You are on page 1of 14

The Role of the Information Environment

in Partisan Voting
Erik Peterson, Dartmouth College

Voters are often highly dependent on partisanship to structure their preferences toward political candidates and policy
proposals. What conditions enable partisan cues to “dominate” public opinion? Here I theorize that variation in voters’
reliance on partisanship results, in part, from the opportunities their environment provides to learn about politics. A
conjoint experiment and an observational study of voting in congressional elections both support the expectation that
more detailed information environments reduce the role of partisanship in candidate choice. These findings clarify
previously unexplained cross-study variation in party cue effects. They also challenge competing claims that partisan
cues inhibit responsiveness to such a degree that voters fail to use other information or that high-information envi-
ronments increase voter reliance on partisanship.

P artisans in the electorate overwhelmingly vote for co-


partisan candidates (Bartels 2000; Campbell et al. 1960;
Rahn 1993) and frequently adopt the issue positions ad-
vocated by their elite copartisans (Cohen 2003; Druckman,
Peterson, and Slothuus 2013; Zaller 1992). While partisan-
how the amount of information available to a voter will in-
teract with their use of partisanship. If partisan cues largely
serve as substitutes for information that is costly to obtain,
additional information should reduce the role of partisanship
as voters are provided with more relevant attributes with
ship is often prominent in voter decision making, there is dis- which to assess politicians (Bullock 2011; Downs 1957). How-
agreement about the conditions that enable partisan cues to ever, this runs counter to other predictions. First, prior stud-
“dominate” public opinion. In one set of accounts this domi- ies of partisan cue taking identify a number of mechanisms
nance results from a fundamental tendency for voters to ig- through which partisan resistance limits the degree to which
nore or counterargue with information that would lead them information can lead voters to oppose candidates sharing their
to defect from their party (Bolsen, Druckman, and Cook 2014). party label (Bolsen et al. 2014; Campbell et al. 1960; Rahn 1993;
Other perspectives suggest this dominance is more circum- Slothuus and De Vreese 2010). Second, accounts in political
stantial. The public may rely heavily on partisanship, but this psychology predict that additional information provision will
often stems from the absence of other pieces of choice-specific increase voters’ reliance on partisanship by forcing them to use
information (Bullock 2011) or the complex nature of some party labels to cope with information overload (Lau and Red-
political decisions (Lau and Redlawsk 2006). lawsk 2006, 242–46; Riggle 1992).
I test between these perspectives by focusing on the inter- Extending research on the role of information environ-
action between voters’ use of partisanship and the amount of ments in voter decision making (Delli Carpini, Keeter, and
information, beyond party labels, available to them when eval- Kennamer 1994; Jerit, Barabas, and Bolsen 2006; Kuklinski
uating politicians. How does the information environment af- et al. 2001), I examine how the amount of candidate-specific
fect the degree to which voters rely on partisan cues? Theories information available to voters affects partisan voting in con-
of partisan cue taking present starkly different predictions about gressional elections. The research designs employed here di-

Erik Peterson (erik.j.peterson@dartmouth.edu) is a postdoctoral research associate in Dartmouth College’s Program in Quantitative Social Science, Hanover,
NH 03755.
This project was approved by Stanford University’s Institutional Review Board. This material is based on work supported by the National Science Foun-
dation Graduate Research Fellowship under grant DGE-114747. Any opinion, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this material are
those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Science Foundation. Data and supporting materials necessary to reproduce the
numerical results in the paper are available in the JOP Dataverse (https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataverse/jop). An online appendix with supplementary material
is available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/692740.

The Journal of Politics, volume 79, number 4. Published online August 16, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/692740
q 2017 by the Southern Political Science Association. All rights reserved. 0022-3816/2017/7904-006$10.00 1191
1192 / Role of Information Environment in Partisan Voting Erik Peterson

rectly manipulate the amount of available information at several iation in the effect of partisanship on voter preferences that
points on the path from an information-poor to an information- “defeats most attempts to generalize” (Bullock 2011, 509; see
rich environment. This is accomplished with a doubly random- also Druckman 2014, 477).
ized conjoint experiment that varies both the amount and type Individual differences offer one explanation for this vari-
of information respondents encounter about a pair of candi- ation. Voters with a dispositional need for cognition (Bullock
dates to examine partisan voting in different settings (see also 2011; but see Kam 2005), conflicted partisan identities (La-
Hainmueller, Hopkins, and Yamamoto 2015). To assess the vine, Johnston, and Steenbergen 2012), or who lack an under-
generalizability of these findings to a campaign environment, standing of party brands (Sniderman and Stiglitz 2012) all
where pressure to vote the party line may be particularly pro- depend less on party labels. Features of the political environ-
nounced (e.g., Gelman and King 1993; Huddy, Mason, and ment also contribute. Klar (2014) shows that discussions with
Aaroe 2015; Iyengar, Mason, and Aaroe 2012) and voters can out-partisans reduce voters’ reliance on partisanship. Druck-
choose to avoid encountering political information (Prior 2007), man et al. (2013) and Levendusky (2010) identify aspects of elite
these experimental results are paired with an observational polarization that increase the tendency for voters to follow party
study leveraging misalignment between newspaper markets labels, and Iyengar et al. (2012) discuss the role of campaigns
and political constituencies to examine differences in partisan in generating antipathy for out-partisans.
voting based on the quality of the media environment for con- While these efforts offer broad outlines for differences in
gressional elections. the importance of partisanship, they fail to explain substantial
In both settings, I find that additional candidate-specific residual variation in voters’ use of partisanship. In reviewing
information reduces partisan voting. Absent detailed candi- a relatively homogenous set of experimental studies on par-
date information, voters use partisanship to fill in unknowns. tisan cues—which do not vary on any of the aforementioned
They rely on partisanship to a reduced, although still sub- environmental features—Bullock (2011) observes substantial
stantial, extent when provided with more information. These differences in the extent to which partisan cues affect opin-
studies also fail to offer evidence of increased dependence ions toward political candidates and policy proposals. A com-
on cues in more detailed environments. Voters in areas with mon, but untested, explanation attributes differences in party
extensive media coverage of congressional elections or who cue effects to aspects of the information environment in which
are provided with lengthy candidate profiles continue to de- individuals evaluate candidates or policies. For example, Schaf-
crease their reliance on partisanship. In tandem, these find- fner and Streb (2002) identify large party cue effects and ref-
ings challenge competing claims that partisan cues inhibit erence the low-information nature of the elections they ex-
responsiveness to such a degree that voters fail to use other amine to explain these results (see also Meredith and Grissom
information or that partisan cues grow more effective in high- 2010). Bullock (2011) finds small party cue effects and attri-
information environments. They also clarify previously unex- butes them to the detailed policy descriptions in which the cues
plained cross-study variation in party cue effects. were embedded. While these explanations make intuitive sense,
credible alternative theories about the way information envi-
ronments interact with voters’ use of partisanship, reviewed
PARTISANSHIP AND VOTER DECISION MAKING in the next section, propose the opposite pattern or predict no
Voters’ partisan attachments affect their evaluations of po- relationship between the information environment and cue use.
litical candidates (e.g., Bartels 2000; Rahn 1993), their atti- Moreover, these contrasting expectations have not been as-
tudes toward policies (Zaller 1992) and even intrude on their sessed in a cohesive design that directly manipulates the amount
perceptions of the economy (Bartels 2002; but see Bullock et al. of information available to voters.
2015). While a wealth of evidence establishes the importance
of partisanship, a pat conclusion that it “matters” ignores sub-
stantial variation in the extent to which voters make use of INFORMATION ENVIRONMENTS
these attachments. For all the evidence supporting the domi- AND PARTISAN VOTING
nance of partisanship in voter decision making, in a number In this study the information environment refers to the
of settings partisan cues exert a more limited effect on opin- amount of detail, beyond party labels, available to voters when
ion (Bullock 2011; Nicholson 2011) and the public continues they evaluate political candidates. This information typically
to respond to other information even when partisan cues are stems from media sources providing election coverage. Infor-
available (Arceneaux 2008; Boudreau and MacKenzie 2014; mation environments contribute to political knowledge (Delli
Sniderman and Stiglitz 2012). Considering the literature as a Carpini and Keeter 1996, 106–16; Luskin 1990), and the op-
whole, there is substantial and unexplained cross-study var- portunities for political learning created by an informative
Volume 79 Number 4 October 2017 / 1193

environment can increase knowledge even for those with low ample, in Downs’s (1957) conception cues are so powerful
degrees of political sophistication (Jerit et al. 2006) or who are largely because individuals refuse to bear the cost of search-
uninterested in politics (Downs 1957, 223; Hayes and Lawless ing out additional information on their own. If directly pro-
2015). While research links information-rich environments vided with more detail, however, there is nothing to stop in-
to increased political participation (Schulhofer-Wohl and Gar- dividuals from making use of other attributes to evaluate
rido 2013), political knowledge (Arnold 2004, Hayes and Law- candidates (see also Bullock 2011, 490; Green, Palmquist, and
less 2015), and even improved voter decision making on par- Schickler 2002, chap. 5; Popkin 1991).
ticular policy issues (Kuklinski et al. 2001), less attention has This is relevant because additional information is likely
been paid to how the information environment affects can- to introduce new considerations into candidate evaluation
didate preferences.1 that would not otherwise be present if voters focused only
Despite limited empirical examination, connections be- on candidate partisanship. While partisan cues signal many
tween the information environment and voters’ reliance on things, they are still an imperfect shortcut (Kuklinski and
party labels underpin many theories of partisanship and Quirk 2000). Some relevant information is not clearly linked to
cue taking. In one portrayal the importance of party labels party reputations (e.g., a candidate’s educational background).
stems from difficulties in obtaining other types of informa- Also, cues only serve as a reliable proxy for candidate issue
tion, at least for those uninterested in investing substantial positions when voters are aware of party reputations and can-
time pursuing political news (Downs 1957). This means vot- didates take stereotypical stances (Delli Carpini and Keeter
ers frequently decide between candidates based on limited 1996; Hutchings 2003; Snyder and Ting 2002). A richer infor-
amounts of political information (Converse 1964; Delli Car- mation environment allows individuals to assess candidate is-
pini and Keeter 1996). Absent detailed knowledge of partic- sue positions directly and incorporate details that are not part
ular candidates, voters use shortcuts to form candidate pref- of party reputations into their decisions, both points which
erences (Popkin 1991; Sniderman, Brody, and Tetlock 1991). support the expectation that more detailed information envi-
While voters turn to a variety of heuristics to evaluate can- ronments should reduce the role of partisanship in candidate
didates in low-information environments (e.g., Cutler 2002; evaluation.
Matson and Fine 2006; McDermott 2005; Popkin 1991), can- This intuitive expectation contrasts with research in which
didate partisanship serves as the “preeminent electoral cue” partisan cues are not only a shortcut but also alter the way
(Basinger and Lavine 2005, 171). Given elite efforts to culti- individuals use other pieces of information they encounter.
vate a consistent party brand (Cox and McCubbins 2005), Group attachment perspectives on partisanship focus on the
knowledge of a candidate’s partisanship offers insight into way partisan cues introduce a “perceptual lens” (e.g., Bartels
their issue positions (Grynaviski 2010; Snyder and Ting 2002) 2002; Campbell et al. 1960) to evaluations and generate par-
and priorities (Petrocik 1996). This allows partisan cues to tisan motivated reasoning (Bolsen et al. 2014; Druckman et al.
substitute for more detailed candidate information. Consis- 2013), leading voters to asses information so as to be as fa-
tent with this claim, partisan cues help individuals articulate vorable as possible to their partisan attachments. Absent strong
candidate choices (Garlick 2015; Schaffner and Streb 2002) and accuracy incentives, this motivated reasoning model describes
exert a large effect on vote choice (Meredith and Grissom 2010; the default type of political information processing in which
Schaffner, Streb, and Wright 2001). individuals engage (Bolsen et al. 2014; Bullock et al. 2015). This
suggests a muted effect for additional content as cues will lead
Partisan cues in low- and moderate- voters to discount unfavorable (favorable) information they
information environments receive about copartisan (out-partisan) candidates (e.g., Jerit
Although a variety of theoretical perspectives can accommo- and Barabas 2012; Slothuus and De Vreese 2010).
date large party cue effects in a low-information environment, Dual-process theories of partisan cue taking produce sim-
expectations differ for how additional information affects the ilar expectations through a different mechanism. Here parti-
role of partisanship. One hypothesis is that the availability of san cues reduce the costs of processing political information
additional information will reduce partisan cue use. For ex- (Eagly and Chaiken 1993; Petty and Cacioppo 1986). If the ad-
ditional information provided to respondents is difficult to as-
1. One exception is Snyder and Strömberg (2010, 383–87), which shows sess or they approach the candidate evaluation task with lim-
that incumbency is more relevant to voters in areas with higher levels of ited motivation to process these details, then voters should
candidate-specific media coverage. However, given findings in which party
and incumbency are not substitutes in candidate evaluation, this does not
ignore additional information and continue to use partisan cues
necessarily imply that more detailed information environments also reduce as the primary determinant of their evaluation when provided
partisan voting (e.g., Ansolabehere and Snyder 2002, 328). with more detailed candidate profiles (e.g., Rahn 1993).
1194 / Role of Information Environment in Partisan Voting Erik Peterson

Partisan cues in high-information environments by Survey Sampling International (SSI).2 Each respondent saw
A final hypothesis concerns the role of partisan cues in par- three pairs of candidate profiles. In the experiment respon-
ticularly rich information environments. While voters may dents received information about a pair of congressional can-
process modest amounts of information, in some campaign didates, one Republican and one Democrat, and selected which
settings they may become overwhelmed by the amount of po- one of the two candidates they would prefer to see in Con-
litical content they encounter (Barton 2015; Lau and Redlawsk gress. The two candidates were always from opposing polit-
2006; Rahn, Aldrich, and Borgida 1994; Riggle 1992; Simon ical parties, simulating a general election matchup, and can-
1985). Even if cue effects decline in the presence of moderate didate partisanship was always the first feature in the profile.
amounts of information, theories drawn from the social psy- Holding the placement of partisanship constant across profiles
chology literature on stereotypes and task complexity predict ensures that any change in the use of partisanship in longer
that partisan cues may become even more influential in en- profiles only results from the availability of other pieces of in-
vironments where citizens are exposed to a great deal of in- formation and not due to changes in the probability candidate
formation. As Lau and Redlawsk (2001, 955) write, “because partisanship received a prominent profile position.3 Lending
heuristics provide cognitive efficiency, they should be relied the exercise some external validity, these profiles closely re-
upon more heavily in more cognitively complex situations.” semble the voter guides distributed by many media organiza-
When a decision is particularly difficult, in this case because tions during political campaigns (e.g., Boudreau, Elmendorf,
of the amount of detail provided to voters and the array of po- and MacKenzie 2015; Mummolo and Peterson 2016).
tential dimensions on which to compare politicians, voters may The conjoint design randomly assigned several other as-
turn to cues to simplify the process of generating a summary pects of the candidate profiles. First, the amount of infor-
judgment (Bodenhausen and Lichentstein 1987; Malhotra 1982) mation that respondents received about the candidates varied
and to avoid systematic information processing under con- across profile pairs. While the profiles always included can-
ditions of high cognitive load (e.g., Tormala and Petty 2004, didate partisanship, they also featured one, three, five, seven,
430; see also Abelson and Levi 1985). or nine additional pieces of candidate information.4 Second,
In politics, partisanship offers a prominent and widely the type of information respondents encountered varied. For
available cue for voters to simplify decision making when example, among those receiving one additional piece of in-
faced with complexity. For instance, the revival of research formation, some respondents learned the candidates’ positions
on partisan selective exposure in news consumption is cred- concerning spending on government services while others re-
ited, in part, to an evolving media environment that has be- ceived information about their educational backgrounds.5 There
come capable of delivering much higher volumes of political were nine types of candidate information in total, so respon-
information, necessitating the use of partisan cues by news dents in the highest information condition all received the same
consumers to sort through this overwhelming information information types, although the order in which this was pre-
flow (Iyengar and Hahn 2009, 34). Moving to candidate eval- sented in the profile was randomized. Third, the values taken
uation, several studies find that voters become increasingly by these information attributes varied independently for each
reliant on partisanship in more complex information envi- candidate. This means a candidate’s position on government
ronments. Riggle (1992) tasks survey respondents to evaluate spending was unrelated to other aspects of their profile or the
either a single candidate or make comparative assessments of government spending stance taken by the other candidate.6
multiple politicians. In the complex comparative setting, re-
spondents depend more on partisanship to form evaluations.
2. Since the study examines partisan cues, only partisans were sam-
Lau and Redlawsk (2001, 960) compare the candidate infor-
pled. Subjects were quota sampled from SSI to match benchmarks among
mation that voters search for on static versus dynamic infor- partisans in the 2012 CCES. See appendix A for further details.
mation boards. They identify greater use of partisan cues in 3. This would be the case if the position of candidate partisanship
the more complex dynamic environments. In the present case, varied at the same time the number of candidate attributes in the profile
also changed.
support for this theory would indicate an increased reliance
4. Within each profile pair, respondents received the same amount of
on partisan cues in high-information conditions. information for each candidate.
5. These types of information were drawn from earlier candidate
STUDY 1: PARTISAN CUE EFFECTS conjoint experiments (Hainmueller et al. 2014, 17) and the types of can-
IN A CONJOINT EXPERIMENT didate information commonly provided in voter guides. The order of these
other pieces of information randomly varied across candidate profile pairs.
I first examine the effect of information volume on parti- 6. There were no restrictions imposed on candidate profile combi-
san voting using a conjoint survey experiment conducted on nations although there were unequal weights assigned to some attribute
1,057 partisan respondents recruited from a panel maintained levels. See appendix A for further description.
Volume 79 Number 4 October 2017 / 1195

Figure 1. Example conjoint profiles in different information conditions. A, One additional piece of candidate information. B, Nine additional pieces of
candidate information.

Figure 1 displays example profiles from the lowest and apps. A, B available online). This enables a test of expectations
highest information conditions.7 In the left panel the profile that high volumes of candidate information will overload re-
contained one additional piece of information beyond can- spondents’ ability to effortfully process each individual piece
didate partisanship, in this case information about the edu- and increase their use of heuristic evaluations based on par-
cational background of the candidates, which took the same tisan cues (Hainmueller, Hopkins, and Yamamoto 2014, 25;
value (“BA from state university”) for the candidate pair. The Malhotra 1982).
right panel shows an example from the highest information
condition in which respondents received details about the can- Analyzing the conjoint experiment
didate pair on nine different pieces of information beyond In examining the role of copartisanship in voting in the ex-
partisanship. In this pairing respondents were informed about periment, I estimate regression models of the following form.
the stance of the candidates on major social (abortion) and eco- Following the notation used in Hainmueller et al. (2014), i
nomic (government spending) issues, as well as demographic indexes individuals, k indexes the three pairs of profiles each
and biographical details such as the candidate’s race, gender individual received, and j indexes the two alternatives present
and profession. within a choice task:
Candidate partisanship is present in all conditions, which
enables a comparison of the role of partisanship in candidate Pref er Candidateijk p b0 1 b1 Copartisanijk
preferences across drastically different information environ- 1 b2 Inf ormation Amountijk
ments. As the actual content of this other information was also 1 b3 Copartisanijk
#Inf ormation Amountijk 1 ϵijk :
randomly assigned, both in terms of the attributes available
to evaluate a candidate and the specific attribute values, this
design allows an examination of the effects of information vol- The combination of multiple profiles and choice tasks
ume on partisan voting in a way that generalizes beyond one for each respondent means that 6,216 profile evaluations are
particular candidate profile. Finally, the profiles in the high- available for analysis. The outcome is an indicator variable for
information conditions contained an extensive amount of can- whether the respondent preferred that candidate. Copartisan
didate information. As evidenced by the additional time re- is an indicator variable for whether the candidate shared a
spondents took responding to these longer profiles, this placed respondent’s partisanship. Information Amount takes the value
more extensive information processing demands on respon- of the number of other pieces of information included in the
dents (see app. A for a description of this manipulation check; candidate profile. The interaction between these terms enables
an examination of changes in the role of copartisanship as re-
7. Examples from all information conditions can be found in ap- spondents received different amounts of candidate informa-
pendix A. tion. While some subsequent analyses control for the partic-
1196 / Role of Information Environment in Partisan Voting Erik Peterson

by 29 percentage points (95% confidence interval [21, 37]).


Between these two poles there is a decline in the effect of co-
partisanship on vote choice. There does not appear to be in-
creased cue taking even at high information levels.9
To provide a more concise summary of these results, table 1
displays estimates from regression models where information
amount enters the regression as a continuous variable. The mar-
ginal effects from this model are indicated by the gray line in
figure 2. This produces the estimate that each additional piece
of information reduces the effect of copartisanship on candi-
date preference by 4.5 percentage points (95% confidence in-
terval [25.6, 23.5]). As the right two columns of table 1
show, including controls for the information types available
in the candidate profiles and the particular levels the candidates
took on these attributes leaves the relationship between infor-
mation amount and reliance on partisan cues unchanged.10
Figure 2. Effect of copartisanship on candidate support. Data from a conjoint
survey experiment conducted on SSI (n p 1,059). Each respondent evaluated
Effects of information types on partisan voting
three profile pairs. Figure shows the effect of copartisanship on vote choice
at varying levels of information. Estimates obtained from an interaction model
The previous section shows an overall decline in partisan
in which copartisanship is interacted with a separate dummy variable for each voting due to increased information. This section examines
information level. The 95% confidence intervals were obtained from robust heterogeneity in copartisan voting by the types of candidate
standard errors, clustered by respondent. The gray line indicates the marginal information provided. These models interact the types of in-
effect of copartisanship from an interaction model where information amount
formation received with copartisanship to assess changes in
is coded as a continuous variable.
the effect of partisanship on candidate preferences due to the
availability of particular information types. A series of indi-
ular attributes available to evaluate a candidate and the values cator variables represent whether a particular type of infor-
these attributes took, these other aspects of the profiles were mation was available in a candidate pairing. Figure 3 shows the
randomly assigned and including them does not appreciably marginal effect of copartisanship when other types of candi-
change estimates of the main coefficients of interest. date information are available, conditional on the total amount
Figure 2 displays the marginal effect of copartisanship on of information an individual received.11
vote choice, indicating the extent to which respondents pre- Figure 3 shows that the role of partisanship is most
ferred copartisan candidates at these different information lev- sharply reduced when respondents have information about
els. To avoid imposing a functional form on the relationship the policy positions taken by the candidates on two key issues:
between information and partisan voting, particularly because government spending and abortion. For example, relative to
some theories generate expectations of nonlinearities, the in- a baseline with information about candidate race, the effect
formation amount is entered into the regression as a series of of copartisanship declined by 24 percentage points (95% con-
separate indicator variables for each level.8 fidence interval [232, 216]) when respondents received the
As expected, partisanship exerts a powerful effect on vote candidates’ positions on abortion policy. This decline aligns
choice. When provided with only one other piece of infor-
mation, copartisanship increased the probability that a re-
9. The decline in partisan voting is particular prominent when mov-
spondent preferred a candidate by 70 percentage points (95% ing from one piece of information to three and seven pieces of information
confidence interval [64, 76]). However, this effect declines in to nine. While this study focuses on the general relationship between and
a more information-rich environment. At the highest infor- partisan cue effectiveness, explaining this heterogeneity presents a topic
for future research.
mation level included in this experiment, copartisanship in-
10. Information type refers to the presence or absence of a particular
creased the probability that a respondent selected a candidate attribute (e.g, military service) in the candidate profiles. Information
content refers to the particular values of these attributes (e.g., served in the
military or did not serve in the military). Indicator variables for the
8. This is implemented in a fully saturated regression model interacting presence or absence of a particular attribute/attribute level are included in
copartisanship with dummy variables for each information level. This non- the regressions to control for the presence of these features.
parametric estimation approach does not depend on functional form as- 11. Appendix A, figures A8 and A9 show individual attribute effects
sumptions (Angrist and Pischke 2009, 51; Hainmueller et al. 2014, 15). for Democrats and Republicans.
Volume 79 Number 4 October 2017 / 1197

Table 1. Probability (Prefer Candidate) by Information Amount partisan match-ups, with a Republican candidate taking lib-
eral positions on abortion policy and government spending
Controls: facing a Democrat taking conservative positions on these
Controls: Info Type 1
same issues. High levels of polarization between the two par-
Baseline Info Type Content
ties in contemporary politics mean this type of candidate
pairing is rarely encountered by voters (McCarty, Poole, and
(Intercept) .147* .147* .148*
Rosenthal 2006). Previous research also finds that this sort of
(.015) (.015) (.015)
Copartisan .705* .705* .703* counter-stereotypical position taking can lead to harsh sanc-
(.030) (.030) (.030) tions for candidates at odds with their party’s reputation on
Information Amount .023* .023* .010 salient issues (Arceneaux 2008; Nicholson 2011). One possi-
(.003) (.003) (.006) bility is that the reduction in copartisan voting may be largely
Copartisan # driven by these counter-stereotypical match-ups.
Information Amount 2.045* 2.045* 2.045* To examine whether these findings are due to counter-
(.005) (.005) (.005)
stereotypical pairings, the left panel of figure 4 reestimates
N 6,216 6,216 6,216
these relationships after discarding 1,566 profile pairs with
Note. Robust standard errors are in parentheses, clustered by respondent. counter-stereotypical candidate pairs (i.e., profiles in which
* Indicates significance at p ! .05. the Republican candidate took a more liberal position than
the Democrat). These results are largely similar, although re-
moving these profiles slightly attenuates the extent to which
well with theories in which party labels are powerful, in part, additional information reduces the role of copartisanship in
because of the issue content they convey (e.g., Downs 1957; vote choice. Moving from the lowest to highest informa-
Sniderman and Stiglitz 2012). When this information is di- tion condition, the effect of copartisanship on candidate prefer-
rectly provided, party cues lose some of their importance. ences declines by 33 percentage points (95% confidence in-
Candidate profession, military service, family status, and terval [244, 223]). Even without counter-stereotypical issue
education also produce more moderate declines in party cue
effects, consistent with studies where personal characteristics of
politicians are also an important input into voting decisions
(e.g., McDermott 2005; Popkin 1991). For instance, relative
to the baseline condition with candidate race, the effect of
copartisanship declined by 11 percentage points (95% con-
fidence interval [219, 23]) for respondents who received in-
formation about a candidate’s education. Finally, partisan cues
exerted the strongest effect on voter preferences when the other
information consisted of candidate demographics such as age,
gender, and race. These are important candidate attributes
in their own right (e.g., Cutler 2002), but in this setting they
appear to have a more limited role, relative to these other types
of information, in reducing the effect of partisanship.
While figure 3 shows that information about issue posi-
tions is a large contributor to declines in partisan voting, one
potential concern is that these findings are conditional on the
distribution of candidate positions presented to voters in the
Figure 3. Effect of copartisanship on candidate support by information type.
experiment. As Hainmueller et al. (2014, 10–12) make clear,
Data from a conjoint survey experiment conducted on SSI (n p 1,059). Each
the treatment effect estimated for any individual attribute in respondent evaluated three profile pairs. Figure shows the effect of copar-
a conjoint design depends on the underlying distribution of tisanship on vote choice when different types of information are presented
the other attribute values in the experiment. Since no restric- along with party. Estimates obtained from a model interacting copartisanship
tions were imposed on candidate issue positions, they were with an indicator for whether a type of information was available in the pro-
file. The reference condition (indicated by the square point and dashed line)
unrelated to a candidate’s party affiliation. This means the ef- is the marginal effect of copartisanship in profiles with information about a
fects are conditional on a particular type of information flow candidate’s race. The 95% confidence intervals were obtained from robust
in which some candidate pairs involved counter-stereotypical standard errors, clustered by respondent.
1198 / Role of Information Environment in Partisan Voting Erik Peterson

Figure 4. Effect of copartisanship on candidate support—subset by information type. Data from a conjoint survey experiment conducted on SSI (n p 1,059).
Each respondent evaluated three profile pairs. Figure shows the effect of copartisanship on vote choice at varying levels of information subset by the types of
information in the profile. Estimates obtained from an interaction model interacting copartisanship with a separate dummy variable for each information
level. The 95% confidence intervals were obtained from robust standard errors, clustered by respondent. Gray lines indicate the marginal effect of copartisanship
from an interaction model where information amount is coded as a continuous variable.

information, additional information can still reduce individu- STUDY 2: PARTISAN VOTING IN
als’ reliance on partisan cues. CONGRESSIONAL ELECTIONS
As a final check on whether nonissue information can pro- The conjoint experiment shows that additional information
duce declines in partisan voting, the right panel of figure 4 reduces the role of partisanship in vote choice. While findings
examines whether these same patterns emerge when issue from conjoint experiments—particularly the paired profile de-
content is entirely removed from the options presented to sign used here—have shown a high degree of external validity
respondents. This subsets the analysis to the 1,746 profiles in when compared to real world decisions (Hainmueller, Han-
which individuals received no issue information about the can- gartner, and Yamamoto 2015), it remains unclear how the
didates and necessarily removes the highest information con- findings in the previous section generalize outside of a survey
dition in which all respondents received issue information. experiment environment. There are two key concerns about
Even without issue content there is still a decline in copartisan the generalizability of these results. First, the experiment in-
voting when respondents are presented with additional infor- volved hypothetical candidates in an election that did not mat-
mation. For example, moving from the low-information condi- ter for the respondents. The broader campaign environment
tion to one in which respondents received five additional pieces in which elections take place means pressures to heed parti-
of information the effect of copartisanship declined by 18 per- sanship may be more prominent during real elections (Gelman
centage points (95% confidence interval [236, —1]). While the and King 1993; Huddy et al. 2015; Iyengar et al. 2012). Second,
point estimate for the effect of copartisanship increases slightly the experiment provided information directly to voters. Given
when moving from five to seven pieces of information when the public’s news consumption preferences, many individuals
no issues are present, this estimate is very imprecise as there will avoid encountering additional information if given the
were relatively few of these profiles in which individuals re- option (Prior 2007).
ceived no policy information (n p 46). Overall, while issue This section turns to an observational analogue to the ex-
content is a particularly strong contributor to reduced partisan periment and examines variation in the role of copartisan-
voting in the high information conditions, additional infor- ship in voting for Congress based on differences in the quality
mation provision still reduces the role of partisanship even of the information environment. Prior research reveals wide
when information about candidate positioning is unavailable.12 variation in the extent to which newspapers—the primary
source of original reporting in the local media environment
(Mondak 1995; Pew 2010)—devote attention to congressional
elections (e.g., Arnold 2004; Hayes and Lawless 2015; Snyder
12. Table A8 in appendix B displays similar results when information and Strömberg 2010). Several factors contribute to whether a
enters as a continuous variable. particular race receives media attention such as the economic
Volume 79 Number 4 October 2017 / 1199

health of news outlets (Meyer 2008), the perceived competi- stead that while the paper remains the sole news provider in
tiveness of the election (Hayes and Lawless 2015), and the that particular county district, its readership is instead evenly
manner in which media markets align with political constit- spread across two different congressional districts. The con-
uencies (Snyder and Strömberg 2010). gruence score for that particular county district would fall
Snyder and Strömberg (2010) introduce a measure of the to .5, indicating the paper would split its coverage efforts to
extent to which voters receive information about their mem- provide information to both sets of readers. This means news-
ber of Congress based on the alignment between media mar- readers would often encounter reporting on a member of
kets and congressional districts. This measure stems from the Congress that did not represent them. Snyder and Strömberg
finding that the amount of coverage a newspaper devotes to (2010, 369) validate this measure using the relationship be-
a particular member of Congress is highly dependent on the tween congruence and the number of articles written by a
share of the paper’s readership residing in that district (see newspaper about a particular member of Congress. They re-
also Arnold 2004; Hayes and Lawless 2015; Levy and Squire port that a one standard deviation change in congruence is as-
2000). For example, if most of a newspaper’s readership re- sociated with the average person reading 10 additional news-
sides in a single congressional district with a small portion paper articles about their member of Congress each term.
spread across other districts, the member of Congress repre- Congruence measures the quality of the information envi-
senting most of the paper’s readership will receive substan- ronment, with respect to congressional elections, in which
tially more press attention than representatives of the out- an individual resides. At high levels of congruence, —.voters
lying districts. This means the newsreaders in outlying districts encounter more news about both the incumbent and chal-
encounter less coverage of their representative. Snyder and lenger candidates in their district (Snyder and Strömberg 2010,
Strömberg (2010) formalize this notion using a measure called 384). While less precise than varying information levels piece
Congruence based on county-level newspaper sales data from by piece as in the conjoint experiment, variation in congruence
the Audit Bureau of Circulations in 1982 and for every year be- represents an observational analogue to earlier experimental
tween 1991 and 2004. For the period between 1983 and 1990, results. Importantly, congruence offers a plausibly exogenous
a newspaper’s county sales figures are interpolated (Snyder and shift in the information environment. Previous research shows
Strömberg 2010, 362). that the relationships between congruence and congress-specific
Congruence is defined at the level of county-congressional voter knowledge are robust to a number of estimation ap-
district pairs and, averaging across all the newspapers with sub- proaches, an extensive battery of control variables, and pass
scribers in a given county, provides a measure of the average several placebo checks (e.g., Snyder and Strömberg 2010, 377).
share of newspaper readership living in that congressional dis- This allows greater confidence in a causal interpretation of
trict. This measure is weighted by the market share of each any relationships between congruence and copartisan vot-
newspaper in that county. With c indexing counties, d index- ing. This also sets congruence apart from candidate-controlled
ing congressional districts, and m indexing each paper sold sources of variation in the campaign information environment
in a given county, Snyder and Strömberg (2010) compute Con- (e.g., television advertising), which may be specifically tar-
gruence in the following manner: geted toward voters or areas with a tendency to defect from
M the party line. For this reason, using these other types of mea-
Congruencecd p o Market Share
mp1
mc Reader Sharemd : sures to characterize the information environment could pro-
duce a spurious relationship between information volume and
In this equation Market Sharemc always sums to one across patterns of copartisan voting.
all the newspapers available in a county, Reader Sharemd ranges In what follows I use data matching respondents to the
between zero and one for each individual newspaper, and National Election Studies to data on congruence for the pe-
Congruencecd ultimately ranges between zero (very low infor- riod between 1982 and 2004.13 I assess the role of copartisan-
mation congressional districts) and one (very high informa- ship in voting decisions in a similar manner to the conjoint
tion congressional districts). To provide intuition on this mea- experiment by interacting an individual’s partisanship with
sure, consider the simplified case where a single newspaper is congruence to examine variation in voting for copartisan can-
available in a county (i.e., Market Share is equal to one with didates based on the quality of the information environment.
no need to sum over different newspapers). A congruence score This analysis employs two different specifications to isolate
equal to one implies that all of the newspaper’s readers reside
in the same congressional district and indicates that the paper
will focus its reporting efforts on a single member of Congress 13. This comes from the replication file for Snyder and Strömberg (2010;
that is relevant to its entire readership. However, suppose in- http://www.jstor.org/stable/suppl/10.1086/652903/suppl_file/2008113data.zip).
1200 / Role of Information Environment in Partisan Voting Erik Peterson

the causal effect of the information environment on partisan correlated with congruence produce a spurious relationship be-
voting. tween congruence and voting.
The first specification uses within-district variation in This specification takes the following form:
congruence. Following notation from Snyder and Strömberg
Vote Democratic Candidatei p b0 1 b1 Copartisani
(2010), i indexes individuals, c indexes counties and d indexes 1 b2 Congruencecd
congressional districts: 1 b3 Copartisani
Vote Democratic Candidatei p b0 1 b1 Copartisani #Congruencecd
1 b2 Congruencecd 1 ac 1 asy 1 gi 1 rr 1 ϵi :
1  b3 Copartisani Here ac is a set of county-fixed effects, asy is a set of state-
#Congruencecd year fixed effects, and rr is a set of control variables concerning
1    ady 1 gi 1 dc 1 ϵi :
characteristics of a district’s incumbent congressional repre-
Copartisan takes the value of one if the incumbent party sentative.15 Other variables are the same as the within-district
candidate in an individual’s district shares their party label model.
and zero otherwise; Congruence runs from zero to one and is Figure 5 presents the marginal effect of copartisanship
defined at the county-district level. The interaction between on vote choice at different levels of congruence. For each
these two variables allows for differences in the tendency of specification there is a downward slope in the marginal effect
individuals to vote for copartisan candidates at different lev- of copartisanship on candidate support. This indicates that
els of congruence. The vector ady contains fixed effects for each in more information-rich media environments voters are
congressional district in each election year. This means the less likely to vote for copartisan members of Congress. Be-
only variation used in estimating this model occurs from in- cause there is an expectation that overload can occur at
dividuals living in different counties of the same district. This particularly high levels of information, figure 5 contains
holds constant both observable (e.g., campaign spending) and points which represent the marginal effects of copartisanship
unobservable (e.g., the quality differential between the two on vote choice with congruence binned into three separate
candidates) characteristics of these elections that do not vary categories rather than entering the regression in a continu-
within district. Finally, gi is a vector of individual-level control ous manner. As in the conjoint experiment, this nonpara-
variables from the surveys including education, income, and metric approach fails to reveal increased reliance on partisan
political interest; dc is a set of controls for county-level vari- cues in high information environments.
ables such as racial composition and median income.14 The Table 2 assesses the statistical significance of these rela-
analysis is conducted among partisan respondents to the NES tionships. In the within-district model the interaction be-
in elections with candidates from each party. tween copartisanship and congruence falls short of con-
A second redistricting specification uses changes in con- ventional levels of significance (p p .16, two-tailed test).
gruence introduced at the county-level when the alignment However, in the redistricting specification the interaction
between media markets and political constituencies changes between copartisanship and congruence is statistically signif-
due to redistricting. For example, a county may become more icant. In substantive terms, a typical change in congruence—
congruent if during redistricting it is moved to a congressional which Snyder and Strömberg (2010, 369) report is equivalent
district that is better aligned with its local newspapers. To iso- to the typical district resident reading 10 additional news-
late variation in congruence due to redistricting, a fixed mea- paper articles per term about their incumbent representative—
sure of each newspaper’s sales in a county (the average sales produces an expected decline in an individual’s tendency
over 1982–2004) is used for all years when calculating the ver- to vote for a copartisan candidate by .4 percentage points
sion of congruence used in the redistricting model. Since the (95% confidence interval [2.9, .1]) in the within-district model
sales data do not change over time, the only variation in con- and .8 percentage points (95% confidence interval [21.7,
gruence that occurs after placing county fixed effects into the 2.04]) in the redistricting model.16
model stems from a county’s changing relationship to con- As a check on the degree to which these results can receive a
gressional districts due to redistricting (see Snyder and Ström- causal interpretation, table 3 presents estimates from several
berg 2010, 376). The use of these over-time changes helps to
15. These representative-specific control variables are all interacted
remove concerns that unmeasured variables cross-sectionally with representative partisanship to allow their consequences for Demo-
cratic support to vary based on incumbent partisanship.
16. This typical change is based on a one standard deviation shift in
14. See appendix B for a full list of these other covariates for both congruence using the residual variation in congruence net of other
model specifications. covariates included in the model.
Volume 79 Number 4 October 2017 / 1201

Figure 5. Copartisanship and candidate support by level of congruence. Data from the National Election Study (1982–2004) (n p 4,792). Figure shows the
increase in the probability of voting for a copartisan congressional candidate at varying levels of media market congruence. Estimates from a model in-
teracting copartisanship with congruence. The 95% confidence intervals were obtained using robust standard errors, clustered by congressional race
(within-district model) or county (redistricting model). Points are estimates of the increase in support for copartisan candidates from an interaction model
with separate indicator variables for three binned levels of congruence.

placebo specifications relating congruence to vote choice in their analysis, which they attribute to media coverage infor-
elections for other offices. The notion behind these placebos is ming constituents of their incumbent representative’s accom-
that, as congruence is based around the alignment between plishments (see also Schaffner 2006). Paired with the findings
congressional districts and media markets, it should be unre- from study 2, this reveals a trade-off between incumbency
lated to the extent to which voters receive information about and partisan cues here that is not present in some other set-
other offices (Snyder and Strömberg 2010, 376). For example, a tings (e.g., Ansolabehere, Hirano, and Snyder 2006; Ansola-
newspaper can offer coverage of presidential politics that is behere and Snyder 2002) and suggests that the additional
relevant to all its readers, no matter its relationship to local incumbent-specific information received by more congruent
congressional districts. As table 3 indicates, these placebos are districts contributes to reduced partisan voting. Second, while
generally supportive as they fail to find an interaction between this demonstrates the capacity for the local media environ-
congruence and the tendency to vote for copartisan candidates ment to influence partisan voting, the analysis ends in 2004.
for governor or president (app. B contains tables for the within-
district specification). However, there is a relationship between
Table 2. Probability (Vote for Politician) by Level of Con-
congruence and copartisan voting in Senate elections that is
gruence
similar in magnitude to the finding in table 2.
These placebo results suggest some caution in interpret- Within District Redistricting
ing the congruence estimates as completely the product of
local media coverage of Congress, as congruence should not Congruence .22 .13
matter for Senate coverage. However, when paired with the (.20) (.10)
conjoint experiment and the generally supportive results for Copartisan .57* .62*
voting for the other two offices, this analysis provides some (.03) (.02)
evidence that information environments causally contribute Copartisan # Congruence 2.08 2.15*
to declines in copartisan voting (see app. B for a full descrip- (.06) (.05)
N 4,792 4,906
tion of these placebo results).
In assessing these results, several additional points are rel-
Note. Robust standard errors are in parentheses, clustered by congres-
evant. First, Snyder and Strömberg (2010, 383–87) identify a sional race (within-district) or county (redistricting).
larger incumbency advantage in high-congruence districts in * p ! .05.
1202 / Role of Information Environment in Partisan Voting Erik Peterson

Table 3. Probability (Vote for Politician) by Level of Con- than portraying information-rich settings as an abstract ideal
gruence—Redistricting Specification that arise only in experiments, study 2 demonstrates that high-
information local media environments have consequences for
Senator Governor President
voters’ reliance on partisanship in real elections.
Second, these findings challenge common mechanisms
Congruence .28* .05 2.06
thought to explain partisan cue effects. Along with several other
(.11) (.13) (.10)
Copartisan .60* .55* .75*
studies, I find that cues fail to distort or mute the role of other
(.02) (.03) (.02) information as individuals form opinions about policies and
Copartisan # Congruence 2.11* 2.03 2.02 candidates (Boudreau and MacKenzie 2014; Bullock 2011).
(.04) (.06) (.04) While there are certainly countervailing instances in which
N 4,892 2,875 4,046 partisanship does lead individuals to engage in motivated pro-
cessing of information or ignore content that fails to align with
Note. Robust standard errors, clustered by county, are in parentheses. All
their partisan predispositions (Druckman et al. 2013; Slothuus
models include county and state-year fixed effects along with individual and
congressional race covariates.
and De Vreese 2010), partisan cues fail to impede information
* p ! .05. processing in a number of politically relevant settings. What
conditions lead partisan cues to interact with information pro-
cessing? Explaining this type of cross-study variation represents
Given the tremendous declines in the local newspaper indus- an important next step for this line of research (see also Leeper
try that have since occurred (Hayes and Lawless 2015; Meyer and Slothuus 2014).
2008; Schulhofer-Wohl and Garrido 2013), the local media Third, these results contrast with expectations that in-
environment today likely has less capacity to affect voter creased information provision may increase voters’ reliance
preferences than in the period examined here. Finally, while on partisan cues (e.g., Lau and Redlawsk 2001). The findings
the direction of these findings is consistent with study 1, the here show that more information, at least over the levels
substantive effects of information on reduced partisan voting available in congressional elections, does not appear to have
are much smaller in study 2. The same features that make this this consequence. This may change if even more detailed in-
setting a tough test for observing information-induced declines formation environments were examined. For example, Barton
in partisan voting in the first place (e.g., no forced exposure (2015) reports high levels of self-reported information over-
to information) also appear to attenuate the consequences of load in presidential election campaigns. However, the settings
changes in the information environment. examined here are relevant for a wide array of political sit-
uations. Study 1 approximates the detailed voter guides pro-
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION vided to voters by media outlets (e.g., Mummolo and Peter-
Across two studies more detailed information environments son 2016), and study 2 examines real-world variation in the
reduced the extent to which individuals relied on partisanship amount of information offered by newspapers.
to structure their candidate preferences. The conjoint exper-
iment in study 1 allowed precise control of the information ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
provided to respondents and enabled an examination of the I thank Justin Grimmer, Jay Hamilton, Shanto Iyengar, Rune
contribution of different types of information to reduced co- Slothuus, Jonathan Mummolo, and Gabor Simonovits for
partisan voting. Study 2 used variation in the quality of the helpful comments and suggestions and David Strömberg for
local media environment for congressional elections to show sharing data. Previous versions of this article were presented
that these patterns persist even when partisan pressures are at annual meetings of the Midwest Political Science Associa-
high, elections have consequences and voters can choose to tion and American Political Science Association.
avoid political information.
These findings demonstrate the conditions that underpin
REFERENCES
large partisan cue effects. Absent other information, voters use Abelson, Robert P., and Ariel Levi. 1985. “Decision Making and Decision
partisanship to evaluate candidates. They depend on partisan- Theory.” In Gardner Lindzey and Elliot Aronson, eds., The Handbook
ship to a reduced, although still substantial, extent when pro- of Social Psychology. New York: Random House, 231–309.
vided with more detail. While previous research provided sug- Angrist, Joshua D., and Jörn-Steffen Pischke. 2009. Mostly Harmless
Econometrics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
gestive evidence that high-information environments reduce Ansolabehere, Stephen, Shigeo Hirano, and James M. Snyder Jr. 2006. “Party
the effects of partisan cues on opinion (Bullock 2011, 510), this and Incumbency Cues in Voting: Are They Substitutes?” Quarterly Jour-
study demonstrates it directly in two settings. Moreover, rather nal of Political Science 1 (2): 119–37.
Volume 79 Number 4 October 2017 / 1203

Ansolabehere, Stephen, and James M. Snyder Jr. 2002. “The Incumbency Eagly, Alice H., and Shelly Chaiken. 1993. The Psychology of Attitudes. San
Advantage in US Elections: An Analysis of State and Federal Offices, Diego, CA: Harcourt.
1942–2000.” Election Law Journal 1 (3): 315–38. Garlick, Alex. 2015. “ ‘The Letter after Your Name’: Party Labels on
Arceneaux, Kevin. 2008. “Can Partisan Cues Diminish Democratic Ac- Virginia Ballots.” State Politics and Policy Quarterly 15 (2): 147–70.
countability?” Political Behavior 30 (2): 139–60. Gelman, Andrew, and Gary King. 1993. “Why Are American Election
Arnold, R. Douglas. 2004. Congress, the Press, and Political Accountability. Campaign Polls So Variable When Votes Are So Predictable.” British
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Journal of Political Science 23 (4): 409–51.
Bartels, Larry M. 2000. “Partisanship and Voting Behavior, 1952–1996.” Green, Donald, Bradley Palmquist, and Eric Schickler. 2002. Partisan
American Journal of Political Science 44 (1): 35–50. Hearts and Minds: Political Parties and the Social Identities of Voters.
Bartels, Larry M. 2002. “Beyond the Running Tally: Partisan Bias in Po- New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
litical Perceptions.” Political Behavior 24 (2): 117–50. Grynaviski, Jeffrey D. 2010. Partisan Bonds: Political Reputations and
Barton, Dona-Gene. 2015. “Enough Already! Alleviating Political Infor- Legislative Accountability. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
mation Overload by Avoiding Political News.” Presented at the annual Hainmueller, Jens, Dominik Hangartner, and Teppei Yamamoto. 2015.
meeting of the American Political Science Association. “Validating Vignette and Conjoint Survey Experiments against Real-
Basinger, Scott J., and Howard Lavine. 2005. “Ambivalence, Informa- World Behavior.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112
tion, Electoral Choice.” American Political Science Review 99 (2): 169–84. (8): 2395–400.
Bodenhausen, Galen V., and Meryl Lichtenstein. 1987. “Social Stereotypes Hainmueller, Jens, Daniel J. Hopkins, and Teppei Yamamoto. 2014. “Casual
and Information-Processing Strategies: The Impact of Task Com- Inference in Conjoint Analysis: Understanding Multidimensional Choices
plexity.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 52 (5): 871–80. via Stated Preference Experiments.” Political Analysis 22 (1): 1–30.
Bolsen, Toby, James N. Druckman, and Fay Lomax Cook. 2014. “The Hainmueller, Jens, Daniel J. Hopkins, and Teppei Yamamoto. 2015. “Learn-
Influence of Partisan Motivated Reasoning on Public Opinion.” Po- ing More from Conjoint Experiments through a Doubly Randomized
litical Behavior 36 (2): 235–52. Design.” Presented at International Methods Colloquium, October 23.
Boudreau, Cheryl, Christopher S. Elmendorf, and Scott A. MacKenzie. Hayes, Danny, and Jennifer L. Lawless. 2015. “As Local News Goes, So
2015. “Informing Electorates via Election Law: An Experimental Study Goes Citizen Engagement: Media, Knowledge, and Participation in US
of Partisan Endorsements and Nonpartisan Voter Guides in Local House Elections.” Journal of Politics 77 (2): 447–62.
Elections.” Election Law Journal 14 (1): 2–23. Huddy, Leonie, Lilliana Mason, and Lene Aaroe. 2015. “Expressive Par-
Boudreau, Cheryl, and Scott A. MacKenzie. 2014. “Informing the Elec- tisanship: Campaign Involvement, Political Emotion and Partisan
torate? How Party Cues and Policy Information Affect Public Opin- Identity.” American Political Science Review 109 (1): 1–17.
ion about Initiatives.” American Journal of Political Science 58 (1): 48– Hutchings, Vincent. 2003. Public Opinion and Democratic Accountability.
62. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Bullock, John, Alan Gerber, Seth Hill, and Gregory Huber. 2015. “Partisan Iyengar, Shanto, and Kyu S. Hahn. 2009. “Red Media, Blue Media: Evi-
Bias in Factual Beliefs about Politics.” Quarterly Journal of Political dence of Ideological Selectivity in Media Use.” Journal of Communi-
Science 10:519–78. cation 59 (1): 19–39.
Bullock, John. 2011. “Elite Influence on Public Opinion in an Informed Iyengar, Shanto, Gaurav Sood, and Yphtach Lelkes. 2012. “Affect, Not
Electorate.” American Political Science Review 105 (3): 469–515. Ideology: A Social Identity Perspective on Polarization.” Public Opinion
Campbell, Angus, Philip Converse, William Miller, and Donald Stokes. Quarterly 76 (3): 405–31.
1960. The American Voter. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley. Jerit, Jennifer, and Jason Barabas. 2012. “Partisan Perceptual Bias and the
Cohen, Geoffrey L. 2003. “Party over Policy: The Dominating Impact of Information Environment.” Journal of Politics 74 (3): 672–84.
Group Influence on Political Beliefs.” Journal of Personality and Social Jerit, Jennifer, Jason Barabas, and Toby Bolsen. 2006. “Citizens, Knowl-
Psychology 85 (5): 808–22. edge, and the Information Environment.” American Journal of Polit-
Converse, Phillip E. 1964. “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics.” ical Science 50 (2): 266–82.
In David Apter, ed., Ideology and Discontent. Washington, DC: Free Kam, Cindy D. 2005. “Who Toes the Party Line? Cues, Values and In-
Press, 206–61. dividual Differences.” Political Behavior 27 (2): 163–82.
Cox, Gary W., and Matthew D. McCubbins. 2005. Setting the Agenda: Klar, Samara. 2014. “Partisanship in a Social Setting.” American Journal of
Responsible Party Government in the U.S. House of Representatives. Political Science 58 (3): 687–704.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kuklinski, James H., and Paul J. Quirk. 2000. “Reconsidering the Rational
Cutler, Fred. 2002. “The Simplest Shortcut of All: Sociodemographic Public: Cognition, Heuristics, and Mass Opinion.” In Arthur Lupia, Matthew
Characteristics and Electoral Choice.” Journal of Politics 64 (2): 466–90. McCubbins, and Samuel Popkin, eds., Elements of Reason: Cognition, Choice
Delli Carpini, Michael, and Scott Keeter. 1996. What Americans Know and the Bounds of Rationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
about Politics. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Kuklinski, James H., Paul J. Quirk, Jennifer Jerit, and Robert F. Rich. 2001.
Delli Carpini, Michael, Scott Keeter, and J. David Kennamer. 1994. “Ef- “The Political Environment and Citizen Competence.” American Journal
fects of the News Media Environment on Citizen Knowledge of State of Political Science 45 (2): 410–24.
Politics and Government.” Journalism Quarterly 71 (2): 443–56. Lau, Richard R., and David P. Redlawsk. 2001. “Advantages and Dis-
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: advantages of Cognitive Heuristics in Political Decision-Making.”
Harper & Row. American Journal of Political Science 45 (4): 951–71.
Druckman, James N. 2014. “Pathologies of Studying Public Opinion, Lau, Richard R., and David P. Redlawsk. 2006. How Voters Decide: Infor-
Political Communication, and Democratic Responsiveness.” Political mation Processing during Election Campaigns. Cambridge: Cambridge
Communication 31 (3): 467–92. University Press.
Druckman, James N., Erik Peterson, and Rune Slothuus. 2013. “How Elite Lavine, Howard G., Christopher D. Johnston, and Marco R. Steenbergen.
Partisan Polarization Affects Public Opinion Formation.” American 2012. The Ambivalent Partisan: How Critical Loyalty Promotes De-
Political Science Review 107 (1): 57–79. mocracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
1204 / Role of Information Environment in Partisan Voting Erik Peterson

Leeper, Thomas J., and Rune Slothuus. 2014. “Political Parties, Motivated Prior, Markus. 2007. Post-Broadcast Democracy: How Media Choice In-
Reasoning, and Public Opinion Formation.” Political Psychology 35 (1): creases Inequality in Political Involvement and Polarizes Elections. Cam-
129–56. bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Levendusky, Matthew. 2010. “Clearer Cues, More Consistent Voters: A Rahn, Wendy M. 1993. “The Role of Partisan Stereotypes in Information
Benefit of Elite Polarization.” Political Behavior 32 (1): 111–31. Processing about Political Candidates.” American Journal of Political
Levy, Dena, and Peverill Squire. 2000. “Television Markets and the Com- Science 37 (2): 472–96.
petitiveness of U.S. House Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 25 (2): Rahn, Wendy M., John H. Aldrich, and Eugene Borgida. 1994. “Individual
313–25. and Contextual Variations in Political Candidate Approval.” American
Luskin, Robert C. 1990. “Explaining Political Sophistication.” Political Political Science Review 88 (1): 193–99.
Behavior 12 (4): 331–61. Riggle, Ellen D. 1992. “Cognitive Strategies and Candidate Evaluations.”
Malhotra, Naresh K. 1982. “Information Load and Consumer Decision American Politics Quarterly 20 (2): 227–46.
Making.” Journal of Consumer Research 8 (4): 419–30. Schaffner, Brian F. 2006. “Local News Coverage and the Incumbency
Matson, Marsha, and Terri Suan Fine. 2006. “Gender, Ethnicity, and Advantage in the U.S. House.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 31 (4):
Ballot Information: Ballot Cues in Low-Information Elections.” State 491–511.
Politics and Policy Quarterly 6 (1): 49–72. Schaffner, Brian F., and Matthew J. Streb. 2002. “The Partisan Heuristic
McCarty, Nolan M., Keith T. Poole, and Howard Rosenthal. 2006. Polarized in Low-Information Elections.” Public Opinion Quarterly 66 (4): 559–81.
America: The Dance of Ideology and Unequal Riches. Cambridge, MA: Schaffner, Brian F., Matthew J. Streb, and Gerald Wright. 2001. “Teams
MIT Press. without Uniforms: The Nonpartisan Ballot in State and Local Elections.”
McDermott, Monika L. 2005. “Candidate Occupations and Voter Infor- Political Research Quarterly 54 (1): 7–30.
mation Shortcuts.” Journal of Politics 67 (1): 201–19. Schulhofer-Wohl, Sam, and Miguel Garrido. 2013. “Do Newspapers
Meredith, Marc, and Jason A. Grissom. 2010. “Partisanship in Local Elections: Matter? Short-Run and Long-Run Evidence from the Closure of the
Regression Discontinuity Estimates from Unconventional School Board Cincinnati Post.” Journal of Media Economics 26 (2): 60–81.
Races.” Working paper. http://www.sas.upenn.edu/marcmere/workingpa Simon, Herbert A. 1985. “Human Nature in Politics: The Dialogue of
pers/MeredithGrissomPartisanship.pdf. Psychology with Political Science.” American Political Science Review
Meyer, Phillip. 2008. The Vanishing Newspaper: Saving Journalism in the 79 (2): 293–304.
Information Age. 2nd ed. Columbia: University of Missouri Press. Slothuus, Rune, and Claes H. de Vreese. 2010. “Political Parties, Motivated
Mondak, Jeffrey. 1995. Nothing to Read: Newspapers and Elections in a Reasoning, and Issue Framing Effects.” Journal of Politics 72 (3): 630–45.
Social Experiment. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Sniderman, Paul M., Richard A. Brody, and Philip E. Tetlock. 1991. Rea-
Mummolo, Jonathan, and Erik Peterson. 2016. “How Content Preferences Limit soning and Choice: Explorations in Political Psychology. Cambridge: Cam-
the Reach of Voting Aids.” American Politics Research 45 (2): 159–85. bridge University Press.
Nicholson, Stephen P. 2011. “Dominating Cues and the Limits of Elite Sniderman, Paul M., and Edward H. Stiglitz. 2012. The Reputational
Influence.” Journal of Politics 73 (4): 1165–77. Premium. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Petrocik, John R. 1996. “Issue Ownership in Presidential Elections, with Snyder, James M., and David Strömberg. 2010. “Press Coverage and Po-
a 1980 Case Study.” American Journal of Political Science 40 (3): 825– litical Accountability.” Journal of Political Economy 118 (2): 355–408.
50. Snyder, James M., and Michael M. Ting. 2002. “An Informational Ra-
Petty, Richard E., and John T. Cacioppo. 1986. “The Elaboration Likelihood tionale for Political Parties.” American Journal of Political Science 46
Model of Persuasion.” Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 19:124– (1): 90–110.
205. Tormala, Zakary L., and Richard E. Petty. 2004. “Source Credibility and
Pew Research Center. 2010. “How News Happens.” January 11, 2010. Attitude Certainty: A Metacognitive Analysis of Resistance to Per-
http://www.journalism.org/2010/01/11/how-news-happens/. suasion.” Journal of Consumer Psychology 14 (4): 427–42.
Popkin, Samuel L. 1991. The Reasoning Voter: Communication and Persua- Zaller, John R. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Cambridge:
sion in Presidential Campaigns. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Cambridge University Press.

You might also like