You are on page 1of 11

Journal of Business Ethics (2009) 84:217–227 Ó Springer 2008

DOI 10.1007/s10551-008-9698-z

A Brief History of Long Work Time and


the Contemporary Sources of Overwork Lonnie Golden

ABSTRACT. What are some of the key historical trends preferences, external incentives, and employers’
in hours of work per worker in US? What economic, constraints? What motivates employees to desire to
social-psychological, organizational and institutional for- work longer work hours? Can work become over-
ces determine the length of individuals’ working hours? work – risking harm to workers, families, or econo-
How much of the trend toward longer working hours mies – or workaholism, an unforced addiction to
among so many workers may be attributable to workers’
incessant work activity? The first part of this article
preferences, workplace incentives or employers’ con-
straints? When can work become overwork or worka-
traces the history of the length of working hours and
holism – an unforced addiction to incessant work activity its recent polarization. The second develops a multi-
which risk harm to workers, families or even economies? disciplinary model to identify the motivations behind
The first part of this article traces the history of the length more workers desiring or getting longer hours. The
of working hours and its recent polarization. The second final section briefly suggests policies that might curb
part develops a multi-disciplinary model to identify the persistence of long hours by addressing its
motivations behind working longer hours. Individuals’ underlying economic and social sources.
desired work hours will stem from the weighted contri-
bution of five sources: (1) current real wage rates; (2)
forward-looking, wage trajectories; (3) relative status The long-run historical trend of hours
associated with hours of labor; (4) intrinsic rewards, of work
process benefits or amenities acquired through work; (5)
hours demanded by the employer and other structural Most scholars begin the quest for identifying the
constraints, to which workers may adapt. Employers and secular trends in work hours with the onset of the
their established conditions of work have influenced the
industrial revolution (Alvarez-Cuadrado, 2007;
course of long run trends labor supply and in work time
structures. The final section suggests policies that might
Bienefeld, 1972; Costa, 1998; Cross, 1988; Hopkins,
address the persistence of long hours. 1982; Thompson, 1967). There are essentially three
identifiable stages of development in the duration of
KEY WORDS: working hours, working time, overwork, weekly or annual hours worked since the 1800s:
labor supply, hours constraints, labor history, workaholism gradual reduction, stabilization, and then more re-
cently, polarization. In the first wave, during the
JEL CLASSIFICATIONS: B25, J22, J28 initial transformation from agricultural to industrial
type jobs and workplaces, many workers in the US
were working as long as 70 h per week or more
Overview (Whaples, 2001). Most of the increase in hours
occurred on an annual basis, with a rise in the length
What are some of the key historical trends and patterns of the workyear and disappearance of seasonal down
in hours of work per worker in US? What forces and time. Daily hours appear to have peaked by 1830 in
counterforces determine the length of individuals’ the US and declined somewhat during the rest of the
work hours-economic, social–psychological–cultural, century as employers accommodated workers calls
organizational, and institutional? How much of the for a shorter workday. It was facilitated by tech-
trend in work hours may be attributable to workers’ nology and mechanization that made it possible for
218 Lonnie Golden

employers to maintain original output levels even Trends began to change about 1970 or soon
while shortening daily hours (Atack et al., 2003). thereafter. What has occurred since then is not yet
The decline in hours spread with the advent of the settled. A stir was created by evidence that average
shorter hours movements in the latter quarter of the annual hours in the US reversed course and started
19th century. Labor strikes to limit work hours be- rising (Leete and Schor, 1994). The overall average
gan as early as 1791 in the US and even earlier in length of weekly hours is clearly not the ideal indi-
Britain (Brody, 1989; Roediger and Foner, 1989). cator of work time trends because the average may be
The secular decline in the workweek length has suppressed if there is growing percentage of the labor
tended to be non-linear or cyclical. Historically, force working in less than full-time or year-round
declines in the ‘‘standard’’ workweek have occurred employment, such as involuntary part-time and
during growth periods following periods of eco- contingent work. The trend in weekly hours among
nomic stagnation. Demand for shorter work time only full-time workers has exhibited a slight increase
became pent up and only could be exercised once since the early 1970s. It has risen clearly among those
workers garnered sufficient leverage to negotiate for employed in managerial, professional, transportation,
shorter hours (Roche, 1987). This was not sustain- and sales occupations and among the relatively
able without the establishment of new institutions, highest wage-earners (Bernstein and Kornbluh,
such as labor unions, the labor movement and 2005; Costa, 1998; Drago, 2000; Rones et al., 1997).
favorable labor protection laws, particularly in the At least among the most educated in the work force
early 20th century developed economies (Martorana and white men, average hours have lengthened
and Hirsch, 2001; Ueberfeldt, 2006; Whaples, (Coleman and Pencavel, 1993). Trends vary
2001). Otherwise, hours might have continued depending on samples and estimation methodology.
increasing. The hyper-competitive, unregulated Analysis of average weekly hours of work in the
market for labor in the 19th century contributed to manufacturing sectors, however, reinforces findings
long hours per week that left workers’ desire for a from households (Hetrick, 2000). There are detrac-
shorter workday often unfulfilled (Altman, 1999; tors who observe no recent increase in hours at all
Atack et al., 2003; Bourdieu and Reynaud, 2001). (Greenwood and Vandenbroucke, 2005; McGratten
By the 1920s in the US, the average workweek and Rogerson, 2004; Ramey and Francis, 2006).
was down to about 48 h per worker. In the first What is most clear is that the last few decades may
years of the Great Depression, workweeks dropped be more accurately characterized as one of polariza-
precipitously. Work-sharing practices spread, where tion of work hours or a time-divide (Bluestone and
employers reduced operating days per week or shift Rose, 1998; Drago, 2000; Jacobs and Gerson, 2004;
lengths, actively encouraged by Federal government Messenger, 2004). The share of employed men
policies (Hunnicutt, 1988). Fair Labor Standards working 50 or more hours per week has been rising
Act legislation was passed in 1938 that instituted a among highly educated, high-wage, salaried and
standard workweek, enforced by the now familiar older-aged workers (Drago et al., 2005; Epstein and
time-and-a-half premium requirement for ‘‘over- Kalleberg, 2004; Kuhn and Lozano, 2006). Currently,
time’’ hours beyond 40 in a given one-week period almost 19% of the US work force works 50 or more
for workers. However, the shorter hours movement hours per week, and almost one-third works longer
dissipated thereafter, with greater interest among than 40-h per week. Also, there has been growth in
workers for reaping the rewards for productivity the shorter-hour tail of the hours distribution. Table I
gains through pay increases and consumption summarizes several studies of work hours in the US
growth rather than shortened hours. Workers through the 1990s. Corresponding trends in average
interest regarding hours became more of stabilizing leisure time have been a recent battleground. A con-
the workweek through, to keep income predict- sensus is emerging that there has been growing
able. Indeed, the workweek showed remarkable inequality in the distribution of leisure, mirroring the
stability for decades thereafter (Bernanke and inequality of wages – higher earners have experienced
Powell, 1986; Golden, 1990). Technological pro- a loss of leisure time (Aguiar and Hurst, 2007).
gress, particularly in supervisory activity, would In contrast to the trends in the U.S., starting about
forever restrain the workweek (Ueberfeldt, 2006). the same time, 1970, annual and weekly hours in
A Brief History of Long Work Time and the Contemporary Sources of Overwork 219

TABLE I
Trends in work hours, worker surveys, selected research findings

Period Change in work hours Sample Data Sources

1979–2000 16% increase Married Couples CPS Bernstein and


(490#) annual hours Kornbluh (2005)
1979–2002 50% increase Wives in Married
(466#) annual hours Couples
1976–1993 2.4% (1 hour) weekly, Wage and Salary CPS Rones et al. (1997)
100#annual; Employed Men;
5.9% (2 hours), 233# Women, age 16+
increases
1967–1989 3.3% increase (66 hours), All employed, PSID, CPS Bluestone and
avg. annual hrs. per year; Rose (1998)
1982–1995 140 annual avg. hours, Prime-age (25–54)
600 annual avg. hours workers, working couples
1969–1989 Increase of 7% (86#) in annual Average worker, working family CPS Leete and Schor
hours, 16% increase (1994)
1969–1987 Increase of 163, 98 and 305 Average employed, Men, Women CPS Schor (1992)
#annual hours
1976–1988 Increase, 3.0 hours Married couples, wife works; PSID Roberts and Rupert
Decrease 0.4 hours wife does not (1995)
1960–1988 Decreases of 2.1% and Men: White, Black; Women: Census, CPS Coleman and
4.7 % (99#), and 2% White, Black, avg. Pencavel (1993)
and 3% (56#); weekly, annual hours
3.5%, 1.7% (27#), increases
of 7.2% and 10.7% (159#)

continental Western Europe declined, at least workers. Yet, US workweeks remain considerably
through the 1980s (Burgoon and Baxandal, 2004; longer than elsewhere, particularly in the non-Anglo
Hagen, 2005; Huberman and Minns, 2007). This countries. Americans average 25 working hours per
decline occurred at different rates and in diverse person of working age and 46 weeks per year in
forms in the various EU countries. Several social and contrast to the Germans average of less than 19 h
institutional factors account for the cross-country and French average of 40 weeks per year. The evi-
differences, including statutory, and collectively dence suggests that most of discrepancy between the
bargained restrictions on standard and overtime continents is explained by labor market regulations
hours (Bell and Freeman, 1995; Bosch, 1999; Rey- that limit hours or extend vacation time, promoted
nolds, 2004; Rubery et al., 2005; Stier and Lewin- by strong labor unions and adopted by governments
Epstein, 2003). For example, from 1960 to 1985, the to cope with declining industries, and has less to do
Netherlands, Belgium, and West Germany experi- with differential tax rates or innate cultural differ-
enced a reduction in annual hours. The trend toward ences (Altonji and Oldham, 2003; Alesina et al.,
shorter hours has slowed in the last two decades 2005; Ueberfeldt, 2006).
(Blyton, 1989; Messenger, 2004). Employers and
governments have pursued greater variability in
working time, such as annualization of hours, in part Explanations of long hours: structural,
to compensate employers for the reduction in the economic, social, and behavioral factors
standard. As in the U.S., there is an increasing
diversity of work patterns in Europe since the 1970s, What explains this growing proportion of the work
across sectors, industries, and even individual force working more or longer hours, at least in some
220 Lonnie Golden

countries and among certain types of workers? A more than a starting point, particularly when in
consistent set of contributing factors can be applied search of understanding longer-term trends and
across time and countries, but vary across disciplines cross-sectional variation in work hours over time
considering the question. The same underlying and among individuals (Huberman and Minns,
structural economic factors that economic historians 2007), or its well-being consequences (Layard,
have identified as the drivers in the preceding cen- 2006). Conventional labor supply studies have paid
tury may now be at work in the opposite direction. scant attention to the influence of social, cultural,
When hours rose, in historical periods, it was associated and workplace conditions over preference formation
with structural factors such as a higher capital-labor (Philp et al., 2005; Nyland, 1991). Moreover, it
ratio, larger enterprise size and greater pool of cannot explain sufficiently the level and timing of
immigrants and agricultural workers (Whaples, changes in the average hours per worker over the
2001). There was a supporting role for wage trends, twentieth century (Altman, 2001). The recent run
protective labor legislation, union power, and other up of hours in the US cannot be attributed to
characteristics of the work force at the time. There changes in the demographic composition of the
are counterforces that suppress any further escalation labor force, changes in the mix of occupations and
of work hours, such as the rise in real wage rates and industries or a simple reallocation of labor supply
decline in price of many key leisure goods that within workers’ life cycles (toward middle years).
enhanced the value of non-market time (Drago Opening the ‘‘black box’’ of preferences would
et al., 2005; Greenwood and Vandenbroucke, incorporate psychological, social and cultural sources
2005). However, these same factors may not be as of workers’ constraints and preference adaptation, to
relevant, post-1970. arrive at a deeper understanding of the roots of
trends in the time devoted toward work. Suppose a
model of the individual’s desired hours of labor
Work hours determination: Pure
supply is:
economics of labor supply and beyond
"  
Conventional economic analysis portrays the deter- ? w e
H ¼ a þ h1 þ h2 NY þ h3 Dwtþ1
mination of working time as the result of the p t
interaction between optimizing agents supplying and #
agents demanding labor services. Workers’ preferred þ h4 I þ h5 S þ h6 Htd
hours of labor supply are assumed to reflect a com-
bination of innate ‘‘preferences’’ reflecting their ðweights : h1 þ h2 þ    þ h6 ¼ 1Þ
unique, inherent taste or distaste for work or leisure,
and voluntary responses to external incentives, such where, H* desired hours of work (per week, year);
as their available wage rate and income from non- W current wage rate; P price level; We expected
labor sources. The net effect of wage rate increases future wage adjustment; NY non-wage and net asset
reveals whether workers wish to increase or decrease income; S relative status gained by individual among
their preferred hours of labor supply. The long-run reference groups; I internal rewards, intrinsic
trend in average worktime is believed to vary rewards; Hd hours demanded by employer; a het-
inversely with real wage rates, since the income erogeneous, individuals’ physiological capacity for
effect is presumed to dominate in the long run. work; 0  h1 ; h3  1; h2 ; h4 ; h5 ; a  0
Preferences are associated with a worker’s stage of Individuals are motivated to work by both
the life – inversely with the presence of non-wage extrinsic and intrinsic rewards (Ellingsen and
income and the female or youth composition of the Johannesson, 2007; Wolfe, 1997). Desired work
work force – and positively with education levels, hours reflect one’s perceived social roles other than
household production technological advances, or a as ‘‘employee’’ (Kelloway et al., 2004). For one
composition of consumption toward services. thing, these roles may place constraints at various
However, the conventional model’s focus on stages in their life-cycle (e.g., as a parent, caregiver,
rational individual or household choice provides no provider, student, and transitioning to retirement).
A Brief History of Long Work Time and the Contemporary Sources of Overwork 221

Even beyond that are the more subtle underlying positions, there is a positive relationship between the
characteristics of the workplace, organizational or number of work hours they prefer and the actual work
culture that exert influence on preference formation hours of their co-workers (Brett and Stroh, 2003;
regarding the value of work, material goods and Eastman, 1998; Feldman, 2002). There is also an
services and uses of time. To the extent such pref- incentive to put in extra hours of work to amass sav-
erences are adaptable, individuals’ desired work ings or serve a protective device against the risk of
hours will stem from the weighted contribution of future job loss, demotion or pay cut, particularly if the
its five sources: (1) current real wage rates; (2) for- extent of job or income insecurity is rising (Bluestone
ward-looking, potential reward of higher wage tra- and Rose, 1998).
jectories; (3) relative status conferred upon
individuals for hours of labor effort; (4) intrinsic
rewards, process benefits, or amenities acquired The intrinsic value of work: amenities,
through work; (5) hours demanded by the em- process benefits and satisfaction
ployee, reflecting structural constraints. The latter
term makes explicit that employers and their estab- The full value of work to the one who performs it
lished conditions of work have indeed influenced includes the intrinsic value of the work itself and its
the course of long run trends in labor supply and in net social outcomes. Clearly, generating income to
work time structures (Huberman and Minns, 2007). reach some desired material standard of living is the
Specifying five separate arguments is not meant to primary motivation for working. However, once
suggest there is no endogeneity. Nor is this model individuals reach a physiologically and socially
meant to be directly, empirically tractable. Rather, acceptable minimum standard of living, ‘‘needs’’
the purpose here is to present the potential con- tend to move up the Maslow’s pyramid toward the
tributing factors, each entering in with its own higher order. Individuals may be increasingly moti-
weight, derived from the emphases of separate re- vated by the inherent value of labor conferred
search literatures. through the individually transformative act of
working. The quaint notion of working more in
order to earn more time off from work has given
Work as forward-looking investments way to Americans taking ever shorter vacations and
in future wage growth trajectory even leaving ever more available vacation time on
and signaling tactics the table (Galinsky et al., 2005).
If work activity is becoming more intrinsically
Spending more time on the job may reflect an effort to rewarding, safer, discretionary and autonomous,
acquire more human capital, to enhance probability of rather than stress or anxiety-producing, hazardous,
future promotion or career progression (Michelacci onerous, routinized, and alienating, worker resistance
and Pijoan-Mas, 2007). When productivity cannot be to working long hours may fall. Certain jobs or work
monitored at little cost, employers may use long hours tasks provide ‘‘process benefits,’’ or outcomes that
as a mechanism to rank the productivity of workers. actually improve well being (Juster and Stafford,
Highly productive workers will choose to work 1985). Some high-paying managerial and professional
inefficiently long hours (Sousa-Poza and Ziegler, jobs are also rewarding in terms of the social interac-
2003), choosing to perform extra work, face-time, or tions and self-growth, so that their incumbents feel
presenteeism, beyond the standard or norm of a job or exalted more than exploited (Feldman, 2002; Hewlett
workplace, as a way to signal future promotability. and Luce, 2006). Perks of the workplace may be more
Many employers may create a few shorter-hour jobs, available to those workers willing to work additional
as a way to screen out potentially less productive hours (Douglas and Morris, 2006). When the work-
workers (Rebitzer and Taylor, 1995). Over time, place offers more amenities, work time becomes more
there may be more jobs that valorize long hours, alluring relative to time spent in the household, par-
where requesting shorter hours is feared to be a neg- ticularly for those who shoulder the relatively larger
ative signal (Landers et al., 1996; Yakura, 2001). burden of household responsibilities (Hochschild,
Among those who expect to be in managerial 2005). Largely because of greater job autonomy and
222 Lonnie Golden

satisfaction, the self-employed tend to work longer tising and promotional efforts eventually lead
hours than those employed by organizations (Hyyti- workers to develop a taste for an array of products or
nen and Ruuskanen, 2007). More autonomy in services that once was considered a luxury or ame-
scheduling tends to be offered to individuals in orga- nity into a necessity (George, 1997; Fraser and Pa-
nizations who are presumed to adhere to the ‘‘ideal ton, 2003). This process is solidified by bandwagon
worker’’ norm (Drago et al., 2005). The extension of effects, if individuals derive satisfaction from con-
hours has been facilitated by teleworking – comput- suming goods and services that others are consuming
erization and network-based telecommunications (Altman, 2001). Whereas income serves a positional
that allow work to be ever more portable and asyn- function, leisure time provides virtually no gain in
chronous, albeit also more intrusive into nonwork relative rank (Carlsson et al., 2007). Such consum-
time (Argandona, 2003; Hübler, 2000; Taskin and erism is a primary force behind a rising proportion of
Devos, 2005). workers engaged in very long hours of work in
Australia (Drago et al., 2005). Indeed, those who
work overtime even when it is not mandatory tend
Relative status and inequality: worker to be from the relatively higher income households
positioning at the workplace and (Golden and Wiens-Tuers, 2005). One potential
household in consumption counter force is if respect is accorded those who
work few hours yet produce much value per hour
The rising proportion of workers working long weekly (Haight, 1997), perhaps in lieu of pay (Ellingsen and
hours cannot be attributed to changes in real average Johannesson, 2007). However, the term S will be
hourly earnings. However, compensation practices that unambiguously positive if more respect is granted
have heightened variation in earnings within each just for being busy (Gershuny, 2005).
occupational classification have raised the incentive to
supply weekly hours beyond 40 per week (Kuhn and
Lozano, 2006). The wider gap among pay grades in The role of employers’ demand: hours
occupations lead more workers to attempt to exceed constraints and overemployment
the hours worked by their co-workers or the tacit norm
in the workplace (Bell and Freeman, 1995; Bowles and In the conventional labor market model, the
Park, 2005; Drago et al., 2005). Indeed, occupations demand side is considered a passive force, accom-
with longer workweeks have higher hourly earnings in modating workers’ preferences, at least in the long
the US (Hecker, 1998). Thus, if future wage trajecto- run. Alternative approaches presume employers can
ries in more jobs are getting steeper (or short hours all but dictate the length of the working day. They
penalty more severe), worker concern for long-term set limits on hours only because they confront
relative status lengthens average hours. humans’ physical and mental limitations (Nyland,
Individuals may try to compete for higher relative 1991). Consequently, working time currently may
social status by accumulating status-conferring goods be arranged less according to employee preferences,
and services (Schor, 1999). To the extent that and more as part of rigorous market competition
individuals seek a higher relative position in con- (Horrell and Rubery, 1991). Most workers face a
sumption, they may wish more paid market work confined range of hours options in jobs (Rebitzer
(Altman, 2001). In the context of growing income and Taylor, 1995). The standard employer demand
inequality, this requires that relatively less well-off for hours model assumes that continuous production
individuals work more hours in order to sustain their necessarily creates multiple shifts of fixed lengths
relative position in consumption levels, to emulate (Hart, 2004). In addition, there are ‘‘fixed costs’’ of
the consumption patterns of the already wealthy adding employees. This includes the costs of hiring
(Bowles and Park, 2005; Schor, 1992). In addition, and training new, particularly skilled, employees and
decisions to work more hours may be motivated by also costs of contributions to employee benefits that,
keeping pace with reference groups such as family or in the US, are affixed to the number of employees
siblings (Neumark and Postlewaite, 1998). More- rather than overall hours or payroll size. Thus, firms
over, the cumulative effects of intensifying adver- are incentivized to lengthen hours of existing
A Brief History of Long Work Time and the Contemporary Sources of Overwork 223

employees rather than hire new employees in up- The length of hours per worker in a given
turns, and offer more part-time jobs rather than country or sector is not only a consequence, but also
shorten hours of full-time employees during may be a cause of workaholism. Workaholism
downturns (Golden, 1990). occurs when there is an excessive, sustained alloca-
The employer demand side may impose con- tion of time devoted toward work-related activities
straints where work hours exceed individuals’ pre- that is not derived from necessity or other external
ferred number per week or per year. For example, if pressures (Snir et al., 2006). It is characterized by a
there were unwelcome but mandatory overtime, tendency to over-commit time at work, in excess of
inadequate vacation time or too few quality part- that expected either organizationally or financially or
time jobs. A worker employed beyond their desired at the expense of one’s own health or family and
number of work hours, willing but unable to sacri- social time (Buelens and Poelmans, 2004; Scott
fice pay for reduced hours, is overemployed. Most et al., 1997). Workaholism is at least slightly posi-
workers may quite rationally settle for a longer than tively associated with work hours (McMillan and
optimal workweek, because compensation losses O’Driscoll, 2006). Working long hours may often
associated with part-time status are far more than reflect an individual’s personality-based, positive
proportional to the hours reduction. Estimates of the relationship to work effort or striving for improved
overemployment rate range widely, between coun- equity (Porter, 2005; Peiperl and Jones, 2001).
tries and within the United States, from as little as Workaholism becomes problematic when long
6% to as much as 50% (Golden and Gebreselassie, hours go beyond an enthusiastic work ethic or sig-
2007; Lang and Kahn, 2001; Reynolds, 2004; Schor, naling of commitment, and becomes an addiction or
1999; Stier and Lewin-Epstein, 2003). compulsion, particularly as the life cycle progresses.
When work involvement is manifest through long
work hours, especially organizationally based, it may
Adaptive preferences for hours: yield detrimental types of workaholism (Burke,
overemployment, persistence 1999). About 30% in the US and Canada
and workaholism self-identify as workaholic (Kemeny, 2002). The
rate is 53% among those who report working 60 or
One likely response of overemployed workers is to more average hours per week. It is highest among
eventually adapt upward their number of preferred the upper income (Hamermesh and Slemrod,
hours of work. Overemployment inevitably creates a 2005).
feeling of time scarcity in the household. This in
turn may lead a household to alter its preferences
from self-produced goods and services to those that Summary and implications for research
are market-produced. The household may also then and policy
shift from time-using goods and services to the more
time-saving type. In addition, households are likely Long work hours have a long history. The most salient
to shift preferences from time-intensive to income- recent trend is the growing proportion of the work
intensive leisure activities. All three such shifts may force that works very long hours. Overwork, hours per
ratchet upward individuals’ targeted income levels. day, week, or year worked beyond one’s physical and
This is likely to gradually dissipate the initial desire mental capacity, is embedded in underlying economic,
for shorter work hours (Rothschild, 1982). Likely institutional, cultural, and behavioral factors that make
for this reason, the overemployment rate in the US long work hours an ostensibly rational choice for many
was no higher in 2001 than it was in 1985 despite individuals or households. An individual’s preference
higher real wage rates and a longer average work- for longer work hours reflects not only changes in their
week (Altman and Golden, 2004; Golden and Ge- own real wage, non-wage income or life-cycle con-
breselassie, 2007). Persistence occurs in the sense that straints, but their surrounding social reference groups,
workers who usually work 50 or more hours per organizational incentives, and legal institutions. Even
week more continue working such long hours when self-imposed, long work hours create may spill-
indefinitely into the future (Drago et al., 2005). over social costs (Hamermesh and Slemrod, 2005). A
224 Lonnie Golden

gradual, dynamic process involving social interactions Alesina, A., E. Glaeser and B. Sacerdote: 2005, ‘Work
can make long work hours habituated and persistent and Leisure in the U.S. and Europe: Why So Differ-
over time, particularly if spillovers of overwork are ent?’, NBER Macroeconomic Annual 2005 20, 1–64.
discounted. An enlightening direction for future re- Altman, M.: 1999, ‘New Estimates of Hours of Work and
search would be to explore more deeply the dynamic Real Income in Canada from the 1880s to 1930:
Long-Run Trends and Workers’ Preferences’, Review
processes by which workers’ drive to work long or
of Income and Wealth 45(3), 353–372.
excessive hours is motivated more by personal disen- Altman, M.: 2001, ‘Preferences and Labor Supply: Cast-
gagement or organizational values and incentives, and ing Some Light into the Black Box of Income-Leisure
the extent to which the former is adapted to the latter Choice’, Journal of Socio-Economics 30, 199–219.
(Burke, 1999). Altman, M. and L. Golden: 2004, ‘Alternative Approaches
Overwork may be addressed by policy levers of Regulating Hours’, in M. Oppenheimer and
that would counteract the historical, economic, N. Mercuro (eds.), Alternative Approaches in Law and
social, and institutional forces behind it. At the Economics (pp. 286–307).
individual level, there are potential medical solu- Altonji, J. and J. Oldham: 2003, ‘Vacation Laws and
tions (Kawase et al., 2006). Legal limits on Annual Work Hours’, Economic Perspectives: Federal
working hours are usually in response to risks of Reserve Bank of Chicago Fall, 19–29.
fatigue or errors to workers’ and/or public health Alvarez-Cuadrado, F.: 2007, ‘Envy, Leisure, and Restric-
tions on Working Hours’, Canadian Journal of Economics/
and safety due, to compel rest and time off duty,
Revue canadienne d’Economique 40(4), 1286–1310.
even when there are forward-looking and human Argandona, A.: 2003, ‘The New Economy: Ethical
capital formulation reasons to justify working long Issues’, Journal of Business Ethics 44(1), 3–22.
hours, such as for medical interns and residents Atack, J., F. Bateman and R. Margo: 2003, ‘Productivity
(Wiesing, 2007). Policies ranging from innovations in Manufacturing and the Length of the Working Day:
in the regulation of overtime work, curbs on Evidence from the 1880 Census of Manufacturers’,
consumer debt and advertising, and a more pro- Explorations in Economic History 40(2), 170–194.
gressive income tax may counter the role played Bell, L. and R. B. Freeman: 1995, ‘Why do Americans
by positioning, envy and consumerism feeding the and Germans Work Different Hours?’, in F. Butler,
habituation of longer work hours (Frank, 1999; W. Franz, R. Shettkat and D. Soskice (eds.), Institu-
Hamermesh and Slemrod, 2005). Restrictions on tional Frameworks and Labor Market Performance: Com-
working hours provide a last resort tool to induce parative Views on the US and German Economies.
Bernanke, B. and J. Powell: 1986, ‘The Cyclical Behavior
a more efficient allocation of work hours (Alvarez-
of Industrial Labor Markets: A Comparison of the Pre
Cuadrado, 2007). Since temporal patterns of work War and Post War Eras’, in R. J. Gordon (ed.), The
and legal standards are collectively constructed, American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change (Uni-
working time structures providing a better balance versity of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL), pp. 583–737.
and diversity of options can be reconstructed Bernstein, J. and K. Kornbluh: 2005, Running Faster to
(Rakoff, 2002). A large step forward would be Stay in Place: The Growth of Family Work Hours and
adoption of the recently proposed legislation, Incomes (New America Foundation, Work and Family
Working Family Flexibility Act (H.R. 4301). This Program, Washington DC).
will provide employees the right to request mod- Bienefeld, M.: 1972, Working Hours in British Industry: An
ifications in their hours, schedule, or work loca- Economic History (Weidenfeld and Nicolson, London).
tion, in an interactive process that balances Bluestone, B. and S. Rose: 1998, ‘Macroeconomics of
employee needs against potential disruption to the Work Time’, Review of Social Economy 56, 425–441.
Blyton, P.: 1989, ‘Work Time Reductions and the
employer’s business.
European Work-Sharing Debate’, in A. Gladstone
(ed.), Current Issues in Labour Relations: An International
Perspective (Walter de Gruyter, New York).
References Bosch, G.: 1999, ‘Working Time: Tendencies and
Emerging Issues’, International Labour Review 138(2),
Aguiar, M. and E. Hurst: 2007, ‘Measuring Trends in 131–149.
Leisure: The Allocation of Time over Five Decades’, Bourdieu, J. and B. Reynaud: 2001, Externalities and
Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(3), 969–1006. Institutions: The Decrease in Working Hours in Nineteenth
A Brief History of Long Work Time and the Contemporary Sources of Overwork 225

Century France (Laboratoire d’Economie Appliquee, Frank, R. H.: 1999, Luxury Fever (The Free Press, New
Research Unit Working Paper 00-01, Paris France). York).
Bowles, S. and Y. Park: 2005, ‘Emulation, Inequality, and Fraser, S. and D. Paton: 2003, ‘Does Advertising Increase
Work Hours: Was Thorsten Veblen Right?’, The Labour Supply? Time Series Evidence from the UK’,
Economic Journal 115(507), F397–F412. Applied Economics 35(11), 1357–1368.
Brett, J. and L. Stroh: 2003, ‘Working 61 Plus Hours a Galinsky, E., J. Bond, S. Kim, L. Backon, E. Brownfield
Week: Why do Managers do It?’, Journal of Applied and K. Sakai: 2005, Overwork in America: When the Way
Psychology 89(1), 67–78. we Work Becomes too much (Families and Work Institute,
Brody, D.: 1989, ‘Time and Work During Early Amer- New York).
ican Industrialism’, Labor History 30, 5–46. George, D.: 1997, ‘Working Longer Hours: Pressure
Buelens, M. and S. Poelmans: 2004, ‘Enriching the Spence from the Boss or from Marketers?’, Review of Social
and Robbins’ Typology of Workaholism: Demographic, Economy 55(1), 33–65.
Motivational and Organizational Correlates’, Journal of Gershuny, J.: 2005, ‘Busyness as the Badge of Honor for
Organizational Change Management 17(5), 440–458. the New Superordinate Working Class’, Social Research
Burgoon, B. and P. Baxandal: 2004, ‘Three Worlds of 72(2), 287–314.
Working Time: The Partisan and Welfare Politics of Golden, L.: 1990, ‘The Insensitive Workweek: Trends
Work Hours in Industrialized Countries’, Politics & and Determinants of Average Hours in U.S. Manu-
Society 32(4), 439–473. facturing, 1929–1987’, Journal of Post Keynesian Eco-
Burke, R.: 1999, ‘It’s not How Hard you Work but How nomics 13(1), 79–110.
you Work Hard: Evaluating Workaholism’, Interna- Golden, L. and T. Gebreselassie: 2007, ‘Which Workers
tional Journal of Stress Management 6(4), 225–239. Prefer to Exchange Income for a Change in Work
Carlsson, F., O. Johansson-Stenman and P. Martinsson: Hours in the US?’, Monthly Labor Review 130(4), 18–
2007, ‘Do you Enjoy Having more than Others? 37.
Survey Evidence of Positional Goods’, Economica Golden, L. and B. Wiens-Tuers: 2005, ‘Mandatory
74(296), 586–598. Overtime Work: Who, What and Where?’, Labor
Coleman, M. and J. Pencavel: 1993, ‘Changes in Work Studies Journal 30(1), 1–23.
Hours of Male Employees, 1940 1988’, Industrial and Greenwood, J. and G. Vandenbroucke: 2005, ‘Hours
Labor Relations Review 46(2), 262–283. Worked: Long-Run Trends’, in L. Blume and S.
Costa, D. L.: 1998, ‘The Unequal Work Day: A Long- Durlauf (eds.), New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd
Term View’, American Economic Review 88(2), 330–334. Edition (Palgrave Macmillan, London).
Cross, G.: 1988, ‘Worktime in International Disconti- Hagen, K.: 2005, Working Time and International Compet-
nuity, 1886–1940’, in G. Cross (ed.), Worktime and itiveness. Friedberg Ebert Siftung Briefing Paper,
Industrialization: An International History (University of Geneva, April.
Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia). Haight, A. D.: 1997, ‘Padded Prowess: A Veblenian
Douglas, E. and R. Morris: 2006, ‘Workaholic, or Just Interpretation of the Long Hours of Salaried Workers’,
Hard Worker?’, Career Development International 11(5), Journal of Economic Issues 31, 29–38.
394–417. Hamermesh, D. and J. Slemrod: 2005, The Economics of
Drago, R.: 2000, ‘Trends in Working Time in the US: A Workaholism: Why we Should not have Written this Paper.
Policy Perspective’, Labor Law Journal 51(4), 212–218. National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Drago, R., D. Black and M. Wooden: 2005, The Existence Paper 11566.
and Persistence of Long Hours. IZA Discussion Paper No. Hart, R.: 2004, The Economics of Overtime Working
1720, Bonn Germany, August. (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK).
Eastman, W.: 1998, ‘Working for Position: Women, Hecker, D.: 1998, ‘How Hours of Work Affect
Men, and Managerial Work Hours’, Industrial Relations Occupational Earnings’, Monthly Labor Review 121,
37, 51–66. 8–18.
Ellingsen, T. and M. Johannesson: 2007, ‘Paying Respect’, Hetrick, R.: 2000, ‘Analyzing the Upward Surge in
Journal of Economic Perspectives 21(4), 135–149. Overtime Hours’, Monthly Labor Review 123, 30–33.
Epstein, C. F. and A. Kalleberg: 2004, Fighting for Time: Hewlett S. A. and C. B. Luce: 2006, ‘Extreme Jobs: The
Shifting Boundaries of Work and Social Life (Russell Sage Dangerous Allure of the 70-Hour Workweek’, Har-
Foundation, New York). vard Business Review 84, 49–59.
Feldman, D.: 2002, ‘Managers’ Propensity to Work Hochschild, A.: 2005, ‘On the Edge of the Time Bind:
Longer Hours: A Multilevel Analysis’, Human Resource Time and Market Culture’, Social Research 72(2), 339–
Management Review 12, 339–357. 354.
226 Lonnie Golden

Hopkins, E.: 1982, ‘Working Hours and Conditions Leete, L. and J. Schor: 1994, ‘Assessing the Time Squeeze
During the Industrial Revolution: A Re-Appraisal’, Hypothesis Hours Worked in the United States: 1969–
Economic History Review 35, 52–66. 89’, Industrial Relations 33(1), 25–43.
Horrell, S. and J. Rubery: 1991, ‘Gender and Working Martorana, P. and P. Hirsch: 2001, ‘The Social Con-
Time’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 15, 373–391. struction of ‘‘Overtime’’’, Transformation of Work 10,
Huberman, M. and C. Minns: 2007, ‘The Times they are 165–187.
not Changin’: Days and Hours of Work in Old and McGratten, E. and R. Rogerson: 2004, ‘Changes in
New Worlds, 1870–2000’, Explorations in Economic Hours Worked, 1950–2000’, Federal Bank of Minne-
History 44(4), 538–567. apolis Quarterly Review 28, 14–33.
Hübler, O.: 2000, ‘All Goes Faster but Lasts Longer: McMillan, L. H. and M. P. O’Driscoll: 2006,
Computer Use and Overtime Work’, Ifo Studien 46(2), ‘Understanding Workaholism: The Case for Behav-
49–271. ioral Tendencies’, in R. Burke (ed.), Research Com-
Hunnicutt, B.: 1988, Work Without End: Abandoning panion to Working Time and Work Addiction (Edward
Shorter Hours for the Right to Work (Temple University Elgar).
Press, Philadelphia). Messenger, J.: 2004, Working Time and Workers’ Preferences
Hyytinen, A. and O.-P. Ruuskanen: 2007, ‘Time Use of in Industrialized Countries: Finding the Balance (ILO
the Self-Employed’, Kyklos 60(1), 105–123. Conditions of Work and Employment Programme,
Jacobs, J. and K. Gerson: 2004, The Time Divide: Work, Geneva).
Family, and Gender Inequality. Family and Public Policy Michelacci, C. and J. Pijoan-Mas: 2007, The Effects of
Series (Harvard University Press, Cambridge and Labor Market Conditions on Working Time: The US-EU
London). Experience. CEMFI Working Paper 0705, June.
Juster, T. and F. Stafford: 1985, ‘Process Benefits and Neumark, D. and A. Postlewaite: 1998, ‘Relative In-
The Problem of Joint Production’, in T. Juster and come Concerns and the Rise in Married Women’s
F. Stafford (eds.), Time, Goods and Well-Being (ISR, Employment’, Journal of Public Economics 70,
Ann Arbor, Michigan). 157–183.
Kawase, Y., S. Horiea, N. Sasakia, C. Naganoa, T. Nyland, C.: 1991, Reduced Working Time and the Man-
Tsutsuia and T. Hoshuyamaa: 2006, ‘Solutions to agement of Production (Cambridge University Press,
Long Overtime Work Advised by Occupational Cambridge UK).
Physician’, International Congress Series 294, 105–108. Peiperl, M. and B. Jones: 2001, ‘Workaholics and
Kelloway, K., D. Gallagher and J. Barling: 2004, ‘Work, Overworkers: Productivity or Pathology?’, Group &
Employment and the Individual’, in B. Kaufman (ed.), Organization Management 26(3), 369–394.
Theoretical Perspectives on Work and the Employment Philp, B., G. Slater and D. Harvie: 2005, ‘Preferences,
Relationship (Industrial Relations Research Association Power, and the Determination of Working Hours’,
Series, Urbana, IL). Journal of Economic Issues 39(1), 75–91.
Kemeny, A.: 2002, ‘Driven to Excel: A Portrait of Porter, G.: 2005, Workaholism Sloan Work and Family
Canada’s Workaholics, Canadian Social Trends’, Encyclopedia Entry, Sloan Work and Family Research
Spring Statistics Canada, Catalogue No. 11-008. Network. Retrieved from http://wfnetwork.bc.edu/
Kuhn, P. and F. Lozano: 2006, The Expanding Workweek? encyclopedia_entry.php?id=1191.
Understanding Trends in Long Work Hours among U.S. Rakoff, T.: 2002, A Time for Every Purpose Law and the
Men, 1979–2004. IZA Discussion Paper No. 1924, Balance of Life (Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Berlin. MA).
Landers, R., J. Rebitzer and L. Taylor: 1996, ‘Rat Race Ramey, V. A. and N. Francis: 2006, A Century of Work
Redux: Adverse Selection in the Determination of and Leisure. NBER Working Papers 12264, National
Work Hours in Law Firms’, American Economic Review Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
86, 3229–3248. Rebitzer, J. and L. Taylor: 1995, ‘Do Labor Markets
Lang, K. and S. Kahn: 2001, ‘Hours Constraints: Theory Provide Enough Short-Hour Jobs? An Analysis of
Evidence and Policy Implications’, in G. Wong and Work Hours and Work Incentives’, Economic Inquiry
G. Picot (eds.), Working Time in a Comparative Per- 33, 257–273.
spective, Vol. 1 (Upjohn Institute for Employment Reynolds, J.: 2004, ‘When too much is not Enough
Research Institute, Kalamazoo MI). Actual and Preferred Work Hours in the United States
Layard, R.: 2006, ‘Happiness and Public Policy: A and Abroad’, Sociological Forum 19(1), 89–120.
Challenge to the Profession’, The Economic Journal Roche, W. K.: 1987, ‘Leisure, Insecurity and Union
116(510), C24–C33. Policy in Britain: A Critical Extension of Bienefeld’s
A Brief History of Long Work Time and the Contemporary Sources of Overwork 227

Theory of Hours Rounds’, British Journal of Industrial Inefficient Long Working Hours’, Labour Economics
Relations 25(1), 1–17. 10(6) December, 727–747.
Roediger, D. and P. Foner: 1989, Our Own Time: A Stier, H. and N. Lewin-Epstein: 2003, ‘Time to Work: A
History of American Labor and the Working Day (Verso, Comparative Analysis of Preferences for Working
London). Hours’, Work and Occupations 30(3), 302.
Rones, P., R. Ilg and J. Gardner: 1997, ‘Trends in Hours Taskin, L. and V. Devos: 2005, ‘Paradoxes from the Indi-
of Work Since the Mid 1970s’, Monthly Labor Review vidualization of Human Resource Management: The
120(4), 3–14. Case of Telework’, Journal of Business Ethics 62(1), 13–24.
Rothschild, K.: 1982, ‘A Note on Some of Economic and Thompson, E.: 1967, ‘Time, Work-Discipline and
Welfare Aspects of Working Time Regulations’, Industrial Capitalism’, Past and Present 38, 56–97.
Australian Economic Papers 21, 214–218. Ueberfeldt, A.: 2006, Working Time over the 20th Century.
Rubery, J., K. Ward, D. Grimshaw and H. Beynon: Bank of Canada Working Paper 2006-18, May.
2005, ‘Working Time, Industrial Relations and the Whaples, R.: 2001, Hours of Work in U.S. History.
Employment Relationship’, Time & Society 14, 89– EH.Net Encyclopedia, August 15.
111. Wiesing, U.: 2007, ‘Ethical Asepcts of Limiting Residents’
Rupert, P. and K. Roberts: 1995, ‘The Myth of the Work Hours’, Journal of Busines Ethics 21(7), 398–405.
Overworked American’, Economic Commentary (Federal Wolfe, A.: 1997, ‘The Moral Meaning of Work’, Journal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland) (January 15), 1–4. of Socio-Economics 26(6), 559–570.
Schor, J. B.: 1992, The Overworked American (Basic Books, Yakura, E.: 2001, ‘Billables: The Valorization of Time in
New York). Consulting’, American Behavioral Scientist 44(7), 1076–
Schor, J.: 1999, The Overspent American: Upscaling Down- 1096.
shifting and the New Consumer (Basic Books, New
York). Economics and Labor Studies, Abington College,
Scott, K., S. Moore and M. Miceli: 1997, ‘An Explora- Penn State University,
tion of the Meaning and Consequences of Worka- 0119 Sutherland Building, 1600 Woodland Rd.,
holism’, Human Relations 50, 287–314. Abington, PA 19001, U.S.A.
Snir, R., I. Harpaz and R. Burke: 2006, ‘Workaholism in E-mail: lmg5@psu.edu
Organizations New Research Directions’, Career
Development International 11(5), 369–373.
Sousa-Poza, A. and A. Ziegler: 2003, ‘Asymmetric In-
formation About Workers’ Productivity as a Cause for

You might also like