You are on page 1of 52

A New Measure of State Capacity, 1789-2018

Colin O’Reilly
Creighton University

Ryan H. Murphy
Southern Methodist University

7/4/20

ABSTRACT: This paper contributes to the literature on state capacity by creating a measure with
far more comprehensive data coverage across time than has previously been possible. It uses data
from the Varieties of Democracy dataset on fiscal capacity, a state’s control over its territory, the
rule of law, and the provision of public goods used to support markets. Like previous literature, it
demonstrates the historical prevalence of warfare to predict state capacity. It also links state
capacity to economic growth. Unlike previous literature, it is able to test these findings using
panel data. We are also able to quantitatively assess the position conjectured by Acemoglu and
Robinson (2019) regarding the importance of balance between the power of society and the
power of the state. These applications are meant to illustrate the ways in which the measure can
improve upon the rigor of existing literature on state capacity.

Keywords: State Capacity; Fiscal Capacity; Legal Capacity; Rule of Law; Varieties of
Democracy; Institutional Development; The Narrow Corridor

JEL Codes: H11; O43; H20; P14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


I. Introduction

The development of effective state institutions has emerged as a hypothesis explaining

the origins of economic growth and the modern world. State capacity, broadly defined as

governmental institutions capable of achieving the goals they set for themselves, encapsulates

the ability to raise revenue efficiently, the ability to enforce a monopoly on violence within its

territory, and the provision of public goods in such a way that supports the functioning of

markets, especially the legal capacity to attain the rule of law. The measurement of state

capacity, as is the case of other attempts at measuring institutions, is difficult and amorphous.

While empirical research on state capacity often has a heavy historical bent to it, historical state

capacity is typically measured via the percentage of GDP a sovereign is capable of raising during

a time of war. We do not dispute this is a reasonable way of addressing the question, though it

only captures one element of state capacity, fiscal capacity.

A rich measure of state capacity available over a long period is necessary to fully

evaluate some of the leading theories of economic and political development. We propose

aggregating six variables from the Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) dataset (Coppedge et al.

2019) to provide a panel of estimates of state capacity, 1789-2018, building on initial work by

Murphy and O’Reilly (Forthcoming). The potential for applying the V-Dem dataset, which is

extraordinarily dense and broad in scope, for institutions besides those pertaining narrowly to

democracy are only now beginning to be realized (Lawson and Murphy 2019: 189-190; Cornell

et al. Forthcoming). We create three versions of an index of state capacity, the broadest of which

covers all aspects of state capacity and is available for a large number of countries, but only

becomes available starting in 1900.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


More specifically, in its comprehensive form, our measure of state capacity is the first

principal component of the V-Dem variables measuring the rule of law, the authority of the state

over its territory, the rigorousness and impartiality or public administration, whether public

expenditures are on particularistic or public goods, the modernity of the state’s source of its

revenue, and the universality of the provision of education. The second version of the index

removes the universality of the provision of education due to its conceptual ambiguity (i.e.,

whether it is appropriate to think of it as state capacity rather than human capital). The third

version removes the state’s source of its revenue due to gaps in its data coverage.

We take a few steps to replicate previous results in the state capacity literature to

demonstrate the effectiveness of the index. We first follow Besley and Persson (2009) in

empirically demonstrating the link between the frequency of warfare and state capacity as of

1975. We are able to find the relationship using both their original specification and state

capacity as of 1900. We then separately specify a panel of 10-year intervals 1825-2005, finding a

relationship between war and state capacity. In making use of this data, we are able to show a

potential causal link between state warfare and state capacity in a far more comprehensive set of

specifications than previously considered.

A more descriptive application of our methodology is using state capacity in conjunction

with a measure of civil society, also from V-Dem, to quantitatively specify where countries are

with respect to Acemoglu and Robinson’s (2016; 2017; 2019) “narrow corridor,” whereby

institutional and economic development occurs when state and society are in balance with one

another. We are thus able to use the methodology to provide firmer quantitative foundations for a

prominent new hypothesis within political economy. Finally, we perform a series of growth

regressions using 10-year dynamic panels, 1815-2015 and historical GDP per capita data from

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


the Maddison project. Results from standard panel estimates and system GMM estimates

strongly point in the direction of state capacity contributing to economic growth.

The structure of this paper follows. Section II will review much of the existing literature

on state capacity. Section III constructs our index. Section IV replicates the findings of Besley

and Persson (2009) by linking war to state capacity, and then performs a series of extensions

which show the link to be robust, if with qualifications. Section V presents the data in the frame

of Acemoglu and Robinson (2019) and performs an informal but informative test of their model.

Section VI applies the data to a series of growth regressions. Section VII concludes.

II. Literature Review and Theory

A steady stream of reviews characterizing the state capacity literature have appeared from

a variety of perspectives in recent years (Dincecco 2015; Savoia and Sen 2015; Johnson and

Koyama 2017; Berwick and Christia 2018; Piano 2019). The literature closest to the analysis that

is performed in this paper is Hendrix (2010), which we will discuss in Section III. But the

historical starting point we choose is the conclusion of North and Weingast (1989): that the

Glorious Revolution in Britain created the political incentives to effect an accountable, limited

government which sought to protect property rights. While this reading of the history has

ultimately been questioned (Oglivie and Carus 2014), those within the tradition of North and

Weingast observed that what the Glorious Revolution allowed the monarch to do was to borrow

money on much easier terms. Rather than a straightforward story about the revolution causing

the state to “get out of the way,” counterintuitively, it became one of empowering the state to

perform functions that it previously performed poorly or not at all.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Moreover, what led political leaders to invest in state capacity was the threat of war.

While this argument originates in its modern form with Tilly (1992; c.f. Brewer 1989; Acemoglu

and Robinson 2019: 269-272), a two-period model from Besley and Persson (2009; 2010)

characterizes the decision to invest in legal and fiscal capacity. This functions as the formal

starting point for the question of state capacity and war. In their model, two groups in society

consume a private good by spending wages, 𝑤𝑤(𝜋𝜋), and a public good, 𝐺𝐺𝑠𝑠 , which is produced by

the government. The government, or the group in control of the government, can invest in legal

capacity (𝜋𝜋2 − 𝜋𝜋1 ) and invest in fiscal capacity (𝜏𝜏2 − 𝜏𝜏1 ), where 𝜋𝜋𝑠𝑠 and 𝜏𝜏𝑠𝑠 represent the level of

legal and fiscal capacity in period s. The marginal cost of the public good is represented by 𝜆𝜆1

and the cost functions for investments in legal capacity and investments in fiscal capacity are

𝐿𝐿(𝜋𝜋2 − 𝜋𝜋1 ) and 𝐹𝐹(𝜏𝜏2 − 𝜏𝜏1 ) respectively.

The value of the public good, national defense, is determined by the state of the world 𝛼𝛼𝑠𝑠 ,

which is equal to a high value, 𝑎𝑎𝐻𝐻 > 2 with probability 𝜃𝜃, or a low value, 𝑎𝑎𝐿𝐿 < 2, otherwise. In

the spirit of Tilly (1992), the random variable 𝜃𝜃 can be interpreted as the risk of war and 𝛼𝛼𝑠𝑠

represents the severity of the war. Therefore, the expected value of public funds in the second

period is 𝐸𝐸( 𝜆𝜆2 ) = 𝜃𝜃𝛼𝛼𝐻𝐻 + 2(1 − 𝜃𝜃)(1 − 𝛾𝛾) , where the first term is the value of national defense

given a war in period one, and the second term is the value of redistribution to the incumbent

group which retains power with probability (1 − 𝛾𝛾). 1 To solve the model Besley and Persson

assume that the incumbent group holds political power and optimizes by maximizing,

𝑤𝑤(𝜋𝜋2 )(1 − 𝜏𝜏2 ) + 𝐸𝐸(𝜆𝜆2 )[𝜏𝜏2 𝑤𝑤(𝜋𝜋2 ) + 𝐸𝐸(𝑧𝑧2 )] − 𝜆𝜆1 [𝐿𝐿(𝜋𝜋2 − 𝜋𝜋1 ) + 𝐹𝐹(𝜏𝜏2 − 𝜏𝜏1 )]. (1)

The first term is the value of production after taxes and the second term is the value of

expenditure on public goods from taxes and natural resource rents, 𝑧𝑧2 . The final term represents

1
Both 𝛾𝛾 and 𝜃𝜃 are bounded between zero and one.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


the cost of investment in state capacity. The incumbent faces a tradeoff between private

consumption and public goods consumption because the public good is produced by investments

in legal and fiscal capacity. They derive the first order condition with respect to legal capacity,

𝑤𝑤𝑝𝑝 (𝜋𝜋2 ){1 + 𝜏𝜏2 [𝐸𝐸(𝜆𝜆2 ) − 1]} ≤ 𝜆𝜆1 𝐿𝐿𝜋𝜋 (𝜋𝜋2 − 𝜋𝜋1 ) (2)

and with respect to fiscal capacity,

𝑤𝑤(𝜋𝜋2 )[𝐸𝐸(𝜆𝜆2 ) − 1] ≤ 𝜆𝜆1 𝐹𝐹𝜏𝜏 (𝜏𝜏2 − 𝜏𝜏1 ). (3)

Assuming that 𝐸𝐸(𝜆𝜆2 ) > 1, the first order conditions in Equation 2 and Equation 3 imply

that legal and fiscal capacity are complements, and that investments in legal and fiscal capacity

are increasing in the expected value of the public good, 𝐸𝐸(𝜆𝜆2 ). 2 All this is ultimately to mean

that the likelihood of conflict increases the value of national defense, and therefore investment in

both legal capacity and fiscal capacity. 3

The empirics in support of the theory that external war leads to the accumulation of state

capacity begins with Besley and Persson (2008) who showed that instances of war from the

Correlates of War dataset from the period 1945-1997 predict higher tax revenue as a percent of

GDP from 1975-1997. Similarly, Besley and Persson (2009) use data on the incidence of war

from 1816-1975 to successfully predict various measures of both legal and fiscal capacity.

Karaman and Pamuk (2010) compare the fiscal capacity of the Ottoman Empire to that of

countries in Europe, finding the Empire to lag behind other states, but its state responded to

military defeats with increases in fiscal capacity. Gennaioli and Voth (2015) argue that the cost

of fighting wars increased rapidly following 1500, forcing political consolidations of fragmented

2
Besley and Persson (2010) note that complementarity implies that monotone comparative statics are appropriate to
apply.
3
Analytically speaking, the derivative of the expected value of the public good with respect to the probability of
𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕(𝜆𝜆2 )
war, 𝜃𝜃, is = 𝛼𝛼𝐻𝐻 − 2(1 − 𝛾𝛾). The conclusion follows from the fact that 𝛼𝛼𝐻𝐻 is strictly greater than 2.
𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


states and the rise of fiscal capacity of the states that remained; in empirical support, they point

out that following 1500, wealth became much more highly correlated with military success.

Conversely, Chowdury and Murshed (2016) find that civil war reduces fiscal capacity in a

modern dynamic panel of countries 1980-2010, although the finding that civil wars do not build

fiscal capacity is consistent with Besley and Persson (2008), among others. Finally, Dincecco et

al. (2019) find that the relationship between war and fiscal capacity is not limited to Europe and

can be generalized to Africa as well.

The model also makes predictions about the severity of war, 𝛼𝛼𝑠𝑠 . 4 In their more detailed

model, Besley and Persson (2009) present the following proposition, “A higher expected demand
𝐽𝐽
for public goods, a first-order stochastically dominating shift in 𝛼𝛼, raises 𝜆𝜆2 and thereby

investment in state capacity.” To investigate this proposition, Karaman and Pamuk (2013) collect

data on tax revenue for twelve European states – Austrian Habsburgs, the Dutch Republic,

England, France, the Ottoman Empire, the Polish-Lithuanian Commonwealth, Portugal, Prussia,

Russia, Spain, Sweden, and Venice – from the sixteenth century to the end of the eighteenth

century, and show that it relates to totals of war casualties. Also in the Besley and Persson

model, market income, 𝑤𝑤(𝜋𝜋𝑠𝑠 ), is generated through interactions in capital markets, and is

therefore a function of legal capacity. Equation 5 characterizes the relationship between state

capacity and economic growth.

𝑌𝑌2 −𝑌𝑌1 𝑤𝑤(𝜋𝜋2 )−𝑤𝑤(𝜋𝜋1 )+𝑅𝑅2 −𝑅𝑅1


= (5)
𝑌𝑌1 𝑤𝑤(𝜋𝜋1 )+𝑅𝑅1

Besley and Persson (2010) explain, “If we ignore the exogenous resource rents [𝑅𝑅𝑠𝑠 ], higher

growth is generated solely by having higher legal capacity and hence better support for private

4
Note that, in the Besley and Persson (2009) model, the derivative of the expected value of public goods with
𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕(𝜆𝜆2 )
respect to the severity of war is = 𝜃𝜃.
𝜕𝜕𝛼𝛼𝐻𝐻

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


markets.” Their model functions, in some sense, as an outline of a comprehensive history of

economic development. War incentivizes fiscal capacity, which in turn creates institutions

capable of supporting markets. A large literature connecting state capacity to economic

performance has followed. Dincecco and Prado (2012) use historical war casualties as an

instrument for modern levels of taxation, which in turn predicts modern economic performance.

Cantoni and Yuchtman (2014) argue that the founding of universities in medieval Germany led

to the skills necessary for legal capacity, which in turn led to economic performance down the

road. Acemoglu et al. (2016) connects the presence of post offices in nineteenth century America

to the prevalence of patents granted as evidence of the U.S. government playing a market-

supporting role. 5 Dincecco and Katz (2016) use countries coded as accomplishing “fiscal

centralization” the first year that the state is able to raise revenue using a tax system with

uniform rates throughout its territory, and this predicts both fiscal capacity and economic

performance in a panel of data spanning four centuries. Similarly, precolonial centralization in

Africa is associated with modern development outcomes (Gennaioli and Rainer 2007). Evidence

that the quality of bureaucracies improve economic performance, while a narrower research

question than the effects of state capacity, can also be viewed as evidence of a link between state

capacity and economic performance (see, e.g., Dell et al. 2018; Cornell et al. forthcoming).

Criticisms of state capacity as an origin of development are less widespread. There are

two very recent arguments which make a variation on “backwards causality” as an explanation

for the empirical findings. Geloso and Salter (Forthcoming) argue that a reasonable reading of

the findings is that any country which became wealthy without developing state capacity would

be invaded by a country with a military, explaining the lack of modern examples of wealthy

5
See also Geloso and Makovi (2020), who are unable to reproduce the result for the Canadian province of Quebec.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


countries that have little state capacity. Secondly, Grier et al. (2020) turn much of the literature

on its head by empirically arguing that legal capacity predicts fiscal capacity, as opposed to the

other way around. How these new counterarguments will be addressed in the broader literature in

the future remains to be seen, but they are worth noting.

Those who have identified the importance of developing state capacity in a more applied,

development-focused context include Fukuyama (2004; 2011; 2014) and Andrews et al. (2017).

Fukuyama weaves state capacity and state building into his broad statements on the history of

political development, with emphasis placed on declines in state capacity within the developed

world as an explanation for weaker economic performance and stagnation in recent decades. This

is also reflected in development programs such as the Commission on State Fragility, Conflict

and Development, which counts the aforementioned Timothy Besley as one of its directors

(International Growth Centre 2018). The new Sustainable Development Goals explicitly include

state capacity in Goal 17.9, “targeted capacity-building in developing countries to support

national plans to implement all the sustainable development goals” (United Nations 2018).

Andrews et al. (2017) identify the practical challenges of building state capacity or capability

and implement their findings in developing countries in conjunction with the Building State

Capacity program at the Center for International Development. Development practitioners see

state capacity as having clear importance for economic development.

Finally, Acemoglu and Robinson (2019; 2017; 2016) re-conceptualize previous

statements on institutional development (see especially Acemoglu and Robinson 2012) in terms

of state capacity. According to Acemoglu and Robinson, what is needed for development is a

balance between the strength of the state and strength of society. If society is too weak, countries

will veer into totalitarianism. If the state is too weak, countries will fail to develop a state capable

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


of supporting markets because it will be strangled by traditional social institutions. When state

and society are in balance with one another, the country enters the “narrow corridor” of

institutional development whereby both state and society grow in strength together and feed off

one another. Later on, we will be able to assess the descriptions of Acemoglu and Robinson

rather directly using our method of measuring state capacity.

Theorists and practitioners alike emphasize the importance of state capacity. Yet, unlike

institutional concepts such as democracy, no measure of state capacity exists for a broad set of

countries over long periods of time. In the section that follows we attempt to address the paucity

of quantitative measures by constructing an index of state capacity. Later, we will assess the

ways in which it does and does not support the findings we have discussed.

III. Constructing State Capacity and Descriptive Findings

One survey of the literature on state capacity, Savoia and Sen (2015: 442-443), explicates

the five dimensions of state capacity: bureaucratic and administrative quality, legal capacity (a

functioning legal system), infrastructural capacity (state control over its territory), fiscal capacity

(the ability to raise revenue), and military capacity (a monopoly on violence). Our

comprehensive measure of state capacity includes variables concerning all of these dimensions,

and also correlates well with each of the measures of state capacity identified by Andrews et al.

(2017). As another point of reference, the defining aspects of state capacity given by Hendrix

(2010) are military capacity (border enforcement and a monopoly of violence), administrative

capacity (collecting and managing information), bureaucratic quality, the rule of law, and the

coherence of political institutions.6

6
In listing these, Hendrix also emphasizes that natural resource rents undermine state capacity, and uses their
presence as another measure of (a lack of) state capacity

10

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Our comprehensive index, 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , is the first principal component of six variables from

the V-Dem dataset. In reference to Savoia and Sen’s inventory of dimensions, we measure

“bureaucratic and administrative quality” using V-Dem’s measures of “particularistic or public

goods” (V-Dem code: v2dlencmps), “rigorous and impartial public administration” (v2clrspct),

and “educational equality” (v2peedueq). Concerning the “educational equality,” it reflects

whether basic universal education is achieved, not the quality thereof, and this falls under the

basic competency of the state. (See Table 1 for a complete description of all variables.) We

measure “legal capacity” using V-Dem’s rule of law sub-index (v2x_rule), which makes use of

fifteen indicators of the rule of law, and we measure both “infrastructural capacity” and “military

capacity” using “state authority over territory” (v2svstterr), which is the percentage of its

territory which a state credibly controls.

We measure “fiscal capacity” using V-Dem’s “state fiscal source of revenue” data

(v2stfisccap), which requires a longer explanation. It does not measure exactly how much

revenue a state could hypothetically raise, but it is conceptually very close. There are five

categories of responses that could be assigned to a country for a given year (while the categories

are ordinal, the final data is continuous). The lowest score (0) is received when the state is

incapable of raising revenue, followed by (1) the state relies on external financing, (2) the state

relies on ownership of assets (such as natural resources or public monopolies), (3) the state

primarily taxes land and trade, and (4) the state primarily taxes consumption, income, profits, or

capital. We would argue that this question is actually preferable to typical measures of fiscal

capacity, as it more closely corresponds to the state possessing the administrative capability of a

modern tax system. An additional benefit, in our view, of the way this variable is defined is that

11

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


penalizes countries that have superficially high state capacity but are actually dependent on

natural resource rents.

Thus in our comprehensive index, 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , we use the first principal component of the six

measures described above, “particularistic or public goods,” “rigorous and impartial public

administration,” “educational equality,” “rule of law,” “state authority over territory,” and “state

fiscal source of revenue” (which we will refer to as “fiscal capacity” from this point forward).

The second version of the index, 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , notes the slight conceptual ambiguity of “educational

equality” data, dropping it and re-running the principal component analysis. Although we feel

justified in interpreting educational equality as a measure of the capability of the state, we

remove it for those concerned that it may be instead measuring human capital. Practically

speaking, 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 is not available for years prior to 1900, and it differs little from 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , where

data are available for both.

The third, narrow version of the index, 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 eliminates fiscal capacity, not because of

conceptual reasons, but because it is a binding constraint for certain important periods for data

coverage; for example, it is unavailable for the United States between 1920 and 2005. 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 ,

which is comprised of the four remaining variables, is available for more than 20 countries as far

back as 1789 and for 174 countries in 2018.

The results of the three principal component analyses are summarized in Table 2. 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐

explains 46% of the variation in both the public administration variable and the rule of law

variable, as well as 41% of the variation in the public goods variable and the educational equality

variable. The index also explains 37% and 32% of the variability in the fiscal source of revenue

and the authority over territory variables. 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑎𝑎𝑟𝑟 explain similar proportions of the

variation in the variables included. The most comprehensive state capacity index, 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , captures

12

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


63% of the total variation in the underlying variables, whereas the most narrow state capacity

index, 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑟𝑟 , captures 68% of the variation. See Appendix A for additional details from the

principal component analysis.

The summary statistics for all three versions are presented in Table 3. 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 is available

for over 200 years for 20 countries, but for most countries it is available for fewer periods. See

Appendix B1 for a list of the top 20 and bottom 20 countries for 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 in the year 2000, and, in

Appendix B2, the countries which have seen their scores increase or decrease the most from

2000 to 2018. The average time dimension in the unbalanced panel of 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 is 94 years, whereas

the average time dimension of 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 is about 70 years, still a notable improvement relative to

existing measures of state capacity. The full 230-year time-series of 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 is plotted in Figure 1

for the 14 countries with complete data. Many notable historical events are clear in the figure.

State capacity declined in Russia with the fall of the Soviet Union and an increase in state

capacity in the United Kingdom coincided with a series of reforms to political institutions around

1870. As observed by Fukuyama (2014), state capacity appears to have decreased in several

developed countries recently including Denmark, France, Sweden and the United States – though

the decrease is modest in these cases.

To assess how well our new index captures state capacity, we compare each version to

existing measures of state capacity during the period they overlap. Andrews et al. (2017) identify

three measures of state capacity: the rule of law component from the International Country Risk

Guide (data first available in 1984), the Failed State Index (available in 2005), and the sum of

three components from the World Bank World Governance Indicators (“WGI;” available in

13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


1996). 7 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 all have a correlation of 0.79 or higher with each of the three

measures of state capacity given by Andrews et al. (2017). The correlation between 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 and

the sum of the three WGI indicators is 0.92. The correlations found in Table 4 also show that

𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 track the existing measures of state capacity well over a limited sample.

Finally, in Table 4 we also present cross-sectional correlations between each of the

aforementioned variables (in 2010) and the static measure of state history from Borcan et al,

(2018). For all seven measures of state capacity, the correlation with state history is less than 0.3;

the relationship with 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑠𝑠𝑐𝑐 , and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 is particularly weak.

Measures of convergent validity assess how well different survey questions or variables

measure the “same” concept. We report Cronbach’s alpha (see, e.g., Ott 2018) to assess the

convergent validity of different measures of institutional quality. 8 The Cronbach’s alpha between

each of the three measures identified by Andrews et al. (2017) and 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 are all

greater than 0.85. That is to say, 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 appear to be measuring the same latent

concept of state capacity.

The closest that previous literature has come to our approach is Hendrix (2010), who uses

factor analysis to decompose state capacity. Hendrix buttresses the standard International

Country Risk Guide data and one measure of fiscal capacity with measures of military spending

(signaling more state capacity) and commodity exports (less). However, Hendrix also includes

GDP per capita and five measures of democracy. 9 These indirect proxies, which are perhaps

7
The measure of state capacity from World Governance Indicators is the sum of the control of corruption index, the
government effectiveness index and the rule of law index. This can be compared with Fukuyama (2014: 61-63), who
used a combination of control of corruption and government effectiveness.
8
Scores are bounded between zero and one. In its standard applications, scores above 0.8 are considered an
indication of high validity.
9
Much of the motivation in Hendrix (2010) for using democracy comes from the idea that countries with middling
scores in democracy are the most prone to conflict (and democracy thereby has an inverted-U relationship with
conflict). This was pointed out by Vreeland (2008) to be the residue of how the Polity IV index was designed.

14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


problematic more often than not for hypothesis testing in general, are simply no longer necessary

given the presence of the Varieties of Democracy data. Other literature that makes use of

questionable proxies for state capacity include those which use the Doing Business report

(Larsson 2013), which on many margins is about limiting the power of government, or Polity

IV’s executive constraint (Asadullah and Savoia 2018) which is a measure of democratic

political institutions. And even in their seminal article, Fearon and Laitin (2003) use the log of

GDP per capita as a proxy for military and bureaucratic capacity.

In the following sections, we turn to applications of 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 . These

applications further test the validity of the approach and demonstrate ways it can be used to test

hypotheses in the literature. For the remainder of this paper we will at times refer to our approach

and 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 as “an” index, for rhetorical purposes. We will still specify which

version of the index we are referring to, as appropriate.

IV. Application 1: State Capacity and War

The first application of the index tests the hypotheses developed by Besley and Persson

(2010) and sketched in Section II, namely that war contributes to the development of state

capacity. Following Besley and Persson (2009), we test if the proportion of years a country was

at war prior to 1975 is associated with greater state capacity since 1975. Equation 1 regresses

state capacity, 𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖 , on the proportion of years at war, 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖 , which is defined as the number of years

at war between 1816 and 1975, or since the country joined the interstate system. 10 Instead of

measuring state capacity by tax revenue as a share of GDP, as in Besley and Persson (2009), we

Oddly, Hendrix acknowledges this and includes both Polity IV and its squared term anyway, as well as Vreeland’s
adjustment to it (and its squared term).
10
War years and membership in the interstate system is obtained from the Correlates of War dataset for consistency
with Besley and Persson (2009). Joining the interstate system often corresponds to gaining independence.

15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


test the hypothesis using 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 , and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 developed in Section III. Additional control

variables, 𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖 , include dummy variables for legal origin and the average democracy index from

the V-Dem dataset.

𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖 = 𝛽𝛽𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖 + 𝛿𝛿𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖 (1)

Earlier empirical studies of state capacity and war have relied on cross-sectional

measures of state capacity, as long panels were unavailable. Using the new indexes, we construct

an unbalanced panel of 10-year periods from 1825 to 2005 (for example, the 1825 period

includes years from 1825 to 1816). To test for the effect of war on future state capacity, we

regress state capacity in period t on the proportion of years at war in period t, period t-1, and

period t-2 as shown in Equation 2. 11 Adding country fixed effects, a lagged dependent variable

and additional control variables in Equation 3 extends the model.

𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 𝛼𝛼𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛽𝛽1 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 + 𝛽𝛽2 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−2 + 𝜏𝜏𝑡𝑡 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 (2)

𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 𝛼𝛼𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝛽𝛽1 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 + 𝛽𝛽2 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−2 + 𝛾𝛾𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 + 𝛿𝛿𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 + 𝜇𝜇𝑖𝑖 + 𝜏𝜏𝑡𝑡 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 (3)

The results of estimating the cross-sectional regression in Equation 1 using each of the

three new state capacity measures are presented in Table 5. The first three columns show the

relationship between the proportion of years at war prior to 1975 and state capacity after 1975.

The final three columns include controls for legal origin and the average level democracy before

1975. 12 Consistent with Besley and Persson (2009), greater exposure to war prior to 1975 is

associated with greater state capacity in all specifications. The relationship is robust to using

1900 as the threshold rather than 1975, as shown in Table 6. Results from a long cross-section

11
Ten-year periods for which fewer than five observations are available are dropped from the sample to avoid high
values of proportion of years at war based on limited data. Including these observations produces similar estimates.
Equation 2 also includes period dummy variables, 𝜏𝜏𝑡𝑡 .
12
We use V-Dem’s high-level index of electoral democracy which attempts to answer the question “To what extent
is the ideal of electoral democracy in its fullest sense achieved?”

16

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


are consistent with the theoretical predictions and previous empirical evidence that war or the

threat of war leads to greater state capacity.

Panel estimation is feasible by exploiting the longer time dimension of the new state

capacity index. The results of estimating the pooled model in Equation 2 are in the first column

of Tables 7 through 9. In all three specifications the contemporaneous proportion of years at war

has an insignificant association with the index of state capacity. Since the index includes a

measure of the state’s control over territory and interstate war usually involves the challenging of

borders, an insignificant or even negative contemporaneous effect of war on the state capacity

index is expected. A positive coefficient on one of the lags of the proportion of years at war is

evidence that war induces investments in future state capacity as predicted by the Besley and

Persson (2009, 2010) model. The first lag of war in Column 1 is not significant, but the second

lag of war has a positive and significant effect, indicating that war is associated with greater state

capacity decades later.

The pooled model may suffer from omitted variable bias and serial correlation. If the

propensity for war is determined by time invariant country characteristics such as geography, the

correct model accounts for country fixed effects. However, if war is determined by recent

investments in state capacity, the correct model accounts for lags of the dependent variable. The

results from a lagged dependent variable model are presented in Column 2 and show that the

contemporaneous effect of war on state capacity is negative, whereas the lagged effect of war is

positive. A greater proportion of years at war is associated with greater state capacity in the

following decade and the net effect of all three war proportion coefficients is statistically

17

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


significant. 13 The results from estimating a lagged dependent variable model are robust to the

inclusion of legal origin and democracy, as shown in Column 4.

Alternatively, the fixed effects model in Column 3 does not materially change the

estimate of the contemporaneous effect of war, but the effects of lagged war are not statistically

significant. 14 Controlling for country-specific effects renders the effect of war on future state

capacity insignificant. Either country fixed effects that are correlated with war are sapping the

explanatory power of the lagged war variable, or country-specific factors are the ultimate

determinant of state capacity. Assuming that countries with a greater proportion of years at war

tend to have high state capacity, the fixed effects model will underestimate the parameter and

lagged dependent variable model will overestimate the parameter. 15 Therefore, panel estimates

are somewhat inconclusive. Moreover, these kinds of techniques are of course incomplete in

assessing causality; the point we wish to emphasize is that they are an improvement over existing

literature and this improvement is made possible by the development of the index.

Applying the long time dimension of the new index reveals certain nuances that earlier

cross-sectional estimates could not. Specifically, limited evidence suggests the possibility that

country-specific factors, not war, may determine state capacity. Though the regressions here may

raise more questions about the ultimate causes of state capacity than they resolve, 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 , 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 ,

and 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 may facilitate more rigorous attempts to resolve those questions empirically. This

section demonstrates that richer measures with better data coverage may help us better

understand the determinants of state capacity. The sections that follow show similar applications

of the new index to questions about the consequences of state capacity.

13
The sum of the coefficients on the war proportion variables yields a significant F-statistic of 5.13.
14
A Hausman test rejects a random effects model.
15
See the discussion found in Angrist and Pischke 2009: 243-247.

18

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


V. Application 2: State Capacity and The Narrow Corridor

With our method of measuring state capacity in hand, we are able to operationalize the

diagrammatic model of institutional development presented in Acemoglu and Robinson (2019;

c.f. 2016; 2017) and in effect, to test it. (We will refer to Acemoglu and Robinson for the

remainder of this section as AR). AR argue that the source of institutional and economic

development is the dynamic played out between the strength of the state and the strength of

society. A weak society with a strong state will see its society get crushed (via a “Despotic

Leviathan”), while a strong society with a weak state will prevent the state from gaining in its

capabilities (an “Absent Leviathan”). Countries that develop are in the “narrow corridor” where

society and the state, effectively balancing one another, grow in unison (with a “Shackled

Leviathan”). More formally, Acemoglu and Robinson (2017) model the narrow corridor as a

saddle path that propels countries toward a strong state and strong civil society if they achieve a

sufficient balance between the two forces.

AR convey this argument diagrammatically throughout the book (e.g., 2019: 64, 268,

290), with the strength of society on the x-axis and the strength of the state on the y-axis. The

corridor is denoted by an area falling between two positively-sloped lines emanating from the

origin. The corridor is larger when both state and society are stronger. While historical events

may move countries into or out of the corridor, the crux of the model is that countries falling

within the corridor will continue moving outwards within the corridor, while countries outside of

it will collapse towards one of the axes. The slow-changing nature of institutions means that

existing measures of state capacity are ill suited to capture the dynamic nature of the AR model.

Figure 2 attempts to illustrate this relationship with data. On the x-axis, we use the civil

society organization participatory environment index from Varieties of Democracy, which

19

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


“include[s], but [is] not limited to, interest groups, labor unions, spiritual organizations if they

are engaged in civic or political activities, social movements, professional organizations,

charities, and other non-governmental organizations” (Coppedge et al. 2019: 47). On the y-axis,

we use 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 , such that as many countries as possible appear on the chart. We include any country

for which both 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 and the civil society index are available in the year 1850. Both indexes are

presented in a standardized form. On the chart, we plot each country’s position in 1850 and 2010

and linearly smooth the movement of the country in state capacity and civil society space to

visualize the dynamics over the long run. To capture the idea of a widening corridor in AR, we

draw two dashed lines with a widening gap as both state capacity and civil society increase. The

boundaries of the corridor intersect when state capacity and civil society are two standard

deviations below their mean value, and the corridor widens to two standard deviations in size

when the corridor is two standard deviations greater than the mean value of each variable. (This

is by nature arbitrary but produces a visually acceptable result.) This plot is the first empirical

representation of AR’s narrow corridor over period long enough to capture the model’s long term

dynamics.

We are able to make out a corridor in some sense. Nearly all countries have increased

both their strength of society and their strength of the state over this period. But it’s unclear

whether this supports the hypothesis of AR, especially the existence of a saddle path relationship.

We do not observe countries falling into one of three categories (Despotic Leviathan, Absent

Leviathan, or Shackled Leviathan); rather, nearly all countries, over this time frame, appear to be

in a broad corridor with leviathans in the process of being shackled. Using the reference lines as

a theoretical corridor, seven countries enter the corridor and then remain in the corridor

20

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


thereafter as the AR dynamics predict. In contrast, 33 countries exit the corridor after previously

being in the corridor. Appendix C summarizes these dynamics.

Of course, there is significant heterogeneity across time in most of these countries and the

linear representation of their dynamics masks substantial variation over the 160 years. We

provide a deeper breakdown by decade in Figure 3 for the 53 countries with data available

starting in 1900. But we still do not observe the trifurcating process described by AR in most

cases. Furthermore, several countries exhibit the dynamics predicted for countries that are “in the

corridor” although they would not have been thought of as exemplars, from our reading of AR.

By this we not only mean that they improved on both margins from 1850 to 2010, but have

moved upwards and rightwards at least somewhat continuously. These include countries such as

Thailand, Morocco, and Nepal. Costa Rica behaves as AR expect it to, but Guatemala is observed

to have a more powerful society than a powerful state, which is the opposite of what AR claim.

This is also to say that the lack of trifurcation is not due to the selective sample of 53 countries.

We also do not observe countries that “should” be in the corridor behaving as expected.

According to our measures, countries such as Austria, Denmark, Switzerland, and the United

States have been roughly stagnant since 1950, even though AR’s “Red Queen” effect posits that

these countries should be improving still further. Countries like those four have seen institutional

development since then, but perhaps this development is better thought of as economic

liberalization than it is as either state or social capacity.

To provide an even more direct test of The Narrow Corridor, we place all countries (once

per decade) in a grid and create a pseudo-transition probability matrix. We look to see, for

example, the probability of a country which falls in the interval of [-0.2,0.2] in its power of

society and [-0.2,0.2] in its state capacity will move northeast on the grid over the following

21

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


decade. 16 If The Narrow Corridor is correct, countries that are balanced should have a higher

probability of doing so. We do not observe this dynamic in Figure 4A. In the course of creating

the figure, however, the observed pattern is sensitive to small changes in how institutional

improvement is defined, which is to say that whatever pattern that you observe in this

presentation of the data is not especially robust. This can be seen in Figure 4B, where the only

change that is performed is increasing the size of the interval to create larger “buckets.”

Though we are able operationalize and even observe AR’s narrow corridor, the dynamic

behavior implied by AR is not borne out by the data. This does not completely falsify AR, and the

intention of this exercise was to provide another application of our methodology. One may view

the lack of corroboration of AR as problematic for our methodology. However, we did not

identify any example in Figure 2 as being facially unreasonable, and practically speaking, AR

had not chosen to use hard data over long periods in their diagrams. While we are ultimately able

to find support for what is generally found in the state capacity literature in the rest of this article,

this application of the state capacity data is not consistent with the core arguments of AR.

VI. Application 3: State Capacity and Economic Performance

An additional prediction of the Besley and Persson (2010) model, among others, is that

greater fiscal capacity and, in turn, greater legal capacity are associated with economic

performance. To test the hypothesis that state capacity is a determinant of economic

performance, we regress the logged level of real gross domestic product per capita on the level of

state capacity in the previous ten-year period as expressed in Equation 4. To address concerns of

16
We define a movement to the northeast as either an increase in state capacity, an increase in civil society or an
increase in both.

22

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


both endogeneity and Nickell bias, in the most complete specification we estimate a dynamic

panel using system GMM.

𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 = 𝛼𝛼𝑦𝑦𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 + 𝛽𝛽𝑐𝑐𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 + 𝛾𝛾𝑥𝑥𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖−1 + 𝜏𝜏𝑡𝑡 + 𝜇𝜇𝑖𝑖 + 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 (4)

The results of estimating Equation 4 are presented in Tables 10 through 12. Regardless of the

measure of state capacity, the effect of state capacity on growth is positive and significant in the

pooled model without period effects in Column 1, and with period effects in Column 2. The

inclusion of country fixed effects in Column 3 increases the magnitude of the effect. The model

in Column 4 includes both country and period effects. Though the effect of state capacity is

positive, it is consistently significant only if 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 is used. The final two columns show that the

results from the pooled specifications are robust to controlling for absolute latitude. The positive

association between state capacity and economic performance in the long panel at hand is

consistent with the literature analyzing short panels and historical cases.

The fixed effects models described above may suffer from Nickell bias because of the

inclusion of a lagged dependent variable as well as endogeneity. To assuage these concerns, we

estimate the results using system GMM in Table 13. One drawback of using system GMM

estimation on such a long panel is the abundance of instruments which can lead to unreliable

tests due to overidentification (Roodman 2009). We reduce the number of instruments by

collapsing all instrument sets and limiting the lags used as instruments. Odd numbered columns

present estimates using only the first valid instrument available whereas even numbered columns

present estimates using as many as two additional lags or lagged differences as instruments. The

effect of state capacity is positive and significant in all specifications.

These results suggest that state capacity is associated with high standards of living across

three measures of state capacity. The results here are the first cross-country evidence from a long

23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


panel testing the hypothesis that state capacity impacts the standard of living. Our cross-country

findings complement the rich historical evidence that state capacity is associated with economic

development.

VII. Conclusion

We construct an index of state capacity which runs from 1789-2018 and includes as many

as 174 countries. The comprehensive version of the index contains measures of all the major

dimensions of the concept: fiscal capacity, the quality of the bureaucracy, legal capacity, and a

monopoly of violence within a state’s borders. We also re-calculate the index by removing two

measures, one of which is conceptually ambiguous, and the second of which improves data

coverage. Our index is highly correlated with the measures of state capacity emphasized by

Andrews et al. (2017), although not state history.

We apply this data to questions previously posed in the literature. Because we have a

very lengthy (although unbalanced) panel, we are able to employ panel data methods that are

more rigorous than those that were used previously. We are also more able to directly test the

hypotheses in question by using a more general measure of state capacity in place of

unidimensional measures of fiscal capacity. Broadly speaking, we are able to corroborate what

was previously found in the literature.

First, we are able to corroborate the causal (or at the least correlative) relationship

between war and state capacity. We first match the methodology of Besley and Persson (2009)

and subsequently employ a series of panels using country-decades of 1825-2005 as units of

observation. Our panel estimates raise questions about the nature of the relationship between war

and state capacity that earlier cross-sectional methods could not. We then consider the recent

24

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


arguments from Acemoglu and Robinson (2019; 2016). We are able to observe some of the

patterns they describe vis-à-vis institutional development, but not others. Finally, we place our

state capacity measure in a series of growth regressions. Generally, our findings support what has

been found in the literature, namely that state capacity has a positive effect on growth.

We see future uses for our method of measuring state capacity as twofold. First, we are

able to give historical estimates of state capacity that are not wholly reliant on fiscal capacity and

war, which, we believe, are better tests of the hypotheses formulated in the literature. Second, the

broader data coverage allows for more robust testing of hypotheses than those outlined by

Andrews et al. (2017); data coverage using our methodology now approaches the quality of data

coverage in democracy indexes, for example. The extensive historical time-series opens the door

for researchers to leverage potentially countless historical quasi-natural experiments to make

causal inferences both about building state capacity and its relation to economic development.

It should also be emphasized that the broader versions of our index (𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 and 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 )

encapsulate each of the dimensions of state capacity, which more sharply distinguishes this

measure from the generic “institutions matter” hypothesis. Finally, we owe our ability to create

this methodology to the extensive work performed by the authors of the Varieties of Democracy

project, and we suspect that there are many other potential uses for their dataset that remain

unexplored.

25

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


WORKS CITED

Acemoglu, Daron, Jacob Moscona, and James A. Robinson. 2016. “State Capacity and American
Technology: Evidence from the Nineteenth Century.” American Economic Review Papers and
Proceedings 106, no. 5: 61-67.
Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power,
Prosperity, and Poverty. New York: Crown.
---. 2016. “Paths to Inclusive Institutions.” In Economic History of Warfare and State Formation,
Jari Eloranta, Eric Golson, Andrei Markevich, and Nikolaus Wolf, eds. Springer, p. 3-50.
---. 2017. “The Emergence of Weak, Despotic and Inclusive States.” NBER Working Paper no.
23657. http://www.nber.org/papers/w23657
---. 2019. The Narrow Corridor: States, Societies, and the Fate of Liberty. New York: Penguin
Press.
Andrews, Matt, Lant Pritchett, and Michael Woolcock. 2017. Building State Capability:
Evidence, Analysis, Action. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Angrist, Joshua D. and Jorn-Steffen Pischke. 2009. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An
Empiricist’s Companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Asadullah, M. Niaz, and Antonio Savoia. 2018. “Poverty Reduction during 1990–2013: Did
Millennium Development Goals Adoption and State Capacity Matter?” World Development 105:
70–82.
Berwick, Elissa and Fotini Christia. 2018. “State Capacity Redux: Integrating Classical and
Experimental Contributions to an Enduring Debate.” Annual Review of Political Science 21: 71-
91.
Besley, Timothy and Torsten Persson. 2008. “Wars and State Capacity.” Journal of the
European Economic Association 6, no. 2-3: 522-530.
---. 2009. “The Origins of State Capacity: Property Rights, Taxation, and Politics.” American
Economic Review 99, no. 4: 1218-1244.
---. 2010. “State Capacity, Conflict, and Development.” Econometrica 78, no. 1: 1–34.
Brewer, John. 1989. The Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English State, 1688-1783. New
York: Knopf.
Borcan, Oana, Ola Olsson, and Louis Putterman. 2018. “State History and Economic
Development: Evidence from Six Millennia.” Journal of Economic Growth 23(1): 1–40.
Cantoni, Davide and Noam Yuchtman. 2014. “Medieval Universities, Legal Institutions, and the
Commercial Revolution.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129, no. 2: 823-887.
Chowdury, Abdur R. and Syed Mansoob Murshed. 2016. “Conflict and Fiscal Capacity.”
Defence and Peace Economics 27, no. 5: 583-608.
Coppedge, Michael, John Gerring, Carl Henrik Knutsen, Staffan I. Lindberg, Jan Teorell, David
Altman, Michael Bernhard, M. Steven Fish, Adam Glynn, Allen Hicken, Anna Luhrmann, Kyle
L. Marquardt, Kelly McMann, Pamela Paxton, Daniel Pemstein, Brigitte Seim, Rachel Sigman,
Svend-Erik Skaaning, Jeffrey Staton, Agnes Cornell, Lisa Gastaldi, Haakon Gjerlow, Valeriya
26

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Mechkova, Johannes von Romer, Aksel Sundtrom, Eitan Tzelgov, Lucas Uberti, Yi-Ting Wang,
Tore Wig, and Daniel Ziblatt. 2019. V-Dem Codebook v9. Gothenburg: Varieties of Democracy
Project.
Coppedge, Michael, John Gerring, Carl Henrik Knutsen, Staffan I. Lindberg, Jan Teorell, Kyle
L. Marquardt, Juraj Medzihorsky, Daniel Pemstein, Josefine Pernes, Johannes von Römer,
Natalia Stepanova, Eitan Tzelgov, Yi-ting Wang, and Steven Wilson. 2019. V-Dem Methodology
v9. Varieties of Democracy Project.
Cornell, Agnus, Carl Henrik Knutsen, and Jan Teorell. “Bureaucracy and Growth.” Comparative
Political Studies, forthcoming.
Dell, Melissa, Nathan Lane, and Pablo Querubin. 2018. “The Historical State, Local Collective
Action, and Economic Development in Vietnam.” Econometrica 86, no. 6: 2083-2121.
Dincecco, Mark. 2015. “The Rise of Effective States in Europe.” Journal of Economic History
75, no. 3: 901-918.
Dincecco, Mark, James Fenske, and Massimiliano Gaetano Onorato. 2019. “Is Africa Different?
Historical Conflict and State Development.” Economic History of Developing Regions 34, no. 2:
209-250.
Dincecco, Mark and Gabriel Katz. 2016. “State Capacity and Long-Run Economic
Performance.” The Economic Journal 126, no. 590: 189-218.
Dincecco, Mark and Mauricio Prado. 2012. “Warfare, Fiscal Capacity, and Performance.”
Journal of Economic Growth 17: 171-203.
Fearon, James D. and David D. Laitin. 2003. “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War.” American
Political Science Review 97, no. 1: 75-90.
Fukuyama, Francis. 2004. State-Building: Governance and World Order in the 21st Century.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
---. 2011. The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution. New
York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
---. 2014. Political Order and Political Decay: From the Industrial Revolution to the
Globalization of Democracy. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
Geloso, Vincent and Michael Makovi. 2020. “State Capacity and the Post Office: Evidence from
19th Century Quebec.” Working paper,
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3526153
Geloso, Vincent and Alex Salter. “State Capacity and Economic Development: Causal
Mechanism or Correlative Filter?” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, forthcoming.
Gennaioli, Nicola, and Ilia Rainer. 2007. “The Modern Impact of Precolonial Centralization in
Africa.” Journal of Economic Growth 12(3): 185–234.
Gennaioli, Nicola and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2015. “State Capacity and Military Conflict.” The
Review of Economic Studies 82, no. 4: 1409-1448.
Grier, Kevin, Robin Grier, and Andrew Young. 2020. “The Casual Effect of Rule of Law and
Property Rights on Fiscal Capacity.” Working paper,
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3561899
27

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Hendrix, Cullen S. 2010. “Measuring State Capacity: Theoretical and Empirical Implications for
the Study of Civil Conflict.” Journal of Peace Research 47, no. 3: 273–85.
International Growth Centre. 2018. “Escaping the Fragility Trap.” LSE-Oxford Commission on
State Fragility, Growth and Development. https://www.theigc.org/research-
themes/state/fragility-commission/
Johnson, Noel D. and Mark Koyama. 2017. “States and Economic Growth: Capacity and
Constraints.” Explorations in Economic History 64: 1-20.
Karaman, K. Kivanc and Sevket Pamuk. 2010. “Ottoman State Finances in European
Perspective.” Journal of Economic History 70, no. 3: 593-629.
---. 2013. “Different Paths to the Modern State in Europe: The Interaction Between Warfare,
Economic Structure, and Political Regime.” American Political Science Review 107, no. 3: 603-
626.
Larsson, Tomas. 2013. “The Strong and the Weak: Ups and Downs of State Capacity in
Southeast Asia.” Asian Politics & Policy 5, no. 3: 337-358.
Lawson, Robert and Ryan H. Murphy. 2019. “Economic Freedom in the World in the 1950s and
1960s.” In Economic Freedom of the World 2019, James Gwartney, Robert Lawson, Joshua Hall,
and Ryan H. Murphy. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.
Maxwell, Laura. Kyle L. Marquardt and Anna Lührmann. 2018. The V-Dem Method for
Aggregating Expert-Coded Data. Policy Brief No. #17, 2018. Varieties of Democracy Project.
Murphy, Ryan H. and Colin O’Reilly. “Assessing State Capacity Libertarianism.” Cato Journal,
forthcoming.
North, Douglass and Barry Weingast. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of
Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” Journal of Economic
History 49, no. 4: 803-832.
Ogilvie, Sheilagh and A.W. Carus. 2014. “Institutions and Economic Growth in Historical
Perspective.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 2A, Philippe Aghion and Steven
Durlaf, eds. Elsevier, p. 403-515.
Ott, Jan. 2018. “Measuring Economic Freedom: Better Without Size of Government.” Social
Indicators Research 135, no. 2: 479–98.
Pemstein, Daniel. Kyle L. Marquardt, Eitan Tzelgov, Juraj Medzihorsky, Joshua Krusell, Farhad
Miri, and Johannes von Römer. 2018. The V-Dem Measurement Model: Latent Variable Analysis
for Cross-National and Cross-Temporal Expert-Coded Data". University of Gothenburg,
Varieties of Democracy Institute: Working Paper No. 21.
Piano, Ennio E. 2019. “State Capacity and Public Choice: A Critical Survey.” Public Choice
178, no. 1: 289–309.
Roodman, David. 2009. “A Note on the Theme of Too Many Instruments*.” Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics 71, no. 1: 135–58.
Savoia, Antonio and Kunel Sen. 2015. “Measurement, Evolution, Determinants, and
Consequences of State Capacity: A Review of Recent Research.” Journal of Economic Surveys
29, no. 3: 441-458.

28

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Tilly, Charles. 1992. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1992. Revised Edition.
Malden: Blackwell Publishers.
United Nations. 2018. “Transforming Our World: The 2030 Agenda for Sustainable
Development.” United Nations. www.sustainabledevelopment.un.org
Vreeland, James. 2008. “The Effect of Political Regime on Civil War: Unpacking Anocracy.”
Journal of Conflict Resolution 52, no. 3: 401-425.

29

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 1: Varieties of Democracy Indicator Descriptions

Rule of law:
To what extent are laws transparently, independently, predictably, impartially, and
equally enforced, and to what extent do the actions of government officials comply with
the law?

Underlying indicators from V-Dem: compliance with high court, compliance with
judiciary, high court independence, lower court independence, executive respects
constitution, rigorous and impartial public administration, transparent laws with
predictable enforcement, access to justice for men, access to justice for women, judicial
accountability, judicial corruption decision, public sector corrupt exchanges, public
sector theft, executive bribery and corrupt exchanges, executive embezzlement and
theft. Full variable descriptions available in the V-Dem codebook.

State authority over territory:


Over what percentage (%) of the territory does the state have effective control?

Rigorous and impartial public administration:


Are public officials rigorous and impartial in the performance of their duties?

Particularistic or public goods:


Considering the profile of social and infrastructural spending in the national budget,
how "particularistic" or "public goods" are most expenditures?

Educational equality:
To what extent is high quality basic education guaranteed to all, sufficient to enable
them to exercise their basic rights as adult citizens?

State fiscal source of revenue:


On which of the following sources of revenue does the central government primarily
rely to finance its activities?

Notes:
1) These abridged descriptions are from the V-Dem codebook (Coppedge et al. 2019).
2) The rule of law variable is constructed using Bayesian factor analysis to both extract the latent concept
of rule of law from the set of underlying indicators and to account for measurement error. The V-Dem
Methodology describes this procedure in more detail (Coppedge et al. 2019b).
3) The V-Dem indicators are constructed by aggregating the ordinal responses of multiple country experts
to the question corresponding each indicator. Responses must be aggregated across coders, converted
from an ordinal to an interval scale, and adjusted for the possibility that country experts have different
thresholds for coding. A Bayesian item response model developed by Pemstein et al. (2019) recovers the
latent concepts being measured and makes various adjustments and corrections for coding differences.
See the Maxwell et al. (2018) policy brief for an accessible description and Pemstein et al. (2019) for
technical details. An exception is the state control over territory indicator which uses a bootstrapping
method to aggregate the responses of country experts.

30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 2: Principal Components – Proportion of Variation Explained
Comprehensive Narrow w/ Fiscal Narrow
𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛
Rule of law index 0.4631 0.518 0.5558
State authority over territory 0.3166 0.3581 0.3868
Rigorous and impartial public admin. 0.4609 0.5121 0.5500
Particularistic or public goods 0.4125 0.4336 0.4889
State fiscal source of revenue 0.3712 0.3912
Educational equality 0.4061

Notes: The table reports the proportion of variation in each input variable explained by each of
the three versions of the state capacity index.

31

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 3: Summary Statistics:
State Capacity Mean Standard Minimum Maximum Observations
Variable Deviation

Narrow Index overall 0.000 1.649 -4.459 3.536 N = 18248


(𝒄𝒄𝒏𝒏𝒏𝒏𝒏𝒏 ) between 1.316 -3.025 2.841 n = 194
within 0.855 -4.843 2.923 T-bar = 94.1

Narrow with overall 0.000 1.752 -4.982 3.922 N = 17307


Fiscal Index between 1.423 -3.195 3.224 n = 192
(𝒄𝒄𝒇𝒇𝒇𝒇𝒇𝒇𝒇𝒇 ) within 0.921 -5.700 3.770 T-bar = 90.1

Comprehensive overall 0.000 1.940 -5.663 4.214 N = 12127


Index (𝒄𝒄𝒄𝒄𝒄𝒄𝒄𝒄𝒄𝒄 ) between 1.663 -4.080 3.498 n = 175
within 0.878 -4.616 3.000 T-bar = 69.3
Notes: Summary statistics of unbalanced annual panel data for 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 and 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 from 1789 to 2018
and for 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 from 1900 to 2018.

32

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 4: Correlations and Cronbach’s Alpha for Measures of State Capacity
*State
History ICRG WGI FFI 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐
State Correlation 1
History N 157

ICRG Correlation 0.2821 1


N 125 4492
Cronbach .4001
WGI Correlation 0.1776 0.9339 1
N 154 2680 3395
Cronbach 0.2998 0.9469
FFI Correlation -0.1669 -0.8786 -0.9166 1
N 152 1857 2328 2328
Cronbach 0.2765 0.9131 0.9573
Correlation
𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 -0.0072 0.7854 0.8813 -0.8314 1
N 156 4491 3395 2328 18248
Cronbach 0.0129 0.8503 0.8923 0.8962
Correlation
𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 0.0091 0.7834 0.8872 -0.8501 0.9817 1
N 156 4259 3323 2328 17307 17307
Cronbach 0.0171 0.8591 0.9144 0.8962 0.9882
Correlation 0.031 0.8032 0.9004 -0.875 0.9747 0.987 1
𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 N 156 4259 3323 2328 12127 12127 12127
Cronbach 0.0573 0.8739 0.9213 0.9099 0.9678 0.9880
Note: Pairwise correlations and the number of observations and Cronbach’s alpha shown. ICRG
is the rule of law measure from the International Country Risk Guide. FFI is the Failed States
Index. WGI is sum of the three indexes from the World Governance Indicators described in
Section III. We use the state history variable constructed using a 5% discount rate from Borcan,
Olsson and Putterman (2018). Cross-sectional correlations for the state history variable use
observations from 2010 for all other variables.

33

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 5: War and State Capacity – Long Cross-section (1975)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑟𝑟 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐

War Proportion 3.944*** 4.985*** 5.677*** 2.481** 3.351*** 3.778***


(1.181) (1.290) (1.429) (0.971) (1.041) (1.170)
French -0.00458 -0.0586 0.0260
(0.227) (0.244) (0.272)
German 1.279*** 1.384*** 1.776***
(0.260) (0.286) (0.317)
Scandinavian 1.508*** 1.692*** 2.085***
(0.468) (0.477) (0.511)
Democracy 4.076*** 4.633*** 5.113***
(0.470) (0.496) (0.567)
Constant 0.161 0.233 0.0397 -1.102*** -1.167*** -1.582***
(0.139) (0.153) (0.172) (0.271) (0.283) (0.317)

Observations 140 140 140 140 140 140


R-squared 0.062 0.079 0.081 0.536 0.568 0.573
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Notes: War proportion is the proportion of years at war between 1816 is 1975 from the
Correlates of War dataset. Legal origin dummy variables are included for French, German and
Scandinavian legal origins. Democracy is the democracy index of from the V-Dem dataset.

34

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 6: War and State Capacity – Long Cross-section (1900)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐

War Proportion 3.202** 3.703*** 4.112** 3.058*** 3.592*** 4.154***


(1.265) (1.362) (1.579) (1.011) (1.139) (1.285)
French -0.285 0.00645 0.142
(0.386) (0.337) (0.382)
German 1.611** 1.947** 2.408***
(0.727) (0.719) (0.781)
Scandinavian 2.379*** 2.924*** 3.369***
(0.430) (0.353) (0.368)
Democracy 6.314*** 7.252*** 7.861***
(1.450) (1.521) (1.775)
Constant -0.104 -0.00144 -0.393 -1.301*** -1.650*** -2.341***
(0.304) (0.332) (0.372) (0.457) (0.421) (0.498)

Observations 41 41 41 40 40 40
R-squared 0.062 0.070 0.069 0.622 0.637 0.629
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Notes: War proportion is the proportion of years at war between 1816 is 1900 from the
Correlates of War dataset. Legal origin dummy variables are included for French, German and
Scandinavian legal origins. Democracy is the democracy index of from the V-Dem dataset.

35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 7: War and State Capacity – Panel (𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 )
(1) (2) (3) (4)
VARIABLES Time FE LDV Time + Country FE Controls + LDV

State Capacity (t-1) 0.918*** 0.885***


(0.0110) (0.0205)
War Proportion 0.445 -0.337** -0.368* -0.280*
(0.385) (0.157) (0.199) (0.158)
War Proportion (t-1) 0.483 0.432*** 0.0236 0.456***
(0.323) (0.152) (0.220) (0.150)
War Proportion (t-2) 0.889*** 0.171 0.206 0.218
(0.339) (0.151) (0.140) (0.148)
French -0.0185
(0.0576)
German 0.196***
(0.0733)
Scandinavian 0.321***
(0.0595)
Democracy 0.0239
(0.124)
Constant -0.148 0.272** -1.447*** 0.130
(0.509) (0.136) (0.257) (0.161)

Observations 947 936 947 929


R-squared 0.053 0.851 0.414 0.851
Number of countries 152 152 152 152
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Notes: War proportion is the proportion of years at war during the 10-year period from the
Correlates of War dataset. Legal origin dummy variables are included for French, German and
Scandinavian legal origins. Democracy is the democracy index of from the V-Dem dataset. LDV
indicates that a lagged dependent variable is included.

36

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 8: War and State Capacity – Panel (𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 )
(1) (2) (3) (4)
VARIABLES Time FE LDV Time + Country FE Controls + LDV

State Capacity (t-1) 0.934*** 0.907***


(0.0102) (0.0197)
War Proportion 0.521 -0.442** -0.440** -0.390**
(0.445) (0.170) (0.195) (0.175)
War Proportion (t-1) 0.483 0.344** -0.159 0.370***
(0.365) (0.140) (0.202) (0.138)
War Proportion (t-2) 0.867** 0.202 0.0222 0.246
(0.411) (0.151) (0.146) (0.150)
French 0.0132
(0.0584)
German 0.230***
(0.0751)
Scandinavian 0.294***
(0.0602)
Democracy 0.0514
(0.138)
Constant 0.0188 0.315** -1.544*** 0.105
(0.506) (0.154) (0.274) (0.152)

Observations 890 866 890 859


R-squared 0.048 0.869 0.459 0.869
Number of countries 152 152 152 152
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Notes: War proportion is the proportion of years at war during the 10-year period from the
Correlates of War dataset. Legal origin dummy variables are included for French, German and
Scandinavian legal origins. Democracy is the democracy index of from the V-Dem dataset. LDV
indicates that a lagged dependent variable is included.

37

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 9: War and State Capacity – Panel (𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 )
(1) (2) (3) (4)
VARIABLES Time FE LDV Time + Country FE Controls + LDV

State Capacity (t-1) 0.940*** 0.919***


(0.0110) (0.0213)
War Proportion 0.597 -0.434* -0.758*** -0.406*
(0.566) (0.220) (0.270) (0.224)
War Proportion (t-1) 0.645 0.446** -0.339 0.460**
(0.446) (0.211) (0.314) (0.208)
War Proportion (t-2) 1.063** 0.179 -0.0921 0.202
(0.481) (0.198) (0.204) (0.194)
French 0.0137
(0.0637)
German 0.249***
(0.0840)
Scandinavian 0.335***
(0.0686)
Democracy 0.00855
(0.154)
Constant -0.836** -0.127 -1.156*** -0.207*
(0.387) (0.0992) (0.129) (0.123)

Observations 756 702 756 700


R-squared 0.065 0.876 0.500 0.877
Number of countries 151 151 151 151
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Notes: War proportion is the proportion of years at war during the 10-year period from the
Correlates of War dataset. Legal origin dummy variables are included for French, German and
Scandinavian legal origins. Democracy is the democracy index of from the V-Dem dataset. LDV
indicates that a lagged dependent variable is included.

38

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 10: State Capacity and Growth: 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES Pooled Period FE Country FE Period& Pooled Period FE
Country FE

Log GDP per capita (t-1) 0.995*** 0.968*** 0.933*** 0.621*** 0.991*** 0.946***
(0.0127) (0.0143) (0.0228) (0.0339) (0.0129) (0.0144)
State Capacity (t-1) 0.0177** 0.0269*** 0.0675*** 0.0226 0.00966 0.0135
(0.00892) (0.00865) (0.0191) (0.0161) (0.0103) (0.00994)
Absolute Latitude 0.00154* 0.00359***
(0.000793) (0.000889)
Constant 0.233** 0.288*** 0.726*** 2.455*** 0.225** 0.280***
(0.102) (0.107) (0.184) (0.229) (0.101) (0.102)

Observations 1,118 1,118 1,118 1,118 1,118 1,118


R-squared 0.917 0.929 0.838 0.887 0.918 0.931
Number of Countries 159 159 159 159 159 159
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 11: State Capacity and Growth: 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES Pooled Period FE Country FE Period & Pooled Period FE
Country FE

Log GDP per capita (t-1) 0.992*** 0.959*** 0.920*** 0.608*** 0.989*** 0.940***
(0.0133) (0.0150) (0.0267) (0.0359) (0.0135) (0.0151)
State Capacity (t-1) 0.0174** 0.0292*** 0.0717*** 0.0324* 0.0113 0.0178*
(0.00873) (0.00854) (0.0218) (0.0182) (0.0101) (0.00969)
Absolute Latitude 0.00123 0.00333***
(0.000821) (0.000905)
Constant 0.260** 0.354*** 0.832*** 2.553*** 0.248** 0.336***
(0.107) (0.112) (0.213) (0.245) (0.107) (0.108)

Observations 1,047 1,047 1,047 1,047 1,047 1,047


R-squared 0.914 0.927 0.833 0.883 0.915 0.929
Number of Countries 159 159 159 159 159 159
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

39

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 12: State Capacity and Growth: 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES Pooled Period FE Country FE Period & Pooled Period FE
Country FE

Log GDP per capita (t-1) 0.963*** 0.950*** 0.854*** 0.597*** 0.957*** 0.935***
(0.0156) (0.0168) (0.0344) (0.0386) (0.0151) (0.0164)
State Capacity (t-1) 0.0287*** 0.0304*** 0.0837*** 0.0335 0.0197* 0.0195*
(0.00911) (0.00893) (0.0249) (0.0214) (0.0105) (0.0103)
Absolute Latitude 0.00222** 0.00314***
(0.000953) (0.00103)
Constant 0.515*** 0.470*** 1.419*** 2.956*** 0.509*** 0.478***
(0.130) (0.131) (0.285) (0.282) (0.125) (0.125)

Observations 911 911 911 911 911 911


R-squared 0.908 0.920 0.770 0.835 0.908 0.921
Number of Countries 159 159 159 159 159 159
Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

40

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Table 13: State Capacity and Growth: GMM Estimation
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐

Log GDP per capita (t-1) 0.901*** 0.850*** 0.858*** 0.795*** 0.829*** 0.750***
(0.0645) (0.0630) (0.0874) (0.0769) (0.107) (0.0987)
State Capacity 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 (t-1) 0.139*** 0.155***
(0.0433) (0.0450)
State Capacity 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓 (t-1) 0.149*** 0.167***
(0.0527) (0.0495)
State Capacity 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 (t-1) 0.151** 0.185***
(0.0604) (0.0590)
Constant 1.104** 1.547*** 1.221* 1.758*** 1.495* 2.170***
(0.544) (0.534) (0.735) (0.649) (0.909) (0.841)
Year Effects X X X X X X
Observations 1,118 1,118 1,047 1,047 911 911
Number of ccode 159 159 159 159 159 159
Hansen stat 0.574 3.459 0.328 1.989 0.409 2.171
Hansen pvalue 0.750 0.749 0.849 0.921 0.815 0.903
AR1 -5.162 -5.295 -4.746 -4.944 -4.541 -4.644
AR1 pvalue 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
AR2 -0.555 -0.616 -0.613 -0.662 -0.491 -0.538
AR2 pvalue 0.579 0.538 0.540 0.508 0.624 0.591
Instruments 24 28 24 28 15 19
Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Notes: Odd numbered columns are estimates using only the third lag as an instrument for state
capacity and GDP in the levels equation, and only the fifth lag as an instrument for GDP in the
differenced equation. Even numbered columns use the third through fourth lag as an instrument
for all expect GDP in the differenced equation where the fifth and sixth lag are used. All
instrument sets are collapsed.

41

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Figure 1. State Capacity from 1789 to 2018 (𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 )

Panel A: State Capacity for Select Countries


4 2
State Capacity
-2 0
-4

1800 1850 1900 1950 2000


Year

China Denmark
France Iran
Japan Nepal
Portugal
Note: Only countries with the full 230 years of data incldued.

Panel B: State Capacity for Select Countries


4 2
State Capacity
-2 0
-4

1800 1850 1900 1950 2000


Year

Russia Spain
Sweden Thailand
Turkey United Kingdom
United States of America
Note: Only countries with the full 230 years of data incldued.

Note: State capacity is measured by standardized 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 and is plotted for the 14 countries with no
missing observations between 1789 and 2018.

42

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Figure 2. The Narrow Corridor, Quantitatively Operationalized
2 Panel A: The Narrow Corridor, Country Group 1

DNK
State Capacity

FRA

DEU
AUT
0

CRI
CHL GRC
MMR EGY
GTM BRA CHN

BOL
HTI COL
SLV
HND DOM
IRN ECU
-2

-2 0 2
Civil Society

1850 2010

Panel B: The Narrow Corridor, Country Group 2


2

CHE
NLD
State Capacity

SWE
USA
JPN
GBR
0

ESP
KOR PRT
PER LBR TUR
VEN MEX
MDG
PRY NPL RUS
MAR
THA
-2

URY

-2 0 2
Civil Society

1850 2010

Notes: State capacity is measured by standardized 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 and civil society is measured by the
standardized CSO participatory environment index. Dashed lines represent a narrow corridor
originating at (-2,-2) and widening to a width of one standard deviation in each direction at point
(2,2).

43

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Figure 3. The Narrow Corridor by Country, 1850-2010

Argentina Austria Belgium Bolivia


2

2010 2010
1900

2010
1870 1850 2010
0

1850
-2

Brazil Bulgaria Burma/Myanmar Canada

2010
2

2010 2010 1870

1880
0

1850 1850
2010
-2

Chile China Colombia Costa Rica


2

2010 2010

2010 2010
0

1850 1850
1850
1850
-2

-2 0 2 -2 0 2 -2 0 2 -2 0 2

Graphs by Country name

Denmark Dominican Republic Ecuador Egypt

2010
2

1850

2010 2010
0

1850
2010
1850
1850
-2

El Salvador Ethiopia France Germany

2010
2

2010
1850
2010 1850
2010
0

1850 1860
-2

Greece Guatemala Haiti Honduras


2

2010
0

1850 2010 2010 2010


1850
1850
1850
-2

-2 0 2 -2 0 2 -2 0 2 -2 0 2

Graphs by Country name

44

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Figure 3. The Narrow Corridor by Country, 1850-2010 (Continued)

Iran Italy Japan Liberia


2

2010
2010
1850
2010 2010
0

1870 1850

1850
-2

Luxembourg Madagascar Mexico Montenegro

2010
2

1900

2010 2010
0

1900
2010
1850 1850
-2

Morocco Nepal Netherlands Nicaragua


2

2010
1850

2010 2010
0

2010
1900

1850 1850
-2

-2 0 2 -2 0 2 -2 0 2 -2 0 2

Graphs by Country name

Oman Paraguay Peru Portugal


2

2010

2010 2010
2010
0

1850 1850
1900
1850
-2

Romania Russia Serbia South Korea


2

2010
2010
2010
1880 2010
0

1880
1850

1850
-2

Spain Sweden Switzerland Thailand

2010 2010
2

2010 1850

1850
2010
0

1850

1850
-2

-2 0 2 -2 0 2 -2 0 2 -2 0 2

Graphs by Country name

45

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Figure 3. The Narrow Corridor by Country, 1850-2010 (Continued)

Turkey United Kingdom United States of America


2

2010 2010

1850
2010 1850
0

1850
-2

-2 0 2

Uruguay Venezuela
2

2010
0

2010
1850
-2

1850

-2 0 2 -2 0 2

Graphs by Country name

Notes: State capacity is measured by the standardized 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 and civil society is measured by the
standardized CSO participatory environment index (10-year periods). Dashed lines represent a
narrow corridor originating at (-2,-2) and widening to a width of one standard deviation in each
direction at point (2,2).

46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Figure 4A. Transition Probability Matrix of the Corridor (step size 0.4)

Transitional Probability of the Narrow Corridor


2.2

1.8

P
1.4
0.75
1 0.70
0.66
.6 0.61
State Capacity

0.56
.2
0.52
0.47
-.2
0.43
-.6 0.38
0.34
-1 0.29
0.25
-1.4
0.20
0.16
-1.8
0.11
-2.2

< -2.2

< -2.2 -2.2 -1.8 -1.4 -1 -.6 -.2 .2 .6 1 1.4 1.8 2.2
Civil Society

Notes: Probability that either state capacity or civil society scores increase in the next 10-year
period. State capacity is measured by the standardized 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 and civil society is measured by the
standardized CSO participatory environment index. Areas with fewer than 10 observations are
omitted. Axes are labeled at the lower bound of each bin.

47

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Figure 4B. Transition Probability Matrix of the Corridor (step size 0.6)

Transitional Probability of the Narrow Corridor


2.4

1.8
P
0.68
1.2
0.64
0.60
.6 0.56
State Capacity

0.52
0 0.47
0.43
0.39
-.6
0.35
0.30
-1.2 0.26
0.22

-1.8 0.18
0.13
0.09
-2.4

< -2.4

< -2.4 -2.4 -1.8 -1.2 -.6 0 .6 1.2 1.8 2.4


Civil Society

Notes: Probability that either state capacity or civil society scores increase in the next 10-year
period. State capacity is measured by the standardized 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 and civil society is measured by the
standardized CSO participatory environment index. Areas with fewer than 10 observations are
omitted. Axes are labeled at the lower bound of each bin.

48

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Appendix A. Complete Principal Component Analyses
Principal Component Analysis: State Capacity – 𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑟𝑟

Number of observations 18,248


Trace 4
Rho 0.6798

Component Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative


Component 1 2.7192 2.0213 0.6798 0.6798
Component 2 0.6979 0.2475 0.1745 0.8543
Component 3 0.4505 0.3180 0.1126 0.9669
Component 4 0.1324 . 0.0331 1

Principal Component Analysis: State Capacity – 𝑐𝑐𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓𝑓

Number of observations 17,307


Trace 5
Rho 0.6136

Component Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative


Component 1 3.0681 2.3597 0.6136 0.6136
Component 2 0.7084 0.0447 0.1417 0.7553
Component 3 0.6638 0.2372 0.1327 0.8881
Component 4 0.4266 0.2935 0.0853 0.9734
Component 5 0.1331 . 0.0266 1

Principal Component Analysis: State Capacity – 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐

Number of observations 12,127


Trace 6
Rho 0.6274

Component Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative


Component 1 3.7646 3.0426 0.6274 0.6274
Component 2 0.7220 0.0948 0.1203 0.7478
Component 3 0.6272 0.1988 0.1045 0.8523
Component 4 0.4284 0.0822 0.0714 0.9237
Component 5 0.3463 0.2346 0.0577 0.9814
Component 6 0.1116 . 0.0186 1

Note: Appendix 1 presents the results of principal component analysis. The eigenvalue and the
proportion of total variation explained by each principal component is shown. Each index of
state capacity is defined as the first principal component. As shown in the tables all three
versions of the index capture over 60% of the variation in the underlying data.

49

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Appendix B1: Top and Bottom 20: 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 in Year 2000

State State
Top Country Capacity Bottom Country Capacity

1 Denmark 4.14 1 Somalia -5.65


2 Switzerland 3.90 2 Afghanistan -2.90
3 Sweden 3.89 3 Burma/Myanmar -2.83
4 Australia 3.76 4 Yemen -2.75
5 Finland 3.73 5 Sierra Leone -2.66

6 Germany 3.64 6 Angola -2.54


7 Netherlands 3.63 7 Azerbaijan -2.50
8 Belgium 3.57 8 Republic of the Congo -2.45
9 Spain 3.54 9 Egypt -2.34
10 France 3.51 10 Liberia -2.32

11 Luxembourg 3.47 11 Chad -2.18


12 New Zealand 3.46 12 Lebanon -1.92
13 South Korea 3.21 13 Equatorial Guinea -1.90
14 Taiwan 3.20 14 Tajikistan -1.89
15 Slovenia 3.18 15 North Korea -1.86

16 Portugal 3.16 16 Guinea-Bissau -1.83


17 Estonia 3.13 17 Nicaragua -1.74
18 Costa Rica 3.09 18 Iraq -1.66
19 Austria 2.97 19 Comoros -1.62
20 Botswana 2.96 20 Solomon Islands -1.62

Note: Appendix 2A lists the top and bottom 20 countries in the year 2000 using the
comprehensive state capacity index (𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 ).

50

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Appendix B2: Top and Bottom 20: 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 Movements 2010-2018
State State State State
Capacity, Capacity, Capacity, Capacity,
Top Country 2000 2018 Bottom Country 2000 2018

1 Sierra Leone -2.66 0.64 1 Syria -1.08 -3.80


2 Myanmar -2.83 -0.14 2 Burundi -0.68 -2.85
3 The Gambia -0.83 1.16 3 Turkey 0.86 -1.27
4 Liberia -2.32 -0.33 4 Yemen -2.75 -4.79
5 Angola -2.54 -0.81 5 Venezuela -0.85 -2.87

6 Tunisia -0.33 1.37 6 Thailand 0.86 -1.12


7 Somalia -5.65 -4.22 7 Zimbabwe 0.29 -1.35
8 Cote D’Ivoire -0.51 0.88 8 Haiti -1.13 -2.55
9 Benin 0.44 1.74 9 Hungary 2.69 1.39
10 Kyrgyzstan -1.04 0.10 10 Central African Republic -1.45 -2.75

11 Uzbekistan -1.44 -0.36 11 Libya -1.43 -2.61


12 Rwanda 0.66 1.71 12 South Africa 1.71 0.58
13 Sri Lanka -0.53 0.50 13 Iran 0.12 -1.00
14 Fiji 0.59 1.55 14 Nicaragua -1.74 -2.76
15 Mozambique -0.56 0.38 15 Bulgaria 2.19 1.25

16 Lebanon -1.92 -1.04 16 Brazil 0.92 0.09


17 Malaysia -0.06 0.79 17 Zambia 1.13 0.33
18 Solomon Islands -1.62 -0.80 18 Sweden 3.89 3.15
19 Ethiopia -0.66 0.16 19 France 3.51 2.81
20 Guyana 0.33 1.10 20 Dominican Republic -0.07 -0.72

Note: Appendix 2B shows the largest increases and the largest decreases in the comprehensive state capacity index (𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 ) between
2000 and 2018.

51

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637


Appendix C: Group Countries by Movement into an out of Corridor (𝑐𝑐𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛𝑛 )
Always in Corridor: Entered and Remained in Corridor:

Canada Belgium
Switzerland Costa Rica
United States China
Denmark
Japan
Sweden
United Kingdom

Never in the Corridor: Entered and Exited the Corridor:

Dominican Republic Argentina Italy


Honduras Austria Luxembourg
Liberia Bolivia Mexico
Oman Brazil Netherlands
Bulgaria Nepal

Chile Nicaragua
Colombia Paraguay
El Salvador Peru
Ethiopia Portugal
France Romania

Germany Russia
Greece Serbia
Guatemala South Korea
Haiti Spain
Iran Thailand

Turkey
Uruguay
Venezuela

Notes: Appendix 3 presents a categorization of countries based on how they move in state
capacity and civil society space between 1850 and 2018. For the purpose here, the narrow
corridor is defined as the area between the dashed lines in Figure 2. Specifically, the narrow
corridor originates at (-2,-2) with a width of zero and widens to a width of one standard deviation
in each direction at point (2,2).

52

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3643637

You might also like