You are on page 1of 3

Potential game

In game theory, a game is said to be a potential game if the incentive of all players to change their strategy can be expressed using a single
global function called the potential function. The concept originated in a 1996 paper by Dov Monderer and Lloyd Shapley.[1]

The properties of several types of potential games have since been studied. Games can be either ordinal or cardinal potential games. In
cardinal games, the difference in individual payoffs for each player from individually changing one's strategy, other things equal, has to
have the same value as the difference in values for the potential function. In ordinal games, only the signs of the differences have to be the
same.

The potential function is a useful tool to analyze equilibrium properties of games, since the incentives of all players are mapped into one
function, and the set of pure Nash equilibria can be found by locating the local optima of the potential function. Convergence and finite-
time convergence of an iterated game towards a Nash equilibrium can also be understood by studying the potential function.

Potential games can be studied as repeated games with state so that every round played has a direct consequence on game's state in the
next round.[2] This approach has applications in distributed control such as distributed resource allocation, where players without a central
correlation mechanism can cooperate to achieve a globally optimal resource distribution.

Definition
We will define some notation required for the definition. Let be the number of players, the set of action profiles over the action sets
of each player and be the payoff function.

Given a game , a function is called:

an exact potential function if ,

That is: when player switches from action to action , the change in the potential equals the change in
the utility of that player.

a weighted potential function if there is a vector such that ,

That is: when a player switches action, the change in


equals the change in the player's utility, times a positive player-specific weight. Every exact PF is a weighted PF
with wi=1 for all i.

an ordinal potential function if ,

That is: when a player switches action, the sign of


the change in equals the sign of the change in the player's utility, whereas the magnitude of change may differ.
Every weighted PF is an ordinal PF.

a generalized ordinal potential function if ,

That is: when a player switches action, if the


player's utility increases, then the potential increases (but the opposite is not necessarily true). Every ordinal PF
is a generalized-ordinal PF.

a best-response potential function if ,

where is the best action for player given .

A simple example
In a 2-player, 2-action game with externalities, individual players' payoffs are given by the function u i(a i, a j) = b i a i + w a i a j, where
ai is players i's action, aj is the opponent's action, and w is a positive externality from choosing the same action. The action choices are +1
and −1, as seen in the payoff matrix in Figure 1.
This game has a potential function P(a 1, a 2) = b 1 a 1 + b 2 a 2 + w a 1 a 2.

If player 1 moves from −1 to +1, the payoff difference is Δu 1 = u 1(+1, a 2) – u 1(–1, a 2) = 2 b 1 + 2 w a 2.

The change in potential is


ΔP = P(+1, a2) – P(–1, a2) = (b1 + b2 a2 + w a2) – (–b1 + b2 a2 – w a2) = 2 b1 + 2 w a2 = Δu1.

The solution for player 2 is equivalent. Using numerical values b 1 = 2 , b 2 = −1 , w = 3 , this example transforms into a simple battle of
the sexes, as shown in Figure 2. The game has two pure Nash equilibria, (+1, +1) and (−1, −1). These are also the local maxima of the
potential function (Figure 3). The only stochastically stable equilibrium is (+1, +1), the global maximum of the potential function.

+1 –1 +1 –1 +1 –1

+1 +b1+w, +b2+w +b1–w, –b2–w +1 5, 2 –1, –2 +1 4 0

–1 –b1–w, +b2–w –b1+w, –b2+w –1 –5, –4 1, 4 –1 –6 2

Fig. 1: Potential game example Fig. 2: Battle of the sexes Fig. 3: Battle of the sexes
(payoffs) (potentials)

A 2-player, 2-action game cannot be a potential game unless

Potential games and congestion games


Exact potential games are equivalent to congestion games: Rosenthal[3] proved that every congestion game has an exact potential;
Monderer and Shapley[1] proved the opposite direction: every game with an exact potential function is a congestion game.

Potential games and improvement paths


An improvement path (also called Nash dynamics) is a sequence of strategy-vectors, in which each vector is attained from the previous
vector by a single player switching his strategy to a strategy that strictly increases his utility. If a game has a generalized-ordinal-potential
function , then is strictly increasing in every improvement path, so every improvement path is acyclic. If, in addition, the game has
finitely many strategies, then every improvement path must be finite. This property is called the finite improvement property (FIP). We
have just proved that every finite generalized-ordinal-potential game has the FIP. The opposite is also true: every finite game has the FIP
has a generalized-ordinal-potential function.[4] The terminal state in every finite improvement path is a Nash equilibrium, so FIP implies
the existence of a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. Moreover, it implies that a Nash equlibrium can be computed by a distributed process, in
which each agent only has to improve his own strategy.

A best-response path is a special case of an improvement path, in which each vector is attained from the previous vector by a single
player switching his strategy to a best-response strategy. The property that every best-response path is finite is called the finite best-
response property (FBRP). FBRP is weaker than FIP, and it still implies the existence of a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. It also implies
that a Nash equlibrium can be computed by a distributed process, but the computational burden on the agents is higher than with FIP, since
they have to compute a best-response.

An even weaker property is weak-acyclicity (WA).[5] It means that, for any initial strategy-vector, there exists a finite best-response path
starting at that vector. Weak-acyclicity is not sufficient for existence of a potential function (since some improvement-paths may be cyclic),
but it is sufficient for the existence of pure-strategy Nash equilibirum. It implies that a Nash equilibrium can be computed almost-surely by
a stochastic distributed process, in which at each point, a player is chosen at random, and this player chooses a best-strategy at random. [4]

See also
Congestion game
Econophysics
A characterization of ordinal potential games.[6]

References
1. Monderer, Dov; Shapley, Lloyd (1996). "Potential Games". Games and Economic Behavior. 14: 124–143.
doi:10.1006/game.1996.0044 (https://doi.org/10.1006%2Fgame.1996.0044).
2. Marden, J., (2012) State based potential games http://ecee.colorado.edu/marden/files/state-based-games.pdf
3. Rosenthal, Robert W. (1973), "A class of games possessing pure-strategy Nash equilibria", International Journal of
Game Theory, 2: 65–67, doi:10.1007/BF01737559 (https://doi.org/10.1007%2FBF01737559), MR 0319584 (https://math
scinet.ams.org/mathscinet-getitem?mr=0319584), S2CID 121904640 (https://api.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:121904
640).
4. Milchtaich, Igal (1996-03-01). "Congestion Games with Player-Specific Payoff Functions" (https://www.sciencedirect.co
m/science/article/pii/S0899825696900275). Games and Economic Behavior. 13 (1): 111–124.
doi:10.1006/game.1996.0027 (https://doi.org/10.1006%2Fgame.1996.0027). ISSN 0899-8256 (https://www.worldcat.org/
issn/0899-8256).
5. Young, H. Peyton (1993). "The Evolution of Conventions" (https://www.jstor.org/stable/2951778). Econometrica. 61 (1):
57–84. doi:10.2307/2951778 (https://doi.org/10.2307%2F2951778). ISSN 0012-9682 (https://www.worldcat.org/issn/001
2-9682). JSTOR 2951778 (https://www.jstor.org/stable/2951778).
6. Voorneveld, Mark; Norde, Henk (1997-05-01). "A Characterization of Ordinal Potential Games" (https://www.sciencedire
ct.com/science/article/pii/S0899825697905546). Games and Economic Behavior. 19 (2): 235–242.
doi:10.1006/game.1997.0554 (https://doi.org/10.1006%2Fgame.1997.0554). ISSN 0899-8256 (https://www.worldcat.org/
issn/0899-8256). S2CID 122795041 (https://api.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:122795041).

External links
Lecture notes of Yishay Mansour about Potential and congestion games (http://www.math.tau.ac.il/~mansour/course_ga
mes/scribe/lecture6.pdf)
Section 19 in: Vazirani, Vijay V.; Nisan, Noam; Roughgarden, Tim; Tardos, Éva (2007). Algorithmic Game Theory (http://
www.cs.cmu.edu/~sandholm/cs15-892F13/algorithmic-game-theory.pdf) (PDF). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press. ISBN 0-521-87282-0.
Non technical exposition by Huw Dixon of the inevitability of collusion Chapter 8, Donut world and the duopoly
archipelago (http://www.huwdixon.org/SurfingEconomics/chapter8.pdf),Surfing Economics (http://www.huwdixon.org/Sur
fingEconomics/index.html).

Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Potential_game&oldid=1162340964"

You might also like