You are on page 1of 5

Economic History and Economics

Author(s): Robert M. Solow


Source: The American Economic Review , May, 1985, Vol. 75, No. 2, Papers and
Proceedings of the Ninety-Seventh Annual Meeting of the American Economic
Association (May, 1985), pp. 328-331
Published by: American Economic Association

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1805620

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic
Review

This content downloaded from


103.221.254.68 on Thu, 06 Jul 2023 06:33:25 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Economic History and Economics

By ROBERT M. SOLOW*

I have in the back of my mind a picture of experiments on its smaller parts, or even
the sort of discipline economics ought to be observe them in isolation, the classical hard-
-or at least the sort of discipline I wish it science devices for discriminating between
were. If economics were practiced in that competing hypotheses are closed to us. The
way there would be nothing problematical main alternative device is the statistical anal-
about its reciprocal relationship with eco- ysis of historical time-series. But then another
nomic history. It would be pretty clear what difficulty arises. The competing hypotheses
it is that economic theory offers to economic are themselves complex and subtle. We know
history and what economic history offers to before we start that all of them, or at least
economic theory. I will try to describe what I many of them, are capable of fitting the data
mean below. in a gross sort of way. Then, in order to
For better or worse, however, economics make more refined distinctions, we need long
has gone down a different path, not the one I time-series observed under stationary condi-
have in mind. One consequence, not the most tions.
important one, but the one that matters for Unfortunately, however, economics is a
this discussion, is that economic theory learns social science. It is subject to Damon
nothing from economic history, and eco- Runyon's Law that nothing between human
nomic history is as much corrupted as en- beings is more than three to one. To express
riched by economic theory. I will come to the point more formally, much of what we
that, too, later on. observe cannot be treated as the realization
You will notice that I am using strong of a stationary stochastic process without
language. I am prepared to admit right away straining credulity. Moreover, all narrowly
that I may be dead wrong in my judgements. economic activity is embedded in a web of
But there is no point in pussyfooting. Blunt- social institutions, customs, beliefs, and atti-
ness may lead to an interesting discussion. tudes. Concrete outcomes are indubitably
After all, no one would remember the old affected by these background factors, some
German Historical School if it were not for of which change slowly and gradually, others
the famous Methodenstreit. Actually, no one erratically. As soon as time-series get long
remembers them anyway. (There must be a enough to offer hope of discriminating among
lesson in that.) complex hypotheses, the likelihood that they
To get right down to it, I suspect that the remain stationary dwindles away, and the
attempt to construct economics as an axiom- noise level gets correspondingly high. Under
atically based hard science is doomed to fail. these circumstances, a little cleverness and
There are many partially overlapping reasons persistence can get you almost any result you
for believing this; but since that is not the want. I think that is why so few econometri-
topic under discussion today, I do not have cians have ever been forced by the facts to
to lay them out in an orderly way. I hope the abandon a firmly held belief. Indeed, some
following hodgepodge will convey what I of Fortune's favorites have been known to
mean. write scores of empirical articles without once
A modern economy is a very complicated feeling obliged to report a result that con-
system. Since we cannot conduct controlled tradicts their prior prejudices.
If I am anywhere near right about this, the
interests of scientific economics would be
better served by a more modest approach.
*Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute There is enough for us to do without pre-
of Technology, Cambridge, MA 02139. tending to a degree of completeness and
328

This content downloaded from


103.221.254.68 on Thu, 06 Jul 2023 06:33:25 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 75 NO. 2 ECONOMIC HISTORY 329

precision which we cannot deliver. To my economist is conscious of the fact that differ-
way of thinking, the true functions of ana- ent social contexts may call for different
lytical economics are best described infor- background assumptions and therefore for
mally: to organize our necessarily incomplete different models.
perceptions about the economy, to see con- The other direction of influence, what eco-
nections that the untutored eye would miss, nomic history offers to that kind of economic
to tell plausible- sometimes even convincing theory, is more interesting. If the proper
-causal stories with the help of a few central choice of a model depends on the institu-
principles, and to make rough quantitative tional context-and it should-then eco-
judgments about the consequences of eco- nomic history performs the nice function of
nomic policy and other exogenous events. In widening the range of observation available
this scheme of things, the end product of to the theorist. Economic theory can only
economic analysis is likely to be a collection gain from being taught something about the
of models contingent on society's circum- range of possibilities in human societies. Few
stances-on the historical context, you might things should be more interesting to a civi-
say-and not a single monolithic model for lized economic theorist than the opportu-
all seasons. nity to observe the interplay between social
I hope no one here will think that this institutions and economic behavior over time
low-key view of the nature of analytical and place.
economies is a license for loose thinking. I am going to illustrate by referring to the
Logical rigor is just as important in this work of W. H. B. Court, not merely because
scheme of things as it is in the more self-con- his book The Rise of the Midland Industries
sciously scientific one. The same goes for was on A. P. Usher's reading list when I took
econometric depth and sophistication, maybe his course in the late 1940's. I choose Court
even more so. I mentioned "rough" quantita- for no better reason than that I happened to
tive judgment a moment ago, but that was run across an obituary article about him in
only to suggest that the best attainable, in the Proceedings of the British Academy for
macroeconomics anyway, is not likely to be 1982. (Since Court died in 1971, Fate did
precise, if we are honest with ourselves and seem to be playing a hand.)
others. It would be a useful principle that Here, for instance, is an excerpt from
economists should actually believe the em- Court's volume on Coal in the U.K.'s official
pirical assertions they make. That would re- history of World War II.
quire more discipline than most of us now
exhibit, when many empirical papers seem Observers who found the conduct of
more like virtuoso finger exercises than any- the mineworkers puzzling assumed that,
in the normal way, a man who finds
thing else. The case I am trying to make
himself faced with the possibilities of
concerns the scope and ambitions of eco-
higher earnings will be prepared to put
nomic model building, not the intellectual
out extra effort to obtain them. An
and technical standards of model building. assumption about the conduct of an
I claimed earlier that the natural relation individual is as a rule, however, also an
between economics and economic history assumption of some sort about the
would be clear and straightforward if only society in which he lives and of which
economics were practiced in the fashion I he is a member. The individual's de-
have just sketched. Now I had better say mand for income, his views upon the
what I meant. If economists set themselves getting and spending of money, are
usually formed by the part of society
the task of modeling particular contingent
which he is most in touch with. For
social circumstances, with some sensitivity to
most men the social code, whatever it
context, it seems to me that they would may be in their time and place, is
provide exactly the interpretive help an eco- something which they accept as given
nomic historian needs. That kind of model is and take over with little demur or ques-
directly applicable in organizing a historical tioning. Before one can assume that a
narrative, the more so to the extent that the demand for additional income existed

This content downloaded from


103.221.254.68 on Thu, 06 Jul 2023 06:33:25 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
330 A EA PA PERS A ND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1985

on the coalfields and could easily trans- will have maximized a familiar-looking pres-
late itself into extra work, one has to ent-value integral, made a few familiar log-
ask whether the mining community had linear approximations, and run the oblig-
those standards or those habits. If it atory familiar regression. The familiar
did not, and if it was unable to develop
coefficients will be poorly determined, but
them in a short time, then even a rapid
about one-twentieth of them will be signifi-
rise of wage rates might bring about no
appreciable change in the working cant at the 5 percent level, and the other
habits of the industry. nineteen do not have to be published. With a
little judicious selection here and there, it
will turn out that the data are just barely
In his own methodological writing, Court consistent with your thesis adviser's hypothe-
made the point explicitly that men "living as sis that money is neutral (or nonneutral, take
they do in different societies ... make their your choice) everywhere and always, modulo
decisions according to different schemes of an information asymmetry, any old informa-
values and according to the habits and struc- tion asymmetry, don't worry, you'll think of
tures of the society they find themselves liv- one.
ing in." Therefore an economic historian All right, so I exaggerate. You will recog-
should be an "observer and re-creator of the nize the kernel of truth. We are socialized to
codes, loyalties and organizations which men the belief that there is one true model and
create and which are just as real to them as that it can be discovered or imposed if only
physical conditions." Add to that a com- you will make the proper assumptions and
mand over two-stage least squares and you impute validity to econometric results that
have the kind of economic historian from are transparently lacking in power.
whom theorists have most to learn, if only Of course there are holdouts against this
they are willing to try. I have naturally lit on routine, bless their hearts.
this passage about the labor market because As I inspect current work in economic
that is the branch of theory I happen to be history, I have the sinking feeling that a lot
engaged in right now, but no doubt the of it looks exactly like the kind of economic
thought would apply equally well to con- analysis I have just finished caricaturing: the
sumer spending or rivalry among firms. I same integrals, the same regressions, the same
must promise myself, before I lecture again substitution of t-ratios for thought. Apart
on wage bargaining, to ask my students to from anything else, it is no fun reading the
read the chapters on "The Wage Bargain" stuff any more. Far from offering the eco-
and "The Concept of the Minimum" in nomic theorist a widened range of percep-
Court's British Economic History, 1870- tions, this sort of economic history gives
1914: Commentary and Documents. I wonder back to the theorist the same routine gruel
what they will make of it. that the economic theorist gives to the
So much for the normative. If you read the historian. Why should I believe, when it is
same journals I do, you may have noticed applied to thin eighteenth-century data,
that modern economics has an ambition and something that carries no conviction when it
style rather different from those I have been is done with more ample twentieth-century
advocating. My impression is that the best data?
and brightest in the profession proceed as if The situation reminds me of a story I once
economics is the physics of society. There is heard told by an anthropologist who had
a single universally valid model of the world. spent some months recording the myths and
It only needs to be applied. You could drop legends of a group of Apache in New Mexico.
a modern economist from a time machine- a One night, just before she was scheduled to
helicopter, maybe, like the one that drops the end her field work and depart, the Indians
money-at any time, in any place, along said to her: We have been telling you our
with his or her personal computer; he or she legends all these months-why don't you tell
could set up in business without even us one of yours? The anthropologist thought
bothering to ask what time and which place. fast and then responded brilliantly by telling
In a little while, the up-to-date economist the Indians a version of the story of Beowulf.

This content downloaded from


103.221.254.68 on Thu, 06 Jul 2023 06:33:25 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VIOL. 75 NO. 2 ECONOMIC HISTORY 331

Years later she picked up a copy of an In that case, we need a different approach.
anthropological journal and found in the The function of the economist in this ap-
table of contents an article entitled "On the proach is still to make models and test them
Occurrence of a Beowulf-like legend among as best one can, but the models are more
the such-and-such Apache." If economic his- likely to be partial in scope and limited in
tory turns into something that could be de- applicability. "Testing" will have to be less
scribed as "The Occurrence of an Overlap- mechanical and more opportunistic, encom-
ping-Generations-like Legend among the passing a broader collection of techniques.
Seventeenth-Century Neapolitans," then we One will have to recognize that the validity
are at the point where economics has nothing of an economic model may depend on the
to learn from economic history but the bad social context. What is here today may be
habits it has taught to economic history. gone tomorrow, or, if not tomorrow, then in
Let me recapitulate. If the project of turn- ten or twenty years' time. In this dispensa-
ing economics into a hard science could suc- tion there is a clear and productive division
ceed, it would surely be worth doing. No of labor between the economist and the eco-
doubt some of us should keep trying. If it nomic historian. The economist is concerned
did succeed, then there would be no dif- with making and testing models of the eco-
ference between economics and economic nomic world as it now is, or as we think it is.
history other than the source of data, no The economic historian can ask whether this
more than there is a difference between the or that story rings true when applied in
study of astronomical events taking place earlier times or other places, and, if not, why
now and those that took place in the Middle not. So the economic historian can use the
Ages. In this dispensation an economic tools provided by the economist but will
historian is merely an economist with a high need, in addition, the ability to imagine how
tolerance for dust or-what is rarer these things might have been before they became
days-a working knowledge of a foreign lan- as they now are. These are the sensitiv-
guage. ities Court spoke of in the passage quoted
There are, however, some reasons for pes- above. I take it, naively perhaps, that they
simism about the project. Hard sciences represent the comparative advantage of the
dealing with complex systems-but possibly historian.
less complex than the U.S. economy-like In return, economic history can offer the
the hydrogen atom or the optic nerve seem economist a sense of the variety and flexibil-
to succeed because they can isolate, they can ity of social arrangements and thus, in par-
experiment, and they can make repeated ob- ticular, a shot at understanding a little better
servations under controlled conditions. Other the interaction of economic behavior and
sciences, like astronomy, succeed because other social institutions. That strikes me as a
they can make long series of observations meaningful division of labor. It was once
under natural but essentially stationary con- suggested-by my kind of economist-that
ditions, and because the forces being studied the division of labor is limited by the extent
are not swamped by noise. Neither of these of the market. Perhaps what I have just been
roads to success is open to economists. doing can be thought of as marketing.

This content downloaded from


103.221.254.68 on Thu, 06 Jul 2023 06:33:25 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like