in the studies reviewed.

Vol. 26, No. 1, 2002 23


Policies Affecting the Price of
Alcohol and Alcohol Consumption

The major policy element of U.S. programs to deter upon conviction raised the expected legal costs of
teenage and young adult drinking has been to increase drinking and driving.
State minimum legal drinking ages (MLDAs). This Many States and localities also have adopted poli­
trend began in 1976 with the increase in the MLDA in cies that raise the time costs associated with obtaining
Minnesota from 18 to 19 years of age. An additional 27 alcoholic beverages or otherwise reduce alcohol avail-
States had increased their MLDAs by the time Congress ability for all drinkers. For example, these policies
passed the Federal Uniform Drinking Age Act of 1984. include regulations that limit the places and/or times
This Act pressured all States into raising the MLDA to where alcohol can be sold, restrict or ban “happy
21 years by withholding part of their Federal highway hours,” require server training and/or licensing, and
funding if they failed to comply. After an unsuccessful hold servers liable for the harmful actions related to the
challenge to the law’s constitutionality, all States raised excessive drinking of those they are serving.
their MLDAs to 21 years by July 1988.1 In addition, sev­ One policy that has only rarely been used, however,
eral States have recently adopted laws targeting underage is an increase in the monetary price of alcohol, which
drinking drivers by making it per se illegal to drive either could be achieved by raising taxes on alcoholic beverages.
with blood alcohol concentrations (BACs) well below During the past 50 years, Federal, State, and local taxes
those considered the legal limit of intoxication in adults on alcohol have been raised only modestly and infre­
(i.e., 0.08 to 0.1 percent) or, in some States, with any quently and almost always with the intent of increasing
measurable BACs. These measures have made it more revenues rather than discouraging alcohol use and
difficult for youths to obtain alcohol and have increased abuse. For example, Title XI of the Omnibus Budget
the expected legal costs of drinking by imposing fines for Reconciliation Act of 1990 increased Federal excise tax
the possession of alcohol and for drinking and driving by rates on beer and wine for the first time since November
underage people. 1951 and the tax on distilled spirits for only the second
Other policies in the campaign to discourage alco­ time during this period.2 This act doubled the tax on
hol abuse have targeted all drinkers, and some mea­ beer from 16 cents to 32 cents per six-pack; raised the
sures have targeted abusive drinkers. For example, tax on wine nearly sevenfold, from just over 3 cents to
Public Law 100–690 mandated that, beginning in about 21 cents per 750-ml bottle; and increased the
November 1989, a label warning of the dangers of tax on distilled spirits from $2 to $2.16 per fifth of
drinking and driving, alcohol consumption during 80-proof alcohol.
pregnancy, and other (unspecified) health conse­ Although some evidence suggests that Congress may
quences of drinking appear on all alcoholic beverage have been motivated by the health promotion aspects
containers. By raising awareness of potential health of higher alcoholic-beverage taxes (Cook and Moore
consequences of drinking, such warning labels can 1993), these increases fell well short of those recom­
increase consumers’ perceptions of the costs associated mended by several public health organizations (Godfrey
with drinking alcoholic beverages. 1990). The increases also left the tax rates well below
Similarly, the Alcohol Traffic Safety Act of 1983 the 25 cents per ounce of pure alcohol in any beverage
encouraged States to enact hundreds of new and that initially had been proposed by the first Bush
stronger laws related to driving under the influence of Administration (Godfrey 1990). Thus, the Federal excise
alcohol (DUI). For example, these measures eased the tax rates resulting from the 1991 tax increase are approx­
standards required for arresting and convicting drunk imately 10 cents, 7 cents, and 21 cents per ounce of
drivers, imposed more severe and certain penalties pure alcohol for beer, wine, and distilled spirits, respec­
upon conviction for drunk driving, and increased the tively. Furthermore, these tax increases failed to offset
allocation of resources for apprehending drunk drivers. inflation since 1951. For example, the tax on distilled
Again, such increases in the probabilities of arrest and spirits would have needed to increase to approximately
conviction for drunk driving as well as in the penalties $8.80 per fifth of 80-proof liquor (i.e., approximately

24 Alcohol Research & Health


Effects of Price on Alcohol Consumption and Consequences

fourfold higher) to have the same real value as this tax Bethesda, MD: National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism,
had in 1951. Similarly, the tax on beer would have needed 1993. pp. 33–58.
to increase more than fivefold to 84 cents per six-pack to GODFREY, J. Alcohol taxes: From the whiskey rebellion to the 1990 budget
offset inflation. Only the increase in the wine tax was summit. Tax Notes 48(2):137, 1990.
large enough to offset the effects of inflation since 1951.3
The potential effects of greater increases in the mone­
tary price of alcohol are explored in the feature article.
1
So-called grandfather clauses in some States kept the effective age below 21 until
— Frank J. Chaloupka, mid-1989.
Michael Grossman, Henry Saffer
2
Excise taxes differ from sales taxes in that they are a flat tax amount based on the
quantity purchased rather than a certain percentage of the purchase price. Generally,
References excise taxes are not paid directly by consumers but are passed on to consumers in
the form of higher retail prices. In contrast, consumers pay a sales tax directly when
COOK, P.J., AND MOORE, M.J. Taxation of alcoholic beverages. In: Hilton, they make a purchase.
M.E., and Bloss, G., eds. Economics and the Prevention of Alcohol-Related
Problems. NIAAA Research Monograph No. 25, NIH Pub. No. 93–3513. 3
These computations are based on Bureau of Labor Statistics data from various years.

Drinking by Youths Two studies estimated the effects levels among the youth, including light
and Young Adults of price on alcohol use by youths ages drinkers who consumed one or two
16 to 21 using data from the National cans of beer, fairly heavy drinkers who
Much of the alcohol-related economic Health and Nutrition Examination consumed three to five cans, and heavy
research considers alcohol consumption Surveys (Grossman et al. 1987; Coate drinkers who consumed six or more
by all segments of the population. and Grossman 1988). The data were cans on a typical drinking day. Again,
Nevertheless, it is crucial to focus on collected in two cycles of surveys con­ the fractions of fairly heavy and heavy
the price sensitivity of youth and young- ducted from 1971 to 1975 and from drinkers declined more in both abso­
adult drinking and heavy drinking 1976 to 1980, respectively. Both stud­ lute and percentage terms than did the
because the incidence of alcohol-related ies concluded that beer consumption is fraction of light drinkers in response to
problems, particularly drinking and inversely related to both the monetary price increases.
driving, is disproportionately high among price of beer and the State minimum Laixuthai and Chaloupka (1993)
these age groups. Fatal motor vehicle legal drinking age (MLDA). The stud­ updated this research using data from
crashes are the leading cause of death of ies also evaluated whether the effects the 1982 and 1989 surveys of high school
people under the age of 35, and alco­ of price differ according to the youths’ seniors conducted by the University of
hol is involved in more than one-half consumption patterns. To this end, the Michigan’s Institute for Social Research
of these fatal crashes. In 1995, fatalities investigators classified the youths into as part of the Monitoring the Future
per car miles of travel of people between infrequent drinkers who consumed project. The analyses used three differ­
the ages of 16 and 24 were more than beer less than once per week, fairly fre­ ent measures of alcohol consumption
twice as large as those of people ages quent drinkers who consumed beer one that were constructed from the survey
25 and over (Dee and Evans 2001). to three times per week, and frequent data, as follows:
Moreover, abuse of and dependence drinkers who consumed beer four to
on alcohol are highest among people seven times per week. These analyses • Drinking frequency in the past year,
between the ages of 18 and 29 (Grant found that higher prices and MLDAs which classified youths as frequent
et al. 1991). Finally, it is important to reduced not only the fraction of youths drinkers (more than 30 drinking
focus on the young because alcohol abuse who drank beer infrequently but that occasions in the past year), fairly fre­
in adolescence appears to be associated the fractions of youths who consumed quent drinkers (10 to 30 drinking
with alcohol abuse in later life (Rachal beer fairly frequently and frequently occasions), infrequent drinkers (1 to
et al. 1980). Consequently, policies to declined more in both absolute and 9 drinking occasions), or abstainers
curb alcohol abuse by youths and percentage terms than did the fraction (no drinking in the past year)
young adults might be the most effec­ of infrequent drinkers when prices
tive means to curb it in all segments of rose. The investigators also conducted • Drinking frequency in the past
the population. similar analyses for different drinking month, which was structured similarly

Vol. 26, No. 1, 2002 25


• The presence of at least one binge- tion. Conversely, when the average MLDA of underage college women who drank
drinking occasion (i.e., consump­ and the associated indirect costs of alco­ in the past year by about 15 percent
tion of five or more drinks on one hol are high (as in the 1989 sample), and the number of underage and older
occasion) in the 2 weeks prior to a similar increase in alcohol taxes will college women engaging in any binge
the survey. These binge-drinking have a relatively small impact on the drinking by roughly 20 percent. In
occasions, which serve as an indicator full price of alcohol and on consump­ contrast to these statistically significant
of heavy drinking, are most likely tion. Accordingly, high school seniors negative effects of price on underage
to have negative consequences and, in 1989, who faced higher indirect drinking and binge drinking by female
therefore, are of most concern to costs of obtaining alcohol than their students, no such effect was found for
policymakers. 1982 counterparts, responded less to male students.
changes in the monetary costs. The insignificant effects of price on
The researchers analyzed the 1982 drinking among male college students
and 1989 samples separately to exam­ and the relatively small effects for female
ine potential changes in the price sensi­ college students likely result, at least
tivity of youth alcohol use resulting in part, from errors in the measure of
from the introduction of a uniform Higher beer excise price used (Chaloupka and Wechsler
MLDA of 21 years in all States. For
both years, higher beer excise taxes sig­
taxes significantly 1996). Researchers generally use aver-
age local retail prices as a measure of
nificantly reduced both the frequency reduced both the the monetary price of alcohol, thereby
of youth drinking and the probability neglecting alcohol consumption that
of heavy drinking. As with the studies frequency of youth occurs at parties or other occasions at
by Grossman and colleagues (1987)
and Coate and Grossman (1988), the
drinking and the which the drinker does not pay retail
price for the alcohol. Such errors are a
estimates implied that a tax increase probability of general problem in econometric studies
would reduce the fractions of frequent of alcohol demand using individual-
and fairly frequent young drinkers to heavy drinking. level data but likely are more significant
a greater extent than the fraction of when studying college students, for
infrequent drinkers. More interestingly, whom average local retail prices may
Laixuthai and Chaloupka (1993) also not be a good proxy for the prices paid
found that the price sensitivity of youth Chaloupka and Wechsler (1996) by the student. For example, much of
drinking fell after the MLDA of 21 years examined the effects of various factors the drinking among college students,
was enacted in all States. For example, on drinking and binge drinking among particularly binge drinking, takes place
the investigators estimated that an increase students in U.S. colleges and universi­ at parties where alcohol is available at
in the Federal beer tax offsetting the effect ties. The analyses were based on data no charge or at local bars that offer
of inflation since 1951 would have from the 1993 Harvard College Alcohol sharply discounted prices to attract col­
reduced the probability of having any Survey, which included a nationally lege students.
binge-drinking episodes by 18.4 percent representative sample of 17,592 students
in 1982 but only by 6.5 percent in 1989. enrolled at 140 U.S. 4-year colleges and
Laixuthai and Chaloupka (1993) universities. The alcohol-related factors
Studies Accounting for the
attributed this change in the price sen­ evaluated included beer prices, alcohol
Addictive Nature of Alcohol
sitivity of youth drinking to the change availability (i.e., the presence of an on- At least for some consumers, the demand
in the full price of drinking resulting campus bar and the number of alcohol for alcoholic beverages may differ from
from the higher MLDAs in 1989. For outlets within 1 mile of the campus), the demands for most other consumer
a youth, the full price of consuming and policies related to driving under the products because of the addictive
alcohol can be thought of as the mone­ influence (DUI) (i.e., a State-level index nature of alcohol. Prior to the work by
tary price of alcohol plus the indirect reflecting the restrictiveness of the State’s Becker and Murphy (1988), economic
costs of illegal drinking. These indirect drunk-driving laws targeting youths). models of addiction assumed myopic
costs include such legal obstacles as the The investigators estimated the behavior in which consumers ignore
MLDA, the time spent obtaining alco­ potential results of a policy that would the future consequences of their current
hol, and the money and time spent have equated the tax on the alcohol in actions. Becker and Murphy (1988)
obtaining false identification. When beer to the tax on the alcohol in dis­ developed a theoretical model that
the average MLDA and, consequently, tilled spirits in 1951 and adjusted the extends the utility-maximizing approach
the associated indirect costs of alcohol, tax for the rate of inflation since 1951. of economics to addictive substances.
are relatively low (as in the 1982 sample), Such an increase would have resulted The consumption of these substances is
a given increase in alcohol taxes will in a more than tenfold increase in the influenced not only by their utility and
have a relatively large impact on the full tax. The results implied that such a the satisfaction they provide but also by
price of alcohol and thus on consump- policy would have reduced the number acquired tolerance, reinforcement, and

26 Alcohol Research & Health


Effects of Price on Alcohol Consumption and Consequences

withdrawal. The main element of this such an approach accounting for the Using the estimates derived from mod­
and other models of addiction is the addictive aspects of alcohol consump­ els accounting for addiction, Grossman
assumption that an increase in the past tion may be more relevant to this sam­ and colleagues (1998) predicted the
consumption of an addictive substance ple than to a sample including all age effects of changes in beer taxes on con­
raises the current consumption of that groups. Using data obtained in baseline sumption. For example, the investigators
substance. Unlike previous models of surveys of high school seniors conducted examined the effects of a tax increase
addiction, the Becker-Murphy model from 1976 through 1985 and in followup that would have matched the taxes on
treats addicts as “farsighted” in the sense surveys conducted through 1989, the the alcohol in beer to those on the
that they consider, at least to some investigators estimated alcohol demand alcohol in distilled spirits in 1951 and
extent, the future consequences of their both in the context of the model of then accounted for the rate of inflation
consumption decisions. This assump­ addictive behavior and in the context of since 1951. Such an increase was esti­
tion implies that a person’s current con­ models that ignore the addictive aspects mated to have reduced average con­
sumption decisions will respond to of consumption. sumption by more than 40 percent in
changes in the expected future costs of The study found consistent evidence 1982 and 1983 (the middle years of
consumption, such as an anticipated that increases in the price of alcohol the sample).
increase in price or new information resulting from higher monetary prices Taken together, these findings on the
about the health consequences of con­ significantly reduced the number of relationship between price and demand
sumption. Although this assumption alcoholic drinks consumed by young for alcohol have important implications
may appear to be counterintuitive, it adults in the past year. Moreover, the for policies aimed at curbing alcohol use
generates a prediction that can be tested analyses provided strong evidence that and abuse among youths and young
using data on alcohol consumption by drinking in this age group is addictive in adults. First, this research demonstrates
the same person in 3 or more years. For the sense that a strong interdependency that increases in the price of alcoholic
example, the model predicts that the existed among past, current, and future beverages, which could be achieved by
benefits of consumption this year depend alcohol consumption. That is, current raising alcohol taxes, effectively can
on expected consumption next year. drinking decisions depended on past reduce drinking and heavy drinking.
Accordingly, a reduction in next year’s alcohol consumption and influenced Second, the results demonstrate that
consumption due to an increase in next future consumption. These findings are the long-run price elasticity of demand
year’s price should cause this year’s con­ generally consistent with studies employ­ when accounting for the addictive
sumption to fall, a prediction that can ing data from the National Longitudinal aspects of drinking is well above both
be readily tested. Survey of Youth to estimate alcohol the short-run elasticity and the elasticity
The Becker-Murphy model also demand using a model that also accounts obtained when ignoring addictive aspects.
predicts that the short-term price elas­ for the addictive nature of alcohol con­ This finding implies that previous esti­
ticity, which holds past consumption sumption. mates of the effects of tax increases on
constant, must be smaller in absolute The finding that drinking by young alcohol use among youths and young
value than the long-term price elastic­ adults can be considered an addictive adults and its consequences signifi­
ity, which allows past consumption to behavior has important implications cantly understate the benefits of higher
vary.4 For example, a price increase in for the effects of price on alcohol con­ taxes. Third, the finding that young
2001 according to the model would sumption. For example, when Grossman adults are farsighted in terms of future
reduce consumption in 2001, with and colleagues (1998) used models that alcohol consumption implies that poli­
consumption in previous years held ignored the addictive aspects of alcohol cies that raise the perceived future costs
constant. Because of the addictive nature consumption to analyze their data, they of alcohol use and abuse can significantly
of alcohol, the model also predicts that estimated an average price elasticity of reduce current drinking.
consumption in 2002 and in all future alcohol demand of -0.29. When they
years also would fall. Consequently, the used the model accounting for the
reduction in consumption observed addictive nature of alcohol, however,
Limitations of the Analyses
over several years (i.e., in the long term) the estimated average long-term price As is the case with much social science
after the price increase would exceed elasticity of demand was more than research, these findings and implications
the reduction observed in 2001 (i.e., in twice as high at -0.65, indicating that must be qualified because they are not
the short term). price had a much greater influence on derived from controlled experiments
Grossman and colleagues (1998) alcohol consumption. Moreover, the that can definitively establish that a cer­
applied the Becker-Murphy model to estimate of the long-term price elastic­ tain factor causes a specific outcome.
alcohol consumption by young adults ity of demand was approximately 60 One can argue that the effects of taxes
ages 17 to 29 using the longitudinal percent higher than the estimate of the
data from the Monitoring the Future short-term elasticity (which, in turn,
4
project. Given that the prevalence of was almost 40 percent higher than the For a detailed review of alternative economic models of
addiction and their applicability to the estimation of the
alcohol dependence and abuse is high­ average estimate derived using nonad­ demand for alcoholic beverages and heavy drinking, see
est in this age group (Grant et al. 1991), dictive models). Grossman (1993).

Vol. 26, No. 1, 2002 27


or prices in the studies just summarized tax on drinking participation and binge expected to affect drinking and driving
are biased because they do not account drinking actually increased significantly and the probability of fatal crashes.
for unmeasured determinants of con­ in State fixed-effects models. Both studies concluded that increases
sumption that are correlated with the This discrepancy in findings may in beer taxes or MLDAs would signifi­
cost of alcohol. For example, States stem from the fact that the relative sta­ cantly reduce youth motor vehicle
in which antidrinking sentiment is bility of the beer tax makes it highly fatalities. For example, the studies pre­
widespread and alcohol consumption correlated with other State indicators dicted that a policy adjusting the beer
is low may enact high alcohol excise (e.g., overall drinking sentiments). tax for the inflation rate since 1951
taxes as part of the political process. Accordingly, it is difficult to distinguish would have reduced fatalities among
In this case, the price elasticities that the effects of the beer tax and other State 18- to 20-year-old youths by 15 percent.
emerge from analyses that only con­ fixed effects. Furthermore, as men­ Moreover, a uniform MLDA of 21 years
sider price but omit overall drinking tioned earlier, State excise taxes are an would have lowered youth fatalities by
sentiment overstate the true influence imperfect measure of the price of alco­ 8 percent between 1975 and 1981.
of price. Conversely, States in which hol, and biases resulting from measure­ Chaloupka and colleagues (1993)
pro-drinking sentiment is widespread ment errors are exacerbated in fixed- extended and updated this research by
(i.e., antidrinking sentiment is weak) effects models. Thus, although most considering the effects of beer taxes,
and alcohol consumption is high may of the empirical literature supports MLDAs, alcohol availability, and all
enact high alcohol taxes because the taxa­ the conclusion that excise tax increases major State-level policies related to
tion of alcohol is an attractive source of tend to curtail alcohol consumption drinking and driving on youth and
revenue. In these cases, price elasticities and heavy drinking by underage youths adult motor vehicle fatality rates for
are understated if they are obtained from and young adults, more research on this the period from 1982 through 1988.
analyses that omit drinking sentiment. important issue is necessary. The study included numerous drunk-
Using data from the Monitoring the driving policies, as follows:
Future surveys of high school seniors
conducted between 1977 and 1992, Effects of Price • Implied consent laws, which pre­
Dee (1999) addressed this issue by on Consequences sume that a person with a driver’s
comparing the relationship between of Alcohol Abuse license agrees to be tested for alco­
alcohol consumption and State beer hol and other drugs on request or
excise taxes among all States over time. In addition to examining the effects of face license suspension or revocation
In this analysis, Dee included a fixed- the price of alcohol on consumption,
effects indicator for each State to con­ numerous economists have studied the • Preliminary breath tests prior to
trol for unmeasured determinants of impact of price on consequences of alco­ arrest to establish probable cause
alcohol consumption and the State’s hol use and abuse. These consequences for a DUI arrest
excise tax on beer.5 This analysis found include fatal and nonfatal motor vehicle
that once the State indicators were crashes and other injuries, liver cirrhosis • No-plea-bargaining provisions,
held constant, beer excise taxes no mortality and other health consequences, which prohibit a person charged
longer had a significant negative effect and violence and other crime. This sec­ with DUI to plea bargain to reduce
on consumption, suggesting that other, tion summarizes findings from recent the charge to a nonalcohol-related
unmeasured factors rather than differ­ research conducted by the authors of offense, such as reckless driving
ences in price account for differences this article as well as from other key
in alcohol consumption. studies (for a more detailed review of • Dram shop laws, which allow those
These conclusions are not definitive, this literature, see Chaloupka et al. 1998). injured by an intoxicated person to
however. For example, Grossman and Because MLDAs and drunk-driving laws bring suit against the person or
colleagues (1998) found only a modest play important roles in motor vehicle establishment that served the alcohol
reduction in their estimate of the long- crashes, their effects as well as those of
term price elasticity of demand (i.e., prices or taxes also are discussed. • Administrative per se laws, which
from -0.65 to -0.54) when controlling require the state licensing agency to
for fixed effects. Furthermore, Cook suspend or revoke a person’s license
and Moore (2001), who used data on
Motor Vehicle Crashes after a DUI arrest but prior to any
young adults participating in the National Saffer and Grossman (1987a,b) first court penalty
Longitudinal Survey of Youth conducted examined the impact of beer excise taxes
between 1982–1985 and 1988–1989, and MLDAs on youth fatality rates • Open container laws, which make
found that the effect of the State beer from motor vehicle crashes. The inves­ it illegal to carry open containers of
tigators used State-level fatality rates for alcoholic beverages in the car
5
youths ages 15 to 17, 18 to 20, and 21
These indicators were dichotomous variables for each
State except one. This means that each variable assumes
to 24 for the years 1975 through 1981 • Mandatory fines, license suspen­
the value of 1 for a given State and 0 for all other States. and controlled for various other factors sion/revocation, jail sentences,

28 Alcohol Research & Health


Effects of Price on Alcohol Consumption and Consequences

and/or community service upon More recent research using both youth victims of fatal daytime crashes
conviction for drunk driving. aggregate and individual-level data (i.e., youths who drink during the day
similarly has concluded that increases and then drive), while smaller than the
In addition to examining overall in beer taxes and MLDAs, as well as potential pool of victims of nighttime
fatality rates, the researchers considered strong laws related to drinking and crashes, may be more sensitive to price
two fatality rates that are closely related driving, can reduce self-reported drink­ than other youth drinkers. This would
to drinking and driving: ing and driving and involvement in be the case if the youths in question are
nonfatal traffic crashes. For example, frequent or heavy drinkers, because as
• The number of drivers killed a comprehensive study using aggregate mentioned earlier, evidence suggests
between 12:00 a.m. and 3:59 a.m., data for the period from 1982 through that those youths who drink frequently
75 to 90 percent of whom have 1988 found consistent evidence that or heavily are quite sensitive to price.
been estimated to have been drink­ higher beer taxes significantly reduce Another study analyzed fatal motor
ing (National Highway Traffic motor vehicle crash fatalities in a vari­ vehicle crashes among people of all ages
Safety Administration 1986) ety of models that account for potential for the years 1984 to 1992 using fixed-
omitted variables biases (Ruhm 1996).6 effect models (Mast et al. 1999). These
• The number of drivers with elevated These findings are notable because analyses found that the beer tax has no
BACs killed in traffic crashes. most of the models used included State- effect on the overall fatality rate but has
fixed effects. Another study based on a significant negative effect on the fatality
The study by Chaloupka and col­ self-reported data on drinking and rate for drivers involved in nighttime,
leagues (1993) concluded that several driving obtained in the 1985 National single-vehicle crashes, which commonly
drunk-driving laws, especially laws associ­ Health Interview Survey estimated that involve alcohol. The investigators down-
ated with relatively severe sanctions, can be a 10-percent increase in the price of played the importance of the beer tax,
effective deterrents to drinking and driv­ alcoholic beverages would reduce the however, because the size of its effect
ing. In particular, the investigators found probability of drinking and driving by varied when other variables were intro­
that whereas existing administrative per about 7.4 percent for men and 8.1 per- duced into the models. Nevertheless, a
se license suspensions with relatively weak cent for women (Kenkel 1993). Even careful examination of the study’s results
penalties have little effect on fatality rates, larger reductions of 12.6 percent among reveals significant negative tax effects in
a relatively severe mandatory license sus­ men and 21.1 percent among women most of the fixed-effects models used.7
pension of 1 year significantly reduces would occur among people ages 21 The key conclusion to be drawn
drunk driving. Severe mandatory mini- years and younger. A study using self- from this research is that increases in
mum fines and license sanctions upon reported data on involvement in traffic the full price of alcohol—whether they
conviction for DUI are also effective crashes obtained during the 1982 and result from increases in monetary price,
deterrents, although somewhat less effec­ 1989 Monitoring the Future surveys reduced availability, or increases in the
tive than more immediate administrative concluded that a policy adjusting the expected legal costs of drinking and
penalties that can be imposed without Federal beer tax for the inflation rate driving (i.e., more severe drunk-driving
court proceedings. In addition, both pre­ since 1951 would reduce the probabil­ laws)—can reduce drinking and driv­
liminary breath test laws, which raise the ity of nonfatal traffic crashes by almost ing and its consequences among all age
probability of arrest for DUI, and no- 6 percent for both men and women groups. As is the case with the effects of
plea-bargaining provisions, which raise (Chaloupka and Laixuthai 1997). beer taxes on consumption, however,
the expected penalties, deter drinking Two studies examined factors con­ the estimated magnitude of the beer
and driving. Reduced availability, result­ tributing to the mortality rate resulting tax effects on motor vehicle mortality
ing from both local prohibitions on alco­ from motor vehicle crashes among 18- depends somewhat on whether State-
hol sales and higher MLDAs, also can to 20-year-olds between 1977 and fixed effects are included in the statisti­
reduce drinking and driving, although 1992 (Dee 1999) or between 1977 cal models used. For example, Saffer
the MLDA effects were limited to youths and 1997 (Dee and Evans 2001). Both and Grossman (1987a) reported much
and young adults. studies also reported significant nega­ greater tax effects when using a fixed-
Chaloupka and colleagues (1993) tive effects of increases in the beer tax effects model. Similarly, significant tax
also concluded that higher beer excise on the motor vehicle mortality rates. effects in the studies by Ruhm (1996),
taxes are among the most effective Dee (1999) and Dee and Evans (2001)
means for reducing drinking and driv­ dismiss these findings, however, because 6
Omitted variables biases arise if determinants of fatal
ing in all segments of the population. the researchers found similar tax effects crashes are not included in the regression model and are
For example, between 1982 and 1988, regardless of whether they studied correlated with variables used to predict these crashes.
a policy adjusting the Federal beer tax nighttime fatalities (which commonly 7
The tax effect becomes insignificant in models account­
for the inflation rate since 1951 would are attributable to alcohol use) or day- ing for the percentages of the State populations that are
have reduced total fatalities by 11.5 time fatalities (which are related to members of various religious denominations. This variable
was available only for 2 of the years studied (i.e., 1980
percent and fatalities among 18- to 20- alcohol use much less often). Yet one and 1990), however, and had to be obtained for other
year-olds by 32.1 percent. could argue that the potential pool of years by interpolation and extrapolation.

Vol. 26, No. 1, 2002 29


Dee (1999), Mast and colleagues (1999), not significantly reduce deaths that are days from nonfatal workplace injuries
and Dee and Evans (2001) also were primarily related to alcohol, mainly by 4.6 million, reducing the costs of
based on this specification. deaths from liver cirrhosis. This finding lost productivity by $491 million. In
is surprising, given the results of the contrast, alcohol availability has little
earlier studies. In addition, however, impact on nonfatal workplace injuries
Health Effects the study considered the effects of price according to these analyses.
Excessive alcohol consumption can on various other death rates related to Chesson and colleagues (2000)
have numerous adverse health effects; focused on a different outcome—
accordingly, reductions in alcohol con- sexually transmitted disease rates—in
sumption related to price increases an analysis of all States for the years
might also reduce adverse health effects. The investigators 1981 to 1995. After controlling for State
Several studies have examined the and year effects, the investigators con-
impact of alcohol prices on liver cirrho- concluded that cluded that a $1 increase in the per-
sis mortality rates, a key adverse out-
come associated with long-term heavy
increases in the excise gallon liquor tax can reduce gonorrhea
rates by 2.1 percent; furthermore, a beer
alcohol consumption that accounts for taxes on distilled tax increase of 20 cents per six-pack
more than 20,000 deaths annually. For can reduce gonorrhea rates by 8.9 per-
example, Cook and Tauchen (1982) spirits would cent. Similar, or even somewhat larger,
analyzed annual State-level cirrhosis significantly reduce effects of liquor and beer taxes were
mortality rates for States that licensed found for syphilis rates.
the sale of alcoholic beverages from deaths from Again, the general conclusion that
1962 through 1977. The investigators
concluded that increases in the excise
liver cirrhosis. can be drawn from this research is that
increases in the full price of alcoholic
taxes on distilled spirits would signifi- beverages would reduce various diseases,
cantly reduce deaths from liver cirrhosis. injuries, and deaths related to alcohol
For example, a $1 increase in the dis­ alcohol use and abuse, including deaths use and abuse. Moreover, given the results
tilled spirits tax was estimated to lower from motor vehicle crashes, homicides of most studies analyzing liver cirrhosis
cirrhosis death rates by 5.4 to 10.8 per- (which are discussed in the following rates, these reductions of adverse health
cent. Thus, the study contradicted the section), suicides, diseases for which effects would not be limited to injuries
then-conventional wisdom that heavy, alcohol is a contributing factor (e.g., and deaths among light and moderate
addictive alcohol consumption was cancers of the alimentary tract), and drinkers but would also affect heavy
unresponsive to price. accidental deaths. Sloan and colleagues drinkers.
This finding was confirmed by (1994) concluded that increases in the
Grossman (1993) when he applied the monetary price of alcoholic beverages
Becker-Murphy model of addiction to would reduce suicides and deaths from
Violence and Other Crime
heavy alcohol consumption as reflected diseases for which alcohol is a contribut­ Because a variety of crimes are related
by the cirrhosis mortality rate. Using ing factor, but not deaths that are pri­ to alcohol use and abuse (Bureau of
data for all States for the period from marily related to alcohol. Conversely, Justice Statistics 1988), numerous studies
1961 through 1984, Grossman con­ the study found that alcohol availabil­ have assessed the influences of changes
cluded that long-term heavy consump­ ity, which is another component of the in alcohol prices on crime rates. For
tion is responsive to price. For example, full price of alcoholic beverages, has a example, Cook and Moore (1993)
he estimated that a 10-percent increase significant impact on many of the examined the impact of per capita alco­
in the price of alcohol would reduce death rates estimated, including deaths hol consumption and beer excise taxes
cirrhosis mortality by 8.3 to 12.8 per- primarily related to alcohol; suicides; on violent crime rates (i.e., homicides,
cent after the levels of heavy drinking and deaths from drowning, falls, and assaults, rapes, and burglaries), using
have fully adjusted to the price change other injuries. annual State-level data obtained from
in future years. (This adjustment would Ohsfeldt and Morrisey (1997) also the 1979 through 1987 Uniform Crime
extend over many years because due to examined the impact of alcohol price Reports. Employing fixed-effects models,
the addictive nature of heavy drinking, and availability on injuries, specifically in which the only independent variable
a price increase in 1 year would reduce nonfatal workplace injuries, using State- other than State and year indicators
drinking not only in that year but also level data for the period from 1975 was the beer tax, the investigators con­
in all future years.) through 1985. These analyses found cluded that higher beer taxes would lead
In contrast to the two studies just a strong inverse relationship between to significant reductions in rapes and
discussed, Sloan and colleagues (1994), workplace injuries and beer taxes. For robberies but would have little impact
using State-level death rates for the example, the investigators predicted on homicides and assaults. These findings
period from 1982 through 1988, found that a 25-cent increase in the beer tax are generally confirmed by an analysis
that higher alcoholic beverage prices do in 1992 would have reduced work-loss of homicide rates obtained from the

30 Alcohol Research & Health


Effects of Price on Alcohol Consumption and Consequences

Vital Statistics data, which also concluded time as well as for the pooling of several women in the United States, of whom
that higher alcoholic beverage prices years and the addition of State-level 3.6 percent were estimated to be abused,
and reduced alcohol availability would fixed effects. Such fixed effects are a 1-percent increase in the price of pure
lower homicide rates (Sloan et al. 1994). important in determining whether the alcohol would have decreased the num­
Several studies examined the effects effects of the State-level alcohol regula­ ber of abused married women by
of alcohol regulation on violence and tion variables reflect State sentiment approximately 104,600.
crime using individual-level data. Marko­ toward regulation and violence, which Grossman and Markowitz (2001)
witz and Grossman (1998) focused cannot be measured directly, rather explored the effects of variations in
their analysis on child abuse, using data than true policy effects. alcoholic beverage prices among States
from the 1976 National Family Violence The results of these analyses indi­ on violence on college campuses. The
Survey on children residing in two- cated that increases in the beer tax may study used data from the 1989, 1990,
parent families. The study estimated decrease the incidence of child abuse and 1991 Core Alcohol and Drug
the effects on violent outcomes of a committed by women but not by men. Surveys of College Students, which
variety of factors, including the State Thus, a 10-percent increase in the excise include almost 120,000 college students
excise tax rate on beer, illegal drug tax on beer was estimated to reduce the from approximately 200 colleges and
prices, marijuana decriminalization, number of mothers who commit violent universities throughout the United
laws restricting alcohol advertising, per acts against their children by approxi­ States and contain measures of alcohol
capita number of outlets licensed to sell mately 2 percent. This estimate was not use and its adverse consequences. These
alcohol, and demographic and socio­ influenced by State-level fixed effects, sug­ adverse consequences include four indi­
economic characteristics of the parents. gesting that it was indeed a policy effect. cators of violence, as follows:
The results demonstrated that increases Another study focused on the rela­
in the beer tax can be an effective pol- tionship between alcohol prices and • Getting in trouble with the police
icy tool in reducing child abuse. Thus, spouse abuse (i.e., both wife abuse and or with residence hall or other
a 10-percent increase in the excise tax husband abuse) (Markowitz 2000). college authorities
on beer was estimated to reduce the This analysis used data from the 1985
probabilities of overall child abuse and National Family Violence Survey as • Damaging property or pulling a fire
severe child abuse by 1.2 percent and well as respondents from that survey alarm
2.3 percent, respectively. Furthermore, who were interviewed again in 1986
such an increase was estimated to reduce and 1987. Hence, the study was based • Getting into an argument or a fight
unconditional overall child abuse (i.e., on a panel of three observations on
a measure of child abuse that includes each person. The statistical analysis also • Taking advantage of another person
the frequency of the abuse) by about included individual-level fixed effects sexually or having been taken advan­
2.1 percent. Even such a seemingly small to control for unmeasured characteris­ tage of sexually.
reduction in child abuse rates could tics in the panel. One example of such
have a dramatic impact on the lives of characteristics is the person’s sentiment The study found that the incidence
many children. In 1975, approximately toward alcohol consumption, which of each of these four acts of violence is
40 million children between the ages may be correlated with his or her propen­ inversely related to the beer price in the
of 3 and 17 lived with both parents. sity to commit violence, with overall State in which the student attends col­
According to the National Family alcohol sentiment in his or her State lege. For example, a 10-percent price
Violence Survey, 14.4 percent of these of residence, and with the rate at which increase would result in the following
children (i.e., 5.8 million) were victims alcohol is taxed. The results consistently reductions in violent acts:
of severe abuse. Hence, a 10-percent indicated that increases in the price per
increase in the beer tax would have ounce of pure alcohol (as measured by • The proportion of students who get
lowered the number of severely abused a weighted average of the prices of alco­ into trouble with the police and col­
children by approximately 132,500. hol from beer, wine, and liquor) reduce lege authorities would decline from
Markowitz and Grossman (2000) the probability of severe violence (kick­ 12.3 percent to 11.7 percent.
expanded upon this study in two ing, biting, hitting with a fist or other
important ways. First, they performed object, choking, and using or threaten­ • The proportion of students involved
the analyses separately by gender of the ing to use a gun or knife) aimed at wives. in property damage would be reduced
parent, which is important because dif­ Using an average of the estimates from from 7.5 percent to 7.1 percent.
ferent patterns of drinking and violence the fixed-effects specification, Markowitz
have been observed for men and women. (2000) estimated that a 1-percent
Second, they added data from another increase in the price per ounce of pure
comparable survey conducted 10 years alcohol would decrease the probability 8
Markowitz (2000) cautions that the value of this estimate
later, the 1985 National Family Violence of being a victim of wife abuse by 5.3 is somewhat imprecise because the 95-percent confi­
dence interval, which gives the range that with a 95-
Survey, which allows for a comparison percent.8 This means that in 1985, percent certainty contains the “real value” of the variable,
of the effects of alcohol regulation over when there were 54.4 million married is -1.0 to -9.7 percent.

Vol. 26, No. 1, 2002 31


G L O S S A R Y

Aggregate data: Data based on information (e.g., on alcohol con­ Individual-level data: Data based on information (e.g., on alco­
sumption) from large groups of people, such as the United hol consumption) from specific people.
States population as a whole or the population of individual Long-term price elasticity of demand: Percentage change in
States, either at a certain point in time or over time.
current consumption resulting from a 1-percent increase in
Dichotomous variable: Assumes the value of 1 if an observa­ price several years earlier; exceeds short-term price elasticity in
tion has a certain characteristic and assumes the value of 0 absolute value because a reduction in consumption this year
if an observation does not have that characteristic; for example,
resulting from an increase in price this year causes consump­
a dichotomous variable for residence in California equals 1
if a consumer lives in California or if an observation on tion to fall next year and in all future years.
alcohol consumption or motor vehicle accident mortality Myopic model of addiction: A model in which consumers
pertains to California. ignore the future harmful consequences of their current
Economic model of addiction: A model in which current con­ actions.
sumption of a certain good is positively related to past con­ Price elasticity of demand: Percentage change in consumption
sumption of that good. resulting from a 1-percent increase in price.
Farsighted model of addiction: A model in which consumers Short-term price elasticity of demand: Percentage change in
take into account the future harmful consequences of their
current consumption resulting from a 1-percent increase in
current actions.
price this year, with consumption last year held constant.
Fixed-effects regression model: Takes into account unmeasured
effects that vary among States or individuals but do not vary Utility maximizing approach: The approach to consumer
over time by including dichotomous variables for States or behavior taken by economists in which consumers select the
individuals as independent variables; can be implemented basket of goods and services that yields the largest amount
only if there is more than one observation for each State or of satisfaction or utility subject to their income and to the
individual. prices of those goods and services.

• The percentage of students who get crime and that the magnitude of these the view that increases in the monetary
into verbal or physical fights would effects generally is larger for people under prices of alcoholic beverages, which can
fall from 31.2 percent to 30.2 percent. age 21 than for people over age 21. be achieved by raising Federal, State
In summary, the findings discussed and local alcohol taxes, significantly
• The proportion of students involved in this section clearly indicate that, as reduce alcohol consumption.
in sexual misconduct would decline with alcohol consumption and other Of course, one must keep in mind
from 14.3 percent to 13.8 percent. outcomes related to alcohol abuse, the caveat mentioned previously con­
increases in the full price of alcoholic cerning the need to exercise caution in
• The number of students involved in beverages are an effective means of interpreting cause-and-effect relationships
violence each year would be reduced reducing alcohol-related violence and from the types of analyses discussed in
by approximately 200,000, or by 4 other crime. this article. Nevertheless, the weight of
percent. the evidence is impressive. Moreover,
several studies have concluded that
Saffer (2001) estimated the effective­ Discussion these reductions in consumption are
ness of alcohol and other drug abuse not limited to the infrequent, light, or
policies in reducing crime. The study This article has summarized the eco­ moderate drinkers but also pertain to
used data from more than 32,000 peo­ nomic research examining the impact frequent and heavy drinkers. Further-
ple participating in the 1991 National of the full price of alcoholic beverages more, increases in price also lead to
Household Survey on Drug Abuse on drinking and heavy drinking by reductions in many of the consequences
(NHSDA), which was complemented teenagers and young adults. It also has of heavy drinking. Two studies, how-
with data on State beer taxes. The anal­ reviewed similar research that explores ever, have suggested that a subset of
ysis estimated the effectiveness of drug the relationship between price and out- heavy drinkers—the upper 5 percent—
control spending and beer taxes on comes related to the abuse of alcohol may be unresponsive to price (Manning
arrests, property crime, property dam- by youths and adults, including drinking et al. 1995; Kenkel 1996). Because both
age, use of force, and drug selling, both and driving and motor vehicle crashes, of these studies analyzed the drinking
for the entire sample and for people health consequences of alcohol consump­ behavior of people of all ages, however,
under age 21. The results demonstrated tion, and violence and other crime. The they are not inconsistent with the notion
that increased beer taxes can reduce majority of this research clearly supports that youths and young adults—the age

32 Alcohol Research & Health


Effects of Price on Alcohol Consumption and Consequences

groups with disproportionately high the identification of population sub- COOK, P.J., AND TAUCHEN, G. The effect of liquor
alcohol-related problems—are generally groups that are most or least sensitive to taxes on heavy drinking. Bell Journal of Economics
13(2):379–390, 1982.
more responsive to increases in price alcohol prices and taxes deserve high pri­
than are adults. ority on an agenda for future research. ■ DEE, T.S. State alcohol policies, teen drinking and
Given this evidence, increases in the traffic accidents. Journal of Public Economics 72(2):
289–315, 1999.
prices of alcoholic beverages appear to
be an effective policy for reducing alco­ References DEE, T.S., AND EVANS, W.N. Teens and traffic
hol consumption and its consequences. safety. In: Gruber, J., ed. Risky Behavior Among
BECKER, G.S., AND MURPHY, K.M. A theory of Youth: An Economic Perspective. Chicago: University
In reality, however, alcoholic beverage of Chicago Press, 2001. pp. 121–165.
prices have declined relative to the prices rational addiction. Journal of Political Economy
96(4):675–700, 1988. GRANT, B.F.; HARFORD, T.C.; CHOU, P.; ET AL.
of other goods and services for most of
Prevalence of DSM–III–R alcohol abuse and
the past 50 years. This price decline is Bureau of Justice Statistics. Report to the Nation on
dependence. Alcohol Health & Research World
the result in large part of the infrequent Crime and Justice, 2nd Edition. Washington, DC:
15(2): 91–96, 1991.
and relatively small changes in Federal U.S. Department of Justice, 1988.
GROSSMAN, M. The economic analysis of addictive
and State taxes. Based on the evidence Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of behavior. In: Hilton, M.E., and Bloss, G., eds.
presented here, it appears likely that Labor. Monthly Labor Review, various years. Economics and the Prevention of Alcohol-Related
this decline in real prices has kept alcohol CAMARGO, C.A., JR.; STAMPFER, M.J.; GLENN, R.J.; Problems. NIAAA Research Monograph No. 25,
consumption and many of the prob­ ET AL. Moderate alcohol consumption and risk for
NIH Pub. No. 93–3513. Bethesda, MD: National
lems associated with alcohol use and Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism, 1993.
angina pectoris or myocardial infarction in U.S.
pp. 91–123.
abuse at levels higher than they would male physicians. Annals of Internal Medicine
otherwise be. 126(5):372–375, 1997. GROSSMAN, M., AND MARKOWITZ, S. Alcohol reg­
In formulating the appropriate alco­ ulation and violence on college campuses. In:
CHALOUPKA, F.J., AND LAIXUTHAI, A. Do youths Grossman, M., and Hsieh, C.R., eds. Economic
hol tax policies, it would be useful to substitute alcohol and marijuana? Some economet­ Analysis of Substance Use and Abuse: The Experience
have information on the differential ric evidence. Eastern Economic Journal 23(3):253– of Developed Countries and Lessons for Developing
price responsiveness of the outcomes 276, 1997. Countries. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward
considered here by gender, race, and Elgar, 2001. pp. 257–289.
CHALOUPKA, F.J., AND WECHSLER, H. Binge drink­
ethnicity. For example, evidence sug­ ing in college: The impact of price, availability, and GROSSMAN, M.; COATE, D.; AND ARLUCK, G.M.
gests that certain drinking patterns are alcohol control policies. Contemporary Economic Policy Price sensitivity of alcoholic beverages in the United
more sensitive to price among female 14(4):112–124, 1996. States. In: Moore, M.H., and Gerstein, D.R., eds.
Control Issues in Alcohol Abuse Prevention: Strategies
college students than among male col­ CHALOUPKA, F.J.; SAFFER, H.; AND GROSSMAN, M. for States and Communities. Greenwich, CT: JAI
lege students. It also appears as if child Alcohol-control policies and motor-vehicle fatali­ Press, 1987. pp. 169–198.
abuse committed by women is more ties. Journal of Legal Studies 22(1):161–186, 1993.
GROSSMAN, M.; CHALOUPKA, F.J.; AND SIRTALAN,
responsive to price than child abuse CHALOUPKA, F.J.; GROSSMAN, M.; AND SAFFER, H. I. An empirical analysis of alcohol addiction:
committed by men, although that find­ The effects of price on the consequences of alcohol Results from the Monitoring the Future panels.
ing is based on fairly old data. To date, use and abuse. In: Galanter, M., ed. Recent Develop­ Economic Inquiry 36(1):39–48, 1998.
however, no large-scale studies have ments in Alcoholism, Volume 16: The Consequences of
KENKEL, D.S. Drinking, driving and deterrence: The
considered gender differences in price Alcohol. New York: Plenum Press, 1998. pp. 331–346.
effectiveness and social costs of alternative policies.
effects for a variety of outcomes in a CHESSON, H.; HARRISON, P.; AND KASSLER, W.J. Journal of Law and Economics 36(2):877–914, 1993.
systematic fashion. Similarly, little is Sex under the influence: The effect of alcohol pol- KENKEL, D.S. New estimates of the optimal tax on
known about racial or ethnic differ­ icy on sexually transmitted disease rates in the alcohol. Economic Inquiry 34(2):296–319, 1996.
ences in price effects. Thus, researchers United States. Journal of Law and Economics 43(1):
215–238, 2000. LAIXUTHAI, A., AND CHALOUPKA, F.J. Youth alco­
do not know whether the beneficial hol use and public policy. Contemporary Policy Issues
effects of tax increases on alcohol abuse COATE, D., AND GROSSMAN, M. Effects of alco­ 11(4):70–81, 1993.
will be shared equally by all population holic beverage prices and legal drinking ages on
youth alcohol use. Journal of Law and Economics LEUNG, S.F., AND PHELPS, C.E. “My kingdom for a
subgroups, or whether policies in addi­ drink . . .?” A review of estimates of the price sensitiv­
tion to tax increases must be pursued 31(1):145–171, 1988.
ity of demand for alcoholic beverages. In: Hilton,
to curtail abuse in certain groups. COOK, P.J., AND MOORE, M.J. Economic perspec­ M.E. and Bloss, G., eds. Economics and the Prevention
Another area in which knowledge is tives on reducing alcohol-related violence. In: of Alcohol-Related Problems. NIAAA Research
lacking pertains to how the beneficial Martin, S.E., ed. Alcohol and Interpersonal Violence: Monograph No. 25, NIH Pub. No. 93–3513.
Fostering Multidisciplinary Perspectives. NIAAA Bethesda, MD: National Institute on Alcohol Abuse
effects of moderate alcohol consump­ and Alcoholism, 1993. pp. 1–32.
Research Monograph No. 24, NIH Pub. No.
tion would be altered by tax increases. 93–3496. Bethesda, MD: National Institute on
For example, would coronary heart dis­ MANNING, W.G.; BLUMBERG, L.; AND MOULTON,
Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism, 1993. pp. 193–212. L.H. The demand for alcohol: The differential
ease rise, and if so, by how much? And response to price. Journal of Health Economics
what is the trade-off between reductions COOK, P.J., AND MOORE, M.J. Environment and
14(2):123–148, 1995.
persistence in youthful drinking patterns. In:
in alcohol abuse and deteriorations in Gruber, J., ed. Risky Behavior Among Youth: An MARKOWITZ, S. The price of alcohol, wife abuse
coronary health that may accompany tax Economic Perspective. Chicago: University of and husband abuse. Southern Economic Journal
hikes? Answers to these questions and Chicago Press, 2001. pp. 375–437. 67(2):279–303, 2000.

Vol. 26, No. 1, 2002 33


MARKOWITZ, S., AND GROSSMAN, M. Alcohol reg­ OHSFELDT, R.L., AND MORRISEY, M.A. Beer taxes, of Developed Countries and Lessons for Developing
ulation and domestic violence towards children. workers’ compensation and industrial injury. The Countries. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward
Contemporary Economic Policy 16(3):309–320, 1998. Review of Economics and Statistics 79(1):155–160, 1997. Elgar, 2001. pp. 291–307.

MARKOWITZ, S. AND GROSSMAN, M. The effects of POGUE, T.F., AND SGONTZ, L.G. Taxing to control SAFFER, H., AND CHALOUPKA, F.J. Alcohol tax
beer taxes on physical child abuse. Journal of Health social costs: The case of alcohol. American Economic equalization and social costs. Eastern Economic
Economics 19(2):271–282, 2000. Review 79(1):235–243, 1989. Journal 20(1):33–43, 1994.

MAST, B.D.; BENSON, B.L.; AND RASMUSSEN, D.W. RACHAL, J.V.; GUESS, L.L.; HUBBARD, R.L.; ET AL. SAFFER, H., AND GROSSMAN, M. Beer taxes, the
The Extent and Nature of Adolescent Alcohol Abuse:
Beer taxation and alcohol-related traffic fatalities. legal drinking age, and youth motor vehicle fatali­
The 1974 and 1978 National Sample Surveys. NTIS
Southern Economic Journal 66(2):214–249, 1999. ties. Journal of Legal Studies 16(2):351–374, 1987a.
No. PB81-199267. Springfield, VA: National
National Highway Traffic Safety Administration. Technical Information Service, 1980. SAFFER, H., AND GROSSMAN, M. Drinking age laws
Fatal Accident Reporting System, 1984. DOT HS RUHM, C.J. Alcohol policies and highway vehicle fatali­ and highway mortality rates: Cause and effect.
Report Number 806 919. Washington, DC: National ties. Journal of Health Economics 15(4):435–454. 1996. Economic Inquiry 25(3):403–417, 1987b.
Highway Traffic Safety Administration, 1986.
SAFFER, H. Substance abuse control and crime: SLOAN, F.A.; REILLY, B.A.; AND SCHENZLER, C.
NELSON, J.P. Broadcast advertising and U.S. demand Evidence from the National Survey of Drug Abuse. Effects of prices, civil and criminal sanctions, and
for alcoholic beverages. Southern Economic Journal In: Grossman, M., and Hsieh C.R., eds. Economic law enforcement on alcohol-related mortality.
65(4):774–790, 1999. Analysis of Substance Use and Abuse: The Experience Journal of Studies on Alcohol 55:454–465, 1994.

Are these NIAAA Research Monographs


in your collection?
Each monograph
Each monograph presents
pr researchch by
by noted
noted scientists,
scientists, reviews
reviews research
r ch progress,
pr ess, and
and
offers a glimpse of future research in key areas. Scientists, clinicians, and others with an
interest in alcohol research will find these volumes a welcome addition to their library.

Alcohol and Intracellular Signaling (No. 35) presents research on alcohol’s


effects on intracellular signaling pathways and their implications for alcohol-
induced organ injury and the development of alcoholism. Topics include:
• Biochemical mechanisms of alcoholic liver disease
• The role of genetics in alcoholism vulnerability
• The use of animal models to study alcohol’s effects on
cellular protein synthesis
• Alcohol’s effects on the inflammatory process
• Intracellular effects that contribute to fetal alcohol syndrome

Alcohol Epidemiology of Small Geographic Areas (No. 36) reviews progress


made over the past decade in the study of alcohol consumption and prob­
lems in small geographic areas. Topics include:
• Estimating rates of alcohol problems within demographic
and geographic subgroups
• Measuring the severity of psychiatric and addictive disorders
• Determining the effectiveness of local prevention programs
• Evaluating the relative need for alcoholism treatment
services in different communities
• Predicting alcohol-related risks on a geographic basis

Supplies are limited. To order your free copies, contact National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism
Publications Distribution Center, P.O. Box 10686, Rockville, MD 20849–0686. You may fax your order to
(703) 312–5230 or order through NIAAA’s World Wide Web site (www.niaaa.nih.gov).

34 Alcohol Research & Health

You might also like