You are on page 1of 13

Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Rural Studies


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jrurstud

Collective action in a smallholder oil palm production system in


Indonesia: The key to sustainable and inclusive smallholder palm oil?
Idsert Jelsma a, b, *, Maja Slingerland c, Ken E. Giller c, Jos Bijman d
a
Geosciences Faculty, Utrecht University, The Netherlands
b
Centre for International Forestry Research, Jalan Cifor, Situ Gede, Sindang Barang, 16115 Bogor, Indonesia
c
Plant Production Systems, Wageningen University, Droevendaalsesteeg 1, 6708 PB Wageningen, The Netherlands
d
Management Studies Group, Wageningen University, Hollandseweg 1, 6706 KN Wageningen, The Netherlands

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Indonesian smallholder oil palm generally yield much less than corporate plantations. We analysed a
Received 20 September 2016 smallholder oil palm production system in West Sumatra which outperformed its nucleus estate plan-
Received in revised form tation, consistently producing yields far above the national average for over 25 years. Its institutional
4 May 2017
setup allowed farmers to combine the advantages of smallholder and plantation agriculture by capi-
Accepted 5 June 2017
talizing on collective action. Collective action design principles (Ostrom, 1990; Cox, 2010) are used to
assess the institutional setup of a smallholder production system. This case study demonstrates that with
a strong institutional arrangement, smallholder oil palm farmers can participate in supply chains on
Keywords:
Oil palm
advantageous conditions and substantially increase productivity, thereby contributing to both rural
Smallholders development and land sparing.
Intensive agriculture © 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Collective action
West-Sumatra
Indonesia

1. Introduction With an estimated annual production of 33 M metric tons and a


global market share of 54% in 2015/2016, Indonesia is the world's
Global demand for vegetable oil will double from 120 to 240 largest producer of palm oil (USDA, 2016). Nearly 75% of this was
million tons per year by 2050, driven by increasing per capita in- exported (USDA, 2016), generating US$22.9 billion in export earn-
comes and population growth (Alexandratos and Bruinsma, 2012; ings from palm oil in 2014 (DJP, 2015). Oil palm undoubtedly has
Corley, 2009). Palm oil will play a major role in meeting this contributed substantially to national, as well as local economic
future demand; a further 7e25 million ha of oil palm is projected to development (Budidarsono et al., 2013; McCarthy and Zen, 2016;
be required over the next 40 years (Corley, 2009). The prominent Rist et al., 2010). Zen et al. (2015) estimates that, based on cur-
role of oil palm is due to its versatility in food and non-food uses rent trends, oil palm expansion will continue to grow from 10.6
and unparalleled ability to convert solar radiation, water and nu- million hectare in 2013 to 13.7 million hectare in 2020.
trients into vegetable oil under proper management (Corley, 2006; Expansion of oil palm has had major impacts on land use
de Vries et al., 2010). With a combined 38% share of global vege- (Brockhaus et al., 2012; Sayer et al., 2012; Wicke et al., 2011),
table oil production, palm oil and palm kernel oil are already the deforestation and loss of biodiversity (Fitzherbert et al., 2008; Koh
most traded vegetable oils in the world (USDA, 2016). Expansion of and Wilcove, 2007), and emission of greenhouse gases (Fargione
palm oil production, particularly in low-income countries, is et al., 2008; Pye and Bhattacharya, 2012; Zen et al., 2015). It is
regarded as crucial for meeting future demand of affordable edible also associated with adverse socio-economic effects due to
oil (Corley, 2009; Shean, 2010). displacement of local populations (Colchester et al., 2006;
McCarthy, 2010) and inclusion in oil palm value chains under un-
clear and disadvantageous terms, leaving smallholders vulnerable
to manipulation by companies and government officials (Cramb,
* Corresponding author. Centre for International Forestry Research, Jalan Cifor,
2013; Gillespie, 2011; McCarthy, 2010). Yet, oil palm is a suitable
Situ Gede, Sindang Barang, 16115 Bogor, Indonesia.
E-mail addresses: ijelsma@gmail.com (I. Jelsma), maja.slingerland@wur.nl crop for smallholder farmers and can provide high returns to land,
(M. Slingerland), ken.giller@wur.nl (K.E. Giller), jos.bijman@wur.nl (J. Bijman). labour and capital, and has improved the livelihoods for many

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2017.06.005
0743-0167/© 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210 199

smallholder farmers (Budidarsono et al., 2013; Feintrenie et al., smallholders to capitalise on the advantages of small-scale agri-
2010; Susila, 2004). Smallholder oil palm cultivation also carries culture as well as to reap the benefits of a large-scale plantation. In
the potential to stimulate rural development (Budidarsono et al., the final section we discuss findings and conclude what insights the
2013; Hayami, 2010; Wiggins et al., 2010), particularly when analysis of the Ophir smallholder institutional set-up has given us
compared with companies that transfer profits to urban share- regarding collective action in smallholder production systems and
holders, leaving migrant company workers in rural areas who the usefulness of the design principles. Thereby we identify
contribute only marginally to the local economy (Sinaga, 2013). potentially useful components for including smallholders on pref-
Smallholders have vigorously embraced oil palm and in 2015 erential terms in modern agro-supply chains and specifically
cultivated roughly 40% of the oil palm area in Indonesia (DJP, 2015). within the oil palm sector.
Government statistics and multiple studies on smallholder oil palm
production however show that smallholder oil palm farming is 2. Methods
inefficient in land use with sub-standard yields (DJP, 2015; Zen
et al., 2016). Data for this article is primarily based on a six-week field visit in
In this article we analyse a highly successful smallholder plan- 2009, in which 34 semi-structured interviews were conducted with
tation scheme, called Ophir, which includes 2400 smallholders 1) the leaders of the supra-cooperative, 2) the leaders of the five
managing 4800 ha of oil palm, to indicate that smallholders are not cooperatives, and 3) leaders of kelompoks, the local term for farmer
always poorly productive. This smallholder plantation has by far groups. A kelompok meeting in one of the cooperatives was
outperformed the national average for smallholders and many attended. Interviews were held with the managers of the nucleus
nucleus estates. By analysing the Ophir plantation, we seek to estate, local and international academics who performed research
identify factors that could lead to more efficient smallholder pro- in the area, and three retired staff of the German development
duction, and thereby address current sustainability challenges in organisation GTZ, currently known as GIZ, involved in establishing
smallholder oil palm cultivation. These include increasing pro- the plantation. Multiple Ophir smallholders were interviewed as
ductivity (Lee et al., 2013) and allowing smallholders to participate well as three workers in the Ophir plantation, and local community
in oil palm cultivation on preferential terms (McCarthy and Zen, members not involved in the project. Further, a survey was con-
2016). In conjunction with proper land use planning, increased ducted amongst 105 randomly selected farmers in a stratified
production of smallholder systems can spare land for food, forest or kelompok sample framework, providing a proportional distribution
other purposes (Baudron and Giller, 2014). of farmers from the different cooperatives. Former GTZ staff shared
Smallholder production systems and corporate plantation sys- documentation on the support they gave to farmers in setting up
tems have distinct advantages and disadvantages. The strengths of the plantation. Long-term yield data was provided by the co-
corporate plantation agriculture lie in the use of clear hierarchical operatives and supra-cooperative. An introductory letter from
structures (Goldthorpe, 1994; Mintzberg, 1979), low transaction former GTZ staff and a visit of former GTZ staff facilitated trust and
costs due to scale, access to capital and market knowledge (Hayami, engagement with the smallholders. In 2011, 2014 and 2016 the lead
2010; Hazell et al., 2010). Hierarchical structures allow for author revisited Ophir and interviewed farmers, cooperative staff
centralized coordination and control, formal assignment of tasks, and (former) supra cooperative staff.
standardization of production methods, and specialization of the
workforce (Grandori, 1997). On the other hand, smallholder pro- 3. History of the NES/PIR schemes
duction has the advantages of efficient use of family labour, strong
incentives to produce high yields due to the direct relationship Oil palm has been cultivated at commercial scale in Indonesia
between effort and reward, high commitment and low cost of since 1911 but production stagnated during World War II, only to be
monitoring workers (Poulton et al., 2010). Agency costs are an revived by the New Order regime which came to power in the late
inherent disadvantage for corporate plantations because the idio- 1960s (Badrun, 2011; McCarthy et al., 2012). A major goal of the
syncratic nature of agricultural production prevents easy New Order regime was to revitalise the plantation sector to in-
measuring the result of hired labour (Byerlee, 2014; Hayami, 2010; crease export earnings, capitalise on the availability of land and
Poulton et al., 2010). Yet the yields of smallholders are usually much create job opportunities on the outer islands of Indonesia (Badrun,
less than those obtained by corporate plantations (DJP, 2015; 2011; McCarthy et al., 2012; Zen et al., 2016). The Indonesian gov-
Molenaar et al., 2013). ernment created state-owned plantation companies that focused
In this article we explain how in Ophir, through effective col- on the cultivation of export crops such as coffee, coconut, rubber
lective action, the advantages of plantation agriculture were com- and oil palm. With the support of the World Bank and Asian
bined with the advantages of smallholder agriculture. We use the Development Bank the Nucleus Estate Smallholder/Perkebunan Inti
design principles framework developed by Ostrom (1990) and Rakyat (NES/PIR) schemes were introduced in the late 1970s. The
updated by Cox et al. (2010) to analyse how this was achieved. On first wave of NES/PIR projects started in the 1980s, consisting of 31
the basis of original data, we demonstrate that smallholder oil palm schemes covering 213,011 ha of oil palms, with smallholders ac-
farming can be highly efficient in terms of yield and farmer income counting for 148,590 ha (70%) and nucleus estates covering
when the correct institutions are in place. Support for institutional 64,421 ha (30%). First plantings with the NES/PIR schemes usually
development and facilitating collective action could provide an took place in fairly remote areas and ceased in 1994 (Badrun, 2011).
alternative to the current unbridled expansion of poor-yielding Later waves of NES/PIR projects included PIR-Trans schemes and
individual smallholder oil palm production systems, or corporate the PIR-KKPA (Kredit Kooperasi Primer Anggota) schemes in which
plantations with relatively high costs and limited benefits for local the state-owned companies were replaced by the private sector.
communities. When the New Order regime collapsed the models changed again
The remainder of this article is structured as follows. After the under the influence of a powerful oil palm industry, which argued
methodology section, a description of the Ophir plantation and the that smallholder cultivation was inefficient (Gillespie, 2011).
achievements of the Ophir smallholders is provided. Subsequently Smallholder schemes therefore further developed towards giving
design principles for successful collective action are introduced. smallholders less responsibility in plantation management, less
With this framework we analyse how collective action was ach- compulsory smallholder area and an increase in company man-
ieved in the smallholder plantation and how this allowed agement (Budidarsono et al., 2013; McCarthy, 2010).
200 I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210

Typically, in NES/PIR schemes the nucleus estate and associated private sector started to revive and independent oil palm small-
processing factory were sufficiently large to allow appointment of holders were nearly unheard of. Although the NES/PIR projects are
professional managers. The smallholders produced under contract now generally regarded as successful, in the mid-1980s many of
with the nucleus estate facing monopsonistic market conditions. these projects experienced serious problems leading to abandon-
The nucleus estate set standards for crop management, and pro- ment. Causes given were the complete dependence of smallholders
vided agronomic, managerial and credit services to farmers. The on state-owned companies and lack of technical and financial ca-
smallholders, which were locals or trans-migrants, were usually pacity of these companies (BMZ, 1992; Zen et al., 2016).
organised in cooperatives. These cooperatives offered services not
provided by the nucleus estate. In the ideal situation the nucleus 4. The Ophir plantation: structure and performance
estate provided: physical infrastructure such as roads, housing,
market centres, schools and medical facilities; management of crop The Ophir plantation (0 1.660 N, 99 51.640 E) is located in the
nurseries with high quality planting material for the plantation's District of West-Pasaman (0 300 -0 110 N, 99 100 -100 040 E) in
own use and for the smallholders; forest clearing and block West-Sumatra, Indonesia (see Fig. 1). The topography is charac-
planting of the perennial crop, and maintenance to maturity before terised by flat lowlands around 60 m above sea level (masl) in the
handing each plot over to the smallholders; inspection and advi- west to more hilly and dissected terraces at elevations up to 400
sory services; training of farmers; collection, processing and mar- masl in the east. The environment in Ophir is ideal for oil palm.
keting of produce; bulk buying, storage and sale to farmers of Yield potential varies along an east-west gradient with a greatest
inputs such as fertilisers and pesticides; and credit. Participating yield potential on the flat, fine textured soils with less rainfall
smallholders usually received a two ha plot with oil palm, a house (3000 mm year1) and less cloud cover in the west to lower yield
and a 0.5 ha home garden plot which was crucial for food pro- potential in the undulating to hilly, coarser-textured soils with
duction during the first years before the oil palms began to produce. rainfall up to 5000 mm year1 in the east.
For the first three to four years, before the oil palms began to yield, The first plantation was established in 1926 by the Cultuur-
the nucleus estate was responsible for management, including maatschappij Ophir NV, which bought 8600 ha for the cultivation of
fertiliser application, maintenance and weeding. Subsequently the coffee and rubber. Oil palm was first planted in 1937 but abandoned
plantation was transferred from the state-owned company to the during the Japanese occupation in 1941 (Rosenquist and Anderson,
cooperative and the individual smallholders, who had signed a 1975). After independence the area was given to the military for
contract to repay costs incurred during the establishment phase retired staff and only in 1979 became state land again. Already in
plus the interest on the loan from the Indonesian government. After the 1970s the project area was ethnically mixed: most were Min-
the loan was repaid, the land title was transferred to the individual angkabau (55.8%) followed by Batak (35.4%) and Javanese (8.8%). In
landowner. In the contract it was stated that smallholders should 1991, the participants in the Ophir plantation comprised of Min-
reside in the settler area (Badrun, 2011). As projects were usually angkabau (55%), Javanese (30%) and Batak (15%), meaning the share
initiated in fairly remote areas, this condition proved difficult to of Javanese was slightly overrepresented compared with the gen-
fulfil. eral population in the project area. Although many were settlers,
By the mid-1980s, state-owned companies and their small- most participants already resided in West Sumatra before the
holders accounted for 70% of oil palm cultivation in Indonesia, the project commenced (Bergschneider, 1990). Our 2009 survey

Fig. 1. Location and layout of the Ophir oil palm plantations, West Sumatra, Indonesia.
I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210 201

indicated that, although 69% of farmers were first generation April 2009 with wife of the head of Kelompok 23; interview with a
farmers and 31% of farmers were second generation, ethnic villager within the plantation area but not part of Ophir, April
composition of plot owners remained stable, hinting that there had 2009). Respondents indicated better maintenance and fertilization
been limited sales of plots or ethnic diversification or concentration as explanations for the differences, as well as peer pressure in the
within the plantation. Interviews in 2009, 2014 and 2016 suggest kelompok and the lack of a monitoring and sanctioning system in
that most smallholders still reside in the area. their individually managed plots.
The area was one of the ‘pockets of poverty’ of West-Sumatra
and was included in the Area Development Plan developed by 5. The design principles
the governments of Indonesia and West-Germany in the late 1970s
(Kievelitz, 1985). In this plan, the Ophir plantation was designed to The achievements of Ophir demonstrate that smallholders were
function as an engine for rural development and, in principle, had able to manage their oil palm plantation efficiently over a pro-
the same characteristics as the other NES/PIR projects. A major longed period of time. To analyse the institutional setup of Ophir
difference was the technical support funded by the German gov- and the remarkable achievement of the farmers, we use the design
ernment next to support from the state-owned company, PTPN VI. principles for effective collective action in common pool resources
The German government insisted that smallholders would partic- developed by Ostrom (1990). These design principles were initially
ipate in the creation of management structures, become self-reliant developed in reaction to two dominant ideas on the limitations of
and have a sense of ownership in the project to avoid dependency collective action (Acheson, 2011; Blaikie, 2006; Ostrom, 1990).
on PTPN VI and strengthen the commitment of smallholders to the Hardin’s (1968) famous ‘Tragedy of the Commons’ provided an
project. The NES/PIR Ophir project started in 1982 with the estab- example of the collapse of a common pool resource. The author saw
lishment of Cooperative Plantation I, which would be followed by the solution in strong autocratic governance. Olson (1965), in ‘The
the establishment of four more cooperative plantations (see Logic of Collective Action’, claimed that people coordinate their
Table 1). Technical assistance provided by GTZ continued until 1993 activities mainly based on their individual benefit and not for the
with an additional three years for knowledge transfer to other common good per se, emphasizing free-rider behaviour and the
projects, amounting to 11 years of smallholder guidance (BMZ, consequent demise of collective action. These arguments led to
1986, 2004; Jahn et al., 1999). policy prescriptions that promote either state regulation or private
Ophir can be termed a great success in terms of the yields ownership as solutions to the challenges of managing common
achieved and quick repayment of credit. Fig. 2 illustrates that Ophir pool resources (Agrawal, 2003; Ostrom, 1990; Saunders, 2014).
smallholders and its nucleus estate both achieved yields consid- However, Ostrom (1990) demonstrated that many natural re-
erably above the national averages, with Ophir smallholders nearly sources, usually commons such as fisheries, grazing grounds and
obtaining double the average yields of smallholders. forests, can be managed and maintained by communities for pro-
Credit repayment, an issue frequently mentioned as a cause of longed periods without privatization or strong state regulation.
failure of smallholder projects (McCarthy, 2010; Zen et al., 2016), Drawing on 14 empirical cases and guided by game theory, Ostrom
was quickly achieved in Ophir. Credit for the establishment of the developed a set of design principles for successful long-term col-
oil palm plots, infrastructure, house and garden was repaid in a lective action in managing natural resources (Ostrom, 1990; Robson
relatively short period ranging from 6 to 7 years instead of the et al., 2014; Saunders, 2014). These design principles have been
expected 15e17 years (Table 1). taken up widely by policy makers, donors and NGO's in
The Ophir plantation also benefitted from favourable natural community-based natural resource management (Blaikie, 2006;
conditions and good quality planting material; the latter is often Saunders, 2014; Shackleton et al., 2010). They have also been
lacking in independent smallholder oil palm (Boer et al., 2012; broadly embraced by academics, with the Ostrom (1990) seminal
Molenaar et al., 2013). But good natural conditions and planting work having been cited 27,734 times (Google Scholar, as of 09-04-
material were not sufficient conditions for high yields. Even the 2017). Over the last two decades, the design principles have proven
nucleus estate, which is located adjacent to the smallholder co- themselves as a valid heuristic tool for analysis of collective action
operatives and thus benefitted from the similar natural conditions (Cox et al., 2010; Robson et al., 2014; Wilson et al., 2013) and
and planting material, was outperformed considerably for more therefore as a relevant framework for analysis.
than 20 years (see Fig. 3). As yields are a result of However, the design principles have also received criticism,
genotype  environment  management interactions, and the first both from practitioners and scholars. One the main critiques refers
two were similar, the difference can be attributed to better man- to its lack of acknowledgement of heterogeneity of communities
agement by the smallholders. and related multiple uses of resources (Agrawal, 2003; Blaikie,
Although no quantitative information is available, Ophir small- 2006; Saunders, 2014). Another, critique refers to the emphasis
holders and a local resident in a village surrounded by the Ophir on efficiency and functionality in the theory behind the design
plantation indicated that the Ophir cooperative plots deliver more principles, which, once applied to common pool projects, does not
fruits than oil palm plots outside the Ophir plantation (interview sufficiently acknowledge social mechanisms like participation,

Table 1
Overview of the initiation of the Ophir smallholder oil palm plantations, the number of members and their repayment of establishment costs (data from Cooperatives 1 to 5 and
Peeters, 1995).

Cooperative Start 2009 2013 Repayment

Year of planting Year of first harvest Area Members Members Members Actual completion Predicted No. of years
(ha)

1 82 1985 1180 591 590 526 91/92 2002 6e7


2 82/83 1986 677 334 354 190 92 2003 7
3 83/84 1987 987 500 612 418 93/94 2004 6
4 85/86 1991 1331 667 539 530 98 2007 7
5 84 1989 623 306 306 233 95 2005 6
Total 4797 2398 2401 1897
202 I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210

Yields (MT 3
CPO/year/ha)
2

0
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Year

NaƟonal smallholder Ophir smallholders


NaƟonal State-owned company Ophir nucleus
NaƟonal company

Fig. 2. Comparison of national average crude palm oil (CPO) production for private companies, state-owned companies, smallholders in Indonesia and the Ophir plantations
(DJP, 2001e2009, PTPN VI and Ophir smallholder cooperatives).
Note: In calculating the yields/ha only the area of mature plantations were included. In order to convert yields in Ophir to CPO/ha a 21% Oil extraction rate was used. This is the oil
extraction rate provided by the mill which processed the fruits, hence most likely a conservative estimation in order to reduce payments to farmers.

Fig. 3. Yields of fresh fruit bunches of oil palm from the five cooperatives and the nucleus estate in Ophir from 1985 to 2010 (source: Cooperative managements þ PTPN VI Nucleus
estate).

social capital, social learning and empowerment. In the Discussion revised design principles as presented by Cox et al. (2010). The
section we will elaborate on these limitations of the design prin- adapted design principles are: 1a) Clear user boundaries; 1b) Clear
ciples, and discuss to what extent the critique applies to the Ophir resource boundaries; 2a) Appropriation and provision rules are
case. congruent with local social and environmental conditions; 2b)
As the design principles were initially developed in the late Appropriation and provision rules are proportional to the input
1980s and much research has been conducted since, we use the required; 3) Collective choice arrangements; 4a) Monitoring of
I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210 203

users; 4b) Monitoring the resource; 5) Graduated sanctions; 6) the supra-cooperative was established. The roll-out of organisa-
Conflict resolution mechanisms; 7) Minimal recognition of rights; tional structures, procedures, and plantation management pro-
and 8) Nested enterprises. ceeded from Cooperative 1, which set the bar for the whole project.
A stepwise approach was used in setting up the smallholder or-
6. Analysing the institutional set-up of Ophir with the design ganizations, starting with trainings at the kelompok level and
principles framework working upwards.
Ostrom (2005) emphasises the importance of polycentric or-
Our analysis starts with the eighth principle of ‘Nested Enter- ganizations. With polycentric decision-making, there is space for
prises’ as it provides an overview the structure of the smallholder experimentation and adaption of rules and regulations, which is
organisation and the plantation as a whole (Fig. 4). necessary as conditions change. Having multiple decision-making
centres allows rules and regulations to be adapted to the interests
6.1. Nested enterprises and needs of sub-groups. In Ophir different kelompoks and co-
operatives have slightly different operational rules whilst having
Ostrom (1990) claims that when a system exceeds a certain size, the same basic rules, crafted under the guidance of GTZ. In the next
responsibilities and activities can be more efficiently managed in sections, the activities and responsibilities of the different levels in
sub-organizations. Smallholders in Ophir were organised at three the smallholder plantation are discussed.
levels: first the kelompok or group level, second the cooperative
level, and third the supra-cooperative level (Fig. 4). The kelompok 6.1.1. Individual farmer level
and cooperative levels were created first. Once the organizations at The Ophir plantation consists of 2400 farmers, each of whom
these levels were functioning and had control mechanisms in place, received a 2 ha plot planted with oil palm and a debt which was

Fig. 4. Overview of the nested structure of the management of the smallholder oil palm plantations in Ophir and their respective responsibilities (adapted from Peeters, 1995).
204 I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210

paid off through deductions made automatically through the optimising production. These topics clearly indicate a business-
cooperative. After repayment of the debt the farmer became the orientated approach. All cooperatives have their own administra-
legal holder of the land. Initially the land title certificates were kept tive offices. Cooperatives covered the costs for their services by
at the cooperative level. This changed over time among the co- making deductions on the revenues from smallholder FFB sales and
operatives and had considerable implications for future collective interest on credit provided to members.
management of the plantation. Smallholders were responsible for
tending the plantation, including applying fertilisers, weeding, 6.1.4. Supra-cooperative
harvesting, transporting fruits to pick up points and maintaining While the cooperatives bore most of the responsibilities for
these pickup points; managing their individual home plot; electing providing services to the smallholders and their kelompoks, the
kelompok leaders; and for (informally) monitoring effort and per- supra-cooperative provided services which were more efficiently
formance of other kelompok members and the labourers small- organised at this top level. The responsibilities of the supra-
holders employed. cooperative included: 1) representation of all members to outside
organizations, including mills; 2) maintain road maintenance ve-
6.1.2. Kelompok level hicles; 3) administration of farmer payments (e.g. operation of a
There were 102 kelompoks in the plantation, which on average digital payment system) including printed reports; and 4) man-
covered 50 ha and had 25 smallholder members. A key feature of agement of the farmers’ bank, which was established in the 1990s
the Ophir scheme was the introduction of a group income in which to deal with smallholder, kelompok and cooperative finances.
proceeds from sale of fresh fruit bunches were divided equally The supra-cooperative also facilitated communication among
among the individual kelompok members, with only small pre- cooperatives and between cooperatives and third parties,
miums for individual performance. This approach combined group expressing the shared goals and providing a single desk for problem
and individual responsibility and had crucial impact on the func- solving. Smallholders did not directly control the supra-cooperative
tioning of the kelompoks. First, individual income could only in- as this was done through the cooperative leaders. As a conse-
crease when all members managed their plots properly. Second, quence, this organisational level was only indirectly accountable to
shared income generated peer pressure amongst farmers to ensure smallholders. Costs were covered by deductions from FFB sales and
that individual farmers did not fall behind on important tasks in interest on credit provided to members.
plantation management, leading to uniform standards. Third, each
kelompok decided on its own rules and penalties for non- 6.2. Clear boundaries
compliance with group standards for harvesting, fertiliser appli-
cation, and attendance at kelompok meetings. Penalties were 6.2.1. Clear user boundaries
imposed after discussion at monthly kelompok meetings. Fourth, it The legitimate users of the plantation resources were small-
was in the interest of all farmers to assist members that could not holders who were registered as members in Ophir. All members
harvest or apply fertiliser due to illness or absence. In such cases, had their own 2 ha plot, which could not be subdivided. The re-
other farmers in the kelompok (or labourers arranged by the head sponsibilities of all actors within the smallholder plantation were
of the kelompok) would manage the member's crop and charge the collectively agreed upon.
member for the services rendered. Fifth, the key tasks like fertiliser As the Ophir plantation was in essence a settler project and
application and harvesting were checked by kelompok leadership although most settlers were from within West Sumatra but ethni-
so that individual farmers were less tempted to side-sell fertilisers cally diverse (see Section 4), there was no initial sense of commu-
or fresh-fruit bunches (FFB). nity hence trust and belief in the possibilities for effective
The kelompok was a grassroots organization with leaders elec- cooperation had to be created. A sense of community and increased
ted from among the members. The kelompok leadership consisted interaction amongst members was facilitated by the creation of
of a kelompok leader, a vice-kelompok leader, treasurer, secretary four villages so that people lived near their section of the planta-
and technical manager who checked and reported on compliance tion. By living in close proximity, visiting the same mosques and
with the kelompok rules to the members in monthly meetings. churches, and sending their children to the same schools, people
They received a salary for doing this from the proceeds of selling interacted with each other on a day to day basis, creating ties
FBB and the interest farmers paid on credit provided by the coop- beyond managing the plantation. Project facilitators acknowledged
erative. Issues which could not be solved at kelompok level were sensitive issues such as keeping pigs, therefore clustering Chris-
reported to the cooperative. tians and Muslims within villages. People from different ethnicities,
religions and former livelihood activities, lived in the same villages
6.1.3. Cooperatives and worked together, and as a farmer in Plasma 2 indicated during
There are five cooperatives in Ophir, each comprised of about an interview in March 2016, assisted one another in constructing a
500 farmers, 1000 ha and 20 kelompoks. Cooperatives have a church or mosque. Multiple ties between participants supported
technical unit and a general manager to provide services that reciprocity and mutual interest in sustaining the resource.
cannot be arranged effectively at individual or kelompok level due Although living together in villages close to the plantation was
to scale, associated costs and professional requirements. The common in NES/PIR schemes, in Ophir community building was
technical units perform regular checks on diseases, road condition, nurtured by GTZ through continuous training of farmers in mana-
maintenance of crop collection points, and arrange storage and the gerial and technological skills, as well as in dealing with group
distribution of fertilisers to all the kelompoks in the cooperative. dynamics (Heering, 1993). These trainings also aimed to develop a
Activities of the management are procurement of fertiliser (which sense of pride and success, demonstrating that they were more
involves large sums of money), developing harvesting schemes, than just farmers waiting for company hand-outs but a collective
transportation of FFB from the farmer's plot to a mill, financial which was determined to successfully manage an oil palm
services, road maintenance and quality control of produce. The plantation.
cooperatives made annual plans, which were subject to approval by Overall, general exit and entry requirements for NES/PIR
representatives of all kelompoks during the annual meetings. At schemes were determined by the Indonesian developers of these
the annual meetings kelompok representatives discuss financial schemes. Kievelitz (1985) mentions that recruitment of small-
reports, maintenance plans for the cooperative, and proposals for holders was from rural families of peasant origin within the project
I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210 205

area or the project vicinity with small, uneconomic lands or ten- management is essential to cultivate and maintain the ‘resource’.
ancy rights, and retired army personnel who fulfilled the same Management includes knowledge and skills in agronomy, such as
general standards for selection. Other entry requirements timely and adequately weeding, pruning, fertilization and har-
mentioned by former GTZ staff (interview Peters April 2009; vesting as well as operational aspects, such as transport of FFB,
interview Heering, March 2009) were that smallholders should be procurement and distribution of fertilisers, marketing, road repair
married, no communist association and be able to provide labour. teams, pest and disease control teams, mechanisms for monitoring
Former GTZ staff indicated it was difficult to attract smallholders in and sanctioning.
the early phases as it was unclear whether the plantation would be
a success, whilst at a later stage it was getting difficult to keep 6.3. Appropriation and provision rules
people out who did not meet the criteria but were attracted by the
success of the plantation. 6.3.1. Rules congruent with local social and environmental
Often smallholders left PIR schemes due to poor support from conditions
the state-owned companies, with papers still in their name. This Clearly the physical environmental conditions in Ophir were
currently leads to many difficulties with replanting as land certifi- favourable for cultivation of oil palm, which provided the oppor-
cates are officially held by people who can no longer be traced tunity for high yields and profits (appropriation by smallholders)
(Budidarsono et al., 2013). In Ophir, this problem was avoided, when the right inputs were provided (provision by smallholders).
partly due to the concerted efforts by GTZ and other stakeholders to Water shortages due to natural conditions were not relevant.
sustain the engagement of smallholders in the plantation and the However, during times of low oil palm prices, the rules for savings
quickly obtained financial benefits (interviews former GTZ staff and credit could be altered by members through their
2009 and 2016). Entry and exit rules for membership once the organizations.
plantation was running varied slightly among kelompoks due to Harvesting was arranged through schemes developed at coop-
decision making at kelompok and cooperative level. The ‘husband, erative level which also arranged transport to the mill. Small-
wife, children’ system was a fundament, as it was in other PIR- holders were obliged to follow the scheme of the cooperatives but
schemes. In this system the spouse and later the children of the arrange harvesting individually, whilst maintaining standards.
owner inherit the plot when the owner passed away, allowing the Appropriation of income was arranged through a shared income
plot to remain in family hands hence within the community. In based on the kelompok produce with deductions for services. Co-
order to keep ownership clear the general rule amongst coopera- operatives, supra-cooperatives and smallholders were not allowed
tive and kelompok leaders was that the plot itself could not be sub- to market produce individually. Basically the smallholders appro-
divided and remained registered under one name but profits could priated income and services from the kelompok, cooperative and
be divided amongst family members. Jahn et al. (1999) mentions supra-cooperative, and provided plot management, implementa-
that in practice this was not always adhered to. Although in the tion of kelompok and cooperative recommendations and partici-
early stages land certificates were held at cooperative level at all pation in meetings at different organisational levels. Transparency
cooperatives, members in cooperatives 2, 3, 4 and 5 demanded that within the organizations was a key requirement for members to
these be returned to the individual members. In case of sales to develop trust; for instance, the cost of services rendered was
outsiders, it was up to the kelompok whether to accept the change revealed at monthly kelompok meetings using a computerised
in ownership. Certainly in the early years, when there were few payment system from 1987 onwards.
opportunities to operate independently, good relations within Besides the ethnic diversity described in Section 6.2.1, the pro-
kelompok were crucial for farmers but also this rule undoubtedly fessional backgrounds of smallholders were also diverse, consisting
had different levels of adherence among the kelompoks. By main- of former lower military staff, some civil servants and former em-
taining property within the kelompok and cooperative, a sense of ployees, and many local farmers. This diversity enhanced social
community is maintained and members remain aware of how the conditions which allowed for an efficient development of the in-
kelompok functions. Reasons for this choice of rules were to secure stitutions required and uptake of the knowledge provided by fa-
possibilities for future generations of the current smallholders and cilitators as settlers brought previously attained skills to the project
to prevent entrance of outsiders. With outsiders the risk of rent (Heering, 1993; Peeters, 1995). Convincing members of the benefits
seeking was perceived to be higher, as the community had fewer of a relatively complex high-input high-output system was done
means to enforce regulations. through numerous meetings between members, cooperative
leaders, government officials and project implementers, where
6.2.2. Clear resource boundaries calculations were made and shared with the members, who sub-
The boundaries of the resource, the smallholder oil palm plan- sequently had to approve (or disapprove) the plans of the kelom-
tation, were clearly defined. For the entire smallholder plantation poks and cooperative. Although GTZ and their Indonesian partners
of 4800 ha, the cooperatives ranged from 612 ha to 1238 ha, the advised smallholders, they had no sanction to force smallholders to
kelompoks from 32 ha to 60 ha and each smallholder was implement measures. The decision to implement measures to
responsible for their own 2 ha plot. As indicated above, subdivision enhance oil palm yields rested entirely with the smallholder
of the 2 ha plots was not allowed, and although theoretically it was organizations.
possible to add extra hectares, people or even kelompoks to the
cooperatives, this did not happen except that several kelompoks 6.3.2. Rules proportional to the input required
moved from one cooperative to another. The boundaries remained We describe above the importance of actors in convincing
stable until 2010, when replanting became a critical issue. All oil members of the need to implement certain measures. An example
palms and infrastructure in the smallholder plantation were of the clear understanding between input requirements (provision)
developed by PTPN VI, setting clear boundaries in the landscape. and yields, and hence income, is reflected by the upkeep of inputs
The ‘resource’ however goes beyond simply the palms and the even at times when prices for farmers were down. During times of
physical infrastructure. The real resource was the 4800 ha of high low market prices smallholders are often tempted to reduce fer-
yielding oil palm plantation. Good planting material ensured that a tiliser inputs. This translates into decreased yields months later
high performing genotype was present throughout the plantation when prices may have recovered, leading to permanent reduced
and the environment was favourable for oil palm, but good fertiliser inputs due to reduced income (Samosir et al., 2013; Zen
206 I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210

et al., 2016). The rules related to appropriation and provision, and not performed to standards.
the long-term planning by cooperatives, appear to have avoided Monitoring of the hired labourers became increasingly relevant
such a situation as fertilizer was ordered in advance and yields as over time a strong shift occurred from family labour to hired
remained high from the start of production until 2010, after which labour. Whereas in 1990 60% of labour activities were performed by
systematic yield data could no longer be obtained. the smallholder household members, by 2009 on average only 23%
Until at least 2010, almost all of the smallholders remained of labour activities were performed by smallholder households
members of the cooperatives and maintained a highly profitable, themselves (survey results). This shift is attributed to increases in
high input (of fertilisers and management) e high output (of high wealth of the smallholders, the availability of cheap labour, and the
yields and income) system. The technical and logistical support absence of younger family members who were in school or
provided in the Ophir plantations was critical to their success, and preferred to find work outside the plantation. Participants moved
the smallholder organizations paid for these services. The overall away from the more remote areas and often spent more time in the
running costs of smallholder organisation in Ophir,1 being 19% of local town, spending less time in the plantation to monitor activ-
gross revenues in 1991 and 13% in 2008 respectively (BMZ, 1992; ities and leaving more responsibilities to the kelompok leaders
own survey 2009), were clearly outweighed by the income gener- (interviews farmers and leaders, August 2009). These observations
ated, and in line with the suggestion of Zen et al. (2016) that in most are also reflected in the lowest household participation in labour
smallholder situations increased input supply benefits profitability. activities in the more remote Cooperatives 3, 4 and 5 in 2009
(survey results).
6.4. Collective choice arrangements
6.5.2. Monitoring the resource
Rules and regulations were created bottom-up, starting at the The responsibility of managing individual oil palm plots rested
kelompok level. Kelompok meetings were held each month and with the smallholder. Yet the kelompok manager had to follow up
attended by smallholders or their representatives. During annual when activities were not up to standard. Problems due to absen-
meetings the cooperative leaders presented plans, which were then teeism were solved by deducting from the income of the absentee
presented by the kelompok leaders at kelompok meetings and owner to cover the costs incurred for maintaining high standards.
discussed among the members. If needed, adjustments to the plans Side-selling of FFB was not accepted as it would reduce the income
were proposed at these kelompok meetings (Bauer, 1991; Heering, of all other kelompok members. Some kelompoks organised
1993). Smallholders could also visit the cooperative or supra- monthly walks together through their land, whilst other kelompoks
cooperative office to discuss pressing issues or obtain information left it to the kelompok managers to report on field conditions
about decisions and practices. during the monthly meetings. Individual members were free to
Having the freedom of experimenting with local rules and walk throughout the whole plantation, check for themselves and
regulations provided smallholders with the opportunity of adapt- report during kelompok meetings. Whenever activities within the
ing these to fit decentralized conditions. Locally crafted rules can plantation were not done to the satisfaction of kelompok members
often deal with ‘local realities’. In addition, having a voice in or their leadership, this was reported to the responsible person. The
determining the rules is known to increase the ease of imple- cooperative leaders were responsible for monitoring road condi-
menting the rules. Such a collective choice arrangement strongly tion, nutrient deficiencies and pests and diseases, but required
links to the appropriation and provision rules and their congruence input from the kelompok leaders to perform their tasks efficiently.
with local conditions as mentioned above. Monitoring of the finances and plantation activities was also
At the project inception, as members were grouped together for facilitated by implementation of a clear accounting system with
the first time, it was important to have a facilitator to guide the monthly print-outs distributed to all members, and bank accounts
need for quick establishment of constitutional rules, and opera- for all members. These sheets provided clear and transparent re-
tional rules which could later be adapted. Clear guidelines were cords of yields, FFB prices, costs, loans by smallholders and de-
established to avoid misunderstanding and confusion about rights ductions. Allowing smallholders to check the numbers and
and responsibilities and this was a core tenet of technical cooper- calculations strengthened their trust in the leadership of the
ation provided by GTZ (Bauer, 1991; Heering, 1993). plantation.

6.6. Graduated sanctions


6.5. Monitoring

Rules can only be upheld if there are sanctions that can be


6.5.1. Monitoring of users
invoked in case of non-compliance. The kelompok leaders were
As Ophir smallholders received a joint income based on the
most directly involved in sanctioning members, although the social
output of the kelompok, there was a strong incentive for members
mechanism of shame and blame within the local community sup-
to monitor performance of their fellow kelompok members. In
ported adherence to agreed standards. The first formal level of
Ophir, each kelompok had between 16 and 30 members which
sanctions was mentioning of non-compliance during meetings,
allowed members to know each other. Costs for monitoring were
while stronger sanctions involved fines. An example of this was a
low as ‘hiding in anonimity’ was not easily possible due to social
50,000 IDR (5 USD) fine for not attending the monthly kelompok
control and the limited size of kelompoks. First responsibility for
meetings. Although this might have been a reasonable amount in
monitoring of plots was with the farmers, who were responsible for
the early phases of the project, nowadays this would not even cover
maintaining high standards in their own plot and monitoring their
the costs of fuel to come from Padang, let alone the opportunity
neighbours. Farmers were also responsible for the labourers they
cost. The ultimate sanction, exclusion from the kelompok, was
hired. The kelompok leadership however had to monitor whether
never invoked.
the members performed and had to hire extra labour if work was

6.7. Conflict resolution mechanism


1
This includes fertilizers, pest and disease control, supervisory costs/manage-
ment fee, road maintenance, crop transport and other physical repairs but exclude Conflict resolution mechanisms were organised at different
plantation labour and land tax. levels. At kelompok level, issues among individual members and
I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210 207

with the kelompok management were mostly resolved during Examples of these services are road maintenance, purchase of fer-
monthly meetings or informal gatherings at the house of the farmer tilizers, marketing of FFB, access to technology and pest and disease
or head of the kelompok, with a possibility of cooperative managers control, and in the case of Cooperative 1, replanting with high
providing assistance when no solution could be reached between quality planting materials, reducing transaction costs for individual
kelompok leaders and individual farmer. The leaders of different smallholders. The Ophir project moved from what McCarthy and
kelompoks discussed among each other and with cooperative Zen, (2016) terms exogenous oil palm development, instigated
managers in case of a conflict that affected more than one kelom- and led by outsiders, towards endogenous oil palm development, in
pok. In case of a conflict with third parties, the cooperative leaders which farmers lead. This is most obvious in Cooperative 1, which
directly contacted the third party or worked with the supra- has managed replanting without outside assistance. The key to
cooperative to resolve the issue. Meetings in the early phases of inclusion is that smallholders participate in decision-making,
the project were facilitated by GTZ staff, but as experience grew obtain reasonable compensation, and have access to services and
GTZ was no longer needed. inputs as capital, good quality planting material, fertilizers and
marketing networks. This was achieved through collective action in
6.8. Minimal recognition of rights Ophir and thereby confirms Poulton et al.'s (2010) claim that col-
lective action can reduce the transaction costs smallholders usually
The project was initiated by the Government of Indonesia, with face.
a clear recognition of land rights of participants and regulations The design principles provide a systematic tool to analyse
associated with the NES/PIR schemes. What distinguished Ophir complex systems in which large numbers of social and natural
from other schemes was the institutional arrangement designed to variables and their interactions at different levels determine out-
create self-reliance, a sense of ownership and smallholder comes (Cox et al., 2010). Managing a resource such as a collective
commitment. Interviews with former GTZ project staff (2009) smallholder plantation clearly fits the description of such a com-
revealed that there was frequent tension with PTPN VI concerning plex system. A frequent criticism on the design principles is that
the institutional arrangement proposed by GTZ and the small- they are incomplete, and for successful collective action there are
holders. An important actor regarding preventing and resolving many other relevant criteria (Agrawal, 2003; Cox et al., 2010;
conflicts was the Provincial Coordinating Committee (PCC) which Saunders, 2014). Agrawal (2003) estimates there are between 30
supervised and coordinated the responsibilities of the relevant and 40 relevant criteria and, as also Ostrom indicates in later works
government organizations and nucleus estate and negotiated in (Ostrom, 2009), it is the correlations and balances between criteria
case of conflicts of interests (Bauer, 1991; Heering, 1993). Even which determine successful collective action in the management of
within the Indonesian government there were individuals who commons. Cox (2008) claims that in developing the principles,
were proponents and opponents of the Ophir approach. The Ostrom (1990) has suppressed ‘ … detail of variations between units
external assistance provided by GTZ and the collaboration with (rules) at one level by aggregating them into a higher-level unit (design
higher levels of authority within the Indonesian government pro- principle) based on important common features’. Due to this aggre-
vided extra opportunity for experimentation (interview Peters gation, the design principles became somewhat container concepts.
March 2009; interview Heering, March 2009). Although all design principles are present in our case study, there
most likely are many more relevant enabling conditions present in
7. Discussion Ophir which remained unmentioned. However, a key point we take
from the design principles is the holistic view which emphasizes
Collective action allowed smallholders to combine the advan- that successful collective action consists of many interacting com-
tages of large-scale agriculture, being capitalized on at cooperative ponents of which some might fit in different contexts. We therefore
and supra-cooperative level, and the advantages of smallholder agree with the literature (e.g. Agrawal and Ribbot, 2014; Ostrom,
farming, being capitalized on at the kelompok and individual level, 1990) that finds the design principles useful in highlighting key
with farmers having a direct interest in the production of their own components required for collective action and how these can take
plot as well as the plots of their group members due to their shared shape, but that the design principles should not be used as a
income. Sutton (1989) highlights that a shared income had also blueprint for successful collective action as they only provide
been tried in the FELDA schemes in Malaysia, but that perceived aggregated theoretical components but do not provide guidance on
free-riding of non-performing members, a major threat to collec- how to deal with the dynamic complexity of the multitude of
tive action (Olson, 1965), rendered this system unpopular. The relevant enabling conditions and their relations.
Ophir case, however, shows that institutions can be developed to Another often expressed critique of the Ostrom design princi-
address the free riding problem. The kelompok structure, with its ples is not paying attention to power relations and the position of
leaders and active members keen on maintaining high incomes, powerless groups. Saunders (2014) explains that the lack of
monitored the activities in the plantation, and through a system of acknowledgment of politics is due to the theoretical findings of the
collectively defined rules, regulations and monitoring ensured that design principles which emphasize that collective action is the
free-riders were disciplined. In line with the findings of Baldassarri result of rational choices of individuals, in which it becomes clear
(2015) that cooperation is induced by patterns of reciprocity that that working together generates more benefits than working alone.
emerge through repeated interaction, farmers in Ophir had multi- We propose that power relations are implicitly acknowledged in
ple levels of interactions, both socially and managing the planta- the design principles as weaker actors always have agency and will
tion, which supported reciprocity and mutual interest in sustaining protest if not acknowledged enough, potentially threatening the
the resource. resource (Latour, 2005; Scott, 1985). Examples of principles which
Regarding the unfavourable and dependent position of farmers needed to incorporate power issues are: Principle 2a&b, appro-
in outgrower schemes, frequently involving limited transparency priation and provision rules, where the balance between what
concerning the costs companies charge to smallholders (Cramb, farmers put in and receive from the system are determined, hence
2013), in Ophir dependency on the nucleus estate (PTPN VI) whether it is interesting for a farmer to comply or whether the
ended with the repayment of debts (Table 1). Already during the farmer will resist; Principle 3, collective choice arrangements, in
maturing of the plantation cooperatives and supra-cooperative which farmers demand answers from their managements, for
provided services usually arranged by the nucleus estate. example in annual meetings; Principle 7, the minimal recognition
208 I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210

of rights which highlight the importance of e.g. GTZ and PCC and farmers receive little support from government or companies,
related lobbying power at higher levels; Principle 8, the relations which lead to an environment with limited opportunities for many
between the nested enterprises, indicating relations between smallholders to cultivate on advantageous conditions and
layers. All of these principles inherently need to deal with politics explaining their frequent poor yields (Cramb and McCarthy, 2016).
which threaten the functioning of the resource, and during prac- The role of outside support appears to have been crucial in Ophir,
tical implementation clearly the politics cannot be left out, as GTZ providing farmers with good planting material state of the art
staff emphasized regularly. As the plantation was managed effi- plantation science. Institution building was the responsibility of
ciently for over 25 years it is clear that overall political tensions GTZ which proved capable and successful but at substantial costs.
were dealt with sufficiently. However, by including the power re- These costs were estimated at US$7.6 M, or 1588 US$/ha (3175 US$
lations component into the design principles the design principles per farmer), or 16.8% of total expenditures (BMZ, 1992).2 The
become even more the aforementioned container concepts, lacking expense of the Ophir approach is likely one of the main reasons
again clear guidance on how to develop collective action. why it has not been implemented elsewhere in Indonesia. How-
Linking Ostrom's design principles to practice in the field, a ever, Fig. 2 illustrates that the higher yields from the Ophir farmers
frequently expressed critique is that the design principles often do compared with the nucleus estate was on average 1.29 MT of CPO/
not work for new projects for community-based management of ha/year3 from 1999 till 2008. Considering the average CPO price
natural resources (Blaikie, 2006; Saunders, 2014). Saunders (2014) from 1999 till 2008 of 452.0 US$/MT (Index Mundi, 2017), and an
claims that while the design principles are based on multiple cases estimated average production costs of Ophir farmers between 20
of successful community-based management of natural resources, and 25% of gross sales (BMZ, 1992; Peeters, 1995), it appears the
they only address part of the complexity of such community-based 1588 US$/ha investments for institution building were earned back
management of a natural resource. Particularly the norms, values over a 25 year period. If Ophir smallholders are compared to the
and customs that have developed over long periods of time and are national averages for smallholders for the same period (2.76 vs.
crucial for directing human interaction in those communities, are 5.27 MT of CPO/year/ha), results are even more spectacular,
insufficiently captured by the design principles. This becomes although a straight comparison is complicated by differences in
particularly problematic when outside supporters, such as NGOs or average age of oil palm stands.
governmental agencies, impose the design principles on the com-
munity and prioritize project objectives above community needs.
However, as Ophir was a settler project and the resource was newly 8. Conclusion
established, the sense of community with shared norms, values and
customs within the plantation was limited and had to be devel- There is debate amongst policy makers about smallholder
oped. This relatively ‘clean sheet’ allowed the project implementers agriculture in modern agricultural value chains, with claims that
to emphasize their vision; to develop an efficient oil palm planta- smallholders are excluded from global value chains or only being
tion which allows independent smallholders to capitalize optimally included on adverse terms (du Toit, 2009; McCarthy and Zen, 2016;
from their 2 ha oil palm plot, whilst only modestly having to deal Poulton et al., 2010). In the near future, certification for oil palm
with conflicting local norms, values or other traditional uses of the smallholders will be mandatory in Indonesia. Sustainability certi-
resource. The role of capable and long term external facilitators in fication includes attention for using best management practices,
Ophir has been crucial in providing concerted trainings on technical socio-economic development and decision rights for smallholders.
as well as managerial aspects, leading to good yields and thereby Ophir, with its nested structures, internal control systems and high
creating trust amongst smallholder to co-develop their institutions, yields, provides an example of how these threats can be countered
obtain the political clout to counterbalance the position of the and that oil palm smallholders can be at least as efficient as oil palm
nucleus estate and eventually leading to smallholder indepen- companies. Ophir has shown that with well-designed collective
dence. Although Vollan (2012) highlights the threats of externally action rules, smallholders can participate in value chains that face
imposed collective action with their opportunities for elite capture, increasingly strict traceability and quality requirements, and can
this did not undermine collective action in Ophir. Instead of het- maintain good yields which can benefit efficient land use.
erogeneity of resource users being an obstacle, with ethnicity being The Ostrom design principles highlighted enabling conditions
an acknowledged factor in politics and development (Aspinall and which need to be in place for successful collective action and pro-
Sukmajati, 2016) and also a relevant issue in smallholder oil palm vided a useful framework for illustrating how these enabling con-
developments in Indonesia where migrants appear to benefit more ditions took shape in Ophir. Collective institutions as shared
than locals (McCarthy and Zen, 2016), ethnic diversity, with income, trainings on cultivation and administrative management,
attributed cultural characteristics, and especially professional four levels of rights and responsibilities, transparency by using
backgrounds provided valuable assets to the project according to computerized systems and print outs, regular meetings amongst
project implementers. The diversity of participants allowed the members and the multiple relations amongst farmers, demon-
willing and capable to join management and lead, whilst partici- strated their relevance in Ophir and can provide inspiration for
pants with less skills participated as members and voted for change achieving collective action in other situations. However, the design
when not convinced by management. Although Ophir clearly pro- principles nor Ophir are a blueprint for successful collective action
vides a particular case regarding the resource being newly devel- or a high yielding smallholder oil palm plantation. Clearly every
oped by project implementers, there are clear links between the project has its particular conditions which need to be acknowl-
efficient management of an oil palm plantation as Ophir and edged, delicate balances between wide range of enabling condi-
CBNRM. Thereby this Ophir case study contributes to the literature tions need to be found and in some cases collective action might
on CBNRM, but vice-versa the CBNRM literature, with all its cases
and reasons for successes and failures, can also provide relevant
2
inspiration to policy developers and implementers for improving Amounts mentioned in BMZ, 1992 are 12.7 M DM, an USD-DM exchange rate of
1e1.67 was applied as exchange rate for 1993, based on GTZ 1995a data. This 7.62 M
collective action amongst farmers.
USD includes salaries of GTZ experts present in the field for 11 years, computers for
However, the development of institutions as in Ophir did not fit cooperatives, motorbikes, a stone crusher for road maintenance, and much more
in the laissez-faire phase of smallholder development policies in hardware smallholders and project implementers used.
3
Indonesia which started in the late 1990s. Since then smallholder An average extraction rate of 21% is used.
I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210 209

not be achievable. OPHIR Indonesien. BMZ, Bonn, p. 204.


BMZ, 2004. Final Report for Ex-Post Evaluation of the Area Development Project in
From 2010 onwards even in Ophir members started to leave the
West Pasaman. Indonesia, Jakarta, p. 189.
cooperatives (Table 1) and although the need for replanting ap- Boer, R., Nurrochmat, D.R., Ardiansyah, M., Hariyadi Purwawangsa, H., Ginting, G.,
pears to be an underlying cause, further research is required to 2012. Reducing agricultural expansion into forests in Central Kalimantan-
understand farmers reasons for leaving. Nevertheless, Cooperative Indonesia: analysis of implementation and financing gaps. In: University, B.A.
(Ed.), Center for Climate Risk & Opportunity Management, p. 79. Bogor.
1 successfully replanted collectively and maintained nearly 90% of Brockhaus, M., Obidzinski, K., Dermawan, A., Laumonier, Y., Luttrell, C., 2012. An
its members (data obtained during fieldwork in 2016). With the overview of forest and land allocation policies in Indonesia: is the current
other cooperatives having produced intensively for over 25 years, framework sufficient to meet the needs of REDDþ? For. Policy Econ. 18, 30e37.
Budidarsono, S., Susanti, A., Zoomers, A., 2013. Oil Palm Plantations in Indonesia:
Ophir provides an interesting case study which demonstrates that the Implications for Migration, Settlement/Resettlement and Local Economic
smallholder oil palm farming has great potential for rural devel- Development.
opment, intensive land use and can participate on advantageous Byerlee, D., 2014. The fall and rise again of plantations in tropical asia: history
repeated? Land 3 (3), 574e597.
terms in modern supply chains. Colchester, M., Jiwan, N., Andiko Sirait, M., Firdaus, A.Y., Surambo, A., Pane, H., 2006.
Palm Oil and Land Acquisition in Indonesia: Implications for Local Communities
Funding and Indigenous Peoples. Forest Peoples Programme, Perkumpulan Sawit Watch,
HuMa. World Agroforestry Centre, Moreton-in-Marsh and Bogor.
Corley, R.H.V., 2006. Is the oil palm industry sustainable? Planter 82, 121e135.
The initial research was funded by Shell Global Solutions, under Corley, R.H.V., 2009. How much palm oil do we need? Environ. Sci. Policy 12,
an agreement that the researchers would have unrestrained 134e139.
Cox, M., 2008. Balancing accuracy and meaning in common-pool resource theory.
freedom in drawing conclusions and disseminating information Ecol. Soci 13.
without restriction. UKAID and USAID provided funds for follow Cox, M., Arnold, G., Villamayor Toma s, S., 2010. A review of design principles for
ups in 2014 and 2016 respectively. community-based natural resource management. Ecol. Soc. 15 [online] URL:, 38.
Cramb, R.A., 2013. Palmed off: incentive problems with joint-venture schemes for
oil palm development on customary land. World Dev. 43, 84e99.
Submission declaration Cramb, R., McCarthy, J.F., 2016. The Oil Palm Complex: Smallholders, Agribusiness
and the State in Indonesia and Malaysia. NUS Pres, Singapore.
de Vries, S.C., van de Ven, G.W.J., van Ittersum, M.K., Giller, K.E., 2010. Resource use
None of these results have been published elsewhere.
efficiency and environmental performance of nine major biofuel crops, pro-
cessed by first-generation conversion techniques. Biomass Bioenergy 34,
Acknowledgements 588e601.
DJP, 2001. Statistik Perkebunan Indonesia; Kelapa Sawit 1999-2001. Direktorat
Jenderal bina produksi Perkebunan, Jakarta, p. 63.
This article would not have been possible without the guidance DJP, 2004. Statistik Perkebunan Indonesia: Kelapa Sawit 2001-2003. Direktorat
of Dr. T.H. Fairhurst who introduced the lead author to former GTZ Jenderal bina produksi Perkebunan, Jakarta, p. 48.
staff and the farmers in Ophir, and provided valuable insights and DJP, 2006a. Statistik Perkebunan Indonesia: Kelapa Sawit 2003-2005. Direktorat
Jenderal Perkebunan, Jakarta, p. 57.
data on the smallholder organizations. Other former GTZ staff were DJP, 2006b. Statistik Perkebunan Indonesia: Kelapa Sawit 2004-2006. Direktorat
very helpful in sharing data and views. The initial research was Jenderal Perkebunan, Jakarta, p. 69.
funded by Shell Global Solutions, and UKAID and USAID financed DJP, 2007. Statistik Perkebunan Indonesia: Kelapa Sawit 2006-2008. Direktorat
Jenderal Perkebunan, Jakarta, p. 43.
2014 and 2016 field visits respectively; their financial support was DJP, 2008. Statistik Perkebunan Indonesia: Kelapa Sawit 2007-2009. Direktorat
indispensable. We thank all smallholders and managers in Ophir Jenderal Perkebunan, Jakarta, p. 63.
for welcoming us over the years and generously sharing their in- DJP, 2009. Statistik Perkebunan Indonesia: Kelapa Sawit 2008-2010. Direktorat
Jenderal Perkebunan, Jakarta, p. 60.
sights, and lastly thank Dr. Guus van Westen, Dr. Robert Fletcher DJP, 2015. Statistik Perkebunan Indonesia; Kelapa Sawit 2014-2016. Direktorat
and two anonymous reviewers for their useful comments on an Jenderal Perkebunan, Jakarta, p. 69.
earlier version of this paper. du Toit, A, 2009. Adverse incorporation and agrarian policy in South Africa, or, how
not to connect the rural poor to growth. Escaping Poverty Traps Connecting
Chronically Poor Econ. Growth, Febr. 26-27, 2009 26. Washington, D.C.
References Fargione, J., Hill, J., Tilman, D., Polasky, S., Hawthorne, P., 2008. Land clearing and the
biofuel carbon debt. Science 319, 1235e1238.
Acheson, J., 2011. Ostrom for anthropologists. Int. J. Commons 5, 319e339. Feintrenie, L., Chong, W., Levang, P., 2010. Why do farmers prefer oil palm? lessons
Agrawal, A., 2003. Sustainable governance of common-pool resources: context, learnt from Bungo District, Indonesia. Small-Scale For. 9, 379e396.
methods, and politics. Annu. Rev. Anthropol. 32, 243e262. Fitzherbert, E.B., Struebig, M.J., Morel, A., Danielsen, F., Brühl, C.A., Donald, P.F.,
Agrawal, A., Ribbot, J., 2014. Are Ostrom's design principles enough for design? In: Phalan, B., 2008. How will oil palm expansion affect biodiversity? Trends Ecol.
Robson, J.P., Davidson-Hunt, Iain J., Delaney, Alyne, Lichtenstein, Gabriela, Evol. 23, 538e545.
Magole, Lapologang, Mead, Aroha Te Pareake (Eds.), Remembering Elinor Gillespie, P., 2011. How does legislation affect oil palm smallholders in the sanggau
Ostrom: Her Work and its Contribution to the Theory and Practice of Conser- District of Kalimantan, Indonesia? Australasian. J. Nat. Resour. Law Policy 14,
vation and Sustainable Natural Resource Management. Policy Matters, Gland, 1e37.
CH, pp. 111e116. Goldthorpe, C., 1994. An organisational analysis of plantation agriculture. Planter
Alexandratos, N., Bruinsma, J., 2012. World Agriculture towards 2030/2050, the 13.
2012 Revision. Food and Agriculture Organization, Rome. Grandori, A., 1997. Governance structures, coordination mechanisms and cognitive
Aspinall, E., Sukmajati, M., 2016. Electoral Dynamics in Indonesia: Money Politics, models. J. Manag. Gov. 1, 29e47.
Patronage and Clientalism at the Grassroots. NUS press, Singapore. Hardin, G., 1968. The tragedy of the commons. Science 1243e1248.
Badrun, M., 2011. Milestone of Change: Developing a Nation through Oil Palm 'PIR'. Hayami, Y., 2010. Chapter 64 plantations agriculture. In: Prabhu, P., Robert, E. (Eds.),
Directorate General of Estate Crops, Jakarta. Handbook of Agricultural Economics. Elsevier, pp. 3305e3322.
Baldassarri, D., 2015. Cooperative networks: altruism, group solidarity, reciprocity, Hazell, P., Poulton, C., Wiggins, S., Dorward, A., 2010. The future of small farms:
and sanctioning in ugandan producer organizations. Am. J. Sociol. 121, 355e395. trajectories and policy priorities. World Dev. 38, 1349e1361.
Baudron, F., Giller, K.E., 2014. Agriculture and nature: trouble and strife? Biol. Heering, R., 1993. Zehn jahre beratungsarbeit beim aufbau einer kleinbauern-
Conserv. 170, 232e245. plantage in NESP-Ophir projekt, West Sumatra. Ein Arbeitsbericht ueber den
Bauer, E., 1991. Promising Approaches in the Extension Work of Technical Cooper- Zeitraum Juli 1982 bis Februar 1992, Jakarta, p. 112.
ation: Case Study Nucleus Smallholder Estate Participation Project OPHIR Jahn, U., MacLellan, M., Pamuncak, E., Schmidt-Kallert, E., 1999. Ex-Post-Wirkung-
(NESP). GTZ, West Sumatera, p. 37. sanalyse von FZ- und TZ-Vorhaben in West-Sumatra (Indonesien). Bericht über
Bergschneider, 1990. Socio Economic Target Group Analysis of the Ophir Settler €
die Evaluierung des Olpalmenvohabens NESP-Ophir I. KfW, p. 55.
Families. GTZ, Padang, p. 112. Kievelitz, U., 1985. The Prerequisites for a Smallholder Organization: Socio Eco-
Blaikie, P., 2006. Is small really Beautiful? community-based natural resource nomic Situation, Social Structures and Peasants' Attitudes in the Nucleus Estate
management in Malawi and Botswana. World Dev. 34, 1942e1957. Smallholder Project Ophir, Pasaman, West Sumatra. ADP Working Paper. GTZ/
BMZ, 1986. Berlin workshop on the Ophir and Abai Siat Smallholder Projects, West BMZ, p. 88.
Sumatra, Indonesia. ADP Working Paper. BMZ/GTZ/Government of Indonesia, Koh, L.P., Wilcove, D.S., 2007. Cashing in palm oil for conservation. Nature 448,
Padang & Eschborn, p. 114. 993e994.
BMZ, 1992. Hauptbericht Evaluierung Kleinba €
€uerliche Olpalmenplantage NESP- Latour, B., 2005. Reassembling the Social : an Introduction to Actor-network-theory.
210 I. Jelsma et al. / Journal of Rural Studies 54 (2017) 198e210

Oxford University Press, Oxford; New York. Project in West Sumatra on Behalf of the Natomas Harrisons Fleming. Duns,
Lee, J., Ghazoul, J., Obidzinski, K., Koh, L., 2013. Oil palm smallholder yields and Scotland.
incomes constrained by harvesting practices and type of smallholder man- Samosir, Y.M.S., Drajat, B., Gillespie, P., 2013. Fertilizer and Oil Palm in Indonesia: an
agement in Indonesia. Agron. Sustain. Dev. 34, 501e513. Overview of the Industry and Challenges for Small-scale Oil Palm Farmer
McCarthy, J.F., 2010. Processes of inclusion and adverse incorporation: oil palm and Application. Daemeter, Bogor.
agrarian change in Sumatra, Indonesia. J. Peasant Stud. 821e850. Saunders, F.P., 2014. The promise of common pool resource theory and the reality of
McCarthy, J.F., Zen, Z., 2016. Agribusiness, agrarian change, and the fate of oil palm commons projects. Int. J. Commons 8, 636e656.
smallholders in Jambi. In: McCarthy, J.F., Cramb, R. (Eds.), The Oil Palm Com- Sayer, J., Ghazoul, J., Nelson, P., Klintuni Boedhihartono, A., 2012. Oil palm expansion
plex: Smallholders and the State in Indonesia and Malaysia, 1 ed. National transforms tropical landscapes and livelihoods. Glob. Food Secur. 1, 114e119.
University of Singapore, Singapore, pp. 109e154. Scott, J.C., 1985. Weapons of the Weak; Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. Yale
McCarthy, J.F., Gillespie, P., Zen, Z., 2012. Swimming upstream: local Indonesian University Press.
production networks in “Globalized” palm oil production. World Dev. 40, Shackleton, C.M., Willis, T.J., Brown, K., Polunin, N.V.C., 2010. Reflecting on the next
555e569. generation of models for community-based natural resource management.
Mintzberg, H., 1979. The Structuring of Organizations. A Synthesis of the Research. Environ. Conserv. 37, 1e4.
Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Shean, M., 2010. In: Foreign Agricultural Service (Ed.), Indonesia: Rising Global
Molenaar, J.W., Persch-Orth, M., Lord, S., Taylor, C., Harms, J., 2013. Diagnostic Study Demand Fuels Palm Oil Expansion. USDA.
on Indonesian Palm Oil Smallholders: Developing a Better Understanding of Sinaga, H., 2013. Employment and Income of Workers on Indonesian Oil Palm
their Performane and Potential. International Finance Corporation, p. 96. Plantations: Food Crisis at the Micro Level. Future of Food, vol. 1.
Index Mundi, 2017. http://www.indexmundi.com/commodities/?commodity¼ Susila, W.R., 2004. Contribution of oil palm industry to economic growth and
palm-oil&months¼300, visited 28-03-2017. poverty alleviation in Indonesia. J. Penelit. Dan. Pengemb. Pertan. 3, 107e114.
Olson, M., 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Sutton, K., 1989. Malaysia's FELDA land settlement model in time and space. Geo-
Groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. forum 20 (3), 339e354.
Ostrom, E., 1990. Governing the Commons: the Evolution of Institutions for Col- USDA, 2016. In: Foreign Agricultural Service (Ed.), Oilseeds: World Markets and
lective Action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. Trade. USDA, p. 35.
Ostrom, E., 2005. Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton University Press, Vollan, B., 2012. Pitfalls of externally initiated collective action: a case study from
Princeton. South Africa. World Dev. 40, 758e770.
Ostrom, E., 2009. A general framework for analyzing sustainability of social- Wicke, B., Sikkema, R., Dornburg, V., Faaij, A.P.C., 2011. Exploring land use changes
ecological systems. Science 325, 419e422. and the role of palm oil production in Indonesia and Malaysia. Land Use Policy
Peeters, K.D., 1995. In: GTZ (Ed.), Facts and Figures of Development and Strategy 28, 193e206.
NESP PIR-BUN Project, Ophir, West Sumatra, p. 36. Jakarta. Wiggins, S., Kirsten, J., Llambí, L., 2010. The future of small farms. World Dev. 38,
Poulton, C., Dorward, A., Kydd, J., 2010. The future of small farms: new directions for 1341e1348.
services, institutions, and Intermediation. World Dev. 38, 1413e1428. Wilson, D.S., Ostrom, E., Cox, M.E., 2013. Generalizing the core design principles for
Pye, O., Bhattacharya, J., 2012. The Palm Oil Controversy in Southeast Asia. A the efficacy of groups. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 90 (Suppl.), S21eS32.
Transnational Perspective ISEAS Publishing, Singapore. Zen, Z., McCarthy, J.F., Chalil, D., Sitorus, H., Shahputra, M., 2015. Consulting study
Rist, L., Feintrenie, L., Levang, P., 2010. The livelihood impacts of oil palm: small- 14; case study of Indonesian oil palm impact on socio-economic aspects of high
holders in Indonesia. Biodivers. Conservation 19, 1009e1024. carbon stocks (HCS). Proj. High. Carbon Stock (HCS) 55.
Robson, J.P., Davidson-Hunt, I.J., Delaney, A., Lichtenstein, G., Magole, L., Mead, A.T.P., Zen, Z., Barlow, C., Gondowarsito, R., McCarthy, J.F., 2016. Interventions to promote
2014. Remembering elinor Ostrom: her work and its contribution to the theory smallholder oil palm and socio-economic improvement in Indonesia. In:
and practice of conservation and sustainable natural resource management. Cramb, R., McCarthy, J.F. (Eds.), The Oil Palm Complex: Smallholders, Agri-
Policy Matters 124. CEESP and IUCN, Gland, CH. business and the State in Indonesia and Malaysia. National University of
Rosenquist, E.A., Anderson, L., 1975. An Appraisal of a 4,000 Hectares Oil Palm Singapore, Singapore, pp. 78e108.

You might also like