You are on page 1of 17

CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS: IDENTIFYING INCREASING

MARGINAL COST

JAEBIN AHN and ALEXANDER F. MCQUOID∗

This study revisits a central assumption of standard trade models: constant marginal
cost technology. The presence of increasing marginal costs for exporters introduces
significant market interdependence across borders missing from traditional models
of international trade that rely on constant marginal cost technology. Such market
interdependence represents an additional channel through which local shocks are
transmitted globally. To identify increasing marginal cost at the level of the firm, we
build in flexible production assumptions that nest increasing, decreasing, and constant
marginal cost technology to an otherwise standard international trade model. We
derive an estimating equation that can be taken directly to the data. Our structural
equation explicitly guides our inference on the shape of the marginal cost curve from
estimated coefficients. The results suggest that increasing marginal cost is predominant
at the firm level. Moreover, utilizing plant-level information on physical and financial
capacity constraints, we find that the degree of increasing marginal cost is significantly
exacerbated by both types of constraints. The evidence suggests that access to larger
markets through greater international integration may not have the expected welfare
gains typically predicted in standard models. (JEL F12, F14)

I. INTRODUCTION consequences, these models may be ignoring


important features.
Standard intermediate microeconomics The presence of increasing marginal cost
courses teach that short-run marginal cost is
among exporters matters as it represents an
increasing with output due to fixed factors in
production. In practice, most theory models additional channel through which shocks are
in international trade assume that firms face transmitted globally. That is, capacity con-
constant marginal cost. To the extent that the strained exporters selling in a foreign country
model is used to study relatively short-run react to purely foreign shocks by adjusting
behavior locally, and the response is larger when
∗ This paper is a substantially revised version of the paper
foreign shocks are larger or when exporters are
previously circulated under the title “Capacity Constrained
more highly constrained. While previous work
Exporters: Micro Evidence and Macro Implications.” We has shown that financial constraints are important
thank Don Davis, Amit Khandelwal, Eric Verhoogen, and for selection into export markets, and for export
Jon Vogel for early comments on the project. We are grate-
ful to George Akerlof, Martin D.D. Evans, Ina Simonovska, sales levels, we show that physical and financial
Catherine Thomas, and Hâle Utar as well as seminar partic- constraints are important sources of increasing
ipants at Columbia, IMF, Florida International, 2012 RMET marginal cost for firms. The presence of increas-
Conference at UBC, 2012 Rimini Conference in Economics
and Finance, Spring 2013 MIEG Conference, 10th IIOC ing marginal costs for capacity constrained
meeting, Advances in International Trade Workshop 2014 at exporters introduces market interdependence
Georgia Tech, and the 2015 WEAI Annual Conference for across borders missing from traditional models
helpful comments and discussions. The views expressed in
this paper are those of the authors and should not be attributed
to the International Monetary Fund, its Executive Board, or
its management. ABBREVIATIONS
Ahn: Economist, Research Department, International Mone- BPS: Indonesia Central Bureau of Statistics
tary Fund, Washington, DC 20431. Phone 202-623-5998,
Fax 202-623-4661, E-mail jahn@imf.org CPI: Consumer Price Index
McQuoid: Assistant Professor, Economics Department, GDP: Gross Domestic Product
United States Naval Academy, Annapolis, MD 21402. TFP: Total Factor Productivity
Phone 410-293-6893, Fax 410-293-6899, E-mail WTO: World Trade Organization
mcquoid@usna.edu

1175
Economic Inquiry doi:10.1111/ecin.12429
(ISSN 0095-2583) Online Early publication February 28, 2017
Vol. 55, No. 3, July 2017, 1175–1191 © 2017 Western Economic Association International
1176 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

of international trade that rely on constant using properties of the structural model, we show
marginal cost technology. that the key estimated coefficient is only consis-
Utilizing a flexible production structure tent with increasing marginal cost. Our approach
that nests increasing, decreasing, and constant may understate the true magnitude of increasing
marginal cost, we derive the appropriate esti- marginal cost, but provides a lower bound on the
mating equation from an otherwise standard scope and scale of increasing marginal cost.
international trade model. The structural spec- We estimate key cost parameters using
ification is then taken directly to the data, and Indonesian plant-level data, and find robust
provides direct evidence on the presence of support for the view that exporting firms are
increasing marginal cost as a first-order fea- operating with increasing marginal cost tech-
ture of the data. We further exploit plant-level nology. A particularly valuable feature of our
information on physical and financial capac- Indonesian data is that they record plant-level
ity constraints, which is rarely available in capacity utilization over time, which is not
other datasets, and confirm that both physical available in most plant-level data. We utilize this
and financial capacity constraints are primary information to construct measures of physical
sources of increasing marginal cost. capacity constraints that are plant-specific and
It is important to highlight a distinction vary over time. Combined with standard mea-
between capacity constraints that are a direct sures of financial constraints from the corporate
consequence of (optimal) firm investment deci- finance literature, we show that physical and
sions, and capacity constraints that are due to financial capacity constraints are the primary
factors beyond the direct control of the firm. In sources of increasing marginal cost for firms.
the presence of demand uncertainty, firms may Increasing marginal cost is a first-order feature
optimally choose their ex ante capacity level, of the data among exporters. Our estimates and
which ex post may be binding after the realiza- conclusions are robust to alternative measures
tion of demand shocks. There is little for policy of financial and physical capacity constraints, as
to do in this regard since capacity level is chosen well as alternative measures of productivity.
optimally given available information. However, New international trade theory is grounded
financial constraints, which are often beyond the in the idea that access to export markets allows
control of the firm, limit the ability of firms to firms to take advantage of increasing returns
choose the optimal level of capacity, generating to scale to production. The evidence presented
scope for policy interventions. Our findings here suggests that access to larger markets
on the importance of financial constraints in through greater international integration may
addition to physical capacity constraints are not have the expected welfare gains typically
especially noteworthy from this perspective. predicted in these models. For one thing, costly
Our study begins from the notion that firms adjustment of physical capacity may delay
with increasing marginal cost face a trade-off and reduce the realization of gains from trade.
between domestic and export sales—when a firm Perhaps more troubling, gains from trade may
alters export sales in response to an external be permanently delayed if financially con-
demand shock, it will incur a change in marginal strained firms are unable to invest sufficiently in
cost, which in turn makes it optimal for the production capacity.
firm to alter domestic sales. Firms with constant
marginal cost, on the other hand, have no incen-
A. Related Literature
tive to alter domestic sales in response to an
export demand shock since changing production The point of departure for this paper comes
to meet demand abroad has no effect on the level from the standard models of international trade
of marginal cost. that have followed from Krugman (1979, 1980)
Our formal theoretical structure starts with and Melitz (2003). The key feature of those
demand side assumptions that are standard in models, which we focus on directly here, is
international trade theory, while our production the assumption of constant marginal cost, which
side is flexible enough to nest increasing, decreas- allows domestic and foreign markets to be treated
ing, or constant marginal cost within a single as independent markets in the analysis.
parameter. We derive our estimating equation There is an emerging literature that explores
accordingly, which makes explicit that the omit- the relationship between domestic and export
ted variable bias is likely to be present when sales as evidence for the presence of increas-
estimating the primary specification. However, ing marginal cost. In the management literature,
AHN & MCQUOID: CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS 1177

Ghemawat and Mitchell (2011) document the This paper is also close to the literature that
interrelationship between foreign and domestic studies credit constraints and international trade.
sales for a single large producer of beer, and Previous studies focus on export fixed costs
conclude that sales growth in domestic markets financing, and thus extensive margin effects
often crowds out sales in foreign markets (and of credit constraints (Chaney 2016; Manova
vice versa). 2013). Indeed, there is abundant evidence that
In the economics literature, Blum, Claro, and credit constrained firms are less likely to become
Horstmann (2013) find a negative correlation exporters (Muûls 2008, among others). Our
between domestic and export sales growth from paper complements this literature by exploring
Chilean firm-level data, which they attribute to the intensive margin, and showing that credit
physical capacity constraints. Soderbery (2014) constraints affect incumbent exporters as well
finds a similar pattern when looking at firm-level through the marginal cost channel. This is also
data from Thailand, and uses a similar measure of consistent with the trade finance literature that
capacity utilization as here to document the exis- studies intensive margin adjustments during the
tence of physically constrained firms. Berman, great trade collapse (e.g., Ahn 2011; Paravisini
Berthou, and Héricourt (2015) also find a similar et al. 2015). Recent work by Feenstra, Li, and Yu
pattern from French firm-level data, but find that (2014) suggests that credit constraints endoge-
the pattern is reversed when they instrument for nously tighten as exports become a larger share
export sales growth using information on des- of a firm’s revenue, which would amplify the
tination markets. They conjecture that capacity effect discussed here.
constraints might make foreign and domestic The remainder of the paper proceeds as fol-
market sales substitutes, while unconstrained lows: Section II formally derives the estimating
firms might see foreign and domestic sales as equation. Section III discusses our identifi-
complements. Based on a similar observation cation strategy and lays out possible sources
from French firms covered in the Amadeus driving increasing marginal cost. Section IV
database, Vannoorenberghe (2012) further describes the firm-level dataset from Indone-
explores firm-level output volatility, and con- sia used in this paper, while Section V reports
the empirical results. Section VI concludes
cludes that the constant marginal cost assumption
the paper.
may be inappropriate. Nguyen and Schaur (2011)
also study the effects of increasing marginal
cost on firm-level volatility using Danish II. ECONOMETRIC SPECIFICATION
firm-level data.
Our empirical approach resembles the strat- We extend the baseline model in the seminal
egy used in Fazzari et al. (1988). They start works on structural approaches to international
from the theoretical notion that, in the pres- trade (Aw, Roberts, and Xu 2011; Das, Roberts,
ence of imperfect financial markets, credit con- and Tybout 2007) by allowing for flexible
strained firms’ investment will be sensitive to marginal cost assumptions.1 There are two seg-
their cash flow. Higher cash-flow sensitivity of mented markets, domestic and export markets,
investment for credit constrained firms in the each of which is governed by a constant elasticity
data serves as supporting evidence for imperfect of substitution demand function. Specifically,
financial markets. In a similar vein, we draw out domestic demand faced by each firm i at time t is
the implications of different types of marginal given as:
cost for export and domestic sales, and find a (1) ( )−σ ( )1∕σ ( d )−1∕σ
negative relationship as evidence for increasing qdit = Φdt zdit pdit ⇐⇒ pdit = Φdt zdit qit
marginal cost. where σ > 0 is the elasticity of substitution
The main findings can serve as direct between goods. The aggregate demand level in
micro-evidence that justifies the modeling the domestic market at each time t, Φdt , deter-
strategy in several recent papers that con- mines the position of the demand curve common
sider decreasing returns to scale production to every firm, and zdit is an idiosyncratic domestic
or borrowing constraints to explain salient demand shifter.
features of new exporter dynamics (Kohn
et al. 2016; Rho and Rodrigue 2016; Ruhl and 1. Section A of Appendix S1 (Supporting Information)
Willis 2014) or patterns of foreign acquisitions provides an illustrative interpretation of the mathematical
(Spearot 2012). approach presented in this section.
1178 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

Similarly, firm-specific export demand curve Finally, substituting Equation (7) into
is given as: Equation (8) above and rearranging in logs, we
( ex )−σ reach the empirically implementable equation2
(2) qex ex ex
it = Φt zit pit ⇐⇒ (9)
( ) ( )−1∕σ ln qdit = α + β ln qex
pex ex ex 1∕σ
qex it + σ ln ωit + FEt + ηit ,
it = Φt zit it ,
( )
where Φex is the common aggregate export where α = σln ) − 1∕σ))
( d((σ
2
[ −d σ κln] τex , β =
t
demand level, and zex is an idiosyncratic −σκ, FEt = ln Φ(t )− σκln (Φt)∕Φex t , ( )and
it
export demand shifter. Firm-level domestic ηit = (1 − σκ) ln zdit − σln ϵit + σκln zex it
.
and export demand shifters, zdit and zex it
, are
exogenously drawn from a bivariate distribution.
In the presence of any import tariff imposed III. IDENTIFICATION STRATEGY
by foreign countries (i.e., τex > 1), the price
exporters receive (p∗,ex it
) will deviate from Of particular interest to us in Equation (9)
the price paid by foreign consumers (i.e., is the coefficient on export sales, β, which pro-
pex
it
= p∗,ex
it
τex ). vides information on the shape of the marginal
Domestic sales revenue and export sales rev- cost curve. In the case of constant marginal
enue are then expressed as: cost, κ = 0, which implies that β is zero as
( )1∕σ ( d )(σ−1)∕σ well. This confirms our intuition discussed
(3) ritd = pdit qdit = Φdt zdit qit , above: when firms face constant marginal cost,
foreign and domestic markets are treated inde-
and
(4) pendently, and there should be no observable
( ex ex )1∕σ ( ex )(σ−1)∕σ relationship between foreign and domestic sales
ritex = p∗,ex
it
qex
it = Φt zit qit ∕τex , once all relevant factors are accounted for in
from domestic and export market demand func- the data.
tion in Equations (1) and (2), respectively. With increasing marginal cost, κ > 0, which
Marginal cost is a function of firm-specific in turn implies that β < 0. Estimating a nega-
productivity level, ωit , and possibly of total tive relationship between domestic and foreign
output level: sales, after properly accounting for other influ-
( )( )κ ences, implies that firms are facing increasing
(5) MCit = 1∕ωit qdit + qex it , marginal costs in production, and domestic and
where κ is a parameter that governs the type of foreign markets are effectively interdependent
marginal cost (i.e., constant marginal cost when markets. In practice, when the baseline specifi-
κ = 0, increasing marginal cost when κ > 0, and cation is taken to the data, the estimated coeffi-
decreasing marginal cost when κ < 0). cient of β will be biased since foreign demand
The optimality condition that equates shocks are not directly observable; our combined
marginal cost with marginal revenue in each error term, ηit , includes
( )the foreign demand shock
market is given as: via the term, σκln zex it
, which is correlated with
export sales, ln qex it
. With constant marginal cost
(6) MRex d
it = MRit = MCit ϵit , (i.e., κ = 0), foreign demand shocks do not enter
into the specification, and there will be no bias,
where an (random) optimization error ϵit ,
possibly capturing unobserved productivity while with increasing marginal cost (i.e., κ > 0),
shocks, is taken into account. The first equal- the positive correlation between foreign demand
ity in Equation (6) (i.e., MRex = MRdit ) leads shocks term and export sales will bias the esti-
it mated coefficient of β upwards toward zero. In
to the following relation between export and
domestic sales: this particular case, however, it is assured that
[( d ex ) ( d ex )]
(7) qdit = qex ex σ
zit ∕zit Φt ∕Φt , ( [ ])
it (τ ) 2. In derivation, ln 1 + τσex Φdt zdit ∕Φex ex
t zit is approxi-
( σ [ d d ex ex ])
mated to ln τex Φt zit ∕Φt zit . This assumption is valid
while the second equality (i.e., MRdit = MCit ϵit )
only if the export-to-domestic sales ratio is sufficiently large
leads to the following relation: which occurs when variable trade costs are very high and/or
( )−1∕σ ( d d )1∕σ foreign demand is very small relative to domestic demand.
(8) ((σ − 1) ∕σ) qdit Φt zit When this condition does not hold, one would not be able
( )[ ( d )κ ] to separate out aggregate demand components from idiosyn-
= 1∕ωit ϵit qit + qex it . cratic demand components as in Equation (9), but this should
not affect the coefficient estimate on exports.
AHN & MCQUOID: CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS 1179

the magnitude of omitted variable bias is such (2011) noted, productivity growth measures are
that the sign of the estimated coefficient will less vulnerable to potential bias, so we take
never switch: even in the presence of omitted (yearly) differences of Equation (9) as the pre-
variable bias, the estimated coefficient of β will ferred specification:4
always be negative when firms face increasing
marginal cost.3 (10) Δln qdit = β Δln qex
it + σ Δln ωit
Exactly opposite is true for decreasing + ΔFEt + Δηit .
marginal cost. With decreasing marginal cost,
κ < 0, which in turn implies that β > 0. The Our baseline specification will also con-
negative correlation between foreign demand sider industry-year fixed effects and firm fixed
shocks term and export sales, will bias the effects. Industry-year fixed effects will, in addi-
estimated coefficient of β downwards toward tion to absorbing year-specific effects ΔFEt ,
zero. However, even in the presence of omitted capture any industry-year-specific effects such
variable bias, the estimated coefficient of β will as tariff changes or effective exchange rate
be always positive when firms face decreasing movements. Likewise, firm fixed effects will
marginal cost. pull out any constant time trends that are
Practically speaking, observing a negative firm-specific.
estimated coefficient β is only consistent with It is important to note that firm produc-
increasing marginal cost, and similarly for a tivity evolves over time. In fact, productivity
positive coefficient estimate with decreasing growth, negative or positive, will affect export
marginal cost. Furthermore, our approach will and domestic sales in the same direction. Even
tend to understate the presence of increas- with increasing marginal cost, if a firm’s pro-
ing marginal cost in cases where estimates ductivity improves, the marginal cost curve
are negative but not statistically signifi- will shift down, and the relevant marginal cost
cant because of upward bias associated with level decreases, possibly leading to observed
omitted variables. increases in both domestic and export sales
Despite the clear identification strategy, when in the face of increasing marginal cost and
it comes to the empirical implementation, the positive foreign demand shocks. Failure to
usual caveats apply. With potentially endogenous include productivity in Equation (10) would
variables, we are worried about potential bias bias the estimates against finding increasing
arising from simultaneity, omitted variables, marginal cost.
and measurement error. The ideal approach
would be to identify a credible instrument A. Physical and Financial Capacity Constraints
for the potentially endogenous variable. How-
ever, lacking such an instrument, we instead The last piece of our approach is to focus
rely on a combination of theory and empiri- on specific sources of increasing marginal cost
cal techniques to bound, isolate, and mitigate by controlling for capacity constraints explic-
these concerns. itly in addition to the analysis presented above.
A particularly common concern for most stud- The idea is that if it is increasing marginal costs
ies using firm-level survey data is the lack of that are driving the observed negative correlation
observable physical output data (i.e., qdit and qex ). between export sales and domestic sales, it is to
it
For this reason, we follow the standard, but be expected that this pattern will be stronger for
imperfect, solution to replace output with sales firms that are capacity constrained since these
(i.e., ritd and ritex ) deflated by an industry-level firms are facing steeper costs associated with
price index. This applies not only to domestic
and export sales directly but also to the produc- 4. There are two important implications—one economic
tivity estimation process as well. As De Loecker and the other for data—of using the yearly difference mea-
sure. First, it guides us to focus on short-run marginal cost
over an annual horizon, and thus limits our analysis to contin-
3. The ( omitted variable bias is uing exporters. Second, our export sales information comes
( ) ( )) expressed from the “percentage of total outputs” that is exported. To the
as σκ Cov ln qex it
, ln zexit
∕Var ln qex
it
, where
extent that the information is subject to reporting errors, it is
σκ = − β. Since ln qex it
includes the exogenous for- possible that such reporting errors generate a systemic neg-
eign demand shocks ln zex according to Equation (2), ative correlation between domestic and export sales. If we
( ) ( it )
Cov ln qexit
, ln zex
it
∕Var ln qex it
cannot be greater believe reporting errors are persistent over time at the firm-
than 1, and hence, the bias cannot be greater than |β| in level, growth measures will not be affected by such reporting
absolute term. errors (see, e.g., Vannoorenberghe 2012).
1180 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

expanding production. The corresponding spec- Furthermore, there are possible factors that
ification will be given as: may affect domestic demand and foreign demand
simultaneously, possibly in opposing ways. To
Δln qdit = β1 Δln qex
it + β2 (capacity constraint)it the extent that domestic demand shocks are neg-
+ β3 Δln qex atively correlated with export demand shocks,
it × (capacity constraint)it
negative trade-offs between export and domes-
+ σ Δln ωit + ΔFEt + Δηit . tic sales may arise even with constant marginal
The capacity constraint is a dummy variable cost curve, which could bias the empirical results
with 1 for constrained firms and 0 otherwise. towards our interpretation incorrectly. Although
Our main focus will be on the coefficient of literature on business cycle co-movement sug-
the interaction term, β3 . β3 < 0 implies that gests this is unlikely, it is also not entirely implau-
constrained firms show a stronger negative cor- sible.7 On the other hand, if they are positively
relation between export status and domestic correlated, it will bias the results against find-
sales growth, supporting the increasing marginal ing negative trade-offs. In our results below, we
cost story. present systematic evidence that our findings are
Although we allow for the possibility of not simply driven by such negatively correlated
decreasing marginal cost in our empirical anal- demand shocks.
ysis, since the evidence strongly suggests the Although our conceptual discussion is most
prevalence of increasing marginal costs in the applicable when a firm produces and sells an
data, we turn next to outlining some likely identical product for two segmented markets
sources of increasing marginal cost. (i.e., domestic and export markets), it is valid
in more general cases as well. For example,
multi-products firms even with a dedicated
B. Sources of Export-domestic Sales Trade-offs export market product line will face such trade-
The most common rationale for increasing offs by reallocating resources when they face
marginal cost is the presence of fixed factors capacity constraints.8
in production. For example, when a firm cannot Given these sources of export-domestic
freely change the capital stock in the short run, sales and guided by our theoretical apparatus,
the usual Cobb-Douglas production technology we next turn to estimation using Indonesian
leads to an increasing marginal cost (e.g., as plant-level data.
modeled in Blum, Claro, and Horstmann 2013).
Even when factors are flexible to adjust, still
it is often increasingly costly as exemplified by IV. DATA
overtime pay for labor.
More generally, we can think of various types The period under study for Indonesia was
of capacity constraints, which may be either one of significant macroeconomic change, as
physical or financial in nature. Any incumbent Indonesia began the process of official integra-
production line or plant itself has maximum tion into the world trading system, becoming a
capacity it can produce, and since it takes time World Trade Organization (WTO) member on
to expand the production facility, it is natural to January 1, 1995. The process of tariff reductions
expect a firm to face a physical capacity con- began prior to ascension, but the major tariff
straint. In addition, financial institutions often set commitments were required over a 10-year
a line of credit to each borrower, beyond which a window starting after official entry into the
borrower has to pay a prohibitive premium. Exist-
ing collateral value or credit history may also entrepreneur’s managerial skill exhibits decreasing returns to
act as a natural borrowing limit for each firm, scale of the whole operation such that as the entrepreneur
devotes her time and efforts in expanding export markets,
which will in turn limit the maximum feasible the firm starts selling less in the domestic market because
production level.5,6 she cannot spend as much time and effort on the domestic
operation as before, and vice versa.
5. It is worth noting that increasing fixed costs of reaching 7. Bilateral or multilateral trade liberalization as well as
new (foreign) customers as in Arkolakis (2010) will generate exchange rate movements may also generate such patterns,
export-domestic sales trade-offs only when firms face finan- affecting domestic and export sales in opposing ways, which
cial constraints. is why we take care to control for industry-year shocks in our
6. An alternative source of capacity constraints comes empirical implementation.
from managerial ability constraints, often referred to as a 8. See, for example, Verhoogen (2008) in the case of a
span of control problem à la Lucas (1978). Simply put, an Volkswagen plant in Mexico.
AHN & MCQUOID: CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS 1181

FIGURE 1 The data are drawn from a commonly used


Growth Rates of Macro Variables, Indonesia, plant-level dataset collected by the Indonesia
1970–2010 Central Bureau of Statistics (BPS).10 The
survey includes all medium and large manu-
facturing plants with more than 20 employees
50

starting from 1975. However, information on


exporting was not included in the questionnaire
until 1990. We choose to start our analysis
in 1990 for this reason, leaving us with a
0

7-year panel.
The Indonesian dataset is quite rich, with
information on sector of main product, type
of ownership, output, exports, assets, disaggre-
-50

1970 1980 1990 1996 2000 2010


gated inputs (including energy, raw materials, and
year labor), and a variety of other measures that give a
Inflation Rate Real GDP Growth complete portrait of firm boundaries, production,
Real Exchange Rate Growth
and sales decisions.
The survey is conducted at the plant level. The
BPS sends out a questionnaire each year, and
when the questionnaires are not returned, field
WTO.9 Indonesia was severely impacted by the agents visit the plant to ensure compliance or ver-
East Asian Financial Crisis starting in 1997, ify the plant is no longer in operation. An addi-
and due to concerns over measurement error in tional survey is sent to the head office of each
the reported data, we end our study just prior multi-plant firm.11 Government laws require that
in 1996. Initially, Indonesia was not considered the data collected will only be used for statistical
at risk from contagion with a stable macroeco- purposes and will not be disclosed to tax author-
nomic environment including low inflation, a ities (for further details, see Blalock and Gertler
trade surplus, and significant foreign exchange 2004). This suggests the financial data are reason-
reserves, but was nonetheless swept up in the ably well reported.
regional crises. Using an industry-level wholesale price index
Over the sample considered, 1990–1996, the published by the BPS, we deflate our measures
average consumer price index (CPI) inflation of sales, materials, and capital used in the anal-
rate was 8.7% and was relatively consistent with ysis, which effectively removes industry-level
a standard deviation of 0.84%. Indonesia was inflationary trends.
also experiencing significant economic growth The Indonesian dataset is particularly use-
with an average of 8% real gross domestic ful for our purposes because it contains infor-
product (GDP) growth per year. The lowest year mation on both physical and financial capacity
of real economic growth for Indonesia during constraints, allowing us to disentangle these two
this time was 6.5%, with a high of 9.0% annual possible sources of increasing marginal cost. The
growth. Furthermore, the real exchange rate questionnaire asks specifically about capacity uti-
was nearly unchanged over this time period, lization (i.e., “what percentage of capacity does
appreciating by an average of only 0.02% each the firm utilize?”), which forms the basis of our
year. There was some volatility associated measure of physical capacity constraints. Our pri-
with the real exchange rate, appreciating 3.5% mary measure of physical capacity constraints
in 1995, but depreciating by 5.4% in 1996. is 100% capacity utilization, while the continu-
Figure 1 shows the evolution of real GDP, ous measure of capacity utilization is used for
CPI, and the real exchange rate in Indonesia robustness checks.
over time, revealing the relative stability during
the years under consideration here. Overall, 10. Other studies that employed the same dataset include
while Indonesia was undergoing rapid institu- Blalock and Gertler (2004, 2008), Rodrigue (2014), Mobarak
tional change, it was doing so within a stable and Purbasari (2006), Amiti and Konings (2007), and Sethu-
macroeconomic environment. pathy (2008) among others.
11. Our data do not allow us to distinguish between single
and multi-plant firms. The BPS suggests that about 5% of
9. For further information on trade liberalization in plants are part of a multi-plant firm. For the rest of the paper,
Indonesia, see Amiti and Konings (2007). we will use plant and firm interchangeably.
1182 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

TABLE 1
Mean Values by Export Classification
Continuing Continuing
All Plants Nonexporters Exporters Exporters Exporters (n > 2)
Total output (in 1,000 Rupiah) 5,516 3,554 17,343 24,943 27,313
Export sales (in 1,000 Rupiah) 1,193 0 8,383 11,311 12,139
Domestic sales (in 1,000 Rupiah) 4,323 3,554 8,959 13,632 15,174
Paid workers 180.4 125.5 511.3 640.7 679.7
Output per worker (in 1,000 Rupiah) 17.6 15.5 30.2 35.9 37.2
Number of observations 124,715 106,970 17,745 7,183 5,805

Notes: Mean summary statistics are provided for alternative classifications of plants. In the first column, all plants in the
dataset are included. Columns 2 and 3 split the sample into plants that are observed to export at least once in the sample, and
plants that never export. Column 4 includes only observations from plants that export in at least two consecutive years. Column
5 represents the sample used when plant fixed effects are included in the analysis (plants with two or more growth observations).

We also construct a measure of financial con- with export status and duration. Consistent with
straints based on financial information of the previous studies, exporters are bigger and better
firm. Specifically, our measure of financial dis- in various dimensions than non-exporters. Fur-
tress uses the ratio of a firm’s cash flow to assets, thermore, continuing exporters are even bigger
where financially constrained firms are defined and better than the typical exporter in the same
as the bottom 50% of firms ranked by this mea- dimensions, accounting for 61% and 62% of
sure. This measure of financial distress is one total exports and domestic sales among exporters
of the most widely used proxies for financial in Indonesia over the reported time period. This
constraints in the corporate finance literature.12 fractal quality of plant characteristics along
As a robustness check, we follow Manova, Wei, exporting classification is a well-known feature
and Zhang (2015) and use an alternative mea- of plant-level data.
sure of financial constraints based on ownership What is less well-known is the relationship
structure, where firms with foreign ownership between capacity constraints and firm outcomes.
share larger than 50% are classified as financially We are interested in two dimensions of capac-
unconstrained firms. ity constraints, physical and financial constraints.
The entire sample of firms over the 7-year Table 2 highlights the distinct nature of these two
panel includes nearly 125,000 observations, types of capacity constraints.
from 32,388 unique plants. Our primary analysis In columns 1 and 2 of Table 2, plant char-
will focus on a panel of continuing exporters. acteristics are broken out between physically
When we restrict our sample to just continuing constrained and physically unconstrained obser-
exporters, we are left with 3,248 plants that are vations for continuous exporters. Being physi-
observed to export in consecutive years, giving cally constrained is relatively rare in the sample,
us 7,183 observations. In some specifications, comprising about 8% of all observations and 6%
we will include plant fixed effects to account of firms in the sample. By comparing the two
for plant-specific growth trends likely reflecting columns, we can see that physically constrained
plant-specific demand projections, which are plants tend to sell more both domestically and
particularly relevant for optimizing plants invest- abroad compared to their unconstrained coun-
ing in physical capacity. These specifications terparts. Moreover, physically constrained plants
contain a sample of 5,805 observations. hire more paid workers and are more produc-
Table 1 provides a brief description of the tive in terms of output per worker. One can infer
sample, broken down by export classification. from this that plants are likely to be considered
It is important to note that patterns observed in physically constrained (i.e., using 100% of their
the Indonesian data are similar to those found in capacity) when they are experiencing unexpect-
other plant-level datasets. Namely, there is sig- edly high demand shocks in a given year. Despite
nificant heterogeneity across plants, exporting is being bigger and more productive, they are phys-
rare, and plant outcomes are positively correlated ically constrained in a given year because they
cannot fully meet demand in that year. One ratio-
12. See, for example, Kaplan and Zingales (1997), nalization of this observation is that plants choose
Whited and Wu (2006), and Lin, Ma, and Xuan (2011). optimal physical capacity given their best guess
AHN & MCQUOID: CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS 1183

TABLE 2
Mean Values for Constrained and Unconstrained Continuing Exporters
Physically Financially Financially
Unconstrained Constrained
(Foreign (Domestic
Unconstrained Constrained Unconstrained Constrained Owned) Owned)
Total output (in 1,000 24,515 29,832 32,448 18,600 39,846 22,504
Rupiah)
Export sales (in 1,000 11,023 14,595 13,137 9,136 20,340 9,834
Rupiah)
Domestic sales (in 1,000 13,491 15,237 19,312 9,464 19,506 12,671
Rupiah)
Paid workers 635 701 675 630 745 624
Output per worker (in 35.2 43.3 38.4 29.6 75.4 29.4
1,000 Rupiah)
Number of observations 6,605 578 2,701 3,604 1,010 6,173

Notes: Mean summary statistics are provided for alternative classifications of continuing exporters based on constraints in a
given year. The first two columns split observations into unconstrained and physically constrained (defined as capacity utilization
of 100%). Columns 3 and 4 split sample observations into unconstrained and financially constrained based on the ratio of cash
flow to assets. Columns 5 and 6 provide an alternative measure of financial constraints based on foreign ownership, where
majority-owned foreign plants are classified as unconstrained.

about likely demand as well as costs associated firms tend to work primarily with inefficient local
with unused capacity compared to foregone profit credit markets. In columns 5 and 6 of Table 2,
opportunities when plants stock out, and are ex domestic-owned plants sell less domestically and
post physically constrained for particularly large abroad, hire fewer workers, and produce less
realizations of demand shocks.13 per worker employed when compared to foreign-
Financial constraints, on the other hand, owned plants.
could stem from imperfections in the financial To further understand the prevalence and
market, which would be particularly relevant in importance of capacity constraints, Table 3
developing countries like Indonesia. In this case, provides an alternative look that focuses on dif-
financially constrained plants will be unable to ferences between plants based on how often they
achieve optimal scale, and instead pick capacity are capacity constrained. We split up the sample
with an additional borrowing constraint. Our into three groups representing those plants that
sample of continuing exporters are classified as are never constrained over the sample, plants
financially constrained in 57% of observations, that are sometimes constrained over the sample
suggesting that financial constraints are more (defined as 50% or less of the time), and those
prevalent among exporters relative to the typ- plants that are often constrained over the sample
ical firm. In columns 3 and 4, we see that the
(more than 50% of the time).
patterns of size and productivity are reversed
Consistent with Table 2, plants that are never
when compared to physically constrained plants.
financially constrained sell more domestically
Financially constrained plants sell less domesti-
cally and abroad, employ fewer workers, and are and abroad, and are more productive, although
less productive. they employ slightly fewer workers. Interest-
As an alternative measure of financial con- ingly, by breaking out plants into prevalence of
straints, we follow Manova, Wei, and Zhang physically constrained, we see that firms that
(2015) who argue that particularly in countries are often (nearly always) constrained physically
with thin or inefficient financial markets, access sell less overall than never constrained plants,
to foreign capital is a good proxy for liquidity. but are far more internationally oriented with
Firms that are majority foreign-owned face less export sales nearly twice that of domestic sales.
severe credit constraints since these firms typi- Plants that are often constrained physically are
cally have either internal or external access to the largest in terms of sales and workers, and
foreign credit markets, while domestically owned are also more productive than plants that are
never constrained.
13. This observation is consistent with the evidence pre- To better understand the relationship between
sented in Soderbery (2014) for Thai firms. plants and capacity constraints, Table 4 reports
1184 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

TABLE 3
Mean Values for Continuing Exporters—Constraint Prevalence Classification
Physically Constrained Financially Constrained
Sometimes Often Sometimes Often
Never (≤50%) (>50%) Never (≤50%) (>50%)
Total output (in 1,000 Rupiah) 23,172 41,973 19,102 36,380 20,459 20,031
Export sales (in 1,000 Rupiah) 10,224 19,382 12,689 14,504 10,586 9,610
Domestic sales (in 1,000 Rupiah) 12,949 22,591 6,413 21,876 9,873 10,420
Paid workers 618 843.6 598 630 648 644
Output per worker (in 1,000 Rupiah) 33.7 52.0 39.2 44.4 36.9 29.5
Number of observations 6,065 755 363 2,107 1,950 3,126
Number of plants 2,819 221 208 1,214 622 1,412
% Observations 0.84 0.11 0.05 0.29 0.27 0.44
% Plants 0.87 0.07 0.06 0.37 0.19 0.43

Notes: Mean summary statistics are provided for alternative classifications of continuing exporters. The first three columns
split continuing exporters into physical constraint prevalence. Column 1 is plants that are never constrained physically. Column
2 includes plants that are sometimes constrained physically (less than or equal to half the time observed in the sample). Column
3 includes plants that are often constrained physically (more than half the time observed in the sample). Columns 4–6 replicate
the classification, but for financial constraints.

TABLE 4
Becoming Constrained and Unconstrained
Becoming Physically Becoming Financially
Unconstrained Constrained Unconstrained Constrained
Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median
Total sales growth 0.031 0.055 0.140 0.093 0.275 0.189 −0.130 −0.057
Export sales growth 0.025 0.007 0.183 0.118 0.283 0.210 −0.095 −0.047
Domestic sales growth 0.106 0.045 0.041 0.009 0.287 0.166 −0.200 −0.060
Employment growth −0.024 0.017 0.084 0.021 0.055 0.027 0.028 0.003
Number of observations 314 314 315 315 818 818 790 790

Notes: Mean and median growth rates are reported for four sets of continuing exporters. Columns 1 and 2 report mean and
median growth rates for plants in the year they switch from being constrained physically and unconstrained physically. Columns 3
and 4 report mean and median growth rates for plants in the year they switch from being unconstrained to constrained physically.
Columns 5 through 8 repeat using financial constraints.

mean and median growth rates for plant char- constraints resulted in pent-up demand and sub-
acteristics in years in which plants become optimal scale in previous periods. Conversely,
constrained or become unconstrained for both when plants switch into being classified as
physical and financial capacity constraints. In financially constrained, growth rates are actu-
years in which plants become physically con- ally negative, which is consistent with a plant
strained, they experience significant sales growth shrinking into a financial capacity constraint but
rates, particularly export sales growth rates. This also with a reallocation of resources away from
is again consistent with the view that plants sales and marketing and towards savings to fund
become physically constrained when faced with future productive capacity. Significant reductions
unexpectedly large demand shocks. When plants in domestic sales growth rates are particularly
become unconstrained physically, growth rates correlated with financial constraints.
are significantly lower and consistent with less Of further interest is the relative stability of
extreme demand shocks. employment growth across the four categories.
Differences in growth rates for plants becom- Over the entire sample, the median employment
ing financially constrained and financially growth rate is 1.7%. In comparison, switching
unconstrained are even starker. When plants into or out of a physical capacity constraint has
switch from being constrained to unconstrained little to no effect of the employment growth rate
financially, they experience enormous growth relative to average employment growth rate. For
rates, which is possibly indicative of growing financial constraints, however, there are notice-
out of a constraint but also perhaps that financial able differences. For a firm becoming financially
AHN & MCQUOID: CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS 1185

constrained, the employment growth is essen- physically and/or financially constrained firms.
tially zero, although still positive. On the other The identification strategy is that for firms
hand, for a plant becoming unconstrained finan- exhibiting constant marginal cost, there should
cially, the employment growth rate is noticeably be no observed relationship between domestic
higher at 2.7%, which is again consistent with sales and foreign sales after properly accounting
the interpretation of financially constraints pre- for relevant forces (such as productivity). For
venting optimal firm scale. While these statistics firms facing increasing marginal cost, on the
are illuminating and show important differences other hand, the estimated coefficient on foreign
between physical and financial constraints and sales should be negative, although the actual
plant characteristics, to fully understand the role estimate will be biased upwards toward zero
of capacity constraints and increasing marginal because of omitted variable bias driven by unob-
cost, we need to move beyond descriptive statis- served foreign demand shocks, which will tend
tics and utilize theory to guide econometric anal- to underestimate the prevalence of increasing
ysis, which we do in the next section. marginal cost technology in the data.
These two types of capacity constraints appear Our first result for continuing exporters veri-
to be truly distinct in terms of mechanisms and fies that there is a significant negative relation-
observable plant characteristics. In fact, there is ship between export sales growth and domestic
essentially no correlation between the two types sales growth for individual firms, suggesting the
of constraints in the data, with the partial cor- prevalence of increasing marginal cost at the firm
relations between physical and financial indica- level.15
tors of −0.02 for either financial classification. For a first glance, consider the simple cor-
Given that physical capacity constraints likely relation between domestic sales growth and
arise from unexpected demand in a given year, export sales growth. The correlation coefficient
whereas financial constraints are due to imper- is −0.02 in column 1 of Table 5, but is not
fect credit markets, it will be important to dis- statistically significant. One interpretation is that
tinguish the source of the capacity constraint for on average firms are best described as having
policy implications.14 constant marginal cost technology, and there
In terms of identification strategy, however, is no observed relationship between foreign
we will exploit the fact that distinct sources of and domestic sales. In column 2 of Table 5,
capacity constraints have the same observable we include sector-year fixed effects with no
economic effect. When a firm is constrained, noticeable change in our estimated coefficient.
either financially or physically, the ability to In column 3, however, incorporating firm fixed
produce and sell one more unit is restricted, effects has the effect of correcting for firm-
leading to increasing marginal cost of produc- specific trends over time, yielding a statistically
tion for that next unit. As our theory developed significant coefficient estimate four times larger.
above suggests, firms that are facing increasing This is consistent with the view that firm-specific
marginal cost will face more severe trade-offs time trends, likely related to persistent demand
between sales abroad and domestically, leading shocks, were hiding the underlying trade-off
to an observed negative correlation between for- between foreign and domestic markets, a hall-
eign and domestic sales. To formally estimate and mark of increasing marginal cost. Column 4 adds
identify the relationship, we now take our model- both firm-level and sector-year fixed effects,
based econometric specification to the data. confirming the pattern.
As we noted above, simple correlations in the
data may not tell the whole story. In particular,
V. RESULTS
omitted variables such as productivity might mat-
Based on the structural econometric spec- ter, though in the case of productivity growth,
ification developed in Section II, we evaluate omission should bias upward the estimated coef-
the prevalence of increasing marginal cost at ficients of export sales growth. To account for
the firm level, and then show that increas-
ing marginal cost is particularly relevant for
15. While focusing on continuing exporters allows us to
best isolate the role of marginal costs, Section B of Appendix
14. To account for potential concerns in capacity con- S1 (Supporting Information) provides additional evidence
straint measurement, we use multiple measures of physical that our findings hold for firms that switch in to and out
and financial capacity constraints to verify the robustness of of export markets as well, consistent with our increasing
the findings. marginal cost interpretation.
1186 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

TABLE 5
Identifying Increasing Marginal Cost
𝚫 ln(domestic sales) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
Δ ln(export sales) −0.02 −0.03 −0.08 −0.09 −0.14 −0.14 −0.19 −0.18 −0.16
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)***
Δ ln(productivity):
Labor 0.35 0.34 0.32
(0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)***
TFP growth 0.27
(0.03)***
Levinsohn–Petrin 0.26
(0.03)***
Sector-year FE No Yes No Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Plant FE No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes Yes
Observations 7,183 7,183 5,805 5,805 7,183 7,183 5,805 4,802 4,780
R2 0.00 0.03 0.22 0.25 0.05 0.08 0.28 0.32 0.32
Prob > F 0.190 0.000 0.000 0.082 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

Notes: The dependent variable is the yearly change in log(domestic sales). Productivity in this regression is labor productivity
measured as (value added outputs)/(total labor employed) in columns 5, 6, and 7. Column 8 reports the regression result with
productivity as TFP deviation from the sector-year mean. Column 9 reports the regression result with productivity estimated
using the methodology of Levinsohn and Petrin (2003). All standard errors are clustered at the sector-year level and provided in
parentheses. FE, fixed effects. Significance: *, 10%; **, 5%; ***, 1%.

this possibility, Table 5 includes multiple mea- to be negative and statistically significant as well,
sures of productivity growth (measures based suggesting that physical capacity constraints can
on labor productivity, simple total factor pro- explain part but not all of the negative relation-
ductivity (TFP) growth, and a measure based ship between export sales growth and domestic
on Levisohn–Petrin). As expected, the inclusion sales growth.
of productivity strengthens the basic story that Column 3 considers financial constraints
export sales and domestic sales are negatively separately. First, the interaction term between
correlated for a firm, demonstrating that the omis- financial capacity constraints and export sales
sion of productivity was biasing upward the esti- growth is negative and statistically significant,
mated coefficient on export sales growth by over suggesting that financially distressed exporters
50%. The results are consistent across alternative face greater trade-offs between domestic sales
measures of productivity.16 and export sales growth than unconstrained
Having shown the prevalence of increas- exporters. A second intriguing finding is that
ing marginal cost at the firm level, we turn export growth is no longer separately significant
to considering various sources of increasing with a positive coefficient estimate.
marginal cost. Our empirical strategy takes the Column 4 includes both physical and finan-
view that if it is increasing marginal costs that cial capacity constraints. Both interaction terms
are driving the observed negative correlation are negative and statistically significant. The size
between export sales and domestic sales, we of the reported coefficients implies that a phys-
should expect that this pattern will be stronger ically constrained exporter experiences a 0.27%
for firms that are capacity constrained since these decrease in domestic sales for every 1% increase
firms are facing steeper costs associated with in export sales compared to an unconstrained
expanding production. exporter. If the exporter is both physically and
Results are reported in Table 6. Column 1 financially constrained, the decrease in domes-
restates the initial finding of a negative corre- tic sales growth is −0.49 (−0.27 + −0.22)% for
lation between export sales and domestic sales every 1% increase in export sales growth. For
growth for reference (column 4 of Table 5). Col- unconstrained firms, there is no apparent relation-
umn 2 investigates the impact of physical capac- ship between export and domestic sales growth.
ity constraints. The interaction term between Taken together, the results presented in column
exporting and capacity constraints is negative and 4 strongly suggest that for a subset of firms that
statistically significant. Export growth continues are capacity constrained, either physical or finan-
cial, there is an economically significant nega-
16. Inference is robust to alternative clustering groups. tive relationship between export sales growth and
AHN & MCQUOID: CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS 1187

TABLE 6
Identifying Increasing Marginal Cost with Capacity Constraints
5 6 7
Labor TFP LP
𝚫 ln(domestic sales) 1 2 3 4 Productivity Productivity Productivity
Δ ln(export sales) −0.09 −0.08 0.03 0.05 −0.07 −0.04 −0.03
(0.03)*** (0.03)** (0.08) (0.08) (0.07) (0.08) (0.08)
Physically constrained 0.04 0.04 0.04 −0.01 −0.01
(0.08) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07) (0.07)
Δ ln(export sales)*physical −0.23 −0.27 −0.26 −0.29 −0.27
(0.09)** (0.11)** (0.10)** (0.11)*** (0.11)***
Financially constrained −0.24 −0.24 −0.03 −0.04 −0.06
(0.05)*** (0.05)*** (0.05) (0.06) (0.06)
Δ ln(export sales)*financial −0.22 −0.22 −0.16 −0.19 −0.18
(0.09)** (0.09)** (0.08)** (0.09)** (0.09)**
Δ ln(productivity) 0.30 0.25 0.24
(0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)***
Sector-year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Plant FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 5,805 5,805 4,985 4,985 4,985 4,802 4,780
R2 0.25 0.25 0.27 0.27 0.30 0.30 0.29
Prob > F 0.082 0.066 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

Notes: The dependent variable is the yearly change in log(domestic sales). Productivity in this regression is labor productivity
measured as (value added outputs)/(total labor employed) in column 5. Column 6 reports the regression result with productivity
as TFP deviation from the sector-year mean. Column 7 reports the regression result with productivity estimated using the
methodology of Levinsohn and Petrin (2003). Physical capacity constraint dummy is 1 for plants with 100% capacity utilization
and 0 otherwise. Financial capacity constraint dummy is 1 for firms with a (cash-flow)/(asset) ratio in the bottom 50% for each
year and 0 otherwise. All standard errors are clustered at the sector-year level and provided in parentheses. FE, fixed effects.
Significance: *, 10%; **, 5%; ***, 1%.

domestic sales growth, and that the negative cor- access to internal capital markets (borrow from
relation we observed in the baseline specifica- parent directly) or access to foreign financial
tion is being driven by firms that are physically markets through parent relations. As such, we
or financially capacity constrained. Columns 5 would expect that foreign-owned firms expe-
through 7 show the result is robust to the inclu- rience less severe financial constraints, while
sion of alternative productivity measures. purely domestically owned firms are more likely
Overall, Tables 5 and 6 provide strong evi- to experience increasing marginal cost driven by
dence that export sales and domestic sales growth financial constraints.
are negatively related for individual firms, and Table 7 confirms this intuition. Column 1
this relationship is particularly pronounced for finds that firms that are domestically owned
firms that are facing physical and financial con- show a significant negative relationship between
straints. Moreover, once capacity constraints are export sales and domestic sales, implying these
accounted for, there is no noticeable relationship firms face increasing marginal cost of produc-
between export sales and domestic sales growth. tion. Column 2 shows the result is robust to
As our theory above makes clear, this is prima the inclusion of physical capacity constraints.
facie evidence for the prevalence of increas- Columns 3 through 5 show the results are again
ing marginal cost at the firm level. However, consistent with alternative measures of produc-
as demonstrated above, it should be emphasized tivity. In sum, using an alternative proxy for
that, because of attenuation bias, we are likely financial constraints based on the concept intro-
understating the existence of firms operating with duced by Manova, Wei, and Zhang (2015), we
increasing marginal cost. find strong evidence for the existence of increas-
Next, we repeat the analysis using an alterna- ing marginal cost at the firm level.
tive measure of financial constraints, following While Tables 6 and 7 provide evidence about
Manova, Wei, and Zhang (2015) who argue that the nature of capacity constraints and the interre-
foreign-owned subsidiaries, especially in under- lation of foreign and domestic sales, we consider
developed financially markets, tend to face fewer a number of additional robustness checks to
financial constraints than domestically owned confirm the findings. To test the robustness of
competitors. Firms with foreign parents have our baseline measures of capacity constraints, we
1188 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

TABLE 7
Financial Constraints—Foreign Ownership Status
3 4 5
𝚫 ln(domestic sales) 1 2 Labor Productivity TFP Productivity LP Productivity
Δ ln(export sales) 0.11 0.13 0.00 0.05 0.06
(0.13) (0.12) (0.10) (0.14) (0.14)
Financially constrained 0.11 0.12 0.09 0.34 0.35
(0.18) (0.18) (0.18) (0.21) (0.22)
Δ ln(export sales)*financial −0.24 −0.24 −0.21 −0.25 −0.24
(0.13) * (0.13)* (0.10)** (0.15)* (0.14)*
Physically constrained 0.04 0.06 0.003 0.001
(0.08) (0.08) (0.08) (0.07)
Δ ln(export sales)*physical −0.24 −0.23 −0.30 −0.28
(0.09)*** (0.08)*** (0.11)*** (0.10)***
Δ ln(productivity) 0.32 0.27 0.26
(0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)***
Sector-year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Plant FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 5,805 5,805 5,805 4,802 4,780
R2 0.25 0.25 0.29 0.30 0.29
Prob > F 0.023 0.017 0.000 0.000 0.000

Notes: The dependent variable is the yearly change in log(domestic sales). Productivity in this regression is labor productivity
measured as (value added outputs)/(total labor employed) in column 3. Column 4 reports the regression result with productivity
as TFP deviation from the sector-year mean. Column 5 reports the regression result with productivity estimated using
the methodology of Levinsohn and Petrin (2003). Physical capacity constraint dummy is 1 for firms with 100% capacity
utilization and 0 otherwise. Financial capacity constraint dummy is 1 for domestically owned and controlled (foreign ownership
share < 50%) firms and 0 for foreign owned and controlled (foreign ownership share > 50%) subsidiaries. All standard errors are
clustered at the sector-year level and provided in parentheses. FE, fixed effects. Significance: *, 10%; **, 5%; ***, 1%.

consider alternative definitions. We start by using up the measure of financial constraints, increas-
a continuous measure of capacity utilization. The ing the likelihood that firms that are financially
intuition is that while there may be measure- distressed will be classified as financially uncon-
ment error in reported capacity utilization, strained. Empirically, this will tend to increase
managers reporting higher capacity utilization the magnitude of the negative coefficient on
are indicating greater production constraints exports, and reduce statistical significance
compared to lower reported capacity utiliza- between groups.
tion values. Beta coefficients on this alternative Column 3 of Table 8 looks at the alternative
measure of physical constraints are reported in measure of financial capacity constraints in
the table. isolation and again finds a statistically signifi-
In column 1 of Table 8, the alternative mea- cant and negative interaction effect. Column 4
sure of physical capacity constraints when includes the original measure of physical con-
interacted with export sales is again negative straints along with the alternative measure of
and statistically significant. The interpreta- financial constraints, and Column 5 uses both
tion is that firms experiencing higher capacity alternative measures of capacity constraints.
utilization also experience greater trade-offs Both interaction effects are negative and sta-
between domestic and foreign sales, consistent tistically significant, suggesting that the results
with increasing marginal costs of production. In are not being driven by the specific threshold
column 2, our alternative measure of physical level of firm-level financial capacity constraints.
capacity constraints are robust to the inclusion of The last three columns of Table 8 include
financial constraints, with no noticeable impact three different measures of productivity growth,
on estimated coefficients. Both interaction terms which attest to the robustness of the underlying
are negative and significant, suggesting results economic mechanism.
are robust to alternative measures of physical Finally, although there are particularly useful
capacity constraints. aspects of this dataset for measuring sources of
As an alternative measure of financial distress, capacity constraints, one concern that relates to
only firms in the bottom 10% in terms of rank- our use of the Indonesian data is that our key
ing by cash flow to asset ratio are categorized variables of interest (export and domestic sales)
as financially distressed. This effectively tightens are constructed using a single question on the
AHN & MCQUOID: CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS 1189

TABLE 8
Identifying Increasing Marginal Cost with Alternative Measures of Financial and Physical Constraints
6
Alt 7 8
5 Physical Alt Alt
Alt Alt Physical Physical
1 2 3 4 Physical Financial Alt Alt
Alt Alt Alt Alt Alt Labor Financial Financial
𝚫 ln(domestic sales) Physical Physical Financial Financial Financial Productivity TFP LP
Δ ln(export sales) −0.11 0.02 −0.05 −0.04 −0.08 −0.17 −0.16 −0.15
(0.03)*** (0.07) (0.05) (0.05) (0.04)* (0.04)*** (0.04)*** (0.04)***
Physically constrained 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.02
(0.03) (0.03) (0.07) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)
Δ ln(export sales)*physical −0.08 −0.09 −0.28 −0.08 −0.07 −0.08 −0.09
(0.03)** (0.03)*** (0.11)** (0.04)** (0.03)** (0.03)** (0.03)***
Financially constrained −0.24 −0.18 −0.18 −0.18 −0.01 −0.10 −0.07
(0.05)*** (0.05)*** (0.05)*** (0.05)*** (0.05) (0.05)* (0.05)
Δ ln(export sales)*financial −0.22 −0.19 −0.19 −0.16 −0.13 −0.14 −0.13
(0.08)*** (0.08)** (0.08)** (0.07)** (0.07)* (0.07)* (0.07)*
Δ ln(productivity) 0.30 0.26 0.25
(0.03)*** (0.03)*** (0.03)***
Sector-year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Plant FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 5,805 4,985 4,985 4,985 4,985 4,985 4,802 4,780
R2 0.25 0.28 0.27 0.27 0.27 0.30 0.30 0.29
Prob > F 0.020 0.000 0.004 0.003 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000

Notes: The dependent variable is the yearly change in log(domestic sales). Productivity in this regression is labor productivity
measured as (value added outputs)/(total labor employed) in column 6. Column 7 reports the regression result with productivity
as TFP deviation from the sector-year mean. Column 8 reports the regression result with productivity estimated using the
methodology of Levinsohn and Petrin (2003). Physical capacity constraint dummy is 1 for firms with 100% capacity utilization
and 0 otherwise. Financial capacity constraint dummy is 1 for firms with a (cash-flow)/(asset) ratio in the bottom 50% for each
year and 0 otherwise. Alternative physical capacity constraint is continuous measure of capacity utilization, standardized so that
the coefficient can be interpreted as a beta coefficient. Alternative financial capacity constraint dummy is 1 for firms with a (cash-
flow)/(asset) ratio in the bottom 10% for each year and 0 otherwise. All standard errors are clustered at the sector-year level and
provided in parentheses. FE, fixed effects. Significance: *, 10%; **, 5%; ***, 1%.

underlying survey. Firms are asked to report the of increasing marginal cost, driven by financial
percentage of total output exported from which and physical capacity constraints.
export and domestic sales are inferred. The con-
cern here is that errors in reporting, including
measurement error, will tend to show up mechan- VI. CONCLUSION
ically as a negative relationship between export
In this paper, we show that the assumption
sales and domestic sales. We addressed these
of constant marginal cost technology, which is
concerns in a longer working paper version of
implicit or explicit in most theory models of
this paper (Ahn and McQuoid 2012) by explor-
international trade, has predictions about firm-
ing and confirming the results presented above level foreign and domestic sales which are incon-
using Chilean plant-level data, where export and sistent with the data. Guided by the estimating
domestic sales are independently recorded in the equation derived from a structural model, we doc-
underlying survey. ument a strong empirical pattern of a negative
In sum, we have shown that there exists a neg- relationship between domestic sales and exports
ative relationship between domestic sales growth sales. We show an estimated negative coefficient
and export sales growth from Indonesian plant- on export sales is only consistent with increasing
level data. Furthermore, our results show that marginal cost, and this represents a lower bound
such patterns are particularly acute for capac- on the true intensity and prevalence of increasing
ity constrained firms, be it either financially or marginal cost technology firms. Given the like-
physically. Leveraging the model-driven empiri- lihood of attenuation bias because of unobserv-
cal estimation to guide our interpretation, we take able foreign demand shocks, the importance of
these results as strong evidence for the presence increasing marginal cost is likely understated.
1190 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

Furthermore, we explore the sources of this by each country differs. The robustness of the
increasing marginal cost technology, and find results in different developing contexts reaffirms
that physically and financially constrained firms the importance of physical and financial con-
have significant and large negative correlations straints for developing countries.
between export and domestic sales. Financial For developed countries, financial markets are
constraints are shown to be at least as important presumably thicker and more efficient, which
as physical capacity constraints in contributing to would suggest that financial constraints may be
the observed trade-off. Our findings are robust to less important for firms in developed countries,
multiple measures of physical and financial con- which would imply fewer firms facing increasing
straints as well as alternative measures of produc- marginal costs. However, as shown in Midrigan
tivity. This suggests that a constant marginal cost and Xu (2014), even countries with sophisticated
view is inappropriate for internationally active financial markets such as South Korea face finan-
firms, and that persistent constraints at the plant cial frictions that significantly impact firm invest-
level could be quite significant for understanding ment choices related to technology adoption and
aggregate outcomes. market entry. They hypothesize further that long-
The presence of increasing marginal cost is a lived investments that only pay off gradually, and
firm-level micro phenomenon, and it will have a hence are difficult to self-finance, are problem-
direct impact on the firm-level export-domestic atic even in financially developed countries. So
sales relationship. In this sense, our findings are while increasing marginal cost is likely to be less
expected to serve as the rationale behind the serve in developed countries, the impact on delay-
micro-foundation of a growing number of theory ing gains from trade may still be notable.
models in macroeconomics that adopt decreasing After all, exporters facing increasing marginal
returns to scale technology to explain salient fea- cost provide a conduit through which shocks are
tures of firm-level behaviors. transmitted across borders. Purely foreign shocks
The sources of increasing marginal costs iden- spill over into the domestic market as these firms
tified in this paper are relevant for industrial re-optimize in each market. Such spillovers can
and trade policy. We show that both physical affect all aspects of firm behavior including pric-
and financial constraints are relevant and distinct ing, and thus should be considered more care-
sources of increasing marginal cost for firms. fully in trade models, particularly when short-run
While physical capacity constraints are likely adjustment behaviors are under consideration.
to be the result of unexpectedly large demand
shocks that may dissipate quickly, financial con- REFERENCES
straints will tend to be beyond the control of the
Ahn, J. “A Theory of Domestic and International Trade
firm and therefore longer lasting. Physical capac- finance.” IMF Working Paper, (11/262), 2011.
ity constraints may be mostly beyond the control Ahn, J., and A. McQuoid. “Capacity Constrained Exporters:
of policymakers, but the impact for trade policy Micro Evidence and Macro Implications.” FIU Working
Paper Series, 2012.
may be minor to the degree that costly adjustment Amiti, M., and J. Konings. “Trade Liberalization, Intermedi-
merely delays realizations of gains from trade. ate Inputs, and Productivity: Evidence from Indonesia.”
Financial capacity constraints, to the degree that American Economic Review, 97(5), 2007, 1611–38.
Arkolakis, C. “Market Penetration Costs and the New Con-
they are driven by financial market inefficiencies, sumers Margin in International Trade.” Journal of Polit-
can be more directly addressed by policymakers, ical Economy, 118(6), 2010, 1151–99.
which is particularly relevant since gains from Aw, B. Y., M. Roberts, and D. Xu. “R & D Investment, Export-
trade may be permanently delayed if financial ing, and Productivity Dynamics.” American Economic
Review, 101(4), 2011, 1312–44.
constraints are persistent for firms. Berman, N., A. Berthou, and J. Héricourt. “Export Dynam-
The general applicability of the results pre- ics and Sales at Home.” Journal of International Eco-
sented here depends on the relative frequency nomics, 96(2), 2015, 298–310.
Blalock, G., and P. J. Gertler. “Learning from Exporting
and persistence of physical and financial con- Revisited in a Less Developed Setting.” Journal of
straints across countries. In a related paper (Ahn Development Economics, 75(2), 2004, 397–416.
and McQuoid 2012), we replicate the approach . “Welfare Gains from Foreign Direct Investment
through Technology Transfer to Local Suppliers.” Jour-
taken here for manufacturing firms in Chile from nal of International Economics, 74(2), 2008, 402–21.
1995 to 2006, and find similar qualitative and Blum, B., S. Claro, and I. Horstmann. “Occasional vs Peren-
quantitative results. While Chile and Indonesia nial Exporters: The Impact of Capacity on Export
are both developing countries, their production Mode.” Journal of International Economics, 90(1),
2013, 65–74.
and export structures are quite distinct, and the Chaney, T. “Liquidity Constrained Exporters.” Journal of
nature and type of foreign demand shocks faced Economic Dynamics and Control, 72, 2016, 141–54.
AHN & MCQUOID: CAPACITY CONSTRAINED EXPORTERS 1191

Das, S., M. J. Roberts, and J. R. Tybout. “Market Entry Mobarak, A. M., and D. P. Purbasari. “Corrupt Protection for
Costs, Producer Heterogeneity, and Export Dynamics.” Sale to Firms: Evidence from Indonesia,” 2006.
Econometrica, 75(3), 2007, 837–73. Muûls, M. “Exporters and Credit Constraints: A Firm-Level
De Loecker, J. “Recovering Markups from Production Data.” Approach.” Working Paper Research No. 139, National
International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29(3), Bank of Belgium, 2008.
2011, 350–5. Nguyen, D., and G. Schaur. “Cost Linkages Transmit Volatil-
Fazzari, S. M., R. G. Hubbard, B. C. Petersen, A. S. Blinder, ity Across Markets.” EPRU Working Paper Series,
and J. M. Poterba. “Financing Constraints and Corpo- 2011.
rate Investment.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activ- Paravisini, D., V. Rappoport, P. Schnabl, and D. Wolfenzon.
ity, 1988(1), 1988, 141–206. “Dissecting the Effect of Credit Supply on Trade: Evi-
Feenstra, R. C., Z. Li, and M. Yu. “Exports and Credit Con- dence from Matched Credit-export Data.” Review of
straints Under Incomplete Information: Theory and Evi- Economic Studies, 82(1), 2015, 333–59.
dence from China.” Review of Economics and Statistics, Rho, Y.-W., and J. Rodrigue. “Firm-Level Investment and
96(4), 2014, 729–44. Export Dynamics.” International Economic Review,
Ghemawat, P., and J. Mitchell. “Grolsch: Growing Globally.” 57(1), 2016, 271–304.
Technical Report, Harvard Business School Case Study, Rodrigue, J. “Multinational Production, Exports, and Aggre-
2011. gate Productivity.” Review of Economic Dynamics,
Kaplan, S. N., and L. Zingales. “Do Investment-Cash Flow 17(2), 2014, 243–61.
Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Financing Ruhl, K. J., and J. L. Willis. “New Exporter Dynamics.”
Constraints?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Working Paper,
1997, 169–215. (14–10), 2014.
Kohn, D., F. Leibovici, and M. Szkup. “Financial Frictions Sethupathy, G. “Does Exporting Lead to Productivity
and New Exporter Dynamics.” International Economic Spillovers in Horizontal or Vertical Industries? Evi-
Review, 57(2), 2016, 453–86. dence from Indonesia.” Discussion Paper No. 0708-01,
Krugman, P. R. “Increasing Returns, Monopolistic Competi- Department of Economics, Columbia University,
tion, and International Trade.” Journal of International 2008.
Economics, 9(4), 1979, 469–79. Soderbery, A. “Market Size, Structure, and Access: Trade
. “Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the with Capacity Constraints.” European Economic
Pattern of Trade.” American Economic Review, 70(5), Review, 70(6), 2014, 276–98.
1980, 950–59. Spearot, A. C. “Firm Heterogeneity, New Investment and
Levinsohn, J., and A. Petrin. “Estimating Production Func- Acquisitions.” Journal of Industrial Economics, 60(1),
tions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables.” 2012, 1–45.
Review of Economic Studies, 70(2), 2003, 317–41. Vannoorenberghe, G. “Firm-Level Volatility and Exports.”
Lin, C., Y. Ma, and Y. Xuan. “Ownership Structure and Finan- Journal of International Economics, 86(1), 2012,
cial Constraints: Evidence from a Structural Estima- 57–67.
tion.” Journal of Financial Economics, 102(2), 2011, Verhoogen, E. A. “Trade, Quality Upgrading, and Wage
416–31. Inequality in the Mexican Manufacturing Sector.”
Lucas, R. E. J. “On the Size Distribution of Business Firms.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 2008,
The Bell Journal of Economics, 9(2), 1978, 508–23. 489–530.
Manova, K. “Credit Constraints, Heterogeneous Firms, and Whited, T. M., and G. Wu. “Financial Constraints Risk.”
International Trade.” Review of Economic Studies, 80, Review of Financial Studies, 19n, 2006, 531–59.
2013, 711–44.
Manova, K., S.-J. Wei, and Z. Zhang. “Firm Exports and SUPPORTING INFORMATION
Multinational Activity Under Credit Constraints.”
Review of Economics and Statistics, 97(3), 2015, Additional Supporting Information may be found in the
574–88. online version of this article:
Melitz, M. J. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-industry Real- Appendix S1. A. Graphical Illustration of Shape of
locations and Aggregate Industry Productivity.” Econo- Marginal Cost Curve and Co-movement of Export and
metrica, 71(6), 2003, 1695–725. Domestic Sales; B. New Exporters and Increasing Marginal
Midrigan, V., and D. Y. Xu. “Finance and Misallocation: Cost
Evidence from Plant-Level Data.” American Economic
Review, 104(2), 2014, 422–58.

You might also like