You are on page 1of 11

Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/eneco

Energy–growth conundrum in energy exporting and importing


countries: Evidence from heterogeneous panel methods robust to
cross-sectional dependence
Abdul Jalil ⁎
School of Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University Islamabad, 45320, Pakistan

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This article uses the panel methods for energy exporting and importing countries that discuss the heterogeneity
Received 18 November 2013 and cross sectional dependence in investigating the linkages between energy consumption and economic
Received in revised form 20 April 2014 growth. The findings of the study suggest that the energy consumption is an important input not only in the en-
Accepted 22 April 2014
ergy importing but also in energy exporting countries. Furthermore, the results of the present paper suggest that
Available online 5 May 2014
the policy options should be different for the different countries in the back drop of heterogeneous slope
JEL classification:
coefficients.
C23 © 2014 Published by Elsevier B.V.
O44
Q43

Keywords:
Energy
Economic growth
Heterogeneity
Cross sectional dependence

1. Introduction growth. The energy endowment and high subsidization on energy in-
puts lead to low energy prices and therefore make energy as a cheap fac-
The literature on energy economics provides a lively debate on the tor of production in energy exporting countries (Damette and Seghir,
linkages between energy consumption and economic growth over the 2013). This further leads to distribution state benefits of energy endow-
last three decades which shows that the energy is a more important fac- ments for the welfare of population and eventually contributes to eco-
tor of production than it is considered by the researchers (Ayres et al., nomic growth of energy exporting country. Keeping recent increase in
2013). The proponents of energy led growth theory argue that all pro- demand for energy and energy-intensive industries in view, it can be
duction activities involve energy as an indispensable input; therefore, safely claimed that energy exporting countries are the energy-
it is a key factor in economic growth. On the other hand, conventional intensive countries as well (Damette and Seghir, 2013).
growth theories consider capital stock, labor and residuals as the Additionally, huge exports of energy resources and domestic utiliza-
major contributing factors in economic growth of an economy and dis- tion of energy would lead to the rapid depletion of energy resources
pel the belief that energy consumption plays any important role in eco- which may hit the level of economic growth of these countries in near
nomic growth. Both schools have their arguments and draw on different future. Furthermore, Chen and Galbraith (2011) note that when energy
data, models and methodologies to support their stance. resources deplete and technological cost increases, more financial re-
A major chunk of literature considers that energy consumption de- sources are consumed which crowds out other economic activities.
termines the level of economic growth.1 However, it is taken for granted Therefore, discussing the energy exporting countries along with energy
that energy is an important input in only energy importing countries. importing countries is the need of the hour.
These studies do not consider the importance of energy consumption Despite the above mentioned facts, the researchers have not yet se-
in energy exporting countries for determining the level of economic riously explored the panel studies of energy exporting countries. There
are few studies, for example Al-Iriani (2006), Mehrara (2007) and
Damette and Seghir (2013) that analyze the panel of oil exporting coun-
⁎ Tel.: +92 51 90643044.
E-mail addresses: jalil.hanif@gmail.com, abdul.jalil@qau.edu.pk.
tries. The studies are based on single homogenous slope assumption
1
The reverse causality, bidirectional causality and neutrality hypothesis is also reported and produce mixed results. Moreover, Al-Iriani (2006) and Mehrara
in the literature (see Jalil and Feridun, 2014; Ozturk, 2010). (2007) note that causality runs from economic growth to energy

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2014.04.015
0140-9883/© 2014 Published by Elsevier B.V.
A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324 315

consumption. Damette and Seghir (2013), using heterogeneous panel group estimators and pooled mean group estimators are more appro-
data, document that the pace of economic growth sets the consumption priate in our case. Finally, the issue of structural breaks is taken into ac-
of energy in short run and vice versa in long run. Importantly, none of count in estimating the unit root and cointegration testing procedures.
these studies take structural breaks into account despite using the lon- Importantly, according to the best of our knowledge, none of the studies
ger time series panel data. Furthermore, we may expect that the results on the energy–growth nexus tests the slope homogeneity condition in
are sensitive to the selection of econometric technique. Therefore, tak- panel data and provides the heterogeneous slope parameters for the
ing heterogeneity of slope and structural breaks into account may short run.2
alter the findings of Al-Iriani (2006), Mehrara (2007) and Damette Although, there are numerous investigations regarding the energy–
and Seghir (2013). growth nexus but there is controversy among the researchers. It may
The linkages between energy consumption and economic growth be due to the subject/country selections, data time spans, empirical
are explored in several studies, for example Lee (2005), Al-Iriani econometric model settings or other explanatory variable selections.
(2006), Mehrara (2007), Lee and Chang (2008), Mahadevan and Therefore, it can be further investigated by taking the heterogeneity,
Asafu-Adjaye (2007), Lee and Chang (2008), Huang et al. (2008), structural breaks and cross sectional dependence into account. The em-
Narayan and Smyth (2008), Lee and Chang (2008), Apergis and pirical results will show how energy–growth relationship is affected by
PayneJ (2009) and Ozturk et al. (2010) by using panel data and present these factors. This study finds that most of the data series are stationary
inconclusive empirical findings. But almost all of them assume homog- at first difference with and without structural breaks. The null hypothesis
enous slope parameters in the panel. This implies that the single slope of slope homogeneity is clearly rejected; therefore, we prefer the hetero-
parameter will be generalized for the whole sample space of the geneous panel methods for the estimation of our specified models. We
study. The implications of single slope parameter may be more severe find that energy consumption, capital stock, investment flows, level of
in the presence of inconclusive findings on the energy–growth nexus. employment and trade openness have a positive impact on the economic
In addition, since the policies in oil importing and oil exporting coun- growth of both energy net exporter and importer countries.
tries are different in relation to the nature of the macroeconomic deter- The conventional style is followed for the organization of the article,
minant of the economic growth, therefore, the homogeneity condition that is, Section 2 will present the brief literature review, Section 3 will
may lead to misleading results for the countries. Furthermore, the pat- discuss estimation strategy, data and variable construction will be pre-
terns of economic growth and energy consumption are not homoge- sented in Section 4, Section 5 will discuss the empirical results and
neous in different regions of the world; hence, the assumption of Section 6 will conclude the article.
slope homogeneity is not very attractive in this case. Keeping this draw-
back in view, the theoretical studies of Pesaran and Smith (1995) and 2. Literature review
Pesaran et al. (1999) provide an opportunity for estimating the hetero-
geneous slopes of regression. Thus, the energy–growth nexus should be The empirical investigation on energy–growth nexus can be traced
revisited in the context of heterogonous panel data. back to Kraft and Kraft (1978). Since then a plethora of research pro-
Furthermore, Lee (2005), Al-Iriani (2006), Mehrara (2007), Lee and vides inconclusive results based on the different samples of countries,
Chang (2008), Mahadevan and Asafu-Adjaye (2007), Lee and Chang data, estimation techniques and variables. Lee (2006), Zachariadis
(2008), Huang et al. (2008), Narayan and Smyth (2008), Lee and (2007) and Ozturk (2010) provide the excellent reviews on the subject.
Chang (2008), Apergis and Payne (2009) and Ozturk et al. (2010) Importantly, Ozturk (2010) reviews the four possible hypotheses in the
don't consider cross section dependence. The possibility of cross sec- context of energy–growth nexus, that is, growth hypothesis, conservation
tional dependence cannot be denied in the present macroeconomic, fi- hypothesis, feedback hypothesis and neutrality hypothesis.
nancial and trade integration. Specifically, this is a more relevant The major chunk of the literature advocates the growth hypothesis
argument in the backdrop of common global shocks like oil crises and which implies that the energy consumption determines the level of eco-
financial crises, shared institutions like International Monetary Fund nomic growth of an economy. For example Yu and Choi (1985), Masih
and World Trade Organization, and the spillover effects among the re- and Masih (1996), Asafu-Adjaye (2000), Yang (2000), Lee and Chang
gions and countries (Liddle and Lung, 2014). Therefore, Kapetanios (2005), Soytas and Sari (2003), Altinay and Karagol (2005), Shiu and
et al. (2011) note that the validity of conventional econometric tools, Lam (2004), Morimoto and Hope (2004), Oh and Lee (2004), Narayan
like first generation panel unit root tests, the cointegration tests and and Smyth (2008), Squalli (2007), Ho and Siu (2007), and Belloumi
the estimators which estimate the cointegration vector, which are (2009) document that energy is the vital input in the production of a
based on the assumption of cross section independence, become ques- country. Therefore, the limitations of energy consumptions may hurt
tionable. In addition to this, the existence of structural breaks may the process of economic growth.
lead to misleading inferences regarding the order of integration, that The conservation hypothesis implies that the economic growth
is, a stationary series may be taken as non-stationary and can bias the drives energy consumption not the other way round. Even Kraft and
examination of cointegration (Narayan and Smyth, 2008). Kraft (1978), the pioneer study on the subject, document that the in-
In this backdrop, this study separates itself from the existing litera- crease in income is a cause of increased energy consumption. Then
ture in many respects. First, we shall test the energy–growth nexus for Cheng (1998), Cheng (1999), Chang and Wong (2001), Soytas and
energy exporting countries as well as the energy importing countries. Sari (2003), Narayan and Smyth (2005), Zamani (2007), Ang (2008)
Several studies like Damette and Seghir (2013) and Mehrara (2007) and Zhang and Cheng (2009) find unidirectional causality from eco-
consider the oil exporting countries as energy exporting countries, how- nomic growth to energy.
ever, Ayres et al. (2013) note that coal and natural gas along with oil The Erol and Yu (1988), Hwang and Gum (1991), Hondroyiannis
have become an important input in the last two decades, therefore, et al. (2002), Glasure (2002), Soytas and Sari (2003), Jumbe (2004),
we shall take the net energy exporting and the net energy importing Masih and Masih (1996), Paul and Bhattacharya (2004), Ghali and El-
countries into consideration. Secondly, the article tests the cross sec- Sakka (2004), Zachariadis and Pashouortidou (2007), and Erdal et al.
tional dependence and concludes that the first generation panel unit (2008) document that the energy consumption and economic growth
root tests and cointegration tests invalidate the findings of previous jointly determine each other. Ozturk (2010) termed this line of research
studies, therefore, we shall consider second generation panel unit root as feedback hypothesis.
tests and Westerlund (2007) tests of cointegration. Thirdly, we test
slope homogeneity condition through Swamy (1970) test and conclude 2
Recently, Damette and Seghir (2013) and Liddle and Lung (2014) use the heteroge-
that the slope homogeneity condition is violated in a panel of long time neous panel data but these studies don't speak on the heterogeneous coefficients in the
series (T), therefore heterogeneous panel data estimators like mean short run.
316 A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324

Then Akarca and Long (1980), Yu and Hwang (1984), Yu and Choi (2013) appear unconvincing as they do not take into account capital
(1985), Yu and Jin (1992), Stern (1993), Cheng (1995) Fatai et al. stock, labor and other controlling factors in the production function.
(2002), Altinay and Karagol (2004), Jobert and Karanfil (2007), Payne Therefore, we follow the multivariate setting of Ghali and El-Sakka
(2009), Soytas and Sari (2009) and Halicioglu (2009) think that ener- (2004), Soytas and Sari (2007), Yuan et al. (2008) and Jalil and
gy–growth nexus is an over stressed term. According to them there is Feridun (2014) who think that energy is a chief candidate in determin-
no link between energy and economic growth. Neither energy deter- ing the level of economic growth. The specified function is as follows:
mines economic growth nor growth is a source of increased consump-  
tion of energy. Ozturk (2010) termed it neutrality hypothesis. Y i;t ¼ f K i;t ; Li;t ; Ei;t ð1Þ
Specifically, Paul and Salahuddin (2010) document that the neutrality
hypothesis mainly prevails in developed countries.
where Y is real GDP, K is the capita stock, L is level of employment, E is
Most of the above mentioned studies are based on the single country
total energy consumption, i is for cross sectional group and t is for time.
cases. Therefore, the researchers utilize time series data for estimating
However, Jayadevappa and Chhatre (2000) point out that trade
causality and dynamic relationships between energy consumption and
openness, energy and economic growth are interlinked. Furthermore,
economic growth. The time series analysis, despite having some advan-
Cole et al. (1998), Ades and Glaeser (1999), Choudhri and Hakura
tages, may be sensitive to span of time period, number of variables on
(2000) and Beck (2002) also reinforce that trade openness should
independent side and estimation techniques. Therefore, the analyses
enter positively in the growth regression. Therefore, we also allow
based on panel data are more reliable (Huang et al., 2008) which com-
trade in the above function for converting it from closed economy to
pensate for the deficiency of small sample size. The studies of Lee
open economy's production function. The augmented production func-
(2005), Al-Iriani (2006), Mehrara (2007), Lee and Chang (2008),
tion is:
Mahadevan and Asafu-Adjaye (2007), Lee and Chang (2008), Huang
et al. (2008), Narayan and Smyth (2008), Lee and Chang (2008),  
Apergis and Payne (2009) and Ozturk et al. (2010) can be referred to Y i;t ¼ f K i;t ; Li;t ; Ei;t ; TRi;t ð2Þ
see energy–growth nexus in panel data context. However, it is impor-
tant to mention here that the empirical evidence on the energy–growth where TR is total trade to GDP ratio.
nexus is mixed and researchers provide contradictory findings with re- We can write the growth equation by using this augmented produc-
spect to the direction of causation. One possible justification is that the tion function which is as follows:
empirical results are sensitive to the methodological weakness. More
clearly, country-specific heterogeneity in climate conditions, economic yi;t ¼ α 0 þ β1 ln ki;t þ β2 ln li;t þ β3 lnei;t þ β4 ln tr i;t þ εit ð3Þ
development and energy consumption patterns may alter the results.
The above mentioned studies are based on the assumption that all coun- where y, k, l, e and tr indicate the natural logarithms of Y, K, L E and TR. β,s
tries are homogenous when it comes to the patterns of economic refers to the long-run elasticities and ε is Gaussian errors.
growth and energy consumption. We have to consider several econometric problems in estimating
This assumption postulates that a single slope parameter will be Eq. (3). For example, the traditional panel data methods consider all
generalized for the whole sample of the countries in the study. Since countries as a single entity and therefore provide a single homogenous
the countries regarding consumption of energy and nature of macroeco- slope parameter for all countries. Furthermore, these methods are based
nomic determinant are different from on another, therefore, homogene- on the assumption of cross sectional dependence. More importantly,
ity condition may lead to misleading results for all countries. Keeping these methods don't take into account the structural break in the data
this drawback in mind, Damette and Seghir (2013) attempt to differen- series. Consequently, this paper uses panel methods that consider the
tiate the long run and short run coefficients in a panel data setting, how- slope heterogeneity and cross sectional dependence with and without
ever, calculate the long run coefficients with slope homogeneity structural breaks. The following steps are taken to accomplish this
assumption and don't allow the slope heterogeneity for the short run task. First, we shall set Eq. (3) in an autoregressive distributed lag
analysis. Furthermore, the issue of cross sectional dependence is not (ARDL) framework as suggested by Pesaran et al. (1999). Second, we
well discussed in the existing literature on energy consumption and shall test the slope heterogeneity. Third, we shall test the unit root prob-
economic growth conundrum. In addition to this, the existence of struc- lems and cointegration with and without structural breaks. Finally, the
tural breaks may lead to misleading inferences regarding the order of in- pooled mean group (PMG), mean group (MG) and common correlated
tegration, that is, a stationary series may be taken as non-stationary and effect mean group (CCEMG) estimators are used to estimate the long
can bias the examination of cointegration (Narayan and Smyth, 2008). run and short coefficients along with the error correction terms.
The issue of structural break is not taken into account in the study of Huang et al. (2008) use dynamic panel estimator for the estimation
Damette and Seghir (2013). Therefore, the finding of Damette and of Eq. (3). However, Huang et al. (2008) themselves recognize that
Seghir (2013), that energy is determined by the pace of economic panel data estimation consider all countries as a single entity, therefore,
growth in the oil exporting countries, is questionable. The present arti- we cannot identify the differences in the dynamic relationship between
cle contributes in the existing literature on energy–growth nexus by energy consumption and economic growth for individual countries. As
taking heterogeneity of slope, cross section dependence and structural the level of economic development in each country is different, there-
breaks into account. fore, the dynamic relationship among the variables should also be dif-
ferent for each country. Specifically, Lee (2006) notes that the
3. Model and methodology relationship between energy and economic growth should be different
when the level of economic development is different.
The earlier attempts by Hudson and Jorgenson (1974) and Jorgenson Keeping this discussion in view, we follow the argument of
(1978) to treat energy as an explicit factor of production next to labor Blackburne and Frank (2007) who note that datasets are now large
and capital show the importance of energy in response to Arab oil em- enough in time (T) dimension such that each country can be estimated
bargo and energy crises of 1973–74. Then there is a large and still grow- separately. Therefore, Pesaran and Smith (1995), Pesaran et al. (1999),
ing literature which still considers energy as an important factor in the Phillips and Moon (2000) and Im et al. (2003) document that assump-
production function. One of the most recent studies by Damette and tion of homogeneity of slope parameters is often inappropriate in case
Seghir (2013) proposes a bivariate model for investigating the linkages of large cross section (N) and large time. Therefore, Pesaran et al.
between energy consumption and economic growth for the oil (1999) suggest that one should estimate the N time series regressions,
exporting countries. However, the findings of Damette and Seghir in the case of large T. Additionally, when assumption of homogenous
A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324 317

slope is being violated, then panel data is termed as heterogeneous where βi are the estimates from pooled Ordinary Least Square (OLS) es-
(Blackburne and Frank, 2007). timators, β e are the estimates from the weighted fixed effect estimators
w
Pesaran and Smith (1995) propose mean group (MG) estimator and and M is the identity matrix. The test has an asymptotic normal distribu-
pooled mean group (PMG) estimators for estimating the heterogeneous tion under the null hypothesis with condition of (N, T) → ∞.
panel data. The idea behind MG estimator is very simple. It estimates a Furthermore, Pesaran and Smith (1995) also point out that countries
long run model for each cross section and then takes the average of the may have a common long run despite the fact that they have different
slope parameters for each cross section. Therefore, MG estimator allows slope parameters in the short run. This argument is more relevant in
variability in intercepts, slopes and variance of error terms across groups. our context when we are explaining the economic growth through en-
The estimates of the MG estimator are reliable and consistent only if the ergy and other relevant variables. Because, Parente and Prescott (1994)
data consists of long time series for large cross sections. Pesaran et al. and Eaton and Kortum (1996) document that all countries grow at com-
(1999) set the MG estimator in an autoregressive distributed lag mon rate due to the transfer of technology which keeps the growth rate
(ARDL) model settings due to its various advantages over other constant among the countries (Hall and Jones, 1999). This scenario
autoregressive models (Pesaran et al., 2001). Then, it is super consistent paves way for using PMG estimator which is proposed by Pesaran
in the small sample size and takes care of the problem of endogeneity et al. (1999). The PMG estimator follows the MG estimator, that is, it al-
which is more relevant in our case as some of the studies mention that lows the varying intercepts, slope coefficients and standard error across
the causality runs from growth to energy consumption. However, the as- the cross sectional units. However in long run coefficients should be the
sumption of strict exogeneity makes the model more restrictive. same across countries. We are also interested in the different dynamics
The ARDL model takes the following form in our case: of the short run in different countries. The PMG estimators lie between
the mean group estimators and fixed effect approach.
X
p X
q It is important to mention here that both unit roots and cointegration
yi;t ¼ ηi þ λi; j yi;t− j þ δi; j zi;t− j þ εi;t ð4Þ testing have to consider the presence of potential breaks, given the long
j¼1 j¼0
period under study as well as the fact that a number of serious events re-
lated to energy occurred during the period 1970 to 2012. The existence
where yi,t is the level of GDP in i group at t time, ηi represents the fixed
of structural breaks may lead to misleading inferences regarding the
effects in the data and zit is vector of explanatory variables which in-
order of integration, that is, a stationary series may be taken as non-
cludes k, l, e, and tr. After re-parameterization Eq. (4) can be written
stationary (Perron, 1989) and can bias the examination of cointegration
as first difference form.
(Narayan and Smyth, 2008). Furthermore, as mentioned earlier, Breitung
and Pesaran (2008) point out that it is inappropriate to assume the cross
section independence in the usage of panel data methods because the as-
X
p−1

X
q−1
 sumption of independence is often not valid in the use of macroeconom-
Δyi;t ¼ ηi þ ϕi yi;t−1 þ φi zi;t þ λi; j Δyi;t− j þ δi; j Δzi;t− j þ εi;t ð5Þ
j¼1 j¼0 ic indicators (Urbain and Westerlund, 2006). Keeping this in view, the
! present study uses the recently developed methodologies which take
p p p
where ϕi ¼ − 1−∑ λi; j , φi ¼ −∑ δi; j , λi; j ¼ − ∑ λi;m , and δi; j ¼ into account both potential structural breaks and cross-sectional
q j¼1 j¼0 m¼ jþ1 dependence.
− ∑ δi;m with j = 1, 2, ….p − 1. The cross-section dependence (CD) test is proposed by Pesaran
m¼ Jþ1
(2004) under the null hypothesis of no dependence across the section
Eq. (5) can be written as follows when we group the variables in
of panel. Pesaran (2004) documents that CD test can be applied for
levels,
the variety of models, especially for the dynamic heterogeneous panels
with structural breaks. The test is defined as:
h i Xp−1 X 
q−1

Δyi;t ¼ ηi þ φi yi;t−1 −θi zi;t þ λi; j Δyi;t− j þ δi; j Δzi;t− j þ εi;t ð6Þ sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi0 1
j¼1 j¼0 2T @NX −1 X
N
CD ¼ ^ ijA→Nð0; 1Þ
ρ ð8Þ
NðN−1Þ i¼1 j¼iþ1
φ
where θi ¼ − ϕi .
This shows the long run relationship between the var-
i
iable involved and ϕi is the speed of adjustment towards the long run ^ ij is the sample estimate of correlation of residuals. More clearly:
where ρ
equilibrium.
We should not use MG estimators or PMG estimators without test- XT
u^ u
^
ing the homogeneity condition as Catao and Terrones (2005) note that ^ ij ¼ ρ
^ ji ¼ X t¼1 it jt
ρ 1 = X 1 = : ð9Þ
T T
if restriction of slope homogeneity holds then the estimates derived ^ 2 it
u 2
^ 2 jt
u 2
t¼1 t¼1
from mean group will be inefficient and slope homogeneity condition
does not capture heterogeneity due to country specific characteristics
(Breitung, 2005). Interestingly, Damette and Seghir (2013) apply PMG Testing stationary properties in long T as compared to N cross sec-
estimator without testing homogeneity condition, therefore, their find- tions is a natural start to avoid the spurious regressions. The literature
ings are not very convincing. offers several tests for testing the stationary properties of the panel
Swamy (1970) proposes a slope homogeneity test on slope parame- data series. These tests can be distinguished as first generation panel
ters which are obtained from panel data estimators. However, Pesaran unit root tests and second generation panel unit root tests. The first gen-
and Yamagata (2008) criticize the restriction of Swamy (1970) test eration panel unit root tests, for example Maddala and Wu (1999), Levin
that it requires small T as compared to N. Keeping this drawback of et al. (2002) and Im et al. (2003) are based on the assumption of no
Swamy test in mind Pesaran and Yamagata (2008) proposed a modified cross section dependence. While the second generation panel unit
version of Swamy test which does not have any restriction on N or T. The root test, for example Bai and Ng (2004), Moon and Perron (2004),
modified version is as follows3: Choi (2001) and Pesaran (2007) assume that there is a cross section de-
pendence. But there are several reasons for cross sectional dependence
Xn  0 x0 M−x2   in the modern economy. For example, the higher economic integration,
0
S ¼ e
β i −β i i e
βi −β ð7Þ financial integration of countries, and trade interdependence may be
w w
σ 2
i¼1 the chief reasons.
To avoid the problem, Pesaran (2007) panel unit root test is estimat-
3
Pesaran and Yamagata (2008) is referred for the details of Swamy test. ed which is based on the assumption of cross section independence.
318 A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324

However, the unit root problem testing has to consider the presence of estimates of capital stocks but we shall generate capital stock series
potential breaks, given the long period under study as well as the fact for each country by using perpetual inventory method.
that a number of serious events related to energy occurred during the The basic idea of the perpetual inventory flow method is that if the
last four decades. Therefore, the present study will use Bai and rate of decay of capital is κ then capital series will be Kt + 1 = It +
Carrion-i-Silvestre (2009) panel unit root test which takes into account (1 − κ)Kt. It is assumed that there is a constant rate of depreciation,
the problem of structural breaks and cross section dependence. then Kt + 1 = (1 − κ)Kt + It. The word perpetual implies that all as-
Before moving to long run and short run estimates of the energy sets are endlessly part of inventory capital stocks and the quantity of
growth nexus, it is advisable to test the long run relationship among services provided by the capital declines over time but never reaches at
the variables. For this purpose we shall use four different statistics ∞
zero. Therefore we can obtain K tþ1 ¼ ∑ ð1−κ Þi It−i by repeatedly
which are developed by Westerlund (2007). Two of them test the null i¼0
hypothesis that the panel is not cointegrated as a whole and named as substituting Kt + 1 = (1 − κ)Kt + It for the capital stock. In practice
‘panel test’, Pt and Pa. Whereas the rest of the two statistics test the alter- ∞
native hypothesis that at least one element in the panel is cointegrated Nehru and Dhareshwar (1993) replaced K tþ1 ¼ ∑ð1−κ Þi It−i by K tþ1 ¼
i¼0
and named as ‘group mean test’ Ga and Gt. Importantly, all these four t−1
t i
tests are applicable in the presence of cross section dependence and het- ð1−κ Þ K ð0Þ þ ∑ I t ð1−κ Þ due to non-availability of infinite number of
i¼0
erogeneous panel data.
past investment flows. The K(0) is the initial stock in period zero, in our
However, the panel cointegration test of Westerlund (2007) does
case the capital stock is beginning in 1970, and It is the level of invest-
not take account of the structural breaks in the longer data series. For
ment. The researchers estimate K(0) through several methods. For ex-
this purpose we shall use Westerlund and Edgerton (2008) panel
ample, it is assumed that the initial capital is three times of the
cointegration test that considers not only the cross sectional depen-
output. Some of the researchers estimate a linear regression of the log
dence but the structural breaks as well. More specifically, Westerlund
of investment against time. The fitted value of initial investment
and Edgerton (2008) give two statistics under the null hypothesis of
is used to calculate initial capital stock using the following equation:
no cointegration. Finally, we shall use common correlated effect mean
Kt = It/(g + κ). Here, g is the rate of growth of output (GDP). We shall
group (CCEMG) estimator, along with MG and PMG estimators, which
prefer the second method because first method is not advisable in the
is proposed by Pesaran (2006) and which take into account structural
context of panel data estimation. As every country has a different level
breaks and cross sectional dependence. Furthermore, Kapetanios et al.
of GDP at the initial point, therefore, the results of initial capital esti-
(2011) document that CCEMG estimators are consistent and robust in
mates will not be suitable for comparison.
the presence of structural breaks.4
The other important decision in the perpetual flow method is about
the rate of depreciation of capital stock. Kamps (2006) suggests differ-
ent rates of depreciation based on the nature of assets and time span
4. Data and variable construction
of the data series. Specifically, it varies from 4 to 8.25% for government
assets and private residential assets respectively. Similarly, Khan
Our empirical analysis is based on two samples of countries over the
(2005) documents that capital depreciation rate may be 4 to 5% for
period of 1970 to 2012, that is, 29 countries which are net energy im-
the developing countries. Similarly, Nadiri and Purcha (1996) estimate
porter and 19 net energy exporter countries. One of the major short-
the depreciation rate as 5% for the developed countries. Therefore, we
comings of the previous studies, for example Damette and Seghir
shall take 5% rate of depreciation for all countries which are included
(2013), is that they take the oil exporting countries as a proxy of energy
in our sample. However, the rate of depreciation may vary from country
exporting countries. Obviously, this is not a comprehensive definition of
to country and the capital series may change accordingly. Keeping this
energy exporting countries. We shall use the definition of International
point in view, we shall use real investment to GDP ratio as an alternative
Energy Agency (2012) in this regard which states that the net energy
variable for testing robustness of our model.
imports are estimated as energy use minus production and both are
Before going for the estimation, we shall take the natural log of every
measured in oil equivalents.5 Specifically, and a negative value indicates
variable for mitigating the risk of several econometric problems. There-
that the country is a net exporter. Some of the countries like Libya,
fore, the estimated coefficients are the economic growth elasticities
Kuwait, Iraq, Angola, Oman, Yemen and Brunei Darussalam are exclud-
with respect to the independent variables.
ed from our sample due to unavailability of data. Similarly, Argentina is
also excluded from the sample due to its different dynamics, because
she was a net importer from 1971 to 1982 and from 1986 to 1988 and 5. Empirical results
net exporter from 1983 to 1985 and from 1989 to 2010 and recently
she is again a net importer. Testing the unit root problem is a natural start in a long time series
In order to apply MG and PMG estimation techniques, per capita real panel model. In addition to this the structural breaks may also occur in
GDP, real energy consumption and trade openness data are directly ob- a longer time series. Therefore, as mentioned earlier, we shall use
tained from the World Development Indicators. Trade openness ratio tr, three different panel unit root tests to test the unit root problems with
is the total value of exports and imports as share of nominal GDP. and without cross sectional dependence and structural breaks. The re-
Since there are no official estimates for aggregate capital stock, sults of Maddala and Wu (1999) panel unit root test are presented in
therefore researchers try different options. For example, Lee and Chien the upper panel of Table 1. The p-values suggest that the order of inte-
(2010) use net capital stock constructed by Kamps (2006) and several gration is sensitive to the number of lags. However, most of the variables
other studies on energy–growth nexus use gross fixed capital formation are I (1).
to GDP ratio. We shall take both data series keeping robustness of the However, Maddala and Wu (1999) test is developed on the assump-
estimates in mind. However, we shall not use the Kamps (2006) tion of cross section independence. But there are several reasons for
cross sectional dependence in the modern economy. For example, the
higher economic integration, financial integration of countries, and
4
The mathematical derivation and expressions are deliberately dropped from the text trade interdependence may be the chief reasons. We are not taking all
keeping brevity in mind. We refer to the original papers for technicalities. these factors into our regression models; therefore, cross section inter-
5
Energy use refers to the use of primary energy before transformation to other end-use
fuels, which is equal to indigenous production plus imports and stock changes, minus ex-
dependence may exhibit in the residuals. Breusch and Pagan (1980) La-
ports and fuels supplied to ships and aircraft engaged in international transport. Browse grange Multiplier (LM) test and Pesaran (2004) cross sectional
http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/EG.IMP.CONS.ZS for more details. dependence test are used in this article. The LM statistics of Breusch–
A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324 319

Table 1 Table 3
Panel unit root tests without structural breaks: p-values are given with null hypothesis Slope heterogeneity test.
that series is I (1).
Swamy stats 6.0323***
Energy net exporter Energy net importer Adjusted Swamy stats 5.1149***

Lag 0 Lag 1 Lag 2 Lag 0 Lag 1 Lag 2 *** 1% level of significance.

(A) Maddala and Wu panel unit root test


y 0.3601 0.4493 0.2434 0.3887 0.4621 0.3133
l 0.7946 0.2761 0.3821 0.4594 0.9531 0.9682 However, it may be possible that a different non-linear specification
e 0.2223 0.3579 0.0095 0.3113 0.7951 0.2844 would change the analysis considerably, that is, the slope homogeneity
tr 0.7121 0.5400 0.1178 0.0898 0.1690 0.1835 be more reasonable instead of slope heterogeneity. To overcome this
k 0.2857 0.0244 0.9183 0.8506 0.9441 0.9332
problem, we test functional form under the null hypothesis that the
(B) Pesaran panel unit root test model is correctly specified. The results are presented in Table 8. We
y 0.1964 0.1589 0.0907 0.9624 0.9815 0.7486 let go of this discussion for a while; however it is important to mention
l 0.5163 0.1927 0.9231 0.5576 0.7542 0.7722
e 0.6509 0.6358 0.6026 0.7979 0.7828 0.5902
that the functional forms are correctly specified.
tr 0.9835 0.8181 0.2395 0.4380 0.8780 0.2747 The next task is to estimate the long run relationship among the var-
k 0.7096 0.6255 0.0138 0.3823 0.0953 0.4996 iables. For this purpose, as mentioned earlier, we use Westerlund
(2007) and Westerlund and Edgerton (2008) panel cointegration
tests. Westerlund (2007) is applicable in the presence of cross section
Pagan is 289.0098 and Pesaran statistics is 5.9971, which clearly reject
dependence and heterogeneous panel data, but does not consider the
the null hypothesis of no cross section dependence. Therefore, this re-
structural breaks. Therefore, we shall use Westerlund and Edgerton
sult may invalidate the results of Maddala and Wu (1999). To avoid
(2008) panel cointegration test for taking structural breaks into ac-
the problem, Pesaran (2007) panel unit root test is estimated which is
count. The results of Westerlund (2007) panel cointegration test are
based on the assumption of cross section dependence. The results are
presented in Table 4 and Westerlund and Edgerton (2008) are present-
presented in the lower panel of Table 1. However, the different order
ed in Table 5.
of integration is shown at a different lag order and this suggests that
The null hypothesis of no cointegration is clearly rejected, in both
the estimation in ARDL framework is an appropriate strategy.
cases, for both energy exporting and energy importing countries. There-
However, Pesaran (2007) test doesn't take into account the structur-
fore, we can conclude that there exists a long run relationship between
al breaks. For this purpose, we are using Bai and Carrion-i-Silvestre
energy consumption and economic growth both in energy exporting
(2009) panel unit root test which takes into account the problem of
and energy importing countries.
structural breaks and cross section dependence. The results are present-
The cointegration test establishes the long relationship among the
ed in Table 2 which show that taking structural breaks into account do
variables but does not indicate the direction of the causality. In order
not alter the decision of panel series that has a different order of integra-
to ascertain the direction of causality, Granger causality test has been
tion at a different lag order.
applied by using PMG estimator. The error correction model can be es-
Next we shall test the slope homogeneity condition. For this pur-
timated through Eq. (6). Furthermore, the measure of energy consump-
pose, we shall apply two tests, the standard version of Swamy's test
tion will be a dependent variable in the other version of Eq. (6). Then the
and adjusted version of the Swamy's test adjusted for the small sample
direction of causality can be determined by testing for the significance
properties. The results are presented in Table 3.
of the coefficients of each dependent variable in equations under the
Null hypothesis of homogenous slope parameters is clearly rejected
null hypothesis of no causality. The results are reported in Table 6.
which implies that application of long run estimates based on the
We find the uni-directional causality from energy consumption to
panel vector autoregressive model or error correction model by means
economic growth in the case of energy importer and all countries
of generalized method of moments and of pooled least square estimators
cases, while we find the bi-directional causality in the case of energy
will be misleading in investigating the linkages between energy and eco-
exporting countries. One reasonable reason for this mix results is the
nomic growth. Therefore, we shall move with heterogeneous estimation.
methodical weakness or the assumption of cross sectional country-
specific heterogeneity in climate conditions, economic development
Table 2 and energy consumption patterns.
Panel unit root tests with structural breaks: p-values are given with null hypothesis that The next task is to estimate the long run and short run elasticities.
series is I (1).
Several estimators are used for estimating the cointegration vector in
Energy net exporter Energy net importer the literature based on the dynamics of data. For this purpose, we use
Lag 0 Lag 1 Lag 2 Lag 0 Lag 1 Lag 2 MG, PMG and CCEMG estimators. The long run estimates of MG, PMG
and CCEMG estimators are presented in Table 7.
Constant and trend
y 0.2628 0.5254 0.1149 0.1799 0.3743 0.7900
We estimate a number of regressions for different samples. First, we
l 0.9769 0.6458 0.6392 0.7112 0.2632 0.5775 estimate several regressions through PMG, MG and CCEMG estimators
e 0.8581 0.5610 0.9795 0.2658 0.8931 0.7314 for the energy exporting countries, keeping robustness of the coefficient
tr 0.8736 0.4893 0.1544 0.8456 0.3365 0.6983
k 0.6089 0.0898 0.3612 0.6907 0.3231 0.1887
Table 4
Mean shift
Westerlund error correction panel cointegration tests.
y 0.1816 0.6435 0.3689 0.5706 0.2657 0.1964
l 0.0308 0.7627 0.4815 0.4553 0.3645 0.8081 Null hypothesis: Null hypothesis:
e 0.5009 0.1383 0.9967 0.8431 0.6872 0.0305 No cointegration No cointegration
tr 0.2419 0.4269 0.3867 0.2074 0.0782 0.1624
k 0.0741 0.1709 0.8376 0.9782 0.1347 0.8572 Energy net exporter Energy net importer

Statistic Value p-Value Robust Value p-Value Robust


Trend shift
y 0.9264 0.0244 0.0787 0.9772 0.0049 0.4660 Gt −3.9829 0.0437 0.0002 −3.5993 0.0628 0.0001
l 0.4222 0.1541 0.8017 0.2897 0.4662 0.6177 Ga −5.3751 0.1486 0.0007 −4.7701 0.0085 0.0000
e 0.8935 0.6457 0.8875 0.3679 0.6371 0.3024 Pt −8.8647 0.0081 0.0015 −7.2994 0.0005 0.0001
tr 0.9518 0.5068 0.2213 0.0122 0.8691 0.8858 Pa −11.3036 0.0019 0.0001 −12.2150 0.0061 0.0000
k 0.2809 0.8992 0.3005 0.7614 0.6071 0.2705
Note: Gt and Ga are the group mean statistics. Pt and Pa are panel mean statistics.
320 A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324

Table 5 Table 6
Panel cointegration test results with structural breaks and cross sectional dependence. Panel causality test results for energy consumption and GDP.

Model Zφ (N) p-Value Zτ (N) p-Value Dependent variable Sources of causation

No break 6.6951 0.007035 2.4248 0.0142 Short run Long run


Mean shift 2.7804 0.002619 1.7850 0.0281
Δy Δe Δtr Δk ECT
Regime shift 3.0880 0.001321 1.8417 0.0920
Energy net importers
Note: The test is implemented using the Campbell and Perron (1991) automatic procedure
Δy NA 0.4187⁎⁎ 0.4057⁎⁎⁎ 0.4974⁎⁎⁎ −0.0472⁎
to select the lag length.
NA (0.1960) (0.1722) (0.0876) (0.0287)
Δe 0.3556 NA 0.8055 0.7279⁎⁎ −0.0924⁎⁎⁎
in mind. The basic model is estimated using energy consumption, capi- (0.3775) NA (0.6602) (0.3414) (0.0386)
tal stock and trade openness as independent variables (see columns 1, 2
Energy net exporters
and 3) through PMG, MG and CCEMG estimators. It is important to men- Δy NA 0.6083⁎ 0.7019⁎⁎⁎ 0.6516⁎⁎⁎ −0.0987⁎⁎⁎
tion here that taking structural breaks into account through CCEMG NA (0.3170) (0.2438) (0.2364) (0.0114)
does not alter the sign and statistical significance of the major coeffi- Δe 0.2789⁎⁎ NA 0.9971⁎ 0.3635 −0.0811⁎⁎⁎
cients. More clearly, the energy enters significantly positive in the (0.1059) NA (0.5941) (0.3138) (0.0278)

growth regression in all three estimators which implies that the use of All countries
energy has a significant impact on the economic growth of countries. Δy NA 0.3081⁎⁎ 0.2367 0.4169⁎⁎⁎ −0.0585⁎⁎
Our results are in line with those of Damette and Seghir (2013), Li NA (0.1591) (0.1561) (0.1538) (0.0257)
Δe 0.8214 NA 0.7289⁎⁎⁎ 0.7085⁎⁎ −0.0584⁎⁎
et al. (2011), Wu et al. (2008), Huang et al. (2008), and Yu and Meng (0.9642) NA (0.2048) (0.3169) (0.0254)
(2008). Huang et al. (2008) divide the sample into four different sam-
⁎⁎⁎ 1% level of significance.
ples, low income, lower middle, upper middle and high income coun- ⁎⁎ 5% level of significance.
tries. The important outcome of their analysis is that the energy ⁎ 10% level of significance.
consumption enters significantly positive into all four regressions.
Therefore, we can say that the inclusion of developed and underdevel-
oped countries in a single sample has no effect on the biasedness of distinguishing the energy exporting and energy importing countries
the results. The other control variables k and tr are statistically signifi- keeping robustness in our mind. The lowest panel of Table 7 presents
cant, positive and according to a priori expectations. These imply that the results.
the level of capital growth and increase in international trade may The results of PMG and MG are not different at least in term of signs.
raise the level of economic growth of energy exporting countries. Fur- Even then the decision about the selection between PMG and MG is im-
thermore, the results are consistent with those of Lee and Chang portant for the policy making point of view. Pesaran et al. (1999) use
(2008), Narayan and Smyth (2008) and Lee and Lee (2010). However, Hausman test in selecting between MG and PMG under the null hypoth-
most of the coefficients are smaller than our findings. For example, esis that PMG estimator is better fit than MG estimator, that is, there is
Lee and Chang (2008) find a long run coefficient of energy consumption slope homogeneity in the long run. The results of Hausman test is re-
of 0.25, Narayan and Smyth (2008) document 0.12, 0.16 and 0.39 and ported in Table 7. The p-values of the test show that we shall select
Lee and Lee (2010) report 0.52. However, the size of magnitude is not the PMG estimates.
a big issue because they include energy prices with different control var- Huang et al. (2008) point out a disadvantage of the panel data that it
iables along with different sets of countries. treats the whole sample as single and differences in the slope coeffi-
Then we include the level of employment into regression along with cients of the countries cannot be discussed. For this purpose the re-
the energy consumption, capital stock and trade openness. The compa- searchers estimate the time series data on a country to country basis.
rable data on employment is available since 1990. Therefore, the sample However, PMG estimators allow heterogeneity for short run estimates.
is almost half as compared to the last estimation. Westerlund (2007) ar- The short run results of the basic model are presented in Table 8.
gues that Ga statistics may show no cointegration in the short span of The energy consumption has a significant positive impact on eco-
time. However, Pa and Pt statistics show a long run relationship nomic growth in almost all energy exporting countries except Egypt
among the variables.6 The long run coefficients are presented in col- and Venezuela. It implies that energy consumption is also an important
umns 4, 5 and 6 of Table 7. Energy consumption, capital stock, employ- factor for explaining the growth of energy exporting countries. Howev-
ment and trade openness enter significantly positive in the regression er, we find the different sizes of magnitudes for different countries.
line and are in line with the a priori expectation. Some of them are very high as compared to other studies for example
As mentioned earlier, we constructed the capital stock series based Korea, Sri Lanka and Turkey and some of them are very low for example
on several assumptions. The most crucial assumption is about the rate Japan and India. There are several possible reasons. One of them is that
of depreciation of capital stock which is assumed as 5% for all countries the other studies include energy prices with different control variables
and capital stock series enters significantly positive in all regression along with different samples of data and different techniques. Further-
therefore we need to check the robustness of outcome. For this purpose, more, the impact of energy consumption on the economic growth pro-
we use investment to GDP as a proxy to capital stock series. The invest- cess of the countries may be associated with huge global shocks. For
ment to GDP ratio does alter the sign or the level of significance. example the first oil crisis in 1973, Iraq's invasion of Kuwait in 1990,
The middle panel of Table 7 presents the results of 29 energy net im- the Asian crisis in 1997–1999 when there were sharp oil price decreases
porter countries. We repeat the same strategy for the energy importer and after the 9/11 attacks in 2001. Similarly, there was a large and con-
countries. That is, first we run the regression through MG and PMG for tinued rise in oil prices during the time period of 2005 to 2008. The
the basic model, then enter the level of employment into the regression whole decade of 1980s cannot be neglected due to 1978 Iranian revolu-
and then replace investment to GDP ratio with capital stock. The find- tion and the Iran–Iraq War. More importantly, there were some other
ings for the energy importer countries are in line with the theory, that important events which shaped the global macroeconomics, for exam-
is, energy, capital stock, employment and trade openness enter signifi- ple, the period of high inflation during the late 1970s along with the ex-
cantly positive into regressions. We also estimate the same 8 regres- ploding oil prices, the global economic recession in the early 1980s, the
sions line for all countries which are included in our sample without fall in oil prices in 1986, the Wall Street stock market was crashed in
1987, and then the periods of low economic growth and inflation in
Western industrialized countries in the late 1980s. All these shocks
6
The results are not presented here keeping brevity in mind. struck these countries differently. Therefore, the magnitude of the
A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324 321

Table 7
The long run effect of energy consumption on economic growth.

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

Regressors PMG MG CCEMG PMG MG CCEMG PMG MG CCEMG PMG MG CCEMG

Energy net exporters


e 0.3916⁎⁎⁎ 0.6005⁎⁎ 0.6837⁎⁎⁎ 0.6727⁎⁎⁎ 0.6723⁎⁎ 0.6072⁎⁎⁎ 0.2134⁎⁎ 0.3073 0.5127⁎⁎ 0.8183⁎⁎⁎ 0.6211⁎ 0.9197⁎⁎
(0.1214) (0.2869) (0.1822) (0.2525) (0.3319) (0.2109) (0.0948) (0.2823) (0.2500) (0.2126) (0.3448) (0.4377)
k 0.3747⁎⁎ 0.5174⁎⁎ 0.7759⁎⁎ 0.4939⁎⁎ 0.4744⁎⁎⁎ 0.4898⁎ NA NA NA NA NA NA
(0.1758) (0.2536) (0.3769) (0.2522) (0.1831) (0.2812) NA NA NA NA NA NA
tr 0.1301⁎⁎⁎ 0.7500⁎⁎⁎ 0.7972⁎⁎⁎ 0.7995⁎⁎ 0.7616⁎⁎ 0.5761⁎⁎⁎ 0.3997⁎⁎⁎ 0.8044⁎⁎⁎ 0.4297⁎ 0.417 0.6011⁎⁎ 0.9337⁎⁎⁎
(0.0540) (0.2462) (0.0958) (0.3911) (0.3561) (0.1368) (0.1298) (0.2570) (0.2200) (0.3294) (0.2855) (0.1163)
l NA NA NA 0.6371⁎⁎ 0.9139⁎⁎⁎ 0.7995⁎⁎⁎ NA NA NA 0.5025⁎⁎⁎ 0.1893⁎ 0.4475⁎⁎⁎
NA NA NA (0.2776) (0.3197) (0.1208) NA NA NA (0.1451) (0.0977) (0.1749)
I NA NA NA NA NA NA 0.2235⁎⁎⁎ 0.4713⁎ 0.3421⁎⁎⁎ 0.6220⁎ 0.4309⁎⁎ 0.7193⁎⁎⁎
NA NA NA NA NA NA (0.0490) (0.2784) (0.1338) (0.3425) (0.1851) (0.2078)
Housman test 0.4300 0.4954 0.5147 0.5250

Energy net importers


e 0.8500⁎⁎ 0.7059⁎⁎ 0.3194⁎⁎⁎ 0.9153⁎⁎⁎ 0.5492⁎⁎⁎ 0.2082⁎⁎⁎ 0.1485⁎ 0.4525⁎⁎⁎ 0.9515⁎⁎⁎ 0.5021⁎⁎⁎ 0.7164⁎⁎⁎ 0.8246⁎
(0.3740) (0.3280) (0.0997) (0.2866) (0.1399) (0.0862) (0.0765) (0.1897) (0.2907) (0.1652) (0.2325) (0.4224)
k 0.2967⁎⁎⁎ 0.9296⁎⁎⁎ 0.5902⁎ 0.3224⁎⁎ 0.5322⁎⁎⁎ 0.7471⁎⁎⁎ NA NA NA NA NA NA
(0.1212) (0.2063) (0.3294) (0.1370) (0.2015) (0.2796) NA NA NA NA NA NA
tr 0.7872⁎⁎ 0.3313⁎⁎⁎ 0.4062⁎⁎⁎ 0.2665⁎⁎ 0.8375 0.7611⁎⁎⁎ 0.4629⁎⁎⁎ 0.6930⁎⁎⁎ 0.3131⁎⁎ 0.6840⁎ 0.8851⁎⁎⁎ 0.9978⁎⁎⁎
(0.3781) (0.1312) (0.1564) (0.1296) (0.5869) (0.1056) (0.1782) (0.1677) (0.1464) (0.4841) (0.2650) (0.2842)
l NA NA NA 0.6347⁎⁎⁎ 0.8499⁎⁎⁎ 0.1497⁎⁎⁎ NA NA NA 0.7231⁎⁎ 0.6901⁎⁎⁎ 0.5927⁎⁎⁎
NA NA NA (0.2615) (0.2786) (0.0586) NA NA NA (0.3647) (0.2440) (0.1681)
I NA NA NA NA NA NA 0.3376⁎⁎⁎ 0.2439 0.9156⁎⁎⁎ 0.5574⁎⁎ 0.5940⁎⁎⁎ 0.8767⁎⁎⁎
NA NA NA NA NA NA (0.1180) (0.1782) (0.1224) (0.2687) (0.2055) (0.2075)
Housman test 0.2394 0.5707 0.5295 0.5881

All countries
e 0.6853⁎⁎⁎ 0.8088⁎ 0.4977⁎⁎⁎ 0.4989⁎ 0.9501⁎⁎⁎ 0.3243⁎⁎⁎ 0.2477⁎⁎⁎ 0.2145⁎⁎⁎ 0.8466⁎⁎ 0.4274⁎⁎⁎ 0.3563⁎⁎ 0.9164⁎⁎⁎
(0.2624) (0.4248) (0.2065) (0.2560) (0.2558) (0.1299) (0.0994) (0.0713) (0.4250) (0.1623) (0.1639) (0.2033)
k 0.3176⁎⁎ 0.6683⁎⁎⁎ 0.3972⁎⁎⁎ 0.3815⁎⁎⁎ 0.3128⁎ 0.8777⁎⁎⁎ NA NA NA NA NA NA
(0.1498) (0.2442) (0.1677) (0.0778) (0.1841) (0.1349) NA NA NA NA NA NA
tr 0.2797⁎⁎ 0.4806⁎⁎⁎ 0.4092⁎ 0.4867⁎⁎⁎ 0.8765⁎ 0.4148⁎⁎⁎ 0.3382⁎ 0.6319⁎⁎⁎ 0.8177⁎⁎⁎ 0.2767⁎⁎⁎ 0.3306⁎ 0.2615⁎⁎
(0.1248) (0.1486) (0.2174) (0.2061) (0.4674) (0.1460) (0.1771) (0.2335) (0.2759) (0.1127) (0.1762) (0.1258)
l NA NA NA 0.2546 0.3679⁎⁎ 0.7238⁎⁎⁎ NA NA NA 0.3314 0.6845⁎⁎ 0.2384⁎⁎⁎
NA NA NA (0.1758) (0.1306) (0.2993) NA NA NA (0.2181) (0.2409) (0.0885)
I NA NA NA NA NA NA 0.3771⁎⁎ 0.272 0.8509⁎⁎⁎ 0.4143⁎ 0.6926⁎ 0.8466⁎⁎⁎
NA NA NA NA NA NA (0.1656) (0.2303) (0.2549) (0.2448) (0.3881) (0.1547)
Housman test 0.2084 0.4364 0.3835 0.5877

Note: The standard errors are presented in parentheses.


⁎⁎⁎ 1% level of significance.
⁎⁎ 5% level of significance.
⁎ 10% level of significance.

impact of energy may differ from country to country. Thus, setting the Furthermore, the p-value of functional form is an evidence of well spec-
policy based on the single homogenous slope is not a good strategy, es- ification of the model and p-value is an indication of the acceptance of
pecially, in the short run. Similarly, capital and trade openness are also the null hypothesis of normality assumption of the residuals. Therefore,
important determinants in the short run in energy importer countries. the preferred growth equation can be used for policy decision-making
Energy consumption, capital stock and trade openness also enter signif- purposes, such that the impact of policy changes considering the ex-
icantly in the energy exporter countries which is consistent with the planatory variables of growth equation will not cause major distortion
conventional result. This implies that any restriction on energy con- in the level of per capita GDP, since the parameters in this equation
sumption or imports of energy may hurt the growth of these countries. seem to follow a stable pattern during the estimation period.
The error correction (ECM) term is an important outcome. The re-
sults are presented in Table 8. The ECM term is significant for all coun-
tries and correct in sign. It is a speed of adjustment from short run 6. Conclusion
equilibrium to long run equilibrium. It varies from country to country.
Specifically it varies from 0.02 for Albania to 0.6 for New Zealand. This Indeed, investigating the linkages between energy consumption and
implies, nearly 2% of the disequilibria of the previous year's shock adjust economic growth is not a unique idea. However, the present article sep-
back to the long run equilibrium in the current year in case of Albania arates itself from the existing literature in several ways. First, we inves-
and this adjustment will move to almost 60% in the case of New tigate about the energy net exporter countries, instead of oil exporting
Zealand. Another important implication of these results is that if energy countries, as well as the energy importers countries. Secondly, the
reservoirs are depleted in Albania then Albania will take almost cross sectional dependence is allowed and tested for the selected coun-
50 years to get their long run equilibrium and New Zealand will take al- tries. Thirdly, the use of second generation panel unit root tests which
most 2 years in case of sudden stop of energy from abroad.7 are based on cross section dependence. Fourth, the assumption of
Our model passes through the diagnostic tests. The results are re- slope homogeneity is no more valid for long time series data and there-
ported in last four columns of Table 8. The p-values of the χ2 state that fore uses the heterogeneous panel data estimation techniques. Fifth, the
there is no evidence of serial correlation and heteroscedasticity. use of four different statistics which are introduced by Westerlund
(2007) based on cross sectional dependence and heterogeneous panel
7
Although both these countries represent the extreme values. The rest of the countries data. Sixth, we estimate the homogeneous long run coefficients and het-
may be interpreted in the same way. erogeneous short run coefficients for the cointegration vector.
322 A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324

Table 8
Short run dynamics.

Diagnostic tests

Δe Δk Δtr ECM χ2sc χ2ff χ2nor χ2het

Energy exporter countries


Albania 0.1437** 0.8667*** 0.9571** −0.0263** 0.2949 0.1723 0.6521 0.9574
Algeria 0.2481* 0.7953** 0.1830** −0.1096** 0.5492 0.4754 0.1616 0.9838
Australia 0.1757* 0.7693** 0.9411*** −0.1492** 0.7599 0.8149 0.2259 0.3752
Bolivia 0.3850** 0.2184*** 0.3232* −0.1401** 0.2391 0.8145 0.1849 0.2327
Canada 0.4545* 0.4749** 0.1169*** −0.1283*** 0.2981 0.7715 0.7597 0.6471
Colombia 0.1407* 0.9527*** 0.7813** −0.1808** 0.8383 0.7005 0.3343 0.6383
Ecuador 0.2966* 0.3209** 0.0377** −0.1592** 0.1190 0.9343 0.7551 0.3090
Egypt −0.3347 0.7334** 0.7572*** −0.1655** 0.9701 0.3366 0.3598 0.4833
Gabon 0.6770* 0.5404** 0.1812** −0.1348** 0.6662 0.4073 0.3490 0.7245
Indonesia 0.1658*** 0.1354*** 0.8285** −0.1683** 0.1477 0.4287 0.8600 0.7247
Iran 0.2923** 0.6691** 0.2759** −0.1795** 0.2255 0.7178 0.8476 0.2917
Nigeria 0.2222* 0.9997** 0.5181*** −0.1158*** 0.1152 0.6353 0.3198 0.4163
Norway 0.3528* 0.5165** 0.6107** −0.1305** 0.5019 0.9176 0.3389 0.6433
Syria 0.4675** 0.6213** 0.1926** −0.1883* 0.4367 0.5233 0.9673 0.7199
Trinidad 0.1197** 0.4633** 0.8552* −0.1621*** 0.6712 0.7969 0.6914 0.6744
UAE 0.7871** 0.6029** 0.3533* −0.1702** 0.6697 0.2315 0.1655 0.7021
Venezuela −0.7601** 0.5756*** 0.5303*** −0.0903** 0.6156 0.3940 0.6707 0.2628
Sudan 0.3003* 0.3353*** 0.4792** −0.1869*** 0.3591 0.4460 0.6793 0.1738
South Africa 0.6124* 0.7527** 0.4139*** −0.1091** 0.1748 0.2548 0.8714 0.1177

Energy importer countries


Austria 0.3024** 0.2287** 0.0846** −0.1331** 0.8893 0.7487 0.8458 0.6936
Belgium 0.7928** 0.6267*** 0.2075 −0.1646** 0.7317 0.6677 0.6536 0.1534
Bangladesh −0.1158*** 0.5231*** 0.7142 −0.1242* 0.2466 0.2036 0.6583 0.6323
Brazil 0.6998* 0.0692** 0.5534* −0.0244*** 0.5237 0.7593 0.4828 0.1936
Chile 0.3905* 0.5853** 0.8152* −0.1686*** 0.8473 0.4522 0.7403 0.5244
China 0.2923* 0.5767** 0.8398** −0.1599* 0.3453 0.3920 0.4116 0.6002
Czech Republic 0.6018* 0.9681* 0.2700 −0.1361*** 0.1592 0.8276 0.7912 0.5142
Germany 0.1962* 0.5697*** 0.8435 −0.1870** 0.2780 0.5595 0.9274 0.8153
Denmark 0.4141* 0.8165** 0.6198** −0.3410** 0.8042 0.2957 0.4665 0.1308
Spain 0.3522* 0.6638** 0.2049** −0.1935** 0.2037 0.4338 0.8757 0.7240
Finland 0.1431** 0.7413** 0.1962* −0.1413** 0.1468 0.1464 0.8859 0.3500
France 0.3361* 0.1606** 0.8423 −0.1272*** 0.2582 0.8186 0.3590 0.4491
United Kingdom 0.7974* 0.5223** 0.8321 −0.1103** 0.1166 0.3084 0.1330 0.6295
Hungry 0.6944* 0.3764** 0.2660 −0.2238** 0.2049 0.2554 0.1317 0.3021
India 0.1415* 0.8610** 0.2199 −0.1060** 0.6698 0.8312 0.8332 0.5621
Italy −0.0603* 0.9773* 0.2116* −0.3048* 0.5422 0.1941 0.2071 0.4841
Japan 0.0747* 0.5218** 0.7282 −0.2598*** 0.1371 0.4336 0.9617 0.1225
Korea 0.9439*** 0.4310** 0.0716** −0.1696** 0.7147 0.2772 0.7240 0.8648
Sri-Lanka 0.8483** 0.6508** 0.6783 −0.3247* 0.4072 0.4312 0.2718 0.3919
Netherland 0.6552* 0.7477* 0.2908* −0.3512* 0.8944 0.5473 0.8602 0.0213
New Zealand 0.2727** 0.1711* 0.9855* −0.6237** 0.3065 0.6700 0.1184 0.2731
Pakistan 0.2364** 0.2361*** 0.1199 −0.2354*** 0.2119 0.0284 0.5468 0.8340
Philippines 0.1697** 0.6065** 0.0348* −0.3580** 0.5130 0.6039 0.0637 0.7249
Portugal 0.4997** 0.0473** 0.4595 −0.7267** 0.8611 0.2818 0.7212 0.1069
Sweden −0.0378* 0.7623* 0.0700* −0.5496** 0.5981 0.7725 0.1092 0.7056
Thailand 0.4037* 0.5736* 0.7316 −0.2579* 0.4507 0.8244 0.0534 0.2578
Turkey 0.8059** 0.3819** 0.9456* −0.2683* 0.5422 0.1885 0.4300 0.1249
United States 0.6452** 0.8890** 0.3753 −0.1875** 0.8266 0.1749 0.4584 0.2565
Vietnam 0.7313** 0.2967** 0.3896* −0.2525** 0.8254 0.8360 0.1935 0.6085

Note: χ2sc, χ2ff, χ2nor, and χ2het are the p-values for serial correlation, functional form, normality and heteroscedasticity tests respectively.
***1% level of significance.
**5% level of significance.
*10% level of significance.

We find that energy consumption, capital stock, investment flows, the economic growth. Thus, the energy security becomes more chal-
level of employment and trade openness have a positive impact on lenging and immediate issue in the scenario of volatile prices of energy
the economic growth of both energy net exporter and importer coun- and limited supply of energy resources.
tries. We postulate that energy exporter countries have subsidized en- However, the other part of controversy on energy–growth nexus that
ergy sector; therefore, reduction in the energy sector subsidies will energy does not contribute in the process of economic growth suggests
hurt the economic growth. Similarly, the energy importer countries that the reduction of overall energy consumption to minimize the carbon
may face a slump if they curtail the energy related import for improving dioxide (CO2) emission for a cleaner environment is indispensible. But,
their trade balance. the findings of this study suggest that governments should implement
Therefore, the policy-makers are advised to take the necessary ac- energy policies that stress the use of alternative energy sources instead
tions to make an efficient use of energy. The explicit unidirectional cau- of completely trying to reduce overall energy consumption in order to at-
sality implies that energy conservation policies may be adopted with tain a cleaner environment. We also follow the lines of Narayan and
some effect on the GDP. Since it is established in this article that energy Smyth (2008) and Lee and Lee (2010) who suggest that the govern-
is one of the engines of growth, along with labor, capital and interna- ments should take the required steps to increase the physical and
tional trade; therefore any reduction in the energy use will dampen human investments in energy sector for its restructuring. This
A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324 323

infrastructure and restructuring of the energy sector should change the Bai, J., Ng, S., 2004. A PANIC attack on unit roots and cointegration. Econometrica 72,
1127–1177.
composition of energy consumption to replace environmental friendly Beck, T., 2002. Financial development and international trade: is there a link? J. Int. Econ.
energy sources for fossil fuels. Furthermore, the governments should 57, 107–131.
prepare such policies which encourage their industrial sector to invest Belloumi, M., 2009. Energy consumption and GDP in Tunisia: cointegration and causality
analysis. Energy Policy 37, 2745–2753.
in the cleaner technologies along with direct investment in the energy Blackburne, E.F., Frank, M.W., 2007. Estimation of non-stationary heterogeneous panels.
sector. Furthermore, Costantini and Martini (2010) note that the produc- Stata Journal 7, 197–208.
tivity of the energy sector may rise with the usage of the more efficient Breitung, J., 2005. A parametric approach to the estimation of cointegration vectors in
panel data. Econ. Rev. 24, 151–173.
option as compared to less efficient options. Therefore, shifting from
Breitung, J., Pesaran, M.H., 2008. Unit roots and cointegration in panels. In: Matyasand, L.,
less efficient usage to more efficient usage of energy will stimulate the Sevestre, P. (Eds.), The Econometrics of Panel Data: Advanced Studies in Theoretical
economic growth along with improvements in the environment. In addi- and Applied Econometrics. , vol. 46. Springer, pp. 279–322.
Breusch, T.S., Pagan, A.R., 1980. The Lagrange multiplier test and its application to model
tion to this the efficient use may increase energy revenues of energy
specifications in econometrics. Rev. Econ. Stud. 47, 239–253.
exporting countries which may have a positive impact on the economic Campbell, J., Perron, P., 1991. Pitfalls and opportunities: what macroeconomists should
growth when these revenues will be reinvested in the economy. know about unit roots. In: Blanchard, O.J., Fischer, S. (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics
The other important finding of the paper is the existence of the cross Annual. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 141–201.
Catao, L.A.V., Terrones, M.E., 2005. Fiscal deficits and inflation. J. Monet. Econ. 52,
section dependence among the countries. More clearly, there is cross- 529–554.
sectional dependence in real energy consumption, real GDP, real invest- Chang, Y., Wong, J.F., 2001. Poverty, energy and economic growth in Singapore. Working
ment, trade and their long-run relationship. This implies that the policy Paper. Department of Economics, National University of Singapore.
Chen, J., Galbraith, J., 2011. Institutional structures and policies in an environment of in-
makers should take into account the dependency on the other countries creasingly scarce and expensive resources: a fixed cost perspective. J. Econ. Issues
while preparing the policies for the energy sector. Therefore, the policy 45, 301–308.
makers have to consider the relations with the other countries while Cheng, B.S., 1995. An investigation of cointegration and causality between energy con-
sumption and economic growth. J. Energy Dev. 21, 73–84.
setting their future targets regarding the economic growth of their Cheng, B.S., 1998. Energy consumption, employment and causality in Japan: a multivari-
countries. In a nut shell, this paper motivates both researchers and pol- ate approach. Indian Econ. Rev. 33, 19–29.
icy makers to follow this new line of direction of research for properly Cheng, B.S., 1999. Causality between energy consumption and economic growth in India:
an application of cointegration and error-correction modeling. Indian Econ. Rev. 34,
gauging energy models, robust future prediction and realistic targets 39–49.
for the usage of energy consumption which may impact their future Choi, I., 2001. Unit root tests for panel data. J. Int. Money Financ. 20, 249–272.
economic growth. Choudhri, E.U., Hakura, D.S., 2000. International trade and productivity growth: exploring
the sectoral effects for developing countries. IMF Staff. Pap. 47, 30–53.
This study has some important implications for academia along with
Cole, M.A., Rayner, A.J., Bates, J.M., 1998. Trade liberalization and the environment: the
the policy makers. As this study follows growth hypothesis taking case of the Uruguay Round. World Econ. 21, 337–347.
heterogeneity, structural breaks and cross sectional dependence into ac- Costantini, V., Martini, C., 2010. The causality between energy consumption and economic
count, therefore, we suggest that the researchers who confirm conserva- growth: a multi-sectoral analysis using non-stationary cointegrated panel data. Ener-
gy Econ. 32 (3), 591–603.
tion hypothesis, feedback hypothesis and neutrality hypothesis in their Damette, O., Seghir, M., 2013. Energy as a driver of growth in oil exporting countries? En-
studies should re-estimate the models by considering heterogeneity, ergy Econ. 37, 193–199.
cross sectional dependence and structural breaks, at least, in future re- Eaton, J., Kortum, S., 1996. Trade in ideas patenting and productivity in OECD. J. Int. Econ.
40, 251–278.
search. Similarly, the theoretical economists should incorporate hetero- Erdal, G., Erdal, H., Esengun, K., 2008. The causality between energy consumption and
geneity and cross sectional dependence in their theoretical research. economic growth in Turkey. Energy Policy 36, 3838–3842.
Because having consensus on the linkage between economic growth Erol, U., Yu, E.S.H., 1988. On the causal relationship between energy and income for indus-
trialized countries. J. Energy Dev. 13, 113–122.
and energy consumption is more than necessary keeping the role of en- Fatai, K., Oxley, L., Scrimgeour, F., 2002. Energy consumption and employment in New
ergy in production process as a vital input and its contribution towards Zealand: searching for causality. Paper Presented at NZAE Conference, Wellington,
the environment related issues. 26–28 June 2002.
Ghali, K.H., El-Sakka, M.I.T., 2004. Energy use and output growth in Canada: a multivariate
cointegration analysis. Energy Econ. 26, 225–238.
Acknowledgments Glasure, Y.U., 2002. Energy and national income in Korea: further evidence on the role of
omitted variables. Energy Econ. 24, 355–365.
Halicioglu, F., 2009. An econometric study of CO2 emissions, energy consumption, income
I thank J. Carrion-i-Silvestre and J. Westerlund for providing their and foreign trade in Turkey. Energy Policy 37, 1156–1164.
GAUSS codes. The comments from two anonymous reviewers helped Hall, R., Jones, C., 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker
to improve the final version. than others? Q. J. Econ. 114, 83–116.
Ho, C.Y., Siu, K.W., 2007. A dynamic equilibrium of electricity consumption and GDP in
Hong Kong: an empirical investigation. Energy Policy 35, 2507–2513.
References Hondroyiannis, G., Lolos, S., Papapetrou, E., 2002. Energy consumption and economic
growth: assessing the evidence from Greece. Energy Econ. 24, 319–336.
Ades, A.F., Glaeser, E.L., 1999. Evidence on growth, increasing returns, and the extent of Huang, B.N., Hwang, M.J., Yang, C.W., 2008. Causal relationship between energy consump-
the market. Q. J. Econ. 114, 1025–1045. tion and GDP growth revisited: a dynamic panel data approach. Ecol. Econ. 67, 41–54.
Akarca, A.T., Long, T.V., 1980. On the relationship between energy and GNP: a reexamina- Hudson, E., Jorgenson, D.W., 1974. US energy policy and economic growth. Bell J. Econ.
tion. J. Energy Dev. 5, 326–331. Manag. Sci. 5, 461–514.
Al-Iriani, M., 2006. Energy–GDP relationship revisited: an example from GCC countries Hwang, D., Gum, B., 1991. The causal relationship between energy and GNP: the case of
using panel causality. Energy Policy 34, 3342–3350. Taiwan. J. Energy Dev. 16, 219–226.
Altinay, G., Karagol, E., 2004. Structural break, unit root, and the causality between energy Im, K.S., Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., 2003. Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. J.
consumption and GDP in Turkey. Energy Econ. 26, 985–994. Econ. 115 (1), 53–74.
Altinay, G., Karagol, E., 2005. Electricity consumption and economic growth: evidence for Jalil, A., Feridun, M., 2014. Energy consumption: an engine of growth in China. Emerg.
Turkey. Energy Econ. 27, 849–856. Mark. Trade Finan. (forthcoming).
Ang, J.B., 2008. Economic development, pollutant emissions and energy consumption in Jayadevappa, R., Chhatre, S., 2000. International trade and environmental quality: a sur-
Malaysia. J. Policy Model 30, 271–278. vey. Ecol. Econ. 32, 175–194.
Apergis, N., Payne, J.E., 2009. Energy consumption and economic growth in Central Jobert, T., Karanfil, F., 2007. Sectoral energy consumption by source and economic growth
America: evidence from a panel cointegration and error correction model. Energy in Turkey. Energy Policy 35, 5447–5456.
Econ. 31, 211–216. Jorgenson, D.W., 1978. The role of energy in the US economy. Natl. Tax J. 31, 209–220.
Asafu-Adjaye, J., 2000. The relationship between energy consumption, energy prices and Jumbe, C.B.L., 2004. Cointegration and causality between electricity consumption and
economic growth: time series evidence from Asian developing countries. Energy GDP: empirical evidence from Malawi. Energy Econ. 26, 61–68.
Econ. 22, 615–625. Kamps, C., 2006. New estimates of government net capital stocks for 22 OECD countries,
Ayres, R.U., van den Bergh, Jeroen C.J.M., Lindenberger, D., Warr, B., 2013. The 1960–2001. IMF Staff. Pap. 53, 120–150.
underestimated contribution of energy to economic growth. Struct. Chang. Econ. Kapetanios, G., Hashem Pesaran, M., Yamagata, T., 2011. Panels with non-stationary mul-
Dyn. 27, 79–88. tifactor error structures. J. Econ. 160, 326–348.
Bai, J., Carrion-i-Silvestre, J.L., 2009. Structural changes, common stochastic trends, and Khan, S.U., 2005. Macro determinants of total factor productivity in Pakistan. SBP Re-
unit roots in panel data. Rev. Econ. Stud. 76, 471–501. search Bulletin 2, 383–401.
324 A. Jalil / Energy Economics 44 (2014) 314–324

Kraft, J., Kraft, A., 1978. On the relationship between energy and GNP. J. Energy Dev. 3, Pesaran, M.H., 2004. General diagnostic tests for cross section dependence in panels.
401–403. CESifo Working Paper No. 1229.
Lee, C., 2005. Energy consumption and GDP in developing countries: a cointegrated panel Pesaran, M.H., 2006. Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a mul-
analysis. Energy Econ. 27, 415–427. tifactor error structure. Econometrica 74, 967–1012.
Lee, C.C., 2006. The causality relationship between energy consumption and GDP in G-11 Pesaran, M.H., 2007. A simple panel unit root test in the presence of cross section depen-
countries revisited. Energy Policy 34, 1086–1093. dence. J. Appl. Econ. 22, 265–312.
Lee, C.C., Chang, C.P., 2005. Structural breaks, energy consumption, and economic growth Pesaran, H.M., Smith, R., 1995. Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heteroge-
revisited: evidence from Taiwan. Energy Econ. 27, 857–872. neous panels. J. Econ. 68, 79–113.
Lee, C.C., Chang, C.P., 2008. Energy consumption and economic growth in Asian econo- Pesaran, M.H., Yamagata, T., 2008. Testing slope homogeneity in large panels. J. Econ. 142,
mies: a more comprehensive analysis using panel data. Resour. Energy Econ. 30, 50–93.
50–65. Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., Smith, R.P., 1999. Pooled mean group estimation of dynamic het-
Lee, C.C., Chien, M.S., 2010. Dynamic modelling of energy consumption, capital stock, and erogeneous panels. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 94, 621–634.
real income in G-7 countries. Energy Econ. 32, 564–581. Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., Smith, R.J., 2001. Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level
Lee, C.C., Lee, J., 2010. A panel data analysis of the demand for total energy and electricity relationships. J. Appl. Econ. 16, 289–326.
in OECD countries. Energy J. 31, 1–23. Phillips, P.C., Moon, H.R., 2000. Nonstationary panel data analysis: an overview of some
Levin, A., Lin, C.F., J. Chu, C.S., 2002. Unit root test in panel data: asymptotic and finite sam- recent developments. Econ. Rev. 19, 263–286.
ple properties. J. Econ. 108, 1–24. Shiu, A., Lam, P., 2004. Electricity consumption and economic growth in China. Energy
Li, F., Dong, S., Li, X., Liang, Q., Yang, W., 2011. Energy consumption–economic growth and Policy 32, 47–54.
carbon dioxide emissions in China. Energy Policy 39, 568–574. Soytas, U., Sari, R., 2003. Energy consumption and GDP: causality relationship in G-7
Liddle, B., Lung, S., 2014. The long run causal relationship between transport energy con- countries and emerging markets. Energy Econ. 25, 33–37.
sumption and GDP: evidence from heterogeneous panel methods robust to cross- Soytas, U., Sari, R., 2007. The relationship between energy and production: evidence from
sectional dependence. Econ. Lett. 121, 524–527. Turkish manufacturing industry. Energy Econ. 29, 1151–1165.
Maddala, G.S., Wu, S., 1999. A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and a Soytas, U., Sari, R., 2009. Energy consumption, economic growth, and carbon emissions:
new simple test. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 631–652 (special issue). challenges faced by an EU candidate member. Ecol. Econ. 68, 1667–1675.
Mahadevan, R., Asafu-Adjaye, J., 2007. Energy consumption, economic growth and prices: Squalli, J., 2007. Electricity consumption and economic growth: bounds and causality
a reassessment using panel VECM for developed and developing countries. Energy analyses for OPEC members. Energy Econ. 29, 1192–1205.
Policy 35, 2481–2490. Stern, D.I., 1993. Energy and economic growth in the USA. A multivariate approach. Ener-
Masih, A., Masih, R., 1996. Energy consumption and real income temporal causality, re- gy Econ. 15, 137–150.
sults for a multi-country study based on cointegration and error-correction tech- Swamy, P.A.V., 1970. Efficient inference in a random coefficient regression model.
niques. Energy Econ. 18, 165–183. Econometrica 38, 311–323.
Mehrara, M., 2007. Energy–GDP relationship for oil-exporting countries: Iran, Kuwait and Urbain, J., Westerlund, J., 2006. Spurious regression in nonstationary panels with cross
Saudi Arabia. OPEC Rev. 31, 1–16. unit cointegration. METEOR Research Memorandum No. 057.
Moon, H.R., Perron, B., 2004. Testing for a unit root in panels with dynamic factors. J. Econ. Westerlund, J., 2007. Testing for error correction in panel data. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 69,
122, 81–126. 709–748.
Morimoto, R., Hope, C., 2004. The impact of electricity supply on economic growth in Sri Westerlund, J., Edgerton, D.L., 2008. A simple test for cointegration in dependent panels
Lanka. Energy Econ. 26, 77–85. with structural breaks. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 70, 665–704.
Nadiri, M.I., Purcha, I., 1996. Estimation of depreciation rate of physical and R&D capital in Wu, Q.S., Chen, L., Zhang, Y.T., 2008. Retesting the Granger causality between energy con-
the U.S. total manufacturing sector. Econ. Inq. 34, 43–56. sumption and GDP in China: based on the provincial panel data analysis. J. Quant.
Narayan, P.K., Smyth, R., 2005. Electricity consumption, employment and real income in Tech. Econ. 6, 27–40.
Australia evidence from multivariate Granger causality tests. Energy Policy 33, Yang, H.Y., 2000. A note on the causal relationship between energy and GDP in Taiwan.
1109–1116. Energy Econ. 22, 309–317.
Narayan, P.K., Smyth, R., 2008. Energy consumption and real GDP in G7 countries: new ev- Yu, E.S.H., Choi, J.Y., 1985. The causal relationship between energy and GNP: an interna-
idence from panel cointegration with structural breaks. Energy Econ. 30, 2331–2341. tional comparison. J. Energy Dev. 10, 249–272.
Nehru, V., Dhareshwar, A., 1993. A new database on physical capital stock: sources, meth- Yu, E.S.H., Hwang, B.K., 1984. The relationship between energy and GNP: further results.
odology and results. Revista de Analisis Economica 8, 37–59. Energy Econ. 6, 186–190.
Oh, W., Lee, K., 2004. Causal relationship between energy consumption and GDP: the case Yu, E.S.H., Jin, J.C., 1992. Cointegration tests of energy consumption, income and employ-
of Korea 1970–1999. Energy Econ. 26, 51–59. ment. Resour. Energy 14, 259–266.
Ozturk, I., 2010. A literature survey on energy–growth nexus. Energy Policy 38, 340–349. Yu, Q.U., Meng, W.D., 2008. The relationship between energy consumption and Chinese
Ozturk, I., Aslan, A., Kalyoncu, H., 2010. Energy consumption and economic growth rela- economic growth based on the panel data. Syst. Eng. 26, 68–72.
tionship: evidence from panel data for low and middle income countries. Energy Pol- Yuan, J., Kang, J.-G., Zhao, C., Hu, Z., 2008. Energy consumption and economic growth: ev-
icy 38, 4422–4428. idence from China at both aggregated and disaggregated levels. Energy Econ. 30,
Parente, S.L., Prescott, E.C., 1994. Barriers to technology adoption and development. J. 3077–3094.
Polit. Econ. 102, 298–321. Zachariadis, T., 2007. Exploring the relationship between energy use and economic
Paul, S., Bhattacharya, R.N., 2004. Causality between energy consumption and economic growth with bivariate model: new evidence from G-7 countries. Energy Econ. 29,
growth in India: a note on conflicting results. Energy Econ. 26, 977–983. 1233–1253.
Paul, B.P., Salahuddin, S., 2010. Energy and output dynamics in Bangladesh. Energy Econ. Zachariadis, T., Pashouortidou, N., 2007. An empirical analysis of electricity consumption
33, 480–487. in Cyprus. Energy Econ. 29, 183–198.
Payne, J.E., 2009. On the dynamics of energy consumption and output in the US. Appl. En- Zamani, M., 2007. Energy consumption and economic activities in Iran. Energy Econ. 29
ergy 86, 575–577. (6), 1135–1140.
Perron, P., 1989. The great crash, the oil price shock, and the unit root hypothesis. Zhang, X.P., Cheng, X.M., 2009. Energy consumption, carbon emissions, and economic
Econometrica 57 (6), 1361–1401. growth in China. Ecol. Econ. 68, 2706–2712.

You might also like