You are on page 1of 14

Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.journals.elsevier.com/economic-modelling

Trade, investment and size inequalities between countries and the


asymmetry in double taxation agreements
Janusz Kudła a, *, Katarzyna Kopczewska a, Monika Stachowiak-Kudła b
a
University of Warsaw, Faculty of Economic Sciences, Długa 44/50, 00-241, Warsaw, Poland
b
Warsaw School of Economics, Madalińskiego 6/8, 02-513, Warsaw, Poland

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Handling Editor: Sushanta Mallick The inequalities among countries and their bilateral relationship affect the asymmetry of rules in double taxation
agreements. The asymmetry in rules appears when one country prefers tax credit while another country
JEL classification: exemption, for the same type of income. According to the literature, the inequalities involve trade, investment
H25 relations, economy size and tax competition. However, the relative importance of these factors for the design and
H87
asymmetry of tax treaties is not recognised well. To address this problem we use ANOVA, Hierarchical Linear
K33
Model and Ordered Logistic Regression with spatial lags on the sample of tax treaties from large European
K34
countries. The most important factor for low asymmetry is the intensity of bilateral trade. The differences in
Keywords:
countries’ wealth and taxation increase asymmetry but they are of less importance. These findings help to
Double taxation agreements
Tax competition improve the negotiation of tax treaties and spur bilateral cooperation, especially when differences among
Economic asymmetry countries are substantial.
Tax credit
Tax exemption
Tax treaties

1. Introduction 2004a). DTAs allow for a more restrictive policy of taxing multinationals
as they involve the setting of common rules by two countries.1 For
The paper strives to investigate the application of asymmetric rules example, Hearson (2018b) showed that British officials used tax treaties
in double taxation agreements (DTAs) to balance the inequalities in to disseminate the common Organization for Economic Co-operation
foreign investment, trade, size of economies and harmful tax competi­ and Development (OECD) standards to constrain other countries’ abil­
tion. The double taxation agreements are aimed at the prevention of ity to tax inward investment. It required the abolishment of rules that
cross-border discrimination of investments and supporting bilateral in­ were better fitted to benefit British enterprises. Finally, the network of
vestments through the alleviation of international double taxation. In­ tax agreements decreases the cost of channelling corporate income from
ternational double taxation occurs when two countries impose taxation one country to another, making foreign direct investment (FDI) more
on the same income or assets. There are also opinions that signing a DTA profitable (Petkova et al., 2020). The reasons listed above indicate that
facilitates access to information about the foreign investment of do­ bilateral relations have to be sufficiently intensive to justify the
mestic entities (Keen and Ligthart, 2006) and counteracts international assignment of a treaty. The signed treaties are relatively hard to be
tax avoidance. In this last view, the avoidance of excessive (double) terminated because they provide at least some informational value to
taxation or effective allocation of capital are a secondary matter (Chisik involved parties. Therefore, even strong but transitory events inducing
and Davies, 2004b; Davies, 2004). The agreement is the most effective an increase in protectionism (e.g., Covid 2019 pandemic) should not
when bilateral investments are high because it lowers the possibility of affect them substantially.
withdrawal from the agreement, as the second party can ‘punish’ If countries decide to sign a DTA, they must negotiate the double
tax-related investments made by the first party (Chisik and Davies, taxation avoidance methods which are applied to different types of

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: jkudla@wne.uw.edu.pl (J. Kudła), kkopczewska@wne.uw.edu.pl (K. Kopczewska), mstachowiak@poczta.fm (M. Stachowiak-Kudła).
1
Haufler et al. (2018) postulate a similar effect for cooperative settlement of thin capitalization and controlled foreign company rules that should be higher than
set in a non-cooperative way.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2023.106244
Received 3 March 2022; Received in revised form 19 February 2023; Accepted 20 February 2023
Available online 1 March 2023
0264-9993/© 2023 The Authors. Published by Elsevier B.V. This is an open access article under the CC BY license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

assets and income. In general, they can choose between tax credits and detailed tax provisions depend on the intensity of bilateral relations. It
tax exemptions but the particular rule can be different for different types excludes countries located further away because their economic re­
of income or assets. Tax exemption means that income from foreign lationships are small (especially with the smaller nations of Europe)
investments is not taxed while tax credit assumes that foreign income is which affects both the existence and the content of tax treaties.2 If re­
taxed like domestic income but allows for the subtraction of tax paid lationships are not intensive, then the need for signing a DTA is low or
abroad. The subtraction cannot be larger than the tax due in the country countries prefer the use of general rules without detailed provisions.3
of investment origin. The tax exemption fosters an increase in capital We decided to investigate countries belonging to the European Union
outflow. Thus, every difference in taxation between the two countries in2017.4 It was the last year before the implementation of the OECD
should affect the decision to invest abroad. In countries favouring tax Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to
credit, the capital outflow should be smaller because owners of capital Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (Multilateral Instrument, MLI).
sometimes have to pay additional tax, if the domestic tax rate is higher We decided to not consider provisions of MLI, which entered into force
than the tax rate in the host country. As long as taxation in the host on July 1, 2018. The MLI modifies existing tax treaties by adding new
country is lower than the domestic tax, the latter does not affect the regulations and replacing the existing ones (Kleist, 2016). There are two
decision to invest abroad. Therefore, widespread tax credits can be reasons for excluding MLI: 1) the multilateral convention is general and
treated as a means to protect against excessive capital export (Becker not country-specific, and 2) there is no evidence of its implementation
and Fuest, 2011) and harmful tax competition. Therefore, any increase yet because only a fraction of countries has ratified it.
in protectionism should lead to more frequent use of the tax credit rule at The choice of members of the EU is important because the Com­
the expense of the tax exemption rule. Conversely, using an exemption munity Law harmonised regulation on investment and trade but did not
instead of tax credits may be desirable from a political point of view if affect DTAs signed among countries. It increases the importance of the
governments strive to intensify capital flows. The tax credit is more DTAs as a tool for compensating inequalities in investment and taxation,
demanding for tax administration but potentially offers higher tax rev­ particularly for cases not regulated by Community Law. It was also
enues and better information about the international operations of do­ important for our study to include countries with diversified economies.
mestic entities. The exemption is cheaper for tax administration but The diversification of an economy increases the need for detailed rules in
implies lower revenues and worse information about foreign in­ DTA, providing higher differentiation of applied rules. It inspires us to
vestments. This trade-off permits a choice of different general double consider highly populated countries because their economies are more
taxation avoidance rules by different countries. diversified compared to countries with smaller populations. Finally,
The chosen rules can be symmetric (the same rule applied to income because we also investigate tax avoidance, it is important to omit
or assets in both countries) or asymmetric (different rules in both countries perceived as tax havens. For example, the Netherlands was
countries). Asymmetry can be triggered by the application of the method excluded from the sample because of the special tax treatment of
preferred by one country with a partner preferring the alternative multinational holdings (Weyzig and van Dijk, 2009) which classifies this
method, or it can be set strategically for other deliberate reasons. The country as a “conduit country”. A conduit country facilitates the transfer
symmetric rules should be preferred as it treats income and assets in of income to other law regimes with low taxation through the beneficial
both countries equally, not discriminating against the investments of treatment of incoming transfers and the network of tax treaties with
either party of the treaty. The asymmetric rules are reasonable if poli­ other countries. It affects not only the policy of the Netherlands but also
cymakers would like to limit the perceived advantage of the other party the policy of their tax treaty partners, making the Netherlands’ a special
or to equalise the business conditions for inflowing or outflowing case.
investments. Based on the existing literature, we can formulate three hypotheses
The reasons behind the use of asymmetric rules are not explicit and referring to the three groups of factors affecting the shape of double
they are also not well-recognised in the literature on DTAs. Therefore, taxation agreements: intensiveness of relations, differences in econo­
we propose a new and original quantitative approach to model this mies and investments and tax competition.
issue. The results of the modelling shed some light on the reasons for the Intuitively, one can expect that intensive tax competition and higher
diversification of tax provisions and their relative importance. This differences in economies and bilateral investments favour the asym­
further contributes to the understanding of the reasons driving the metry of rules. This is because the asymmetry is introduced to mitigate
policies in international relations. The relationships between countries the benefits resulting from comparative advantages or tax preferences
are rarely equal as countries differ in size, economic development, offered by one party of the DTA. However, the relative strength and
preferred policies and attractiveness for foreign investment. The DTA’s cause of these factors are unknown. Moreover, these factors are modi­
regulations can mitigate these inequalities by providing some provision fied by the insensitivity of bilateral relations. We formulate the
for the tax treatment of income or assets coming from another country. following three hypotheses:
Such compensation is not unique, for example, Sanz-Córdoba (2020) has
Hypothesis 1. If the relations between the home and host country are
noticed that infrastructure investment and productivity-enhancing pol­
weak, then the concord choice of rules is of minor importance and each
icies are used as strategic substitutes for capital taxation. Moreover,
country can choose the preferred method of tax avoidance (tax exemp­
attractive infrastructure increases the effectiveness of policy preventing
tion or tax credits). The asymmetry in such a case should be undeter­
tax-motivated profit shifting (Pieretti and Pulina, 2020). A similar effect
mined (it can be high or low).
can be obtained through the deliberate shaping of the rules included in
If the international relations between countries are not intensive,
DTAs, limiting of competitive advantages of other countries. This role is
then the diversification of tax rules is redundant. A country can choose
particularly important when other political tools (like tariffs and
non-tariff barriers) are not available. Particularly, the latter situation
applies to countries forming an economic union with a free flow of
2
capital and trade. For example, Japan has no tax treaty with Cyprus, Greece, and Malta and
This motivated us to investigate the bilateral double taxation only recently (2017) signed tax agreement with Estonia.
3
The general rule means the rule (tax credit or exemption) applied to income
agreements of six relatively large countries (France, Germany, Italy,
or assets received or possessed by residents of one country in another country if
Poland, Spain, and the United Kingdom) with other members of the
the given income or assets are not on the list of detailed provisions. The detailed
European Union. We analyse only countries from one region of the world provision includes items for which the opposite rule should be applied. The
(Europe) because it ensures intensive investment and trade relationships general rules also can be discordant, if one country applies a tax credit and the
between countries, due to low transportation costs and similar institu­ other - an exemption.
tional conditions. It is important because the need for signing a DTA and 4
The United Kingdom exited the European Union in 2021.

2
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

the preferred method of tax avoidance or agree to the same method as


preferred by the second country. This is because we are close to the
situation when a DTA is not necessary because of rare bilateral relations.
Contrary to this, the intensification of international cooperation (deep­
ening globalisation) increases the number and type of relations,
affecting the complexity of tax treaties positively. This is because the
need for investment protection becomes more important, and the need
for regulatory autonomy is less important (Montal et al., 2020). Insen­
sitivity of relations can also affect the structure of taxation, for example,
the taxation of dividends can depend on the share of a foreign investor’s
ownership (Petkova, 2021).
Hypothesis 2. If relations between countries are asymmetric (e.g., one
country’s economy is large and the second is small) or the benefits of the
agreement are asymmetric (one country’s benefits from the investment
are larger than the other), then the rules should be asymmetric.
Several scenarios can be considered here. For example, tax credits
capture some tax benefits of international investment flows. This is more
important for large or more affluent countries for which relations with
small countries are not so important. For a small country, a relationship
with a large country is more important, so the exemption should be
chosen more eagerly. Similarly, small countries should prefer exemp­
tions in relations with other small countries (Dickescheid, 2004). These Fig. 1. The factors affecting the asymmetry of rules in double taxation agree­
different choices should yield higher asymmetry in tax agreements, ments and their expected impact.
where less developed countries agree to reduce the withholding tax rates
on outgoing dividends and interest payments to promote foreign in­ check whether there are visible differences between countries with
vestment (Janský and Šedivý, 2019), trade (Pham et al., 2019) or different DTAs provisions. HLM works similarly to ANOVA but allows
financial aid (Braun and Zagler, 2018). There is evidence that the switch for a hierarchy of explanatory variables and their inter-dependence (in
from fully equal investments between countries to only ANOVA they are assumed independent). The ordered logistic regressions
one-side-investment raises the withholding tax by five percentage points are used to indicate variables affecting the probability of higher asym­
in German double taxation agreements and affects the definition of metry in tax treaties. Auxiliary, only to identify whether the relation­
permanent establishment (Rixen and Schwarz, 2009). However, similar ships can be non-linear, we use box plots. Statistics allows for detailed
research on a sample of tax treaties between developed and developing insight into relations between data, while econometrics generalises
countries reveals that these effects are moderated by the size of the these relationships. In selected regression models we included spatially
government’s revenue base and its reliance on corporate tax (Hearson, lagged variables to capture spatial effects. The use of spatial methods is
2018a). Some non-economic factors can also affect the asymmetry of becoming more popular in the study of double taxation agreements. For
rules, e.g., the differences in a country’s power or knowledge and the example, Barthel and Neumayer (2012) and Neumayer and Plümper
bargaining skills of negotiators involved in signing a tax treaty (Allee (2010) focused on the decision of signing a tax treaty as an effect of
and Peinhardt, 2014; Kangave, 2009). mimicking the behaviour of a country’s neighbour. Hearson (2018a)
Hypothesis 3. If tax competition intensifies (diversification of tax investigated the probability of signing a treaty between developed and
burden on corporate income or assets in both countries is substantial) developing countries and other spatial studies concentrated on the
then asymmetry increases because countries negatively affected by tax impact of tax treaty rules on FDI (Azémar and Dharmapala, 2019).
competition choose tax credits over exemptions and countries with low However, according to our knowledge, spatial models have not yet been
taxation still prefer exemption. used to investigate asymmetry in tax treaties.
Some types of incomes are especially liable to switch (like dividends, The contribution that this paper provides to the literature also in­
royalties or interests) when differences between countries in taxation cludes a quantitative identification of the reasons affecting the content
rates increase. Countries negatively affected by tax competition should of Double Taxation Agreements and the assessment of their importance
prefer tax credits to control the income of their residents investing (see Fig. 1). The main results of our research indicate that the intensity of
abroad (Gordon, 1992). The exemption is not resistant to tax competi­ bilateral relations (and especially the intensity of bilateral trade) is
tion, so the symmetry obtained by tax exemptions should be more crucial for the asymmetry of rules in DTA. In general, based on the
frequent when tax competition is low. Exemption of income is particu­ regression results, the higher bilateral FDI and trade stimulate higher
larly preferred by small countries, according to the theory of asymmetric symmetry of rules. The imbalance of FDI spurs higher asymmetry in DTA
tax competition (Bucovetsky, 1991; Peralta and van Ypersele, 2005; when inward investments are larger than outward investments. In other
Rixen, 2011; Haufler and Stähler, 2013), to attract income and invest­ words when the larger (first) country is more attractive to investment
ment from large countries. As Mongrain and Wilson (2018) showed, than the smaller (second) country. The differences in size measured by
small countries are inclined to choose the preferential tax regime and the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) are less important and work in the
when the distribution of moving costs of firms is non-uniform, the opposite direction than differences in the average affluence of countries
preferential regime may dominate. This can enhance a larger country to measured by PPS per capita. A large difference in GDP size decreases
increase the asymmetry of rules in tax treaties to minimize the harm asymmetry, while a large difference in affluence increases it. One can
caused by the tax competition of a smaller country. (The general idea is guess that a small country is more willing to approve the proposition of a
shown in Fig. 1). large country if differences are limited to country size and conversely, a
To test the hypotheses, we applied a statistical approach with large country can approve any rules with a small country because it is
ANOVA, Hierarchical Linear Model (HLM) and an econometric not affecting its economy much. The differences in affluence affect the
approach with ordered logistic regression models (OLR). The ANOVA is benefits from bilateral investments so a poorer country can agree to the
used to examine whether double taxation avoidance rules can be used to preferred treatment of investments from a wealthier country. Evidence
group the countries according to their economic performance – this is to on the impact of tax competition on asymmetry is limited. Only when

3
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

the diversification of tax rates among countries is substantial, can one The referred arguments indicate that DTAs are unnecessary, inef­
observe higher asymmetry; but the number of observations is too small fective for FDI, or even harmful to domestic welfare. This paper proposes
to conclude unambiguously. Nevertheless, this observation is in line a broader view of the reasons for signing DTAs as a tool not only for
with the theory of asymmetric tax competition. In a small country, the attracting FDI but also for reducing tax and size inequalities6 that affect
benefits of a preferential tax regime can be so high that the government bilateral relationships.
of this country is not able to withdraw tax preferences even if other There are several empirical studies on the rules used in tax treaties.
countries respond with retaliation.5 Loretz (2007) uses data on effective taxation between OECD countries to
The paper is structured as follows: in the first section, we discuss the confirm the preference for tax credits by countries with a high GDP and
economic purposes of signing double taxation agreements. The next relatively high taxation of capital. He showed that countries prefer tax
section describes the data and variables used in the ANOVA, a Hierar­ exemption over tax credits because the latter does not require interna­
chical Linear Model and Ordered Logistic Regression. In the fourth tional negotiations. Based on probit analysis, the probability of signing a
section, we model the differences in tax treaties. Finally, we present the double taxation treaty depends on the average distance between coun­
results of the analysis. The paper ends with a brief discussion of the tries and the sum of their GDPs. Both factors transpire to be essential but
implications of the study for policymakers. they are only responsible for around 5% of the change in the likelihood
of establishing a DTA. Contrary to this research, our analysis does not
2. The economic purposes of signing double taxation concern the probability of signing a DTA.
agreements Chisik and Davies (2004b) investigated the impact of asymmetry
between countries signing double taxation agreements on the level of
Investigation of double taxation agreements (DTAs) requires un­ tax rates on the data of US affiliates’ sales and FDI stocks. A greater
derstanding the reasons for signing this type of international treaty. This asymmetry between countries favours higher taxation at source,
is not trivial because DTAs generate at least some contradictions with regardless of the type of regulated payments (dividends, royalties, in­
their declared purposes. terest, etc.). The taxation in a country can be set high if the response of
For the first time, an economic analysis of double taxation rules was the other country would not be very harmful to the investment abroad.
presented formally by Koichi Hamada (1966). He showed that double This is possible when the investments of both countries are asymmetric.
taxation treaties could improve the situation of countries competing in Formally, it stems from the occurrence of two effects of a DTA. The first
equilibrium. However, market conditions usually mean that capital ex­ effect is the reduction of withholding tax levied by the other party,
porters lose on this. The use of DTAs makes sense only for large coun­ which makes it easier to invest abroad, but at the expense of tax reve­
tries, which can thus share the benefits of the impact on the price of nues obtained by a foreign country. The second effect is related to the
global capital. However, in small countries (i.e., countries that do not reduction of administrative and tax control costs, and it is always pos­
affect the global rate of return on capital), DTAs do not bring benefits for itive for both parties. The level of tax rates is also dependent on tax
effective capital allocation. These arguments indicate that we can expect exemption for foreign income, and tax exemption by one of the countries
less diversified DTAs when at least one small country is involved in the fostering a decline in withholding tax rates. Contrary to the described
agreement. In such a case the main source of asymmetry can be the paper, our study treats tax rates as determinants of the rules included in
preference for one of the double taxation avoidance rules. a DTA and we left aside sales of affiliates focusing analysis on macro­
The unilateral exemption is worse than a lack of exemption if economic data.
countries maximise their domestic welfare and do not want to share tax Several other empirical studies have checked the impact of tax credit
revenues with foreign countries (Whalley, 2011). Therefore, agreements or tax exemption rules on the size of foreign direct investments and their
with asymmetric rules should be rare but as one can see from the study localisation (Nguyen, 2019; Egger et al., 2009; Bénassy-Quéré et al.,
sample, about 41% of treaties apply different general rules (see details in 2005; Mills and Newberry, 2004; Gorter and Parikh, 2003). The syn­
the Appendix). Attempts to explain this phenomenon usually relate to: thesis of this stream of research is a meta-analysis conducted by Mooij
maximising global welfare instead of national, the differences in the and Ederveen (2003). However, this part of the literature is not related
monitoring costs of domestic and foreign incomes (to the detriment of to the asymmetry in tax treaties.
the latter), or the limited possibilities of withdrawal from the agreement
because of fear of retaliation by the other party. Moreover, the use of tax 3. Asymmetry and the variables used for analysis
credits at similar tax rates in both contracting countries does not lead to
welfare improvement and is unreasonable from an economic point of Our sample consists of 147 DTAs and one case without a double
view. For example, if a country of origin would like to promote in­ taxation agreement (France- Denmark) in the form valid for 2017, be­
vestments of its entities abroad, it can apply an exemption of foreign tween six highly populated countries (Germany, Poland, France, Italy,
income from taxation without any international agreement Spain, and the United Kingdom) and 27 European countries - members
(Davies, 2004). In small countries, taxation does not change the profit­ of the European Union at the time. We analyse the consistency of the
ability of capital, while the presence of foreign investments stimulates general rule and nine detailed rules which affects the asymmetry. The
excessive taxation. Therefore, in a non-cooperative equilibrium of two dataset is a complex system of information. The dependent phenomenon
small economies applying source taxation, the maximisation of national – asymmetry of DTAs - is a set of variables. It includes in total 10 dummy
welfare requires exemption as a rule (Dickescheid, 2004). This result is variables for 9 individual detailed rules and general rule (0-the same
different from that obtained by Davies (2003) for large countries. A rule, 1-different rules), while the asymmetry variable is a total of 9
country is large if taxation does affect the profitability of capital. Tax dummies for individual rules (asymmetry = 0 means all individual rules
credits should be preferred in large countries as it affects the global rate between two countries are the same). The same value of asymmetry can
of return on capital. The tax credit choice is also supported by compe­
tition from many countries offering lower taxation of capital
(Scharf, 2001) and by the maximisation of national income when 6
For example, Canada benefited from the United States tax credit rule due to
compensatory payments (between countries) or harmonisation of tax the inflow of US investments and the possibility of applying relatively high
rates are not available (Janeba, 1995). national taxation (without outflow of investors to the US). At the same time,
Canada lost revenues on taxes imposed on passive income of various types, as
they were taxable to the recipient in the United States. The associated income
5
Some evidence of such a resistant’s strategies of small countries provides flows were larger in the direction to the United States than to Canada because of
Crasnic (2020). the different sizes in the economies (Davies, 2004).

4
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

result from differently defined DTAs (e.g. asymmetry = 4 can result from in the first country and absolute outgoing foreign direct investments
dissimilarities in 4 different rules, theoretically 4 rules can be selected (FDIoutward) in the first country. These variables indicate the
out of 9 rules on more than 1.5 thousands ways). importance of bilateral FDI. The sum of export and import (Expimp)
The preliminary analysis of DTAs in the sample reveals some inter­ captures the insensitivity of trade. The values of these variables are
esting asymmetries. Germany and Poland prefer exemption, while calculated on the reports of the first country. Another variable, the
France, Italy, Spain, and the United Kingdom prefer tax credit as a distance between the capitals of countries (Distance), is a proxy of the
general rule (see Tables A.1-A.6 in Appendix). Tax exemption, as a potential intensity of other relations – generally, a higher distance
general rule, was applied in 16 treaties from Poland, 15 from Germany, means higher transportation cost which limits the number of actual
11 from France, nine from Italy, seven from Spain and six from the UK.7 bilateral connections.
If we consider the nine types of income, namely business profits, divi­ b) Variables determining the inequalities between countries include
dends, interest, royalties, alienation of property, independent personal the net difference of FDI to the GDP of the second country (FDI.net­
services, pensions, director’s fees and entertainers, the variable Asym­ diff.relative), a net difference of FDI to the GDP of the first country
metry is defined as the number of inconsonant detailed rules in each DTA (FDI.netdiff.in.first.GDP), the absolute value of trade balance related
(see the final columns in Tables A.1-A.6 in Appendix). This number can to the GDP of the first country (Tradebalanceabstogdpfirst), the dif­
vary from 0 to 9. The value 0 means no difference in rules, and this is the ference in purchasing power standard per capita measured as an
most common situation covering 41 cases in the sample. The value 9, absolute value of the difference between GDP in Purchasing Power
representing the full difference, appears only once when there is no DTA Standard per capita (PPSdiffabs), and the relative size of GDP
(Denmark-France). calculated as the maximum relation of nominal GDP between two
The lowest discrepancies involve dividends (8 inconsistent cases out countries in market prices (Sizerelation). These variables refer to the
of 121), royalties (16 cases) and interest (19 cases), while discrepancies differences in size and affluence affecting the economic relations (e.
in other income categories exceed, on average, 50 cases. The most g., the capital flows are more likely to be from the richer partner to
common rules in these three types of income are tax credit, if the the poorer one, and from larger to smaller rather than vice versa).
ownership share is small, and exemption, if the ownership share tres­ c) Variables capturing the tax competition calculated as an absolute
passes a threshold limit. The rules of taxation applying to these types of value of differences in tax rates between countries for personal in­
income are important for investments, so it is in line with the expecta­ come tax (PITdiffabs) and effective average tax rate (EATRdiffabs).
tion that they should not be differentiated to foster higher bilateral The first measure captures the differences in personal taxation, while
investments. the second covers the intensity of tax competition and the possible
The fundamental question in this study is the relation between the profitability of avoidance strategies by entrepreneurs. The tax dif­
economic and institutional performance of countries and legal differ­ ferences are proxies for the tax competition and profit-shifting
ences in DTAs between countries. The set of variables used in the study is (Nerudova et al., 2023). Effective Average Tax Rate (EATR) pro­
extensive and represents the relations between country characteristics. vides the measure of the tax burden for a hypothetical investment
The variables are chosen to illustrate the country’s performance and considering not only tax rates but also a definition of the tax base and
relations – in investment and import/export, GDP, affluence, and tax rules of amortisation in a country (Devereux and Griffith, 2003). It is
competition (described below). We set the first country as one of the six valid for the assumed form of investment financing (e.g. own capital
large countries (Germany, France, Italy, Spain, Poland and the United or debt). The EATR values are provided by ZEW (Leibniz-Zentrum für
Kingdom) and the second country as a partner in the EU or the UK. In Europäische Wirtschaftsforschung in Mannheim) and frequently used in
some pairs, the second country is a country from the first group (e.g., the analysis of taxation (e.g., Hristu-Varsakelis et al., 2011). We
Germany with France where Germany is the first country and France the decided to omit the corporate income tax variable because it is less
second country). The most appropriate would be the use of variables informative than EATR and the absolute value of tax wedge differ­
that were valid at the time of signing an agreement. Unfortunately, it is ence as the latter depends on the marital status and the demographic
not possible because there is no such data on international investment structure of a society.
and trade relations that are consistent and complete. For example, d) Variables describing the differentiation of double taxation
complete data on FDI from OECD are available since 2013, the data avoidance rules in individual categories of income or property.
about trade since the beginning of the 1990’s and data from Eurostat These are dummy variables for country pairs, where 0 means the
since 1995; while most European DTAs were signed before 1990. same double taxation avoidance rule and 1 means different rules.
Moreover, treaties are sometimes modified, so there is a problem The following items were collected: General_rule, Business_profits,
whether the data from the year of the last change or the year of a DTA Dividends, Interest, Royalties, Alienation_of_property, Inde­
signing should be chosen. However, the factors potentially affecting the pendent_personal_services, Pensions, Director’s_fees, and Entertainers.
content of the treaties are changing slowly, and similarly, the changes in The General rule measures the concordance of the main rules used in
the latter are not frequent. Therefore, we built our analysis on the the DTAs, while the next nine variables compare the rules for
assumption that, in the long run, treaties are adjusting to the economic different types of income or property. The General rule affects the
factors, and represent a compromise, balancing the interests of countries asymmetry measure because the rules which are not determined in
even if they possess different bargaining power. It allows the comparison other ways reveal the same concordance as the General rule. The
between the rules and economic factors at one time to find some asso­ General rule increases Asymmetry when inconsistent (equals 1) and
ciations or interdependences. decreases it when consistent (equals 0). The differences in the impact
We strive to capture the relative validity of the relations, so some of economic variables on Asymmetry and General rule are presented in
variables are related to the GDP of the first or second country. All the the two last columns of Table 1, where common variance is analysed.
variables are divided into four groups: In the regressions, the General rule is used as a control variable. It
captures the asymmetry in rules stemming from general preferences
a) Variables illustrating the intensity of bilateral relations between for the exemption or the tax credit. If all economic factors are irrel­
countries: absolute incoming foreign direct investments (FDIinward) evant, then the whole asymmetry is caused by the discordance of the
General rule. There are also differences not determined by the general
rules and we tried to explain them in regressions using economic
7
Each country can have 26 treaties with other members of the EU or the factors.
United Kingdom, for example, 20 treaties of the United Kingdom use tax credits, e) We also constructed spatially lagged explanatory variables, which
as a general rule. are used in some statistical analyses. They include information from

5
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

geographical neighbourhood to capture the distance-dependence

Asymmetry
and over-border relations. They involve all variables from the: a, b,

Model 3
and c groups above, but without, the variable Distance. These vari­
ables are identified by the ‘lag’ at the end of their names. In some

*
*
.
graphical analyses, the application of variables of different sizes is
not convenient, so we present the results on normalised variables
Model 2

General
rule
(these variables are transformed by subtraction of mean and division
by standard deviation). These variables are identified by the ‘norm’

.
at the end of their names.
Entertainers

It is worth underlining that this study refers much more to associa­


tions than causal relations. First, DTAs are stable legal contracts and are
.
rarely renegotiated (even if this is possible). Secondly, one cannot expect
.
that a particular DTA may change significantly the properties of the
economy of a given country. Thus, we are to explain the existing
Director’s

asymmetry in DTAs, while conclusions may be used to fine-tune existing


fees

contracts or design new ones.


The trade data was collected from the World Integrated Trade Solution
Pensions

Database. The trade data can reveal the true importance of bilateral
relations because FDI is less dependent on current international relations
**
*

and less sensitive to transaction costs. It should be noted that trade


.

variables are counted for 2017, and in most cases, they do not refer to
Independent_personal_services

the time when a DTA was signed. Moreover, exports and imports
declared by a given country are not the same as reported by the coun­
terpart due to errors, omissions and different definitions of exports and
imports.8 We assume that the relative importance of countries in trade is
relatively stable over time (despite the increasing volume of trans­
actions). The data about FDI is taken from the OECD database and re­
flects the investment between countries in 2017. Dispersion of FDI is
higher than that of trade because making a direct investment in a
*

country located far away is easier than trade due to the transportation
Alienation_of_property

cost. This cost is negligible for long-term investments.


FDI data describes the relations which are partially subsidiary and
partially complementary to the trade, but unfortunately, it includes
many gaps. The geographic distances between capitals are calculated
Significance of factors in ANOVA – Sum of Squares of type III in three models for normalised variables.

using flight (orthodromic) distances, from online calculators and the


economic data is taken from the Eurostat database. To avoid operating
**

*
.

on too many variables, we decided to work on selected variables


Royalties

extracted from a broader group of variables measuring the differences in


economies, the intensity of bilateral relations and tax competition
***
***
***

**
*

measures. For example, this broader group includes the relation to the
second country’s GDP instead of the first, variables presenting the di­
Interest

rection of asymmetry, and the absolute values of measures or their


***

relative values. Most of these omitted variables are highly correlated


with the final variables subsequently used in the analysis. We dropped
Dividends

them because they do not provide more valuable insight into the
problem.
*

Below we present the statistical analysis of dependent (Fig. 2a) and


explanatory (Fig. 2b) variables. The variables concerning double taxa­
Business_profits

tion avoidance rules generally show a significant positive correlation


(Fig. 2a), only for a dividend is this correlation negative (but insignifi­
cant). This means the countries predictably construct their DTAs. High
correlations in Fig. 2a mean that if countries A and B agree on rule 1 then
Significance: *** 0.001; ** 0.01; * 0.05;. 0.1.

they agree on rule 2. Asymmetry is generated by all rules except for


Dividends, Interest and Royalties DTAs Our question is how this regu­
Model 1

General

larity can be explained. In a group of explanatory variables, one observes


rule

***
*

varying correlations, both positive and negative, weak and strong


(Fig. 2b). Stronger correlations are visible in groups referring to the
FDI.netdiff.in.first.GDP.norm

same economic factors (like bilateral investments or trade).


Tradebalanseabstogdpfirst.

FDI.netdiff.relative.norm
Explanatory variables:

Dependent variable:

4. Modelling the differences in tax treaties


FDI.outward.norm

EATRdiffabs.norm

Sizerelation.norm
FDI.inward.norm

PPSdiffabs.norm
PITdiffabs.norm
Distance.norm
Expimp.norm

We have used several statistical and econometric techniques to


norm
Table 1

8
E.g., sometimes re-export is treated as an export from a given country.

6
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

Fig. 2. A. Correlation of variables for the tax treaty rules. Fig. 2B. Correlation of variables for explanatory variables and their spatially lagged values.

7
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

determine which variables are interrelated with double taxation − y1 ∼ 1| x1 …xn – the hierarchical linear model (HLM) measures the
avoidance rules, especially with asymmetry. This a complex problem as association between tax avoidance concordance rules x1 … xn
the dependent phenomenon is not a single variable but a set of variables. (considered jointly) on chosen economic process yn (for each y1, ….,
Therefore, we search for associations rather than for causality. We apply yn we calculate a separate model). HLM is an extension of ANOVA.
multidimensional methods to possibly best capture the non-obvious Contrary to ANOVA, the HLM models the fixed effects resulting from
regularities. The statistical approach, including analysis of vari­ explanatory variables (economic variables) and random effects as
ance (ANOVA) and hierarchical linear model (HLM), is to find the controls (tax avoidance concordance rules) and allows for a nesting
factors (here the tax rules) that separate different groups within the hierarchy of variables. HLM allows for inter-relatedness (correlation)
target variable (here the economic performance of countries). If sub­ of explanatory factors (McNeish et al., 2017). The results of HLM are
groups with diversified distributions exist (e.g. subgroups of low/high interpreted by the shares of variance explained by a given variable.
values), then the factors should distinguish them. ANOVA and HLM are
interpreted in terms of associations: if e.g. GDP distribution (of all The final stage includes ordered logistic regression to explain the
countries) can be divided by some factor into two different GDP distri­ drivers of the asymmetry of rules in DTAs. Regression is used to identify
butions (in subgroups of countries), then we say that GDP level matters the direction and significance of impact triggered by economic variables
for the factor value. Both methods allow for more than one grouping on the asymmetry of double taxation avoidance rules. Ordered logistic
factor. There are two major differences between ANOVA and HLM: the regression provides information about the increasing or decreasing
first one lies in the independence of grouping factors, while the second probability of asymmetry. As a robustness check, we apply Ordinary
one in the hierarchy (multilevel) of factors, by introducing fixed and Least Squares (OLS) regression. The ordered logit is applied because the
random effects. ANOVA assumes that the grouping variables are inde­ dependent variable Asymmetry is multilevel and discrete – the model
pendent and on the same hierarchical level. HLM allows for interde­ explains the probability of a given (from 0 to 9) level of asymmetry
pendence among grouping factors and for the mixture of fixed and considering the economic performance of two countries. Additionally,
random effects. Both are used to identify the relations between double we present box plots to disclose the possible non-linear effect of some
taxation avoidance rules and theirasymmetry, and economic variables. economic variables - for example, moderate differences in tax rates can
This statistical analysis is augmented by an econometric approach, be irrelevant for a small level of asymmetry but can be reversed for large
including linear regression, a spatial lag model (SLM) and two or­ differences when countries are perceived as engaging in harmful tax
dered logistic models, ordinary and with spatially lagged variables. competition. This is a reliable way to deal with non-linearity.
The ordered logistic regression fits the investigated problem because the Econometric models, ordered logistic regression and OLS, were
dependent variable Asymmetry is categorical and can take 10 values extended by adding spatially lagged variables which include informa­
representing all levels of possible asymmetry. OLS is used here as a tion from the geographical neighbourhood. We consider this an impor­
benchmark. Spatial lags are to control a geographical neighbourhood of tant novelty as the neighbourhood interactions of countries and over-
countries. border similarities may matter in DTAs. The spatially lagged variables
The purpose of the modelling in the first stage (with ANOVA and (labelled with lag in the name) are derived with the use of a contiguity
HLM) is to determine the differences between countries related to spatial weights matrix W. This matrix assumes that neighbours are the
double taxation avoidance rules. From a modelling point of view, this is countries that share the border. The spatially lagged variable expresses
a complex system of interdependence between rules of avoidance and the arithmetic average of values from the neighbourhood. In the case of
economic factors. Precisely, we would like to determine to what extent a islands or neighbours from outside the sample, the spatial lag of the
particular double taxation avoidance rule’s concordance is related to the given variable equals 0.
level of economic factors and whether separate groups can be distin­ The results of different types of analysis should be treated as com­
guished by economic variables. What is more, one may expect non- plementary, not substitutive, as they focus on various aspects of
linearity in taxation rules, which should be detected with in-depth sta­ modelled relations. Modelling this complex system of interdependencies
tistical analysis. We decided to use: requires diversified approaches, which are capable of capturing non-
obvious relations. The proposed methodological solutions turned out
− y1 ∼ x1 …xn – the ANOVA model investigating the association be­ to be the most efficient ones among a wide menu of statistical and
tween tax avoidance concordance rules x1 … xn (considered jointly) econometric tools which were tested to solve this problem.
on the chosen economic processes represented by variable y1.
ANOVA (Analysis Of Variance) examines the extent to which it is 5. The results of modelling
possible to distinguish coherent groups concentrated around the
mean value of a variable. The homogeneity of these groups is tested Table 1 presents subsequent ANOVA models in rows, in which eco­
by evaluating the variance of the data around the mean – if mean nomic variables are explained by the General rule and a set of tax
values in subgroups differ (and this difference is more than the avoidance concordance rules for different types of assets or income
standard deviation), then we consider the difference as significant. (Model 1). The penultimate column presents the results only for the
The result of ANOVA is a sum of squares (SS) (deviations) within and General rule (Model 2) and the last column only for Asymmetry (Model 3).
between groups. The high (between) intergroup SS (understood as Asterisks point out the significance of taxation policies in the analysis of
between-group heterogeneity) and the low (within) intragroup SS type III sums of squares (i.e., regardless of the order of variables in the
(within-group homogeneity) demonstrate the existence of distinct model). Significant tax policies (with asterisks in a table) are the factors
groups. When the sums of intragroup and intergroup squares are that separate the groups of countries due to their economic performance.
equal, we treat the data as belonging to one group. The F-test for Interpretation of Table 1 results is as follows: if the explanatory variable
variance determines the significance of these differences. In multi- (factor in a column) is significant in a given model (in rows), then the
factor ANOVA, the most convenient to interpret are marginal value of the economic variable (in rows) matters for the similarity of
squared sums of type III as they are independent of the order of DTAs (in columns).
variables and take into account interactions between variables Discussing the results of specific double taxation avoidance rules, the
(Kuznetsova et al., 2017). The interactions refer to tax avoidance most significant variables are the rules relating to Royalties. Royalties are
concordance rules as the other economic variables are not present in linked to FDI and differences in personal income tax rates, but also to the
this approach. The analysis (Table 1) is provided on normalised data trade balance, so they cover variables from all three groups of factors
and includes three models (detailed rules concordance and asym­ that can affect asymmetry. Interest is related to differences in personal
metry and General rule concordance). income tax rates, while Dividends to the EATR differences. It can indicate

8
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

that this group of rules is under the pressure of tax competition. The Asymmetry is a grouping variable for Expimp, EATRdiffabs and
other rules are not associated with taxation differences or the grouping Tradebalnseabstogdpfirst – countries with a similar degree of similarity
effect remains small (the latter refers to the Alienation of property and (from 0 to 9) perform similarly economically for these variables. On this
Entertainers). The variables referring to the differences in bilateral trade basis, it can be concluded that a high level of trade, a large differenti­
relations affect the Royalties and Alienation of property rules. In the ation in corporate taxation and a trade imbalance contribute to the
context of the stated hypotheses, the differentiation in terms of divi­ differentiation of double taxation avoidance rules. The asymmetry af­
dends, royalties and interest rules is related to the intensity of bilateral fects the variables from all three groups of factors but is of the lowest
relations and tax competition, while the impact of inequalities between significance for the trade balance. The latter hints that true inequalities
countries is of lesser importance. This is in line with expectations between countries are less important than tax competition and bilateral
because the tax structures including royalties, interest and dividends are trade intensity. This result also indicates that differences in investment
frequently used for tax avoidance and minimisation of tax liabilities. do not affect the content of the treaties as much as trade differences. Due
If we look at the general rule solely (without considering the indi­ to the correlations of economic and taxation factors, one can observe the
vidual double taxation avoidance rules) in the penultimate column, only effect of, “the strongest” variable in the group (intensity of relations, tax
inward FDI and differences in wealth per capita (PPSdiffabs) are signif­ competition and inequality of relations) which becomes significant for
icant. Finally, if we consider only Asymmetry, it is related to the intensity explaining the tax asymmetry.
of bilateral relations and differences in size and affluence between Finally, we can compare the results of the regression of dependent
countries, but not to the tax competition variables. economic variables on the Asymmetry dependent variable (Table 3). In
Table 2 shows the results of the hierarchical linear model. Estimated general, all models reveal similar significant variables and consistency
models for consecutive economic variables are presented in the col­ in coefficient signs. The basic source of asymmetry is the concordance of
umns. Only the random effects are reported as they refer to the general rules between countries, which significantly increases the R2 of
concordance of avoidance rules. The fixed effects are omitted as they models (in the 6th column, the only model without a General rule as a
refer to the set of economic variables (they were controlling for inter- dependent variable shows the lowest R2 equal to 0.05). Unfortunately,
dependency between economic factors). Each model considers the full data about FDI is not complete, so it generates gaps in spatially lagged
set of tax policies with Asymmetry and the General rule. It should be variables, and the number of observations drops in these regressions to
stressed that HLM may yield different results than ANOVA due to 121, making these results less credible.
possible correlations between explanatory factors (economic variables), The level of FDI affects asymmetry but inward and outward in­
embedded hierarchy and the use of random and fixed effects. In HLM the vestments work in different directions. Greater inward investments in­
focus is on the proportion of explained total variance by a given crease the asymmetry of rules in a DTA, while greater outward
grouping factor (represented by random effects - related to avoidance investments decrease it. The size of this effect is similar for both types of
rules concordance) when the other economic variables are present (fixed FDI (inward and outward). Countries with greater outward investments
effects, controls). Interpretation of Table 2 results is as follows: if the are likely to be more important for the first country, so the rules will be
explanatory variable (factor in a column) is significant in a given model more reciprocal than in the case where the first country (in general, a
(in rows), then the value of the economic variable (in rows) matters for larger country) is important predominantly for the second country. A
the similarity of DTAs (in columns), when controlling for inter- larger country is more attractive as a place for inward investment than a
dependency of economic variables and hierarchy of impact. The small one, so this may increase the asymmetry in tax treaties due to
higher the proportion of explained variance, the more influential the larger-country-bargaining-power. This is similar to the effect observed
factor in the separation of groups of similar countries. (Asterisks in the between Canada and the United States (Whalley, 2011), with regula­
table represent the degree of explained variance.) tions favouring American investors.
The Royalties are the most prominent and significant in six different Intensifying trade mitigates asymmetry in tax treaties and this is
models. There is no significant impact for such double taxation avoid­ visible in the sign of spatially lagged variable Expimp. Interestingly, this
ance rules as Director’s fees and Business profits. Most economic variables is a non-necessarily linear relationship (a very low and very high level of
are related to between one and three tax avoidance concordance rules - asymmetry (0,1,9) is associated with low trade values, and a moderate
except the Expimp, which is related to four rules. level of asymmetry (2–5) seems to be associated with high bilateral trade

Table 2
Hierarchical linear model (HLM) – random effects.
Dependent Intensity of relations Tax competition Inequality of relations
variables:

Explanatory Distance Expimp FDI. FDI. PITdiffabs EATRdiffabs PPSdiffabs Sizerelation Tradebalanseabstogdpfirst FDI. FDI.
variables: inward outward netdiff. netdiff.
relative in.first.
GDP

General.rule * . ***
Interest . *** **
Royalties . ** *** *** *** ***
Alienation.of. . . ** . ** .
property
Independent. *** ***
personal.
services
Director.s.fees
Entertainers . ** *
Pensions ***
Business.
profits
Dividends .
Asymmetry ** *** *

Note: Asterisks illustrate the share of a factor in total variance, greater than 0%, intervals are as follows: 2% * 5% ** 10% *** 20%.

9
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

Table 3
Results of the regression models (values of continuous variables are standardised).
Dependent variable: Ordinary Least Ordinary Ordered logistic Ordered logistic Ordered logistic Ordered logistic regression
Asymmetry Squares with spatial Least Squares regression with regression regression without without General rule and
lags spatial lags General rule country dummies
Explanatory variables:

Distance − 0.33* − 0.2. − 0.67* − 0.34 − 0.13 − 0.37*


Expimp − 0.53. − 0.06 − 1.29* − 0.42 -*0.52 − 0.3
FDI.inward 0.94 0.78* 1.87. 1.24. 1.7** 1.22*
FDI.outward − 0.93. − 0.62 − 1.87. − 1.15. − 1.82** − 1.54*
PITdiffabs 0.2 0.23 0.34 0.33. 0.27 0.24*
EATRdiffabs 0.1 0.1 0.06 0.08 − 0.33 − 0.13
PPSdiffabs 0.18 0.22. 0.41. 0.39* 0.28 0.33*
Sizerelation − 0.18 − 0.31** − 0.73. − 0.81** − 0.57** − 0.48**
Tradebalanseabstogdpfirst 0.22 − 0.03 0.52 0.16 0.57** 0.51
FDI.netdiff.relative − 0.01 − 0.17 − 0.31 − 0.47* − 0.44* − 0.4.
FDI.netdiff.in.first.GDP − 0.55* − 0.17 − 0.81 − 0.28 − 0.59* 0.41
Expimp.lag − 0.35. − 1.1*
FDI.inward.lag 0.26 0.6
FDI.outward.lag 0.23 0.18
PITdiffabs.lag − 0.08 − 0.28
EATRdiffabs.lag 0.05 0.37
PPSdiffabs.lag 0.14 0.26
Sizerelation.lag − 0.32 − 0.64.
Tradebalanseabstogdpfirst. − 0.06 0.1
lag
FDI.netdiff.relative.lag − 0.01 0.01
FDI.netdiff.in.first.GDP.lag 0.32 0.28
Spain − 1.27.
France − 0.09
Italy − 1.18*
Germany 0.15
United Kingdom − 1.48*
General rule 4.82*** 4.72*** 7.98*** 5.89***
Constant 0.59*** 0.69***
R2 or Pseudo R2 0.82 0.79 0.41 0.33 0.07 0.05
Observations 117 162 121 162 162 162

Significance: *** 0.001; ** 0.01; * 0.05; . 0.1.

– Fig. 3). The intensity of bilateral relations is more visible for trade than or different from that used by the second country. If the relations are
for direct investment. Perhaps, trade better reflects the importance of intense, the rules are more carefully negotiated and more differentiated.
close relations between countries than FDI, which may be more Finally, the very high level of bilateral trade lowers asymmetry because
geographically dispersed (occurring in countries with which a given it points out that economies are very similar and the same provisions are
country does not have strong relations) and more random (direct in­ beneficial to both parties of agreement to the same extent.
vestments are less susceptible to transaction costs compared to foreign The differences in size or affluence also affects DTA rules. The dif­
trade). This confirms hypothesis 1, that low-intensity trade and invest­ ference in affluence PPSdiffabs increases asymmetry in most models (the
ment relations favour the choice of a very large or small asymmetry, exception is the OLS regression with spatial lags and OLR with country
which probably means that a given country chooses the preferred dummies) but the size of this effect is relatively low. The analysis of the
method of avoiding double taxation, and this method may be convergent box plot reveals that for the lowest level of asymmetry (0–2), the

Fig. 3. Expimp and the level of asymmetry.

10
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

difference in affluence is particularly low (Fig. 4). Contrary to this effect, of factors have an impact on the asymmetry of double taxation avoid­
the relative size of economies (measured in GDP) is negatively related to ance rules. However, the importance of these groups is not the same. The
the asymmetry, so treaties with small countries (measured by the GDP) most important group is the intensity of trade and investment relations
are concordant in the applied rules of both parties. This relation seems to where trade is more important for asymmetry than investments (ac­
be linear. The intuitive explanation behind this result is that greater PPS cording to the HLM results). This suggests that DTA rules are more suited
per capita means a more diversified economy and requires different to the specific interests of the countries involved in the agreement.
provisions to cover specific relations. It should be noted that spatially We can guess what the reasons behind this result are. Probably one of
lagged Sizerelation is also significant and negative in the OLR with the important factors is favourable business environment. The investi­
spatial lag. gated countries cooperate intensively in the European Union (the UK
The results of regression point out the insignificance of tax variables. exit the European Union in 2021) establishing the free movement of
Only in the models without the General rule (the last column in Table 3), goods, capital, services and persons. These freedoms intensify relation­
PIT’s absolute difference is significant at the 5% level; but this model ships between all members, reducing costs of trade and investments and
does not control for the preference of countries in one of the double stimulating the development of more detailed DTAs. On one hand, the
taxation avoidance rules. In general, we cannot identify the clear di­ quality of bureaucracy is another factor that may contribute to the
rection of effects generated by this group of variables. This result is in greater use of detailed provisions in tax treaties. A tax administration
line with the results of ANOVA. However, we know from the HML that at can deal with complicated rules only if it is adequately effective which is
least EATRdiffabs can be used to group treaties concerning the level of more likely in the developed countries signing a treaty. On the other
asymmetry. Therefore, the insignificance of this variable can be an effect hand, we know that high quality bureaucracy stimulates international
of the non-linear impact of taxation differences on the avoidance rules investments, so the impact can be reciprocal (Busse and Hefeker, 2007).
(negligible for small taxation differences and substantial for large dif­ The inequalities of countries signing a DTA is the second most
ferences). Indeed, analysis of the EATRdiffabs box plot (Fig. 5) confirms important group. The relative size of countries and differences in
various effects on asymmetry concerning the level of taxation differ­ affluence may be associated with taxation differences, as small and
ences. It is especially evident for the high level of Asymmetry (value 7–9) poorer countries usually prefer lower levels of tax burdens to attract
where the value of this variable is higher than a moderate or low level of capital and limit the outflow of workers abroad. However, these factors
asymmetry (0–6). affect asymmetry differently. The differentiation of citizens’ wealth fa­
Similarly, for PITdiffabs, the value of this variable is higher for a level vours higher asymmetry while differentiation in the size of the GDP of
of asymmetry between 7 and 8 (Fig. 6). The asymmetry of level 9 is countries favours lower asymmetry. Several explanations arise here. In
different but includes only three cases (treaties between France and the case of differences in wealth, the treaties may be more asymmetric to
Ireland, the lack of a treaty between France and Denmark, and the treaty protect the investment benefits of a wealthier country. This result can
between the United Kingdom and Belgium), so it is atypical. also stem from the differences in bargaining power among countries of
The obtained result suggests that the existence of tax competition different affluence or is a consequence of different structures of econo­
could have an impact on the content of double taxation agreements but mies at different levels of development. In the case of differences in GDP
only for the large differences in tax rates. For small differences, the size (but not affluence), the number of bilateral relations is limited and
asymmetry of double taxation avoidance rules remains low, and the thus leads to the simplification of DTA rules. The absolute value of this
differentiation of tax burden is not confirmed by the regression results. It effect is lower, not only from the variables representing the intensity of
can indicate that countries have a high level of tolerance for govern­ bilateral relations but also from the effects related to the GDP difference.
ments granting tax preferences to entities in one of the contracting Perhaps, the effect is weakened for countries in the region with rela­
countries and they react only when the differences are substantial. In the tively small differences in affluence.
latter situation, the rules cease to be symmetrical to limit the tax ad­ Tax competition is the third most important group. Particularly, tax
vantages offered by one of the parties to the agreement. variables are not significant in regressions and, according to the ANOVA
and HLM results, they refer mainly to rules applied to Royalties and In­
6. Conclusions and policy implications terest. Probably, the impact of tax competition on tax treaty rules is non-
linear, as we can guess from the observation of box plots. For a low level
This study confirmed that the variables representing all three groups of asymmetry, the tax competition (measured by taxation differences) is

Fig. 4. PPSdiffabs and the level of asymmetry.

11
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

Fig. 5. EATRdiffabs and the level of asymmetry.

Fig. 6. PITdiffabs and the level of asymmetry.

moderate but for large asymmetry (seven or more) it increases rapidly. low-intensive relations, inward investment should prevail. The second
One can conclude that a country’s government establishes other double hypothesis is not fully supported as the empirical evidence is mixed.
taxation avoidance rules if tax competition is evident than when tax Inequality in a country’s size, measured by Gross Domestic Product,
differences are on an average level. This observation supports the decreases the asymmetry while the difference in affluence measured by
statement of Rixen (2011), that changes in the tax regime are solely Purchasing Power Standard triggers higher asymmetry. Therefore, one
insufficient to suppress harmful tax competition. can expect that only the difference in the level of economic development
Referring to the hypotheses set out in the introduction, the first hy­ increases asymmetry in tax treaties while the difference in the size of
pothesis is true. The regression result confirms the negative relation economies is not relevant.
between trade turnover and asymmetry but the observation of box plots The third hypothesis is not confirmed. Looking at the box plot of tax
reveals that asymmetry is increasing for lower levels of trade. The non- variables, we can observe that a higher asymmetry on EATR and PIT’s
linear impact of exports/imports confirms that countries with low trade differences appears for very a high level of asymmetry (value of Asym­
turnover choose rules in line with their general preferences to double metry of 7–9. Moreover, the difference in EATR is a grouping variable in
taxation avoidance rules. It provides either very large or very small HLM but it does not directly explain the asymmetry of rules. Never­
differentiation of avoidance rules (they choose tax credits or tax theless, these results should be treated with caution as they refer to the
exemption according to their general preference). This hypothesis is also relatively small group of 11 DTAs with high asymmetry and they are
indirectly confirmed by the impact of distance between the capitals, supported neither by the ordered logistic regression nor by ANOVA. We
which indicates lower asymmetry when the countries are further apart. can suppose that, if another country is perceived as engaging in harmful
The regression results indicate that the high value of FDI in a smaller tax competition, the double taxation avoidance rules are also altered,
country decreases asymmetry. The latter can be an indicator of more providing a higher level of asymmetry; but it would require further
intensive and better-balanced investment relationships because one can studies to better capture tax competition and the changes in tax treaties
expect that a more populated country (ceteris paribus) is potentially with countries offering preferred tax regimes.
more attractive for investments than less populated ones. Therefore, for The basic policy implication of this study hints that there is no

12
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

universal principle for assigning tax treaties with symmetric and Barthel, F., Neumayer, E., 2012. Competing for scarce foreign capital: spatial dependence
in the diffusion of Double Taxation Treaties. Int. Stud. Q. 56 (4), 645–660. https://
asymmetric rules. When the benefits of a treaty are limited to selected
doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2478.2012.00757.x.
income or assets, a government should extract them by the asymmetry in Becker, J., Fuest, C., 2011. The taxation of foreign profits – the old view, the new view
tax treaty rules. In this context, the practice of adopting rules that and a pragmatic view. Intereconomics 46 (2), 92–97. https://doi.org/10.1007/
comply with the general rule preferred by a given country, when bilat­ s10272-011-0369-4.
Bénassy-Quéré, A., Fontagné, L., Lahrèche-Révil, A., 2005. How does FDI react to
eral trade and investment relations are scarce, is not optimal. Such a rule corporate taxation? Int. Tax Publ. Finance 12 (5), 583–603. https://doi.org/
neither provides all benefits, which can be captured by the regulation, 10.1007/s10797-005-2652-4.
nor is stable over time. It is because, with the intensification and Braun, J., Zagler, M., 2018. The true art of the tax deal: evidence on aid flows and
bilateral double tax agreements. World Econ. 41 (6), 1478–1507. https://doi.org/
diversification of relations, such a simple rule generates distortions and 10.1111/twec.12628.
benefits only one of the parties of the treaty. The policy of asymmetric Bucovetsky, S., 1991. Asymmetric tax competition. J. Urban Econ. 30, 167–181.
rules is better at least in the middle run. In the long run, one can expect Busse, M., Hefeker, C., 2007. Political risk, institutions and foreign direct investment.
Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 23 (2), 397–415. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
that the symmetry of rules should be higher because of the intensifica­ ejpoleco.2006.02.003.
tion of bilateral relations. It creates a space for renegotiation of tax Chisik, R., Davies, R., 2004a. Gradualism in tax treaties with irreversible foreign direct
treaties in the direction of higher symmetry of rules. Similarly, it is investment. Int. Econ. Rev. 45 (1), 113–139. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-
2354.2004.00119.x.
surprising that only high tax discrepancies reveal some asymmetry of Chisik, R., Davies, R., 2004b. Asymmetric FDI and tax-treaty bargaining: theory and
rules in tax treaties. Therefore, it is worth considering a higher differ­ evidence. J. Publ. Econ. 88 (6), 1119–1148. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727
entiation of rules between countries using different tax burdens where (03)00059-8.
Crasnic, L., 2020. Resistance in tax and transparency standards: small states’
tax difference indicates the possibility of harmful tax competition.
heterogenous responses to new regulations. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 255–280. https://
doi.org/10.1080/09692290.2020.1800504.
Funding Davies, R., 2003. The OECD model tax treaty: tax competition and two-way capital flows.
Int. Econ. Rev. 44 (2), 725–753. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00087.
Davies, R., 2004. Tax treaties and foreign direct investment: potential versus
This research did not receive any specific grant from funding performance. Int. Tax Publ. Finance 11 (6), 775–802. https://doi.org/10.1023/B:
agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors. The Open ITAX.0000045331.76700.40.
Devereux, M.P., Griffith, R., 2003. Evaluating tax policy for location decisions. Int. Tax
access has been financed by the University of Warsaw. Publ. Finance 10 (2), 107–126. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1023364421914.
Dickescheid, T., 2004. Exemption vs. credit method in international double taxation
Credit author statement treaties. Int. Tax Publ. Finance 11 (6), 721–739. https://doi.org/10.1023/B:
ITAX.0000045328.78142.d9.
Egger, P., Loretz, S., Pfaffermayr, M., Winner, H., 2009. Bilateral effective tax rates and
Janusz Kudła: Conceptualization, Methodology, Formal analysis, foreign direct investment. Int. Tax Publ. Finance 16 (6). https://doi.org/10.1007/
Investigation, Data curation, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & s10797-008-9092-x.
Gordon, R., 1992. Can capital income taxes survive in open economies? J. Finance 47,
editing, Visualization, Supervision, Project administration, Katarzyna 1159–1180. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1992.tb04009.x.
Kopczewska: Methodology, Formal analysis, Writing – original draft, Gorter, J., Parikh, A., 2003. How sensitive is FDI to differences in corporate income
Writing – review & editing, Monika Stachowiak-Kudła: Investigation, taxation within the EU? Economist 151, 193–204. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:
1023913618978.
Data curation, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing, Hamada, K., 1966. Strategic aspects of taxation of foreign investment income. Q. J. Econ.
Visualization. 80, 361–375. https://doi.org/10.2307/1880725.
Haufler, A., Stähler, F., 2013. Tax competition in a simple model with heterogeneous
firms: how larger markets reduce profit taxes. Int. Econ. Rev. 54 (2), 665–692.
Declaration of competing interest https://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12010.
Haufler, A., Mardan, M., Schindler, D., 2018. Double tax discrimination to attract FDI
and fight profit shifting: the role of CFC rules. J. Int. Econ. 114, 25–43. https://doi.
The authors declare that they have no known competing financial org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2018.04.007.
interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence Hearson, M., 2018a. When do developing countries negotiate away their corporate tax
base? J. Int. Dev. 30, 233–255. https://doi.org/10.1002/jid.3351.
the work reported in this paper. Hearson, M., 2018b. Transnational expertise and the expansion of the international tax
regime: imposing ‘acceptable’ standards. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 25 (5), 647–671.
Data availability https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290.2018.1486726.
Hristu-Varsakelis, D., Karagianni, S., Saraidaris, A., 2011. Equilibrium conditions in
corporate tax competition and Foreign Direct Investment flows. Econ. Modell. 28
The dataset is attached to submission as an excel file. (1–2), 13–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2010.10.005.
Janeba, E., 1995. Corporate income tax competition, double taxation treaties, and
foreign direct investment. J. Publ. Econ. 56, 423–445. https://doi.org/10.1016/
Acknowledgements 0047-2727(94)01424-M.
Janský, P., Šedivý, M., 2019. Estimating the revenue costs of tax treaties in developing
Many thanks for valuable comments are due to the participants of the countries. World Econ. 42 (6), 1828–1849. https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12764.
Kangave, J., 2009. The dominant voices in double taxation agreements: a critical analysis
10th Annual Conference of the Spanish Association of Law and Eco­ of the ‘dividend’ article in the agreement between Uganda and The Netherlands. Int.
nomics (Porto, Portugal, June 27–28, 2019). We are also very grateful to Community Law Rev. 11 (4), 387–407.
three anonymous referees and the editors of Economic Modelling for Keen, M., Ligthart, J.E., 2006. Information sharing and international taxation: a primer.
Int. Tax Publ. Finance 13 (2–3), 81–110. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-006-
their detailed comments, which helped us to improve the paper. 3090-7.
Kleist, D., 2016. A multilateral instrument for implementing changes to double tax
treaties: problems and prospects. Intertax 44 (11), 823–830. https://doi.org/
Appendix A. Supplementary data
10.54648/taxi2016075.
Kuznetsova, A., Brockhoff, P.B., Christensen, R.H., 2017. lmerTest package: tests in linear
Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https://doi. mixed effects models. J. Stat. Software 82, 1–26.
org/10.1016/j.econmod.2023.106244. Loretz, S., 2007. Determinants of bilateral effective tax rates: empirical evidence from
OECD countries. Fisc. Stud. 28 (2), 227–249. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-
5890.2007.00055.x.
References McNeish, D., Stapleton, L.M., Silverman, R.D., 2017. On the unnecessary ubiquity of
hierarchical linear modeling. Psychol. Methods 22 (1), 114–140. https://doi.org/
10.1037/met0000078.
Allee, T., Peinhardt, C., 2014. Evaluating three explanations for the design of bilateral
Mills, L., Newberry, K., 2004. Do foreign multinationals’ tax incentives influence their U.
investment treaties. World Polit. 66 (1), 47–87. https://doi.org/10.1017/
S. income reporting and debt policy? Natl. Tax J. 57 (1), 89–107.
S0043887113000324.
Mongrain, S., Wilson, J.D., 2018. Tax competition with heterogeneous capital mobility.
Azémar, C., Dharmapala, D., 2019. Tax sparing agreements, territorial tax reforms, and
J. Publ. Econ. 167, 177–189. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2018.08.005.
foreign direct investment. J. Publ. Econ. 169, 89–108. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jpubeco.2018.10.013.

13
J. Kudła et al. Economic Modelling 122 (2023) 106244

Montal, F., Potz-Nielsen, C., Sumner, J.L., 2020. What states want: estimating ideal Pham, A.D., Pham, H., Cuong Ly, K., 2019. Double taxation treaties as a catalyst for trade
points from international investment treaty content. J. Peace Res. 57 (6), 679–691. developments: a comparative study of Vietnam’s relations with ASEAN and EU
https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343320959130. member states. J. Risk Financ. Manag. 12 (4), 1–16. https://doi.org/10.3390/
Mooij, R.A. de, Ederveen, S., 2003. Taxation and foreign direct investment: a synthesis of jrfm12040172.
empirical research. Int. Tax Publ. Finance 10 (6), 673–693. https://doi.org/ Pieretti, P., Pulina, G., 2020. Does eliminating international profit shifting increase tax
10.1023/A:1026329920854. revenue in high-tax countries? Econ. Modell. 93, 717–727. https://doi.org/10.1016/
Nerudova, D., Dobranschi, M., Solilová, V., Litzman, M., 2023. Onshore and offshore j.econmod.2020.01.020.
profit shifting and tax revenue losses in the European Union. Econ. Modell. 119 Rixen, T., Schwarz, P., 2009. Bargaining over the avoidance of double taxation: evidence
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.106111. from German tax treaties. Finanzarchiv: Public Finance Analysis 65 (4), 442–471.
Neumayer, E., Plümper, T., 2010. Spatial effects in dyadic data. Int. Organ. 64 (1), Rixen, T., 2011. From double tax avoidance to tax competition: explaining the
145–166. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0020818309990191. institutional trajectory of international tax governance. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 18 (2),
Nguyen, A.T.N., 2019. A global analysis of factors impacting the intensive and extensive 197–227. https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290.2010.481921.
margins of bilateral foreign direct investment. World Econ. 42 (9), 2649–2667. Sanz-Córdoba, P., 2020. The role of infrastructure investment and factor productivity in
https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12827. international tax competition. Econ. Modell. 85, 30–38. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Peralta, S., van Ypersele, T., 2005. Factor endowments and welfare levels in an econmod.2019.05.003.
asymmetric tax competition game. J. Urban Econ. 57 (2), 258–274. https://doi.org/ Scharf, K., 2001. International capital tax evasion and the foreign tax credit puzzle. Can.
10.1016/j.jue.2004.10.007. J. Econ. 34 (2), 465–480. https://doi.org/10.1111/0008-4085.00084.
Petkova, K., 2021. Withholding tax rates on dividends: symmetries versus asymmetries Weyzig, F., van Dijk, M., 2009. Incoherence between tax and development policies: the
or single- versus multi-rated double tax treaties. Int. Tax Publ. Finance 28 (3), case of The Netherlands. Third World Q. 30 (7), 1259–1277.
890–940. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09637-y. Whalley, J., 2011. Puzzles over international taxation of cross-border flows of capital
Petkova, K., Stasio, A., Zagler, M., 2020. On the relevance of double tax treaties. Int. Tax income. In: Jovanović, M.N., Sidjanski, D. (Eds.), International Handbook on the
Publ. Finance 27, 575–605. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-019-09570-9. Economics of Integration, Volume II. Edward Elgar Publishing (chapter 17).

14

You might also like