You are on page 1of 11

Asia Pacific Educ. Rev.

(2016) 17:391–401
DOI 10.1007/s12564-016-9436-7

Conditional cash transfer against child labor: Indonesia Program


Keluarga Harapan
Kye Woo Lee1 • Miae Hwang2

Received: 22 January 2016 / Revised: 25 April 2016 / Accepted: 10 May 2016 / Published online: 28 June 2016
Ó Education Research Institute, Seoul National University, Seoul, Korea 2016

Abstract This study aims to analyze whether subsidies Keywords Child labor  Conditional cash transfer 
provided by the Indonesian conditional cash transfer Indonesia  Evaluation  Financial analysis  Net present
against child labor program (Program Keluarga Harapan: value
PKH) were sufficient for children to stop working and go
back to schooling. Ex-post evaluations of the program
found that it did not improve children’s enrollment rate and Introduction
reduce child labor significantly. To search out reasons, this
study analyzed the financial returns, on the short-, medium- The purpose of this study is to find out why Indonesian
, and long-term bases, of the children who attend school by conditional cash transfer against child labor program, Pro-
participating in the program, in comparison with those gram Keluarga Harapan, failed to reduce child labor (as
children who did not attend school. The data for the elaborated later in the Literature review section) and to
analysis were obtained from the Indonesia Family Life suggest some policy options to attain the program objectives.
Survey data from the RAND Corporation and Indonesian Generally, conditional cash transfer is one of the policy
government statistical data. The results demonstrated that options to deal with the child labor issue. By adopting this
the financial returns to children joining PKH to attend policy, the government or other public agency provides
primary school were lower than those of their non-partic- cash to a household when a family has school-age children.
ipating counterpart in the short and medium terms. Only in The assumption behind this policy is that increasing school
the long term, the financial returns to most program par- enrollment of children would lead to a decrease in child
ticipants were greater than those of non-participating labor since children cannot work while they are studying at
counterparts. The subsidy was too low and short to make school. The Indonesian government also implemented a
children attend school, driving children to workplaces. conditional cash transfer program against child labor,
Therefore, this study recommends that the government called Program Keluarga Harapan (PKH).
extend the subsidy period and sensitize poor family par- However, past evaluation papers such as Main Findings
ents, or reduce their burden of educational expenditures by from the Impact Evaluation of Indonesia’s Pilot Household
awarding them scholarships for their children’s education, Conditional Cash Transfer Program, written by Alatas in
or combine both policy actions. 2011, stated that the program did not improve very poor
household children’s school enrollment and did not reduce
their waged labor significantly (as elaborated further in the
Literature review section). At 95 %, the elementary school
& Kye Woo Lee enrollment rate in Indonesia was already high, but it did not
kwlee@kdischool.ac.kr
lead to a meaningful decrease in children’s waged working
1
KDI School of Public Policy and Management, 263 hours since school dropout rates were high. About 20 % of
Namsejong-ro, Sejong City 30149, Korea students in Indonesia dropped out from primary or junior
2
Korea Energy Economics Institute, 405-11 Jongga-ro, high school, and they were estimated at 750,000 children in
Jung-gu, Ulsan 681-300, Korea 2010 (Tifa 2011).

123
392 K. W. Lee, M. Hwang

Considering human rights and economic development, effects of conditional cash transfers will be conducted. In
dealing with the child labor problem is important. First, section 3, the methodology and data used for the hypoth-
child labor causes children’s health problems. It is note- esis test will be discussed, followed by section 4, which
worthy to mention that Indonesian children still work in will show the analysis results. Section 5 will cover con-
hazardous conditions and unsafe environments where ele- clusions and recommendations.
ments like inflammable and gaseous gear, toxic chemicals,
dangerous heights, and perilous machinery and equipment
severely threaten children’s lives (Aldobrandini 2012). Literature review
Without a doubt, eradicating child labor, especially the
worst form of child labor in Indonesia, is a truly global and Before making the hypotheses tests, a short introduction of
important issue. the conditional cash transfer program in Indonesia, Pro-
Second, child labor disturbs economic development in the gram Keluarga Harapan (PKH), is made, followed by a
long term. The accumulation of human capital is a key factor short review of the child labor situation in Indonesia and
of economic development in the long run. In particular, the effects of conditional cash transfer programs for child
education and health investment for human capital accu- education and against child labor will be made.
mulation is important since it has a positive relationship with
productivity (Galli 2001). However, children cannot be Program Keluarga Harapan
educated because of the work they are required to do. The
working hours of children in Indonesia are above the inter- Program Keluarga Harapan started implementation from
national norm of 3 h on school days and 8 h on non-school 2007 in five provinces; DKI Jakarta, West Java, East Java,
day, which means that they have no enough time to devote to NTT, and Gorontalo. By 2012, it was expanded to 25 out of
schooling. Even though they can enroll in schools, they do 33 provinces with 118 districts targeted, and about 778,000
not have a sufficient amount of time to do homework or the households participated in the program led by the Ministry
physical strength to simultaneously perform study and work. of Social Affairs (Kemensos).
This unfortunate phenomenon can cause low productivity Like other cash transfer programs, Program Keluarga
and can negatively affect the domestic economy in the long Harapan (PKH), aims to mitigate household poverty in the
term. Therefore, eradicating child labor is crucial for per- short term while improving human capital investment by
sonal and national development. increasing school enrollment and enhancing health condi-
To eradicate child labor, it is necessary to find why tions of children and pregnant women in the long term. The
children keep working. Many literature reviews mentioned provision of subsidies for 4 years in principle is conditional
that main reasons for child labor were related to economic on the fulfillment of the following conditions: for pregnant
problems. Therefore, this study also assumes that condi- women, they must take iron supplements and visit an office
tional cash transfer amount is insufficient for meeting for postnatal care; for children aged \6 years, they must
children’s living standards and expenditures, so they decide complete immunization and regularly receive health
to work instead of participating in PKH and attending checkups; and for children aged 6–15 years, they must
school. To examine the validity of such an argument, this achieve 85 % school attendance. The amount of subsidy is
study will test two hypotheses, (1) net revenue of children IDR 800,000 per year for children aged \6 years and
participating in the program is lower than that of non- pregnant women. Primary school students (aged 7–12)
participating children; and (2) the net present value (NPV), receive IDR 600,000 per year, while IDR 1,000,000 per
i.e., the present value of net benefit, of participating in the year is provided for secondary school students (age 13–15).
program is lower than the NPV of not participating in the Since the fixed basic transfer is IDR 200,000, the remain-
program. For analysis, this study will use program’s sub- ing amount of transfer varies, depending on the age joining
sidy (cash transfer), children’s current average wage the program. The government limited the maximum
income, education expenditure, and expected average wage transfer to IDR 2,200,000, regardless of the number of
income over the lifetime, depending on the educational children per household.
attainment level. Our empirical test results confirm the both
hypotheses, and therefore, we can conclude that one of the Indonesian Child Labor
important reasons for the PKH’s failure in eradicating child
labor is the insufficient level of the conditional cash The Child Labor Act 1986 in Indonesia defines child labor
transfer amount (i.e., the program subsidy) to the program as work of children whose ages are under 14 years. UNI-
participants. CEF defines ‘‘A child is considered to be involved in child
This paper is composed of five chapters. In the next labor activities under the following classification: (a) chil-
chapter, a literature review on Indonesian child labor and dren under 11 years of age that during the week preceding

123
Conditional cash transfer against child labor: Indonesia Program Keluarga Harapan 393

the survey did at least 1 h of economic activity or at least working children succeed in continuing their schooling,
28 h of domestic work, and (b) children 12–14 years of age Aldobrandini (2012) showed that working children in
that during the week preceding the survey did at least 14 h Indonesia are less likely to attend school than non-working
of economic activity or at least 42 h of economic activity children, and, needless to say, working hours and school
and domestic work combined’’ (Unicef 2015). ILO defines attendance had a strong and negative relationship. Con-
‘‘Child labor as work that deprives children of their sidering that the average working hours of children is about
childhood, their potential and their dignity, and that is 24.2 h in a week, working children have less time to study,
harmful to their physical and mental development’’ (ILO so their highest education level attained is lower than non-
2015). In this paper, child labor will be defined as children working children, and they therefore typically drop out of
whose ages are between 7 and 15 years working more than school (Aldobrandini 2012).
1 h per week, since in Indonesia all children are required to To deal with the problem, the Indonesian government
attend school and complete the junior secondary schooling. tried to increase school enrollment and reduce child labor
Child labor in Indonesia is as serious as in many other by supporting poor households through many programs
developing countries. According to Aldobrandini (2012), (Table 1).
Indonesian children who work, irrespective of the kinds of
tasks they perform, were estimated at 6.7 % of the child Effects of conditional cash transfer programs
population, or 2.3 million children in 2009. The main
reason for child labor is based on the economic situation. The Conditional Cash Transfer program (CCT) is a pro-
Children’s income, which is typically crucial for household gram offering cash to poor families, and it comes to the
survival, gives way to the increasing supply of child labor fore as one of the effective ways for eradicating child labor.
(Kis-Katos and Schulze 2011; Priyambada et al. 2005, Originally, CCT was designed to increase children’s school
Amin et al. 2004). Income shock and unemployment of enrollment (attendance) and to enhance household mem-
adults also increase the demand for child labor since child bers’ health by muting household poverty. CCT usually
work could make up for the loss from income shock. requires family members to go to health centers for regular
Similarly, unemployment of adults and the supply of child health checkups and children to go to school with at least
labor have a positive relationship. Children are increasingly 85 % attendance. Filmer and Schady (2009) mentioned that
expected to work when one of the adults in the family loses about 29 countries including Brazil, Mexico, Cambodia,
his or her job, or does not have the opportunity to work. and Ecuador have implemented CCT.
Similarly, Ranjan’s (1999) study supports this idea in The literature shows that the impact of CCT is sub-
another way. He found that formal credit markets, espe- stantial. For example, a study by Filmer and Schady (2011)
cially long-term credit markets, are desperately needed to on Cambodia’s CCT program called CESSP Scholarship
make children go to school. For the poor, a loan is the Program (CSP) demonstrates a positive relationship
easiest way to acquire assets. Unfortunately, it is difficult between CCT and school enrollment. The program dis-
for the impoverished to have that opportunity since there is tributed $45 per year to each household, which is equal to 2
nothing that guarantees their credit. Therefore, they send or 3 % of household expenditure. The improvement in
their children not to school, but to work. school dropout rates was about 25 % compared to the non-
Central Board of Statistics (BPS) and ILO-IPEC (2010) beneficiaries whose school completion rate was only 44 %.
mentioned that about 57.2 % of working children aged Oportunidades (the CCT program in Mexico) showed
between 5 and 17 are employed in agriculture, forestry, similar outcomes. Households enrolled in the program
hunting, and fishery. In the agriculture sector, children received subsidies depending on the number of children,
especially work at plantations where they produce rubber, and not surprisingly, results in children education were
palm oil, and tobacco. Such occupations are hazardous to significant. The outcome was notable at entry into sec-
children since there are many factors that may possibly ondary school. Without the program, just 36 % of students
harm the children. Also, working affects the children’s enrolled in secondary school; but with the program, this
education. figure increased to 76 % (de Janvry et al. 2006; Rawlings
Child labor in general induces children to quit their and Rubio 2003; de Janvry and Sadoulet 2004).
schooling (Angrist and Lavy 2009; Fiszbein et al. 2009; Additionally, CCT reduces child labor as an indirect
Hanushek et al. 2006; Glewwe and Kremer 2006). They benefit. Increasing school enrollment implies that children
found that when children’s income, which can be under- who work or do nothing start going to school. For working
stood as an opportunity cost to children in school, rises, the children, the time for working is replaced by time spent in
school dropout rates also increase. Since older children and school, so it obviously reduces child labor. Jones and
boys tend to get higher salaries, the school dropout rates of Marquez (2014), Fernandez and Saldarriaga (2014), and
boys and children aged 11–13 is also higher. Even though Perova and Vakis (2009) illustrate that CCT shrinks child

123
394 K. W. Lee, M. Hwang

labor. In Peru, the Juntos (which means ‘‘together’’) Pro- does not cover schooling expenditures, so school-age
gram was implemented, and its influence extended to paid children tend not to go to school, but to work. This phe-
and unpaid working children. Once per 2 months, a treat- nomenon can be one of the reasons for the failing CCT in
ment group received 200 Soles ($63), and the result cal- Indonesia. Even though many evaluation studies on the
culated from Young Lives data in 2009 showed that the Indonesia CCT program, Program Keluarga Harapan
paid working children in a beneficiary group were ten times (PKH), showed the impact of the program, they did not
fewer than those in a non-beneficiary group. Dearden et al. mention about the opportunity cost of participating in the
(2009) also proved the positive relationship between CCT program. Nazara and Rahayu (2013) also just mentioned
and child labor. Unlike the Juntos Program, Education that the inappropriate time of disbursing subsidy might
Maintenance Allowance in the UK reduced child labor by have failed to increase school enrollment in secondary
preventing inactive children from becoming workers. The school and reducing working children in that age group.
program transferred subsidies corresponding to 12 % of Therefore, this paper will examine whether financial
household income to families earning \£13,000. The transfer flows of PKH cover living expenses and educa-
scholarship value enlarged full-time students by 6.7 % tional expenditures of program participants to compensate
point. for their loss of working wage earnings in the short term.
However, in some cases, it appears that the poorest Also, this study will check whether the net present value
household children do not follow the general outcome. Even (NPV) of participating in the program is higher than the
though they could get the subsidy by going to school and get NPV of not participating in the program in the long run.
more labor earnings in the future, they chose working instead The next chapter will introduce what methodology and data
of studying. Mo et al. (2013) illustrated this phenomenon will be used for the test of these hypotheses.
with a randomized controlled trial (RCT) done in China. The
project randomly selected people in a village and gave them
500 RMB per year. Contrary to a control group which had Methodology and data
13.3 % working children, the treatment group had only
5.3 % working children, showing an 8 % points difference. The literature review has pointed out that high opportunity
However, it was not significant among the poorest children cost is one of the important barriers to participating in the
group. The study found that they were usually working at off- CCT program, and the ineffective results of PKH on edu-
farm jobs and earned 100 RMB per month. To them, par- cation and child labor may also have been caused by high
ticipating in that program causes damages to their household opportunity costs of participating in the PKH and attending
economy. Edmonds and Shrestha (2014) focused on chil- school. Children who do not participate in the PKH pro-
dren’s opportunity cost, showing the Nepal CCT Program gram may believe that working continuously will probably
case. They argued that even though it reduced working girls give a higher revenue and net financial return than
in weaving by 75 % and prevented them from failing school attending school. To verify such assumptions, this study
exams by 66 %, the researchers could not find positive net will examine whether or not participating in PKH incurs
returns to education, stressing that foregone child labor high opportunity costs and whether the private financial
earnings should have been considered. returns to participating in the PKH is greater than those of
In order to evaluate the CCT program (PKH) in non-participation.
Indonesia, the World Bank in 2011, 4 years after the ini-
tiation of PKH, assessed some performance indicators, Methodology
such as poverty level of beneficiaries, child malnutrition
level, consumption of high-energy and high-protein food, Two hypotheses will be examined.
average education attainment level, attendance rate of
1) Net revenue of children participating in the program
children, the number of children’s working hours, and the
is higher than or same with that of non-participating
rate of children’s work participation (Alatas et al. 2011).
children on a 1-year basis.
Surprisingly, most of the indicators improved from the
2) NPV of children participating in the program is
baseline. However, the number of working hours and the
higher than or same with the NPV of non-participants
rate of work participation indicated that the program did
in the program in the short (5-year), medium (10-
not mitigate child labor. Even though the result indicated
year), and long terms (45-year).
an improvement, the degree of improvement was too low at
only two percent (World Bank 2012). For the test, this study classifies all children into two
The assessments also illustrated that PKH not always groups. The first group is the children who are currently
affected all households equally. For the poorest household enrolled in school and face a decision on whether to con-
children, subsidy for the participation in the CCT program tinue to study while receiving the subsidy (participating in

123
Conditional cash transfer against child labor: Indonesia Program Keluarga Harapan 395

PKH), or to start working on a full-time basis, giving up items are considered: the subsidy of PKH, current wage
schooling (not participating in PKH). This first group of income, expected future wage income, education expen-
children participating in the program are a treatment group diture, and cost of living (Table 4). Net revenue is defined
and are subdivided into four subgroups (A, B, C, and D as total receipt of income, net of education expenditures
groups), depending on the level of educational attainment and living costs. NPV is the present value of the sum of net
and the age when they will be participating in PKH. The revenue in each year during the period considered, i.e.,
second group of children who do not participate in the each year’s net revenue was discounted at the opportunity
program is a control group and is subdivided into two cost of capital to convert the future values to the equivalent
subgroups (E and F groups), depending on the level and present time value and then was summed up.
age of schooling (Tables 2 and 3).
The groups are categorized as follows: Data
A. Children participate in the PKH during ages 7–12.
Data of ‘‘child wage income’’ and ‘‘education expenditure’’
They attend and finish the 6-year primary schooling.
in Indonesia are taken from the Indonesia Family Life
However, they do not continue schooling after com-
Survey (IFLS) 4, which was done by RAND Corporation in
pleting primary education.
2007. Indonesia Family Life Survey (IFLS) has been
B. Children participate in the PKH during ages 7–12.
implemented once every 4 years, and it covers only 13 of
They attend primary school, finish it, and enroll in
the 33 provinces in Indonesia. Nevertheless, using it is
junior high school. However, they do not complete
reasonable since surveyed areas cover all PKH areas, and
secondary school.
83 % of Indonesians live in those 13 provinces. ‘‘Educa-
C. Children participate in the PKH during ages 7–12.
tional expenditure’’ contained the expenditure for not only
They complete primary school with participation in the
both primary and secondary schools, but also Islamic
program. And they continue to junior high school until
schools. To avoid double counting with per capita cost of
they complete secondary schooling.
living, only schooling-related expenditure was considered
D. Children participate in the PKH during ages 13–15.
as educational expenditure. ‘‘Current wage income’’ was
They attend junior high school and complete it.
computed for both children participating in the program
E. Children do not participate in the PKH during ages
and non-participants. Children participating in the program
7–12. Even after those ages, they do not experience
not only attend school, but also work on a part-time basis
schooling at all.
(on average, 11.6 h per week), while children not partici-
F. Children do not participate in the PKH during ages
pating in the program work on a full-time basis (on aver-
13–15. They have already acquired a primary school
age, 24.4 h per week) (Aldobrandini 2012). Current child
diploma without participating in the program, but do
wage income was computed for all students enrolled in
not attend junior high school.
general (non-religious) elementary schools and general
For the analysis, this study will calculate the net revenue junior high schools since samples of Islamic schools were
of children participating in the program on the short-term too small (only eight) to use.
(5 years), midterm (10 years) and long-term (until retiring Information on the program ‘‘subsidy’’ was taken from the
age) bases. The computation of the NPV of the children is social assistance program and public expenditure review 6
also made for different periods, as follows: on PKH conditional cash transfers written by the World Bank
(World Bank 2012). Children whose age are 7–12 receive
a) Calculate until 20 years old, which is 5 years from
IDR 600,000 per year while children whose age are 13–15
the age of 15, the year that ILO sets as the minimal
receive IDR 1,000,000 per year (US$ = IDR 9090 in 2007
age required to start working.
when the program started). This amount is about 3–6 % of
b) Calculate until 25 years old, which is 10 years from
the average household expenditure.
the age of 15.
Data on ‘‘expected future income’’ and ‘‘per capita living
c) Calculate until 60 years old, which is the average
cost’’ were obtained from government’s Badan Pusat Statistik
retirement age in Indonesia.
(BPS: Central Board of Statistics, Indonesia, 2014 and 2015).
However, the starting point of the calculation will vary Primary and secondary school ‘‘child’s living costs’’ were
since children can start the program in any age during the age derived by dividing the average cost of living of a household
group mentioned above. Therefore, we will not consider by four, which is the average family size, and then multiplying
previous educational expenditure, expenditure before join- it by 2/3 since a child spends less than an adult. To avoid
ing the program, because such expenditures are sunk costs. double counting, educational expenditure was deducted from
To estimate the net revenue and NPV of children par- the average household living cost. To establish ‘‘expected
ticipating or not participating in the PKH, the following future income,’’ average income by educational attainment

123
396 K. W. Lee, M. Hwang

level over the working lifetime was taken since it was the earnings were also lower than non-participating children’s
only data available (Table 5). since most children participating in the program also work
at the same time, but their working hours are much shorter
than those of non-participants who work on a full-time
Analysis basis.
The net revenue of children who are in primary school,
Net revenue and living costs receiving a subsidy, is IDR -2,167,161, while that of
children who are in junior high school, receiving subsidy,
During 1 year in which children participate in the program, is IDR -2,713,981 (Table 6). Both of them are smaller
the total net revenue of children participating in the pro- than those of non-participating children. Also, participant’s
gram showed negative figures. Even though they received net revenue will go worse over time since subsidy is pro-
subsidy, they spent a lot of money on education, and their vided for 4 years only, so they need to endure some part of

Table 1 Governmental
Name Type Year
program for reducing child
labor and education Program Bantuan Tunai Unconditional Cash Transfer Program 2005
Program Keluarga Harapan Conditional Cash Transfer Program 2007
Generasi Sehatdan Cerdas Community CCT Program 2007
Raskin Rice Subsidy Program 2006
Urban Poverty Program – 1998
Kecamatan Development Program – 1998
Program Nasional Pemberdayan Masyarakat National Program for Community Empowerment 2006

Table 2 Children enrolled in primary school and participating in PKH


Age participating in Participate in Attend primary Complete primary Attend junior high Complete junior high
program PKH? school? school? school? school?

A 7–12 O O O X X
B 7–12 O O O O X
C 7–12 O O O O O
D 13–15 O O O O O
O means ‘‘yes’’ to the question, X means ‘‘no’’ to the question

Table 3 Children not participating in PKH


School Participate in Attend primary Complete primary Attend junior high Complete junior high
age PKH? school? school? school? school?

E 7–12 X X X X X
F 13–15 X O O X X
O means ‘‘yes’’ to the question, X means ‘‘no’’ to the question

Table 4 Variables for children participating and non-participating in PKH


Variables for children participating in PKH Variables for children not participating in PKH

Revenue (income) of child Subsidy, –


Current wage income, Current wage income,
Expected future wage income Expected future wage income
Expenditure of child Education expenditure, –
Cost of living Cost of living

123
Conditional cash transfer against child labor: Indonesia Program Keluarga Harapan 397

Table 5 Average annual lifetime labor earnings by education level


Level of education Less than primary education Primary education Junior secondary education
completed completed completed

IDR IDR 7,808,400 IDR 9.370,800 IDR 11,340,000


INDEX 100 120 121
– 100 145
Source: Badan Pusat Statistik (State Council of Statistics, Indonesia) 2014

Table 6 Net revenue of


Primary school children Junior high school children
children participating in PKH in
2007 [unit: IDR] Participants Non-participants Participants Non-participants

Expenditure (A)
Educational expenditure 1,248,172 2,303,791
Cost of living 2,738,104 2,738,104 2,738,104 2,738,104
Revenue (B)
Subsidy 600,000 – 1,000,000 –
Current income 1,219,115 2,543,326 1,327,914 2,770,303
Net revenue total (B)–(A) -2,167,161 -194,778 -2,713,981 32,199
Source: Sect. 3.2 data

the whole schooling period without any subsidy (primary over the working lifetime, depending on the level of edu-
schooling is for 6 years, and junior secondary schooling is cational attainment. Therefore, a more adequate compar-
for 3 years). The program subsidy covers neither the living ison between the two (treatment or program-participating,
cost, nor the educational expenditure fully. The level of and control or program-non-participating) groups would be
subsidy is too low to cover the educational expenditure, to consider their revenue and expenditures over longer
which is about two times as high as the program subsidy. periods or throughout their working lifetime, i.e., the pre-
Although children participating in PKH also work on a sent value of net revenue or net present value (NPV). For
part-time basis, their current wage income is less than half the computation of NPVs, a discount rate of 10 % per year
that of the non-participating children. Program partici- was used to discount the future net revenues to the present
pants’ current wage income barely covers the educational value (as of December 31, 2007), following the practice of
expenditure and cannot cover the living cost fully. There- the World Bank and other international development
fore, the first null hypothesis is rejected, and the alternative finance institutions.
hypothesis that the net revenue of children participating in First, NPVs are compared between program participants
the program is lower than the net revenue of non-partici- and non-participants in the short term, i.e., after 5 years
pants is accepted. from the age of 15, the age of finishing mandatory edu-
This study has simulated how much the subsidy level cation (Table 7). The results show that the NPVs of most
should be increased to pay off the educational expenditure children in groups B and C, who participated in the pro-
(and/or living cost). The program subsidy has to be gram during ages 7–12 and continued to secondary edu-
increased by about 400 % of the current level of subsidy cation (Tables 2, 3), were less than those of the children
for the primary school children and by about 300 % for the who did not participate in the program. In other words, the
junior secondary school children to cover the expenses. present value of the net benefits of participating in the
Then, the net revenue of the children participating in the program is smaller than those of non-participants. This
program will become positive and greater than that of non- phenomenon is due to the expensive secondary education
participating counterparts. expenditure, as well as the low levels of program subsidy
and lower current wage income due to the low level of
Comparing net present value of program schooling. Even though government designed the program
participants and non-participants subsidy that covered tuition, it did not consider transport
fees and other costs like uniforms, school supplies, and
Comparing the net revenue of participating and non-par- other expenditures related to schooling. The amount of
ticipating children on 1-year basis is insufficient, since educational expenditures is about the same as children’s
expected future wage income will increase at different rates current income, so compensation of the living cost requires

123
398 K. W. Lee, M. Hwang

Table 7 Comparing NPV in


Starting age Participating in program Not participating in program
the short run (5 years after
15 Years of age) [unit: IDR] Group A Group B Group C Group D Group E Group F

7 -1,664,795 -5,843,665 -4,108,893 5,661,971


8 847,338 -3,593,366 -1,685,216 6,442,424
9 3,766,738 -1,118,036 981,038 7,300,922
10 6,527,289 1,905,352 4,214,333 8,245,270
11 9,665,540 5,231,079 7,770,959 9,284,053
12 13,015,971 8,138,064 11,683,246 10,426,714
13 15,235,448 11,683,641
14 19,744,372 12,816,586
15 24,704,188 14,062,826
Bold and Italic figures indicate that NPV of participating children will be greater than that of non-
participating children

a lot of wage-earning time. But their working hours are participants. However, all children, who complete primary
sacrificed by attending school, and the opportunity cost education participating in PKH and proceed to secondary
attending school is as high as half the current wage income school but fail to complete it (group B), have a lower NPV
of non-participating children. than their non-PKH participants. Therefore, to benefit from
On the other hand, however, exceptions are children PKH, it is important for children to complete primary
who join the PKH in the last 2 years of primary education education and junior secondary schooling, since they can
(at age 11 or 12) to complete it (group A in Tables 2, 3) benefit from the sharply higher future wage income based
and children who started the program at the age 13–15 and on the junior secondary education diploma.
complete the secondary schooling (group D in Tables 2, 3). Then, the NPVs of children after 10 years from the age
Their NPV (marked by underlined numbers) is greater than of 15 have been computed (Table 8). It again shows most
their non-participating counterparts (groups E and F in children, who participate in the program during ages 7–12
Tables 2, 3). In the case of group D (Tables 2, 3), the and proceed to secondary school but fail to complete it
expected future income with a secondary school diploma is without participating in PKH (group B), as well as chil-
significantly higher than the expected income with a pri- dren, who join the program before age 10 to complete
mary school diploma only (Table 5), and this difference primary school (some in group A) or to proceed to sec-
enables group D children to have a higher NPV than ondary school (some in group C,) will have lower NPV
children in other groups including group F children (who than their non-participating counterpart (the control groups
attended primary school, but do not attend junior secondary E and F).
school since they do not participate in the program). Some However, exceptions are children who joined the pro-
children of group A (who join the program at age 11 or 12) gram after the age 10 and complete primary education only
complete primary school with the benefit of PKH, but do (some in group A), children who started the program after
not attend secondary school. Their NPV is greater than that the age 10 to complete primary school and then proceed to
of non-participating counterpart, since they are free from secondary school to complete it (some in group C), and all
the expenditure burden of the long primary education children in group D, who complete secondary school by
period. Also, some children of group C (who join the joining the program. Their NPV is greater than their
program at age 12) complete primary school, but also counterpart (control groups E and F). All children in group
progress to junior secondary school to complete it. Their D could meet the higher secondary school expenses with
NPV is likewise greater than that of non-participating greater subsidy and sharply higher future wage income due
counterpart, since they can meet the higher secondary to the secondary school diploma over the 10-year period
education expenditure with the greater subsidy and sharply after schooling (Table 5). Some children in groups A and C
higher future wage income owing to the completion of joined the program later in primary schooling, and there-
secondary education. fore, they could complete primary school with the program
In sum, some children, who do not go to junior sec- subsidy that lasted for 4 years. Some children in group C
ondary school after completion of primary school, partic- started the program at the later ages of primary schooling
ipating in PKH (group A), and all children, who do go to and then completed their junior secondary schooling, but
junior secondary school to complete it with participation in they could cover the higher secondary school expenses
PKH (group D), have a higher NPV than that of non-PKH with greater subsidy and much higher future wage income

123
Conditional cash transfer against child labor: Indonesia Program Keluarga Harapan 399

Table 8 Comparing NPV in


Starting age Participating in program Not participating in program
the medium run (over 10 years
after age 15) [unit: IDR] Group A Group B Group C Group D Group E Group F

7 4,114,981 -63,890 3,833,174


8 7,205,091 2,764,387 7,051,030 10,913,014
9 10,760,266 5,875,492 10,590,939 12,218,571
10 14,220,170 9,598,233 14,785,225 13,654,684
11 18,127,709 13,693,248 19,398,939 15,234,408
12 22,324,357 17,446,450 24,474,025 16,972,105
13 29,305,304 18,883,571
14 35,221,214 20,736,509
15 41,728,714 22,774,741
Bold and Italic figures indicate that NPV of participating children will be greater than that of non-
participating children

based on the secondary education diploma over the 10-year expenditure burden and the living costs. Educational
period after schooling (Table 5). expenditure in junior secondary school is almost 2.0 times
Nevertheless, children belonging to group B (complete higher than that of primary school, while the PKH subsidy
primary education with PKH and then progress to junior rises only by 0.6 times, and expected future income with a
secondary school, but do not complete it), as well as some secondary school diploma is 1.2 times that of children who
children, who belong to groups A and C, but participate in complete their education with a primary school diploma
the program too early to cover the whole primary schooling only (Table 5). This explains why those children in group
expenses and living costs with PKH subsidies, have NPVs B is the most disadvantaged since they have to compensate
lower than the children who do not participate in the pro- for their junior secondary education expenditure, which is
gram (groups E and F). This finding illustrates again that relatively higher than primary education expenditure, with
once starting junior secondary education, it is critical for expected future wage earnings of primary education
program participants to complete it to have a higher NPV attainment only. It also implies that it is critical for children
than their non-participating counterparts. Those who do not to enroll for junior secondary education, and once they
complete junior secondary school cannot benefit from the enroll in junior secondary school, it is advantageous to
much higher expected future wage income based on a complete it.
secondary school diploma over the 10-year working period. It has been demonstrated earlier that the comparative
Finally, children’s NPVs after 45 years (the average situation of the net revenue between program participants
retirement age in Indonesia) from the age of 15 shows that and non-participants does not change with some minor
most children who participate in the program at a primary increases in the level of subsidy. Unless the subsidy is
schooling age will get NPVs higher than those of children increased by 300–400 % of the current level, the compar-
who do not participate in the program (Table 9). This is ative situation of the NPV between the two groups would
contrary to the situation in the short (5-year) and medium not change either (Table 6).
(10-year) terms. Therefore, the timing of joining the pro-
gram seems to be important in making NPVs of partici- Findings and discussion
pating in the program greater than those of non-
participants. The critical age is above 9 for group A and The findings of our analysis can be summarized in two
above 11 for group B. There is no critical age restriction for points. First, our analysis shows that in the short (5 years
groups C and D. after age 15)- and medium (10 years after age 15)-term
If children in groups A and B join earlier than the planning horizons, children participating in PKH at age 10
critical age, their NPVs become lower than their non-par- or under would rarely find their NPVs greater than those of
ticipating counterparts. This is partly because the children non-participating counterparts. Therefore, joining PKH at
have to endure some years without the program subsidy, an early age of primary schooling (age 7–12) is not prof-
which lasts only 4 years while primary schooling is itable for the participants in PKH. The reason is that par-
6 years, and partly because their expected future wage ticipating children’s revenue cannot meet the educational
earnings that depend on the level of educational attainment and living expenditure since the program subsidy is at a
are insufficient to compensate for the educational low level and does not cover the full 6-year primary

123
400 K. W. Lee, M. Hwang

Table 9 Comparing NPV in


Starting age Participating in program Not participating in program
the long run (over 45 years after
age 15) [unit: IDR] Group A Group B Group C Group D Group E Group F

7 13,245,228 9,066,358 16,379,169 16,146,272


8 17,248,363 12,807,659 20,851,559 17,975,156
9 21,807,866 16,923,091 25,771,593 19,986,927
10 26,372,529 21,750,592 31,483,945 22,199,875
11 31,495,304 27,060,843 37,767,531 24,634,119
12 37,028,711 32,150,805 44,679,476 27,311,786
13 54,939,065 30,257,221
14 63,418,350 33,247,524
15 72,745,565 40,660,252
Bold and italic figures indicate that NPV of participating children will be greater than that of non-
participating children

education period, and current wage earnings are sacrificed Therefore, the government will have to take two-pron-
by attending school. This fact is the main reason why the ged actions. One action is to make the long-term prospects
CCT in Indonesia (PKH) has not been so effective in of NPVs for children joining PKH clear and transparent,
increasing children’s enrollment rates and reducing child and then educate/sensitize parents of poor families.
labor. Another action is to make the short- and medium-term
Our analysis also shows that children completing sec- prospects of NPVs for children joining PKH at an early
ondary school with participation in PKH always find their stage more favorable. Since cash transfers cannot be
NPV greater than non-participants. Therefore, it is desir- increased sharply by 300–400 % of the current level to
able to ensure that children complete secondary education cover both children’s educational expenditures and living
with the benefit of PKH. Although joining PKH at a later costs in the short run due to heavy fiscal burden, awarding
age of primary schooling or at secondary schooling ages poor family children scholarships by exempting tuition,
makes participating children’s NPV greater than that of fees, and school supplies would be relatively less costly to
non-participants, children have to start enrolling in primary the government and more practically helpful for parents.
school first and then should not dropout out of school to Currently, the program subsidy (cash transfer) covers only
complete primary and secondary school. We have seen that half the educational expenditure, let alone children’s living
increasing the level of program subsidy is not a practical costs (Table 6).
option since the rate of increase should be so high a level as
300 or 400 % with negative fiscal implications.
One possible solution for making the program effective Conclusions and recommendations
in eradicating child labor is to extend the program subsidy
period beyond the current 4 years. Currently, if children This study aimed to discover the main reason why children
join PKH at an early age of primary schooling, they will do not participate in or drop out of the conditional cash
have to endure some years of primary and secondary transfers program (PKH) in Indonesia and found that high
schooling without subsidy and have to bear the direct educational and living expenditures and low subsidies
educational expenses and the opportunity cost of losing drive children to working instead of attending school. The
potential wage earnings due to schooling. This burden will costs of primary schooling in Indonesia are as high as
be allayed by extending the subsidy provision period children’s income and about two times as high as program
beyond the current 4 years to cover the full primary and subsidies. Junior high school students’ educational expen-
secondary schooling period. ditures also are more than two times as high as children’s
Secondly, our finding is that, on the long and working income and program subsidies. Moreover, the program
lifetime planning horizon, the NPVs of children who joined subsidy is not given more than 4 years, which is shorter
PKH during the early age of primary schooling are greater than the full 6-year primary and 3-year secondary school-
than their non-participating counterparts. The issue, how- ing period.
ever, is whether the children and their parents, especially Accordingly, children joining PKH to attend primary
those of poor families, would be apt to make a decision on school at an early school age do not find their net present
a long-term basis. They are more likely to make decisions value (NPV) greater than that of their non-participating
on the basis of short- and medium-term prospects of NPVs, counterparts in the short and medium terms. Only in the
which are adversary to joining PKH. long and working lifetime term, they find their net present

123
Conditional cash transfer against child labor: Indonesia Program Keluarga Harapan 401

value greater than that of their non-participating counter- Edmonds, E. V., & Shrestha, M. (2014). You get what you pay for:
part. Children attending junior secondary school with Schooling incentives and child labor. Journal of Development
Economics, 111, 196–211.
participation in PKH always find their NPV greater than Fernandez, F., & Saldarriaga, V. (2014). Do benefit recipients change
that of their non-participating counterparts mainly because their labor supply after receiving the cash transfer? Evidence
their expected future labor earning is much higher than that from the Peruvian Juntos program. IZA Journal of Labor &
of primary school completers. Development, 3(1), 1–30.
Filmer, D., & Schady, N. (2009). Are there diminishing returns to
Therefore, this study recommends, first, that the gov- transfer size in conditional cash transfers? World Bank Policy
ernment extend the duration of program subsidy provision Research Working Paper Series.
beyond the current 4-year period, so that poor children can Filmer, D., & Schady, N. (2011). Does more cash in conditional cash
enroll primary school at an earlier age with participation in transfer programs always lead to larger impacts on school
attendance? Journal of Development Economics, 96(1),
PKH and continue with junior secondary schooling for 150–157.
completion. Second, the government educate and sensitize Fiszbein, A., Schady, N. R., & Ferreira, F. H. (2009). Conditional
poor family parents regarding the profitable long-term cash transfers: reducing present and future poverty. World Bank
prospects of NPV of the children joining PKH to attend Publications.
Galli, R. (2001). The economic impact of child labour (Vol. 128).
primary and secondary school. Third, the government Geneva: International Institute for Labour Studies.
lower parents’ burden of educational expenditures by Glewwe, P., & Kremer, M. (2006). Schools, teachers, and education
awarding poor family children scholarships for primary and outcomes in developing countries. Handbook of the Economics
junior secondary education, for example, by exempting of Education, 2, 945–1017.
Hanushek, E. A., Lavy, V., & Hitomi, K. (2006). Do students care about
them from paying school fees and tuition. school quality? Quality-consistent estimates of dropout behavior
in developing countries (NBER Working Paper No. 12737).
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
ILO. (2015). http://www.ilo.org/ipec/facts/lang–en/index.htm.
References Jones, N., & Marquez, E. V. (2014). Is cash the answer? Lessons for
child protection programming from Peru: The Juntos (Together)
program has the potential to improve children’s care and
Act. (1986). The Child Labour (Prohibition and Regulation) Act, protection. Child Abuse and Neglect, 38(3), 383–394.
1986, 107–112. Kis-Katos, K., & Schulze, G. G. (2011). Child labour in Indonesian
Alatas, V., Cahyadi, N., Ekasari, E., Harmoun, S., Hidayat, B., Janz, small industries. Journal of Development Studies, 47(12),
E., & Wai-Poi, M. (2011). Main findings from the impact 1887–1908.
evaluation of Indonesia’s pilot household conditional cash Mo, D., Zhang, L., Yi, H., Luo, R., Rozelle, S., & Brinton, C. (2013).
transfer program. World Bank. School dropouts and conditional cash transfers: Evidence from a
Aldobrandini, V. (2012). Understanding children’s work and youth randomised controlled trial in rural China’s Junior High Schools.
employment outcomes in Indonesia. Understanding children’s The Journal of Development Studies, 49(2), 190–207.
work and youth. Nazara, S., & Rahayu, S. K. (2013). Program Keluarga Harapan
Amin, S., Quayes, M. S., & Rives, J. M. (2004). Poverty and other (PKH): Indonesian conditional cash transfer programme.
determinants of child labor in Bangladesh. Southern Economic Research brief, No. 42. Jakarta: International Policy Centre for
Journal, 70(4), 876–892. Inclusive Growth.
Angrist, J. D., & Lavy, V. (2009). The effect of high stakes high Perova, E., & Vakis, R. (2009). Welfare impacts of the ‘‘Juntos’’
school achievement awards: evidence from a school-centered Program in Peru: Evidence from a non-experimental evaluation
randomized trial. The American Economic Review, 99(4), (pp. 1–59). Washington: The World Bank.
1384–1414. Priyambada, A., Suryahadi, A., & Sumarto, S. (2005). What happened
Bandan Pusat Statistik. (2014). Statistik pendapatan. Jakarta: Bandan to child labor in Indonesia during the economic crisis: The
Pusat Statistik. trade-off between school and work. Jakarta: SMERU Research
Bandan Pusat Statistik. (2015). Rata–Rata Pengeluaran per Kapita Institute.
Sebulan Menurut Kelompok Barang (rupiah), 1998–2012. http:// RAND. (2007). IFLS-4 survey description. www.rand.org/labor/FLS/
www.bps.go.id/linkTabelStatis/view/id/965. IFLS/ifls4.html. Accessed 1 June 2015.
Central Board of Statistics(BPS), & ILO-IPEC. (2010). Working Ranjan, P. (1999). An economic analysis of child labor. Economics
children in Indonesia 2009 (BPS Catalo). International Labour Letters, 64(1), 99–105.
Organization: Statistics Indonesia. Rawlings, L. B., & Rubio, G. (2003). Evaluating the impact of
De Janvry, A., Finan, F., Sadoulet, E., & Vakis, R. (2006). Can conditional cash transfer programs: Lessons from Latin America
conditional cash transfer programs serve as safety nets in (Vol. 3119). Washington, DC: World Bank.
keeping children at school and from working when exposed to Tifa, A. (2011). Education Ministry targets reduction in drop-out rate.
shocks? Journal of Development Economics, 79(2), 349–373. The Jakarta post.
De Janvry, A., & Sadoulet, E. (2004). Conditional cash transfer UNICEF. (2015). Definition of child labor. http://www.unicef.org/
programs: Are they really magic bullets? ARE Update, 7(6), infobycountry/stats_popup9.html.
9–11. World Bank. (2012). PKH conditional cash transfer. In Social
Dearden, L., Emmerson, C., Frayne, C., & Meghir, C. (2009). assistance program and public expenditure review 6. World
Conditional cash transfers and school dropout rates. Journal of Bank Office, Jakarta.
Human Resources, 44(4), 827–857.

123

You might also like